03.05.2015 Views

o_19kdfsn0q18e31dfraas1esh19vta.pdf

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

the lower-case non-preferences will always be an exact mirror of the upper-case letters of the<br />

preferences. The last four letters aren’t a “shadow” or “inferior”--they are preferences in their own<br />

right, albeit less used ones. Indeed, for a person who has several borderline 6/10 preferences, the<br />

lowercase trailing letters may be almost as important as the upper case letters. Thus it is proper to<br />

include them.<br />

Strong Preference(s)<br />

There is no reason why a person cannot have more than one strong preference. Suppose that an<br />

INTJ has both very clear I and very clear J, and both preferences are 10/10 when measured on a<br />

test? In this case, we can designate this INTJ as (say) an IJTNsfpe, underlining the top preferences<br />

to show that they are clearest.<br />

It is possible to have one, two, three or even four clear preferences. It is also possible to have no<br />

preferences at all.<br />

Conclusion<br />

The method above explains individual variation without the need to resort to unproven hypothetical<br />

constructs, namely type dynamics and cognitive functions. Furthermore, it is empirically sound and<br />

can be measured on a test. It also matches up with existing field observations. As a simpler and<br />

more elegant solution, it deserves consideration within the internet type community as an alternative<br />

to an increasingly shaky theory.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!