16.05.2015 Views

Master's thesis - Student Positive Awards

Master's thesis - Student Positive Awards

Master's thesis - Student Positive Awards

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Master’s <strong>thesis</strong><br />

The impact of the Belgian political crisis<br />

on Belgian company results:<br />

evidence from stock market reaction<br />

Supervisor: Pr Dr Gani Aldashev<br />

Reader: Pr Dr Bertrand Candelon<br />

Thesis presented by Thomas Jeegers<br />

in order to obtain the titles of<br />

Master 120 en Sciences Economiques<br />

Orientation Générale - Finalité spécialisée<br />

and<br />

Master’s 60 in International Economics Studies<br />

ACADEMIC YEAR 2011-2012<br />

Economics School of Louvain/UCL · Place Montesquieu 3 · 1348 Louvain-la-Neuve<br />

Economics School of Louvain/FUNDP · Rempart de la Vierge 8 · 5000 Namur<br />

School of Business and Economics/UM · P.O. Box 616 · 6200 MD Maastricht


Acknowledgements<br />

It is a sincere pleasure to thank all those who made this <strong>thesis</strong> possible.<br />

First and foremost, I would like to thank Professor Gani Aldashev, my <strong>thesis</strong> supervisor,<br />

for his expert advice on the different topics covered in the coming pages. His support during<br />

the months needed to write this <strong>thesis</strong>, his encouraging comments and his suggestions were<br />

of priceless value. I would also like to thank Professor Bertrand Candelon, not only as the<br />

reader of this <strong>thesis</strong>, but also as my former Professor at Maastricht University, for having given<br />

me the burning desire to analyse further many macroeconomic issues. With regard to this<br />

<strong>thesis</strong>, his sharp understanding of the macroeconomic processes at work and his suggestions for<br />

improvement provided me with expert guidance and enabled me to reach this level of precision<br />

for the different econometric regressions.<br />

In addition, I am grateful to Professor Pierre Giot for his helpful advice concerning the<br />

financial aspects of the analysis driving this <strong>thesis</strong> and to Professor Paul Wynants for his detailed<br />

and clear scrutiny of the Belgian political crisis and without whose help this work would not<br />

have reached such relevancy. Their recommendations certainly contributed significantly to the<br />

completion of this <strong>thesis</strong> and to the insights that were able to be drawn from it.<br />

Moreover, I would like to thank my friends for their comments, for the time they spent on<br />

reading the previous versions of this <strong>thesis</strong> and for their unflinching motivation in the many<br />

projects we undertook together. Their contributions were so varied that I could not rank them,<br />

so I will simply list them in alphabetical order. Grateful thanks to Bastien, Joris, Julien, Kevin,<br />

Maxime, Stéphane, Xavier and last but not least, to Stefanie, my endless source of inspiration.<br />

In addition to that, special thanks to my parents for daily challenging my perspectives for<br />

the future and for their unconditional support over so many years.<br />

Finally, I would like to thank all the people I have met during my travels around the world,<br />

for having broadened my mind on global issues. It gave me the opportunity to take a step back<br />

and think about the Belgian political difficulties from a different angle. I owe them intellectually<br />

much more than I could possibly acknowledge. I hope that I will meet them again and be able<br />

to bring them as much as they brought me.<br />

Thomas Jeegers<br />

ii


Abstract<br />

In 2010-2011, Belgium experienced the longest political crisis of recent history. But how did the<br />

Belgian stock market react to this crisis? Theory suggests that, under the assumption of market<br />

efficiency, any political event should be anticipated and should have no impact on stock prices.<br />

But are the markets really efficient in a period of crisis? Or do they respond to political events<br />

once these events have actually occurred? These are the questions that we will be investigating<br />

in the coming pages.<br />

The Belgian 2010-2011 political crisis 1 gives us a unique opportunity to analyse the economic<br />

impacts of political events in the context of a crisis. This analysis consists of an event study<br />

built upon the Belgian political occurrences relevant to the outcome of the crisis. Unlike some<br />

other similar approaches, we do not analyse the impact of isolated individual events. Instead, we<br />

take advantage of the uninterrupted sequence of events that have shaken the Belgian political<br />

scene by investigating how a series of political events impacts the main indicator of the stock<br />

market of Belgium: the BEL20.<br />

As was underlined by MacKinlay (1997), event studies are particularly useful for such kinds<br />

of dissection of a period, since they reflect the impact of different types of events immediately in<br />

stock and security prices. Abnormal stock returns are, therefore, usually central to most event<br />

studies. However, it is not our purpose to focus on abnormal returns. The objective, instead, is<br />

put on the process of building a relevant political indicator of the Belgian political crisis and on<br />

the analysis of its effect on the daily returns of the BEL20 index, in a well-specified model, free<br />

of endogeneity, of anticipatory movements and robust to heteroskedastic residuals.<br />

Evidence of significant and robust results is provided. Methodical and punctilious, we<br />

tried as much as we could to provide a thorough analysis reflecting the complex reality of the<br />

political world. We place the Belgian political crisis of 2010-2011 in context, give details about<br />

the selection of the events necessary to build the political indicator and justify why we take<br />

particular events into account if their inclusion may be considered subjective. With regard to<br />

the econometric regressions, intermediate steps and results are provided, most of the common<br />

problems for least squares regressions are tested and corrected if necessary and different tests of<br />

robustness are conducted. Finally, we extend the analysis to more sophisticated models in order<br />

to fit the reality of the stock market as closely as possible.<br />

Keywords: financial economics, political crisis, stock market reaction, BEL20, event study.<br />

1 And still on-going at the time this <strong>thesis</strong> was begun.<br />

iii


Contents<br />

Acknowledgements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ii<br />

Abstract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iii<br />

Contents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . iv<br />

List of tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . vi<br />

List of figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . viii<br />

List of abbreviations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . ix<br />

Introduction 1<br />

1 Literature review 4<br />

2 The Belgian context 8<br />

2.1 Political aspects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8<br />

2.1.1 Insights into the Belgian political system . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8<br />

2.1.2 Brief review of Belgian political history . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9<br />

2.1.3 Political risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11<br />

2.2 Economic aspects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11<br />

2.2.1 Brief review of recent Belgian economic history . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12<br />

2.2.2 Macroeconomic situation: some key features . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13<br />

2.2.3 The BEL20 index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14<br />

2.3 Insights into the 2010-2011 crisis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15<br />

3 Setting up the indicator 16<br />

3.1 Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16<br />

3.2 Timespan . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17<br />

3.3 The different political indicators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18<br />

3.4 Computing the returns . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 20<br />

4 Significant events 23<br />

4.1 Politically significant events . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23<br />

4.2 Rating agencies’ outlooks and downgrades . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28<br />

4.2.1 Standard & Poor’s . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28<br />

4.2.2 Moody’s . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28<br />

4.2.3 Fitch Ratings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29<br />

4.2.4 Conclusion about the ratings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29<br />

4.3 Summary of the events . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29<br />

iv


v<br />

5 Impact of political events on the Brussels stock market 31<br />

5.1 Theoretical background . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31<br />

5.1.1 Efficient market hypo<strong>thesis</strong> . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32<br />

5.1.2 Capital asset pricing model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32<br />

5.1.3 Arbitrage pricing theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33<br />

5.2 Multiple regression analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34<br />

5.2.1 Simplistic return-analysis model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34<br />

5.2.2 Adding the main political indicator, free of endogeneity, to the model . . 36<br />

5.2.3 Adding the control variables to the model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38<br />

5.2.4 Heteroskedasticity: verification and correction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46<br />

5.2.5 Autocorrelation: verification for both the returns and the residuals . . . . 48<br />

5.2.6 Anticipation and late reaction effects . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49<br />

5.2.7 Robustness of the political indicator: dropping the events, each in turn . 50<br />

5.2.8 Robustness of the political indicator: alternative indicators . . . . . . . . 51<br />

5.2.9 Robustness of the rating dummy: alternative indicator . . . . . . . . . . . 53<br />

5.2.10 Summary of the main model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54<br />

5.3 Extensions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56<br />

5.3.1 Testing for unit root . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56<br />

5.3.2 Error correction model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57<br />

5.3.3 Generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity model . . . . . . 60<br />

5.3.4 Exponential generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity model 63<br />

6 Discussion 65<br />

7 Conclusion 70<br />

Appendices 73<br />

Bibliography 84<br />

Books . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84<br />

Articles in journals . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86<br />

Online newspapers . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92<br />

Databases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97<br />

Others . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98


List of Tables<br />

5.1 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, controlling for interdependence with the<br />

European stock market index Euro Stoxx 50. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35<br />

5.2 Instrumental variables (2SLS) regression of the BEL20 daily returns, using an ad<br />

hoc estimator of the political indicator as the instrument. . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38<br />

5.3 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding the square of the daily returns of<br />

the Euro Stoxx 50 index as a regressor. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39<br />

5.4 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding an indicator of rating agencies’<br />

modifications in outlook and downgrades as a regressor. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40<br />

5.5 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding as a regressor the daily change in<br />

the yield of Belgian government bonds on the secondary market, with one-year<br />

maturity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41<br />

5.6 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding the predictability of the political<br />

events as a regressor, measured as a three-day lagged estimation of the variance. 42<br />

5.7 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding the change in the interbank interest<br />

rate (one-year maturity Euribor) as a regressor. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43<br />

5.8 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding as a regressor the monthly growth<br />

of M3 (free of endogeneity) as an estimator for inflation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44<br />

5.9 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all selected control variables and adding<br />

the squared residuals as a regressor for an heteroskedasticity check. . . . . . . . . 47<br />

5.10 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all selected control variables, with the<br />

residuals robust to heteroskedasticity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47<br />

5.11 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, using a one-day lagged version of the main<br />

political indicator as a regressor. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49<br />

5.12 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, using a one-day anticipated version of the<br />

main political indicator as a regressor. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50<br />

5.13 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all selected control variables, with the<br />

residuals robust to heteroskedasticity and with separate indicators for positive<br />

and negative events. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51<br />

5.14 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all selected control variables, robust to<br />

heteroskedasticity, using more political events in the political indicator. . . . . . 52<br />

5.15 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all selected control variables, with the<br />

residuals robust to heteroskedasticity and using the “main political indicator 2”<br />

purged from endogeneity. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53<br />

5.16 Regression of the BEL20 daily returns on all selected control variables, with<br />

the political indicator purged from endogeneity and the residuals robust to<br />

heteroskedasticity, replacing the rating dummy by a more sophisticated indicator. 54<br />

5.17 Vector error correction model, with the residuals corrected for heteroskedasticity. 59<br />

5.18 Generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity regression. . . . . . . . 62<br />

5.19 Exponential generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity regression. . 64<br />

vi


A.1 Final results of the main model, corrected for endogeneity and heteroskedasticity:<br />

2SLS regression, using a generated instrumental variable for the political indicator. 83<br />

A.2 Final results of the main model, corrected only for heteroskedasticity: basic OLS<br />

regression, robust to an arbitrary form of heteroskedasticity. . . . . . . . . . . . . 83<br />

vii


List of Figures<br />

2.1 Belgian Public Debt (1981 - 2010). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13<br />

4.1 Main Belgian political events against the BEL20 and Euro Stoxx 50 indices daily<br />

returns, April 19, 2010 - December 31, 2010 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30<br />

4.2 Main Belgian political events against the BEL20 and Euro Stoxx 50 indices daily<br />

returns, January 01, 2011 - December 13, 2011 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 30<br />

A.1 Constituency Brussels-Halle-Vilvoorde. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81<br />

A.2 Frequency distribution of the daily returns of the BEL20 over the period: April<br />

19, 2010 - December 13, 2011. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82<br />

viii


List of abbreviations<br />

2SLS:<br />

Two-stage least squares<br />

APT:<br />

Arbitrage pricing theory<br />

ARCH:<br />

Autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity<br />

BHV:<br />

Brussels-Halle-Vilvoorde<br />

CAPM:<br />

Capital asset pricing model<br />

CD&V:<br />

Christen-Democratisch en Vlaams<br />

cdH:<br />

Centre Démocrate Humaniste<br />

CRSP:<br />

Center for Research in Security Prices<br />

CVP:<br />

Christelijke Volkspartij<br />

DF-GLS: Dickey–Fuller generalised least squares<br />

DW:<br />

Durbin-Watson<br />

ECM:<br />

Error correction model<br />

EGARCH: Exponential generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity<br />

EMH:<br />

Efficient market hypo<strong>thesis</strong><br />

Eonia:<br />

Euro overnight index average<br />

Euribor: Euro interbank offered rate<br />

FDF: Front Démocratique des Francophones (before January 2010)<br />

FDF: Fédéralistes Démocrates Francophones (since January 2010)<br />

FFR:<br />

Federal fund rate<br />

GARCH: Generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity<br />

IID:<br />

Independent and identically distributed<br />

IV:<br />

Instrumental variable<br />

Libor:<br />

London interbank offered rate<br />

MR:<br />

Mouvement Réformateur<br />

MLE:<br />

Maximum likelihood estimate<br />

N-VA:<br />

Nieuw-Vlaamse Alliantie<br />

OLS:<br />

Ordinary least squares<br />

Open Vld: Open Vlaamse Liberalen en Democraten<br />

PS:<br />

Parti Socialiste<br />

RW:<br />

Rassemblement Wallon<br />

S&P:<br />

Standard & Poor’s<br />

sp.a:<br />

Socialistische Partij Anders<br />

Std. Err.: Standard error<br />

VB: Vlaams Block (before November 2004)<br />

VB: Vlaams Belang (since November 2004)<br />

VECM:<br />

Vector error correction model<br />

WLS:<br />

Weighted least squares<br />

ix


Introduction<br />

“The goal in the end is not to win elections. The goal is to change society.”<br />

Paul Krugman, 2012<br />

In 2011, Belgium became “world champion” as the country with the most extended political<br />

crisis, when it took from Iraq the record of the longest period in times of peace without a<br />

federal government. From April 26, 2010, the resignation date of the Leterme II government,<br />

to December 6, 2011, when Elio Di Rupo took the oath as the new Prime Minister, the 589<br />

days 2 during which Belgium lacked a government made of this period a unique, harmful and<br />

interesting political crisis to analyse.<br />

The behaviour of stock markets in difficult political periods or times of war has received a lot<br />

of attention in economic and financial literature over the past 20 years. As identified by Fama<br />

(1990) and evidenced over a longer period by Schwert (1990), more than 40% of the variations<br />

in price on the stock market cannot be explained by real economic activity. Many authors have,<br />

therefore, tried to identify the other variables that can explain the variations in stock prices,<br />

within which the political events are a substantial part. In this paper, we add to this literature<br />

by covering an issue which, to the best of our knowledge, has not been analysed before, i.e. the<br />

impact of the Belgian political crisis (2010-2011) on the Brussels stock exchange main index;<br />

the BEL20.<br />

A stock market approach to the behaviour of a government concedes that the policies it<br />

implements are essential in determining the environment in which investors will conduct their<br />

transactions. These transactions will in turn collectively influence the price, and thus the return,<br />

of a firm’s stock. In the Belgian case, a temporary government was in place during the 2010-2011<br />

crisis, but its purpose was to take care of current and urgent affairs and it was not supposed<br />

to deal with important topics that had been stalemated while the previous government was in<br />

power. Therefore, the environment for investors was, at best, unstable and likely to provoke<br />

uncertainties. Empirical results confirm this instability since we find evidence for significant<br />

reaction in the stock prices concurrent to major political events, during the crisis.<br />

The logic behind event studies 3 is often based on the efficient market hypo<strong>thesis</strong> (EMH),<br />

according to which all available information and expectations are reflected by the prices of the<br />

market 4 . A political event study consists of analysing the reaction of the market (typically the<br />

stock market) after one or several political events that are likely to have an impact on stock<br />

prices. These reactions are typically evaluated through the analysis of abnormal returns within<br />

the period of interest. A literature review on the topic seems to indicate that political event<br />

studies reach more significant results when the political environment is unstable (i.e. during<br />

2 If we consider the federal election of June 13, 2010 as the starting date, as many sources do, then the length<br />

of the crisis amounts to 541 days.<br />

3 See Wells (2004).<br />

4 For further information, see section 5.1.1 or Fama (1970).<br />

1


2<br />

political crises, in highly politically risky environments or in emerging markets). However,<br />

depending on the periods and the markets analysed, evidence is found for both significant effects<br />

of political events on the stock markets and non-significant effects.<br />

The “event window”, as defined by MacKinlay (1997) for an event study, is “the period<br />

over which the security prices of the firms involved [...] will be examined”. In our case, the<br />

key beginning and ending dates are April 26, 2010 and December 6, 2011, as this is the period<br />

characterised by the absence of a government in Belgium. As pointed out by Zach (2003),<br />

not much literature shows direct evidence of a link between political events and stock market<br />

fluctuations. Nevertheless, this is mainly due to the fact that it is typically hard to quantify<br />

political change. This literature, though, can be split up into short-window event studies and<br />

long-horizon studies. Our analysis falls within the first of these groups. Further categorising<br />

our approach, we build an ad hoc political indicator, slightly more sophisticated than a dummy<br />

variable. This approach has not been extensively covered in literature but seems to fit the case<br />

at hand very well.<br />

The aim of this <strong>thesis</strong> is dual. On the one hand, we want to make the <strong>thesis</strong> conclusions<br />

useful for any possible future political crisis. On the other hand, the procedure can be reiterated<br />

for another country, in order to evaluate to what extent the stock market depends on the political<br />

situation. Such information is particularly interesting for potential investors since, as mentioned<br />

in the literature review, some countries are more subject than others to strong variations in<br />

stock returns after significant political events.<br />

The procedure consists of a multi-factor least squares approach, fitting a regression of the<br />

daily returns 5 of the BEL20 index on an indicator of political events. We use several control<br />

variables in the process, in order to explain a bigger proportion of the BEL20 fluctuations and,<br />

therefore, to decrease the variance of the political indicator. We find interesting and somewhat<br />

counterintuitive results. The negative political events (not in favour of the formation of a<br />

government) have a positive impact on the stock market, on the day of the event, and the<br />

positive events have a negative impact. These results are robust to the specification of the<br />

model and remain valid even when we drop some of the political events. Our results show a high<br />

level of significance (within a 2% threshold) and are relatively free of endogeneity, anticipatory<br />

movements and heteroskedasticity.<br />

An empirical work in financial econometrics is never easy to conduct. Every econometric<br />

model has some drawbacks and some weaknesses. While simple models have the benefits of clarity,<br />

which led to their extensive use in literature, their limitations have often been reported. It made<br />

econometricians establish more sophisticated models, which are an interesting complement to the<br />

basic approaches, but they often need many assumptions to fit the complex reality of the political<br />

and financial worlds. In addition, econometrics is a discipline in which a causal relationship can<br />

never be found. We can only draw conclusions on causal inference, that is, a likelihood that<br />

a causal relationship between two or more variables exist. However, these weaknesses do not<br />

discard the econometric approach, as techniques exist to release the implausible assumptions, to<br />

correct for possible bias and ultimately to adequately fit reality.<br />

The source of the data for stock prices is Datastream (2012); the different indicators that we<br />

use as control variables come from the National Bank of Belgium (2012) or from Datastream<br />

(2012); the source of the data for the political events is Faniel (2011), completed by personal<br />

researches and with the help and supervision of Professor Paul Wynants, who teaches Belgian<br />

5 We decided to restrict our attention to an analysis of the daily returns of this index, in order to keep the<br />

focus on one single idea and to conduct a proper investigation into it. We initially also investigated parallel topics,<br />

such as the impact of the political events on the volatility of the BEL20 or on the daily volume of transactions.<br />

But we finally disregarded these additions, because they are of little added value while excluding them allowed us<br />

to keep the light shed on one key aspect of the financial market.


3<br />

Politics at the University of Namur (Belgium).<br />

In chapter 1, we start off by reviewing the state of the art concerning political event studies<br />

and dummy variable event studies, whose combination is the methodology used in this <strong>thesis</strong>.<br />

Chapter 2 provides the reader with the necessary background knowledge about Belgium and its<br />

political system and history, leading to a better understanding of the crisis, of the events that<br />

precipitated it and ultimately of the reason why their impact on the stock market is significant.<br />

In chapter 3, the methodological and practical aspects of the procedure are covered. The detailed<br />

analysis of the political events to be investigated is done in chapter 4. Finally, the econometrical<br />

work is performed in chapter 5. This chapter covers the theoretical foundations of stock return<br />

analyses for the model that we investigate and also covers some extensions to this model. The<br />

complexity of the econometric work is progressive: we start with an overly simplistic model that<br />

gets more and more sophisticated as we go along. We add one by one seven control variables<br />

and justify their addition to the model. We correct for endogeneity of the political indicator<br />

and for heteroskedasticity of the residuals. We also test the robustness of our results according<br />

to different approaches. Finally, the extensions include the application of an error correction<br />

model and of autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models. We finish the <strong>thesis</strong> with<br />

a discussion about the relevancy of our methodology. This is done through a series of short<br />

reviews, each concerning a particular topic raised in this study and by establishing the basis for<br />

possible further extensions of the current work.


Chapter 1<br />

Literature review<br />

Event studies are a common procedure in economic, accounting and finance literature, measuring<br />

the impact of an event of interest on some economic variables. The first event study that can be<br />

found in literature probably dates back to the interwar period with Dolley (1933), analysing the<br />

effect of stock splits on stock prices. Over the following three decades, the procedure of event<br />

studies became slightly more sophisticated, including control variables in the analyses. The event<br />

study literature during this period was characterised by authors such as Myers and Bakay (1948),<br />

Barker (1958) and Ashley (1962) 6 . In the late 1960s, event studies started to be commonly used<br />

in relevant literature, with Fama et al. (1969) 7 sparking this habit (Pynnönen (2005)). In the<br />

following few years, the aim of this kind of studies was focused on the fluctuations of security<br />

prices (Binder (1998)). Later, other variables of interest were used in this type of literature,<br />

such as the exchange or interest rates. Event studies were often used to measure the effect of<br />

corporate events on wealth or to test the efficient market hypo<strong>thesis</strong> 8 and they blossomed in<br />

such literature, with at least 565 papers in relevant finance journals between 1974 and 2000<br />

(Aktas et al. (2007)). The results of previous event studies have shown that stock prices respond<br />

to news about corporate control and about policies and macroeconomic conditions that are<br />

likely to affect fundamentals of the economy.<br />

The link between political events (exclusively) and share prices was left aside in literature<br />

until the late 1980s. In the same period, other fields started to be analysed by event studies,<br />

such as insurance literature (Henderson (1990)). Some of the political event studies have been<br />

performed with positive results, under some circumstances and during certain periods. In<br />

this chapter, we review some intriguing papers considering political event studies (mainly the<br />

short-window ones), since this is the procedure that we follow in the remainder of the paper.<br />

Other authors, their procedure and their results will also be introduced in further chapters<br />

(especially in chapter 5) of this <strong>thesis</strong>, where we investigate sharper financial and econometrical<br />

models 9 . Some papers in the coming list are not strictly restricted to political events, but all of<br />

6 Cited by MacKinlay (1997), page 14 and by Campbell et al. (1997), page 150.<br />

7 Fama et al. (1969) used the term “event study” for the first time, describing a new methodology for measuring<br />

the adjustment process of stock prices. Their methodology is very similar to contemporary event studies and<br />

their paper was cited more than 500 times in the following 25 years, showing that their trailblazing approach was<br />

the basis behind the many following event studies.<br />

8 They are called “market efficiency studies” and evaluate the rapidity and accuracy of market reactions to new<br />

information. The EMH states that all available information and expectations are reflected by market prices, and<br />

that any news is integrated without delay into these prices. We investigate the EMH into more details in section<br />

5.1.1.<br />

9 This choice was made for two reasons; firstly it allows us to keep the focus on the link between politics and<br />

the stock market throughout the first four chapters, rather than entering financial and econometrical models<br />

before alluding to the context or explaining our procedure. Secondly it enables the reader to link theory with<br />

empirical evidence of the case under scrutiny, in chapter 5.<br />

4


5<br />

them include at least political events as a potential cause for stock price fluctuations. Moreover,<br />

some studies are not directly applicable to Belgium, as they focus on the impact on the stock<br />

market of elections and of the party holding the power. We will not cover that kind of analysis in<br />

this <strong>thesis</strong>, because Belgium is a particracy (see section 2.1.1 for further details), which implies<br />

that no party fully controls the political scene. Therefore, the approach of using either the<br />

impact of elections or the changes in the main party in the country makes less sense in the<br />

case of Belgium, since the impact is likely to be more limited in a country with this political<br />

structure. However, the results of this literature are worth mentioning, since they evidence the<br />

existence of a relationship between politics and the stock markets. As political event studies<br />

do not show a strong tendency of being cumulative 10 , we cannot build a proper “history” of<br />

this art, i.e. how the procedure evolved over the years. However, most papers rely on the basic<br />

approach of Fama et al. (1969), which has become the most accepted standard in event studies.<br />

Since the cumulative approach is not possible for this topic, we present the existing papers on<br />

the topic in a chronological way.<br />

Niederhoffer (1971) analyses how world events, including some political events, affect the<br />

movements of the stocks in the S&P 500 index. These events are selected according to the<br />

magnitude of their headlines in the New York Times, measured according to the number of<br />

columns in the newspaper. His results show that on days following world events, the returns are<br />

more extreme than on other days. It evidences that the selected events have an impact on the<br />

fluctuations of the stocks included in the S&P 500.<br />

Huang (1985) shows that the party affiliation of the U.S. president yields a difference of<br />

annual rates of return on stocks, concluding that those returns are higher under Democratic<br />

presidents over the period 1929-1980. He also discovered a pattern of four-year cycles in stock<br />

returns in the United States, corresponding to the presidential terms. His result was confirmed<br />

over the period 1888-2001 by Siegel (2002) 11 .<br />

Cutler et al. (1989) investigate the impact of political and world events on the Dow Jones<br />

stock index, using monthly stock returns from 1926 to 1985. They discovered a small and<br />

non-significant impact of main events on stock returns, but their results show a higher volatility<br />

of the returns on days characterised by a major event, on average, than on other days.<br />

Kim and Mei (1994) measure the impact of political risk on asset prices in Hong Kong, over<br />

the period from 1989 to 1993. They show that adding a political risk dummy “significantly<br />

increases the explanatory power of return regressions” and that China’s political policy has an<br />

effect on the stock market of Hong Kong. They also model the fluctuations in volatility as a<br />

function of political events.<br />

Chan and Wei (1996) investigate further this work, focusing on the impact of occurences<br />

of political events on the stock market of Hong Kong. They find an impact on the volatility<br />

of the stocks of several indices. The impact on the returns of the stocks is not significant for<br />

all indices, however. For the index for which they find significance, the direction of the shock<br />

after political events is opposed to what we found for Belgium: they find a positive impact after<br />

favourable events and negative impacts after unfavourable events.<br />

Pantzalis et al. (2000) analyse, from 1974 to 1995 and through an event study, how the<br />

stock market reacts before and after political election dates. Using indices of 33 countries, they<br />

conclude that the stock returns in the weeks preceding the political elections are abnormally<br />

higher than usual. They also find more significant results for countries for which the press has<br />

less freedom.<br />

10 “Cumulativeness” in literature is the fact that each author can rely upon his predecessors and build his<br />

work upon existing literature. Hedges (1987) argues, for example, that literature in physical science is usually<br />

cumulative, while the cumulativeness in social sciences is usually much smaller.<br />

11 Cited in Jones and Banning (2009).


6<br />

Zach (2003) finds evidence that in Israel, returns on stocks are more extreme on days that<br />

follow political events than on days that do not. The fact that Israeli stocks traded only in the<br />

United States do not show such extreme returns make it even more likely that it is indeed the<br />

political events that are the cause of the extreme stock returns movements in Israel.<br />

Abadie and Gardeazabal (2003) try to measure the economic cost of political conflicts<br />

(terrorist attacks) in the Basque country, notably through the stock market. They find significant<br />

and robust evidence that the stocks of the Basque country comparatively underperform during<br />

unstable periods, while they outperformed the non-Basque stocks during the cease-fire period of<br />

1998-1999.<br />

Leblang and Mukherjee (2004) refer to the financial impact of electoral systems, elections,<br />

partisanship and political uncertainty. They analyse how the stock market responds to public<br />

signals. Another point of their argumentation is the fact that when an electoral victory of a<br />

left-wing party is anticipated, then the volatility of stock prices increases 12 .<br />

Aquino (2004) reviews the impact of major events in the Philippines during the period from<br />

July 1987 to May 2004. His results confirm that the stock market is influenced by political and<br />

economic events, and even by natural phenomena.<br />

Chen et al. (2005) analyse further emerging markets, with the case of Taiwan. Using simple<br />

least squares models to analyse the impact of political events on the stock market, they find<br />

significant abnormal returns following these events but using a multivariate regression model,<br />

this evidence is attenuated (except for some important events).<br />

Jensen and Schmith (2005) study the effect of the election of a politician on the stock market<br />

in Brasil. One result they find, which is an expected one, is that electoral uncertainty increases<br />

stock market volatility.<br />

Aktas and Oncu (2006) test the efficient market hypo<strong>thesis</strong>. Their test consists of measuring<br />

the returns of different portfolios of the Turkish stock market after main events in Turkey,<br />

including political events. Their results clearly show no overreaction or underreaction from the<br />

investors. The assumptions of the EMH are, therefore, not violated with this study.<br />

Romero-Meza et al. (2007) investigate the cause of the nonlinearities in the stock market<br />

index in Chili. They call it a “reverse form of event study”, since they search for economic<br />

and political events explaining the stock market index fluctuations. They find that the events<br />

explaining the abnormal fluctuations are mainly regulatory changes and international events.<br />

Benton (2008), along the same lines as Jensen and Schmith (2005), analyse the impact of<br />

campaign commitments on the stock market in Mexico. They find that investors react negatively<br />

to electoral uncertainty, while no significant move is found after electoral commitments of the<br />

candidates.<br />

Ali et al. (2010) assess the short-run stock overreaction in Malaysia. They use political events<br />

to represent domestic events because of the strong political involvement in Malaysia, implying<br />

interconnections between business and politics. Their findings confirm that the Malaysian stock<br />

market overreacts significantly to economic events, which is coherent with the results of Bilson<br />

et al. (2002), showing that, in emerging markets, political risk is an important explanatory factor<br />

in the returns’ fluctuations.<br />

Milyo (2012) summarises previous event studies on possible political corruption, finding<br />

evidence that firms located in the neighbourhood of powerful political actors in the US are<br />

subject to favoritism and are, therefore, more likely to show abnormal returns.<br />

Junqué de Fortuny et al. (2012) conduct a different type of event study. They analyse the link<br />

between political events and political news during the Belgian political crisis 2010-2011. Their<br />

approach is based on an analysis of the opinions contained within the articles of the Flemish<br />

12 Established notably by Herron (2000), Cohen (1993), Alesina et al. (1997), Freeman et al. (2000) and Gemmill<br />

and Saflekos (2000).


newspapers, over the 541 days of the crisis (June 13, 2010 - December 6, 2011). Detecting<br />

the sentiments of 68 000 articles through fully computerised “opinion mining”, they find that<br />

newspapers show peaks of negative or positive opinion, during the hottest moments of the<br />

negotiations. Their approach is thus very different from ours, but their conclusions somehow<br />

complement ours, since they find a correlation between newspapers opinions and the key moments<br />

of the crisis. Since we mainly use newspapers as references for the establishment of a political<br />

indicator (see chapter 4), the work of Junqué de Fortuny et al. (2012) seems to confirm that<br />

newspapers are indeed a reasonably good reflection of the political process in progress.<br />

As one can notice, most of these analyses concern politically unstable or emerging countries.<br />

It is worth mentioning it, since the political instability of the Belgian political scene might cast<br />

doubts on the efficiency of its stock market. Now that we have reviewed the results of authors<br />

on the existing relationship between politics and the stock market, we will dig into the details<br />

of the Belgian structure, both economically and politically. Investigating the particularities of<br />

Belgium will enable the reader to recognise the importance of this relationship for the Belgian<br />

case.<br />

7


Chapter 2<br />

The Belgian context<br />

“There are in Belgium, the Walloon and the Flemish; there are no Belgians.” 13<br />

Jules Destrée (1963)<br />

To gain an understanding of the events of the Belgian political crisis, some background<br />

knowledge about this particular country is needed. In this chapter, we review in turn the political<br />

background in which the longest governmental crisis of history emerged, some key fundamentals<br />

of the Belgian economy and finally, some insights into the political stalemate of 2010-2011.<br />

2.1 Political aspects<br />

In order to correctly understand the political crisis that shook Belgium from April 2010 to<br />

December 2011, one needs to understand how Belgium is ruled and especially, the particular<br />

history of the country. This section is heavily based on Delwit et al. (1999) and Deschouwer<br />

(2009), which are two of the few references giving the opportunity to understand how the Belgian<br />

political system has been forged over the years. We first briefly review the Belgian political<br />

system, then we draw attention to some milestones in the political history of Belgium. In no<br />

way do we claim to be exhaustive about any of the topics raised in this section; the objective is<br />

rather to provide the reader with the necessary background knowledge about Belgian politics to<br />

fully understand the extent and the interpretation of the analysis at hand.<br />

2.1.1 Insights into the Belgian political system<br />

“In Belgium, the political system reflects, as elsewhere, the social complexity.”<br />

Pascal Delwit et al. (1999)<br />

Understanding the underlying reasons for the political crisis in Belgium is a tough task if one<br />

does not know how complicated the Belgian political structure is. Based on a federal parliamentary<br />

democracy and under a constitutional monarchy, Belgium has one central government in<br />

addition to which there are three regions, each with a government responsible for many essential<br />

matters, such as education, environment or public health. These regions are the Walloon Region,<br />

the Flemish Region and the Region of Brussels-Capital. A federal state is based on the rule of<br />

equity. In Belgium, this rule of equity exists, but only within each community or each region<br />

(Delwit et al. (1999)).<br />

13 Originally in French: “Il y a en Belgique, des Wallons et des Flamands; il n’y a pas de Belges.”<br />

8


9<br />

There are three communities; Flemish, French and German-speaking (one for each of the three<br />

national languages; Dutch, French and German), but in each of these communities, municipalities<br />

offering their public services also in some or all of the other national languages exist. To be<br />

exact, 25 municipalities benefit from these language facilities 14 . In addition to the three regions<br />

and the three communities, Belgium is also divided into four language areas; the Dutch language<br />

area, the French one, the German one and Brussels, which is bilingual (French/Dutch).<br />

The form of government in Belgium is based on group representation, a typical form for very<br />

divided societies, called “consociationalism” (Deschouwer (2009)). This scheme is designed to<br />

avoid conflicts and requires the parties involved to agree or to face a standstill for the matters<br />

concerning them all. Yet, the parties are usually given a large autonomy. Belgian federalism can<br />

be termed confrontational federalism 15 . Indeed, the two big linguistic communities make it hard<br />

to manage the equilibrium. Belgium is, therefore, subject to continuous identity and community<br />

crises.<br />

The proportional representation characterising the Belgian political scene has led to a<br />

“particracy” system, a government where different parties have a significant influence on the<br />

political process. In Belgium, the parties are the most influential political actors (Deschouwer<br />

(2009)). Finally, three historical political pillars exist; Social Christian, Socialist and Liberal 16 .<br />

2.1.2 Brief review of Belgian political history<br />

“When Belgian independence was declared, language reflected social-class differences more than a<br />

cultural cleavage.”<br />

Robert Mnookin (2007)<br />

Since its foundation, Belgium had a composite population. Built as a buffer between different<br />

rival countries and not according to a nationalistic movement as was the case for Italy or Germany,<br />

it has long been considered as divided between the Flemish and the Walloons. Belgium has a<br />

long history of internal conflicts, however these never became violent.<br />

Broadly speaking, during the first century of its existence, the elite in Belgium were all<br />

French-speaking, no matter whether they were Flemish, Walloon or inhabitants of Brussels.<br />

During the 20 th century however, the Flemish grew in importance, as Flanders rose. In 1970,<br />

the federalisation of the State took place with the first State reform, establishing cultural<br />

communities, at the behest of the Flemish.<br />

The political dualisation of Belgian society dates from the late 19 th century 17 , when two<br />

political structures developed; one Catholic, the other socialist. It was only in 1954 that a party,<br />

the Christelijke Vlaamse Volksunie (fast abandoning the Christian denomination), was built<br />

around a federalist structure. They revendicated a two-sided federal State, with Brussels as<br />

federal district. Its growth was important in the 1960s and the early 1970s while another party<br />

grew in parallel; the Front démocratique des Bruxellois (later renamed Front démocratique des<br />

Francophones (FDF), then Fédéralistes Démocrates Francophones in January 2010), fighting for<br />

the rights of the French speakers in Brussels. The third regional party to rise during this period<br />

(in addition to the VU, in Flanders, and to the FDF, in Brussels) is the Rassemblement Wallon<br />

(RW), in Wallonia. The RW was established in 1965 to protect the interests of a declining<br />

Wallonia, but this party no longer exists today. There was a turning point in the late 1960s,<br />

14 Figure A.1 on page 81 illustrates the proportion of native French-speakers in the Brussels-Halle-Vilvoorde<br />

(BHV) constituency. One can notice on this figure how diverse the population in the area around Brussels is.<br />

15 Originally “fédéralisme de confrontation” by Delwit et al. (1999), p.57.<br />

16 The parties representing these pillars notably established together the consociational logic ruling the country,<br />

after World War I (Deschouwer (2009)).<br />

17 The coming paragraph is based on Delwit et al. (1999), pages 113 to 153.


10<br />

when the decline of the historical parties started, leaving room for another type of dualisation on<br />

the Belgian political scene. The Christian Social Party 18 was the first one to break up because<br />

of internal disagreements between the Flemish and French-speaking sides. The move of the<br />

French-speaking section of the Catholic University of Louvain from Flanders to Wallonia, in<br />

1968, was major evidence of the split. The political environment of the 1970s saw another<br />

important change; the existence of a different dominant party in each of the three regions (the<br />

Socialist Party in Wallonia, the FDF in Brussels and the CVP in Flanders).<br />

In the early 1980s, two ecologist parties were founded in Belgium; Agalev (today known<br />

as Groen!) and Ecolo. In addition to these new ones, at about the same period, Belgium<br />

also saw the establishment of far-right parties. In Flanders, in 1979, it was the Vlaams Block<br />

(VB), built from a cartel between two Flemish parties; the Vlaams Nationale Partij and the<br />

Vlaamse Volkspartij. Distinguishing features of the Vlaams Block were notably an elitism based<br />

on nationality and a strong Flemish patriotism. This party quickly rose in Antwerp, then in the<br />

whole of Flanders. In the French-speaking Community, the Front National is another far-right<br />

party, founded during the same period. It grew over the following few years, but it never held a<br />

substantial share of the government.<br />

The 1990s, and in particular the elections of 1991, fragmented the Belgian political scene.<br />

Many small parties rose, while the three historical Belgian political families lost a significant<br />

share of their voters. This fragmentation increases all along the decade (Delwit mentions,<br />

in Jaumain (1997), a record number of candidates for the elections of 1995) and reaches its<br />

maximum at the turn of the century (Delwit (2003)). The years 1996-1997 know a deep evolution<br />

of the Belgian structure, as a consequence to the shocks and traumatisms of Belgian society<br />

during this period (Mabille (2000)). A new era begins for the country, implying a different way<br />

to look at the political scene.<br />

The tensions between the French-speaking and Flemish Communities did not decrease in<br />

the 2000s. In October 2001, a new centre-right Flemish nationalist party, the Nieuw-Vlaamse<br />

Alliantie (N-VA), was replaced from its predecessor, the Volksunie. The N-VA craves an<br />

independent Flanders, which would be part of the European Union. In 2004, the Vlaams Block<br />

renamed itself Vlaams Belang (Erk (2005)). Together, the VB and the N-VA form the main<br />

secessionist right-wing Flemish parties, wishing for Flanders to be directly represented in the<br />

European Union (Rochtus (2010)). With the rise of the N-VA, a new page has been turned,<br />

since a democratic Flemish-nationalist party enjoys success based on its secessionist objectives,<br />

as Rochtus (2010) states, “contrary to the Vlaams Belang which is assumed to thank its previous<br />

successes to its xenophobic slogans”. The leading role of the N-VA on the political scene in the<br />

late 2000s is largely attributed to its main charismatic figure and leader: Bart De Wever. He<br />

also played, as we will see, a meaningful role in the 2010-2011 Belgian political crisis.<br />

Since its establishment, the country has undergone six State reforms, each of which took place<br />

within the last 42 years; in 1970, 1980, 1988-1989, 1993, 2001 and 2011. Let us briefly overview<br />

the main modifications resulting from each of these reforms 19 . In 1970, the three “Cultural<br />

Communities” were established, corresponding to the current Communities of the country.<br />

The National Parliament was divided into two language groups and a French-speaking/Dutchspeaking<br />

parity was imposed on the Council of Ministers (with the exception of the Prime<br />

Minister). Each language group could also, from this reform on, resort to an “alarm bell” if<br />

a proposed law would hurt its interest or disturb the good functioning of the country 20 . In<br />

1980, the power of the two main regions was enhanced, allowing their decrees to have the same<br />

18 “Christelijke Volkspartij” (CVP) and “Parti Social Chrétien”, respectively in Dutch and in French.<br />

19 We are mainly based on Rochtus (2010) for this part of the historical analysis.<br />

20 In april 2010, this procedure was used three days after the fall of the government (see section 4.1 for more<br />

details).


11<br />

value as federal law. The “Cultural” denomination of the Communities was abandoned, as their<br />

competences increased. In 1993, the Constitution was amended, giving more freedom to the<br />

Regions and Communities. The reforms of 2001 and 2011 gave even more power to these Regions<br />

and Communities and the recent reform also established the split of the BHV constituency.<br />

From 1991 to 2007, four governments reached the term of their four-years mandate, testifying<br />

to a relative political stability (Deschouwer (2009)). From June 2007 to December 2007, the<br />

country was shaken by another political crisis. This one was based on the question of whether,<br />

and to which extent, another State reform was necessary. The two opposing views on the topic<br />

were held by the Flemish, on the one hand, claiming that reforming the State would lead to a<br />

better governance of the country, and the French-speaking parties, on the other hand, fearing an<br />

eventual split of the country (Rochtus (2010)). The years following this period were characterised<br />

by political instability, as several governments (including some “interim governments”) were<br />

in place: Verhofstadt III, Leterme I, Van Rompuy I, Leterme II. Doubts have been expressed<br />

about the relevancy of Belgian federalism, notably because of the series of state reforms and the<br />

continuous Belgian political instability. It is beyond our scope to analyse whether these doubts<br />

are justified. Instead, we will investigate the impact of this political instability on the stock<br />

market. But before doing so, we investigate Belgium’s political risk and economic background,<br />

to which we now turn.<br />

2.1.3 Political risk<br />

Though this complex structure and wavering history might darken the functioning of the country,<br />

the political risk associated with the country is actually in the same category as other West-<br />

European countries. According to the PRS Group (2011), establishing yearly country reports<br />

for a hundred countries all over the world, the political risk of Belgium is not especially high. In<br />

particular, in 2010, Belgium had the twentieth lowest political risk in the world, halfway between<br />

its neighbours the Netherlands and France (respectively the world’s 5 th and 34 th lowest), and<br />

equivalent to the one of Germany. The PRS Group forecasts the risk of turmoil in international<br />

business, which is based on probable regime scenarios and on types of government interventions<br />

and it has estimated Belgium as a “low risk” country.<br />

Rating agencies play a large role in estimating a country’s risk. Those agencies are of even<br />

greater interest for the purpose of this <strong>thesis</strong>, since agencies’ notations have a direct impact<br />

on the price of a country’s company stocks. The three main rating agencies are Standard and<br />

Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch. As an example, in mid-December 2010, Standard & Poor’s warned<br />

the Belgian interim regime that it might downgrade Belgium if the setting up of a government<br />

continued to be delayed (L’Echo (May 7, 2011)). This threat remained pending for almost a<br />

year but was finally executed at the end of November 2011; Belgium was downgraded from<br />

“AA+” to “AA” in S&P’s notation (L’Echo (November 26, 2011)). Such kind of events will be<br />

included in our analyses of the stock market (see section 4.2 for further details).<br />

2.2 Economic aspects<br />

In this section, we review some macroeconomic indicators of the state of the Belgian economy,<br />

at the beginning of the crisis (2010). We also introduce some background about the economic<br />

history of the country, in order to better appraise the current situation.


12<br />

2.2.1 Brief review of recent Belgian economic history<br />

The context leading to the multiple crises and reforms of the past few decades in Belgium is<br />

intrinsically linked with the economic background of the country. Let us briefly review some of<br />

the main features of it, with a focus on the regional development of Belgium.<br />

Generally speaking 21 , after World War II, Belgium experienced thirty years of growth with<br />

low employment. This rise suddenly stopped at the end of the 1970s, as a consequence of<br />

the oil crisis and the increase in prices. The change was also characterised by the end of the<br />

Bretton-Woods era, and therefore the end of the convertibility of the American dollar into gold<br />

(August 15, 1971). The oil crisis led to a situation of stagflation in Belgium during the mid-1970s,<br />

notably because of its foreign dependence in the energy sector. This crisis significantly shook the<br />

Belgian economy, and is a considerable break in its history. In the 1980s, a social era began in<br />

Belgium, bringing with it higher wage demands and therefore inflation. In face of this rampant<br />

inflation, a minimum level of unemployment was used by companies, as a way to cap wage<br />

demands. Unemployment rose from 2% to 11% from 1970 to 1982. In 1982 and 1984, different<br />

mechanisms were used to help the economy to bounce back, including a devaluation of the<br />

Belgian franc. As a result, Belgium recovered some competitiveness but the imposed austerity<br />

resulted in an increase of the public-sector debt while investment fell. The drop in investment<br />

was also due to the sudden rise of interest rates, giving incentives to the owners of capital<br />

not to invest in the real economy but in monetary markets. In the 1980s, as a consequence<br />

to the baby-boom, a strong intensification of unemployment arose. The following years are<br />

characterised by a Europeanisation process and more generally by globalisation, allowing the<br />

country’s economy to bounce back. With regard to Belgian monetary policy, it was relinquished<br />

to the European System on June 1, 1998 and the Euro was adopted on January 1, 1999.<br />

If we turn to the picture within the country 22 , we can notice that Wallonia was dominant (in<br />

terms of regional GDP) until the 1960. In this period, simultaneously Flanders caught up with<br />

Wallonia and the industrial sector, mostly constituted of coal mining and the metal industry<br />

and mainly present in Wallonia, started declining. This fall, affecting most industrial regions of<br />

the European Union, brought about many job losses. Flemish politicians were claiming more<br />

autonomy for the Regions, in order for Flanders to stop subventionning Wallonia. From the<br />

mid-1980s to the mid-1990s, the growth of Flanders was higher than that of Wallonia and it<br />

resulted in a much higher GDP in the northern part of the country. This period represented a<br />

significant modification in the development of the country; in particular, Flanders previous to<br />

the 1950s was known to be mostly agrarian, while Wallonia was already more industrialised.<br />

From the end of the 1990s to the end of the 2000s, the growth rate of both regions did not<br />

differ widely, but their share in the Belgian GDP showed a steady gap. Over the same period,<br />

the share of Wallonia in the Belgian GDP fluctuated from 23% to 24%, while that of Flanders<br />

was between 57% and about 58% 23 . For the year 2005, if we normalise the EU27 PIB/capita<br />

average at 100, Flanders lies at 120.1 while Wallonia reaches only 87.5 24 . Finally, Quevit (2010)<br />

concludes that the regional transfers and the opinion of Wallonia firmly established in Flanders<br />

are largely exaggerated and do not correctly reflect the reality.<br />

21 The coming paragraph mainly relies on Savage (2004) and Maes (2010).<br />

22 The coming paragraph mainly relies on Quevit (2010) and Rochtus (2010).<br />

23 Source: own computation based on Eurostat database (European Commission (2012)).<br />

24 Source: Eurostat 2007, cited in Quevit (2010).


13<br />

2.2.2 Macroeconomic situation: some key features<br />

Globally speaking, the Belgian economy performs well, but different negative trends imply<br />

potential risks for Belgium (European Commission (2012)). Let us investigate some key macroeconomic<br />

features of the country, that are of interest to help us comprehend the situation of<br />

Belgium for the coming analysis. We review first the public-sector debt of the country, which is<br />

key to understanding the reasons behind the downgrades of the main rating agencies. Then, we<br />

turn to a problem that might cast some doubts on the future growth of Belgium: its decreasing<br />

competitiveness due to its labour market. Finally, we review an important element of Belgium’s<br />

international positioning: its trade openness. As for the section about the political system<br />

of the country, we do not aim to be exhaustive, but just to briefly cover some aspects of its<br />

macroeconomic position, in order to be able to grasp the in-depth analysis of the following<br />

chapters.<br />

Considerable public-sector debt<br />

Peeking at the 2010 financial situation of Belgium, one will notice a public-sector debt burden<br />

problem. The European Commission identifies it as the main source of internal imbalances for<br />

Belgium (European Commission (2012)). The IMF remind us that at the beginning of 2011,<br />

Belgium had the third largest public debt-to-GDP ratio in the Eurozone, just after Greece and<br />

Italy (International Monetary Fund (2011)). At the end of the year it became the fifth largest<br />

(with Ireland and Portugal coming ahead) (European Commission (2012)). The Belgian public<br />

debt has lain above 88% of GDP for 30 years (with the exception of 2007).<br />

Figure 2.1: Belgian Public Debt (1981 - 2010).<br />

Source: own computation based on National Bank of Belgium data.<br />

We can see on figure 2.1 that public debt reached its peak at 137.8% of GDP in 1993 and<br />

decreased regularly from then until 2007, when the tendency was inverted. It then climbed back<br />

to reach 95.9% in 2010 (and 98.2% in 2011). It is also worth noting that only 3% of this debt is<br />

denominated in foreign currencies and that the largest share (about 90%) of this burden is held<br />

by the federal government (International Monetary Fund (2011)).<br />

Even though its public sector debt is considerable, Belgium was well rated by the main<br />

rating agencies, before the 2010-2011 crisis: just one grade under the top AAA-rating. As we<br />

will see, this grade was reviewed by all three rating agencies in 2011 and 2012.


14<br />

Weaknesses in its external competitiveness<br />

Over the decade before the financial crisis of the late 2000s, Belgium progressively lost an<br />

important share of its external competitiveness (European Commission (2012)). In 2011-2012,<br />

Belgium is ranked 15 th out of 142 by the Global Competitiveness Index, but has some weaknesses<br />

with regards to its labour market efficiency. In particular, it is ranked 129 th for its flexibility<br />

of wage determination and 131 th for its hiring and firing practices (World Economic Forum<br />

(2011)). The European Commission reports that these weaknesses are due to the restrictive<br />

labour regulation of Belgium: a rigid labour market, combined with a “highly structured wage<br />

bargaining system” (European Commission (2012)). The IMF testifies that Belgium has lost,<br />

like other developed countries, market share (due to its lack of competitiveness), but this is not<br />

particular to the Belgian case (International Monetary Fund (2011)). However, the IMF also<br />

establishes that the loss of Belgian competitiveness was caused by high labour costs.<br />

Trade openness<br />

After World War II, Belgium greatly expanded its trade relations beyond the national border<br />

(Maes (2010)) and became a largely open economy. It explains why “[t]he Belgian economy was<br />

harder hit by the international economic crisis than some other countries (Buyst et al. (2005),<br />

p.216)” 25 . It is worth mentioning, though, that the Belgian share in total exports have been<br />

globally declining for the past few decades, in line with trends in many Eurozone’s countries<br />

(International Monetary Fund (2011)), but it does not change its status of open economy.<br />

Since a substantial part of the activity of the BEL20 companies is pursued cross-border, the<br />

political crisis is not supposed to have a significant impact on their results.<br />

2.2.3 The BEL20 index<br />

The BEL20 is a real-time index, constituted of 20 leading firms in Belgium, i.e. (at the beginning<br />

of the crisis) AB Inbev, Ackermans & van Haaren, Ageas (formerly known as Fortis), Befimmo-<br />

Sicafi, Bekaert, Belgacom, Cofinimmo-Sicafi, Colruyt, Delhaize Group, Dexia, GBL, GDF Suez,<br />

KBC, Mobistar, Nyrstar, Omega Pharma, Solvay, Telenet Group, UCB and Umicore 26 . According<br />

to Euronext, these are the most liquid Belgian shares on Brussels stock market. The firms in<br />

this index must never be more than 20 in number. They have a different weight in the value of<br />

the BEL20, but none of them can weigh more than 15% of the total.<br />

The original value of the index was 1000, on December 30, 1990. It was 2665.34 on April 26,<br />

2010 (date retained as the beginning of the political crisis) and 2086.05 on December 6, 2011<br />

(date retained as the end of the political crisis).<br />

25 Cited by Maes (2010).<br />

26 It is worth noting that this constitution of the BEL20 is different from the current one, as since March 19,<br />

2012, Dexia and Omega Pharma left the main Belgian stock index and they were replaced by Elia and D’Ieteren.


15<br />

2.3 Insights into the 2010-2011 crisis<br />

“It is one of the key precepts of the ‘political economy of reform’ that every crisis is an opportunity<br />

to be exploited to drive reform forward.”<br />

Paul Cammack (2009)<br />

We will now review some principles that ruled the 2010-2011 political crisis and that can help us<br />

better understand why the crisis took place and how it could last so long.<br />

Before the crisis even began, a reform had already been envisaged by some, including Kris<br />

Peeters, Minister President of Flanders. He clearly stated that he was looking forward to more<br />

competences relinquished from the federal state to the regions (Quevit (2010)). The Flemish<br />

objective was not exclusively a split of Belgium, as Professor Bruno De Wever states (cited by<br />

Quevit (2010)), but if the Flemish leaders had to choose between the state interests or their<br />

linguistic community’s interest, the community would prevail.<br />

In early 2010, the lack of consensus concerning the Brussels-Halle-Vilvoorde constituency 27<br />

prompted the Open Flemish Liberal and Democrats party (Open Vld) to quit the government<br />

on April 22, 2010. Immediately afterwards, the Prime Minister Yves Leterme handed in his<br />

resignation to King Albert II, but it took effect only four days later. The electorate was then<br />

invited to elect new members to the House of Representatives and the Senate. The previous<br />

election at the time had been held on June 10, 2007. The Belgian political crisis of 2010-2011<br />

thus began after the resignation of the government on April 26 and was confirmed by the Belgian<br />

legislative federal elections on June 13, 2010. From April 26, 2010 to December 6, 2011, a<br />

caretaker government was in charge of dealing with the day-to-day business of state.<br />

Since Belgium is a particracy, there was a large number of different negotiating parties. Their<br />

opposing interests were not easy to conciliate. In total, nine parties took part in the negotiations<br />

but, unable to find a solution, some were removed from the negotiation table. Another feature<br />

that played a crucial role in the problem of setting up a government was the fact that when a<br />

party is offered a first suggestion and accepts it, then it is hard for it to accept a subsequent less<br />

favourable one. The large number of mediators (eight in total) implied that many suggestions<br />

were made and, therefore, the likelihood of finding one that would be accepted by everybody<br />

was low.<br />

In 2011, at the end of the crisis, even more competencies were transferred to the regions and<br />

the BHV constituency was split 28 .<br />

27 In the appendices, figure A.1 illustrates how plurilinguistic this constituency is, which gives an idea of why<br />

finding a solution suiting both the minority of French speakers on Flemish soil (which are the majority in some of<br />

the municipalities concerned) and the Flemish was an uphill struggle.<br />

28 To be exact, the split only came into effect in 2012, whereas the agreement was made in 2011.


Chapter 3<br />

Setting up the indicator<br />

“If a business does well, the stock eventually follows.”<br />

Warren Buffett<br />

The impact of significant political events in times of political crisis on the stocks of Belgium’s<br />

main stock index can be measured in different ways. The most conventional procedure in event<br />

studies consist of analysing the abnormal returns, after a computation of what the “normal”<br />

returns should be (see Brown and Warner (1985), Campbell et al. (1997) or Binder (1998) for a<br />

detailed analysis of classical procedures). However, as Henderson (1990) explains, event studies<br />

exist under different forms and it is not exceptional to see authors using a combination of several<br />

approaches. We believe that the procedure that we use, and that is presented in this chapter, is<br />

the most adapted for the case of analysis and we will strive to justify it as we go along, with<br />

every choice we make.<br />

This chapter starts with a description of our methodology, then lists the different procedures<br />

that we investigate in order to set up the political indicator. We also weigh their respective<br />

strengths and weaknesses, as well as their interests and limitations for the case at hand. This<br />

should, therefore, legitimise why we proceed to a particular regression for a particular analysis<br />

in the chapter 5.<br />

3.1 Methodology<br />

The dummy-variable regression model for event studies is the procedure on which we base our<br />

approach. This model is opposed to classical event studies, more frequently found in literature,<br />

consisting of (i) computing the event window, (ii) measuring the normal returns of a stock<br />

(index) though an “estimation window”, (iii) computing abnormal returns and finally (iv) testing<br />

significance 29 . We chose not to strictly follow the conventional models because the Belgian<br />

political crisis is a unique period and, therefore, the use of an out-of-sample estimation window,<br />

as is the case in most conventional event studies, may not be appropriate. Indeed, we believe that<br />

the political uncertainty due to the absence of a government had an impact on the determination<br />

of the stock prices. Therefore, the estimation of the “normal returns” of the BEL20 index, during<br />

the political crisis, cannot be correctly measured by an estimation window prior to April 2010.<br />

The dummy-variable regression model for event studies was first introduced by Karafiath<br />

(1988), then re-used by other authors (notably Aktas et al. (2007)). Basically, this model is<br />

applied in two steps. Primarily, a dummy variable is built, taking value 1 for days belonging to<br />

29 The most detailed procedure of a classical event studies that we found is available in Campbell et al. (1997),<br />

chapter 4.<br />

16


17<br />

the event window (i.e. either solely the days of the event, or some days before and after the<br />

event as well, depending on the context) and taking value 0 otherwise. For our analysis, we<br />

explain how we build the indicator in section 3.3 and how we select the events in chapter 4.<br />

Once we have built the dummy variable, the second step consists of measuring the impact of this<br />

variable on the returns of a firm, free of the movements of a previously selected market-portfolio.<br />

Formally, we regress the following equation:<br />

where<br />

• R i,t is the return of firm i, at time t,<br />

• R m,t is the return of the market-portfolio m at time t,<br />

• D t is the dummy variable,<br />

R i,t = α i + β i R m,t + γ i D t + ɛ i,t (3.1)<br />

• α i , β i and γ i are the coefficients estimated by the model to fit the regression and<br />

• ɛ i,t is the residual of the regression, for firm i and at each point in time.<br />

As Aktas et al. (2007) establish when they present the same model, γ i can be used as a measure<br />

of “abnormal returns”. This model usually sets as standard assumptions the independence and<br />

identical distribution of the disturbance ɛ i,t . We verify this assumption in section 5.2.5.<br />

For our analysis, we slightly adapt this method, taking the returns of an index (the BEL20)<br />

instead of the returns of a firm as the dependent variable. And as equivalent to the market<br />

portfolio, we take the returns of another index (the Euro Stoxx 50).<br />

As Brown and Warner (1985) state, the model does not need further consideration. In<br />

particular, they establish that “[d]aily data generally present few difficulties for event studies.<br />

Standard procedures are typically well-specified even when special daily data characteristics are<br />

ignored”. However, over the past 27 years (since the publication of Brown and Warner (1985)),<br />

advances have been made on the topic. We will, therefore, add several control variables and<br />

apply procedures to the model in order to correct for endogeneity and heteroskedasticity. We<br />

will also use autoregressive models in order to obtain the best possible fit to our data.<br />

3.2 Timespan<br />

There are 589 days separating April 26, 2010 and December 6, 2011, respectively the fall of<br />

Leterme II’s government and the establishment of Di Rupo I’s government. If we add one week<br />

before this period and one week after this period, in order to take these two important events<br />

into account, the starting and ending dates are April 19, 2010 and December 13, 2011. This is<br />

our “event-window”. We arbitrarily chose one week, because we believe that taking a longer<br />

period would “drown” the political events in a long series 30 and taking a shorter period might<br />

not let us have had enough flexibility when we lag a variable of several days. One week seemed<br />

to be a good compromise between the two.<br />

However, the stock market is open only five days a week and was closed during Easter<br />

Monday and Easter Friday 2011. These two days and the week-ends were the only closed days<br />

30 In other words, a longer period would have meant even more “normal” days for only few days with a significant<br />

political event.


18<br />

over the period of analysis 31 . Subtracting these stock-market free days, we obtain 430 days<br />

relevant to our analysis.<br />

If an event happened when the stock market was closed, we chose to attribute the event to<br />

the next open day. This choice was made in order to correctly assign the impact of the event to<br />

the first moment when the stock market was able react to this event. The same applies if an<br />

event occurred during the night between two days (as was the case for the agreements on BHV).<br />

It is worth noting that we do not take into account a period before the event window as most<br />

of the event studies do. It is not the only approach that differs from conventional event studies.<br />

The justification for this is that we are analysing a period of crisis. Taking a pre-event-window<br />

for computing the “normal return” of the market (frequently used procedure in event studies)<br />

would be an arguable decision. Indeed, it seems possible that the returns in times of political<br />

crisis are different than in times of political stability. We, therefore, chose to use only the period<br />

of consideration (no pre- or post event window period) as we believe that using another approach<br />

could bias the results.<br />

3.3 The different political indicators<br />

In this section, we explain how we build the different political indicators that we will use to<br />

assess the impact of the political events on Brussels stock market. In particular, we will primarily<br />

use (in chapter 5) one main indicator, and then we will test our results with seven alternative<br />

versions of this indicator. In order to better understand the procedure used for the construction<br />

of the different versions of the indicators, refer to the appendices which list the selected dates<br />

day by day and the corresponding value of each indicator.<br />

The easiest way to understand how we built the different indicators is to start with the two<br />

most simple ones. In order to understand the impact of the selected political events on the<br />

BEL20 returns, we would like to differentiate between the events with a negative connotation<br />

for the stability of the country (i.e. events that are likely to push the stock market downward),<br />

from events with a positive connotation (i.e. events that are likely to pull the market upward).<br />

The two basic dummy variables are:<br />

1. “Significant positive event” takes value 1 every time a significantly positive event takes<br />

place (e.g. Johan Vande Lanotte is designated as mediator, the CD&V agrees to start<br />

negotiating without the N-VA, a collective agreement on BHV is reached). Otherwise, the<br />

variable takes value 0.<br />

2. “Significant negative event” is a variable taking value 1 every time a significantly<br />

negative event takes place (e.g. Alexander de Croo leaves the government, the official<br />

resignation of the government, Johan Vande Lanotte resigns from his mission of forming a<br />

government). Otherwise, the variable takes value 0.<br />

These two variables are meant to be used together in the econometric regressions, as they are<br />

complementary. There are 10 days for which significant positive event takes value 1 and 13 days<br />

for which significant negative event does. Therefore, it is respectively 2.33% and 3.02% of the<br />

period we analyse (430 days).<br />

The indicator that we will use the most in our analysis is:<br />

3. “Main political indicator”. This indicator is a combination of significant positive event<br />

and significant negative event. In particular, it takes value 1 when significant positive event<br />

31 Apart from these days, the BEL20 index fluctuated on every day of the period, including on the national day<br />

and for Christmas.


19<br />

has value 1 and takes value −1 when significant negative event has value 1. It takes value<br />

0 when neither of them is positive. Formally:<br />

Main political indicator =<br />

Significant positive event − Significant negative event (3.2)<br />

Since no positive and negative event took place on the same day, over the period we<br />

analysed, this variable has 5.35% of non-zero values.<br />

It is worth justifying the choice of building an indicator that can take only three values<br />

for the analysis at hand. More sophisticated indicators can be easily thought of, such as<br />

indicators that would measure on a scale (from −4 to 4 for example) how good or how<br />

bad a political event is, for the stability of the country. An indicator able to measure<br />

the relative importance of the political events of the crisis would be very interesting, but<br />

extremely arbitrary as well and therefore subject to easy manipulations. In order to limit<br />

as much as possible the “arbitrary” component in the selection of the events, we have used<br />

an indicator that distinguishes only between “significant positive”, “significant negative”<br />

or “non-significant”.<br />

Another interesting indicator would consist of verifying if the significant political events,<br />

regardless whether they are positive or negative, have an impact on the stock market. For this<br />

reason, we computed the indicator:<br />

4. “Significant event dummy”. This indicator is another type of combination of significant<br />

positive event and significant negative event. In particular, it takes value 1 whenever<br />

significant positive event or significant negative event has value 1. It takes value 0 when<br />

neither of them is positive. In other words, it is the absolute value of the main political<br />

indicator. Formally:<br />

Significant event dummy =<br />

Significant positive event + Significant negative event (3.3)<br />

Just as for the main political indicator, this variable has 5.35% of non-zero values.<br />

In order to verify if our arbitrary selection of events (see chapter 4 for more details about it)<br />

is justified, we created a larger version of main political indicator:<br />

5. “All political events”. This indicator includes more events than just those that are very<br />

significant. Instead of having 23 events, we therefore have 40, which corresponds to 9.30%<br />

of non-zero values.<br />

Making inference when the event date is uncertain may be a source of trouble to our analysis.<br />

By uncertain, we mean that newspapers release a piece of information at time t, but the<br />

event might have been known by some investors holding private information at time t − 1.<br />

Fortunately, a procedure exists to solve this problem, as presented by Campbell et al. (1997).<br />

This procedure consists of enlarging the event window, so that it covers two days (day 0 and<br />

day 1). This procedure is double-edged since on the one hand the risk of missing events is<br />

reduced, while on the other hand, the significance may decrease because many days included in<br />

the event window do not correspond to any political events. This procedure has been analysed<br />

by Ball and Torous (1988), who compare it with more sophisticated models including maximum<br />

likelihood estimations. They find that the simple process of enlarging the event window yields<br />

approximately the same results as more sophisticated models. The approach, therefore, seems<br />

worth trying. Following this procedure, we created the following three indicators:


20<br />

6. “Main political indicator 2 ” takes value 1 or −1 when the main political indicator<br />

has this value. But, in addition, main political indicator 2 takes the same value the day<br />

following the event considered.<br />

7. “Significant event dummy 2 ” takes value 1 when the significant event dummy has this<br />

value. But, in addition, significant event dummy 2 takes the same value the day following<br />

the event considered.<br />

8. “All political events 2 ” takes value 1 or −1, as all political events does. But, in addition,<br />

all political events 2 takes the same value the day following the event considered 32 .<br />

Thanks to these different variables, we have relevant building blocks for the analyses of<br />

chapter 5. Some variables, such as significant positive event and significant negative event, share<br />

the qualities of simplicity and clarity, while other variables, slightly less simple, such as main<br />

political indicator 2 avoid the problem of having too few non-zero-valued entries and, therefore,<br />

will not be drowned among too large a number of zero-valued dates.<br />

Let us note, finally, that the different tests that we performed, as a way to “explore” the<br />

topic, included some other variables, which were combinations or slight modifications of the<br />

aforementioned possibilities. We have decided to mention here only the most relevant variables<br />

and to leave aside the recurrent results and the non-informative ones.<br />

As previously mentioned, a summary of the indicators presented in this chapter, and of the<br />

value they take for each of the selected political event, is available in the appendices, at the end<br />

of this <strong>thesis</strong>.<br />

3.4 Computing the returns<br />

As Campbell et al. (1997) put it, focusing on the returns in finance-related topics is justified<br />

since “the return is a complete and scale-free summary of the investment opportunity”. However,<br />

the return on stock prices can be computed according to different processes. The process<br />

chosen for such computation is important because the results of the analysis will depend on<br />

it 33 . Ultsch (2009) summarises three processes used for computing daily returns, and points out<br />

the advantages and the weaknesses of each of them. The simplest one is the arithmetic return<br />

rate. The most used one in recent literature is the logarithm of the ratio of successive prices<br />

or logarithmic return rate. Finally, Ultsch (2009) establishes that these first two ratios have<br />

weaknesses, in particular with regards to series taking occasionally extreme values (compared<br />

to the rest of the series). He, therefore, sets up an alternative way to compute the returns,<br />

called the relative difference, which does not bear the same weaknesses as the other previously<br />

mentioned ratios. This is particularly useful when extreme values are identified in the series.<br />

Let us have a deeper look at each of them.<br />

32 Two precisions are required for the arbitrary computation of this variable. Firstly, when two events follow<br />

each other, e.g. a positive event at time t 1 and another positive event at time t 2, then the indicator will take<br />

value 1 for the time t 1,2,3. In particular, in time t 2, the value of the indicator is only 1 (and not 2 as some might<br />

have thought). However, as there are only four cases like this, for the 40 events selected, the implication of this<br />

choice is not drastic. Secondly, when a negative event (at time t 1) is followed by a positive event (at time t 2), the<br />

values of the indicator are the following: t 1 = −1, t 2 = 1 and t 3 = 1.<br />

33 Even if, as we will see, the difference is negligible for our data.


21<br />

Arithmetic return rate<br />

This first measurement of ratios is done by following the formula:<br />

Arithmetic return t = P t − P t−1<br />

P t−1<br />

(3.4)<br />

Where P t is the closing value of the stock index, on day t. The choice of taking the closing<br />

value, rather than the mean value or the opening one, is done simply to stick to the standard in<br />

financial literature.<br />

This return is also called “simple net return” by Campbell et al. (1997), as opposed to the<br />

“simple gross return” which is the simple net return to which we add 1.<br />

Logarithmic return rate<br />

The most common measure in literature is computed by the following formula:<br />

( ) Pt<br />

Logarithmic return t = ln<br />

P t−1<br />

The logarithmic return is an approximation of the arithmetic one. They do not differ much<br />

from each other for small values. However, when the return is large (i.e. tens of percents, in<br />

absolute value), then using the logarithmic approach allows us to restrain the value of the return.<br />

Moreover, as Cootner (1964) 34 evidenced, the logarithmic return for a stock price follows a<br />

random walk.<br />

Relative difference<br />

The relative difference consists of comparing the price difference from one day to another to the<br />

average of these prices. The exact formula is the following:<br />

Relative difference t =<br />

It can also be expressed more simply, as follows.<br />

1<br />

2<br />

(3.5)<br />

P t − P t−1<br />

( ) (3.6)<br />

Pt + P t−1<br />

Relative difference t = 2 × P t − P t−1<br />

P t + P t−1<br />

(3.7)<br />

The returns computed by their relative difference have the desirable property that they are<br />

contained within a finite range: [−200%, 200%].<br />

Abnormal returns<br />

“Abnormal returns” is a concept that occurs over and over again in literature about event studies<br />

regarding stock returns. Probably one of most influential papers on this topic was the one of<br />

MacKinlay (1997) in which he defines what abnormal returns are and how to calculate them.<br />

Basically, he explains a statistical procedure consisting of defining a market model to measure<br />

the normal returns calculated out of the sample (calculated just before the sample begins for<br />

example). Then, the abnormal return is the disturbance term of this market model when we<br />

apply it to the sample. Formally, the model is set as the following equation:<br />

Abnormal return t = return t − ̂α − ̂β return mt (3.8)<br />

34 Cited in Parkinson (1980).


22<br />

Where<br />

• return t is the return of the stock within the sample,<br />

• return mt is the return of the stock according to the market model,<br />

• ̂α and ̂β are the coefficients estimated by the model.<br />

As Pynnönen (2005) shows, “the traditional event study with non-overlapping event windows<br />

is equivalent to estimating dummy variable regressions over the combined sample and event<br />

windows” and continues “[t]he dummy variable coefficients corresponds to the abnormal returns”.<br />

We will not conduct an exhaustive analysis of abnormal returns for two reasons. Firstly because,<br />

as just mentioned, it is equivalent to our dummy variable approach. Secondly, because doing<br />

this analysis in parallel and comparing it with the dummy variable methodology exceeds the<br />

scope of this <strong>thesis</strong>, but such a work is a possible extension of our work.<br />

Conclusion about the computation of the return<br />

For the coming analyses, we use the logarithmic return as a reference, since it is widely accepted<br />

as the standard in event studies. Moreover, it is worth mentioning that the weaknesses that<br />

it bears (and that the relative difference addresses) are not crucial for the case at hand, since<br />

no value of the BEL20 index can be considered as “extreme” (no value exceeds 10% return<br />

in absolute value on a day-to-day basis and only three values exceed 5% return in absolute<br />

value and on the same basis 35 ). The logarithmic approach, therefore, seems the most suitable<br />

approach.<br />

Let us now digress from finance and econometry for one chapter and investigate in more<br />

detail what the milestones of the Belgian political crisis were.<br />

35 These three values are May 10, 2010 (8.9550%), August 12, 2011 (5.3539%) and September 22, 2011 (−5.4925%).<br />

And even for these values, the relative difference method ends up with very similar results: 8.9490%, 5.3526% and<br />

5.4911% respectively, for each of these three dates.


Chapter 4<br />

Significant events<br />

“One thing is sure. We have to do something. We have to do the best we know how at the moment.<br />

If it doesn’t turn out right, we can modify it as we go along.”<br />

Franklin D. Roosevelt<br />

We will now review all politically significant events that have come up since the beginning of<br />

the Belgian political crisis. The chapter is divided into different sections, within which the events<br />

are classified chronologically. We briefly investigate in turn the events related to the formation<br />

of government then the downgrades of the rating agencies. The dates that will be retained as<br />

a basis for forming our main political indicator of the Belgian political crisis (established in<br />

section 3) are indicated in bold. The selection of these "significant" dates among the elements<br />

listed hereunder has been done according to the importance of the events and under the advice<br />

and supervision of Pr P. Wynants 36 , based on Faniel (2011). In the appendices, each event and<br />

its impact on each of our different political indicators is summarised.<br />

For each event mentioned, we ascribe a relevant source, to which the interested reader can<br />

refer. These references are exclusively quality newspapers (or official sources), a choice made<br />

because newspapers convey one of the main building blocks of public opinion 37 and therefore<br />

are one of the bases for stock investors’ reaction. In order to be as politically-neutral as possible,<br />

we chose Belgian reference newspapers both in French and in Dutch 38 and also added some<br />

international newspapers to complete the analysis. The newspapers are also an interesting source<br />

for the period of analysis since, as Junqué de Fortuny et al. (2012) put it, “Belgium has seen a<br />

unique governmental crisis in 2007-2010 during which both political parties and politicians have<br />

had wide media coverage”.<br />

4.1 Politically significant events<br />

During the major part of the crisis, seven parties were negotiating the formation of the government<br />

(politically from left to right, French-speaking/Dutch-speaking); PS/sp.a, Ecolo/Groen!,<br />

cdH/CD&V, N-VA, i.e. three French-speaking and four Dutch-speaking parties.<br />

From the beginning of the crisis and up to December 6, 2011 eight mediators were<br />

mandated by the King with the ultimate aim of forming a permanent government. Specific titles<br />

36 Teacher of Belgian politics at the University of Namur.<br />

37 It has been established, notably by Savigny (2002), that mass media, and especially the Internet, play a<br />

crucial role in the formation of public opinion. Let us also remember that Junqué de Fortuny et al. (2012) have<br />

found that the Flemish newspaper articles show peaks of positive or negative public opinions concomitantly with<br />

the milestones of the Belgian political crisis 2010-2011.<br />

38 In the same proportion.<br />

23


24<br />

were given to them, in the following order; Bart De Wever as informateur 39 , Elio di Rupo as<br />

préformateur, Danny Pieters and André Flahaut as mediators, Bart De Wever as clarifier, Johan<br />

Vande Lanotte as mediator, Didier Reynders as informateur, Wouter Beke as negotiator, Elio di<br />

Rupo as formateur (La Libre (May 17, 2011)). Various other events in the political arena had a<br />

significant influence and were thus added between these milestones of the Belgian political crisis<br />

of 2010-2011. We also include some less meaningful events, in order to provide a comprehensive<br />

analysis of the progress of the negotiations.<br />

Open Vld’s departure from government<br />

On April 22, 2010, Alexander de Croo, leader of the Flemish liberal party Open Vld, decides<br />

to leave the government after months of unsuccessful negotiations on the BHV issue (Le Soir<br />

(April 22, 2010)). Two days earlier, Jean-Luc Dehaene (Belgian Prime Minister from 1992 to<br />

1999), considers his mission finished, handing in recommendations which could have been the<br />

basis for an agreement between the different parties (Le Soir (April 20, 2010)). Five months<br />

earlier, he had been tasked by the King Albert II, to make a suggestion on the institutional<br />

problems of Belgium, with a particular focus on BHV. In the days following the event, Didier<br />

Reynders is put in charge of finding a solution while the French newspaper Le Monde (April 23,<br />

2010) carries the headline “La Belgique est morte le 22 avril 2010”, “Belgium died on April 22,<br />

2010”.<br />

Fall of the government<br />

On April 26, 2010, the King accepts the government’s resignation (De Standaard (April 26,<br />

2011)). Leterme II’s government had been in charge since November 25, 2009 (Service Public<br />

Fédéral Belge (November 25, 2009)) and now becomes a caretaker government, in charge of<br />

dealing with the day-to-day business of the state but not empowered to do major reforms (The<br />

Guardian (April 26, 2010)).<br />

Massive reaction on the legislative proposal about BHV<br />

On April 29, 2010, almost all French-speaking members of Parliament file a motion triggering<br />

the alarm on the legislative proposal about the splitting of BHV (De Standaard (April 29, 2010)).<br />

Federal legislative elections<br />

The Federal legislative elections take place on June 13, 2010 40 .<br />

Bart De Wever as informateur<br />

On June 17, 2010, the winner of the elections Bart De Wever, leader of the New Flemish<br />

Alliance 41 , is mandated by the King to identify the different possible coalitions (De Tijd (June<br />

18, 2011)).<br />

39 His title, “informateur”, is written in French in most articles about the topic written in English; similarly for<br />

the other titles written in French, such as “pré-formateur” or “formateur”.<br />

40 The results are available at Federal Public Service Home Affairs (June 13, 2010).<br />

41 Originally in Dutch: Nieuw-Vlaamse Alliancie (N-VA)


25<br />

Elio di Rupo as préformateur<br />

On July 8, 2010, after the period given to Bart De Wever for gauging the temperature, Elio<br />

di Rupo is put in charge of forming a government. His main tasks concern notably the public<br />

finances and the extent of the State reform, including the BHV file (Le Soir (July 9, 2010)).<br />

Officially, he truly believes that a solution is possible until September 3, when he will openly<br />

accept his failure (L’Echo (May 18, 2011)).<br />

Refusal of di Rupo’s resignation by the King<br />

On August 29, 2010, the King refuses di Rupo’s resignation (De Morgen (August 29, 2010)).<br />

Danny Pieters and André Flahaut as mediators<br />

On September 4, 2010, King Albert II finally accepts di Rupo’s resignation and mandates<br />

André Flahaut (president of the Chamber of Representatives) and Danny Pieters (president of<br />

the Senate) as mediators (La Libre (September 4, 2010)).<br />

Bart De Wever as clarifier<br />

On October 4, the N-VA holds a conference in which it unilaterally interrupts the negotiations<br />

with seven parties (De Morgen (December 10, 2011)). The next day, the King relieves Flahaut<br />

and Pieters of their mission (De Standaard (October 5, 2010)).<br />

On October 8, 2010, Albert II puts Bart De Wever in charge of the different files. Now<br />

being clarifier, De Wever has ten days to hand in a report based on meetings with the seven<br />

negotiating parties and with the ultimate objective of bridging the differences between each<br />

perspective (Le Soir (October 9, 2010)).<br />

On October 18, 2010, the leader of the N-VA declares "Fabula acta est", literally "the<br />

story is over", quoting the Roman emperor Augustus during his very last days. He expresses a<br />

strong disappointment about the reaction of the three French-speaking parties. On the same<br />

day, the King agrees to relieve him from his mission (BBC News (October 18, 2010)).<br />

Johan Vande Lanotte as mediator<br />

Designated on October 21, 2010, Johan Vande Lanotte gives great hope to the country, as he<br />

is more likely to reach an agreement than the previous mediators (De Tijd (October 21, 2010)).<br />

Unfortunately, he resigns for the first time on January 6 (La Libre (January 6, 2011)) but<br />

finally accepts, under the pressure of the King, to make one more attempt, before definitely<br />

resigning on January 26, 2011 (De Morgen (January 26, 2011)).<br />

Belgian record of the longest political crisis<br />

On December 25, 2010, Belgium beats its own record for the longest duration without any<br />

federal government: 194 days (2007) (La Libre (December 23, 2010)).<br />

European record of the longest political crisis<br />

On January 8, 2011, the European record, previously held by the Netherlands (1977), is taken<br />

by Belgium: 208 days without a government (L’Echo (January 7, 2011)).


26<br />

Empowerment of the temporary government<br />

On February 2, 2011, the King asks Yves Leterme, Prime Minister, to present the budget<br />

guidelines and estimates for 2011, and to take any necessary measure to respond to the European<br />

requests with regard to budgetary policies and structural reforms (De Morgen (February 2,<br />

2011)).<br />

Didier Reynders as informateur<br />

On February 2, 2011, Didier Reynders, former Finance Minister, is named informateur by the<br />

King and has two weeks to report to the King whether there is a possibility of reaching an<br />

agreement (La Libre (February 2, 2011)). A month after his nomination he hands the file over<br />

to his successor Wouter Beke (Le Monde (March 2, 2011)).<br />

Wouter Beke as negotiator<br />

On March 2, 2011, Wouter Beke is entrusted with the mission of negotiating the agreement<br />

on the State reform (Le Soir (March 2, 2011)). Even though he has no official deadline, the<br />

N-VA want to impose one, end of April, but the other Flemish parties are opposed to it (De<br />

Standaard (March 5, 2011)). Some weeks later, on May 12, 2011, he hands in his “note” and<br />

waits for the next person that will be in charge: most likely Bart De Wever or Elio Di Rupo (De<br />

Standaard (May 12, 2011)).<br />

World record of the longest political crisis<br />

On March 30, 2011, after 294 days, Belgium now holds the world’s record for the longest<br />

period without a federal government in times of peace (previously held by Iraq (2009)). The<br />

Flemish newspaper De Tijd contradicts it, claiming that Cambodia holds this record (De Tijd<br />

(March 30, 2011)) even though it has been widely recognised and even attested by the Guinness<br />

World Record Book (De Morgen (April 19, 2011)).<br />

Elio di Rupo as formateur<br />

On May 16, 2011, the King accepts the note of Wouter Beke and his request to relieve him. In<br />

an eighth attempt, the King tasks Elio Di Rupo with forming a government (De Standaard (May<br />

16, 2011)). On July 4, the French-speaking socialist president hands in a 111-page long note,<br />

based on his contacts with the nine parties (in addition to the seven parties implied, he had<br />

contacts with the French-speaking and Dutch-speaking liberals, MR and Open Vld respectively,<br />

which now also have a seat at the table of negotiation). Three days later, the N-VA refuses to<br />

start negotiating on the basis of this note (De Morgen (July 7, 2011)). The CD&V asks for<br />

some modifications to the note, while the other seven parties agree to start the negotiation (De<br />

Morgen (July 19, 2011)).<br />

Eight parties around the table<br />

On July 21, 2011, the CD&V finally agrees to start negotiating without the presence of the<br />

N-VA, which is a new start, unblocking the situation (Le Soir (July 22, 2011)).<br />

First agreement on BHV<br />

During the night between September 14 and 15, 2011, an agreement of the eight parties on<br />

the electoral district BHV is reached (De Tijd (September 15, 2011)).


27<br />

Agreement on the financing law<br />

On September 24, 2011, a second agreement is reached. This one concerns the law about the<br />

financing of the Regions and the Communities, about fiscal autonomy and about the refinancing<br />

of Brussels (De Tijd (September 26, 2011)).<br />

Second agreement on BHV<br />

During the night preceding October 5, 2011, a similar agreement is reached concerning the<br />

judiciary district BHV (De Standaard (October 5, 2011)).<br />

Global agreement<br />

On October 8, 2011, a global agreement on the whole constitutional file is reached, after<br />

530 days of crisis (482 days since the elections). The entire agreement is published in Le Soir<br />

(December 2, 2011).<br />

Sixth reform of the State<br />

On October 11, 2011, the sixth reform of the State is designed and agreed upon by the parties.<br />

The reform includes the decisions reached in the previous recent agreements (Le Soir (October<br />

11, 2011)).<br />

Six parties left<br />

On October 13, 2011, the ecologist parties, Ecolo and Groen!, are forced to quit the negotiating<br />

table. Six parties are left (De Standaard (October 13, 2011)).<br />

Political agreement on the budget<br />

On November 26, 2011, after 18 hours of negotiations, the budget for 2012 is agreed (Le Soir<br />

(November 26, 2011)). The downgrade of Belgium by S&P the day before created a pressure<br />

from the markets, which was probably a decisive variable in this agreement (The New York<br />

Times (December 14, 2011)).<br />

Conclusion of the governmental agreement<br />

On November 30, 2011, an agreement is reached on the formation of a government which<br />

would be led by Elio Di Rupo (Washington Times (November 30, 2011)). He would be the first<br />

French-speaking Prime Minister for more than three decades and the first socialist to hold that<br />

position since 1974 (BBC News (December 6, 2011)).<br />

Formation of a government<br />

On December 6, 2011, Elio di Rupo takes the oath and becomes Prime Minister of the new<br />

government. The government is constituted of the Social Democrats (PS/sp.a), the Christian<br />

Democrats (cdH/CD&V) and the Liberals (MR/Open Vld), but excludes the N-VA (Le Soir<br />

(December 5, 2011)). This date marks the end of the world’s longest political crisis.


28<br />

4.2 Rating agencies’ outlooks and downgrades<br />

We now move on to another kind of event which has an impact on the stock market. As for<br />

the previous section (4.1), we bold the dates that are important and that we will use in the<br />

econometric regressions in the next chapter. We list hereunder the different events related to<br />

the main rating agencies (Standard & Poor’s, Moody’s and Fitch). As evidenced by data, the<br />

threat of downgrading the rating of Belgium by the agencies or the actual downgrade of this<br />

rating have an impact on the daily returns of the BEL20 index. We, therefore, need to take<br />

these parameters into account, in order for our political indicator to be more accurate. In other<br />

words, if a movement in the stock market is due to an announcement of a rating agency and<br />

not to a political event taking place at the same moment, and if we do not take into account<br />

the rating agencies’ impact, then an ordinary econometric regression will wrongly attribute this<br />

movement to the political event. In order to avoid this kind of inaccuracies, we will create a new<br />

dummy variable, called “Rating”, taking value 1 when a rating agency announces that it starts<br />

reviewing Belgium for a potential downgrade or when this downgrade takes place. Let us now<br />

go through each of the three major rating agencies one by one.<br />

4.2.1 Standard & Poor’s<br />

Negative outlook<br />

On December 14, 2010, S&P threatens Belgium with a potential downgrade. Their outlook<br />

for Belgian debt turns to “negative”, as one of the Eurozone’s most indebted countries might<br />

encounter higher borrowing costs (Reuters (December 14, 2010)). Quoting Reuters; “[i]f the<br />

country’s inability to form a government threatened deficit- and debt-reduction goals, S&P<br />

said Belgium’s AA+ rating could be downgraded within six months”. Let us note that “AA+”<br />

corresponds to the second best grade, in S&P’s ranking, out of a list of 22 grades.<br />

S&P’s downgrade<br />

On November 25, 2011, Standard & Poor’s decides to apply its one-year-old threat of<br />

downgrading Belgium. The Belgian grade thus goes down from “AA+” to “AA” (third best<br />

grade), and “negative perspectives” were bound to this new grade. According to the economic<br />

newspaper L’Echo (November 26, 2011), this will have an unquestionable impact on the real<br />

economy. The decision was motivated by a pressure on financing and market risk, increasing the<br />

likelihood for complementary state support. In the same article, a relevant question for this<br />

<strong>thesis</strong> is addressed to Alexandre De Groote (CEO of Petercam Institutional Bonds); “should we<br />

fear a sudden rise of the returns after this downgrade?” He believes that the market fluctuation<br />

already incorporated this information. Data however are less clear about it: the BEL20 index<br />

did not decrease on that day, it even increased slightly but much less than the Euro Stoxx 50<br />

index. Therefore, it seems that this event was not totally forecast and incorporated by the<br />

market.<br />

4.2.2 Moody’s<br />

Moody’s reviews Belgium’s “Aa1”<br />

On October 07, 2011, the high level of Belgian debt combined with the “long-term funding<br />

risk on the euro-area sovereign” encouraged Moody’s to review Belgium for a possible downgrade<br />

in the future (Moody’s (October 7, 2011)).


29<br />

Moody’s downgrade<br />

On December 16, 2011, Belgium’s credit rating is downgraded by Moody’s from Aa1 to Aa3<br />

(from second best to fourth best grade, in a list of 21 different grades), which corresponds to a<br />

“negative outlook” (Moody’s (December 16, 2011)). However, this event happens after the end<br />

of the period we analyse here. We cannot, therefore, take it into account.<br />

4.2.3 Fitch Ratings<br />

Negative outlook<br />

On May 23, 2011, the outlook of Fitch on the sovereign rating of Belgium changes from “stable”<br />

to “negative”.<br />

Rating watch and downgrade<br />

On December 16, 2011, as Moody’s downgrades Belgium, the rating watch of Fitch turns to<br />

negative. The actual downgrade from Fitch takes place on January 27, 2012 (Fitch Ratings<br />

(2012)).<br />

4.2.4 Conclusion about the ratings<br />

Even if only four relevant rating-related events are highlighted during the political crisis 2010-<br />

2011, using this data enables us to capture some fluctuations of the BEL20 daily returns. It<br />

frees our political indicator of some possible inaccuracies.<br />

4.3 Summary of the events<br />

In order to provide a global view of the Belgian crisis to the reader, we established a timeline<br />

(on page 30), summarising the aforementioned events. The previous analysis appears to provide<br />

23 key dates relating to the Belgian political crisis 2010-2011, and 17 less important dates. With<br />

regard to the “rating dummy”, we identified four key events. We include the most important<br />

events chronologically on the following timeline, which is split into two parts; the first one for<br />

2010 and the second one for 2011. We also added to this summary the value of the BEL20 and<br />

the Euro Stoxx 50, as a percentage compared to their value on April 19, 2010 (just before the<br />

resignation of Leterme II’s government). As these figures show, it is hard, if at all possible, to<br />

notice an impact of the political events on the daily return of the BEL20. However, we can<br />

clearly identify that the BEL20 and the Euro Stoxx 50 move closely together and respond to<br />

the same shocks.


Figure 4.1: Main Belgian political events against the BEL20 and Euro Stoxx 50 indices<br />

daily returns, April 19, 2010 - December 31, 2010<br />

30<br />

Figure 4.2: Main Belgian political events against the BEL20 and Euro Stoxx 50 indices<br />

daily returns, January 01, 2011 - December 13, 2011


Chapter 5<br />

Impact of political events on the<br />

Brussels stock market<br />

“As we realise that more and more things have global impact, I think we’re going to get people<br />

increasingly wanting to get away from a purely national interest.”<br />

Peter Singer 42 .<br />

As the literature review has shown, the stock market is closely linked with political conditions,<br />

and in particular with political events. We have seen that it was especially the case when we<br />

considered emerging markets and politically unstable countries. Belgium, during the 2010-<br />

2011 political crisis, might be considered to fall into this second category. We investigate,<br />

in this chapter, the impact of the politically significant events highlighted in the previous<br />

chapter on the evolution of the return of the BEL20 index. Significant results are found,<br />

evidencing the connection between the political and economic worlds in Belgium. We first start<br />

by reviewing some basics of financial econometrics; we then introduce a simple static model that<br />

we progressively sophisticate as we go along. In the extensions, we end with an error correction<br />

model and with autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models. Some topics with regard<br />

to our approach for this chapter are raised in the next chapter - Discussion - as they do not<br />

concern one subsection in particular.<br />

5.1 Theoretical background<br />

Two main theoretical models are of interest for our analysis. The first one is the capital asset<br />

pricing model (CAPM), introduced by the Nobel laureate William Sharpe (1964) and by Lintner<br />

(1965). This is probably the most widely used model for the evaluation and management of<br />

financial portfolios. Even though the CAPM was a theoretical success, empirical evidence seems<br />

not to validate it (Fama and French (2004)). The second model of interest is the arbitrage pricing<br />

theory (APT), established by Ross (1976), determining the expected return of a stock (or more<br />

generally of an asset) as a function of multiple factors. The CAPM was the standard in event<br />

studies during the 1970s (Campbell et al. (1997)) but later studies preferred using multi-factor<br />

models derived from the APT because it prevents one from using incorrect assumptions on the<br />

expected returns.<br />

In this section, we review the efficient market hypo<strong>thesis</strong> (EMH) at the basis of these two<br />

models, then we briefly introduce the foundation of each of them.<br />

42 Australian Inspiration (2010)<br />

31


32<br />

5.1.1 Efficient market hypo<strong>thesis</strong><br />

Financial econometrics is based on the uncertainty faced by investors (Campbell et al. (1997)).<br />

Anticipation and expectations are, therefore, key to understand how the stock markets react.<br />

Since Samuelson (1965), who proved that “properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly”, the<br />

EMH (summarised by Fama (1970)) has often been challenged in literature. Basically, it states<br />

that stock markets are supposed to “fully reflect” all available information, or at least to reflect<br />

correctly the relevant stock-related information. The EMH has a direct implication, which is<br />

unfortunate for greedy investors: that stock returns must be random. It should thus not be<br />

possible for an investor to make profit based on the available information.<br />

Having perfect market efficiency is unlikely, not only because the expectations are not<br />

always rational, but also because some of the relevant information comes at a price. However,<br />

challenging the hypo<strong>thesis</strong> of efficiency of the markets is always tricky. Indeed, if the hypo<strong>thesis</strong><br />

is rejected, it can mean either that the market is inefficient or that the model that has been<br />

used is not properly defined (Campbell et al. (1997)).<br />

For these reasons, the debate about the EMH remains open in the context of the capital<br />

asset pricing model and the arbitrage pricing theory. We now turn to the rationale of these<br />

models.<br />

5.1.2 Capital asset pricing model<br />

The CAPM establishes what the optimal point between the risk and the return of a portfolio<br />

is. One that lies on this point is called “mean-variance efficient” (Campbell et al. (1997)). The<br />

CAPM is formulated as follows:<br />

(<br />

)<br />

E(R i ) = R f + β im E(R m ) − R f (5.1)<br />

where<br />

• E(x) is the expected value of x,<br />

• R i is the return on an asset i,<br />

• R f is the return of a risk-free asset (the model assumes that there is such asset),<br />

• R m is the return of the market portfolio and<br />

• β im is a measure of the risk of an asset. This measure can be defined as follows:<br />

β im = Cov(R i, R m )<br />

V ar(R m )<br />

(5.2)<br />

where<br />

• Cov(R i , R m ) is the covariance of the respective returns of the asset i and the market<br />

portfolio and<br />

• V ar(R m ) is the variance of the market portfolio.<br />

Putting words on formula 5.2, one of the main findings of the CAPM is that a stock’s<br />

expected return is a linear function of its covariance with the market.<br />

The CAPM is sometimes used to measure the expected return of a stock in event studies. It<br />

is worth noting that several weaknesses and inaccuracies have been debated in the literature


33<br />

about the CAPM. In particular, Campbell et al. (1997) mention that some CAPM frameworks<br />

consider that it holds only conditionally: only period per period or only conditionally to the<br />

state of the economy, for example. Other reasons for this debate include statistical evidence (in<br />

the US market) against the CAPM, or the fact that the CAPM should be replaced by other<br />

sources of risk.<br />

5.1.3 Arbitrage pricing theory<br />

The APT, introduced by Ross (1976), is a general theory about the pricing of assets, stating<br />

that the return on an asset is a linear function of the expected return on that asset and of a set<br />

of relevant variables. Formally, it is expressed as follows:<br />

where<br />

• r i is the return on asset i,<br />

• E i is the expected return on asset i,<br />

r i = E i + β i1 X 1 + ... + β ik X k + ɛ i (5.3)<br />

• the X k are the k zero-mean factors termed X, whose subscript goes from 1 to k,<br />

• to each factor, is joined a coefficient β, measuring the sensitivity of asset i to the factor in<br />

consideration,<br />

• the n different assets are identified by their subscript i, going from 1 to n and finally,<br />

• ɛ i is the residual (also called “noise” or “disturbance” 43 ) of the asset i.<br />

Basic assumptions are made, notably (i) that ɛ i is an unsystematic idiosyncratic risk<br />

component such that E(ɛ i |X j ) = 0, (ii) monotonicity and (iii) concavity. It follows the same<br />

intuition as the CAPM (Roll and Ross (1980)), since it also considers a linear process for<br />

estimating the return. One distinction between these two models is the fact that the APT does<br />

not rely on any market portfolio 44 . Another major difference resides in the fact that the APT<br />

allows the expected return to be a function of several other variables. Literature evidencing the<br />

fact that several factors are likely to affect the process of return generating can be found in<br />

Rosenberg and Marathe (1975).<br />

Shanken (1982) claims that the APT is more likely to be validated empirically than the<br />

CAPM, but no clear-cut answer has been found as to which of these models better reflects reality.<br />

As he presents it (based on the argumentation of Roll (1977)), testing the CAPM is tricky since<br />

it relies on an assumption hardly ever met: the existence of an efficient market portfolio, which<br />

should be used in the test of the CAPM.<br />

In the coming analyses, we mainly follow the intuition of the APT, building a model explaining<br />

the fluctuations of the BEL20 index by the fluctuations of several other variables. However,<br />

we also keep the “market” trend approach of the CAPM, since we use the Euro Stoxx 50 as a<br />

regressor in our model. The Euro Stoxx 50 can indeed be considered as the equivalent to the<br />

market portfolio for the BEL20 index. As we mention in the following paragraphs, the strong<br />

correlation between the BEL20 index and the Euro Stoxx 50 as well as the significance of the<br />

different control variables analysed confirm that our approach is justified.<br />

43 In the coming pages, we will indifferently use any of these denominations.<br />

44 As Roll and Ross (1980) put it: “[i]n general, the market portfolio plays no special role whatsoever in the<br />

APT, unlike its pivotal role in the CAPM”.


34<br />

5.2 Multiple regression analysis<br />

In this section, we start by adopting a simplistic model, that gets more and more sophisticated as<br />

we go along. We do not extensively interpret the results before the end of the section, since the<br />

coefficients of the different variables used and their significance change as the model gets better<br />

specified. Section 5.2.10 brings together the conclusions of each subsection of the main model.<br />

It is a useful summary for the reader who does not feel confortable with the econometric details<br />

presented hereunder. However, the reader may be interested to observe how the coefficients of<br />

the various regressors evolve, as we sharpen the analysis.<br />

5.2.1 Simplistic return-analysis model<br />

The basic estimation of the impact of political events, taken all together, on the BEL20 index<br />

returns is:<br />

where<br />

{BEL20 return} t = β 0 + β 1 {P olitical indicator} t + β 2 X t + ɛ t (5.4)<br />

• {BEL20 return} t is the return of the BEL20’s index, on day t,<br />

• {P olitical indicator} t is the value of the main political indicator built in section 3.3, on<br />

day t,<br />

• X t is a vector of exogenous variables 45 ,<br />

• the βs are the coefficients estimated by the model for each regressor and for the intercept<br />

(β 0 ). They capture the sensitivity of their respective regressor with regards to the dependent<br />

variable 46 . And<br />

• ɛ t is the residual, or disturbance, of the regression for the observation t 46 .<br />

With ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions, several assumptions have to be made. In<br />

particular, we assume that the residuals ɛ t :<br />

1. are normally distributed: ɛ t ∼ N(·, ·),<br />

2. have a zero mean: ɛ t ∼ N(0, ·),<br />

3. have a constant variance: ɛ t ∼ N(0, σ 2 ),<br />

4. are not serially correlated and<br />

5. are not correlated with the explanatory variables.<br />

These assumptions can be considered as strong ones because usually: “security returns are<br />

not normally distributed, [...] [t]here is evidence of slight serial correlation in security returns,<br />

[...][t]here is evidence that variance shifts sometimes are associated with financial events” and<br />

“[t]here is evidence that the residuals are correlated with values of the independent variable[s]”<br />

(Henderson (1990)). Techniques exist to deal with these problems in event studies. We will,<br />

45 Here, as in the following equations, we indicate vectors by bolded letters.<br />

46 In the remainder of the <strong>thesis</strong>, we will not explicitly state what these β coefficients are, or whichever Greek<br />

letter we attribute to them. The same applies to the disturbances ɛ.


35<br />

therefore, release some of these assumptions in further sections. In particular, we will deal with<br />

endogeneity of some regressors, with the heteroskedasticity of the residuals and analyse the<br />

serial correlation present within these residuals.<br />

The null hypo<strong>thesis</strong> associated with this model is that the stock market is efficient, anticipates<br />

every political move and, therefore, does not react to political events. Significance for the political<br />

indicator means that the null hypo<strong>thesis</strong> is rejected (using a two-sided t-test). In other words,<br />

that the coefficient is statistically different from zero. The significance is accompanied by a<br />

threshold value 47 , measuring how certain it is that the null hypo<strong>thesis</strong> is rejected. As a way to<br />

put it simply, we will often just refer to the threshold value to describe the level of significance<br />

of an estimated coefficient 48 .<br />

Interdependence on other stock markets<br />

Forbes and Rigobon (2002) show that major events in stock markets can have a significant<br />

impact on other stock markets across the globe, even if these markets differ in size and in<br />

structure. With regard to our analysis, the period that we investigate is characterised, at best,<br />

by instability of the different stock markets around the world, due to the financial crisis. Using a<br />

more global stock index as a control variable, we are able to free the BEL20 from the fluctuations<br />

due to global shocks 49 . Two such indices seem to be particularly appropriate for our analysis;<br />

the Euro Stoxx 50 and the S&P 500. The Euro Stoxx 50 is the index covering the leading<br />

companies in the main sectors of the Eurozone. The S&P 500 is the most commonly used index<br />

for American companies; it includes 500 U.S. leading companies within the main industries in<br />

the American economy.<br />

We use the European index Euro Stoxx 50 instead of the S&P 500, because the European<br />

index responds to some events and variables that the American one does not consider. In<br />

particular, it considers all monetary-policy related events and variables, because the Eurozone<br />

has a unique and common monetary policy whose impact will be obviously much bigger on<br />

the Euro Stoxx 50 than on the S&P 500. Putting numbers to this intuition: ordinary least<br />

squares (OLS) regressions show that the fraction of the fluctuations in the BEL20 returns that<br />

is explained by the S&P 500 returns is 45.90%, while if we use the Euro Stoxx 50, we reach<br />

89.05% 50 . In other words, the European index fluctuations explain about twice as much as the<br />

American one. We consider this as a sufficient reason for using the Euro Stoxx 50.<br />

As Table 5.1 shows 51 , this control variable is highly significant, which means that the Belgian<br />

stock market largely fluctuates in tandem with the European one. It confirms the trend that we<br />

already saw in figure 4.1.<br />

Table 5.1: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, controlling<br />

for interdependence with the European stock<br />

market index Euro Stoxx 50.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.811 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Intercept -0.014 (0.024)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

47 This threshold depends on the p-value for the test of the null hypo<strong>thesis</strong>.<br />

48 The lower the threshold, the more significant the coefficient is.<br />

49 It will also integrate seasonality effects, such as the “January effect” and the “week-end effect”, well known in<br />

financial time series.<br />

50 The data comes from Datastream (2012).<br />

51 In this table, as in the following ones, we indicate the latest added regressor in bold.


36<br />

It should be noted, however, that the BEL20 index is part of the Euro Stoxx 50 index and<br />

therefore, it is not surprising that they are, to some extent, correlated. Though, it should be<br />

noted that the European index is principally constituted of French companies (36.2%) and<br />

German ones (31.5%) while Belgium has a very weak weight in it (3.4%) 52 . Therefore, using<br />

this index does not seem inappropriate.<br />

The Euro Stoxx 50 explains the major part of the fluctuations of the BEL20 index. However,<br />

we will add several other macroeconomic variables in order to have a model as well-specified as<br />

possible. This approach seems justified, as Campbell et al. (1997) explain about the procedure<br />

to be used in event studies, since “in principle, [...] increases in R 2 could be achieved by using a<br />

multi-factor model”. But it is worth mentioning that “[i]n practice, however, the gains in R 2<br />

from adding additional factors are usually small”, which is confirmed with our data.<br />

The positivity of the coefficient is a coherent result, since we expected these two indices<br />

to move in tandem. We believe that a similar correlation can be expected for the volatilities<br />

of these stocks. Indeed, as Black (1976) 53 mentions while talking about the correspondence<br />

between a stock and its market portfolio: “[i]n general, it seems fair to say that when stock<br />

volatilities change they all tend to change in the same direction”.<br />

5.2.2 Adding the main political indicator, free of endogeneity, to the model<br />

Endogeneity is a serious problem. If our regressions are subject to endogeneity for the political<br />

indicator, i.e. if both the returns have an effect on political events and political events have an<br />

effect on the returns, then one of the most basic assumptions made in our OLS regressions is<br />

broken. This assumption is that errors are not correlated with any of the dependent variables.<br />

Endogeneity can result in biased and inconsistent estimators. We, therefore, have to check it for<br />

the political indicator, because it is likely that we observe some endogeneity, which would bias<br />

our interpretations. The addition of the main political indicator to the model, after having freed<br />

it of endogeneity with the BEL20 index return, is the purpose of this subsection.<br />

Dealing with endogeneity: building the instrumental variable<br />

We follow a procedure that has been extensively used previously in literature to control for<br />

possible endogeneity between stock market returns and political actions: the instrumental<br />

variable approach 54 .<br />

As investigated by Rigobon and Sack (2001) and pointed out by D’Amico and Farka (2002),<br />

“[f]or the majority of cases [...], the stock market is allowed to instrument itself through its<br />

own lagged values”. However, since the stock market is likely to anticipate political events, the<br />

bidirectional causal relationship may remain, implying that the lagged values of the stock market<br />

are not a valid instrument. It is also hard to conceive instruments totally independent from<br />

political events but determining stock market fluctuations. As a solution to this problem, we<br />

can construct our own instrument, based on the BEL20 return and on the indicator of political<br />

events. This choice may cause a problem of generated regressor, investigated further in this<br />

section, but seems appropriate since the resulting instrument would bear the desirable properties<br />

of a good instrument. This simple approach is based on the work of D’Amico and Farka (2002)<br />

but is highly intuitive.<br />

52 Source: Stoxx Limited (June 29, 2012).<br />

53 Cited by Schwert (1990).<br />

54 As cited by Angrist and Pischke (2009), the first author to use this method is Wright (1928), while the term<br />

“instrumental variable” is due to Reiersøl (1941). For a good summary of the theory about this method, refer to<br />

Wooldridge (2009).


37<br />

We start by establishing a system that on the one hand is likely to characterise the stock<br />

return function and on the other hand shows some possibility for political events to be influenced<br />

by the stock market.<br />

where<br />

• RBel is the daily return on the BEL20 index,<br />

• P OL is the political indicator,<br />

• X is the set of different control variables and<br />

• the ε are the residuals for each equations.<br />

RBel t = βP OL t + θX t + ε RBel<br />

t (5.5)<br />

P OL t = αRBel t + δX t + ε P OL<br />

t (5.6)<br />

We will now build a proper instrumental variable, addressing the possible endogeneity<br />

problem by eliminating the correlation between the residuals of the Belgian stock market daily<br />

returns (ε RBel<br />

t ) and the indicator of political events (P OL t ).<br />

The construction of the instrument is done by regressing our political indicator on the returns<br />

of the BEL20 index, then using the resulting residuals as the new political indicator in the<br />

initial equation (equation (5.4)). Similar procedures using a generated regressor as instrumental<br />

variable have been used by several authors in literature, notably Barro (1977), Barro (1979) and<br />

Pagan (1984). Oxley and McAleer (1993) provide a summary of the danger of using generated<br />

regressors if one does not correct the standard errors. Fortunately, using a two-stage least<br />

squares (2SLS) approach, as we do, corrects these standard errors and seems thus perfectly<br />

appropriate. Murphy and Topel (1985) are usually seen as a reference for two-step econometric<br />

models, yielding asymptotically correct standard errors.<br />

With regard to our case, we proceed to:<br />

By construction, the residuals of equation (5.7):<br />

P OL t = γ 0 + γ 1 RBel t + e IV<br />

t (5.7)<br />

ê IV = P OL t − ̂P OL t (5.8)<br />

ê IV = P OL t − (̂γ 0 + ̂γ 1 RBel t ) (5.9)<br />

are the share of P OL t that is not correlated with ε RBel<br />

t , because êIV contains all the information<br />

of the political indicator that is not explained by the Belgian stock market main index.<br />

These residuals bear two attributes of interest: first, they are highly correlated 55 with our<br />

initial political indicator P OL t ; second, they are not correlated 56 with the returns of the BEL20<br />

index RBel t . We can, therefore, use these residuals as a valid instrument for the political<br />

indicator. Since this indicator is now purged from ε RBel<br />

t , we have eliminated any possible<br />

endogeneity.<br />

55 To be exact, the correlation is 99.43%.<br />

56 Correlation of 0.00%.


38<br />

Testing the results, free of endogeneity<br />

Proceeding to this methodology and replacing the political indicator by êIV in equation 5.4,<br />

we obtain the results of table 5.2. As expected, the model defined by equation 5.4 showed<br />

endogeneity between the political indicator and the daily returns of the BEL20 57 .<br />

Table 5.2: Instrumental variables (2SLS) regression of the<br />

BEL20 daily returns, using an ad hoc estimator of the<br />

political indicator as the instrument.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.206 ∗ (0.104)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.814 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Intercept -0.015 (0.024)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

As the table shows, all regressors are significant. In particular, for êIV , referred to as “main<br />

political indicator” in table 5.2, the significance threshold for the test of the null hypo<strong>thesis</strong> that<br />

political events do not cause fluctuations in the return of the BEL20 index is 4.7% 58 .<br />

Its coefficient suggests that for every positive political event, on the day of the event, the<br />

return of the BEL20 decreases by 0.2 percentage points 59 , and for every negative event, it<br />

increases by the same amount, on average.<br />

However, both the coefficient and the significance of the regressors of the above regression<br />

can be inexact because of missing control variables. Fortunately, extensive literature about<br />

the variables that can have an impact on the stock market exists. Adding the correct missing<br />

independent variables to the model will give us a coefficient that is more accurate for the political<br />

indicator. Now, let us turn to the explanatory variables that should be included in the X t of<br />

equation 5.4, i.e. the variables that would help us better specify our model.<br />

5.2.3 Adding the control variables to the model<br />

Several other variables may have an impact on stock prices and therefore on stock market returns.<br />

Not including them in our regression might result in what is called “an omitted variable bias”.<br />

To be more precise, we have to distinguish between equation 5.4 and equation 5.10:<br />

{BEL20 return} t = β 0 + β 1 {P olitical indicator} t + ɛ t (5.10)<br />

Indeed, if a control variable included in equation 5.4 and not in equation 5.10 is correlated<br />

with the political indicator, then the coefficient β 1 will be biased in equation 5.10 (Angrist and<br />

Pischke (2009)). The procedure of adding control variables will therefore yield a more precise<br />

estimate of the effect of the political indicator on the fluctuations of the BEL20 index daily<br />

return. Angrist and Pischke (2009) also establish that “a longer regression - one with controls<br />

[...] - has a causal interpretation while a shorter regression does not”. Since establishing if such<br />

a causal relationship exists is exactly what we are looking for, adding control variables seems<br />

the best procedure to follow.<br />

57 In the appendices, we indicate the results of our final model if we do not control for endogeneity, which<br />

evidences that the main political indicator in the initial model was indeed endogenous.<br />

58 For the sake of clarity, in the following paragraphs we will loosely express it as “the significance threshold is<br />

x%”.<br />

59 This coefficient is only approximate, so far, since we still need to add the control variables.


39<br />

This section therefore explains in detail which variable we add to our regression and how the<br />

results are affected by the addition of each of these variables 60 . We also provide the reader with<br />

some theoretical background about the use of each of them, by briefly reviewing some of key<br />

literature about the topic. In particular, potential control variables might be the changes in<br />

rating from rating agencies, the change in the interest rate of the government bonds, the change<br />

in the inter-bank overnight interest rate (Eonia), the monetary growth, but also the change in<br />

the sovereign debt risk, the fluctuations in the price of other assets (such as gold) or the state of<br />

the economy. These variables, if they can be correctly measured, if regularly released data can<br />

be obtained and if they participate in the explanation of the fluctuations of the BEL20 index,<br />

should be used as control variables. This is done in order to purge our analysis from possible<br />

over- or under-estimations due to variations wrongly attributed to political events, instead of<br />

attributing them to these neglected macroeconomic variables. In this section, we briefly mention<br />

the authors who have analysed these variables, their results and explain why we believe that<br />

including them in our regression is relevant for the analysis at hand.<br />

We will review possible control variables one by one and keep the ones that increase the<br />

fraction of the BEL20 which is explained by the regressors (econometrically speaking, it is the<br />

coefficient of multiple determination or “adjusted R 2 ” 61 ). In other words, we will keep the ones<br />

that are significant or close to being significant, i.e. the variables with which the model is better<br />

specified.<br />

Quadratic interdependence on other stock markets<br />

Several tests with the data reveal that the BEL20 index and the Euro Stoxx 50 may not be<br />

solely correlated linearly. The square of the daily returns of the Euro Stoxx 50 should be used as<br />

well as a control variable, because in addition to a linear correlation, the Belgian stock market<br />

seems to react quadratically to this index. As table 5.3 indicates, using these squared returns<br />

is not only a significant control variable, but it also improves the significance of the political<br />

indicator 62 . The coefficient of the square of the Euro Stoxx 50 return is not large, but it is<br />

significant at a 5% threshold, evidencing that it captures some part of the BEL20 fluctuations.<br />

Table 5.3: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding<br />

the square of the daily returns of the Euro Stoxx 50 index<br />

as a regressor.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.234 ∗ (0.104)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.813 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.008 ∗ (0.003)<br />

Intercept -0.040 (0.026)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

60 Some of the data is not available daily but only monthly or quarterly. In order to solve the missing data<br />

problem due to different frequencies in the publication of data, we considered that every day between two valued<br />

dates (e.g. between the first of each month, for monthly data) take the same value as the previously valued date.<br />

Similarly for the return, we considered that it remained the same for every day of these non-valued periods.<br />

61 The adjusted R 2 , contrary to the R 2 , takes into account the number of independent variables in the specification<br />

of the regression. In other words, while the R 2 can only increase if a regressor is added to a regression, the<br />

adjusted R 2 can also decrease if this regressor does not significantly improve the specification of the equation.<br />

62 Its coefficient now reaches the 2.4% threshold.


40<br />

Rating dummy<br />

The changes in the outlook or in the rating given to a country by the main rating agencies are<br />

likely to have an impact on the Belgian stock market. Indeed, Kaminsky and Schmukler (2002)<br />

found that ratings have an impact on stock returns, and also have a spillover effect across the<br />

financial markets. Their analysis goes even further; “[i]nterestingly, rating changes trigger more<br />

widespread market instability during times of turmoil, suggesting that rating changes may act<br />

like a wake-up call or a signal that coordinates investors towards a bad equilibrium”. It seems,<br />

therefore, particularly relevant to add this variable for our analysis.<br />

Through adding the dummy variable about the changes in the outlook or in the rating of a<br />

country by the main rating agencies 63 , we obtain the results reported in table 5.4. In particular,<br />

when an outlook is modified to “negative” or when Belgium is downgraded by one of the three<br />

main rating agencies, then the daily return on the BEL20 index seems to decrease.<br />

Table 5.4: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding<br />

an indicator of rating agencies’ modifications in outlook<br />

and downgrades as a regressor.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.232 ∗ (0.103)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.813 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.008 ∗ (0.003)<br />

Rating dummy -0.511 ∗ (0.245)<br />

Intercept -0.035 (0.026)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

One can notice that with this specification of the model, our rating dummy is significant at<br />

a 5% threshold. The significance of the political indicator remains unchanged compared to the<br />

regression with only the Euro Stoxx 50 daily returns and their square as control variables.<br />

In section 5.2.9, we test the robustness of this “rating” indicator, by replacing it by an<br />

alternative measure of it.<br />

Changes in the yield of Belgian government bonds on the secondary market<br />

As Bernhard and Leblang (2006) conclude, the interest rate on government bonds is likely to have<br />

an impact on political outcomes. Should this rate be high, it will be harder for a government to<br />

manage fiscal policy (implementation of new programmes or tax cuts for example). It, therefore,<br />

seems to be a relevant control variable for our analyses.<br />

In line with the predictions of Bernhard and Leblang (2006) about the potential impact<br />

of a change in the yield of a country’s government bonds on the stock market, we find almost<br />

significant results evidencing this link. For our data, we used the one-year maturity yield of<br />

Belgian government bonds, exchanged on the secondary market 64 . Our results show a negative<br />

link between this variable and the BEL20 daily returns, even if this link is rather small. In<br />

particular, when the yield increases, then the return of the BEL20 seems to slightly decrease, on<br />

average 65 .<br />

63 This is the dummy variable that we built in section 4.2.<br />

64 The data comes from the National Bank of Belgium (2012).<br />

65 This control variable has a significance threshold of 11.1%, and very slightly affects the measure of the political<br />

indicator, whose coefficient (in absolute value) increases and standard error decreases. The significance is therefore<br />

bigger.


41<br />

Table 5.5: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding as a<br />

regressor the daily change in the yield of Belgian government<br />

bonds on the secondary market, with one-year maturity.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.237 ∗ (0.103)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.813 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.008 ∗ (0.003)<br />

Rating dummy -0.491 ∗ (0.244)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 (0.005)<br />

Intercept -0.031 (0.026)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

It is worth mentioning that over the period of interest in this analysis, there are 13 dates<br />

missing with respect to the stock market days, i.e. there are 13 days for which there is a value<br />

for the stock market, but no value for the interest rate on government bonds. These dates are in<br />

2010: May 13, May 14, May 24, July 21, November 1 and November 11, and in 2011: June 2,<br />

June 3, June 13, July 21, August 15, November 1 and November 11. We considered that the<br />

return for these days is simply zero, because the value of the stock remains the same as for the<br />

previous day.<br />

We also tried a similar regression, using the yield on Belgian bonds as control variable, with<br />

every different maturity for which the National Bank of Belgium (2012) gives the data, i.e. two<br />

years, three years, four years, five years and “six years and more”. The results are that the<br />

“government bonds yield” indicator is not even close to being significant for the other maturities.<br />

Contrary to the one-year maturity yield, they do not improve the explanation of the BEL20’s<br />

fluctuations. We will therefore keep only the one-year maturity yield in further regressions.<br />

Predictability<br />

The predictability of political events should have a strong impact on our results. Indeed the<br />

more predictable an event is, the less strong the impact on stock prices will be, and vice versa.<br />

Predictability includes not only the outcome of similar past events, but also the opinion given in<br />

the main newspapers about the likelihood that the event will end up with a successful outcome.<br />

According to Bernhard and Leblang (2006), this predictability may be evaluated by the volatility<br />

of the stock market before the event; indeed the higher the volatility, the less certain stock price<br />

forecasts are.<br />

As a way to measure the volatility, we refer to the most cited source on the topic, which is<br />

Parkinson (1980) who provides a good estimate of the variance for stock prices. This estimation<br />

is easily computed as:<br />

( ) Hight<br />

Est t = ln<br />

Low t<br />

(5.11)<br />

where<br />

• Est t is the estimation of the variance at time t,<br />

• High t is the highest price reached by the stock, over the period of consideration, here the<br />

day t, and


42<br />

• Low t is the lowest price reached by the stock, for the same period.<br />

We, therefore, compute this estimated variance for each day of the period of interest. Then,<br />

we lag the results from one, two, three, four or five periods in order to fit the estimator of<br />

predictability established by Bernhard and Leblang (2006). Adding each of these lags of the<br />

estimated variance separately to our regression shows that the resulting variable is the most<br />

significant when we use a three-day lag on the estimator of the variance. The results of this<br />

addition can be seen in table 5.6.<br />

Table 5.6: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding the<br />

predictability of the political events as a regressor, measured<br />

as a three-day lagged estimation of the variance.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.244 ∗ (0.103)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.813 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.006 † (0.004)<br />

Rating dummy -0.493 ∗ (0.243)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 (0.005)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.057 ∗ (0.024)<br />

Intercept -0.116 ∗ (0.045)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

One can see on this table that this estimator of predictability is largely significant (1.9%<br />

threshold) and that some other regressors are impacted as well. In particular, firstly, the change<br />

in the yield of Belgian government bonds on the secondary market and the square of the return<br />

of the Euro Stoxx 50 are both less significant than before 66 . Secondly, the political indicator’s<br />

significance is also impacted but positively 67 .<br />

Therefore, it is important to consider the predictability, as we see that there is an anticipatory<br />

movement of the market prior to political events. This movement is significant for all three days<br />

preceding the event and is the most significant in t − 3, meaning that on average, it is three<br />

days before a political event happens that the market fluctuates the most.<br />

Changes in the Eonia and in the Euribor<br />

Bernanke and Kuttner (2005) find that an unexpected 25-basis-point rate cut of the federal<br />

funds rate (FFR) would typically imply an increase of about 1% in stock prices of the CRSP<br />

value-weighted index 68 . Even if the context is different, the approach brings some pieces of<br />

interesting information about a possible control variable that could have an impact on stock<br />

prices: the federal fund rate.<br />

However, this rate is a good control variable for the American market; indeed Bernanke and<br />

Kuttner (2005) worked with an American index. For Europe, fortunately, there is an equivalent<br />

short-maturity rate to the FFR, which is the Eonia 69 and which is the average rate at which<br />

European banks lend to each other overnight.<br />

66 Their thresholds are 9.5% and 12.4% respectively (instead of 2.8% and 11.1%), so they are still worth<br />

consideration.<br />

67 It is now at the 1.8% threshold, with a coefficient that is larger in absolute value.<br />

68 The CRSP (Center for Research in Security Prices) indices are considered as a benchmark for both academic<br />

research and investment. They are based on the NYSE, Amex, NASDAQ and Arca markets and are, therefore,<br />

an alternative to the S&P 500.<br />

69 Euro OverNight Index Average


43<br />

There also exists another European benchmark, very similar to the Eonia, which is the<br />

Euribor 70 , the Eurozone-equivalent of the Libor 71 (Euribor-rates.eu (2012)).<br />

Using the change in the Eonia does not show any significance, but using that of the Euribor<br />

(one-year maturity) does. It lies within the 10% significance upper bound and contributes to the<br />

explanation of the BEL20 index fluctuations, we will, therefore, keep it as a control variable. Its<br />

inclusion gives us table 5.7.<br />

Table 5.7: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding<br />

the change in the interbank interest rate (one-year maturity<br />

Euribor) as a regressor.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.244 ∗ (0.103)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.811 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.007 † (0.004)<br />

Rating dummy -0.490 ∗ (0.243)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 (0.005)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.060 ∗ (0.024)<br />

Euribor change 0.074 † (0.044)<br />

Intercept -0.131 ∗∗ (0.046)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

National inflation and money growth<br />

Feldstein (1980) shows that for the U.S. market, increased inflation had an adverse effect on<br />

stock prices. What is of particular interest to us is that national inflation can have an impact<br />

on the stock market. Similarly, monetary growth has been identified by Rozeff (1974) to be<br />

in favour of an increase in stock returns. The paper of Thorbecke (1997) about the effects of<br />

monetary policy on stock market returns backs up the view of Rozeff, at least in the short term.<br />

His findings support the hypo<strong>thesis</strong> that the causality is due to firms’ access to credit. It seems<br />

thus that national inflation is an interesting variable, worth including in our model.<br />

Testing for this relationship, our first approach is to use the monthly change in the Consumer<br />

Price Index in Belgium 72 as an estimator for inflation. Adding it as a regressor shows that this<br />

variable is not significant. Worse, it reduces the adjusted R 2 of the model. Therefore, we cannot<br />

use it.<br />

As alternative measures of inflation, we verify the relevancy of the change in M1, then M2<br />

then M3 73 . These three measures estimate the quantity of money in the Belgian economy going<br />

from the most liquid money (M1, principally constituted of demand deposit accounts), then M2<br />

(constituted of M1, plus saving deposits and slightly less liquid assets) and finally M3 (including<br />

longer-time deposits as well). When we use M1 or M2, the result does not show any closeness to<br />

significance. However, the control variable M3 is close to being significant and improves the<br />

adjusted R 2 . To be precise, the significance threshold reached by this variable is 16.6%. In<br />

literature, M3, or the sum of the liabilities of the financial intermediaries, was found by King and<br />

Levine (1993) to have an impact on economic growth. Therefore, it confirms that its inclusion<br />

in our model makes sense.<br />

70 EURo InterBank Offered Rate.<br />

71 London InterBank Offered Rate.<br />

72 Computed by the Belgian National Institute of Statistics.<br />

73 The data comes from Datastream and has one-month interval.


44<br />

However, several authors show that some problems arise if we want to use this variable, as it<br />

is identified as being largely subject to endogeneity. As was extensively established in previous<br />

literature, the causality effect goes in both ways between stock market returns and monetary<br />

growth. In particular, the link between the two has been investigated by Boudoukh et al. (1994),<br />

Bernanke and Gertler (2000), and D’Amico and Farka (2002), through analyses of monetary<br />

policies. D’Amico and Farka state that “[s]tock market fluctuations are likely to be an important<br />

determinant of monetary policy decisions because of their potential impact on macroeconomy”.<br />

Bernanke and Gertler (2000) mention that stock returns should be included as a regressor to<br />

estimate the impact of asset price volatility on monetary policy, because monetary policy could<br />

be pursuing other objectives, besides stabilisation of output and expected inflation 74 .<br />

These discussions brought us to verify a possible endogeneity between monetary growth and<br />

the return of the BEL20 index over the period of interest. We find that these variables are<br />

indeed endogenous. After correcting this endogeneity, as we did for the political indicator in<br />

section 5.2.2, we obtain the results reported in table 5.8.<br />

Table 5.8: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, adding as<br />

a regressor the monthly growth of M3 (free of endogeneity)<br />

as an estimator for inflation.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.240 ∗ (0.102)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.812 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.007 † (0.004)<br />

Rating dummy -0.515 ∗ (0.242)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.009 † (0.005)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.058 ∗ (0.024)<br />

Euribor change 0.084 † (0.044)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.128 ∗∗ (0.045)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

We can see from this table that money growth, when corrected for endogeneity, is significant<br />

(6.4% threshold) and that including it in the model increases the absolute value of the yield on<br />

Belgian government bonds, making it significant at a 10% threshold.<br />

One might wonder if using more than one instrumented variables is relevant, since it is not<br />

common in literature 75 . Wooldridge (2001), seen as a reference in econometrics 76 , uses several<br />

instrumented variables (with as many instruments) for estimating the impact of education and<br />

skin colour on wages. We therefore believe that it is relevant to apply a similar procedure:<br />

correcting more than one variable for endogeneity by using several instrumented variables and<br />

several instruments.<br />

State of the economy<br />

Romer and Romer (2007) use interesting control variables, not only to free the regressions from<br />

endogeneity and anticipatory movements, but also to evaluate the robustness of their paper.<br />

74 It is worth mentioning that some authors, such as Boudoukh et al. (1994), do not completely agree with this<br />

possible endogeneity, considering that the potential causal effects between monetary growth and the real economy<br />

are a question that is still open.<br />

75 To the best of our knowledge.<br />

76 Many thousands of sources cite his books and papers.


45<br />

Notably, they use the state of the economy, as measured by the lagged GDP growth (quarterly<br />

data). Some major differences remain, however, between their analyses and ours: i.e. firstly the<br />

topic varies greatly since they evaluate the macroeconomic effects of tax changes; secondly, the<br />

timeframe is substantially different since their analysis is made over half a century.<br />

GDP data is available for Belgium 77 , but only as quarterly data. We tried to add the<br />

lagged GDP of Belgium to our regression, and found that the lagged GDP is significant at a 5%<br />

threshold if we lag it of 30 to 55 days and even at the 1% level if we lag it of 55 days to 65 days.<br />

To be precise, it is 60-trading days (thus 12 weeks), which corresponds to about three months,<br />

and therefore the lag corresponds to a quarter.<br />

However, we will not include this lagged GDP growth as a regressor in the coming regressions<br />

for multiple reasons. First and foremost, since our timeframe is not even two years long, using<br />

this variable as a control would not be relevant for the analysis at hand, because only seven<br />

different measures can be made (because we have only quarterly data). Another reason, which<br />

should be sufficient for this decision not to include the lagged GDP growth, is that its addition<br />

seriously reduces the adjusted R 2 . It implies that if we add it, then a bigger fraction of the<br />

BEL20 daily returns is not explained by the model, even though the coefficient is significant.<br />

This variable seems, therefore, inappropriate for the specification of our model.<br />

Output<br />

As Blanchard (1981) mentions, “the effect of output on the stock market is ambiguous”, but he<br />

does not discard the possibility that output has an impact on the stock market. We therefore<br />

verify if including this variable as a regressor is relevant in our analysis.<br />

Using measures of the output such as the unemployment rate 78 or the net exports 79 show<br />

that for Belgium and over the period of interest, the output has no significant impact on the<br />

variations of the BEL20 index. The inclusion of these variables actually worsens the model,<br />

given the number of regressors. We, therefore, consider the output as irrelevant for the case at<br />

hand and we do not include it in the model.<br />

The reasons for this non-significance is likely to be that the Euro Stoxx 50 already captures<br />

the change in output. Indeed, as Belgium is such an open country (see section 2.2.2), its output<br />

is largely correlated with the output of other countries.<br />

Fluctuations in gold price<br />

Gold is often considered as a refuge currency against inflation. It seems therefore possible that<br />

in difficult times, more investors turn to gold instead of to the stock market. The return on gold<br />

is thus likely to affect the stock market.<br />

However, proceeding to the addition of the daily return on gold as a regressor 80 shows that<br />

this variable is not significant in our analysis. Thus, we will not take it into account.<br />

Sovereign debt risk<br />

The report about financial stability of the National Bank of Belgium (2011) mentions an<br />

intensification of market concerns with regard to the sovereign debt risk (these concerns were<br />

already present in 2010). The same report underlines that an increase of this risk has strong<br />

77 The data comes from the National Bank of Belgium (2012).<br />

78 The data comes from Datastream and were verified with the data coming from the National Bank of Belgium<br />

(2012) (monthly data).<br />

79 The data comes from Datastream (monthly data).<br />

80 The data comes from the National Bank of Belgium (2012).


46<br />

negative consequences for a country, since it would increase the financing cost of that country.<br />

An indicator of this risk would be useful for our analysis, since a stock market full of concerns<br />

seems less likely to generate positive returns than an optimistic stock market.<br />

Unable to find such an indicator for Belgium, we use an estimator of sovereign debt risk:<br />

the amount of the government’s debt itself 81 . We tried both for central government’s debt and<br />

for general government’s debt and the results are similar: non-significance. Thus, the debt of<br />

the Belgian government does not explain the fluctuations in the BEL20 index over the period<br />

of analysis. The reason behind it may be the same as for the state of the economy: that the<br />

data about the debt are only available quarterly, while our event-window is relatively short.<br />

Alternatively, it could simply be that the amount of the debt has no direct 82 impact on the<br />

stock market. Finally, it is also possible that the “rating” variable captures part of the sovereign<br />

debt risk, since the rating agencies use this risk to determine the countries rating. In any case,<br />

we will not use an explicit measure of the sovereign debt risk for our analysis.<br />

Conclusion about the control variables<br />

To summarise this section, the formal expression of our regression, with the control variables<br />

that we use, is the following:<br />

{BEL20 return} t = β 0 + β 1 {Main P olitical indicator} t<br />

+ β 2 {Euro Stoxx 50 return} t<br />

+ β 3 {Euro Stoxx 50 return} 2 t<br />

+ β 4 {Rating dummy} t<br />

+ β 5 {Y ield on government bonds} t<br />

+ β 6 {P redictability indicator} t<br />

+ β 7 {Euribor change} t<br />

+ β 8 {Money growth} t + u t (5.12)<br />

The results of this regression are contained in table 5.8, on page 44. However, this model<br />

may suffer from a weakness that we are about to verify: its residuals may not be constant over<br />

time. This common problem for financial econometrics is called heteroskedasticity. We cannot<br />

interpret the data before verifying if our model is subject to it.<br />

5.2.4 Heteroskedasticity: verification and correction<br />

A possible problem in least squares regressions is heteroskedasticity. We are in presence of<br />

heteroskedasticity when the residuals of a regression are not constant over time. Such a problem<br />

would result in a biased variance of the estimators, thereby directly affecting the standard errors<br />

and resulting in biased confidence intervals and significance thresholds.<br />

Harrington and Schrider (2002) deal with the problem of heteroskedasticity in event studies.<br />

They finish by advising to complete the OLS regressions with a Weighted Least Squares (WLS)<br />

approach, robust to arbitrary forms of heteroskedasticity. In this section, we start by verifying<br />

that we are in presence of heteroskedasticity, then we follow the procedure advised by Harrington<br />

and Schrider.<br />

81 The data comes from Datastream.<br />

82 We have seen that it has an indirect impact: a high debt drives the rating agencies to downgrade a country,<br />

which has a significant impact on the stock market.


47<br />

In order to check if the residuals of our model are heteroskedastic, we conduct a Breusch-<br />

Pagan test. First, we compute the residuals of equation 5.12, then we add the square of these<br />

residuals as a regressor in the model, which gives us the results of table 5.9.<br />

Table 5.9: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all selected<br />

control variables and adding the squared residuals as a regressor for an<br />

heteroskedasticity check.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.231 ∗ (0.101)<br />

Squared residuals of equation 5.12 0.185 ∗∗ (0.054)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.815 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.006 † (0.003)<br />

Rating dummy -0.516 ∗ (0.239)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 (0.005)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.034 (0.025)<br />

Euribor change 0.090 ∗ (0.043)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.130 ∗∗ (0.450)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

As one can notice, our regression is largely subject to heteroskedasticity (even at a 1%<br />

threshold, as the variable “squared residuals of equation 5.12” shows). We must, therefore,<br />

correct it before being able to draw any conclusion from the results. Easily-computed methods<br />

exist to correct heteroskedasticity. The one we use is based on a WLS approach, giving a<br />

different weight to observations depending on how well they behave (i.e., the “robust” tool of<br />

Stata). This yields standard errors that are asymptotically exact (Angrist and Pischke (2009)).<br />

The results of our model, robust to heteroskedasticity, are contained in table 5.10.<br />

Table 5.10: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on<br />

all selected control variables, with the residuals robust<br />

to heteroskedasticity.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.240 ∗ (0.098)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.812 ∗∗ (0.018)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.007 (0.005)<br />

Rating dummy -0.515 ∗ (0.232)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.009 ∗ (0.004)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.058 (0.039)<br />

Euribor change 0.084 ∗ (0.040)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.128 ∗ (0.058)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

As table 5.10 contains the final results of our model, we interpret it in section 5.2.10. What<br />

we can already notice, as a comparison with our non-robust model, is that the standard error<br />

of the square of the returns of the Euro Stoxx 50 and the standard error of the estimator for<br />

the predictability have increased. Their respective coefficients do not lie in the 10% significance<br />

area anymore.


48<br />

5.2.5 Autocorrelation: verification for both the returns and the residuals<br />

Another possible problem with financial time series is that the returns are autocorrelated. In<br />

other words, the return in time t is influenced by the return in time t − 1. Autocorrelation is a<br />

problem because it would contradict one of the assumptions of the least squares models: that<br />

the returns are independent and identically distributed (IID). We start with a verification of a<br />

simple linear form of autocorrelation of the returns, then also verify if the disturbances of the<br />

model are serially correlated.<br />

Autocorrelation: verification for the BEL20 daily returns<br />

The simple linear form is formally expressed as follows:<br />

where<br />

• r t is the return considered at time t and<br />

r t = α + βr t−1 + ɛ t (5.13)<br />

• α, β and ɛ are respectively the intercept, the coefficient of the lagged returns and the<br />

residuals of the model.<br />

Fitting equation 5.13 to the BEL20 daily returns, no evidence of autocorrelation is found.<br />

The BEL20 index returns are therefore IID. We also find that, as predicted by the theory, they<br />

have a zero-mean.<br />

This test of autocorrelation corresponds to the simplest approach to testing for unit root, i.e.<br />

testing that after a shock the series has a tendency to come back to the trend. Testing for unit<br />

root can be better specified, by using a dynamically complete model. We do it in the extensions:<br />

section 5.3.1.<br />

Autocorrelation: verification for the disturbances of the model<br />

In our regression model, not only do we have to verify a possible autocorrelation of the returns<br />

but we must also consider whether the disturbances of the model are serially correlated, i.e.<br />

if they are not IID. Probably the most well-known test of serial correlation, constructed with<br />

the residuals, is the Durbin-Watson (DW) statistics, based on Durbin and Watson (1950) and<br />

Durbin and Watson (1951). The statistic is computed as follows:<br />

DW =<br />

∑ Tt=2<br />

(û t − û t−1 ) 2<br />

∑ Tt=1 û 2 t<br />

(5.14)<br />

where<br />

• û t is the disturbance of the least squares regression at time t.<br />

The DW statistic lies within the [0, 4] interval and if it differs significantly from value 2, then<br />

we can assume that the residuals of the least squares regression are autocorrelated. With our<br />

model, the DW statistic yields a value of 0, indicating that the residuals are certainly not IID.<br />

In order to correctly fit the model, given this result, we need to use an autoregressive process.<br />

We proceed to such process in further sections (5.3.3 and 5.3.4), however since it requires a<br />

significantly more advanced knowledge of econometrics, we introduced it as an extension.<br />

The fortunate thing, however, is that even though the residuals are serially correlated, it<br />

does not imply bias of the least squares estimators computed above. The coefficients previously<br />

presented are therefore still consistent.


49<br />

5.2.6 Anticipation and late reaction effects<br />

Glascock et al. (1987) find that daily stock prices react significantly to anouncements of Moody’s,<br />

but this adjustment is lagged. This result convinces us that it is possible that the effect of the<br />

political events on the stock market is lagged, i.e. that a fraction of the investors have a delayed<br />

reaction to the events. The other way round, we believe that it is possible that the market<br />

anticipates events. These two verifications are the purpose of this section. For each, we proceed<br />

to an analysis of the results with a lag or an anticipation of one, two or three days. We do not<br />

go further than three days, because it is unlikely that the market needs more than three days to<br />

adjust or that it significantly anticipates more than three days in advance 83 .<br />

Late reaction: lagging the indicator<br />

In order to have a well-specified model for the lagged indicator analysis, we have to re-consider<br />

an assumption that we made: endogeneity. Previously, we believed that political events have<br />

an impact on the stock market and that the stock market has an impact on the occurence of<br />

the political events. Now that we lag the indicator, we have to envisage that it might not be<br />

endogenous anymore. It is indeed likely that political events have an impact on the stock market<br />

on the days following the events. However, it is not possible that the returns of the BEL20 index<br />

on the days following a political event have an impact on the occurence of this event. In other<br />

words, an event cannot possibly be influenced by the daily return of a future date. Therefore,<br />

no endogeneity should be assumed for this section.<br />

The results of the regressions using a lagged version of the main political indicator 84 are<br />

clear: there is no “late reaction effect”, as the lagged indicator is not significant in the model.<br />

We present the results of a one-day lagged version of the main political indicator in table 5.11.<br />

We can see on this table that the coefficients, standard errors and significances of all other<br />

regressors are not very different than previously, evidencing robustness of the model.<br />

Table 5.11: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, using a one-day lagged<br />

version of the main political indicator as a regressor.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator, lagged of one day -0.023 (0.101)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.807 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.006 † (0.004)<br />

Rating dummy -0.519 ∗ (0.243)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 † (0.005)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.056 ∗ (0.025)<br />

Euribor change 0.084 † (0.044)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.122 ∗∗ (0.046)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

The hypo<strong>thesis</strong> that the coefficient of the one-day lagged version of the main political<br />

indicator is different from zero cannot be rejected. The result is similar for the different lags<br />

83 Except for one particular event: if a piece of news makes the occurence of the event very likely, then the<br />

market could shift abruptly, several days in advance. However, as we consider an indicator made of a set of<br />

multiple events, our assumption seems reasonable.<br />

84 To be more precise, we keep the same control variables as for our main model, we do not correct for endogeneity<br />

of the lagged political indicator and the results do not vary whether we correct for heteroskedasticity or not.


50<br />

that we used, the entire reaction of the stock market to the political events seems therefore to<br />

occur no later than on the day of the events.<br />

Anticipating the events<br />

As for the lagged-indicator analysis, we have to consider if the presence of endogeneity is likely<br />

or not for this new specification of the model. With an “anticipation analysis”, firstly, we wonder<br />

if the stock market a few days before the political event has an impact on the occurence of this<br />

event. We believe that it is indeed likely that events are somehow a response to good or bad<br />

conditions in the stock market. Secondly, we wonder if a political event might have an influence<br />

on the stock market a few days before this event. Since it is likely that investors anticipate<br />

political events, we believe that this influence indeed exists. This two-way causality relationship<br />

convince us to use an endogeneity-corrected anticipated indicator for this section.<br />

As for the lagged-indicator analysis, the results that we find by advancing the political<br />

indicator by one or more days show non-significance, no matter how many days of anticipation<br />

we use. In particular, table 5.12 show the results with a one-day anticipation of the main political<br />

indicator.<br />

Table 5.12: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, using a one-day anticipated<br />

version of the main political indicator as a regressor.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator, advanced by one day 0.052 (0.106)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.807 ∗∗ (0.014)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.006 † (0.004)<br />

Rating dummy -0.545 ∗ (0.249)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 † (0.005)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.053 ∗ (0.025)<br />

Euribor change 0.083 † (0.044)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.118 ∗ (0.046)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

One can notice, however, that even if the coefficient of the advanced political indicator is<br />

insignificant, there seems to be a slight positive tendency. We believe that it is possible that the<br />

market anticipates an event, even over-anticipates it, then adjusts (in the opposite direction) on<br />

the day of the event (as we will argue in the conclusions of the model). This positive tendency for<br />

the one-day advanced political indicator seems in line with this possibility. But, let us mention<br />

it one more time, since the coefficient is insignificant, we cannot build a strong theory on it.<br />

5.2.7 Robustness of the political indicator: dropping the events, each in turn<br />

To verify that our results are robust, one possible check consists of dropping key events one by<br />

one, and verifying if the coefficient of the indicator is unwavering or if it fluctuates significantly.<br />

If the coefficient remains steady, then it proves that the political indicator is robust, since it is<br />

not a particular event that biasses the whole indicator. This is the first robustness check that<br />

we investigate.<br />

Fitting 23 new least squares regressions, each time dropping a significant event, for each of<br />

the 23 non-zero values of the main political indicator, we find that the indicator is robust to a<br />

certain degree. In particular, the coefficient of the political indicator fluctuates between −0.2020


51<br />

and −0.2688. The gap is relatively important, but this result does not fundamentally change<br />

the conclusions previously reached: even at its least significant value, the political indicator still<br />

lies within the 3% significance threshold, testifying to its robustness.<br />

If we compute the mean of these coefficients, we obtain −0.23990, while the coefficient of<br />

the regression with all events is −0.23988. The fact that these two values are so close evidences<br />

robustness of our main political indicator.<br />

5.2.8 Robustness of the political indicator: alternative indicators<br />

The second robustness check consists of replacing the main political indicator that we have used<br />

so far by the other versions of the indicator, that we introduced in section 3.3. We use the same<br />

control variables as previously and follow the same approach with regard to endogeneity and<br />

heteroskedasticity. That is, we fit equation 5.12, just replacing the main political indicator by<br />

each alternative version in turn, using endogeneity-corrected indicators and residuals robust to<br />

an arbitrary form of heteroskedasticity.<br />

Regressing with these other versions of the political indicator is very useful, as it confirms<br />

the intuitive conclusions that we could draw from previous regressions and it gives even more<br />

information about the impact of political events on the returns of the BEL20 index. Let us<br />

now investigate one by one each of these alternative versions of the political indicator that we<br />

established.<br />

Separate indicators for positive and negative events<br />

The main political indicator that we used so far was built on the combination of a dummy<br />

variable for the events favourable to the formation of a government and of another dummy<br />

variable for the events unfavourable to the formation of a government. Our results with the<br />

main political indicator (see table 5.10) indicated a negative coefficient and therefore, on average<br />

a positive reaction of the market after negative events and reversely, a negative reaction of the<br />

market after positive events. The estimated coefficient was about −0.24. We will now be able to<br />

verify if the reactions to negative and to positive events are indeed in the reverse directions and<br />

if one of the two types of event drives the coefficient of the main political indicator or if both<br />

are significant.<br />

Table 5.13: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all selected<br />

control variables, with the residuals robust to heteroskedasticity and<br />

with separate indicators for positive and negative events.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Significant positive event dummy -0.402 ∗ (0.162)<br />

Significant negative event dummy 0.118 (0.123)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.808 ∗∗ (0.018)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.007 (0.005)<br />

Rating dummy -0.519 ∗ (0.232)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 † (0.004)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.056 (0.039)<br />

Euribor change 0.083 ∗ (0.039)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.125 ∗ (0.058)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%


52<br />

As table 5.13 shows, our intuition for the sign of the coefficients was correct. However several<br />

comments are worth mentioning. Firstly, the absolute value of the coefficient of the significant<br />

positive event dummy is much bigger than that of the significant negative event dummy (0.402<br />

versus 0.118). It seems, therefore, that the market reacts much more to positive events than<br />

to negative events. Secondly, the standard errors of both coefficients are bigger than for the<br />

main political indicator. It is likely to be due to the smaller number of non-zero values for<br />

each of these two indicators. Thirdly, as the consequence of the smaller coefficient and larger<br />

standard errors, the significance of the negative event dummy has plummeted, such that we<br />

can no longer reject the hypo<strong>thesis</strong> that its coefficient is equal to zero. However, we can still<br />

observe a positive tendency. With regards to the significance of the positive event dummy, it<br />

almost reaches the 1% threshold and is even more significant than the main political indicator<br />

presented earlier. Finally, the coefficients and standard errors of the other variables have not<br />

meaningfully changed, evidencing their robustness in this model.<br />

Significant event dummy<br />

With the results we have found so far, mixing positive and negative events in one indicator taking<br />

only value 1 or 0, no matter what kind of event occurs, is highly unlikely to give significant<br />

results. Proceeding to a regression with the significant event dummy instead of the main political<br />

indicator confirms this intuition: evidence of non-significance is found. We do not include the<br />

related table, since it does not contain any other relevant new information.<br />

All political events<br />

The next alternative indicator consists of selecting not only the most significant political events,<br />

but also the less significant ones (the appendices show the detail of which event is selected). The<br />

results yielded by the regression with this indicator are summarised in table 5.14<br />

Table 5.14: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all selected<br />

control variables, robust to heteroskedasticity, using more<br />

political events in the political indicator.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

All political events indicator -0.138 † (0.079)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.810 ∗∗ (0.018)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.006 (0.005)<br />

Rating dummy -0.516 ∗ (0.232)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 † (0.004)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.059 (0.040)<br />

Euribor change 0.086 ∗ (0.039)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.129 ∗ (0.059)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

As we can see, the indicator’s significance is smaller than the significance of the main political<br />

indicator. It shows that the stock market reacts less (if at all) to the less meaningful political<br />

events. The standard error of the new indicator is also smaller, which allows the coefficient to<br />

be still significant at the 10% threshold.


53<br />

Main political indicator 2<br />

Using the indicator taking value 1 or −1 not only on the day of the most important political<br />

events, but also on the days following these events, i.e. the indicator that we called “main<br />

political indicator 2”, we obtain the results reported in table 5.15.<br />

Table 5.15: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns, on all<br />

selected control variables, with the residuals robust to heteroskedasticity<br />

and using the “main political indicator 2”<br />

purged from endogeneity.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator 2 -0.153 ∗ (0.067)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.811 ∗∗ (0.018)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.007 (0.005)<br />

Rating dummy -0.514 ∗ (0.233)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.009 ∗ (0.004)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.059 (0.040)<br />

Euribor change 0.084 ∗ (0.040)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.131 ∗ (0.059)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

As the table shows, the coefficient of the political indicator has dropped by 0.09 percentage<br />

point, compared to table 5.10. Even though the standard errors are smaller as well, the indicator<br />

is less significant than before, but still lies within the 5% threshold. This loss of significance<br />

indicates that the effect of an event happens mainly on the day of the event and not on the day<br />

following the event. This result confirms what we found when investigating the late reaction<br />

effect of the stock market, in section 5.2.6.<br />

Significant event dummy 2<br />

As we found no significance for the variable “significant event dummy” and a decrease in the<br />

significance of the main political indicator when we add value 1 on the days following the events<br />

as well, we do not have great expectations of significance for the variable “significant event<br />

dummy 2”. The data confirms this intuition.<br />

All political events 2<br />

As for the variable “all political events”, the negative tendency of the indicator “all political<br />

events 2” is still present, but the statistic test cannot significantly reject the hypo<strong>thesis</strong> that the<br />

coefficient is equal to zero. Its coefficient drops to −0.067 with a standard error of 0.055.<br />

5.2.9 Robustness of the rating dummy: alternative indicator<br />

Finally, we verify the robustness of our “rating dummy” as well, by replacing this dummy by<br />

another indicator, built upon the same events but taking an incremental value for each event. In<br />

particular, instead of using a dummy variable taking value 1 only on the day of the modification<br />

to a negative outlook or the day of the downgrade, we can build a variable whose value increases<br />

for each of these dates. This approach makes sense from an economic point of view, since a


54<br />

downgrade is not an event that is likely to affect the BEL20 during one period only, but that is<br />

likely to affect it continuously (i.e. it is a persistent shock).<br />

We have, therefore, built this indicator, standardised for our period and thus starting at<br />

value 0 at the beginning of the period of interest. We increment this variable on four dates; on<br />

December 14, 2010, on May 23, 2011, on October 7, 2011 and on November 25, 2011 (section<br />

4.2 gives more detail about these particular events).<br />

If we replace the previously used rating dummy by this “rating indicator”, we obtain the<br />

results summarised in table 5.16.<br />

Table 5.16: Regression of the BEL20 daily returns on<br />

all selected control variables, with the political indicator<br />

purged from endogeneity and the residuals robust<br />

to heteroskedasticity, replacing the rating dummy by<br />

a more sophisticated indicator.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator -0.218 ∗ (0.092)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.812 ∗∗ (0.018)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.007 (0.005)<br />

Rating indicator -0.048 ∗ (0.023)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.009 ∗ (0.004)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.070 † (0.040)<br />

Euribor change 0.070 (0.045)<br />

Money growth -0.025 (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.101 † (0.060)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

The coefficient of the new indicator is much smaller than that of the previously used dummy,<br />

but its significance is similar. We could expect such change in the coefficient, since many more<br />

observations are now non-zero valued and the value of some is also bigger. We can interpret these<br />

results as follows: when one of the main rating companies downgrades Belgium or places it under<br />

a negative outlook, then the daily returns of the BEL20 index is significantly and continuously<br />

negatively affected. In other words, it does not just cause a one-day fall then bounces back<br />

and fully recovers, it is, instead, a persistent shock. However, it is worth remembering, as the<br />

previously used rating dummy showed, that the impact on the day of the event is much bigger,<br />

which makes sense since this change might appear as unexpected for some investors.<br />

5.2.10 Summary of the main model<br />

Let us briefly summarise the results reached in this section about the impact of political events<br />

on the daily returns of the BEL20 index.<br />

First and foremost, the results of the main model are reported on page 47, in table 5.10,<br />

which puts together the results of the analysis after correcting for both endogeneity of the<br />

political indicator and heteroskedasticity of the residuals. This model uses as control variables<br />

the daily returns of the Euro Stoxx 50, their square, an indicator for the changes in rating, the<br />

changes in the yield on Belgian government bonds, an indicator of the predictability, the changes<br />

in the Euribor and the growth of money. The two control variables that do not reach the 10%<br />

threshold in this model are not far from being significant, as they are only a few percents above<br />

this threshold. Each control variable used is useful, since dropping any of them decreases the<br />

coefficient of determination (the adjusted R 2 ), i.e. the share of the fluctuations of the BEL20


55<br />

index daily returns that is explained by the regressors 85 . One can observe that the political<br />

indicator is almost significant at a 1% threshold 86 , meaning that the political events that we<br />

identified have had a meaningful effect on the BEL20 index returns. To be more precise, the<br />

coefficient indicates that, all other things being equal, when a positive event took place, the<br />

BEL20 index daily return decreased on average. And when a negative event happened, the<br />

daily return increased, on average. These movements are significant on the particular day of<br />

the event and the average fluctuation has an absolute value of about 0.24 percentage points.<br />

The negative sign leads us to believe that the Belgian stock market anticipates events and even<br />

over-anticipates their effect, then readjusts when the event actually takes place.<br />

Secondly, even though we expected that the market would partially anticipate the outcome<br />

of the events and would partially react with a lag to these events, no such evidence can be found.<br />

It seems therefore that if there is some anticipation of the outcome of political events, this<br />

anticipation is slightly absorbed by the market over several days, such that there is no sudden<br />

fluctuation due to this event before the day when the event actually takes place. Similarly, the<br />

market seems to have fully absorbed the news on this particular day, such that no significant<br />

lagged reaction can be found. Though, even if the anticipation is not significant, there seems<br />

to be a positive tendency on the day before the event (the stock market yields higher returns<br />

before positive events and smaller before negative event). This tendency backs up our theory of<br />

over-anticipation of the market.<br />

Thirdly, we also identified that we face a relative robustness of the political indicator.<br />

Dropping some events may change the coefficient of this indicator, dropping to about −0.20,<br />

but even in this case, the political indicator is still significant at a 3% threshold, testifying from<br />

robustness.<br />

Fourthly, we found that positive events have on average a bigger (negative) net impact on<br />

the BEL20 than negative events (positive impact). The impact of positive events is about −0.40<br />

percentage point and is very significant, while that of negative events is about 0.12 percentage<br />

point but this result is not significant at a 10% threshold.<br />

Fifthly, data shows that the market reacts to a lesser extent to less important political events<br />

than to the most meaningful ones.<br />

Sixthly, the rating dummy used in the analysis is robust as well, since replacing it by an<br />

alternative indicator does not fundamentally change its significance, nor does it substantially<br />

affect the coefficient of the other regressors of the model.<br />

Last but not least, we find that the BEL20 index daily return over the period of analysis<br />

bears the properties of financial time series found in similar previous literature. In particular,<br />

(i) the daily returns are independent and identically distributed with a zero-mean and (ii) the<br />

disturbance of the simple least squares models used show significant serial correlation, which<br />

implies that an autoregressive process would better fit the data. We now turn to the extensions,<br />

where we use such a process to model the volatility of the BEL20 daily returns.<br />

85 Let us remember that the adjusted R 2 , contrary to the R 2 , takes into account the number of regressors. In<br />

other words, if an independent variable added as a regressor does not significantly improve the explanation of the<br />

fluctuations of the dependent variable, then the adusted R 2 would decrease (while the R 2 can only increase).<br />

86 The significance threshold of this indicator is 1.4%.


56<br />

5.3 Extensions<br />

“A politician needs the ability to foretell what is going to happen tomorrow, next week, next month,<br />

and next year. And to have the ability afterwards to explain why it didn’t happen.”<br />

Winston Churchill, 1965<br />

This section enlarges the scope of the <strong>thesis</strong> in different respects. We analyse topics that<br />

are more advanced than the simple previous regressions, which mainly consisted of using the<br />

basic econometric tools through a dummy variable event study. This section is an interesting<br />

complement to the analysis conducted so far, as it reaches slightly different conclusions, by<br />

using more sophisticated tools. We start by verifying if our data has a unit root, a necessary<br />

step before being able to investigate the three models of interest for these extensions. These<br />

models, that we review in turn, are the error correction model, and two augmented versions of<br />

the autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity model: one linear in its parameters and the<br />

other logarithmic, allowing thereby more flexibility of the fit.<br />

5.3.1 Testing for unit root<br />

In section 5.2.5, we briefly mentioned the rationale for unit root testing. Let us investigate it<br />

here in more detail. We first introduce the necessary concepts for a complete understanding of<br />

the model; then we proceed to an augmented version of a Dickey-Fuller (DF) test.<br />

Stationarity, for a time series, is the attribute of remaining constant over time. In econometrics,<br />

a time series is stationary if its mean, its variance and its autocorrelation do not change<br />

when they are shifted in time.<br />

If a time series is not stationary, then it can be differentiated until it is made approximately<br />

stationary. The degree of integration (introduced by Granger (1981)) can be understood as follows;<br />

if a time series needs to be differentiated d times to be made approximately stationary, then its<br />

degree of integration is d. In order to check for cointegration and to apply an autoregressive<br />

conditional heteroskedasticity model, it first needs to be verified that our data is stationary or if<br />

it needs to be integrated.<br />

Testing for unit root consists of testing if a shock at time t has an impact not only at time t,<br />

but also in the following periods. In other words, it tests if the series takes some time to adjust<br />

(if it ever does). For example, the daily closing price of the BEL20 index over the period we<br />

analyse in this <strong>thesis</strong> is found to have a unit root 87 , in other words, the price of the index is<br />

largely dependent on its value the day before and does not bounce back after a shock, which<br />

seems very intuitive.<br />

A series has a unit root if and only if β = 1 in equation 5.13 (page 48). We have already seen<br />

that under the simple specification of equation 5.13, the return on the BEL20 index does not<br />

have a unit root. However, this model was not dynamically complete, since it did not take into<br />

account the values of every previous return in the series. A dynamically complete model would<br />

follow a Dickey-Fuller distribution and unit root for this distribution can be tested through a<br />

Dickey-Fuller test, as established by Dickey and Fuller (1979).<br />

We proceed to a more recent version of this test, called an augmented DF-GLS 88 test, a<br />

model that was suggested by Elliott et al. (1996). The DF-GLS test is applied with 1 to k<br />

lags, where k is selected by the Schwert Criterion (see Schwert (1989)). This test consists of<br />

estimating a regression of the following equation:<br />

∆y t = α + βy t−1 + δt + ζ 1 ∆y t−1 + ... + ζ k ∆y t−k + u t (5.15)<br />

87 To be exact, we cannot reject the hypo<strong>thesis</strong> of the presence of a unit root.<br />

88 Acronym for “Dickey–Fuller Generalised Least Squares”.


57<br />

where ∆ represents the change from one period to the next and y is the variable whose unit root<br />

we want to test. Then, we test the null hypo<strong>thesis</strong> that y t has a unit root against the alternative<br />

hypo<strong>thesis</strong> that β = δ = ζ 1 = ... = ζ k = 0, in other words, that y t follows a random walk.<br />

Proceeding to this test with our data shows that the results are highly significant (1%<br />

threshold) for each of the 1 to 17 lags selected by the Schwert criterion, which means that the<br />

null hypo<strong>thesis</strong> is rejected. Therefore, even a dynamically complete model evidences that the<br />

daily return on the BEL20 index does not have a unit root. In other words, it follows a random<br />

walk.<br />

This absence of a unit root confirms that the data do not need to be differentiated before<br />

applying the autoregressive models of the coming sections. Understanding stationarity is also<br />

key for the application of the error correction model, to which we now turn.<br />

5.3.2 Error correction model<br />

An error correction model allows us to identify both the long-term and the short-term trends of<br />

a time series. As a complement to the analysis of section 5.2, it would be interesting to have<br />

statistical evidence suggesting whether the impact of political events has a long-term effect or if<br />

it is only short-term. The model of this section was first established for two time series that are<br />

cointegrated, but it can also be applied to stationary time series (according to authors that we<br />

will cite), and to more than two series. In this section, we review in turn the original model of<br />

error correction, then argue why it can be applied for stationary data and finally, we present an<br />

augmented version of the model: the vector error correction model (VECM), which consists of<br />

using more than one independent variable. Ultimately we are able to gain some insights into the<br />

short-term/long-term components of our independent variables.<br />

Error correction model for cointegrated time series (original model)<br />

As Engle and Granger (1987) established, for two or more time series x t , if it is possible to find<br />

a linear combination α ′ x t that is stationary, then “the time series x t are said to be cointegrated<br />

with cointegrating vector α”. In other words, if these series have a degree of integration 1<br />

(i.e. they are “first-order integrated”) while there exists a vector of coefficents that can form<br />

a stationary linear combination of them, then the series are cointegrated. And cointegration<br />

implies, in short-term dynamics, the need to use an error correction model.<br />

In their paper, Engle and Granger (1987) suggested a model of error correction for cointegrated<br />

time series. This Engle-Granger model is defined in two steps and needs all data to be previously<br />

made stationary. The first step consists of a simple regression of the control variable (denoted<br />

X in the following equations), for which we isolate the residuals:<br />

The residuals are given by:<br />

Y t = α + βX t + ɛ t (5.16)<br />

ɛ t = Y t − βX t − α (5.17)<br />

The second step consists of a regression of the change in Y on the lagged change in X and the<br />

lagged errors:<br />

where<br />

∆Y t = β 0 + β 1 ∆X t−1 − γɛ t−1 + u t (5.18)


58<br />

• β 1 captures the short-term effect of X t−1 on Y t . In other words, the short term effect of<br />

the regressor one period before t on the dependent variable in period t.<br />

• γ captures the rate of adjustment of the system, in response to a shock. Since it measures<br />

how fast the errors of the model are corrected over time (which gave its name to the<br />

model), it can thus be understood as the “speed of error correction”.<br />

• u t are the disturbances of the model.<br />

Error correction model for stationary data<br />

Econometricians using stationary data may want to know what the short-term and long-term<br />

effects of their independent variables are and therefore they may want to use an error correction<br />

model for stationary data (and not just for integrated data). Whether the error correction<br />

model can be applied to stationary data has been at the core of many debates (see Beck (1992),<br />

Beck (1993) and Durr (1993) 89 ). Keele and De Boef (2005) 90 devote particular attention to the<br />

topic and find empirical evidence that this model remains valid even for stationary data. We<br />

follow his approach: we proceed to an error correction model with our data and assume that<br />

the results of this model are correct, even though the current debate on the topic is not clear<br />

whether this approach is justified.<br />

Vector error correction model<br />

The vector error correction model (VECM) is based on the approach of Engle and Granger<br />

(1987), but uses a vector of independent variables instead of only one regressor. This approach<br />

has one main drawback; since there is only one long-term coefficient, this coefficient reflects<br />

the long-term effect of all independent variables taken together. The long-term coefficient<br />

can therefore not always be interpreted properly. However, the significance of the short-term<br />

coefficient of each independent variable indicates if the corresponding variable has any significant<br />

short-term effect or not on the dependent variable. If it does not, then we can assume that the<br />

impact of the regressor is mainly long-term. If it does, then we can assume that it has some<br />

effect in the short-term but we cannot say anything about its long-term effect.<br />

Adapting the approach of Engle and Granger (1987), the first step (equation 5.16) needs<br />

only to be adjusted for a vector:<br />

where<br />

Y t = α + βX t + ɛ t (5.19)<br />

ɛ t = Y t − βX t − α (5.20)<br />

• X t represents the vector of all the independent variables of the model.<br />

For our analysis, we first isolate the residuals of equation 5.12 (page 46).<br />

89 It is worth mentioning that all of these papers have been published in the same journal: Political Analysis.<br />

90 It is worth mentioning that this reference is a working paper and has, therefore, never been published.


59<br />

where<br />

The second step, using our independent variables, is formalised as follows:<br />

∆{BEL20 return} t = β 0 +β 1 ∆{Main P olitical indicator} t−1<br />

+β 2 ∆{Euro Stoxx 50 return} t−1<br />

+β 3 ∆{Euro Stoxx 50 return} 2 t−1<br />

+β 4 ∆{Rating dummy} t−1<br />

+β 5 ∆{Y ield on government bonds} t−1<br />

+β 6 ∆{P redictability indicator} t−1<br />

+β 7 ∆{Euribor change} t−1<br />

+β 8 ∆{Money growth} t−1<br />

+γɛ t−1 + u t (5.21)<br />

• β i captures the short-term effect of the corresponding i’s regressor.<br />

• γ captures the long-term effect of all regressors combined.<br />

The results of equation 5.21 are reported in table 5.17 91 .<br />

Table 5.17: Vector error correction model, with the residuals corrected for heteroskedasticity.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

∆{Main P olitical indicator} t−1 0.512 ∗ (0.233)<br />

∆{Euro Stoxx 50 return} t−1 -0.312 ∗∗ (0.054)<br />

∆{Euro Stoxx 50 return} 2 t−1 -0.013 (0.018)<br />

∆{Rating dummy} t−1 1.458 ∗ (0.633)<br />

∆{Y ield on government bonds} t−1 0.042 ∗∗ (0.015)<br />

∆{P redictabilityindicator} t−1 -0.038 (0.124)<br />

∆{Euribor change} t−1 0.028 (0.129)<br />

∆{Money growth} t−1 0.063 (0.216)<br />

Lagged residuals of equation 5.19 -1.366 ∗∗ (0.261)<br />

Intercept -0.004 (0.087)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

What table 5.17 suggests is primarily that some of the regressors have long-term effects<br />

(since the coefficient for the lagged residuals is highly significant). Secondly, it also indicates that<br />

the square of the Euro Stoxx 50 daily returns, the estimator of the predictability, the changes in<br />

the Euribor and the growth of M3 seem not to have significant short-term effects. Finally, it<br />

suggests that political events, the returns of the Euro Stoxx 50, the change in rating of the main<br />

rating companies and the changes in the yield on government bonds have short-term effects on<br />

the return of the BEL20. It does not, however, erradicate the possibility that these variables<br />

also have a long-term effect: we just cannot draw any conclusions about it from this model.<br />

91 This regression, initially largely subject to heteroskedasticity of the residuals, has been corrected and is robust<br />

to any arbitrary form of heteroskedasticity.


60<br />

5.3.3 Generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity model<br />

Variance is a measure of volatility. As Engle (1982) mentions, “[i]n financial theory, the variance<br />

as well as the mean of the rate of return are determinants of portfolio decisions”. Moreover, if<br />

the disturbances of a standard regression at time t are found to be correlated with those at time<br />

t − 1, then we are in a situation of autocorrelation. In such a case, the standard errors (and<br />

thus the variance as well) are likely to be biased downward, thus affecting the significance of the<br />

results. Correctly identifying the variance is, therefore, crucial.<br />

Rationale of the GARCH model<br />

Traditional econometric models, such as those we have used above (ordinary least squares and<br />

two-stage least squares) assume that the disturbances are independent and identically distributed<br />

(IID). It implies that the variance of the regression is constant over time (i.e. the residuals<br />

are homoskedastic). However, this assumption was found to be “very strongly” rejected by<br />

Hsieh (1991) for stock returns. In the 1980s, models releasing this IID implausible assumption<br />

were established. In particular the autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity model (ARCH),<br />

introduced by Engle (1982), enables a fraction of the variance to change over time, as a function<br />

of its past disturbances. This fraction is called the conditional variance. The rest of the variance,<br />

the unconditional variance, remains constant. With an ARCH model, the variance can, therefore,<br />

learn from its history and adjust over time 92 . Bollerslev (1986) generalised the approach of<br />

Engle (introducing the generalised ARCH or GARCH model), by allowing the variance to be<br />

not only a function of the past disturbances, but also a function of its own past values.<br />

We believe that it is likely that our data are subject to conditional heteroskedasticity because,<br />

several authors find evidence of such heteroskedasticity in daily asset price returns (notably<br />

Bollerslev (1986) and Hsieh (1991) but also 93 Theodossiou (1994), Koutmos and Theodossiou<br />

(1994) and Lobo and Tufte (1998)). In addition, Pynnönen (2005) establishes that ARCH-like<br />

models (in particular the GARCH model) are a better approach to represent the volatility of<br />

stock returns 94 . Indeed, these models are white noise processes, implying non-autocorrelated<br />

residuals (E(ɛ t |ɛ t−1 ) = 0).<br />

It seems also worth mentioning two other interesting qualities of ARCH processes for our<br />

analysis. Firstly, the daily returns of stocks are often subject to leptokurtic distributions (see<br />

the frequence distribution of the daily BEL20 returns over the period of analysis on figure A.2,<br />

page 82), i.e. fat-tailed data, common for stock returns, that an ARCH-like process can correct<br />

(Hsieh (1991)). Secondly, ARCH-like models also capture the effects of variables that would<br />

have been omitted in the estimated model.<br />

In this section, we apply a GARCH model to our results in order to have a relevant measure<br />

of the volatility.<br />

Application of a GARCH model<br />

As we saw previously, if the returns are stationary, then a GARCH process correctly generates<br />

data. We know, since section 5.3.1, that the daily returns of the BEL20 index is stationary. We<br />

can therefore apply the GARCH model without further consideration. This model will reveal if<br />

the variance of the residuals of the models used in section 5.2 were correctly specified. Let us<br />

92 This model, therefore, solves the problem of volatility clustering found in financial data by Mandelbrot (1963).<br />

As he claimed: “large changes tend to be followed by large changes, of either sign, and small changes tend to be<br />

followed by small changes”.<br />

93 The following authors are cited by Bernhard and Leblang (2006), page 185.<br />

94 However, the model also has limitations. As Gregory and Reeves (2010) note, ARCH models do not<br />

appropriately capture extreme movements of data, such as crashes of the stock market.


61<br />

start with a definition of autoregressive models and the theoretical specification of the model<br />

before applying it.<br />

Box and Jenkins (1970) define an autoregressive model in the following way: it is the<br />

expression of the value of a process at time t as a linear function of its previous values and of a<br />

shock. Formally, it can be expressed as:<br />

where<br />

ỹ t = φ 1 ỹ t−1 + φ 2 ỹ t−2 + ... + φ p ỹ t−p + a t (5.22)<br />

• ỹ is the deviation of the dependent variable y from its mean µ: ỹ = y − µ,<br />

• a t is an exogenous shock happening at time t,<br />

• φ v is the estimated coefficient attributed to the lagged deviation of the dependent variable<br />

at time t − v.<br />

The basic generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity model estimates the<br />

following equation:<br />

Where<br />

{BEL20 return} t = βX t + ɛ t (5.23)<br />

V ar(ɛ t ) = σ 2 t = γ 0 + A(σ t , ɛ t ) + B(σ t , ɛ t ) 2 (5.24)<br />

• βX t is the vector of control variables and their respective coefficient,<br />

• γ 0 is a constant in the model of the residuals’ variance,<br />

• A() and B() are functions that are added to an OLS regression 95 and that depend on σ t<br />

and ɛ t ,<br />

• ɛ t is the vector of residuals of equation 5.23 and<br />

• σ t is the vector of the standard deviations of the residuals ɛ t , at time t.<br />

This regression on our data gives us the results reported in table 5.18. The upper part of the<br />

table is the estimation of the impact of each regressor on the BEL20 index return. It corresponds<br />

to the analysis we made in 5.2, but using a different measure of the volatility. This volatility<br />

is given by the last three lines of the table, which fit the conditional variance estimate, as a<br />

function of its own lag and of a lag of the disturbance. It can be summarised as the following<br />

formula:<br />

where<br />

• ω is the intercept,<br />

• q is the order of the ARCH term ɛ 2 ,<br />

q∑<br />

p∑<br />

σt 2 = ω + α i ɛ 2 t−1 + β i σt−1 2 (5.25)<br />

i=1<br />

i=1<br />

• α i is the coefficient of the lagged squared disturbance of equation 5.23, which corresponds<br />

to L.arch in table 5.18,<br />

95 If A() = B() = 0, then the model is a simple linear regression.


62<br />

• p is the order of the GARCH term σ 2 and<br />

• β i is the coefficient of the lagged variance, which corresponds to L.garch in table 5.18.<br />

“GARCH(1,1) [i.e. the model used here] has been found to capture adequately stock return<br />

volatility” (Pynnönen (2005)).<br />

Table 5.18: Generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity regression.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Equation 1 : BEL20 return<br />

Main political indicator -0.153 (0.117)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.799 ∗∗ (0.012)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.002 (0.003)<br />

Rating variable -0.497 ∗ (0.243)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.009 † (0.005)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.040 † (0.021)<br />

Euribor change 0.074 † (0.039)<br />

Money growth -0.020 (0.014)<br />

Intercept -0.076 † (0.041)<br />

Equation 2 : ARCH<br />

L.arch 0.243 ∗∗ (0.063)<br />

L.garch 0.442 ∗∗ (0.133)<br />

Intercept 0.072 ∗∗ (0.024)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

The results of table 5.18 can be interpreted as follows. The conditional variance is given by<br />

equation 5.26, whose estimated coefficients (given by the second equation), the intercept, the<br />

ARCH term and the GARCH term, have been added to the theoretical equation 5.25.<br />

σ 2 t = 0.072 + 0.243ɛ 2 t−1 + 0.442σ 2 t−1 (5.26)<br />

All three coefficients of this equation are highly significant, as table 5.18 shows. The<br />

conditional variance therefore increases with time, which evidences that our previous models (the<br />

simple OLS and 2SLS used in section 5.2) were too simplistic. In these previously used models,<br />

the variance was incorrectly specified, which implies that the significance of the coefficient might<br />

have been exaggerated.<br />

Now that we let the residuals change over time, the coefficients of the regressors (in the upper<br />

part of table 5.18) have changed. In particular, the impact of political events on the BEL20<br />

index is smaller, in absolute value, than before, while its standard error has increased. As a<br />

consequence, the significance of the indicator has decreased. The sign of the coefficient remains<br />

the same, indicating that, even though our previous analyses are likely to have overestimated<br />

the impact of political events on the BEL20 returns, the qualitative conclusion that we drew<br />

remains valid.<br />

Even though the flexibility allowed by this model can enhance the relevancy of the analysis, it<br />

is worth noting that the GARCH model suffers from some drawbacks. As Nelson (1991) presents,<br />

the GARCH model’s assumptions are sometimes violated and analysing the long-term effect of<br />

shocks with this model is not easy, since the usual measures of persistence do not agree. We will<br />

now turn to a non-linear model that, according to Nelson (1991), “meets these objections”.


5.3.4 Exponential generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity<br />

model<br />

Hsieh (1991) investigates why stock market returns are found not to follow independent,<br />

identically distributed processes. After reviewing exogenous changes in the environment and<br />

chaotic dynamics, he finds that the reason behind this rejection is conditional heteroskedasticity.<br />

However, even though we proceeded to a GARCH model on our data, it seems not to be enough<br />

to fully capture the non-linearity of stock returns. Hsieh (1991) uses a model more flexible than<br />

the ARCH or GARCH models and which accommodates the nonlinearity of stock returns better:<br />

the exponential generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity model (or EGARCH).<br />

Rationale of the EGARCH<br />

This model is attributed to Nelson (1991) 96 , who replaced the linear dependence of the GARCH<br />

model by a logarithmic dependence. Doing so, the EGARCH allows to better fit asymmetric<br />

responses of the variance of stock returns to the direction of the dependent variable. Simply put,<br />

it allows the variance to be bigger when the return is negative than when the return is positive.<br />

This is the reason why the EGARCH model is sometimes called a “leverage” or “asymmetric”<br />

volatility model (Engle and Viktor (1993)).<br />

Formally, the conditional variance estimated by the GARCH model (equation 5.25) is now<br />

modified to fit:<br />

q∑<br />

p∑<br />

log(σt 2 ) = ω + α i ɛ 2 t−1 + β i log(σt−1) 2 (5.27)<br />

i=1<br />

where the only modification to equation 5.25 is the logarithmic fit of the variance σ 2 and of its<br />

lagged value.<br />

Using an EGARCH model seems therefore an even more flexible solution than the GARCH<br />

that we used above. This intuition is confirmed by the comparison “GARCH vs. EGARCH” of<br />

Lee and Brorsen (1997). However, Engle and Viktor (1993) find evidence that the variability of<br />

the conditional variance might be overly high when using the EGARCH model. It is not clear<br />

whether the GARCH or the EGARCH model would better reflect the reality of the Belgian stock<br />

market during the 2010-2011 political crisis. Thereafter, we present the results of an EGARCH<br />

model, using the same specifications as for the previous model.<br />

Application of an EGARCH model<br />

Table 5.19 reports the result of the application of an EGARCH model.<br />

The estimation of the volatility, according to the EGARCH model, results in this equation<br />

for the logarithmic variance of the model:<br />

i=1<br />

log(σ 2 t ) = 0.785 + 0.539ɛ 2 t−1 + 0.576log(σ 2 t−1) (5.28)<br />

As we can see, only little difference is found between the GARCH and EGARCH models,<br />

respectively table 5.18 and table 5.19. The coefficients and standard errors of the regressors are<br />

not drastically different. However, we can observe that the political indicator is now slightly more<br />

significant than with the GARCH model (it now reaches the 11% threshold), as the coefficient<br />

is bigger in absolute value and the standard error smaller. Another difference resides in the<br />

indicator of predictability 97 , which is now bigger and more significant than before.<br />

96 Nelson mentions, however, that authors before him (Pantula and Geweke) used similar models, called<br />

log-GARCH models.<br />

97 Which is a three-day lagged estimation of the variance, computed according to Parkinson (1980).<br />

63


64<br />

Table 5.19: Exponential generalised autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity regression.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Equation 1 : BEL20 return<br />

Main political indicator -0.174 (0.109)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.801 ∗∗ (0.012)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.002 (0.003)<br />

Rating variable -0.508 ∗ (0.242)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 (0.005)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.053 ∗ (0.021)<br />

Euribor change 0.066 † (0.037)<br />

Money growth -0.019 (0.014)<br />

Intercept -0.096 ∗ (0.043)<br />

Equation 2 : ARCH<br />

L.arch 0.539 ∗∗ (0.162)<br />

L.egarch 0.576 ∗∗ (0.135)<br />

Intercept -0.785 ∗∗ (0.239)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

Before summarising the results of the different models and tests investigated so far and<br />

establishing our conclusions, let us turn to some discussion about related topics that are worth<br />

mentioning and investigate some aspects that have not been raised so far.


Chapter 6<br />

Discussion<br />

In this chapter, we investigate various topics that did not belong to any of the previous sections<br />

of this paper. We dig slightly further with regard to our analysis; we give the basis for possible<br />

further investigations of our work and we invite the reader to establish his or her own critical<br />

assessment of our conclusions.<br />

Rationale for the selection of daily data<br />

One choice that we have not discussed so far is the time interval between two consecutive<br />

observations in our procedure. We chose to use daily data, but this is not the shortest interval<br />

that can be used. Indeed, Barclay and Litzenberger (1988) use intradaily observations for event<br />

studies and discuss the relevancy of using such intervals. They find that using intradaily data<br />

increases the power of statistic tests 98 . However they highlight that several methodological<br />

questions should be raised by such an approach. Campbell et al. (1997) conclude that it remains<br />

unclear whether using intradaily data is beneficial. The relevancy of our choice of using daily<br />

data therefore seems untouched.<br />

Possible bias due to uneven intervals between observations<br />

The source data that we selected is the closing price of the daily BEL20 index. The closing<br />

price of a stock reflects the price at which the last transaction of this stock was traded on a<br />

particular day. As Campbell et al. (1997) remind us, it is a common mistake to consider that<br />

the series derived from the closing price has observations that are evenly spaced (24-hour gap).<br />

In fact, if it is not the case (most of the time), then we observe a “nonsynchronous trading<br />

effect”, which results in a bias for the computation of the returns. This effect has been heavily<br />

reviewed in literature 99 but mostly concerns the analysis of one stock at a time. In the case<br />

at hand, however, the possibility for nonsynchronous trading effect is much less likely than<br />

in this literature, because we consider an index instead of a stock. The BEL20 is a real-time<br />

index, computed every 15 seconds, and including the change in the price of any of the 20 stocks<br />

composing it. Given this high regularity, it is most unlikely that our analysis suffers from a<br />

significant bias due to nonsynchronous trading effect.<br />

98 Which means that it increases the probability of rejecting the null hypo<strong>thesis</strong> if this hypo<strong>thesis</strong> is indeed<br />

wrong.<br />

99 See Campbell et al. (1997), page 85, for relevant literature about the topic. Box and Jenkins (1970) insist on<br />

this equal spacing in time condition for the GARCH model notably.<br />

65


66<br />

The normality assumption<br />

The analyses in section 5.2 are based on a model assuming that the returns are jointly normally<br />

distributed (the APT). This assumption may not be empirically verified 100 , which would imply<br />

that the results of the analysis are only asymptotic. However, as Brown and Warner (1985)<br />

discuss, in most cases, this is not considered as an issue since the statistic tests converge rapidly<br />

to their asymptotic distribution. Therefore, our results remain relevant even when we release<br />

the implausible normality assumption.<br />

The same issue has also been raised by Brown and Warner (1985) and by Berry et al. (1990),<br />

but they provide another reason why we should not be worried about it: even if the daily returns<br />

are most of the time not normally distributed, the residuals usually are. And even when the<br />

null hypo<strong>thesis</strong> of normality has to be rejected, they do not find any gain in power of using test<br />

statistics that are distribution-free.<br />

Cross-sectional dependence due to clustered events<br />

One of the possible problems of event studies is cross-sectional dependence, i.e. when events<br />

are “clustered” (issue analysed by Brown and Warner (1980)) 101 . This dependency problem<br />

disappears when events happen randomly within the event-window (Binder (1998)). In our<br />

analysis, one can see (on figure 4.2 or in the appendices) that, during the last quarter of the<br />

period of analysis, the events seem to be somehow clustered. Indeed, the agreements were<br />

reached one after the other during this period. At the same time, Moody’s placed the Belgian<br />

grade under review and S&P downgraded the country. As Brown and Warner (1980) mention,<br />

this clustering 102 affects the randomness in the selection of securities performing well. However,<br />

this is something very different to what we are doing (since we do not rely on our data to select<br />

particular securities) and therefore it does not challenge the relevancy of our approach. We<br />

considered that it was worth mentioning, though.<br />

Inconsistent coefficient estimates due to a model driven by the choices of agents<br />

The paper of Acharya (1993) about latent information in event studies mentions that “coefficient<br />

estimators in a dummy variable model are inconsistent when data on the dependent variable<br />

(stock return) are limited by the choices of agents (decision rules that trigger events)”. It seems,<br />

therefore, natural to consider whether our analysis suffers from inconsistency of the coefficient<br />

estimates, because political events may be somehow driven by the choices of the political actors.<br />

We believe that it is not the case for two reasons. Firstly, Acharya focuses on the returns of<br />

particular firms, after company-specific events, such as the announcement of a dividend. In this<br />

case, the event is indeed a choice, while for our analysis, the events that we consider are more the<br />

consequence of a process (attempts to the formation of a government). Secondly, the example of<br />

Acharya concerns one or few agents (the board of the company), while in our case, there is a<br />

multitude of agents commonly responsible for the occurence of the events. In particular there<br />

are at least the nine parties which had a role in the negotiations during the political crisis, as<br />

well as the King, the rating agencies and most likely many other institutions with an influence<br />

on the political scene. Therefore, as for the previous potential problems considered, our analysis<br />

seems not to suffer from this weakness.<br />

100 Even though, as figure A.2 (in the appendices) shows, the returns of the BEL20 index over the period of<br />

consideration seem to show an approximately normal distribution. However, one can also notice that kurtosis<br />

seem to be present in the data.<br />

101 The clustering problem is also sometimes called “Moulton problem” (Angrist and Pischke (2009)).<br />

102 Called “calendar clustering” or “event clustering” by Henderson (1990).


67<br />

Bias of the instrumental variables<br />

As Angrist and Pischke (2009) remind us, instrumental variables can sometimes be a source<br />

of bias, especially in small samples, which would imply that the estimated coefficients are<br />

not correct. The source of this common bias in empirical studies using 2SLS is due to weak<br />

instruments, that is, instruments that are not very correlated with the parameter they estimate.<br />

However, we should not worry about such a bias in our case since, as we presented earlier, the<br />

correlation between the instrumental variable and the instrumented variable is above 99%. The<br />

resulting coefficient of the regression can, therefore, be assumed to be consistent.<br />

Another way to verify the validity of our instrumental variable is to proceed to a Sargan test.<br />

It consists of testing the overidentifying restrictions, or in other words to testing if the instruments<br />

are correlated to the residuals and therefore if we can rely on them as good instruments. To<br />

proceed to this test, we (i) isolate the residuals ɛ t of equation 5.12, (ii) fit the same regression<br />

but replacing BEL20 return t by ɛ t and (iii) verify if any of the regressors are significant.<br />

Doing so indicates that no regressor significantly explains the residuals. It therefore suggests<br />

that our instruments are correct and thus that the estimated coefficients are unbiased.<br />

Possible endogeneity of the rating variable with other regressors<br />

One problem we have not raised so far is the possibility that the rating variable has an influence<br />

on the other independent variables of the model. In other words, this dummy variable may be<br />

endogenous with the other regressors. The implication of this possibility would be that the<br />

coefficient of the dummy and of the regressors with which it is endogenous would be biased.<br />

However, as long as the rating variable is not endogenous with the political indicator, it is<br />

not a major problem for our analysis. What is of interest to us is to measure the impact of<br />

the political indicator on the fluctuations of the BEL20 daily returns, not the impact of the<br />

other variables on it, therefore, the presence of a bias due to endogeneity between two control<br />

variables should not change the conclusions of our model. After verification, the rating dummy<br />

variable is not a significant explanatory variable of the variations in our political indicator. We<br />

can, therefore, consider that the inclusion of the rating dummy variable is perfectly justified and<br />

does not bias our conclusions.<br />

Not unique maximum likelihood estimate (MLE) of the coefficient, due to the<br />

presence of dummy variables<br />

Doornik and Ooms (2008) have investigated GARCH and EGARCH models using dummy<br />

variables and find that this procedure might result in a “multimodality problem”. In such a case,<br />

the coefficient of the dummy variable, as computed by the MLE, might not be unique.<br />

What can be done to solve that problem is to simplify the specification of the problem,<br />

eliminating (at least some of) the dummy variables and to re-estimate the model. Following this<br />

procedure, we fitted other GARCH and EGARCH models, according to the same specification<br />

as in the extensions of this <strong>thesis</strong>, but without the rating dummy variable. Doing so, we may<br />

lose some accuracy (since a relevant control variable is omitted), but according to Doornik and<br />

Ooms (2008), at least our indicators would be convergent. The results obtained are interesting:<br />

the coefficient of the political indicator (β 1 ) increases and its standard error decreases, making it<br />

more significant for both the GARCH and the EGARCH model. The coefficient of the political<br />

indicator becomes 0.172 and 0.184, respectively for each of these models, and is even significant<br />

at the 10% threshold for the EGARCH model.<br />

One can notice that following this procedure yields results that are closer to the conventional<br />

least squares model. However, since we could not find many authors applying this relatively


68<br />

recent procedure, we simply indicated these results as a discussion and we did not replace the<br />

models used in the extensions. Further investigations of the paper of Doornik and Ooms (2008)<br />

are probably necessary to provide a proper summary of the relevancy of this procedure.<br />

Alternative versions of the EGARCH model<br />

The original EGARCH model established by Nelson (1991), and used in section 5.3.4, can<br />

be modified in several respects, in order to better accommodate the possible asymmetries of<br />

exogenous shocks. In particular, separate coefficients can be used for small and for large shocks.<br />

This procedure has been investigated by Wu and Xiao (2002), who use seven different versions<br />

of the EGARCH model to find the best possible fit for the conditional volatility of returns<br />

subject to shocks. Their results show that, indeed, doing so enabled them to better capture<br />

the asymmetric effect of shocks on returns. Reaching such level of precision for the conditional<br />

volatility of our model is beyond the scope of this <strong>thesis</strong> but a more advanced study of the topic<br />

could investigate these alternative EGARCH models. As we found that the impact of positive<br />

and negative political events are different from each other, the volatility is likely to respond<br />

differently as well. This approach constitutes, therefore, a possible continuation to our work.<br />

Let us now turn to other possibilities of extension of this analysis.<br />

Possible further work<br />

The simple model of this paper (section 5.2) seems rather exhaustive, since it takes into account<br />

(to the best of our knowledge) most important control variables, it corrects the weaknesses of the<br />

data and its robustness is tested in several respects. However, further work could complete this<br />

<strong>thesis</strong>. Firstly, our models do not take into account the news about the future macroeconomic<br />

situation that is known by the public but not contained within the variables used at the time<br />

of the analysis. Analysing that kind of events was not our purpose, but their inclusion in the<br />

analysis is clearly a first possible broadening of our work.<br />

Secondly, we introduced relevant extensions to this simple model, but the analysis that we<br />

provided in section 5.3, extensions, is not exhaustive. Indeed, other models (even if we believe<br />

that they are less relevant than those we used) could provide a complementary analysis of the<br />

topic. Verifying whether their results are in line with what we found would be another way to<br />

evaluate the robustness of our conclusions.<br />

Thirdly, as we have mentioned in the literature review, most papers finding significant results<br />

about the topic were done in periods of political instability. As another way to check the<br />

robustness of this paper, it would be interesting to see how much political events affect the stock<br />

market in periods of political stability. Such additional work would allow us to derive conclusions<br />

about whether the causality relationship between political events and the stock market was<br />

affected by the fact that the country had no federal government during the period of analysis.<br />

Fourthly, the robustness of our findings could also be tested further by analysing other<br />

political crises in Belgium. Fortunately for the researcher interested in the topic, Belgium<br />

provides many other political crises to analyse, even though they are not as long as the 2010-2011<br />

one. In particular, in 2007, 194 days were necessary to form a government in Belgium. Proceeding<br />

to a similar analysis, but over this period, would be a good way to confirm (or not) the relevance<br />

of our results.<br />

Fifthly, as Pynnönen (2005) showed, an “abnormal return” analysis is equivalent to a dummy<br />

variable event study, under certain conditions (non-overlapping event windows). Analysing the<br />

Belgian political crisis of 2010-2011 following the classical abnormal return analysis could be<br />

interesting to test further the robustness of our analysis and to verify if the two methods are<br />

indeed similar, as Pynnönen (2005) claims theoretically.


As a final word about these possible further works, we would like to mention that even<br />

though some more results could certainly be found from these extensions, it is likely that they<br />

would be of only little added-value compared to the conclusions that we reached in this <strong>thesis</strong>.<br />

Let us now present them.<br />

69


Chapter 7<br />

Conclusion<br />

The political history of Belgium has shown how two very different communities could be<br />

held together, by means of agreements and reforms. As Flanders prospered, the claims of its<br />

inhabitants became increasingly more constraining, requiring successive governments to modify<br />

the political structure of Belgium, which eventually became exceedingly complex. Craving more<br />

independence over the past decades and taking advantage of its recently acquired economic<br />

prosperity, Flanders successfully obtained larger competences, draining the power from the<br />

federal state to the regional level. At the same time, the Europeanisation process weakened the<br />

Belgian federal state as other competences were relinquished to the supranational level. The<br />

national issues grew in importance, casting doubts on the existence of a Belgian identity for the<br />

inhabitants. The governments stalemated one after the other on the increasingly problematic<br />

community disagreements. It is against this background that the Belgian political crisis 2010-2011<br />

took place. Eventually, Belgium endured the world’s longest period in recent history as a state<br />

without a federal government. It was our purpose to analyse this period through a stock market<br />

approach.<br />

Our political event study was based on multiple models, very common in financial econometrics,<br />

which showed interesting and significant causal relationships between the political<br />

events which drove the Belgian political crisis and the fluctuations of the stock market over this<br />

period. We detailed each model and provided the results of intermediary steps, so as to let the<br />

reader evaluate the relevancy of each component of it. We started with a basic ordinary least<br />

squares model, which we corrected for endogeneity of the political indicator, therefore applying<br />

a two-stage least squares procedure. Once augmented with relevant macroeconomic variables 103 ,<br />

the model was corrected for the heteroskedasticity of its residuals. Different robustness tests<br />

were performed in order to challenge the relevancy of the significant results found. Then, we<br />

extended the procedure to more sophisticated models, including error correction and autoregressive<br />

conditional heteroskedasticity models 104 . The plurality of models within the analysis was<br />

interesting as it let us take some distance with the topic by analysing different views of the same<br />

data. Hereafter, we summarise our conclusions, but we remain open to the possibility of further<br />

improvement of the models used and therefore of the results. Let us also remember that these<br />

conclusions are context-specific. We do not claim that they are applicable to any political crisis<br />

situation, even though we believe, given the robustness of the indicators, that similar contexts<br />

are likely to yield, to some extent, similar results.<br />

In our main model, using a two-stage least squares procedure, we gave robust evidence that<br />

103 The problem of the presence of an economic crisis simultaneously with the political crisis was solved through<br />

the addition of these variables to the model.<br />

104 In particular, we proceed to a VECM, to a GARCH model and to an EGARCH model.<br />

70


71<br />

the main political events had a highly significant impact 105 on the fluctuations of the main<br />

Belgian stock index, the BEL20. This result is relatively free of endogeneity, of anticipatory<br />

movements and of heteroskedasticity of the residuals. As we extensively argued, every control<br />

variable used seems relevant to the analysis, therefore enhancing the accuracy of the political<br />

indicator. The political indicator shows a negative relationship between the political events and<br />

the stock market fluctuations: it reacts positively to negative events and negatively to positive<br />

events. By “positive event”, we mean events that are favourable to the establishment of a fully<br />

empowered government and therefore to the end of the political crisis. Similarly, by “negative<br />

event”, we mean events that are unfavourable to it. The average reaction of the stock market<br />

to a meaningful political event is about 0.24 percentage points, but the reaction is different<br />

depending on the type of event. For positive events, the average (negative) reaction amounts<br />

about 0.40 percentage points while for negative events, the (positive) reaction reaches only about<br />

0.12 percentage points and is therefore much less significant.<br />

Further specifications of the model showed that dropping some of the key-events of the<br />

crisis did not make the indicator lose its high significance, which testified to its robustness.<br />

We also found that the market seemed to fully react to a political event on the exact date of<br />

the event: no significant anticipatory or lagged movement could be found. In addition, we<br />

provided evidence that the market reacts more importantly to more meaningful political events<br />

than to less meaningful ones. As an extension to our main model, we investigated a vector<br />

error correction model which seemed to indicate that the events had a significant short-term<br />

impact on the Belgian stock returns, but we cannot eliminate the possibility that part of the<br />

impact has long-term consequences. As the time series of the BEL20 daily returns seemed to<br />

be characterised by the same shape and features as usual financial time series, we used models<br />

designed to better fit such series. The autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity models used<br />

showed that the coefficient and significance of our indicator might have been exagerated by the<br />

more conventional models, but the direction of the shocks (the negative sign) was validated.<br />

Finally, let us now suggest a possible interpretation of these results. Based on the evidence<br />

we found, we believe that the stock market progressively and smoothly anticipates the political<br />

events, and even overanticipates them. Then, on the day of the event, the market adjustment is<br />

negative, as a response to the overanticipation. The results of the many tests and regressions to<br />

which we proceeded are in line with this interpretation. However, despite the significance and<br />

robustness of the results reached, we cannot argue that these conclusions apply to countries other<br />

than Belgium. As we saw in the literature review, authors find different results for other parts<br />

of the world and during different periods. The Belgian case seems, therefore, very particular, if<br />

not unique.<br />

A topic such as this one can never be fully investigated. Further work is always possible to<br />

understand it more completely. However, we believe that we have provided a relevant analysis,<br />

addressing the main problems of the subject matter and using appropriated approaches to model<br />

it. We have sketched some ideas for possible further investigations, in the discussions of this<br />

<strong>thesis</strong>.<br />

Political event studies are, unfortunately, underexploited in econometric literature. “Standing<br />

on the shoulders of giant” is only possible to a limited extent in this field, because these studies<br />

do not seem to be built on one another, but only on a restrained set of papers. We believe,<br />

though, in the high potential value of political event studies, as it can help investors to refine<br />

their expectations of the financial markets.<br />

We would like to end with a word about the political crisis. As Gordon Brown puts it when<br />

referring to the recent financial crisis: “[s]ometimes it’s a crisis that forces change. The world<br />

105 The coefficient of our political indicator reaches almost the 1% threshold, implying that the hypo<strong>thesis</strong> that<br />

the coefficient is equal to zero is strongly rejected.


72<br />

that emerges out of the economic and financial crisis of 2007-2010 won’t be the same. The<br />

banking and finance system will be based on sounder principles. There is a huge opportunity<br />

over the next 10 or 20 years (to improve things)” 106 . We believe that a similar school of thought<br />

applies to the Belgian political crisis. The reform resulting from the crisis has certainly given<br />

more power to the federated entities of Belgium. But the objective is not holding a bigger share<br />

of power, the objective is to efficientely share it, in order to have a country “based on sounder<br />

principles”. The 2010-2011 crisis was far from being the first political crisis of Belgium and it<br />

will probably not be the last. However, we hope that this crisis raised awareness for all Belgians,<br />

about the common outlook for the future that they all share.<br />

106 Cited in Benedikter (2011).


Appendices<br />

73


Number of non-zero observations: 4 10 13 23 23 40 46 46 75<br />

Proportion of non-zero observations: 0.93% 2.33% 3.02% 5.35% 5.35% 9.30% 10.70% 10.70% 17.44%<br />

74<br />

Day<br />

Event<br />

Value<br />

Mon 19 Apr 10 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 20 Apr 10 April 20: J.-L. Dehaene considers his mission finished. 2 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

Wed 21 Apr 10 3 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1<br />

April 22: Alexander de Croo ( Open VLD) leaves the<br />

Thu 22 Apr 10<br />

government.<br />

4 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Fri 23 Apr 10 5 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

April 26: the King Albert II accepts the government's<br />

Mon 26 Apr 10<br />

resignation.<br />

6 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Tue 27 Apr 10 7 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

Wed 28 Apr 10 8 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

April 29: the Flemish parties start examining BHV. A<br />

Thu 29 Apr 10 motion is filed by French-speaking parties, triggering 9 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

the alarm.<br />

Fri 30 Apr 10 10 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

Mon 3 May 10 11 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 4 May 10 12 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 5 May 10 13 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 6 May 10 14 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 7 May 10 15 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 10 May 10 16 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 11 May 10 17 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 12 May 10 18 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 13 May 10 19 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 14 May 10 20 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 17 May 10 21 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 18 May 10 22 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 19 May 10 23 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 20 May 10 24 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 21 May 10 25 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 24 May 10 26 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 25 May 10 27 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 26 May 10 28 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 27 May 10 29 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 28 May 10 30 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 31 May 10 31 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 1 Jun 10 32 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 2 Jun 10 33 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 3 Jun 10 34 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 4 Jun 10 35 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 7 Jun 10 36 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 8 Jun 10 37 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 9 Jun 10 38 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 10 Jun 10 39 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 11 Jun 10 40 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 14 Jun 10 June 13: federal legislative elections. 41 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Tue 15 Jun 10 42 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

Wed 16 Jun 10 43 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

June 17: Bart De Wever wins the elections. He is<br />

Thu 17 Jun 10<br />

appointed as informateur.<br />

44 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

Fri 18 Jun 10 45 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1<br />

Mon 21 Jun 10 46 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 22 Jun 10 47 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 23 Jun 10 48 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 24 Jun 10 49 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 25 Jun 10 50 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 28 Jun 10 51 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 29 Jun 10 52 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 30 Jun 10 53 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Rating dummy<br />

Significant positive event<br />

Significant negative event<br />

Main political indicator<br />

Significant event dummy<br />

All political events<br />

Main political indicator 2<br />

Significant event dummy 2<br />

All political events 2


75<br />

Thu 1 Jul 10 54 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 2 Jul 10 55 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 5 Jul 10 56 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 6 Jul 10 57 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 7 Jul 10 58 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

July 8: Bart De Wever gives up. Elio Di Rupo is put in<br />

Thu 8 Jul 10<br />

charge of forming a government.<br />

59 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1<br />

Fri 9 Jul 10 60 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

Mon 12 Jul 10 61 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 13 Jul 10 62 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 14 Jul 10 63 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 15 Jul 10 64 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 16 Jul 10 65 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 19 Jul 10 66 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 20 Jul 10 67 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 21 Jul 10 68 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 22 Jul 10 69 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 23 Jul 10 70 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 26 Jul 10 71 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 27 Jul 10 72 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 28 Jul 10 73 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 29 Jul 10 74 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 30 Jul 10 75 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 2 Aug 10 76 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 3 Aug 10 77 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 4 Aug 10 78 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 5 Aug 10 79 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 6 Aug 10 80 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 9 Aug 10 81 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 10 Aug 10 82 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 11 Aug 10 83 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 12 Aug 10 84 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 13 Aug 10 85 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 16 Aug 10 86 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 17 Aug 10 87 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 18 Aug 10 88 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 19 Aug 10 89 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 20 Aug 10 90 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 23 Aug 10 91 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 24 Aug 10 92 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 25 Aug 10 93 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 26 Aug 10 94 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 27 Aug 10 95 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

August 29: refusal of Di Rupo's resignation by the<br />

Mon 30 Aug 10<br />

King.<br />

96 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Tue 31 Aug 10 97 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

Wed 1 Sep 10 98 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 2 Sep 10 99 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 3 Sep 10 September 3: Di Rupo openly accepts his failure. 100 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

September 4: the King accepts Di Rupo's<br />

Mon 6 Sep 10 101 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

resignation. Pieters and Flahaut are put in charge.<br />

Tue 7 Sep 10 102 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

Wed 8 Sep 10 103 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 9 Sep 10 104 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 10 Sep 10 105 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 13 Sep 10 106 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 14 Sep 10 107 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 15 Sep 10 108 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 16 Sep 10 109 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 17 Sep 10 110 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 20 Sep 10 111 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 21 Sep 10 112 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 22 Sep 10 113 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 23 Sep 10 114 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 24 Sep 10 115 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 27 Sep 10 116 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 28 Sep 10 117 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 29 Sep 10 118 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 30 Sep 10 119 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0


Fri 1 Oct 10 120 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

October 4: press conference of the N-VA, unilaterally<br />

Mon 4 Oct 10 121 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

interrupting the negotiations with seven parties.<br />

October 5: the King relieves Flahaut and Pieters from<br />

Tue 5 Oct 10<br />

their mission.<br />

122 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1<br />

Wed 6 Oct 10 123 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 7 Oct 10 124 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 8 Oct 10 October 8: De Wever becomes clarifier.<br />

125 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 11 Oct 10 126 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 12 Oct 10 127 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 13 Oct 10 128 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 14 Oct 10 129 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 15 Oct 10 130 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 18 Oct 10 October 18: Bart De Wever: “fabula acta est”. 131 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Tue 19 Oct 10 132 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

Wed 20 Oct 10 133 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

October 21: Johan Vande Lanotte is designated as<br />

Thu 21 Oct 10<br />

mediator.<br />

134 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Fri 22 Oct 10 135 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

Mon 25 Oct 10 136 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 26 Oct 10 137 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 27 Oct 10 138 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 28 Oct 10 139 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 29 Oct 10 140 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 1 Nov 10 141 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 2 Nov 10 142 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 3 Nov 10 143 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 4 Nov 10 144 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 5 Nov 10 145 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 8 Nov 10 146 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 9 Nov 10 147 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 10 Nov 10 148 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 11 Nov 10 149 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 12 Nov 10 150 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 15 Nov 10 151 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 16 Nov 10 152 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 17 Nov 10 153 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 18 Nov 10 154 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 19 Nov 10 155 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 22 Nov 10 156 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 23 Nov 10 157 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 24 Nov 10 158 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 25 Nov 10 159 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 26 Nov 10 160 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 29 Nov 10 161 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 30 Nov 10 162 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 1 Dec 10 163 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 2 Dec 10 164 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 3 Dec 10 165 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 6 Dec 10 166 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 7 Dec 10 167 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 8 Dec 10 168 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 9 Dec 10 169 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 10 Dec 10 170 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 13 Dec 10 171 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

December 14: S&P place Belgium under negative<br />

Tue 14 Dec 10<br />

outlook and threaten it with a downgrade.<br />

172 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 15 Dec 10 173 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 16 Dec 10 174 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 17 Dec 10 175 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 20 Dec 10 176 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 21 Dec 10 177 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 22 Dec 10 178 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 23 Dec 10 179 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 24 Dec 10 180 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

December 25: Belgian record of the longest political<br />

Mon 27 Dec 10<br />

crisis.<br />

181 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Tue 28 Dec 10 182 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

Wed 29 Dec 10 183 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 30 Dec 10 184 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 31 Dec 10 185 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

76


Mon 3 Jan 11 186 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 4 Jan 11 187 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 5 Jan 11 188 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 6 Jan 11 January 6: Vande Lanotte resigns.<br />

189 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Fri 7 Jan 11 190 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

January 8: European record of the longest political<br />

Mon 10 Jan 11<br />

crisis.<br />

191 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

January 11: the King refuses the resignation of Johan<br />

Tue 11 Jan 11<br />

Vande Lanotte.<br />

192 0 0 0 0 0 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Wed 12 Jan 11 193 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1<br />

Thu 13 Jan 11 194 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 14 Jan 11 195 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 17 Jan 11 196 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 18 Jan 11 197 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 19 Jan 11 198 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 20 Jan 11 199 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 21 Jan 11 200 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 24 Jan 11 201 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 25 Jan 11 202 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

January 26: Vande Lanotte definitely resigns. The<br />

Wed 26 Jan 11<br />

King accepts his resignation.<br />

203 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Thu 27 Jan 11 204 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

Fri 28 Jan 11 205 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 31 Jan 11 206 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 1 Feb 11 207 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

February 2: the King increases the power of the<br />

Wed 2 Feb 11 caretaker government. Didier Reynders is named 208 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1<br />

informateur.<br />

Thu 3 Feb 11 209 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

Fri 4 Feb 11 210 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 7 Feb 11 211 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 8 Feb 11 212 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 9 Feb 11 213 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 10 Feb 11 214 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 11 Feb 11 215 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 14 Feb 11 216 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 15 Feb 11 217 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

February 16: the King increases the length of Reynders'<br />

Wed 16 Feb 11 218 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1<br />

mission, allowing him to hand in a more detailed report.<br />

Thu 17 Feb 11 219 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

Fri 18 Feb 11 220 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 21 Feb 11 221 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 22 Feb 11 222 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 23 Feb 11 223 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 24 Feb 11 224 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 25 Feb 11 225 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 28 Feb 11 226 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 1 Mar 11 March 1: Reynders is relieved from his mission<br />

227 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

Wed 2 Mar 11 March 2: Wouter Beke is designated as negotiator. 228 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1<br />

Thu 3 Mar 11 229 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

Fri 4 Mar 11 230 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 7 Mar 11 231 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 8 Mar 11 232 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 9 Mar 11 233 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 10 Mar 11 234 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 11 Mar 11 235 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 14 Mar 11 236 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 15 Mar 11 237 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 16 Mar 11 238 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 17 Mar 11 239 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 18 Mar 11 240 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 21 Mar 11 241 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 22 Mar 11 242 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 23 Mar 11 243 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 24 Mar 11 244 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 25 Mar 11 245 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 28 Mar 11 246 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 29 Mar 11 247 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 30 Mar 11 March 30: world record of the longest political crisis. 248 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Thu 31 Mar 11 249 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

77


78<br />

Fri 1 Apr 11 250 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 4 Apr 11 251 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 5 Apr 11 252 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 6 Apr 11 253 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 7 Apr 11 254 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 8 Apr 11 255 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 11 Apr 11 256 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 12 Apr 11 257 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 13 Apr 11 258 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 14 Apr 11 259 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 15 Apr 11 260 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 18 Apr 11 261 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 19 Apr 11 262 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 20 Apr 11 263 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 21 Apr 11 264 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

April 22: anniversary of the fall of Leterme II's<br />

Tue 26 Apr 11 government. April 26: one year without a fully<br />

265 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

empowered government.<br />

Wed 27 Apr 11 266 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1<br />

Thu 28 Apr 11 267 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 29 Apr 11 268 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 2 May 11 269 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 3 May 11 270 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 4 May 11 271 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 5 May 11 272 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 6 May 11 273 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 9 May 11 274 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 10 May 11 275 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 11 May 11 276 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

May 12: Wouter Beke asks the King to relieve him from<br />

Thu 12 May 11<br />

his duties.<br />

277 0 0 1 -1 1 -1 -1 1 -1<br />

Fri 13 May 11 278 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1 1 -1<br />

May 16: the King accepts the request of Wouter Beke,<br />

after having consulted all nine parties. Di Rupo is tasked<br />

Mon 16 May 11<br />

to be formateur with the request to take any necessary<br />

279 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

measures.<br />

Tue 17 May 11 280 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

Wed 18 May 11 281 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 19 May 11 282 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 20 May 11 283 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

May 23: Fitch's outlook changes from “stable” to<br />

Mon 23 May 11<br />

“negative”.<br />

284 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 24 May 11 285 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 25 May 11 286 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 26 May 11 287 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 27 May 11 288 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 30 May 11 289 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 31 May 11 290 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 1 Jun 11 291 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 2 Jun 11 292 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 3 Jun 11 293 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 6 Jun 11 294 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 7 Jun 11 295 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 8 Jun 11 296 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 9 Jun 11 297 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 10 Jun 11 298 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 13 Jun 11 June 13: Belgium voted a year ago. 299 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

Tue 14 Jun 11 300 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1<br />

Wed 15 Jun 11 301 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 16 Jun 11 302 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 17 Jun 11 303 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 20 Jun 11 304 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 21 Jun 11 305 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 22 Jun 11 306 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 23 Jun 11 307 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 24 Jun 11 308 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 27 Jun 11 309 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 28 Jun 11 310 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 29 Jun 11 311 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 30 Jun 11 312 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0


79<br />

Fri 1 Jul 11 313 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

July 4: Di Rupo hands in a 111-page long note, based on<br />

Mon 4 Jul 11 314<br />

his meetings with all nine parties.<br />

0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1<br />

Tue 5 Jul 11 315 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

Wed 6 Jul 11 316 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 7 Jul 11 July 7: N-VA refuses to start negotiating from this note. 317 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

July 8: In reply to this refusal, Di Rupo asks the King for<br />

Fri 8 Jul 11<br />

permission to resign.<br />

318 0 0 0 0 0 -1 0 0 -1<br />

Mon 11 Jul 11 319 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 -1<br />

Tue 12 Jul 11 320 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 13 Jul 11 321 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 14 Jul 11 322 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 15 Jul 11 323 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 18 Jul 11 324 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 19 Jul 11 325 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 20 Jul 11 326 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

July 21: The CD&V agrees to start negotiating<br />

Thu 21 Jul 11<br />

without the N-VA.<br />

327 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Fri 22 Jul 11 328 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

Mon 25 Jul 11 329 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 26 Jul 11 330 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 27 Jul 11 331 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 28 Jul 11 332 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 29 Jul 11 333 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 1 Aug 11 334 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 2 Aug 11 335 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 3 Aug 11 336 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 4 Aug 11 337 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 5 Aug 11 338 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 8 Aug 11 339 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 9 Aug 11 340 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 10 Aug 11 341 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 11 Aug 11 342 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 12 Aug 11 343 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 15 Aug 11 344 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 16 Aug 11 345 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 17 Aug 11 346 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 18 Aug 11 347 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 19 Aug 11 348 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 22 Aug 11 349 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 23 Aug 11 350 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 24 Aug 11 351 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 25 Aug 11 352 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 26 Aug 11 353 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 29 Aug 11 354 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 30 Aug 11 355 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 31 Aug 11 356 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 1 Sep 11 357 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 2 Sep 11 358 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 5 Sep 11 359 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 6 Sep 11 360 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 7 Sep 11 361 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 8 Sep 11 362 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 9 Sep 11 363 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 12 Sep 11 364 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 13 Sep 11 365 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 14 Sep 11 366 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Night 14-15: agreement on the electoral district of<br />

Thu 15 Sep 11<br />

BHV.<br />

367 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Fri 16 Sep 11 368 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

Mon 19 Sep 11 369 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 20 Sep 11 370 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 21 Sep 11 371 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 22 Sep 11 372 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 23 Sep 11 373 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 26 Sep 11 September 24: agreement on the financing law. 374 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Tue 27 Sep 11 375 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

Wed 28 Sep 11 376 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 29 Sep 11 377 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 30 Sep 11 378 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0


80<br />

Mon 3 Oct 11 379 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 4 Oct 11 380 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

October 5: agreement on the judiciary district of<br />

Wed 5 Oct 11<br />

BHV.<br />

381 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Thu 6 Oct 11 382 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

October 7: Moody's decision to place Belgium's Aa1<br />

Fri 7 Oct 11<br />

rating on review for possible downgrade.<br />

383 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 10 Oct 11 October 8: global agreement. 384 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Tue 11 Oct 11 October 11: the sixth reform of the state is done. 385 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1 1<br />

Wed 12 Oct 11 386 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

October 13: Ecolo and Groen! are removed from the<br />

Thu 13 Oct 11 387 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 1<br />

negotiating table. Six parties are left to negotiate.<br />

Fri 14 Oct 11 388 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1<br />

Mon 17 Oct 11 389 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 18 Oct 11 390 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 19 Oct 11 391 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 20 Oct 11 392 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 21 Oct 11 393 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 24 Oct 11 394 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 25 Oct 11 395 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 26 Oct 11 396 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 27 Oct 11 397 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 28 Oct 11 398 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 31 Oct 11 399 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 1 Nov 11 400 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 2 Nov 11 401 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 3 Nov 11 402 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 4 Nov 11 403 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 7 Nov 11 404 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 8 Nov 11 405 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 9 Nov 11 406 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 10 Nov 11 407 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 11 Nov 11 408 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 14 Nov 11 409 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 15 Nov 11 410 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 16 Nov 11 411 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 17 Nov 11 412 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 18 Nov 11 413 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 21 Nov 11 414 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 22 Nov 11 415 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Wed 23 Nov 11 416 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Thu 24 Nov 11 417 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 25 Nov 11 November 25: S&P downgrade Belgium. 418 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 28 Nov 11 November 26: political agreement on the budget. 419 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Tue 29 Nov 11 420 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

November 30: conclusion of the governmental<br />

Wed 30 Nov 11<br />

agreement.<br />

421 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Thu 1 Dec 11 422 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

Fri 2 Dec 11 423 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 5 Dec 11 424 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 6 Dec 11 December 6: Elio Di Rupo takes the oath.<br />

425 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Wed 7 Dec 11 426 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 1<br />

Thu 8 Dec 11 427 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Fri 9 Dec 11 428 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Mon 12 Dec 11 429 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0<br />

Tue 13 Dec 11 430 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0


Figure A.1: Constituency Brussels-Halle-Vilvoorde.<br />

Source: La Libre Belgique (in de Coorebyter (2011)).


82<br />

Figure A.2: Frequency distribution of the daily returns of the BEL20<br />

over the period: April 19, 2010 - December 13, 2011.<br />

Source: own computation, based on Datastream data.<br />

The returns on financial assets usually do not follow a normal distribution. Akgiray<br />

and Booth (1987) investigated the topic in more detail 107 , reporting that stock returns,<br />

as other financial assets, are leptokurtic (higher peaks around the mean and larger tails).<br />

Similar results can be found in Mandelbrot (1963) and Fama (1965). This kurtosis<br />

problem can be partially solved by ARCH-like processes, as Hsieh (1991) develops, which<br />

explains why these models represent better financial time series.<br />

107 Cited in Cheung and Lai (1993).


83<br />

Table A.1: Final results of the main model, corrected for endogeneity and<br />

heteroskedasticity: 2SLS regression, using a generated instrumental variable for<br />

the political indicator.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator, free of endogeneity -0.240 ∗ (0.098)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.812 ∗∗ (0.018)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.007 (0.005)<br />

Rating dummy -0.515 ∗ (0.232)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.009 ∗ (0.004)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.058 (0.039)<br />

Euribor change 0.084 ∗ (0.040)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.128 ∗ (0.058)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

Table A.2: Final results of the main model, corrected only for heteroskedasticity:<br />

basic OLS regression, robust to an arbitrary form of<br />

heteroskedasticity.<br />

Variable Coefficient (Std. Err.)<br />

Main political indicator, endogeneous -0.163 † (0.095)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 0.810 ∗∗ (0.018)<br />

Euro Stoxx 50 return 2 0.007 (0.005)<br />

Rating dummy -0.516 ∗ (0.231)<br />

Government bonds yield -0.008 † (0.004)<br />

Predictability indicator 0.057 (0.039)<br />

Euribor change 0.084 ∗ (0.040)<br />

Money growth -0.030 † (0.016)<br />

Intercept -0.126 ∗ (0.058)<br />

Significance levels: † : 10% ∗ : 5% ∗∗ : 1%<br />

The absence of correction for endogeneity of the political indicator substantially<br />

modifies its significance, as the comparison between tables A.1 and A.2 shows. The<br />

coefficients, standard errors and significance of the other regressors remain almost<br />

unchanged.


Bibliography<br />

Books<br />

Alesina, A., Roubini, N. and Cohen, G. (1997), Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy, MIT<br />

Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.<br />

Angrist, J. and Pischke, J. (2009), Mostly Harmless Econometrics, Princeton University Press,<br />

Princeton, New Jersey.<br />

Benedikter, R. (2011), Social Banking and Social Finance: Answer to the Economic Crisis,<br />

Springer, New York.<br />

Bernhard, W. and Leblang, D. (2006), Democratic Processes and Financial Markets - Pricing<br />

Politics, Cambridge University Press, New York.<br />

Box, G. and Jenkins, G. (1970), Time Series Analysis: Forecasting and Control, Holden-Day,<br />

San Francisco, California.<br />

Buyst, E., Maes, I., Pluym, W. and Danneel, M. (2005), The Bank, the Franc and the Euro, A<br />

History of the National Bank of Belgium, Lannoo, Tielt.<br />

Campbell, J., Lo, A. and MacKinlay, A. (1997), The Econometrics of Financial Markets,<br />

Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey.<br />

Cootner, P. (1964), The Random Character of Stock Market Prices, M.I.T. Press, Boston,<br />

Massachusetts.<br />

Delwit, P. (2003), Composition, Décomposition et Recomposition du Paysage Politique en<br />

Belgique, Labor, Bruxelles.<br />

Delwit, P., De Waele, J. and Magnette, P. (1999), Gouverner la Belgique, Presses universitaires<br />

de France, Paris.<br />

Deschouwer, K. (2009), The Politics of Belgium: Governing a Divided Society, Palgrave<br />

Macmillan, Basingstoke (1 st edition).<br />

Destrée, J. (1963), La Lettre au Roi, Edition de la Wallonie libre, Gembloux.<br />

Jaumain, S. (1997), La Réforme de l’État... et Après?, Éditions de l’Université de Bruxelles,<br />

Brussels.<br />

Mabille, X. (2000), Histoire Politique de la Belgique, Facteurs et Acteurs de Changement, CRISP,<br />

Brussels.<br />

Maes, I. (2010), A Century of Macroeconomic and Monetary Thought at the National Bank of<br />

Belgium, National Bank of Belgium, Brussels.<br />

National Bank of Belgium, (2011), Rapport 2011: Stabilité Financière et Contrôle Prudentiel,<br />

National Bank of Belgium, Brussels.<br />

84


85<br />

Quevit, M. (2010), Flandre-Wallonie, Quelle Solidarité?, Couleur livres, Brussels.<br />

Savage, R. (2004), Histoire Inédite de l’Économie en Belgique, Couleur livres, Charleroi.<br />

Wooldridge, J. (2009), Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, South-Western<br />

Publishing, Canada (4 th edition).<br />

Wright, P. (1928), The Tariff on Animal and Vegetable Oils, MacMillan, New York.


86<br />

Articles in journals<br />

Abadie, A. and Gardeazabal, J. (2003), « The Economic Costs of Conflict: A Case Study of the<br />

Basque Country», The American Economic Review, 93(1), 113–132.<br />

Acharya, S. (1993), « Value of Latent Information: Alternative Event Study Methods», The<br />

Journal of Finance, 48(1), 363–385.<br />

Akgiray, V. and Booth, G. (1987), « Compound Distribution Models of Stock Returns: An<br />

Empirical Comparison», Journal of Financial Research, 10(3), 269–280.<br />

Aktas, H. and Oncu, S. (2006), « The Stock Market Reaction to Extreme Events: The Evidence<br />

from Turkey», International Research Journal of Finance and Economics, (6), 78–85.<br />

Ali, N., Nassir, A., Hassan, T. and Abidin, S. (2010), « Short Run Stock Overreaction: Evidence<br />

from Bursa Malaysia», Journal of Economics and Management, 4(2), 319–333.<br />

Ashley, J. (1962), « Stock Prices and Changes in Earnings and Dividends: Some Empirical<br />

Results», Journal of Political Economy, 70(1), 82–85.<br />

Ball, C. and Torous, W. (1988), « Investigating Security-Price Performance in the Presence of<br />

Event-Date Uncertainty», Journal of Financial Economics, 22, 123–153.<br />

Barclay, M. and Litzenberger, R. (1988), « Announcement Effect of New Equity Issues and the<br />

Use of Intraday Price Data», Journal of Financial Economics, 21, 71–100.<br />

Barker, C. (1958), « Evaluation of Stock Dividends», Harvard Business Review, 36, 101–106.<br />

Barro, B. (1977), « Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment in the United States»,<br />

American Economic Review, 67(2), 101–115.<br />

Barro, B. (1979), « Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment in the United States:<br />

Reply», American Economic Review, 69(5), 101–115.<br />

Beck, N. (1992), « Comparing Dynamic Specifications: the Case of Presidential Approval»,<br />

Political Analysis, 3, 27–50.<br />

Beck, N. (1993), « The Methodology of Cointegration», Political Analysis, 4, 237–248.<br />

Benton, A. (2008), « Do Investors Assess the Credibility of Campaign Commitments? : The<br />

Case of Mexico’s 2006 Presidential Race», Political Research Quarterly, 61(3), 403–418.<br />

Bernanke, B. and Kuttner, K. (2005), « What Explains the Stock Market’s Reaction to Federal<br />

Reserve Policy», The Journal of Finance, 60(3), 1221–1257.<br />

Berry, M., Gallinger, G. and Henderson, G. (1990), « Using Daily Stock Returns in Event Studies<br />

and the Choice of Parametric versus Nonparametric Test Statistics», Quarterly Journal of<br />

Business and Economics, 29(1), 70–85.<br />

Bilson, C., Brailsford, T. and Hooper, V. (2002), « The Explanatory Power of Political Risk in<br />

Emerging Market», International Review of Financial Analysis, 11(1), 1–27.<br />

Binder, J. (1998), « The event study methodology since 1969», Review of Quantitative Finance<br />

and Accounting, 11, 111–137.


87<br />

Blanchard, O. (1981), « Output, the stock market and interest rates», The American Economic<br />

Review, 71(1), 132–143.<br />

Bollerslev, T. (1986), « Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity», Journal of<br />

Econometrics, 31, 307–327.<br />

Boudoukh, J., Richardson, M. and Whitelaw, R. (1994), « A Tale of Three Schools: Insights<br />

on Autocorrelation of Short Term Stock Returns», The Review of Financial Studies, 7(3),<br />

539–573.<br />

Brown, S. and Warner, J. (1980), « Measuring Security Price Performance», Journal of Financial<br />

Economics, 8, 205–258.<br />

Brown, S. and Warner, J. (1985), « Using Daily Stock Returns: The Case of Event Studies»,<br />

Journal of Financial Economics, 14, 3–31.<br />

Cammack, P. (2009), « All Power to Global Capital!», Papers in the Politics of Global Competitiveness,<br />

July(10), 1–17.<br />

Chan, Y. and Wei, J. (1996), « Political Risk and Stock Price Volatility: The Case of Hong<br />

Kong», Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, 4(2-3), 259–275.<br />

Chen, D., Bin, F. and C., Chen (2005), « The Impacts of Political Events on Foreign Institutional<br />

Investors and Stock Returns: Emerging Market Evidence from Taiwan», International Journal<br />

of Business, 10(2), 165–188.<br />

Cheung, Y. and Lai, K. (1993), « Do Gold Market Returns Have Long Memory», The Financial<br />

Review, 26(2), 181–202.<br />

de Coorebyter, V. (2011), « Principaux Partis et Dernières Élections en Belgique», Pouvoirs,<br />

136, 5–8.<br />

Dickey, D. and Fuller, W. (1979), « Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time<br />

Series With a Unit Root», Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74, 427–431.<br />

Dolley, J. (1933), « Characteristics and Procedures of Common Stock Split-Ups», Harvard<br />

Business Review, 11, 316–327.<br />

Doornik, J. and Ooms, M. (2008), « Multimodality in GARCH Regression Models», International<br />

Journal of Forecasting, 24, 432–448.<br />

Durbin, J. and Watson, G. (1950), « Testing for Serial Correlation in Least Squares Regression:<br />

I», Biometrika, 37, 409–428.<br />

Durbin, J. and Watson, G. (1951), « Testing for Serial Correlation in Least Squares Regression.<br />

II», Biometrika, 38, 159–177.<br />

Durr, R. (1993), « An Essay on Cointegration and Error Correction Models», Political Analysis,<br />

4, 185–228.<br />

Elliott, G., Rothenberg, T. and Stock, J. (1996), « Efficient Tests for an Autoregressive Unit<br />

Root», Econometrica, 64(4), 813–836.<br />

Engle, R. (1982), « Autoregressive Conditional Heteroscedasticity with Estimates of the Variance<br />

of United Kingdom Inflation», Econometrica, 50(4), 987–1008.


88<br />

Engle, R. and Granger, C. (1987), « Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation,<br />

Estimation and Testing», Econometrica, 55(2), 251–276.<br />

Engle, R. and Viktor, K. (1993), « Measuring and Testing the Impact of News on Volatility»,<br />

The Journal of Finance, 48(5), 1749–1778.<br />

Erk, J. (2005), « From Vlaams Blok to Vlaams Belang: The Belgian Far-Right Renames Itself»,<br />

West European Politics, 28(3), 493–502.<br />

Fama, E. (1965), « The Behavior of Stock-Market Prices», The Journal of Business, 38(1),<br />

34–105.<br />

Fama, E. (1970), « Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work», The<br />

Journal of Finance, 25(2), 383–417.<br />

Fama, E. (1990), « Stock Returns, Expected Returns, and Real Activity», The Journal of<br />

Finance, 45(4), 1089–1108.<br />

Fama, E. and French, K. (2004), « The Capital Asset Pricing Model: Theory and Evidence»,<br />

Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(3), 25–46.<br />

Fama, E., Fischer, L., Jensen, M. and Roll, R. (1969), « The Adjustment of Stock Prices to New<br />

Information», International Economic Review, 10, 1–27.<br />

Feldstein, M. (1980), « Inflation and the Stock Market», American Economic Review, 70,<br />

839–847.<br />

Forbes, K. and Rigobon, R. (2002), « No Contagion, Only Interdependence: Measuring Stock<br />

Market Co-movements», The Journal of Finance, 57(5), 2223–2261.<br />

Freeman, J., Hays, C. and Stix, H. (2000), « Democracy and Markets: The Case of Exchange<br />

Rates», American Journal of Political Science, 44(3), 449–468.<br />

Gemmill, G. and Saflekos, A. (2000), « How Useful are Implied Distributions? Evidence From<br />

Stock Index Options?», The Journal of Derivatives, Spring 2000, 1–17.<br />

Glascock, J., Davidson, W. and Henderson, G. (1987), « Announcement Effects of Moody’s<br />

Bond Rating Changes on Equity Returns», Quarterly Journal of Business and Economics, 26<br />

(3), 67–78.<br />

Granger, C. (1981), « Some Properties of Time Series Data and their Use in Econometric Model<br />

Specification», Journal of Econometrics, 16, 121–130.<br />

Gregory, A. and Reeves, J. (2010), « Estimation and Inference in ARCH Models in the Presence<br />

of Outliers», Journal of Financial Econometrics, 8(4), 547–549.<br />

Hedges, L. (1987), « How Hard Is Hard Science, How Soft Is Soft Science?»,<br />

Psychologist, 42(2), 443–455.<br />

American<br />

Henderson, G. (1990), « Problems and Solutions in Conducting Event Studies», Journal of Risk<br />

and Insurance, 57, 282–306.<br />

Herron, M. (2000), « Estimating the Economic Impact of Political Party Competition in the<br />

1992 British Election», American Journal of Political Science, 44(3), 326–337.


89<br />

Hsieh, D. (1991), « Chaos and Nonlinear Dynamics: Application to Financial Markets», The<br />

Journal of Finance, 46(5), 1839–1877.<br />

Huang, R. (1985), « Common Stock Returns and Presidential Elections», Financial Analysts<br />

Journal, 41(2), 58–61.<br />

Jensen, N. and Schmith, S. (2005), « Market Responses to Politics: The Rise of Lula and the<br />

Decline of the Brazilian Stock Market», Comparative Political Studies, 38(10), 1245–1270.<br />

Jones, S. and Banning, K. (2009), « US Elections and Monthly Stock Market Returns», Journal<br />

of Economics and Finance, 33(3), 273–287.<br />

Junqué de Fortuny, E., De Smedt, T., D., Martens and W., Daelemans (2012), « Media Coverage<br />

in Times of Political Crisis: A Text Mining Approach», Expert Systems with Applications, 39<br />

(14), 11616–11622.<br />

Kaminsky, G. and Schmukler, S. (2002), « Emerging Markets Instability: Do Sovereign Ratings<br />

Affect Country Risk and Stock Returns?», World Bank Economic Review, 16(2), 171–195.<br />

Karafiath, I. (1988), « Using Dummy Variables in the Event Methodology», Financial Review,<br />

23(3), 351–357.<br />

King, R. and Levine, R. (1993), « Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right», Journal<br />

of Economics, 108(3), 717–737.<br />

Koutmos, G. and Theodossiou, P. (1994), « Time-Series Properties and Predictability of Greek<br />

Exchange Rates», Managerial and Decision Economics, 15, 159–167.<br />

Leblang, D. and Mukherjee, B. (2004), « Presidential Elections and the Stock Market: Comparing<br />

Markov-Switching and (FIE)GARCH Models of Stock Volatility», Political Analysis, 12(3),<br />

1–56.<br />

Lee, H. and Brorsen, W. (1997), « A Non-Nested Test of GARCH vs. EGARCH Models»,<br />

Applied Economics Letters, 4(12), 765–768.<br />

Lintner, J. (1965), « The Valuation of Risk Assets and the Selection of Risky Investments in<br />

Stock Portfolios and Capital Budgets», Review of Economics and Statistics, 47(1), 13–37.<br />

Lobo, B. and Tufte, D. (1998), « Exchange Rate Volatility: Does Politics Matter?», Journal of<br />

Macroeconomics, 20(2), 351–365.<br />

MacKinlay, C. (1997), « Event Studies in Economics and Finance»,<br />

Literature, 35(1), 13–39.<br />

Journal of Economic<br />

Mandelbrot, B. (1963), « The Variation of Certain Speculative Prices», The Journal of Business,<br />

36(4), 394–419.<br />

Mnookin, R. (2007), « Ethnic Conflicts: Flemings and Walloons, Palestinians and Israelis»,<br />

Daedalus, 136(1), 103–119.<br />

Murphy, K. and Topel, R. (1985), « Estimation and Inference in Two-Step Econometric Models»,<br />

Journal of Business and Econometric Statistics, 3(4), 88–97.<br />

Myers, J. and Bakay, A. (1948), « Influence of Stock Split-ups on Market Prices», Harvard<br />

Business Review, 26, 251–265.


90<br />

Nelson, D. (1991), « Conditional Heteroskedasticity in Asset Returns: A New Approach»,<br />

Econometrica, 59(2), 347–370.<br />

Niederhoffer, V. (1971), « The Analysis of World Events and Stock Prices», The Journal of<br />

Business, 44(2), 193–219.<br />

Oxley, L. and McAleer, M. (1993), « Econometric Issues in Macroeconomic Models with<br />

Generated Regressors», Journal of Economic Surveys, 1(1), 1–40.<br />

Pagan, A. (1984), « Econometric Issues in the Analysis of Regressions with Generated Regressors»,<br />

International Economic Review, 25(1), 221–247.<br />

Pantzalis, C., Stangeland, D. and Turle, H. (2000), « Political Elections and the Resolution of<br />

Uncertainty: The International Evidence», Journal of Banking & Finance, 24, 1575–1604.<br />

Parkinson, M. (1980), « The Extreme Value Method for Estimating the Variance of the Rate of<br />

Return», The Journal of Business, 53(1), 61–65.<br />

Pynnönen, S. (2005), « On Regression Based Event Study», Acta Wasensia, 143, 327–354.<br />

Reiersøl, O. (1941), « Confluence Analysis By Means of Lag Moments and Other Methods of<br />

Confluence Analysis», Econometrica, 9(1), 1–24.<br />

Roll, R. (1977), « A Critique of the Asset Pricing Theory’s Tests: Part I: On Past and Potential<br />

Testability of the Theory», The Journal of Financial Economics, 4(2), 129–176.<br />

Roll, R. and Ross, S. (1980), « An Empirical Investigation of the Arbitrage Pricing Theory»,<br />

The Journal of Finance, 35(5), 1073–1103.<br />

Romero-Meza, R., Bonilla, C. and M., Hinich (2007), « Nonlinear Event Detection in the Chilean<br />

Stock Market», Applied Economics Letters, 14, 987–991.<br />

Ross, S. (1976), « The Arbitrage Theory of Capital Asset Pricing», Journal of Economic Theory,<br />

13, 341–360.<br />

Rozeff, M. (1974), « Money and Stock Prices: Market Efficiency and the Lag in Effect of<br />

Monetary Policy», Journal of Financial Economics, 1(3), 245–302.<br />

Samuelson, P. (1965), « Proof that Properly Anticipated Prices Fluctuate Randomly», Industrial<br />

Management Review, 6, 41–49.<br />

Savigny, H. (2002), « Public Opinion, Political Communication and the Internet», Politics, 22<br />

(1), 1–8.<br />

Schwert, G. (1989), « Margin Requirements and Stock Volatility», Journal of Financial Services<br />

Research, 3, 153–164.<br />

Schwert, G. (1990), « Stock Return and Real Activity: a Century of Evidence», The Journal of<br />

Finance, 45(4), 1237–1257.<br />

Shanken, J. (1982), « The Arbitrage Pricing Theory: is it Testable?», The Journal of Finance,<br />

37(5), 1129–1140.<br />

Sharpe, W. (1964), « Capital Asset Prices: A Theory of Market Equilibrium under Conditions<br />

of Risk», The Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425–442.


91<br />

Theodossiou, P. (1994), « The Stochastic Properties of Major Canadian Exchange Rates»,<br />

Financial Review, 29(2), 193–221.<br />

Thorbecke, W. (1997), « On Stock Market Returns and Monetary Policy», The Journal of<br />

Finance, 52(2), 635–654.<br />

Ultsch, A. (2009), « Is Log Ratio a Good Value for Measuring Return in Stock Investments», In:<br />

A. Fink, B. Lausen, W. Seidel & A. Ultsch (Eds.), Advances in Data Analysis, Data Handling<br />

and Business Intelligence, 505–511. Springer.<br />

Wells, W. (2004), « A Beginner’s Guide to Event Studies», Journal of Insurance Regulation, 22<br />

(4), 61–70.<br />

Wooldridge, J. (2001), « Applications of Generalized Method of Moments Estimation», Journal<br />

of Economic Perspectives, 15(4), 87–100.<br />

Wu, G. and Xiao, Z. (2002), « A Generalized Partially Linear Model of Asymmetric Volatility»,<br />

Journal of Empirical Finance, 9, 287–319.<br />

Zach, T. (2003), « Political Events and the Stock Market - Evidence from Israel», International<br />

Journal of Business, 8(3), 243–266.


92<br />

Online newspapers<br />

Australian Inspiration, Philosophy & Ethics, 2010. Available at: http://www.<br />

australianinspiration.com.au/Quotes/Wisdom/Philosophy.aspx. Consulted on June 8,<br />

2012.<br />

BBC News, Belgium swears in new government headed by Elio Di Rupo, December 6, 2011.<br />

Available at: http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-europe-16042750. Consulted on August<br />

7, 2012.<br />

BBC News, Belgium fails to break political deadlock, October 18, 2010. Available at: http:<br />

//www.bbc.co.uk/news/world-europe-11568174. Consulted on August 7, 2012.<br />

De Morgen, Belgisch wereldrecord regeringsvorming erkend door Guinness<br />

World Records, April 19, 2011. Available at: http://www.<br />

demorgen.be/dm/nl/5036/Wetstraat/article/detail/1252745/2011/04/19/<br />

Belgisch-wereldrecord-regeringsvorming-erkend-door-Guinness-World-Records.<br />

dhtml. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Morgen, Chronologie van 207 dagen politieke stilstand, August 29, 2010. Available at:<br />

http://www.demorgen.be/dm/nl/6956/Verkiezingen-2010/article/detail/1203964/<br />

2011/01/06/Chronologie-van-207-dagen-politieke-stilstand.dhtml. Consulted on<br />

August 7, 2012.<br />

De Morgen, Regeringsonderhandelingen: een calvarie van 545 dagen, December 10, 2011. Available<br />

at: http://www.demorgen.be/dm/nl/5036/Wetstraat/article/detail/1361080/<br />

2011/12/10/Regeringsonderhandelingen-een-calvarie-van-545-dagen.dhtml. Consulted<br />

on August 7, 2012.<br />

De Morgen, Reynders krijgt twee weken, February 2, 2011. Available at: http:<br />

//www.demorgen.be/dm/nl/5036/Wetstraat/article/detail/1216935/2011/02/02/<br />

Reynders-krijgt-twee-weken.dhtml. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Morgen, Vande Lanotte gooit de handdoek, January 26, 2011. Available at:<br />

http://www.demorgen.be/dm/nl/5036/Wetstraat/article/detail/1213689/2011/<br />

01/26/Vande-Lanotte-gooit-de-handdoek.dhtml. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Morgen, "Nota aanpassen kan ik niet maken tegenover de rest", July 19, 2011. Available<br />

at: http://www.demorgen.be/dm/nl/3625/De-Formatie/article/detail/1294496/<br />

2011/07/19/CD-V-en-zeven-partijen-vergaderen-vanmiddag.dhtml. Consulted on August<br />

8, 2012.<br />

De Morgen, N-VA maakt brandhout van nota, July 7, 2011. Available at: http:<br />

//www.demorgen.be/dm/nl/989/Binnenland/article/detail/1289137/2011/07/07/<br />

N-VA-maakt-brandhout-van-nota.dhtml. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Standaard, Koning aanvaardt ontslag regering, April 26, 2011. Available at: http://www.<br />

standaard.be/artikel/detail.aspx?artikelid=DMF20100426_036. Consulted on August<br />

8, 2012.<br />

De Standaard, BHV van de baan: Franstaligen luiden alarmbel, April 29, 2010. Available at: http:<br />

//www.standaard.be/artikel/detail.aspx?artikelid=DMF20100429_058. Consulted on<br />

August 7, 2012.


93<br />

De Standaard, CD&V: ’Beke heeft geen deadline’, March 5, 2011. Available at: http://www.<br />

standaard.be/artikel/detail.aspx?artikelid=DMF20110305_011. Consulted on August<br />

8, 2012.<br />

De Standaard, Wouter Beke wil landing inzetten, May 12, 2011. Available at: http://www.<br />

standaard.be/artikel/detail.aspx?artikelid=5U3A23J1. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Standaard, Di Rupo wordt formateur, May 16, 2011. Available at: http://www.standaard.<br />

be/artikel/detail.aspx?artikelid=DMF20110516_168. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Standaard, LETTERLIJK. Reactie van Groen! op keuze van formateur, October 13, 2011.<br />

Available at: http://www.standaard.be/artikel/detail.aspx?artikelid=DMF20111013_<br />

150. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Standaard, Pieters en Flahaut niet langer bemiddelaar, October 5, 2010. Available at: http:<br />

//www.standaard.be/artikel/detail.aspx?artikelid=DMF20101005_012. Consulted on<br />

August 7, 2012.<br />

De Standaard, Akkoord over gerechtelijke splitsing BHV is rond, October 5, 2011. Available<br />

at: http://www.standaard.be/artikel/detail.aspx?artikelid=DMF20111005_002. Consulted<br />

on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Tijd, Bart De Wever wordt informateur, June 18, 2011. Available at: http://www.tijd.be/<br />

nieuws/politiek_economie_belgie/Bart_De_Wever_wordt_informateur.8929079-3136.<br />

art. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Tijd, België toch geen wereldrecordhouder, March 30, 2011. Available at:<br />

http://www.tijd.be/nieuws/politiek_economie_belgie/Belgie_toch_geen_<br />

wereldrecordhouder.9039246-3136.art. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Tijd, BIO Johan Vande Lanotte, October 21, 2010. Available at: http://www.tijd.be/<br />

nieuws/politiek_economie_belgie/BIO_Johan_Vande_Lanotte.8977268-3136.art. Consulted<br />

on August 8, 2012.<br />

De Tijd, Akkoord over BHV, September 15, 2011. Available at: http://www.tijd.be/nieuws/<br />

politiek_economie_belgie/Akkoord_over_BHV.9104022-3136.art. Consulted on August<br />

8, 2012.<br />

De Tijd, De financieringswet van A tot Z, September 26, 2011. Available at:<br />

http://www.tijd.be/nieuws/politiek_economie_belgie/De_financieringswet_van_<br />

A_tot_Z.9108160-3136.art. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

La Libre, La crise politique la plus longue, December 23, 2010. Available<br />

at: http://www.lalibre.be/actu/politique-belge/article/631652/<br />

la-crise-politique-la-plus-longue.html. Consulted on August 7, 2012.<br />

La Libre, Le roi a chargé Didier Reynders d’une mission de 2 semaines, February 2,<br />

2011. Available at: http://www.lalibre.be/actu/politique-belge/article/640137/<br />

le-roi-a-charge-didier-reynders-d-une-mission-de-2-semaines.html. Consulted on<br />

August 7, 2012.<br />

La Libre, Vande Lanotte ne veut plus de sa mission, January 6, 2011. Available<br />

at: http://www.lalibre.be/actu/politique-belge/article/634143/<br />

vande-lanotte-ne-veut-plus-de-sa-mission.html. Consulted on August 8, 2012.


94<br />

La Libre, Di Rupo entre dans le champ de mines, May 17, 2011. Available<br />

at: http://www.lalibre.be/actu/politique-belge/article/661203/<br />

di-rupo-entre-dans-le-champ-de-mines.html. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

La Libre, Flahaut et Pieters désignés médiateurs, Di Rupo déchargé, September 4,<br />

2010. Available at: http://www.lalibre.be/actu/politique-belge/article/607140/<br />

flahaut-et-pieters-designes-mediateurs-di-rupo-decharge.html. Consulted on August<br />

7, 2012.<br />

Le Monde, La Belgique est morte le 22 avril 2010, April 23, 2010. Available<br />

at: http://www.lemonde.fr/europe/article_interactif/2010/04/23/<br />

la-belgique-est-morte-le-22-avril-2010_1341870_3214.html. Consulted on November<br />

6, 2011.<br />

Le Monde, Crise belge : d’un médiateur à l’autre, March 2, 2011. Available at: http://www.<br />

lemonde.fr/europe/portfolio/2011/03/02/crise-belge-d-un-mediateur-a-l-autre_<br />

1487504_3214.html. Consulted on November 6, 2011.<br />

Le Soir, Jean-Luc Dehaene refile BHV à Yves Leterme, April 20, 2010.<br />

Available at: http://blog.lesoir.be/jour-apres-jour/2010/04/20/<br />

la-proposition-de-dehaene-pour-les-habitants-de-la-peripherie.../. Consulted<br />

on February 2, 2012.<br />

Le Soir, Crise sur BHV : la chronologie de la journée, April 22, 2010.<br />

Available at: http://www.lesoir.be/actualite/belgique/2010-04-22/<br />

crise-sur-bhv-la-chronologie-de-la-journee-765871.php. Consulted on April<br />

27, 2012.<br />

Le Soir, Voici l’accord de gouvernement en intégralité, December 2, 2011. Available<br />

at: http://www.lesoir.be/actualite/belgique/elections_2010/2011-12-02/<br />

voici-l-accord-de-gouvernement-en-integralite-881093.php. Consulted on April 27,<br />

2012.<br />

Le Soir, Le Roi a nommé Elio Di Rupo Premier ministre, December 5, 2011.<br />

Available at: http://www.lesoir.be/actualite/belgique/elections_2010/2011-12-05/<br />

le-roi-a-nomme-elio-di-rupo-premier-ministre-881543.php. Consulted on April 27,<br />

2012.<br />

Le Soir, Le CD&V lâche la N-VA et accepte de négocier, July 22, 2011. Available at:<br />

http://archives.lesoir.be/le-cd-amp-v-lache-la-n-va-et-accepte-de-negocier_<br />

t-20110722-01HAHX.html. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

Le Soir, Di Rupo nommé "préformateur", July 9, 2010. Available at:<br />

http://www.lesoir.be/actualite/belgique/elections_2010/2010-07-08/<br />

di-rupo-nomme-preformateur-780791.php. Consulted on August 7, 2012.<br />

Le Soir, Wouter Beke, jeune président peu connu, March 2, 2011. Available<br />

at: http://www.lesoir.be/actualite/belgique/elections_2010/2011-03-02/<br />

wouter-beke-jeune-president-peu-connu-825532.php. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

Le Soir, En route vers un gouvernement, November 26, 2011. Available at:<br />

http://www.lesoir.be/actualite/belgique/elections_2010/2011-11-26/<br />

en-route-vers-un-gouvernement-879570.php. Consulted on June 2, 2012.


95<br />

Le Soir, La réforme de l’Etat, qu’est-ce que ca change ?, October 11, 2011.<br />

Available at: http://www.lesoir.be/actualite/belgique/elections_2010/2011-10-11/<br />

la-reforme-de-l-etat-qu-est-ce-que-ca-change-869012.php. Consulted on June 2,<br />

2012.<br />

Le Soir, De Wever nommé "clarificateur", October 9, 2010. Available at:<br />

http://www.lesoir.be/actualite/belgique/elections_2010/2010-10-08/<br />

de-wever-nomme-clarificateur-797291.php. Consulted on April 27, 2012.<br />

L’Echo, Record d’Europe de la crise politique, January 7, 2011. Available at:<br />

http://www.lecho.be/actualite/economie_politique_belgique/Record_d_Europe_<br />

de_la_crise_politique.9007132-3154.art. Consulted on August 8, 2012.<br />

L’Echo, 8 juillet 2010: le bonheur est dans le pré, May 18, 2011. Available at: http://blogs.<br />

lecho.be/humeurs/2011/05/8-juillet-2010-le-bonheur-est-dans-le-pré-.html.<br />

Consulted on April 27, 2012.<br />

L’Echo, S&P menace toujours la Belgique, May 7, 2011. Available at: http:<br />

//www.lecho.be/actualite/economie_politique_belgique/S_P_menace_toujours_<br />

la_Belgique.9055204-3154.art. Consulted on November 20, 2011.<br />

L’Echo, La Belgique au pied du mur: sa note est dégradée par S&P, November 26, 2011. Available<br />

at: http://www.lecho.be/actualite/economie_politique_belgique/La_Belgique_<br />

au_pied_du_mur_sa_note_est_degradee_par_S_P.9131225-3154.art. Consulted on July<br />

11, 2012.<br />

Moody’s, Moody’s downgrades Belgium’s credit ratings to Aa3, negative outlook,<br />

December 16, 2011. Available at: http://www.moodys.com/research/<br />

Moodys-downgrades-Belgiums-credit-ratings-to-Aa3-negative-outlook--PR_<br />

233667. Consulted on June 3, 2012.<br />

Moody’s, Key drivers of Moody’s decision to place Belgium’s Aa1 rating on review for<br />

possible downgrade, October 7, 2011. Available at: http://www.moodys.com/research/<br />

Key-Drivers-of-Moodys-Decision-to-Place-Belgiums-Aa1-Rating--PBC_136680. Consulted<br />

on June 3, 2012.<br />

Reuters, Belgium faces threat of S&P downgrade, December 14, 2010. Available at: http://www.<br />

reuters.com/article/2010/12/14/us-belgium-sp-downgrade-idUSTRE6BD1UB20101214.<br />

Consulted on June 3, 2012.<br />

Service Public Fédéral Belge, Nouveau gouvernement Leterme II, November 25, 2009.<br />

Available at: http://www.belgium.be/fr/actualites/2009/news_nieuwe_federale_<br />

regering_leterme_2.jsp. Consulted on June 8, 2012.<br />

The Guardian, Belgium’s five-party coalition government collapses, April<br />

26, 2010. Available at: http://www.guardian.co.uk/world/2010/apr/26/<br />

belgian-government-collapses-leterme-resigns. Consulted on August 7, 2012.<br />

The New York Times, Belgium, December 14, 2011. Available at: http://topics.nytimes.com/<br />

top/news/international/countriesandterritories/belgium/index.html. Consulted on<br />

August 8, 2012.


Washington Times, At long last, Belgium nearing a government, November<br />

30, 2011. Available at: http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2011/nov/30/<br />

at-long-last-belgium-nearing-a-government/?page=all. Consulted on August 7,<br />

2012.<br />

96


97<br />

Databases<br />

Datastream, Thomson Financial, 2012.<br />

European Commission, Eurostat, 2012.<br />

National Bank of Belgium, Belgostat, 2012.


98<br />

Others<br />

Aktas, N., de Bodt, E and Cousin, J. (2007), « Assessing the Power and Size of the Event Study<br />

Method Through the Decades », 1–23, working paper.<br />

Aquino, R. (2004), « News, Noise and Stock Price Movements», Philippine Management Review,<br />

(0404), discussion paper.<br />

Bernanke, B. and Gertler, M. (2000), « Monetary Policy and Asset Price Volatility», National<br />

Bureau of Economic Research, (7559), 1–74, working paper.<br />

Cohen, G. (1993), Pre and Post-Electoral Macroeconomic Fluctuations, PhD <strong>thesis</strong>, Harvard<br />

University, Cambridge, MA.<br />

Cutler, D., Poterba, J. and Summers, L. (1989), « What moves stock prices?», National Bureau<br />

of Economic Research, (2538), 1–27, working paper.<br />

D’Amico, S. and Farka, M. (2002), « The Fed and Stock Market: a Proxy and Instrumental<br />

Variable Identification», Manuscript, Columbia University, 1–33.<br />

Euribor-rates.eu, Euribor, 2012. Available at: http://www.euribor-rates.eu. Consulted on<br />

July 14, 2012.<br />

European Commission, (2012), « In-Depth Review for Belgium », May,<br />

working document.<br />

Commission Staff<br />

Faniel, J. (CRISP) (2011), « Chronologie de la Crise Politique Belge 2007-2011 », 1–4, working<br />

document.<br />

Federal Public Service Home Affairs, Elections, June 13, 2010, June 13, 2010. Available at:<br />

http://www.polling2010.belgium.be/en/. Consulted on August 7, 2012.<br />

Fitch Ratings, Fitch - Complete Sovereign Rating History, 2012. Available at: http:<br />

//www.fitchratings.com/web_content/ratings/sovereign_ratings_history.xls. Consulted<br />

on June 3, 2012.<br />

Harrington, S. and Schrider, D. (2002), « All Events Induce Variance: Analyzing Abnormal<br />

Returns When Effects Vary Across Firms » SSRN, 1–41, working paper.<br />

International Monetary Fund, (2011), « Belgium: Selected Issues Paper », 1–41, IMF Country<br />

Report No. 11/82, Washington, D.C.<br />

Keele, L. and De Boef, S. (2005), « Not Just for Cointegration: Error Correction Models with<br />

Stationary Data » Nuffield College, Oxford University, (2005-W7), 1–19, working paper in<br />

politics.<br />

Kim, H. and Mei, J. (1994), « Political Risk and Stock Returns: the Case of Hong Kong » New<br />

York University, (FD-94-39), 5–8, working paper.<br />

Milyo, J. (2012), « Stock Market Reactions to Political Events: What Can We Learn about the<br />

Efficacy of Political Connections? », 1–18, working paper.<br />

PRS Group, (2011), « Belgium » Political Risk Yearbook: Belgium Country Report, 1–32.<br />

Rigobon, R. and Sack, B. (2001), « Measuring the Reaction of Monetary Policy to the Stock<br />

Market » National Bureau of Economic Research, (8350), 1–32, working paper.


99<br />

Rochtus, D. (2010), « Is the Renascence of the Flemish Nationalism Due to the Charismatic<br />

Authority of N-VA Chairman Bart De Wever? » ASEN Conference ‘Nation and Charisma’,<br />

(London 13-15 April 2010), 1–19, Lessius University College/Association KU Leuven, Belgium.<br />

Romer, C. and Romer, D. (2007), « The Macroeconomic Effects of Tax Changes: Estimates<br />

Based on a New Measure of Fiscal Shocks», National Bureau of Economic Research, (13264),<br />

1–47, working paper.<br />

Rosenberg, B. and Marathe, V. (1975), « Test of Capital Asset Pricing Model Hypotheses »,<br />

(32), 1–154, working paper.<br />

Stoxx Limited, Euro Stoxx 50 Index, June 29, 2012. Available at: www.stoxx.com/download/<br />

indices/factsheets/sx5e_fs.pdf. Consulted on June 3, 2012.<br />

World Economic Forum, (2011), The Global Competitiveness Report 2011-2012, Klaus Schwab,<br />

Geneva.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!