Farm/non-farm linkages in smallholder agriculture - Student Positive ...

Farm/non-farm linkages in smallholder agriculture - Student Positive ... Farm/non-farm linkages in smallholder agriculture - Student Positive ...

positive.awards.be
from positive.awards.be More from this publisher
16.05.2015 Views

Katholieke Universiteit Leuven Faculteit Bio-ingenieurswetenschappen Farm/non-farm linkages in smallholder agriculture: Evidence from Tigray, Northern Ethiopia (De link tussen landbouwbedrijf en niet-landbouwbedrijf gerelateerde activiteiten in kleinschalige landbouw: bewijs uit Tigray, Noord-Ethiopië) Promotor: Prof. Erik Mathijs Copromotor: Prof. Miet Maertens Departement Aard- en Omgevingswetenschappen Afdeling Landbouw- en Voedseleconomie Masterproef voorgedragen tot het behalen van het diploma van Master in de bio-ingenieurswetenschappen: land- en bosbeheer Vandercasteelen Joachim Juli 2011

Katholieke Universiteit Leuven<br />

Faculteit Bio-<strong>in</strong>genieurswetenschappen<br />

<strong>Farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> <strong>smallholder</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong>:<br />

Evidence from Tigray, Northern Ethiopia<br />

(De l<strong>in</strong>k tussen landbouwbedrijf en niet-landbouwbedrijf gerelateerde activiteiten <strong>in</strong><br />

kle<strong>in</strong>schalige landbouw: bewijs uit Tigray, Noord-Ethiopië)<br />

Promotor: Prof. Erik Mathijs<br />

Copromotor: Prof. Miet Maertens<br />

Departement Aard- en Omgev<strong>in</strong>gswetenschappen<br />

Afdel<strong>in</strong>g Landbouw- en Voedseleconomie<br />

Masterproef voorgedragen<br />

tot het behalen van het diploma van<br />

Master <strong>in</strong> de bio-<strong>in</strong>genieurswetenschappen:<br />

land- en bosbeheer<br />

Vandercasteelen Joachim<br />

Juli 2011


“Dit proefschrift is een examendocument dat na de verdedig<strong>in</strong>g niet meer werd<br />

gecorrigeerd voor eventueel vastgestelde fouten. In publicaties mag naar dit proefwerk<br />

verwezen worden mits schriftelijke toelat<strong>in</strong>g van de promotor, vermeld op de<br />

titelpag<strong>in</strong>a.”


Acknowledgements<br />

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS<br />

I would like to put a note of thanks to all the people who helped me with realiz<strong>in</strong>g my<br />

master thesis. First of all, I would like to thank all the people <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> my Ethiopian<br />

research. I would like to express my gratitude to the VLIR (Vlaamse Interuniversitaire<br />

Raad) for award<strong>in</strong>g me a travel grant, the MU-IUC (Mekelle University – Institutional<br />

University Cooperation) for provid<strong>in</strong>g me with an office at the University of Economics &<br />

Bus<strong>in</strong>ess and the Afdel<strong>in</strong>g Landbouw- en Voedseleconomie for giv<strong>in</strong>g me the<br />

opportunity to do research <strong>in</strong> a develop<strong>in</strong>g country. Special message of thanks to<br />

professors Erik Mathijs and Miet Maertens for guid<strong>in</strong>g, support<strong>in</strong>g and assist<strong>in</strong>g me<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g my research and writ<strong>in</strong>g this thesis process.<br />

This study wouldn‟t be possible without the help and supervision of Kidane. He<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduced me to the research area, methodology and the country. Further, I owe many<br />

thanks to all the other supervisors, Alemtsehay, Abebe and Berhanu because they<br />

helped me to make my stay <strong>in</strong> Mekelle as nice as possible and <strong>in</strong>troduced me to the<br />

<strong>in</strong>credible Ethiopian food. I would also like to thank Daan, who helped me with<br />

statistical issues and treated me with a lot of coffees. Also a big thank you to the<br />

extension agents Mebratu en Tesfai for assist<strong>in</strong>g me dur<strong>in</strong>g the field trips. Although we<br />

have spent only a short time together, they have become real friends.<br />

I‟m also very thankful for all the people that lived with us <strong>in</strong> Mekelle. Thanks to all the<br />

faranji‟s that stayed <strong>in</strong> our house, Lutgart and Daan and his wife Anita. Next to this, I<br />

want to thank all the Ethiopians I have met at university and beyond: the drivers of the<br />

VLIR, Kidanemariam Hailu, Jemael, Aklilu and Temesgen. Thanks for your help,<br />

k<strong>in</strong>dness and laughter. Special gratitude to Tsegay, my dear friend <strong>in</strong> Mekelle. He<br />

<strong>in</strong>troduced me to Mekelle and the Ethiopian culture and he taught me so many th<strong>in</strong>gs.<br />

He made my stay <strong>in</strong> Mekelle unforgettable and he will always rema<strong>in</strong> a special friend of<br />

m<strong>in</strong>e.<br />

Last but not least, I would like to express my gratitude to all the people around me.<br />

Especially my parents and sister, without them it wouldn‟t be possible for me to come<br />

this far. Thank you for your support and the opportunities you gave me. I also like to<br />

thank my girlfriend Hanne, who has always been there for me. Also thanks to my close<br />

friends who made it possible for me to relax after work. F<strong>in</strong>ally, I want to thank my<br />

roommates Sebastian, Mattias, Jeroen and Jan for creat<strong>in</strong>g a nice work<strong>in</strong>g atmosphere<br />

at home.<br />

i


Abstract<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

The rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment sector has become an important component of the<br />

rural economy <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. The (historical) dom<strong>in</strong>ance of the agricultural<br />

sector raises questions how the two sectors are <strong>in</strong>ter-l<strong>in</strong>ked <strong>in</strong> a synergistic rural<br />

development approach. Literature has identified several mechanisms of <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. This dissertation focuses on the complementary <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> between<br />

<strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities as suggested <strong>in</strong> the recent literature. Investment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

imply that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is used by <strong>farm</strong> households as an additional <strong>in</strong>come source<br />

to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>farm</strong> activities. They occur when these households face credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts,<br />

which hamper their <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. The ultimate objective of the study is to exam<strong>in</strong>e<br />

whether households that participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities spend more money on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and expenditures. We differentiated the impact for wage and selfemployment<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use and the different types of <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments. We used cross-sectional data from a household survey conducted <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Tigray region of Ethiopia <strong>in</strong> 2009. An <strong>in</strong>strumental variable regression was used <strong>in</strong> order<br />

to overcome the endogeneity problem caused by omitted variable bias.<br />

The <strong>in</strong>strumental variable estimation results showed that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is significant<br />

and positively related with <strong>farm</strong> expenditures and <strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>in</strong> particular with<br />

livestock and equipment <strong>in</strong>vestments. We derived similar f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs when we estimated<br />

the relationship separately for wage <strong>in</strong>come; while self-employment activities did not<br />

have a significant impact on agricultural activities. Hence, our results supported the<br />

hypothesis that access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come has alleviated <strong>farm</strong>ers‟ credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

However, access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> did not <strong>in</strong>crease the <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use because of<br />

unfavorable local conditions. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the estimation of the level of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

showed that the family size (both dependent and labor forces) and low agricultural<br />

wealth (especially of low livestock assets) are major determ<strong>in</strong>ants, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

households with sufficient labor supply and poor resources are pushed <strong>in</strong>to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. The results did not provide exclusive evidence that entry barriers are present<br />

<strong>in</strong> Tigray. This might <strong>in</strong>dicate the low level of skill and capital requirement to participate<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Hence, a virtuous circle could possibly exist, <strong>in</strong> which access to<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> expenditure and hence modernize agricultural<br />

production. This would suggest that <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> availability and access of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities will have a positive impact on <strong>farm</strong> activities. These f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs support policies<br />

<strong>in</strong> rural parts of Ethiopia that effectively target less endowed and marg<strong>in</strong>al <strong>farm</strong><br />

households.<br />

ii


Nederlandstalige Samenvatt<strong>in</strong>g<br />

NEDERLANDSTALIGE SAMENVATTING<br />

De landelijke niet-agrarische sector is uitgegroeid tot een belangrijk onderdeel van de<br />

plattelandseconomie <strong>in</strong> ontwikkel<strong>in</strong>gslanden. De dom<strong>in</strong>antie van landbouw doet vragen<br />

rijzen hoe de twee sectoren verbonden zijn. De literatuur identificeert een aantal<br />

mechanismen van <strong>agriculture</strong>le/niet-<strong>agriculture</strong>le verbanden. Deze studie richt zich op<br />

complementaire <strong>in</strong>vester<strong>in</strong>gsverbanden, die impliceren dat niet-agrarisch <strong>in</strong>komen<br />

gebruikt wordt als extra bron van <strong>in</strong>komsten om agrarische activiteiten te f<strong>in</strong>ancieren.<br />

Ze komen voor wanneer huishoudens tegen kredietbeperk<strong>in</strong>gen aanlopen, die hen<br />

belemmeren om te <strong>in</strong>vesteren <strong>in</strong> landbouw. Het uite<strong>in</strong>delijke doel van deze studie is om<br />

te onderzoeken of huishoudens die actief zijn <strong>in</strong> niet-agrarische activiteiten meer geld<br />

<strong>in</strong>vesteren <strong>in</strong> hun boerderij. We onderscheidden de effecten voor het loon en<br />

zelfstandige niet-agrarische <strong>in</strong>komsten, landbouw<strong>in</strong>put gebruik en de verschillende<br />

soorten <strong>in</strong>vester<strong>in</strong>gen. We maakten gebruik van cross-section gegevens uit een<br />

onderzoek onder huishoudens <strong>in</strong> 2009 uitgevoerd <strong>in</strong> de Tigray regio van Ethiopië. Een<br />

<strong>in</strong>strumentele variabele regressie werd gebruikt om het endogeniteit probleem,<br />

veroorzaakt door ongemerkte heterogeniteit, te overw<strong>in</strong>nen.<br />

De resultaten van deze schatt<strong>in</strong>g toonden aan dat niet-agrarisch <strong>in</strong>komen significant en<br />

positief gerelateerd is met landbouw uitgaven, en <strong>in</strong> het bijzonder met <strong>in</strong>vester<strong>in</strong>gen <strong>in</strong><br />

vee en uitrust<strong>in</strong>g. We bekwamen gelijkaardige bev<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gen wanneer we deze relatie<br />

afzonderlijk schatten voor <strong>in</strong>komen uit loon, terwijl zelfstandige activiteiten geen<br />

significante <strong>in</strong>vloed hebben op agrarische activiteiten. Onze resultaten ondersteunden<br />

de hypothese dat de toegang tot niet-agrarisch <strong>in</strong>komen de kredietbeperk<strong>in</strong>gen van<br />

boeren versoepelt. Dit <strong>in</strong>komen verhoogde het gebruik van landbouw<strong>in</strong>put echter niet<br />

omwille van plaatselijke ongunstige omstandigheden. Uit de schatt<strong>in</strong>g van het niveau<br />

van niet-agrarisch <strong>in</strong>komen bleek ten slotte dat de gez<strong>in</strong>sgrootte en beperkt agrarische<br />

rijkdom belangrijke determ<strong>in</strong>anten zijn, waaruit volgt dat huishoudens met arbeid<br />

overschot en we<strong>in</strong>ig middelen „geduwd‟ worden <strong>in</strong> niet-agrarische activiteiten. De<br />

resultaten boden geen exclusief bewijs dat toetred<strong>in</strong>gsdrempels aanwezig waren <strong>in</strong><br />

Tigray. Niet agrarische activiteiten vereisen dus slechts we<strong>in</strong>ig kennis of kapitaal.<br />

Bijgevolg is het mogelijk dat een deugdzame cirkel bestaat waar<strong>in</strong> de toegang tot nietagrarisch<br />

<strong>in</strong>komen de <strong>in</strong>vester<strong>in</strong>gen (en dus ook de moderniser<strong>in</strong>g) <strong>in</strong> de<br />

landbouwproductie doet stijgen. Een stijg<strong>in</strong>g van de beschikbaarheid van en toegang<br />

tot niet-agrarische activiteiten zal dus een positieve <strong>in</strong>vloed hebben op de landbouw<br />

activiteiten. Deze bev<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gen ondersteunen het plattelandsbeleid <strong>in</strong> Ethiopië om<br />

m<strong>in</strong>derbedeelde en marg<strong>in</strong>ale boerderij huishoudens effectief te bereiken.<br />

ii


List of abbreviations and symbols<br />

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS AND SYMBOLS<br />

2SLS<br />

BoANRD<br />

CSA<br />

ETB<br />

IV<br />

REST<br />

RNFE<br />

TDA<br />

masl<br />

MU-IUC<br />

OLS<br />

VLIR<br />

: Two Stage Least Squares<br />

: Bureau of Agriculture and Natural Resource Development<br />

: Central Statistical Agency of Ethiopia<br />

: Ethiopian birr<br />

: Instrumental Variables<br />

: Relief Society of Tigray<br />

: Rural Non-<strong>Farm</strong> Employment<br />

: Tigray Development Agency<br />

: meters above sea level<br />

: Mekelle University – Institutional University Cooperation<br />

: Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares<br />

: Vlaamse Interuniversitaire Raad<br />

iii


List of tables<br />

LIST OF TABLES<br />

Table 4.1: Households‟ total <strong>farm</strong> expenditures, <strong>in</strong>put use and <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> ETB .. 37<br />

Table 4.2: Households' <strong>in</strong>come composition <strong>in</strong> ETB .............................................. 40<br />

Table 4.3: The nature of wage and self-employment jobs ..................................... 42<br />

Table 4.4: Wage employment requirements and duration (<strong>in</strong> percentages) ............. 43<br />

Table 4.5: Attitude towards additional <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment ................................ 44<br />

Table 4.6: Comparison of households with and without access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come .. 45<br />

Table 4.7: Summary statistics of <strong>in</strong>dividual and household characteristics ............... 47<br />

Table 4.8: Summery statistics of the <strong>in</strong>struments used <strong>in</strong> the 2SLS ........................ 48<br />

Table 4.9: First stage OLS regression results ....................................................... 51<br />

Table 4.10: OLS and 2SLS estimations results of total <strong>farm</strong> expenditures ................. 56<br />

Table 4.11: OLS and 2SLS estimations results of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments ......................... 58<br />

Table 4.12: IV estimation results of <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> water&land, livestock,<br />

equipment and build<strong>in</strong>g ..................................................................... 60<br />

Table 4.13: OLS and 2SLS estimations results of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use ............................. 61<br />

Table 4.14: OLS and 2SLS estimations results of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with wage<br />

<strong>in</strong>come ............................................................................................ 63<br />

Table 4.15: OLS and 2SLS estimates results of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with bus<strong>in</strong>ess<br />

<strong>in</strong>come ............................................................................................ 64<br />

Table 4.16: Summary of the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and control variables .......... 69<br />

iv


List of figures<br />

LIST OF FIGURES<br />

Figure 3.1: Map of Ethiopia (small) and Tigray Regional state ................................. 25<br />

Figure 3.2: Research area .................................................................................. 26<br />

v


Table of Contents<br />

TABLE OF CONTENTS<br />

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS ........................................................................................ I<br />

ABSTRACT ......................................................................................................... II<br />

NEDERLANDSTALIGE SAMENVATTING ............................................................... II<br />

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS AND SYMBOLS ......................................................... III<br />

LIST OF TABLES ................................................................................................ IV<br />

LIST OF FIGURES ............................................................................................... V<br />

TABLE OF CONTENTS ......................................................................................... VI<br />

1 INTRODUCTION .......................................................................................... 1<br />

1.1 Background ............................................................................................ 1<br />

1.2 Problem statement ................................................................................. 2<br />

1.3 Research questions and hypothesis ........................................................ 4<br />

1.4 Significance of the study ........................................................................ 4<br />

2 LITERATURE REVIEW ................................................................................. 6<br />

2.1 <strong>Farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> ........................................................................ 6<br />

2.1.1 Def<strong>in</strong>itions ..................................................................................... 6<br />

2.1.2 Evidence ....................................................................................... 7<br />

2.2 The impact of <strong>farm</strong> activities on the RNFE sector ................................... 8<br />

2.3 The impact of the RNFE sector on <strong>farm</strong> activities ................................... 9<br />

2.3.1 Underestimation of the RNFE sector ................................................ 10<br />

2.3.2 Importance of the RNFE sector ....................................................... 11<br />

2.3.3 Participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities .................................................. 13<br />

2.3.4 The nature of the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities ................................ 15<br />

2.3.4.1 Compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> ........................................................................... 16<br />

2.3.4.2 Complementary <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> .................................................................... 17<br />

2.4 Investment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> ............................................................................. 19<br />

2.4.1 Def<strong>in</strong>ition..................................................................................... 19<br />

2.4.2 Liquidity and credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts ....................................................... 19<br />

2.4.3 Evidence ..................................................................................... 21<br />

vi


Table of Contents<br />

2.5 Virtuous circle ...................................................................................... 23<br />

3 METHODOLOGY ........................................................................................ 25<br />

3.1 Study and survey area .......................................................................... 25<br />

3.2 Survey design ....................................................................................... 28<br />

3.3 Data analysis ........................................................................................ 29<br />

3.3.1 Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares estimation ................................................. 30<br />

3.3.2 Omitted variable bias .................................................................... 31<br />

3.3.3 Two Stage Least Squares estimation ............................................... 32<br />

3.3.4 Instrumental Variables .................................................................. 34<br />

4 RESULTS AND DISCUSSION ...................................................................... 37<br />

4.1 Descriptive statistics ............................................................................ 37<br />

4.1.1 <strong>Farm</strong> expenditure, <strong>in</strong>put use and <strong>in</strong>vestments .................................. 37<br />

4.1.2 <strong>Farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities ......................................................... 39<br />

4.1.3 Households with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come vs. households without <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come ........................................................................................ 44<br />

4.1.4 Control and <strong>in</strong>strumental variables.................................................. 46<br />

4.2 Multivariate analysis ............................................................................ 49<br />

4.2.1 First Stage Results ........................................................................ 50<br />

4.2.2 Second Stage Results .................................................................... 54<br />

4.2.2.1 The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures ............................ 55<br />

4.2.2.2 The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on durables <strong>in</strong>vestments ....................... 57<br />

4.2.2.3 The effect on different types of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments .................................. 59<br />

4.2.2.4 The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts ..................................... 60<br />

4.2.2.5 The effect of different types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come ................................... 62<br />

4.2.3 Discussion ................................................................................... 64<br />

4.2.3.1 The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come ........................................................... 64<br />

4.2.3.2 The effect of control variables ............................................................. 68<br />

5 CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS ................................................ 71<br />

5.1 Conclusion ............................................................................................ 71<br />

5.2 Policy Recommendations ...................................................................... 73<br />

REFERENCES .................................................................................................... 75<br />

APPENDIX 1 ..................................................................................................... 81<br />

APPENDIX 2 ..................................................................................................... 83<br />

vii


Chapter 1: Introduction<br />

1 INTRODUCTION<br />

1.1 Background<br />

Agriculture has historically been dom<strong>in</strong>at<strong>in</strong>g the rural economy of Ethiopia. The lead<strong>in</strong>g<br />

role of the agricultural sector was reflected <strong>in</strong> earlier government policies as<br />

development programs and <strong>in</strong>terventions focused ma<strong>in</strong>ly on the agricultural sector. As<br />

observed <strong>in</strong> other develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, most efforts of the local government to develop<br />

rural growth, corresponded with policies to enhance <strong>farm</strong> productivity (Escobal, 2001)<br />

or <strong>in</strong>crease employment <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> (Woldenhanna, 2000) and they thereby<br />

neglected the importance of the rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector (Woldenhanna, 2002; Adams,<br />

2002). Despite the importance of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> the Ethiopian economy, the country has<br />

been fac<strong>in</strong>g structural food <strong>in</strong>security s<strong>in</strong>ce the early 1970s (Belay and Abebaw, 2004;<br />

Shimelis and Bogale, 2007). This makes it doubtful whether the agricultural sector is<br />

capable to support rural development on its own and questions the lead<strong>in</strong>g role of<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> overall economic processes. Two major factors enhanced this recognition,<br />

mak<strong>in</strong>g the traditional view of <strong>agriculture</strong> be<strong>in</strong>g the sole eng<strong>in</strong>e of rural growth <strong>in</strong> rural<br />

Ethiopia to be superseded.<br />

First, the agricultural productivity <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa is the lowest <strong>in</strong> de world (Ehui<br />

and Pender, 2005). Agriculture is not able to provide sufficient food for its human<br />

population because of the stagnat<strong>in</strong>g, subsistence-oriented, small-scaled agricultural<br />

sector; the low utilization of modern <strong>in</strong>puts; crucial dependence on ra<strong>in</strong>fall, poor<br />

resources endowment; poor policy environment and poor public <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

(Woldenhanna, 2002; Belay and Abebaw, 2004; Ehui and Pender, 2005; Pender et al.,<br />

2005). Despite the importance of <strong>agriculture</strong>, Ethiopia has been fac<strong>in</strong>g structural food<br />

<strong>in</strong>security s<strong>in</strong>ce the early 1970s (Belay & Abebaw 2004, Shimelis & Bogale 2007).<br />

Moreover, the OECD (2010) believes that Ethiopia will cont<strong>in</strong>ue to face food <strong>in</strong>security.<br />

Population pressure has resulted <strong>in</strong> land fragmentation, decreased <strong>farm</strong> size and<br />

environmental degradation. It is assumed that further labor absorption <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

will be difficult due to these natural and human <strong>in</strong>duced problems (Woldenhanna, 2002;<br />

Jayne et al., 2003). This will only be possible through the <strong>in</strong>tensification of agricultural<br />

production and irrigation use, which is unlikely <strong>in</strong> the short term (Woldenhanna, 2002).<br />

The <strong>in</strong>itial policy of the Ethiopian government to promote access to credit, high yield<strong>in</strong>g<br />

crop varieties and fertilizer to achieve productivity <strong>in</strong>crease has not been successful <strong>in</strong><br />

the majority of Ethiopia (Holden et al., 2004; Ashworth, 2005).<br />

1


Chapter 1: Introduction<br />

Second, the rural development literature has po<strong>in</strong>ted out that rural households make<br />

up their livelihood based on complex strategies and not just on agricultural production<br />

(Ellis, 1998; Woldenhanna, 2000; Barrett et al., 2001; Adams, 2002; Reardon et al.,<br />

2006; Shimelis and Bogale, 2007; Kilic et al., 2009). It is recognized that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come sources are becom<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly important for rural households <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g<br />

countries (Islam, 1997; Reardon et al., 1998; Escobal, 2001; Lanjouw et al., 2001).<br />

The livelihood of rural households is the result of the <strong>in</strong>teraction between complex<br />

strategies and multiple <strong>in</strong>come generat<strong>in</strong>g activities (Kilic et al., 2009). The livelihood<br />

concept should therefore be adopted <strong>in</strong> development programs (Islam, 1997;<br />

Farr<strong>in</strong>gton et al., 2000). Although <strong>agriculture</strong> rema<strong>in</strong>s the most important sector, the<br />

study of diversification behavior offers <strong>in</strong>sights necessary for broader development<br />

strategies (Barrett et al., 2001). The recognition of the importance of the rural <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

sector <strong>in</strong> the rural development process has promoted Rural Non-<strong>Farm</strong><br />

Employment (RNFE) as a policy and ga<strong>in</strong>ed the support from a broad range of<br />

development agencies. This trend occurs especially <strong>in</strong> countries like Ethiopia, which<br />

suffer from consumption and <strong>in</strong>come shocks (Block and Webb, 2001).<br />

These considerations make it clear that policy makers are obligated to look for wider,<br />

alternative development strategies, <strong>in</strong> order to successfully tackle poverty and food<br />

<strong>in</strong>security <strong>in</strong> the East African highlands (Block and Webb, 2001; Jayne et al., 2003;<br />

Holden et al., 2004). Employ<strong>in</strong>g rural people <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities has several<br />

advantages: it offers an alternative remunerative allocation of resources, provides a<br />

socially cost-effective expansion of the economy, dim<strong>in</strong>ishes land pressure and<br />

degradation and reduces rural outmigration. Moreover, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come provides<br />

<strong>farm</strong>ers additional <strong>in</strong>come and is less risky and fluctuat<strong>in</strong>g (Islam, 1997; Lanjouw and<br />

Lanjouw, 2001; Ruben and van den Berg, 2001; Woldenhanna, 2002). Development<br />

policies should therefore focus on an alternative synergistic approach <strong>in</strong> which<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> is comb<strong>in</strong>ed with other sources of employment and the different sectors<br />

receive equal emphasis. The role of RNFE <strong>in</strong> overall rural development gave researchers<br />

<strong>in</strong>centives to study the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector and its components (Islam, 1997).<br />

1.2 Problem statement<br />

The awareness of the importance of the RNFE sector and the need for a synergistic<br />

development approach produces an economy where both the agricultural and <strong>non</strong>agricultural<br />

sector are emphasized. In such economies, the <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> between these two<br />

sectors become important. While the impact of <strong>agriculture</strong> on RNFE has been a major<br />

2


Chapter 1: Introduction<br />

object of study, the study of the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities on <strong>agriculture</strong> is only<br />

recent. The impact of RNFE on <strong>farm</strong> activities is, however, not clear a priori: RNFE<br />

could be complementary or compet<strong>in</strong>g with agricultural production. The RNFE literature<br />

provides evidence of both effects of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>agriculture</strong>, mak<strong>in</strong>g the overall<br />

impact of RNFE not ambiguously def<strong>in</strong>ed. Complementarity implies that RNFE provides<br />

<strong>non</strong>-labor variable <strong>in</strong>puts, credit or capital to <strong>farm</strong>ers which can be used to <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

agricultural productivity, consumption or <strong>in</strong>tensification. Compet<strong>in</strong>g implies that RNFE<br />

withdrawals resources from the <strong>farm</strong> and thus decreases <strong>farm</strong> agricultural productivity.<br />

We therefore want to exam<strong>in</strong>e the direction of the impact of RNFE on agricultural<br />

activities. One particularly important type of complementary l<strong>in</strong>kage are <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. These <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> imply that <strong>in</strong>come gathered from RNFE is used to f<strong>in</strong>ance<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> durables or <strong>in</strong>put use. By this, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is spent on their<br />

<strong>farm</strong>. Investment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are likely to occur <strong>in</strong> the presence of liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

Households lack credit or liquidity to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> their <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g activities, and therefore<br />

look for other sources of credit. Households are will<strong>in</strong>g to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities, as the latter result <strong>in</strong> additional cash which can be re<strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> the <strong>farm</strong>.<br />

The objective of this study is to <strong>in</strong>vestigate whether positive <strong>in</strong>vestment effects<br />

outweigh the loss <strong>in</strong> family <strong>farm</strong> labor availability. This is done by regress<strong>in</strong>g <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments on <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and other household and <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g a substantial and positive impact of the RNFE on the purchased <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts and<br />

capital <strong>in</strong>vestments will have important implications. RNFE could be a potentially<br />

important determ<strong>in</strong>ant of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment when <strong>farm</strong> households face credit market<br />

failures. Davies et al. (2009) hypothesize the existence of a virtuous circle. Promot<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the RNFE, through access to microcredit or tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, enhances the access to the RNFE<br />

and facilities the vanquish of the associated entry restrictions. Households could<br />

provide themselves with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>in</strong>crease their total budget. <strong>Farm</strong>ers are<br />

able to modernize, commercialize or <strong>in</strong>tensify agricultural production via <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. It is assumed that this will either <strong>in</strong>crease the demand for agricultural wage<br />

labor or create a surplus of capital to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> education, migration and higher skilled<br />

RNFE. This will <strong>in</strong> turn promote the RNFE sector. By this, a circle of self-re<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

mechanisms is set up. If the existence of such a virtuous circle is likely to occur,<br />

potential opportunities for policymakers and development agents will be created.<br />

3


Chapter 1: Introduction<br />

1.3 Research questions and hypothesis<br />

The possible existence of such a virtuous circle poses some <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g research<br />

questions. It hypothesizes that households who participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities will<br />

use the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> their <strong>farm</strong>. As the <strong>farm</strong> becomes<br />

modernized, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> wage labor demand will be <strong>in</strong>creased. In this way, a selfre<strong>in</strong>forc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

effect will be launched. To <strong>in</strong>dicate whether such virtuous circle is realistic to<br />

occur, this dissertation will <strong>in</strong>vestigate the <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> between the RNFE and agricultural<br />

sector. More specific, we <strong>in</strong>vestigate whether <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> and <strong>farm</strong> activities are<br />

complementary or not. We therefore look at the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and expenditures.<br />

We hypothesize that households use <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come as an additional capital source to<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>farm</strong> activities. We thus assume a positive relation between <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. This favorable relation is suggested to be driven by credit<br />

restra<strong>in</strong>ts. We therefore suppose that households are ma<strong>in</strong>ly pushed <strong>in</strong>to RNFE because<br />

they face credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts, and use <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come to overcome these restrictions.<br />

We will also dist<strong>in</strong>guish different types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>farm</strong> expenditures. By<br />

analyz<strong>in</strong>g the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures, not only the impact of<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities on agricultural production will be evaluated, but also the <strong>in</strong>fluence of<br />

human capital, household characteristics and regional factors will be exam<strong>in</strong>ed.<br />

However, if such virtuous circle exists, the existence of factors that constra<strong>in</strong> the<br />

participation <strong>in</strong> RNFE will h<strong>in</strong>der the modernization or diversification of <strong>farm</strong><br />

households. Several studies have <strong>in</strong>vestigated the existence of such „entry barriers‟ by<br />

study<strong>in</strong>g the concentration <strong>in</strong> RNFE over households (Dercon and Krishnan, 1996;<br />

Dercon, 1998; Barrett et al., 2001; Davies et al. 2002). These studies <strong>in</strong>dicate the<br />

existence of entry barriers to participate <strong>in</strong> the more lucrative RNFE. For example,<br />

Woldenhanna and Oskam (2001) f<strong>in</strong>d entry barriers <strong>in</strong> the Tigray region of Ethiopia.<br />

This study will therefore also pay attention to the determ<strong>in</strong>ants of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come to<br />

exam<strong>in</strong>e exactly which factors h<strong>in</strong>der or enhance participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

1.4 Significance of the study<br />

Our research focuses on Ethiopia, a poor country <strong>in</strong> the Horn of Africa. The <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

between the agricultural and RNFE sector are believed to be very important <strong>in</strong><br />

develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. In the African context, Davies et al. (2002) conclude that forward<br />

4


Chapter 1: Introduction<br />

and backward production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are generally limited because of low agricultural<br />

<strong>in</strong>puts. Instead, they hypothesize that agricultural growth affects the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector<br />

ma<strong>in</strong>ly through expenditure <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> the form of both consumption and <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. This f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is consistent with the results of Woldenhanna (2002) <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia<br />

and Hazell and Hojjati (1995) <strong>in</strong> Zambia. Hence, this study will add to the empirical<br />

strand of literature on complementary <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries.<br />

Our results will provide evidence of the existence of <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> between<br />

agricultural activities and RNFE. By this, the study will contribute to a better<br />

understand<strong>in</strong>g of the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on agricultural production and the role<br />

of the RNFE <strong>in</strong> the rural development process. If our results <strong>in</strong>dicate that the RNFE is<br />

complementary to <strong>farm</strong> activities and is used to overcome credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts, promot<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the RNFE will be important, if not necessary, to modernize <strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong> rural areas<br />

of develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. As a result, some policy recommendations to promote the<br />

access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and hence <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments can be formulated.<br />

Recent literature has focused on the RNFE sector and studied its role <strong>in</strong> rural<br />

development. We are therefore <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> the importance of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come (and<br />

its different sources) <strong>in</strong> rural parts of Ethiopia. We will study the nature of the RNFE<br />

and which factors may be important <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the level of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

Simple descriptive statistics will <strong>in</strong>dicate the significance of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong> rural<br />

areas and will contribute to literature focus<strong>in</strong>g on the importance the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector.<br />

Next to this, we will try to dist<strong>in</strong>guish between the different types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. The access, nature and requirements of the various types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities are different and they hence have a different effect on <strong>farm</strong> agricultural<br />

activities. Most studies of <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> do not differentiate between wage<br />

and self-employment activities (except for, among others, Woldenhanna and Oskam,<br />

2001; Maertens, 2009).<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, our study is well-founded by a robust empirical model. This is done for two<br />

reasons. First, the deviation of the normality assumption of the error term must be<br />

dealt with. Second, it is recognized that, for several reasons, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities are<br />

endogenously related with agricultural production and simple regressions will be<br />

therefore biased. An advanced empirical model will be used to solve the possible<br />

endogenous effects of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. This methodology might serve as an example<br />

for other empirical research that deals with the endogeneity problem.<br />

5


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

2 LITERATURE REVIEW<br />

2.1 <strong>Farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

2.1.1 Def<strong>in</strong>itions<br />

The relationship between the <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector is mostly described by us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the concept of <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> (Reardon et al., 1998). L<strong>in</strong>kages are f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

transactions between the two sectors over time. A dist<strong>in</strong>ction between production and<br />

expenditure <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> is made. Production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> can be further divided <strong>in</strong>to upwards<br />

and downwards production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Upward production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are found <strong>in</strong> the <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

sector when agricultural output is used as <strong>in</strong>put. Raw agricultural outputs are<br />

processed and distributed by <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> enterprises (Woldenhanna, 2000). Growth <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g stimulates agricultural productivity and hence the capacity to supply <strong>in</strong>puts and<br />

services to the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector. Downward production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> refer to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities that provide <strong>in</strong>puts to agricultural production, such as agrochemicals, water<br />

pumps or fertilizers. The <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector is encouraged to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> supply capacity of<br />

agroprocess<strong>in</strong>g and distribution services (Reardon et al., 1998; Davies et al., 2002).<br />

The characteristics of the local <strong>agriculture</strong> will determ<strong>in</strong>e whether the production<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> will be upward or downward. For example, <strong>farm</strong> size determ<strong>in</strong>es the<br />

profitability of markets for tractors (Reardon et al., 1998).<br />

Expenditure <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> occur when households f<strong>in</strong>ance spend<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> one sector by the<br />

money earned from another sector. <strong>Farm</strong>ers can for example purchase <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

products with <strong>in</strong>come generated from <strong>farm</strong> activities. On the contrary, people that have<br />

access to RNFE buy food and other agricultural output with the <strong>in</strong>come derived from<br />

that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activity. When these expenditures are related to household consumption,<br />

consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> establish. <strong>Farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases the demand of basic goods and<br />

services and results <strong>in</strong> diversification of consumption (Woldenhanna, 2000). Investment<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong>clude expenditures used to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> or <strong>farm</strong> activities, which are<br />

ma<strong>in</strong>ly important with<strong>in</strong> households. Returns from <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities can be used to<br />

make <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities and thereby enhance agricultural productivity<br />

(Davies et al., 2002). The profitability of these expenditure <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> depends on the<br />

level and distribution of the <strong>in</strong>come. Poor households will spend more on local goods<br />

and services <strong>in</strong> the RNFE, while richer households are more likely to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> goods<br />

from the modern and urban manufactur<strong>in</strong>g sectors or <strong>in</strong> imports.<br />

6


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

The structure of the agricultural sector and the type of growth determ<strong>in</strong>es the type of<br />

l<strong>in</strong>kage that will occur. Davies et al. (2002) illustrates this with several examples. If<br />

significant external <strong>in</strong>puts are needed for agricultural production, it is expected that<br />

backward production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> will occur. Agricultural output that requires process<strong>in</strong>g<br />

before sell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>duces forward production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. If growth <strong>in</strong> the agricultural sector is<br />

capable of <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g rural <strong>in</strong>come growth, consumption and potential <strong>in</strong>vestments will be<br />

enhanced by expenditure <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>.<br />

2.1.2 Evidence<br />

There exists numerous literature that reviews the <strong>in</strong>ter-sectoral <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> rural areas.<br />

Refer to Islam (1997) and Lanjouw and Lanjouw (2001), who reviewes the earlier work<br />

done on <strong>in</strong>ter-sectoral <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Cross-sectional <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> seem to be crucial for the<br />

<strong>in</strong>itial development of the RNFE. Studies proof that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities positively<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluence the <strong>farm</strong> activities and vice versa ma<strong>in</strong>ly through production and consumption<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Islam (1997) states that growth <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come stimulates the consumption<br />

of goods and <strong>in</strong>puts, while agricultural raw material is processed <strong>in</strong> the rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

sector. The growth pattern <strong>in</strong> agricultural <strong>in</strong>come and the technology used <strong>in</strong> production<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>es the strength of the production and consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Andreosso-<br />

O‟Callaghan and Yue (2004) did a comparative analysis of the traditional and modern<br />

methods <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>kage analysis <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a between 1987 and 1997. They conclude that<br />

forward and backward <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> have generally <strong>in</strong>creased, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>tersectoral<br />

dependency. Blunch and Verner (2006) observe two-way spillover effects<br />

between <strong>in</strong>dustrial and agricultural growth <strong>in</strong> three African countries, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>terdependence <strong>in</strong> sectoral growth.<br />

Davies et al. (2002) discuss several case studies of <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Africa<br />

and Lat<strong>in</strong> America where sp<strong>in</strong>-off activities already exist. In low–<strong>in</strong>come countries such<br />

as Ghana, Kenya or Ethiopia, limited local demand and limited <strong>in</strong>vestments oblige for<br />

sp<strong>in</strong>-off activities. In Kenya, contract <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g acts as the primary means of <strong>in</strong>teraction<br />

between <strong>farm</strong>ers and the agro-<strong>in</strong>dustry. This creates an <strong>in</strong>come surplus which can be<br />

spent <strong>in</strong> local markets. In Ghana, substantial forward <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are noticed <strong>in</strong> the low<strong>in</strong>put<br />

cassava sector because process<strong>in</strong>g is necessary and transportation is required.<br />

Other research <strong>in</strong> Africa has been conducted by Hazell and Hojjati (1995), who<br />

exam<strong>in</strong>ed different types of <strong>in</strong>ter-sectoral <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Zambia. First, they observe that<br />

credit <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> might occur s<strong>in</strong>ce agricultural <strong>in</strong>come could be used to f<strong>in</strong>ance and<br />

<strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> easy-entry <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Second, it is concluded that seasonal labor<br />

7


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

shortage affects both <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. The authors suggest the existence<br />

of a shift of labor depend<strong>in</strong>g on the seasonal requirement of the sectors. This effect is<br />

uncerta<strong>in</strong> s<strong>in</strong>ce the opposite is also observed. Third, it is noted that production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

are most pronounced <strong>in</strong> the agricultural growth of small <strong>farm</strong>s. Long-term <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

<strong>in</strong> the <strong>farm</strong> are assumed to create demand <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> to both the <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

sector. F<strong>in</strong>ally, consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are considered to be the most dom<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> Zambia.<br />

In Ethiopia, research on <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> the Tigray region has been done by<br />

Woldenhanna (2002). First, it is observed that production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>, both backward and<br />

forward, are limited because the households‟ purchase of fertilizer and pesticides was<br />

very low. The agricultural sector is unable to support the process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry due to the<br />

fact that households consume most of their own <strong>farm</strong> products. <strong>Farm</strong> households only<br />

sell 15% or less of their production. These limited production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> imply that the<br />

correlation between RNFE and <strong>farm</strong> activities is rather weak. Second, the significant use<br />

of wholesale and retail trades by <strong>farm</strong>ers <strong>in</strong>dicates that consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are more<br />

important than production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. These consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are the strongest<br />

expressed <strong>in</strong> locally produced food. The author also concludes a positive relation<br />

between the demand for consumption goods and agricultural <strong>in</strong>come. Third, it is<br />

suggested that agricultural production has the potential to enhance the demand for<br />

<strong>non</strong>-food goods. The elasticities of local <strong>non</strong>-food expenditures are high, imply<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

when households‟ <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases, their importance <strong>in</strong> the household budget also<br />

rises. However, this effect is only valid <strong>in</strong> the short term, as the elasticities of imported<br />

<strong>non</strong>-food expenditures are even higher. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities absorb labor that<br />

cannot be allocated on agricultural activities. This is suggested by the negative relation<br />

between agricultural output and small enterprises.<br />

2.2 The impact of <strong>farm</strong> activities on the RNFE sector<br />

The previous section shows that the rural development literature attributed attention to<br />

<strong>in</strong>ter-sectoral <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Furthermore, the existence of <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> rural<br />

areas is suggested. Given the historical dom<strong>in</strong>ant role of <strong>agriculture</strong> and the fact that<br />

the majority of the rural population is engaged <strong>in</strong> it, the rural development literature<br />

<strong>in</strong>itially emphasized the foster<strong>in</strong>g role of <strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> the overall economy. It was<br />

believed that the rural sector <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries was entirely driven by <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

and that agricultural growth would stimulate overall economic growth by promot<strong>in</strong>g<br />

other sectors via production and consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> (Islam, 1997; Reardon et al.,<br />

8


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

1998; Woldenhanna, 2000; Escobal, 2001; Adams, 2002). Rural development policies<br />

and programs <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries prioritized the <strong>in</strong>come derived from agricultural<br />

production, while the activities related to the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector received little attention to<br />

date (Reardon et al., 1998; Woldenhanna, 2000; Escobal, 2001). As a consequence, it<br />

was believed that agricultural growth would be the ma<strong>in</strong> stimulus for overall economic<br />

growth by promot<strong>in</strong>g other sectors (Islam, 1996; Lanjouw et al., 2001; Ashworth,<br />

2005). Hill (1982), as cited by Reardon (1997), mentions that until the early 1980s the<br />

widespread view persisted that rural African <strong>farm</strong>ers ma<strong>in</strong>ly undertook <strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

and less <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities, except when they migrated out of the rural areas.<br />

Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Mills, this resulted <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>itial neglect and underestimation of the rural<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector.<br />

In develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, the impact of <strong>agriculture</strong> on RNFE occurs ma<strong>in</strong>ly through both<br />

production and consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> (Haggblade et al., 1989; Islam, 1997; Lanjouw<br />

and Lanjouw, 2001; Blunch and Verner, 2006). Haggblade et al. (1989) provide<br />

evidence suggest<strong>in</strong>g that consumption and production <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> expla<strong>in</strong> the positive<br />

effect of agricultural growth on RNFE and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. They <strong>in</strong>dicate that higher<br />

agricultural <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases households‟ demand multiplier effect across the rest of<br />

the rural economy, especially <strong>in</strong> closed economies. Many develop<strong>in</strong>g countries face<br />

closed economies due to high transaction costs, but this result was more pronounced <strong>in</strong><br />

Asia compared to Africa. Ellis (1998) reviews earlier work done on rural growth <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries and f<strong>in</strong>ds that agricultural growth provided the stimulus for the<br />

growth <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities ma<strong>in</strong>ly due to consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Reardon et al.<br />

(2001) discuss the growth eng<strong>in</strong>es for the development of RNFE and notice the positive<br />

relation between the rise <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> output (and <strong>in</strong>come) and demand for <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

products through consumption <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Ashworth (2005) states that the <strong>in</strong>itial<br />

development programs <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia expected agricultural growth to simulate <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

sector development and RNFE creation as well as overall economic growth. The number<br />

of people directly dependent on <strong>agriculture</strong> for their <strong>in</strong>come and subsistence reduces as<br />

employment <strong>in</strong> the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector is created.<br />

2.3 The impact of the RNFE sector on <strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities on agricultural production has not been a major topic<br />

<strong>in</strong> literature of develop<strong>in</strong>g economies. However, the RNFE literature has <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

paid attention to the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities on agricultural production dur<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

last decades. Moreover, this switch <strong>in</strong> focus of literature is only recent, both because of<br />

9


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

the mastery of the agricultural sector and the historical disregard<strong>in</strong>g and<br />

underestimation of the RNFE sector. Drivers beh<strong>in</strong>d the change <strong>in</strong> focus are the<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g acknowledgement of the significant role and importance of the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

sector <strong>in</strong> rural areas and the stagnation of the agricultural sector (Islam, 1997;<br />

Woldenhanna, 2002). Therefore, the rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector has recently received<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g attention from both analysts and policymakers.<br />

2.3.1 Underestimation of the RNFE sector<br />

Previously, the common view persisted that rural growth <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries is<br />

entirely driven by <strong>agriculture</strong> and that <strong>non</strong>-agricultural activities are not significant.<br />

Davies et al. (2009) and Pfeifer et al. (2009) po<strong>in</strong>t out that previous literature assumed<br />

that <strong>farm</strong> households ma<strong>in</strong>ly rely on <strong>farm</strong> activities to atta<strong>in</strong> their food security and that<br />

the contribution of the RNFE <strong>in</strong> rural development was mostly ignored. Only if the <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities were not able to fulfill the household‟s needs, households‟ members would<br />

work on other <strong>farm</strong>ers‟ land for wage or would be sent out as migrants for remittances.<br />

The bias aga<strong>in</strong>st the rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector has been further enhanced by the fact that<br />

the sector was <strong>in</strong>itially a poorly understood component of the rural economy of<br />

develop<strong>in</strong>g countries and little was known about its role <strong>in</strong> the broader development<br />

process. Further, it was wrongly assumed that the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector was characterized<br />

by low productivity and production of low quality goods; and that it will vanish as a<br />

country develops (Lanjouw and Lanjouw, 2001).<br />

As a consequence, most government policies were did not support the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector,<br />

nor did the governments devote resources to upgrade the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector (Islam,<br />

1997; Lanjouw and Lanjouw, 2001). In Ethiopia, Woldenhanna (2000) confirms that<br />

the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector has been ignored because of the power given to the agricultural<br />

sector. He states that “while substantial resources have been spent on agricultural<br />

research and extension to alleviate food shortage <strong>in</strong> the nation, no research and<br />

extension have been done on the issue of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment versus <strong>farm</strong><br />

employment. Despite this fact, <strong>farm</strong>ers are engaged <strong>in</strong> a variety of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

to diversify their <strong>in</strong>come and to feed themselves dur<strong>in</strong>g crop failures” (Woldenhanna<br />

2000, p. 94).<br />

As a result, the impact of the RNFE on agricultural production and activities has been<br />

mostly ignored. Pfeiffer et al. (2009, p. 139) state that “as rural households become<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities, their on-<strong>farm</strong> production changes. The<br />

10


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

ways <strong>in</strong> which <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities transform agricultural production have not been a<br />

major subject of <strong>in</strong>quiry <strong>in</strong> the development literature”. Also Davies et al. (2009, p.<br />

120) state “that the RNFE impact on <strong>agriculture</strong>, especially on micro level, has received<br />

relative little attention, although the importance of the RNFE has been proven and<br />

attention has been given to <strong>agriculture</strong> as a determ<strong>in</strong>ant of RNFE”. Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and Davis<br />

(2009, p. 177) review the previous literature and f<strong>in</strong>d that “the exist<strong>in</strong>g empirical<br />

literature on household-level <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> between rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g is<br />

limited and <strong>in</strong>conclusive”.<br />

2.3.2 Importance of the RNFE sector<br />

The literature and empirical research of the significance of the RNFE sector has<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased, s<strong>in</strong>ce the late 1980s (Davies et al., 2009). This literature provides evidence<br />

of the importance of the RNFE sector and thereby removes the bias aga<strong>in</strong>st it. In this<br />

way, the significance of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector has been revealed and, to some extent, the<br />

attitude towards the RNFE has changed. A review of this literature can be found <strong>in</strong> Ellis<br />

(1998), Escobal (2001) and Lanjouw and Lanjouw (2001). In developed countries like<br />

the U.S., Fernandez-Cornejo et al. (2007) state that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work has risen steadily<br />

and has become the most important component of <strong>farm</strong> household <strong>in</strong>come, far more<br />

important than <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. However, the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is not that<br />

straightforward <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries (Reardon, 1997). It is assumed that <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities rema<strong>in</strong> important <strong>in</strong> rural households as they provide the ma<strong>in</strong> source of<br />

employment and <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> rural areas of develop<strong>in</strong>g countries (van den Berg and<br />

Kumbi, 2006). For example, Reardon (1997) f<strong>in</strong>ds that there was little known about<br />

why or how much <strong>farm</strong> households engage <strong>in</strong> RNFE, especially <strong>in</strong> Africa. Carswell<br />

(2002) concludes that it is not the importance of the RNFE that is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g, but the<br />

<strong>in</strong>terest and recognition given to it.<br />

Nevertheless, it is a widely observed phenome<strong>non</strong> that the rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector <strong>in</strong><br />

African develop<strong>in</strong>g countries is grow<strong>in</strong>g rapidly (Islam, 1997; Lanjouw et al., 2001;<br />

Reardon et al., 2001; Escobal, 2001). Reardon et al. (1994) are among the firsts to<br />

provide evidence from Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso that show that <strong>in</strong>come from RNFE can be an<br />

important source of household cash. Islam (1997) reviews earlier studies and published<br />

data on the RNFE <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries and states that globally 23% to 50% of total<br />

households‟ <strong>in</strong>come is made up by <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> earn<strong>in</strong>gs. In Lat<strong>in</strong> America, Asia and Africa<br />

respectively 26%, 28% and 14% of the rural labor force is employed <strong>in</strong> the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

sector. Reardon (1997) reviews earlier studies on <strong>in</strong>come diversification, small<br />

11


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

enterprises and <strong>in</strong>ter-sectoral <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan Africa. He notices that local<br />

wage labor earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector were dom<strong>in</strong>ant <strong>in</strong> the majority of the case<br />

studies. The average share of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> total household <strong>in</strong>come for the<br />

different case studies was 45%, rang<strong>in</strong>g from 22% (Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso) to 93% (Namibia).<br />

Reardon et al. (1998) study the nature, importance and determ<strong>in</strong>ants of the RNFE <strong>in</strong><br />

develop<strong>in</strong>g countries based on a review of about 100 household surveys. They show<br />

that the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector accounts for 25% of employment and that it generates 40%<br />

of household <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> rural Lat<strong>in</strong> America. The <strong>in</strong>come shares for the RNFE accounts<br />

for 32% <strong>in</strong> Asia and 42% <strong>in</strong> Africa. Escobal (2001) concludes that <strong>in</strong> rural Peru almost<br />

35% of the labor is allocated to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and 51% of the <strong>in</strong>come comes from<br />

the RNFE. He therefore suggests that the RNFE no longer has a marg<strong>in</strong>al contribution.<br />

Lanjouw and Lanjouw (2001) review conceptual and empirical literature concern<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

RNFE and focus on the experience <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. They made a review of<br />

aggregate data of the RNFE based on than 60 surveys with<strong>in</strong> the RNFE literature on<br />

develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. They conclude that the RNFE sector is substantial <strong>in</strong> many<br />

countries and has been grow<strong>in</strong>g over time. They stress that the percentage of RNFE<br />

may be underestimated because of temporary <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> jobs dur<strong>in</strong>g slack periods <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> or unremunerated work (especially done by women).<br />

De Janvry et al. (2005) use a detailed household survey dataset from Hubei prov<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong><br />

Ch<strong>in</strong>a to analyze the impact of economic reforms. They state that <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g rema<strong>in</strong>s the<br />

ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>come source for rural households. However, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is becom<strong>in</strong>g more<br />

important. The study shows that 72% of the rural households have a <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

that accounts on average for 36% of total household <strong>in</strong>come. The average <strong>in</strong>come of<br />

households that only participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities is lower than the average <strong>in</strong>come of<br />

households that have access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Next to this, the authors f<strong>in</strong>d that<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come decreased <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality and reduced rural poverty. Ruben and<br />

van den Berg (2001) use the national <strong>in</strong>come expenditure survey from 1993 to 1994 <strong>in</strong><br />

Honduras to study the role of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come of rural <strong>farm</strong> households. They estimate<br />

that 68% of the rural adults are somewhat <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

Furthermore, the <strong>in</strong>come from <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> wage en self-employment accounts for 16-<br />

25% of the household‟s <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

Kilic et al. (2009) review empirical evidence on the RNFE <strong>in</strong> a number of develop<strong>in</strong>g<br />

countries. They came across literature stat<strong>in</strong>g that RNFE <strong>in</strong>come accounts for 50% and<br />

35% of the total <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> respectively Lat<strong>in</strong> America and Africa. Compar<strong>in</strong>g this with<br />

other literature, RNFE <strong>in</strong>come accounts for 58% of the total <strong>in</strong>come on a global scale.<br />

12


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

Refer to Jayne et al. (2003), Otsuka and Yamano (2006) and Reardon et al. (2006) for<br />

more recent data on the <strong>in</strong>creased importance of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and patterns of<br />

RNFE <strong>in</strong> case studies from Asia, Lat<strong>in</strong> America and Africa. Carswell (2002) f<strong>in</strong>ds<br />

evidence that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> and off-<strong>farm</strong> activities are carried out by a significant<br />

proportion of adults <strong>in</strong> Wolayat, southern Ethiopia. Trad<strong>in</strong>g, a form of self-employment,<br />

seems to be the most important activity, carried out by 14% of the adults. 84% of the<br />

participants <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities does this at least once a week, while for more than<br />

50% the job is active throughout the year.<br />

2.3.3 Participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

The actual participation of households <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities depends on the <strong>in</strong>centive<br />

and capacity to participate (Reardon, 1997) and the occurrence of entry barriers<br />

(Dercon and Krishnan, 1996). Two opposite forces will determ<strong>in</strong>e the households‟ motif<br />

to diversify its <strong>in</strong>come sources. Push factors (or necessity) are the <strong>in</strong>voluntary and<br />

sometimes desperate reasons to diversify; they <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>come risk management,<br />

cop<strong>in</strong>g mechanisms, dim<strong>in</strong>ish<strong>in</strong>g or time-vary<strong>in</strong>g returns to productive assets, longterm<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts or smooth<strong>in</strong>g household consumption (Ellis, 1998; Ellis, 2000b;<br />

Barrett et al., 2001; Reardon et al., 2001). Voluntary diversification is opted for<br />

accumulation objectives (Reardon et al., 2006) or with the goal to maximize profits<br />

(Kilic et al., 2009). Reardon et al. (2000) suggest that poor households will be attracted<br />

to low-risk RNFE <strong>in</strong> order to decrease <strong>in</strong>come variability, even though they might have<br />

low returns (Reardon et al., 2006). Wealthier households will be less diversified <strong>in</strong> their<br />

<strong>in</strong>come sources because risk aversion motivation decl<strong>in</strong>es as wealth <strong>in</strong>creases under<br />

perfect market conditions. Pull factors will attract households to the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector<br />

when the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities offer higher returns compared to <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g. For the poor,<br />

their relative return is higher because they have a lower reservation wage<br />

(Woldenhanna and Oskam, 2001; Reardon, 1997). However, rich households can be<br />

pulled <strong>in</strong>to the RNFE to maximize their profits (Kilic et al., 2009).<br />

Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Davies et al. (2009) the ability of households to act on these <strong>in</strong>centives<br />

depends on a set of capacity variables. On the micro level, these variables <strong>in</strong>clude the<br />

vector of assets such as physical, social, human, and organizational capital, and<br />

liquidity from sources such as cash cropp<strong>in</strong>g. On the meso level, these variables conta<strong>in</strong><br />

access to local assets such as hard <strong>in</strong>frastructure (roads) and soft <strong>in</strong>frastructure<br />

(f<strong>in</strong>ancial services). The access to credit and f<strong>in</strong>ancial markets proofs to play a crucial<br />

13


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

role (Dercon and Krisnan, 1996; Barrett et al., 2001b; Reardon et al., 2006; Davies et<br />

al., 2009).<br />

However, high return <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities have certa<strong>in</strong> requisites to enter these<br />

activities. These requirements <strong>in</strong>clude among others education, skills and <strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

Activities with no or low entry barriers generally offer low returns, while activities with<br />

significant entry restrictions have higher returns. Participation <strong>in</strong> these lucrative <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

activities is thus conditioned by the possibility to overcome the required entry<br />

barriers. When enter<strong>in</strong>g a <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activity requires substantial <strong>in</strong>vestments, liquidity<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts will hamper households with restricted assets to enter these activities<br />

(Dercon and Krishnan, 1996; Woldenhanna, 2000; Barrett et al., 2001; van den Berg<br />

and Kumbi, 2006). The ability of households to overcome these entry barriers depends<br />

on their capacity variables (Davies et al., 2009). Collateral requirements, market<br />

imperfections and differences <strong>in</strong> repayment capacity make credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts more<br />

severe for poor households than for rich (Woldenhanna, 2000). As a consequence, poor<br />

households will be unable to overcome these entry barriers while wealthier households<br />

will have less problems <strong>in</strong> diversify<strong>in</strong>g their <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

Not everyth<strong>in</strong>g is decided based on motivation only. Participation is also <strong>in</strong>fluenced by<br />

capacity and entry barriers. As a result, the opposite outcome of what would seem<br />

logical could be observed. Poorer households might be motivated to diversify their<br />

<strong>in</strong>come for risk aversion, but entry barriers prevent this (Dercon and Krishnan, 1996;<br />

Dercon, 1998; Barrett et al., 2001; Escobal, 2001; Davies et al., 2002) result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong><br />

participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities with lower returns and higher risks (Sumberg et al.,<br />

2004) and thus less diversified <strong>in</strong>come sources. On the contrary, rich households may<br />

have less <strong>in</strong>centive to diversify, but they f<strong>in</strong>d themselves <strong>in</strong> a superior position to make<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments to overcome entry barriers (Reardon et al., 2000). Even though the<br />

marg<strong>in</strong>al value of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities exceeds the reservation wage, entry barriers will<br />

prevent poor households to enter. They are forced to participate <strong>in</strong> low-return <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities for which the entry barriers are low, most probably wage employment.<br />

Wealthier households will face less b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts and will engage <strong>in</strong> highreturn<br />

activities with higher entry barriers, mostly self-employment (Woldenhanna and<br />

Oskam, 2001). Rich households have a great freedom to choose among a wider range<br />

of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities, while poor households are rely<strong>in</strong>g on unskilled labor and<br />

activities with low barriers and therefore low returns (Sumberg et al., 2004).<br />

14


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

2.3.4 The nature of the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

As it is suggested that the RNFE has a substantial impact on <strong>agriculture</strong>, the question<br />

emerges how participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong>fluences the households‟ <strong>farm</strong><br />

decisions. Ellis (1998) f<strong>in</strong>ds that possible adverse (competition for labor and credit) and<br />

beneficial (re<strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>in</strong>surance) impacts of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on household<br />

level are suggested <strong>in</strong> the literature. The net impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities is however<br />

highly specific <strong>in</strong> time and space. Reardon et al. (1994) did research <strong>in</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso<br />

and suggest that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong>directly through capital<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment and <strong>in</strong>put acquisition. They hypothesize that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities can either<br />

draw resources away from agricultural production or stimulate re<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong><br />

activity. Whether <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities are complementary or compet<strong>in</strong>g to <strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

depends on both physical, economic and <strong>in</strong>stitutional factors and determ<strong>in</strong>ants of<br />

households‟ allocation choice of resources over <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

On the one hand, Woldenhanna (2000) states that productivity can be decreased due to<br />

lack of specialization, management <strong>in</strong>efficiency and competition for <strong>in</strong>puts. On the other<br />

hand, productivity can be <strong>in</strong>creased because <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong>crease manager<br />

skills, reduce land pressure and provide credit for <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> case of credit or<br />

capital constra<strong>in</strong>ts. It is concluded that <strong>in</strong>come diversification can have both a positive<br />

and a negative impact on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and its net impact cannot be determ<strong>in</strong>ed a<br />

priori. Pfeiffer et al. (2009) suggest that as market imperfections occur, agricultural<br />

<strong>in</strong>come can be affected by <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> different ways. A first direct impact is<br />

through the loss of labor, because agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts must be sacrificed when<br />

household members are participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Under perfect labor market<br />

conditions, households are able to hire perfect substitutes for miss<strong>in</strong>g labor on the <strong>farm</strong><br />

and agricultural production can be ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong>ed. However, develop<strong>in</strong>g countries face<br />

labor market constra<strong>in</strong>ts and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities will reduce the labor <strong>in</strong>put <strong>in</strong><br />

agricultural activities. The <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come affects agricultural production <strong>in</strong> a direct<br />

and <strong>in</strong>direct way when credit and liquidity markets imperfections occur. The direct<br />

effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is the relaxation of household budget constra<strong>in</strong>ts and the<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease of the purchase of normal goods. The <strong>in</strong>direct effects of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> are more<br />

complex: <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities provide households capital, security and liquidity to <strong>in</strong>vest<br />

<strong>in</strong> technology or <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts.<br />

15


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

2.3.4.1 Compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

Many authors recognize that the impact of the RNFE on the agricultural sector can be<br />

either complementary or compet<strong>in</strong>g. Compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> occur if households‟ decisions<br />

about <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> and <strong>farm</strong> activities are made jo<strong>in</strong>tly and households face limited<br />

resources and <strong>in</strong>puts such as capital and labor (Reardon et al., 1994). Participation <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities requires reallocation of those limited resources and results <strong>in</strong> an<br />

<strong>in</strong>evitable withdrawal from the <strong>farm</strong>. For example, RNFE consumes agricultural labor so<br />

that the labor availability on the <strong>farm</strong> decreases. Another consequence of the<br />

compet<strong>in</strong>g nature is that the factor bias of <strong>farm</strong> technology can be affected (Reardon et<br />

al., 1998). If <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities have a higher return and agricultural <strong>in</strong>vestments are<br />

risky, <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> land conservation and technology could be impeded (Reardon et<br />

al., 2000). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Reardon et al. (2001), the high productivity and higher returns<br />

of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities lead to concentration of resources <strong>in</strong> the RNFE. As a<br />

consequence, participation by households <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities can hamper their own<br />

<strong>farm</strong> productivity (Ellis and Freeman, 2004; Phimister and Roberts, 2006). Agricultural<br />

production and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come will decrease and thereby hampers agricultural<br />

commercialization or modernization (Ruben and van den Berg, 2001). The amount of<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities performed and the importance of each activity depends on the<br />

relative returns to <strong>farm</strong> versus <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and their <strong>in</strong>put requirements.<br />

There is empirical evidence of compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> between <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. Goodw<strong>in</strong> and Mishra (2004) studiy the relationship between <strong>farm</strong> efficiency<br />

and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> labor supply <strong>in</strong> the U.S. They report that high <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities decreases <strong>farm</strong> efficiency. They suggest that this <strong>in</strong>verse relationship can be<br />

expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the hypothesis of Smith (2002, as cited <strong>in</strong> Goodw<strong>in</strong> and Mishra, 2004)<br />

“Does off-<strong>farm</strong> work h<strong>in</strong>der smart <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g”. Smith suggests that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

have strong implications for the efficiency of <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g, because less attention can be<br />

devoted to issues important for <strong>farm</strong> productivity such as adoption of best management<br />

practices. As Goodw<strong>in</strong> and Mishra (2004) f<strong>in</strong>d evidence that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> labor allocation<br />

and <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g efficiency are jo<strong>in</strong>tly determ<strong>in</strong>ed, their results show that <strong>farm</strong>ers who are<br />

more efficient on the <strong>farm</strong> (this is a higher implicit <strong>farm</strong> wage) tend to allocate less<br />

labor to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. This is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the results of Chang and Wen (2010) <strong>in</strong><br />

Taiwan. They suggest that <strong>farm</strong>ers without RNFE are likely to have better knowledge of<br />

and pay more attention to <strong>farm</strong> management. Therefore, their use of <strong>in</strong>puts is more<br />

productive than <strong>farm</strong>ers with access to RNFE. Huang et al. (2009) study the <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> labor markets and the on-<strong>farm</strong> labor allocation to production of fruit<br />

crops <strong>in</strong> the Shandong Prov<strong>in</strong>ce of Ch<strong>in</strong>a. Among other th<strong>in</strong>gs, the authors conclude<br />

16


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

that the <strong>in</strong>tensity of fruit production is reduced with <strong>in</strong>creased RNFE. The fruit<br />

production sector is associated with lower entry barriers than the RNFE, attract<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>dividuals that are unable to engage <strong>in</strong> the RNFE because of high age or low education.<br />

Kilic et al. (2009) use data from the 2005 Albania Liv<strong>in</strong>g Standards Measurement<br />

Survey to explore the overall impact of the RNFE on agricultural expenditures and<br />

technical efficiency of rural households. They f<strong>in</strong>d that Albanian households do not use<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> earn<strong>in</strong>gs to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> time-sav<strong>in</strong>g, efficiency <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g agricultural<br />

technologies. Less expenditures are made <strong>in</strong> productivity enhanc<strong>in</strong>g crop <strong>in</strong>put<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments. The authors suggest that the existence of sectoral problems is driv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>come diversification out of crop production but towards livestock production. In the<br />

Ethiopian context, Holden et al. (2004) f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities negatively<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>farm</strong> production <strong>in</strong> two ways. First, better access to the RNFE reduces total<br />

agricultural production and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts expenditure. Second, rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

reduces households‟ <strong>in</strong>centive to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> conservation measures, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g land<br />

degradation and soil erosion. Not only agricultural <strong>in</strong>tensity is decreased, a drop <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong><br />

productivity is suggested. This has important consequences for rural development, as<br />

the need to import food <strong>in</strong> the area <strong>in</strong>creases.<br />

2.3.4.2 Complementary <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

Complementary <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come acts as an important source of<br />

capital and cash <strong>in</strong> the households‟ total budget. This extra budget could be used by the<br />

household to <strong>in</strong>vest, hire labor, purchase <strong>in</strong>puts or f<strong>in</strong>ance consumption. Reardon et al.<br />

(1994) suggest that consumption and <strong>in</strong>vestments compete for the use of household<br />

<strong>in</strong>come and therefore household decisions affect the nature of the consumption and<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. It is not clear how the households allocate their resources over<br />

consumption and <strong>in</strong>vestments. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Woldenhanna (2000), Ruben and van den<br />

Berg (2001) and Pfeifer et al. (2009), <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is important to satisfy<br />

consumption requirements when agricultural production cannot provide food security. It<br />

can, however, also be used to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>farm</strong> activities. Non-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come might have a<br />

positive impact on <strong>agriculture</strong> as it can be used to buy food which frees up other<br />

resources that can be <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities (Kilic et al., 2009; Woldenhanna,<br />

2000) or to buy <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts (Ruben and van den Berg, 2001). However, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come might also be used outside the <strong>farm</strong> because of complex agricultural sectoral<br />

problems that cannot easily be surmounted. In such case, f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> the<br />

RNFE, education and tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g or to migrate out of the rural sector (Kilic et al., 2009).<br />

17


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

Complementary <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> have been suggested earlier. Reardon et al. (1994) show that<br />

RNFE can provide an important source of cash for households <strong>in</strong> Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso. Reardon<br />

et al. (1998) f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong>come from agro<strong>in</strong>dustrial activities <strong>in</strong>fluences <strong>farm</strong> households‟<br />

capacity to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put, capital and appropriate technology. It is suggested that<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities are potentially important for long-term food security because it<br />

stimulates spend<strong>in</strong>g on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts and thereby <strong>farm</strong> productivity. The authors provide<br />

evidence from Burk<strong>in</strong>a Faso, the Niger and Senegal, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is<br />

usually the ma<strong>in</strong> source of cash for the purchase <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts. The authors suggest a<br />

dynamic effect as <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come surplus is <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts, creat<strong>in</strong>g capital<br />

that substitutes for labor and thus reduces <strong>farm</strong> labor demand. Lanjouw and Lanjouw<br />

(2001) suggest that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come leads to higher average <strong>in</strong>come from <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> two different ways. First, technologies or crop varieties with higher productivity are<br />

often related to higher variability. Access to an alternative stable <strong>in</strong>come source will<br />

facilitate the adoption of these technologies or varieties. Second, if access to low cost<br />

credit is absent, additional <strong>in</strong>come sources can stimulate the <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>puts. Davies et al. (2002) suggest that the growth <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> that arise from a first<br />

round of agricultural boom could be re<strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> capitaliz<strong>in</strong>g <strong>agriculture</strong>. Moreover, the<br />

RNFE sector can provide opportunities for households to reduce agricultural risks and<br />

stabilize their <strong>in</strong>come (Phimister and Roberts, 2006).<br />

Chang and Wen (2010) study the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> wages on agricultural efficiency<br />

and production risks <strong>in</strong> Taiwan. They use a nationwide survey of rice <strong>farm</strong>ers to<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestigate the efficiency and yield difference between households that participate <strong>in</strong><br />

RNFE and households that do not. It is noticed that the resource use for both<br />

households is different and that RNFE does not necessarily <strong>in</strong>duce technical <strong>in</strong>efficiency.<br />

In the lower percentiles of the efficiency distribution, <strong>farm</strong>ers with RNFE are more<br />

efficient than <strong>farm</strong>ers without. Lien et al. (2010) analyze the determ<strong>in</strong>ants of the <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

work decision and its <strong>in</strong>fluence on <strong>farm</strong> performance, based on panel data from<br />

Norwegian gra<strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong>s from 1991 to 2005. They did not observe a negative impact of<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work on <strong>farm</strong> efficiency or production. They show evidence that households<br />

that participate <strong>in</strong> RNFE could <strong>in</strong>crease production to some extent. This positive effect<br />

first <strong>in</strong>creases but then decreases with <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g hours spend on <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work.<br />

18


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

2.4 Investment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong><br />

2.4.1 Def<strong>in</strong>ition<br />

While the previous section suggests compet<strong>in</strong>g and complementary <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> possible to<br />

occur, we now turn our focus to <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. In the context of <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>, <strong>farm</strong> households selectively engage <strong>in</strong> the rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> market to earn an<br />

additional <strong>in</strong>come. This supplementary <strong>in</strong>come is a source of liquidity and credit for the<br />

household. Moreover, Reardon et al. (1994, p. 1175) state that “<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come can<br />

also serve as collateral and thus facilitate access to credit”. The additional source of<br />

credit and liquidity can be used by the household to f<strong>in</strong>ance risky <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> (Barrett et al., 2001; Kilic et al., 2009; Pfeifer et al., 2009). Households use<br />

their <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come sources to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments, to self <strong>in</strong>sure or purchase<br />

cash <strong>in</strong>puts for agricultural production (Reardon et al., 1994; Ellis, 1998; Barrett et al.,<br />

2001; Davies et al., 2002; Reardon et al., 2006). Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters (2009) and Pfeifer<br />

et al. (2009) expect the surplus of cash generated by <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come to directly<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluence the purchase of agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts.<br />

Under the condition that the additional source of credit is <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> durable<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put purchase, households are <strong>in</strong> the position to <strong>in</strong>crease their<br />

<strong>farm</strong> expenditures and expand <strong>in</strong>vestments (Reardon et al., 1994; Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters,<br />

2009). The <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come thereby improves <strong>farm</strong> productivity and boosts the<br />

agricultural production and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the long or short term (Pfeiffer et al., 2009).<br />

The former refers to the purchase of <strong>in</strong>puts like fertilizer, while the latter refers to the<br />

adoption of productivity <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g technologies like improved seeds. The ultimate<br />

result is that RNFE could be an important driver to foster <strong>farm</strong> commercialization,<br />

modernization or agricultural diversification <strong>in</strong>to higher value activities or agricultural<br />

production <strong>in</strong>tensification (Davies et al., 2009; Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009).<br />

2.4.2 Liquidity and credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts<br />

Investment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are likely to occur when households are pushed <strong>in</strong>to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities because they face credit and liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts or access to other sources of<br />

cash is not available (Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009; Pfeifer et al., 2009). These credit<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts hamper households‟ <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> production and productivity <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

technologies and <strong>in</strong>puts. As a result, credit restrictions drive households to self-<strong>in</strong>sure<br />

or f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>put expenditure with their own credit (Reardon et al., 2006; Oseni and<br />

W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009). Participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities could be an important way to<br />

19


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

generates cash and substitute for the absence of credit or the high cost l<strong>in</strong>ked with<br />

borrow<strong>in</strong>g credit. It implies that households diversify their livelihood <strong>in</strong>to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities to overcome some of the credit and <strong>in</strong>surance constra<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

How reasonable is it to expect that credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts determ<strong>in</strong>e the l<strong>in</strong>kage between<br />

<strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities? Households‟ engagement <strong>in</strong> RNFE is conditioned by their<br />

motives (push or pull), capacities and the existence of entry barriers, as expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong><br />

section 2.2.3. While it is viable that a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of motives drive participation <strong>in</strong> the<br />

RNFE, some authors suggest that the most important reason for households <strong>in</strong> rural<br />

areas of develop<strong>in</strong>g countries to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities is the relaxation of<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts (Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009; Pfeifer et al., 2009; Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and Davis, 2009).<br />

In Tigray, Woldenhanna (2000) suggests that if a b<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>t is present,<br />

these constra<strong>in</strong>ts will <strong>in</strong>duce <strong>farm</strong> households to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities to<br />

help them f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put and hire <strong>farm</strong> labor.<br />

The constra<strong>in</strong>ed accessibility of credit is driven by market imperfections (Oseni and<br />

W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009; Pfeifer et al., 2009; Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and Davis, 2009). Credit or <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

market failures imply low availability and access to credit which hampers households‟<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> production and productivity. Reardon et al. (2004) already suggested<br />

that the RNFE is likely to have a positive impact on <strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong> cases where the<br />

rural markets do not function properly. This is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the arguments given by Kilic<br />

et al. (2009), who suggest that “given the imperfect covariance between <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> earn<strong>in</strong>gs may help households overcome credit and <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

market constra<strong>in</strong>ts by provid<strong>in</strong>g liquidity that can be utilized for productivity enhanc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>put purchase and long-term <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> (Kilic et al., 2009, p. 140)”.<br />

Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters (2009) and Pfeifer et al. (2009) state that market imperfections are<br />

likely to occur. Moreover, several studies suggest the existence of imperfect markets <strong>in</strong><br />

develop<strong>in</strong>g countries (Ellis, 2000b; Barrett et al., 2001). De Janvry and Sadoulet<br />

(2003) review literature deal<strong>in</strong>g with market imperfections and study households‟<br />

behavior under market imperfections. They conclude that market imperfections are<br />

present. Pfeifer et al. (2009) f<strong>in</strong>d evidence that labor and credit markets are imperfect<br />

<strong>in</strong> rural Mexico. They suggest that either liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts or the presence of<br />

transaction costs <strong>in</strong> markets impede access for small <strong>farm</strong>ers to hired labor. Oseni and<br />

W<strong>in</strong>ters (2009) state that <strong>in</strong> rural areas of develop<strong>in</strong>g countries, credit and <strong>in</strong>surance<br />

markets do not function properly or even <strong>non</strong>-existent <strong>in</strong> some cases. The lack of<br />

access to credit h<strong>in</strong>ders households‟ <strong>in</strong>vest<strong>in</strong>g possibilities and consumption smooth<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

In conclusion, market imperfections exist, and merely occur <strong>in</strong> credit markets.<br />

20


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

Woldenhanna (2000) assumes that <strong>farm</strong> households <strong>in</strong> Tigray are not fully <strong>in</strong>tegrated<br />

<strong>in</strong>to the market. The survey respondents stated that their demand for credit is not fully<br />

satisfied. Moreover, private supply of credit and consumption credit is almost absent.<br />

The available credit is supplied by public organizations and l<strong>in</strong>ked with participation <strong>in</strong><br />

extension activities. Pender et al. (2006) state that credit is practically absent for<br />

<strong>smallholder</strong>s <strong>in</strong> the East African highlands. However, there is limited credit available<br />

through cooperatives, private firms and government support programs, but there are<br />

almost no opportunities to borrow from formal f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions such as commercial,<br />

<strong>in</strong>surance or construction banks. Moreover, these organizations require collateral and<br />

<strong>in</strong>volve time consum<strong>in</strong>g screen<strong>in</strong>g processes (Woldenhanna, 2000). Households are<br />

therefore left with uncerta<strong>in</strong> loans provided by credit schemes or small traders.<br />

2.4.3 Evidence<br />

In response to the awareness that the impact of the RNFE on agricultural production<br />

could be ma<strong>in</strong>ly through <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>, the evidence prov<strong>in</strong>g the existence of<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> is grow<strong>in</strong>g. Phimister and Roberts (2006) <strong>in</strong>vestigate the extent to<br />

which the RNFE changes the <strong>in</strong>tensity of agricultural <strong>in</strong>put for 2,419 <strong>farm</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> England.<br />

Their results suggest that fertility <strong>in</strong>tensity decl<strong>in</strong>es while conservation <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

with RNFE. Ellis and Freeman (2004) make a comparison of the rural livelihoods <strong>in</strong><br />

Uganda, Kenya, Tanzania and Malawi. One of their f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs is the positive relation<br />

between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment and agricultural production, which can be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by<br />

the availability of cash to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts or conservation practices and to hire<br />

labor. De Janvry et al. (2005) f<strong>in</strong>d that participation <strong>in</strong> RNFE has a positive spillover<br />

effect on household agricultural production. They use a household survey dataset from<br />

the Hubei prov<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a and study the <strong>in</strong>fluence of the RNFE on households‟<br />

<strong>in</strong>come, poverty and <strong>in</strong>equality. Deficient rural credit markets force households to<br />

engage <strong>in</strong> RNFE, enhanc<strong>in</strong>g on-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment capacity, mitigate <strong>in</strong>come fluctuations<br />

and function as <strong>in</strong>surance system.<br />

Ruben and van den Berg (2001) analyze the role of the RNFE of <strong>farm</strong> households, us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a national expenditure and <strong>in</strong>come survey from 1993 to 1994 <strong>in</strong> Honduras. Among<br />

other th<strong>in</strong>gs, they conclude that rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come can be used as a capital source<br />

to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>vestments used to optimize yield and labor productivity. This l<strong>in</strong>kage is<br />

most pronounced if credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts occur as <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities can be considered<br />

the collateral for borrow<strong>in</strong>g. Anriquez and Daidone (2009) explore the effect of the<br />

21


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

grow<strong>in</strong>g RNFE on <strong>farm</strong> diversification, household <strong>in</strong>put demands and production<br />

efficiency <strong>in</strong> Ghana. The <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> between agricultural and RNFE are measured by a<br />

household level <strong>in</strong>put distance function. They conclude that the expansion of the RNFE<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> most agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts. Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and Davis (2009) exam<strong>in</strong>e<br />

the use of agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts as a result of the relationship between participation <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>non</strong>-agricultural labor activities and <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g production decisions. The authors use a<br />

longitud<strong>in</strong>al survey from 1993 to 1998 <strong>in</strong> Vietnam. They state that households that<br />

engage <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-agricultural labor activities spend significantly more on agricultural<br />

<strong>in</strong>puts. In case of <strong>in</strong>complete credit markets, participation <strong>in</strong> RNFE relaxes credit<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts through credit provision for purchases of agricultural <strong>in</strong>put. Also, the share<br />

of the RNFE <strong>in</strong> total rural <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases over the same period.<br />

Maertens (2009) mentions that access to low-skilled RNFE has alleviated <strong>farm</strong>ers‟<br />

liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>smallholder</strong> agricultural production. The<br />

author uses a household survey dataset <strong>in</strong> the ma<strong>in</strong> horticulture region <strong>in</strong> Senegal. The<br />

results prove that the <strong>in</strong>come from employment <strong>in</strong> the horticulture export <strong>in</strong>dustry is<br />

used to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> the <strong>farm</strong>, result<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> higher expenditures, higher <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>comes and<br />

larger <strong>farm</strong> sizes. Entry barriers <strong>in</strong> credit and <strong>in</strong>put markets can be tackled by the<br />

RNFE. Hertz (2009) documents the relationship between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and<br />

agricultural <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> Bulgaria. More specifically, the <strong>in</strong>fluence of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> wage<br />

employment and pensions on expenditures, work<strong>in</strong>g capital and <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong><br />

livestock is studied. <strong>Farm</strong> expenditure is regressed aga<strong>in</strong>st RNFE and other variables <strong>in</strong><br />

a two part model. This research po<strong>in</strong>ts out that <strong>farm</strong>ers fund <strong>farm</strong> expenses from <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come and use credit for consumption. The latter implies that if credit is available<br />

or the access to credit would be enhanced, the borrowed funds are not used to f<strong>in</strong>ance<br />

agricultural <strong>in</strong>vestments but used for consumption purposes.<br />

Pfeiffer et al. (2009) use the 2003 National Rural Household Survey Dataset from<br />

Mexico to explore the effect of the RNFE on agricultural production activities.<br />

Instrumented variable models were used to study whether households with and without<br />

RNFE differ <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> decisions. The authors state that RNFE negatively <strong>in</strong>fluences the<br />

family labor <strong>in</strong> crop production and <strong>farm</strong> output, but <strong>in</strong>creases the use of purchased<br />

<strong>in</strong>puts. As access to RNFE is <strong>in</strong>creased, households will earn more and this <strong>in</strong>duces a<br />

shift out of cropp<strong>in</strong>g. This effect is caused by both the relaxation of the credit constra<strong>in</strong>t<br />

but and the effort by households to seek for family labor substitutes when the returns<br />

of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work <strong>in</strong>crease. F<strong>in</strong>ally, Woldenhanna (2000) <strong>in</strong>vestigates the impact of<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment and <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> households and agricultural production. His<br />

analysis uses a <strong>farm</strong> household model with liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts build upon a <strong>farm</strong><br />

22


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

household survey from Tigray, northern Ethiopia. He f<strong>in</strong>ds that <strong>farm</strong> households with<br />

more diversified sources of <strong>in</strong>come have a higher agricultural productivity. Non-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come surplus helps households to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g activities such as the <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong><br />

labor and <strong>in</strong>puts (seeds, fertilizer and pesticides). When <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases by<br />

1% expenditures on variable <strong>in</strong>put will <strong>in</strong>crease by 0.43%. Hence, the author concludes<br />

that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come can be complementary to <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come if households face<br />

borrow<strong>in</strong>g constra<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

2.5 Virtuous circle<br />

The existence of a virtuous circle is important for rural development. When households<br />

face liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts, they will be pushed <strong>in</strong>to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Promot<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

latter makes access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment easier for households. In this way,<br />

households <strong>in</strong>crease their <strong>in</strong>come and diversify their <strong>in</strong>come sources. This <strong>in</strong>come<br />

surplus will then be re<strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> the <strong>farm</strong>, facilitat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>farm</strong> modernization and<br />

commercialization. It is assumed that this will <strong>in</strong>crease agricultural productivity and<br />

demand for agricultural labor which ends the virtuous circle (Davies et al., 2009).<br />

Investment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> should enhance rural modernization, commercialization and<br />

specialization, because the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> agricultural productivity enables households to<br />

participate <strong>in</strong> the RNFE without lower<strong>in</strong>g agricultural production (Kilic et al., 2009).<br />

The hypothesis of such a virtuous circle is however not new. John Mellor, (undated)<br />

cited by Lanjouw and Lanjouw (2001), observes a virtuous cycle emerg<strong>in</strong>g whereby<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g agricultural productivity and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come would be magnified by multiple<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> with the RNFE. Increased agricultural <strong>in</strong>come would enlarge demand for goods<br />

and services, but also potential <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> through the supply of capital and labor were<br />

assumed to occur. The <strong>in</strong>creased agricultural productivity will reallocate labor or<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>come so that the new agricultural surplus could be used for <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong><br />

the RNFE. The assumed growth <strong>in</strong> the RNFE would <strong>in</strong> turn stimulate further growth <strong>in</strong><br />

agricultural productivity via lower <strong>in</strong>put costs and the fact that profits are <strong>in</strong>vested back<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>agriculture</strong> and technological improvements. Mellor believes the <strong>in</strong>come and<br />

employment <strong>in</strong> the agricultural and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector are mutually re<strong>in</strong>forced when the<br />

both sectors grow.<br />

If the virtuous circle occurs, it is important to promote the access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

and to make sure households can enter the RNFE sector. The existence of entry<br />

barriers h<strong>in</strong>der poor households to participate <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. These<br />

23


Chapter 2: Literature review<br />

entry barriers can be present <strong>in</strong> the form of abilities or credit (Dercon and Krishnan,<br />

1996). Some <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities require better education and specialized skills. Credit<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts h<strong>in</strong>der poor households to make the required <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> capital and<br />

equipment necessary for the participation <strong>in</strong> the RNFE. As a result, <strong>in</strong>come<br />

diversification <strong>in</strong> high return niches with<strong>in</strong> the RNFE will be more difficult to obta<strong>in</strong> for<br />

poor households than for rich households. More educated, skilled and better endowed<br />

households will have better access to high-return <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities (Dercon and<br />

Krishnan, 1996; Barrett et al., 2001; Woldenhanna and Oskam, 2001).<br />

The existence of entry barriers h<strong>in</strong>ders households to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities,<br />

and as a result the ga<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come cannot be used as a liquidity source for<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. The occurrence of entry barriers determ<strong>in</strong>es whether <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are likely to occur. Barrett et al. (2001, p. 324) suggest that “those with the<br />

least agricultural assets and <strong>in</strong>come are typically also least able to make up this<br />

deficiency through <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> earn<strong>in</strong>gs because they cannot meet the <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

requirements for entry <strong>in</strong>to remunerative <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities”. Davies et al. (2002)<br />

po<strong>in</strong>t out that the lack of access to credit can hamper the l<strong>in</strong>kage between RNFE and<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong> <strong>in</strong> several ways. First, households‟ capacities to expend their current<br />

activities may be limited, underm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the households‟ ability to exploit the<br />

opportunities for sell<strong>in</strong>g to agribus<strong>in</strong>ess. Credit is necessary to enter <strong>in</strong> these activities,<br />

which will foster the development and expansion of the RNFE. Access to credit will not<br />

be a guarantee for this, but it will facilitate the process. Second, credit is necessary to<br />

adopt new crops and technology <strong>in</strong> order to produce the required process<strong>in</strong>g quality.<br />

An <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g study <strong>in</strong> the Tigray region of Ethiopia has been conducted by<br />

Woldenhanna and Oskam (2001). They prove that <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g access to RNFE can<br />

expand the economic activity <strong>in</strong> Tigray, but due to entry barriers, relative wealthy<br />

households will dom<strong>in</strong>ate the most profitable RNFE such as petty trade, masonry and<br />

carpentry. They conclude that constra<strong>in</strong>ed access to credit and liquidity is the most<br />

important underly<strong>in</strong>g factor that h<strong>in</strong>ders participation <strong>in</strong> RNFE. However, van den Berg<br />

and Kumbi (2006) present evidence that entry barriers for the poor to participate <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector are low and they therefore participate actively <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong><br />

the Oromia state. The <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector provides an alternative to use labor excess from<br />

agricultural production. They conclude that further growth <strong>in</strong> the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector will<br />

not <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality, as is sometimes assumed.<br />

24


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

3 METHODOLOGY<br />

3.1 Study and survey area<br />

The survey area is located <strong>in</strong> Tigray, the most northern Federal State of Ethiopia<br />

(Figure 3.1). Tigray is divided <strong>in</strong>to six zones, which are further subdivided <strong>in</strong>to 34<br />

woredas. Each woreda conta<strong>in</strong>s a number of tabias which are regarded as the lowest<br />

adm<strong>in</strong>istrative hierarchy (Negash, 2008). Accord<strong>in</strong>g to the Central Statistical Agency of<br />

Ethiopia (CSA), Tigray covers an area of more than 50 thousand km² and has an<br />

estimated population of 4.6 million with an average annual population growth rate of<br />

above 2.6% (CSA, 2008; cited by Negash, 2008). The altitude <strong>in</strong> the region ranges<br />

between 300 meters above sea level (masl) <strong>in</strong> the east and more than 3,000 masl <strong>in</strong><br />

the north and central part, cover<strong>in</strong>g three agro-climatic zones: lowland (kolla: below<br />

1,500 masl), medium highland (wo<strong>in</strong>a dega: between 1,500 and 2,3000 masl) and<br />

upper highland (douga: between 2,300 and 3,200 masl) (Kidane, undated).<br />

Figure 3.1: Map of Ethiopia (small) and Tigray Regional state<br />

source: Figure created by the local organiz<strong>in</strong>g committee of the International Congress Water<br />

2011 [onl<strong>in</strong>e], available at http://ees.kuleuven.be/water2011/excursions/<strong>in</strong>dex.html [date of<br />

search: 13/04/2011]<br />

25


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

The analysis of the <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> l<strong>in</strong>kage is based on the survey of rural households<br />

conduced <strong>in</strong> 2009 at a sample of 734 households <strong>in</strong> the Geba catchment. The research<br />

site covers 4600 km² and conta<strong>in</strong>s 8 woreda and 168 tabias <strong>in</strong> the Tigray region. Us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a structured questionnaire, a survey was conducted <strong>in</strong> Tanqua, Samre, Atsbi and Wukro<br />

woreda (Figure 3.2). The woredas were not chosen at random as it would be impossible<br />

to survey the extensive area and the available time and budget were limited. Moreover,<br />

it is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the research areas of the MU-IUC Collaboration Program. The woredas<br />

<strong>in</strong> the Geba Catchment were stratified <strong>in</strong>to three agro-climatic zones. Based on<br />

population, four woredas were picked randomly: one from the highland, two from the<br />

middle-highland and one from the lowland. By this, the survey was designed to be<br />

representative for the whole region, as the contrast<strong>in</strong>g socio-economic (access to<br />

market <strong>in</strong> woreda and Mekelle) and agro-climatic (altitude, temperature and ra<strong>in</strong>fall)<br />

zones were reflected. From each woreda, samples were drawn randomly to constitute<br />

sample research sites. As a result, from each Woreda two Tabias were selected<br />

randomly (so 8 Tabias <strong>in</strong> total): Rubafeleg, Barka, Negash, Adiqsanded, Addisalem,<br />

Andewoyane, Lemlem and Hadnet. Households were drawn from each tabia based on<br />

their respective population size and participation <strong>in</strong> agricultural extension service, with<br />

densely populated tabias gett<strong>in</strong>g a relative higher number of households quota.<br />

Figure 3.2: Research area<br />

Source: BoANRD 2004 (Bureau of Agriculture and Natural Resource Development)<br />

26


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

Next to the variability of ra<strong>in</strong>fall and susceptibility to droughts, the fragile Ethiopian<br />

highlands still suffer from natural soil erosion depletion and other land degrad<strong>in</strong>g<br />

processes, low soil fertility and aridification (Pender, 2000; Block and Webb, 2001;<br />

Holden et al., 2004; Ehui and Pender, 2005). These natural problems are enhanced by<br />

population pressure, <strong>in</strong>tensive land (over)use by livestock graz<strong>in</strong>g and cultivation,<br />

crop/animal pests, cultivation of marg<strong>in</strong>al lands on steep slopes and deforestation<br />

(Woldenhanna, 2000; Negash, 2008; Tesfay, 2009). Furthermore, the region has<br />

suffered from droughts, fam<strong>in</strong>es, food <strong>in</strong>securities, civil wars, political conflicts, border<br />

conflicts, poor governance, underdeveloped <strong>in</strong>frastructure, restricted access to formal<br />

f<strong>in</strong>ancial <strong>in</strong>stitutions and underdeveloped education or tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g (Pender, 2000;<br />

Woldenhanna, 2002; Negash, 2008; Tesfay, 2009). This all resulted <strong>in</strong> environmental<br />

and ecological problems, degraded and fragmented land and poor resource<br />

management and hence even poorer performance of <strong>agriculture</strong> (Woldenhanna, 2000).<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> households participate <strong>in</strong> a wide variety of both <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

Subsistence <strong>agriculture</strong> 1 rema<strong>in</strong>s the ma<strong>in</strong> occupation of the rural people <strong>in</strong> Tigray<br />

which is highly dependable from variability <strong>in</strong> ra<strong>in</strong>fall and recurrent droughts (Tesfay,<br />

2009). Teff is the ma<strong>in</strong> staple food and occupies the largest share of cultivate land, but<br />

maize production is <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> importance (Pender et al., 2006). Woldenhanna<br />

(2002) f<strong>in</strong>ds that <strong>in</strong> 1996, 78% of the households was engaged <strong>in</strong> mixed <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g, while<br />

only 19% was engaged <strong>in</strong> cropp<strong>in</strong>g only and 3% <strong>in</strong> livestock husbandry only. Next to<br />

this, 81% of the rural households participated <strong>in</strong> various <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. He also<br />

shows that, on average, <strong>farm</strong> production accounted for 57% of the total <strong>in</strong>come and<br />

hence <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities 43%.<br />

In 1996, the average <strong>farm</strong> size was 0.97 ha and 70% of the households owned less<br />

than one ha (Woldenhanna, 2002). The average <strong>farm</strong> size now ranges from 0.6 ha <strong>in</strong><br />

the eastern part to 1.2 ha <strong>in</strong> the western part and average landhold<strong>in</strong>gs generally<br />

decrease with altitude. Agricultural production is below the natural average, on average<br />

below one ton per hectare, even <strong>in</strong> good years (Woldenhanna, 2002). Yields have<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased only marg<strong>in</strong>ally because of <strong>in</strong>creased maize yields and expansion of the<br />

fertilized area (Dercon and Christiaensen, 2010). As a result, agricultural production is<br />

not able to support <strong>farm</strong> households of five to six members for longer than six months<br />

(TBORAD, 2008; as cited <strong>in</strong> Kidane, undated). Deforestation, cont<strong>in</strong>uous cultivation,<br />

1 mixed <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g, subsistence oxen plough s<strong>in</strong>gle cropp<strong>in</strong>g cereal crop dom<strong>in</strong>ated comb<strong>in</strong>ed with livestock<br />

rear<strong>in</strong>g production is the typical <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g system (Kidane, undated)<br />

27


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

soil nutrient depletion, us<strong>in</strong>g dung and crop residues as fuel and severe soil erosion<br />

have resulted <strong>in</strong> low fertilizer application use (below 15kg/ha). <strong>Farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g systems <strong>in</strong><br />

Tigray are characterized by traditional technology use, ma<strong>in</strong>ly ra<strong>in</strong>-fed land and animal<br />

traction. Dur<strong>in</strong>g drought years, people become fully dependent on food aid (Kidane,<br />

undated). It is assumed that further <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> agricultural employment is difficult<br />

because of the above mentioned constra<strong>in</strong>ts (Woldenhanna, 2002).<br />

In 2003, the Agricultural Sample Enumeration (CSA, 2003; as sited <strong>in</strong> Kidane, undated)<br />

reported the total livestock <strong>in</strong> Tigray to be 10.8 million animals of which 2.8 million<br />

cattle, 1.8 million goats and 0.7 million sheep. Households on average own 3.2 units of<br />

cattle. This makes the Ethiopian herd to be the largest <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa (Pender et<br />

al., 2006). The average milk production is low, about 1.5 liters per day per cow.<br />

Woldenhanna (2002) states that livestock plays a secondary role, but oxen plough<br />

stays very important. Also, the lack of pasture, fodder and scarcity of veter<strong>in</strong>ary cl<strong>in</strong>ic<br />

constra<strong>in</strong> livestock development. Moreover, after a drought, the revival of livestock<br />

<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g is difficult because a significant number of the livestock dies. There are almost<br />

230,000 beehives <strong>in</strong> Tigray. The annual honey production is estimate at 19,000 ton of<br />

which 98% comes from traditional beehives.<br />

3.2 Survey design<br />

The survey was conducted under the supervision of Kidane M.G. Egziabher, as part of<br />

his Ph.D. to study the impact of agricultural extension on household <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>in</strong>come<br />

diversification <strong>in</strong> 2009. Refer to Kidane (undated) for a description of the methodology<br />

used <strong>in</strong> this research. Both qualitative and quantitative methods were used to collect<br />

data. The qualitative method <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong>-depth semi-structured <strong>in</strong>terviews and focus<br />

group discussions with policy makers, agricultural researchers, development<br />

practitioners, <strong>farm</strong>ers and development agents. The quantitative method <strong>in</strong>cluded 500<br />

rural household surveys and 200 household choice experimentation surveys us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

questionnaires.<br />

The dataset conta<strong>in</strong>s detailed <strong>in</strong>formation collected us<strong>in</strong>g questionnaires about the<br />

households‟ head <strong>in</strong>dividual characteristics (age, gender, education, …), households‟<br />

characteristics (family size, access to irrigation, …), households‟ access to capital<br />

(f<strong>in</strong>ance, landhold<strong>in</strong>gs, livestock, fixed, …), types of households‟ occupation (migration,<br />

transfer, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> and <strong>farm</strong>), local conditions (regional variables, access to markets<br />

and capital, …), <strong>in</strong>vestments (durables and <strong>in</strong>puts) and consumption (food and <strong>non</strong>-<br />

28


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

food). The questionnaire designed for the household survey was planned to be collected<br />

<strong>in</strong> two rounds and was adm<strong>in</strong>istered for each of the selected head of household to<br />

collect the relevant <strong>in</strong>formation by deploy<strong>in</strong>g tra<strong>in</strong>ed enumerators. However, this<br />

research only uses first round data (cross-sectional data set). Separate checklists were<br />

developed to gather secondary <strong>in</strong>formation. Focus group approach (adm<strong>in</strong>istered by the<br />

researcher) was used to collect <strong>in</strong>-depth <strong>in</strong>formation through discussion on a wide<br />

range of issues related to households‟ recruitment criteria to extension package<br />

programs, technology selection, <strong>farm</strong>s and policy makers perception regard<strong>in</strong>g<br />

programs performance and possible perspectives as how to improve the lives of<br />

<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g communities.<br />

Qualitative data <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong>formation about extension (<strong>in</strong>stitutional <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>,<br />

coord<strong>in</strong>ation, research outputs and priority sett<strong>in</strong>g processes), <strong>farm</strong>ers‟ satisfaction<br />

level (extension, market<strong>in</strong>g and credit systems), development agents‟ skills and<br />

<strong>farm</strong>ers‟ attitude. This qualitative <strong>in</strong>formation was gathered through desk review of<br />

government policy documents, previous studies and related <strong>in</strong>formation available <strong>in</strong> the<br />

study area. Relevant <strong>in</strong>formation for the desk review was acquired from the Bureau of<br />

Rural Development and Agriculture, Regional Agricultural Research Institute, Regional<br />

Market<strong>in</strong>g Agencies, Food security Office, Micro-F<strong>in</strong>ance Institutions, Local Government<br />

adm<strong>in</strong>istrators and Cooperative Development Offices and ngo‟s active <strong>in</strong> the area.<br />

The validity of the research questionnaires and checklists was verified through pilot<br />

tests. Based on the results of pilot test, to revise and modify the questionnaires were<br />

revised and modified. To improve the quality of the survey, qualified enumerators were<br />

recruited and tra<strong>in</strong>ed. Despite this careful data collection it is reasonable to expect<br />

some underestimation of the actual <strong>in</strong>come, expenditures and assets. This is due to the<br />

sensitive nature of the <strong>in</strong>formation on <strong>in</strong>come and expenditure, the limited capacity to<br />

recall on all the transactions by the respondents and unwill<strong>in</strong>gness of the respondents<br />

to disclose to outsiders. These are however natural shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs and the data will give<br />

a reasonable picture of the research sites.<br />

3.3 Data analysis<br />

Our primary <strong>in</strong>terest lied on the analysis of the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come (x) on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments (y). We First def<strong>in</strong>ed these <strong>in</strong>vestments as the total household expenditure<br />

on <strong>farm</strong> activities. These expenditures <strong>in</strong>cluded both <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> durables and <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>put use. Afterwards, we narrowed our analysis to both types of <strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

29


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

Households‟ durables <strong>in</strong>cluded land and water conservation measures, animals,<br />

build<strong>in</strong>gs and equipment. We expanded our analysis to these different types of <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments. <strong>Farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use <strong>in</strong>cluded local and improved seeds, fertilizer and labor. In<br />

the empirical specification of the econometric model used, we used the general term<br />

„<strong>in</strong>vestments‟ and the latter might refer to either of both <strong>in</strong>vestments. Our most<br />

important <strong>in</strong>dependent variable was <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. This was def<strong>in</strong>ed as the <strong>in</strong>come<br />

earned by <strong>farm</strong> households by participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the RNFE sector. Next to this, we<br />

<strong>in</strong>cluded a large set of observable variable <strong>in</strong> the model. These control variables <strong>in</strong>clude<br />

(1) household head age, sex and school<strong>in</strong>g; (2) households landhold<strong>in</strong>g, animal assets<br />

and fixed assets; (3) distance to Mekelle and (4) edir membership, access to irrigation<br />

and number of adult work<strong>in</strong>g labor forces.<br />

Non-<strong>farm</strong> activities were def<strong>in</strong>ed as rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> labor activities and therefore<br />

consisted only of wage <strong>in</strong>come and self-employment. We thus not <strong>in</strong>cluded migration<br />

and transfer <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. The rationale beh<strong>in</strong>d this def<strong>in</strong>ition is that<br />

transfer <strong>in</strong>come is not a real <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> labor activity as it is support received from the<br />

government or ngo‟s. As migration <strong>in</strong>come is not <strong>in</strong>fluenc<strong>in</strong>g households‟ decisions<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g the time of production season, we prefered not to <strong>in</strong>clude it <strong>in</strong> our analysis.<br />

Migratory activities contrast with rural activities because households‟ allocation of labor<br />

resources dur<strong>in</strong>g the production season does not affect migratory activities. It is<br />

assumed that wage and self-employment activities are important for <strong>farm</strong> households.<br />

In order to avoid sample selection bias we added a positive constant to the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come variable and take logarithms: ln(x+c). The same is done for <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments,<br />

because the logarithmic form is also necessary to correct for the clear positive<br />

skewness at the right side of the <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>in</strong>vestment variable. This prevented<br />

outliers to <strong>in</strong>fluence our estimates, especially <strong>in</strong> small samples.<br />

3.3.1 Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares estimation<br />

The effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments was analyzed by compar<strong>in</strong>g<br />

households that have access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come with those households that do not,<br />

while controll<strong>in</strong>g for a set of observable factors. The systematic differences between<br />

these two groups of households were captured through the <strong>in</strong>clusion of these<br />

observable <strong>in</strong>dividual and household characteristics. The follow<strong>in</strong>g regression equation<br />

estimates the effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments, and is referred as the<br />

structural equation:<br />

y=β 0<br />

+β 1<br />

x+β i<br />

n i + u (eq. 1)<br />

30


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

where β 0 is the <strong>in</strong>tercept, β 1 is the parameter associated with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, β i the<br />

parameter of the i th explanatory variable n i and u the error term. Assume that the<br />

vector N i of explanatory variables is exogenous, but x is correlated with u and is<br />

therefore an endogenous explanatory variable, this is Cov(x,u)≠0. The latter condition<br />

causes the Ord<strong>in</strong>ary Least Squares (OLS) estimation of eq. 1 to be <strong>in</strong>consistent<br />

(Wooldridge, 2002b).<br />

3.3.2 Omitted variable bias<br />

Cov(x,u)≠0 is caused by the fact that u conta<strong>in</strong>s omitted variables that are correlated<br />

with x, but not with N i . This means that unobserved variables are present that <strong>in</strong>fluence<br />

both our dependent variable <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments and our most important explanatory<br />

variable <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. Exclud<strong>in</strong>g them from the regression analysis makes x<br />

correlated with u and thus the zero conditional mean assumption to fail. As a result, the<br />

coefficients <strong>in</strong> a simple OLS regression will be biased. This is termed omitted variable<br />

bias or unobserved heterogeneity. The most optimal solution to this problem is the use<br />

of panel data to control for time-<strong>in</strong>variant unobserved households-level fixed effects,<br />

f<strong>in</strong>d a suitable proxy variable for these unobserved variables or use the <strong>in</strong>strumental<br />

variable (IV) method. In the absence of the first two possibilities, we will use the IV<br />

regression model. As many researchers deal<strong>in</strong>g with this problem have po<strong>in</strong>ted out: the<br />

solution is to cure the disease rather than prevent it (Wooldridge 2002b).<br />

It is most likely that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is correlated with unobserved variables that also<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>farm</strong> decisions. Several different possible sources of omitted variable bias are<br />

found <strong>in</strong> the literature, such as Hertz (2009), Kilic et al. (2009), Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters<br />

(2009) and Maertens (2009). This literature has po<strong>in</strong>ted out that it is impossible to<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>e a-priori the direction and magnitude of the omitted variable bias. <strong>Farm</strong> and<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come activities are complex related and our data set <strong>in</strong>cludes many sources<br />

of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>farm</strong> activities. Many potential effects could therefore be<br />

present and it is impossible to assume one mechanism to be dom<strong>in</strong>ant. It is more likely<br />

that several factors will have a plausible effect.<br />

Entrepreneurship and general ability are assumed to have a positive effect on most<br />

economic activities, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g both <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Economic<br />

motivation might drive household members to seek for <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment as well<br />

as to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> their <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g activities. Both unobserved variables would lead to an<br />

upward bias <strong>in</strong> the estimated effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. However,<br />

31


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

economic motivation can also force households to gradually leave <strong>farm</strong> activities as<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities have a better pay-off and therefore spend less money on <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. Also risk aversion might have such ambiguous effect. On the one hand, it<br />

may stimulate households to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong> order to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments. By this, they reduce the risks associated with <strong>farm</strong> activities. On the other<br />

hand, risk aversion might lead to a downward effect: households are avoid<strong>in</strong>g costly<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities and focus on <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities to diversify their <strong>in</strong>come<br />

sources. Households that face more constra<strong>in</strong>ts to agricultural production might allocate<br />

more labor to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

3.3.3 Two Stage Least Squares estimation<br />

The bias <strong>in</strong> the estimation can be reduced by <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g as much as theoretically<br />

relevant control variables as possible <strong>in</strong> our analysis. These control variables should be<br />

correlated with the unobservable variables. It is however impossible to exclude all<br />

variation <strong>in</strong> the error term and a more specialized method is necessary. To overcome<br />

the problem of omitted variables here, we use the IV approach <strong>in</strong> order to isolate<br />

exogenous variation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. This approach tries to solve the omitted<br />

variable bias problem by leav<strong>in</strong>g the unobserved variables <strong>in</strong> the error term and us<strong>in</strong>g<br />

estimation methods that recognize the presence of omitted variables (Wooldridge 2002,<br />

Wooldridge 2002b). By f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g appropriate IV we isolate the movements <strong>in</strong> x that are<br />

uncorrelated with y.<br />

We will describe the Two Stage Least Squares (2SLS) estimation model follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Wooldridge (2002, 2002b). Recall the structural equation eq. 1 where <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

is the endogenous dependent variable, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come x is the ma<strong>in</strong> explanatory<br />

variable of <strong>in</strong>terest, that is likely endogenous, and N i is a set of exogenous variables.<br />

Assume that z j is a set of exogenous variables that are not <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> eq. 1 and which<br />

are assumed to be a set of valid <strong>in</strong>struments. An appropriate IV candidate for x must<br />

satisfy two econometric assumptions. First, the <strong>in</strong>strument z j should be uncorrelated<br />

with the error term u: Cov(z j ,u)=0. This is often referred as the orthogonality<br />

assumption and <strong>in</strong>dicates that the <strong>in</strong>struments z j should have no partial effect on<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments y and z j is uncorrelated with other factors that affect y. Second, the<br />

<strong>in</strong>strument must be correlated with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, this is Cov(z j ,x)≠0, mean<strong>in</strong>g that<br />

z j must be related to the endogenous <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come (Wooldridge, 2002b).<br />

32


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

The regression equation (eq. 1) is solved us<strong>in</strong>g a two stage least squares (2SLS)<br />

model. In the first stage of the 2SLS model, x is written as a l<strong>in</strong>ear function of the<br />

exogenous variables (<strong>in</strong>struments and control variables) and an error term v. This<br />

equation is the reduced form equation for x:<br />

x=η 0<br />

+η j<br />

z j +η i<br />

n i +v (eq. 2)<br />

Out of all possible l<strong>in</strong>ear comb<strong>in</strong>ations of the exogenous variables that can be used as<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments for x, 2SLS will choose that which is the most correlated with x. The key<br />

identification assumption is that there is at least one of the π j or ≠ 0. The best IV for x<br />

is the l<strong>in</strong>ear comb<strong>in</strong>ation of z j and n i which is called x * ,<br />

x * =η 0<br />

+η j<br />

z j +η i<br />

n i (eq. 3)<br />

and is uncorrelated with u. By this, we can see that eq. 2 consist of two parts: x * and<br />

v. x * can be <strong>in</strong>terpreted as the part of x that is uncorrelated with u while v is possible<br />

related to u. To obta<strong>in</strong> the fitted value x (this is the estimated version of x * ), a<br />

regression on eq. 2 is run:<br />

x=η 0<br />

+η j<br />

z j +η i<br />

n i (eq. 4)<br />

Therefore, the first stage of 2SLS purifies x of its correlation with u before do<strong>in</strong>g an OLS<br />

regression. It estimates the relationship between on one side the control variables and<br />

the IV and on the other side <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. By this, the component of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come that is uncorrelated with the error term is isolated. The second stage uses this<br />

component to estimate the coefficient of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

regression. The second stage is the OLS regression, but with x <strong>in</strong>stead of x, which gives<br />

us the reduced form for y:<br />

y=β 0<br />

+β 1<br />

x * +β i<br />

n i + u +β 1<br />

v (eq. 5)<br />

The composite error u + β 1 v has zero mean and is uncorrelated with all explanatory<br />

variables x * and n i . the OLS will give unbiased results for the reduced form parameters<br />

because of the latter feature.<br />

Another advantage of IV methods is that it is a general solution to isolate exogenous<br />

variation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come (Wooldridge, 2002b). Simultaneity bias could occur when<br />

the decision to allocate labor (to <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g, but also to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities or leisure) are<br />

made simultaneously with decisions related to expenditures on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. The<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is therefore related with the error term. If large <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities free up labor time devoted to <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g, this labor time could be allocated to<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. This would create a positive relation between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and<br />

33


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

the error term, lead<strong>in</strong>g to an upward bias <strong>in</strong> our estimates on its effect. It is however<br />

also possible that <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong>tensify <strong>farm</strong> activities and thereby draw<strong>in</strong>g labor<br />

away from <strong>farm</strong> activities. This would reduce <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and create a downward<br />

bias (Hertz, 2009). Also Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and Davies (2009) suggest the OLS regression to be<br />

downward biased because <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> labor decisions are made jo<strong>in</strong>tly. They<br />

suggest that the more households <strong>farm</strong>, the less likely they are to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

activities.<br />

The use of 2SLS methods br<strong>in</strong>gs however also some limitations. First, the IV technique<br />

produces less precise estimates as it exploits only a part of the correlation between the<br />

dependent variable and the exogenous regressors. This correlation is determ<strong>in</strong>ed by the<br />

correlation between the exogenous regressors and the <strong>in</strong>struments (Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and<br />

Davis, 2009; Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009). Moreover, the calculated causal effect places<br />

greater weight on those households most <strong>in</strong>fluenced by the <strong>in</strong>struments and thereby<br />

captur<strong>in</strong>g the effects of a subpopulation (Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009). Next to this,<br />

Wooldridge (2002) states that an important cost related to the IV estimation is the<br />

larger asymptotic variance of the IV estimator which is sometimes much larger than the<br />

asymptotic variance of the OLS estimator. This implies that 2SLS are <strong>in</strong>herently biased<br />

as their standard errors are larger than those from OLS. The magnitude of the standard<br />

errors of 2SLS depends on the quality of the IV used <strong>in</strong> estimation. Therefore, solv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the omitted variable bias always comes with the cost of efficiency.<br />

3.3.4 Instrumental Variables<br />

As stated before, appropriate <strong>in</strong>struments must satisfy two assumptions. Good<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments should be both valid and relevant, this is orthogonal to the errors and<br />

correlated with the endogenous covariate <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come (Baum et al., 2003). The<br />

orthogonality assumption can never be checked as the error term u is unobservable.<br />

However, if an equation is overidentified, we can test whether the <strong>in</strong>struments are<br />

uncorrelated with the error process. Roughly speak<strong>in</strong>g, we test whether the<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments are correlated with <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments or not. This is what is called<br />

<strong>in</strong>strumental exogeneity and can be tested through the overidentify<strong>in</strong>g restriction test.<br />

As we only can suggest <strong>in</strong>strumental exogeneity <strong>in</strong>stead of prov<strong>in</strong>g it, we must be sure<br />

that the <strong>in</strong>struments have strong theoretical grounds. The second assumption is often<br />

referred as the relevance of <strong>in</strong>struments and can be tested by the significance of the<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments <strong>in</strong> the first stage IV regression, the underidentification test and weak<br />

<strong>in</strong>strument identification test. Variation <strong>in</strong> relevant <strong>in</strong>struments causes variation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<br />

34


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come which is uncorrelated with the error term. Underidentification test is a test<br />

whether the regression is identified, mean<strong>in</strong>g correlated with the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, and<br />

is essentially a test of the full column rank of a matrix. Weak identification refers to<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments that are weakly correlated to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, caus<strong>in</strong>g estimators to<br />

perform poor (Wooldridge, 2002b; Baum, 2006). These tests will be discussed together<br />

with the results.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g appropriate <strong>in</strong>struments is not obvious. Ideally, a set of <strong>in</strong>struments or<br />

alternative sets of <strong>in</strong>struments should be used to avoid focus<strong>in</strong>g on a subpopulation<br />

(Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009). The best <strong>in</strong>struments are those that reflect push and pull<br />

factors driv<strong>in</strong>g households <strong>in</strong>to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities but have no direct impact on <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. Such factors could <strong>in</strong>clude distance to nearby a factory, literacy <strong>in</strong> English<br />

and so on. Dur<strong>in</strong>g the time of survey, not much attention was given to collect<br />

<strong>in</strong>formation related to push and pull variables. We therefore lack <strong>in</strong>formation about<br />

dist<strong>in</strong>ct push and pull factors, so alternative sets of <strong>in</strong>struments were not found. We<br />

were however able to construct one push and one pull variables that might serve as<br />

strong <strong>in</strong>struments.<br />

Our first <strong>in</strong>strument is the number of dependents <strong>in</strong> the household (dependents). This<br />

variable <strong>in</strong>cludes all children younger than 14 years and all elderly older than 65 years.<br />

It is assumed that these members of the household are no work<strong>in</strong>g forces at the time<br />

of survey. They must therefore be supported by the labor forces with<strong>in</strong> the household.<br />

Households are pushed <strong>in</strong>to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities because they must f<strong>in</strong>d means to<br />

ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> all their dependents. It is hypothesized that the number of dependent<br />

stimulate households to allocate labor forces to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities for additional<br />

<strong>in</strong>come and that it does not affect <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments directly. Its effect is <strong>in</strong>direct,<br />

through its effect on <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. However, it might be unrealistic to th<strong>in</strong>k that<br />

the number of dependents has no <strong>in</strong>fluence on <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g decisions <strong>in</strong> any way. The more<br />

dependent people <strong>in</strong> the family, the more effort that needs to be devoted to <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

and food production. The tests of <strong>in</strong>struments validity and weakness will decide<br />

whether the number of dependents is an appropriate <strong>in</strong>strument.<br />

The second <strong>in</strong>strument is the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come share <strong>in</strong> the total household <strong>in</strong>come at<br />

tabia level (<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong>share_tabia). This variable is calculated as the mean of the<br />

households‟ <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come share for each tabia. The latter is constructed by divid<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come by the total household <strong>in</strong>come for each household <strong>in</strong> the tabia.<br />

This <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come share is a proxy for the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment rate at the tabia<br />

level. It <strong>in</strong>dicates the households‟ potential to diversify their <strong>in</strong>come sources and to<br />

35


Chapter 3: Methodology<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease their <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come if they are will<strong>in</strong>g to do so. This variable can thus be<br />

used as an <strong>in</strong>dicator of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment opportunities and a predictor for <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come. The existence of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities on its turn is a proxy for the demand<br />

for <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> labor. We hypothesize that the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come share positively<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluences <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and has no direct effect on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. The fact that<br />

the <strong>in</strong>strument is def<strong>in</strong>ed at tabia level and we control for regional effects (through the<br />

distance to Mekelle) makes it unlikely that the <strong>in</strong>strument is correlated with other local<br />

factors that affect <strong>farm</strong> activities (Kilic et al., 2009).<br />

36


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

4 RESULTS AND DISCUSSION<br />

4.1 Descriptive statistics<br />

4.1.1 <strong>Farm</strong> expenditure, <strong>in</strong>put use and <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

Our data conta<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>formation about the value of households‟ <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

activities. As described <strong>in</strong> section 3.3, the latter consist of <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> durables as<br />

well as expenditures on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put. All <strong>in</strong>vestments are expressed <strong>in</strong> Ethiopian Birr 2<br />

(ETB). The total value of all <strong>in</strong>vestments made <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities is def<strong>in</strong>ed as the total<br />

<strong>farm</strong> expenditure and hence <strong>in</strong>cludes all money spent by households on durable<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use. Table 4.1 shows that the value of <strong>farm</strong> expenditures is<br />

on average 3,247 ETB. 96% of the households <strong>in</strong> the Geba catchment spends at least<br />

some money on <strong>farm</strong> expenditure and this value ranges from zero to 44,000 ETB. More<br />

importantly, Table 4.1 shows that <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> durables make up the major<br />

part (79%) and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use only a m<strong>in</strong>or part (21%) <strong>in</strong> the total <strong>farm</strong> expenditures.<br />

Table 4.1: Households’ total <strong>farm</strong> expenditures, <strong>in</strong>put use and <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> ETB<br />

Variable Mean Std. Dev. M<strong>in</strong> Max Share Access<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> expenditures 3,246.78 4,099.92 0 44,000 1.00 0.96<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use 693.56 580.47 0 3,684 0.21 0.90<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments 2,553.22 3,956.55 0 43,250 0.79 0.86<br />

Input use types<br />

Fertilizer 209.96 245.05 0 1,620 0.26 0.62<br />

Improved seeds 109.27 206.87 0 1,600 0.14 0.37<br />

Local seeds 361.29 346.78 0 2,634 0.57 0.88<br />

Other <strong>in</strong>puts 10.42 33.41 0 368 0.02 0.13<br />

Labor 2.62 7.95 0 87 0.01 0.18<br />

Investments types<br />

Water and Land 557.77 1,567.56 0 22,750 0.29 0.50<br />

Livestock 1,039.22 1,750.35 0 23,400 0.39 0.53<br />

Build<strong>in</strong>gs 718.94 2,470.19 0 31,000 0.15 0.22<br />

Equipment 237.29 873.47 0 15,950 0.17 0.59<br />

Notes: observations=733, shares calculated if value > 0 (<strong>in</strong>put use= 661 obs; <strong>in</strong>vestments= 663 obs)<br />

2 One ETB = 0,06397 € (National Bank of Ethiopia, http://www.nbe.gov.et, 08/06/2009)<br />

37


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

To get a view of the <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g system, households were asked about their usage of<br />

fertilizer, improved seeds, local seeds, other <strong>in</strong>puts and labor usage. 86% of the<br />

households has used any of these <strong>in</strong>puts dur<strong>in</strong>g the last production season. The total<br />

value of the agricultural <strong>in</strong>put use is on average 694 ETB, with a maximum amount of<br />

3,684 ETB. Almost n<strong>in</strong>e out of ten households has access to local seeds which makes<br />

up the biggest part of their spend<strong>in</strong>g (361 ETB). Out of the total sample households,<br />

62% of them has used some fertilizers on their fields, which on average has a value of<br />

210 ETB. One on three households has used improved seeds dur<strong>in</strong>g the last production<br />

season, with an estimated value of only 110 ETB on average. 13% of the households<br />

has used other <strong>in</strong>puts, but the value of these <strong>in</strong>puts is low (10 ETB). Also the use of<br />

<strong>farm</strong> labor seems to be rather low, only 18% of the households has actually spent<br />

some money on labor dur<strong>in</strong>g the last production season. The local seeds have the<br />

highest share <strong>in</strong> total <strong>in</strong>put use (57%), followed by fertilizer(26%) and improved seeds<br />

(14%). The contribution of both labor and other <strong>in</strong>puts is very small, respectively 1%<br />

and 2%. As we expected, the values of the fertilizer and improved seeds used by<br />

households are low and <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use is restricted. Households may<br />

hence face liquidity problems to buy <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts and rely on local seeds.<br />

Other studies have found that household <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use is rather low <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia.<br />

Pender et al. (2006) f<strong>in</strong>d that households‟ <strong>in</strong> Tigray on average cover only 27% and 2%<br />

of their plots with respectively fertilizer and improved seeds. The total use of seeds<br />

amounts to 118 kg/ha. Dercon and Christiaensen (2010) report that on average 22% of<br />

the households use fertilizer <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia. They note that fertilizer use <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia has<br />

rema<strong>in</strong>ed limited because of limited knowledge and education, risk preferences, credit<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts, low profitability of fertilizer use, lack of market access as well as limited or<br />

untimely availability of <strong>in</strong>puts. The low use of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put is <strong>in</strong> contradiction with the<br />

efforts done by the government <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia to promote the adoption of modern varieties<br />

and accompany<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>in</strong> order to boost productivity. The Ethiopian government<br />

supports two hold<strong>in</strong>g companies who control the market for fertilizer. In addition, spot<br />

markets are very th<strong>in</strong>. Fertilizer use is heavy promoted by the government extension<br />

and credit program (Pender et al., 2006; Dercon and Christiaensen, 2010).<br />

Herweg (1993), as cited by Pender et al. (2006), notes that fertilizer use is more risky<br />

and less profitable <strong>in</strong> low-ra<strong>in</strong>fall areas due to the fact that the uptake of nutrients may<br />

be limited by <strong>in</strong>adequate soil moisture. Contrary, adoption of soil and water<br />

conservation measures might be less risky and more profitable here because they have<br />

a larger impact on yields <strong>in</strong> the short term. Also Ehui and Pender (2005) and Pender<br />

(2004) state that <strong>in</strong> areas with lower agricultural potential, <strong>in</strong>tensification of <strong>agriculture</strong><br />

38


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

through fertilizer use and improved seed use is more limited. Investments <strong>in</strong> irrigation,<br />

water harvest<strong>in</strong>g or water and soil conservations to overcome soil moisture constra<strong>in</strong>ts<br />

have more potential.<br />

Table 4.1 describes the value of expenditures for households‟ <strong>in</strong>vestment on durables<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g the last production season. We see that 86% of households <strong>in</strong> the Geba<br />

catchment makes <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments of any k<strong>in</strong>d, and spends on average 2,553 ETB on<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. Follow<strong>in</strong>g Table 4.1, the households‟ <strong>in</strong>vestments can be divided <strong>in</strong><br />

four big groups. First, households make <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> water and land which <strong>in</strong>clude<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> terrac<strong>in</strong>g, water pond, water well and water diversion projects. At least<br />

half of the households spends some money on these <strong>in</strong>vestments, with an average<br />

amount spent represent<strong>in</strong>g 558 ETB. Second, <strong>in</strong>vestments are made <strong>in</strong> the households‟<br />

livestock resources. More than half of the households has made at least some<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> cows, oxen, sheep and goats, poultry and/or equ<strong>in</strong>e (donkey, horse and<br />

mule). Households spend on average 1,039 ETB on animal related <strong>in</strong>vestment. Third,<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> build<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong>clude <strong>in</strong>vestments or renovation <strong>in</strong> respectively new and old<br />

houses for both human and animal purpose. Only one out of five of the households<br />

spends money on their hous<strong>in</strong>g and <strong>in</strong>vests on average 719 ETB. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong><br />

treadle pump, generator, plow, axe and spade and beehive and bees are collected <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> equipments. 59% of the households spends money on equipment, which<br />

represents an average value of 237 ETB. Table 4.1 concludes that the share of livestock<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> the total households‟ <strong>in</strong>vestments (39%) is the highest, followed by the<br />

share of <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> water and land (29%). The shares of <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> build<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

and equipment are lower, both close to 15%.<br />

4.1.2 <strong>Farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

Table 4.2 summarizes the different <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities undertaken by<br />

households <strong>in</strong> the Geba catchment. Of the total 734 households, one household has<br />

reported to have no <strong>in</strong>come of any k<strong>in</strong>d, and is therefore excluded from our analysis.<br />

The total household <strong>in</strong>come is on average 8,301 ETB ranges from 315 ETB up to<br />

213,425 ETB. 97% of the households <strong>in</strong> the survey has access to <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, which is<br />

the major share of the households‟ <strong>in</strong>come (65%). <strong>Farm</strong> activities refer to the<br />

production or gather<strong>in</strong>g of unprocessed crops, livestock, forest or fish products from<br />

natural resources (Barrett et al., 2001). <strong>Farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come can be broken down <strong>in</strong>to crop<br />

<strong>in</strong>come and livestock <strong>in</strong>come. Crop <strong>in</strong>come is derived from sell<strong>in</strong>g crops dur<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

three different seasons (Kiremt, Belg and Irrigation). Households cultivate different<br />

39


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

crops, ma<strong>in</strong>ly teff, barley, wheat, maize and sorghum. Livestock <strong>in</strong>come is generated<br />

from sell<strong>in</strong>g livestock such as oxen, cows, heifers, calves, sheep, goats, horses, camels,<br />

mules, donkeys, beehives and poultry.<br />

Table 4.2: Households' <strong>in</strong>come composition <strong>in</strong> ETB<br />

Income Obs Mean Std. Dev. M<strong>in</strong> Max Share Access<br />

Total 733 8,302.58 10,841.39 315 213,425 1.00 1.00<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> 733 5,639.93 6,273.28 0 67,410 0.65 0.97<br />

Crop 733 4,883.96 6,025.16 0 67,200 0.55 0.94<br />

Livestock 733 755.97 1,181.34 0 13,877 0.10 0.66<br />

Non-<strong>Farm</strong> 733 1,873.39 4,358.04 0 97,000 0.27 0.80<br />

Wage 733 1,439.41 3,316.94 0 80,000 0.22 0.74<br />

Bus<strong>in</strong>ess 733 433.98 2,070.61 0 44,000 0.05 0.22<br />

Transfer 731 596.41 7,427.93 0 200,000 0.06 0.29<br />

Migration 730 190.84 821.21 0 10,500 0.02 0.13<br />

Note: miss<strong>in</strong>g values are <strong>in</strong>terpreted as zeros <strong>in</strong> the calculation of <strong>in</strong>come shares<br />

Table 4.2 describes the different types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities available <strong>in</strong> the dataset.<br />

Non-<strong>farm</strong> activities are def<strong>in</strong>ed as the opposite of <strong>farm</strong> activities: all activities<br />

undertaken by rural households that are not related with agricultural production on the<br />

<strong>farm</strong> (Barrett et al., 2001). Dist<strong>in</strong>ction is made based on the nature of the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. First, dist<strong>in</strong>ction is made between labor and <strong>non</strong>-labor <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

This dist<strong>in</strong>ction is crucial because <strong>non</strong>-labor activities do not have an impact on the<br />

labor availability of the <strong>farm</strong> household, and thus require no <strong>farm</strong> labor <strong>in</strong>put. The <strong>non</strong>labor<br />

activities are present <strong>in</strong> the form of transfers from governments, ngo‟s (food aid,<br />

cash or <strong>in</strong> k<strong>in</strong>d), friends or relatives. 29% of the households has access to transfer<br />

<strong>in</strong>come which is on average 596 ETB. It only has a m<strong>in</strong>or share <strong>in</strong> the total household<br />

<strong>in</strong>come (6%).<br />

Labor <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities can be further divided <strong>in</strong>to self-employment, wage activities<br />

and migration. Self-employment (or bus<strong>in</strong>ess) activities <strong>in</strong>clude any activities run and<br />

owned by the household located <strong>in</strong> their home or nearby towns. Self-employment<br />

activities <strong>in</strong>clude weav<strong>in</strong>g, mill<strong>in</strong>g, handicraft, trade <strong>in</strong> gra<strong>in</strong>, trade <strong>in</strong> livestock,<br />

traditional healer (or religious teacher), transport by pack animal, sell<strong>in</strong>g cactus, sell<strong>in</strong>g<br />

wood and charcoal, sell<strong>in</strong>g food and/or dr<strong>in</strong>ks and others. Wage activities <strong>in</strong>clude all<br />

types of agricultural and <strong>non</strong>-agricultural wage employment such as <strong>farm</strong> worker,<br />

traditional labor shar<strong>in</strong>g, professional (teacher, government worker, adm<strong>in</strong>istration,<br />

health worker, clerical), skilled laborer (builder, thatcher, barber), trader, soldier,<br />

40


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

driver/mechanic, unskilled worker, domestic servant, food for work and others.<br />

Migration remittance is the <strong>in</strong>come sent back or brought back by a migrant labor<br />

members liv<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> other parts of Ethiopia or <strong>in</strong> foreign countries. Migratory refers to<br />

domestic urban and foreign activities and therefore does not come to terms with rural<br />

activities.<br />

Several authors (Dercon, 1998; Barrett et al., 2001; Woldenhanna and Oskam, 2001;<br />

Maertens, 2009) stress the importance to make a dist<strong>in</strong>ction between the different <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. Dercon (1998) states that it is <strong>in</strong>correct to treat all <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

as the same, because possible entry and returns are likely to be different. The nature,<br />

structure and <strong>in</strong>put requirements for <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities are different and pose different<br />

demands on the household asset base. Non-<strong>farm</strong> self employment requires more<br />

capital and skills than wage employment. If credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts occur, the participation <strong>in</strong><br />

wage employment will be easier than <strong>in</strong> self employment. Wage employment is more<br />

likely to be available <strong>in</strong> areas near to towns and commercialized <strong>agriculture</strong>. <strong>Farm</strong><br />

households can participate <strong>in</strong> petty trade activities <strong>in</strong> areas far from urban centers.<br />

Contrary, near to urban areas, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment may face serious competition<br />

(Dercon, 1998; Woldenhanna, 2000).<br />

Table 4.2 shows that the majority (80%) of the sample households earns <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come. Hence, four out of five households has a member who is active <strong>in</strong> a <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activity of any k<strong>in</strong>d. Although <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities have a lower share <strong>in</strong> the total<br />

household <strong>in</strong>come than <strong>farm</strong> activities, their contribution is far from marg<strong>in</strong>al (27%).<br />

Non-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is ma<strong>in</strong>ly ga<strong>in</strong>ed from participation <strong>in</strong> wage activities (72%) while<br />

only one on five households are engaged <strong>in</strong> self-employment activities. The mean<br />

<strong>in</strong>come generated from wage activities is also higher than the <strong>in</strong>come derived from<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess activities, respectively 1,439 ETB and 434 ETB. It seems as if wage <strong>in</strong>come<br />

activities are easy accessible for the households and also have a higher payoff <strong>in</strong> the<br />

Geba catchment. This is <strong>in</strong> contrast with the conventional idea that self-employment<br />

activities offer a higher <strong>in</strong>come than wage activities. Only 13% of the households has<br />

access to migration <strong>in</strong>come which has only a share of 2% <strong>in</strong> the total household<br />

<strong>in</strong>come. The average amount of money sent back to the household by migrant<br />

members is on average 191 ETB. These numbers are <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of<br />

Woldenhanna and Oskam (2001) and Woldenhanna (2002) <strong>in</strong> Tigray.<br />

The survey conta<strong>in</strong>s specific <strong>in</strong>formation about wage and self-employment activities.<br />

The household head and his or her spouse were <strong>in</strong>quired after the nature of their <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

jobs. We constructed the participation of households <strong>in</strong> the different types of self-<br />

41


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

employment, based on the mean total days worked by the household head and his/her<br />

spouse on the specific type of bus<strong>in</strong>ess activity, because there was no other <strong>in</strong>formation<br />

available. Table 4.3 shows that households worked most of the days on trade (general<br />

and livestock), handicraft and others. As Woldenhanna (2000) notes, <strong>farm</strong> households<br />

need to <strong>in</strong>vest some level of work<strong>in</strong>g capital to get started <strong>in</strong> self-employment activities<br />

such as petty trade, handicraft, etc.<br />

Table 4.3: The nature of wage and self-employment jobs<br />

Percentage of total amount wage<br />

employment jobs<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> worker 7.22<br />

Trad. labor shar<strong>in</strong>g<br />

1.71<br />

Professional<br />

0.01<br />

Laborer<br />

5.12<br />

Trader<br />

2.62<br />

Soldier<br />

0<br />

Driver/mechanic<br />

0<br />

Unskilled worker<br />

18.18<br />

Domestic servant<br />

60.09<br />

Food for work<br />

3.41<br />

Percentage of total amount of selfemployment<br />

jobs<br />

Weav<strong>in</strong>g 2.90<br />

Mill<strong>in</strong>g<br />

6.47<br />

Handicraft<br />

10.42<br />

General trade<br />

21.86<br />

Livestock trade<br />

11.78<br />

Trad. healer/rel. teacher<br />

2.36<br />

Transport<br />

0.87<br />

Sell<strong>in</strong>g cactus<br />

4.05<br />

Sell<strong>in</strong>g wood<br />

1.40<br />

Sell<strong>in</strong>g food<br />

10.57<br />

others<br />

27.32<br />

In total, 762 wage jobs are performed by the household head an his or her spouse.<br />

Table 4.3 describes the contribution of each type of wage employment <strong>in</strong> the total<br />

amount of wage jobs. „Food for work‟ is the most important wage employment, which is<br />

clearly the dom<strong>in</strong>ant wage job (60%). Food for work is followed by unskilled work<br />

(18%) and <strong>farm</strong> work (7%). Household members participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> wage employment<br />

were also asked if they needed qualification, experience or educational tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g to get<br />

the wage job. The responses are reported <strong>in</strong> Table 4.4. It is clear that more than half of<br />

the wage employments did not need any qualification or tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. If such th<strong>in</strong>g was<br />

required, experiences seemed the most appropriate. Next to this, Table 4.4 shows that<br />

most wage employment are of temporary nature. Baumeister (1996) cited by Ruben &<br />

van den Berg (2001) notes that permanent wage labor is ma<strong>in</strong>ly engaged by landless<br />

<strong>farm</strong>ers, while small <strong>farm</strong>ers will seek temporary employment dur<strong>in</strong>g the off-season on<br />

other <strong>farm</strong>s <strong>in</strong> their neighborhood.<br />

42


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

Table 4.4: Wage employment requirements and duration (<strong>in</strong> percentages)<br />

Does the job require qualification, experience or educational tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g?<br />

Experience only 24.15<br />

Tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g only 10.37<br />

Qualification/tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g only 0.78<br />

Noth<strong>in</strong>g 64.70<br />

Temporary or permanent work?*<br />

Permanent 9.82<br />

Temporary 90.18<br />

Note*: <strong>in</strong>formation on the duration of the wage employment was miss<strong>in</strong>g for 39 of the <strong>in</strong> total 762 wage-jobs<br />

Woldenhanna (2000) f<strong>in</strong>ds very similar results <strong>in</strong> Tigray. Food for work is the dom<strong>in</strong>ant<br />

wage type because it does not require experience, skill and <strong>in</strong>itial capital <strong>in</strong>vestment. It<br />

wage rate is however the lowest of all types of wage employment. Poorer households<br />

are given priority when there are not enough jobs <strong>in</strong> the program. Unskilled wage<br />

employment requires some purchase of equipment and although experience and skill<br />

are not required, households spend a lot of time <strong>in</strong> f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g such a job. Skilled wage jobs<br />

require the most <strong>in</strong>vestments, skills and experience, but the wage rate is the highest.<br />

Ehui and Pender (2005) f<strong>in</strong>d that dur<strong>in</strong>g 1998-1998 food for work projects accounted<br />

for 40% of the average <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and more than 10% of the average total<br />

household <strong>in</strong>come. Households that participate <strong>in</strong> such projects also earn higher<br />

<strong>in</strong>comes than other households (Pender et al., 2006).<br />

Next to this, Woldenhanna (2002) states that most <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work <strong>in</strong> Tigray is of<br />

temporary nature and does not require skilled labor. As Woldenhanna and Oskam<br />

(2001) po<strong>in</strong>t out, most <strong>farm</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> Tigray have difficulties with acquir<strong>in</strong>g skills, startup<br />

capital and jobs <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Until 1998, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> workers had to obta<strong>in</strong> their<br />

skills and experience without tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and could only acquire them dur<strong>in</strong>g employment.<br />

There are no schools for build<strong>in</strong>g, carpentry or other technical tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g, except some<br />

limited tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g given by the Tigray Development Agency (TDA). The only organization<br />

which provides credit to small <strong>farm</strong>ers is the Relief Society of Tigray (REST). Access to<br />

jobs <strong>in</strong> urban areas is only possible after a long process of search<strong>in</strong>g, via relatives and<br />

family.<br />

In summary the descriptive statistics show that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is an important part<br />

of the total household <strong>in</strong>come and is accessible for most households <strong>in</strong> the survey. In<br />

addition, some <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>formation about the attitude of the households towards the<br />

RNFE is available. Table 4.5 describes the attitude towards additional <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work.<br />

43


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

Three quarter of the households has a member will<strong>in</strong>g to work for additional wage if a<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> job would be offered to that member. Even 40% of the households has<br />

reported to have a household member that is will<strong>in</strong>g to work dur<strong>in</strong>g plant<strong>in</strong>g, weed<strong>in</strong>g,<br />

harvest<strong>in</strong>g or thresh<strong>in</strong>g season. Table 4.5 shows that <strong>agriculture</strong> is unable to absorb all<br />

the available household labor and could <strong>in</strong>dicate that households have a positive<br />

attitude towards <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and are will<strong>in</strong>g to work more <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> if they<br />

would have the opportunity. Similar, Woldenhanna and Oskam (2001) f<strong>in</strong>d that 66% of<br />

the <strong>farm</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> their sample did not work more hours <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities because<br />

they could not get <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment. They suggest that this response <strong>in</strong>dicates the<br />

fact that not all available labor could be allocated to <strong>agriculture</strong>.<br />

Table 4.5: Attitude towards additional <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment<br />

Attitude towards Mean Std. Dev. M<strong>in</strong> Max<br />

additional <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work 0.75 0.43 0 1<br />

work for wages dur<strong>in</strong>g plant<strong>in</strong>g weed<strong>in</strong>g harvest<strong>in</strong>g<br />

and thresh<strong>in</strong>g<br />

0.40 0.49 0 1<br />

Note: observations=733<br />

4.1.3 Households with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come vs. households without <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come<br />

Table 4.6 describes the differences <strong>in</strong> characteristics between households that have<br />

access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and those that do not. The mean difference between these<br />

two groups is calculated and we will check if this difference is significant us<strong>in</strong>g a t-test 3 .<br />

As 80% of the households has access to the RNFE (Table 4.2), we can see that 150<br />

households do not participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities, while 583 households do.<br />

Households with access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities have on average a significant lower total<br />

household <strong>in</strong>come (8,035 ETB vs. 9,344 ETB), <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come (5,170 ETB vs. 7,470 ETB)<br />

and households‟ resources. Households with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come have lower landhold<strong>in</strong>gs,<br />

number of animals and fixed assets than households that do not participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. It seems as if the participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities is not conditioned by the<br />

households‟ resource base. This could <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities are especially<br />

important for less endowed households.<br />

3 Although the normality assumption for most variables is violated, the t-statistic has approximately a t<br />

distributions, at least <strong>in</strong> large sample sizes (Wooldridge 2000b)<br />

44


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

Table 4.6: Comparison of households with and without access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

Variable Mean (150 obs) Mean (583 obs) Mean difference<br />

Income<br />

Only <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come=0<br />

Non-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come > 0<br />

Total household 9,344.16 8,034.59 1,309.57 *<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> 7,469.99 5,169.08 2,300.91 ***<br />

Fm1age 52.34 41.77 10.57 ***<br />

Fm1sex 0.77 0.73 0.04<br />

Fm1schooled 0.27 0.39 - 0.12 ***<br />

hhlandholdsize 5.23 4.17 1.06 ***<br />

animalasset 8,060.20 5,921.62 2,138.58 ***<br />

fixedasset 21,695.56 11,086.02 10,609.55 **<br />

tabiadismak 66.58 71.13 -4.55**<br />

edirm 0.24 0.23 0.01<br />

havei 0.26 0.21 0.05 *<br />

adults 3.03 2.91 0.12<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> expenditures 3,278.70 3,238.57 40.13<br />

Investments<br />

Total 2,391.77 2,594.76 -202.99<br />

Water and Land 829.55 487.84 341.72<br />

Livestock 911.31 1,072.13 -160.83<br />

Build<strong>in</strong>gs 360.83 811.08 -450.25**<br />

Equipment 290.08 223.71 66.37<br />

<strong>Farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use 886.93 643.81 243.12<br />

Fertilizer 285.27 190.58 94.68 ***<br />

Improved seeds 165.56 94.78 70.78 ***<br />

Local seeds 423.34 345.33 78.01 **<br />

Other <strong>in</strong>puts 8.07 11.03 -2.96<br />

Labor 4.70 2.09 2.67 ***<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%<br />

Households with access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come tend to have a family head that is almost<br />

10 years younger than those <strong>in</strong> households not hav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> earn<strong>in</strong>gs. This<br />

difference is significant at the level of one percent. This <strong>in</strong>dicates that households with<br />

younger heads are more likely to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. The contrary is true<br />

for education, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities require more education or skills.<br />

Remarkable is that the gender of the household head, the households‟ edir membership<br />

and the number of work<strong>in</strong>g forces do not vary much between the two groups and these<br />

differences are <strong>in</strong>significant. Households with access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come live significant<br />

further away from the regional capital city, which is however doubtful as <strong>in</strong>tegration <strong>in</strong><br />

45


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

markets is lower. Households without <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come are more likely to have access<br />

to irrigation.<br />

More <strong>in</strong>terest<strong>in</strong>g is, as shown <strong>in</strong> Table 4.6, that <strong>farm</strong> expenditures differ <strong>in</strong>significantly<br />

between the two groups. Households that have access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come spend on<br />

average more on total <strong>in</strong>vestments. However, this difference is also <strong>in</strong>significant. The<br />

picture is somewhat different if we divide the <strong>in</strong>vestments accord<strong>in</strong>g to their nature. On<br />

the one hand, households with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>vest more <strong>in</strong> livestock and build<strong>in</strong>gs,<br />

of which only the latter is significant. On the other hand, households without access to<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>vest more <strong>in</strong> water and land and equipment of which only the<br />

former is significant. <strong>Farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use is higher for households that do not have access to<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, then dose with access. The same can be said for the value of<br />

fertilizer, improved seeds, local seeds and labor use. All these difference are significant.<br />

Only the value of other <strong>in</strong>puts is higher for households who participate <strong>in</strong> RNFE, but this<br />

difference is <strong>in</strong>significant. So based on the descriptive statistics, some <strong>in</strong>dications about<br />

the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments can be made. We will however<br />

analyze this impact more detailed through empirical analysis.<br />

4.1.4 Control and <strong>in</strong>strumental variables<br />

In addition to <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>in</strong>vestments, several <strong>in</strong>dividual and household characteristics<br />

are used <strong>in</strong> the empirical estimation. These variables <strong>in</strong>clude a set of <strong>in</strong>dividual,<br />

household and regional characteristics, as summarized <strong>in</strong> Table 4.7. The <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

variables refer to the characteristics of the household head (fm1) and <strong>in</strong>clude gender<br />

(fm1sex), age (fm1age), school<strong>in</strong>g (fm1schooled) and educational level (fm1leveled).<br />

Table 4.7 shows that on average 73% of the household heads is male and they have<br />

an average age of almost 44 years. Only one on three household heads has had some<br />

form of education. In case of some education, they f<strong>in</strong>ished on average at least primary<br />

school. So, most households <strong>in</strong> the Geba catchment are headed by a male of middle<br />

age who acquired limited education.<br />

Among the household characteristics we dist<strong>in</strong>guish households‟ wealth, membership <strong>in</strong><br />

social capital, access to irrigation and the number of adult labor forces. The households‟<br />

wealth is measured by the households‟ resources of land (hhlandholdsize), livestock<br />

(animalasset) and fixed assets (fixedasset). The households‟ resource base <strong>in</strong>fluences<br />

the ability of the households to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>vestments and to obta<strong>in</strong> credit. The land<br />

46


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

accessible to households <strong>in</strong> the Geba catchment is on average 4.4 Tsimidi 4 (1.1 ha) and<br />

is measured as the total plot size of the plots owned by the households. This illustrates<br />

that most <strong>farm</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> the Geba catchment are <strong>smallholder</strong>s.<br />

Table 4.7: Summary statistics of <strong>in</strong>dividual and household characteristics<br />

Variable Obs Mean Std. Dev. M<strong>in</strong> Max<br />

fm1sex 733 0.73 0.44 0 1<br />

fm1age 733 43.93 14.61 16 87<br />

fm1schooled 733 0.37 0.48 0 1<br />

fm1leveled 268 2.42 1.37 1 12<br />

hhlandholdsize 733 4.38 3.37 0 23<br />

animalasset 733 6,359.25 8,131.34 0 111,900<br />

fixed 733 13,257.14 50,790.70 22 1,201,296<br />

adults 733 2.93 1.55 0 10<br />

tabiadismak 733 70.20 29.68 42 120<br />

edirm 733 0.23 0.42 0 1<br />

haves 733 0.11 0.32 0 1<br />

takenloan1000 733 0.50 0.50 0 1<br />

havei 733 0.22 0.41 0 1<br />

The average value of the livestock owned by the households is almost 6,359 ETB and is<br />

measured as the sum of the number of each animal multiplied by the value of that type<br />

of animal. The animal types taken <strong>in</strong>to consideration are oxen, cows, heifers, calves,<br />

sheep, goats, horses, camels, mules, donkeys, beehives and poultry. The households‟<br />

fixed asset is on average nearly 11,612 ETB and <strong>in</strong>cludes furniture and households‟<br />

durable, agricultural equipment, electronics, valuables and hous<strong>in</strong>g equipment. To<br />

avoid simultaneity bias between households‟ wealth <strong>in</strong>dicators and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong><br />

the empirical estimation, we def<strong>in</strong>e new variables for animal („livestock‟) and fixed<br />

assets („fixed‟) <strong>in</strong> which all types of respectively animals and fixed assets on which<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong>formation is available are excluded.<br />

Households have on average almost three adult labor forces available and it can take<br />

up to maximum 10 persons. Almost one out of four households is member of edir,<br />

resembl<strong>in</strong>g the social capital of the household. Edir, <strong>in</strong> the context of rural and<br />

specifically the research site, is def<strong>in</strong>ed by Kidane (undated) as a community–based<br />

4 1 Tsimid = 1/4 of an hectare<br />

47


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

<strong>in</strong>stitution established on mutual <strong>in</strong>terest of members. Its primary objective is to<br />

support members dur<strong>in</strong>g the time of crises, such as death of family members. Social<br />

capital is an <strong>in</strong>dicator for <strong>farm</strong>er networks and access to (better) <strong>in</strong>formation. One out<br />

of five households <strong>in</strong> our sample has access to irrigation, which is highly important <strong>in</strong><br />

smallscale <strong>agriculture</strong>. This number is higher than the 5.7% reported by Woldenhanna<br />

(2002). The distance to the regional capital city Mekelle (tabiadismak) is <strong>in</strong>cluded as<br />

regional variable, and is on average 70 km. Distance is an important factor determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

the access to the RNFE sector and markets. This variable captures many area specific<br />

characteristics like population density, land size and various agro-climatic features.<br />

Next to this, households were asked if they had access to sav<strong>in</strong>gs and if they have<br />

taken up loan <strong>in</strong> the last five years. On average only 11% of the households had<br />

sav<strong>in</strong>gs dur<strong>in</strong>g the last production season, while 50% has ever taken out a loan of at<br />

least 100 ETB. These rather low responses could <strong>in</strong>dicate the existence and importance<br />

of liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts. Information about credit and sav<strong>in</strong>gs is endogenous to both<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and these variables are therefore excluded<br />

from the empirical analysis. F<strong>in</strong>ally, Table 4.8 reports the descriptive statistics of the<br />

two variables used to <strong>in</strong>strument <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. It can be seen that households on<br />

average have more than two dependent members <strong>in</strong> the household, and this number<br />

can range from zero to seven people. The <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> share <strong>in</strong> the tabia is on average<br />

26%, which <strong>in</strong>dicates that on average and on the tabia level, the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment<br />

rate is slightly higher than 25%.<br />

Table 4.8: Summery statistics of the <strong>in</strong>struments used <strong>in</strong> the 2SLS<br />

Instruments Mean Std. Dev. M<strong>in</strong> Max<br />

dependent 2.35 1.49 0 7<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong>share_tabia 26.40 10.21 15.04 42.03<br />

Note: observations=733<br />

48


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

4.2 Multivariate analysis<br />

The empirical analysis was conducted us<strong>in</strong>g the statistical software package STATA11.<br />

We ran a two-stage least squares regresses on equation eq. 1 us<strong>in</strong>g an <strong>in</strong>strumental<br />

variable estimator, as outl<strong>in</strong>ed above. In stata11, the IVREG2 command will be used to<br />

obta<strong>in</strong> an 2SLS estimation. We will first discuss the first stage and afterwards the<br />

second stage. The former is necessary to check the relevance, significance and strength<br />

of our <strong>in</strong>struments. Our ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest lied <strong>in</strong> the second stage, and more specifically <strong>in</strong><br />

the sign and significance of the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. We<br />

compared the 2SLS estimation with the OLS estimation to check the direction of the<br />

omitted variable bias.<br />

After runn<strong>in</strong>g the regression <strong>in</strong> STATA11, the homoskedasticity 5 assumption of our<br />

regression was checked. Homoskedasticity means that the variance of the error term is<br />

constant, conditional on the explanatory variables. It assumes that the error terms are<br />

<strong>in</strong>dependently and identically distributed. If the homoskedasticity assumption is not<br />

valid (this is <strong>non</strong>-constant variance), we speak of heteroskedasticity (Wooldridge<br />

2002b). It is important to assume homoskedasticity, as it is needed to justify the usual<br />

statistical test (Baum et al., 2003). Moreover, Wooldridge (2000b) states that if<br />

heteroskedasticity is suspected, the reported standard errors <strong>in</strong> the estimation are<br />

<strong>in</strong>valid and corrective action should be taken. We tested for homoskedasticity us<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

Pagan-Hall general test statistic. This statistic <strong>in</strong>volves regression of the squared OLS<br />

residuals on the <strong>in</strong>dependent variables (Wooldridge, 2002b). The null hypothesis, that<br />

the disturbance is homoskedastic, was strongly rejected, reveal<strong>in</strong>g the presence of<br />

(arbitrary) heteroskedasticity.<br />

The problem of heteroskedasticity can partially be addressed through the use of<br />

heteroskedasticity-consistent (or robust) standard errors and statistics. The<br />

conventional IV estimator is consistent but not efficient <strong>in</strong> the presence of<br />

heteroskedasticity (Baum et al., 2003). As a consequence, we used the two-step<br />

feasible generalized method of moments (2-Step GMM) estimator to get efficient<br />

estimates of the coefficients and consistent estimates of the standard errors (Baum,<br />

2006; Baum et al., 2003). The generalized method of moments (GMM) estimator of the<br />

coefficients <strong>in</strong> equation eq. 1 is based on the moment or orthogonality conditions. The<br />

5 Homoskedasticity assumes that the error terms are <strong>in</strong>dependently and identically distributed<br />

49


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

advantage of the GMM is that it does not require the distribution of the data to be fully<br />

known, unlike the maximum likelihood estimation. The disadvantage of the use of GMM<br />

is the poor small sample properties (Baum et al., 2003).<br />

4.2.1 First Stage Results<br />

The first stage of the 2SLS model is a simple OLS regression of equation (2), whereby<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is regressed on the control variables and the IV. The OLS estimates<br />

with robust standard errors are reported <strong>in</strong> Table 4.9. The <strong>in</strong>terpretation of these OLS<br />

results must be done with much caution, because most literature analyz<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ants of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come use more specific models like Heckman or Cragg<br />

double hurdle model. These models try to deal with <strong>in</strong>cidental truncation of potential<br />

outcomes: <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come might not be observed because of the outcome of another<br />

latent variable. Households only have <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come if they participate <strong>in</strong> the RNFE<br />

sector. These models therefore consist of two parts: first the participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities is analyzed, and second for those who participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities, the<br />

level of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is analyzed. However, these models have been criticized<br />

because <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is an observed outcome: it is zero for households that do not<br />

have access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities (corner solution). Moreover, it is very difficult to<br />

meet the exclusion restriction (Hertz, 2009). Our ma<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest lies <strong>in</strong> the second stage<br />

of the 2SLS, and the first stage will only be used to <strong>in</strong>dicate which factors may<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come (and hence determ<strong>in</strong>e the access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities)<br />

and, more importantly, to evaluate the relevance of the <strong>in</strong>strumental variables.<br />

As can be seen from Table 4.9, most control variables do not seem to significantly<br />

<strong>in</strong>fluence <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. However, the age of the household head seems to have a<br />

significant and negative impact on <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. This seems to be odd, as it is<br />

expected that older people earn more <strong>in</strong>come, but this might illustrate the<br />

shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs of the OLS regression to determ<strong>in</strong>e <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come determ<strong>in</strong>ants.<br />

Because we were not able to separate the effect of the control variables on the<br />

participation and level of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, it is impossible to dist<strong>in</strong>guish the effect of<br />

the age of the household head on either participation <strong>in</strong> or the level of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come. It can however be assumed that younger household heads are more likely to<br />

participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities, and therefore age has a negative impact on <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come. Younger household heads might be less bounded to traditional agricultural<br />

activities. This is <strong>in</strong> agreement with the results found by Woldenhanna and Oskam<br />

(2001). The authors suggest population pressure to h<strong>in</strong>der younger <strong>farm</strong> households to<br />

50


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

get enough land to support their livelihood and they are therefore obliged to participate<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Non-<strong>farm</strong> activities also require more physical strength and<br />

effort, which is more likely to be done by younger <strong>in</strong>dividuals. Besides this, older<br />

household heads were historically prohibited to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities,<br />

mak<strong>in</strong>g them <strong>in</strong>experienced with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and more productive <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities.<br />

Table 4.9: First stage OLS regression results<br />

OLS<br />

Coef.<br />

Std. Err.<br />

fm1sex 0.3283 0.2759<br />

fm1age - 0.0673 *** 0.0088<br />

fm1schooled 0.0645 0.2328<br />

hhlandholdsize - 0.0667 0.0487<br />

livestock - 0.0667 * 0.0339<br />

fixed - 0.0094 0.0844<br />

tabiadismak 0.0073 0.0051<br />

edirm 0.2662 0.2709<br />

havei - 0.2565 0.2845<br />

adults 0.3218 *** 0.0815<br />

dependents 0.2201 *** 0.0751<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong>share_tabia 0.0674 *** 0.0121<br />

constant 5.2844 0.8467<br />

Jo<strong>in</strong>t significance of IV<br />

F test of excluded <strong>in</strong>struments 20.11***<br />

Angrist-Pischke multivariate F test of IV 20.11***<br />

Underidentification test<br />

Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic 35.41***<br />

Weak identification test<br />

Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic 19.39<br />

Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic 20.11<br />

Weak-<strong>in</strong>strument-robust <strong>in</strong>ference<br />

Anderson-Rub<strong>in</strong> Wald test 16.70***<br />

Stock-Wright LM S statistic 15.70***<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

The effect of both gender and education is positive, but not significant however. It is<br />

often hypothesized that an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> educated level lowers the <strong>in</strong>centive for <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities and encourages participation <strong>in</strong> (more remunerative) <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

51


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

(Corral and Reardon, 2001; De Janvry and Sadoulet, 2003). Van den Berg and Kumbi<br />

(2006) f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia, only formal and primary education significantly <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, while higher education seems to be irrelevant. We have tried to<br />

<strong>in</strong>corporate different dummies for education levels, but <strong>non</strong>e of them where statistically<br />

significant. This could be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the fact that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities are dom<strong>in</strong>ated<br />

by food for work and unskilled wage employment, which does not require much<br />

education or skills. Our results do not strongly suggest a gender bias, which is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e<br />

with the observations of van den Berg and Kumbi (2006). It seems as if the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

sector does not significantly consist of jobs that have higher returns to education nor<br />

does men have better access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

Surpris<strong>in</strong>gly, regional effects do not have a significant negative effect. We expected<br />

households that live further from the capital city to be less engaged <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities, because of fewer opportunities and more costs related with transport. Our<br />

results <strong>in</strong>dicate a positive effect, but the coefficient is statistically not different from<br />

zero. Membership <strong>in</strong> social capital does <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, but its impact is not<br />

significant. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the number of adult labor forces has a positive and very significant<br />

impact on the level of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. As we expected, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is positively<br />

related with the number of adults that are potential work<strong>in</strong>g forces <strong>in</strong> household. The<br />

latter could <strong>in</strong>dicate the availability of excess family labor that cannot be allocated on<br />

the <strong>farm</strong> and households are therefore obligated to look for <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

Moreover, Woldenhanna (2000) notes that larger family size decreases the marg<strong>in</strong>al<br />

value of households‟ consumption of leisure. Our f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>in</strong> accordance with the<br />

results of Ruben and van den Berg (2001), Woldenhanna and Oskam (2001), Matsche<br />

and Young (2004) and van den Berg and Kumbi (2006).<br />

The animal assets of the households also have a negative and statistically significant<br />

impact on <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. Aga<strong>in</strong>, it looks like households with a higher value of their<br />

livestock participate less <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and hence have lower <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

Hav<strong>in</strong>g more animals will probably <strong>in</strong>dicate that households are highly engaged <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities and livestock require <strong>in</strong>tensive care (Ruben and van den Berg, 2001). The<br />

impact of both the total plot size (as <strong>in</strong>dicator of <strong>farm</strong> size) and the total value of the<br />

fixed assets on the level of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is negative, but statistically not<br />

significantly different from zero. Overall, shortage of households‟ wealth <strong>in</strong>dicators can<br />

push <strong>farm</strong> households <strong>in</strong>to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities: <strong>farm</strong> households without land or with<br />

small <strong>farm</strong>s; and households with less fixed or animal assets seem to seek for<br />

additional <strong>in</strong>come by participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. Hav<strong>in</strong>g more assets could<br />

52


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease the returns to labor on the <strong>farm</strong> and work less off the <strong>farm</strong>. However, only the<br />

number of livestock has a significant impact.<br />

Another push factor could be the lack of access to irrigation, although not statistically<br />

significant. Non-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come might be important to set up an irrigation system.<br />

Another explanation could be that, because access to irrigation decreases <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come, households with irrigation systems spend more time on the <strong>farm</strong>. In<br />

conclusion, our results do not provide an <strong>in</strong>dication of the existence of entry barriers:<br />

better educated or endowed households do not earn more <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. This is<br />

consistent with the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of Ruben and van den Berg (2006) <strong>in</strong> Oromia, but <strong>in</strong><br />

contradiction with Block and Webb (2001) <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia and Woldenhanna and Oskam<br />

(2002) <strong>in</strong> Tigray.<br />

The requirement that <strong>in</strong>struments are correlated with the endogenous <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

can easily be tested by exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the fit of the first stage regression. Both <strong>in</strong>struments<br />

are positive and highly significant related with <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, which suggests the<br />

relevance of the <strong>in</strong>struments. The positive impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work opportunities is<br />

straightforward: hav<strong>in</strong>g better access to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities makes it more likely to<br />

participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and hence <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. The more<br />

dependents <strong>in</strong> a household (hence a larger household) <strong>in</strong>creases the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

This confirms our hypothesis that households with more members that need to be<br />

supported are more likely to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. As they are not potential<br />

work<strong>in</strong>g forces and therefore cannot significantly <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>farm</strong> productivity, the<br />

household will be „pushed‟ to look for additional <strong>in</strong>come sources. This f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e<br />

with Block and Webb (2001) who f<strong>in</strong>d a positive relation between participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

activities and the dependency ratio. Woldenhanna (2000) f<strong>in</strong>ds that the number of<br />

dependents affects <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> work decisions because larger family size <strong>in</strong>creases the<br />

availability of labor, reduces the marg<strong>in</strong>al utility of consumption and leisure.<br />

The <strong>in</strong>struments passed the test for jo<strong>in</strong>t significance of the <strong>in</strong>struments, as both the F-<br />

test for excluded <strong>in</strong>struments and the Angrist-Pischke multivariate F-test of excluded<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments were highly significant. They were both higher than the critical values 6<br />

developed by Stock-Yogo (2005) for s<strong>in</strong>gle endogenous regressor. This <strong>in</strong>dicates that<br />

these test values are high enough to reject the hypothesis that the weak <strong>in</strong>strument<br />

bias is greater than 10% of the magnitude of the endogeneity bias under OLS, at the 5<br />

6 Stock-Yogo weak ID test critical values for s<strong>in</strong>gle endogenous regressor at 10% maximal IV size is 19.93<br />

53


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

% level of significance. The Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic was used as<br />

underidentification test and is highly significant, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the relevance of our<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments. Also the weak identification tests (Cragg-Donald Wald F-statistic and<br />

Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F-statistic) were conducted to test whether the estimator is<br />

weakly identified: <strong>non</strong>-zero but small correlation between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and the two<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments. These statistics were higher than the critical values given by the Stock-<br />

Yogo weak ID test, reveal<strong>in</strong>g the strength of our <strong>in</strong>struments. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the Weak<strong>in</strong>strument-robust<br />

<strong>in</strong>ference test was used to test for the significance of the<br />

endogenous regressors <strong>in</strong> the structural equation be<strong>in</strong>g estimated. The test was also<br />

highly significant, reject<strong>in</strong>g the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the regressors <strong>in</strong><br />

the structural equation are jo<strong>in</strong>tly equal zero.<br />

4.2.2 Second Stage Results<br />

We began our empirical analysis with the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on total <strong>farm</strong><br />

expenditures. <strong>Farm</strong> expenditures <strong>in</strong>cluded all expenses on <strong>farm</strong> related activities. In the<br />

last two sections, we expanded our analysis to the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on two<br />

types of <strong>in</strong>vestments, and the results will be discussed separately. For each regression<br />

estimation, both OLS and 2SLS estimates are reported. Before we <strong>in</strong>terpret the<br />

regression estimates, an endogeneity test is performed to <strong>in</strong>dicate whether it is<br />

necessary to use an IV method or not. Us<strong>in</strong>g IV methods always comes with the price<br />

of efficiency loss. We are however will<strong>in</strong>g to pay this price if the OLS estimates are<br />

<strong>in</strong>consistent and biased. It is therefore useful to test the necessary of IV method and<br />

the appropriateness of the OLS estimation (Baum et al., 2003). As the conditional<br />

homoskedasticity is violated, we use the heteroskedasticity robust GMM distance<br />

endogeneity test 7 . This test is a variant of the Durb<strong>in</strong>-Wu-Hausman test of the<br />

endogeneity of regressors. Under the null hypothesis, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come can actually be<br />

treated as exogenous.<br />

7 The C statistic is computed as the difference between two J statistics: one us<strong>in</strong>g the unrestricted regression<br />

with the regressor be<strong>in</strong>g tested as endogenous (less efficient but consistent estimator) and one us<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

restricted regression with the regressor treated as exogenous (more efficient estimator) (Baum et al 2003)<br />

54


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

4.2.2.1 The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures<br />

Both OLS and 2SLS estimations of <strong>farm</strong> expenditures are reported <strong>in</strong> Table 4.10. Our<br />

results show that we fail to reject the null hypothesis that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is<br />

exogenous <strong>in</strong> the <strong>farm</strong> expenditure regression. As a consequence, it is not proven that<br />

the OLS estimates will yield <strong>in</strong>consistent estimates. Moreover, it implies that we do not<br />

have a statistical-based argument to prefer the IV method over the OLS regression.<br />

However, such endogeneity tests are restricted as they depend on the <strong>in</strong>struments<br />

used for <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. It is therefore difficult to conclude that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is<br />

actually endogenous based on these k<strong>in</strong>ds of endogeneity tests, and the test might only<br />

serve as an <strong>in</strong>dication of the presence of endogenous effects of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. We<br />

prefer to work with the IV estimation as the endogenous effects of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

have a strong theoretical background.<br />

With the gmm option, the overidentify<strong>in</strong>g condition can be tested by the Hansen J<br />

statistic. The null hypothesis is that the <strong>in</strong>struments are jo<strong>in</strong>tly valid, conditional on at<br />

least one be<strong>in</strong>g valid and that the excluded <strong>in</strong>struments are correctly excluded from the<br />

estimated equation. Rejection implies that the <strong>in</strong>struments do not satisfy the<br />

orthogonality assumption. This is plausible because either they are <strong>in</strong>correctly excluded<br />

from the regression or because they are not truly exogenous. We fail to reject the null<br />

hypothesis (p=0.15) which implies that the validity of the used <strong>in</strong>strument is not<br />

disproven. Interpretation of this statistic is however not straightforward. As Hertz<br />

(2009) has po<strong>in</strong>ted out, rejection of the null hypothesis could <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>non</strong>e, some<br />

or either all of the <strong>in</strong>struments are valid.<br />

Table 4.10 shows that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities have a positive and significant impact on<br />

<strong>farm</strong> expenditures. Non-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases the total expenditures households made<br />

on <strong>farm</strong> related activities <strong>in</strong> both the OLS and IV estimation. After comparison of the<br />

OLS and 2SLS models, we see that the coefficient of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the OLS<br />

estimation is five times lower than the coefficient of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the IV<br />

estimation (respectively 0.04 and 0.18). the IV method hence predicts that a<br />

percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> expenditures with 0.18% and<br />

this effect is significant at the one percent level. In the OLS estimation, the effect is<br />

only 0.04%. We see that the OLS underestimates the effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on<br />

<strong>farm</strong> expenditures. When potential factors that make <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come endogenous are<br />

removed, the effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> expenditure is even greater. As a<br />

result, fail<strong>in</strong>g to correct for the endogeneity of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come underestimates the<br />

impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on total <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g that the coefficient of<br />

55


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the OLS regression is downward biased. We assume that the<br />

downward bias is caused by omitted variables.<br />

Table 4.10: OLS and 2SLS estimations results of total <strong>farm</strong> expenditures<br />

OLS<br />

IVREG2<br />

Coef. Std. Err. Coef. Std. Err.<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>come 0.0365 * 0.0206 0.1792 * 0.0924<br />

fm1sex 1.1756 *** 0.1817 1.1586 *** 0.1831<br />

fm1age - 0.0043 0.0055 0.0049 0.0082<br />

fm1schooled 0.1685 0.1212 0.1639 0.1260<br />

hhlandholdsize 0.0546 *** 0.0197 0.0678 *** 0.0223<br />

livestock 0.0541 *** 0.0161 0.0655 *** 0.0170<br />

fixed 0.2103 *** 0.0552 0.1881 *** 0.0598<br />

tabiadismak - 0.0046 * 0.0025 -0.0055** 0.0025<br />

edirm 0.5918 *** 0.1227 0.5678 *** 0.1269<br />

havei 0.2737 ** 0.1350 0.3082 ** 0.1478<br />

adults 0.2621 *** 0.0437 0.2180 *** 0.0546<br />

constant 3.8269 *** 0.5361 2.8614 *** 0.8395<br />

Endogeneity test<br />

Endogeneity test of endogenous regressors 2.53<br />

Overidentification test<br />

Hansen J statistic 2.09<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

We describe the effect of <strong>in</strong>dividual and household characteristics on the amount spend<br />

on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures more detailed for <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> durables and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use<br />

separately. Some first <strong>in</strong>dications are given here. Of the household head characteristics<br />

it is surpris<strong>in</strong>g that only gender has a significant impact on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures. Male<br />

headed households are more likely to <strong>farm</strong> on a bigger scale and thus spend more<br />

money on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures. Both the age and school<strong>in</strong>g of household does not seem<br />

to have a significant impact on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures. All types of household wealth<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicators are positive and significant (at the one percent level) related with <strong>farm</strong><br />

expenditures. Hav<strong>in</strong>g more agricultural and fixed assets <strong>in</strong>creases the expenses on total<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

The distance to Mekelle is negative related with <strong>farm</strong> expenditures, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

importance of be<strong>in</strong>g close located to markets and the capital city. However, this effect<br />

56


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

is not so pronounced: every addition km that the household is located further from<br />

Mekelle decreases <strong>farm</strong> expenditure with 0.6%. As we expected, households with<br />

access to irrigation significant spend more money on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures than<br />

households that do not have access to irrigation. This result shows that more <strong>in</strong>puts are<br />

used and <strong>in</strong>vestments are required if households have an irrigation system on their<br />

<strong>farm</strong>. Also membership <strong>in</strong> edir enhances the <strong>farm</strong> expenditures, which underl<strong>in</strong>es the<br />

importance of social capital. This effect is the strongest (except for gender): be<strong>in</strong>g<br />

member <strong>in</strong> edir <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments by 57% and this effect is highly significant<br />

at the one percent level. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the number of adult labor forces <strong>in</strong> the household has<br />

a positive impact on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures and this effect is highly significant. When<br />

households have more members that could participate <strong>in</strong> labor markets, they are able<br />

to spend more on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures.<br />

4.2.2.2 The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on durables <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

We turn now to the effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on the money households spend on<br />

durable <strong>in</strong>vestments. Table 4.11 reports the coefficients of the OLS and IV estimation of<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, <strong>in</strong>dividual and household characteristics. Our results show that the<br />

null hypothesis of the endogeneity test is rejected at one percent significance level. As<br />

a consequence, the OLS estimates will be <strong>in</strong>coherent. The endogenous effect of <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment is hence mean<strong>in</strong>gful and an IV method is required.<br />

The overidentify<strong>in</strong>g restriction is tested with the Hansen J statistic. We significantly fail<br />

to reject the null hypothesis, and this effect is much stronger as before (p=0.991),<br />

which proves the validity of the <strong>in</strong>struments. We thus have strong statistical evidence<br />

that our <strong>in</strong>struments are mean<strong>in</strong>gful and the 2SLS method will give the most<br />

appropriate results.<br />

The results <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come has a statistically significant, positive and<br />

strong impact on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> both regressions. The elasticity of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the OLS regression is 0.087 and 0.58 <strong>in</strong> the IV regression. The results of the<br />

IV regression <strong>in</strong>dicate that an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come by one percent <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with 0.58%. Compar<strong>in</strong>g both estimations, the statistical significance<br />

rema<strong>in</strong>s the same but the coefficient of the IV estimation is more than six times the<br />

OLS coefficient. When potential factors that make <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come endogenous are<br />

removed, the effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments is even greater<br />

57


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

Table 4.11: OLS and 2SLS estimations results of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

OLS<br />

IVREG2<br />

Coef. Std. Err. Coef. Std. Err.<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>come 0.0869 *** 0.0320 0.5819 *** 0.1686<br />

fm1sex 1.0199 *** 0.2651 0.9109 *** 0.3069<br />

fm1age 0.0068 0.0083 0.0372 *** 0.0141<br />

fm1schooled 0.3621 * 0.2115 0.2833 0.2417<br />

hhlandholdsize 0.0160 0.0355 0.0876 * 0.0469<br />

livestock 0.0484 0.0296 0.0805 ** 0.0358<br />

fixed 0.3146 *** 0.0860 0.2368 ** 0.1040<br />

tabiadismak - 0.0160 *** 0.0047 - 0.0199 *** 0.0052<br />

edirm 0.7910 *** 0.1904 0.7700 *** 0.2350<br />

havei 0.2866 0.2089 0.4680 * 0.2701<br />

adults 0.3330 *** 0.0704 0.1717 * 0.0990<br />

constant 2.0796 *** 0.7573 - 1.2001 1.3541<br />

Endogeneity test<br />

Endogeneity test of endogenous regressors 11.52***<br />

Overidentification test<br />

Hansen J statistic 0.00<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

As expected, the age and gender of the household head have a positive impact on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and are significant at the one percent level. The gender effect is the<br />

strongest of all effects: male headed households have larger, almost double, <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment than female headed households. It <strong>in</strong>dicates that there is still a clear gender<br />

bias. The effect of age is less strong: every additional year of life experience <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with almost four percent. Hence, male and older household heads<br />

positively affect the money spend on durable <strong>in</strong>vestments. More surpris<strong>in</strong>g is that<br />

school<strong>in</strong>g does not have a significant impact on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. We expected more<br />

educated household heads to have higher expenditures on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments because<br />

they are more literate. The coefficient of education <strong>in</strong> the OLS estimation might suggest<br />

this, however the coefficient <strong>in</strong> the IV method is not statistically significant.<br />

Households‟ wealth on the contrary has a clear positive impact on the total <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

households made on water and land, livestock, equipment and build<strong>in</strong>gs. Every<br />

additional Tsimidi of land a household owns, <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with 9 %.<br />

Almost the same effect is reported for livestock and fixed assets, but their coefficients<br />

are lower. A percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the total value of heifer, calves or camels owned<br />

58


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with 0.08%. For fixed assets, the effect is slightly stronger:<br />

a percentage <strong>in</strong>crease of the value of fixed assets <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with<br />

0.24%. The household wealth <strong>in</strong>dicators seem to have a positive effect on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments and the effect of landhold<strong>in</strong>gs is the most pronounced. Also access of the<br />

household to social capital has a positive impact on durable <strong>in</strong>vestments: be<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

member of edir <strong>in</strong>creases the expenditure on durables with 77%.<br />

Similarly, the number of adult labor forces <strong>in</strong> the household <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments, suggest<strong>in</strong>g that households with more members of work<strong>in</strong>g forces are<br />

able to <strong>in</strong>vest more <strong>in</strong> durables. Durable <strong>in</strong>vestments are <strong>in</strong>creased by 17% for every<br />

additional adult labor force. Access to irrigation has a comparable effect: hav<strong>in</strong>g an<br />

irrigation system <strong>in</strong>creases the expenditure on durable <strong>in</strong>vestments with 47%. F<strong>in</strong>ally,<br />

the only variable that seems to have a negative impact on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments is the<br />

distance to Mekelle. Every additional km <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the distance from the households‟<br />

residence to the capital city, decreases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with two percent. Although<br />

this effect is small, it is statistically highly significant. We expected that households that<br />

live further away from Mekelle will have fewer opportunities to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> durables.<br />

4.2.2.3 The effect on different types of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

Next to this, we broke <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments up <strong>in</strong>to its different parts: water and land,<br />

livestock, equipment and build<strong>in</strong>gs. This is done to see whether <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come has<br />

more <strong>in</strong>fluence on a particular type of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment. We regressed <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

and the control variables on each of the types of <strong>in</strong>vestments. The results of the<br />

different IV estimations are reported <strong>in</strong> Table 4.12 and the results of the OLS<br />

estimation are given <strong>in</strong> appendix 2. For both <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> livestock and equipment,<br />

the results are similar with the results on total <strong>in</strong>vestments: <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is<br />

positively related with <strong>in</strong>vestments and this relation is significant at the one percent<br />

level. The coefficient of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the livestock and equipment regression is<br />

however higher than the coefficient of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> the total <strong>farm</strong> expenditures<br />

regression: 0.63 and 0.89 respectively. The effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments is thus most pronounced <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments made <strong>in</strong> equipment and livestock.<br />

Aga<strong>in</strong>, the OLS regression underestimates the effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on the two<br />

types of <strong>in</strong>vestments, and this downward bias <strong>in</strong> OLS estimation is most probably<br />

caused by the omitted variables bias.<br />

59


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

Table 4.12: IV estimation results of <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> water&land, livestock, equipment and build<strong>in</strong>g<br />

2SLS estimation coefficients<br />

Water&Land Livestock Equipment Build<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>come 0.1557 0.6326 *** 0.8921 *** 0.3539 **<br />

fm1sex 0.5844 * - 0.0031 1.1762 *** 0.4714 *<br />

fm1age 0.0098 0.0604 *** 0.0667 *** 0.0110<br />

fm1schooled 0.1395 0.9964 *** - 0.0409 0.1217<br />

hhlandholdsize 0.1630 *** 0.0002 0.0870 0.0330<br />

Livestock 0.0086 0.1340 *** 0.0757 * 0.0201<br />

Fixed - 0.1556 0.1911 0.1730 0.4631 ***<br />

tabiadismak - 0.0241 *** - 0.0003 - 0.0197 *** - 0.0114 **<br />

Edirm 0.3675 0.8191 ** - 0.1134 0.4794<br />

Havei 0.2727 0.7220 * 0.5108 0.1489<br />

Adults 0.3467 *** - 0.0089 - 0.0564 - 0.1774 *<br />

constant 2.1850 - 4.9654 *** - 6.4511 *** - 3.4033 **<br />

Endogeneity test 1.34 6.51 ** 41.02 *** 0.12<br />

Overidentification 10.82 *** 0.21 0.41 2.17<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

Non-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come has also a positive and significant impact (at the five percent level)<br />

on <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> build<strong>in</strong>gs. The endogeneity test is however unable to reject the null<br />

hypothesis that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is exogenous and the IV method is hence not<br />

preferred or even necessary. We discussed the weakness of such endogeneity tests<br />

before, and assume that the model is valid. F<strong>in</strong>ally, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come has a positive, yet<br />

<strong>in</strong>significant effect on <strong>in</strong>vestments made <strong>in</strong> water and land. The model validity is<br />

questioned as the endogeneity test cast doubts on <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come‟s endogeneity and<br />

the overidentification test fails to prove the <strong>in</strong>struments validity. It seems as if the<br />

number of dependents and the share of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come are related with the<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> water and land. Indeed, when both of them are separately <strong>in</strong>cluded as<br />

control variables, they significantly <strong>in</strong>fluence water and land <strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

4.2.2.4 The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally we estimated the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use. We restricted<br />

the <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use to the value of fertilizer and improved seeds. This means that we<br />

excluded local seeds (which however make up the biggest part) and labor use (which is<br />

the smallest part). This dist<strong>in</strong>ction was made to estimate the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come on modern <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts. The results of the estimation are reported <strong>in</strong> Table<br />

60


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

4.13. The null hypothesis of the endogeneity test is strongly rejected, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

necessity of use of the IV estimation. The test of the validity of the <strong>in</strong>struments<br />

however performs dramatically. The overidentification test is strongly rejected which<br />

cast doubts on the legitimacy of the <strong>in</strong>struments used. Indeed, when we regress both<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments as part of the control variables they are highly significant <strong>in</strong> expla<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the<br />

value of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts. As a result, we will focus on the OLS estimation.<br />

Table 4.13: OLS and 2SLS estimations results of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use<br />

OLS<br />

IVREG2<br />

Coef. Std. Err. Coef. Std. Err.<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>come - 0.0535 ** 0.0269 -0.8939*** 0.1905<br />

fm1sex 1.3215 *** 0.2424 1.4288 *** 0.3257<br />

fm1age - 0.0092 0.0069 -0.0615*** 0.0151<br />

fm1schooled 0.0602 0.1912 0.2297 0.2641<br />

hhlandholdsize 0.2570 *** 0.0349 0.1375 ** 0.0597<br />

livestock 0.1107 *** 0.0273 0.0514 0.0406<br />

fixed - 0.0630 0.0657 0.0385 0.0999<br />

tabiadismak - 0.0161 *** 0.0038 -0.0096* 0.0057<br />

edirm 0.7076 *** 0.1946 0.7339 ** 0.2921<br />

havei 0.8808 *** 0.1943 0.5569 * 0.3087<br />

adults 0.2136 *** 0.0605 0.4915 *** 0.1091<br />

constant 2.8783 *** 0.6175 8.7494 1.5262<br />

Endogeneity test<br />

Endogeneity test of endogenous regressors 34.06***<br />

Overidentification test<br />

Hansen J statistic 13.05***<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

Participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities seems to have a negative impact on the<br />

expenditures made on fertilizer and improved seeds. This <strong>in</strong>verse effect is significant at<br />

the five percentage level, but the estimated coefficient is only small. A percentage<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come decreases households‟ expenditures on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts by<br />

0.05%. Most of the control variables have the same effect on modern <strong>in</strong>puts<br />

expenditure as they had on total expenditure and durable <strong>in</strong>vestments. The estimation<br />

of effect of the sex and educational level of the household head, the landhold<strong>in</strong>g size,<br />

the value of the livestock assets, the distance to Mekelle, the membership <strong>in</strong> edir, the<br />

access to irrigation and the number of adult work<strong>in</strong>g forces <strong>in</strong> the household is similar<br />

<strong>in</strong> comparison with the estimations <strong>in</strong> the <strong>farm</strong> expenditure and durable <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

61


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

regressions. Male headed households with bigger landhold<strong>in</strong>gs seem to spend more<br />

money on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts. The effect of the gender of the household is aga<strong>in</strong> the strongest:<br />

be<strong>in</strong>g a male household head <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with 132%.<br />

Moreover, if the household has access to irrigation or more labor forces, the level of<br />

expenditures on fertilizer and improved seeds is <strong>in</strong>creased. This effect is the strongest<br />

for <strong>farm</strong> modern <strong>in</strong>puts: hav<strong>in</strong>g an irrigation <strong>in</strong>stallation <strong>in</strong>creases the expenditure on<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put with 88%. Next to this, if the household is member of edir they will spend<br />

more money on modern <strong>in</strong>puts. The latter effect has the same magnitude as before:<br />

be<strong>in</strong>g a member of edir <strong>in</strong>creases the purchase of modern <strong>in</strong>puts with 71%. Households<br />

that live further away from Mekelle spend significantly less on modern <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, both the education of the household head and the value of fixed assets do not<br />

have a significant impact on the expenditure on fertilizers and improved seeds. Their<br />

estimated coefficient is not statistically significant different from zero.<br />

4.2.2.5 The effect of different types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we broke <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come up <strong>in</strong>to its components and study their effect<br />

separately on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. The rationale beh<strong>in</strong>d this dist<strong>in</strong>ction was that the two<br />

types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities differ <strong>in</strong> nature. Hence, we regressed equation eq. 1 but<br />

with respectively wage and self-employment (bus<strong>in</strong>ess) <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>stead of total <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come. We used durable <strong>in</strong>vestments rather than total <strong>farm</strong> expenditure because<br />

the model specification of the former are superior. Both OLS and IV estimation results<br />

of these regressions with wage and self-employment are respectively given <strong>in</strong> Table<br />

4.14 and Table 4.15. As we were unable to construct separate <strong>in</strong>struments for both<br />

wage and self-employment <strong>in</strong>come, we run the IV regression with the same<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments used for <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

Appendix 1 reports the first stage results of the regression of the control variables and<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments on both wage and self-employment <strong>in</strong>come. It seems as if the number of<br />

dependents and the share of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come are good <strong>in</strong>struments for wage <strong>in</strong>come,<br />

as all the previous discussed tests perform even better. Table 4.14 shows that the<br />

endogeneity test is rejected, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g the requirement of an IV method. Wage <strong>in</strong>come<br />

positively <strong>in</strong>fluences <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments and has an elasticity of 0.42. Hence, a<br />

percentage <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> wage <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with 0.42%. this effect<br />

is significant at the one percent level. Similarly, the OLS regression underestimates the<br />

62


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

impact of the wage <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments: the coefficient of wage <strong>in</strong>come is only<br />

0.07.<br />

Table 4.14: OLS and 2SLS estimations results of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with wage <strong>in</strong>come<br />

OLS<br />

IVREG2<br />

Coef. Std. Err. Coef. Std. Err.<br />

wage<strong>in</strong>come 0.0748 ** 0.0283 0.4233 *** 0.1167<br />

fm1sex 1.0132 *** 0.2646 0.8958 *** 0.2906<br />

fm1age 0.0066 0.0083 0.0304 ** 0.0121<br />

fm1schooled 0.3720 * 0.2116 0.3557 0.2265<br />

hhlandholdsize 0.0158 0.0356 0.0731 * 0.0413<br />

livestock 0.0485 0.0296 0.0755 ** 0.0336<br />

fixed 0.3230 *** 0.0857 0.2977 *** 0.0943<br />

tabiadismak - 0.0161 *** 0.0048 - 0.0198 *** 0.0050<br />

edirm 0.8214 *** 0.1928 0.9445 *** 0.2257<br />

havei 0.2863 0.2097 0.4321 * 0.2501<br />

adults 0.3332 *** 0.0707 0.2027 ** 0.0880<br />

constant 2.1436 *** 0.7527 - 0.2387 1.0650<br />

Endogeneity test<br />

Endogeneity test of endogenous regressors 10.92***<br />

Overidentification test<br />

Hansen J statistic 0.03<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

Appendix 1 shows that for self-employment, the two <strong>in</strong>struments perform problematic,<br />

as they fail for the overidentification, underidentification and weak <strong>in</strong>strument test. The<br />

<strong>in</strong>struments used are not strong related with self-employment <strong>in</strong>come. Also<br />

Woldenhanna and Oskam (2001) f<strong>in</strong>d that the number of dependents affects wage<br />

activities but not self employment activities. Moreover, accord<strong>in</strong>g to Table 4.15, the<br />

endogenous nature of self-employment <strong>in</strong>come is questioned. Although the model is not<br />

valid, it suggest that self-employment is negatively, but <strong>in</strong>significant, related to <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

63


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

Table 4.15: OLS and 2SLS estimates results of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments with bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>come<br />

OLS<br />

IVREG2<br />

Coef. Std. Err. Coef. Std. Err.<br />

bus<strong>in</strong>ess<strong>in</strong>come 0.0188 0.0329 - 1.2242 1.1183<br />

fm1sex 1.0495 *** 0.2657 0.2941 0.7315<br />

fm1age 0.0018 0.0082 - 0.0157 0.0221<br />

fm1schooled 0.3790 * 0.2129 0.2262 0.4099<br />

hhlandholdsize 0.0036 0.0353 - 0.0001 0.0624<br />

livestock 0.0429 0.0298 0.0423 0.0534<br />

fixed 0.3241 *** 0.0852 0.6044 ** 0.2791<br />

tabiadismak - 0.0151 *** 0.0048 - 0.0232 ** 0.0109<br />

edirm 0.7873 *** 0.1920 1.2957 ** 0.5994<br />

havei 0.2580 0.2081 0.0365 0.4567<br />

adults 0.3615 *** 0.0692 0.3088 ** 0.1220<br />

constant 2.6227 *** 0.7389 4.7342 2.2847<br />

Endogeneity test<br />

Endogeneity test of endogenous regressors 2.19<br />

Overidentification test<br />

Hansen J statistic 4.42**<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

4.2.3 Discussion<br />

4.2.3.1 The impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

Our results <strong>in</strong>dicate a positive relation between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and both <strong>farm</strong><br />

expenditures and <strong>in</strong>vestments. This means that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases the amount<br />

of money spent on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures and <strong>in</strong> particular on <strong>in</strong>vestments. Hence, our<br />

results provide evidence that participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities has a positive impact<br />

on agricultural activities: households are able to <strong>in</strong>crease their expenditures and<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities. Our results are <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the empirical evidence of the<br />

literature on <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> (Ruben and van den Berg, 2001; Anriquez and<br />

Daidone, 2009; Maertens, 2009; Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and Davis, 2009).<br />

The effect of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is the strongest on durable <strong>in</strong>vestments. We have<br />

dist<strong>in</strong>guished the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on the different types of <strong>in</strong>vestments and<br />

our results <strong>in</strong>dicated that the impact of RNFE is particularly important for livestock and<br />

equipment. The former result might be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the f<strong>in</strong>d<strong>in</strong>gs of Pender and<br />

64


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

Gebremedh<strong>in</strong> (2004) <strong>in</strong> Tigray. The authors f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> livestock <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

crop productivity and households‟ <strong>in</strong>come. Hence, it can be assumed that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come would be <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities with the highest payoff such as livestock.<br />

The strong impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on equipment <strong>in</strong>dicates the RNFE can support<br />

the purchase of new or improved tools, replacement of old materials and the adoption<br />

of modern techniques. This makes sense, as Woldenhanna (2002) f<strong>in</strong>ds that the<br />

dom<strong>in</strong>ant type of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put <strong>in</strong> Tigray is traditional <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g technology: simple hand<br />

tools and oxen-driven implements. F<strong>in</strong>ally, the RNFE also has a strong impact on<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments made <strong>in</strong> build<strong>in</strong>gs. This result might suggest that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is seen<br />

as an <strong>in</strong>come surplus which can be <strong>in</strong>vested <strong>in</strong> important, though not vital, <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

<strong>in</strong> the <strong>farm</strong>. Other sources of cash might be used to f<strong>in</strong>ance daily consumption needs.<br />

Non-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come did not have a significant effect on <strong>in</strong>vestments made <strong>in</strong> water and<br />

land. This is a somewhat surpris<strong>in</strong>g result. Pender et al. (2006) note that the most<br />

common <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> Tigray are stone terraces and soil bunds. These <strong>in</strong>vestments<br />

have been widely promoted through food for work programs and community labor or<br />

private <strong>in</strong>centives for soil and water conservation. Pender et al. (2006) and Pender<br />

(2004) f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> stone terraces <strong>in</strong>creases crop production, because they<br />

help households to overcome soil moisture deficiency. The average rate of return to<br />

stone terraces ranges between 34% (Pender and Gebremedh<strong>in</strong>, 2004) and 46%<br />

(Pender et al., 2006). Hence, it is not clear why <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come does not <strong>in</strong>crease<br />

these <strong>in</strong>vestments, as it is found that these <strong>in</strong>vestments have a high payoff.<br />

Although the RNFE had a stimulat<strong>in</strong>g effect on <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> durables, the impact of<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use was <strong>in</strong>verse. Households with more <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come spend significantly less money on modern <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use. Our results are <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e<br />

with other literature <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia that suggest or f<strong>in</strong>d the same relation. Both Pender<br />

(2004) and Holden et al. (2004) f<strong>in</strong>d a negative relation between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

and fertilizer use <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia. This outcome is however <strong>in</strong> contradiction with the results<br />

found by Woldenhanna (2000). He f<strong>in</strong>ds the use of variable <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts to be highly<br />

and statistically significant <strong>in</strong>fluenced by <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come. His results show that<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come by 1% <strong>in</strong>creases expenditure on <strong>in</strong>put use by 0.43%.<br />

How can it be expla<strong>in</strong>ed that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come decreases expenditures on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put?<br />

The profitability of modern <strong>in</strong>puts <strong>in</strong> low agricultural areas is limited (Pender, 2004;<br />

Ehui and Pender, 2005). Pender et al. (2006) f<strong>in</strong>d that on average, fertilizer use is<br />

unprofitable <strong>in</strong> Tigray because the use of fertilizer has only a marg<strong>in</strong>al impact on crop<br />

production. This yield <strong>in</strong>crease is <strong>in</strong>sufficient to cover the average costs of fertilizer.<br />

65


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

This expla<strong>in</strong>s the abhorrent attitude of <strong>farm</strong>ers towards the adoption of modern <strong>in</strong>puts<br />

despite the governments‟ efforts to promote its use. Our descriptive statistics show that<br />

the use of fertilizer and improved seeds was restricted, and its value was m<strong>in</strong>or <strong>in</strong><br />

comparison with <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> durables (Table 4.1). Moreover, the purchase of<br />

modern <strong>in</strong>puts is closely bound with credit obta<strong>in</strong>ed from extension programs<br />

(Woldenhanna, 2002). Fertilizer is hence supplied on credit basis, and households<br />

participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> extension programs are less likely to spend their <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on<br />

modern <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts (Kidane, undated).<br />

Not only are modern <strong>in</strong>puts unprofitable, Kidane (undated) suggests the net benefit<br />

cost ratio for <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use to be low <strong>in</strong> comparison to alternative <strong>in</strong>vestment l<strong>in</strong>es. It<br />

is hence more profitable to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> livestock for example. Also Dercon and<br />

Christiaensen (2010) f<strong>in</strong>d that the ma<strong>in</strong> raison for not us<strong>in</strong>g modern <strong>in</strong>puts is the high<br />

price. Input use is expensive and real fertilizer prices have <strong>in</strong>creased. Moreover, the<br />

availability of credit for <strong>in</strong>puts is widespread because of parastatal structures of<br />

fertilizer provision, but the high <strong>in</strong>terest rates are problematic. This has decreased the<br />

relative output-fertilizer price ratio. This trend is especially problematic when harvests<br />

are poor, for example because of poor weather conditions. The sunk cost of fertilizer<br />

will hence decrease the returns, which will be lower than the returns if fertilizer was not<br />

used. The use of fertilizer is thus a risky activity with moderately higher returns<br />

compared to not us<strong>in</strong>g fertilizer (Dercon and Christiaensen, 2010).<br />

In the majority of regressions, we were unable to reject the endogenous nature of <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come. Hence, the use of an IV method was necessary and superior to the OLS<br />

estimation. Overall, the two variables used to <strong>in</strong>strument <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come have proved<br />

to be appropriate <strong>in</strong>struments. In most regressions, the under-, over- and weakidentification<br />

tests have proven the validity and relevance of the <strong>in</strong>struments. However,<br />

both <strong>in</strong>struments were positively related with <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use and water and land<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments. We were aware of the possible relation between the number of<br />

dependents and <strong>farm</strong> decisions. However, the <strong>in</strong>strument pass all the tests <strong>in</strong> other<br />

models, so we can assume that our <strong>in</strong>struments are not too weak <strong>in</strong> general.<br />

In the expenditure and <strong>in</strong>vestment regressions, the OLS estimates underestimate the<br />

coefficient of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> comparison with the IV estimation. Hence, the impact<br />

of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is stronger if we elim<strong>in</strong>ate the endogenous effects of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come, caus<strong>in</strong>g the OLS estimation to be biased downward. Such a bias was expected<br />

and can be expla<strong>in</strong>ed by several possible omitted variables. Various factors might be at<br />

stake, and because of the latter, the direction of the bias was not clear a priori.<br />

66


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

However, as our hypothesis that households use <strong>in</strong>come from RNFE to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities is likely to be confirmed, this could <strong>in</strong>dicate that the omitted variable bias is<br />

highly related with credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts. As we were not able to gather <strong>in</strong>formation and<br />

hence control for the latter, it is possible that they have a strong correlation with the<br />

omitted variables.<br />

Our results hence suggest that households participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong> order to<br />

earn additional cash to overcome credit or liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts. This additional <strong>in</strong>come<br />

gives <strong>farm</strong> households the opportunity to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> their <strong>farm</strong> activities. Similarly,<br />

Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and Davies (2009) and Lee and Sadawa (2007) f<strong>in</strong>d that <strong>in</strong> the context of<br />

liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts, omitt<strong>in</strong>g variables associated with these credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts causes<br />

a downward bias <strong>in</strong> the regression result. The direction of the bias is the result of the<br />

product of the signs of, on the one hand the covariance between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and<br />

the omitted variable and on the other hand the covariance between the omitted<br />

variable and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. As Stamp<strong>in</strong>i and Davies (2009) po<strong>in</strong>t out, the former is<br />

positive (households react to credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts by engag<strong>in</strong>g more <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><br />

activities) and the latter is negative (credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts h<strong>in</strong>der households to spend<br />

money on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments). Lee and Sadawa (2007) f<strong>in</strong>d that the estimation of<br />

precautionary sav<strong>in</strong>gs suffers from omitted variable bias when a large proportion of the<br />

households is credit constra<strong>in</strong>ed. This results <strong>in</strong> a downward bias: correct<strong>in</strong>g for the<br />

omitted variable bias <strong>in</strong>creases the regression coefficient of the estimated prudence.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we have also dist<strong>in</strong>guished the impact of the two types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities on<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment and found a dist<strong>in</strong>ct effect. The difference <strong>in</strong> impact of wage and selfemployment<br />

<strong>in</strong>come is however not surpris<strong>in</strong>g. Wage employment is the dom<strong>in</strong>ant type<br />

of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activity and therefore has the biggest contribution to the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

and hence total household <strong>in</strong>come. Hence, it dom<strong>in</strong>ates the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. Wage jobs are easily accessible and important for households<br />

dur<strong>in</strong>g and outside <strong>farm</strong>-<strong>in</strong>tense periods. Self-employment <strong>in</strong>come is only a m<strong>in</strong>or<br />

component of the households‟ total <strong>in</strong>come, as can be seen <strong>in</strong> Table 4.2. This expla<strong>in</strong>s<br />

why the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and wage <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments is highly<br />

similar, whereas self-employment has a small (and even <strong>in</strong>significant) impact.<br />

The different effect of wage and self-employment <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>in</strong>vestments can be<br />

expla<strong>in</strong>ed by the <strong>in</strong>herent differences between the two types of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

Woldenhanna (2000) observes that households <strong>in</strong> Tigray participate <strong>in</strong> off-<strong>farm</strong> wage<br />

employment because of push factors and self-employment because of pull factors. The<br />

latter implies that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> wage activities can be considered as residual employment<br />

67


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

that absorbs family labor which cannot be fully employed on the <strong>farm</strong>. Self employment<br />

activities are undertaken by households to reap the attractive returns. Wage and selfemployment<br />

activities also require different <strong>in</strong>put requirements. Self employment<br />

generally requires more capital and managerial skills than wage employment so<br />

undertak<strong>in</strong>g self-employment might be more difficult than wage employment. If the<br />

access to credit is constra<strong>in</strong>ed and own capital is restricted, <strong>farm</strong>ers will prefer <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

activities that require less <strong>in</strong>itial capital (Woldenhanna, 2000).<br />

Wage employment might also be a safer and more direct source of liquidity and plays a<br />

stronger role <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>duc<strong>in</strong>g spend<strong>in</strong>gs (Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters, 2009). Moreover, Hertz (2009)<br />

notes that wage <strong>in</strong>come is an important cash-on-hand, especially if there are no<br />

alternative opportunities for sav<strong>in</strong>g, or if there is a big difference between the <strong>in</strong>terest<br />

rates on sav<strong>in</strong>gs versus loans. It will therefore have a stronger role <strong>in</strong> determ<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

households‟ <strong>in</strong>vestment expenditures. It is more likely that households will participate<br />

<strong>in</strong> wage activities to overcome liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts. Accord<strong>in</strong>g to Hertz (2009), it makes<br />

sense that cheaper forms of f<strong>in</strong>ance would be used for <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g if the coverage of<br />

current bills is mandatory and agricultural expenditure are optional and risky. Selfemployment<br />

jobs require <strong>in</strong>vestments, which compete with <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. Liquidity<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts hamper the entry to these jobs, hence these activities suffer from liquidity<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts rather than solv<strong>in</strong>g it. Only households with a good asset position may face<br />

relatively less credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts and hence prefer to work <strong>in</strong> (more remunerative) selfemployment<br />

activities (Woldenhanna, 2000). We therefore observe a negative,<br />

although not significant impact of self-employment <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

4.2.3.2 The effect of control variables<br />

The impact of the control variables on the amount of money spent by the households<br />

on expenditures, seems to be similar for total expenditures, durable <strong>in</strong>vestments and<br />

<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put use. Table 4.16 gives an overview of the effect of the different <strong>in</strong>dividual and<br />

household characteristics that have a statistically significant effect on total <strong>farm</strong><br />

expenditures, durable <strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>in</strong>put use. The sex of the household head is an<br />

important factor that determ<strong>in</strong>es all tree expenditures. Male household heads <strong>in</strong>vest<br />

substantially and significantly more than their female counterparts. Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ter<br />

(2009) f<strong>in</strong>d the same relationship and suggest that females are more likely to <strong>farm</strong> on a<br />

smaller scale and hence spend less on agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts. However, as the regression<br />

did not <strong>in</strong>corporate the amount of male and female household members, our results<br />

does not say anyth<strong>in</strong>g about the gender bias with<strong>in</strong> households. Other studies, like<br />

68


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

Maertens (2009) f<strong>in</strong>d evidence of a clear gender bias with<strong>in</strong> the household: female<br />

household members work on family plots while male household members control the<br />

land and make <strong>farm</strong> decisions.<br />

Table 4.16: Summary of the impact of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and control variables<br />

Total expenditures Durable <strong>in</strong>vestments Input use<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>come + + -<br />

fm1sex + + +<br />

fm1age 0 + 0<br />

fm1schooled 0 0 0<br />

hhlandholdsize + + +<br />

livestock + + +<br />

fixed + + 0<br />

tabiadismak - - -<br />

edirm + + +<br />

havei + + +<br />

adults + + +<br />

Notes: +: positive impact, -: negative impact and 0 : no statistical significant impact<br />

The age of the household head <strong>in</strong>creases the expenditures on durable <strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

Older <strong>in</strong>dividuals tend to have more agricultural experience and means to make<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments than then their younger counterparts. It is however more likely that there<br />

is a convex relationship at work: <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong>crease with age until a certa<strong>in</strong> threshold<br />

is reached and decrease afterwards (the life cycle effect, as noted <strong>in</strong> Woldenhanna,<br />

2000). Kidane (undated) suggests that older people spend less of the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

Due to the possible risk of high multicoll<strong>in</strong>earity we have chosen not to <strong>in</strong>corporate the<br />

squared term of the age of the household head <strong>in</strong> our regression. The <strong>in</strong>significant<br />

relationship between <strong>in</strong>put use and the age of the household head is rather surpris<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

We expected more educated household heads to have higher expenditures on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments because they are more literate. Our results suggest that education has a<br />

positive effect on all types of <strong>in</strong>vestments, and this is <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with most empirical<br />

evidence. These studies usually f<strong>in</strong>d a positive effect on <strong>in</strong>vestments but at a<br />

decreas<strong>in</strong>g rate (Kilic et al., 2009). However, the effect of education is not statistical<br />

significant for any type of <strong>in</strong>vestment. This is consistent with the effect of education on<br />

fertilizer expenditure found by Kidane (undated). He suggests that education does not<br />

have the power to expand fertilizer use because the average education atta<strong>in</strong>ment <strong>in</strong><br />

the Geba catchment is low (below first grade level).<br />

69


Chapter 4: Results and discussion<br />

The total size of landhold<strong>in</strong>gs and the value of the livestock owned by the household<br />

both <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments of any k<strong>in</strong>d. The effect of landhold<strong>in</strong>gs is much stronger<br />

than that of livestock. Our results suggest that landless <strong>farm</strong>ers spend less on<br />

agricultural <strong>in</strong>puts than <strong>farm</strong>ers who own their cultivated land. Oseni and W<strong>in</strong>ters<br />

(2009) note that this is not surpris<strong>in</strong>g because landless households usually rent land or<br />

sharecrop, while landlords are responsible for the expenditures of <strong>in</strong>vestments. Larger<br />

<strong>farm</strong>s may have the advantage of economies of scale and their use of modern <strong>in</strong>puts is<br />

more likely to be profitable. Households‟ value of fixed assets on the one hand<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> durables, while on the other hand it decreases <strong>in</strong>put use. The<br />

latter is however statistically not significant. This confirms that households with more<br />

land and assets spend more money on <strong>farm</strong> related activities. This could <strong>in</strong>dicate that<br />

more endowed <strong>farm</strong>ers are more active <strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities and therefore make more<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> their <strong>farm</strong>. Also Kidane (Undatedb) suggests that <strong>farm</strong>ers with more<br />

assets have more <strong>in</strong>centives to use modern <strong>in</strong>puts or adopt new technologies.<br />

Households‟ wealth can help <strong>farm</strong>ers to afford, bear or spread risks associated with<br />

adoption and larger <strong>farm</strong>s have more opportunities to adopt new <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g practices.<br />

Moreover, the larger the land size, the more beneficial fertilizer and <strong>in</strong>put use becomes.<br />

Besides these household wealth <strong>in</strong>dicators, social capital has a strong and highly<br />

significant impact on all types of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. Social networks such as edir often<br />

offer relevant and qualitative <strong>in</strong>formation to its members, mak<strong>in</strong>g them more likely to<br />

<strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> agricultural activities. Kilic et al. (2009) suggest social capital enhances <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments because it reduces risk and <strong>in</strong>creases access to capital when reciprocal<br />

relations are important. The distance to Mekelle has the most pronounced negative<br />

impact on the amount of money spent on all types of <strong>in</strong>vestments. It is believed that<br />

rural areas close to urban centres have greater <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> (Davis et al.,<br />

2002). Our results confirm that <strong>farm</strong>ers that live near Mekelle have superior access to<br />

markets and are therefore <strong>in</strong> a better position to <strong>in</strong>vest <strong>in</strong> their <strong>farm</strong>. <strong>Farm</strong>ers they live<br />

further away from the regional capital are discouraged to use modern agricultural<br />

<strong>in</strong>puts because of the high transport cost (Kidane, undated). Hav<strong>in</strong>g access to an<br />

irrigation system also enhances the expenditures on <strong>in</strong>vestments of any k<strong>in</strong>d, <strong>in</strong>dicat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

that irrigated land requires more <strong>in</strong>puts and is cultivated more <strong>in</strong>tensively. This result<br />

shows that irrigation systems promote <strong>in</strong>vestments and the use of <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>puts. F<strong>in</strong>ally,<br />

the number of adult labor forces has a positive impact on <strong>farm</strong> expenditure. This<br />

suggests that households with more contribut<strong>in</strong>g members of work<strong>in</strong>g forces are able to<br />

<strong>in</strong>vest more <strong>in</strong> their <strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

70


Chapter 5: Conclusions and Recommendations<br />

5 CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS<br />

5.1 Conclusion<br />

In Ethiopia, rural development drives the agricultural sector <strong>in</strong> stimulat<strong>in</strong>g the rural<br />

economy. However, environmental problems, low agricultural productivity, <strong>in</strong>adequacy<br />

of previous policies and the emergence of the livelihood concept necessitate a wider<br />

and more synergistic development path. In this context, the development of the RNFE<br />

sector was <strong>in</strong>evitable. Nowadays the <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector is considered to be a significant<br />

component of the rural economy. As the RNFE and agricultural sector become equally<br />

important <strong>in</strong> a synergistic development approach, it is essential to study how these two<br />

sectors are <strong>in</strong>ter-l<strong>in</strong>ked. The aim of this study was therefore to explore the impact of<br />

RNFE on agricultural production, focus<strong>in</strong>g on a possible complementary relation<br />

between <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments.<br />

Recent development literature has hypothesized the existence of <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>.<br />

Investment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> imply that <strong>farm</strong>ers use <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

which will result <strong>in</strong> an <strong>in</strong>crease of the expenditures on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>in</strong>put use<br />

and enable <strong>farm</strong> modernization. These <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are especially important for<br />

credit constra<strong>in</strong>ed households, s<strong>in</strong>ce these are restricted from spend credit on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments. Non-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come might be used to overcome these credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

However, empirical evidence does not unambiguously confirm that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

complements <strong>farm</strong> activities. It is studied that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities sometimes withdraw<br />

resources from the <strong>farm</strong> and hence compete with agricultural production. The primary<br />

objective of this study was therefore to determ<strong>in</strong>e whether <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come enhances<br />

<strong>farm</strong> expenditures through <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>.<br />

In addition, the importance of the RNFE sector for rural households <strong>in</strong> a develop<strong>in</strong>g<br />

country such as Ethiopia was of <strong>in</strong>terest. Simple descriptive statistics confirm that <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come constitutes a substantial part of the total household <strong>in</strong>come and access<br />

seems not to be restricted. 80% of the households had at least some <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on average accounts for 27% of the total household <strong>in</strong>come. We<br />

found no <strong>in</strong>dication for the existence of entry barriers which hamper the entrance <strong>in</strong>to<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Participation <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities is ma<strong>in</strong>ly determ<strong>in</strong>ed by push<br />

factors: dependent household members that need to be supported, excess labor forces<br />

and low <strong>in</strong>volvement <strong>in</strong> livestock activities. However, credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts are assumed to<br />

71


Chapter 5: Conclusions and Recommendations<br />

be one of the most (or even the most) important push factor. We were unfortunately<br />

not able to <strong>in</strong>corporate this <strong>in</strong> our regression model.<br />

The lack of <strong>in</strong>formation about credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts is suggested to be the major source of<br />

unobserved heterogeneity (omitted variable bias), although several other factors might<br />

be at stake. Omitted variable bias causes <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come to be endogenously related<br />

with <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments. As a consequence a bias <strong>in</strong> the OLS regression occurs.<br />

Moreover, decisions about RNFE and <strong>farm</strong> activities might be taken jo<strong>in</strong>tly, creat<strong>in</strong>g a<br />

simultaneity bias between <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Us<strong>in</strong>g IV methods,<br />

we were able to deal with both biases. Comparison of the IV and OLS estimations<br />

<strong>in</strong>dicated that the OLS estimates of the coefficient of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come are biased<br />

downwards, and this due to omission of liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts variables We suggested<br />

that unobserved credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts hamper households to <strong>in</strong>vest on their <strong>farm</strong>, but push<br />

households to seek for additional, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come sources.<br />

Us<strong>in</strong>g household survey data from Tigray prov<strong>in</strong>ce, we provided evidence for the<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment l<strong>in</strong>kage hypothesis. The regression results proved that RNFE has a<br />

substantial and positive impact on <strong>farm</strong> expenditures and <strong>in</strong>vestments. A percentage<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> expenditures and <strong>in</strong>vestments with<br />

respectively 0.18% and 0.58%. Moreover, these <strong>in</strong>vestments seem to concentrate<br />

ma<strong>in</strong>ly on livestock and equipment. These results <strong>in</strong>dicate that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come is an<br />

important source to f<strong>in</strong>ance <strong>in</strong>vestments that have the highest payoff (and hence<br />

impact) on <strong>farm</strong> activities. It is assumed that this relationship is ma<strong>in</strong>ly driven by <strong>farm</strong><br />

liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts, forc<strong>in</strong>g households to look for additional credit sources.<br />

Households participate <strong>in</strong> the RNFE to ga<strong>in</strong> a surplus <strong>in</strong>come that can be used to <strong>in</strong>vest<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong> activities, <strong>in</strong> which they would be unable to engage otherwise.<br />

One seem<strong>in</strong>gly surpris<strong>in</strong>g result was that <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come does not <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>put<br />

use and hence does not fit <strong>in</strong> with the evidence of <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. We suggested<br />

that this apparent contradiction is the result of local conditions. While extension and<br />

credit programs have <strong>in</strong>creased the access of <strong>farm</strong>ers to <strong>in</strong>puts (especially fertilizers),<br />

the efficiency (and profitability) of modern <strong>in</strong>puts is low because of a decreased<br />

output/fertilizer price ratio, higher rate of return to other <strong>in</strong>vestments or vulnerability to<br />

<strong>in</strong>adequate soil moisture. Hence, households prefer to spend the credit that is obta<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

by participat<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities on more profitable <strong>in</strong>vestments such as livestock<br />

or equipment. The latter are the two most important types of traditional technology<br />

used by <strong>farm</strong>ers <strong>in</strong> Tigray.<br />

72


Chapter 5: Conclusions and Recommendations<br />

The regression analysis also <strong>in</strong>dicated the importance of divid<strong>in</strong>g <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>to<br />

its dist<strong>in</strong>ct sources. In our analysis, <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong>clude both wage and selfemployment<br />

activities. Wage <strong>in</strong>come is the most important <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activity <strong>in</strong> Tigray.<br />

Wage jobs are ma<strong>in</strong>ly temporary and do not require specific education or tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g. They<br />

are therefore accessible to many rural <strong>farm</strong> households and form a direct source of<br />

cash. On the contrary, self-employment activities only have a m<strong>in</strong>or share <strong>in</strong> the total<br />

household <strong>in</strong>come and it is assumed that some <strong>in</strong>itial <strong>in</strong>vestments are required. As a<br />

result, we noticed that wage <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments and expenditures,<br />

while self-employment did not have a significant impact on <strong>farm</strong> activities.<br />

Overall, the credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>farm</strong>ers face can be superseded by participation <strong>in</strong> the<br />

RNFE sector. This implies that <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> are present <strong>in</strong> the development<br />

of the RNFE, and should therefore play an important role <strong>in</strong> the rural development<br />

approach. The suggested virtuous circle is therefore possible: promot<strong>in</strong>g access to<br />

RNFE <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> modernization through <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Better access and<br />

availability of <strong>farm</strong> households to <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments and<br />

expenditures. This <strong>in</strong> turn <strong>in</strong>creases demand for <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities, especially <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

wage labor. The next section summarizes policy recommendations, suggested<br />

from our analysis, that should contribute to a more synergistic rural development path.<br />

5.2 Policy Recommendations<br />

<br />

The analysis emphasizes the importance of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> rural areas of<br />

Ethiopia. Not only is it a substantial share of the total household <strong>in</strong>come, it is<br />

used to overcome liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts. It seems therefore highly recommended<br />

to <strong>in</strong>corporate RNFE <strong>in</strong> rural development, as it can be assumed as an<br />

alternative path to overcome poverty.<br />

<br />

Non-<strong>farm</strong> activities should be wider available and wage rates should improve <strong>in</strong><br />

order to <strong>in</strong>crease the <strong>in</strong>centive and capacity of households to participate <strong>in</strong> <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

activities. Especially wage employment has a strong impact on <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments. Policies should encourage the growth of the RNFE and strengthen<br />

the l<strong>in</strong>k between the different activities and sectors.<br />

<br />

As no <strong>in</strong>dication of entry barriers to participate <strong>in</strong> the RNFE exist, it is not<br />

necessary to promote policies to overcome entry restrictions. Rather, the<br />

profitability of RNFE activities should be improved. Provid<strong>in</strong>g better tra<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g and<br />

73


Chapter 5: Conclusions and Recommendations<br />

education, encourag<strong>in</strong>g small-scale enterprises, improv<strong>in</strong>g access to markets<br />

and improv<strong>in</strong>g public <strong>in</strong>frastructure will stimulate growth <strong>in</strong> the RNFE sector and<br />

enable households to take advantage of the opportunities that already exist.<br />

<br />

In addition, our results show that <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities are <strong>in</strong>ter-l<strong>in</strong>ked:<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come can be used to support agricultural production via <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Non-<strong>farm</strong> and <strong>farm</strong> activities cannot be seen <strong>in</strong> isolation. This implies<br />

that both the RNFE and <strong>farm</strong> sector should be simultaneously supported <strong>in</strong> rural<br />

policies <strong>in</strong> order to improve durable rural development and stimulate <strong>farm</strong><br />

modernization. The l<strong>in</strong>k between both sectors should be re<strong>in</strong>forced by<br />

complementary programs and policies. Hence, a synergistic development path<br />

seems to be appropriate <strong>in</strong> Ethiopia, where the agricultural sector is<br />

omnipresent.<br />

<br />

Policies should <strong>in</strong>corporate evidence of <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> order to target<br />

credit constra<strong>in</strong>ed households. Liquidity restrictions <strong>in</strong> the agricultural sector<br />

hamper <strong>farm</strong> productivity but can be surmounted by additional sources of credit<br />

and liquidity. Systems should be set up to relax the credit constra<strong>in</strong>ts of poor<br />

households, besides promotion of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities. Development of rural<br />

credit markets or microf<strong>in</strong>ance will help households to improve their <strong>farm</strong><br />

activities.<br />

<br />

RNFE has a positive impact ma<strong>in</strong>ly on <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestments, yet the <strong>in</strong>verse relation<br />

is observed for modern <strong>in</strong>put use. While previous extension systems focused<br />

primarily on the distribution of fertilizers and modern <strong>in</strong>puts, it did not seem<br />

successful. Therefore, the Ethiopian government should embrace both <strong>farm</strong> and<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities and emphasize on the development of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> activities<br />

because these foster <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> livestock, build<strong>in</strong>gs and equipment.<br />

<br />

Overall, a virtuous circle is possible and should therefore be promoted. However,<br />

more empirical evidence of such self-enforc<strong>in</strong>g effects should be provided by<br />

means of further studies. It is thereby suggested to conduct further research.<br />

74


References<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Andreosso - O‟Callaghan, B. & Yue, G. (2004). Intersectoral <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> and key sectors <strong>in</strong><br />

Ch<strong>in</strong>a, 1987 - 1997. Asian Economic Journal, 18: 165-183.<br />

Anriquez, G. & Daidone, S. (2010). L<strong>in</strong>kages between the <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> sectors at<br />

the household level <strong>in</strong> rural Ghana: a consistent stochastic distance function<br />

approach. Agricultural Economic, 41: 51–66.<br />

Barrett, C.B., Reardon, T. & Webb, P. (2001). Non<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come diversification and<br />

household livelihood strategies <strong>in</strong> rural Africa: concepts, dynamics, and policy<br />

implications. Food Policy, 26: 315–331.<br />

Baum, C.F. (2006). An <strong>in</strong>troduction to modern econometrics us<strong>in</strong>g Stata. College<br />

Station, Stata Press Publication. Texas. 341p.<br />

Baum, C.F., Schaffer, M.E. & Stillman, S. (2003). Instrumental variables and GMM:<br />

estimation and test<strong>in</strong>g. Stata Journal, 3: 1-31.<br />

Belay, K. & Abebaw, D. (2004). Challenges fac<strong>in</strong>g agricultural extension agents: a case<br />

study from south-western Ethiopia. African Development Review, 16: 139-168.<br />

Block, S. & Webb, P. (2001). The dynamics of livelihood diversification <strong>in</strong> post-fam<strong>in</strong>e<br />

Ethiopia. Food Policy, 26: 333-350.<br />

Blunch, N.H. & Verner, D. (2006). Shared sectoral growth versus the dual economy<br />

model: Evidence from Cote d'Ivoire, Ghana and Zimbabwe. African Development<br />

Review, 18: 283-308.<br />

Carswell, G. (2002). Livelihood diversification: <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> importance or <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly<br />

recognized? Evidence from southern Ethiopia. Journal of International Development,<br />

14: 789-804.<br />

Chang, H.H. & Wen, F.I. (2010). Off-<strong>farm</strong> work, technical efficiency, and rice production<br />

risk <strong>in</strong> Taiwan. Agricultural Economics, 42: 269-278.<br />

Corral, L. & Reardon, T. (2001). Rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>comes <strong>in</strong> Nicaragua. World<br />

Development, 29: 427-442.<br />

75


References<br />

Davis, B., Reardon, T., Stamoulis, K. & W<strong>in</strong>ters, P. (2002). Promot<strong>in</strong>g <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> for rural development: Case studies from Africa and Lat<strong>in</strong> America. FAO,<br />

Rome. 196p.<br />

Davies, B., W<strong>in</strong>ter, P., Reardon, T. & Stamoulis, K. (2009). Rural <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> employment<br />

and <strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g: household-level <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong>. Agricultural Economics, 40: 119-123.<br />

De Janvry, A. & Sadoulet, E. (2003). Income strategies among rural households <strong>in</strong><br />

Mexico: the role of off-<strong>farm</strong> activities. World Development, 29: 467-480.<br />

De Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E. & Zhu, N. (2005). The role of <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>comes <strong>in</strong> reduc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

rural poverty and <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a. CUDARE work<strong>in</strong>g paper 1001. University of<br />

California, Berkeley. 1-29.<br />

Dercon, S. (1998). Wealth, risk and activity choice: cattle <strong>in</strong> Western Tanzania. Journal<br />

of Development Economics, 55: 1-42.<br />

Dercon, S. & Christiaensen, L. (2010). Consumption risk, technology adoption and<br />

poverty traps: Evidence from Ethiopia. Journal of Development Economics, Article <strong>in</strong><br />

press.<br />

Dercon, S. & Krishnan, P. (1996). Income portfolios <strong>in</strong> rural Ethiopia and Tanzania:<br />

choices and constra<strong>in</strong>ts. The Journal of Development Studies, 32: 850-875.<br />

Egziabher, K.G. (undated). Are <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come relax<strong>in</strong>g <strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment liquidity<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts for marg<strong>in</strong>al <strong>farm</strong>s? A double hurdle approach. Chapter <strong>in</strong> Ph.D. thesis.<br />

K.U.Leuven, Belgium. Forthcom<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Ehui, S. & Pender, J. (2005). Resource degradation, low agricultural productivity and<br />

poverty <strong>in</strong> sub-Saharan Africa: pathways out of the spiral. Agricultural Economics,<br />

32: 225-242.<br />

Ellis, F. (1998). Household strategies and rural livelihood diversification. Journal of<br />

Development Studies, 35: 1-38.<br />

Ellis, F. (2000). Rural livelihoods and diversity <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. Oxford<br />

University Press, Oxford. 279p.<br />

Ellis, F. (2000b). The determ<strong>in</strong>ants of rural livelihood diversification <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g<br />

countries. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 51: 289-302.<br />

76


References<br />

Ellis, F. & Freeman, H.A. (2004). Rural livelihoods and poverty reduction strategies <strong>in</strong><br />

four African countries. Journal of Development Studies, 40: 1-30.<br />

Escobal, J. (2001). The determ<strong>in</strong>ants of <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come diversification <strong>in</strong> rural Peru.<br />

World Development, 29: 497-508.<br />

Fernandez-Cornejo, J., Mishra, A.K., Nehriung, R.F., Hencricks, C., Southern, M.,<br />

Gregory, A. (2007). Off-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, technology adoption and <strong>farm</strong> economic<br />

performance. United States Department of Agriculture Economic Research Report,<br />

36: 1-53.<br />

Goodw<strong>in</strong>, B.K. & Mishrea, A.K. (2004). <strong>Farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g efficiency and the determ<strong>in</strong>ants of<br />

multiple job hold<strong>in</strong>g by <strong>farm</strong> operators. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,<br />

86: 722-729.<br />

Haggblade, S., Hazell, P. & Brown, J. (1989). <strong>Farm</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> rural sub-<br />

Saharan Africa. World Development, 17: 1173-1201.<br />

Hazell, P.B. & Hojjati, B. (1995). <strong>Farm</strong> <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> growth <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> Zambia. Journal Of<br />

African Economies, 4: 406-435.<br />

Hertz, T. (2009). The effect of <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come on <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> Bulgarian family<br />

<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>g. Agricultural Economics, 40: 161-176.<br />

Holden, S., Shiferaw, B. & Pender, J. (2004). Non-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, household welfare, and<br />

susta<strong>in</strong>able land management <strong>in</strong> a less-favored area <strong>in</strong> the Ethiopian highlands. Food<br />

Policy, 29: 369-392.<br />

Huang, J., Wu, Y. & Rozelle, S. (2009). Mov<strong>in</strong>g off the <strong>farm</strong> and <strong>in</strong>tensify<strong>in</strong>g agricultural<br />

production <strong>in</strong> Shandong: A case study of rural labor market L<strong>in</strong>kages <strong>in</strong> Ch<strong>in</strong>a.<br />

Agricultural Economics, 40: 203–218.<br />

Islam, N. (1997). The <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> sector and rural development: review of issues and<br />

evidence. Food, Agriculture and the Environment Discussion Paper, 22. IFPRI,<br />

Wash<strong>in</strong>gton D.C. 1-48.<br />

Jayne, T.S., Yamano, Y., Weber, M.T., Tschirley, D., Benfica, R., Chapoto, A. & Zulu, B.<br />

(2003). Smallholder <strong>in</strong>come and land distribution <strong>in</strong> Africa: implications for poverty<br />

reduction strategies. Food Policy, 28: 253-275.<br />

77


References<br />

Kilic, T., Carletto, C., Miluka, J. & Savastano, S. (2009). Rural <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and its<br />

impact on <strong>agriculture</strong>: Evidence from Albania. Agricultural Economics, 40: 139-160.<br />

Lanjouw, J.O. & Lanjouw, P. (2001). The rural <strong>non</strong>‐<strong>farm</strong> sector: issues and evidence<br />

from develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. Agricultural Economics, 26: 1-23.<br />

Lanjouw, P., Quizon, J. & Sparrow, R. (2001). Non-agricultural earn<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> peri-urban<br />

areas of Tanzania: evidence from household survey data. Food Policy, 26: 385-403.<br />

Lee, J.J. & Sawada, Y. (2010). Precautionary sav<strong>in</strong>g under liquidity constra<strong>in</strong>ts:<br />

Evidence from rural Pakistan. Journal of Development Economics, 91: 77–86.<br />

Lien, G., Kumbhakar, S.C. & Hardaker, J.B. (2010). Determ<strong>in</strong>ants of off-<strong>farm</strong> work and<br />

its effects on <strong>farm</strong> performance: the case of Norwegian gra<strong>in</strong> <strong>farm</strong>ers. Agricultural<br />

Economics, 41: 577-586.<br />

Maertens, M. (2009). Horticulture exports, agro-<strong>in</strong>dustrialization and <strong>farm</strong>-<strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> with the <strong>smallholder</strong> <strong>farm</strong> sector: evidence from Senegal. Agricultural<br />

Economics, 40: 219-229.<br />

Negash, Z.Z. (2008). Microf<strong>in</strong>ance loan delivery, utilization and impact: with specific<br />

reference to Tigray, northern Ethiopia. Ph.D. thesis. K.U.Leuven, Belgium. 190p.<br />

Matshe, I. & Young, T. (2004). Off-<strong>farm</strong> labour allocation decisions <strong>in</strong> small-scale rural<br />

households <strong>in</strong> Zimbabwe. Agricultural Economics, 30: 175-186.<br />

OECD (2010), "Ethiopia", <strong>in</strong> OECD/African Development Bank/United Nations Economic<br />

Commission for Africa, African Economic Outlook 2010, OECD Publish<strong>in</strong>g. 281p.<br />

Oseni, G. & W<strong>in</strong>ters, P. (2009). Rural <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> activities and agricultural crop<br />

production <strong>in</strong> Nigeria. Agricultural Economics, 40: 198-201.<br />

Pender, J. (2004). Development pathways for hillsides and highlands: some lessons<br />

from Central America and East Africa. Food Policy, 29: 339-367.<br />

Pender, J., Place, F. & Ehui, S. (2006). Strategies for susta<strong>in</strong>able land management <strong>in</strong><br />

the East African highlands. International Food Policy Research Institute, Wash<strong>in</strong>gton,<br />

D.C. 483p.<br />

78


References<br />

Pender, J. & Gebremedh<strong>in</strong>, B. (2004). Impact of policies and technologies <strong>in</strong> dryland<br />

<strong>agriculture</strong>: evidence from Northern Ethiopia. In: challenges and stategies for<br />

dryland <strong>agriculture</strong>. S.C. Rao and J. Ryan (eds.). American Society of Agronomy and<br />

Crop Science of America (CSSA) special Publication, 32. Madison, W.I. 434p.<br />

Pfeiffer, L., Lopez-Feldman, A. & Taylor, J.E. (2009). Is off-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come reform<strong>in</strong>g the<br />

<strong>farm</strong>? Evidence of Mexico. Agricultural Economics, 40: 125-138.<br />

Phimister, E. & Roberts, D. (2006). The effect of off-<strong>farm</strong> work on the <strong>in</strong>tensity of<br />

agricultural production. Environmental & Resource Economics, 34: 493-515.<br />

Reardon, T. (1997). Us<strong>in</strong>g evidence of household <strong>in</strong>come diversification to <strong>in</strong>form study<br />

of the rural <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> labor market <strong>in</strong> Africa. World Development, 25: 735-747.<br />

Reardon, T., Berdegué, J. & Escobal, G. (2001). Rural <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> employment and<br />

<strong>in</strong>comes <strong>in</strong> Lat<strong>in</strong> America: Overview and policy implications. World Development, 29:<br />

395-409.<br />

Reardon, T., Berdegué, J., Barrett, C.B. & Stamoulis, K. (2006). Household <strong>in</strong>come<br />

diversification <strong>in</strong>to rural <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> activities. In: Transform<strong>in</strong>g the Rural Non<strong>farm</strong><br />

Economy. Haggblade, S., Hazell, P., Reardon, T. (eds.). John Hopk<strong>in</strong>s University<br />

Press, Baltimore, M.D., 115-141.<br />

Reardon, T., Crawford, E. & Kelly, V. (1994). L<strong>in</strong>ks between <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come and <strong>farm</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> African households: Add<strong>in</strong>g the capital market perspective. American<br />

Journal of Agricultural Economics, 74: 1172-1176.<br />

Reardon, T., Stamoulis, K., Cruz, M.E., Balisacan, A., Berdegué, T.A. & Banks, D.<br />

(1998). Rural <strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries. Special chapter <strong>in</strong> The State<br />

of Food and Agriculture 1998. FAO, Rome. 283–356.<br />

Reardon, T., Tayler, E.J., Stamoulis, K., Lanjouw, P. & Balisacan, A. (2000). Effects of<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> employment on rural <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>in</strong> develop<strong>in</strong>g countries: an <strong>in</strong>vestment<br />

perspective. Journal of Agricultural Economics, 51: 266-288.<br />

Ruben, R. & van den Berg, M. (2001). Non<strong>farm</strong> employment and poverty alleviation of<br />

rural <strong>farm</strong> households <strong>in</strong> Honduras. World Development, 26: 549-560.<br />

Shimelis, A. & Bogale, A. (2007). Rural development policies and programs strategies<br />

among rural households <strong>in</strong> Dire Dawa, eastern Ethiopia. Tropical Science, 47: 73-80.<br />

79


References<br />

Stamp<strong>in</strong>i, M. & Davis, B. (2009). Does <strong>non</strong>agricultural labor relax <strong>farm</strong>ers‟ credit<br />

constra<strong>in</strong>ts? Evidence from longitud<strong>in</strong>al data for Vietnam. Agricultural Economics,<br />

40: 177–188.<br />

Sumberg, J., Gilbert, E. & Blackie, M. (2004). Income diversity, technology choice and<br />

agricultural research policy <strong>in</strong> Sub-Saharan Africa. Development Policy Review, 22:<br />

131-146.<br />

Tesfay, G.B. (2009). Econometric analyses of microf<strong>in</strong>ance credit group formation,<br />

contractual risks and welfare impacts <strong>in</strong> Northern Ethiopia. Ph.D. thesis. Wagen<strong>in</strong>gen<br />

University, Holland. 146p.<br />

van den Berg, M., & Kumbi, G. E. (2006). Poverty and the rural <strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> economy <strong>in</strong><br />

Oromia, Ethiopia. Agricultural Economics, 35: 469-475.<br />

Woldenhanna, T. (2000). Economic analysis and policy implications of <strong>farm</strong> and off<strong>farm</strong><br />

employment: a case study <strong>in</strong> the Tigray Region of Northern Ethiopia. Ph.D.<br />

thesis, Agricultural Economics and Rural Policy Group, Wagen<strong>in</strong>gen University,<br />

Holland. 277p.<br />

Woldenhanna, T. (2002). Rural <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> <strong>in</strong> northern Ethiopia. In:<br />

Promot<strong>in</strong>g <strong>farm</strong>/<strong>non</strong><strong>farm</strong> <strong>l<strong>in</strong>kages</strong> for rural development: case studies from Africa<br />

and Lat<strong>in</strong> America. Davis, B., Reardon, T., Stamoulis, K., W<strong>in</strong>ters, P. (eds.). FAO,<br />

Rome, 121-144.<br />

Woldenhanna, T., & Oskam, A. (2001). Income diversification and entry barriers:<br />

evidence of the Tigray region <strong>in</strong> northern Ethiopia. Food Policy, 26: 351-365.<br />

Wooldbridge, J.M. (2002). Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. MIT<br />

Press. Cambridge, MA. 805p.<br />

Wooldbridge, J. M. (2002b). Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, 2nd<br />

edition. Thomson South-Western. C<strong>in</strong>c<strong>in</strong>nati, O.H. 735p.<br />

80


Appendix 1<br />

APPENDIX 1<br />

Table A1.1: First stage OLS regression with wage <strong>in</strong>come<br />

OLS<br />

Coef. Std. Err.<br />

fm1sex 0.5192 * 0.2795<br />

fm1age -0.0765*** 0.0089<br />

fm1schooled -0.0843 0.2477<br />

hhlandholdsize -0.0553 0.0504<br />

livestock -0.0771** 0.0361<br />

fixed -0.1605* 0.0903<br />

tabiadismak 0.0095 * 0.0053<br />

edirm -0.0410 0.2846<br />

havei -0.2657 0.3012<br />

adults 0.3690 *** 0.0828<br />

dependents 0.2796 *** 0.0772<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong>share_tabia 0.0945 *** 0.0127<br />

constant 4.9861 0.8612<br />

Jo<strong>in</strong>t significance of IV<br />

F test of excluded <strong>in</strong>struments 35.52 ***<br />

Angrist-Pischke multivariate F test of IV 35.52 ***<br />

Underidentification test<br />

Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic 56.93 ***<br />

Weak identification test<br />

Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic 33.86<br />

Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic 35.52<br />

Weak-<strong>in</strong>strument-robust <strong>in</strong>ference<br />

Anderson-Rub<strong>in</strong> Wald test 16.70 ***<br />

Stock-Wright LM S statistic 15.70 ***<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

81


Appendix 1<br />

Table A1.2: First stage OLS regression with bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>come<br />

OLS<br />

Coef. Std. Err.<br />

fm1sex -0.4740 0.3118<br />

fm1age -0.0162** 0.0079<br />

fm1schooled -0.1764 0.2406<br />

hhlandholdsize -0.0057 0.0412<br />

livestock 0.0001 0.0350<br />

fixed 0.2283 ** 0.0926<br />

tabiadismak -0.0066 0.0049<br />

edirm 0.4053 0.2891<br />

havei -0.1640 0.2793<br />

adults -0.0138 0.0801<br />

dependents -0.0989 0.0734<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong>share_tabia 0.0009 0.0130<br />

constant -0.4740 0.3118<br />

Jo<strong>in</strong>t significance of IV<br />

F test of excluded <strong>in</strong>struments 0.91<br />

Angrist-Pischke multivariate F test of IV 0.91<br />

Underidentification test<br />

Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic 1.85<br />

Weak identification test<br />

Cragg-Donald Wald F statistic 0.84<br />

Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic 0.91<br />

Weak-<strong>in</strong>strument-robust <strong>in</strong>ference<br />

Anderson-Rub<strong>in</strong> Wald test 16.70 ***<br />

Stock-Wright LM S statistic 15.70 ***<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

82


Appendix 2<br />

APPENDIX 2<br />

Table A2.1:OLS estimations of <strong>in</strong>vestments <strong>in</strong> water & land, livestock, equipment and build<strong>in</strong>g<br />

OLS estimation coefficients<br />

Water&Land Livestock Equipment Build<strong>in</strong>gs<br />

<strong>non</strong>-<strong>farm</strong><strong>in</strong>come -0.0623 0.1360 **<br />

0.0492 0.1160 ***<br />

fm1sex 0.6252 ** 0.1146 * 1.3598 *** 0.5260 **<br />

fm1age -0.0055 0.0301 **<br />

fm1schooled 0.1673 1.0729 ***<br />

0.0154 ** -0.0035<br />

0.0936 0.1724<br />

hhlandholdsize 0.1394 *** -0.0723 * -0.0334 -0.0008<br />

Livestock -0.0090 0.1009 ** 0.0196 0.0033<br />

Fixed -0.1128 0.2686 **<br />

0.3080 *** 0.5012 ***<br />

tabiadismak -0.0229*** 0.0037 * -0.0129*** -0.0095**<br />

Edirm 0.3488 0.8483 **<br />

-0.0667 0.4894 *<br />

Havei 0.1728 0.5356 * 0.1953 0.0638<br />

Adults 0.3969 *** 0.1517 0.2137 *** -0.0987<br />

constant 3.7491 *** -1.6775 * -0.8813 -1.8389 **<br />

Notes: *,**,*** respectively significant at 10%, 5% and 1%; robust standard errors<br />

83

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!