sustainable development 20 years on from the ... - José Eli da Veiga

sustainable development 20 years on from the ... - José Eli da Veiga sustainable development 20 years on from the ... - José Eli da Veiga

25.04.2015 Views

237 from these sectors could suffer given that consumers from developed countries are increasingly aware of the environmental impact of the goods they purchase (UNEP/MERCOSUR Network, ong>20ong>11). (v) Promote studies and measures to value the economic contribution of biodiversity and ecosystem services, using methodologies already available. Valuation does not imply that all ecosystem services must be privatized or traded and it is acknowledged that this option entails a range of issues including equity for the current users of common resources and future generations, as well as considerations of economic efficiency (TEEB, ong>20ong>10). Despite these limitations, however, experiences indicate that the use of market-based mechanisms for biodiversity conservation may be appropriate in certain circumstances. The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB) study provides several examples in the region. The challenge for decision makers is to assess when market-based solutions to biodiversity loss are likely to be culturally acceptable, as well as effective, efficient and equitable. Guideline 3 Internalize the environmental and social costs and benefits of public and private economic decisions Principle 16 of the Rio Declaration states that “national authorities should endeavour to promote the internalization of environmental costs and the use of economic instruments, taking into account the approach that the polluter should, in principle, bear the cost of pollution, with due regard to the public interest and without distorting international trade and investment”. In addition to internalizing costs, the benefits of environmental protection should be internalized, for example, by increasing the profitability of activities, sectors and technological choices that have a smaller environmental impact or positive externalities. The following actions are suggested under this guideline: (a) Adopt regulatory measures and economic instruments (such as fiscal tools, public investment and credit, and government procurement, among others) which attribute value to externalities (both positive and negative) and enable agents to calculate the overall costs and benefits of their activities The pricing of activities that pollute or cause environmental degradation should reflect the social cost of the externalities in question. Public investment decisions and the policies of ong>developmentong> finance institutions should be based on a book value assigned to environmental damage and health costs, risk management and the application of appropriate long-term discount rates, so that a proper comparison of the various investment options can be made. The high discount rate used to arrive at public investment decisions interferes with or precludes the use of options that could create synergies among economic growth, quality infrastructure and reduced environmental and social impacts over the medium and long terms (Ocampo, Cosbey and Khor, ong>20ong>11). This practice should be revisited based on the methodology related to social discount rates. The concept of eco-efficiency could also serve as a useful frame of reference for incorporating sustainability criteria in the evaluation of investments (see chapter I).

238 (b) (c) Allocate financial, human and technological resources to strengthen the enforcement of environmental laws and regulations and increase the costs of non-compliance Increase the profitability of activities, sectors and technological choices that have a smaller environmental impact and create or enhance incentives to promote them. Eliminate direct or indirect subsidies for activities or technologies that damage the environment Environmental criteria can be applied to public and private investment decisions, government procurement, the emission of pollutants and access to natural resources, whether in the form of laws or regulations or in the form of the costs of pollution and environmental degradation (charges for pollution rights, access rights or royalty fees). 4 This would bring private or market costs more closely into line with social or economic costs, thereby sending correct market or normative signals. (d) Encourage environmental and ecosystem protection by generating economic alternatives for communities located in areas prone to degradation, in accordance with the cultural values of each country and community The social benefits of protecting the environment and biodiversity are generally greater than those actually perceived by the private agents responsible for deciding whether to conserve or degrade the environment. Environmental protection can be promoted by undertaking new activities that are based on better knowledge and greater capacity for managing ecosystems. In the region, for example, countries such as Costa Rica and Brazil have implemented systems of payment for environmental services. Promoting ong>sustainableong> tourism as part of a broader poverty-reduction and job-creation strategy which includes training and targets women and young people in particular can also help to create a virtuous circle between protection of the environment and ecosystems and job creation. Special attention should be paid to establishing a system for accessing and distributing the benefits arising from the use of genetic resources and relevant technologies given that the possession of traditional knowledge is an income source for populations that conserve forests and related biological diversity (United Nations, ong>20ong>10). (e) Create or adjust mechanisms such as royalties to channel resources into human capital training and other sources of competitiveness to facilitate transformation of the production structure In a region that is highly dependent on non-renewable natural resources, public policy should seek to increase the capital available for its citizens. The loss of natural capital without a corresponding increase in human capital, infrastructure and innovation will have an adverse impact on the well-being of future generations. This is especially relevant in the mining and oil extraction sectors (see chapter I). 4 This can be accomplished, for example, by calculating the book values of pollutants. At the investment evaluation stage, this would alter a project’s estimated profit ratio by providing an increasingly accurate indication of its social and environmental costs.

237<br />

<strong>from</strong> <strong>the</strong>se sectors could suffer given that c<strong>on</strong>sumers <strong>from</strong> developed countries are<br />

increasingly aware of <strong>the</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>mental impact of <strong>the</strong> goods <strong>the</strong>y purchase<br />

(UNEP/MERCOSUR Network, <str<strong>on</strong>g>20</str<strong>on</strong>g>11).<br />

(v) Promote studies and measures to value <strong>the</strong> ec<strong>on</strong>omic c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of biodiversity and<br />

ecosystem services, using methodologies already available. Valuati<strong>on</strong> does not imply that all<br />

ecosystem services must be privatized or traded and it is acknowledged that this opti<strong>on</strong><br />

entails a range of issues including equity for <strong>the</strong> current users of comm<strong>on</strong> resources and<br />

future generati<strong>on</strong>s, as well as c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s of ec<strong>on</strong>omic efficiency (TEEB, <str<strong>on</strong>g>20</str<strong>on</strong>g>10). Despite<br />

<strong>the</strong>se limitati<strong>on</strong>s, however, experiences indicate that <strong>the</strong> use of market-based mechanisms for<br />

biodiversity c<strong>on</strong>servati<strong>on</strong> may be appropriate in certain circumstances. The Ec<strong>on</strong>omics of<br />

Ecosystems and Biodiversity (TEEB) study provides several examples in <strong>the</strong> regi<strong>on</strong>. The<br />

challenge for decisi<strong>on</strong> makers is to assess when market-based soluti<strong>on</strong>s to biodiversity loss<br />

are likely to be culturally acceptable, as well as effective, efficient and equitable.<br />

Guideline 3<br />

Internalize <strong>the</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>mental and social costs and benefits of public<br />

and private ec<strong>on</strong>omic decisi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Principle 16 of <strong>the</strong> Rio Declarati<strong>on</strong> states that “nati<strong>on</strong>al authorities should endeavour to promote <strong>the</strong><br />

internalizati<strong>on</strong> of envir<strong>on</strong>mental costs and <strong>the</strong> use of ec<strong>on</strong>omic instruments, taking into account <strong>the</strong> approach<br />

that <strong>the</strong> polluter should, in principle, bear <strong>the</strong> cost of polluti<strong>on</strong>, with due regard to <strong>the</strong> public interest and<br />

without distorting internati<strong>on</strong>al trade and investment”. In additi<strong>on</strong> to internalizing costs, <strong>the</strong> benefits of<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>mental protecti<strong>on</strong> should be internalized, for example, by increasing <strong>the</strong> profitability of activities,<br />

sectors and technological choices that have a smaller envir<strong>on</strong>mental impact or positive externalities.<br />

The following acti<strong>on</strong>s are suggested under this guideline:<br />

(a)<br />

Adopt regulatory measures and ec<strong>on</strong>omic instruments (such as fiscal tools, public<br />

investment and credit, and government procurement, am<strong>on</strong>g o<strong>the</strong>rs) which attribute value<br />

to externalities (both positive and negative) and enable agents to calculate <strong>the</strong> overall costs<br />

and benefits of <strong>the</strong>ir activities<br />

The pricing of activities that pollute or cause envir<strong>on</strong>mental degra<strong>da</strong>ti<strong>on</strong> should reflect <strong>the</strong> social<br />

cost of <strong>the</strong> externalities in questi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Public investment decisi<strong>on</strong>s and <strong>the</strong> policies of <str<strong>on</strong>g>development</str<strong>on</strong>g> finance instituti<strong>on</strong>s should be based<br />

<strong>on</strong> a book value assigned to envir<strong>on</strong>mental <strong>da</strong>mage and health costs, risk management and <strong>the</strong> applicati<strong>on</strong><br />

of appropriate l<strong>on</strong>g-term discount rates, so that a proper comparis<strong>on</strong> of <strong>the</strong> various investment opti<strong>on</strong>s can<br />

be made. The high discount rate used to arrive at public investment decisi<strong>on</strong>s interferes with or precludes<br />

<strong>the</strong> use of opti<strong>on</strong>s that could create synergies am<strong>on</strong>g ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth, quality infrastructure and reduced<br />

envir<strong>on</strong>mental and social impacts over <strong>the</strong> medium and l<strong>on</strong>g terms (Ocampo, Cosbey and Khor, <str<strong>on</strong>g>20</str<strong>on</strong>g>11).<br />

This practice should be revisited based <strong>on</strong> <strong>the</strong> methodology related to social discount rates.<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>cept of eco-efficiency could also serve as a useful frame of reference for incorporating<br />

sustainability criteria in <strong>the</strong> evaluati<strong>on</strong> of investments (see chapter I).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!