12.04.2015 Views

journal of european integration history revue d'histoire de l ...

journal of european integration history revue d'histoire de l ...

journal of european integration history revue d'histoire de l ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN<br />

INTEGRATION HISTORY<br />

REVUE D’HISTOIRE DE<br />

L’INTÉGRATION EUROPÉENNE<br />

ZEITSCHRIFT FÜR GESCHICHTE DER<br />

EUROPÄISCHEN INTEGRATION<br />

edited by the<br />

Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison <strong>de</strong>s pr<strong>of</strong>esseurs d’histoire contemporaine<br />

auprès <strong>de</strong> la Commission européenne<br />

2002, Volume 8, Number 1<br />

NOMOS Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n


Editors<br />

Published twice a year by the<br />

Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison <strong>de</strong>s pr<strong>of</strong>esseurs d’histoire<br />

contemporaine auprès <strong>de</strong> la Commission européenne<br />

in cooperation with the<br />

Jean Monnet Chairs in History <strong>of</strong> European Integration<br />

with the support <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European Commission, DG X University Information<br />

Editorial Board<br />

LOTH, Wilfried (chairman)<br />

Universität Essen<br />

Jean Monnet Chair<br />

BITSCH, Marie-Thérèse<br />

Université <strong>de</strong> Strasbourg III Robert Schuman<br />

Jean Monnet Chair<br />

BOSSUAT, Gérard<br />

Université <strong>de</strong> Cergy-Pontoise,<br />

Jean Monnet Chair<br />

DEIGHTON, Anne<br />

Wolfson College, Oxford<br />

DUMOULIN, Michel<br />

Université catholique <strong>de</strong> Louvain<br />

Jean Monnet Chair<br />

GUIRAO, Fernando<br />

Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Barcelona<br />

Jean Monnet Chair<br />

LAURSEN, Johnny<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Aarhus<br />

MILWARD, Alan S.<br />

European University Institute, Florence<br />

SCHWABE, Klaus<br />

Rheinisch-Westfälische Technische Hochschule Aachen<br />

Jean Monnet Chair<br />

TRAUSCH, Gilbert<br />

Centre Robert Schuman, Université <strong>de</strong> Liège<br />

VAN <strong>de</strong>r HARST, Jan<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Groningen<br />

Jean Monnet Chair<br />

VARSORI, Antonio<br />

Università <strong>de</strong>gli Studi di Firenze<br />

Jean Monnet Chair<br />

JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN<br />

INTEGRATION HISTORY<br />

REVUE D’HISTOIRE DE<br />

L’INTÉGRATION EUROPÉENNE<br />

ZEITSCHRIFT FÜR GESCHICHTE DER<br />

EUROPÄISCHEN INTEGRATION<br />

Editorial Secretariat<br />

Charles Barthel, director<br />

Address:<br />

Centre d’étu<strong>de</strong>s et <strong>de</strong> recherches européennes<br />

Robert Schuman<br />

4 Rue Jules Wilhelm<br />

L-2728 Luxembourg<br />

Tel.: (3 52) 4 78 22 90/4 78 22 91<br />

Fax.: (3 52) 42 27 97


JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN INTEGRATION HISTORY<br />

REVUE D’HISTOIRE DE L’INTÉGRATION EUROPÉENNE<br />

ZEITSCHRIFT FÜR GESCHICHTE DER EUROPÄISCHEN INTEGRATION<br />

edited by the<br />

Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison <strong>de</strong>s pr<strong>of</strong>esseurs d’histoire contemporaine<br />

auprès <strong>de</strong> la Commission européenne<br />

2002, Volume 8, Number 1


The Liaison Committee <strong>of</strong> Historians came into being in 1982 as a result <strong>of</strong> an important international<br />

symposium that the Commission had organized in Luxembourg to launch historical research on European<br />

<strong>integration</strong>. The committee is composed <strong>of</strong> historians <strong>of</strong> the European Union member countries<br />

who work on contemporary <strong>history</strong>.<br />

The Liaison Committee:<br />

– gathers and conveys information about work on European <strong>history</strong> after the Second World War;<br />

– advises the European Union on research projects concerning contemporary European <strong>history</strong>.<br />

Thus, the Liaison Committee was commissioned to make publicly available the archives <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Community institutions;<br />

– enables researchers to make better use <strong>of</strong> the archival sources;<br />

– promotes research meetings to get an update <strong>of</strong> work in progress and to stimulate new research:<br />

seven research conferences have been organized and their proceedings published.<br />

The Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History – Revue d’histoire <strong>de</strong> l’intégration européenne – Zeitschrift für<br />

Geschichte <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Integration is in line with the preoccupations <strong>of</strong> the Liaison Committee. Being<br />

the first <strong>history</strong> <strong>journal</strong> to <strong>de</strong>al exclusively with the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European Integration, the Journal <strong>of</strong>fers the<br />

increasing number <strong>of</strong> young historians <strong>de</strong>voting their research to contemporary Europe, a permanent forum.<br />

The Liaison Committee is supported by the European Commission, but works completely in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>ntly<br />

and according to historians’ critical method.<br />

❋<br />

Le Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison <strong>de</strong>s pr<strong>of</strong>esseurs d’histoire contemporaine auprès <strong>de</strong> la Commission <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Communautés européennes s’est constitué en 1982 à la suite d’un grand colloque que la Commission<br />

avait organisé à Luxembourg pour lancer la recherche historique sur la construction<br />

européenne. Il regroupe <strong>de</strong>s pr<strong>of</strong>esseurs d’université <strong>de</strong>s pays membres <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne, spécialistes<br />

d’histoire contemporaine.<br />

Le Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison a pour mission:<br />

– <strong>de</strong> diffuser l’information sur les travaux portant sur l’histoire <strong>de</strong> l’Europe après la Secon<strong>de</strong> Guerre<br />

mondiale;<br />

– <strong>de</strong> conseiller l’Union européenne sur les actions scientifiques à entreprendre avec son appui; ainsi<br />

le Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison a assuré une mission concernant la mise à la disposition du public <strong>de</strong>s archives<br />

<strong>de</strong>s institutions communautaires;<br />

– d’ai<strong>de</strong>r à une meilleure utilisation par les chercheurs <strong>de</strong>s moyens <strong>de</strong> recherche mis à leur disposition<br />

(archives, sources orales...);<br />

– d’encourager <strong>de</strong>s rencontres scientifiques afin <strong>de</strong> faire le point sur les connaissances acquises et<br />

<strong>de</strong> susciter <strong>de</strong> nouvelles recherches: sept grands colloques ont été organisés et leurs actes publiés.<br />

L’édition du Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History – Revue d’histoire <strong>de</strong> l’intégration européenne<br />

– Zeitschrift für Geschichte <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Integration se situe dans le droit fil <strong>de</strong>s préoccupations<br />

du Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison. Première <strong>revue</strong> d’histoire à se consacrer exclusivement à l’histoire <strong>de</strong> la<br />

construction européenne, le Journal se propose <strong>de</strong> fournir un forum permanent au nombre croissant<br />

<strong>de</strong> jeunes historiens vouant leurs recherches à l’Europe contemporaine.<br />

Le Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison bénéficie du soutien <strong>de</strong> la Commission européenne. Ses colloques et publications<br />

se font en toute indépendance et conformément à la métho<strong>de</strong> critique qui est celle <strong>de</strong>s historiens.


JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN INTEGRATION HISTORY<br />

REVUE D’HISTOIRE DE L’INTÉGRATION EUROPÉENNE<br />

ZEITSCHRIFT FÜR GESCHICHTE DER EUROPÄISCHEN INTEGRATION<br />

2002, Volume 8, Number 1<br />

Johnny LAURSEN, coordinator<br />

Johnny LAURSEN<br />

Towards a Supranational History?<br />

Introduction............................................................................................ 5<br />

Milène WEGMANN<br />

Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 ..........................11<br />

Bertrand VAYSSIÈRE<br />

Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen pendant<br />

la Secon<strong>de</strong> Guerre mondiale .................................................................37<br />

Seung-Ryeol KIM<br />

France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» ..........61<br />

Lise Rye SVARTVATN<br />

In Quest <strong>of</strong> Time, Protection and Approval:<br />

France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in<br />

the European Economic Community, 1955-56...............................85<br />

Juhana AUNESLUOMA<br />

An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and<br />

British Policy towards Scandinavia 1949-1951..................................103<br />

Erin DELANEY<br />

The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe........................121<br />

Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen ....................139<br />

Abstracts – Résumés – Zusammenfassungen .....................................155<br />

Notices – Informations – Mitteilungen...............................................163<br />

Contributors - Auteurs - Autoren........................................................165<br />

Books received – Livres reçus – Eingegangene Bücher.....................167


Editorial notice<br />

Articles for inclusion in this <strong>journal</strong> may be submitted at any time. The editorial board will then<br />

arrange for the article to be refereed. Articles should not be longer than 6000 words, footnotes<br />

inclu<strong>de</strong>d. They may be in English, French or German.<br />

Articles submitted to the Journal should be original contributions and not be submitted to any<br />

other publication at the same time as to the Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History. Authors<br />

should retain a copy <strong>of</strong> their article. The publisher and editors cannot accept responsibility for<br />

loss <strong>of</strong> or damage to authors’ typescripts or disks.<br />

The accuracy <strong>of</strong>, and views expressed in articles and reviews are the sole responsibility <strong>of</strong> the<br />

authors.<br />

Authors should ensure that typescripts conform with the <strong>journal</strong> style. Prospective contributors<br />

should obtain further gui<strong>de</strong>lines from the Editorial Secretariat.<br />

Articles, reviews, communications relating to articles and books for review should be sent to the<br />

Editorial Secretariat.<br />

Citation<br />

The Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History may be cited as follows:<br />

JEIH, (Year)/(Number), (Page).<br />

ISSN 0947-9511<br />

© 2002 NOMOS Verlagsgesellschaft, Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n and the Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison <strong>de</strong>s pr<strong>of</strong>esseurs<br />

d’histoire contemporaine auprès <strong>de</strong> la Commission européenne. Printed in Germany.<br />

All rights reserved. No part <strong>of</strong> this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or<br />

transmitted in any form or by any means, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise,<br />

without prior permission <strong>of</strong> the publishers.


5<br />

Towards a Supranational History?<br />

Introduction<br />

Johnny Laursen<br />

As these lines are being written the European Convent has for some time been<br />

engaged in a <strong>de</strong>bate over what form the future European Union should take. In a<br />

sense this discussion also involves a <strong>de</strong>bate over the European past. How should we<br />

un<strong>de</strong>rstand the nature and future <strong>of</strong> the European nation states? What are the exact<br />

nature and dynamics <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>integration</strong> process? What relationship<br />

between the European community and the Europe beyond? Does there exist – from<br />

Reykjavik to Diyarbakïr – a European polity with shared values and concepts?<br />

While politicians are struggling with these questions in an effort to shape the future,<br />

historians and social scientists are struggling with much the same questions in<br />

an effort to shape the past. Past, present and future European <strong>integration</strong> is in many<br />

ways equally elusive. Just as the present European or<strong>de</strong>r is up to discussion also the<br />

<strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> is hard to <strong>de</strong>fine.<br />

First, the historians <strong>of</strong> the EU are studying a subject matter which has not yet<br />

found its final shape. Hence, the transient, still changing nature and bor<strong>de</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> the<br />

EU and <strong>of</strong> the other European institutions can make it difficult to find a common<br />

perspective and a shared set <strong>of</strong> research questions. This is much more so as the <strong>history</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> is not only pursued by historians, but also by other<br />

disciplines such as political science, law etc.<br />

Secondly, the field embraces a variety <strong>of</strong> methods and approaches in the way researchers<br />

work on the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>. The established tradition in<br />

the field is that <strong>of</strong> the empirical, archive-based and severely footnoted ‘histoire<br />

événementielle’, closely related to its near cousin the diplomatic <strong>history</strong>. However,<br />

although the subject matter – <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> – is obligatory, the<br />

methods and the aca<strong>de</strong>mic backgrounds <strong>of</strong> the stu<strong>de</strong>nts <strong>of</strong> the field are far from exclusive.<br />

Not only historians (<strong>of</strong> which there are many kinds already), but also political<br />

scientists, sociologists, lawyers and many others apply themselves to this rich<br />

field. It is an example <strong>of</strong> an enriching, interdisciplinary exchange between archive-based,<br />

empirical <strong>history</strong> and more theory-oriented approaches. The variety <strong>of</strong><br />

methods and approaches is a source <strong>of</strong> scientific innovation and copiousness, although<br />

this admittedly does little to narrow down what the study <strong>of</strong> the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

European <strong>integration</strong> is really about.<br />

Third, we are <strong>de</strong>aling with a subject which is not easy to <strong>de</strong>fine in terms <strong>of</strong> geography<br />

and chronology. If we chose the easy and conventional way to <strong>de</strong>fine the<br />

subject matter, that is to say that the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> is the <strong>history</strong><br />

about the creation and <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> the European Union, many questions remain<br />

open. What place does the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the coming new memberstates <strong>of</strong> the EU such<br />

as the Czech Republic, Estonia or Malta take in such a framework? Is the historical<br />

experience <strong>of</strong> these countries really only relevant from the point <strong>of</strong> view <strong>of</strong> mem-


6<br />

Johnny Laursen<br />

bership, or can the study <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> embrace wi<strong>de</strong>r issues and broa<strong>de</strong>r<br />

chronological periods <strong>of</strong> time than that <strong>of</strong> the existence <strong>of</strong> the European community?<br />

Does there exist, beneath the Iron Curtain <strong>of</strong> the Cold War, a <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European<br />

<strong>integration</strong> shared by the peoples <strong>of</strong> both Eastern and Western Europe? In<strong>de</strong>ed,<br />

the boundaries <strong>of</strong> the subject matter seem to change as the focus shifts between institutions,<br />

politics, security issues and i<strong>de</strong>ntities and perceptions.<br />

Fourth, and most important the field has special features which constitute a challenge.<br />

In many ways the study <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> is and has been – and should<br />

to a large extent be – national <strong>history</strong>. It is on the other hand also a field that highlights<br />

the limitations <strong>of</strong> the national <strong>history</strong> perspective. We are looking at a process<br />

where power and political dynamics are vested into something above the national –<br />

something supranational – so if we want to explain this or that negotiation process or<br />

this or that set <strong>of</strong> i<strong>de</strong>ntity patterns we will have to look at the nation state plus something<br />

beyond, a complex pattern <strong>of</strong> interaction between national governments, Nonstate<br />

actors and more or less supranational institutions and processes.<br />

Even though this issue <strong>of</strong> the Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History is an open issue<br />

and not a thematic one, the six contributions are nevertheless a fairly representative<br />

selection <strong>of</strong> the established research areas <strong>of</strong> the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>.<br />

Milène Wegmann’s study on the Neo-liberal Conception <strong>of</strong> a European Fe<strong>de</strong>ration,<br />

1918-1945 can be consi<strong>de</strong>red a study <strong>of</strong> the intellectual pre-<strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>integration</strong><br />

process. The author <strong>de</strong>monstrates how a group <strong>of</strong> influential neo-liberal economists<br />

such as von Hayek, Röpke, Einaudi and Robbins <strong>de</strong>veloped a set <strong>of</strong> politico-economic<br />

doctrines in the interwar period, where a customs union within a liberal<br />

economic system was intrinsically linked to a political fe<strong>de</strong>ration and an international<br />

system <strong>of</strong> states based on international law. During the Second World War these thinkers<br />

moved towards a stronger focus on the requirements <strong>of</strong> social and cultural <strong>integration</strong><br />

as a necessary foundation for a successful fe<strong>de</strong>ration. The author is able to trace<br />

back the <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> a number <strong>of</strong> key concepts in the fe<strong>de</strong>ralist thinking to the intellectual<br />

origins in the period 1918-1945. Bertrand Vayssière’s work on The Italian Origins<br />

<strong>of</strong> European Fe<strong>de</strong>ralism during the Second World War investigates the emergence<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Movimento Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista Europeo and the influences and the circumstances <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Manifesto <strong>de</strong> Ventotene edited by Altiero Spinelli in collaboration with Ernesto Rossi<br />

and Eugenio Colorni in 1943. The militant fe<strong>de</strong>ralism <strong>of</strong> these oppositional Italian intellectuals<br />

who were convinced <strong>of</strong> the central role that a fe<strong>de</strong>ral European solution would<br />

play in the future peace system explains the particular strength <strong>of</strong> European fe<strong>de</strong>ralism<br />

in Italy and throws light on one <strong>of</strong> the main sources <strong>of</strong> the emergence <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

fe<strong>de</strong>ralist movements. Moreover, Bertrand Vayssière carries the analysis beyond intellectual<br />

and elitist political <strong>history</strong> with his analysis <strong>of</strong> how the Italian fe<strong>de</strong>ralists failed<br />

to adapt to the hard peacetime realities <strong>of</strong> the primacy <strong>of</strong> national priorities in the<br />

post-war world. Here we move into another important current in the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European<br />

<strong>integration</strong>.<br />

The pursuit by national elites <strong>of</strong> European power politics and <strong>of</strong> national political<br />

agendas has with good cause played a central role in the studies <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

<strong>integration</strong> process in the 1950’s. This holds good for both the abortive ventures


Introduction 7<br />

such as the attempt to create a European Defence Community and for the more successful<br />

un<strong>de</strong>rtakings such as the Schuman plan and the negotiation <strong>of</strong> the Treaties<br />

<strong>of</strong> Rome. The traditional focus on the 1950’s and on the incentives – and the lack<br />

there<strong>of</strong> – in the nation states to engage in the <strong>integration</strong> process is well justified.<br />

The time <strong>of</strong> birth <strong>of</strong> the European Community undoubtedly is the crux for un<strong>de</strong>rstanding<br />

why nation states have engaged in ceding sovereignty to the supranational<br />

community and what was the original ‘contract’ <strong>of</strong> the <strong>integration</strong> process. Examining<br />

why the Six set sails for the <strong>integration</strong> process that en<strong>de</strong>d with the EU – and<br />

why others did not (at that point <strong>of</strong> time at least) – is still an important subject for<br />

researchers. Two <strong>of</strong> the contributions to this issue are analyzing these problems in a<br />

country where dynamics and reluctance at one and the same time seem to have<br />

been most manifest. Seung-Ryeol Kim’s article on France’s Agony between «Vocation<br />

Européenne et Mondiale»: The Union Française as an Obstacle in the French<br />

Policy <strong>of</strong> Supranational European Integration, 1952-1954 is a study <strong>of</strong> France’s attempts<br />

to reconcile her priorities in the European policy with her world power status.<br />

European consi<strong>de</strong>rations – especially in relation to Germany – brought the<br />

French political lea<strong>de</strong>rship to engage first in the green pool negotiations and later in<br />

the attempt to establish a European Army with a European Political Community as<br />

a ‘ro<strong>of</strong> organization’. It was, however, difficult to reconcile these policies with the<br />

preservation <strong>of</strong> France’s world power role in which the Union Française was the<br />

main pillar. Thus, Seung-Reyol Kim shows how the concern for the endangered<br />

system <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>ncy between France and her earlier colonies contributed to the<br />

French rejection <strong>of</strong> the green pool and to the failure to ratify the EDC treaty. While<br />

Seung-Reyol Kim’s article focusses on the overseas aspect <strong>of</strong> French European<br />

policy, Lise Rye Svartvatn’s In Quest <strong>of</strong> Time, Protection and Approval: France<br />

and the Claims for Social Harmonisation in the European Economic Community,<br />

1955-56 turns the attention to the French domestic political consi<strong>de</strong>rations during<br />

the negotiations on the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome. Lise Rye Svartvatn’s work shows how<br />

France’s social policy pursued at European level inten<strong>de</strong>d to achieve the domestic<br />

aims <strong>of</strong> securing a continued expansion and mo<strong>de</strong>rnisation <strong>of</strong> French industry. In itself<br />

a reflection <strong>of</strong> temporal problems and domestic, political disunity on the question<br />

<strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>, the line pursued by France had nevertheless longterm effects<br />

on the institutional and policy-oriented compromises in the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome.<br />

Still, however important this original compromise on the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome was,<br />

the functions and dynamics <strong>of</strong> the European Communities met with changes in the<br />

face <strong>of</strong> challenges from outsi<strong>de</strong> forces. Even though the <strong>integration</strong> process initiated<br />

by the Six was progressively to become the heart <strong>of</strong> the <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> European<br />

institution-building and co-operation, it should be remembered that the Six did<br />

not have the monopoly in European <strong>integration</strong> and co-operation in the 1950’s and<br />

1960’s. Till now the relationship between those insi<strong>de</strong> the union and those outsi<strong>de</strong><br />

(or waiting to join) has been one <strong>of</strong> the most critical factors <strong>of</strong> the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

community. This was so already with the divi<strong>de</strong> between the Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

functionalists and the Continental fe<strong>de</strong>ralists at the time <strong>of</strong> the foundation <strong>of</strong><br />

the Council <strong>of</strong> Europe in 1949, the break-up <strong>of</strong> the OEEC in 1958-59 and the Euro-


8<br />

Johnny Laursen<br />

pean market schism between The Six and The Seven throughout the 1960's. Juhana<br />

Aunesluoma’s contribution An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation<br />

and British Policy towards Scandinavia 1945-51 analyses the perceptions and<br />

aims in the British Scandinavian policy and in the establishment <strong>of</strong> the so-called<br />

Uniscan co-operation between the UK, Norway, Denmark and Swe<strong>de</strong>n. For a brief<br />

moment in 1949 the Uniscan had potential to achieve more than the eventual formless<br />

consultations. This study <strong>of</strong> Uniscan allows a glimpse <strong>of</strong> the perceptions <strong>of</strong><br />

many British and Scandinavian <strong>de</strong>cision-makers in the 1950’s. In this sense it is an<br />

important contribution to the pre-<strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> EFTA.<br />

Of course the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> is not limited to the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European Communities. On the one hand the <strong>integration</strong> process exerted an influence<br />

that went far beyond the tariff wall <strong>of</strong> the EEC. The creation <strong>of</strong> the Schuman<br />

Plan and the EEC became important factors for other European states such as<br />

Greece, Portugal and Austria. On the other hand, the influence worked also the other<br />

way round. Two <strong>of</strong> the most momentous events for the <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Communities was when the British <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d first to stay alo<strong>of</strong> and later on to join<br />

the EEC. As today the question <strong>of</strong> enlargement <strong>of</strong> the European Communities did<br />

not only pose a challenge to the Community in terms <strong>of</strong> wi<strong>de</strong>ning, but touched<br />

upon the balance <strong>of</strong> power between states and institutions, upon <strong>de</strong>cision-making<br />

procedures and policies. Is it actually possible to explain the <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

EEC without evoking the question <strong>of</strong> the British EEC-membership hovering over<br />

the organisation throughout the 1960’s? The question <strong>of</strong> enlargement has been one<br />

<strong>of</strong> the most dynamic and conflict-rid<strong>de</strong>n factors in the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the Community<br />

during its existence. But it is also an issue which makes it necessary to re<strong>de</strong>fine the<br />

research questions <strong>de</strong>signed for the study <strong>of</strong> the 1950’s. While the 1950’s might<br />

shed light on why nation states join forces and ce<strong>de</strong> sovereignty – or not – creating<br />

a supranational community, the rise <strong>of</strong> the enlargement question from 1961 onwards<br />

shifts the question to why nation states should <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong> to join an already existing<br />

supranational co-operation with an established institutional structure and a<br />

fixed body <strong>of</strong> law. Archive-based historical research has in later years begun to till<br />

this land. Hopefully the next few years will see the publication <strong>of</strong> historical studies<br />

<strong>of</strong> the first successful enlargement <strong>of</strong> the EC in 1972-73 based on primary sources.<br />

The implications cannot yet be clearly seen. The many variants <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong> theory<br />

will also hopefully receive new stimulus from these research results. It is a real<br />

challenge to the many more or less theoretical efforts to come to grasp the <strong>integration</strong><br />

process and the nature <strong>of</strong> the ever closer union trying to incorporate the changing<br />

dynamics and factors as the community grew from six to fifteen nation states.<br />

Perhaps it would require two sets <strong>of</strong> theory: one explaining why nation states<br />

should come together and create a supranational community and the other analysing<br />

why nation states should join such a community created after the <strong>de</strong>signs <strong>of</strong><br />

others.<br />

Another challenge to the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> is the progress <strong>of</strong> the<br />

archive-based studies <strong>of</strong> community policies ma<strong>de</strong> into the field former monopolised<br />

by policy studies. In recent years researchers have broa<strong>de</strong>ned our knowledge


Introduction 9<br />

about the structures and policies <strong>of</strong> the emerging community. Beginning with the<br />

1960’s a number <strong>of</strong> the early policy areas have been studied and mapped in greater<br />

<strong>de</strong>pth than before. Lise Rye Svartvatn’s aforementioned contribution and Erin Delaney’s<br />

The Labour Party’s Changing Relationship to Europe. The Expansion <strong>of</strong><br />

European Social Policy, are in fact examples <strong>of</strong> this trend. While the former looks<br />

at the French strategies used in the field <strong>of</strong> social policy, the latter focuses on the<br />

British Labour Party’s views on the social policies implemented by the EC. The<br />

first looks at the French position at the time <strong>of</strong> the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome, while the latter<br />

traces the long term patterns <strong>of</strong> continuity and change in the British Labour Party’s<br />

views <strong>of</strong> the EC using the example <strong>of</strong> the EC’s <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> social policies. Both<br />

approaches have their merits. Delaney is thus able to show on the one hand how the<br />

Euro-scepticism <strong>of</strong> the British Labour Party had strong roots in its initial perception<br />

<strong>of</strong> the social nature <strong>of</strong> the Common Market, and on the other hand how the growth<br />

<strong>of</strong> the community’s social policies had a backlash on the Labour Party’s doctrines<br />

in general and on the Labour Party’s European policy in particular. This contribution<br />

reminds archival researchers <strong>of</strong> how useful it can be to take a broa<strong>de</strong>r look that<br />

un<strong>de</strong>rlines the inert nature <strong>of</strong> political perceptions and i<strong>de</strong>ologies, the importance<br />

<strong>of</strong> long term change and macro-historical patterns.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the fascinating aspects <strong>of</strong> the policy studies analysing the origins <strong>of</strong> important<br />

EEC-policies in the 1960’s is that they throw light on the emerging community<br />

institutions and the maze <strong>of</strong> community <strong>de</strong>cision-making processes. This can<br />

be seen in Piers Ludlow’s studies <strong>of</strong> the European Commission at important turning<br />

points in the 1960’s as well as in Ann-Christine Lauring Knudsen’s Ph.D.-thesis on<br />

the making <strong>of</strong> the EEC’s Common Agricultural Policy. Other research results in<br />

fields such as the tra<strong>de</strong> policy, the Common Market and the GATT-negotiations and<br />

the relationship to the less <strong>de</strong>veloped countries <strong>of</strong> the world could be mentioned.<br />

In<strong>de</strong>ed only in the 1960’s the community archives <strong>of</strong> the EEC institutions really begin<br />

to abound with documents that can <strong>of</strong>fer an alternative or a supplement to the<br />

documents in national archives. With an overall view <strong>of</strong> the <strong>integration</strong> process <strong>of</strong><br />

the 1960’s and 1970’s emerging, the discipline will have covered a first, long exhaustive<br />

stretch comparable to the political feat marked by the consolidation and<br />

expansion <strong>of</strong> the European Community at the end <strong>of</strong> that period. With an in-<strong>de</strong>pth<br />

overview <strong>of</strong> the <strong>integration</strong> <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the 1960’s the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong><br />

will furthermore have moved from its origins as either fe<strong>de</strong>ral <strong>history</strong> or as a<br />

particular aspect <strong>of</strong> this or that country’s foreign policy to a discipline that is also<br />

supranational in the sense that its subject matter is more than the accumulated sum<br />

<strong>of</strong> national policies. The <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> is still a quite national<br />

business or a special branch <strong>of</strong> foreign policy studies. We tend to write on ‘Country<br />

X and the European Y’ or ‘Country X, Country Y and the European Z’. Sources<br />

from the national foreign ministry archives abound in this kind <strong>of</strong> research. Still,<br />

this is important work – also for the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>. However, with<br />

the shift in focus from the pioneering years <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> research – the<br />

1950’s – to the following <strong>de</strong>ca<strong>de</strong>s one may hope that the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong><br />

will also move even more towards a more supranational focus. The French


10<br />

Johnny Laursen<br />

historians will hardly claim a veto. British historians will not want to renegotiate<br />

their – admittedly momentous – contribution to European <strong>integration</strong> <strong>history</strong>, nor<br />

will Danish historians vote no. In this respect it is encouraging that many <strong>of</strong> the<br />

contributions to this issue are from younger scholars working on source materials<br />

and subjects other than that <strong>of</strong> their own nationality. However, there remains an enlargement<br />

issue confronting stu<strong>de</strong>nts <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>integration</strong> <strong>history</strong>. It is important<br />

that EU <strong>history</strong> should also be seen from the perspective <strong>of</strong> non-EU countries,<br />

from coming member-countries and that non-EU aspects <strong>of</strong> European<br />

<strong>integration</strong> should also be inclu<strong>de</strong>d.<br />

The 1970’s and 1980’s will bring new questions and an expansion <strong>of</strong> the subject<br />

to new policies, themes and institutions. But empirical, archive-based historical research<br />

is moving slowly and will always be lingering at the threshold <strong>of</strong> the access<br />

limits to the archives. It is therefore a strength that the field is broa<strong>de</strong>r and more<br />

varied than this classical school <strong>of</strong> historical studies. Other methods and approaches<br />

can – and should – be applied to the recent epochs <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong><br />

inaccessible for the archive-grinding historian, to the past already covered by this<br />

school <strong>of</strong> <strong>history</strong> and to entirely other themes and subject areas <strong>of</strong> the elusive phenomenon<br />

we know as European <strong>integration</strong>. It appears that the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> European<br />

<strong>integration</strong> is, as Ernest Hemingway called his memoirs about the years in Paris, a<br />

moveable feast.<br />

In the 19th century many historians played an important role in laying the foundations<br />

for the emerging nation states not to mention for the emerging European<br />

nationalisms. After the catastrophes <strong>of</strong> the 20th century the craft attained new functions<br />

as a critical voice that contributed to political and moral reflection in the European<br />

<strong>de</strong>mocracies. The painful past, war and peace, the workings <strong>of</strong> the political<br />

or<strong>de</strong>r and the limits <strong>of</strong> liberty were scrutinized by many political historians. And<br />

rightly so. A functioning <strong>de</strong>mocracy needs a critical and inquisitive <strong>history</strong> writing<br />

in or<strong>de</strong>r to stimulate discussion on the workings <strong>of</strong> the <strong>de</strong>mocratic and social institutions.<br />

As the European Union has grown to a political and social factor <strong>of</strong> the first<br />

rank for many <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>de</strong>mocracies it is now more necessary than ever to<br />

subject the making <strong>of</strong> European policy in the nation states to the searching light <strong>of</strong><br />

historians and other stu<strong>de</strong>nts <strong>of</strong> the field. Moreover, as the European Union is becoming<br />

a political entity with strong <strong>de</strong>mocratic and social institutions also supranational<br />

Europe itself will require such a critical <strong>history</strong> with an interpretative<br />

framework broa<strong>de</strong>r than that <strong>of</strong> the single nation state. It might well be difficult to<br />

say what conclusions the European Convent will arrive at, but it is a reasonably fair<br />

guess that the proceedings will be wordy and that they will focus on the <strong>de</strong>mocratic<br />

institutions. And <strong>de</strong>mocracies – also supranational or fe<strong>de</strong>ral <strong>de</strong>mocracies – need<br />

their <strong>history</strong>.


11<br />

Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

Die geschichts- und wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Literatur, die auf die Kritik <strong>de</strong>utscher<br />

Neoliberaler an <strong>de</strong>n Formen <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Integration eingeht, beruht für<br />

die Zeit vor 1945 in erster Linie auf Röpkes Werk International Economic Dis<strong>integration</strong><br />

(1942). 1 Diese Abhandlung Röpkes fand bei frühen Vertretern <strong>de</strong>r europäischen<br />

Integration wie Walter Hallstein 2 beson<strong>de</strong>re Beachtung. Die historische Integrationsforschung<br />

hat die Stellungnahmen neoliberaler Wirtschaftswissenschafter<br />

zum Problem <strong>de</strong>r Schaffung einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration aus <strong>de</strong>r Zwischenkriegszeit<br />

und <strong>de</strong>n Jahren <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges bisher kaum berücksichtigt. 3 Nach<strong>de</strong>m<br />

wirtschaftswissenschaftliche Schriften aus Walter Lipgens‘ Quellensammlung<br />

Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationspläne <strong>de</strong>r Wi<strong>de</strong>rstandsbewegungen 1940–1945 ausdrücklich<br />

ausgeklammert wor<strong>de</strong>n sind, ist eine Auswahl zentraler Texte neoliberaler Ökonomen<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Jahre 1939-45 in die Documents on the History <strong>of</strong> European Integration<br />

(1985/86) aufgenommen wor<strong>de</strong>n. Die in <strong>de</strong>n Documents aufgeführten Quellen,<br />

ergänzt um weitere neoliberale Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsentwürfe <strong>de</strong>r Jahre 1918-39 sowie <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Jahre 1939-45, erlauben es, die Frage zu behan<strong>de</strong>ln, ob von spezifisch „neoliberal“<br />

geprägten Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepten gesprochen wer<strong>de</strong>n kann. In <strong>de</strong>r vorliegen<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Studie wer<strong>de</strong>n die Beson<strong>de</strong>rheiten <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Neuordnungsi<strong>de</strong>en<br />

zwischen 1918 und 1945 herausgearbeitet und im Kontext <strong>de</strong>r sich über die nationalen<br />

Grenzen hinweg formieren<strong>de</strong>n Ban<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Wirtschaftswissenschafter<br />

untersucht.<br />

Die Neoliberalen wer<strong>de</strong>n nach 1945 in <strong>de</strong>r Literatur als Integrationsskeptiker wahrgenommen.<br />

Für die Mehrheit <strong>de</strong>r Neoliberalen als internationale Forschungsgemeinschaft<br />

trifft diese Beobachtung zu. Im Gegensatz zur Mehrheit <strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>utschen Neoliberalen<br />

– darunter Röpke – begrüßte jedoch die Mehrheit <strong>de</strong>r italienischen und <strong>de</strong>r<br />

französischen Neoliberalen – darunter Rueff, Villey, Allais und Hornbostel – die<br />

EWG-Integration, weil sie ihr einen liberalisieren<strong>de</strong>n Einfluß auf die Mitgliedstaaten<br />

zuerkannten. Unter <strong>de</strong>n Mitglie<strong>de</strong>rn <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Gesellschaft Mont Pèlerin Society<br />

trat Allais nach 1945 in verschie<strong>de</strong>nen europäischen Organisationen am aktivsten auf:<br />

1. A.J. NICHOLLS, Freedom with Responsibility, Oxford, 1994; H. PEUKERT, Das sozialökonomische<br />

Werk Wilhelm Röpkes, Frankfurt/M., 1992; J. STOHLER, Neoliberalismus und europäische<br />

Integration, in: Europa-Archiv, 17(1962), S.99 ff.; H.J. KÜSTERS, Die Gründung <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen<br />

Wirtschaftsgemeinschaft, Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, 1982; L. HERBST, Die zeitgenössische Integrationstheorie<br />

und die Anfänge <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Einigung 1947-1950, in: Vierteljahreshefte für<br />

Zeitschichte, 34(1986), S.161 ff.<br />

2. Sekretariat für Fragen <strong>de</strong>s Schuman-Plans, PAAA, B 15, Marchtaler, 5.7.1950, S.115.<br />

3. Vereinzelt sind Hinweise auf neoliberale Wirtschaftswissenschafter in <strong>de</strong>n folgen<strong>de</strong>n Beiträgen erfolgt:<br />

J. PINDER, British Fe<strong>de</strong>ralists 1940-1947, From Movement to Stasis, in: M. DUMOULIN (Hrsg.),<br />

Plans <strong>de</strong>s temps <strong>de</strong> guerre pour l’Europe d’après-guerre 1940-1947, Actes du Colloque <strong>de</strong> Bruxelles<br />

12-14 mai 1993, Groupe <strong>de</strong> liaison <strong>de</strong>s historiens auprès <strong>de</strong>s Communautés, Brüssel-Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n,<br />

1995, S.247-274. L. JÍLEK, L’Union Européenne à Bâle entre 1938 et 1946, Pôle helvétique et versant<br />

mondial dans les projets d’une association européaniste, in: M. DUMOULIN (Hrsg.), op.cit., S.277.


12<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

Er hatte seit <strong>de</strong>r Befreiung Frankreichs in die Debatte zur europäischen Frage eingegriffen<br />

und wur<strong>de</strong> dann Mitglied <strong>de</strong>r En<strong>de</strong> 1946 bzw. anfangs 1947 gegrün<strong>de</strong>ten Vereine<br />

Union européenne <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes (UEF) und Ligue Indépen<strong>de</strong>nte européenne <strong>de</strong><br />

Coopération économique (Conseil français). Er gehörte ebenfalls <strong>de</strong>m Conseil français<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Mouvement européen an. Allais veröffentlichte seit 1945 zahlreiche Artikel über ein<br />

Vereinigtes Europa und nahm als Referent am Ersten Kongreß <strong>de</strong>r UEF in Montreux<br />

(27. bis 30.8.1947), – gemeinsam mit Rueff 4 – am Haager Europa-Kongreß (7. bis<br />

10.5.1948) und am Congrès International d’Etu<strong>de</strong>s sur la Communauté européenne du<br />

Charbon et <strong>de</strong> l’Acier in Stresa (Juni 1957) teil. 5 Villey unterbrach seine Lehrtätigkeit<br />

als Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaftswissenschaften an <strong>de</strong>r Universität Poitiers nach <strong>de</strong>m Krieg<br />

für ein Jahr, um für das Projekt einer europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration zu arbeiten. 6 Rueff war<br />

1952-1958 prési<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong> chambre am Gerichtsh<strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>r Montanunion und 1958-1962<br />

Richter und prési<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong> chambre am Gerichtsh<strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Gemeinschaften.<br />

Im September 1958 wur<strong>de</strong> er zum Präsi<strong>de</strong>nten <strong>de</strong>s Comité d’Experts pour la Réforme<br />

Economique et Financière ernannt, das unter <strong>de</strong>m Druck <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Zahlungsunion<br />

und <strong>de</strong>s EWG-Vertrags die Konvertibilität <strong>de</strong>s Franc vorbereitete. Die Wirtschafts-<br />

und Währungsreform von Pinay/Rueff schuf die wirtschaftlichen Grundlagen<br />

<strong>de</strong>r V. Republik. Nach<strong>de</strong>m er seit 1958 mit <strong>de</strong> Gaulle eng zusammengearbeitet hatte, 7<br />

wur<strong>de</strong> Rueff in <strong>de</strong>r V. Republik <strong>de</strong>ssen Finanzberater.<br />

Die ursprünglichen Protagonisten einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration, Röpke, von Hayek und<br />

Robbins, wandten sich jedoch nach <strong>de</strong>m Beginn <strong>de</strong>s Kalten Krieges von <strong>de</strong>n Bestrebungen<br />

zur Schaffung einer europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration ab. Die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten hatten<br />

bis zum En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges die I<strong>de</strong>e einer institutionell abgesicherten „liberalen<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration“ von Staaten als wünschenswerte Alternative zur sozialistischen internationalen<br />

Planung und zu einem sozialistischen europäischen Einheitsstaat vertreten. Sie gingen<br />

dabei von einem engen Zuordnungsverhältnis <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaftsformen und <strong>de</strong>r<br />

politischen Strukturen aus: Marktwirtschaft, nationaler/internationaler Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus und<br />

Weltwirtschaft wür<strong>de</strong>n sich gegenseitig entsprechen. Der Verwirklichung einer solchen<br />

„liberalen Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration“ stan<strong>de</strong>n in <strong>de</strong>n Nachkriegsjahren und nach <strong>de</strong>m Beginn <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Kalten Krieges politische und wirtschaftliche Entwicklungen entgegen, die mit <strong>de</strong>n Voraussetzungen<br />

<strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Europafö<strong>de</strong>rations-Mo<strong>de</strong>lle in Wi<strong>de</strong>rspruch stan<strong>de</strong>n: In <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Mehrzahl <strong>de</strong>r wirtschaftlich führen<strong>de</strong>n Staaten wur<strong>de</strong> die Wirtschaftsplanung in <strong>de</strong>n<br />

Nachkriegsjahren fortgesetzt. Eine europäische Fö<strong>de</strong>ration konnte unter diesen Umstän<strong>de</strong>n<br />

nicht mehr als die „Erfüllung <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Wirtschaftsprogramms“ (von Hayek 1939)<br />

betrachtet wer<strong>de</strong>n. Die Liberalisierung <strong>de</strong>s Außenhan<strong>de</strong>ls verzögerte sich; erst dreizehn-<br />

4. J. RUEFF, Œuvres complètes 1, Paris, 1977, S.225.<br />

5. M. ALLAIS, Erreurs et Impasses <strong>de</strong> la Construction Européenne, Paris, 1992, Anm.2, S.101.<br />

6. Mme Villey, Wortbeitrag an <strong>de</strong>r Versammlung <strong>de</strong>r Mont Pèlerin Society, Caracas, 5.-13.9.1969,<br />

Summary. Typoskript, S.3, Nachlaß Pierre Goodrich: Box 2, Hoover Institution Archives, Stanford<br />

University, CA, USA. Vgl. auch D. VILLEY, Re<strong>de</strong>venir <strong>de</strong>s hommes libres, Paris, 1946,<br />

S.205 ff., S.291.<br />

7. M. VAÏSSE, La gran<strong>de</strong>ur. Politique étrangère du général <strong>de</strong> Gaulle, 1958-1969, Paris, 1998, S.42,<br />

S.167, Anm.9.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 13<br />

einhalb Jahre nach <strong>de</strong>m Kriegsen<strong>de</strong> (27.12.1958) wur<strong>de</strong> die äußere Konvertibilität <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Währungen aller westeuropäischen Staaten wie<strong>de</strong>rhergestellt.<br />

Die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte von 1918 bis 1945 sind aus <strong>de</strong>r aka<strong>de</strong>mischen<br />

Auseinan<strong>de</strong>rsetzung von Theoretikern <strong>de</strong>r Finanz-, Außenwirtschafts- und <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaftsordnungspolitik<br />

hervorgegangen. Robbins (1898-1984) lehrte abwechslungsweise<br />

in Oxford (1924; 1927-29) und an <strong>de</strong>r London School <strong>of</strong> Economics (1925-27), bis er<br />

1929 <strong>de</strong>finitiv in London blieb. Von Hayek (Wien, 1899 – Freiburg i. Br., 1992) war seit<br />

1931 ebenfalls an <strong>de</strong>r London School <strong>of</strong> Economics tätig. Röpke (1899-1966) fand nach<br />

einer etappenreichen Dozentenkarriere – 1924-28 außeror<strong>de</strong>ntlicher Pr<strong>of</strong>essor Universität<br />

Jena, 1927-28 USA, 1928-29 Universität Graz, 1929-31 Universität Marburg a. L.,<br />

1933-37 Universität Istanbul – 1937 seinen endgültigen Platz am Institut Universitaire <strong>de</strong><br />

Hautes Etu<strong>de</strong>s Internationales (Genf). Einaudi (1874-1961) lehrte ab 1898 an <strong>de</strong>r Universität<br />

Turin Finanzwissenschaft, bis er En<strong>de</strong> September 1943 ins Schweizer Exil gehen<br />

mußte. 1944 folgte er einer Einladung, für die italienischen Stu<strong>de</strong>nten in einem Genfer<br />

Flüchtlingslager einen Kurs zu halten, <strong>de</strong>r später unter <strong>de</strong>m Titel Lezioni di politica<br />

sociale veröffentlicht wur<strong>de</strong>. Am 9.12.1944 wur<strong>de</strong> Einaudi nach Italien zurückberufen,<br />

als Präsi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong>r Banca d’Italia. Rueff (1896-1978), aus einer angesehenen jüdischen<br />

Familie stammend, lehrte 1923-30 am Institut <strong>de</strong> Statistique <strong>de</strong> l’Université <strong>de</strong> Paris und<br />

wur<strong>de</strong> 1933 Titularpr<strong>of</strong>essor an <strong>de</strong>r Ecole libre <strong>de</strong>s sciences politiques (Paris). Baudin<br />

(1887-1964) lehrte seit <strong>de</strong>n 20er Jahren an <strong>de</strong>r Faculté <strong>de</strong> Droit <strong>de</strong> Paris et <strong>de</strong> Dijon und<br />

an <strong>de</strong>r Ecole <strong>de</strong>s Hautes Etu<strong>de</strong>s Commerciales, Paris.<br />

Die genannten neoliberalen Wirtschaftswissenschafter übten teils bereits im hier<br />

untersuchten Zeitraum (1918-45), teils nach 1945 Tätigkeiten in Verwaltung und<br />

Politik aus: Robbins wirkte bei <strong>de</strong>r Demobilisierung nach <strong>de</strong>m Ersten Weltkrieg in<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Verwaltung mit und leitete 1941-45 die Wirtschaftsabteilung <strong>de</strong>s Sekretariats <strong>de</strong>s<br />

britischen Kriegskabinetts. Mit Keynes zusammen vertrat er Großbritannien auf verschie<strong>de</strong>nen<br />

internationalen Konferenzen, die sich mit <strong>de</strong>n wirtschaftlichen Nachkriegsproblemen<br />

beschäftigten, so etwa auf <strong>de</strong>r Konferenz von Bretton Woods. Von<br />

Hayek gewann erst unter <strong>de</strong>r Regierung Thatcher politischen Einfluß. Röpke, <strong>de</strong>r<br />

1930-31 Mitglied <strong>de</strong>r Reichskommission zur Krisenbekämpfung (Brauns-Kommission)<br />

war, mußte 1933 aus politischen Grün<strong>de</strong>n nach Istanbul emigrieren. Erst nach<br />

<strong>de</strong>m Krieg konnte er immer wie<strong>de</strong>r formell und informell die Beratung von Bun<strong>de</strong>swirtschaftsminister<br />

Erhard wahrnehmen. Einaudi wur<strong>de</strong> 1919 zum Senator gewählt.<br />

1945 hatte er das Präsidium <strong>de</strong>r Bank von Italien inne. 1947 übte Einaudi das Amt<br />

<strong>de</strong>s stellvertreten<strong>de</strong>n Ministerpräsi<strong>de</strong>nten und Budgetministers im Kabinett De Gasperi<br />

aus. In <strong>de</strong>n Jahren 1948 bis 1955 vertrat er Italien als erster Präsi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong>r Republik.<br />

Zusammen mit <strong>de</strong>m neoliberalen Philosophen Croce gehörte Einaudi zu <strong>de</strong>n<br />

Mitbegrün<strong>de</strong>rn <strong>de</strong>r Liberalen Partei Italiens. Neben seiner wissenschaftlichen Tätigkeit<br />

verfolgte Rueff über mehr als dreissig Jahre eine Karriere als hoher Beamter:<br />

1926 war er „chargé <strong>de</strong> mission“ im Kabinett Poincaré. Um 1927 wur<strong>de</strong> er in die<br />

Wirtschafts- und Finanzsektion <strong>de</strong>s Völkerbundssekretariats gewählt. Von 1939 bis<br />

zur <strong>de</strong>utschen Besetzung Frankreichs diente er als sous-gouverneur <strong>de</strong>r Banque <strong>de</strong><br />

France. 1944 wur<strong>de</strong> Rueff zum Präsi<strong>de</strong>nten <strong>de</strong>r Délégation économique et financière<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Mission militaire pour les Affaires alleman<strong>de</strong>s et autrichiennes ernannt. 1945 war


14<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

er als Wirtschaftsberater <strong>de</strong>s Obersten Kommandieren<strong>de</strong>n über Deutschland tätig,<br />

vertrat Frankreich als Delegierter bei <strong>de</strong>r Reparationskommission in Moskau und saß<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Pariser Reparationen-Konferenz vor. 1946 war Rueff Delegierter an <strong>de</strong>r Pariser<br />

Frie<strong>de</strong>nskonferenz und stellvertreten<strong>de</strong>r Delegierter in <strong>de</strong>r ersten und zweiten Versammlung<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Vereinten Nationen. 1946 (bis 1952) wur<strong>de</strong> Rueff zum französischen<br />

Gesandten in <strong>de</strong>r Agence interalliée <strong>de</strong>s Réparations ernannt und führte <strong>de</strong>ssen Präsidium.<br />

In diesen Jahren nahm er als französischer Kommissar in <strong>de</strong>r Commission tripartite<br />

<strong>de</strong> l'or monétaire Einsitz. 1949-50 war Rueff Staatsminister von Monaco. Wie<br />

Rueff war auch Baudin für <strong>de</strong>n Völkerbund tätig: als französischer Experte im<br />

Comité fiscal (1938). Die damals noch relativ jungen neoliberalen Wirtschaftswissenschafter<br />

vermochten zwischen 1918-45 die Wirtschafts- und Gesellschaftsordnung in<br />

keinem einzigen Staat auch nur ansatzweise in ihrem Sinne zu reformieren,<br />

geschweige <strong>de</strong>nn die I<strong>de</strong>e einer liberalen Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration in die Diskussion <strong>de</strong>r<br />

politischen Entscheidungsträger einzubringen. Nach 1945 jedoch übten Neoliberale<br />

in mehreren europäischen Staaten – West<strong>de</strong>utschland, Frankreich, Italien, Österreich,<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Schweiz – und in <strong>de</strong>n USA Beratertätigkeiten und politische Ämter aus, die in<br />

gewissen Grenzen Möglichkeiten zur Umsetzung <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Prinzipien boten.<br />

Die Beschäftigung mit Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepten im Zeichen <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Internationalismus<br />

1918-45 zeigt, daß sich die Kritik <strong>de</strong>utscher und britischer neoliberaler<br />

Nationalökonomen an <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Integration seit <strong>de</strong>n späteren 40er Jahren<br />

auf jahrelange Studien auf diesem Gebiet stützte, auch wenn ihre Stellungnahmen<br />

in <strong>de</strong>r Folge <strong>de</strong>r verän<strong>de</strong>rten politischen Bedingungen nach 1945 Akzentverschiebungen<br />

erfuhren. Der Vorwurf <strong>de</strong>s Dogmatismus in <strong>de</strong>r Haltung neoliberaler Wirtschaftswissenschafter<br />

gegenüber <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Einigung, von <strong>de</strong>r zeitgenössischen<br />

Rezeption wie <strong>de</strong>r späteren Forschung vielfach erhoben, 8 erscheint in<br />

Anbetracht <strong>de</strong>s Meinungswan<strong>de</strong>ls gera<strong>de</strong> von neoliberalen Hauptexponenten <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte (Robbins, von Hayek, Röpke) als wenig angebracht.<br />

Das Urteil Herbsts, die liberalen Integrationstheoretiker hätten bis zum En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Zweiten Weltkrieges kein Konzept entwickelt, das <strong>de</strong>n regionalen Re<strong>integration</strong>sinteressen<br />

<strong>de</strong>s europäischen Raums und <strong>de</strong>m Deutschlandproblem Rechnung getragen<br />

hätte, 9 wäre zu korrigieren, da sich Röpke in dieser Zeit <strong>de</strong>n Voraussetzungen<br />

und Prinzipien eines fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Zusammenschlusses zugewandt hat und Einaudi,<br />

Robbins und von Hayek konkrete und <strong>de</strong>taillierte Konzepte für die Errichtung einer<br />

Europafö<strong>de</strong>ration erstellt haben. Der vorliegen<strong>de</strong> Beitrag ist als i<strong>de</strong>engeschichtliche<br />

Arbeit zu verstehen. Die Frage nach <strong>de</strong>m Umsetzungspotential <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen<br />

Europavorstellungen bedürfte eigener Forschungen. 10<br />

Nach einer Einführung zum frühen Neoliberalismus wer<strong>de</strong>n die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte<br />

1918-1939 bzw. 1939-1945 geson<strong>de</strong>rt behan<strong>de</strong>lt. In <strong>de</strong>r Phase<br />

1939-1945 sind wesentliche Verän<strong>de</strong>rungen in <strong>de</strong>r Begründung <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte<br />

zu beobachten. Mit <strong>de</strong>m Kalten Krieg begann eine dritte Phase, die bei<br />

8. J. STOHLER, op.cit., S.99.<br />

9. L. HERBST, op.cit., S.182.<br />

10. M. WEGMANN, Früher Neoliberalismus und europäische Integration, Bd. 2, Von <strong>de</strong>n Wirtschaftswissenschaften<br />

zur Politik, in Vorbereitung.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 15<br />

wichtigen Exponenten <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten – darunter Robbins, von Hayek<br />

und Röpke – zu einer Neubeurteilung <strong>de</strong>r Europa<strong>integration</strong> führte. Im Kapitel 2 wer<strong>de</strong>n<br />

die Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte Einaudis, Rueffs, Röpkes, Robbins' und von Hayeks von<br />

1918-39 vergleichend untersucht, in<strong>de</strong>m (2.1) ihre räumliche Gestalt behan<strong>de</strong>lt und<br />

i<strong>de</strong>en- und wissenschaftsgeschichtliche Bezüge zu Cob<strong>de</strong>ns kosmopolitischer Theorie<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Freihan<strong>de</strong>ls und seiner Völkerbundskonzeption einerseits und zu Lists Zollunionsmo<strong>de</strong>ll<br />

an<strong>de</strong>rerseits erörtert wer<strong>de</strong>n. Die bei<strong>de</strong>n genannten Aspekte führen zur Frage<br />

nach <strong>de</strong>r Be<strong>de</strong>utung <strong>de</strong>r Nation und <strong>de</strong>r Einschätzung <strong>de</strong>s Nationalismus im Hinblick<br />

auf die Revision <strong>de</strong>s Liberalismus (2.2). Von da aus gilt es, die Teilung <strong>de</strong>r Souveränität<br />

zwischen <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration und <strong>de</strong>n Mitgliedstaaten nach <strong>de</strong>n Konzeptionen Einaudis,<br />

Robbins' und von Hayeks zu klären und die Rolle <strong>de</strong>r Staatssouveränität zu erörtern<br />

(2.3). Die Neoliberalen erachteten die rechtliche, wirtschaftliche, gesellschaftliche und<br />

politische Ordnung eines Staates als „inter<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt“. Unter 2.4 ist zu untersuchen,<br />

welche Konsequenzen die Neoliberalen aus ihrer For<strong>de</strong>rung nach einer rechtlich-wirtschaftlichen<br />

bzw. gesellschaftlich-politischen „Gesamtordnung“ für die Schaffung<br />

einer internationalen Ordnung und einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration zogen. Im Kapitel 3 wer<strong>de</strong>n<br />

die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsentwürfe während <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges untersucht,<br />

in<strong>de</strong>m sie mit ihren früheren Arbeiten verglichen wer<strong>de</strong>n. Die Aufmerksamkeit gilt<br />

(3.1) <strong>de</strong>m Zusammenhang zwischen <strong>de</strong>n Wirtschaftsformen und <strong>de</strong>n politischen Strukturen<br />

einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration, (3.2) <strong>de</strong>r Frage nach <strong>de</strong>m gesellschaftlichen und kulturellen<br />

Europabild, (3.3) <strong>de</strong>r Rolle <strong>de</strong>r Staatssouveränität und <strong>de</strong>r Einschätzung <strong>de</strong>s Nationalismus<br />

in <strong>de</strong>n Schriften <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten. Anschließend wer<strong>de</strong>n unter 4<br />

die Beson<strong>de</strong>rheiten <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationkonzepte hervorgehoben und die Frage<br />

beantwortet, inwieweit sie sich unter die Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsschriften <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Wi<strong>de</strong>rstandsbewegungen<br />

einordnen lassen. In <strong>de</strong>r Zusammenfassung wer<strong>de</strong>n die wesentlichen<br />

Merkmale <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsentwürfe 1918-1945 hervorgehoben. 11<br />

1. Der frühe Neoliberalismus – ein positives Konzept für eine freiheitliche und<br />

sozial bewußte Wettbewerbswirtschaft<br />

„Neoliberalismus“ bezeichnet zum einen eine wirtschafts- und gesellschaftspolitische<br />

Konzeption und zum an<strong>de</strong>ren ein System von Personen, die durch <strong>de</strong>n Transfer von I<strong>de</strong>en<br />

miteinan<strong>de</strong>r verbun<strong>de</strong>n sind. Der Begriff „Neoliberale“ ist als Selbstbezeichnung erstmals<br />

im Colloque Walter Lippmann En<strong>de</strong> August 1938 in Paris belegt. Alexan<strong>de</strong>r Rüstow hat<br />

ihn dort als Selbstbezeichnung vorgeschlagen, nach<strong>de</strong>m er selbst schon im Herbst 1932<br />

im Verein für Socialpolitik vom „neue[n] Liberalismus“ gesprochen hatte, <strong>de</strong>n er „mit<br />

[s]einen Freun<strong>de</strong>n“ vertrete. 12 In <strong>de</strong>r griechisch-neulateinischen Form geht <strong>de</strong>r Theoriebe-<br />

11. Ausführlicher und weitere Belege vgl. M. WEGMANN, Früher Neoliberalismus und europäische<br />

Integration. Inter<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nz <strong>de</strong>r nationalen, supranationalen und internationalen Ordnung von<br />

Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft (1932-1965), Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, 2002.<br />

12. A. RÜSTOW, Diskussionsbeitrag. Verhandlungen <strong>de</strong>s Vereins für Socialpolitik, Dres<strong>de</strong>n,<br />

28.-29.9.1932, in: Schriften <strong>de</strong>s Vereins für Socialpolitik, 187(1932), S.69.


16<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

griff „Neoliberalismus“ jedoch nicht auf Rüstow zurück. Lavergne hatte <strong>de</strong>n Theoriebegriff<br />

„néo-libéralisme“ schon ein Vierteljahr vor <strong>de</strong>m Colloque Walter Lippmann in seiner<br />

Monographie Essor et déca<strong>de</strong>nce du Capitalisme eingeführt. 13<br />

Der Neoliberalismus entstand aus <strong>de</strong>m Bewußtsein einer tiefen Krise nicht nur<br />

<strong>de</strong>s wirtschaftlichen, son<strong>de</strong>rn auch <strong>de</strong>s gesellschaftlichen Lebens und <strong>de</strong>r tradierten<br />

bürgerlichen Wertvorstellungen in <strong>de</strong>r Zwischenkriegszeit. Der Neoliberalismus,<br />

<strong>de</strong>r sich 1938 in Paris als internationale Forschungsgemeinschaft mit eigenem<br />

Institut formierte, ist <strong>de</strong>n liberalen wirtschaftspolitischen Erneuerungsbestrebungen<br />

zuzuordnen, die in <strong>de</strong>r Folge <strong>de</strong>r großen Depression von 1872-1890 in <strong>de</strong>n westund<br />

mitteleuropäischen Staaten sowie <strong>de</strong>n USA zu beobachten waren. Anlaß zu<br />

<strong>de</strong>n wirtschaftspolitischen Erneuerungsbestrebungen seit etwa 1880 war die<br />

Ernüchterung über die wirtschaftlichen und sozialpolitischen Konsequenzen <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Wirtschaftsliberalismus. Auf <strong>de</strong>r inhaltlichen Ebene jedoch stellte <strong>de</strong>r Neoliberalismus<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Zwischenkriegszeit und <strong>de</strong>r zweiten Nachkriegszeit keine unmittelbare<br />

Fortsetzung einer <strong>de</strong>r früheren liberalen Erneuerungsbewegungen dar. Für die<br />

Zuordnung zu <strong>de</strong>n Neoliberalen ist in <strong>de</strong>r vorliegen<strong>de</strong>n Arbeit die Selbstbezeichnung<br />

<strong>de</strong>r liberalen Wirtschaftswissenschafter, Juristen, Politiker und Philosophen<br />

als „Neoliberale“ und ihre gegenseitige Anerkennung <strong>de</strong>r Zugehörigkeit zu diesem<br />

Kreis maßgebend. Rueff und Baudin (F), Einaudi (I), <strong>de</strong> Madariaga (E), Robbins<br />

(GB), Condliffe (GB), <strong>de</strong>r Wahlbrite von Hayek, von Mises (A), von Haberler (A<br />

bzw. USA), Heilperin (USA), Rappard (CH) und die bei<strong>de</strong>n Deutschen Röpke und<br />

Rüstow erfüllen diese Kriterien.<br />

Die Anfänge <strong>de</strong>s Neoliberalismus waren polyzentrisch: Seit <strong>de</strong>n frühen 20er<br />

Jahren hatten Liberale in verschie<strong>de</strong>nen Staaten – Großbritannien, Österreich, Italien,<br />

Frankreich, Deutschland, USA, Schweiz – ähnliche, ja weitgehend übereinstimmen<strong>de</strong><br />

Ansätze zur Reformierung <strong>de</strong>s Liberalismus entwickelt. Seit 1935 ist<br />

ein enges Beziehungsgeflecht <strong>de</strong>r später sogenannten Neoliberalen über die Staatsgrenzen<br />

und Kontinente hinweg nachzuweisen. Auf Initiative <strong>de</strong>s Pariser Philosophen<br />

Rougier traten die europäischen und US-amerikanischen Neoliberalen in<br />

Paris im Sommer 1938 zu ihrem ersten internationalen Kolloquium zusammen und<br />

grün<strong>de</strong>ten im Frühjahr 1939 ein eigenes Forschungsinstitut, das Centre international<br />

pour la Rénovation du Libéralisme (Paris), <strong>de</strong>ssen Tätigkeiten aber infolge <strong>de</strong>r<br />

nationalsozialistischen Besetzung von Paris eingestellt wer<strong>de</strong>n mußten. Schon<br />

1944 bereitete von Hayek die Neugründung einer internationalen Vereinigung <strong>de</strong>r<br />

13. In <strong>de</strong>r Neoliberalismus-Literatur wird im allgemeinen das Colloque Lippmann als „Geburtsstun<strong>de</strong>“<br />

<strong>de</strong>s griechisch-neulateinischen Theoriebegriffs „Neoliberalismus“ angenommen. G. EISER-<br />

MANN, Alexan<strong>de</strong>r Rüstow, Persönlichkeit und Werk, in: Wirtschaftsordnung und Menschenbild.<br />

Schriftenreihe <strong>de</strong>r Aktionsgemeinschaft Soziale Marktwirtschaft, Heft 4, Köln, 1960, S.149; B.<br />

LAVERGNE, Essor et déca<strong>de</strong>nce du Capitalisme, Paris, 1938, S.172, Anm.1. Das Vorwort <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Ban<strong>de</strong>s ist auf <strong>de</strong>n 20. April 1938, also vor <strong>de</strong>m Colloque Lippmann, datiert. Nach <strong>de</strong>r Eintragung<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Druckerei Dardaillon et Dagniaux (St. Denis) ist das Buch im April 1938 gedruckt wor<strong>de</strong>n.<br />

Lavergnes Monographie war <strong>de</strong>n Kolloquiums-Teilnehmern bekannt. Sie ist im Vorwort <strong>de</strong>r im<br />

Juni 1939 gedruckten Akten zitiert, allerdings unter ungenauer Wie<strong>de</strong>rgabe <strong>de</strong>s Titels. L. ROU-<br />

GIER, Avant-propos, in: Compte-rendu <strong>de</strong>s séances du Colloque Walter Lippmann, Paris, 1939,<br />

S.7, Anm.1.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 17<br />

Neoliberalen vor. Im April 1947 entstand unter seinem Präsidium die Mont Pèlerin<br />

Society als geschlossene Gesellschaft neoliberaler Wirtschaftswissenschafter, Juristen<br />

und Philosophen.<br />

Alle oben erwähnten Wirtschaftswissenschafter und Philosophen traten dieser Gesellschaft<br />

bei. Die Neoliberalen bekannten sich zu einem positiven Konzept für eine freiheitliche<br />

und sozial bewußte Wettbewerbswirtschaft als Antwort auf die Krise <strong>de</strong>s laissez<br />

faire-Liberalismus. Sie konzentrierten sich darauf, die Prinzipien und Voraussetzungen<br />

einer liberalen Gesellschaftsordnung herauszuarbeiten, entwarfen aber kein politisches<br />

Programm im eigentlichen Sinne, <strong>de</strong>nn die Gesellschaft entzieht sich nach liberaler Auffassung<br />

jedwe<strong>de</strong>r Planung. Die Teilnehmer <strong>de</strong>s Colloque Walter Lippmann und die<br />

Hauptexponenten <strong>de</strong>r Mont Pèlerin Society waren von <strong>de</strong>r Überlegenheit einer freien<br />

Gesellschaft selbstbestimmter Individuen überzeugt und sahen ihre Aufgabe darin, die<br />

freie Gesellschaft gegen Angriffe philosophisch zu verteidigen. In <strong>de</strong>r freien Marktwirtschaft<br />

erkannten sie das gegenüber <strong>de</strong>m Kollektivismus o<strong>de</strong>r einer gemischten Wirtschaft<br />

überlegene System. Regierungsinterventionen in <strong>de</strong>n Markt-Preis-Mechanismus wie<br />

staatlich festgesetzte Min<strong>de</strong>stlöhne o<strong>de</strong>r die Subventionierung <strong>de</strong>r Landwirtschaft<br />

betrachteten sie als schädlich. Eine stabile monetäre Ordnung, beruhend auf liberalen<br />

Prinzipien, wäre die erste Voraussetzung <strong>de</strong>s liberalen internationalen Han<strong>de</strong>ls. Unumstritten<br />

war die For<strong>de</strong>rung nach einer liberalen Außenhan<strong>de</strong>lspolitik. Die Neoliberalen –<br />

darunter auch die frühen Chicago-Neoliberalen Knight, Simons und Friedman – wußten<br />

um die Möglichkeit eines Marktversagens und anerkannten die Notwendigkeit staatlichen<br />

Han<strong>de</strong>lns bei öffentlichen Gütern und externen Effekten. Der Gesellschaftsvertrag sollte<br />

nach <strong>de</strong>n Vorstellungen <strong>de</strong>s frühen Neoliberalismus (1932-1965) auf folgen<strong>de</strong>n Grundlagen<br />

beruhen: Stärkung <strong>de</strong>r Macht <strong>de</strong>s Staates zur Durchsetzung und Aufrechterhaltung<br />

<strong>de</strong>r liberalen Wirtschaftsordnung; Aufbau einer internationalen Rechtsordnung für <strong>de</strong>n<br />

internationalen Han<strong>de</strong>l; Stärkung intermediärer Strukturen (Familie, Vereine, Gemein<strong>de</strong>)<br />

auf sozialem und administrativem Gebiet; Stärkung <strong>de</strong>r individuellen Selbstverantwortung<br />

und Konzentration <strong>de</strong>s Staates auf die Fürsorge im eigentlichen Sinne; staatliche<br />

Rahmenpolitik und liberaler, d.h. marktkonformer Interventionismus; monetäre Stabilität,<br />

restriktive Geldpolitik; <strong>of</strong>fene Märkte; starker Staat in <strong>de</strong>r Rolle <strong>de</strong>s Schiedsrichters über<br />

<strong>de</strong>n wirtschaftlichen Interessengruppen; staatliches Han<strong>de</strong>ln bei Marktversagen; Dekonzentration<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaft, Dekartellierung; För<strong>de</strong>rung kleiner und mittlerer Unternehmen<br />

mittels Wettbewerbsrecht.<br />

Die von <strong>de</strong>n Neoliberalen konzipierte Wirtschaftsordnung zielte nicht auf die<br />

Schaffung einer staatsfreien Wirtschaft ab, son<strong>de</strong>rn setzte im Gegenteil <strong>de</strong>n Staat<br />

als Schiedsrichter ein, <strong>de</strong>r die rechtliche Rahmenordnung für das Wirtschaften festlegte<br />

und die Einhaltung <strong>de</strong>r „Spielregeln“ in <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaft überwachte. Da sich<br />

die Aufgaben <strong>de</strong>s neoliberalen „starken Staates“ nicht in <strong>de</strong>r Schaffung von Rahmenbedingungen<br />

<strong>de</strong>r äußeren Sicherheit erschöpften, son<strong>de</strong>rn sich auf die Gestaltung<br />

und Durchsetzung <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaftsordnung sowie auf marktkonforme Interventionen<br />

14 erstreckten, reichten sie über die Aufgaben <strong>de</strong>s „Nachtwächterstaates“<br />

14. Vgl. die „Maximen rationeller Intervention”: W. RÖPKE, Staatsinterventionismus, in: Handwörterbuch<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Staatswissenschaften, Ergänzungsband zur 4. Auflage, Jena, 1929, S.861-882.


18<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Freihändler <strong>de</strong>s 19. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rts hinaus. Diese Feststellung gilt für <strong>de</strong>n<br />

US-amerikanischen Neoliberalismus und insbeson<strong>de</strong>re die frühe Chicago-Gruppe<br />

(d.h. bis 1965) gleichermaßen wie für <strong>de</strong>n europäischen Neoliberalismus. 15<br />

2. Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte im Zeichen <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Internationalismus: vom<br />

En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s Ersten bis zum Ausbruch <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges<br />

2.1. Zwischen Europafö<strong>de</strong>ration und Weltfö<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

Einaudi verfocht in zwei Briefen im Corriere <strong>de</strong>lla Sera vom 5. Januar 1918 und<br />

vom 28. Dezember 1918 die I<strong>de</strong>e, statt <strong>de</strong>s Völkerbun<strong>de</strong>s eine Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration 16<br />

zu grün<strong>de</strong>n. Rueff schlug En<strong>de</strong> 1928, anfangs 1929 vor, die Mitglie<strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>s Völkerbun<strong>de</strong>s<br />

sollten einen „gemeinsamen Markt“ mit einer liberalen Zollpolitik errichten,<br />

<strong>de</strong>r allen beitrittswilligen Staaten <strong>of</strong>fenstehen wür<strong>de</strong>. 17 Röpke sprach sich in<br />

einem Brief an Franz Klein (18.5.1939) dafür aus, in Anbetracht <strong>de</strong>s „trockenen<br />

Krieges“ zwischen <strong>de</strong>n Achsen- und <strong>de</strong>n Status-quo-Mächten „an die Stelle <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Völkerbun<strong>de</strong>s ein europäisches Fö<strong>de</strong>rativsystem“ zu setzen. 18 Robbins entwarf in<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Ausarbeitung seiner 1935 am Genfer Institut Universitaire <strong>de</strong>s Hautes Etu<strong>de</strong>s<br />

Internationales gehaltenen Vorlesungsreihe Economic Planning and International<br />

Or<strong>de</strong>r eine „liberale Fö<strong>de</strong>ration” 19 von Staaten als die wünschenswerte Alternative<br />

zur sozialistischen internationalen Planung und zur internationalen Anarchie. Von<br />

Hayek schließlich trat in einem kurz vor Kriegsbeginn 1939 verfaßten Aufsatz entschie<strong>de</strong>n<br />

ein für die „I<strong>de</strong>e eines fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Zusammenschlusses als konsequent[er]<br />

Entwicklung <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Standpunktes“ und als „neuen Stützpunkt“ für alle diejenigen<br />

Liberalen, die sich vom Liberalismus enttäuscht abgewandt hatten. 20 Die<br />

15. Einzig von Mises vertrat in mancher Hinsicht Positionen, die an die alte Vorstellung <strong>de</strong>s Nachtwächterstaats<br />

erinnerten. Von Mises stand jedoch im Colloque Walter Lippmann und <strong>de</strong>r Mont<br />

Pèlerin Society mit seiner Haltung isoliert da und wur<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>shalb von <strong>de</strong>n Mitglie<strong>de</strong>rn <strong>de</strong>r Gesellschaft<br />

heftig angegriffen. Graham (US) hielt von Mises 1947 vor, einem „jungle”-Kapitalismus<br />

das Wort zu re<strong>de</strong>n. Das Protokoll zur Tagung Free Enterprise or Competitive Or<strong>de</strong>r im Rahmen<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Gründungskonferenz zeugt von <strong>de</strong>r geschlossenen Gegnerschaft <strong>de</strong>r an<strong>de</strong>ren Mitglie<strong>de</strong>r gegen<br />

von Mises‘ radikale Positionen. F.D. Graham, Wortbeitrag, Tagung Free Enterprise or Competitive<br />

Or<strong>de</strong>r, Mont Pèlerin Society Meeting Seelisberg, 1.4.1947, Gesprächsprotokolle, aufgezeichnet<br />

von D. Hahn, Typoskript, Teil 2, S.5, Nachlaß Friedrich A. von Hayek: Box 81, Hoover Institution<br />

Archives. Stanford University, CA, USA.<br />

16. L. EINAUDI, La Società <strong>de</strong>lle Nazioni è un i<strong>de</strong>ale possibile? in: L. EINAUDI (Hrsg.), La Guerra<br />

e l'Unità Europea, Milano, 1948, S.11 ff.; L. EINAUDI, Il dogma <strong>de</strong>lla sovranità e l'i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>de</strong>lla<br />

Società <strong>de</strong>lle Nazioni, in: op.cit., S.23 ff.<br />

17. J. RUEFF, Note sur un projet <strong>de</strong> „pacte économique“, Décembre 1928-mars 1929, in: J. RUEFF,<br />

op.cit., S.291 f.<br />

18. W. RÖPKE, Briefe 1934-1966, Erlenbach-Zürich, 1976, S.33.<br />

19. L. ROBBINS, Economic Planning and International Or<strong>de</strong>r (1937), New York, 1972, S.242 und 245.<br />

20. F.A. von HAYEK, Die wirtschaftlichen Voraussetzungen fö<strong>de</strong>rativer Zusammenschlüsse, in: F.A.<br />

von HAYEK (Hrsg.), Individualismus und wirtschaftliche Ordnung, Salzburg, 1976, S.343.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 19<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte <strong>de</strong>r liberalen Erneuerer waren teils in <strong>de</strong>r Erwartung, 21 teils in<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Folge <strong>de</strong>s Scheiterns <strong>de</strong>s Völkerbun<strong>de</strong>s entstan<strong>de</strong>n. Vorbehaltlos bekannte sich<br />

nur <strong>de</strong>r Neoliberale Rappard (1930) noch zum Völkerbund in seinem Werk Uniting<br />

Europe, 22 erwartete aber, daß in einem Prozeß zunehmen<strong>de</strong>r internationaler Verflechtung<br />

eine „Weltregierung“ <strong>de</strong>n Völkerbund ablösen wer<strong>de</strong>. 23<br />

Die räumliche Gestalt <strong>de</strong>r Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration wur<strong>de</strong> in <strong>de</strong>n erwähnten Texten nicht<br />

<strong>de</strong>finitiv bestimmt; Dem liberalen Kosmopolitismus entsprechend sahen Einaudi, 24<br />

Rueff, 25 Robbins 26 und von Hayek 27 die Möglichkeit vor, die Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsmitgliedschaft<br />

auch für die Vereinigten Staaten von Amerika zu öffnen. Die Grundsätze, die<br />

Robbins entwarf, bezogen sich auf die Schaffung einer Weltfö<strong>de</strong>ration, beanspruchten<br />

aber ebenso Gültigkeit für Fö<strong>de</strong>rationen, die kleiner wären als diese. 28 Die Frage, ob<br />

Deutschland schon zu Beginn in die Fö<strong>de</strong>ration aufgenommen wer<strong>de</strong>n sollte, erfuhr bei<br />

Einaudi wie bei Röpke eine zurückhalten<strong>de</strong> bzw. ablehnen<strong>de</strong> Antwort. Gegen En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Ersten Weltkrieges sah Einaudi im Fortbestehen <strong>de</strong>r Kriegsallianz <strong>de</strong>n Ausgangspunkt<br />

für eine europäische Fö<strong>de</strong>ration. Röpke bezog das „europäische Fö<strong>de</strong>rativsystem“ im<br />

Frühling 1939 auf diejenigen Staaten, die sich in <strong>de</strong>r Gegnerschaft gegen die Achsenmächte<br />

trafen und die I<strong>de</strong>ale <strong>de</strong>s Völkerbun<strong>de</strong>s hochhielten. Auf <strong>de</strong>n „Weltstaat“ griff<br />

Röpke jedoch in verschie<strong>de</strong>nen an<strong>de</strong>ren Arbeiten <strong>de</strong>r dreißiger Jahre als fiktives Vorbild<br />

zurück, um die Freihan<strong>de</strong>lstheorie im Sinne Cob<strong>de</strong>ns (1804-1865) zu erhellen. Das<br />

Währungssystem, das Rechtssystem und die <strong>de</strong>m Währungs- und <strong>de</strong>m Rechtssystem<br />

entsprechen<strong>de</strong>n Normensysteme waren in dieser Sicht die „Substitute <strong>de</strong>s Weltstaates“,<br />

welche die liberale Ära geschaffen hatte und nach <strong>de</strong>m Ersten Weltkrieg zusammengebrochen<br />

waren. 29 In seinem Beitrag L'internationalisme monétaire et sa crise schloß<br />

Heilperin in Anlehnung an Robbins auch Erwägungen über einen Weltstaat und eine<br />

die ganze Welt umfassen<strong>de</strong> Fö<strong>de</strong>ration von Staaten ein und stellte fest, daß sich die<br />

Frage <strong>de</strong>r internationalen Beziehungen in diesem Falle nicht stellen wür<strong>de</strong>, wären dann<br />

21. L. EINAUDI (1918)<br />

22. Der Titel dieses Buches lehnte sich an die Entwicklung an, in <strong>de</strong>ren Verlauf <strong>de</strong>r Völkerbund immer<br />

mehr, wenn auch nicht ausschließlich eine Liga europäischer Staaten wur<strong>de</strong>. W.E. RAPPARD,<br />

Uniting Europe, New Haven, 1930, S.138, 245 und 283. Rappard zog in seinem Aufsatz Europa<br />

und <strong>de</strong>r Völkerbund (1929) die Schlußfolgerung, nicht ein Bund <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Staaten, <strong>de</strong>r sich<br />

einer nichteuropäischen Welt gegenübersehen wür<strong>de</strong>, sei das I<strong>de</strong>al, son<strong>de</strong>rn ein einiges Europa als<br />

wesentlicher Bestandteil eines universellen Völkerbun<strong>de</strong>s. W.E. RAPPARD, Europa und <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Völkerbund, in: Europäische Gespräche, 7(1929), S.221.<br />

23. W.E. RAPPARD, The Beginnings <strong>of</strong> International Government, in: American Political Science<br />

Review, 24(1930), S.1011 f.<br />

24. L. EINAUDI, La Società <strong>de</strong>lle Nazioni è un i<strong>de</strong>ale possibile?, op.cit., S.11.<br />

25. J. RUEFF, Note sur un projet <strong>de</strong> „pacte économique“, op.cit., S.292.<br />

26. L. ROBBINS, Economic Planning …, op.cit., S.247.<br />

27. F.A. von HAYEK, Die wirtschaftlichen Voraussetzungen …, op.cit., S.332 f. und S.336. Vgl. auch<br />

Streits Konzeption einer „(nord-)atlantischen Union“, auf die sich von Hayeks Erörterungen beziehen:<br />

C. STREIT, Union Now: A Proposal for a Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union <strong>of</strong> the Democracies <strong>of</strong> the North<br />

Atlantic, New York, 1939, S.6.<br />

28. L. ROBBINS, Economic Planning …, op.cit., S.245-248 und 255.<br />

29. W. RÖPKE, Weltwirtschaft und internationales Rechtssystem, in: Frie<strong>de</strong>ns-Warte, 36(1936),<br />

S.102.


20<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

die Probleme zwischen <strong>de</strong>n Staaten doch nur auf diejenigen Bereiche beschränkt, in<br />

<strong>de</strong>nen die Staaten noch eigene Souveränitätsrechte besäßen. 30 Im Unterschied zu <strong>de</strong>n<br />

erwähnten Arbeiten Röpkes und Heilperins zog Robbins in seiner Studie von 1935/<br />

1937 <strong>de</strong>n imaginierten Weltstaat nicht nur im Sinne eines fiktiven Referenzrahmens<br />

heran, son<strong>de</strong>rn setzte sich mit seinen theoretischen Grundlagen und mit Alternativen zu<br />

einem <strong>de</strong>rartigen Gebil<strong>de</strong> systematisch auseinan<strong>de</strong>r. Ein vollkommen einheitlicher<br />

Weltstaat erwies sich in Robbins' Analyse als we<strong>de</strong>r realisierbar noch wünschenswert,<br />

da das liberale System nicht min<strong>de</strong>r als <strong>de</strong>r internationale Kommunismus an <strong>de</strong>n<br />

räumlichen Dimensionen, <strong>de</strong>n sprachlichen Voraussetzungen und <strong>de</strong>m mangelhaften<br />

Schutz <strong>de</strong>r Freiheit in einem Weltstaat scheitern müßte.<br />

Die Gedanken neoliberaler Wirtschaftswissenschafter über die Schaffung einer<br />

Europafö<strong>de</strong>ration und einer Weltfö<strong>de</strong>ration waren also in <strong>de</strong>r Zeit vom En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Ersten bis zum Beginn <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges miteinan<strong>de</strong>r verknüpft, wozu <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Völkerbund, sich zwischen <strong>de</strong>r theoretischen Universalität und <strong>de</strong>r Konzentration<br />

auf Europa befin<strong>de</strong>nd, wesentliche Denkanstöße gab.<br />

Die Diskussion um die Schaffung einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration trat anfangs <strong>de</strong>r dreißiger<br />

Jahre ins Spannungsfeld <strong>de</strong>r Kontroverse über Freihan<strong>de</strong>l und Protektionismus. Im<br />

Zusammenhang mit <strong>de</strong>m Fortschreiten <strong>de</strong>s Prozesses <strong>de</strong>r Integration <strong>de</strong>r Volkswirtschaften<br />

zu einer Weltwirtschaft folgte Röpke List, <strong>de</strong>r im Wachsen <strong>de</strong>s räumlichen Bereichs<br />

<strong>de</strong>r „wirtschaftlichen Integration“ (Röpke) Stufen eines einheitlichen Integrationsprozesses<br />

erblickte, <strong>de</strong>r auf eine min<strong>de</strong>stens ebenso enge Verbindung <strong>de</strong>r „zivilisiertesten Nationen<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Er<strong>de</strong>“ (List) hinauslaufen wür<strong>de</strong>, wie die Grafschaften im England <strong>de</strong>s 18. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rts<br />

es gewesen waren. 31 Daß <strong>de</strong>r wirtschaftliche Integrationsprozeß über die<br />

Staatsgrenzen hinwegschreite, nach<strong>de</strong>m er in <strong>de</strong>r Vergangenheit we<strong>de</strong>r an Stadt- noch<br />

Lan<strong>de</strong>sgrenzen haltgemacht hatte, entspricht nach Röpke <strong>de</strong>r „inneren Logik <strong>de</strong>r Entwicklung”.<br />

32 List (1789-1846) hatte die <strong>de</strong>utsche politische und wirtschaftliche Einigung<br />

nicht als Selbstzweck verfochten, son<strong>de</strong>rn als Voraussetzung einer kontinentaleuropäischen<br />

und dann einer universellen Union. 33 Gemäßigte Erziehungsschutzzölle wären als<br />

befristete Maßnahmen berechtigt, um die einzelnen Staaten wirtschaftlich so weit zu entwickeln,<br />

daß sie eine Union mit <strong>de</strong>n an<strong>de</strong>ren industrialisierten Staaten grün<strong>de</strong>n und zum<br />

Freihan<strong>de</strong>l übergehen könnten. 34 Trotz seiner Kritik an einzelnen Prämissen von Adam<br />

Smith‘ Kosmopolitismus war das Ziel Lists <strong>de</strong>r universelle Freihan<strong>de</strong>l und sein wirtschaftspolitisches<br />

Vorbild Großbritannien. 35 Diese Positionen Lists waren mit <strong>de</strong>r klassischen<br />

Lehre <strong>de</strong>r Nationalökonomie vereinbar, die später von J. St. Mill (1806-1873) und<br />

<strong>de</strong>n Neoliberalen vertreten wur<strong>de</strong>n. 36 Rüstow, Röpke, von Haberler, Rueff, Robbins und<br />

30. M.A. HEILPERIN, L'internationalisme monétaire et sa crise, in: P. MANTOUX (Hrsg.), La crise<br />

mondiale, Paris, 1938, S.363 f.<br />

31. F. LIST, Das nationale System <strong>de</strong>r Politischen Ökonomie, Jena, 1928, S.210; W. RÖPKE, Die säkulare<br />

Be<strong>de</strong>utung <strong>de</strong>r Weltkrisis, in: Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 37(1933), S.17.<br />

32. W. RÖPKE, op.cit., S.18 f.<br />

33. F. LIST, op.cit., S.60 ff., 213 f., 268, 526 ff. und 536 f.<br />

34. Ibid., S.213 f., 420 f., 431-434 und 540 f.<br />

35. Ibid., S.53 f. und 208-214.<br />

36. Ibid., S.204-220.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 21<br />

von Hayek räumten in <strong>de</strong>n 20er/30er Jahren Präferenzzöllen und Zollunionen eine positive<br />

Funktion als „Maßnahmen einer liberalen Han<strong>de</strong>lspolitik“ ein. 37 Gleichzeitig machten<br />

sie jedoch auf die Aufgabe aufmerksam, <strong>de</strong>n „partiellen Freihan<strong>de</strong>l“ trotz <strong>de</strong>s liberalen<br />

Gehalts seiner I<strong>de</strong>e vor <strong>de</strong>m Mißbrauch durch protektionistische Bestrebungen zu schützen.<br />

Unmittelbaren Anlaß zu dieser Befürchtung gaben die hochprotektionistischen Zölle<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Vereinigten Staaten von Amerika und das Beispiel <strong>de</strong>r „Empire Free Tra<strong>de</strong>”-Bewegung<br />

Lord Beaverbrooks, welche Präferenzzölle für die Dominions und gleichzeitig<br />

Schutzzölle für das Mutterland for<strong>de</strong>rte. Die – unter internationalem Blickwinkel – positiven<br />

Ansätze, die eine Zollunion rechtfertigten, führten gedanklich konsequenterweise zu<br />

einer die ganze Welt umspannen<strong>de</strong>n Zollunion.<br />

Zwischen <strong>de</strong>m Konzept einer Zollunion nach List und <strong>de</strong>m kosmopolitischen<br />

Freihan<strong>de</strong>l nach Cob<strong>de</strong>n bestand in <strong>de</strong>n während <strong>de</strong>r Zwischenkriegszeit verfaßten<br />

Schriften Röpkes, Rueffs, Robbins‘ und von Hayeks kein unüberbrückbarer<br />

Gegensatz. Die Überlegungen <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Wirtschaftswissenschafter zum Problem<br />

einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration schwankten vor <strong>de</strong>m Beginn <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges<br />

zwischen einer Fö<strong>de</strong>ration globalen und einer Fö<strong>de</strong>ration kontinentalen, europäischen<br />

Ausmaßes.<br />

2.2. Die For<strong>de</strong>rung <strong>de</strong>r liberalen Erneuerer nach Überwindung <strong>de</strong>s Nationalismus<br />

und Beschränkung <strong>de</strong>r nationalstaatlichen Souveränität<br />

Neoliberale wie Robbins, von Hayek, Einaudi, Rueff, Condliffe und Röpke erblickten<br />

im Nationalismus und Bellizismus nach <strong>de</strong>m Ersten Weltkrieg eine vitale<br />

Bedrohung <strong>de</strong>s Wirtschafts- und Sozialsystems, die daran war, die europäische<br />

Kultur zu zerstören, und for<strong>de</strong>rten die Überwindung <strong>de</strong>s Nationalismus, wenn nicht<br />

die „Abschaffung <strong>de</strong>s Nationalstaats“ (von Hayek). 38<br />

Einaudi unterschied zwei graduelle Formen <strong>de</strong>r Souveränität: die „vollkommene<br />

Souveränität“ und die „relative Souveränität“, welch letztere durch die bloße<br />

Existenz an<strong>de</strong>rer Staaten sowie durch die Kooperation mit diesen bestimmt wird.<br />

Einaudi, Robbins und von Hayek bekämpften die Souveränität als in höchstem<br />

Maß schädliche Eigenschaft <strong>de</strong>s Nationalstaates, als die Quelle von Elend und<br />

Armut, von Krieg und Chaos. 39 Mit Blick auf Deutschland erläuterte Einaudi 1918<br />

37. A. RÜSTOW, Was hat die Wirtschaftswissenschaft zur Zollfrage zu sagen? 19.2.1925, Typoskript,<br />

BAK N1169/244; G. von HABERLER, Der internationale Han<strong>de</strong>l (1933), Berlin, 1970,<br />

S.283-289; W. RÖPKE, Liberale Han<strong>de</strong>lspolitik, in: B. GOETZ (Hrsg.), Die Wandlungen <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Wirtschaft im kapitalistischen Zeitalter, Berlin-Grunewald, 1932, S.225; L. ROBBINS, Economic<br />

Planning …, op.cit., S.121 f.; F.A. von HAYEK, Die wirtschaftlichen Voraussetzungen …, op.cit.,<br />

S.331-336; J. RUEFF, op.cit., S.288 f.<br />

38. L. ROBBINS, Economic Planning …, op.cit., S.239, 299 und 325 ff.; W. RÖPKE, Die säkulare<br />

Be<strong>de</strong>utung <strong>de</strong>r Weltkrisis, op.cit., S.27; F.A. von HAYEK, Die wirtschaftlichen Voraussetzungen<br />

…, op.cit., S.341; Colloque Lippmann, op.cit., S.57-66; L. EINAUDI, Il dogma …,op.cit., S.28; J.<br />

Rueff, op.cit., pp. 287-293.<br />

39. L. EINAUDI, Il dogma …,op.cit., S.25; L. ROBBINS, op.cit., S.240-244; F.A. von HAYEK,<br />

op.cit., S.341.


22<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

die „innere Logik“, <strong>de</strong>rgemäß die volle und absolute Souveränität nach <strong>de</strong>r Weltherrschaft<br />

strebe, da sie in sicherheitspolitisch und wirtschaftlich vollen<strong>de</strong>ter Form<br />

nur unter <strong>de</strong>r Bedingung weltumspannen<strong>de</strong>r Hegemonie errichtet wer<strong>de</strong>n könne.<br />

Der Versuch, eine „Società <strong>de</strong>lle Nazioni“ aus souveränen Staaten zu schaffen,<br />

wür<strong>de</strong> im Nichts en<strong>de</strong>n und weiteren Anlaß zu Zwist und Krieg bieten. 40<br />

Einaudi, Robbins und von Hayek machten folgen<strong>de</strong> Bereiche aus, in <strong>de</strong>nen <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Nationalstaat auf seine Souveränität zugunsten <strong>de</strong>s Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaates verzichten<br />

müßte: außenpolitisch auf das Recht <strong>de</strong>r Kriegführung (Robbins); wirtschaftspolitisch<br />

auf das Recht, die freie Bewegung von Kapital und Arbeit zu begrenzen<br />

(Robbins, von Hayek), auf die Unterstützung bestimmter Industrien durch staatliche<br />

Beeinflussung <strong>de</strong>r Preise, auf Staatsmonopole und an<strong>de</strong>re Formen monopolistischer<br />

Organisationen einzelner Industrien, auf eine selbständige Währungs- und<br />

Finanzpolitik, möglicherweise auf eine nationale Zentralbank (Robbins, von<br />

Hayek) und unter Umstän<strong>de</strong>n auch auf verschie<strong>de</strong>ne Formen indirekter Steuern.<br />

Auf <strong>de</strong>m Gebiet <strong>de</strong>s Verfassungsrechts ging Einaudi sogar so weit, das Recht <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Parlamente, innerhalb <strong>de</strong>s Staatsgebietes Gesetze zu erlassen, in seinem Entwurf<br />

eines Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaates zu beschränken.<br />

Röpke zog aus <strong>de</strong>r mangeln<strong>de</strong>n Übereinstimmung <strong>de</strong>s wirtschaftlich und <strong>de</strong>s<br />

politisch integrierten Raumes, aus <strong>de</strong>m Wi<strong>de</strong>rspruch zwischen <strong>de</strong>r weltwirtschaftlichen<br />

Verflechtung und <strong>de</strong>m Nationalismus <strong>de</strong>r freien Völker <strong>de</strong>n Schluß, <strong>de</strong>r einzige<br />

Weg aus <strong>de</strong>r Weltkrisis <strong>de</strong>r 30er Jahre führe zur Lösung, die „wirtschaftliche<br />

Integration“ durch eine „politische“ zu ergänzen, <strong>de</strong>n „Grad <strong>de</strong>r politischen Kooperation<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Völker <strong>de</strong>m Gra<strong>de</strong> ihrer wirtschaftlichen Kooperation“ anzupassen. 41 In<br />

<strong>de</strong>r politischen Kooperation o<strong>de</strong>r Integration – Röpke verwen<strong>de</strong>te die Begriffe synonym<br />

wie in <strong>de</strong>r zeitgenössischen Literatur bis in die ersten Jahre nach <strong>de</strong>m Zweiten<br />

Weltkrieg üblich – erblickte Röpke ein „neues System <strong>de</strong>r internationalen<br />

Sicherheit und <strong>de</strong>s Frie<strong>de</strong>ns“, das die Wohlfahrt und Zivilisation, die Erhaltung und<br />

Erhebung Europas gewährleisten wür<strong>de</strong>. 42<br />

Der integrale Nationalismus und die Verabsolutierung <strong>de</strong>r nationalen Souveränität<br />

im Faschismus und Nationalsozialismus erschütterten die Verbindung von liberaler<br />

und nationaler I<strong>de</strong>e, die von <strong>de</strong>n Anfängen <strong>de</strong>r liberalen Bewegung an ein „Fundamentalprinzip“<br />

(Lothar Gall) <strong>de</strong>s Liberalismus in Europa gebil<strong>de</strong>t hatte. 43 Die vielfachen<br />

liberalen Emanzipationsziele, welche <strong>de</strong>r Liberalismus im Nationalismus <strong>de</strong>s<br />

19. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rts konkretisiert sah, wur<strong>de</strong>n durch die faschistische und nationalsozialistische<br />

Übersteigerung <strong>de</strong>s Nationalen aufgehoben. Röpke, Rueff, Einaudi, Robbins<br />

und von Hayek griffen angesichts dieser Gefährdung <strong>de</strong>s Liberalismus auf <strong>de</strong>ssen<br />

kosmopolitische Tradition zurück, die nicht nur im Bereich <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaft, son<strong>de</strong>rn<br />

40. L. EINAUDI, Il dogma …,op.cit., S. 25-28.<br />

41. W. RÖPKE, Die säkulare Be<strong>de</strong>utung <strong>de</strong>r Weltkrisis, op.cit., S.27; Colloque Lippmann, op.cit.,<br />

S.65.<br />

42. W. RÖPKE, Die säkulare Be<strong>de</strong>utung <strong>de</strong>r Weltkrisis, op.cit., S.27.<br />

43. L. GALL, Liberalismus und Nationalstaat, in: L. GALL, Bürgertum, liberale Bewegung und Nation,<br />

Ausgewählte Aufsätze, München, 1996, S.191.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 23<br />

auch <strong>de</strong>r Geisteshaltung und <strong>de</strong>s Bildungsi<strong>de</strong>als 44 („Weltbürgertum“) im liberalen<br />

Nationalismus <strong>de</strong>s 19. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rts ihren Platz gehabt hatte.<br />

2.3. We<strong>de</strong>r Staatenbund noch Einheitsstaat.<br />

Liberaler Internationalismus gegen hegemoniale „Großräume“<br />

Die von Einaudi, Robbins und von Hayek skizzierten I<strong>de</strong>alvorstellungen zielten<br />

we<strong>de</strong>r auf einen „Staatenbund“ noch auf einen unbeschränkten „Einheitsstaat“ ab,<br />

son<strong>de</strong>rn auf eine „Fö<strong>de</strong>ration“ in <strong>de</strong>r Be<strong>de</strong>utung <strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>utschen Bezeichnung „Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaat“.<br />

Robbins fügte <strong>de</strong>m „Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaat“ das Attribut „super-national“ bei, so<br />

etwa wenn er in Abhebung vom Liberalismus <strong>de</strong>s 19. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rts zur Verwirklichung<br />

<strong>de</strong>s „internationalistischen Liberalismus“ die Notwendigkeit einer übernationalen<br />

Autorität for<strong>de</strong>rte, die einen Apparat darstellen wür<strong>de</strong>, um Recht und Ordnung<br />

aufrechtzuerhalten. 45 Was die Abtretung von Souveränitätsrechten an die<br />

Gemeinschaft anbelangt, reichten die Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte Einaudis, Robbins‘ und<br />

von Hayeks weit über das hinaus, was in <strong>de</strong>n ersten bei<strong>de</strong>n Stufen zur Umsetzung<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Römer Verträge erreicht wer<strong>de</strong>n konnte, und nahmen die wesentlichen Züge<br />

<strong>de</strong>s vollen<strong>de</strong>ten Binnenmarktes vorweg.<br />

Die Analyse <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsentwürfe <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaftswissenschafter, die in <strong>de</strong>n dreißiger<br />

Jahren für einen erneuerten Liberalismus eintraten, läßt die kosmopolitische Ausrichtung im<br />

Zeichen <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Internationalismus als beson<strong>de</strong>res Merkmal dieser Konzepte erkennen.<br />

Als I<strong>de</strong>alfall angestrebt wur<strong>de</strong> eine Weltfö<strong>de</strong>ration, ein die ganze Welt einschließlich<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Kolonialgebiete umfassen<strong>de</strong>r Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaat; die Fö<strong>de</strong>ration sollte allen zur wirtschaftlichen<br />

Verflechtung fähigen Staaten <strong>of</strong>fenstehen. Die liberal-internationalistischen Grundlagen<br />

dieser Konzepte hoben sich <strong>de</strong>utlich von <strong>de</strong>n aufkommen<strong>de</strong>n totalitaristischen Hegemonialplänen<br />

ab, da sie we<strong>de</strong>r auf <strong>de</strong>m Nationalismus noch auf Rassen<strong>de</strong>nken beruhten,<br />

son<strong>de</strong>rn im Gegenteil bei<strong>de</strong> als ver<strong>de</strong>rblich ablehnten. Eine möglichst umfassen<strong>de</strong> Fö<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

von Staaten war dazu bestimmt, die Hegemonie <strong>de</strong>s Stärkeren zu verhin<strong>de</strong>rn. In diesem<br />

Sinne wiesen auch Rüstow und Röpke die Vorstellung von „Großräumen“, wie die<br />

Nationalsozialisten sie propagierten, bereits in <strong>de</strong>n frühen dreißiger Jahren zurück. 46 Gegen<br />

die von <strong>de</strong>n Nationalsozialisten gepriesene autarkische „Raumbildung“ führte Röpke die<br />

han<strong>de</strong>ls- und außenpolitischen Konsequenzen einer „Selbsteinkreisung“ <strong>de</strong>r Deutschen in<br />

Deutschland, Südost- und Osteuropa und das Gegenbeispiel <strong>de</strong>r Kleinstaaten Dänemark,<br />

Nie<strong>de</strong>rlan<strong>de</strong> und Schweiz an, die sich auch „ohne 'Raum'“ bestens entwickelten. 47<br />

Die Prinzipien einer liberalen Weltwirtschaft mit ihrer Politik <strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong>fenen Tür,<br />

von <strong>de</strong>n Neoliberalen in Anlehnung an Cob<strong>de</strong>ns Kosmopolitismus verfochten,<br />

44. H.-U. WEHLER, Deutsche Gesellschaftsgeschichte 1, München, 1987, S.510 f.<br />

45. L. ROBBINS, Economic Planning …, op.cit., S.240 f. Von Hayek verwen<strong>de</strong>te für <strong>de</strong>n Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaat<br />

ebenfalls das Attribut „überstaatlich“. F.A. von HAYEK , Die wirtschaftlichen Voraussetzungen<br />

…, op.cit., S.337.<br />

46. A. RÜSTOW, Autarkie und Export, Berlin, 21.3.1931. Typoskript. BAK N 1169/271.<br />

47. U. UNFRIED (Pseudonym Röpkes), Die Intellektuellen und <strong>de</strong>r „Kapitalismus“, in: Frankfurter<br />

Zeitung, 11.9.1931, Nr.676; W. RÖPKE, Weltwirtschaft, Eine Notwendigkeit <strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>utschen Wirtschaft,<br />

Tübingen, 1932, S.16.


24<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

stan<strong>de</strong>n im krassen Wi<strong>de</strong>rspruch zur Konzeption autarker „Großwirtschaftsräume”.<br />

48 Von Mises wies eine Bildung von Vereinigten Staaten Europas als Weg<br />

zum Krieg mit Amerika und <strong>de</strong>r Sowjetunion aus, wenn in einer europäischen<br />

Union Chauvinismus, Streben nach Autarkie, Imperialismus und Militarismus von<br />

<strong>de</strong>r nationalen Ebene auf einen größeren Kreis von Staaten übertragen wür<strong>de</strong>n. 49<br />

2.4. Freiheit <strong>de</strong>r Teile in <strong>de</strong>r Ordnung <strong>de</strong>s Ganzen<br />

Die vorgestellten Konzepte <strong>de</strong>s internationalistischen Liberalismus stan<strong>de</strong>n im Zeichen<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Pazifismus liberaler Prägung, zu <strong>de</strong>m sich insbeson<strong>de</strong>re Röpke in <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Zwischenkriegszeit wie<strong>de</strong>rholt ausdrücklich bekannte. Das Streben nach einer<br />

„wirksamen internationalen Rechtsordnung“ (von Hayek), einem internationalen<br />

gesetzlichen Rahmenwerk zur freien Entfaltung <strong>de</strong>r persönlichen Initiative, verband<br />

die Wiener bzw. Londoner Vertreter eines revidierten Liberalismus mit <strong>de</strong>n<br />

<strong>de</strong>utschen Neoliberalen. Den spezifischen Ansatz Edwin Cannans, <strong>de</strong>s Begrün<strong>de</strong>rs<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Londoner neoliberalen Schule, spiegelte Robbins‘ Zugangsweise wi<strong>de</strong>r, in<strong>de</strong>m<br />

Robbins die Frage, welche Aufgaben in <strong>de</strong>r Macht <strong>de</strong>r lokalen-staatlichen Autoritäten<br />

eines Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaates verbleiben sollten, nicht im Kontext <strong>de</strong>r nationalstaatlichen<br />

Interessen, son<strong>de</strong>rn im Kontext <strong>de</strong>s gemeinsamen Interesses <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration klärte.<br />

Die Entwürfe einer Fö<strong>de</strong>ration von Staaten im Zeichen <strong>de</strong>s internationalistischen<br />

Liberalismus stellen eine feste Beziehung zwischen <strong>de</strong>n Wirtschaftsformen<br />

und <strong>de</strong>n politischen Strukturen auf. Robbins und Röpke formulierten das Verhältnis<br />

von nationaler Planung und internationaler Unordnung als Kausalbeziehung in <strong>de</strong>m<br />

Sinne, daß die erstere die letztere hervorbringe. 50 In <strong>de</strong>mselben gedanklichen<br />

Zusammenhang erblickte von Hayek im Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaat eine Absicherung gegen<br />

sozialistische Wirtschaftsformen, da mangeln<strong>de</strong> gemeinsame I<strong>de</strong>ale und Wertsetzungen<br />

im Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaat es verhin<strong>de</strong>rn wür<strong>de</strong>n, daß <strong>de</strong>r Bund selbst o<strong>de</strong>r die nationalen<br />

Regierungen noch die Macht zu sozialistischer Planung wür<strong>de</strong>n ausüben<br />

können. 51 Von Hayek sah keinen Ersatz für <strong>de</strong>n Mythos <strong>de</strong>s Nationalismus entstehen,<br />

<strong>de</strong>r wie dieser im Nationalstaat die Lenkung <strong>de</strong>s Wirtschaftslebens legitimatorisch<br />

abzustützen imstan<strong>de</strong> wäre. Gleichzeitig betonte von Hayek <strong>de</strong>n unauflösbaren<br />

Konnex zwischen <strong>de</strong>r politischen und wirtschaftlichen Vereinigung, sei<br />

doch <strong>de</strong>r wirtschaftliche Zusammenschluß unabdingbar, um <strong>de</strong>n politischen<br />

48. W. RÖPKE, Die wirtschaftlichen Elemente <strong>de</strong>s Frie<strong>de</strong>nsproblems II, in: Frie<strong>de</strong>ns-Warte,<br />

37(1937), S.55.<br />

49. L. von MISES, Liberalismus, Jena, 1927, S.125-130.<br />

50. L. ROBBINS, Economic Planning …, op.cit., S.221 ff.; W. RÖPKE, Les problèmes économiques<br />

internationaux d'un mon<strong>de</strong> en transformation, Antrittsvorlesung Institut Universitaire <strong>de</strong> Hautes<br />

Etu<strong>de</strong>s Internationales, Genève, 25.10.1937, in: La crise mondiale, Paris, 1938, S.305. Diese Überlegungen<br />

Robbins‘, Röpkes und von Hayeks (s.u.) sind im Kontext <strong>de</strong>r Planwirtschafts<strong>de</strong>batte <strong>de</strong>r<br />

20er/30er Jahre zu sehen.<br />

51. Diese These von Hayeks hat im Kreise <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaftswissenschafter <strong>de</strong>s Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union Research Institute<br />

während <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges eine große Kontroverse ausgelöst: J.M. WILSON, Economic<br />

Aspects <strong>of</strong> Fe<strong>de</strong>ration, in: Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union Research Institute, First Annual Report, London, 1940.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 25<br />

Zusammenhalt <strong>de</strong>s Bun<strong>de</strong>s zu bewahren. Nicht in min<strong>de</strong>rem Masse waren die politischen<br />

Strukturen und Wirtschaftsformen in Robbins' Weltfö<strong>de</strong>ration von <strong>de</strong>m<br />

einen Prinzip, <strong>de</strong>r „internationalen liberalen Planung”, 52 geformt. In <strong>de</strong>m so konzipierten<br />

Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaat wür<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>mgemäß weniger regiert, ohne daß sich allerdings<br />

laissez faire und Anarchie einstellen wür<strong>de</strong>n, <strong>de</strong>nn dagegen schützte das gesetzliche<br />

Rahmenwerk zur Aufrechterhaltung von Recht und Ordnung. 53<br />

3. Neoliberale Konzepte einer Europafö<strong>de</strong>ration während<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges<br />

Während von Haberler, <strong>de</strong>r 1936 in die Vereinigten Staaten emigriert war, und Lippmann<br />

aus Sorge vor einer erneuten Beherrschung Europas durch Deutschland und aufgrund<br />

<strong>de</strong>r mangeln<strong>de</strong>n geographischen Geschlossenheit Europas die I<strong>de</strong>e einer europäischen<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration als unrealistisch abtaten, 54 zählten sich Einaudi und Röpke,<br />

Robbins und von Hayek während <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges zu <strong>de</strong>n „Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten“. Einaudi,<br />

<strong>de</strong>r zu <strong>de</strong>n frühesten italienischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten gehörte, wur<strong>de</strong> nach seiner Flucht<br />

in die Schweiz (8.9.1943) Mitglied <strong>de</strong>s Movimento Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista Europeo. Röpke schloß<br />

sich keiner Organisation an, bekannte sich aber in seinem Werk Internationale Ordnung,<br />

been<strong>de</strong>t im Januar 1945, ebenso wie in <strong>de</strong>r überarbeiteten Neuauflage von 1954<br />

ausdrücklich zu <strong>de</strong>n „Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten”. 55 1944 veröffentlichte Röpke einen Artikel zur<br />

fö<strong>de</strong>ralistischen Lösung <strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>utschen Frage in <strong>de</strong>n Qua<strong>de</strong>rni <strong>de</strong>l Movimento Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista<br />

Europeo. Robbins gehörte <strong>de</strong>n britischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten (Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union) seit <strong>de</strong>n<br />

Anfängen ihrer Bewegung zu Beginn <strong>de</strong>s Jahres 1939 an. Von Hayek, Robbins und <strong>de</strong><br />

Madariaga, <strong>de</strong>r gleichzeitig Mitglied <strong>de</strong>r Paneuropa-Union war, stellten sich <strong>de</strong>m Londoner<br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union Research Institute zur Verfügung, das im März 1940 in <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Absicht gegrün<strong>de</strong>t wor<strong>de</strong>n war, Wissenschaftern die Möglichkeit zu bieten, die I<strong>de</strong>e<br />

einer europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration möglichst <strong>de</strong>tailliert auszuarbeiten. In seinem Werk The<br />

Quest for Peace since the World War (1940) setzte Rappard (Genf) seine H<strong>of</strong>fnungen<br />

auf das fö<strong>de</strong>rative Prinzip in <strong>de</strong>n internationalen Beziehungen nach <strong>de</strong>m Vorbild <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Schweiz und <strong>de</strong>r Vereinigten Staaten. 56 Zu unmittelbaren Kontakten kam es im Rahmen<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union noch vor <strong>de</strong>r Besetzung Frankreichs zwischen Robbins und von<br />

Hayek einerseits und Rueff und Baudin an<strong>de</strong>rerseits, als eine Gruppe von Ökonomen<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union Research Institute am 13. und 14. April 1940 in Paris ihre Pläne mit<br />

französischen Gleichgesinnten berieten. 57 Aus diesem Treffen ist keine Resolution zu<br />

52. L. ROBBINS, Economic Planning …, op.cit., S.258.<br />

53. F.A. von HAYEK, Die wirtschaftlichen Voraussetzungen …, op.cit., S.337 und 340.<br />

54. G. von HABERLER, The Political Economy <strong>of</strong> Regional or Continental Blocs, in: S.E. HARRIS<br />

(Hrsg.), Postwar Economic Problems, London, 1943, S.335; W. LIPPMANN, US War Aims, London,<br />

1944, S.76 ff.<br />

55. W. RÖPKE, Internationale Ordnung, Erlenbach-Zürich, 1945, S.55.<br />

56. W.E. RAPPARD, The Quest for Peace since the World War, Cambridge/MA, 1940, S.498-501.<br />

57. Anglo-French Ecomomists‘ Conference, Paris, 13.–14.4.1940, in: Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union Research Institute,<br />

First Annual Report, 1939–1940, London, 1940, Quelle ohne Paginierung.


26<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

einem bestimmten Programm hervorgegangen. Die For<strong>de</strong>rung, die vorgesehene Fö<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

müsse eine liberale Außenwirtschaftspolitik annehmen, dürfte von <strong>de</strong>n neoliberalen<br />

Diskussionsteilnehmern eingebracht wor<strong>de</strong>n sein. 58<br />

Während <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges sind Beziehungen zwischen <strong>de</strong>n britischen<br />

(Robbins, von Hayek), italienischen (Einaudi), <strong>de</strong>utschen bzw. schweizerischen<br />

(Röpke, Rappard), französischen (Rueff, Baudin) und spanischen (<strong>de</strong> Madariaga)<br />

neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten nachweisbar, teils durch die FU, teils durch <strong>de</strong>n MFE<br />

vermittelt, teils aber auch außerhalb dieser Strukturen.<br />

3.1. Das Verhältnis <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaftsverfassung und <strong>de</strong>r politischen Strukturen<br />

einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

Der durch von Hayek noch vor Kriegsbeginn ausführlich dargelegte Zusammenhang zwischen<br />

<strong>de</strong>n Wirtschaftsformen und <strong>de</strong>n politischen Strukturen einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

gewann in <strong>de</strong>n Arbeiten seiner neoliberalen Kollegen in Großbritannien, Frankreich, <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Schweiz und Italien große Be<strong>de</strong>utung, nach<strong>de</strong>m sich für die Liberalen die Frage <strong>de</strong>r wirtschaftlichen<br />

Neuordnung nach <strong>de</strong>m Krieg und <strong>de</strong>r Wie<strong>de</strong>rerrichtung liberaler politischer<br />

Strukturen auf nationaler und internationaler Ebene stellte. Die These, daß die Wirtschaftsverfassung<br />

und die politischen Strukturen in einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration wie auf <strong>de</strong>r Ebene <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Nationalstaates in einem strengen Zuordnungsverhältnis stün<strong>de</strong>n, wur<strong>de</strong> von Röpke 1944 in<br />

eine griffige Formulierung gefaßt: Die Antithese zwischen Marktwirtschaft und Kollektivismus<br />

setzte sich auf <strong>de</strong>m Gebiet <strong>de</strong>r internationalen Wirtschaftsbeziehungen in die Antithese<br />

zwischen Weltwirtschaft und kollektivistischer Großraumwirtschaft um.<br />

“Weltwirtschaft ist nichts an<strong>de</strong>res als die marktwirtschaftliche Form und Großraumwirtschaft<br />

nichts an<strong>de</strong>res als die kollektivistische Form <strong>de</strong>r internationalen Wirtschaftsverfassung,<br />

und in bei<strong>de</strong>n Fällen muß die Form <strong>de</strong>r internationalen Wirtschaftsverfassung <strong>de</strong>r<br />

nationalen entsprechen: die Weltwirtschaft <strong>de</strong>r Marktwirtschaft, die Großraumwirtschaft<br />

<strong>de</strong>m Kollektivismus auf <strong>de</strong>r ganzen Linie, d.h. nach außen wie nach innen”. 59<br />

In <strong>de</strong>r Frage nach <strong>de</strong>r Form, in <strong>de</strong>r eine echte Weltwirtschaft möglich wäre, schloß<br />

Röpke 1944 (wie in seinen Aufsätzen vor <strong>de</strong>m Zweiten Weltkrieg) einen vollen<strong>de</strong>ten<br />

Weltstaat als unwahrscheinlich aus und trat für einen multilateralen und freien internationalen<br />

Wirtschaftsverkehr <strong>de</strong>r Staaten ein, für eine weltweite Markt-, Preis- und Zahlungsgemeinschaft.<br />

Was die in diesem Rahmen möglicherweise entstehen<strong>de</strong>n Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>rationen<br />

für einzelne Gebiete o<strong>de</strong>r Staatengruppen anbelangt, hob Röpke die gegenseitige<br />

Zuordnung von Marktwirtschaft – nationalem und internationalem Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus – Weltwirtschaft<br />

hervor, die mit <strong>de</strong>m einzelstaatlichen wie <strong>de</strong>m überstaatlichen Kollektivismus<br />

nicht vereinbar wären, da dieser die Fö<strong>de</strong>ration sprengen wür<strong>de</strong>. 60<br />

58. Der Bericht ordnet die verschie<strong>de</strong>nen Beiträge nicht <strong>de</strong>n jeweiligen Votanten zu. Abgesehen vom<br />

Zeugnis dieses Treffens sind meines Wissens in Rueffs Bibliographie keine Schriften über Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte<br />

aus <strong>de</strong>r Zeit während <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges überliefert.<br />

59. W. RÖPKE, Wirtschaftsverfassung und politische Weltordnung, in: Frie<strong>de</strong>ns-Warte, 43(1943),<br />

S.30 f.; W. RÖPKE, Civitas Humana, Erlenbach-Zürich, 1944, S.387.<br />

60. W. RÖPKE, Von alten zu neuen Wirtschaftsformen, in: Neue Schweizer Rundschau, Neue Folge,<br />

11(1943), S.87 f.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 27<br />

Die dichotomische Gegenüberstellung von Marktwirtschaft – Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>rationen<br />

einerseits und Kollektivismus – Großräumen an<strong>de</strong>rerseits gipfelt in <strong>de</strong>r Gegenüberstellung<br />

einer Frie<strong>de</strong>nsordnung und einer von Spannungen und kriegerischen Auseinan<strong>de</strong>rsetzungen<br />

geprägten Wirtschafts- und Staatsordnung, <strong>de</strong>r kein dauerhafter Bestand beschie<strong>de</strong>n<br />

wird. 61 Die Beschränkung <strong>de</strong>r fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Gewalt auf eine eng <strong>de</strong>finierte Anzahl Aufgaben<br />

in <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration Einaudis ließe sozialistische Wirtschaftsplanung und<br />

ökonomische Zentralisierung ebenfalls nicht zu. 62 Mit Blick auf eine Mitgliedschaft <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Sowjetunion in einer europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration schloß sich Robbins von Hayeks These an<br />

und stellte fest, die totalitäre Diktatur als Regierungsform sei mit <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration freier<br />

Völker inkompatibel. 63 Von Haberler sah die angemessene wirtschaftliche und politische<br />

Verfassung für sozialistische Staaten und für Staaten mit hochentwickeltem wirtschaftspolitischem<br />

Interventionismus nur in einer vollständigen ökonomischen und politischen<br />

Vereinigung, um aus <strong>de</strong>r Arbeitsteilung maximale Vorteile zu ziehen und Produktionspläne<br />

umsetzen zu können. Von Haberler zweifelte jedoch an <strong>de</strong>r freiwilligen und friedlichen<br />

Errichtung eines <strong>de</strong>rartigen Staates. 64<br />

3.2. Gesellschaftliches und kulturelles Europabild<br />

Während sich die Arbeiten neoliberaler Ökonomen zum Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsproblem vor <strong>de</strong>m<br />

Zweiten Weltkrieg auf die wirtschaftlichen Aspekte konzentriert hatten, erkannten die<br />

Neoliberalen in <strong>de</strong>n Studien, die im Zweiten Weltkrieg entstan<strong>de</strong>n, <strong>de</strong>n außerökonomischen<br />

Bedingungen einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration eine vorrangige Be<strong>de</strong>utung zu. So<br />

wur<strong>de</strong> das Verhältnis von ökonomischer und sozialer bzw. von ökonomischer und geistig-moralischer<br />

„Integration“ im Zusammenhang mit <strong>de</strong>n Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepten thematisiert.<br />

Im Unterschied zu <strong>de</strong>n früheren Entwürfen wandten sich die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges <strong>de</strong>m gesellschaftlichen und kulturellen Bild<br />

Europas zu und setzten mit Hilfe <strong>de</strong>s Instrumentariums <strong>de</strong>r historischen und sozio-psychologischen<br />

Nationalismusforschung zu einer Definition <strong>de</strong>r europäischen I<strong>de</strong>ntität an.<br />

Die Frage, ob die soziale Integration als Ergebnis <strong>de</strong>r ökonomischen Integration angestrebt<br />

wer<strong>de</strong>n könnte o<strong>de</strong>r ob die erstere die unabdingbare Voraussetzung <strong>de</strong>r letzteren sei,<br />

entschie<strong>de</strong>n Röpke, Robbins, von Hayek und von Haberler 65 in <strong>de</strong>m Sinne, daß die<br />

soziale und kulturelle Integration <strong>de</strong>r ökonomischen vorangehen müßte, eine institutionelle<br />

Absicherung aber notwendig sei. Die Kontroverse zwischen <strong>de</strong>n sog. „Realisten“<br />

und <strong>de</strong>n „Institutionalisten“ wur<strong>de</strong> nicht so einseitig zugunsten <strong>de</strong>r „Realisten“ ausgetragen,<br />

wie die „Institutionalisten“ nach <strong>de</strong>m Zweiten Weltkrieg es empfan<strong>de</strong>n. Eine<br />

61. Dieser Vergleich greift auf die Augustinische Dichotomie <strong>de</strong>r Civitas Dei und <strong>de</strong>r Civitas diaboli<br />

zurück. W. RÖPKE, Civitas Humana, op.cit., S.391.<br />

62. L. EINAUDI, I problemi economici <strong>de</strong>lla fe<strong>de</strong>razione europea (1944), Milano, 1946, S.7.<br />

63. L. ROBBINS, The Economic Causes <strong>of</strong> War, London, 1939, S.106.<br />

64. G. von HABERLER, The Political Economy …, op.cit., S.342.<br />

65. G. von HABERLER, op.cit., S.339 f.; W. RÖPKE, International Economic Dis<strong>integration</strong>, London,<br />

1942, S.71-81; W. RÖPKE, Die Gesellschaftskrisis <strong>de</strong>r Gegenwart, Erlenbach-Zürich, 1942,<br />

S.379; L. ROBBINS, The Economic Causes <strong>of</strong> War, op.cit., S.106; F.A. von HAYEK, Der Weg<br />

zur Knechtschaft, Erlenbach-Zürich, 1945, S.292.


28<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

institutionelle Lösung schien <strong>de</strong>n neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten angebracht, s<strong>of</strong>ern sich die<br />

wirtschaftliche und politische „Integration“ innerhalb <strong>de</strong>s Rahmens <strong>de</strong>r gesellschaftlichen<br />

und kulturellen „Integration“ vollziehen wür<strong>de</strong>. Dies bedingte, daß nicht nur die<br />

wirtschaftlichen, son<strong>de</strong>rn auch die politischen und gesellschaftlichen Strukturen <strong>de</strong>r Einzelstaaten<br />

und <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration(en) liberal wären, 66 und zwar liberal nach <strong>de</strong>m Konzept <strong>de</strong>s<br />

erneuerten internationalistischen Liberalismus und nicht nach <strong>de</strong>n Grundsätzen <strong>de</strong>s<br />

laissez faire-Liberalismus <strong>de</strong>s 19. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rts.<br />

In Robbins', Röpkes, von Hayeks und Einaudis Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepten <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Kriegsjahre ist gegenüber ihren früheren Überlegungen eine Zurücknahme <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte auf europäische Dimensionen zu beobachten. Nach<strong>de</strong>m sich<br />

Robbins in seinem Werk Economic Planning and International Or<strong>de</strong>r (1937) in<br />

erster Linie mit <strong>de</strong>n Grundlagen einer Weltfö<strong>de</strong>ration befaßt hatte, verwarf er in<br />

einer nach <strong>de</strong>m Ausbruch <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkriegs vollständig überarbeiteten Veröffentlichung<br />

seiner Genfer Vorlesungsreihe vom Frühjahr 1939, The Economic<br />

Causes <strong>of</strong> War, und in seinem Beitrag Economic Aspects <strong>of</strong> Fe<strong>de</strong>ration zum Sammelband<br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union von 1940 eine Weltfö<strong>de</strong>ration als Utopie, 67 um statt<strong>de</strong>ssen<br />

die Grundlagen einer europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration zu erörtern. Röpke, <strong>de</strong>r 1941/1942<br />

noch eine „Weltstaatengemeinschaft“ mit fö<strong>de</strong>rativer Struktur, 68 d.h. zusammengesetzt<br />

aus „regionalen und kontinentalen Untergruppen”, 69 unterstützt hatte, wandte<br />

sich 1943 von <strong>de</strong>r I<strong>de</strong>e einer solchen „Weltstaatengemeinschaft” 70 bzw. einer<br />

„weltumfassend[en] Fö<strong>de</strong>ration” 71 ab und trat in <strong>de</strong>r Folge für die Bildung von<br />

„Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>rationen“ als „Zwischenstufe zwischen <strong>de</strong>m Nationalstaat und <strong>de</strong>r<br />

neuen internationalen Rechtsgemeinschaft“ ein. 72 Eine solche Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

wäre die „europäische Fö<strong>de</strong>ration“, <strong>de</strong>r wie<strong>de</strong>rum straffere „regionale Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>rationen“<br />

(Skandinavien, Atlantikstaaten, Donaulän<strong>de</strong>r, Balkanlän<strong>de</strong>r u.a.) 73 untergeordnet<br />

wären. Während sich von Hayeks Studie von 1939 noch auf Streits Konzeption<br />

einer fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Union, bestehend aus <strong>de</strong>n USA, Großbritannien, Irland,<br />

Kanada, Australien, Neuseeland, Südafrika, Frankreich, <strong>de</strong>r Schweiz, Belgien, <strong>de</strong>n<br />

66. W. RÖPKE, Internationale Ordnung, op.cit., S.64 f.; L. ROBBINS, The Economic Causes <strong>of</strong> War,<br />

op.cit., S.106; G. von HABERLER, The Political Economy …, op.cit., S.340-342.<br />

67. L. ROBBINS, The Economic Causes <strong>of</strong> War, op.cit., S.105; L. ROBBINS, Economic Aspects <strong>of</strong><br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ration, in: M. CHANNING-PEARCE (Hrsg.), Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union (1940), London, 1991, S.184,<br />

Anm.1 und S.185. In einer im Januar 1939 verfaßten Anmerkung zu seinen Ausführungen über<br />

„Fe<strong>de</strong>ration the only Remedy“ <strong>de</strong>s Wintersemesters 1936/37 schränkte Robbins sein Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzept<br />

auf die westlichen Demokratien ein. L. ROBBINS, The Economics <strong>of</strong> Territorial<br />

Sovereignty, abgedruckt in: L. ROBBINS, The Economic Basis <strong>of</strong> Class Conflict and Other Essays,<br />

London, 1939, S.105, Anm.1.<br />

68. W. RÖPKE, Wen<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>r Weltwirtschaft, in: Neue Zürcher Zeitung (NZZ) 30.5.1941, Nr.832; W.<br />

RÖPKE, Die Gesellschaftskrisis <strong>de</strong>r Gegenwart, op.cit., S.378.<br />

69. W. RÖPKE, Die Gesellschaftskrisis <strong>de</strong>r Gegenwart, op.cit., S.378.<br />

70. W. RÖPKE, Civitas Humana, op.cit., S.389.<br />

71. W. RÖPKE, Weltwirtschaft und internationale Geldordnung nach <strong>de</strong>m Kriege, in: Schweizer Monatshefte,<br />

22(1943), S.552.<br />

72. Ibid.<br />

73. W. RÖPKE, Internationale Ordnung, op.cit., S.63.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 29<br />

Nie<strong>de</strong>rlan<strong>de</strong>n, Dänemark, Norwegen, Schwe<strong>de</strong>n und Finnland, 74 bezogen hatte,<br />

hielt er es am En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s Krieges für sinnvoller, einen verhältnismäßig engen Zusammenschluß<br />

in einem Fö<strong>de</strong>rativstaat zunächst auf ein kleineres Gebiet, einen Teil<br />

Westeuropas, zu beschränken und erst sukzessive auszu<strong>de</strong>hnen. 75 Dieser Kern<br />

eines europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>rativstaats wür<strong>de</strong> auf gemeinsamen Grundlagen in <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Kultur, <strong>de</strong>n Weltanschauungen und <strong>de</strong>m Lebensstandard aufbauen. Im März 1945<br />

glaubte Einaudi <strong>de</strong>n Augenblick gekommen, „das Unmögliche zu wollen“ und die<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration Europas zu verwirklichen, nach<strong>de</strong>m diese Lösung im Sommer 1940<br />

noch als Ergebnis eines sehr langen Prozesses erschienen war. 76 Einaudi hatte<br />

schon in seiner Flugschrift vom September 1943 und in seinem Essai von 1944<br />

nicht mehr von einer „Weltfö<strong>de</strong>ration“ gesprochen.<br />

Hatten die Realisierungschancen eines weltumspannen<strong>de</strong>n Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaates in<br />

<strong>de</strong>n theoretischen Entwürfen <strong>de</strong>r Zwischenkriegszeit noch keine vorrangige Be<strong>de</strong>utung<br />

innegehabt, so zwang die unmittelbare Aufgabe, eine konkretisierbare Neuordnung<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaftsbeziehungen für die Nachkriegszeit vorzuschlagen, zur<br />

Ausrichtung nicht nur auf die theoretische Wünschbarkeit, son<strong>de</strong>rn auch auf die<br />

praktische Machbarkeit.<br />

Zur geographischen Redimensionierung <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte<br />

hatte das <strong>de</strong>finitive Scheitern <strong>de</strong>s Völkerbun<strong>de</strong>s wesentlich beigetragen. Für die auf<br />

<strong>de</strong>m europäischen Kontinent verbliebenen neoliberalen Nationalökonomen spielte<br />

die Konfrontation mit <strong>de</strong>n kriegsentschei<strong>de</strong>n<strong>de</strong>n außereuropäischen o<strong>de</strong>r als außereuropäisch<br />

empfun<strong>de</strong>nen Großmächten, insbeson<strong>de</strong>re mit <strong>de</strong>n Vereinigten Staaten<br />

von Amerika und <strong>de</strong>n von ihren Repräsentanten vorgebrachten Europaplänen, eine<br />

entschei<strong>de</strong>n<strong>de</strong> Rolle. Das Bewußtsein, daß sich die machtpolitische Abdankung<br />

Europas – und zwar nicht <strong>de</strong>s „neuen Europas“ <strong>de</strong>r Goebbelsschen Propaganda,<br />

son<strong>de</strong>rn <strong>de</strong>s „Abendlan<strong>de</strong>s“, <strong>de</strong>s „alten Kontinents“ – vollziehe, 77 und das Bestreben,<br />

Europa gegenüber <strong>de</strong>r „jüngeren Nation“ (USA) abzugrenzen, sind als Motivation<br />

erkennbar, die bei Röpke und Einaudi zur Konzentration ihrer Bemühungen<br />

auf Europa geführt hat. 78 Die Großraum-I<strong>de</strong>ologie und die nationalsozialistische<br />

Europa-Propaganda, die nach <strong>de</strong>m Sieg über Frankreich in staatlichen Planungen<br />

74. C. STREIT, op.cit., S.6 f.<br />

75. F.A. von HAYEK, Der Weg zur Knechtschaft, op.cit., S.292.<br />

76. L. EINAUDI, Die Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsi<strong>de</strong>e vor einem Vierteljahrhun<strong>de</strong>rt und heute, in: Neue Schweizer<br />

Rundschau, Nr.11, März 1945, S.660; L. EINAUDI, The Nature <strong>of</strong> a World Peace, in: Annals <strong>of</strong><br />

the American Aca<strong>de</strong>my <strong>of</strong> Political and Social Science, 210(1940), S.66.<br />

77. Zur zeitgenössischen Diskussion um die Abgrenzung <strong>de</strong>r „europäischen“ von <strong>de</strong>r „amerikanischen“<br />

Kultur: A. KELLER, Der Kampf <strong>de</strong>r Kontinente, in: NZZ, 6.6.1943, Nr.892; Redaktion<br />

NZZ, Gedanken über eine „Neuorganisation <strong>de</strong>r Welt“, in: NZZ, 13.11.1943, Nr.1787; E.<br />

SCHÜRCH, Unsere Frie<strong>de</strong>nsvorbereitungen, in: NZZ, 14.12.1943, Nr.2014; Redaktion NZZ,<br />

Staat und Wirtschaft in <strong>de</strong>n Vereinigten Staaten, in: NZZ, 28.2.1944, Nr.346; Redaktion NZZ,<br />

Amerikas und Europas Beiträge zum Wie<strong>de</strong>raufbau <strong>de</strong>r Welt, in: NZZ, 27.5.1944, Nr.897; H.-R.<br />

SCHWYZER, Besinnung auf Europa. Rezension von G. <strong>de</strong> Reynold, La formation <strong>de</strong> l'Europe,<br />

1944, in: NZZ, 20.3.1945, Nr.481.<br />

78. W. RÖPKE, Internationale Ordnung, op.cit., S.57 f.<br />

Einaudis Argumentation setzte bei <strong>de</strong>r ökonomischen Abdankung <strong>de</strong>r neben <strong>de</strong>n USA „klein“ gewor<strong>de</strong>nen<br />

europäischen Nationalstaaten (Frankreich, Italien und Deutschland eingeschlossen) an.


30<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

zur Schaffung einer „europäischen Wirtschaftsgemeinschaft“ o<strong>de</strong>r eines<br />

„Europäischen Staatenbun<strong>de</strong>s“ Gestalt annahm, 79 boten die unmittelbare Herausfor<strong>de</strong>rung,<br />

eine liberale Antwort vorzubereiten, die sowohl auf Europa bezugnehmen<br />

als auch die Einbindung in die Weltwirtschaft gewährleisten wür<strong>de</strong>. Die auf<br />

weltweite, „internationale Integration“ angelegten neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Zwischenkriegszeit wur<strong>de</strong>n daher nicht <strong>de</strong>r europäischen „regionalen<br />

Integration“ geopfert, son<strong>de</strong>rn mit dieser verknüpft: Röpke bezeichnete eine fö<strong>de</strong>rative<br />

„Block”-Bildung als „<strong>of</strong>fen”, 80 ins<strong>of</strong>ern als dieser „Block“ (Röpke) mit <strong>de</strong>n<br />

an<strong>de</strong>ren Staaten <strong>de</strong>r Welt in einer liberalen Markt-, Preis- und Zahlungsgemeinschaft<br />

vereint wäre. Das liberale System eines multilateralen und freien Wirtschaftsverkehrs<br />

sollte nicht bloß auf „regionaler“ Basis wie in einer europäischen<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration, son<strong>de</strong>rn auch international Geltung erlangen. Mit <strong>de</strong>r auf Multilateralität,<br />

einem internationalen Währungssystem und einer konformen Han<strong>de</strong>lspolitik 81<br />

beruhen<strong>de</strong>n Weltwirtschaft, die an <strong>de</strong>n Rahmen einer internationalen Rechtsordnung<br />

und <strong>de</strong>s dazugehörigen Normensystems gebun<strong>de</strong>n ist, verfochten Röpke, 82<br />

Rüstow, 83 Robbins 84 und von Haberler 85 die Alternative „Kollektivismus – laissez<br />

faire“ in <strong>de</strong>n wirtschaftlichen Beziehungen <strong>de</strong>r Staaten o<strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>rationen zu überwin<strong>de</strong>n.<br />

Die auf marktwirtschaftlichen Prinzipien grün<strong>de</strong>n<strong>de</strong> weltwirtschaftliche<br />

Ordnung war dabei nicht als Kompromiß zwischen internationalem Kollektivismus<br />

und internationalem laissez faire gedacht, son<strong>de</strong>rn als ein tertium, als eine dritte<br />

Möglichkeit, die we<strong>de</strong>r mit <strong>de</strong>m Kollektivismus noch mit <strong>de</strong>m laissez faire etwas<br />

gemeinsam haben wür<strong>de</strong>.<br />

Robbins und Röpke beobachteten im Verlauf <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges, daß sich die<br />

Entstehung eines gemeinsamen europäischen Bewußtseins abzeichnete, 86 das auf <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Umwandlung <strong>de</strong>s Nationalgefühls beruhte und Grundlage einer Art von „europäischem<br />

Patriotismus“ (Röpke) wer<strong>de</strong>n könnte. In seinem Entwurf zur Studie The Economics <strong>of</strong><br />

International Fe<strong>de</strong>ration (31.10.1939) ging Röpke von <strong>de</strong>r Überlegung aus, daß für die<br />

politische „Integration“ echte Lei<strong>de</strong>nschaft notwendig sei und zwar eine Art von<br />

„europäischem Patriotismus“, da Lei<strong>de</strong>nschaften und Gefühle stärker seien als ökonomi-<br />

79. W. LOTH, Rettungsanker Europa? Deutsche Europa-Konzeptionen vom Dritten Reich bis zur<br />

Bun<strong>de</strong>srepublik, in: H.-E. VOLKMANN (Hrsg.), En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s Dritten Reiches – En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten<br />

Weltkriegs, Serie Piper 2056, München, 1995, S.201-204.<br />

80. W. RÖPKE, Die internationale Wirtschaftsordnung <strong>de</strong>r Zukunft, Pläne und Probleme, in: Schweizer<br />

Monatshefte, 22(1942), S.375.<br />

81. Die konforme Han<strong>de</strong>lspolitik beschränkt sich auf eine maßvolle Schutzzollpolitik im Gegensatz<br />

zur nichtkonformen Han<strong>de</strong>lspolitik (Kontingents-, Clearings- und Monopolpolitik).<br />

82. W. RÖPKE, Die Lehre von <strong>de</strong>r Wirtschaft (1937), 2., unverän<strong>de</strong>rte Auflage, Erlenbach-Zürich,<br />

1943, S.45 ff.; W. RÖPKE, Civitas Humana, op.cit., S.389.<br />

83. A. RÜSTOW, Nachwort zu W. RÖPKE, International Economic Dis<strong>integration</strong>, op.cit.,<br />

S.274-278.<br />

84. L. ROBBINS, Economic Planning …, op.cit., S.247; L. ROBBINS, Economic Aspects <strong>of</strong> Fe<strong>de</strong>ration,<br />

op.cit., S.185.<br />

85. G. von HABERLER, The Political Economy …, op.cit., S.340-342.<br />

86. L. ROBBINS, The Economic Causes <strong>of</strong> War, op.cit., S.106; W. RÖPKE, The Economics <strong>of</strong> International<br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ration, Projektskizze, Genf, 31.10.1939, in: IUHEI, 40ème anniversaire 1927-1967,<br />

Genf, 1967, S.95; W. RÖPKE, Internationale Ordnung, op.cit., S.56.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 31<br />

sche Interessen und die wirtschaftlichen Konsequenzen einer Fö<strong>de</strong>ration ertragen ließen.<br />

Die Grundlagen <strong>de</strong>s europäischen Patriotismus sahen Röpke und Robbins im europäischen<br />

patrimonium, <strong>de</strong>m gemeinsamen kulturellen Erbe Europas. An eine gemeinsame<br />

gesprochene Sprache (vgl. Her<strong>de</strong>r, Fichte, Meinecke) konnte das europäische Bewußtsein<br />

nicht unmittelbar anknüpfen, jedoch an die gemeinsamen Werte, die durch die griechische<br />

und römische Kultur, die christliche und aufklärerische Tradition vermittelt wur<strong>de</strong>n und in<br />

<strong>de</strong>r humanistischen Bildung vereint waren. Mit Humanität und Toleranz, Vernunft und<br />

Freiheit, Gerechtigkeit und religiöser Ehrfurcht wur<strong>de</strong> von Robbins und Röpke <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Kanon <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Werte beschrieben, die sich in gemeinsamen Gewohnheiten und<br />

einer bestimmten europäischen Lebensart ausdrückten. Röpke zog zur Bestimmung <strong>de</strong>s<br />

europäischen Bewußtseins <strong>de</strong>n Begriff <strong>de</strong>r „Schicksalsgemeinschaft“ heran, <strong>de</strong>r in <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Literatur <strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>utschen Romantik ein Topos dargestellt hatte und von Otto Bauer in die<br />

Nationalismus-Forschung eingeführt wor<strong>de</strong>n war.<br />

Hatten Hayes und Katz auf die Abgrenzung von <strong>de</strong>n An<strong>de</strong>ren und auf die einigen<strong>de</strong><br />

Wirkung eines gemeinsamen Fein<strong>de</strong>s als Bedingung für die Herausbildung<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Wir-Gefühls bei <strong>de</strong>n Angehörigen einer Nation hingewiesen, so erkannten<br />

Röpke und Robbins im Kampf gegen <strong>de</strong>n „Totalitarismus“ und in <strong>de</strong>r gemeinsamen<br />

Erfahrung <strong>de</strong>r Lei<strong>de</strong>n <strong>de</strong>s Krieges eine Chance für die Herausbildung <strong>de</strong>r<br />

europäischen I<strong>de</strong>ntität. 87 De Madariaga sah im Rahmen seiner Studie für das<br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union Research Institute die Schaffung eines permanenten Rates <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

vor, <strong>de</strong>m die Überwachung <strong>de</strong>r Erziehung und Bildung obliegen sollte. Eine<br />

auf die „supernationale“ I<strong>de</strong>ntität ausgerichtete Erziehung und Bildung wäre mittels<br />

Radio, Film, Zeitungen und Theater zu för<strong>de</strong>rn. 88 Der Zweck einer europäischen<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration läge nach Einaudi in <strong>de</strong>r För<strong>de</strong>rung <strong>de</strong>s kulturellen und geistigen<br />

Lebens <strong>de</strong>r einzelnen Glie<strong>de</strong>r, da die Menschen durch die wirtschaftliche Vereinigung<br />

vom Materiellen befreit und nicht etwa versklavt wür<strong>de</strong>n. 89 Anhand <strong>de</strong>s Beispiels<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Kantone <strong>de</strong>r Schweizerischen Eidgenossenschaft und <strong>de</strong>r amerikanischen<br />

Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaaten zeigte Einaudi auf, daß die Befürchtungen <strong>de</strong>r Gegner <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus unbegrün<strong>de</strong>t seien, wonach in einer europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration die<br />

nationalen Kulturen, ihre geistigen Werte, ihre Forschung, ihre Literatur, Musik<br />

und Kunst untergehen müßten und das kulturelle und intellektuelle Leben auf diejenigen<br />

Orte beschränkt sein wür<strong>de</strong>, die zugleich Schwerpunkte wirtschaftlicher<br />

Entwicklung wären.<br />

Im kulturell <strong>de</strong>finierten Europa Röpkes, Robbins‘ und Einaudis sollte Deutschland<br />

unverzichtbares Mitglied sein, wäre <strong>de</strong>r Nationalsozialismus erst einmal „ausgerottet“<br />

und hätten sich die Deutschen vom Totalitarismus geläutert. Großbritannien, gegen <strong>de</strong>s-<br />

87. C.J.H. HAYES, The Historical Evolution <strong>of</strong> Mo<strong>de</strong>rn Nationalism (1931), New York, 1963, S.161<br />

f.; D. KATZ, The Psychology <strong>of</strong> Nationalism, in: J.P. GUILFORD (Hrsg.), Fields <strong>of</strong> Psychology,<br />

New York, 1940, S.163–181; L. ROBBINS, The Economic Causes <strong>of</strong> War, op.cit., S.109; W.<br />

RÖPKE, The Economics <strong>of</strong> International Fe<strong>de</strong>ration, op.cit., S.96; W. RÖPKE, Internationale<br />

Ordnung, op.cit., S.57-61.<br />

88. S. <strong>de</strong> MADARIAGA, Note on Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Powers over Education, in: Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union Research Institute,<br />

Second Annual Report, London, 1941.<br />

89. L. EINAUDI, I problemi economici …, op.cit., S.110.


32<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

sen Mitgliedschaft Robbins und Einaudi auch keine Einwän<strong>de</strong> gelten ließen, stand in<br />

Röpkes Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzept die Führungsrolle zu, nach<strong>de</strong>m es sich durch seine Erfahrung<br />

mit <strong>de</strong>m British Empire, durch seine historische Rolle als ausgleichen<strong>de</strong> Macht in<br />

Europa und Hüterin <strong>de</strong>r Pax Britannica sowie durch seinen Kampf gegen <strong>de</strong>n Nationalsozialismus<br />

zu dieser Aufgabe legitimiert hatte.<br />

3.3. Staatssouveränität und Nationalismus in <strong>de</strong>r Einschätzung neoliberaler<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten während <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges<br />

Röpke und Einaudi orientierten ihre Konzepte am Vorbild eines Fö<strong>de</strong>rativstaates<br />

wie <strong>de</strong>r Schweiz, in <strong>de</strong>m die Eigenrechte <strong>de</strong>r einzelnen Glie<strong>de</strong>r respektiert wer<strong>de</strong>n.<br />

Die Voraussetzung für eine so geartete Fö<strong>de</strong>ration wäre nach Röpke und von<br />

Hayek 90 die fö<strong>de</strong>rative Umbildung <strong>de</strong>r zentralisierten Staaten selbst, so daß sich<br />

schließlich die Glie<strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>r Nation so verhalten wür<strong>de</strong>n wie die Nation zur „Übernation“.<br />

Die Aufgaben wür<strong>de</strong>n bei Röpke, Einaudi und von Hayek jeweils nach<br />

<strong>de</strong>m Subsidiaritätsprinzip zwischen <strong>de</strong>n Glie<strong>de</strong>rn <strong>de</strong>r untersten Stufe und <strong>de</strong>n<br />

jeweils umfassen<strong>de</strong>ren Verbän<strong>de</strong>n o<strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>m Bund verteilt, in<strong>de</strong>m <strong>de</strong>r größeren Einheit<br />

nur diejenigen Aufgaben zufallen, die sich für die kleineren Einheiten als zu<br />

universell erwiesen haben. 91 Röpke bezeichnete diese Fö<strong>de</strong>ration als „internationale<br />

Gemeinschaft“ und bestritt die Notwendigkeit einer „supranationalen Gemeinschaft“,<br />

da diese Struktur zu zentralistisch wäre und einer fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Durchgestaltung<br />

entgegenstün<strong>de</strong>. 92 Um <strong>de</strong>n fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Charakter <strong>de</strong>s Zusammenschlusses<br />

<strong>de</strong>utlich zu machen, sprach von Hayek von einer „Gemeinschaft von Nationen<br />

freier Menschen“ und nicht von einer „Vereinigung von 'freien Nationen'”. 93<br />

Dem Verlangen <strong>de</strong>r Einzelstaaten nach Selbständigkeit kam von Hayek entgegen,<br />

in<strong>de</strong>m er ihnen die Autonomie in inneren Angelegenheiten beließ und <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration nur<br />

ein „Minimum an Befugnissen“ zugestand. Von Hayek beschrieb 1945 die Befugnisse<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration als „im wesentlichen“ mit <strong>de</strong>n „Befugnissen <strong>de</strong>s ultraliberalen ‚Laissez-faire‘-Staates”<br />

94 übereinstimmend. Aus <strong>de</strong>m Kontext gelöst, erweist sich dieser Vergleich<br />

als irreführend und wi<strong>de</strong>rsprüchlich sowohl zu von Hayeks Fö<strong>de</strong>rationsentwurf<br />

von 1939 als auch zu seiner eigenen Kritik am laissez faire-Begriff und an <strong>de</strong>n Anhängern<br />

eines extremen laissez faire-Prinzips im Weg zur Knechtschaft (1945). 95 Auf die Befugnisse<br />

<strong>de</strong>s laissez faire-Staates rekurrierte von Hayek 1945 in Abhebung von <strong>de</strong>n Befugnissen,<br />

welche <strong>de</strong>m Staat „in jüngster Zeit“ übertragen wor<strong>de</strong>n waren. Unter letzteren<br />

sind die staatlichen Lenkungsbefugnisse <strong>de</strong>r Kriegswirtschaft, die keynesianische Wirtschaftspolitik<br />

und die Aufgaben <strong>de</strong>s „Wohlfahrtsstaats“ zu verstehen. Die Befugnisse <strong>de</strong>s<br />

laissez faire-Staates, welche von Hayek an die politische Instanz <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration übertra-<br />

90. F.A. von HAYEK, Der Weg zur Knechtschaft, op.cit., S.285-289.<br />

91. W. RÖPKE, Internationale Ordnung, op.cit., S.55; L. EINAUDI, I problemi economici …, op.cit.,<br />

S.7; F.A. von HAYEK, Der Weg zur Knechtschaft, op.cit., S.288 f.<br />

92. W. RÖPKE, op.cit., S.55 ff.<br />

93. F.A. von HAYEK, Der Weg zur Knechtschaft, op.cit., S.287 und 291.<br />

94. Ibid., S.286. Hervorhebung MW.<br />

95. Ibid., S.111 und 37.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 33<br />

gen wissen wollte, sollten darauf ausgerichtet sein, wirtschaftliche Restriktionen aller Art<br />

zu verhin<strong>de</strong>rn. Damit ist gesagt, daß es einen Staat, <strong>de</strong>r nicht han<strong>de</strong>lt noch Eingriffe<br />

macht, nicht geben darf, 96 son<strong>de</strong>rn dass „ein weites und unumstrittenes Gebiet für die<br />

Betätigung“ <strong>de</strong>s Staates darin besteht, die Bedingungen für das Funktionieren <strong>de</strong>s Wettbewerbs<br />

zu schaffen und Leistungen dort zu erbringen, wo kein echter Wettbewerb möglich<br />

ist. 97 4. Gemeinsamkeiten und Beson<strong>de</strong>rheiten <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte <strong>de</strong>s<br />

liberalen Internationalismus und <strong>de</strong>s nichtkommunistischen Wi<strong>de</strong>rstan<strong>de</strong>s<br />

Die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte aus Italien, Frankreich, Großbritannien und<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Schweiz teilten mit <strong>de</strong>n nichtkommunistischen Wi<strong>de</strong>rstandsgruppen in allen<br />

europäischen Län<strong>de</strong>rn die Absage an <strong>de</strong>n übersteigerten Nationalismus, die Wie<strong>de</strong>rherstellung<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Rechts und <strong>de</strong>r Menschenrechte, <strong>de</strong>n inneren Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus<br />

gegen <strong>de</strong>n zentralisierten Nationalstaat, die „freiwillige“ Fö<strong>de</strong>rierung <strong>de</strong>r europäischen<br />

Völker gegen die „totale Zusammenfassung“ und die Beschränkung <strong>de</strong>r<br />

nationalstaatlichen Souveränität. Wie fast alle nichtkommunistischen Wi<strong>de</strong>rstandsautoren<br />

bejahten die Neoliberalen in ihren Schriften während <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges<br />

die Teilnahme <strong>de</strong>r Deutschen an einer europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration nach <strong>de</strong>m<br />

En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s NS-Regimes und gingen von <strong>de</strong>r Freigabe <strong>de</strong>r Kolonien bzw. <strong>de</strong>r Öffnung<br />

ihrer Märkte aus. Mit ihrer wirtschaftlichen Kritik, die in <strong>de</strong>r Kolonialpolitik weit<br />

höhere Kosten als Gewinne erkannte und <strong>de</strong>n Imperialismus als mit <strong>de</strong>r Vorstellung<br />

einer liberalen Gesellschaft und <strong>de</strong>m Liberalismus überhaupt unvereinbar<br />

erklärte, 98 stellten sich die Neoliberalen in die Tradition <strong>de</strong>r angelsächsischen Liberalen,<br />

die im frühen 19. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rt <strong>de</strong>n Erwerb von Kolonien bekämpft hatten.<br />

Die Entwürfe Einaudis, Robbins' und von Hayeks vom En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s Ersten bis zum<br />

Beginn <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkriegs hatten sich jedoch von <strong>de</strong>r Mehrheit <strong>de</strong>r zeitgenössischen<br />

Pläne abgehoben, ins<strong>of</strong>ern als sie die entschlossene Einschränkung <strong>de</strong>r<br />

nationalstaatlichen Souveränität for<strong>de</strong>rten und nicht nur eine Assoziation von Staaten<br />

unter behutsamer Begrenzung ihrer Souveränität. Von an<strong>de</strong>ren nichtkommunistischen<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepten, die während <strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkieges verfaßt wor<strong>de</strong>n<br />

waren, unterschie<strong>de</strong>n sich die neoliberalen Entwürfe dieser Jahre, in<strong>de</strong>m sie<br />

die Rückkehr zu marktwirtschaftlichen Wirtschaftsformen als Voraussetzung zur<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>rierung Europas erachteten und <strong>de</strong>r Sozialisierung in allen damals erörterten<br />

Formen entgegentraten.<br />

96. Vgl. ibid., S.111.<br />

97. Ibid., S.62.<br />

98. F.A. von HAYEK, Der Weg zur Knechtschaft, op.cit., S.276. R. HAUF, (Hrsg.), Denkschrift 2 <strong>de</strong>s<br />

„Freiburger Kreises“, in: K. SCHWABE (Hrsg.), Gerhard Ritter, Ein politischer Historiker in<br />

seinen Briefen, Boppard, 1984, S.723 f. und 754; L. ROBBINS, The Economics <strong>of</strong> Territorial Sovereignty,<br />

in: L. ROBBINS, The Economic Basis …, op.cit., S.95 f.; L. ROBBINS, The Economic<br />

Causes <strong>of</strong> War, op.cit., S.73-78; W. RÖPKE, Internationale Ordnung, op.cit., S.78.


34<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

5. Zusammenfassung und Schlußfolgerung<br />

Die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten vertraten 1918-1945 eine institutionell abgesicherte<br />

„liberale Fö<strong>de</strong>ration“ von Staaten als „Vollendung <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Wirtschaftsprogramms“<br />

(von Hayek) und wünschenswerte Alternative zur sozialistischen internationalen<br />

Planung. Die institutionelle Absicherung ging in ihren Konzepten über die internationale<br />

Zusammenarbeit hinaus, wenn auch unterschiedlich weit: Einaudi, Robbins<br />

und von Hayek bekannten sich zu einer „übernationalen Regierung“, wohingegen<br />

Röpke 99 zwar eine fö<strong>de</strong>rative „zwischenstaatliche Gemeinschaft“ nach <strong>de</strong>m Muster <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaaten Schweiz und USA befürwortete, nicht jedoch eine „supranationale<br />

Gemeinschaft“. Ein so o<strong>de</strong>r ähnlich verstan<strong>de</strong>ner mittlerer Weg zwischen <strong>de</strong>m Mo<strong>de</strong>ll<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Konfö<strong>de</strong>ration und <strong>de</strong>mjenigen <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration wur<strong>de</strong> von <strong>de</strong>n britischen<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten 100 in <strong>de</strong>r Zwischenkriegszeit als in sich wi<strong>de</strong>rsprüchlich beurteilt, als eine<br />

Lösung, die höchstens vorübergehen<strong>de</strong>n Charakter haben und sich entwe<strong>de</strong>r zu einem<br />

Staatenbund o<strong>de</strong>r einem Bun<strong>de</strong>sstaat entwickeln wür<strong>de</strong>.<br />

Die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten verfochten die These, daß Wirtschaftsformen und<br />

politische Strukturen in einem engen Zuordnungsverhältnis stün<strong>de</strong>n. Aus dieser<br />

Beziehung, die bereits von Robbins und Röpke in früheren Arbeiten erkannt und<br />

durch von Hayek im Zusammenhang mit <strong>de</strong>r Frage <strong>de</strong>r Errichtung einer wirtschaftlichen<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration weiter ausgearbeitet wor<strong>de</strong>n war, leiteten die neoliberalen<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten die Entsprechung Marktwirtschaft – innerer/ äußerer Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus –<br />

Weltwirtschaft ab. Zwischen diesen liberalen wirtschaftlichen und politischen<br />

Strukturen einerseits und Kollektivismus – Zentralismus – Großraumwirtschaft<br />

an<strong>de</strong>rerseits bestand ein unüberbrückbarer Gegensatz. Zollunionen for<strong>de</strong>rten keinen<br />

Wi<strong>de</strong>rspruch heraus (Röpke), solange sie als Maßnahmen liberaler Han<strong>de</strong>lspolitik<br />

eingesetzt wür<strong>de</strong>n, und wur<strong>de</strong>n gera<strong>de</strong>zu als Synonym für die „Fö<strong>de</strong>ration“<br />

verstan<strong>de</strong>n (Einaudi, von Hayek, Robbins). Der Gefahren hochprotektionistischer<br />

Zollunionen waren die Neoliberalen allerdings einge<strong>de</strong>nk.<br />

Die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte zeichneten sich durch eine kosmopolitische<br />

Ausrichtung im Sinne <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Internationalismus aus. Freiheit und Ordnung<br />

sollten durch einen Rahmen gesetzlicher Regelungen in <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration und<br />

durch ein internationales Rechtssystem für die weltweiten zwischenstaatlichen<br />

Beziehungen gesichert sein. Dem liberalen System eines multilateralen und freien<br />

Wirtschaftsverkehrs war nicht nur regionale, son<strong>de</strong>rn internationale Geltung zugedacht.<br />

Wirtschaftspolitisch und gesellschaftlich sollten die Strukturen <strong>de</strong>r Einzelstaaten<br />

wie <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ration als ganzer liberal sein und zwar im Sinne <strong>de</strong>s erneuerten<br />

internationalistischen Liberalismus.<br />

Nach<strong>de</strong>m die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten vom En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s Ersten bis zum Beginn<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Zweiten Weltkrieges die wirtschaftlichen Aspekte von fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Zusammen-<br />

99. W. RÖPKE, Wirtschaftsverfassung und politische Weltordnung, op.cit., S.33.<br />

100. M. CHANNING-PEARCE, Introduction, in: M. CHANNING-PEARCE (Hrsg.), Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union<br />

(1940), London, 1991, S.12; F. ROSSOLILLO, La scuola fe<strong>de</strong>ralista inglese, in: S. PISTONE<br />

(Hrsg.), L’i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>de</strong>ll’unificazione europea dalla prima alla seconda guerra mondiale, Turin, 1975,<br />

S.74 f.


Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte 1918-1945 35<br />

schlüssen untersucht hatten, wandten sie sich im Zweiten Weltkrieg <strong>de</strong>n außerökonomischen<br />

Bedingungen einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration zu und erkannten <strong>de</strong>r gesellschaftlichen<br />

und kulturellen Integration eine primordiale Be<strong>de</strong>utung zu. Röpke,<br />

Robbins, Einaudi, <strong>de</strong> Madariaga und von Haberler, <strong>de</strong>r allerdings eine europäische<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration nicht unterstützte, befaßten sich mit <strong>de</strong>m gesellschaftlich-kulturellen<br />

Bild Europas und <strong>de</strong>r Frage einer europäischen I<strong>de</strong>ntität. Sie erachteten die soziale<br />

und kulturelle Integration als Vorbedingung für die ökonomische Integration und<br />

wiesen auf die Notwendigkeit einer institutionellen Absicherung hin.<br />

Die wesentlichen Merkmale, welche die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte miteinan<strong>de</strong>r<br />

teilten, sind aus <strong>de</strong>m gemeinsamen Diskurs <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen Wirtschaftswissenschafter<br />

hervorgegangen: das Zuordnungsverhältnis von Wirtschaftsformen<br />

und politischen Strukturen, die kosmopolitische Ausrichtung <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte<br />

im Sinne <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Internationalismus, <strong>de</strong>r Primat <strong>de</strong>r sozialen und kulturellen<br />

Integration vor <strong>de</strong>r ökonomischen Integration und die Absage an das laissez<br />

faire in <strong>de</strong>n internationalen Beziehungen.<br />

Dr. phil. Milène Wegmann<br />

Universität Bern


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

Früher Neoliberalismus und<br />

europäische Integration<br />

Der Neoliberalismus wird in dieser grundlegen<strong>de</strong>n<br />

archivgestützten Arbeit als eine wirtschafts- und gesellschaftspolitische<br />

Konzeption und zugleich als ein<br />

System von Personen untersucht, die durch <strong>de</strong>n<br />

Transfer von I<strong>de</strong>en miteinan<strong>de</strong>r verbun<strong>de</strong>n sind. Die<br />

Außenwirtschaftspolitik und die internationale Wirtschaftsordnung<br />

gehören zum Kern <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen<br />

Wirtschaftsordnungspolitik. Das interdisziplinär angelegte<br />

Werk ist die erste umfassen<strong>de</strong> Studie zur neoliberalen<br />

Theorie <strong>de</strong>r Inter<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nz <strong>de</strong>r Ordnung<br />

von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft auf nationaler, supranationaler<br />

und internationaler Ebene. Auf <strong>de</strong>r Suche<br />

nach einer Neuordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft<br />

brachten die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten<br />

1918-1945 eine spezifisch neoliberale Konzeption<br />

einer europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ration hervor. Nach <strong>de</strong>m<br />

Beginn <strong>de</strong>s Kalten Krieges teilten die Neoliberalen in<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Frage <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Integration weiterhin gemeinsame<br />

Ziele und Prinzipien. Weil <strong>de</strong>r Neoliberalismus<br />

einem »<strong>of</strong>fenen System« entspricht, ließ die<br />

gemeinsame Grundhaltung jedoch aufgrund unterschiedlicher<br />

national geprägter Erfahrungs- und Erwartungshorizonte<br />

konkrete Entscheidungen für o<strong>de</strong>r<br />

gegen die EWG zu.<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

Früher Neoliberalismus und<br />

europäische Integration<br />

Inter<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nz <strong>de</strong>r nationalen,<br />

supranationalen und internationalen<br />

Ordnung von Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft<br />

(1932 – 1965)<br />

2002, 574 S., brosch.,<br />

49,– €, 84,– sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7829-8<br />

NOMOS


37<br />

Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen pendant<br />

la Secon<strong>de</strong> Guerre mondiale.<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

La guerre <strong>de</strong> 1939-1945 tient une place particulière dans le renouvellement <strong>de</strong> la<br />

pensée fédéraliste. Elle est d'abord une manifestation <strong>de</strong>s égoïsmes nationaux qui<br />

ne peuvent que déboucher sur <strong>de</strong>s règlements <strong>de</strong> comptes, faute d'arbitrage juridique.<br />

Elle est ensuite une préfiguration du «grand nettoyage», logique espérée par<br />

toutes les tendances du fédéralisme <strong>de</strong> l'entre-<strong>de</strong>ux-guerres. Suivant cette <strong>de</strong>rnière,<br />

certains hommes commencent à envisager <strong>de</strong> nouveaux mo<strong>de</strong>s d'action au sein<br />

même <strong>de</strong> la Résistance.<br />

Ce sont les Italiens qui se montrent les plus prompts à formuler une définition<br />

ambitieuse du fédéralisme, à tel point qu'ils sont les premiers à mettre sur pied,<br />

avant même la fin <strong>de</strong> la guerre, une organisation susceptible <strong>de</strong> faire entendre leur<br />

voix. L'Italie apparaît donc bien comme un «laboratoire du fédéralisme militant»,<br />

qui cherche à combiner théorie et impulsion politique. L'opération <strong>de</strong> «médiatisation»<br />

se fait au sein <strong>de</strong> la Résistance et dans l'exil, précisément dans cette Suisse<br />

neutre qui <strong>de</strong>vient le refuge <strong>de</strong> nombreux Italiens vers la fin <strong>de</strong> la guerre. C'est dans<br />

le cadre <strong>de</strong> cet exil que les premiers contacts vont être établis en <strong>de</strong>hors <strong>de</strong> la communauté<br />

italienne, permettant au fédéralisme <strong>de</strong> franchir les frontières et ainsi<br />

d’acquérir une véritable dimension européenne. Cette dimension européenne est<br />

précisément la seule à même <strong>de</strong> faire comprendre l'originalité <strong>de</strong> l'idée fédéraliste<br />

au sein <strong>de</strong> la Résistance, et l'importance qu'elle a pu avoir après la guerre. Nous<br />

sommes ainsi en désaccord avec l'idée défendue par certains chercheurs, selon<br />

laquelle le fédéralisme ne trouve sa force doctrinale qu'à partir <strong>de</strong> 1945. 1 Certes, si<br />

l'on se réfère à l'exemple français, il est évi<strong>de</strong>nt que la Résistance contrôlée peu à<br />

peu par <strong>de</strong> Gaulle a effacé les différences idéologiques d'un bloc que l'on veut<br />

monolithique, et opposé par nature à tout ce qui est fédéraliste. 2 En revanche, une<br />

étu<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> ce même courant dans le milieu <strong>de</strong> la résistance italienne y montre une<br />

vigueur exceptionnelle, 3 alors que l'on peut voir dans l'organisation du Movimento<br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista Europeo (1943) une préfiguration <strong>de</strong> l’Union Européenne <strong>de</strong>s Fédéralistes,<br />

qui sera effectivement créée en 1946.<br />

A trop étudier l'activisme fédéraliste à l'intérieur <strong>de</strong>s frontières nationales, il est<br />

difficile <strong>de</strong> donner les éléments <strong>de</strong> réflexion susceptibles <strong>de</strong> faire comprendre le<br />

1. Chr. REVEILLARD, Les tentatives <strong>de</strong> construction d'une Europe fédérée (l940-1954). Le fédéralisme<br />

européen contre les nations, Université <strong>de</strong> Paris, 1995, p.100. On trouve la même idée défendue<br />

par A. GREILSAMMER, Les mouvements fédéralistes en France <strong>de</strong> 1945 à 1974, Paris,<br />

Presses d’Europe, 1975, p.33.<br />

2. On peut en trouver une confirmation dans les souvenirs du résistant et fédéraliste H. FRENAY, La<br />

nuit finira, Robert Laffont, Paris, 1973, pp.254-257.<br />

3. Voir en particulier la thèse <strong>de</strong> P. GRAGLIA, L'europeismo nella lotta antifascista: il movimento<br />

di "Giustizia e Liberta" ed i fe<strong>de</strong>ralisti di Ventotene (1929-1943), Facoltà di Scienze Politiche, Firenze,<br />

1988.


38<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

renouveau et la place du fédéralisme européen dans l'après-guerre. On peut même<br />

dire, dans le cas français, que l'étu<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> l'idée fédéraliste sert bien souvent à illustrer<br />

sa nocivité et à justifier a posteriori l'apparente désaffection à son égard. Pour<br />

nous au contraire, l'idée fédéraliste a une place essentielle dans la Résistance, un<br />

«dénominateur commun» selon les mots <strong>de</strong> Norberto Bobbio, qui ne pouvait<br />

qu'éclore dans une pério<strong>de</strong> bouleversée. La guerre, combattue par les fédéralistes,<br />

sera cependant toujours revendiquée par eux comme étant l'une <strong>de</strong> leurs matrices,<br />

comme moteur <strong>de</strong> leur engagement à 1a détruire. 4 A l’image <strong>de</strong> la plupart <strong>de</strong>s idées<br />

politiques qui se font entendre dans l'immédiat après-guerre en Europe, le fédéralisme<br />

s'élève sur un champ <strong>de</strong> ruines, s'insère dans une réalité guerrière et cette origine<br />

le marquera pour longtemps, en particulier dans ses difficultés à s’adapter au<br />

cadre politique inédit <strong>de</strong> la Libération, marqué par la Guerre froi<strong>de</strong>. Il est donc intéressant<br />

<strong>de</strong> voir, à travers son élaboration, comment l’Europe <strong>de</strong>vient une alternative<br />

politique à part entière, et <strong>de</strong> quelle manière les fédéralistes se préparent aux enjeux<br />

<strong>de</strong> l'après-guerre. L’étu<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> l'action <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes italiens pendant la guerre est<br />

donc un bon moyen d'abor<strong>de</strong>r la naissance d'un véritable courant «scientifique»<br />

issu d'une pensée jusque-là brouillonne. Nous verrons aussi comment cette pensée,<br />

déterminée et mo<strong>de</strong>lée selon les circonstances d'une guerre totale, a dû s'adapter au<br />

cadre <strong>de</strong> la Libération.<br />

Les Archives Historiques <strong>de</strong>s Communautés Européennes <strong>de</strong> Florence contiennent<br />

<strong>de</strong> nombreuses sources qui permettent d'éclairer les premiers balbutiements <strong>de</strong><br />

la pensée fédéraliste au sein <strong>de</strong> la Résistance, notamment à travers une volumineuse<br />

documentation <strong>de</strong> diverses origines (fonds Walter Lipgens). Le fonds Altiero<br />

Spinelli éclaire les motivations et le parcours du plus bouillant <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes ainsi<br />

que son activité fébrile, dont on peut sentir l'intensité à travers sa correspondance,<br />

ses écrits ou ses rapports, ainsi que son rôle dans la rédaction du premier document<br />

politique du fédéralisme européen <strong>de</strong> la Résistance, le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene. Ces<br />

travaux permettent également <strong>de</strong> mesurer l'apport intellectuel et l'impact <strong>de</strong> cette<br />

forte personnalité, dans une action qui se veut avant tout collective. 5 D'autres<br />

acteurs italiens ont laissé <strong>de</strong>s souvenirs <strong>de</strong> leur action, dont certains se limitent à<br />

raconter un épiso<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> leur vie: c’est le cas par exemple du fédéraliste Luciano<br />

Bolis qui, dans Mon grain <strong>de</strong> sable, 6 raconte son arrestation par les fascistes à la fin<br />

<strong>de</strong> la guerre, et nous permet <strong>de</strong> comprendre l'importance <strong>de</strong> la Résistance dans son<br />

engagement fédéraliste. Concernant plus précisément l'action menée par les fédéralistes<br />

italiens en terre helvétique à partir <strong>de</strong> septembre 1943, <strong>de</strong> nombreuses<br />

4. «La guerre ne change pas substantiellement les problèmes <strong>de</strong> vie et <strong>de</strong> mort qu’il nous faut résoudre.<br />

Mais elle précipite, elle accélère furieusement leur évolution, elle transforme en un processus<br />

paroxystique ce qui normalement se serait étalé sur un grand espace <strong>de</strong> temps, et elle change avec<br />

une extraordinaire rapidité les conditions <strong>de</strong> réalisation historique», J. MARITAIN, L’Europe et<br />

l'idée fédérale, Mame, Paris, 1993, p.51 (texte écrit en 1940).<br />

5. Voir l'autobiographie d'A. SPINELLI, Come ho tentato di diventare saggio. La goccia e la roccia,<br />

Il Mulino, Bologna, 1987.<br />

6. L. BOLIS, Il mio granello di sabbia, Einaudi, 1946; éd. française, Mon grain <strong>de</strong> sable, La Fosse<br />

aux Ours, Lyon, 1997.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 39<br />

recherches ont été menées outre-Alpes, 7 qui continuent actuellement sous la houlette<br />

du pr<strong>of</strong>esseur Luigi V. Majocchi au Département d'Histoire <strong>de</strong> l'Université <strong>de</strong><br />

Pavie, grâce à l'ouverture d’archives inédites <strong>de</strong> certains <strong>de</strong>s acteurs fédéralistes italiens,<br />

telles que celles <strong>de</strong> Guglielmo Usellini. 8 Enfin, il faut revenir aux Archives <strong>de</strong><br />

Florence pour tout ce qui touche à l'organisation du premier mouvement fédéraliste<br />

européen dans l'après-guerre, l'Union Européenne <strong>de</strong>s Fédéralistes, dont le fonds<br />

est riche <strong>de</strong> plus <strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>ux cents dossiers.<br />

1) Le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene: 9 genèse et enseignements.<br />

Les Italiens sont-ils les initiateurs du militantisme fédéraliste, tel qu'il va s'imposer<br />

à l'issue du conflit? On aurait tendance à le penser en étudiant les textes qu'ils font<br />

alors circuler, au premier chef le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, l'organisation clan<strong>de</strong>stine<br />

qu'ils mettent en place dans leur pays, et enfin les liens qu'ils tissent autour d'eux<br />

avant même la fin <strong>de</strong> la guerre. Il est vrai que les réflexions italiennes sur un éventuel<br />

Etat européen s'appuient sur un héritage d'avant-guerre conséquent. L'un <strong>de</strong>s<br />

auteurs les plus revendiqués par les fédéralistes italiens dès le début du conflit est<br />

l'un <strong>de</strong> leurs compatriotes, Luigi Einaudi, futur prési<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong> la République. Ce <strong>de</strong>rnier<br />

avait écrit dès 1918, dans le Corriere <strong>de</strong>lla Sera, <strong>de</strong>ux articles virulents contre<br />

«l'internationalisme bâtard» que mettait en place la Société <strong>de</strong>s Nations, système<br />

incapable <strong>de</strong> résoudre les problèmes européens et ne pouvant empêcher, par conséquent,<br />

l'exaspération <strong>de</strong> conflits non réglés. 10 Il n'est pas anachronique <strong>de</strong> parler <strong>de</strong><br />

ces textes, dans la mesure où ils sont connus <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes italiens <strong>de</strong> la<br />

Résistance, qui iront jusqu’à les faire publier dans la clan<strong>de</strong>stinité, adoptant ainsi<br />

les points <strong>de</strong> vue <strong>de</strong> l'auteur qui, lui-même, adhère au Movimento Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista Europeo<br />

dès sa création, en 1943. Les critiques <strong>de</strong> Luigi Einaudi sont d'ailleurs «intemporelles»:<br />

elles ne traitent pas précisément <strong>de</strong> la SDN, mais <strong>de</strong>s problèmes que soulève<br />

tout type d'organisation internationale. D'après lui, la SDN est une mauvaise<br />

réponse à ces problèmes, dans la mesure où elle ne s’attaque pas au fond <strong>de</strong> la<br />

7. E. SIGNORI, La Svizzera e i fuorusciti italiani. Problemi e aspetti <strong>de</strong>ll'emigrazione politica,<br />

1943-1945, Milano, 1983; R. BROGGINI, Terra d'asilo. I rifugiati italiani in Svizzera, 1943-1945,<br />

Bologna, 1993; F. POZZOLI, Il fe<strong>de</strong>ralismo europeo organizzato in Svizzera 1943-1945, thèse,<br />

1994-95, Luigi V. Majocchi (directeur).<br />

8. Voir la thèse <strong>de</strong> C. R. MERLO, Guglielmo Usellini, un socialista-fe<strong>de</strong>ralista rifugiato in Svizzera<br />

(dicembre 1943-maggio 1945), thèse, 1994-95, Luigi V. Majocchi (directeur).<br />

9. Le Manifeste ayant été publié maintes fois, nous nous contentons ici <strong>de</strong> signaler sa présence dans<br />

W. LIPGENS, Documents on the History <strong>of</strong> European Integration, vol.1, Continental Plans for<br />

European Union, 1939-1945, De Gruyter, Berlin, New York, 1985, pp.471-484.<br />

10. Luigi Einaudi a d'abord écrit, dans le Corriere <strong>de</strong>lla Sera, «La Società <strong>de</strong>lle Nazioni è un i<strong>de</strong>ale<br />

possibile?» (édition du 5 janvier 1918), puis, «Il dogma <strong>de</strong>lla sovranità e l'i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>de</strong>lla Società <strong>de</strong>lle<br />

Nazioni» (28 décembre 1918). Ces <strong>de</strong>ux articles figurent également dans les Lettere Politiche publiées<br />

à Bari, en 1920, sous le pseudonyme <strong>de</strong> «Junius», puis sous son vrai nom dans La guerra e<br />

l'unità europea, Milano, 1948, réédité en 1950, qui contient les principaux écrits fédéralistes d'Einaudi<br />

datant <strong>de</strong> la pério<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> 1918 à 1948.


40<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

question, celui <strong>de</strong> la souveraineté nationale (premier article). C'est pourquoi<br />

Einaudi propose un autre modèle propre à résoudre les problèmes européens (et<br />

c'est sur ce chapitre que les fédéralistes italiens l'ont suivi), celui <strong>de</strong>s Etats-Unis<br />

d'Amérique, c'est-à-dire celui <strong>de</strong> l'intégration institutionnelle. Le <strong>de</strong>uxième article<br />

est dans la continuité du premier, dans la mesure où il donne les raisons qui ren<strong>de</strong>nt<br />

nécessaire l'unification européenne: il s'agit <strong>de</strong> l'interdépendance économique<br />

croissante <strong>de</strong>s Etats entre eux, qu'en bon libéral il juge plus forte que les réalités<br />

politiques nationales. On peut comprendre l'importance accordée par les fédéralistes<br />

à ces textes qu'ils vont en gran<strong>de</strong> partie récupérer, dans la mesure où, pour<br />

la première fois, les raisons <strong>de</strong> l'unité européenne ne ressortissent pas exclusivement<br />

d'un point <strong>de</strong> vue moralisateur ou pacifiste, mais d'une véritable discussion<br />

critique permise par les incohérences <strong>de</strong> la SDN. 11<br />

Le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene peut faire comprendre les caractéristiques principales<br />

du fédéralisme «<strong>de</strong> guerre». L'une <strong>de</strong>s raisons essentielles en est qu'il a systématiquement<br />

été revendiqué par les fédéralistes eux-mêmes comme l'acte <strong>de</strong> naissance<br />

<strong>de</strong> la vocation politique du fédéralisme, <strong>de</strong> même que son principal initiateur,<br />

Altiero Spinelli, est reconnu comme l'une <strong>de</strong>s personnalités fédéralistes les plus<br />

actives <strong>de</strong> l'après-guerre. L'autre raison en est que le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, outre<br />

les avancées doctrinales qu'il représente dans les domaines politiques et sociaux,<br />

marque un changement majeur dans la perception fédéraliste du mon<strong>de</strong>, qui ne peut<br />

être séparé <strong>de</strong>s conditions dans lesquelles il a été écrit: œuvre clan<strong>de</strong>stine, rédigée<br />

dans les geôles mussoliniennes en 1941, il fait le constat d'un mon<strong>de</strong> qui a sombré<br />

à nouveau dans les affres <strong>de</strong> la guerre, entraîné par la mécanique guerrière du nationalisme.<br />

On ne peut comprendre l'impact <strong>de</strong> ce document dans les cercles fédéralistes, ni<br />

même sa nouveauté, si l'on a pas à l'esprit ce qu'était le fédéralisme avant la guerre,<br />

alors représenté par <strong>de</strong>s mouvements hétéroclites repoussant d'eux-mêmes l'appellation<br />

<strong>de</strong> «fédéralistes». 12 Or, le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, bientôt suivi par divers<br />

textes comme la Déclaration <strong>de</strong>s Résistances européennes (juillet 1944), lui aussi<br />

d'origine italienne, revendique le cadre européen comme étant nécessaire pour<br />

mener une réforme radicale dans les domaines politiques et sociaux. Ce texte,<br />

même s'il faut lui reconnaître une certaine confi<strong>de</strong>ntialité, marque l'introduction,<br />

dans le débat politique, d'un européisme plus militant, constat à la fois d'un sentiment<br />

d'échec et d'une volonté d'en sortir, moule multiforme dans lequel se reconnaissent<br />

tous ceux qui veulent réformer une société jugée «selérosée».<br />

Le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene est rédigé par Altiero Spinelli en collaboration avec<br />

Emesto Rossi, pr<strong>of</strong>esseur d'économie, et avec le socialiste Eugenio Colorni, rédac-<br />

11. La SDN sert également <strong>de</strong> point <strong>de</strong> départ à une autre réflexion <strong>de</strong> type fédéraliste <strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>ux auteurs<br />

italiens, Giovanni Agnelli (fondateur <strong>de</strong> la FIAT) et Attilio Cabiati qui, dans Fe<strong>de</strong>razione Europea<br />

o Lega <strong>de</strong>lle Nazioni?, Torino, 1918, reprochent à la SDN les mêmes défauts qu'Einaudi, plus précisément<br />

la nullité du Tribunal Suprême, et appellent encore plus fortement que lui à la mise en<br />

place <strong>de</strong> la Fédération européenne.<br />

12. Pour Christophe Réveillard, le fédéralisme <strong>de</strong> l'entre-<strong>de</strong>ux-guerres «conservait un caractère <strong>de</strong><br />

confi<strong>de</strong>ntialité affirmée et impliquait la cooptation», op.cit., p.13.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 41<br />

teur en chef <strong>de</strong> l'Avanti. Spinelli est un «militant-né»: très jeune, il entre dans l'activité<br />

clan<strong>de</strong>stine antifasciste du Parti communiste italien dont il <strong>de</strong>vient secrétaire<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Jeunesses pour l’Italie centrale. Le 3 juin 1927, il a seulement 20 ans lorsqu'il<br />

est arrêté par la police mussolinienne, et condamné à 16 ans et 8 mois <strong>de</strong> prison par<br />

le Tribunal spécial fasciste (Tribunal <strong>de</strong> Sûreté <strong>de</strong> l'Etat). Après 10 années <strong>de</strong> prison,<br />

malgré quelques lois d'amnistie, il est maintenu en détention au printemps<br />

1937 à Ponza, 13 avant d'être transféré en juin 1939 sur l'île <strong>de</strong> Ventotene. Mais en<br />

1935, la rupture est consommée, à l'occasion d'une réunion clan<strong>de</strong>stine du parti à<br />

Ponza, où Spinelli se refuse à prendre partie contre Zinoviev, Kamenev et Boukharine,<br />

accusés d'être <strong>de</strong>s espions. Cette rupture n’est pas seulement motivée par <strong>de</strong>s<br />

raisons conjoncturelles: il y a également à ce moment-là dans la démarche <strong>de</strong> Spinelli<br />

la recherche d'une nouvelle forme <strong>de</strong> pensée apte à satisfaire sa vision du<br />

mon<strong>de</strong>, la quête d'une idéologie plus adaptée à ce qui ne peut manquer <strong>de</strong> naître <strong>de</strong><br />

la guerre. Comme il l'explique lui-même dans une lettre à Albert Camus, qu'il<br />

espère gagner à son rêve fédéraliste au moment <strong>de</strong> la Libération:<br />

«J'ai abandonné l'optimisme historique du marxisme qui était sûr que l'humanité<br />

était guidée vers <strong>de</strong>s buts toujours plus élevés par la Provi<strong>de</strong>nce […]. Je suis arrivé à<br />

me persua<strong>de</strong>r que toute l'activité <strong>de</strong> l'homme civilisé est une construction audace<br />

(sic) et frêle au-<strong>de</strong>ssus d'un gouffre qui menace <strong>de</strong> l'engloutir continuellement». 14<br />

Cette vision plus pessimiste mais, selon lui, plus réaliste <strong>de</strong> l'avenir politique, il<br />

la recherche et semble la trouver à la lecture <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes britanniques <strong>de</strong>s<br />

années 30 (Walter Layton, William Beveridge), ainsi que dans les Fe<strong>de</strong>ralist Papers<br />

d'Alexan<strong>de</strong>r Hamilton, John Jay et James Madison. 15 Les Britanniques ont cependant<br />

eu plus d'importance, puisque Spinelli dit s'être inspiré, dans sa réflexion sur la<br />

crise <strong>de</strong> l'Etat national, <strong>de</strong>s ouvrages <strong>de</strong> Lord Lothian et Lionel Robbins. 16 Mêmes<br />

Motivations chez Ernesto Rossi, qui lui aussi paie très cher son engagement antifasciste.<br />

Après avoir adhéré à l'Alleanza Nazionale du député libéral Giovanni<br />

Amendola, suite à l'assassinat <strong>de</strong> Matteotti (10 juin 1924), puis à l'association<br />

secrète Italia Libera, il s'exile en France en 1925, puis revient clan<strong>de</strong>stinement en<br />

Italie à la fin <strong>de</strong> l'année, enseigne l'économie à Bergame et collabore à la Riforma<br />

Sociale <strong>de</strong> Luigi Einaudi. Arrêté en 1930 avec le groupe dirigeant <strong>de</strong> Giustizia e<br />

Libertà auquel il a adhéré, il est condamné à neuf ans <strong>de</strong> prison, qu’il effectuera du<br />

30 octobre 1930 au 12 novembre 1939, avant d'être exilé à Ventotene, où il rencontre<br />

Altiero Spinelli.<br />

Le contexte dans lequel a été décidée l'élaboration du Manifeste est important<br />

pour comprendre les motivations <strong>de</strong> ses auteurs: le document est, en effet, diffusé<br />

13. Regia Questura di Roma, acte du 25 février 1937 du Sig. Giudice di Sorveglianza, AS-142, Archivi Storici<br />

<strong>de</strong>lle Comunità Europee (ASCE), Florence: prolongation faite le 17 du mois, et qui fixe son confinement<br />

à 5 ans sur l’îlot <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, car il est jugé «élément dangereux pour l'ordre <strong>de</strong> l’Etat».<br />

14. Lettera a Camus, 18 mars 1945, p.1, AS-7, ASCE.<br />

15. Ensemble <strong>de</strong>s articles que ces trois hommes font paraître entre octobre 1787 et avril 1788 à l'occasion<br />

<strong>de</strong> la campagne <strong>de</strong> ratification du projet <strong>de</strong> Constitution <strong>de</strong>s Etats-Unis, d'inspiration fédéraliste.<br />

16. Ph. KERR (Lord Lothian), Pacifism is not enough, Oxford University Press, Londres, 1935; L.<br />

ROBBINS, Economic Planning and international or<strong>de</strong>r, MacMillan Press, Londres, 1937.


42<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

sous forme polycopiée sur le continent, dès juillet 1941, par l’intermédiaire<br />

d'Ursula Hirschmann, épouse <strong>de</strong> Colorni (et future femme <strong>de</strong> Spinelli), qui avait<br />

obtenu le droit <strong>de</strong> vivre à Ventotene avec son mari et ses filles, 17 d'Ada Rossi<br />

(femme d’Ernesto) et <strong>de</strong>s sœurs <strong>de</strong> Spinelli, Fiorella et Gigliola. Il a pour titre<br />

«Pour une Europe libre et unie. Projet <strong>de</strong> manifeste». Il est édité clan<strong>de</strong>stinement à<br />

Rome par Eugenio Colorni en janvier 1944, avec <strong>de</strong>ux autres essais d'Altiero Spinelli,<br />

Les Etats-Unis d'Europe et les différentes tendances politiques, et Politique<br />

marxiste et politique fédéraliste, 18 sous le titre général «Problèmes <strong>de</strong> la fédération<br />

européenne». Le Manifeste a donc pu être lu et connu par certains milieux<br />

résistants pendant la guerre, mais seulement en Italie, à Rome ou à Milan et non à<br />

l'extérieur, comme le reconnaît Spinelli lui-même. 19<br />

Le travail <strong>de</strong> rédaction est partagé entre Spinelli, qui s'est chargé <strong>de</strong>s problèmes<br />

<strong>de</strong> la crise <strong>de</strong> la civilisation occi<strong>de</strong>ntale, <strong>de</strong> l'unité européenne et du thème du «parti<br />

révolutionnaire» européen, et Rossi, aidé <strong>de</strong> Colorni, qui a rédigé la partie concernant<br />

la réforme <strong>de</strong> la société. Dans sa Préface à la première édition du Manifeste, le<br />

22 janvier 1944, Spinelli résume sa pensée concernant la manière <strong>de</strong> mettre en<br />

place la future structure politique européenne: «Partir du préalable que le premier<br />

objectif à atteindre, c'est celui d'une organisation unitaire dans le domaine international,<br />

jette une nouvelle lumière sur tous les problèmes». 20 Le texte lui-même,<br />

assez court (24 pages), se partage en trois moments forts: dans la première partie,<br />

intitulée «la crise <strong>de</strong> la civilisation mo<strong>de</strong>rne», les auteurs critiquent les<br />

Etats-nations <strong>de</strong>venus Etats-Moloch, «faiseurs <strong>de</strong> soldats» et briseurs <strong>de</strong>s libertés<br />

individuelles. Face à cette «crise», la seule solution ent<strong>revue</strong> par les auteurs consiste<br />

à créer <strong>de</strong> toutes pièces «l'unité européenne» qui nécessite le recours à<br />

«l'action révolutionnaire». Enfin, cette action politique à gran<strong>de</strong> échelle <strong>de</strong>vrait permettre<br />

<strong>de</strong> mener à bien une tâche plus délicate, «la réforme <strong>de</strong> la société», qui consiste<br />

en un équilibre savant entre socialisme, largement revendiqué, et action individuelle,<br />

un peu à l'image du «socio-libéralisme» qui avait été défendu par le groupe<br />

antifasciste Giustizia e Libertà <strong>de</strong>s frères Rosselli. On voit donc que la revendication<br />

fédéraliste s'accompagne d'une critique totale <strong>de</strong>s cadres politiques nationaux<br />

ainsi que <strong>de</strong> la promesse d'une réforme générale <strong>de</strong>s structures sociales.<br />

17. Voici comment Spinelli relate les «voyages» <strong>de</strong> sa future femme: «La chose était au point <strong>de</strong> vue<br />

matériel relativement facile, car vous <strong>de</strong>viez vous soumettre à une fouille corporelle et <strong>de</strong> vos valises,<br />

qui consistait [pour Ursula] à se faire enfermer par la police dans une pièce avec une vieille<br />

femme <strong>de</strong> ménage qui, au lieu <strong>de</strong> la fouiller empochait un gros pot-<strong>de</strong>-vin, et un quart d'heure après<br />

ouvrait la porte en annonçant que tout allait bien». A. SPINELLI, op.cit., p.316.<br />

18. Ces <strong>de</strong>ux textes figurent dans leur intégralité dans W. LIPGENS, Documents, Berlin, New York,<br />

1985, vol.1, pp.484-492.<br />

19. «Je ne suis pas à même <strong>de</strong> connaître le <strong>de</strong>gré <strong>de</strong> pénétration <strong>de</strong>s écrits fédéralistes. Il faut tenir<br />

compte du fait qu'un seul papier illégal était lu par plusieurs personnes et que souvent on le copiait<br />

à la machine et on le polycopiait çà et là avant <strong>de</strong> le détruire. Ce qui est certain, c'est que les milieux<br />

antifascistes romains, milanais et turinois <strong>de</strong> 1943 connaissaient directement ou indirectement le<br />

Manifeste. Je ne sais pas si Silone le connaissait en 1942 en Suisse. Je ne crois pas que Trentin ait<br />

pu le connaître en France», Le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, in: Les Cahiers <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, Institut<br />

d’Etu<strong>de</strong>s Fédéralistes Altiero Spinelli, Lyon/Ventotene, 1988, p.59.<br />

20. Ibid., p.13.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 43<br />

Le Manifeste insiste sur <strong>de</strong>ux idées importantes, d'après les auteurs eux-mêmes:<br />

«La première était que la fédération n'était pas présentée comme un bel idéal […]<br />

mais comme un objectif dont il fallait hâter la réalisation, dès notre propre génération<br />

[…] la secon<strong>de</strong> idée significative consistait à dire que la lutte pour l'unité européenne<br />

allait créer une ligne <strong>de</strong> partage nouvelle entre les divers courants politiques,<br />

différent <strong>de</strong> celui du passé». 21<br />

C'est dans ces dispositions volontaristes que l'on s'éloigne le plus <strong>de</strong> «l'esprit<br />

intellectualiste» <strong>de</strong>s européistes <strong>de</strong> l'entre-<strong>de</strong>ux-guerres, par exemple d'un Julien<br />

Benda qui voyait dans l'unité européenne la «victoire <strong>de</strong> l’abstrait sur le concret». 22<br />

Avec ce message clair et ambitieux, les fédéralistes <strong>de</strong> la Résistance italienne parviennent<br />

à une phase plus mature, à une prise en compte plus rationnelle <strong>de</strong>s possibilités<br />

<strong>de</strong> réorganisation politique du Vieux continent, où la notion <strong>de</strong> «révolution»,<br />

dans son acception la plus complète, est clairement revendiquée. Créer un nouveau<br />

système exige <strong>de</strong> détruire l'ancien, et d'agir vite car cette issue est envisagée à court<br />

terme.<br />

Le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene se termine ainsi par une invitation à l'action militante,<br />

une main tendue à ceux qui sont près à accepter ces idées, où qu'ils soient:<br />

«Par la propagan<strong>de</strong> et par l'action, en cherchant à nouer, par tous les moyens, <strong>de</strong>s<br />

ententes et <strong>de</strong>s liens entre les divers mouvements qui vont très certainement se former<br />

dans les différents pays, il faut, dès à présent, jeter les bases d'un mouvement qui<br />

sache mobiliser toutes les forces pour donner naissance à la nouvelle organisation<br />

qui sera la création la plus grandiose et la plus novatrice établie en Europe <strong>de</strong>puis <strong>de</strong>s<br />

siècles[…]». 23<br />

Les auteurs du Manifeste font donc un pari sur l'avenir, mais ils cherchent avant<br />

tout, pour <strong>de</strong>s raisons pratiques, à créer un premier mouvement en Italie.<br />

2) Le Movimento Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista Europeo, première forme d'organisation d'un<br />

fédéralisme militant.<br />

Ce mouvement est créé dès la chute du fascisme dans l'ensemble <strong>de</strong> la péninsule, et<br />

la nomination <strong>de</strong> Pietro Badoglio comme chef <strong>de</strong> gouvernement le 25 juillet 1943.<br />

Le Movimento Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista Europeo est mis sur pied lors d'une réunion clan<strong>de</strong>stine<br />

tenue à Milan les 27 et 28 juillet 1943, dans la maison du physicien Mario Alberto<br />

Rollier, que Spinelli avait rencontré en tant que militant du Partito d’Azione et qui<br />

avait été membre du parti fasciste jusqu'à ce que celui-ci adopte les premières lois<br />

antisémites. 24 On peut dire un mot du Partito d’Azione, dans la mesure où cette formation<br />

politique nouvelle joue un rôle important dans l'itinéraire d'une gran<strong>de</strong> par-<br />

21. A. SPINELLI, Come ho tentato …, op.cit., p.312.<br />

22. J. BENDA, Discours à la nation européenne, Folio, Paris, 1992 (éd. Originale, NRF, Paris, 1933).<br />

23. Le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, op.cit., p.36.<br />

24. C. ROGNONI-VERCELLI, Mario Alberto Roltier, un Val<strong>de</strong>se fe<strong>de</strong>ratista, Ed. Universitarie Jaca,<br />

Milano, 1991.


44<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

tie <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes italiens. Celui-ci a été créé par les antifascistes Ferruccio Parri,<br />

Ugo La Malfa, Adolfo Tino, anciens <strong>de</strong> Giustizia e Libertà, qui publient leur premier<br />

manifeste en décembre 1941 et établissent un programme en sept points à<br />

Rome, le 4 juin 1942. Parmi ces sept points, on note l'abolition <strong>de</strong> la monarchie, la<br />

décentralisation, les nationalisations, la réforme agraire, le syndicalisme, la séparation<br />

<strong>de</strong> l'Eglise et <strong>de</strong> l'Etat. Le septième point porte sur la nécessité d'une Fédération<br />

européenne et c'est celui qui permet les rapprochements entre MFE et Partito<br />

d’Azione, qui se vérifie par l'adhésion <strong>de</strong> Spinelli et Rossi à ce <strong>de</strong>rnier, en 1943.<br />

Parmi les personnalités présentes lors <strong>de</strong> la réunion <strong>de</strong> Milan, on peut repérer quelques<br />

futurs acteurs notoires du militantisme européen: les trois auteurs du Manifeste <strong>de</strong><br />

Ventotene (qui ont été libérés au début du mois <strong>de</strong> juillet), Ursula Hirschmann, Franco<br />

Venturi, Guglielmo Jervis, Vindice Cavallera, Leone Ginzburg, Vittorio Foa, Enrico<br />

Giussani, etc. (au total 22 personnes). Difficile <strong>de</strong> trouver une véritable homogénéité<br />

politique parmi ces fondateurs, si ce n’est leur engagement dans la Résistance. La composition<br />

politique <strong>de</strong> cette première assemblée montre cependant que les idées<br />

défendues par le Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene commencent à être connues, suscitant l'adhésion<br />

ou, au moins, la sympathie <strong>de</strong> résistants italiens issus d'horizons politiques différents:<br />

en effet, parmi les 22 personnes présentes, 9 viennent, comme Rossi, Colorni et<br />

Spinelli, <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, 14 ont adhéré au Partito d’Azione, 3 sont ou vont <strong>de</strong>venir socialistes,<br />

et <strong>de</strong>ux sont membres du Parti Républicain, alors que Spinelli, sa femme Ursula<br />

et sa sœur Fiorella se disent «sans parti». 25 Parmi les «thèses politiques» à la base du<br />

MFE, écrites par Spinelli à Ventotene et discutées lors <strong>de</strong> cette réunion <strong>de</strong> Milan, on<br />

trouve quelques principes directement inspirés du Manifeste: le désir d'aller jusqu'à<br />

l'écrasement du nazisme et <strong>de</strong> fon<strong>de</strong>r par la suite une paix soli<strong>de</strong> (point 1); la volonté <strong>de</strong><br />

rompre avec les droits régaliens <strong>de</strong> l’Etat, présentés comme <strong>de</strong>s moyens d'asservissement<br />

<strong>de</strong>s individus au pr<strong>of</strong>it d'un Moloch jamais rassasié (point 2); le refus d'adopter<br />

une formule confédérale du type SDN ou Confédération germanique (point 3); la<br />

volonté <strong>de</strong> mettre en place une Fédération européenne avec tous les pouvoirs<br />

nécessaires (point 4); le désir <strong>de</strong> fon<strong>de</strong>r cette Fédération en mettant d'emblée <strong>de</strong> côté les<br />

aspirations politiques <strong>de</strong>s uns et <strong>de</strong>s autres, celles-ci ne pouvant être satisfaites qu'une<br />

fois que la légitimité du nouvel Etat européen ne sera plus remise en cause (point 5); la<br />

nécessité d'agir vite par un vaste effort <strong>de</strong> propagan<strong>de</strong> et d'information (point 6).<br />

Il faut bien insister sur le fait que les fédéralistes <strong>de</strong> la première heure se mettent<br />

en retrait <strong>de</strong> tout militantisme politique classique, ne faisant la différence qu'entre<br />

partis «progressistes» (plutôt <strong>de</strong> gauche à l'heure <strong>de</strong> la Libération, <strong>de</strong> toute façon<br />

ouverts aux problèmes européens) et «réactionnaires» (les partis qui ont collaboré,<br />

ceux qui montrent <strong>de</strong>s réticences à tout type d'organisation du continent, parmi ces<br />

<strong>de</strong>rniers les partis communistes). Cette attitu<strong>de</strong> est à retenir dans le combat fédéraliste<br />

car elle permet au mouvement une souplesse qui fait passer l'objectif européen<br />

avant toute considération partisane. Même le socialiste Eugenio Colorni, qui a participé<br />

à la rédaction du Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene et à la création du MFE, démythifie<br />

la légen<strong>de</strong> d'une Europe faite par le seul socialisme:<br />

25. A. SPINELLI, Come ho tentato …, op.cit., p.34.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 45<br />

«Nous savons par expérience que les sentiments chauvins et les intérêts protectionnistes<br />

peuvent facilement conduire au conflit et à la concurrence même entre <strong>de</strong>ux démocraties;<br />

et il n'est pas dit qu'un Etat socialiste riche doive nécessairement accepter <strong>de</strong> mettre en<br />

commun ses propres ressources avec un autre Etat socialiste bien plus pauvre, par le seul<br />

fait que dans ce <strong>de</strong>rnier est en vigueur un régime interne similaire au premier» 26 .<br />

Les motivations <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes italiens apparaissent à travers les articles <strong>de</strong><br />

leur organe <strong>de</strong> presse, L'Unità Europea. Ce <strong>journal</strong>, dont le premier numéro paraît<br />

en mai 1943, est le principal organe <strong>de</strong> la pensée fédéraliste au sein <strong>de</strong> la<br />

Résistance italienne: les <strong>de</strong>ux premiers tirages sont réalisés clan<strong>de</strong>stinement à<br />

Rome sous la direction d'Ursula Hirschmann, Ada Rossi, Cerilo Spinelli et<br />

Guglielmo Usellini, puis à Milan (Mario Alberto Rollier), excepté le n°5 édité en<br />

Suisse. Tiré à 4.000 exemplaires en juin 1944, il passe en juin 1945 à 7.000 avant<br />

<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>venir hebdomadaire à partir du 29 avril 1945 et ce jusqu'à la fin <strong>de</strong>s années<br />

quarante, époque où il sera relayé par le nouveau titre du MFE, Europa Fe<strong>de</strong>rata.<br />

Comme pour tout ce qui concerne la presse clan<strong>de</strong>stine, faite dans l'urgence et<br />

donc avec un délai <strong>de</strong> réflexion très court, sans compter le manque <strong>de</strong> moyens, la<br />

valeur <strong>de</strong>s articles <strong>de</strong> L 'Unità Europea est très inégale. Ces articles, bien souvent,<br />

se répètent et sont, bien entendu, anonymes (bien que l'on sache que la plupart ont<br />

été rédigés par Spinelli ou Rossi). Le message est à la fois simple et ambitieux: la<br />

possibilité pour le MFE <strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>venir un élément <strong>de</strong> liaison entre les différents partis<br />

démocratiques, sans pour autant être annexé par un parti («Movimento o Partito?»)<br />

27 et, partant, d'influencer programmes et action («Le Ten<strong>de</strong>nze Fe<strong>de</strong>raliste»,<br />

où l'on insiste sur l'importance d'un «préalable fédéral» avant toute restauration<br />

démocratique). 28 Le terme «Révolution» revient le plus souvent, ainsi que la nécessité<br />

<strong>de</strong> s'insérer dans la politique concrète <strong>de</strong> chaque nation pour ensuite passer à<br />

l'échelle supérieure («Governo di Unione Nazionale o Politica Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista»; 29<br />

«Intransigenza»). 30 En ce qui concerne la métho<strong>de</strong>, on trouve une première contradiction<br />

entre ceux qui se réfèrent au texte <strong>de</strong> Milan d'août 1943, souhaitant en passer<br />

par l'appel aux masses (bien que le mot «Constituante» n'apparaisse jamais dans<br />

ces 8 numéros, terme auquel on préfère pacte), 31 ceux qui croient en la seule bonne<br />

volonté <strong>de</strong>s pays vainqueurs 32 et ceux qui s'en méfient. 33 Ce qui est clair, en revanche,<br />

c'est la nécessité d'abandonner les «mirages» du système confédéral <strong>de</strong><br />

l’Europe «<strong>de</strong> Briand». L'ennemi, lui, est omniprésent, ne serait-ce que par les références<br />

à son rôle dialectique: c'est l'action <strong>de</strong>structrice du Nazisme-Fascisme qui va<br />

26. Eugenio Colorni, préface à l'édition clan<strong>de</strong>stine <strong>de</strong>s Problemi <strong>de</strong>lla Fe<strong>de</strong>razione Europea, janvier 1944.<br />

27. Titre d'un article <strong>de</strong> Guglielmo Usellini, futur secrétaire général <strong>de</strong> l'Union Européenne <strong>de</strong>s Fédéralistes,<br />

(UEF), paru dans L'Unità Europea, n°2, août 1943.<br />

28. Article paru dans L'Unità Europea, n°1, mai 1943 (Altiero Spinelli).<br />

29. Ernesto Rossi, paru dans L’Unità Europea, n°4, janvier 1944.<br />

30. Altiero Spinelli, L’Unità Europea, n°3, septembre 1943.<br />

31. Il faut attendre l'intervention <strong>de</strong> Piero Calamandrei au second Congrès <strong>de</strong> l’UEF à Rome en novembre 1948<br />

pour que le terme «Constituante» <strong>de</strong>vienne un <strong>de</strong>s mots d’ordre principaux <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes italiens.<br />

32. Ainsi en est-il d'un l'article <strong>de</strong> l’Anglaise Edith Monroe, repris dans le n°4 <strong>de</strong> L'Unità Europea, où<br />

le Fédérateur pourrait être l’URSS.<br />

33. E. ROSSI, L'inghilterra e l'Italia, in: L’Unità Europea, n°3, septembre 1943.


46<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

permettre le renouveau politique et social tant attendu. Ainsi, à propos <strong>de</strong> la mort<br />

d'Eugenio Colorni lors <strong>de</strong> la libération <strong>de</strong> Rome (juin 1944) est-il écrit, dans le n°5,<br />

«que parfois [Colorni] était même porté à mettre en avant, paradoxalement, les aspects<br />

positifs <strong>de</strong> la politique hitlérienne, dans la mesure où celle-ci allait renverser toutes ces<br />

absur<strong>de</strong>s souverainetés anachroniques <strong>de</strong> trente-<strong>de</strong>ux Etats-nations qui divisaient notre<br />

continent». 34<br />

Dans le feu <strong>de</strong> l'action, les fédéralistes se soucient cependant encore peu <strong>de</strong>s<br />

réactions <strong>de</strong>s partis classiques, et cherchent d'abord à faire connaître leurs thèses.<br />

La <strong>de</strong>rnière résolution prise à Milan concerne l'organisation du MFE, en Italie et à<br />

l'étranger: Mario Alberto Rollier est nommé responsable du mouvement à Milan et<br />

Eugenio Colorni à Rome, alors que Spinelli et Rossi sont chargés <strong>de</strong> faire connaître<br />

celui-ci hors <strong>de</strong>s frontières italiennes. Les résolutions issues <strong>de</strong> la rencontre clan<strong>de</strong>stine<br />

<strong>de</strong> Milan sont publiées en italien dans L’Unità Europea (septembre 1943).<br />

L'importance <strong>de</strong> la rencontre <strong>de</strong> Milan dans l'amorce d'un véritable activisme fédéraliste<br />

est résumée par Spinelli: d'après lui, la création du MFE doit donner le<br />

départ d'une alliance avec les fédéralistes «d'au-<strong>de</strong>là <strong>de</strong>s Alpes».<br />

3) Le milieu fédéraliste en Suisse.<br />

Les idées du fédéralisme italien ont beau être ambitieuses, elles ne sont pour l'instant<br />

que l'apanage d'une minorité qui vit en vase clos. Dès le départ, les rédacteurs du Manifeste<br />

<strong>de</strong> Ventotene ont compris qu'elles <strong>de</strong>vaient, pour survivre, être diffusées. Ce combat<br />

pour la reconnaissance débute dans le chaos d'une Libération incomplète, celle qui<br />

est opérée sur le territoire italien après la première chute <strong>de</strong> Mussolini (25 juillet 1943).<br />

Avec l'élargissement <strong>de</strong>s principaux protagonistes fédéralistes, la diffusion <strong>de</strong> leurs<br />

idées hors <strong>de</strong>s frontières <strong>de</strong>vient possible. Le premier pays visé est la Suisse, ce qui<br />

s'explique par <strong>de</strong>s raisons pratiques, en même temps qu'idéologiques.<br />

La Suisse est considérée comme un sanctuaire par les premiers fédéralistes. Cette terre<br />

est en effet hospitalière à ceux qui, dans l'exil que leur a imposé la guerre, réfléchissent à<br />

un nouvel ordre européen, et qui vont jusqu'à voir dans ce pays la préfiguration <strong>de</strong> ce que<br />

pourrait être une Europe fédérale. 35 Spinelli, en particulier, veut pr<strong>of</strong>iter <strong>de</strong> son exil pour<br />

34. Un grave lutto <strong>de</strong>l MFE. L'assassinio di Eugenio Colorni da parte <strong>de</strong>i nazifascisti a Roma, in:<br />

L'Unità Europea, juillet 1944, n°5.<br />

35. C'est le cas <strong>de</strong>s réfugiés français. Voir L. VAN VASSENHOVE, L’Europe helvétique: étu<strong>de</strong> sur les possibilités<br />

d’adapter à l’Europe les institutions <strong>de</strong> la Confédération helvétique, La Baconnière, Neuchâtel, 1943;<br />

et R. SILVA, Essai sur la Suisse d'aujourd'hui, Lausanne, 1941, auquel on peut ajouter Au service <strong>de</strong> la Paix.<br />

L’Idée Fédéraliste, La Baconnière, Neuchâtel, 1946. Dans ce <strong>de</strong>rnier ouvrage il écrit que «quoique sur un<br />

plan infiniment plus mo<strong>de</strong>ste [que les Etats-Unis, la Suisse] représente au centre d'une Europe morcelée l'idée<br />

fédéraliste qui a forcé le succès» (p.188). A noter que Luigi Einaudi a lui aussi pr<strong>of</strong>ité <strong>de</strong> son exil en Suisse<br />

pour vanter les mérites du modèle helvétique, dans un texte écrit en 1943, «Di taluni insegnamenti <strong>de</strong>lla Svizzera<br />

nel momento presente» et publié dans La guerra e l’unità europea, Il Mulino, Bologna, 1986, pp.493 ss.<br />

On peut relever que les trois personnages cités dans cette note militeront tous, à <strong>de</strong>s <strong>de</strong>grés divers, pour la Fédération<br />

européenne au sein <strong>de</strong> l'Union Européenne <strong>de</strong>s Fédéralistes.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 47<br />

rassembler autour <strong>de</strong> lui ceux qui étaient déjà fédéralistes, ou «convertibles» au fédéralisme,<br />

et <strong>de</strong> réaliser ainsi l'espoir <strong>de</strong> propagan<strong>de</strong> évoqué à la réunion <strong>de</strong> Milan. 36<br />

L'attraction <strong>de</strong> la Suisse est particulièrement ressentie par les Italiens, qui vont s’y<br />

réfugier en masse vers la fin du conflit. Bien sûr, ce rôle d'asile a déjà joué pour <strong>de</strong> nombreux<br />

antifascistes bien avant la guerre, comme, par exemple, pour Ignazio Silone, fixé à<br />

Zurich <strong>de</strong>puis l930, 37 où il mène une intense activité politique. Mais c'est surtout avec ce<br />

que les Italiens appellent le «Grand Exo<strong>de</strong>» que sont réunies les conditions d'une véritable<br />

ébullition politique dans le milieu <strong>de</strong>s réfugiés en Suisse. Ce «Grand Exo<strong>de</strong>» s'accélère<br />

après la libération <strong>de</strong> Mussolini, alors détenu dans les Abruzzes, par un détachement <strong>de</strong><br />

SS (12 septembre 1943). Comme dans tous les moments <strong>de</strong> panique, se mélangent les<br />

fuyards, quelles que soient leurs origines sociales; le 5 septembre, les douaniers suisses<br />

enregistrent l'entrée <strong>de</strong> la belle-fille et <strong>de</strong> la fille du maréchal Badoglio, les 8 et 9 septembre,<br />

c'est au tour <strong>de</strong> la princesse <strong>de</strong> Piémont, Maria José <strong>de</strong> Savoie, accompagnée <strong>de</strong> ses<br />

quatre enfants; au milieu du mois <strong>de</strong> septembre, on trouve <strong>de</strong> nombreux fédéralistes,<br />

parmi lesquels Ernesto Rossi (le 14 septembre à partir du poste-frontière d'Arogno) et<br />

Altiero Spinelli (le 15 septembre à partir <strong>de</strong> Gandria). L'afflux est alors si important que le<br />

Conseil fédéral suisse déci<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> fermer les frontières le 16 septembre mais, le 17, on enregistre<br />

encore 10.000 entrées et d'autres encore après, parmi lesquelles celle <strong>de</strong> Luigi<br />

Einaudi (22 septembre). 38 Pour <strong>de</strong>s raisons <strong>de</strong> commodité, ces réfugiés sont regroupés<br />

dans le canton du Tessin, autour <strong>de</strong> Lugano, ce qui est une manière <strong>de</strong> les maintenir en<br />

<strong>de</strong>hors <strong>de</strong> la communauté suisse, puisqu'ils échouent tout près <strong>de</strong> la frontière.<br />

C'est dans cet îlot, si proche et si loin <strong>de</strong> la guerre en même temps, que vont s'opérer<br />

les premières actions <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes italiens, notamment en ce qui concerne le recrutement.<br />

Ce sont <strong>de</strong>s Italiens <strong>de</strong> l'exil qui sont les premiers à être engagés dans le tout nouveau<br />

mouvement: c'est en Suisse que Spinelli va rechercher et obtenir l'adhésion <strong>de</strong> Luigi<br />

Einaudi, d'Ignazio Silone, du socialiste Leo Valiani et d'autres figures <strong>de</strong> la Résistance italienne<br />

réfugiées <strong>de</strong> l'autre côté <strong>de</strong>s Alpes, ainsi que d'anciens fascistes ayant tourné le dos<br />

au régime alors en pleine radicalisation. Beaucoup <strong>de</strong>s premiers adhérents au fédéralisme<br />

sont d'ailleurs concernés par ce rejet, faisant partie d'une génération qui n'a connu que les<br />

désillusions du Fascisme. 39 Il se crée donc en Suisse, sous la direction <strong>de</strong> Spinelli et Rossi,<br />

36. A. SPINELLI, Come ho tentato …, op.cit., pp.46 et 54.<br />

37. Entré au PSI en 1921, il a participé à la fondation du PCI, qu'il a représenté à la conférence internationale<br />

<strong>de</strong> Moscou, où il s'est exilé. Il quitte ce parti en 1930 pour venir s'installer en Suisse, où<br />

le rencontrent les fédéralistes. Sa première gran<strong>de</strong> œuvre est Fontamara (1930).<br />

38. On possè<strong>de</strong> quelques données précises sur ces entrées «sauvages» grâce aux notes <strong>de</strong> l'<strong>of</strong>ficier<br />

suisse Antonio Bolzani, chargé <strong>de</strong> l'accueil <strong>de</strong>s réfugiés, qui tient un carnet dans lequel figurent<br />

185 noms et qu'il publie dans Oltre le rete, Milano, 1946.<br />

39. Pour le fédéraliste néerlandais Henri Brugmans, qui a rencontré ses homologues italiens dès la Libération,<br />

Luciano Bolis représente bien en ce sens un symbole: «Tout jeune, il avait été fasciste<br />

avec un enthousiasme sincère. Avec ferveur, il crut d'abord à la logomachie chauvine qui exaltait<br />

le sacrifice comme idéal […] Puis, comme d'autres, il avait été pris par ses premiers doutes et, chemin<br />

faisant, finit dans les rangs d'une clan<strong>de</strong>stinité en armes […] Pouvait-on revenir à la situation<br />

<strong>de</strong>s années 1920, qui avait vécu la décomposition <strong>de</strong>s partis et <strong>de</strong>s syndicats? Non, il fallait un programme<br />

novateur». H. BRUGMANS, A travers le siècle, Presses Interuniversitaires Européennes,<br />

Bruxelles, 1993, p.245.


48<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

une petite communauté italienne active, qui fait découvrir et prospérer dans ce terreau <strong>de</strong>s<br />

réfugiés les thèses fédéralistes. Ces <strong>de</strong>rnières figurent dans les Qua<strong>de</strong>rni <strong>de</strong>l Movimento<br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ralista Europeo, qui publient dans un premier temps sur <strong>de</strong>s feuilles polycopiées,<br />

puis sous forme d’opuscules d'environ 50 pages, les contributions <strong>de</strong> Rossi et Spinelli<br />

sous leurs pseudonymes respectifs (Storeno et Pantalone), ainsi que celles <strong>de</strong> tous ces<br />

auteurs britanniques que les <strong>de</strong>ux italiens ont appris à connaître dans leur exil à Ventotene.<br />

En plus <strong>de</strong> cet exploit éditorial, il faut rappeler qu'en Suisse est publié le n°5 <strong>de</strong> L'Unità<br />

Europea, ainsi que certains opuscules <strong>de</strong>stinés à une large diffusion au sein <strong>de</strong>s exilés italiens.<br />

La chance <strong>de</strong>s Italiens, pendant cette pério<strong>de</strong> suisse, est également d'avoir rencontré<br />

certains intermédiaires d'autres nationalités, qui ont permis aux idées fédéralistes<br />

d'emprunter <strong>de</strong>s circuits variés. Cette activité fébrile n’est cependant pas appréciée par<br />

tout le mon<strong>de</strong>. Le socialiste italien Piero <strong>de</strong>lla Giusta, <strong>de</strong> passage à Genève, rend ainsi<br />

compte du travail <strong>de</strong> Rossi dans son <strong>journal</strong>, à la date du 20 décembre 1943:<br />

«Son ren<strong>de</strong>ment moyen est <strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>ux opuscules <strong>de</strong> 40-60 pages par mois […] Les 12<br />

Tables <strong>de</strong> la Fédération ont la couleur <strong>de</strong> l'exil et <strong>de</strong> l'isolement, et même le goût.<br />

Elles ont été conçues dans une atmosphère vraiment fébrile, irréelle et liée au confinement,<br />

où les rêves d'un avenir meilleur se fon<strong>de</strong>nt avec les espérances d'une justice<br />

plus proche, où l'action est toujours plus lointaine, où l'inaction allume les cerveaux<br />

dans <strong>de</strong>s constructions et <strong>de</strong>s reconstructions idéales, où les proportions et les mesures<br />

semblent se perdre dans les idéalisations juridiques les plus pures». 40<br />

Cependant, les fédéralistes arrivent à créer à Genève, ce même mois, un Centre<br />

d'action pour la Fédération Européenne (pris en charge par Rossi à partir <strong>de</strong> mars<br />

1944), la ville leur accordant l'accès à la bibliothèque imposante du Palais Wilson.<br />

C'est la première fois qu'une occasion est donnée aux fédéralistes <strong>de</strong> se faire connaître<br />

et, au-<strong>de</strong>là <strong>de</strong>s premières désillusions et <strong>de</strong> la faiblesse <strong>de</strong>s moyens dont sont<br />

conscients les propagateurs <strong>de</strong> cette idée, la pério<strong>de</strong> du «Grand Exo<strong>de</strong>» leur donne<br />

une chance d'être entendus. Ainsi, l'historienne italienne Cinzia Rognoni-Vercelli<br />

signale quelques meetings importants tenus par les fédéralistes peu avant la fin <strong>de</strong><br />

la guerre: le 3 février 1945 à Lugano (600 personnes), le 6 février à Lausanne, puis<br />

le soir à Vevey, <strong>de</strong>vant une centaine d'étudiants en ingénierie, et le 7 février au<br />

camp <strong>de</strong> Travail <strong>de</strong> Cassoney (une centaine <strong>de</strong> personnes). 41<br />

On ne peut cependant oublier que cet effort touche essentiellement les Italiens,<br />

dont la réflexion sur la question est déjà bien avancée et dont les ressortissants sont<br />

les plus nombreux dans la Confédération, les Suisses restant étrangers à ces efforts.<br />

L'effet «médiatique» ne doit donc pas être surestimé, même s'il permet un premier<br />

contact. Comme le conclut l'historien Lubor Jilek, on peut dire que<br />

«c’est donc en tant qu'abri, par le biais <strong>de</strong>s débats, <strong>de</strong>s <strong>revue</strong>s, et <strong>de</strong>s bibliothèques<br />

que la Suisse permit à l'européanisme italien d'ét<strong>of</strong>fer, en 1944-1945, le raisonne-<br />

40. P. DELLA GIUSTA, Diario, Milano, 1948, pp.14-15. Cet «idéalisme» a été brocardé par Christophe<br />

Réveillard en <strong>de</strong>s termes assez semblables: «L'une <strong>de</strong>s faiblesses <strong>de</strong> l'argumentation fédérale<br />

est la facilité à construire <strong>de</strong>s systèmes, <strong>de</strong>s plans logiques et ordonnés mais pas tous en phase avec<br />

les réalités psychologiques, sociales, politiques et géographiques du moment». Chr. RE-<br />

VEILLARD, op.cit., p.47.<br />

41. C. ROGNONI-VERCELLI, art.cit., pp. 136-137.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 49<br />

ment hamiltonien conçu à Ventotene dans le fragile espoir <strong>de</strong> pouvoir le faire connaître<br />

à l'échelle continentale». 42<br />

Nous allons maintenant étudier les actions lancées par les fédéralistes <strong>de</strong>puis la<br />

Suisse, les premières qui méritent véritablement le terme d'«européennes» étant<br />

donné qu'elles permettent d'établir <strong>de</strong>s contacts qui vont déboucher sur une première<br />

organisation internationale au moment <strong>de</strong> la Libération.<br />

4) Par-<strong>de</strong>là les frontières.<br />

En effet, lorsque Rossi et Spinelli entrent clan<strong>de</strong>stinement en Suisse, ils se retrouvent<br />

dans un milieu où le flux italien les condamne à l'anonymat et à la méfiance d'autorités<br />

qui interdisent toute réunion politique. Il faut donc sortir <strong>de</strong> ce «ghetto», matérialisé par<br />

le parcage <strong>de</strong>s réfugiés dans certains camps dont il est difficile <strong>de</strong> s'échapper. Malgré<br />

quelques tentatives pour se faire connaître au nom <strong>de</strong> l'antifascisme, 43 les premiers mois<br />

sont assez décevants bien que se manifestent quelques sympathisants. Parmi ceux-ci,<br />

les premiers contacts non-italiens <strong>de</strong> Rossi et <strong>de</strong> Spinelli vont être décisifs par la suite:<br />

François Bondy, socialiste né en Autriche-Hongrie et qui a acquis la nationalité suisse,<br />

les Français Laloi et Jean-Marie Soutou, représentants <strong>of</strong>ficiels à Genève du Comité<br />

Français <strong>de</strong> Libération Nationale (<strong>de</strong>venu le 3 juin 1944 le Gouvernement provisoire <strong>de</strong><br />

la République française) vont avoir un rôle décisif. C'est par leur intermédiaire que<br />

Rossi et Spinelli rencontrent le Secrétaire Général du Conseil œcuménique <strong>de</strong>s Eglises,<br />

le néerlandais Willem Vissert’Ho<strong>of</strong>t, et c'est dans la maison <strong>de</strong> ce <strong>de</strong>rnier que se tiennent<br />

diverses réunions entre représentants <strong>de</strong> certains courants <strong>de</strong> Résistance intéressés<br />

par le thème du fédéralisme européen. Ho<strong>of</strong>t avait déjà fait montre <strong>de</strong> son engagement<br />

pour dénoncer la barbarie nazie, que la hiérarchie <strong>de</strong>s Eglises catholique et protestante,<br />

mis à part certains gestes isolés, s'était bien gardée <strong>de</strong> condamner, et il avait <strong>of</strong>ficiellement<br />

<strong>de</strong>mandé que ces Eglises se prononcent en faveur d'une réorganisation <strong>de</strong> l'ordre<br />

international, dans un sens plus respectueux <strong>de</strong>s valeurs chrétiennes fondamentales. 44<br />

On note quatre rencontres à l'origine <strong>de</strong> la Déclaration <strong>de</strong>s Résistances européennes<br />

(31 mars, 29 avril, 20 mai et 7 juillet 1944), qui en est le résultat direct.<br />

42. L. JILEK, L'idée d’Europe <strong>de</strong>vant la guerre: les exilés et le fédéralisme européen en Suisse, 1938-<br />

1945, in: A. BOSCO (éd.), The Fe<strong>de</strong>ral l<strong>de</strong>a, vol.2, The History <strong>of</strong> Fe<strong>de</strong>ralism since 1945, Lothian<br />

Foundation Press, London, New York, 1992, p.40. Renata Broggini va encore plus loin, en écrivant<br />

que «la présence et l'action menées en Suisse par Rossi et Spinelli, sans compter, évi<strong>de</strong>mment, Einaudi<br />

furent décisives pour le développement d'un fédéralisme organisé. Grâce à eux, les thèses<br />

fédéralistes s'insérèrent dans le débat politico-culturel <strong>de</strong> l'émigration italienne et européenne,<br />

constituant les bases d’un véritable travail international». R. BROGGINI, op.cit., p.325.<br />

43. E. ROSSI et A. SPINELLI, Lettre ouverte du Mouvement italien pour la Fédération européenne<br />

à tous les antifascistes, novembre 1943, original en français.<br />

44. W.A. Vissert’Ho<strong>of</strong>t avait notamment rédigé avec H. Schönfeld, en novembre 1939, un texte rappelant<br />

«la responsabilité <strong>de</strong> l’Eglise envers l’ordre international», texte relayé par un nouvel appel<br />

en avril 1940, «L’Eglise œcuménique et la situation internationale», <strong>de</strong>mandant aux Eglises <strong>de</strong> briser<br />

le silence sur la nature anti-chrétienne <strong>de</strong>s forces en action sur toute l’Europe.


50<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

L'assistance est un véritable méli-mélo <strong>de</strong>s forces d'opposition au nazisme: outre<br />

Rossi et Spinelli représentant le MFE, on compte également Egidio Reale (Partito<br />

Repubblicano), les Français Laloi et Soutou, les Alleman<strong>de</strong>s Hanna Bertholet et<br />

Hilda Monte (<strong>de</strong> son vrai nom Hil<strong>de</strong> Meisel), toutes <strong>de</strong>ux membres <strong>de</strong> l’Internazionaler<br />

Sozialistischer Kampftund (ISK), 45 ainsi que le Yougoslave Lazar Latinovic;<br />

Ho<strong>of</strong>t représente symboliquement les Pays-Bas. En plus <strong>de</strong> ces personnes i<strong>de</strong>ntifiables,<br />

il faut compter un Polonais, un Tchécoslovaque, un Norvégien et un Danois,<br />

quatre acteurs dont l'Histoire n'a pas retenu les i<strong>de</strong>ntités. Nous ne reviendrons pas<br />

sur les différentes péripéties <strong>de</strong>s discussions, retenons seulement le fait qu'elles<br />

<strong>of</strong>frent une plate-forme européenne, même mo<strong>de</strong>ste (n'oublions pas la marginalisation<br />

<strong>de</strong>s idées fédéralistes au sein <strong>de</strong>s mouvements nationaux <strong>de</strong> Résistance), aux<br />

thèses venues d'Italie. Le 29 avril, Rossi et Spinelli obtiennent l'adhésion <strong>de</strong> principe<br />

du Partito Cristiano Sociale, du Partito d’Azione et du Partito Repubblicano à<br />

leur travail, ainsi que celle du Liberal Party le 20 mai. 46<br />

Lors <strong>de</strong> la rencontre du 20 mai 1944, il est décidé d'envoyer un avant-projet <strong>de</strong><br />

déclaration, alors en cours <strong>de</strong> rédaction, à toutes les résistances représentées au<br />

cours <strong>de</strong>s réunions, tout en créant un «Comité provisoire pour la Fédération européenne»<br />

(avec Rossi et Soutou comme directeurs), chargé <strong>de</strong> maintenir <strong>de</strong>s liaisons<br />

plus serrées avec les différentes résistances et <strong>de</strong> recevoir les adhésions. Avec<br />

l'avant-projet est envoyée une lettre, signée Spinelli, où est signalée l'existence <strong>de</strong><br />

ce Comité provisoire et l'urgence <strong>de</strong> répondre aux propositions contenues dans<br />

l'avant-projet <strong>de</strong> Déclaration. Ces réponses sont cependant peu nombreuses,<br />

peut-être à cause d'un contexte qui oblige à l'action plus qu'à la réflexion: <strong>de</strong>ux<br />

semaines après l'envoi, les Alliés débarquent en Normandie et la phase finale <strong>de</strong> la<br />

Résistance se <strong>de</strong>ssine. Parmi les rares réponses, on peut dénombrer celles qui viennent<br />

du Mouvement <strong>de</strong> Libération Nationale et du Comité Français pour la Fédération<br />

Européenne, du Partito d’Azione, du Socialist Vanguard Group (lui aussi<br />

affilié à l’ISK), ou <strong>de</strong> personnalités telles que Lord Layton, ainsi que <strong>de</strong>s réseaux<br />

français Libérer et Fédérer et <strong>de</strong> la Revue libre; 47 en revanche, les Résistances norvégiennes<br />

et danoises restent silencieuses. Certaines réponses montrent <strong>de</strong> la<br />

méfiance vis-à-vis du projet et se contentent <strong>de</strong> promettre l'envoi hypothétique <strong>de</strong><br />

simples observateurs (qui ne viendront jamais), tel ce message du Partito Socialista<br />

Italiano di Unità Proletaria (PSIUP) du 3 juin 1944, qui rappelle que le projet<br />

d'Europe fédérale est pour l'instant une utopie. De toute manière, les grands partis<br />

traditionnels se démarquent <strong>de</strong> cette entreprise et l'on ne retrouve, autour <strong>de</strong> l'idée<br />

fédéraliste défendue à Genève, que <strong>de</strong>s groupes minoritaires: ainsi le Socialist Vanguard<br />

Group, dont le chef est Allan Flan<strong>de</strong>rs, n'est qu'une aile très marginale du<br />

45. L'ISK a été créé à Göttingen par Leonard Nelson, et a essaimé dans quelques pays européens, parmi<br />

lesquels la Gran<strong>de</strong>-Bretagne (Socialist Vanguard Group) et la France (Internationale Militante<br />

Socialiste). Ces mouvements se réclament d'une gauche non-marxiste, tout en prônant un réformisme<br />

social très avancé.<br />

46. Voir L’Unità Europea, n°4 (Milan) et n°5 (Suisse).<br />

47. Il progetto di dichiarazione fe<strong>de</strong>ralista <strong>de</strong>i movimenti di resistenza europei, in: L'Unità Europea,<br />

n°5, juillet-août 1944, pp.1-2.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 51<br />

Labour Party, sur lequel il n'a strictement aucune influence, même s'il peut compter<br />

sur une tribune <strong>de</strong> presse <strong>de</strong> bonne qualité (Socialist Commentary).<br />

Malgré ces contacts limités, une discussion s'est engagée et elle va faire en sorte<br />

que les idées fédéralistes italiennes ne meurent prématurément. Doit-on rappeler<br />

que ce texte, dont la Déclaration finale est adoptée le 7 juillet, reste fortement symbolique,<br />

la Suisse étant un pays neutre, les Allemands et les Italiens étant discrédités<br />

par leurs nationalités, alors que les Français représentent un Etat qui n'est pas<br />

encore en place? Il faut bien reconnaître que la Déclaration reste un document très<br />

confi<strong>de</strong>ntiel, même si l'on peut enregistrer quelques échos à l'étranger, notamment<br />

en Gran<strong>de</strong>-Bretagne, où elle est reproduite dans son intégralité dans la <strong>revue</strong> du<br />

groupe Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Union (créé en 1938) en octobre 1944. 48<br />

On peut cependant signaler quelques initiatives réclamant la Fédération comme<br />

solution politique d'avenir, encouragées par la diffusion <strong>de</strong> ce texte. C'est le cas <strong>de</strong><br />

la Déclaration du Comité français pour la Fédération européenne (CEFE) <strong>de</strong> juin<br />

1944. 49 Le CFFE, créé à Lyon le même mois, émane du Mouvement <strong>de</strong> Libération<br />

Nationale, dirigé par Jacques Baumel (pseudonyme Rossini), Henri Frenay et<br />

André Ferrat. Le MLN a été créé le 8 février 1944 avec les réseaux Combat,<br />

Défense <strong>de</strong> la France, Résistance, Lorraine, alors que le Front National communiste<br />

et l’Organisation Civile et Militaire s’en sont exclus. En réponse à la<br />

Déclaration <strong>de</strong>s Résistances Européennes, parvenue en France fin mai, début juin<br />

1944, le MLN se transforme en CFFE, sous la direction d'Albert Camus (Combat),<br />

André Ferrat (Franc-Tireur) et Gilbert Zaksas (Libérer et Fédérer).<br />

Pour bien comprendre le contexte <strong>de</strong> cette prise <strong>de</strong> position fédéraliste du<br />

CFFE, il faut avoir à l'esprit les particularités <strong>de</strong> la résistance française basée non<br />

loin <strong>de</strong> la Suisse, à Lyon: dans cette ville existe un «milieu résistant» varié, du fait<br />

qu'elle est <strong>de</strong>venue très tôt le principal refuge <strong>de</strong> ceux qui ont fui la France occupée.<br />

C'est à Lyon qu'Emmanuel Mounier fait reparaître Esprit, avec la plupart <strong>de</strong>s<br />

membres <strong>de</strong> l'ancienne rédaction (mais également avec <strong>de</strong> nouveaux venus <strong>de</strong> la<br />

ville elle-même, tels que Jean-Marie Domenach), dont l'un <strong>de</strong>s buts est «d'appr<strong>of</strong>ondir<br />

l'idée fédérative», délaissée jusque-là par cette <strong>revue</strong>; 50 c'est à Uriage, non<br />

loin <strong>de</strong> Lyon, que, sous la direction du capitaine <strong>de</strong> Segonzac, fut créée cette école<br />

<strong>de</strong>s cadres qui penche peu à peu vers la Résistance et que fréquenta <strong>de</strong> temps à<br />

autre Henri Frenay, venu s'installer à Lyon avant <strong>de</strong> fon<strong>de</strong>r le réseau et le <strong>journal</strong><br />

Combat, où il appelle régulièrement à une «résistance européenne […] ciment <strong>de</strong>s<br />

unions <strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>main»; 51 c'est à Lyon, en mars 1944, que Libérer et Fédérer s'associe<br />

48. European Resistance Calls for Fe<strong>de</strong>ration, in: Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Europe, Fe<strong>de</strong>ral News, n°116, Londres, October<br />

1944, pp.1-2 et 11.<br />

49. On peut trouver cette Déclaration dans son intégralité dans L'Europe Fédéraliste, n°1, septembre<br />

1944 (Genève), p.3, reprise dans Cahiers <strong>de</strong> la Fédération européenne (CFFE), vol.1, Paris, février<br />

1945, pp.25-27.<br />

50. Cette idée avait été exprimée par Emmanuel Mounier dans les <strong>de</strong>rniers numéros précédant l'invasion,<br />

notamment dans «Gardons-nous <strong>de</strong> notre ennemi l’Ennemi» in: Esprit, Lyon, janvier 1940,<br />

et «A nos lecteurs», in: Esprit, février 1940.<br />

51. Résistance … Espoir <strong>de</strong> l’Europe, in: Combat (Alger), 12 décembre 1943.


52<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

au mouvement socialiste L’Insurgé, créé en juillet 1942 par Marceau Pivert, en éditant<br />

un manifeste commun où l'on parle d'une «intégration dans les Etats-Unis<br />

d’Europe». 52 A Lyon, gravitent <strong>de</strong>s européistes en rupture <strong>de</strong> milieu parisien, tels<br />

qu'André Philip ou François <strong>de</strong> Menthon, et nombre d'organisations qui jouent un<br />

rôle <strong>de</strong> relais précieux dans l'information <strong>de</strong> la Résistance et qui lui permettent<br />

d'être plus forte malgré la répression. Ainsi que l'écrit Michel Winock, «… ces<br />

groupes sont utiles à l'information: on s'échange <strong>de</strong>s ‘tuyaux’, on accueille <strong>de</strong>s visiteurs<br />

qui reviennent <strong>de</strong> voyage». 53 L'idée européenne y gagne ainsi tout naturellement<br />

<strong>de</strong>s a<strong>de</strong>ptes.<br />

Les appels à la solidarité européenne <strong>de</strong>s forces <strong>de</strong> la Résistance par les fédéralistes<br />

italiens semblent donc porter leurs fruits en cette pério<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> la fin <strong>de</strong> la<br />

guerre. Pour Spinelli, le CFFE, auquel il envoie une «lettre ouverte» dès le mois<br />

d'août 1944 54 paraît être «le parfait équivalent <strong>de</strong> nôtre mouvement italien». 55<br />

L'espoir est tellement fort que le même Spinelli voit dans cette création française<br />

l'amorce d'un «mouvement populaire fédéraliste européen», comme il l'écrira dans<br />

un rapport au MFE d’octobre 1944. 56 En outre, Spinelli fait part <strong>de</strong> considérations<br />

beaucoup plus tactiques, en rapport avec une situation politique en pleine évolution:<br />

les Italiens, discrédités en masse par le régime fasciste, auront peu <strong>de</strong> chance<br />

d'être écoutés dans l'après-guerre, <strong>de</strong> même que les Allemands. Le champion, dans<br />

ces conditions, ne peut être que la France, qui «aura sans doute plus d'autorité<br />

vis-à-vis <strong>de</strong>s gran<strong>de</strong>s puissances mondiales que celle <strong>de</strong> tout autre pays». On<br />

retrouve cette préoccupation chez Rossi qui, dans un mémorandum écrit en décembre<br />

1944, explique qu'<br />

«actuellement le MFE dédie sa principale attention à la France, où il cherche à<br />

susciter un vaste courant d'opinion publique favorable à son programme, car il<br />

estime que c'est la France surtout qui <strong>de</strong>vrait <strong>de</strong>main prendre l'initiative <strong>de</strong> l'union<br />

fédérale européenne». 57<br />

On sent dès 1944 l'enthousiasme <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes italiens et l'assurance que les<br />

espoirs formulés pendant la guerre sont sur le point <strong>de</strong> se réaliser. Cet optimisme<br />

n'empêche pas <strong>de</strong> se poser <strong>de</strong>s questions sur la composition <strong>de</strong> cette Europe unie et,<br />

déjà, certains perçoivent que l'unification va poser <strong>de</strong>s problèmes d'ordre idéologique.<br />

Maintenant que la fin du conflit approche, les fédéralistes ont donc <strong>de</strong> plus en plus tendance<br />

à tenir compte du contexte international, un élément inconnu qui peut avoir un<br />

effet perturbateur dans la poursuite <strong>de</strong> leur idéal. Mais avant cette prise en compte, il<br />

52. Libérer et Fédérer, avril-mai 1944, n°15-16.<br />

53. M. WINOCK, «Esprit». Des intellectuels dans la cité, 1930-1950, Seuil, Paris, 1996, p.226.<br />

54. Déclaration du Comité Français pour la Fédération Européenne et Lettre ouverte du Movimento<br />

Italiano per la Fe<strong>de</strong>razione Europea au Comité Français pour la Fédération Européenne, in:<br />

L’Europe Fédéraliste, n°l, septembre-octobre 1944, pp.3 et 6-7.<br />

55. Lettre d'Altiero Spinelli à Emesto Rossi, 17 août 1944, cité dans E. PAOLINI, Dalla lotta antifascista<br />

alla battaglia per la Fe<strong>de</strong>razione europea. 1920-1948: documenti e testimonianze, Il Mulino,<br />

Bologna, 1996, p.395.<br />

56. Rapport <strong>de</strong> Spinelli, octobre 1944, WL-27, ASCE.<br />

57. E.ROSSI, Mémorandum du 8 décembre 1944, Genève, WL-27, ASCE.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 53<br />

s'agit pour eux <strong>de</strong> son<strong>de</strong>r les forces politiques traditionnelles, dont le Manifeste disait<br />

qu'elles pouvaient tout aussi bien être <strong>de</strong>s «alliées» que <strong>de</strong>s «obstacles».<br />

5) Constats <strong>de</strong>s <strong>de</strong>rniers jours <strong>de</strong> la guerre.<br />

C'est au moment où se termine la Secon<strong>de</strong> Guerre mondiale que les fédéralistes du<br />

MFE tentent <strong>de</strong> faire connaître leur action au plus grand nombre, particulièrement aux<br />

déci<strong>de</strong>urs politiques. Une lettre d’Ernesto Rossi aux militants romains, datée du 7 octobre<br />

1944, raconte le périple commencé la veille par François Bondy et Jean-Marie Soutou,<br />

envoyés en France avec <strong>de</strong>s documents fédéralistes. Les contacts à l'étranger ne<br />

s’arrêtent pas là; dans la même lettre, Rossi donne à ses correspondants du MFE <strong>de</strong>s<br />

nouvelles d'Angleterre, où se trouve un autre envoyé fédéraliste («Robert») 58 qui lui a<br />

signalé l'intérêt pour les idées fédéralistes <strong>de</strong> certains journaux comme le Times et le<br />

Tribune, lui <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s informations sur le MFE pour le Socialist Vanguard Group, et<br />

parle <strong>de</strong> l'espoir <strong>de</strong> ce mouvement que soit élu prési<strong>de</strong>nt du Labour Party Harold<br />

Laski, 59 l'un <strong>de</strong>s plus grands théoriciens du fédéralisme en Gran<strong>de</strong>-Bretagne.<br />

La Libération qui s'annonce correspond à cette page blanche attendue par l'ensemble<br />

<strong>de</strong>s résistants <strong>de</strong>puis les premières heures <strong>de</strong> leur combat. L'attitu<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes<br />

montre cependant que, à côté <strong>de</strong> l'enthousiasme qui prévaut face au succès annoncé, il y<br />

a une gran<strong>de</strong> défiance vis-à-vis <strong>de</strong>s projets <strong>de</strong> libération <strong>de</strong> l'Europe par les Alliés.<br />

Ernesto Rossi, par exemple, se méfie <strong>de</strong> ce qu'il appelle la «Sainte Alliance <strong>de</strong>s trois<br />

gran<strong>de</strong>s puissances victorieuses», 60 mais par-<strong>de</strong>ssus tout <strong>de</strong> l'attitu<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s communistes,<br />

qu'il voit comme les plus sérieux ennemis <strong>de</strong> la paix. Cet anticommunisme va <strong>de</strong>venir<br />

une sorte <strong>de</strong> lien commun propre aux fédéralistes, certains pour les raisons personnelles<br />

que nous avons déjà exposées (Spinelli), la plupart parce que le communisme est à leurs<br />

yeux l'ennemi naturel du fédéralisme, <strong>de</strong>puis que Lénine a explicitement condamné ce<br />

<strong>de</strong>rnier en 1915. 61 Et <strong>de</strong> fait, Rossi dénonce dans sa correspondance un complot soviétique<br />

ourdi à l'échelle européenne, et dont il voit le centre en France:<br />

«En France les communistes ont repris les mots d'ordre <strong>de</strong> L’Action française et se<br />

montrent d'accord avec l'extrême droite dans la propagan<strong>de</strong> du plus étroit nationalisme,<br />

contre les ‘boches’, pour la <strong>de</strong>struction <strong>de</strong> l'Allemagne, etc.». 62<br />

58. Il s'agit du suisse Pierre Robert, militant <strong>de</strong> la Fédération syndicale internationale <strong>de</strong>s Transports.<br />

59. Auteur en particulier <strong>de</strong> Studies in the Problem <strong>of</strong> Sovereignty, Oxford, 1917, The Foundation <strong>of</strong> Sovereignty<br />

and other Essays, London, 1921, et Nationalism and the Future <strong>of</strong> Civilization, London, 1932.<br />

60. Lettre d’Ernesto Rossi à Luciano Bolis, 24 septembre 1944, p.2, WL-27, ASCE.<br />

61. LÉNINE, Sur le mot d'ordre <strong>de</strong>s Etats-Unis d'Europe, Sozial<strong>de</strong>mokrat, 23 août 1915 in: R. MON-<br />

TELEONE, Le ragioni teoriche <strong>de</strong>l rifiuto <strong>de</strong>lla parole d’ordine <strong>de</strong>gli Stati Uniti d’Europa nel movimento<br />

comunista internazionale; S. PISTONE (dir.), L’I<strong>de</strong>a <strong>de</strong>ll’unificazione europea dalla Prima<br />

alla Seconda Guerra mondiale, Fondazione Luigi Einaudi, Torino, 1975, p.83.<br />

62. Lettre d’Ernesto Rossi à Mario Alberto Rollier, Genève, 24 septembre 1944, WL-27, ASCE. Dans<br />

une lettre aux militants <strong>de</strong> Rome du 7 octobre 1944, il s'attaque au mythe du «Parti <strong>de</strong>s fusillés»<br />

orchestré par L'Humanité, WL-27, ASCE. Pour les fédéralistes, le combat contre la monopolisation<br />

<strong>de</strong> la Résistance par les communistes a déjà commencé.


54<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

Pour Rossi, cette tactique, qui consiste à soulever la haine contre le bouc émissaire<br />

allemand, <strong>de</strong>vrait permettre à l’URSS <strong>de</strong> se présenter comme le seul Sauveur<br />

crédible dans le chaos <strong>de</strong> la Libération.<br />

Le danger étant i<strong>de</strong>ntifié, il faut agir vite, surtout dans la mesure où les communistes,<br />

eux aussi, parient sur une situation révolutionnaire pour faire triompher<br />

leurs idéaux. Cependant, c’est au moment où il faut trouver une véritable stratégie<br />

politique que les fédéralistes, comme la plupart <strong>de</strong>s résistants, vont se rendre<br />

compte que les partis traditionnels, par eux condamnés, restent <strong>de</strong> sérieux obstacles.<br />

Les fédéralistes italiens, qui à Ventotene, à Milan ou en Suisse, pariaient sur la<br />

rapidité et la spontanéité pour consoli<strong>de</strong>r leur mouvement à l'heure <strong>de</strong> la Libération,<br />

prennent conscience <strong>de</strong>s difficultés à implanter le MFE. Pour Ernesto Rossi,<br />

qui est encore en Suisse, ces difficultés proviennent <strong>de</strong>s militants eux-mêmes, qui<br />

jouent le jeu <strong>de</strong>s partis traditionnels. Dans une lettre du 2 décembre 1944 aux militants<br />

romains (et qui avaient été présents lors <strong>de</strong> la création du MFE en juillet<br />

1943), il dénonce leur «inactivité» et, plus grave, il déplore «qu'il n'y ait plus personne<br />

parmi vous qui croit vraiment à l'absolue prééminence <strong>de</strong>s problèmes internationaux<br />

sur les problèmes <strong>de</strong> politique intérieure». 63<br />

Dans une lettre envoyée le même jour au seul Vindice Cavallera, il va jusqu'à<br />

dire que «[…] à Rome vous avez laissé mourir le MFE, juste quand était venu le<br />

bon moment pour commencer un travail sérieusement». 64 En fait, Rossi a peur que<br />

la toute nouvelle organisation fédéraliste ne <strong>de</strong>vienne l'exclusivité d'un parti politique,<br />

quel qu'il soit. Il avait d'ailleurs déjà exprimé cette hantise dans une lettre antérieure,<br />

toujours aux militants romains, en affirmant:<br />

«Nous trahirons nos morts et nous nous trahirons nous-mêmes si nous nous mettons<br />

à faire <strong>de</strong> la petite politique, cherchant à nous attirer les bonnes grâces du Vatican, du<br />

gouvernement anglais et américain pour avoir <strong>de</strong>s postes au ministère […] Nous<br />

<strong>de</strong>vons sauver notre drapeau, pour constituer un véritable point <strong>de</strong> rencontre <strong>de</strong>s forces<br />

progressistes». 65<br />

Il faut reconnaître qu'après la mort d'Eugenio Colorni, qui avait été chargé par le<br />

MFE <strong>de</strong> représenter le mouvement à Rome, la tache est difficile pour les fédéralistes<br />

dans la capitale: jouant <strong>de</strong> ses sympathies socialistes, parti que les fédéralistes<br />

considèrent comme le premier <strong>de</strong>s «forces progressistes», Colorni avait pu<br />

recruter certains jeunes adhérents, tels que Leo Solari, Achille Corona ou Mario<br />

63. Lettre d’Ernesto Rossi à Vindice Cavallera, Manlio Rossidoria, Luisa Usellini et autres amis fédéralistes<br />

<strong>de</strong> Rome, Genève, 2 décembre 1944, WL-27, ASCE. Dans cette même lettre, Rossi exprime<br />

la peur que l'européisme ne retombe dans la stérilité <strong>de</strong> l'avant-guerre, lorsque ses plus ar<strong>de</strong>nts<br />

défenseurs n'étaient que <strong>de</strong>s «amants <strong>de</strong> la paix» tels que Dante, Hugo, Cattaneo ou Garibaldi. Le<br />

fait que les premiers militants se retirent peu à peu <strong>de</strong> l’action n'est pas le propre <strong>de</strong>s seuls Italiens,<br />

comme le montre cette lettre <strong>de</strong> Rossi du 4 décembre 1944 (le surlen<strong>de</strong>main), où il écrit: «le mois<br />

<strong>de</strong>rnier nous n’avons plus eu <strong>de</strong> contacts avec <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes, sauf avec Pierre [Soutou] qui maintenant<br />

a une charge <strong>of</strong>ficielle à la légation française et qui donc doit prendre beaucoup plus <strong>de</strong> précautions<br />

que quand il était un simple [privé] comme nous», WL-27, ASCE.<br />

64. Lettre d’Ernesto Rossi à Vindice Cavallera, Genève, 2 décembre 1944, WL-27, ASCE.<br />

65. Lettre d’Ernesto Rossi à Mario Alberto Rollier, Genève, 24 septembre 1944, WL-27, ASCE.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 55<br />

Zagari; après sa mort, ceux-ci vont prendre du recul par rapport au mouvement et,<br />

après la Libération, se consacrer <strong>de</strong> manière exclusive à leur formation politique.<br />

Du côté <strong>de</strong> la démocratie chrétienne, l’homme politique en qui les fédéralistes<br />

italiens avaient le plus confiance pour mener une action conforme à leurs principes<br />

était Carlo Sforza, dans la ligne <strong>de</strong>s idées qu'il avait exprimées en exil dans<br />

l'entre-<strong>de</strong>ux-guerres. 66 Cette confiance avait été affichée dans une lettre que Rossi<br />

et Spinelli lui avaient envoyée <strong>de</strong> Ventotene à la suite du congrès <strong>de</strong> Montevi<strong>de</strong>o<br />

(août 1942), où s'étaient rassemblés <strong>de</strong>s milliers d’Italiens réfugiés en Amérique.<br />

Lors <strong>de</strong> ce congrès présidé par Sforza, il avait été adopté une déclaration dont le<br />

septième point surtout avait attiré l'attention <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes, puisqu'il proclamait la<br />

primauté du droit international. 67 L'idylle avec les idées fédéralistes ne durera<br />

cependant pas, à partir du moment où Sforza réintègre <strong>de</strong>s fonctions <strong>of</strong>ficielles et<br />

adopte un discours moins idéaliste, comme dans cette interview accordée par lui au<br />

New York Times, le 3 mars 1944: Sforza y déclare que l'Italie ne doit rendre les îles<br />

du Dodécanèse à la Grèce que si les populations <strong>de</strong> ces îles le <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>nt par référendum,<br />

que les Alliés doivent restituer les colonies libyenne, érythréenne et somalienne<br />

à l'Italie, et qu'un échange doit se faire avec la Yougoslavie, consistant à conserver<br />

l'Istrie contre la ville <strong>de</strong> Fiume. Ces propos sont dénoncés par Rossi comme<br />

ceux qu'aurait pu tenir «n’importe quel homme politique <strong>de</strong> l'ancien temps qui verrait<br />

les problèmes internationaux du strict point <strong>de</strong> vue <strong>de</strong>s intérêts <strong>de</strong> son propre<br />

pays». 68 Il critique les croyances selon lesquelles le principe national et le droit à<br />

l'autodétermination <strong>de</strong>s peuples suffiraient à faire cesser le cycle guerrier en<br />

Europe: les avertissements d'Einaudi, donnés en 1918, sont bel et bien repris par les<br />

fédéralistes pour critiquer l’attitu<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s hommes politiques italiens.<br />

En ce qui concerne la France, Spinelli s'y rend en septembre 1944, car les fédéralistes<br />

parient encore sur la bonne volonté <strong>de</strong> ses dirigeants pour faire aboutir leurs<br />

efforts: ainsi, le point 7 <strong>de</strong>s directives <strong>de</strong> travail arrêtées par le MFE au Congrès <strong>de</strong><br />

Milan d’août 1943 parlait <strong>de</strong> la «convocation dans un pays neutre d'une conférence<br />

internationale fédéraliste», en apparence la Suisse; en 1945, parce que la France<br />

semble pouvoir <strong>de</strong>venir le champion <strong>de</strong> la cause européenne, le lieu d'élection est<br />

Paris, où va effectivement se tenir la première conférence fédéraliste, au mois <strong>de</strong><br />

mars. Les rapports sur la situation française, que Spinelli envoie régulièrement à<br />

Rossi, toujours en Suisse, sont intéressants pour saisir l'image d'un pays encore<br />

plongé dans le chaos <strong>de</strong> la Libération et surtout pour comprendre les espérances et<br />

les défiances <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes vis-à-vis <strong>de</strong> l’Hexagone.<br />

Ces rapports se focalisent sur la personne du général <strong>de</strong> Gaulle: on peut même<br />

percevoir dans les premières analyses faites <strong>de</strong> ce personnage les futures réticences<br />

envers l'homme politique français. C'est bien lui qui restaure les cadres <strong>de</strong> l’Etat<br />

souverain, par l'intermédiaire <strong>de</strong> la restructuration administrative et <strong>de</strong>s nationalisa-<br />

66. En particulier dans Les Etats-Unis d'Europe, in: Revue <strong>de</strong> l'Université <strong>de</strong> Bruxelles, décembre<br />

1929-janvier 1930, n°2, pp.103-118.<br />

67. Cette déclaration est reproduite dans l'article <strong>de</strong> E. ROSSI, La politica estera italiana, in: L'Unità<br />

Europea, n°5, juillet-août 1944, pp.4-5.<br />

68. E. ROSSI, La politica estera italiana, op.cit., p.5.


56<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

tions, et qui vi<strong>de</strong> la Résistance <strong>de</strong> tout son sens en marginalisant les Comités <strong>de</strong><br />

Libération; 69 <strong>de</strong> plus, il est vu par Spinelli comme l'un <strong>de</strong> ces «vieux hommes politiques»<br />

condamnés par les fédéralistes pendant la guerre, accusés <strong>de</strong> vouloir restaurer<br />

cet ancien régime politique combattu par les idéaux <strong>de</strong> la Résistance:<br />

«De Gaulle vise haut et grand 70 en voulant que la France soit la quatrième puissance<br />

mondiale. Le chauvinisme français se montre très satisfait <strong>de</strong> toutes ses affirmations<br />

<strong>de</strong> gran<strong>de</strong>ur que <strong>de</strong> Gaulle fait <strong>de</strong> manière répétée». 71<br />

Le combat fédéraliste semble <strong>de</strong>voir d'ores et déjà choisir son camp, en opposition<br />

à un homme qui restaure ce que l’on veut anéantir. Les affirmations <strong>de</strong> Spinelli<br />

à ce sujet se veulent par ailleurs rassurantes, bien que l'on y décèle une certaine<br />

gêne: «[…] les meilleures têtes politiques <strong>de</strong> la gauche française - socialistes, syndicalistes,<br />

MLN - sont fédéralistes et participeront à la conférence; cependant, j'ai<br />

dû préparer pratiquement tout le matériel nécessaire pour un tel événement». 72<br />

Ainsi, la première conférence fédéraliste qui doit se tenir à Paris entre les principaux<br />

courants fédéralistes <strong>de</strong> la Résistance, à la fin du mois <strong>de</strong> mars 1945, semble pouvoir<br />

être l'amorce du renouveau politique tant attendu, en même temps qu’un moyen <strong>de</strong> confronter<br />

<strong>de</strong>s idées forgées dans la clan<strong>de</strong>stinité <strong>de</strong>s différentes Résistances.<br />

6) Les «ren<strong>de</strong>z-vous manqués» <strong>de</strong> l’après-guerre.<br />

Si ce ren<strong>de</strong>z-vous international semble marquer une première victoire <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes<br />

italiens, dans la ligne <strong>de</strong> ce qu'ils réclamaient <strong>de</strong>puis l'exil <strong>de</strong> Ventotene, on<br />

peut se <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>r s'ils ont réussi à faire passer leurs idéaux dans leur propre pays et<br />

à vaincre les réticences <strong>de</strong> la classe politique au moment <strong>de</strong> la Libération. On a vu<br />

les liens importants <strong>de</strong> nombreux fédéralistes italiens avec le Partito d’Azione. Pour<br />

certains d'entre eux, ce parti hors normes, issu <strong>de</strong> la «lave incan<strong>de</strong>scente <strong>de</strong> 1945» 73<br />

et donc non entaché par les calculs et les combinaisons <strong>de</strong>s partis politiques traditionnels,<br />

pouvait <strong>de</strong>venir une arme importante, ou, au moins, ce relais politique tant<br />

attendu pendant la Résistance. Dans ses souvenirs, Spinelli explique l'engagement<br />

<strong>de</strong> nombreux fédéralistes, dont lui, dans ce parti, pour <strong>de</strong>s raisons qui semblent<br />

conformes aux objectifs du Manifeste <strong>de</strong> Ventotene:<br />

69. «Le gouvernement provisoire <strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> Gaulle a réussi <strong>de</strong> manière à peu près complète à reconstruire<br />

la structure administrative <strong>de</strong> l’Etat. Les Comités <strong>de</strong> Libération départementaux et communaux,<br />

n’ayant pas réussi à <strong>de</strong>venir <strong>de</strong>s organes d'administration, réduits à être <strong>de</strong> simples organes consultatifs<br />

<strong>de</strong>s préfets et <strong>de</strong>s maires nommés par les préfets, per<strong>de</strong>nt chaque jour plus <strong>de</strong> sens». In: Rapport<br />

d’AItiero Spinelli, 15 mars 1945, p.1 , WL-27, ASCE.<br />

70. En français dans le texte.<br />

71. Rapport <strong>de</strong> Spinelli, 15 mars 1945, p.2, WL-27, ASCE.<br />

72. Ibid., p.2.<br />

73. Expression <strong>de</strong> l'historien italien R. LOMBARDI (et membre du PDA), Problemi di potere in Milano<br />

liberata, p.266, cité par P. GINSBORG, Storia d’Italia dal dopoguerra a oggi, Torino, Einaudi,<br />

1989, p.117.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 57<br />

«Il paraissait assez naturel que l'idée d'une nouvelle bataille politique comme la<br />

nôtre, riche au point <strong>de</strong> vue culturel mais sans passé politique, trouve le meilleur<br />

écho dans ce parti inédit, grouillant d'intellectuels, dans lequel s'effectuait une<br />

recherche fébrile d'horizons nouveaux, et qui ne souffrait pas du frein d'un passé<br />

marqué par la seule action politique quotidienne dans un cadre national». 74<br />

C'est dire que, lorsque Ferruccio Parri, chef du Partito d’Azione (PDA), parvient à la<br />

prési<strong>de</strong>nce du Conseil italien en juin 1945, les espoirs sont grands. Il est vrai que le<br />

PDA se qualifie lui-même <strong>de</strong> «parti <strong>de</strong> la démocratie révolutionnaire», et, dans son programme,<br />

revendique la formule politique du fédéralisme. Lors d'un congrès tenu à<br />

Rome entre les 4 et 8 février 1944, les azionisti ajoutent à leur programme sur l'élection<br />

<strong>de</strong> l'Assemblée constituante un point 9 intitulé «politique étrangère et fédéralisme»,<br />

appelant à «la formation <strong>de</strong>s Etats-Unis d’Europe, le premier pas vers l'abolition <strong>de</strong>s<br />

souverainetés nationales qui ont toujours conduit à la guerre». 75 La volonté que ce point<br />

figure dans la nouvelle Constitution est mise en avant dans le «plan <strong>de</strong> travail» du PDA<br />

rédigé la même année par le juriste Piero Calamandrei (décembre), où il est <strong>de</strong>mandé<br />

que soit incluse dans la Constitution italienne une déclaration portant l'acceptation<br />

d'une limitation <strong>de</strong> souveraineté au cas où une fédération européenne serait mise en<br />

place. 76 La présence d’Altiero Spinelli et d’Ernesto Rossi au secrétariat du PDA à<br />

Rome est une garantie pour les fédéralistes que ce gouvernement va dans leur sens:<br />

beaucoup <strong>de</strong>s hommes du gouvernement, au premier chef Ferruccio Parri, <strong>de</strong> même<br />

que Piero Calamandrei, sont membres du MFE, alors que Rossi a <strong>de</strong>s liens d'amitié<br />

avec certains membres <strong>de</strong> l'ancien mouvement Giustizia e Libertà, largement représenté<br />

dans les rangs du PDA.<br />

C'est pour cette raison que Spinelli et Rossi, pris par leurs nouvelles responsabilités<br />

politiques, prennent du recul par rapport au MFE, dont le premier prési<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong><br />

l'après-guerre est Umberto Campagnolo. Cet éloignement volontaire a une gran<strong>de</strong><br />

importance à l'heure où se rencontrent les différents mouvements fédéralistes européens<br />

dans le but <strong>de</strong> créer une plate-forme commune. En effet, ce sont les représentants<br />

du fédéralisme intégral, inspirés par le personnalisme d'origine française, 77<br />

qui sont présents en masse lors <strong>de</strong>s réunions préparatoires dont le but est <strong>de</strong> réfléchir<br />

à la doctrine et à l'organisation d'un mouvement fédéraliste unifié: Spinelli et<br />

Rossi n’étaient présents ni à la réunion d’Hertenstein (15 au 22 septembre 1946) ni<br />

à celle <strong>de</strong> Luxembourg (13 au 16 octobre 1946), qui prési<strong>de</strong>nt à la constitution <strong>de</strong><br />

l'Union Européenne <strong>de</strong>s Fédéralistes, le 15 décembre 1946, à Paris, dans les locaux<br />

<strong>de</strong> La Fédération (mouvement créé le 4 octobre 1944), même si une délégation du<br />

MFE était présente. Il y a dans ce déséquilibre un élément <strong>de</strong> fragilisation, surtout<br />

si l'on pense que les liens idéologiques avec la Résistance <strong>de</strong> cette toute nouvelle<br />

74. A. SPINELLI, Come ho tentato …, p.34.<br />

75. Ce programme figure dans le <strong>journal</strong> du PDA, L’Italia Libera, 7 avril 1946.<br />

76. Piano di lavoro <strong>de</strong>l PDA, publié dans Qua<strong>de</strong>rni <strong>de</strong>ll’Italia Libera, 30 décembre 1944.<br />

77. Fédéralisme qui se réclame <strong>de</strong> l'héritage proudhonien, dont les principaux inspirateurs sont<br />

Alexandre Marc et Denis <strong>de</strong> Rougemont, et dont le principe est que l'individu doit se mouvoir et<br />

se réaliser au contact <strong>de</strong>s diverses cellules (familiale, communale, pr<strong>of</strong>essionnelle) qu'il est amené<br />

à connaître et dans lesquelles il s'engage pleinement.


58<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

internationale ne sont pas toujours évi<strong>de</strong>nts. 78 De plus, la différence entre les tendances<br />

fédéralistes rési<strong>de</strong> non seulement dans les origines idéologiques, mais également<br />

dans les buts à atteindre, ce que Spinelli résume <strong>de</strong> manière très radicale:<br />

«Le mouvement italien était anti-idéologique, le mouvement français pr<strong>of</strong>ondément<br />

idéologique. Le mouvement italien voulait créer <strong>de</strong>s institutions européennes<br />

dans le but <strong>de</strong> développer un nouveau cadre politique européen qui révolutionnerait<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>ondément l’ensemble <strong>de</strong> la vie nationale et politique. Le mouvement français<br />

regardait les institutions européennes comme un simple élément <strong>de</strong> coordination,<br />

incapable en lui-même <strong>de</strong> provoquer le changement, et pour cette raison soutenait<br />

un programme d’action multiforme concernant toutes les parties <strong>de</strong> la société». 79<br />

Il est vrai que ce point <strong>de</strong> vue est donné bien après les faits (1953). Il n’en témoigne<br />

pas moins du manque crucial d'homogénéité du fédéralisme <strong>de</strong> l’après-guerre, qui s'est<br />

coupé <strong>de</strong> sa source d'inspiration la plus prolifique.<br />

Hélas pour Spinelli et Rossi, l'espoir qui les a fait s'éloigner <strong>de</strong> l'activisme fédéraliste<br />

est très vite déçu. Le PDA ne reprend pas les mots d'ordre du MFE, comme souhaité.<br />

Ce refus peut s'expliquer par <strong>de</strong>s raisons internationales mais également internes, le<br />

PDA perdant sa ferveur révolutionnaire une fois la guerre terminée: ainsi, les Comités<br />

<strong>de</strong> libération nationale formés dans toute la péninsule en 1945, instruments <strong>de</strong> démocratie<br />

directe qu'appuyaient les azionisti pendant la Résistance, per<strong>de</strong>nt-ils peu à peu le<br />

soutien <strong>de</strong> Parri, pressé par l'aile libérale <strong>de</strong> son parti. Dans un document <strong>de</strong> travail<br />

rédigé par Ugo La Malfa en juillet 1945, on peut voir les raisons qui poussent les membres<br />

du PDA à repousser toute revendication fédéraliste. 80 Les raisons internationales<br />

priment et montrent une vision bien différente <strong>de</strong> celle adoptée pendant la guerre: «La<br />

Fédération européenne est une bonne idée, mais il faudrait savoir comment éviter <strong>de</strong><br />

donner à cette fédération un caractère antirusse ou antibritannique. La Russie et<br />

l'Angleterre participeront-elles à la fédération européenne»? La place <strong>de</strong> l'Allemagne<br />

pose aussi <strong>de</strong>s questions angoissantes: «Sans ces nations [Russie et Angleterre] la fédération<br />

finirait par s'acheminer vers une hégémonie alleman<strong>de</strong> […], en gros ce que voulait<br />

obtenir le National-Socialisme».<br />

Les raisons internes ne manquent pas également dans le recul du PDA et le titre<br />

du document <strong>de</strong> travail suffit à exprimer les inquiétu<strong>de</strong>s du parti: «Plan <strong>de</strong> renoncement<br />

à la souveraineté: nous pouvons être traités d'ennemis du pays et d'anti-italiens».<br />

Toutes ces raisons justifient le rejet <strong>de</strong> l'alliance avec les fédéralistes et <strong>de</strong><br />

toute tactique partisane allant dans leur sens: «Tant que ces interrogations ne seront<br />

78. Cette critique vise particulièrement certains membres français <strong>de</strong> l’UEF, qui avaient été tentés pendant<br />

la guerre par l'expérience <strong>de</strong> Vichy, en premier lieu les membres du groupe La Fédération,<br />

dirigé par Jacques Bassot et André Voisin. C'est en pensant à ces <strong>de</strong>rniers que la <strong>revue</strong> Esprit, dans<br />

un numéro spécial consacré au fédéralisme européen (novembre 1948), dénonce «cette pâte très<br />

mêlée d'o<strong>de</strong>urs suspectes» qui lui paraît constituer l'UEF.<br />

79. A. SPINELLI, Storia e Prospettiva <strong>de</strong>l MFE, in: L'Europa nel mondo, s.l., 1953, pp.156-160, cité dans<br />

A. HICK, The European Union <strong>of</strong> Fe<strong>de</strong>ralists, in: W. LIPGENS et W. LOTH, Documents, t.4, p.11.<br />

80. «Piano con la rinuncia alla sovranità: potremo essere tacciati di nemici <strong>de</strong>l paese e di antiitaliani»,<br />

15 juillet 1945, AS-5, ASCE.


Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen 59<br />

pas levées, il n'est pas opportun <strong>de</strong> faire <strong>de</strong> la Fédération européenne la base <strong>de</strong><br />

notre programme <strong>de</strong> politique extérieure». 81<br />

Dans ce secteur comme dans d’autres, le PDA a fait preuve <strong>de</strong> trop d'hésitations.<br />

Celui-ci disparaît à l'issue <strong>de</strong> ce qui sera son <strong>de</strong>rnier congrès, en février 1946,<br />

quand une scission intervient entre les tendances socialistes, représentées par Emilio<br />

Lussu, et les tendances libérales, dirigées par La Malfa. Le parti n'y survivra<br />

pas, et son expérience politique sera <strong>de</strong>s plus courtes: appelé à la prési<strong>de</strong>nce du<br />

Conseil le 21 juin 1945, Parri quitte ses fonctions en décembre <strong>de</strong> la même année,<br />

remplacé par Alci<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> Gasperi, qui n'entretient aucun lien avec le MFE.<br />

Conclusion<br />

Ainsi, la situation politique dans l’Europe <strong>de</strong> l'immédiat après-guerre ne correspond pas<br />

vraiment à ce qu'en espéraient les Italiens, ni du point <strong>de</strong> vue du fédéralisme militant, ni<br />

du point <strong>de</strong> vue <strong>de</strong>s réformes politiques engagées dans chacun <strong>de</strong>s pays.<br />

Bien entendu, suivant leur vœu, une plate-forme internationale a été instaurée,<br />

d'abord au sein <strong>de</strong> l'éphémère Comité International pour la Fédération européenne,<br />

résultat <strong>de</strong> la Conférence <strong>de</strong> Paris (22 au 25 mars 1945), puis <strong>de</strong> l'Union Européenne<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Fédéralistes, mais cette plate-forme n'est homogène que par défaut. Les fédéralistes<br />

semblent bien mal partis, d'autant qu'ils refusent, par principe, l'alliance avec d'autres<br />

mouvements européistes, catalogués comme passéistes et trop timorés. Les trois années<br />

1946-1948 ne permettent pas <strong>de</strong> définir avec certitu<strong>de</strong> quelle tendance s'impose à<br />

l'UEF: les fédéralistes sont à la recherche d’une doctrine, voire d’un «juste milieu», ce<br />

qui explique la position du modéré Henri Brugmans à la tête <strong>de</strong> l'UEF. On peut simplement<br />

constater qu'à l'issue du second Congrès <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes à Rome (novembre<br />

1948), la tendance spinellienne prend un ascendant incontestable dans les esprits, mais<br />

pas encore dans l'organisation. C'est l'échec patent <strong>de</strong> l'«Europe Troisième Force», illustré<br />

par les crises <strong>de</strong> Prague et <strong>de</strong> Berlin, qui va orchestrer le retour <strong>de</strong>s Italiens à l'action<br />

militante, dans la foulée du Plan Marshall.<br />

On ne peut que constater le parallélisme évi<strong>de</strong>nt qu'il y a entre le refroidissement<br />

<strong>de</strong>s relations Est/Ouest et l'affirmation <strong>de</strong>s idéaux fédéralistes, jusqu'à ce que<br />

ces <strong>de</strong>ux correspon<strong>de</strong>nt avec le projet d’armée européenne d'octobre 1950. Autant<br />

dire que l'année 1948 clôt effectivement ce que Denis <strong>de</strong> Rougemont a appelé la<br />

«campagne <strong>de</strong>s Congrès européens»: l’UEF inaugure une nouvelle stratégie, qui<br />

repose sur les contacts personnels au plus haut niveau (Spaak, Schuman, <strong>de</strong> Gasperi)<br />

et qui utilise le relais <strong>de</strong> la presse et <strong>de</strong> l'édition: 82 inutile <strong>de</strong> dire que ce nou-<br />

81. Ibid., p.1.<br />

82. On doit souligner les difficultés <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes à faire connaître leurs idées en passant par les maisons<br />

d’édition traditionnelles: c'est par exemple le cas du livre <strong>de</strong> L. EINAUDI, La guerre et l'unité<br />

européenne, refusé successivement par Plon et Gallimard. Voir lettre <strong>de</strong> Michel Berveiller à Guglielmo<br />

Usellini, 22 décembre 1948, UEF-5, ainsi que par Calmann-Lévy, Lettre <strong>de</strong> refus <strong>de</strong> Raymond<br />

Aron à Michel Berveiller, 18 décembre 1948, UEF-2, ASCE.


60<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

veau combat correspond <strong>de</strong> plus en plus aux attentes <strong>de</strong> Spinelli, très à l'aise dans<br />

ces nouveaux chantiers politiques qui s'ouvrent dans la foulée du Plan Schuman. 83<br />

Nous sommes bien au cœur du combat pour la supranationalité, que les fédéralistes<br />

engagent en s'appuyant sur un militantisme qui semble préservé <strong>de</strong> toute polémique:<br />

l'objectif commun est <strong>de</strong> faire cé<strong>de</strong>r les Etats européens occi<strong>de</strong>ntaux, notamment<br />

avec le projet <strong>de</strong> Communauté Politique européenne qui, s'il venait à aboutir,<br />

permettrait l'aboutissement <strong>de</strong> cette «société fédérale», suivant les prédictions que<br />

Spinelli avait formulées pendant la Secon<strong>de</strong> Guerre mondiale. Cependant, ce retour<br />

mérité et efficace <strong>de</strong>s fédéralistes italiens au premier plan ne doit pas faire oublier<br />

que ceux-ci ont dû renoncer, pour ce faire, à une partie <strong>de</strong> leurs idéaux: le projet<br />

européen pour lequel ils vont alors se battre tourne le dos aux espoirs <strong>de</strong> la<br />

Résistance, vérification supplémentaire que le Vieux Continent, partagé en <strong>de</strong>ux,<br />

n'est plus vraiment maître <strong>de</strong> son <strong>de</strong>stin, et que le Fédéralisme n’a pas su s’imposer<br />

en idéologie autonome …<br />

83. On peut signaler que <strong>de</strong>ux dirigeants «intégraux» <strong>de</strong> l'UEF, respectivement Denis <strong>de</strong> Rougemont<br />

et Henri Brugmans, seront appelés à diriger <strong>de</strong>s instances culturelles européennes créées en 1950,<br />

le Centre européen <strong>de</strong> la Culture à Genève et le Collège <strong>de</strong> Bruges: ces gran<strong>de</strong>s figures prennent<br />

donc <strong>de</strong> la distance avec l’action militante fédéraliste, au pr<strong>of</strong>it du seul Spinelli.


61<br />

France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale»<br />

The Union Française as an Obstacle in the French Policy<br />

<strong>of</strong> Supranational European Integration, 1952-1954<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

Supranational European <strong>integration</strong>, beginning with the Schuman Plan in 1950, was<br />

sought by the first “Six-countries” in or<strong>de</strong>r to reconstruct their economies. But the hid<strong>de</strong>n<br />

goal <strong>of</strong> the most important member state in this European community, France, was<br />

to control West Germany by means <strong>of</strong> supranational European <strong>integration</strong>. It was much<br />

supported by the United States, which inten<strong>de</strong>d to draw upon German economic and<br />

military capacities in view <strong>of</strong> the escalation <strong>of</strong> the Cold War. It therefore had both a<br />

European and a global perspective. 1 To the latter belonged also problems that were<br />

related with the colonies <strong>of</strong> European powers, above all Great Britain and France.<br />

Although the problems regarding colonies did not originally concern supranational<br />

<strong>integration</strong>, they always influenced the process <strong>of</strong> the latter.<br />

In the 1950s Great Britain did not take part in supranational European <strong>integration</strong>.<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the reasons for British non-participation was that Great Britain thought<br />

the consolidation <strong>of</strong> the Commonwealth would not be compatible with the supranational<br />

<strong>integration</strong> in which Great Britain should transfer some parts <strong>of</strong> its sovereignty<br />

to a European community. The British stance on supranational European <strong>integration</strong><br />

began to change in 1956, when the British government estimated that in<br />

the long term the Commonwealth would not have the same impact on the British<br />

economy than the Common Market <strong>of</strong> the “Six-countries”. After a long internal<br />

discussion, Whitehall <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d to participate in supranational European <strong>integration</strong><br />

in 1961. Which role did the Union Française play in early supranational European<br />

<strong>integration</strong>? Contrary to Great Britain, when drawing up the Schuman Plan, France<br />

thought that the Union Française-policy and supranational European <strong>integration</strong><br />

might be compatible. 2 The Territoires d’Outre-Mer (TOM) were exclu<strong>de</strong>d from the<br />

European communities during the negotiations on the European Coal and Steel<br />

Community (ECSC), the European Defence Community (EDC) and the common<br />

agricultural projects in the early 1950s. The questions <strong>of</strong> the relationship between<br />

the Union Française and the supranational European community played a role, but<br />

were not an obstacle for the success <strong>of</strong> these projects. It was not until 1955-1957<br />

that France sud<strong>de</strong>nly wanted to inclu<strong>de</strong> its overseas territories in the supranational<br />

1. C. WURM, Early European Integration as a Research Field: Perspectives, Debates, Problems, in:<br />

C. WURM (ed.), Western Europe and Germany. The Beginnings <strong>of</strong> European Integration<br />

1945-1960, Oxford, Washington, 1995, pp.9-26.<br />

2. These differences between the policies <strong>of</strong> two European powers towards supranational European <strong>integration</strong>,<br />

according to Clemens Wurm, lie in the <strong>de</strong>gree <strong>of</strong> importance <strong>of</strong> their Empires to their national<br />

economies and in their policies over West Germany. France felt a future security threat more seriously<br />

than Great Britain. Therefore, France took supranational <strong>integration</strong> for an inevitable measure to control<br />

an ever stronger West Germany. See C. WURM, Two Paths to Europe: Great Britain and France from<br />

a Comparative Perspective, in: C. WURM (ed.), op.cit., pp.175-200.


62<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

European <strong>integration</strong> process, hoping that it could solve colonial financial problems<br />

with the help <strong>of</strong> the other partner states, which was a great bur<strong>de</strong>n on them.<br />

Did not, however, the “vocation mondiale” make it difficult for France to lead<br />

early supranational <strong>integration</strong>, just as in the case <strong>of</strong> Great Britain? Gérard Bossuat<br />

<strong>de</strong>als with the subtle questions arising from the relationship between the French<br />

overseas areas and the European Political Community (EPC) in 1953. In 1953<br />

France could not control the process <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> and no longer wanted<br />

to play the role <strong>of</strong> lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> integrated Europe. As the subtitle, “from criticism to repudiation<br />

[<strong>of</strong> the projected EPC]; France’s vocation mondiale”* allu<strong>de</strong>s to, according<br />

to Bossuat,<br />

“the European construction failed in 1953, because <strong>of</strong> the French governments’<br />

dilemma, having to choose between Europe, whose <strong>de</strong>stiny they might not be able to<br />

control and the perpetuation <strong>of</strong> France’s world power”*. 3<br />

Bossuat’s outstanding contribution still needs to be completed in some points.<br />

He only analyses the problem <strong>of</strong> the Union Française in the negotiations <strong>of</strong> the<br />

EPC. (Even this aspect he treated too briefly). But problems <strong>of</strong> the TOM in European<br />

<strong>integration</strong> in these years were not only related to the EPC, but also to the process<br />

<strong>of</strong> ratification <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty and the negotiations <strong>of</strong> a European agricultural<br />

community. This article investigates the questions arising from the relationship between<br />

the Union Française and all the projects <strong>of</strong> supranational European <strong>integration</strong><br />

between 1952 and 1954. 4<br />

3. Quotations marked with an * have been translated by the author.<br />

G. BOSSUAT, La France, l’ai<strong>de</strong> américaine et la construction européenne 1944-1954, Paris,<br />

1992, pp.882 and 897. Georges-Henri Soutou refers to these problems in his research which tries<br />

to portray Bidault’s European policies, but does not go as much into <strong>de</strong>tails as Bossuat. G.-H.<br />

SOUTOU, Georges Bidault et la construction européenne 1944-1954, in: Revue d’Histoire Diplomatique,<br />

Paris, 1991, pp.267-306. The writings <strong>of</strong> the politicians who were engaged in early European<br />

<strong>integration</strong>, for example P.-H. TEITGEN (Faites entrer le témoin suivant, 1940-1958, De<br />

la Résistance à la V e République, Paris, 1988), H. ALPHAND (L’étonnement d’être. Journal<br />

(1939-1973), Paris, 1977) and M. DEBRÉ (Trois Républiques pour une France. Mémoires 2: Agir<br />

(1946-1958), Paris, 1988), give us only some information on this subject. In or<strong>de</strong>r to <strong>de</strong>fine their<br />

positions on this subject, therefore, it is better to consult classified documents that they wrote.<br />

4. The points that Bossuat overlooked <strong>de</strong>rive from the fact that he did not consult file 42 <strong>of</strong> the private<br />

archive <strong>of</strong> Georges Bidault in the Archives Nationales (AN) entitled “Europe et Union Française”<br />

(AN Papiers Bidault 42). In 1953, the French government was confronted with problems which<br />

supranational European <strong>integration</strong> would bring about in the Union Française. Conscious <strong>of</strong> this<br />

problem, foreign minister Georges Bidault collected appropriate documents in one special file.<br />

This is file 42. This article is based on the analysis <strong>of</strong> this special file. This <strong>de</strong>fect is found in expert<br />

studies to the “pool vert”, too. See G. NOËL, France, Allemagne et «Europe verte», Berne, 1995;<br />

G. THIEMEYER, Vom «Pool Vert» zur Europäischen Wirtschaftsgemeinschaft. Europäische Integration,<br />

Kalter Krieg und die Anfänge <strong>de</strong>r Gemeinsamen Europäischen Agrarpolitik 1950-1957,<br />

München, 1999.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 63<br />

The Union Française, the ECSC and the EDC, 1950-1952<br />

During the negotiations for the ECSC, Italy <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d that the French overseas<br />

areas should be inclu<strong>de</strong>d in the ECSC because it wanted to import the iron ore<br />

mined at Quenza in eastern Algeria at a low price. Jean Monnet argued that the<br />

inclusion <strong>of</strong> the TOM in the ECSC might raise a difficult problem because <strong>of</strong> the<br />

complexity <strong>of</strong> the customs systems <strong>of</strong> the French overseas territories, which would<br />

require modifications <strong>of</strong> the system <strong>of</strong> the Union Française. Monnet proposed a<br />

compromise solution: ensuring Italy a regular iron supply without incorporating<br />

Algeria into the Schuman Plan. France accepted this proposition. The TOM were<br />

not inclu<strong>de</strong>d in the ECSC, but France was obliged to grant the other member states,<br />

above all Italy, “the same preferential measures”* which it enjoyed. 5<br />

The Pleven Plan for the creation <strong>of</strong> a supranational European Army took into<br />

account France’s special responsibilities in its overseas areas. Those participating<br />

states that had national armed forces would keep their own command <strong>of</strong> the part <strong>of</strong><br />

their existing army that would not be integrated into the European army. 6 France<br />

could have un<strong>de</strong>r its command the part <strong>of</strong> army stationed in its overseas areas as<br />

well as the great part <strong>of</strong> army on the continent. However, during the negotiations<br />

France had to give way to the <strong>de</strong>mands <strong>of</strong> the other partner states which were based<br />

on the principle <strong>of</strong> equality, so that it agreed that direct national command would<br />

remain only in overseas areas. That meant that all troops in Europe should be subordinated<br />

to a supranational EDC. 7<br />

That was a point on which the EDC treaty <strong>of</strong> May 1952 suffered harsh criticism<br />

from EDC opponents. On the one hand, many Frenchmen feared that West Germany<br />

would soon take the supremacy on the continent, because the great part <strong>of</strong> the<br />

French army would have to remain stationed further in the overseas areas, particularly<br />

in Indochina. France might thus drop back to third rank within the EDC, after<br />

Germany and Italy. On the other hand, it was feared that a two-fold division <strong>of</strong><br />

French armed forces - between Europe and the TOM - would leave France too<br />

weak to <strong>de</strong>fend the TOM. 8<br />

The Union Française played a role in the period between 1950-52, but was not<br />

an obstacle to the success <strong>of</strong> these projects. The ECSC was ratified in December<br />

1951. And the EDC treaty was signed in May 1952. The French government could<br />

5. G. BOSSUAT, op.cit., pp.764 ff.; Article 79 <strong>of</strong> the ECSC treaty <strong>of</strong> 18 April 1951 in: FORSC-<br />

HUNGSINSTITUT DER DEUTSCHEN GESELLSCHAFT FÜR AUSWÄRTIGE POLITIK (Hrsg.),<br />

Europa. Dokumente zur Frage <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Einigung, München, 1962, Bd.2, pp.741 ff.<br />

6. Text in: Europa. Dokumente zur Frage <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Einigung, op.cit., pp.814 ff.<br />

7. G.-H. SOUTOU, France and the German Rearmament Problem, in: R. AHMANN et al. (ed.), The<br />

Quest for Stability, Problems <strong>of</strong> West European Security 1918-1957, Oxford, 1993, pp.487-512.<br />

8. Archives du Ministère <strong>de</strong>s Affaires étrangères, Paris (AMAE), Europe 44-60, Généralités, CED,<br />

Vol.69, pp.24-43, JB/SR, Note, 15 mai 1952, A.S. Traité instituant une CED; AMAE Europe<br />

44-60, Allemagne, Vol.378, pp.222-227, Seydoux, Note, La politique franco-alleman<strong>de</strong>, 2.5.1952;<br />

AMAE Europe 44-60, Allemagne, Vol.1.055, pp.57-63, S/D Centraleurope (Sauvagnargues),<br />

Note, A.S. Arrangements contractuels entre les Trois Puissances Alliées et la République Fédérale<br />

d’Allemagne, 8.6.1952; R. MASSIGLI, Une comédie <strong>de</strong>s erreurs, Paris, 1978, pp.322 ff.


64<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

exclu<strong>de</strong> its overseas areas from supranational European <strong>integration</strong>, without fearing<br />

that this would bring about problems for France maintaining the Union Française<br />

and, therefore, its world power position alongsi<strong>de</strong> the U.S. and Great Britain.<br />

The French Initiative for a Political Integration in 1952 and<br />

the Draft EPC Treaty <strong>of</strong> Ad Hoc Assembly<br />

The Assemblée Nationale, especially the parliamentary <strong>de</strong>legation <strong>of</strong> the principal<br />

socialist party, the Section Française <strong>de</strong> l’Internationale Ouvrière (SFIO), had<br />

<strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d certain prerequisites for the EDC ratification in February 1952, one <strong>of</strong><br />

which was the establishment <strong>of</strong> a supranational political authority for the European<br />

Army. 9 That was why the French government proposed a European Political Community<br />

(EPC) to the other EDC member states in July 1952, not quite two months<br />

after the signature <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty <strong>of</strong> May 1952. The EPC aimed at facilitating<br />

the ratification <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty by the Assemblée Nationale. Up to the end, Guy<br />

Mollet, lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the SFIO, still consi<strong>de</strong>red the EPC project as valuable for securing<br />

the agreement <strong>of</strong> the SFIO to the EDC treaty. He therefore <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d that the<br />

French government fulfill this prerequisite. 10 But French governments proved unable<br />

to negotiate an acceptable treaty. During the almost two years <strong>of</strong> EPC negotiations,<br />

France was strongly opposed to the Dutch plan (Beyen Plan) for a customs<br />

union, which the Netherlands took for conditio sine qua non for their accepting the<br />

EPC. The SFIO itself rejected the Beyen Plan as well. Therefore, it seemed that the<br />

Beyen Plan was a principal reason why the EPC project did not serve its original<br />

purpose, i.e. the relief <strong>of</strong> the ratification <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty. Most accounts on the<br />

EPC proceed from this assumption. 11 As will be <strong>de</strong>monstrated in the following<br />

pages, however, documents on the EPC show us a more <strong>de</strong>cisive reason for its failure<br />

than the Beyen Plan - namely, the Union Française.<br />

The supranational military <strong>integration</strong> first required the answer to one question:<br />

Whom should the European Army obey and serve? Without solving this question, a<br />

merger <strong>of</strong> the national armies would remain possible only on a confe<strong>de</strong>ral basis, as<br />

with NATO. 12 Therefore, the <strong>de</strong>mand <strong>of</strong> the Assemblée Nationale was logical and<br />

9. R MITTENDORFER, Robert Schuman - Architekt <strong>de</strong>s neuen Europa, Hi<strong>de</strong>sheim, Zürich, New<br />

York, 1983, pp.382-420.<br />

10. For the position <strong>of</strong> Guy Mollet, see Archives Jean Monnet. Fondation Jean Monnet pour l’Europe,<br />

Lausanne. La Communauté Politique Européenne (AMJ), file 11.<br />

11. G. TRAUSCH (Hrsg.), Die europäische Integration vom Schuman-Plan bis zu <strong>de</strong>n Verträgen von<br />

Rom: Pläne und Initiativen, Enttäuschungen und Mißerfolge, Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, 1993; W LOTH, Die<br />

EVG und das Projekt <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Politischen Gemeinschaft, in: R. HUDEMANN (Hrsg.),<br />

Europa im Blick <strong>de</strong>r Historiker. Europäische Integration im 20. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rt. Bewußtsein und Institution,<br />

München, 1995 (Historische Zeitschrift Beiheft, Bd.21), pp.198-199.<br />

12. W. LIPGENS, Die Be<strong>de</strong>utung <strong>de</strong>s EVG-Projekts für die politische europäische Einigungsbewegung,<br />

in: H.-E. VOLKMANN et al., (Hrsg.), Die Europäische Verteidigungsgemeinschaft,<br />

Boppard am Rhein, 1985, p.23.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 65<br />

reasonable. Which form the political authority for the European army should take,<br />

however, was not clear from the Assemblée Nationale’s <strong>de</strong>mands. On the one hand,<br />

an <strong>integration</strong> <strong>of</strong> the EDC member states’ foreign politics (”pool diplomatique”)<br />

could be inten<strong>de</strong>d; on the other hand, civil and parliamentary control over the military<br />

could also be inten<strong>de</strong>d. In addition, the creation <strong>of</strong> functional sectoral communities<br />

<strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d an authority which could coordinate them. This involved the<br />

ECSC and the EDC directly. For Schuman, however, a “pool diplomatique” was<br />

not acceptable, since this carried too many fe<strong>de</strong>ral characteristics. The important<br />

thing for him was to reinforce the <strong>de</strong>mocratic control over the two technocratic<br />

communities (ECSC, EDC) in a political community. Schuman’s concept for political<br />

<strong>integration</strong> was mainly motivated by the wish to facilitate the parliamentary<br />

agreement to the EDC treaty. 13<br />

At the ECSC conference <strong>of</strong> member states in Luxembourg on 10 September 1952,<br />

the six foreign ministers gave the Common Assembly <strong>of</strong> the ECSC the mandate to draft<br />

a treaty constituting an EPC. The results were then to be submitted within six months.<br />

The new aspect <strong>of</strong> this resolution, in comparison to the French-Italian suggestion <strong>of</strong> July,<br />

was the Dutch initiative for economic <strong>integration</strong>.<br />

The Assembly <strong>of</strong> the ECSC accepted the invitation <strong>of</strong> the six foreign ministers to<br />

draft an EPC treaty and constituted itself for that purpose as an “ad hoc Assembly” in<br />

September 1952. After six months <strong>of</strong> collaboration, the draft treaty was adopted by the<br />

ad hoc Assembly on 10 March 1953. One day earlier the presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly,<br />

Paul-Henri Spaak, had han<strong>de</strong>d over the draft treaty to the acting presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ECSC Council <strong>of</strong> Ministers, the French foreign minister Georges Bidault.<br />

The cornerstone <strong>of</strong> the draft EPC treaty was a directly elected Peoples’ Chamber,<br />

which served as an instrument for effective parliamentary control. It also functioned<br />

as an organic combination <strong>of</strong> the ECSC and the EDC in the EPC, without<br />

bringing about a significant expansion <strong>of</strong> jurisdictions. Perhaps eventually, the EPC<br />

would lead to the creation <strong>of</strong> a common market. But the EPC only had the right to<br />

prepare for the progressive creation <strong>of</strong> a common market. As far as a common foreign<br />

policy was concerned, the draft treaty only proposed that the member states<br />

should coordinate their foreign and security policies within the framework <strong>of</strong> the<br />

EPC. As far as the territories were affected, two articles only referred to France.<br />

Before <strong>de</strong>aling with them, it is worthwhile to look at the structure <strong>of</strong> the Union<br />

Française.<br />

According to the French constitution <strong>of</strong> 13 October 1946 the overseas areas<br />

were divi<strong>de</strong>d into the following four categories:<br />

1) the Départements d'Outre-Mer (DOM), which inclu<strong>de</strong>d the Algerian <strong>de</strong>partments<br />

and, by reason <strong>of</strong> a law from 19 March 1947, the Martinique, the isles<br />

<strong>of</strong> Réunion, Gua<strong>de</strong>loupe and French Guyana, each forming a <strong>de</strong>partment (altogether<br />

approximately 10 million inhabitants);<br />

13. AN MRP 350 AP 50, Commission exécutive 1952-1953, Réunion du 30 oct. 1952 relative aux problèmes<br />

posés par l’Autorité politique européenne, sous la prési<strong>de</strong>nce <strong>de</strong> M. <strong>de</strong> Menthon.


66<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

2) the Territoires d'Outre-Mer (TOM), which referred to all overseas areas<br />

which had formerly been colonies (about 25 million inhabitants);<br />

3) the Territoires associés, which meant the mandates Cameroon and Togo, administered<br />

un<strong>de</strong>r the supervision <strong>of</strong> the trustee council <strong>of</strong> the UN (altogether<br />

about 4 million inhabitants);<br />

4) the Etats associés, which consisted <strong>of</strong> the protectorates Morocco, Tunisia and<br />

Indochina (altogether 35,5 million inhabitants).<br />

Together with the metropolitan France the DOM and the TOM overseas regions<br />

and territories formed the constitutional association <strong>of</strong> the French Republic, which<br />

was un<strong>de</strong>r the sovereignty <strong>of</strong> France (article 60 <strong>of</strong> the French 1946’s constitution).<br />

The Union Française consisted <strong>of</strong> the French Republic and the “Territoires et Etats<br />

associés”. 14<br />

On 24 October 1952 the lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the Mouvement Républicain Populaire<br />

(MRP), Pierre Henri Teitgen, <strong>de</strong>monstrated how complex and sensitive the problem<br />

<strong>of</strong> the relations <strong>of</strong> the Union Française with the supranational EPC was. He assumed<br />

first that<br />

”France was not only a European power but also a world power, whose interests<br />

went beyond the framework <strong>of</strong> the European continent”*<br />

and that the connection between the homeland and its overseas areas was “indivisible”.<br />

He found the suggestion <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> Europe unacceptable that non-European<br />

territories and states, which were in a constitutional relation with European states,<br />

could not become full members, but only be associated. According to him this mere association<br />

would loosen the connection <strong>of</strong> France with its overseas areas. 15 Teitgen<br />

strove to find a solution which ma<strong>de</strong> it possible to drive supranational <strong>integration</strong> further<br />

without endangering the Union Française. Just as Teitgen, the Gaullist Michel Debré<br />

rejected the suggestions <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> Europe. Debré maintained that the French<br />

African areas were to be inclu<strong>de</strong>d as full members into the EPC, that the EPC should<br />

not have <strong>de</strong>cision-making powers over member states’ foreign policies, and that it<br />

should be constructed in a loose form. As a matter <strong>of</strong> fact, if the EPC were vested with<br />

greater powers, it could intervene in the affairs <strong>of</strong> the French overseas areas. 16<br />

In the plenary session <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly on 7 January 1953, the French<br />

Senegalese Léopold Sédar Senghor argued that the French overseas areas should be<br />

inclu<strong>de</strong>d into the EPC. For Senghor, a convinced supporter <strong>of</strong> the i<strong>de</strong>a “Eurafrika”,<br />

it was incomprehensible that the TOM, which were an integrated constituent <strong>of</strong> the<br />

French Republic, should be exclu<strong>de</strong>d from the EPC. Their exclusion risked alternative<br />

<strong>de</strong>velopments, namely in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce from France. These areas were ready to<br />

14. Politisches Archiv <strong>de</strong>s Auswärtigen Amtes, Bonn (PAAA) II, Bd.889, AZ 224-41-03, p.160, Vermerk<br />

über die Struktur <strong>de</strong>r Union Française.<br />

15. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Déclaration faite par Teitgen à la commission préconstituante, 24.10.1952.<br />

16. PAAA II, Bd.854, AZ 240-10 Bd.1, Schwarz-Liebermann, Bericht über die Tätigkeit <strong>de</strong>r Unterausschüsse<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Verfassungsausschusses vom 3.-4. Dezember 1952; PAAA II, Bd.889, AZ<br />

224-41-03, p.157, C.F. Ophüls, Einbeziehung <strong>de</strong>r überseeischen Gebiete (Union Française) vom<br />

30.5.1953.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 67<br />

open their markets for Europe, however, only on the condition that they should become<br />

members <strong>of</strong> the European communities. Senghor <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d an increase in<br />

the number <strong>of</strong> French seats in the People’s Chamber, from 63 to 83. Twenty seats<br />

were inten<strong>de</strong>d for the overseas areas. In the ensuing <strong>de</strong>bate, almost all French <strong>de</strong>legates<br />

including Debré treated the inclusion <strong>of</strong> the TOM into the EPC as already <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d<br />

or natural. Although they had not completely the same opinion as Senghor,<br />

they supported Senghor’s suggestions out <strong>of</strong> fear <strong>of</strong> the separation <strong>of</strong> the TOM<br />

from the metropolitan France. These suggestions met the rejection <strong>of</strong> parliamentarians<br />

from other member states, above all from Germany, so that the <strong>de</strong>bate en<strong>de</strong>d<br />

without result. 17<br />

In February 1953 the French parliamentarians strove again to inclu<strong>de</strong> the<br />

French overseas areas into the EPC. Teitgen maintained that these areas should be<br />

represented at least “symbolically” in the People’s Chamber. For this reason, the<br />

number <strong>of</strong> French seats should be increased. 18 Teitgen’s suggestions were laid<br />

down in article 15 and 101 <strong>of</strong> the draft EPC treaty.<br />

According to article 101, the parts <strong>of</strong> the Union Française that were un<strong>de</strong>r the<br />

sovereignty <strong>of</strong> France should be inclu<strong>de</strong>d through the signing <strong>of</strong> this accord into the<br />

valid area <strong>of</strong> the EPC treaty, if France raised no objections to the signature <strong>of</strong> this<br />

accord. France could list them in a subsequent protocol, if it were first to exclu<strong>de</strong><br />

them from the valid areas <strong>of</strong> the EPC. In addition, France could at its discretion revise<br />

the application <strong>of</strong> the treaty and the community’s laws in the Union Française.<br />

This referred to the DOM and the TOM. Indirectly inclu<strong>de</strong>d were the Territoires associés<br />

and the Etats associés which were not un<strong>de</strong>r the sovereignty <strong>of</strong> France but<br />

which France represented in international affairs. These could also be inclu<strong>de</strong>d<br />

through a special protocol. 19 According to article 15, France would hold in addition<br />

seven extra seats in the People’s Chamber to account for its overseas areas, for a total<br />

<strong>of</strong> 70 seats, if these colonies would be inclu<strong>de</strong>d in the EPC. However, Germany<br />

and Italy would each have 63 seats.<br />

17. Abän<strong>de</strong>rungsvorschlag zum Bericht <strong>de</strong>s Verfassungsausschusses Nr.40 (Senghor), in: Son<strong>de</strong>rversammlung<br />

für die Gründung einer Europäischen Politischen Gemeinschaft, Straßburg, 1953, Kurzbericht<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Beratungen <strong>de</strong>r dritten Sitzung vom 9. Januar 1953, pp.15-23; Son<strong>de</strong>rversammlung für<br />

die Gründung einer Europäischen Politischen Gemeinschaft, Straßburg, 1953, Aussprache.<br />

Wörtlicher Bericht über <strong>de</strong>n Verlauf <strong>de</strong>r Sitzungen, pp.199 ff.; AMAE DE-CE, CECA, Vol.521,<br />

pp.187-197, DGAP/Europe/S/Direction du Conseil <strong>de</strong> l’Europe, note, 15.1.1953, a.s. Réunion <strong>de</strong>s<br />

travaux <strong>de</strong> l’Assemblée ad hoc. This document marked the speech <strong>of</strong> Senghor as “une intervention<br />

très remarquée”.<br />

18. PAAA II, Bd.855, AZ 240-10 Bd.2, von Brentano an Hallstein am 7. Februar 1953; PAAA II,<br />

Bd.855, AZ 240-10 Bd.2, Schwarz-Liebermann an Ophüls vom 11.2.1953; PAAA Materialsammlung<br />

MD Dr. Herbert Blankenhorn, Auswärtiges Amt, Satzung <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Gemeinschaft.<br />

Materialien. 31. März 1953, pp.45-47 and 174-176.<br />

19. PAAA II Bd.889, AZ 224-41-03, pp.158 ff., Ophüls, Einbeziehung <strong>de</strong>r überseeischen Gebiete<br />

(Union Française), 30. Mai 1953.


68<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

French Criticism <strong>of</strong> the Draft EPC Treaty <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly:<br />

France’s “Vocation Mondiale”<br />

After the signature <strong>of</strong> the Bonn and Paris treaties in May 1952, the government<br />

Pinay/Schuman was exposed to increasing criticism in the Assemblée Nationale. It<br />

was alleged that the government promoted the sale <strong>of</strong> France’s national sovereignty<br />

and its historical great power status through European <strong>integration</strong>. The attack on<br />

Schuman’s policies referred concretely to the EDC and the politics <strong>of</strong> the Union<br />

Française. 20 During the EPC negotiations <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly, Paris experienced<br />

a governmental crisis that led to Bidault replacing Foreign Minister Schuman<br />

at the end <strong>of</strong> the year. This followed <strong>de</strong>mands by the Gaullist opposition,<br />

which supported the formation <strong>of</strong> the government <strong>of</strong> the new Prime Minister René<br />

Mayer on the condition that Schuman should be replaced by Bidault. 21<br />

Although it was <strong>of</strong>ficially explained that the previous European policy would<br />

continue unchanged un<strong>de</strong>r the new government, modifications soon became clear,<br />

in particular in France’s concept <strong>of</strong> the European Army. High-level civil servants at<br />

the Quai d’Orsay <strong>de</strong>fen<strong>de</strong>d the opinion that France should carry out a reversal in<br />

policy by giving up the EDC and simultaneously <strong>de</strong>veloping NATO in or<strong>de</strong>r to prevent<br />

the Germans from an unaligned military build-up. 22 The top <strong>of</strong>ficials’ argumentation<br />

was based to a large extent on problems regarding the Union Française.<br />

According to them, by retaining the Union Française, France could continue its<br />

role <strong>of</strong> world power alongsi<strong>de</strong> Great Britain and the USA, and maintain a continental<br />

balance against Germany, which might regain strength. The administrative elite<br />

un<strong>de</strong>rstood that the British did not accept the supranational elements in European<br />

<strong>integration</strong> because <strong>of</strong> their responsibility in relation to the Commonwealth. Now,<br />

however, the EDC threatened to <strong>de</strong>velop into a supranational political community<br />

that would particularly impair the world power position <strong>of</strong> France to the extent that<br />

it split the French army into two sections - one for the homeland and a second for<br />

the overseas territories - and thus weaken the French army as a whole. This would<br />

lead to France possibly losing its overseas territories, although the right to withdraw<br />

the French soldiers from the European army was planned for France in the<br />

case <strong>of</strong> a crisis in the Union Française. 23<br />

Alarmed by his colleagues, Hervé Alphand (presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the Interim Committee<br />

<strong>of</strong> the EDC), a convinced proponent <strong>of</strong> the EDC, criticized this view <strong>of</strong> the EDC, 24<br />

20. See R. MITTENDORFER, op.cit., pp.447-467.<br />

21. R. MITTENDORFER, op.cit., p.475; PAAA Büro Staatssekretäre 1949-1967, Bd.59, pp.152-161,<br />

Hausenstein, Aufzeichnung über meinen Besuch bei Herrn R. Schuman am 19. Januar 1953 und<br />

als Anlage zu meinem Brief vom 21. Januar 1953.<br />

22. AN Papiers Bidault 34, A. Gros, Résumé <strong>de</strong> la conversation du samedi 24 janv. 1953, written on<br />

27 January 1953; AN Papiers Bidault 34, De la Tournelle (directeur politique) et al., Note sur la<br />

CED, 28.1.1953. This document was signed by De la Tournelle as well as by Gros (chef du service<br />

juridique), Seydoux (directeur d’Europe), <strong>de</strong> Leusse (chef du service <strong>de</strong> presse), Boegner (chef du<br />

service <strong>de</strong>s pactes) and De la Tournelle; AN Papiers Bidault 34, Lettre De la Tournelle à Pierre<br />

Louis Falaize (directeur du Cabinet <strong>de</strong> Bidault), 29.1.1953.<br />

23. AN Papiers Bidault 34, De la Tournelle (directeur politique) et al., Note sur la CED, 28.1.1953.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 69<br />

particularly the notion that the EDC would impair French responsibility in relation<br />

to the Union Française and endanger the French world power status. He argued that<br />

the EDC would not endanger France’s legal, economical and moral connection<br />

with the Union Française by any means. The overseas navy was not the object <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>integration</strong>. For a time, about 50 percent <strong>of</strong> the French army would remain un<strong>de</strong>r<br />

national authority. Furthermore, the additional protocols, which were negotiated at<br />

that time, would ascertain France’s privilege to be able to withdraw its army relatively<br />

quickly and without restriction in the case <strong>of</strong> a crisis in the overseas territories.<br />

The only restriction that would limit French foreign policy was policy regarding<br />

<strong>de</strong>fence in Europe. This limitation could be balanced on the one hand by the<br />

reserved rights <strong>of</strong> France in Germany, which had been guaranteed by the Bonn treaties,<br />

on the other hand by the responsibilities in the world. Thus France could remain<br />

in the “permanent Group” <strong>of</strong> NATO alongsi<strong>de</strong> the USA and Great Britain.<br />

“France belongs to two systems”, so Alphand, “one at European level, which will materialize<br />

un<strong>de</strong>r the form <strong>of</strong> the Community, the other at world level, the Union Française;<br />

France while becoming European, will continue to remain a world power”*.<br />

The alternative discussed by the opponents <strong>of</strong> the EDC at the Quai d’Orsay was<br />

out <strong>of</strong> question. The i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> an extension <strong>of</strong> NATO had already proved futile because<br />

<strong>of</strong> American objections. For Alphand it was un<strong>de</strong>r any circumstances unacceptable<br />

to give up the EDC. 25<br />

As for the EPC, the director <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>de</strong>partment <strong>of</strong> the Quai d’Orsay, F.<br />

Seydoux, elucidated French intentions: the danger that the creation <strong>of</strong> the EPC<br />

would lead to a new renouncement <strong>of</strong> sovereignty had to be avoi<strong>de</strong>d. From the beginning<br />

France should resist a complete institutional structure <strong>of</strong> a fe<strong>de</strong>ralist type.<br />

Seydoux therefore only was prepared to accept the creation <strong>of</strong> a directly elected<br />

European Parliament, but its functioning was not necessary in the initial stages <strong>of</strong><br />

the project. The creation <strong>of</strong> a new executive which should replace the High Authority<br />

<strong>of</strong> the ECSC and the Board <strong>of</strong> Commissioners <strong>of</strong> the EDC seemed unnecessary,<br />

even dangerous, because<br />

“its mere creation risked to bring about, by that very fact, new extensions <strong>of</strong> competence,<br />

thus new cessions <strong>of</strong> sovereignty”*. 26<br />

The <strong>de</strong>partment Afrique-Levant at the Quai d’Orsay warned that even the direct<br />

election for a People’s Chamber would seriously weaken, or dissolve in foreseeable<br />

time, the connection between France and its overseas territories. Therefore, the<br />

directly elected parliament should be replaced by an indirectly elected one, with<br />

<strong>de</strong>puties drawn from the national parliaments. 27<br />

24. AN Papiers Bidault 34, Alphand, Note pour le Prési<strong>de</strong>nt, 10. févr. 1953, secret.<br />

25. Ibid.<br />

26. AMAE, Direction <strong>de</strong>s Affaires Economiques et Financières, Service <strong>de</strong> Coopération Economique<br />

(DE-CE) 45-60, Vol.578, pp.1-6, Note <strong>de</strong> Seydoux, 2.1.1953, a.s: Communauté politique européenne.<br />

27. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Direction Générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires Politiques (DGAP), Direction<br />

d’Afrique-Levant, sous-direction d’Afrique, Note, 12.1.1953, a.s./Europe et Union Française.


70<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

With regard to the <strong>integration</strong> <strong>of</strong> foreign policy, the Quai d’Orsay seriously criticized<br />

the mo<strong>de</strong>st result <strong>of</strong> elaboration <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly, and thus the coordination<br />

<strong>of</strong> the foreign policy un<strong>de</strong>r the member states. The legal advisor at the Quai<br />

d’Orsay, Gros, posed the question <strong>of</strong> how a state which surren<strong>de</strong>red its powers <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>de</strong>cision in foreign policy matters to the EPC could carry out its world-wi<strong>de</strong> responsibility.<br />

28<br />

From the beginning the Beyen Plan for the creation <strong>of</strong> a customs union did not find<br />

approval in France. One <strong>of</strong> its most ar<strong>de</strong>nt critics was the director <strong>of</strong> the Service <strong>de</strong><br />

Coopération Economique at the Quai d’Orsay, Olivier Wormser. 29 The question <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Union Française was one <strong>of</strong> the reasons why Wormser was opposed to the Beyen Plan.<br />

Wormser asserted that if the Beyen Plan was accepted and carried out, France would be<br />

forced to open its overseas markets to other European member states. He argued that<br />

France could not simultaneously invest in both the metropolitan territory and in the unproductive<br />

economic areas <strong>of</strong> its overseas territories without letting other countries participate.<br />

Wormser foresaw the danger that the markets <strong>of</strong> the overseas territories would<br />

be opened for the other five states without economic benefit for France, although these<br />

countries participated un<strong>de</strong>r prerequisites favourable to France. Thus, France would be<br />

forced to grant them its privileges in the Union Française, and economic gains would be<br />

lost - almost 40 percent <strong>of</strong> all exports <strong>of</strong> France were sold at this time within the Union<br />

Française. This would entail enormous political problems, and France would lose its<br />

world power position. 30<br />

The French European agricultural policy was likewise adapted to the Quai<br />

d’Orsay’s general change <strong>of</strong> course in European politics, away from pro-community<br />

ten<strong>de</strong>ncies. In the meantime, the dissenting opinion <strong>of</strong> the Pflimlin Plan became<br />

influential. A majority <strong>of</strong> administrative elites in the ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture carried<br />

out the change from a pro-European agricultural policy to a national protectionist<br />

concept, as supported by the majority <strong>of</strong> the pr<strong>of</strong>essional associations. 31 In addition,<br />

the question <strong>of</strong> the relation <strong>of</strong> the French overseas areas to a planned agricultural<br />

commodities market also induced the French government to a reserved position<br />

vis-à-vis the supranational community <strong>of</strong> the Six. The previous negotiations<br />

for agricultural <strong>integration</strong> showed that this question could not be avoi<strong>de</strong>d any<br />

longer. In or<strong>de</strong>r to consi<strong>de</strong>r the situation <strong>of</strong> the overseas territories in agricultural<br />

<strong>integration</strong>, an inter<strong>de</strong>partmental conference took place un<strong>de</strong>r the lea<strong>de</strong>rship <strong>of</strong> the<br />

conseiller technique <strong>of</strong> Bidault’s staff, du Vignaux, on 2 and 5 February 1953, including<br />

the top <strong>of</strong>ficials from the Quai d’Orsay, the Ministère d'Etat, the ministry <strong>of</strong><br />

28. Ibid.; AN Papiers Bidault 38, le jurisconsulte (Gros), Note pour le secrétaire général (Parodi), 18<br />

fév. 1953, a/s. Projet <strong>de</strong> Fédération politique européenne.<br />

29. AMAE DE-CE 45-60, Vol.521, pp.211-214, Note, a/s: proposition Beyen, 7.2.1953; AMAE<br />

DE-CE 45-60, Vol.521, pp.215-230, Note du Service <strong>de</strong> CE, a.s. intégration économique. Entretiens<br />

avec M. Beyen et Conférence <strong>de</strong> Rome, 9.2.1953.<br />

30. Ibid.<br />

31. AN Papiers Bidault 38, Note pour le prési<strong>de</strong>nt, Wormser, 14.2.1953 a.s. pool agricole; G. THIE-<br />

MEYER, op.cit., pp.80 ff.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 71<br />

the Interior, the ministry <strong>de</strong> la France d'Outre-mer, the ministry <strong>of</strong> Economic affairs<br />

and the ministry <strong>of</strong> Agriculture. 32<br />

At this conference Wormser and du Vignaux presented documents which represented<br />

the position <strong>of</strong> the Quai d’Orsay. 33 According to them, contrary to the EC-<br />

SC, the agricultural community was <strong>of</strong> great importance for relations between<br />

France and its overseas areas, since the agricultural sector dominated these economic<br />

relations. There were five possible solutions: 1) total exclusion <strong>of</strong> the overseas<br />

areas from the European agricultural community, 2) the system <strong>of</strong> the ECSC,<br />

3) partial inclusion, 4) total inclusion in the European agricultural community and<br />

5) modification <strong>of</strong> the structure <strong>of</strong> the agricultural community. Solutions 1 and 2<br />

would separate the homeland from its overseas areas. Solution 4, which most seriously<br />

consi<strong>de</strong>red the relationship between metropolitan France and the Union<br />

Française, encountered an insurmountable obstacle, if the agricultural community<br />

inten<strong>de</strong>d to create a supranational agricultural commodities market. France itself<br />

was an important sales market for its overseas areas, just as the overseas areas were<br />

important customers for France’s agricultural (above all, sugars, wheat and preserved<br />

food) and industrial products. These were currently sold un<strong>de</strong>r the preference<br />

system on a higher price level than world prices. If the agricultural sales markets<br />

<strong>of</strong> the other five European states were opened to the French overseas areas by<br />

virtue <strong>of</strong> their being integrated into the European community, it would be favourable<br />

to the French overseas areas. The European states would accept this only on the<br />

condition <strong>of</strong> reciprocity for their industrial products. This meant a great sacrifice<br />

for France, because it would no longer enjoy exclusive access to the preference system.<br />

The substantial problem was whether the European partners were ready to carry<br />

the responsibility for social <strong>de</strong>velopment together with France, although this,<br />

from an economic point <strong>of</strong> view, would be very unproductive. All the arguments<br />

concerning solutions 1, 2 and 4 applied to solution 3. Wormser recommen<strong>de</strong>d solution<br />

5: if France did not intend to sacrifice itself, it was necessary,<br />

“to give up the i<strong>de</strong>a that the objective <strong>of</strong> this Community has to be the creation <strong>of</strong> a<br />

Common Market and to think <strong>of</strong> organizing tra<strong>de</strong> in certain basic products taking<br />

into due consi<strong>de</strong>ration tra<strong>de</strong> with our overseas territories in the negotiations with our<br />

European partners”*. 34<br />

32. AMAE DE-CE 45-60, Vol.577, pp.354-390, Rapport sur la création d’une Communauté européenne<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’agriculture et <strong>de</strong> l’alimentation présenté par M. Philippe Lamour au nom <strong>de</strong> la Commission<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’Agriculture, Paris, 16.10.1952, Conseil Economique Ph.L./J.B. 1625/Agr./120; AN Papiers<br />

Bidault 42, Note relative aux réunions tenues au Quai d’Orsay les 2 et 5 févr. 1953 entre les cabinets<br />

ministériels en vue <strong>de</strong> la préparation d’un comité interministériel, 7.2.1953.<br />

33. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Ministère <strong>de</strong>s Affaires Étrangères, Service <strong>de</strong> Coopération Economique,<br />

Communication au conseil <strong>de</strong>s ministres, 27.1.1953. a.s./ l’organisation européenne <strong>de</strong>s marchés<br />

agricoles et les TOM; AN Papiers Bidault 38, Note pour le prési<strong>de</strong>nt, Wormser, 14.2.1953 a.s. pool<br />

agricole; AN Papiers Bidault 38, Note pour le prési<strong>de</strong>nt, Wormser, 14.2.1953 a.s. pool agricole.<br />

34. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Ministère <strong>de</strong>s Affaires Étrangères, Service <strong>de</strong> Coopération Economique,<br />

Communication au conseil <strong>de</strong>s ministres, 27.1.1953. a.s./ l’organisation européenne <strong>de</strong>s marchés<br />

agricoles et les TOM.


72<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

An organization <strong>of</strong> this type would by no means be a European community, but<br />

a bilateral and intergovernmental organization. It would ultimately be better to negotiate<br />

the question <strong>of</strong> the agricultural community within the framework <strong>of</strong> the<br />

OEEC. All participants in the inter<strong>de</strong>partmental conference shared the basic i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong><br />

this document. 35<br />

In France question <strong>of</strong> the EDC, the EPC, the customs union and the agricultural<br />

community <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>d closely on the kind <strong>of</strong> future relations between the Union<br />

Française and European community to be created. Awareness <strong>of</strong> this problem arose indirectly<br />

through the Strasbourg recommendation <strong>of</strong> the Assembly <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> Europe<br />

in September 1952 for common investments in all overseas areas <strong>of</strong> European<br />

countries, but such awareness was also directly caused by the EDC treaty and the EPC<br />

negotiations <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly. 36 In the Conseil <strong>de</strong> la République and the Assemblée<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’Union Française the problem had been discussed in the context <strong>of</strong> the EDC<br />

several times in 1952. In the discussion many feared that supranational European <strong>integration</strong><br />

would separate France from its overseas areas. 37<br />

In view <strong>of</strong> this procedure the Quai d’Orsay began to intervene. It should be noted<br />

that the <strong>de</strong>partment Afrique-Levant had warned Schuman several times since<br />

October 1952 <strong>of</strong> arising problems for the Union Française from European <strong>integration</strong>.<br />

At that time Schuman did not take the warning seriously. 38 Nor did Monnet<br />

think it wise to tackle this problem at this stage. He asked Schuman,<br />

“to prevent representatives <strong>of</strong> the overseas territories from being <strong>de</strong>signated at the<br />

Common Assembly and consequently to prevent also the question <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Community’s relationship with the overseas territories belonging to the Union<br />

Française from being brought up for discussion at that moment”*.<br />

The Territoires d'Outre-Mer should only be inclu<strong>de</strong>d when Germany would be<br />

reunified, in or<strong>de</strong>r to retain the balance in European communities. 39 The <strong>de</strong>partment<br />

Afrique-Levant consi<strong>de</strong>red a provisional solution: The representatives from<br />

the overseas territories would participate in the parliament <strong>of</strong> the EPC, but the EPC<br />

35. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Note relative aux réunions tenues au Quai d’Orsay les 2 et 5 févr. 1953<br />

entre les cabinets ministériels en vue <strong>de</strong> la préparation d’un comité interministériel, 7.2.1953.<br />

36. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Direction <strong>de</strong>s Affaires politiques 3ème Bureau, Pour M. le Ministre (à l’attention<br />

du pr<strong>of</strong>esseur Luchaire), 6.2.1953, le Directeur-adjoint, Delteil, objet: Proposition <strong>de</strong> résolution<br />

tendant à inviter le Gouvernement à constituer une Commission chargée d’étudier les rapports<br />

entre l’Union Française et l’Organisation Politique <strong>de</strong> l’Europe présentée par Debré, au<br />

Conseil <strong>de</strong> la République; AMAE DE-CE 45-60, Vol.577, pp.420-424, L’entrée <strong>de</strong>s TOM dans la<br />

Communauté Européenne, 26.11.1952, G. Peter, Office du Niger (organisme publique autonome)<br />

à Wormser ou Brunet; AN 457 34, RL/SB, les objections faites à la CED au cours <strong>de</strong>s débats <strong>de</strong><br />

l’Assemblée nationale, du Conseil <strong>de</strong> la République et <strong>de</strong> diverses manifestations politiques, confi<strong>de</strong>ntiel,<br />

undated.<br />

37. AN Papiers Bidault 34, Direction d’Afrique-Levant, S/D d’Afrique, Note a.s: Chambrun, Question<br />

n°4, 17.2.1953.<br />

38. AN Papiers Bidault 42, DGAP, Direction d’Afrique-Levant, sous-direction d’Afrique, Note,<br />

12.1.1953, a.s./Europe et Union Française.<br />

39. Lettre <strong>de</strong> Jean Monnet à Robert Schuman le 28 juin 1952, in: FONDATION JEAN MONNET POUR<br />

L’EUROPE (ed.), Jean Monnet - Robert Schuman, Correspondance, 1947-1953, Lausanne, 1986,<br />

p.148.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 73<br />

should not be endowed with powers over the French overseas territories from the<br />

start, and the jurisdiction <strong>of</strong> the EPC should be exten<strong>de</strong>d only later and gradually<br />

by France to non-European areas.<br />

These were the contents <strong>of</strong> article 101 <strong>of</strong> the draft EPC treaty <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc<br />

Assembly. Problems nevertheless remained:<br />

“1) If we reject the <strong>de</strong> facto extension, the consequence will be a break between metropolitan<br />

France and the overseas territories and a discriminatory treatment”*.<br />

In view <strong>of</strong> the American anti-colonial policy and the intensifying drive towards<br />

in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce within the states <strong>of</strong> the Union Française (Indochina, Morocco and<br />

Tunisia), the weakening <strong>of</strong> the French sovereignty by the supranational European<br />

community would very probably lead to a “coupure” (split) <strong>of</strong> the French Empire.<br />

“2) two disadvantages at least will necessarily appear: a) a break this time between<br />

the Republic and the rest <strong>of</strong> the Union Française b) French sovereignty in the consi<strong>de</strong>red<br />

field will have to be shared with Germany and Italy in particular”*.<br />

In addition, there was no guarantee that the French <strong>de</strong>legates from Africa would<br />

act loyally towards France. Altogether it was to be expected that the relationship<br />

between the European community and the Union Française would superse<strong>de</strong> the<br />

existing connections between France and its overseas areas. This dilemma was to<br />

be taken “extremely serious”*. Amongst the problems caused by supranational European<br />

<strong>integration</strong> it was the most fundamental problem that France was confronted<br />

with at the turn <strong>of</strong> 1952-1953. All the difficulty<br />

“is in<strong>de</strong>ed due to the fact that France can’t belong to the same extent to a European<br />

Community and to the Union Française, unless the two <strong>of</strong> them are completely<br />

merged”*. 40<br />

It was a question <strong>of</strong> priorities. According to some, such as Monnet and Schuman,<br />

Europe was right <strong>of</strong> way, whereas others gave the Union Française first priority.<br />

The convinced Gaullist Michel Debré plea<strong>de</strong>d for the second option. He <strong>de</strong>fined<br />

Monnet’s supranational European communities as “an immense adventure”* for all<br />

and “some kind <strong>of</strong> nightmare” for many. According to him, these communities<br />

should be changed to the extent that the power <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>cision rested with the council<br />

<strong>of</strong> the heads <strong>of</strong> government. The Assembly however should by no means be endowed<br />

with “governmental and legislative power” and the Executive Council<br />

should function only administratively. Thus Debré’s Europe was called “a coalition<br />

<strong>of</strong> national authorities” or “an association <strong>of</strong> sovereignties”. 41 Debré represented<br />

the prevailing opinion <strong>of</strong> the Conseil <strong>de</strong> la République, the Assemblée <strong>de</strong> l’Union<br />

Française and the Comité d'étu<strong>de</strong>s et <strong>de</strong> liaison du patronat <strong>de</strong> l'Union Française<br />

(CELPUF), which was close to the Conseil national du patronat français<br />

40. AMAE Papiers Massigli (PA-AP 217), Vol.76, pp.34-37, DGAP, Note sur la représentation <strong>de</strong>s<br />

TOM dans une éventuelle Assemblée européenne, 10.11.1952; AN Papiers Bidault 42, DGAP, Direction<br />

d’Afrique-Levant, sous-direction d’Afrique, Note, 12.1.1953, a.s./Europe et Union Française;<br />

AN Papiers Bidault 42, Direction d’Afrique-Levant, s/d d’Afrique (Jurgensen), Note, 29<br />

janv. 1953, a.s./Europe et Union Française.<br />

41. AN Papiers Bidault 34, Debré, Note à l’attention <strong>de</strong> M. Bidault, 30.1.1953.


74<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

(CNPF). 42 The minister responsible for the French Territoires d’Outre-Mer, Jacquinot,<br />

shared Debré’s opinion:<br />

“The realization <strong>of</strong> the Union Française prece<strong>de</strong>s and prevails for us over the realization<br />

<strong>of</strong> the European entity. One should not forget that the French gran<strong>de</strong>ur is ma<strong>de</strong><br />

up <strong>of</strong> metropolitan France as well as <strong>of</strong> all its overseas territories”*. 43<br />

The majority <strong>of</strong> the French government was inclined to master this dilemma not<br />

by modifying the old French colonial system but by restructuring European <strong>integration</strong>,<br />

so as to <strong>de</strong>velop from<br />

“a fe<strong>de</strong>ral or merged system into a confe<strong>de</strong>rate or associative system, taking the<br />

Union Française as an indissociable whole, that will only enter into a sufficiently<br />

flexible relationship with Europe”*. 44<br />

With this solution France could benefit from the additional advantage <strong>of</strong> being<br />

able to co-operate with Great Britain in such a confe<strong>de</strong>rate Europe in European and<br />

overseas affairs. 45<br />

Contrary to this train <strong>of</strong> thought, the lea<strong>de</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> the MRP and the SFIO took a<br />

positive position on the question <strong>of</strong> the inclusion <strong>of</strong> the French overseas territories<br />

into the European communities. Guy Mollet, the lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the French socialist party,<br />

was surprised at the negative opinion <strong>of</strong> the Assemblée <strong>de</strong> l’Union Française in<br />

Versailles. He held the view that the specialized communities should be limited to<br />

Europe only, but that in the long run France was not in the position to solve the<br />

problems <strong>of</strong> its un<strong>de</strong>r<strong>de</strong>veloped overseas territories alone. In full agreement with<br />

Mollet, Rose and Alduy emphasized the necessity to tackle the question <strong>of</strong> the<br />

creation <strong>of</strong> a European investment bank in the French overseas areas as soon as<br />

possible. Moreover, in a note which is to be found in Mollet’s private archives<br />

42. Organisation Universitaire <strong>de</strong> Recherche Socialiste, Paris (OURS), Archives Guy Mollet (AGM) 110,<br />

Lettre du Secrétariat Général <strong>de</strong> l’Assemblée <strong>de</strong> l’Union Française à G. Mollet, 13.1.1953; AN Papiers<br />

Bidault 42, Conseil <strong>de</strong> la République, N°14 année 1953, annexe au procès-verbal <strong>de</strong> la séance du 20<br />

janv. 1953, Proposition <strong>de</strong> Résolution tendant à inviter le Gouvernement à constituer une commission<br />

chargée d’étudier les rapports entre l’Union Française et une organisation politique <strong>de</strong> l’Europe présentée<br />

par M. Michel Debré, Exposé <strong>de</strong>s motifs; AN Papiers Bidault 42, «L’Union Française et l’Europe»,<br />

travaux <strong>de</strong> la conférence plénière du CELPUF <strong>de</strong>s 13 et 14 janvier 1953. The CELPUF consisted <strong>of</strong> the<br />

entrepreneurs from the metropolitan France, Algeria, the Départements d’outre-mer, the Territoires<br />

d’outre-mer, the Territoires Associés, the Etats Associés, and the Etats protégés. The Presi<strong>de</strong>nt was<br />

chairman <strong>of</strong> the Comité National du Patronat Français, G. Villiers. The CELPUF <strong>de</strong>dicated its plenary<br />

session on 13 and 14 January 1953 to the study <strong>of</strong> the problem that was raised by the creation <strong>of</strong> an EPC<br />

and a Common Market in relation to the Union Française. (AN Papiers Bidault 42, lettre <strong>de</strong> Villiers à<br />

Bidault, 20.1.1953); AN Papiers Bidault 42, N°111, Conseil <strong>de</strong> la République, année 1953, annexe au<br />

procès-verbal <strong>de</strong> la séance du 26 févr. 1953, Rapport fait au nom <strong>de</strong> la Commission <strong>de</strong>s Affaires étrangères<br />

sur la proposition <strong>de</strong> résolution <strong>de</strong> M. Michel Debré tendant à inviter le Gouvernement à constituer<br />

une commission chargée d’étudier les rapports entre l’Union Française et une organisation politique<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’Europe par M. Marius Moutet (sénateur).<br />

43. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Le Mon<strong>de</strong>, 27.1.1953, Discours <strong>de</strong> M. Jacquinot, 25.1.1952.<br />

44. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Direction d’Afrique-Levant, s/d d’Afrique, Note, 29 janv. 1953, a.s./Europe<br />

et Union Française.<br />

45. Ibid.; AN Papiers Bidault 42, MAE, DGAP, Europe, S/Direction du Conseil <strong>de</strong> l’Europe, Note,<br />

27.1.1953, A/S. Situation <strong>de</strong>s Territoires d’Outre-Mer à l’égard <strong>de</strong>s Communautés européennes.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 75<br />

Nr.106 (Articles et interventions <strong>de</strong> Mollet sur l'Europe, 1948-1955) he completely<br />

agreed with article 101 <strong>of</strong> the draft EPC treaty suggested by Teitgen. 46 For Mollet,<br />

the question <strong>of</strong> the Union Française was not a reason to modify the supranationality<br />

<strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>. The special issue <strong>of</strong> the party newspaper <strong>of</strong> the MRP<br />

(Forces Nouvelles) on 20 December 1952 announced the result <strong>of</strong> the internal discussions<br />

<strong>of</strong> the MRP regarding these problems. According to the expert on the Union<br />

Française, G. Le Brun Keris, these problems were used as a tactical instrument<br />

by opponents <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>integration</strong>. However,<br />

“we cannot give up either the European Union, the answer to German pressure,<br />

among other advantages, or our overseas territories to which so many moral ties are<br />

linking us and without which we would only be a very small power”*.<br />

Le Brun Keris, therefore, advocated that the French Republic as a whole should<br />

be integrated into the EPC and so the jurisdiction <strong>of</strong> the EPC should be exten<strong>de</strong>d to<br />

the French overseas territories. However, one should find a balance between driving<br />

European <strong>integration</strong> forward and retaining the Union Française.<br />

“Just as France judged it necessary for its own legislation and regulations, the European<br />

Community’s legislation and regulations as well will have to be adapted to the<br />

situation <strong>of</strong> the different overseas countries by means <strong>of</strong> application rules <strong>de</strong>termined<br />

by the relevant bodies within the French Republic”*.<br />

Teitgen, the lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the MRP, who was engaged in the negotiations <strong>of</strong> the ad<br />

hoc Assembly, was <strong>of</strong> exactly the same opinion. 47 For Le Brun Keris as well as for<br />

Teitgen, the question <strong>of</strong> the Union Française was not a reason to modify the supranationality<br />

<strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>.<br />

What was Bidault’s position, as the new foreign minister, on European <strong>integration</strong><br />

as a whole? Bidault allu<strong>de</strong>d to making certain modifications to the European policies <strong>of</strong><br />

his pre<strong>de</strong>cessor in favour <strong>of</strong> those who most strongly represented national feelings. He<br />

did not, however, go so far as to abolish the existing achievements. The experienced<br />

French diplomat Chauvel recommen<strong>de</strong>d to Bidault on 25 January 1953, to implement<br />

the EDC in the light <strong>of</strong> the negotiations compromising the positions <strong>of</strong> “the pole MRP<br />

and the pole RPF”, a recommendation which Bidault accepted. On 21 April 1953, Bidault<br />

rejected the <strong>de</strong>mand <strong>of</strong> the French military to modify the <strong>de</strong>termined EDC transition<br />

period to an in<strong>de</strong>finite period <strong>of</strong> time and also the <strong>de</strong>mand <strong>of</strong> the high-level civil<br />

servants <strong>of</strong> the Quai d’Orsay to renounce the EDC. Bidault took account <strong>of</strong> the strong<br />

46. OURS, Comité directeur, procès-verbal, Vol.9, 25 mai 1952 - 26 juin 1953, Réunion du 26 novembre<br />

1952; OURS AGM 106, Note, undated, author unknown (G. Mollet?).<br />

47. AN MRP 350 AP 128, Forces Nouvelles N°28 Samedi 20 décembre 1952, «C’est toute la République<br />

qui doit rentrer dans la Communauté européenne, par G. Le Brun Keris»; AN Papiers Bidault<br />

42, G. le Brun Keris, Note sur les rapports à établir entre les pays d’outre-mer membres <strong>de</strong><br />

la République Française et la Communauté politique européenne, undated. Le Brun Keris suggested<br />

as a measure for this balance that direct elections should not be introduced at the beginning. In<br />

this point he dissociated himself from Teitgen (AN Papiers Bidault 39, Lettre <strong>de</strong> G. Le Brun Keris<br />

(Conseiller <strong>de</strong> l’Union Française) à Bidault, 24.2.1953).


76<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

national feelings in France, but he was not prepared to jeopardize the supranational European<br />

army. 48 Bidault was thus closer to Alphand’s position than to that <strong>of</strong> the opponents<br />

<strong>of</strong> the EDC at the Quai d’Orsay. His attitu<strong>de</strong> towards the EDC laid the foundation<br />

for his position on the EPC.<br />

In or<strong>de</strong>r to <strong>de</strong>fine the French position in view <strong>of</strong> the conference <strong>of</strong> the six foreign<br />

ministers in Rome on 24-25 February 1953, Bidault called a meeting on 11<br />

February, at which all the Quai d’Osay’s top civil servants were present. 49 Teitgen<br />

was invited to report on the work <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly. The top civil servants<br />

criticized many points in Teitgen’s report. The theme <strong>of</strong> this <strong>de</strong>bate <strong>de</strong>alt with the<br />

question <strong>of</strong> whether the Germans could be sufficiently controlled in the supranational<br />

European community or, conversely, whether the community might finally<br />

be controlled by the Germans in the foreseeable future. The participants also discussed<br />

whether promoting supranational European <strong>integration</strong> would be compatible<br />

with France’s world power position, based on the Union Française.<br />

On the one hand, there were Teitgen, Alphand and Maurice Schumann who <strong>de</strong>fen<strong>de</strong>d<br />

the continuation <strong>of</strong> Schuman’s European policies and the compatibility <strong>of</strong><br />

these policies with retaining the Union Française. On the other hand, Parodi, <strong>de</strong> la<br />

Tournelle, <strong>de</strong> Maroerie, Gros, Seydoux, Wormser, Sauvagnargues and du Vignaux<br />

argued for the modification <strong>of</strong> Schuman’s European policies and for a French foreign<br />

policy which put more emphasis on the Union Française than on Europe.<br />

Their position was typically represented by the secretary general at the Quai d’Orsay,<br />

Alexan<strong>de</strong>r Parodi and the head <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>de</strong>partment, F. Seydoux. Parodi<br />

linked the EPC project to French foreign policy as a whole. With the Schuman<br />

Plan, France had taken the initiative and <strong>de</strong>termined the speed and direction <strong>of</strong> European<br />

<strong>integration</strong>. However, France had gradually been <strong>de</strong>prived <strong>of</strong> its initiative<br />

and was driven to the point that it now was confronted with the so-called ‘Luxembourg<br />

resolution’.<br />

“What is the meaning <strong>of</strong> all this? That France has to disappear as an in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt<br />

state (…)? On the other hand, this European Community will not be controlled by<br />

France. When the projects <strong>of</strong> the ECSC and the EDC were put forward, we could<br />

legitimately assume that the European Community, as it was conceived, would operate<br />

un<strong>de</strong>r French lea<strong>de</strong>rship. It is obvious that Germany will be the lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> this<br />

community”*.<br />

48. AN Papiers Bidault 34, Chauvel, Note, 25. janv. 1953; G.-H. SOUTOU, Bidault et la construction<br />

européenne 1944-1954, in: Revue d’histoire diplomatique, 1991, p.298. For the position <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Gaullists on European <strong>integration</strong> see, SEUNG-RYEOL K., Der Fehlschlag <strong>de</strong>s ersten Versuchs<br />

zu einer politischen Integration Westeuropas von 1951 bis 1954, Frankfurt am Main, 2000,<br />

pp.77-83.<br />

49. AMAE DE-CE 45-60, 1948-1954, Vol.578, pp.286-308, Compte-rendu <strong>de</strong> la réunion tenue le<br />

Mercredi 11 février à 20h30 chez M. Bidault sur l’organisation politique <strong>de</strong> l’Europe. Participants:<br />

Bidault, Maurice Schumann (secrétaire d’Etat), Pierre-Henri Teitgen (lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the MRP), Parodi<br />

(secrétaire général), <strong>de</strong> la Tournelle (directeur <strong>de</strong>s Affaires politiques), Alphand (presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Interim Committee <strong>of</strong> the EDC), <strong>de</strong> Maroerie, Pr<strong>of</strong>. Gros, Seydoux (chef <strong>de</strong> la direction pour l'Europe),<br />

Wormser (chef du Service <strong>de</strong> coopération économique), Brouillet, Sauvagnargues (direction<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’Afrique-Levant), du Vignaux, <strong>de</strong> Folin.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 77<br />

If the French overseas areas were opened to Europe, he emphasized, France<br />

would lose its rank as a world power. 50 Bidault replied to Parodi that France, Great<br />

Britain and the U.S. would have to lead the Western world. Seydoux held the view<br />

that it was impossible for France to belong to the Six and at the same time to remain<br />

one <strong>of</strong> the three great powers. Bidault replied again that both should remain<br />

compatible. Bidault seemed to be torn, but was nearer to Teitgen’s thinking than to<br />

Parodi’s. Bidault insisted on a minimum amount <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong>:<br />

“It is not a question <strong>of</strong> giving Europe the possibility to extend its authority to unlimited<br />

fields. It is only a matter <strong>of</strong> uniting the ECSC and the EDC in or<strong>de</strong>r to have few<br />

and centralized organizations”*.<br />

The only new element, which Bidault sought to introduce through the EPC<br />

project, was “suffrage universel”. He therefore finally said that the EPC should<br />

“open its windows by means <strong>of</strong> universal suffrage”. However, he did not take a<br />

clear position on the question <strong>of</strong> the Union Française, which he called “our great<br />

concern”, with the exception <strong>of</strong> the principle quoted above. 51<br />

Bidault however was not convinced <strong>of</strong> the necessity <strong>of</strong> direct elections. At the<br />

meeting <strong>of</strong> the board <strong>of</strong> MRP directors on 4 March 1953, Bidault said: “It seems<br />

most uncertain to me that universal suffrage should be adopted”*. A. Colin replied:<br />

“Universal suffrage is essential in or<strong>de</strong>r to create a certain dynamism”*. 52 Bidault<br />

did not think that direct elections were a measure to speed up the European <strong>integration</strong><br />

as Colin thought, but for him it was only a tactical instrument in or<strong>de</strong>r to make<br />

the ratification <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty easier.<br />

While visiting Paris on 20 February 1953, Beyen asked Bidault whether the<br />

French government inten<strong>de</strong>d to submit the EDC treaty together with the EPC treaty<br />

to Parliament for ratification or whether the government would be content with<br />

“favourable perspectives” regarding the creation <strong>of</strong> a political community. Beyen<br />

said that the first hypothesis would cause difficulties between both states, because<br />

the French Parliament did not want economic <strong>integration</strong>, whilst the Dutch Parliament<br />

was opposed to the EPC, if it were not combined with economic <strong>integration</strong>.<br />

Bidault replied:<br />

“The French Parliament stated, among other necessities, the need to create a political<br />

community. It isn’t sure whether today it would do the same again as one year ago”*.<br />

He therefore did not <strong>de</strong>mand that the EPC treaty should be ready to be signed<br />

before the ratification <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty. 53 So it seemed that both politicians agreed<br />

upon the second hypothesis.<br />

Bidault expressed his basic position regarding the European policy in a speech<br />

at the Assemblée Nationale on 9 March 1953. The aim was, according to Bidault,<br />

to build Europe without breaking France down, to create Europe, but not to dis-<br />

50. Ibid.<br />

51. Ibid.<br />

52. AN MRP 350 AP 50, Commission exécutive du 4 mars 1953, p.10.<br />

53. AN Papiers Bidault 38, Note, 20.2.1953, a.s. Entretien entre le Prési<strong>de</strong>nt Bidault et M. Beyen, Ministre<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Affaires Etrangères <strong>de</strong>s Pays-Bas, le 20 février 1953.


78<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

solve France therein, to raise and maintain France’s lea<strong>de</strong>rship <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

community. The French spoke in the name <strong>of</strong> 120 million people. In their name<br />

they would strengthen the Union Française and create Europe. 54<br />

Bidault’s main positions regarding the EPC can be summarized as follows: balancing<br />

Europe and the Union Française (”vocation européenne et mondiale” – European<br />

calling and world calling); resuming <strong>integration</strong> within the framework <strong>of</strong><br />

the six states; making the jurisdiction <strong>of</strong> the EPC correspond, from the beginning,<br />

to that <strong>of</strong> the ECSC and the EDC; refusal <strong>of</strong> the Beyen Plan; entrusting the EPC<br />

only with the right to make suggestions regarding a Common Market. Besi<strong>de</strong>s the<br />

question <strong>of</strong> direct elections, the questions <strong>of</strong> the concrete structure <strong>of</strong> the EPC’s executive,<br />

and the relationship between the EPC and the Union Française were also<br />

remaining open. 55<br />

The Governmental Conference in Rome in September-October 1953 and the<br />

Failure <strong>of</strong> the EPC Project<br />

The conferences for the additional protocols <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty and for agricultural<br />

<strong>integration</strong> in 1953 en<strong>de</strong>d without results. The four foreign minister conferences <strong>of</strong><br />

the ECSC states <strong>de</strong>aling with the draft <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly 56 also brought no<br />

results. It is remarkable that Bidault referred each time to the difficulties regarding<br />

the Union Française without taking a clear position on this. The diplomatic conference<br />

which was inten<strong>de</strong>d to discuss the draft EPC treaty <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly,<br />

according to article 38 <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty, took place in Rome in September-October<br />

1953. In the following section the internal <strong>de</strong>bates <strong>of</strong> France for the preparation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Rome conference are discussed with special consi<strong>de</strong>ration given to the question<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Union Française. 57<br />

The high-level civil servants <strong>of</strong> the Quai d’Orsay ma<strong>de</strong> every effort to convert<br />

the supranational character <strong>of</strong> the draft treaty <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly into a confe<strong>de</strong>ral<br />

form. They criticized the draft treaty <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly on the points <strong>of</strong><br />

economic <strong>integration</strong>, <strong>of</strong> coordination with regard to foreign policy, <strong>of</strong> its supranational<br />

structure (above all the executive council) and, not least, the relationship be-<br />

54. „Bericht über die Behandlung <strong>de</strong>s Vertragsentwurfes nach <strong>de</strong>m 10. März 1953“, submitted by Dr.<br />

von Brentano on the meeting <strong>of</strong> the Constitutional Committee <strong>of</strong> the ad hoc Assembly on 23 June<br />

1953, in: Leitfa<strong>de</strong>n und amtliche Dokumente <strong>de</strong>s Verfassungsausschusses, Mai-Juli 1953, p.47.<br />

55. AN Papiers Bidault 38, Note du Gouvernement français relative au projet <strong>de</strong> marché commun,<br />

21.2.1953; AN Papiers Bidault 38, Conception française pour l’organisation et le fonctionnement<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’organisation exécutive, undated - author unknown (it is nevertheless sure that this note before<br />

the conference <strong>of</strong> ministers <strong>of</strong> foreign affairs in Rome was drawn up in February).<br />

56. The conferences were held in Rome in February, in Strasbourg in March, in Paris in May and in<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n in August 1953.<br />

57. In May, the Mayer government was brought down. The cabinet crisis lasted until July, when the<br />

new Laniel government was formed. Bidault remained minister <strong>of</strong> foreign affairs. The European<br />

policies <strong>of</strong> the new government continued essentially unchanged.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 79<br />

tween the Union Française and the community. The last point <strong>of</strong> criticism will be<br />

brought un<strong>de</strong>r further analysis in the next paragraph.<br />

On 27 April 1953, an inter<strong>de</strong>partmental conference took place in the <strong>of</strong>fice <strong>of</strong> the<br />

secretary general <strong>of</strong> the French Foreign Office, Parodi, in or<strong>de</strong>r to consi<strong>de</strong>r the consequences<br />

<strong>of</strong> the draft EPC treaty for the Union Française. 58 Bourgeot took the view that<br />

direct elections were unfavourable, since they would set the overseas territories in direct<br />

contact with the five other states. It would be <strong>de</strong>sirable that the European Parliament<br />

would consist <strong>of</strong> the <strong>de</strong>legates selected from the national parliaments. Ratineau drew attention<br />

to the fact that the draft EPC treaty would <strong>of</strong>fer to the overseas territories a “itinéraire<br />

<strong>de</strong> fuite” [escape route] from France. Roaux feared that the draft treaty would<br />

cause the separation <strong>of</strong> Algeria, Morocco and Tunisia from France. Bar<strong>de</strong>t was worried<br />

that, on the one hand, if the Etats associés should participate in the EPC, irregardless <strong>of</strong><br />

form, their direct contacts with the five other states could break <strong>of</strong>f the close connection<br />

between them and France. On the other hand, he was concerned that, if they remained<br />

outsi<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong> the EPC, France would lose its guiding role over them. Burin <strong>de</strong>s Roziers<br />

pointed out that a studying committee, which had been set up on Mayer’s suggestion<br />

within the framework <strong>of</strong> the Centre d'Etu<strong>de</strong>s <strong>de</strong> Politique Etrangère, had recently submitted<br />

its research results. It was agreed that the interested ministries should make their<br />

views clear and a conference among them should take place one day between 4 and 9<br />

May. 59 On the basis <strong>of</strong> the documents that the author examined, it can not be ascertained<br />

whether this conference actually took place. However, it is clear that the views<br />

that had been expressed by the top civil servants from the interested ministries were not<br />

modified at a later stage. For example, the minister in charge <strong>of</strong> France d’Outre-mer, L.<br />

Jacquinot, endorsed Bourgeot’s fears regarding direct elections. Moreover, he pointed<br />

out that the supranational Executive Council should be replaced by an <strong>of</strong>fice whose<br />

head was to be appointed by the Council <strong>of</strong> national ministers. He rejected the extension<br />

<strong>of</strong> jurisdiction <strong>of</strong> the EPC on foreign policy and on economic <strong>integration</strong>. 60<br />

The top civil servants <strong>of</strong> the Quai d’Orsay shared these fears. Jurgensen regar<strong>de</strong>d<br />

the guarantee <strong>of</strong> article 101 <strong>of</strong> the draft treaty as insufficient. He proposed that<br />

the EPC should become “supple” in or<strong>de</strong>r to let the Union Française as a whole<br />

58. AMAE Europe 44-60, Vol.78, p.140, Bidault au Ministère <strong>de</strong> la France d’Outre-mer, <strong>de</strong> l’Intérieur<br />

et <strong>de</strong>s Etats associés, 10 avril 1953; AN Papiers Bidault 42, Compte-rendu <strong>de</strong> la réunion du 27 avril<br />

concernant le problème <strong>de</strong>s rapports entre l’Union Française et la Communauté Européenne, 28<br />

avril 1953. In this meeting participated the ministry <strong>of</strong> Foreign affairs [Parodi, De la Tournelle,<br />

Marchal (directeur d’Afrique-Levant), Jurgensen (Sous-directeur d’Afrique-Levant), Sala<strong>de</strong> (Direction<br />

d’Asie), Argod (Direction d’Europe), Valery (Direction Economique)], the cabinet <strong>of</strong> the<br />

presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the Conseil <strong>de</strong>s ministres [Burin <strong>de</strong>s Roziers, (Conseiller diplomatique au cabinet du<br />

prési<strong>de</strong>nt du conseil)], the Ministère <strong>de</strong> la France d’Outre-mer [Ratineau (Cabinet du Ministre),<br />

Bourgeot (Sous-Directeur aux Affaires politiques), Servoise (Direction <strong>de</strong>s Affaires politiques)],<br />

the Ministère <strong>de</strong>s Etats associés [Aurillac (directeur <strong>de</strong>s Services politiques), Bar<strong>de</strong>t (directeur-adjoint)]<br />

and the Ministère <strong>de</strong> l’Intérieur [Roaux, (sous-directeur d’Algérie)].<br />

59. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Compte-rendu <strong>de</strong> la réunion du 27 avril concernant le problème <strong>de</strong>s rapports<br />

entre l’Union Française et la Communauté Européenne, 28 avril 1953.<br />

60. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Ministère <strong>de</strong> la France d’Outre-mer, Direction <strong>de</strong>s Affaires politiques, JB/<br />

CJ, Note, 5.5.1953, a.s. du projet <strong>de</strong> traité portant statut <strong>de</strong> la Communauté Européenne (en ce qui<br />

concerne les TOM).


80<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

take part in it, without jeopardizing the close connection between those areas and<br />

France. He argued for indirect elections for the European Parliament. He spoke<br />

against the establishment <strong>of</strong> a supranational Executive Council, whose function the<br />

Council <strong>of</strong> national ministers could assume, and he also rejected each extension <strong>of</strong><br />

jurisdiction <strong>of</strong> the EPC on foreign policy and economic <strong>integration</strong>. 61<br />

The research results <strong>of</strong> the above mentioned studying committee (which was chaired<br />

by general Catroux) consisted <strong>of</strong> two parts: 1) the institutional and political aspects, 2) the<br />

economic aspects. The author <strong>of</strong> the first part was Jurgensen, the second part was written<br />

by René Servoise from the ministry <strong>de</strong> la France d'Outre-mer. The first part was i<strong>de</strong>ntical<br />

with the draft that Jurgensen had <strong>de</strong>veloped internally at the Quai d’Orsay. Servoise regar<strong>de</strong>d<br />

the Community <strong>of</strong> the Six as an insufficient framework for the <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> the<br />

economy <strong>of</strong> the French overseas areas. These two parts, which were used as one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

important main documents for laying down the French attitu<strong>de</strong>, were published in the<br />

magazine “Politique Etrangère” <strong>of</strong> the Centre d'Etu<strong>de</strong>s <strong>de</strong> politique étrangère in 1953. Jurgensen<br />

did not want to be revealed as the author <strong>of</strong> the first part. Therefore, the author <strong>of</strong><br />

the first part - “L'Union Française et les institutions européennes”, was called “XXX”. 62<br />

Seydoux summarized the internally <strong>de</strong>veloped thoughts <strong>of</strong> the Quai d’Orsay, in<br />

contact with Bidault. As for the Peoples’ Chamber, its members should be directly<br />

elected by the national parliaments in the first period, and afterwards by the people.<br />

He spoke <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>dly against the establishment <strong>of</strong> a supranational Executive Council.<br />

In his opinion, the Council <strong>of</strong> the National Ministers or the Council <strong>of</strong> the Foreign<br />

Ministers should assume this role. Deviating from the suggestions ma<strong>de</strong> by<br />

Jurgensen, Seydoux recommen<strong>de</strong>d that at first only metropolitan France should<br />

take part in the EPC, because the French government, above all Bidault, had not yet<br />

taken any clear position on this subject. Accordingly, France did not need to be given<br />

additional seats in the People’s Chamber. Along these lines Seydoux prepared<br />

instructions for the French <strong>de</strong>legation <strong>of</strong> the diplomatic conference in Rome. 63<br />

61. AN Papiers Bidault 39, Direction d’Afrique-Levant S/D d’Afrique, Note sur le problème <strong>de</strong>s TOM<br />

dans les Travaux <strong>de</strong> l’Assemblée ad hoc, 23.3.1953; AN Papiers Bidault 39, DGAP, Direction<br />

d’Afrique-Levant S/D d’Afrique, Note sur la position <strong>de</strong> la France en tant que puissance<br />

d’Outre-mer, en présence du statut européen proposé par l’Assemblée ad hoc, 28.4.1953.<br />

62. AN Papiers Bidault 42, «L’Union Française et la Communauté Européenne», Rapport d’un groupe<br />

d’étu<strong>de</strong>s du Centre d’étu<strong>de</strong>s <strong>de</strong> politique étrangère, 15.4.1953, Première Partie: Les aspects institutionnels<br />

et politiques, Deuxième Partie: Les aspects économiques; AN Papiers Bidault 42, Lettre<br />

du général Catroux (prési<strong>de</strong>nt du Groupe d’étu<strong>de</strong>s <strong>de</strong> l’Union Française) à Bidault, 5.5.1953;<br />

XXX, L’Union Française et les institutions européennes, in: Politique Etrangère, 4(1953), Paris,<br />

pp.267-276; R., SERVOISE, L’Union Française <strong>de</strong>vant l’intégration économique européenne, in:<br />

Ibid., pp.278-306.<br />

63. AMAE DE-CE 45-60, Vol.578, pp.355-357, DGAP, Europe, Note 5.5.1953, A/S. Projet <strong>de</strong> statut <strong>de</strong><br />

Communauté Européenne; AMAE DE-CE 45-60, Vol.578, pp.402-409, DGAP, Europe, s/Direction du<br />

Conseil <strong>de</strong> l’Europe, Note, 5.6.1953, A/S. Conférence <strong>de</strong> Rome pour l’étu<strong>de</strong> du projet <strong>de</strong> Communauté<br />

Européenne; AMAE DE-CE 45-60, Vol.579, pp.94-102, DGAP, Europe, Note, 7.9.1953, A/S Communauté<br />

politique européenne; AN Papiers Bidault 40, DGAP, Europe, S/D du Conseil <strong>de</strong> l’Europe, Note,<br />

7.9.1953, A/S Conférence <strong>de</strong> Rome pour l’étu<strong>de</strong> du projet <strong>de</strong> Communauté politique; Bruce David, Notebook<br />

14 September-December 1953, Monday September 14, 1953; Bun<strong>de</strong>sarchiv Koblenz (BA) Nachlaß<br />

(NL) Blankenhorn 24, pp.111-117, letter Blankenhorn (Paris) to Hallstein, 18.9.1953.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 81<br />

On 16 September 1953, a stormy council <strong>of</strong> ministers meeting took place, in<br />

which Bidault was forced by the pro-European wing <strong>of</strong> Laniel’s government (Reynaud<br />

and Teitgen) to withdraw his confe<strong>de</strong>ral instructions and to replace them with<br />

new, more concrete and supranational directives. Thereupon Bidault had to issue<br />

revised instructions, according to which direct elections should take place from the<br />

beginning, but no substantial powers should be awar<strong>de</strong>d to Parliament. An executive<br />

<strong>of</strong> the community could be created, but it should consist <strong>of</strong> the Council <strong>of</strong> national<br />

ministers and the Executive Council <strong>of</strong> the EPC. The Council <strong>of</strong> national<br />

ministers should take “all essential <strong>de</strong>cisions”. The Executive Council should consist<br />

<strong>of</strong> a presi<strong>de</strong>nt to be appointed by the Council <strong>of</strong> national ministers, the presi<strong>de</strong>nt<br />

<strong>of</strong> the ECSC’s High Authority, the presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the Board <strong>of</strong> Commissioners <strong>of</strong><br />

the EDC and two members appointed by the Council <strong>of</strong> national ministers. 64 These<br />

new instructions precipitated a dramatic <strong>de</strong>bate between proponents <strong>of</strong> supranational<br />

<strong>integration</strong> and their opponents. Because <strong>of</strong> this extreme discord within the<br />

French government, the new instructions could no longer be submitted to the Council<br />

<strong>of</strong> Ministers for approval. Instead, Bidault passed the new instructions to the <strong>de</strong><br />

facto director <strong>of</strong> the <strong>de</strong>legation, Seydoux, 65 after obtaining assent from Laniel. In<br />

addition, Bidault indicated that the French <strong>de</strong>legation should not bind itself to anything<br />

final as long as the Assemblée Nationale had not concerned itself in <strong>de</strong>tail<br />

with the entire question. The question <strong>of</strong> the Union Française should be exclu<strong>de</strong>d<br />

from the agenda. 66<br />

The governmental conference went into session in Rome on 22 September<br />

1953. From the beginning, the question <strong>of</strong> the Union Française was exclu<strong>de</strong>d from<br />

the discussion, after the French as well as the Belgian <strong>de</strong>legation had ma<strong>de</strong> a statement<br />

about it before the opening <strong>of</strong> the conference. 67 The conference in Rome en<strong>de</strong>d<br />

again without result, just like the earlier conferences <strong>of</strong> the foreign ministers. It<br />

was <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d to discuss the draft EPC treaty again at a next conference <strong>of</strong> the foreign<br />

ministers in The Hague. The unresolved position <strong>of</strong> France on the EPC project<br />

became clearer.<br />

64. PAAA II, Bd.859, 224-20/22, Siegfried (Brüssel) an Auswärtiges Amt, concerning: Quai d’Orsay<br />

gegen EPG, Brüssel, 15.9.1953; BA NL Blankenhorn 24, pp.173 ff., Vermerk für <strong>de</strong>n Herrn Bun<strong>de</strong>skanzler,<br />

Geheim, Bonn, 14.9.1953, Gespräche mit Monnet und R. Mayer; BA NL Blankenhorn<br />

24, pp.147-149, Blankenhorn (Paris) an A<strong>de</strong>nauer und Hallstein, 16.9.1953, geheim; BA NL Blankenhorn<br />

24, pp.150 ff., Tagebuch, Mittwoch, 16.9.1953, Paris; AN Papiers Bidault 40, Note,<br />

17.9.1953, A/S Exécutif; AN Papiers Bidault 40, Note, 18.9.1953, A/S Instructions pour la délégation<br />

française à la Conférence <strong>de</strong> Rome (22 septembre 1953).<br />

65. The <strong>of</strong>ficial, <strong>de</strong> jure, director <strong>of</strong> the French <strong>de</strong>legation was the French ambassador in Rome, Fouques<br />

Duparc.<br />

66. BA NL Blankenhorn 24, p.127, Tagebuch, Freitag, 18.9.1953; PAAA II, Bd. 859, AZ 224-20/22,<br />

p. 248, Nachrichtenspiegel, 22.9.1953; PAAA II, Bd.851, AZ 224-00, Bd.1, pp.107-108, Telegramm<br />

Walther (Paris) an Auswärtiges Amt, Konferenz Rom, für Staatssekretär, 22. September<br />

1953, Nr.444, Geheim.<br />

67. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Déclaration <strong>de</strong>s délégations française et belge. Rome, 24.9.1953; AN Fond<br />

60, Vol.3077, conférence pour la Communauté politique européenne, Rome, 22.9-9.10.1953, Rapport<br />

aux Ministres <strong>de</strong>s Affaires étrangères, Secrétariat, p.4.


82<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

In a letter at Laniel on 22 October 1953, the minister in charge <strong>of</strong> France<br />

d'Outre-mer, Jacquinot, criticized the instructions prepared by Seydoux concerning<br />

the relationship between the European community and the Union Française, i.e.,<br />

the provisional elimination <strong>of</strong> the representation <strong>of</strong> the French overseas territories<br />

in the European Parliament. Jurgensen supported Jacquinot and expressed that the<br />

EPC structurally should become even looser, so as to inclu<strong>de</strong> the overseas areas as<br />

a whole into the European <strong>integration</strong> without jeopardizing the links between<br />

France and its overseas areas. However, the SFIO and the MRP <strong>of</strong>ficially supported<br />

the regulation <strong>of</strong> the draft EPC treaty as a result <strong>of</strong> Teitgen’s initiative. 68<br />

Bidault gave an important speech on the government's European policies in the<br />

Assemblée Nationale on 20 November 1953: “The real dilemma” was the situation<br />

in which France had to choose between Europe and the Union Française, in other<br />

words, between the “vocation européenne” and the “vocation mondiale”. In or<strong>de</strong>r<br />

to find a solution to this dilemma, one had to start out from political reality, Bidault<br />

argued. The ECSC had come into force. The EDC treaty was already signed. However,<br />

it was not a question to “fe<strong>de</strong>rate” the nations and the states which possessed<br />

a long <strong>history</strong>, but to “make them share” a common function. One had to consi<strong>de</strong>r<br />

the different political situation, for example the division <strong>of</strong> Germany and the overseas<br />

responsibility <strong>of</strong> France. If one started from this reality, both the concept <strong>of</strong> a<br />

“a fe<strong>de</strong>ral system consisting <strong>of</strong> a government or an embryo <strong>of</strong> government <strong>of</strong> the<br />

six countries”*, and the confe<strong>de</strong>ration mo<strong>de</strong>l <strong>of</strong> the Gaullists could not meet this<br />

reality, because the concept <strong>of</strong> a confe<strong>de</strong>ration would run against the ECSC and the<br />

EDC. The true Europeans were “<strong>de</strong>s constructeurs patients” [patient buil<strong>de</strong>rs]. 69<br />

Bidault inten<strong>de</strong>d to balance the European policy <strong>of</strong> his pre<strong>de</strong>cessor with strong nationalistic<br />

thoughts and emotions. He saw the solution not in <strong>de</strong>stroying the previous<br />

accomplishments, but in correcting their contents and reducing the speed <strong>of</strong><br />

European <strong>integration</strong> in favour <strong>of</strong> France.<br />

Still, the kind <strong>of</strong> relationship that would link the Union Française to European union<br />

was not yet clearly <strong>de</strong>fined. In France, this resulted not taking a clear position on the institutional<br />

questions <strong>of</strong> the EPC. So the conference in The Hague again brought no re-<br />

68. AN Papiers Bidault 42, Lettre du ministre <strong>de</strong> la France d’Outre-mer, Jacquinot à Laniel,<br />

22.10.1953; AN Papiers Bidault 42, MAE, HA/MB, M. Schumann, Note pour le prési<strong>de</strong>nt,<br />

6.11.1953, A.S. Communauté Européenne et TOM, Très Secret; AN Papiers Bidault 42, Postel-Vimey<br />

(Directeur <strong>de</strong> la Caisse centrale <strong>de</strong>s TOM), La France d’Outre-mer et la CPE, Projet <strong>de</strong> l’Assemblée<br />

ad hoc et amen<strong>de</strong>ments <strong>de</strong> la Délégation française à la Conférence <strong>de</strong> Rome, 12.11.1953,<br />

AN Papiers Bidault 42, Direction d’Afrique-Levant, S/D d’Afrique, Note sur les relations entre<br />

l’Union Française et la CPE, 23.11.1953; AN Papiers Bidault 42, JDJ/LG, DGAP Direction<br />

d’Afrique-Levant, S/D d’Afrique, Note sur les relations entre l’Union Française et la CPE,<br />

6.1.1954.<br />

69. Speech <strong>of</strong> Un<strong>de</strong>rsecretary <strong>of</strong> State M. Schumann as Bidault’s representative in the Assemblée Nationale.<br />

Compte-rendu analytique <strong>of</strong>ficiel. 2ème séance du vendredi 20 nov. 1953, pp. 19-27<br />

(These minutes are found in PAAA Büro Staatssekretäre 1949-1967, Bd. 59, pp. 16-46); AN<br />

Papiers Bidault 38, Note, author and date unknown. The content indicates that the document for<br />

the preparation <strong>of</strong> this speech was written in November 1953. The document is situated, however,<br />

in the document series which was collected and kept for the conference <strong>of</strong> Rome in February 1952.<br />

Therefore, this classification is false.


France’s Agony between «Vocation Européenne et Mondiale» 83<br />

sults, just like the earlier conferences. The six foreign ministers only set up an expert<br />

committee. This committee went on working until the summer <strong>of</strong> 1954, when the EPC<br />

project disappeared at the <strong>de</strong>mise <strong>of</strong> the EDC in August 1954.<br />

Conclusion<br />

The French government was reserved and careful in its approach to political <strong>integration</strong><br />

in 1952. After the replacement <strong>of</strong> the Pinay-Schuman government with that<br />

<strong>of</strong> Mayer-Bidault, this caution became more obvious. The un<strong>de</strong>rlying cause was the<br />

difficult problem <strong>of</strong> the Union Française: How could France harmonize the advancing<br />

European <strong>integration</strong>, which was mainly directed toward the monitoring <strong>of</strong><br />

Germany, with its world power position mainly based on retaining the colonial system?<br />

Furthermore, this problem involved also the question <strong>of</strong> whether and how<br />

France should appear as one <strong>of</strong> the world powers or whether it should act instead as<br />

lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the united Europe on the stage <strong>of</strong> world politics. France began to split<br />

over these questions.<br />

For Monnet and Schuman, a supranational status was necessary for the protection<br />

<strong>of</strong> a framework in which France and Germany would be reconciled and West<br />

Germany could be sufficiently controlled. They did not lose sight <strong>of</strong> the risk that<br />

the dominating role could be transferred to the Germans in a supranational community,<br />

against which an equilibrium had to be maintained. This equilibrium was to be<br />

constructed in the broa<strong>de</strong>r framework <strong>of</strong> an Atlantic community. According to<br />

Monnet, France’s world power status could be ensured on the basis <strong>of</strong> a leading<br />

role in the supranational European community. This conviction was <strong>de</strong>rived from<br />

the fact that, without a close co-operation with the U.S., France’s world power status<br />

could not be secured. The United States pursued a world-wi<strong>de</strong> anticommunist<br />

strategy at that time, by co-operating closely with Great Britain mainly in the<br />

non-European areas, and with France primarily in Europe. Schuman and Monnet<br />

were ready to <strong>de</strong>legate a still larger part <strong>of</strong> sovereignty to the European communities<br />

than the Gaullists and the high-ranking civil servants at the Quai d’Orsay who<br />

shared strong national feelings.<br />

The opponents <strong>of</strong> Monnet-Schuman’s European policy regar<strong>de</strong>d supranational<br />

European <strong>integration</strong> as an insufficient framework to control the Germans. Rather,<br />

they saw therein the possibility that France would eventually lose the dominant position<br />

in the European community to the advantage <strong>of</strong> the Germans. The Gaullists,<br />

the majority <strong>of</strong> the top civil servants at the Quai d’Orsay and the EDC opponents<br />

generally believed that the French world power position <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>d more on the Union<br />

Française than on Europe. In view <strong>of</strong> the crisis <strong>of</strong> the Union Française, and the<br />

contrary attitu<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong> America in colonial questions, they viewed Monnet’s supranational<br />

communities as a sellout <strong>of</strong> France’s national sovereignty and <strong>of</strong> its historical<br />

world power status. Therefore, they <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d to give up the supranational construction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the community in favour <strong>of</strong> a confe<strong>de</strong>ral construction. These opinions


84<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

gained more influence on France’s European policy in 1953-1954 than previously<br />

un<strong>de</strong>r Monnet and Schuman.<br />

With his realistic European policy, Bidault inten<strong>de</strong>d to meet all French positions<br />

on the question <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>. He could not <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong> however which orientation<br />

to give to French foreign policy, whether to give priority to the Union<br />

Française or to European <strong>integration</strong>. He simply postponed taking a clear position<br />

on this question for later.<br />

Despite the careful attitu<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong> the French government, it seemed that the EPC<br />

would lead in the near future to a fe<strong>de</strong>ration, a framework within which France’s<br />

world power status could be dissolved. France was against the final stage <strong>of</strong> European<br />

supranational <strong>integration</strong>, which it expected in the EPC negotiations. In view<br />

<strong>of</strong> this terrible prospect a number <strong>of</strong> people in France among those who had advocated<br />

the ECSC and the EDC as monitoring control bodies over West Germany recoiled<br />

from European supranational <strong>integration</strong>. The original opponents <strong>of</strong> this<br />

functional <strong>integration</strong>, like the Gaullists, affirmed this regression.<br />

In conclusion, the fear that supranational European <strong>integration</strong> would break<br />

down the Union Française played a great role in France’s rejection <strong>of</strong> the supranational<br />

construction <strong>of</strong> the EDC and the EPC. Thus the EPC project did not serve its<br />

original purpose, the relief <strong>of</strong> the ratification <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty, but proved only to<br />

be a cumbersome bur<strong>de</strong>n for the ratification. France changed its attitu<strong>de</strong> towards<br />

the problem <strong>of</strong> the relationship between the Union Française and a supranational<br />

European union two years later, during the EEC negotiations. At this time France<br />

wanted to inclu<strong>de</strong> its overseas territories in the community. This change in attitu<strong>de</strong><br />

is <strong>of</strong> great importance for the success <strong>of</strong> the EEC negotiations. 70<br />

70. It is very interesting to study why France changed its position in such a short period. But this article<br />

will not tackle this question.


85<br />

In Quest <strong>of</strong> Time, Protection and Approval:<br />

France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in<br />

the European Economic Community, 1955-56<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

The <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> the Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) in the 1960s illustrates<br />

how France solved a national problem by means <strong>of</strong> a European solution. 1 By<br />

making France’s participation in the European Economic Community (EEC) conditional<br />

on the setting up <strong>of</strong> a common agricultural market and a common agricultural<br />

policy in accordance with French preferences, the country succee<strong>de</strong>d in giving<br />

French surplus production new outlets. 2 The French position during the negotiations<br />

that led to the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome indicates that there were similar ambitions<br />

behind the country’s claims for social harmonization. France was not the only<br />

country calling for social harmonization. However, while the Benelux countries<br />

<strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d a harmonization <strong>of</strong> the social policies <strong>of</strong> the participating countries,<br />

France called for a harmonization <strong>of</strong> working regulations, claiming that the diversity<br />

in existing national regulations caused unequal terms <strong>of</strong> competition. More<br />

precisely, France <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d that all members <strong>of</strong> the future common market signed<br />

and ensured the effective application <strong>of</strong> the International Labour Organization’s<br />

(ILO) convention on equal pay for men and women. She also <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d the introduction<br />

<strong>of</strong> uniform overtime pay for hours exceeding an agreed number and the<br />

harmonization <strong>of</strong> paid holiday schemes.<br />

This article argues that the French claims for social harmonization were<br />

launched in or<strong>de</strong>r to secure time, protection and approval. When first presented at<br />

the Messina conference in early June 1955, the claims formed part <strong>of</strong> a scheme that<br />

aimed to gain time for a government unable to take a stand on the proposed common<br />

market. They were sustained in or<strong>de</strong>r to secure continued protection for<br />

French industry. Continued protection was in turn instrumental in securing the National<br />

Assembly’s approval <strong>of</strong> the government’s pro-EEC policy. Maintenance <strong>of</strong><br />

protection simultaneously formed part <strong>of</strong> a superior agenda aiming at the mo<strong>de</strong>rnization<br />

<strong>of</strong> the French industrial structure. France raised the stakes in or<strong>de</strong>r to get her<br />

own way. In October 1956 this led to a <strong>de</strong>adlock in the negotiations. Due to Germany’s<br />

will and ability to accommodate the French claims, France finally obtained an<br />

agreement that ren<strong>de</strong>red a completion <strong>of</strong> the negotiations possible.<br />

A central question in studies <strong>of</strong> French European policy in this period has been<br />

why France took an interest in the new proposals for further <strong>integration</strong> that ap-<br />

1. This article originated as a paper presented at the workshop “The Nordic Countries and West<br />

European Economic Integration up to the EFTA period” in Turku (Åbo), September 1999. I thank<br />

the participants, the anonymous reviewers, Frances M. B. Lynch, Hans Otto Frøland and Siri Rye<br />

Salvesen for helpful suggestions.<br />

2. Centre <strong>de</strong>s Archives Contemporaines (CAC), Secrétariat général du Comité interministériel pour<br />

les questions <strong>de</strong> coopération économique européenne (SGCI) 771468, Art.89, Note sur les objectifs<br />

<strong>de</strong> la France dans la politique agricole commune, 03.11.61.


86<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

peared in spring 1955. Hanns Jürgen Küsters argues that it was the Suez crisis that<br />

“… tipped the balance for the French government’s <strong>de</strong>cision to join the EEC …”. 3<br />

Wilfried Loth stresses that Guy Mollet’s pro-European policy aimed to tie the Fe<strong>de</strong>ral<br />

Republic <strong>of</strong> Germany to the West and to further Europe’s in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce from<br />

the USA. 4 Pierre Guillen sees France’s participation in the common market as a result<br />

<strong>of</strong> her wish for co-operation on research into the use <strong>of</strong> nuclear energy. 5 Thus,<br />

there has been a ten<strong>de</strong>ncy to emphasize the impact <strong>of</strong> geopolitical factors. Others<br />

attach more weight to economic consi<strong>de</strong>rations. Frances Lynch argues that the <strong>de</strong>cision<br />

to sign the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome resulted from the need to find a framework that<br />

would enable a continued mo<strong>de</strong>rnization <strong>of</strong> the French economy through the exposure<br />

to increased, but limited, competition. 6 Lynch downgra<strong>de</strong>s the impact <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Cold War. So does Andrew Moravcsik, who claims that commercial consi<strong>de</strong>rations<br />

were <strong>de</strong>cisive for the French government’s <strong>de</strong>cision to sign the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome. 7<br />

Explanations <strong>of</strong> the claims for social harmonization have emphasized domestic<br />

political imperatives. Alan Milward retraces the claims for social harmonization to<br />

<strong>de</strong>mands from French industry, arguing that the claims were necessary for parliamentary<br />

reasons. 8 Likewise, Hanns Jürgen Küsters writes that<br />

„In Wirklichkeit waren die Diskussionen um die soziale Harmonisierung ein reines<br />

Politikum zur Befriedigung französischer Verbandsinteressen. Die Regierung hatte<br />

sich die For<strong>de</strong>rung teils notgedrungen, teils willkommen zu eigen gemacht, um<br />

zusätzliche Garantien und Schutzklauseln einzuhan<strong>de</strong>ln“. 9<br />

Another view, presented by Paul M. Pitman and in line with the contemporary<br />

justification used by the French government, is that the claims were ma<strong>de</strong> in or<strong>de</strong>r<br />

to compensate for the country’s advanced social legislation, the costs <strong>of</strong> which put<br />

3. H.J. KÜSTERS, West Germany’s Foreign Policy in Western Europe, 1949-58: The Art <strong>of</strong> the Possible,<br />

in: C. WURM (ed.): Western Europe and Germany: The Beginnings <strong>of</strong> European Integration,<br />

Berg Publishers, Oxford, 1995, p.69.<br />

4. W. LOTH, Deutsche und französische Interessen auf <strong>de</strong>m Weg zu EWG und Euratom, in: A. WILKENS<br />

(ed.), Die <strong>de</strong>utsch-französischen Wirtschaftsbeziehungen 1945-60, Jan Thorbecke Verlag, Sigmaringen,<br />

1997, pp.171-187, p.177.<br />

5. P. GUILLEN, La France et la négociation <strong>de</strong>s traités <strong>de</strong> Rome: l’Euratom, in: E. Serra (ed.), The<br />

Relaunching <strong>of</strong> Europe and the Treaties <strong>of</strong> Rome, Bruylant and Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, Brussels<br />

and Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, 1989, p.515.<br />

6. F.M.B. LYNCH, Restoring France: The Road to Integration, in: A.S. MILWARD (et al.), The<br />

Frontier <strong>of</strong> National Sovereignty. History and Theory, 1945-1992, Routledge, London and New<br />

York, 1993; F. M. B. LYNCH, France and the International Economy: From Vichy to the Treaty<br />

<strong>of</strong> Rome, Routledge, London and New York, 1997, pp.214-215.<br />

7. A. MORAVCSIK, The Choice for Europe. Social purpose & State power from Messina to Maastricht,<br />

UCL Press, London, 1999, p.103.<br />

8. A. S. MILWARD, The European Rescue <strong>of</strong> the Nation-State, 2 nd Edition, London 2000, p 212.<br />

Milward traces the <strong>de</strong>mand for harmonized overtime pay back to complaints from the French manufacturing<br />

industry that the working week in France was only forty hours whereas it was forty-eight<br />

in Germany and Belgium. See also A. MORAVCSIK, The Choice for Europe …, op.cit.,<br />

pp.109 and 114. According to Moravcsik, French industry consi<strong>de</strong>red these claims the second best<br />

solution to <strong>de</strong>valuation.<br />

9. H. J. KÜSTERS, Die Gründung <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Wirtschaftsgemeinschaft, Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft,<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, 1982, p.376.


France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community 87<br />

the country at a disadvantage in export markets. 10 While this article does not dispute<br />

that French industry claimed social harmonization, it aims to show that the<br />

French government had reasons <strong>of</strong> her own that were more far-reaching for claiming<br />

social harmonization among the Six. 11<br />

In Quest <strong>of</strong> Time<br />

In spring 1955 France was governed by a centre-right coalition hea<strong>de</strong>d by Edgar Faure<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Radical party. Less than a year had passed since the National Assembly had voted<br />

down the European Defence Community (EDC) with a majority <strong>of</strong> 319 to 264 votes.<br />

The dispute over the EDC had disunited the French people. In his memoirs, Robert<br />

Marjolin <strong>de</strong>picts dinner parties in Paris where guests broke up and left in fury, and compares<br />

the atmosphere to the one prevailing during the Dreyfus affair which began 60<br />

years earlier. 12 National unity, restored at the time <strong>of</strong> the liberation, seemed once again<br />

to be broken. When the Benelux-countries launched their memorandum in April the<br />

following year, there was still consi<strong>de</strong>rable division over the question <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong><br />

both within the French government and in the National Assembly. Several <strong>of</strong> the<br />

ministers were convinced Europeans. Among those were Antoine Pinay at the Quai<br />

d’Orsay, Robert Schuman at the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Justice and Pierre Pflimlin at the Ministry<br />

<strong>of</strong> Finance. It was Pinay’s government that had signed the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Paris on the setting<br />

up <strong>of</strong> a European <strong>de</strong>fence community in 1952, and Pinay had himself <strong>de</strong>fen<strong>de</strong>d the<br />

treaty in the <strong>de</strong>bate in the National Assembly two years later. However, the Faure government<br />

also inclu<strong>de</strong>d Gaullist ministers opposed to supra-nationality, opposed to the<br />

European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC) and opposed to the very person <strong>of</strong> Jean<br />

Monnet. 13 The situation within the political lea<strong>de</strong>rship mirrored the one prevailing elsewhere<br />

in French society. The Foreign Ministry was aware <strong>of</strong> the danger <strong>of</strong> presenting<br />

the National Assembly with another insufficiently prepared proposal. The opinion was<br />

that the EDC inci<strong>de</strong>nt had ma<strong>de</strong> French opinion extremely sensitive to economic risks<br />

in international politics. 14<br />

The Benelux memorandum consisted <strong>of</strong> two parts. One stemmed from a proposal<br />

launched by the Dutch foreign minister Jan Willem Beyen for a common<br />

market among the members <strong>of</strong> the ECSC. The other part consisted <strong>of</strong> a suggestion<br />

presented by his Belgian colleague, Paul Henri Spaak, for an extension <strong>of</strong> Europe-<br />

10. P. M. PITMAN, ‘Un Général qui s’appelle Eisenhower’: Atlantic Crisis and the Origins <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Economic Community, in: Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History, Vol.6, 2(2000),<br />

pp.37-59, p.44. See also Ministère <strong>de</strong>s Affaires Etrangères (MAE), DE-CE 1945-60: 711, Note<br />

pour Monsieur le Prési<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong> la Délégation française, 12.07.56.<br />

11. Since France was the country that launched these claims, and since Germany was the one that accommodated<br />

them, focus hereafter will be on these two countries only.<br />

12. R. MARJOLIN, Le travail d’une vie. Mémoires 1911-1986, Éditions Robert Laffont, Paris 1986, p.274.<br />

13. P. GERBET, La ‘relance’ européenne jusqu’à la Conférence <strong>de</strong> Messine, in: E. SERRA (ed.), The<br />

Relaunching <strong>of</strong> Europe …, op.cit. p.71.<br />

14. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 611, Note, 14.04.55.


88<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

an sectoral <strong>integration</strong> into the fields <strong>of</strong> energy, transport and atomic energy. 15 In<br />

France even pro-Europeans were sceptical <strong>of</strong> the part <strong>of</strong> the memorandum concerning<br />

a common market. Pinay, for instance, feared the consequences <strong>of</strong> a more liberal<br />

policy for French enterprises. 16 He was, again according to Robert Marjolin,<br />

«pr<strong>of</strong>ondément gêné par ce qu’il savait <strong>de</strong>s sentiments français, ceux <strong>de</strong>s élites<br />

industrielles ou administratives, comme ceux du peuple lui-même, à l’égard <strong>de</strong>s problèmes<br />

discutés». 17<br />

The prevailing attitu<strong>de</strong> within Pinay’s own ministry was in accordance with this, that<br />

acceptance <strong>of</strong> the proposal for a common market was very unlikely. The Ministry <strong>of</strong> Foreign<br />

Affairs argued that such a solution would <strong>de</strong>mand the surmounting <strong>of</strong> very serious<br />

technical and social problems. The fact that European agriculture was not ready to confront<br />

free tra<strong>de</strong> was one <strong>of</strong> these. The French Union, Benelux’s insistence on a low common<br />

external tariff, regional imbalances and disparities in prices and productivity constituted<br />

the rest <strong>of</strong> the problems. Additionally, one would have to <strong>de</strong>al with the social<br />

problems resulting from the above listed problems. 18 The Ministry also had political objections<br />

to entering a European common market. If Germany regained her sovereignty<br />

and the right <strong>of</strong> disposing an army, the fear was that <strong>integration</strong> would further German<br />

economic and political hegemony on the continent and that this in turn would imply the<br />

loss <strong>of</strong> all freedom <strong>of</strong> action and diplomatic in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce for France. 19 Another concern<br />

<strong>of</strong> political character was that any <strong>de</strong>velopment that could be interpreted as fe<strong>de</strong>ral would<br />

frighten away large segments <strong>of</strong> the French public opinion. 20<br />

While there were plenty <strong>of</strong> objections to the proposal for the common market,<br />

France was simultaneously unable to reject it. Already twice in two years time the<br />

country had prevented the process <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> from progressing. First in<br />

August 1954 with the National Assembly’s rejection <strong>of</strong> the EDC proposal, and secondly<br />

in 1953, when the government had turned down an earlier version <strong>of</strong> the proposal<br />

for a common market. 21 Since the new proposal inclu<strong>de</strong>d concessions to the objections<br />

raised by France in 1953, another rejection would raise serious doubts about<br />

the country’s will to integrate. 22 The fact that the principle <strong>of</strong> a common market also<br />

figured in the agreement on the Saar recently entered into with Germany, ma<strong>de</strong> a re-<br />

15. F. M. B. LYNCH, France and the International Economy …, op.cit., p.169.<br />

16. P. GERBET, La ‘relance’ européenne …, op.cit., p.83.<br />

17. R. MARJOLIN, Le travail d’une vie …, op.cit., p.279.<br />

18. Documents diplomatiques français (DDF) 1955, I, no.288, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques<br />

et financières. 18 May 1955.<br />

19. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 611, Note, 20.04.55.<br />

20. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 611, Note, 14.04.55.<br />

21. In September 1953 the Dutch foreign minister Jan Willem Beyen proposed that tariff reductions<br />

were to take place within the six ECSC countries, and were to lead to a full customs union. On the<br />

1953 proposal, see R. T GRIFFITHS and A. S. MILWARD, The Beyen Plan and the European<br />

Political Community, in: W. MAIHOFER (ed.), Noi si mura, Selected Working Papers <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

University Institute, Florence, 1986, pp.596-623.<br />

22. The new proposal emphasized that the speed <strong>of</strong> the process <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong> was to be <strong>de</strong>termined by<br />

intergovernmental agreement. It also posed the principle <strong>of</strong> harmonization <strong>of</strong> social charges and<br />

production costs. DDF, 1955, I, no.308, Note du Département, May 1955.


France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community 89<br />

jection even more difficult. 23 The Ministry therefore conclu<strong>de</strong>d that, as matters stood,<br />

the best (and probably only) solution was to play for more time. 24 This was to be<br />

done by <strong>de</strong>manding an examination <strong>of</strong> the problems that would result from the setting<br />

up <strong>of</strong> a common market. At the Messina conference, Minister <strong>of</strong> Foreign Affairs,<br />

Antoine Pinay, acted in accordance with this conclusion. It has been argued that positive<br />

conclusions at Messina were due to concessions ma<strong>de</strong> by France’s partners. 25<br />

The countries agreed to un<strong>de</strong>rtake a study <strong>of</strong> the measures necessary in or<strong>de</strong>r to harmonize<br />

the general policy <strong>of</strong> the participating states in the financial, economic and<br />

social fields. 26 Furthermore, they <strong>de</strong>clared it essential to study the progressive harmonization<br />

<strong>of</strong> regulations now in force in the different states, particularly those relating<br />

to the length <strong>of</strong> the workday and the payment <strong>of</strong> additional benefits. 27<br />

In the time that followed, France ma<strong>de</strong> every effort to change the economic<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> the Benelux proposal. As it had already been established that the proposal<br />

could not be turned down, this was the only logical thing to do. If the economic<br />

terms within a common market could be improved for France, scepticism within<br />

public opinion would <strong>de</strong>crease at the same time as the outlooks on a dominating<br />

German position. Earlier research into French European policy has shown that<br />

French tactics before the Messina conference were to disrupt the link between the<br />

acceptable proposal for sectoral <strong>integration</strong> and the unacceptable proposal for a<br />

common market. This was to be done by focusing on topics most likely to divi<strong>de</strong><br />

the other countries. Social harmonization was consi<strong>de</strong>red to be one such issue. 28<br />

While there is no reason to doubt that disruption was what the Quai d’Orsay hoped<br />

for before the conference, several circumstances indicate the existence <strong>of</strong> additional<br />

motives. One <strong>of</strong> these is that the claims were sustained after the Messina conference<br />

was over and the disrupting tactic had failed.<br />

In Quest <strong>of</strong> Protection and Approval<br />

Scholars commenting on the French claims have contested their economic importance.<br />

29 Robert Marjolin consi<strong>de</strong>red them an absurd <strong>de</strong>mand. 30 However, Marjolin<br />

also gave the following <strong>de</strong>scription <strong>of</strong> what it would take to bring France into the<br />

common market.<br />

23. Ibid.<br />

24. Ibid.: “il s’agirait d’étudier à loisir les conditions <strong>de</strong> réalisation du marché commun”.<br />

25. H. J. KÜSTERS, The Origins <strong>of</strong> the EEC Treaty, in: E. SERRA (ed.), The Relaunching <strong>of</strong> Europe …,<br />

op.cit., p.217.<br />

26. Historical Archives <strong>of</strong> the European Communities (HAEC), CM3/ Nego 001, Introduction. La<br />

Conférence <strong>de</strong> Messine, undated.<br />

27. The Messina Declaration: (http://www.let.lei<strong>de</strong>nuniv.nl/<strong>history</strong>/rtg/res1/messina.htm).<br />

28. F. M. B. LYNCH, France and the International Economy …, op.cit., p.171.<br />

29. A. S. MILWARD, Rescue …, op.cit., p.213. P. M. STIRK, A History <strong>of</strong> European Integration since<br />

1914, Pinter, London, 1996, p.140.<br />

30. R. MARJOLIN, Le travail d’une vie …, op.cit., p.286.


90<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

«La difficulté essentielle qu’il fallait surmonter était l’hostilité <strong>de</strong> la quasi-totalité <strong>de</strong><br />

l’opinion française à l’abolition, même progressive, <strong>de</strong> la protection dont jouissait, je<br />

dirai plutôt souffrait, l’industrie française». 31<br />

The argument presented here is that the <strong>de</strong>mand for social harmonization was<br />

vital in overcoming the French opinion’s hostility to the removal <strong>of</strong> protection that<br />

membership <strong>of</strong> the common market seemed to imply. This did not come as a result<br />

<strong>of</strong> the direct economic significance <strong>of</strong> the French claims, which seems to have been<br />

minor. 32 The indirect significance <strong>of</strong> the claims was on the contrary consi<strong>de</strong>rable,<br />

both politically and economically. Through these claims, France was able to secure<br />

continued protection for French industry within the common market. The claims<br />

were furthermore instrumental in justifying regulations for France within the<br />

OEEC that had resulted in consi<strong>de</strong>rable advantages for French tra<strong>de</strong>. Finally they<br />

enabled French governments to avoid un<strong>de</strong>rtaking an otherwise necessary but politically<br />

un<strong>de</strong>sirable <strong>de</strong>valuation <strong>of</strong> the French franc.<br />

Opposition to membership <strong>of</strong> a common market in the French National Assembly<br />

reflected prevailing sentiments in French public opinion in general, and within<br />

French industry in particular. The industrial sector feared foreign competition and<br />

was reluctant to the removal <strong>of</strong> the protection which French industry enjoyed. 33<br />

This protection consisted <strong>of</strong> a tax reduction on exports and a corresponding surcharge<br />

on imports into the Franc Area. The claims for social harmonization were<br />

conducive to overcoming opposition to economic <strong>integration</strong> by being instrumental<br />

in maintaining these special regulations for French tra<strong>de</strong>. It turned out as follows.<br />

In Brussels France justified her resort to export-aid and special import-taxes with<br />

the importance <strong>of</strong> social charges weighing upon French cost prices. 34 The claims<br />

for social harmonization were in turn justified by the argument that they were ma<strong>de</strong><br />

in or<strong>de</strong>r to harmonize social charges: to prevent countries with less <strong>de</strong>veloped social<br />

legislation from outclassing other countries. 35 Accordingly, as long as the<br />

French claims for social harmonization were not accommodated, special protection<br />

<strong>of</strong> French industry was justified. At the Ministry <strong>of</strong> Foreign Affairs, continuance <strong>of</strong><br />

this protection was consi<strong>de</strong>red a necessity if a treaty on a common market was to be<br />

ratified by the French National Assembly. 36<br />

31. Ibid., p.281.<br />

32. See pp.14-15.<br />

33. R. MARJOLIN, Le travail d’une vie …, op.cit., p.284. See also Ph. MIOCHE, Le patronat français<br />

et les projets d’intégration économique européenne dans les années cinquante, in: G. TRAUSCH<br />

(ed.), The European Integration from the Schuman-Plan to the Treaties <strong>of</strong> Rome, Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

and Bruylant, Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n and Brussels, 1993, p.247. Mioche explains that the employer’s<br />

organization, the Conseil National du Patronat Français (CNPF), was divi<strong>de</strong>d in the question<br />

<strong>of</strong> membership <strong>of</strong> the common market and why this was the case.<br />

34. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 711, Note, 15.09.56.<br />

35. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 711, Note pour Monsieur le Prési<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong> la Délégation française, 12.07.56.<br />

36. DDF 1956, I, no.67, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières, 2 February<br />

1956.


France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community 91<br />

The maintenance <strong>of</strong> the claim for social harmonization in Brussels also contributed<br />

to the keeping up <strong>of</strong> advantages within the OEEC. 37 Within both the OEEC<br />

and GATT, the French system <strong>of</strong> tax reductions on exports had been heavily criticized,<br />

and France had already obliged herself to announce when she would be<br />

ready to diminish or eliminate these reductions. The additional tax on imports was<br />

likewise contested. In or<strong>de</strong>r to explain her mo<strong>de</strong>st liberalizing performance within<br />

the OEEC, France had invoked the disparity between French and foreign prices.<br />

She had argued that it was this disparity that necessitated both tax reductions on exports<br />

and the additional tax on imports. Thus, if France engaged in a common market<br />

without harmonization <strong>of</strong> social legislation at the same time as she had not fulfilled<br />

her obligations versus the OEEC, she would put herself in an awkward<br />

position.<br />

Table 1: Tra<strong>de</strong> liberalization in OEEC countries, 1952-56<br />

(% <strong>of</strong> imports freed from quota restrictions; end years) 38<br />

Intra-OEEC tra<strong>de</strong> 1952 1954 1956<br />

France 0 65 82<br />

Germany 81 90 92<br />

OEEC average 65 83 89<br />

The opinion within the Foreign Ministry was that France during the last few years<br />

had consi<strong>de</strong>rably benefited from the process <strong>of</strong> quota liberalization. In addition to the<br />

general advantages <strong>of</strong> liberated tra<strong>de</strong> and payments following the <strong>de</strong>cisions taken within<br />

the OEEC, exceptions had permitted her to pr<strong>of</strong>it from the ongoing process without<br />

having to commit herself to the same <strong>de</strong>gree as the other countries. 39 In early 1952,<br />

France had suspen<strong>de</strong>d all import-liberalizing measures for a period <strong>of</strong> twenty months<br />

due to balance <strong>of</strong> payments troubles. While doing so she had been allowed to continue<br />

to benefit from the liberalization un<strong>de</strong>rtaken by the other countries. In the same period<br />

the other countries had accepted a 50% reduction in quota-regulated imports into<br />

France without introducing similar measures versus French exports. Furthermore, the<br />

OEEC had accepted the introduction <strong>of</strong> the special tax on imports that appeared in April<br />

1954. And finally, while the OEEC had <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d in January 1955 to remove a certain<br />

number <strong>of</strong> export subventions, the organization had admitted that this obligation would<br />

not automatically apply to France. This <strong>de</strong>cision was due to take effect from December<br />

37. MAE, Papiers Wormser (PW), Vol.31, Note pour le Prési<strong>de</strong>nt, 10.10.55.<br />

38. Source: A. BOLTHO, Convergence, competitiveness and the exchange rate, in: N. CRAFTS and<br />

G. TONIOLO (eds.), Economic Growth in Europe since 1945, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge,<br />

1996, p.121.<br />

39. Between 1952 and 1955 the French economy remained one <strong>of</strong> the most protected economies in<br />

OEEC. F.M.B. LYNCH, Restoring France …, op.cit., p.65.


92<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

31 st 1955 and would as a consequence favour even more French tra<strong>de</strong>. The French Foreign<br />

Ministry was well aware that these advantages had allowed French exports to expand.<br />

Exports had expan<strong>de</strong>d more rapidly than imports, and exports toward the OEEC<br />

countries had expan<strong>de</strong>d faster than exports to the rest <strong>of</strong> the world. 40 To give up a privileged<br />

position within the OEEC while simultaneously having to face increased competition<br />

within a European common market, can not have been a tempting prospect.<br />

Finally, the system <strong>of</strong> export-aid and import-taxes enabled French governments<br />

to avoid un<strong>de</strong>rtaking the otherwise necessary, but from a political point <strong>of</strong> view un<strong>de</strong>sirable,<br />

<strong>de</strong>valuation <strong>of</strong> the French franc. 41 The overvaluation was estimated in<br />

November 1955 to reach approximately 12%. Within the Faure administration it<br />

was consi<strong>de</strong>red the sole guarantee for continued economic and hence political cohesion<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Franc Area. 42 It was regar<strong>de</strong>d as the means that allowed the transformation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the French political union into the Franc Area as an economic unit constituted<br />

by a customs union. The internal price level corresponding to the<br />

overvaluation was consi<strong>de</strong>red advantageous in several respects. It allowed the industrialization<br />

<strong>of</strong> technically un<strong>de</strong>r<strong>de</strong>veloped areas and ma<strong>de</strong> otherwise marginal<br />

agricultural areas pr<strong>of</strong>itable. A common level <strong>of</strong> prices restricted possible markets<br />

to the Franc Area only and led to a common level <strong>of</strong> protection against the rest <strong>of</strong><br />

the world. The overvaluation also obliged the un<strong>de</strong>r-<strong>de</strong>veloped areas to renounce<br />

customs toward France. It obliged all territories in the Area to constitute a customs<br />

union and to engage in a common policy and a common investment-program ensuring<br />

a very advanced <strong>de</strong>gree <strong>of</strong> political cohesion. The fear was that <strong>de</strong>valuation<br />

quickly would lead to an economic and political break-up <strong>of</strong> the French union. The<br />

exchange rate was consi<strong>de</strong>red a necessary, perhaps also sufficient, condition for the<br />

continued existence <strong>of</strong> the Franc Area. Thus, an artificial maintenance <strong>of</strong> an overvalued<br />

currency appeared as an economic and political imperative.<br />

In January 1956, as a result <strong>of</strong> legislative elections, a new government took <strong>of</strong>fice<br />

with Guy Mollet, the lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the Section Française <strong>de</strong> l’Internationale<br />

Ouvrière (SFIO), as head <strong>of</strong> government. With the exception <strong>of</strong> a small number <strong>of</strong><br />

Mendès-France radicals, Mollet’s centre-left coalition, the Republican Front, has<br />

been <strong>de</strong>scribed as more pro-European than the Faure government. The composition<br />

<strong>of</strong> the new National Assembly has been interpreted somewhat differently. While<br />

some argue that it indicated an increased opposition, others claim the opposite. 43<br />

40. MAE, PW, Vol.80. Avantages que la France a tirés <strong>de</strong> sa participation à l’OECE dans le domaine<br />

<strong>de</strong>s échanges et <strong>de</strong>s paiements, 17.01.56.<br />

41. DDF 1956, I, no.265, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières,<br />

21.04.1956.<br />

42. MAE, PW, Vol.77, Note pour Monsieur Clappier, 28.11.55.<br />

43. Frances Lynch shows that on balance the number <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>puties strongly opposed to European <strong>integration</strong><br />

increased. Chapsal and Lancelot claim that the elections ma<strong>de</strong> away with a good number<br />

<strong>of</strong> representatives opposed to European <strong>integration</strong>. F. M. B. LYNCH, France and the International<br />

Economy …, op.cit., p.173. J. CHAPSAL and A. LANCELOT, La vie politique en France <strong>de</strong>puis<br />

1940, PUF, Paris, 1979, (5 th edition), p.296. I believe the disagreement is due to the fact that<br />

Chapsal and Lancelot only seem to take account <strong>of</strong> the <strong>de</strong>cline <strong>of</strong> the Gaullists, ignoring changes<br />

in the number <strong>of</strong> communists and the emergence <strong>of</strong> the Poujadists.


France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community 93<br />

What seems sure is that support for a pro-EEC policy still could not be, and was<br />

not, taken for granted. 44 Improvements in France’s economic position may have<br />

ma<strong>de</strong> it easier for the new government to lead a more pronounced policy in favour<br />

<strong>of</strong> a common market.<br />

Shortly after the Mollet take-over, the director <strong>of</strong> the economic and financial division<br />

at the Quai d’Orsay, Olivier Wormser, wrote a note in which he discussed the<br />

situation faced by the new government. Wormser emphasized that exports to the<br />

OEEC area had expan<strong>de</strong>d consi<strong>de</strong>rably, that gold and currency reserves had increased<br />

and that the country had been able to repay an appreciable part <strong>of</strong> her<br />

<strong>de</strong>bts. 45 However, he simultaneously established that the situation was far from satisfactory,<br />

and also marked by the precarious methods that had been used to obtain<br />

the above mentioned results. Exports <strong>of</strong> finished products were still low, and France<br />

had not yet seen all consequences <strong>of</strong> the loss <strong>of</strong> market shares in Indochina, <strong>of</strong> the<br />

situation in North Africa and <strong>of</strong> the statute for the Saar. As for the methods used by<br />

France, several countries were about to lose their patience with the French system<br />

<strong>of</strong> export subventions and import taxes.<br />

As Wormser put it, the government was faced with two options. One possibility<br />

was to <strong>de</strong>value and eliminate the export subventions and import taxes. The other alternative<br />

consisted in making the other countries accept that the existing system<br />

was a temporary but inevitable solution ma<strong>de</strong> necessary by the disparity between<br />

French and international prices. He did not envisage that the new government<br />

would be willing to <strong>de</strong>value. Nor could the disparity in prices be rapidly eliminated.<br />

It would take time before any policy <strong>of</strong> increased productivity and/or investments<br />

could produce results. The international picture, the situation in North Africa<br />

and the need to maintain full employment ren<strong>de</strong>red a severe policy impossible.<br />

Consequently, he conclu<strong>de</strong>d that the government would have to make the other<br />

countries accept the French system <strong>of</strong> export subventions and a temporary tax on<br />

imports. Wormser emphasized the emergency character and importance <strong>of</strong> the task<br />

in question. Yet he was also aware that the French government seemed unable to<br />

reach a clear and <strong>de</strong>finite solution to the problem. The only way out seemed to be<br />

«… <strong>de</strong> chercher à gagner du temps en érigeant <strong>de</strong>s pratiques en vérité contestables,<br />

en système doctrinal, tout en <strong>de</strong>meurant conscient qu’il s’agit là d’un expédient provisoire».<br />

46<br />

Material produced un<strong>de</strong>r the new government indicates that it en<strong>de</strong>d up in<br />

adopting Wormser’s recommendations. France’s reason to engage actively in the<br />

ongoing work in the Spaak-committee was “l’intérêt politique qui s’attache à faire<br />

un nouveau pas vers la construction <strong>de</strong> l’Europe”. 47 However, the common market<br />

was simultaneously consi<strong>de</strong>red an economic opportunity, where increased but limited<br />

competition would enhance a reform <strong>of</strong> the French economy. Due to prevailing<br />

44. Christian Pineau, in: E. SERRA (ed.), The Relaunching <strong>of</strong> Europe …, op.cit., p.282.<br />

45. MAE, PW, Vol.80, Note, 30.01.56.<br />

46. Ibid.<br />

47. DDF 1956, I, no.62, Note du Service <strong>de</strong> Coopération économique, January 1956.


94<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

sentiments in French economic circles, the Foreign Ministry remained convinced<br />

<strong>of</strong> the need to take account <strong>of</strong> social and fiscal differences among the Six. The outlook<br />

for the ratification <strong>of</strong> a treaty that did not inclu<strong>de</strong> clear arrangements in these<br />

fields was consi<strong>de</strong>red poor. What mattered was therefore to set up a system taking<br />

sufficient care <strong>of</strong> realities in or<strong>de</strong>r to gain the National Assembly’s approval and<br />

necessary support in public opinion. 48 After the elections, instructions to the French<br />

<strong>de</strong>legation in Brussels continued to insist on the need to harmonize social, as well<br />

as fiscal, policies.<br />

Hanns Jürgen Küsters writes that after the elections “a more open-min<strong>de</strong>d approach<br />

to European policy was expected <strong>of</strong> France. The political personalities did<br />

in fact change, but the administration – and with it – its extremely anti-European<br />

stance remained”. 49 It is not my impression that the Foreign Ministry was opposed<br />

to a common market membership. Rather, it appears realistic with regard to the internal<br />

situation in France and what it would take to overcome opposition to the<br />

government’s choice <strong>of</strong> policy. 50 After January 1956 the Ministry no longer advocated<br />

the need for an alignment <strong>of</strong> the social charges belonging to France’s partners<br />

only. Just as consistently, it called for the need to un<strong>de</strong>rtake structural economic<br />

and social domestic reforms. Thus, structural problems were no longer swept un<strong>de</strong>r<br />

the carpet, and self-examination was more pronounced. As soon as the <strong>de</strong>cision to<br />

establish a common market was taken, France would have no choice but to surmount<br />

the problems that membership presented.<br />

Other questions, including the harmonization <strong>of</strong> charges, only constituted a means<br />

to that end. It was ma<strong>de</strong> clear that membership would not be compatible with the maintenance<br />

<strong>of</strong> the present economic and social equilibrium in France. The safeguard clauses<br />

were temporary and would not spare France the necessary social and economic<br />

changes, the importance <strong>of</strong> which could not be un<strong>de</strong>restimated. The common market<br />

would also constitute a step toward a merger <strong>of</strong> the economic policies <strong>of</strong> the countries<br />

involved, and a certain <strong>integration</strong> <strong>of</strong> the countries’ foreign policies. Finally, it would<br />

both legally and practically be impossible to realize simultaneously the merger <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European markets and the markets <strong>of</strong> the French union. Acceptance or refusal <strong>of</strong> these<br />

implications would have to take place. Before doing so, France would have to ascertain<br />

that there was no other way to ensure in a comparable manner a durable reinforcement<br />

<strong>of</strong> European co-operation and suitable conditions for the mo<strong>de</strong>rnization and expansion<br />

<strong>of</strong> the French economy. 51<br />

The Ministry knew at an early point that the forthcoming Spaak report was unlikely<br />

to take account <strong>of</strong> the French claims in a precise manner. 52 Nor was the Con-<br />

48. DDF 1956, I, 67, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières,<br />

02.02.1956.<br />

49. H. J. KÜSTERS, The Origins <strong>of</strong> the EEC Treaty, op.cit., p.222.<br />

50. DDF 1956, I, no.122, Note du Département, 23.02.1956.<br />

51. DDF 1956, I, no.265, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières,<br />

21.04.1956.<br />

52. DDF 1956, I, no.67, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières,<br />

02.02.1956.


France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community 95<br />

seil National du Patronat Français (CNPF) pleased with the report. 53 The employers’<br />

organization ma<strong>de</strong> it clear that it consi<strong>de</strong>red a harmonization <strong>of</strong> the production<br />

conditions an indispensable counterpart to the planned liberalization <strong>of</strong> tra<strong>de</strong>. It insisted<br />

that France <strong>de</strong>mand precise obligations on this point, which in turn would<br />

exclu<strong>de</strong> a fixed schedule for the passage from one stage <strong>of</strong> the transitional period to<br />

another. 54 In other words, the CNPF <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d the ratification and application <strong>of</strong><br />

the convention for equal pay for men and women. It <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d the fixing <strong>of</strong> a common<br />

basis for overtime pay and the harmonization <strong>of</strong> paid holidays. 55 The employers<br />

emphasized the need to ensure the maintenance <strong>of</strong> import-taxes and export-aid.<br />

According to the organisation itself, this system ought to exist as long as the causes<br />

for the general price disparity between French and other international prices were<br />

not eliminated.<br />

It has been argued that the narrower commercial concern <strong>of</strong> export promotion<br />

was central to the preferences <strong>of</strong> the French, German and British governments’<br />

choice for Europe. 56 There is reason to believe that French policy-makers were out<br />

for more than that. Material from the Foreign Ministry says clearly that while, in<br />

January 1956, the expansion <strong>of</strong> exports is well on its way, the need for mo<strong>de</strong>rnization<br />

is still consi<strong>de</strong>red urgent. 57 French lea<strong>de</strong>rs were undoubtedly sensitive to, and<br />

forced to take account <strong>of</strong>, the position <strong>of</strong> French industry. But that is not to say that<br />

French governments claimed social harmonization only to accommodate French<br />

industry. French politicians had reasons <strong>of</strong> their own to maintain the claim for social<br />

harmonization that had little or nothing to do with the French patronat. The<br />

CNPF claimed social harmonization in or<strong>de</strong>r to maintain protection while simultaneously<br />

getting access to a larger market. French political lea<strong>de</strong>rs shared this ambition.<br />

In contrast to the CNPF however, the political lea<strong>de</strong>rship was also out to avoid<br />

un<strong>de</strong>rtaking a <strong>de</strong>valuation, and to obtain support for a policy whose overriding concern<br />

was more far-reaching than export-promotion, namely a much nee<strong>de</strong>d mo<strong>de</strong>rnization<br />

<strong>of</strong> the French economy. 58<br />

The Problems Faced by the French Economy<br />

By pointing social legislation out as a tra<strong>de</strong> distortion, France managed to keep<br />

more fundamental reasons for the country’s lack <strong>of</strong> competitive power out <strong>of</strong> the<br />

53. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 628, Le marché commun européen, 09.08.1956.<br />

54. Ibid.<br />

55. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 628, Le marché commun, 10.08.1956.<br />

56. A. MORAVCSIK, The Choice for Europe …, op.cit., p.88.<br />

57. MAE, PW, Vol.80, Note, 30.01.56.<br />

58. Ibid., DDF 1956, I, no.67, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières,<br />

02.02.1956, DDF 1956, I, no.265, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et<br />

financières, 21.04.56.


96<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

searchlight. France’s problem was that the country’s industrial sector was relatively<br />

small and unproductive. This has been explained by the fact that no net investments<br />

had taken place in the period from 1930 to 1945. Low productivity and lack <strong>of</strong><br />

competitive power has also been traced back to the 1931 sterling <strong>de</strong>valuation and<br />

the introduction <strong>of</strong> a preferential tariff within the British Empire. These steps augmented<br />

France’s tra<strong>de</strong> with its own empire. 59 Since the French Empire was un<strong>de</strong>veloped<br />

and not able to compete in a free market, this tra<strong>de</strong> had been highly protected.<br />

Due to the protection, structural changes that competition otherwise would<br />

have provoked, such as the merger <strong>of</strong> small firms into larger units, had not taken<br />

place. 60 France in the mid-fifties was still protectionist. According to the Foreign<br />

Ministry, economic circles took little interest in exports. Quotas were kept up not<br />

only for balance <strong>of</strong> payment-reasons, but also due to the will, justified or not, to<br />

protect. 61 The fact that France managed to keep its tra<strong>de</strong> on the present level <strong>of</strong> liberalization<br />

was attributed to the system <strong>of</strong> import taxes and export aid. 62<br />

In 1956 the ILO published an investigation into the cost <strong>of</strong> labour that showed that<br />

wage costs and obligatory social charges in France were higher than in Germany.<br />

Table 2: Average hourly earnings, obligatory social charges and<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> days <strong>of</strong>f with pay 63<br />

Average hourly earnings,<br />

1954<br />

Obligatory<br />

social<br />

charges<br />

expressed<br />

as percentage<br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

asseable<br />

wages at<br />

01.01.1956<br />

Cost to employers<br />

<strong>of</strong> days <strong>of</strong>f<br />

with pay as percentage<br />

<strong>of</strong><br />

wages, 1952-53<br />

Wages + obl.<br />

social charges +<br />

cost <strong>of</strong> days <strong>of</strong>f<br />

with pay. Indices:<br />

Switzerland<br />

=100<br />

In Swiss<br />

francs<br />

Indices:<br />

Switzerland<br />

= 100<br />

France 1.88 73 29.8 7.2 92<br />

Germany 1.74 68 11.7 9.8 75<br />

However, the ILO investigation did not take account <strong>of</strong> private agreements between<br />

un<strong>de</strong>rtakings and tra<strong>de</strong> unions that, unlike in France, constituted a consi<strong>de</strong>ra-<br />

59. In the constitution <strong>of</strong> 1946 the term “empire” was replaced by the term “union”.<br />

60. F. M. B. LYNCH, France and the International Economy …, op.cit., Conclusion.<br />

61. DDF 1956, I, no.265, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières, 21.04.1956.<br />

62. DDF 1956, I, no.67, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières,<br />

02.02.1956.<br />

63. Source: International Labour Office: Social Aspects <strong>of</strong> European Economic Co-operation. Report<br />

by a Group <strong>of</strong> Experts, Geneva 1956, p.33. Since the three sets <strong>of</strong> data related to different dates,<br />

the ILO emphasized that the aggregates were approximations. It was consi<strong>de</strong>red unlikely that this<br />

affected the relative magnitu<strong>de</strong> in any substantial <strong>de</strong>gree.


France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community 97<br />

ble part <strong>of</strong> total social charges weighing upon German employers. Nor did it take<br />

account <strong>of</strong> the overvaluation <strong>of</strong> the French franc and the un<strong>de</strong>rvaluation <strong>of</strong> the German<br />

mark. Thus, the disparity in the cost <strong>of</strong> labour in the two countries was, according<br />

to <strong>of</strong>ficials in the Interministerial Committee for Questions <strong>of</strong> European Integration<br />

(SGCI), less than indicated in the table above. The SGCI conclu<strong>de</strong>d that<br />

in the course <strong>of</strong> two years the difference in the cost <strong>of</strong> labour between France and<br />

Germany had <strong>de</strong>creased from 22.6% in 1954 to only 7% in 1956. 64<br />

The Quai d’Orsay was well aware that a harmonization <strong>of</strong> social charges would<br />

not compensate for the disparity between French and foreign prices. The Ministry<br />

was <strong>of</strong> the opinion that this disparity was mainly due to the structure <strong>of</strong> the French<br />

costs and to the sum <strong>of</strong> production costs. After the Second World War, subsequent<br />

French governments had, in contrast to the previous period, led a policy focused on<br />

investments. Simultaneously, a policy <strong>of</strong> increased wages had been pursued. At the<br />

national level the increase in income had balanced the increase in prices. At the international<br />

level these policies had created a gap between French and foreign prices.<br />

65 Consequently, harmonization <strong>of</strong> social legislation would only very slightly<br />

improve the situation for those branches <strong>of</strong> French industry where prices were<br />

higher than in other countries. Nor was such harmonization likely to be accepted by<br />

France’s partners. Not only would it contradict objectives with regard to competition<br />

pursued notably among the Six, social harmonization would also worsen the<br />

European countries’ competitive position on the international market without improving<br />

France’s position versus third countries. 66<br />

The Quai d’Orsay was concerned with the danger involved in <strong>de</strong>scribing the gap<br />

in prices as a general disparity. Export-aid and import-taxes did not concern all<br />

products. This could be interpreted as if disparities did not exist within sectors outsi<strong>de</strong><br />

the scope <strong>of</strong> these arrangements, which would mean that the disparity was not<br />

general. It could also be interpreted as if disparities within these branches were<br />

compensated for by specific distortions to the <strong>de</strong>triment <strong>of</strong> other countries. 67 An investigation<br />

into general price disparities would highlight the need for reform <strong>of</strong> the<br />

structure <strong>of</strong> French costs. 68 Alternatively it could lead France’s partners to recommend<br />

with reinforced insistence a <strong>de</strong>valuation <strong>of</strong> the French franc. The Ministry<br />

was well aware that a permanent elimination <strong>of</strong> price disparities would take both<br />

<strong>de</strong>valuation and reform. Yet while the Mollet government did not share the preceding<br />

government’s reasons against <strong>de</strong>valuation, it was all the same against it. 69 The<br />

system <strong>of</strong> export aid and import taxes was conducive to avoiding <strong>de</strong>valuation. The<br />

argument presented by the French government was that the price disparities were<br />

64. CAC, 910004/2, Note sur l’inci<strong>de</strong>nce <strong>de</strong>s charges sociales et <strong>de</strong> la charge salariale globale, undated.<br />

65. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 711, Note, 15.09.1956.<br />

66. Ibid.<br />

67. Ibid. One is left with the impression that this was the case, since the Ministry advised against a sector-wise<br />

study <strong>of</strong> price disparities since this could reveal specific distortions harmful to certain countries.<br />

68. Ibid.<br />

69. DDF 1956, I, no.265, Note <strong>de</strong> la Direction générale <strong>de</strong>s Affaires économiques et financières,<br />

21.04.1956.


98<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

not only <strong>of</strong> a general character, liable to be corrected by an adjustment <strong>of</strong> exchange<br />

rates, they also correspon<strong>de</strong>d to certain differences in social and fiscal legislation.<br />

That was why France had <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d the harmonization <strong>of</strong> social charges as a precondition<br />

to the common market. The hope was that France’s partners, at least for a<br />

while, would accept the soundness <strong>of</strong> this. 70<br />

So far, little indicated that this would be the case. Outsi<strong>de</strong>rs had long argued<br />

against harmonization and in favour <strong>of</strong> a French <strong>de</strong>valuation. Harmonization,<br />

whether social or fiscal, was not consi<strong>de</strong>red a necessary precondition for a common<br />

market. It would, the argument went, be i<strong>de</strong>ntical with <strong>de</strong>manding that the other<br />

countries would augment their production costs, which was consi<strong>de</strong>red a solution<br />

without any chances <strong>of</strong> succeeding. 71 The Secretariat <strong>of</strong> the Intergovernmental<br />

Committee had also produced a note on distortions in the Common Market with the<br />

intention <strong>of</strong> proving that prior harmonization <strong>of</strong> charges was unnecessary, and that<br />

it would be possible to correct the distortions <strong>of</strong> which France suffered through a<br />

<strong>de</strong>valuation. 72 From a technical point <strong>of</strong> view the French were not foreign to this<br />

kind <strong>of</strong> argument. While their reasons for not wanting to <strong>de</strong>value were <strong>of</strong> political<br />

and psychological nature, they still found this way <strong>of</strong> arguing maladroit. 73<br />

Saved by the Germans<br />

In October the question <strong>of</strong> social harmonization brought the negotiations for a common<br />

market to a standstill. A few weeks later France and Germany hammered out a<br />

compromise that enabled a successful completion <strong>of</strong> the negotiations. This compromise<br />

simultaneously eliminated opposition to the common market within French<br />

industrial circles.<br />

Germany never believed that France’s ability to compete was hampered by social<br />

costs constituting a larger part <strong>of</strong> production costs than in other countries. The<br />

German Foreign Ministry based itself on experience from the ECSC as well as recent<br />

investigations un<strong>de</strong>rtaken by the OEEC, which rejected that the bur<strong>de</strong>n <strong>of</strong> social<br />

and fiscal costs in France would distort competition in a common market. The<br />

German view was that indirect pay constituted a larger part <strong>of</strong> total hourly labour<br />

costs in France than in most ECSC countries, but that total hourly labour costs were<br />

not higher in France than in the other countries. 74 Accordingly, the German Foreign<br />

Ministry was sceptical when the French <strong>de</strong>legation in July 1956 called for an investigation<br />

into the expenditures ma<strong>de</strong> up <strong>of</strong> social costs in the different countries. In<br />

its opinion, the scope <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d by the French was too narrow and could only pro-<br />

70. Ibid.<br />

71. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 612, Bertrand (OEEC) to Valéry (MAE), 11.08.55.<br />

72. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 612, Note pour le Cabinet du Ministre, 19.09.55.<br />

73. Ibid.<br />

74. Bun<strong>de</strong>sarchiv (BA), B 146/594a, Soziallasten, Lohn- und Steuerbelastung und <strong>de</strong>r Wettbewerb auf<br />

<strong>de</strong>m Gemeinsamen Markt, 27.06.56.


France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community 99<br />

duce a result that would be used to justify a French <strong>de</strong>mand for a levelling up <strong>of</strong> the<br />

costs in other countries to French standards. 75 The Germans were convinced that a<br />

more comprehensive investigation would prove that the importance <strong>of</strong> social harmonization<br />

was over-estimated. This was probably why the Ministry referred to the<br />

question <strong>of</strong> social harmonization as a false problem. Nevertheless, it was consi<strong>de</strong>red<br />

a problem and one that, on account <strong>of</strong> negotiating tactics, would have to be<br />

solved as soon as possible. 76<br />

Months went by before a solution was reached. In the time that passed, the discussion<br />

centred around which matters ought to be investigated in or<strong>de</strong>r to <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong> whether<br />

social costs did constitute a tra<strong>de</strong> distortion or not. France <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d an investigation<br />

into the significance <strong>of</strong> equal pay, overtime pay and paid holidays. Germany pressed for<br />

a more comprehensive investigation into the part constituted by direct and indirect wages<br />

on net production value <strong>of</strong> industrial production in the Six states. 77<br />

The Bun<strong>de</strong>swirtschaftsministerium consi<strong>de</strong>red rightly that the problem <strong>of</strong> social<br />

harmonization was political. The Ministry was on the other hand wrong when assuming<br />

that the French government ma<strong>de</strong> use <strong>of</strong> this question in or<strong>de</strong>r to prevent<br />

the setting up <strong>of</strong> a common market that they were opposed to. Still, that was what<br />

they believed, and from that point <strong>of</strong> view Germany was now confronted with two<br />

possible options. On the one hand, they could by means <strong>of</strong> an appropriate investigation<br />

do away with the problem and simultaneously provi<strong>de</strong> the French supporters<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Common Market with arguments against their opponents. On the other hand,<br />

it could be that the French were out to bring the negotiations to an end over this<br />

question. In that case the matter would have to be treated in a way that ensured that<br />

France was left with the blame, and in a way that guaranteed that Germany could<br />

not be accused <strong>of</strong> being socially reactionary. In Ludwig Erhard’s opinion the<br />

French claims were impossible, but in first instance they would still have to be met.<br />

He was convinced <strong>of</strong> the need to bring the topic up to the highest political level. 78<br />

This was also what finally happened.<br />

Prior to this, the French upped the stakes in or<strong>de</strong>r to get their way. When the<br />

<strong>de</strong>legations met in Brussels on July 26 Faure urged quick action, emphasizing the<br />

positive climate created by the recent <strong>de</strong>bate over Euratom in the National Assembly.<br />

He stressed the fact that a governmental crisis could provoke a situation that<br />

would give the opponents <strong>of</strong> a common market time to organize. However, his efforts<br />

were fruitless. A <strong>de</strong>cision was taken to postpone the question <strong>of</strong> social harmonization<br />

until the beginning <strong>of</strong> September when the heads <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>legations were to<br />

present their objections to the system for social harmonization envisaged in the<br />

Spaak-report. 79 When the <strong>de</strong>legations met again on September 13 Faure procee<strong>de</strong>d<br />

in a more <strong>de</strong>cisive manner. This time he stressed the special difficulties faced by<br />

75. BA, B146/594a, Kurzprotokoll über die Ressortbesprechung vom 3. Juli 1956 im Auswärtigen Amt.<br />

76. Ibid.<br />

77. BA, B146/594a, Harmonisierung <strong>de</strong>r Soziallasten im Gemeinsamen Markt, 10.07.56.<br />

78. BA, B146/594a, Ressortbesprechung über Angleichung <strong>de</strong>r Soziallasten im Gemeinsamen Markt<br />

bei Herrn Minister Erhard am 25.07.1956.<br />

79. BA, B146/593, Kurzprotokoll über die Ressortbesprechung vom 27.07.56 im Auswärtigen Amt.


100<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

France where the <strong>de</strong>mands <strong>of</strong> war had created price-disparities. He also stressed the<br />

strong political will to see a common market come true that inclu<strong>de</strong>d France. In or<strong>de</strong>r<br />

to obtain this he suggested a special agreement for France allowing the maintenance<br />

<strong>of</strong> her system <strong>of</strong> import duties and export support as long as price disparities<br />

existed. 80 When a few days later the French <strong>de</strong>legation presented the terms on<br />

which it would be possible for France to participate in the common market, the <strong>de</strong>mands<br />

were even more extensive. The <strong>de</strong>cision to pass from the first to the second<br />

stage <strong>of</strong> the transitional period was to be unanimous, and only to be taken when the<br />

objectives <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d upon had been reached. In the field <strong>of</strong> social harmonization,<br />

France <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d the realization <strong>of</strong> equal pay within a period <strong>of</strong> two years. Within<br />

this period, measures also had to be taken to ensure the harmonization <strong>of</strong> the length<br />

<strong>of</strong> the working week and corresponding overtime pay at the end <strong>of</strong> the first stage, as<br />

well as the harmonization <strong>of</strong> paid holidays. During the following stages, measures<br />

were to be taken in or<strong>de</strong>r to harmonize total wage charges. 81<br />

The French terms met vivid opposition. This was particularly the case with the<br />

claim for the harmonization <strong>of</strong> total wage charges. As far as the question <strong>of</strong> equal<br />

pay was concerned, the countries agreed that this seemed to constitute a specific<br />

distortion that could find its solution through the system <strong>of</strong> safeguard clauses as<br />

proposed in the Spaak-report. In the matter <strong>of</strong> paid holidays, the countries agreed<br />

that this was unproblematic. To the question <strong>of</strong> harmonized overtime pay, a solution<br />

was still to be found. The heads <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>legation seemed ready to accord France a<br />

regime <strong>of</strong> export-subsidies and import-taxes on special conditions. The French <strong>de</strong>legation<br />

argued on its si<strong>de</strong> for the additional possibility <strong>of</strong> introducing safeguard<br />

clauses in case <strong>of</strong> a <strong>de</strong>ficit in the balance <strong>of</strong> payments. This did not please the other<br />

<strong>de</strong>legations. It appeared, however, as if some solution was to be reached. 82<br />

On October 20 and 21 the six states met to <strong>de</strong>al with the questions on which<br />

agreement had not yet been reached. At this meeting the question <strong>of</strong> social harmonization<br />

brought the negotiations to a point that threatened to break them <strong>of</strong>f in<br />

their entirety. This was not due to the other five, since they showed consi<strong>de</strong>rable<br />

will to reach a solution, but to the French who constantly came up with new <strong>de</strong>mands.<br />

The five agreed that France could maintain export-subsidies and import-taxes<br />

in the transitional period un<strong>de</strong>r certain conditions. Safeguard-clauses<br />

were furthermore to be invoked in case <strong>of</strong> problems with the balance <strong>of</strong> payments.<br />

It was when discussing the terms for passing from the first to the second stage<br />

<strong>of</strong> the transitional period that a critical point was reached. France insisted that the<br />

<strong>de</strong>cision had to be unanimous. The other <strong>de</strong>legations favoured qualified majority.<br />

After a long break and the intervention <strong>of</strong> the French Prime Minister a compromise<br />

was reached. This said that the first stage was to last for four years. If a country<br />

found that the targets set for the first stage were not reached, it would be able to<br />

80. BA, B 146/593, Brüsseler Integrationskonferenz; Delegationsleiterausschuss, Sitzung vom 13. September.<br />

81. MAE, DE-CE 1945-60, 610, Mémorandum du Prési<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>de</strong> la Conférence Intergouvernementale<br />

pour le Marché Commun et l’Euratom, 12.10.56.<br />

82. Ibid.


France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community 101<br />

prevent the passing to stage two. Stage one was then to be prolonged by two years,<br />

after which the <strong>de</strong>cision to move to stage two was to be taken by a qualified majority.<br />

However, France then ma<strong>de</strong> it clear that in making her <strong>de</strong>cision on whether to<br />

move from stage one or not she would not only consi<strong>de</strong>r the question <strong>of</strong> social harmonization,<br />

but also the economic situation in its entirety. This provoked the German<br />

<strong>de</strong>legation, who refused to continue the negotiations if France did not accept<br />

the qualified majority voting, nor would the Germans continue the Euratom negotiations.<br />

They also <strong>de</strong>clared themselves unable to accept the proposition concerning<br />

the length <strong>of</strong> the working week and corresponding overtime pay. 83<br />

On the surface a resolution appeared impossible. Un<strong>of</strong>ficial discussions revealed<br />

however, that a solution that did not inclu<strong>de</strong> France was consi<strong>de</strong>red impossible. 84 A solution<br />

was reached when the German chancellor A<strong>de</strong>nauer met with Prime Minister<br />

Mollet in Paris on November 6.<br />

As far as equal pay and paid holidays were concerned, the two heads <strong>of</strong> state sustained<br />

the formula from the conference in Paris in October. They further agreed on a general formula<br />

on social harmonization saying that this would come as a consequence <strong>of</strong> the common<br />

market. On the question <strong>of</strong> special regulations for France, France accepted an annual<br />

investigation into the conditions for maintaining such regulations. The Council <strong>of</strong> Ministers<br />

would also be empowered to <strong>de</strong>mand a lowering <strong>of</strong> the French level <strong>of</strong> taxes and subsidies<br />

if other countries were to be unfairly treated by this system. If this turned out to be<br />

the case, countries negatively affected by the French regulations could also be allowed to<br />

invoke safeguard clauses. France agreed to abolish the system when her balance <strong>of</strong> payments<br />

had been in equilibrium for a year. On the difficult question concerning the length<br />

<strong>of</strong> the work-week and corresponding overtime pay, the countries agreed not to make the<br />

introduction <strong>of</strong> the forty hour week obligatory. 85 In spite <strong>of</strong> this <strong>de</strong>cision, the German<br />

view was that they had ma<strong>de</strong> a consi<strong>de</strong>rable concession. This because one knew for certain<br />

that the forty hour week would not be a reality within the first stage. France would as<br />

a consequence be entitled to safeguard clauses working to the advantage <strong>of</strong> French industry.<br />

86 France renounced, on her si<strong>de</strong>, the claim for veto in connection with the passing<br />

from the first to the second stage <strong>of</strong> the transitional period.<br />

The Franco-German agreement has been <strong>de</strong>scribed as a “… recul sensible <strong>de</strong>s positions<br />

françaises; sur tous les points jusque là posés en préalables, les engagements précis<br />

font place à <strong>de</strong>s déclarations d’intention ou à <strong>de</strong>s formules <strong>de</strong> compromis assez vagues”. 87<br />

83. BA, B146/594, Aussenministerkonferenz <strong>de</strong>r Län<strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>r Montanunion über <strong>de</strong>n Gemeinsamen<br />

Markt und Euratom am 20 u. 21 Oktober in Paris.<br />

84. Ibid.<br />

85. BA, B146/594, Ergebnisprotokoll über die Ressortbesprechung im Auswärtigen Amt am 10. November<br />

über die Probleme <strong>de</strong>s Gemeinsamen Marktes und Euratom.<br />

86. BA, B 146/594, Brüsseler Regierungskonferenz-Ergebnisse <strong>de</strong>r vom Bun<strong>de</strong>skanzler am 5. und<br />

6.11.1956 in Paris geführten Besprechungen über die Probleme <strong>de</strong>s Gemeinsamen Marktes und<br />

Euratom. 12.11.56.<br />

87. P. GUILLEN, L’europe remè<strong>de</strong> à l’impuissance française? Le gouvernement Guy Mollet et la négociation<br />

<strong>de</strong>s traités <strong>de</strong> Rome (1955-1957), in: Revue d’histoire diplomatique, 102(1988),<br />

pp.319-335, p.331. See also W. LOTH: Deutsche und französische Interessen …, op.cit.,<br />

pp.181-182.


102<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

While France undoubtedly obtained less than she had asked for, what she obtained was<br />

what she nee<strong>de</strong>d. French policy-makers had consi<strong>de</strong>red acceptance <strong>of</strong> the common market<br />

proposal unlikely. They had done so because <strong>of</strong> the hostility that existed within France<br />

to the removal <strong>of</strong> protection that membership <strong>of</strong> the common market seemed to imply.<br />

Continued protection was as a consequence consi<strong>de</strong>red a necessity if the treaty on the<br />

common market was to get through Parliament. Through the November agreement with<br />

Germany, France obtained an agreement that secured continued protection <strong>of</strong> French industry.<br />

88 The fact that France gave up her claim for veto in or<strong>de</strong>r to obtain this agreement,<br />

supports the affirmation that this agreement was <strong>of</strong> importance.<br />

Concluding Remarks<br />

The story <strong>of</strong> the French claims for social harmonization illustrates how France<br />

aimed to use the process <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> as a means to ensure a continued<br />

expansion and mo<strong>de</strong>rnization <strong>of</strong> the French economy. The claims for social harmonization<br />

were in turn instrumental in realizing France’s entry into the common market.<br />

In the beginning, these claims bought time for a government divi<strong>de</strong>d over the<br />

question <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>. In the end, they ensured continued protection for<br />

French industry. In the final discussions over this question, France pr<strong>of</strong>ited from the<br />

fact that other countries consi<strong>de</strong>red French membership <strong>of</strong> the common market a<br />

necessity. In the November 6 agreement with Germany, this enabled her to tra<strong>de</strong><br />

their wish for qualified majority voting in return for continued protection <strong>of</strong> French<br />

industry. At national level the maintenance <strong>of</strong> this protection was conducive to<br />

securing the support <strong>of</strong> French industry, and consequently the support <strong>of</strong> the<br />

National Assembly for the government’s pro-European policy.<br />

88. Philippe Mioche shows that head <strong>of</strong> the CNPF, Georges Villiers, set great store by the concessions<br />

obtained and that the agreement was instrumental in turning hesitant industrialists in favour <strong>of</strong> the<br />

common market. Ph. MIOCHE, Le patronat français …, op.cit., p.253.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and<br />

British Policy towards Scandinavia 1949-1951<br />

103<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

Throughout the past half-century <strong>of</strong> European economic and political <strong>integration</strong>, Britain<br />

and Scandinavia have formed a stronghold for “Euro-scepticism”, where reluctance<br />

and outright opposition to new i<strong>de</strong>as about co-operation amongst the European<br />

nation-states has been wi<strong>de</strong>spread. Britain, Denmark and Swe<strong>de</strong>n have been latecomers<br />

in the present day European Union (EU), whereas in Norway the question <strong>of</strong> European<br />

Economic Community (EEC) or EU membership has been rejected twice in national<br />

referenda. Whether in- or outsi<strong>de</strong> these organisations their relationship with more<br />

ar<strong>de</strong>nt Europeans has been problematic over a long period.<br />

Not least because their paths joined in the European Free Tra<strong>de</strong> Association<br />

(EFTA) in 1959-60, the British and the Scandinavians have <strong>of</strong>ten been seen to have<br />

drawn a sense <strong>of</strong> unity from the fact that they all were in the 1950s, for various reasons,<br />

unable to participate in such integrative experiments as the European Coal<br />

and Steel Community (ECSC) or later in the EEC. The similarities in their behaviour<br />

have led to assumptions that even more wi<strong>de</strong>-ranging convergence <strong>of</strong> interests<br />

between the British and the Scandinavians has existed since Europe's economic reconstruction<br />

began in the 1940s.<br />

British and Scandinavian scepticism towards new forms <strong>of</strong> economic and political<br />

co-operation in Europe in the 1950s was embed<strong>de</strong>d in national circumstances<br />

and preferences, but was coupled with their shared feeling <strong>of</strong> the feasibility <strong>of</strong> an<br />

intergovernmental alternative towards economic co-operation in Europe in the<br />

1950s. Further, instead <strong>of</strong> withdrawing into complete isolation, it has been argued<br />

that they sought “meaningful association” with the new institutions, and as can be<br />

seen in the following, with each other. 1 What is argued in the following is, that this<br />

basic convergence <strong>of</strong> interests in the early phase <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> brought<br />

the British, Danish, Swedish and Norwegian governments together into regular<br />

consultations within a specifically established body, Uniscan, which sought to facilitate<br />

a <strong>de</strong>gree <strong>of</strong> co-ordination <strong>of</strong> policies and eventually paved the way for the<br />

speedy establishment <strong>of</strong> EFTA in 1959, when the alternative to create a wi<strong>de</strong>r free<br />

tra<strong>de</strong> area had been exhausted.<br />

None the less, before EFTA realised the original vision outlined in 1949, attempts<br />

towards <strong>de</strong>eper Anglo-Scandinavian economic co-operation beyond the<br />

consultative remit <strong>of</strong> Uniscan proved unsuccessful. In spite <strong>of</strong> similar thinking<br />

about the most fruitful approach to <strong>integration</strong> policies in Europe, co-ordinated policy-making<br />

and the <strong>de</strong>finition <strong>of</strong> collective bargaining positions within and towards<br />

1. On the ‘meaningful association’–thesis concerning British policy, see Chr. LORD, ’With but not<br />

<strong>of</strong>’: Britain and the Schuman Plan, A Reinterpretation, in: Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History<br />

(JEIH), 2/4(1998), pp.23-46, and Chr. LORD, Absent at the Creation: Britain and the Formation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the European Community, 1950-52, Darthmout, Al<strong>de</strong>rshot, 1996.


104<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

different international organisations was found difficult. The following article discusses<br />

the potential and the ramifications <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian co-operation in<br />

the post-Second World War international economy and in the early years <strong>of</strong> European<br />

<strong>integration</strong>, with particular attention to British policy-making.<br />

Reconstruction and Restoration: Attempts to Re-establish Britain's<br />

Economic Positions in Scandinavia after 1945<br />

British economic thinking towards Scandinavia after the Second World War was<br />

characterised by the persistence <strong>of</strong> traditional views, which posited Scandinavia<br />

apart from the rest <strong>of</strong> Western Europe. Scandinavia was in many ways a special<br />

case, culturally and politically different from the continent, and what was most<br />

important, an enclave – in European standards – <strong>of</strong> unexceptionally high economic<br />

inter<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce with Britain.<br />

Although neither the continental European economies nor Scandinavia could challenge<br />

the primacy <strong>of</strong> the Dominions, the Commonwealth and the Sterling area in Britain's<br />

overseas tra<strong>de</strong> in the 1940s and 1950s, the three Scandinavian countries, Norway,<br />

Denmark and Swe<strong>de</strong>n, figured prominently in the economic geography <strong>of</strong> Europe as it<br />

was interpreted at the time in London. In 1946-53, the three Scandinavian countries had<br />

an average share <strong>of</strong> 7.4 per cent <strong>of</strong> Britain's overseas tra<strong>de</strong>, while the area that would<br />

later become the EEC amounted to no more than 11.1 per cent. 2<br />

The close relationship between the Scandinavian economies with Britain and<br />

the network <strong>of</strong> bilateral tra<strong>de</strong> agreements and financial arrangements that were established<br />

between the Sterling bloc and Scandinavia in the 1930s, ma<strong>de</strong> its position<br />

in British eyes to resemble more that <strong>of</strong> the Commonwealth than <strong>of</strong> Europe. Scandinavia<br />

could be seen in the vague terms <strong>of</strong> the “informal empire”, as was <strong>de</strong>scribed<br />

by Ashton Gwatkin <strong>of</strong> the Foreign Office when he interpreted it before the<br />

war to have formed “a kind <strong>of</strong> unacknowledged economic empire <strong>of</strong> which London<br />

is the metropolis”. 3 Intense competition with Adolf Hitler's economically expansive<br />

Germany in the 1930s merely heightened long-held views that Britain's concerns<br />

in the region were primarily economic, and that the essence <strong>of</strong> foreign policy,<br />

when it came to Scandinavia, was about tra<strong>de</strong>, finance and the maintenance <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

spheres <strong>of</strong> influence. 4<br />

2. Bulletins Statistiques <strong>de</strong> l'OECE, Commerce Exterieur, Série I, 1928, 1937-1953, Paris, 1954,<br />

pp.62-67.<br />

3. Quoted in P. LUDLOW, Britain and Northern Europe, 1940-1945, in: Scandinavian Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

History (SJH), 4/2(1979), pp.123-62. Ashton Gwatkin was an economic specialist in the Foreign<br />

Office (FO).<br />

4. A comprehensive account <strong>of</strong> economic and strategic competition between Britain and Germany in<br />

Scandinavia before 1940 is found in P. SALMON, Scandinavia and the Great Powers 1890-1940,<br />

Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, 1997.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy 105<br />

As soon as wartime conditions permitted it in 1944-45, Britain reasserted its economic<br />

positions in the region, including Finland where substantial amounts <strong>of</strong> timber<br />

and pulp were exported to Britain. Alongsi<strong>de</strong> Danish foodstuffs Swe<strong>de</strong>n in particular<br />

became a tra<strong>de</strong> partner <strong>of</strong> prime importance. With its strong balance <strong>of</strong> payments position<br />

it affor<strong>de</strong>d Britain exports <strong>of</strong> vital raw materials effectively on credit in 1945-47, as<br />

the Swedish government and central bank hoped that the transitory period would not<br />

last for too long. 5 New financial ties that persisted long into the 1950s were thus established<br />

between Britain and the Scandinavians in the name <strong>of</strong> economic stabilisation, reconstruction<br />

and the hope for gradual normalisation <strong>of</strong> relations.<br />

The other si<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong> the British economic strategy towards Scandinavia was an attempt<br />

to seize a commanding share <strong>of</strong> the northern markets for industrial goods as<br />

long as German exporters were absent from the markets. 6 However, due to shortages<br />

<strong>of</strong> exportable goods such as coal and steel and <strong>de</strong>clining competitiveness <strong>of</strong> British<br />

manufacturers, this strategy eventually failed to win such a prepon<strong>de</strong>rant position<br />

for British tra<strong>de</strong>rs as had been envisaged. A good example <strong>of</strong> Britain’s<br />

economic <strong>de</strong>cline in the region was how its shipbuilding industry lost its most important<br />

export market – Norway – in 1945-67 when the world market for ships was<br />

most vibrant. 7 None the less, still until the first half <strong>of</strong> the 1950s when German<br />

competition was being fully felt again, the British managed to hold an unexceptionally<br />

strong economic position in the region, if not much longer.<br />

The Scandinavians, for their part, saw their post-war relationship with Great<br />

Britain with certain ambivalence. An important characteristic <strong>of</strong> their economic relationship<br />

with Britain was that it was more important for them than it was for the<br />

British. The direct economic benefits from normal tra<strong>de</strong> relations with Britain were<br />

clear enough, as the ongoing processes <strong>of</strong> mo<strong>de</strong>rnisation <strong>of</strong> the Scandinavian economies<br />

and societies <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>d on their access to world markets <strong>of</strong> industrial goods<br />

and raw materials in scarce supply within the region itself, and on their ability to<br />

sell their own produce as freely as possible to the world. Foreign tra<strong>de</strong> in general<br />

and tra<strong>de</strong> with Britain in particular was vital for all the Scandinavian economies,<br />

which even in times <strong>of</strong> heavy protectionism remained open economies in the sense<br />

<strong>of</strong> their high <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce on international in- and outputs <strong>of</strong> factors <strong>of</strong> production. 8<br />

5. Ö. APPELQVIST, Bruten Brygga. Gunnar Myrdal och Sveriges ekonomiska efterkrigspolitik<br />

1943-1947, Santérus förlag, Stockholm, 2000, pp.340-350.<br />

6. Memorandum for M. L. John Edwards, MP (Parliamentary private secretary to the presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the Board <strong>of</strong><br />

Tra<strong>de</strong>), undated (1945), FO 371/56223; Memorandum for Mr. Marquand (Secretary for the Department <strong>of</strong><br />

Overseas Tra<strong>de</strong>, Board <strong>of</strong> Tra<strong>de</strong>), 27 December 1945, FO 371/56223, Public Record Office (PRO), London.<br />

7. L. JOHNMAN and H. MURPHY, The Norwegian Market for British Shipbuilding, 1945-1967, in:<br />

Scandinavian Economic History Review, 2/XLVI(1998), pp.55-78. Issues such as price, failure to<br />

meet <strong>de</strong>livery dates and to <strong>of</strong>fer competitive credit terms are listed as explanatory factors for the<br />

<strong>de</strong>cline. Britain’s market share was taken over by Norwegian, West German, Japanese and Swedish<br />

shipyards.<br />

8. A sophisticated analysis <strong>of</strong> tra<strong>de</strong> protectionism in an open economy is found in T. PAAVONEN,<br />

Suomalaisen protektionismin viimeinen vaihe. Suomen ulkomaankauppa- ja integraatiopolitiikka<br />

1945-1961 [Finnish Protectionism and International Economic Integration, 1945-1961], Suomen<br />

Historiallinen Seura, Helsinki, 1998.


106<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

Politically most sensitive issues about Britain's post-war economic reconstruction<br />

emerged from the attempts by the British government to restore pre-war arrangements<br />

that were based on bilateralism and the implicit assertion that Scandinavia should be<br />

held as a special preserve for British tra<strong>de</strong>rs. In the absence <strong>of</strong> Germany as an economic<br />

counterweight, the situation could be seen as an attempt to inclu<strong>de</strong> Scandinavia within<br />

Britain's economic sphere <strong>of</strong> influence.<br />

A key element in the future <strong>of</strong> the Anglo-Scandinavian economic relationship<br />

when reconstruction reached its final phase in the early 1950s was to what direction<br />

the traditional, in tra<strong>de</strong> theoretical terms classical, complementary pattern <strong>of</strong> the<br />

national economies would <strong>de</strong>velop. Eventually, the failure <strong>of</strong> the British economy<br />

to create a surplus <strong>of</strong> strategic raw materials such as coal and steel in the 1950s and<br />

the simultaneous process <strong>of</strong> diversification <strong>of</strong> Scandinavian exports away from the<br />

<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce on basic raw materials (iron ore, pulp, paper, timber, agricultural produce)<br />

and semi-finished industrial goods towards more highly refined goods, <strong>de</strong>creased<br />

the complementary nature <strong>of</strong> the British and Scandinavian economies. But<br />

even with such structural changes and the relatively slow <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> intra-industrial<br />

tra<strong>de</strong> within the region, the volume <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian tra<strong>de</strong> in the traditional<br />

sectors remained high, and was eventually enhanced by EFTA, albeit its<br />

growth potential was limited compared to emerging economic contacts and intra-industrial<br />

tra<strong>de</strong> between Britain and Western Europe.<br />

Scandinavia as a Lead in Britain's European Policy 1949-50<br />

The i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> a special institutional arrangement between Britain and Scandinavia<br />

was a recurrent theme in British thinking <strong>of</strong> its European policy and external economic<br />

relations. It was seen in various occasions in Anglo-Scandinavian economic<br />

diplomacy from the end <strong>of</strong> the Second World War in 1945 to the British Free Tra<strong>de</strong><br />

Area proposals in 1957. But until full restoration <strong>of</strong> currency convertibility and<br />

multilateral tra<strong>de</strong> was realised towards the end <strong>of</strong> the 1950s, not much <strong>of</strong> tangible<br />

economic significance was achieved within the Anglo-Scandinavian framework.<br />

Likewise, the plans for a Scandinavian Customs Union, which were discussed<br />

intermittently between 1947-50 and in 1954-57 between Norway, Denmark and<br />

Swe<strong>de</strong>n, en<strong>de</strong>d in failure and were eventually overtaken by the establishment <strong>of</strong><br />

EEC and EFTA, although other aspects <strong>of</strong> Nordic co-operation, such as the creation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Nordic Council in 1952 and a common labour market in 1954 proved to be<br />

more successful aspects <strong>of</strong> regional economic <strong>integration</strong>. 9<br />

9. V. SØRENSEN, Nordic cooperation – A Social Democratic Alternative to Europe?, in: T. B.<br />

OLESEN (ed.), Inter<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce Versus Integration. Denmark, Scandinavia and Western Europe,<br />

1945-1960, O<strong>de</strong>nse University Press, O<strong>de</strong>nse, 1995, pp.40-61; I. SOGNER, The European I<strong>de</strong>a:<br />

The Scandinavian Answer. Norwegian Attitu<strong>de</strong>s Towards a Closer Scandinavian Economic Cooperation<br />

1947-1959, in: SJH, 4/18(1993), pp.307-327.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy 107<br />

Despite political goodwill behind the plans and numerous studies, Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

economic co-operation never took <strong>of</strong>f the ground before EFTA. None the<br />

less, from the viewpoint <strong>of</strong> British European policy in the 1950s, the plans for<br />

<strong>de</strong>epening its economic and political relations with the Scandinavians are not wholly<br />

insignificant, even if they lacked the final push success would have required.<br />

Similarly, the talks the Scandinavian governments held with the British, first on European<br />

economic reconstruction and later on <strong>integration</strong> policy were a substantial<br />

part <strong>of</strong> their general policy towards Europe as well.<br />

The period in 1949-51, when most pressing needs <strong>of</strong> reconstruction began to give<br />

way to long-term schemes <strong>of</strong> Europe's politico-economic or<strong>de</strong>r, is particularly illuminating<br />

in highlighting both the potential and the problems Anglo-Scandinavian economic<br />

co-operation contained. The British government's so called Uniscan-initiative<br />

from late 1949 is a good example <strong>of</strong> the ways in which Scandinavia was seen to fit in<br />

Britain's overall European policy at the time. The internal discussions in London and<br />

the subsequent negotiations that were held in December 1949 and January 1950 with<br />

the Scandinavian governments, showed what political benefits the British government<br />

sought from its closer association with them. The following years showed how severe<br />

the economic ramifications proved to be. However, <strong>de</strong>spite the inherent problems <strong>of</strong><br />

Anglo-Scandinavian economic co-operation that were soon realised, the continuing<br />

work <strong>of</strong> the Anglo-Scandinavian Economic Committee, Uniscan (1950-60), was valued<br />

as an informal consultative group where it was ascertained to which extent these countries<br />

could or could not agree upon a common line towards various problems <strong>of</strong> international<br />

economic policy and <strong>integration</strong>. 10<br />

The i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> re-establishing the pre-war relationship between Scandinavia and<br />

the sterling area surfaced soon after the war. Nevertheless, before 1949 neither specific<br />

plans nor written documents were presented. Schemes for closer co-operation<br />

in the economic field between Britain and the three Scandinavian countries were<br />

first put forward at an <strong>of</strong>ficial level in the Treasury in January 1949, after a suggestion<br />

from the Bank <strong>of</strong> England. 11 As had been done privately before, <strong>of</strong>ficials then<br />

10. Previous authors have been unanimous <strong>of</strong> Uniscan's neglible economic impact, and largely dismissed<br />

it without consi<strong>de</strong>ring its possible political significance. W. DIEBOLD Jr., Tra<strong>de</strong> and Payments<br />

in Western Europe. A Study in Economic Cooperation 1947-51, Harper & Brothers, New<br />

York, 1952, pp.143-144; B. STRÅTH, Nordic Industry and Nordic Economic Cooperation. The<br />

Nordic Industrial Fe<strong>de</strong>rations and the Nordic Customs Union Negotiations 1947-1959, Almqvist<br />

& Wiksell International, Stockholm, 1978, pp.87-92; A. MILWARD, The Reconstruction <strong>of</strong> Western<br />

Europe 1945-51, Routledge, London, 1984, pp.316-319; M. AF MALMBORG, Den ståndaktiga<br />

nationalstaten. Sverige och <strong>de</strong>n västeuropeiska intergrationen 1945-1959, Lund University<br />

Press, Lund, 1994, pp.91-92; K. E. ERIKSEN and H. Ø. PHARO, Kald krig <strong>of</strong> internasjonalisering<br />

1949-1965. Norsk Utenrikspolitikks historie Bind 5, Cappelen, Oslo, 1997, pp.143-145. For a<br />

discussion <strong>of</strong> Uniscan’s relationship to Britain’s cold war policy aims in Northern Europe, see J.<br />

AUNESLUOMA, Britain, Swe<strong>de</strong>n and the Cold War 1945-54, pp. 152-202. Unpublished D.Phil–<br />

thesis, University <strong>of</strong> Oxford, 1998, (to be published by Palgrave Macmillan in 2002).<br />

11. E. W. Playfair (Treasury) (T) to Rowe-Dutton (T), 13 January 1949, T 236/5370, PRO; Playfair to<br />

George Bolton (Bank <strong>of</strong> England), 17 January 1949; Lithiby minute, 21 January 1949, OV 28/31,<br />

Bank <strong>of</strong> England Archive (BEA), London. See also Playfair to Allan Christelow (UK Treasury <strong>de</strong>legation,<br />

Washington), 20 December 1949, FO 371/78139, PRO.


108<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

played with an i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> some kind <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian economic association, or<br />

<strong>of</strong> Scandinavian membership <strong>of</strong> the Sterling area. But it was not until October 1949<br />

before the question <strong>of</strong> Scandinavia's relationship to the Sterling area and closer<br />

co-operation with Britain was put forward to the Cabinet and subsequently adopted<br />

as <strong>of</strong>ficial policy. 12<br />

There were several reasons why different <strong>de</strong>partments in Whitehall opened the<br />

issue <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian economic co-operation in the autumn <strong>of</strong> 1949. The<br />

immediate reason for calling up the representatives <strong>of</strong> the countries to discuss further<br />

economic co-operation was provi<strong>de</strong>d by the US economic aid administration<br />

(ECA), when it increased pressure for the establishment <strong>of</strong> regional economic<br />

groups in Europe. In October 1949, the ECA chief, Paul H<strong>of</strong>fman, <strong>de</strong>livered a<br />

strongly wor<strong>de</strong>d speech for the Ministerial Council <strong>of</strong> the Organisation for European<br />

Economic Co-operation (OEEC), in which he said that the US Congress would<br />

not accept continuance <strong>of</strong> the recovery program without clear <strong>de</strong>termination by the<br />

Europeans to move towards economic <strong>integration</strong>. 13 On 2 November, the Ministerial<br />

Council <strong>of</strong> the OEEC adopted a resolution, in which “the <strong>de</strong>sirability was recognised<br />

<strong>of</strong> promoting regional economic groupings”. 14 From the US viewpoint, this<br />

seemed on the short term to open the best prospects for further <strong>integration</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European economies. At the same time as American thinking was veering in favour<br />

<strong>of</strong> regional arrangements in Europe, the French finally changed si<strong>de</strong>s in the longstanding<br />

Anglo-American dispute over the character and ultimate goals <strong>of</strong> the<br />

OEEC, and joined the Benelux-countries and Italy in exploring further economic<br />

co-operation outlined in the Finebel/Fritalux proposals. 15 This meant that the British<br />

were left alone with the Scandinavians in opposing the increasingly influential<br />

and better-consolidated Franco-American axis within OEEC.<br />

12. Playfair to A. P. Grafftey-Smith (Bank <strong>of</strong> England), 11 October 1949, T 236/5370; Closer Economic<br />

Association between Scandinavia and the Sterling Area, Report by the Official Committee<br />

on Economic Development, 28 November 1949, ER(L)(49)321, CAB 134/245, PRO. Once the<br />

plan was announced British <strong>journal</strong>ists christened it as Uniscan. Other names given by <strong>journal</strong>ists<br />

inclu<strong>de</strong>d Ukiscan, Uniskan, Scandanglia, Scanuk, Brisk (in Norway) or L'uniscan and Uniscam (in<br />

France). These names compared well with such contemporaries as Franebel, Finebel, Fritaluxal,<br />

Fraswitaluxal, Benefrit or Benefit. Cripps said that it was a 'scandangle' that such names should be<br />

allowed at all. Cripps' speech to the Treasury staff, 11.1.1950, Sir Stafford Cripps Papers, Nuffield<br />

College, Oxford. Cripps's own favourite would have been 'Skanuk', as it remin<strong>de</strong>d him <strong>of</strong> 'a viking<br />

war cry'. G. HÄGGLÖF, Fre<strong>de</strong>ns Vägar, P.A. Norstedt & Söners Förlag, Stockholm, 1973, p.179.<br />

13. UK OEEC telegram no.1224 to FO, 30 October 1949, FO 371/7802, PRO; M. HOGAN, The Marshall<br />

Plan. America, Britain, and the reconstruction <strong>of</strong> Western Europe, 1947-1952, Cambridge<br />

University Press, Cambridge, 1987, pp.273-276; M. AF MALMBORG, Den ståndaktiga nationalstaten<br />

…, op.cit., pp.90-91.<br />

14. Henniker memorandum, 'Regional Economic Groupings. I Closer Economic Association between<br />

Norway, Swe<strong>de</strong>n, Denmark, the United Kingdom and the Sterling Area', 12 December 1949, FO<br />

371/78139, PRO.<br />

15. G. BOSSUAT, La France, l'ai<strong>de</strong> américaine et la construction européenne 1944-1954, vol.II,<br />

Ministère <strong>de</strong>s Finances, Paris, 1992, pp.707-712. See also R. T. GRIFFITHS & F. M. B. LYNCH,<br />

The Fritalux/Finebel Negotiations 1949/1950, European University Institute, Florence, 1984.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy 109<br />

The potential emergence <strong>of</strong> regional economic arrangements in Europe highlighted<br />

Britain's problematic position. As the supranational alternative was dismissed in Britain<br />

and its conditional “contract out <strong>of</strong> Europe” prepared, relations with the Scandinavians<br />

were discussed too. A wi<strong>de</strong> consensus existed in Whitehall that in the new situation it was<br />

important to maintain Britain's close relations with Scandinavia, whatever the future relationship<br />

between the continental countries and Britain should be. A contract out <strong>of</strong> the so<br />

called “Little Europe” <strong>of</strong> the Six, which had only a limited bearing for the British economy,<br />

should not be a similar contract out <strong>of</strong> Scandinavia. To maintain Britain's links with<br />

the Scandinavians, which were not presumed to participate in such schemes as the Finebel<br />

negotiations or later in 1950 in the Schuman and the Pleven plans, was a policy objective<br />

that was in British eyes both politically feasible and economically necessary. However, as<br />

discussions in late 1949 and early 1950 revealed, British policy-makers had more<br />

far-reaching goals too about the political utility <strong>of</strong> an opening towards Scandinavia.<br />

The <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> Britain's political and economic relations with Scandinavia<br />

seemed to <strong>of</strong>fer Britain a unique opportunity. As E. W. Playfair presented the Treasury<br />

view in October 1949, the <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> closer relations with Scandinavia<br />

may have been “the only means <strong>of</strong> avoiding being faced by a United Europe which<br />

we either have to keep out or get into”. 16 Scandinavia, according to this reasoning,<br />

could <strong>of</strong>fer an alternative route to formulate Britain's Europeanness in political and<br />

economic terms. From the political point <strong>of</strong> view, a step ahead on the Scandinavian<br />

front seemed to bring certain advantages both as to allay US suspicions <strong>of</strong> British<br />

procrastination in further economic <strong>integration</strong> in Europe, and to bring the Scandinavians<br />

closer to Britain by economic means. The economic motivations <strong>of</strong> Britain's<br />

Scandinavian opening arose from the perceived need to achieve a wi<strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>gree<br />

<strong>of</strong> liberalisation in the unflexible current trading situation, especially in the<br />

field <strong>of</strong> finance and payments. The bilateral, annual tra<strong>de</strong> negotiations framework<br />

was politically troublesome and any steps towards increased flexibility were welcomed<br />

in Britain and in Scandinavia. 17 The Norwegians in particular were keen to<br />

gain access to the capital markets <strong>of</strong> Britain, and to a lesser extent, in Swe<strong>de</strong>n,<br />

which could only be achieved through special arrangements. Furthermore, in the<br />

OEEC-wi<strong>de</strong> liberalisation process and in the talks leading to the European Payments<br />

Union (EPU), the British were keen to enlist the Scandinavians on their si<strong>de</strong>.<br />

The general approach <strong>of</strong> the British and the Scandinavian governments towards questions<br />

<strong>de</strong>alt with in the OEEC had been very similar in 1948-49, but in 1950 a rift opened<br />

between low-tariff countries such as Swe<strong>de</strong>n and Denmark and the British, who sought<br />

further tra<strong>de</strong> liberalisation through curtailing import restrictions which the low-tariff countries<br />

relied upon. 18 However, in organisational questions, they had all been firmly against<br />

the i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> a strong in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt supranational bureaucracy or the suggestion <strong>of</strong> a “super-<br />

16. Playfair to Copleston, 26 October 1949, T 236/5370, PRO.<br />

17. Address by Sir Henry Wilson Smith, December 1949, HP Å 64, vol.HP 2216, Utrikes<strong>de</strong>partement,<br />

1920 års dossiersystem, Riksarkivet (RA), Stockholm.<br />

18. V. SØRENSEN, Nordic cooperation …, op.cit., pp.40-61. Further on tra<strong>de</strong> liberalisation, W. A.<br />

BRUSSE, Tariffs, Tra<strong>de</strong> and European Integration, 1947-1957. From Study Group to Common<br />

Market, St Martin’s Press, New York, 1997.


110<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

man” as a head <strong>of</strong> the permanent organisation in 1947-49. 19 Their approach towards internal<br />

financial problems was remarkably similar too, save perhaps Denmark's lesser preoccupation<br />

with full employment policies. 20 Otherwise the domestic economic policy <strong>of</strong><br />

maintaining price stability in a full employment economy by Keynesian <strong>de</strong>mand management<br />

using budgetary means was common to these countries. Despite disagreements<br />

from 1950 onwards on the most suitable instruments <strong>of</strong> tra<strong>de</strong> liberalisation, in numerous<br />

cases, the British could find the Scandinavians on their si<strong>de</strong> in OEEC discussions on economic<br />

policy. This convergence <strong>of</strong> the basic economic outlook <strong>of</strong> the British and the<br />

Scandinavians was compoun<strong>de</strong>d with a more <strong>de</strong>liberate policy <strong>of</strong> co-operation among the<br />

OEEC <strong>de</strong>legations in Paris. At the same time when the Treasury and the Foreign Office<br />

consi<strong>de</strong>red the Uniscan-scheme in October 1949, the British representative to the OEEC,<br />

Edmund Hall-Patch, suggested that their co-operation should be <strong>de</strong>epened by some special<br />

arrangement within the Paris organisation too. 21<br />

When the Uniscan-plan was introduced in Whitehall in the autumn <strong>of</strong> 1949 enthusiasm<br />

was most pronounced at the Treasury and the Bank <strong>of</strong> England. 22 Foreign<br />

Office <strong>of</strong>ficials saw the merits <strong>of</strong> the plan too, and when Uniscan was established in<br />

January 1950, the Foreign Office support for it was based on calculations <strong>of</strong> the political<br />

usefulness <strong>of</strong> a special channel to the Scandinavians in policy-making, and<br />

when economic benefits failed to materialise from its work, the Foreign Office interest<br />

proved to be <strong>de</strong>cisive to its continuance.<br />

Above the <strong>of</strong>ficial level perhaps the most consistent proponent for closer Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

economic association in Britain during the Labour government<br />

was the Chancellor <strong>of</strong> Exchequer, Sir Stafford Cripps. Whereas Hall-Patch in the<br />

OEEC was an ar<strong>de</strong>nt supporter <strong>of</strong> closer Anglo-Scandinavian co-operation in organisational<br />

and practical questions <strong>of</strong> European economic co-operation, Cripps<br />

took a somewhat broa<strong>de</strong>r view. His assessment was based on what he saw to be the<br />

fundamental unity <strong>of</strong> interest Britain and Scandinavia shared towards the “general<br />

problem, which was inclu<strong>de</strong>d in the talk <strong>of</strong> “economic <strong>integration</strong>” or “unification<br />

<strong>of</strong> Europe”. 23 It seemed<br />

“that England and the Scandinavian countries had to a large <strong>de</strong>gree a common conception<br />

<strong>of</strong> the question <strong>of</strong> economic policy and that we <strong>of</strong>ten distanced ourselves<br />

from the Latin peoples in these questions”. 24<br />

Cripps's rather optimistic views <strong>of</strong> the fundamental similarity <strong>of</strong> outlook between<br />

the British and the Scandinavians in economic and social thinking reflected views that<br />

19. A. S. MILWARD, The Reconstruction …, op.cit., pp.171-211.<br />

20. 'The Internal Financial Policies <strong>of</strong> the Uniscan Countries', report by the Economic Section <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Cabinet Office, May 1950, FO 371/87090.<br />

21. Interview with Erik von Sydow (OEEC), 7 July 1970, Harry S. Truman Library, Oral History Interview<br />

Collection, In<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nce, Missouri. See further on relations between Hall-Patch and Dag<br />

Hammarskjöld, I. HÄGGLÖF, Drömmen om Europa, Norstedts, Värnamo, 1987, p.51.<br />

22. The Bank <strong>of</strong> England held that Treasury and FO enthusiasm behind the scheme was entirely based<br />

on political consi<strong>de</strong>rations. Lithiby minute, 8 November1949, OV 29/31, BEA.<br />

23. Cripps minute, 2 November 1949, T 236/5370, PRO; Östen Undén promemoria, 3 November<br />

1949, HP 64 Å. vol.HP 2216, RA.<br />

24. Ibid.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy 111<br />

were wi<strong>de</strong>ly held amongst British socialists in particular: “On the si<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong> the British Labour<br />

Party, illusions were rife about Scandinavia in general”, Alan Milward <strong>de</strong>scribed<br />

the socialists' “special relationship” over the North Sea in The Reconstruction <strong>of</strong> Western<br />

Europe 1945-51. 25 When the gap between the continent and Britain seemed to wi<strong>de</strong>n<br />

in 1949-51, both ministers and <strong>of</strong>ficials in London sought consolation from the presumed<br />

unity between Britain and the “like-min<strong>de</strong>d” people <strong>of</strong> the North, the<br />

“champions <strong>of</strong> the Welfare state”, or “our staunchest friends and allies in Europe”, as<br />

Roger Makins <strong>of</strong> the Foreign Office put it in the summer <strong>of</strong> 1951, witnessing that such<br />

notions were not confined to socialist circles only. 26<br />

Besi<strong>de</strong>s such a heightened sense <strong>of</strong> similarities between the British and Scandinavian<br />

“mentalités”, and whatever political implications these – undoubtedly sincerely<br />

held – views may have had, the plan Cripps put forward in November 1949<br />

was based on political and economic arguments. For Cripps, as was the case with<br />

<strong>of</strong>ficials in Whitehall as well, Anglo-Scandinavian co-operation was not just a tactical<br />

ploy to manoeuvre into better positions in the Ministerial Council <strong>of</strong> the OEEC<br />

or an act <strong>of</strong> solidarity among the brotherhood <strong>of</strong> socialists around the North Sea.<br />

An opening towards Scandinavia was initially hoped to be at least a partial solution<br />

to Britain's numerous problems in its economic and political position in Europe,<br />

along lines that would build up Britain's economic strength in a way not inimical to<br />

current British – or socialist – economic thinking and political traditions.<br />

The establishment <strong>of</strong> Uniscan<br />

One <strong>of</strong> the most useful political arguments in favour <strong>of</strong> further Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

economic co-operation was that Britain nee<strong>de</strong>d to show that it had kept to its word<br />

about its commitment to regional economic groups as a fundamentally <strong>de</strong>sirable objective.<br />

The British government had confirmed this to both domestic and international<br />

audiences, but words nee<strong>de</strong>d to be supplemented with actions. And if actions fell short<br />

<strong>of</strong> words, something was nee<strong>de</strong>d to sugar the pill in Washington at least. Desperately<br />

looking for a way out, Foreign Office <strong>of</strong>ficials agreed that it could hardly be argued on<br />

the basis <strong>of</strong> a closer economic association between Britain and Scandinavia<br />

“that we should be acting as rather bad Europeans if we associated ourselves with a<br />

regional group which would after all be based in that similarity <strong>of</strong> outlook and economic<br />

structure which is the only logical foundation for any regional groups”. 27<br />

In this view, there was no other serious alternative for Britain, because participation<br />

in the regional group including Belgium and Italy would be more difficult<br />

25. A. S. MILWARD, The Reconstruction …, op.cit., p.316.<br />

26. Henniker memorandum, 'Closer Economic Association between Scandinavia and the Sterling Area',<br />

30 November 1949, FO 371/78137; E. A. Radice minute, undated (1949), FO 371/78136; Sir<br />

Roger Makins memorandum, "Impressions <strong>of</strong> Scandinavia", 28 June 1951, FO 371/94444, PRO.<br />

27. Burrett minute, 8 November 1949, FO 371/78136, PRO.


112<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

for Britain “for obvious reasons”. 28 Hence, if Britain was not to contract out <strong>of</strong> Europe<br />

completely, Scandinavia was their only chance.<br />

Irrespective whether this reasoning ma<strong>de</strong> much sense as a long-term strategy for<br />

Britain's European policy, the economic implications <strong>of</strong> a closer association between<br />

Britain and Scandinavia could not be overlooked. The original British studies over the<br />

pros and cons <strong>of</strong> an Anglo-Scandinavian economic association were remarkably optimistic<br />

both in terms <strong>of</strong> the extent <strong>of</strong> the projected association and the timetable <strong>of</strong> its establishment.<br />

What the British originally suggested was Scandinavia's association with<br />

the sterling area as “non scheduled territories”, without participation in the gold or dollar<br />

pools. In effect, this would have meant full freedom <strong>of</strong> currency convertibility and<br />

capital movements, which would in turn have led to a situation where both the sterling<br />

area and the Scandinavian countries would have agreed to hold each other's currencies<br />

without limit, i.e. would give each other unlimited short term credit. Otherwise the British<br />

did not suggest any far-reaching concessions in the most important and difficult<br />

fields <strong>of</strong> tariffs and the allocation for export <strong>of</strong> scarce raw materials such as coal, but<br />

such an extensive financial liberalisation within the group would undoubtedly have had<br />

implications on tra<strong>de</strong> in due course.<br />

The initial Whitehall view, that there did not appear to be any serious objections<br />

for closer economic association, was subsequently revised when the plans were<br />

first discussed with the Scandinavians in December 1949 and January 1950. 29 The<br />

Swe<strong>de</strong>s in particular were concerned lest they would end up financing the whole<br />

scheme, as they already held substantial sterling balances as a result <strong>of</strong> the imbalance<br />

<strong>of</strong> Britain's imports and exports with Swe<strong>de</strong>n. As the Swe<strong>de</strong>s saw it, the <strong>de</strong>epening<br />

<strong>of</strong> economic relations between Britain and the Scandinavian countries was<br />

ultimately <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt on the <strong>de</strong>gree <strong>of</strong> equilibrium in the tra<strong>de</strong> between the countries<br />

as long as multilateral tra<strong>de</strong> was not re-established elsewhere.<br />

What proved most damaging to the British proposals was how further studies revealed<br />

that they would actually increase the existing disequilibria and probably lead to<br />

further increases <strong>of</strong> sterling balances in Swe<strong>de</strong>n and Denmark in the short term at least:<br />

in plain words, a further increase <strong>of</strong> the credit they were already giving to Britain. 30 Not<br />

surprisingly, this ma<strong>de</strong> the Swe<strong>de</strong>s especially apprehensive that they were to finance the<br />

whole scheme, a concern that was already familiar from studies conducted on the feasibility<br />

<strong>of</strong> further Scandinavian economic <strong>integration</strong>. Hence the Swe<strong>de</strong>s were keen to<br />

find out what the British could give them in return in tra<strong>de</strong> matters. As was soon found<br />

out, there was nothing to be expected on that si<strong>de</strong>. Most important for Swe<strong>de</strong>s and<br />

Danes were British exports <strong>of</strong> coal, which had not been touched upon in the preliminary<br />

discussions. In<strong>de</strong>ed, tra<strong>de</strong> was scarcely mentioned in the discussions, which centred<br />

around financial and payments problems. 31<br />

28. Ibid.<br />

29. Treasury memorandum, 'Scandinavia. The Financial Problems <strong>of</strong> closer Union', 8 November1949, T 236/<br />

5370; Treasury memorandum, 'Scansa', undated, T 236/5371, PRO; Sharman Wright minute, 3 November<br />

1949, OV 28/31, BEA.<br />

30. Berthoud memorandum, 'Ukiscan', 20 December 1949, FO 371/78139, PRO.<br />

31. Playfair to Christelow, 20 December 1949, FO 371/78139, PRO.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy 113<br />

When the reluctance <strong>of</strong> in particular the Swe<strong>de</strong>s and the Danes to embrace Britain's<br />

proposals <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>epening their economic relations dawned in early 1950, Cripps<br />

still tried to instill more life into the Uniscan concept and continued to stress the<br />

importance <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>veloping such co-operation further. But the momentum was hard<br />

to maintain not only because <strong>of</strong> the wi<strong>de</strong>r economic processes which un<strong>de</strong>rcut<br />

Uniscan's potential. The Labour Government was heading towards a general election<br />

and this was not the best <strong>of</strong> moments to break new ground in such a controversial<br />

issue as policy towards Europe. But more ominously for the long term, Cripps<br />

himself, his health ailing, had passed his peak as chancellor. Although he can be<br />

consi<strong>de</strong>red as the “primus motor” behind the Scandinavian orientation <strong>of</strong> Britain's<br />

European policy, his power was not enough to keep it running after the initial push.<br />

A stronger political will was lacking and nobody, either in Britain nor in Scandinavia,<br />

was ready to take on the initiative Cripps himself failed to take further.<br />

Besi<strong>de</strong>s bilateral tra<strong>de</strong> and financial issues between the British and the Scandinavians,<br />

the feasibility <strong>of</strong> their economic co-operation <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>d on wi<strong>de</strong>r issues as well.<br />

From the British point <strong>of</strong> view, there were three main themes running alongsi<strong>de</strong> its attempts<br />

to <strong>de</strong>epen its economic and economic-political relationship with the Scandinavians.<br />

First, on the liberalisation <strong>of</strong> tra<strong>de</strong>, the main progress was being ma<strong>de</strong> in Paris at<br />

the OEEC, and to a lesser extent un<strong>de</strong>r the auspices <strong>of</strong> the General Agreement on Tariffs<br />

and Tra<strong>de</strong> (GATT). Measures agreed in these organisations influenced the participating<br />

states' positions in bilateral tra<strong>de</strong> negotiations as they limited the scope for granting<br />

exclusive concessions. In other words, falling short <strong>of</strong> creating a discriminatory<br />

Anglo-Scandinavian tra<strong>de</strong> bloc, Britain could <strong>of</strong>fer relatively little to the Scandinavian<br />

countries that they did not already have. 32 Second, talks about ending financial restrictions<br />

between Britain and Scandinavia took place at the same time as proposals for a<br />

European Payments Union were being launched in Paris. 33 It was realised that any concessions<br />

ma<strong>de</strong> within Uniscan might have less value if there was an effective arrangement<br />

covering Western Europe as a whole, backed by Marshall aid dollars. Later during<br />

1950, this process completely overtook the incremental and rather mo<strong>de</strong>st payments<br />

liberalisation process attempted within Uniscan in early 1950.<br />

But perhaps the main limiting factor allowing Uniscan to become a more wi<strong>de</strong><br />

reaching economic arrangement during the 1950s was the question <strong>of</strong> the West German<br />

economy. The re-emergence <strong>of</strong> West Germany in international markets challenged Britain's<br />

position as a large-scale supplier <strong>of</strong> industrial goods throughout Europe from the<br />

early 1950s onwards. 34 The Swe<strong>de</strong>s and the Danes were keen to use their accumulated<br />

sterling balances for West German goods, and were therefore very hesitant about joining<br />

any discriminatory bloc in which West Germany was not a member. The West Ger-<br />

32. 'Tra<strong>de</strong> with Europe', The Financial Times, 23 January 1950.<br />

33. For EPU see, A. S. MILWARD, The Reconstruction …, op.cit., pp.299-334; M. HOGAN, The<br />

Marshall Plan …, pp.291-335, 349-359.<br />

34. On Swedish- W.German tra<strong>de</strong>, M. FRITZ, Turbulente Jahre. Schwe<strong>de</strong>ns Außenhan<strong>de</strong>l und Wirtschaft<br />

1945-1954, in: U. OLSSON (ed.), Neuanfang. Beziehungen zwischen Schwe<strong>de</strong>n und<br />

Deutschland 1945-1954. Sieben Beiträge, Umeå Studies in Economic History, Umeå, 1990,<br />

pp.143-164.


114<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

man markets were also becoming more and more lucrative in particular for Danish agricultural<br />

products that had previously flowed to Britain, <strong>of</strong>ten on prices that irritated<br />

Danish producers. As West Germany's participation in any Uniscan arrangements was<br />

consi<strong>de</strong>red early on politically impossible in London, this proved to be a difficult stumbling<br />

bloc for the Danes and the Swe<strong>de</strong>s. 35<br />

Changes took place on the Atlantic front too as it became evi<strong>de</strong>nt that US insistence<br />

on Britain's participation in regional tra<strong>de</strong> groups was relaxing already in<br />

1950. Further, as the European ground shifted in the spring <strong>of</strong> 1950 with the announcement<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Schuman plan, such a limited approach as was typified by Uniscan<br />

had far less sales value as an example <strong>of</strong> British steps towards <strong>integration</strong> from<br />

a Congressional or ECA point <strong>of</strong> view than was anticipated in 1949. In tra<strong>de</strong> liberalisation<br />

and payments questions the most important arena was the OEEC, where<br />

both the British and the Scandinavians had been ever less enthusiastic to follow the<br />

Franco-American lead. The American views had at first been rather positive towards<br />

Cripps's more ambitious plans about co-operation with the Scandinavians,<br />

but the realisation <strong>of</strong> the economic difficulties that were ahead quickly distinguished<br />

much <strong>of</strong> the flair <strong>of</strong> enthusiasm in Washington. 36<br />

The negotiations between the British and the Scandinavian governments en<strong>de</strong>d<br />

in an agreement in January 1950 that the present economic circumstances did not<br />

allow the complete removal <strong>of</strong> all restrictions on payments between the four countries,<br />

but that there was scope for more limited action, which should be studied further.<br />

The practical meaning <strong>of</strong> this was that tourist allowances were increased without<br />

limit, with certain restrictions with Norway – the Scandinavian country,<br />

ironically enough, that had been most eager to <strong>de</strong>velop its economic and political<br />

relations with Britain in the first place. 37 The <strong>de</strong>claration setting up the Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

Economic Committee was signed in Paris on 30 January 1950,<br />

four months before the Schuman Plan, when Cripps and the Scandinavian foreign<br />

ministers approved the <strong>of</strong>ficials' report. 38 On 31 January the Council <strong>of</strong> the OEEC<br />

was formally informed about its establishment and about the first steps towards<br />

payments relaxation within the group. 39<br />

35. British <strong>of</strong>ficials had at first aired a wi<strong>de</strong>r plan covering the Uniscan countries, Netherlands and<br />

West Germany in November 1949, but this was shelved in December for its potential to bring<br />

about unwelcomed political consequences, such as appearing to sabotage the Benelux or the<br />

Fritalux negotiations. Berthoud to Hitchman (T), 9 November 1949, FO 371/78136; J. B. Richards<br />

minute (German political <strong>de</strong>pt.), 2 December 1949, FO 371/78136; Duke minute, 15 December<br />

1949, FO 371/78136, PRO.<br />

36. Sir Oliver Franks telegram no.5739 to FO, 9 December 1949, FO 371/78138; Christelow to Playfair,<br />

13 December 1949, FO 371/78139, PRO.<br />

37. I. SOGNER, The European I<strong>de</strong>a …, op.cit., pp.307-327; K. E. ERIKSEN and H. Ø. PHARO, Kald<br />

krig <strong>of</strong> internasjonalisering …, op.cit., p.143.<br />

38. Report by Officials, 21 January 1950, FO 371/87087; Agreed Minute, 30 January 1950, FO 371/<br />

87088, PRO.<br />

39. Report by the Uniscan countries to the Council <strong>of</strong> OEEC, 'Further measures <strong>of</strong> co-operation: Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

Arrangements', 31 January 1950, C(50)41, micr<strong>of</strong>orm 049, OEEC Archives,<br />

Historical Archives <strong>of</strong> the European Communities, Florence.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy 115<br />

What was the most significant conclusion reached in the negotiations was that possibilities<br />

for further openings should be subjected to continuing study. This in fact became<br />

the rationale for setting up and maintaining Uniscan. Its main function was<br />

“to keep un<strong>de</strong>r review the carrying out <strong>of</strong> the financial recommendations and to<br />

explore further possibilities for economic co-operation”<br />

although later it functioned as an expert body discussing <strong>de</strong>velopments in Europe<br />

and in the international economy. The body began to work on a permanent basis,<br />

meeting on an <strong>of</strong>ficial level normally twice a year in each capital. Informal ministerial<br />

meetings were organised occasionally, normally in conjunction with the<br />

OEEC Council in Paris.<br />

The first Uniscan meeting was held at the Danish Embassy in Paris in April<br />

1950. The <strong>de</strong>legations, consisting <strong>of</strong> senior <strong>of</strong>ficials from the four countries, discussed<br />

organisational questions, actions taken in each country to implement the<br />

January <strong>de</strong>claration, and problems <strong>of</strong> economic disequilibria. The only tangible<br />

move forward on the financial si<strong>de</strong> was the UK <strong>de</strong>legation's statement about steps<br />

for further relaxations <strong>of</strong> controls over possession <strong>of</strong> Scandinavian currencies in<br />

Britain. 40 On the economic policy front, Swedish proposals for studies on disequilibria<br />

were linked up with the work, which was being done within the OEEC “harmonisation”<br />

resolutions. 41<br />

The first meeting set a pattern for the future Uniscan discussions: instead <strong>of</strong><br />

spectacular advances towards Uniscan free tra<strong>de</strong>, the agenda came to be dominated<br />

by “European” and other wi<strong>de</strong>r international questions. In the first meeting there<br />

was only one “European” question on the agenda, the forthcoming OEEC payments<br />

scheme. Characteristically, it was agreed that<br />

“it was <strong>de</strong>sirable that representatives <strong>of</strong> the four Governments in Paris should keep in<br />

close touch and discuss the various proposals for a European Payments Union with a<br />

view <strong>of</strong> ensuring that discussions in the OEEC <strong>of</strong> such proposals take due account <strong>of</strong><br />

the objectives <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian economic co-operation”. 42<br />

In practice this meant an agreement that “these and other points should be followed<br />

continuously in an Anglo-Scandinavian group in Paris in which the U.K.<br />

Delegation will have the initiative”. 43 This meant, that the previously informal<br />

co-operation <strong>of</strong> the British and Scandinavian <strong>de</strong>legations in Paris became institutionalised.<br />

The OEEC <strong>of</strong>fshoot <strong>of</strong> Uniscan adopted a more active role in Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

economic talks from autumn 1950 onwards. The FO instructed<br />

Hall-Patch along these lines in October 1950, but was nevertheless reluctant to reduce<br />

Uniscan just as part <strong>of</strong> the “Paris machinery”. 44 In<strong>de</strong>ed, the leitmotif behind<br />

continuing this co-operation in the EPU era seems to have been a need for a more<br />

comprehensive exchange <strong>of</strong> views and co-ordination <strong>of</strong> policies in the OEEC, but<br />

40. UK OEEC <strong>de</strong>legation telegram no.214 to FO, 4 April 1950, FO 371/87089, PRO.<br />

41. Makins to Berthoud, 3 April 1950, FO 371/87089, PRO.<br />

42. Hall-Patch telegram no.214 to FO, 3 April 1950, FO 371/87089, PRO.<br />

43. Makins to Berthoud, 3 April 1950, FO 371/87089, PRO.<br />

44. FO telegram no.1017 to OEEC Delegation, 3 October 1950, FO 371/87091, PRO.


116<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

also to be able to respond to any new <strong>de</strong>velopments such as the Schuman plan. To<br />

be effective, this also required co-ordination outsi<strong>de</strong> the daily work <strong>of</strong> the OEEC. 45<br />

Co-operation with Limits<br />

With Conservatives back in power in Britain in late 1951, Uniscan meetings continued<br />

along the lines established in 1950 and wi<strong>de</strong>-ranging discussions <strong>of</strong> international<br />

economic policy and European questions were continued. However, it is difficult<br />

to establish the ultimate significance <strong>of</strong> these consultations from the point <strong>of</strong><br />

view <strong>of</strong> national policy-making in Britain or in Scandinavia. The British, who<br />

sensed how keenly the Scandinavians wanted to integrate British responses to such<br />

questions as sectoral <strong>integration</strong> schemes in Europe to their own, had by the end <strong>of</strong><br />

1950 grown somewhat uneasy lest the regular consultations with their Uniscan<br />

partners forced them to tie their hands in advance <strong>of</strong> important policy-<strong>de</strong>cisions in<br />

the OEEC or elsewhere. In November 1950, during Labour's reign, a <strong>de</strong>cision was<br />

ma<strong>de</strong> in London, “that the United Kingdom could not admit that there should<br />

always be a common Uniscan approach to O.E.E.C. problems”. The <strong>de</strong>cision<br />

applied to other topics discussed in the forum as well. 46 However, even if Uniscan<br />

was therefore not let to <strong>de</strong>velop <strong>de</strong> facto <strong>de</strong>cision-making functions, it was appreciated<br />

that even in cases when British and Scandinavian views diverged, a preliminary<br />

exchange <strong>of</strong> views within the group was useful.<br />

Despite fears in Scandinavia, that the new British government would not be as<br />

interested as the Labour government had been in the Scandinavian dimension, various<br />

<strong>de</strong>velopments spoke for the continuance <strong>of</strong> close Anglo-Scandinavian economic<br />

consultations. First <strong>of</strong> all, the Scandinavians themselves seemed to want this,<br />

even if the British sought to restrict the extent Uniscan may have been able to force<br />

their hand. 47 Second, the British <strong>de</strong>legation in the OEEC favoured further openings<br />

on the Uniscan front and set great value to its co-operation with the Scandinavians.<br />

Third, until at least 1954-55 the Treasury did not abandon its original i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> closer<br />

financial association between the United Kingdom and Scandinavia. And last but<br />

not least, <strong>de</strong>velopments in Europe with the establishment <strong>of</strong> the ECSC and other attempts<br />

towards further <strong>integration</strong> in the military and economic spheres increased<br />

the Foreign Office's interest to use the Uniscan framework in keeping a special<br />

channel open to the Scandinavians in European issues. Therefore, from early 1951<br />

onwards there existed a wi<strong>de</strong> inter<strong>de</strong>partmental consensus about the usefulness <strong>of</strong> a<br />

distinctive Anglo-Scandinavian economic forum, a consensus at which the different<br />

Whitehall <strong>de</strong>partments arrived <strong>de</strong>spite their own particular interests.<br />

45. Hall-Patch telegram no.849 to FO, 8 October 1950, FO 371/87091, PRO.<br />

46. Note <strong>of</strong> a UK Uniscan <strong>de</strong>legation meeting held in the Treasury, 17 November 1950, FO 371/87092,<br />

PRO. Emphasis in the original.<br />

47. An example <strong>of</strong> the value Swedish <strong>of</strong>ficials in charge <strong>of</strong> European policy set on Uniscan is found<br />

in the memoirs <strong>of</strong> Ingemar Hägglöf. I. HÄGGLÖF, Drömmen om Europa, op.cit., p.56.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy 117<br />

However, even if the Conservative government accepted the basic line Labour<br />

had had towards Scandinavia and Uniscan, new <strong>de</strong>velopments emerged in Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

relations that were partly due to the new government's foreign<br />

political preferences, and partly due to economic <strong>de</strong>velopments with which the<br />

Conservatives had to react soon after assuming <strong>of</strong>fice in 1951. The first problem<br />

arose with the difficulties the new government encountered with Britain's balance<br />

<strong>of</strong> payments in 1951-52. While disputes over coal exports or fish landings had been<br />

a longstanding problem with the Scandinavians, there was now trouble on a wi<strong>de</strong>r<br />

front. 48 In 1951 serious problems over Britain's balance <strong>of</strong> payments led to drastic<br />

cuts in imports, and this affected all the three Scandinavian economies in their vital<br />

export sectors. On top <strong>of</strong> this, there were problems in meeting previously agreed<br />

levels <strong>of</strong> coal and steel exports to Scandinavia. After much hard bargaining, larger<br />

quantities <strong>of</strong> coal and steel were secured in late 1951, after an intervention by the<br />

Foreign Office, but the continuing import restrictions led to further problems and<br />

strong protests from the Scandinavian governments.<br />

In early 1952, just as tension on the tra<strong>de</strong> sphere was gradually reduced, the Foreign<br />

Secretary Anthony E<strong>de</strong>n introduced the i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> linking the planned European<br />

Defence Community (EDC) with existing European institutions. 49 This created a serious<br />

problem for Swe<strong>de</strong>n and for them it was additional pro<strong>of</strong> that the Conservative<br />

government had a different set <strong>of</strong> priorities towards Scandinavia than Labour had<br />

had. Membership in European institutions with a military role was consi<strong>de</strong>red incompatible<br />

with Swe<strong>de</strong>n's neutrality policy. 50 The prospect <strong>of</strong> Swe<strong>de</strong>n's forced withdrawal<br />

from the Council <strong>of</strong> Europe if the E<strong>de</strong>n plan succee<strong>de</strong>d, posed a grave threat to the<br />

Anglo-Scandinavian axis in other questions concerning Europe too. Arguments highlighting<br />

the need to maintain Britain's 'special relationship' with Scandinavia, however,<br />

were not enough for E<strong>de</strong>n to modify his European policy. Overriding concerns<br />

over the future <strong>of</strong> West Germany in particular, placed Swe<strong>de</strong>n further down on the list<br />

<strong>of</strong> Britain's political priorities. 51 Further, E<strong>de</strong>n was in general less interested in the<br />

different new multilateral forums <strong>of</strong> economic diplomacy that had emerged after the<br />

war, and his general disregard for the OEEC was witnessed by the Swedish ambassador<br />

who in their first encounter had to explain to the embarrassed secretary <strong>of</strong> state<br />

what those four letters stood for. 52 In the end, the fact that the E<strong>de</strong>n plan never seriously<br />

endangered Swe<strong>de</strong>n's already restrained attachment to European institutions<br />

was thanks to the French National Assembly, which rejected the EDC in 1954, and<br />

not to concerns over Britain's relations with Swe<strong>de</strong>n.<br />

48. Accounts <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian tra<strong>de</strong> problems are found in B. NILSON, No Coal without Iron<br />

Ore. Anglo-Swedish tra<strong>de</strong> relations in the shadow <strong>of</strong> the Korean War, in: SJH 1/16(1991), pp.45-<br />

72 and B. NILSON, Butter, Bacon and Coal. Anglo-Danish Commercial Relations, 1947-51, in:<br />

SJH 3/13(1988), pp.257-77.<br />

49. A. EDEN, Full Circle, Cassell, London, 1960, pp.47-48.<br />

50. M. AF MALMBORG, Den ståndaktiga nationalstaten …, op.cit., pp.268-284.<br />

51. Dennis Allen minute, 23 April 1952, FO 371/100931, PRO.<br />

52. Hägglöf to Undén, 6 December 1951, Hp 1 Ba, vol.248, RA. According to Hägglöf, E<strong>de</strong>n however<br />

became more interested in the OEEC later, Hägglöf to Undén, 16 December 1952, Hp 1 Ba,<br />

vol.116, The Archives <strong>of</strong> the Swedish Ministry <strong>of</strong> Foreign Affairs, Stockholm.


118<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

The tra<strong>de</strong> disputes <strong>of</strong> 1952 and the abortive E<strong>de</strong>n plan were both signs that the<br />

Anglo-Scandinavian relationship had after all become more strained when compared<br />

to the Labour government's period in <strong>of</strong>fice in 1945-51. Thus in summer<br />

1952, while acute disagreements between Britain and Scandinavia in tra<strong>de</strong> issues<br />

were patched up, posts in Scandinavia were increasingly apprehensive about the future<br />

prospects <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian economic co-operation, as this time problems<br />

seemed to originate from London and not from Stockholm or Copenhagen. 53<br />

While on the tra<strong>de</strong> si<strong>de</strong> the British were steadily losing ground to West Germany,<br />

on the economic-political front even the Norwegians had become more reserved<br />

towards Britain than they had been in the beginning <strong>of</strong> Uniscan co-operation in late<br />

1949. There was a growing realisation <strong>of</strong> economic changes, which were working<br />

against, not for, further Anglo-Scandinavian economic co-operation. The last occasion<br />

when plans for <strong>de</strong>epening economic relations between these countries were<br />

discussed was in 1953-55, when un<strong>de</strong>r the initiative <strong>of</strong> the Treasury and the Bank<br />

<strong>of</strong> England, feasibility <strong>of</strong> Scandinavia's full Sterling area membership, and even<br />

participation in the British Commonwealth, was studied and abandoned in face <strong>of</strong><br />

Swedish and Danish opposition. This time these i<strong>de</strong>as met with even less enthusiasm<br />

on the behalf <strong>of</strong> the Swe<strong>de</strong>s and Danes than the Uniscan proposals had in<br />

1949, although the Norwegian response was at first positive. 54 Again in 1957-58,<br />

when the British government's Free Tra<strong>de</strong> Area proposal was discussed, the prospects<br />

for any special Anglo-Scandinavian economic arrangements alongsi<strong>de</strong> the<br />

wi<strong>de</strong>r schemes were very low. After the shelving <strong>of</strong> the Sterling area proposals in<br />

1955, no substantial openings for further co-operation within this group were introduced<br />

until 1959.<br />

Conclusion<br />

While <strong>of</strong>ficials at the Board <strong>of</strong> Tra<strong>de</strong> and the Foreign Office tried to counter the<br />

overall trend <strong>of</strong> growing distance between the governments on international economic<br />

policy in the early 1950s, Uniscan's meetings nonetheless continued apace<br />

and remained a part <strong>of</strong> the <strong>of</strong>ficial machinery <strong>of</strong> managing Britain's relations with<br />

the Scandinavians and vice versa. The biannual meetings <strong>of</strong> Uniscan lasted until<br />

1959, when the Swedish government initiated – during what proved to be Uniscan's<br />

last meeting – the negotiations that led to the signature <strong>of</strong> the Stockholm Convention<br />

in November 1959 and the formation <strong>of</strong> EFTA. The arrangement was formally<br />

en<strong>de</strong>d in 1960.<br />

53. Wright to E<strong>de</strong>n, 18 June 1952, FO 371/99082, PRO.<br />

54. Brittain minute, 29 February 1953, T 236/5375, PRO; Bank <strong>of</strong> England memorandum, 'Uniscan<br />

and convertibility', 15 April 1953, OV 29/32, BEA; H. Eggers minute, 5 May 1953; Treasury<br />

memorandum, 'Scandinavia and the Sterling Area', 16.May 1953; Berthoud to Coulson, 17 June<br />

1953, T 236/5375, PRO; K. E. ERIKSEN and H. Ø. PHARO, Kald krig <strong>of</strong> internasjonalisering …,<br />

op.cit., pp.144-145.


An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy 119<br />

In Uniscan policy-makers found a useful forum to discuss long-term strategies<br />

and negotiation positions. Being a multilateral forum it brought the policy-making<br />

machineries together in a manner that would not have been possible using normal<br />

diplomatic channels. This, and the numerous studies conducted over the years for<br />

the use <strong>of</strong> Uniscan meetings on the national economies and Anglo-Scandinavian<br />

economic interaction, eventually paved the way for EFTA – when external conditions<br />

so permitted – and provi<strong>de</strong>d that loose association with an institutional memory<br />

concerning expectations the core members had over the potential and ramifications<br />

<strong>of</strong> co-operation amongst them, and the behaviour and policy-making<br />

processes typical on both si<strong>de</strong>s <strong>of</strong> the North Sea.<br />

Despite consi<strong>de</strong>rable political goodwill behind the scheme, the economic<br />

achievements <strong>of</strong> Uniscan fell far short <strong>of</strong> the original British proposals <strong>of</strong> November-December<br />

1949, when a more comprehensive financial liberalisation had been<br />

envisaged. Had this approach been successful, the pound sterling would have become<br />

convertible within this group which would have directly strengthened the<br />

economic influence <strong>of</strong> Britain in Scandinavia, whose situation would then have<br />

resembled that <strong>of</strong> the sterling area countries.<br />

The utility <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian discussions in Uniscan, were therefore <strong>of</strong><br />

technical and to a lesser extent, <strong>of</strong> political nature. While the ultimate ramifications<br />

Uniscan co-operation was subjected to was acknowledged early on, it was nevertheless<br />

kept alive. Within its limits, it provi<strong>de</strong>d a forum for consultations, discussions<br />

and exchanges <strong>of</strong> view, and occasionally, a place where disagreements could<br />

be <strong>de</strong>alt with “on the domestic plane”, as the British <strong>de</strong>scribed it. More than anything<br />

else, the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> its establishment in 1949-51, illuminates the complex set<br />

<strong>of</strong> perceptions and misperceptions, hopes, fears and different national policy goals<br />

the British and Scandinavian governments had during a key period in European <strong>integration</strong><br />

<strong>history</strong>.


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

European Political Parties between<br />

Cooperation and Integration<br />

This volume conceptualizes political parties on an<br />

European level in terms <strong>of</strong> their constitutional and institutional<br />

regulation as well as their organizational<br />

foundation and evolution. The emerging European<br />

political parties are thus treated as organizations in<br />

their own right.<br />

Schriften <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Zentrum für Europäische Integrationsforschung<br />

Center for European Integration Studies<br />

Karl Magnus Johansson/Peter Zervakis (eds.)<br />

European Political Parties between<br />

Cooperation and Integration<br />

Scholars from Britain, Finland, Germany and Swe<strong>de</strong>n<br />

sharing this field <strong>of</strong> expertise came together at<br />

the Swedish Institute <strong>of</strong> International Affairs to confront<br />

a series <strong>of</strong> guiding research questions.<br />

The book originates from a project coordinated by<br />

the Center for European Integration Studies (ZEI) with<br />

the support <strong>of</strong> the Constitutional Project <strong>of</strong> the Center<br />

for Business and Policy Studies (SNS) in Stockholm.<br />

Table <strong>of</strong> Contents:<br />

Framing European Political Parties: Historical-Institutional<br />

Framework – Constitutional Framework – Organizing<br />

European Political Parties: European People’s<br />

Party – Party <strong>of</strong> European Socialists – European<br />

Liberal Democrat and Reform Party – European Fe<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

<strong>of</strong> Green Parties – Electoral Dimension: Party-Electoral<br />

Linkage – Party Landscape after the<br />

1999 European Elections<br />

Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Karl Magnus Johansson/Peter Zervakis<br />

(eds.)<br />

European Political Parties between<br />

Cooperation and Integration<br />

2002, 239 pp., Hardcover,<br />

46,– €, 79,– sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7684-8<br />

(Schriften <strong>de</strong>s Zentrum für Europäische<br />

Integrationsforschung (ZEI), Vol. 33)<br />

NOMOS


121<br />

The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe.<br />

The Expansion <strong>of</strong> European Social Policy<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

In 1950, the National Executive Committee (NEC) <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party clearly<br />

stated its attitu<strong>de</strong> towards European <strong>integration</strong> involving Britain. 1 “The Executive<br />

argue that no Socialist party could accept a system by which important fields <strong>of</strong><br />

national policy were surren<strong>de</strong>red to a European authority, since such an authority<br />

would have a permanent anti-Socialist majority”. 2 Over the following forty years,<br />

Labour’s i<strong>de</strong>ological opposition to an integrated European community fundamentally<br />

changed, so that by 1994, a Labour spokeswoman was able to claim that<br />

“Europe is now part and parcel <strong>of</strong> our domestic policy in Britain”. 3<br />

Traditional analysis has cited the reasons for this change as a combination <strong>of</strong><br />

numerous factors, including intraparty factionalism, economic pressure, tension<br />

between the lea<strong>de</strong>rship and rank-and-file members and the role <strong>of</strong> the two-party<br />

system. 4 The European Community itself is one factor that has been relatively ignored<br />

in the explanations for this policy change, as has its potential to exert discreet<br />

and discernible influence on policy in general. 5 Without disregarding the importance<br />

<strong>of</strong> the domestic mechanisms, the aim <strong>of</strong> this article is to <strong>de</strong>monstrate that the<br />

changing focus <strong>of</strong> the European Community - from an economically liberal organisation<br />

to one concerned with social welfare - also influenced Labour’s evolving <strong>de</strong>cision<br />

to embrace the EC. As European policies began to merge with Labour’s domestic<br />

agenda, i<strong>de</strong>ological opposition <strong>de</strong>creased, and Labour saw an opportunity to<br />

affect change on the European level, especially when barred from action in the UK.<br />

As the European Community <strong>de</strong>veloped its social conscience, Labour began to<br />

embrace it. The social <strong>de</strong>mocrats first saw the possibilities for socialism through<br />

Europe in the 1960s, but the Labour Left was <strong>de</strong>termined to achieve its aims<br />

through national planning and traditional nation-state socialism. After the economic<br />

hardships <strong>of</strong> the 1970s, and the political wasteland <strong>of</strong> the 1980s, the Labour Left<br />

1. The National Executive Committee (NEC or Executive) <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party conducts the Labour<br />

Party Conferences, and produces the Labour Party Manifesto which is ratified at the Conference.<br />

The Parliamentary Labour Party, the lea<strong>de</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> regional Labour Parties, as well as representatives<br />

from the Tra<strong>de</strong> Unions make up the voting population <strong>of</strong> the Conference - and are the elected members<br />

<strong>of</strong> the NEC.<br />

2. R.W.G. MACKAY, Heads in the Sand, Basil Blackwell, Oxford, 1950, p.18. Mackay was a Labour<br />

MP for Reading North who published his criticism <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party's stance at the time.<br />

3. Quoted in D. BUTLER and M. WESTLAKE, British Politics and European Elections 1994, St.<br />

Martin's Press, New York 1995, p.118.<br />

4. See H. YOUNG, This Blessed Plot , Macmillan, London, 1998 for a <strong>de</strong>tailed analysis <strong>of</strong> how these<br />

factors influenced both the Conservative and Labour Parties’ relationships to Europe.<br />

5. For a discussion <strong>of</strong> the process <strong>of</strong> Europeanization, and its relationship to the national political<br />

process, see R. LADRECH, Europeanization and Political Parties: Towards a Framework for<br />

Analysis, forthcoming, Party Politics, 2002.


122<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

was prepared to review its position. It saw significant changes at the European level<br />

which contributed to its change <strong>of</strong> policy, and the Labour Party emerged reunified<br />

in the late 1980s as the party for Europe.<br />

The first section will provi<strong>de</strong> an historical outline <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party’s opposition<br />

to European <strong>integration</strong>, through the 1950s until the mid 1960s. I then analyse<br />

the changes on the European level during 1965-1967 and <strong>de</strong>monstrate how a faction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Labour Party noted the shift, leading to division and internal breakdown<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Party during 1967-1987. The 1980s and early 1990s marked the final transformation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Labour Party; in this section, I draw the links between this move to<br />

Europe and the expanding possibility for Labour to implement social change on the<br />

European level. 6<br />

Labour Unified in Opposition to European Integration<br />

During the 1950s and early 1960s, the Labour Party remained, by and large, united<br />

against the <strong>integration</strong> movements on the continent. Part <strong>of</strong> their antipathy to European<br />

<strong>integration</strong> stemmed from the dangers they believed European <strong>integration</strong><br />

posed to the Commonwealth countries, as well as to the sovereignty <strong>of</strong> Parliament.<br />

The other major concern <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party was that the proposed organisations<br />

would not further socialist i<strong>de</strong>als in Britain, or in Europe. 7 In addition, there was a<br />

perception that those same organisations and their institutions might go so far as to<br />

hin<strong>de</strong>r or undo successes that the Labour Party had had in implementing a socialist<br />

agenda within Britain.<br />

Faced with the Schuman Plan, the first proposal for <strong>integration</strong> in the nascent<br />

European movement in the early 1950s, the NEC issued a statement on international<br />

affairs entitled, European Unity. 8 The document clarified the Labour Party's attitu<strong>de</strong><br />

toward Europe: “In every respect except distance we in Britain are closer to<br />

our kinsmen in Australia and New Zealand on the far si<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong> the world, than we are<br />

to Europe”. 9 Specifically, the statement outlined Labour’s stance, which had been<br />

established at the 1950 Labour Party Conference, on the fledgling European Coal<br />

and Steel Community (ECSC).<br />

Delegates had spoken out strongly against the ECSC, using socialist rhetoric.<br />

Mr. R. Edwards, a <strong>de</strong>legate representing the National Union <strong>of</strong> Vehicle Buil<strong>de</strong>rs,<br />

6. The author would like to thank Julie Smith and Anne Deighton for their help and advice on earlier<br />

drafts <strong>of</strong> this article.<br />

7. The Party may have had reason to believe this, as the governments <strong>of</strong> the states pushing for <strong>integration</strong><br />

were all led by centre right or Christian-Democrat governments.<br />

8. An earlier attempt at European <strong>integration</strong> was the agreement in 1950 between the governments <strong>of</strong><br />

Denmark, Norway, Swe<strong>de</strong>n and Britain to hold consultation in economic matters. This union was<br />

called the UNISCAN. Its success was short-lived, however, as by 1953 the impetus driving Northern<br />

economic harmonization was the Nordic Council, minus Britain.<br />

9. 49th Annual Conference <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party, (Margate, 1950), p.85.


The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe 123<br />

asked: “Is the Schuman Plan a <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> workers' control <strong>of</strong> the basic industries<br />

<strong>of</strong> Europe, or is it a <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> capitalist control and cartel agreements<br />

which have always been <strong>de</strong>trimental to the working class”? 10 A representative from<br />

a regional Labour party <strong>de</strong>clared that “without public ownership and a policy <strong>of</strong><br />

full employment, the unification <strong>of</strong> European heavy industry will inevitably lead to<br />

a restrictive monopoly, the <strong>de</strong>struction <strong>of</strong> full employment and <strong>of</strong> the workers'<br />

standards <strong>of</strong> living”. 11<br />

Members <strong>of</strong> Parliament also spoke out against joining the ECSC, focusing on<br />

the dangers <strong>of</strong> the supranational aspect and the fears <strong>of</strong> a European body usurping<br />

the Government's right to plan and direct the British economy. In 1952, while in<br />

Opposition, Labour remained faithful to the values it had espoused when in <strong>of</strong>fice.<br />

12 The Rt. Hon. Hugh Dalton clarified:<br />

“There are some who propagate the notion <strong>of</strong> a fe<strong>de</strong>ral Europe <strong>of</strong> which Britain<br />

should be a member. The Labour Party, almost unanimously, has rejected that view.<br />

We are not prepared to join a European fe<strong>de</strong>ration because we are not prepared to<br />

hand over to a supra-national authority <strong>de</strong>cisions on matters which we judge vital to<br />

our national life; such matters as the scope <strong>of</strong> socialisation, the means <strong>of</strong> maintaining<br />

full employment or the distribution <strong>of</strong> wealth through the policy <strong>of</strong> fair shares”. 13<br />

In 1955, the Conservative Government was invited to participate in the furthering<br />

<strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong> at the Messina Conference. The negotiations led to the<br />

Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome, which served as the founding document for the European Economic<br />

Community (EEC). The Preamble resolved to ensure the economic and social<br />

progress <strong>of</strong> signatory countries, though the articles mainly focused on the complex<br />

<strong>de</strong>tails nee<strong>de</strong>d for economic <strong>integration</strong>. 14 The countries that elected to accept<br />

the Treaty became known as the ‘Six’– France, Germany, Italy, Belgium, Luxembourg<br />

and the Netherlands. Britain, un<strong>de</strong>r the Conservatives, sent a <strong>de</strong>legation to<br />

observe, but as in the case <strong>of</strong> the ECSC, <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d to remain alo<strong>of</strong>. In response, Britain<br />

rallied the other European nations who were not involved in the Treaty <strong>of</strong><br />

Rome, to join a European Free Tra<strong>de</strong> Area (EFTA). EFTA would not push for <strong>de</strong>eper<br />

<strong>integration</strong> but would allow member countries to benefit from reduced or eliminated<br />

tariff and non-tariff tra<strong>de</strong> barriers.<br />

The Labourite Shirley Williams advocated in 1958 that EFTA countries should<br />

agree on certain measures <strong>of</strong> ‘social harmonisation’ that were already in place within<br />

the EEC – in or<strong>de</strong>r to bring the two organisations closer together. Although the majority<br />

10. Ibid., p.84. It is interesting to note that at this time, because <strong>of</strong> the strong unity <strong>of</strong> the Party, the<br />

Labour Government is thought to clearly represent the views <strong>of</strong> the Party - this attitu<strong>de</strong> and assurance<br />

did not continue into the 1960s.<br />

11. Ibid., p.164.<br />

12. The Conservatives, led by Winston Churchill, won the 1951 campaign, with 321 seats to 295. Party<br />

positions on the Schuman Plan did not figure into the election, as both parties were against joining.<br />

13. 51st Annual Conference <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party, (Morecambe, 1952), p.113.<br />

14. A section on Social Policy was inclu<strong>de</strong>d, as was the creation <strong>of</strong> a European Social Fund; however,<br />

concrete action was mainly restricted to ‘making studies, <strong>de</strong>livering opinions and arranging consultations.’<br />

(Part 3, Title III, Article 118, Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome) At this time, Labour was still convinced<br />

it could achieve its social aims through national planning.


124<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Labour Party was firmly against the EEC, certain members, such as Williams,<br />

were beginning to see possibilities <strong>of</strong> socialism on the European stage, and a British<br />

connection with the EEC, in this case through EFTA. She claimed that it was necessary<br />

to start planning on the European level because “in ten or twenty years we will be trying<br />

to win the control <strong>of</strong> Europe as a whole for socialism”. 15<br />

By 1960, it was the Conservative Party who was warming to the i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> the<br />

EEC, and broached the subject <strong>of</strong> accession to Europe. In <strong>de</strong>bate, the Parliamentary<br />

Labour Party criticised the fe<strong>de</strong>ralist nature <strong>of</strong> the community. The most crucial<br />

point they stressed was whether or not socialist i<strong>de</strong>als could be implemented within<br />

the EEC. 16 During the October 1961 Conference, the <strong>de</strong>bate on Europe, which in<br />

July had seemed to be a main party focus, was overshadowed by Labour’s economic<br />

and social proposal, 'Signposts for the Sixties'. The relationship between Labour's<br />

proposals and the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome structured the arguments against the EEC.<br />

Only two speakers gave unconditional support to the i<strong>de</strong>a on entry, and the overwhelming<br />

majority voiced concerns similar to those <strong>of</strong> MP Harold Wilson's:<br />

“As I read the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome, and the intentions <strong>of</strong> those who at present operate it,<br />

'Signposts for the Sixties' cannot be implemented without substantial amendment to<br />

the relevant articles <strong>of</strong> the Treaty”. 17<br />

The MP Mr. Tudor Watkins explained further, and synthesised the i<strong>de</strong>ological<br />

argument for socialism with his concern about the EEC:<br />

“I won<strong>de</strong>r if Macmillan would have come to us and begged <strong>of</strong> us in some way or the<br />

other to go to the Common Market if they were all Socialist countries. Not on your<br />

life! […] I<strong>de</strong>als can make institutions, but institutions can kill i<strong>de</strong>as, the i<strong>de</strong>as and<br />

i<strong>de</strong>als we want as a Socialist Movement”. 18<br />

Although sentiment within the Conference turned against entry into the EEC, the<br />

Labour Party did not articulate a clear position on the issue until the following year. In<br />

fact, some scholars have i<strong>de</strong>ntified an abatement in the hostility towards the EEC in the<br />

early 1960s. 19 Labour revisionists, such as Roy Jenkins and Shirley Williams, were<br />

pushing for more involvement with Europe, and even some <strong>of</strong> the tra<strong>de</strong> unions began to<br />

point out advantages to joining Europe based on improved social welfare. At the General<br />

and Municipal Workers’ Union (GMWU) Conference, A.M. Donnet <strong>de</strong>clared:<br />

“Joining the EEC will commit Britain to implementing the principle <strong>of</strong> equal pay. It<br />

could also give ad<strong>de</strong>d impetus towards longer holidays and shorter hours, and may<br />

lead to an improvement <strong>of</strong> training methods and facilities. The harmonization <strong>of</strong><br />

social policies could lead to an improvement in family allowances”. 20<br />

15. S. WILLIAMS, Uneasy Courtship, in: Socialist Commentary, April 1958, as quoted in R. DESAI,<br />

Intellectuals and Socialism: ‘Social Democrats’ and the British Labour Party, Lawrence &<br />

Wishart, London, 1994, p.142.<br />

16. It is important to remember that throughout the early sixties, Labour was sending <strong>de</strong>legations to<br />

the Congress <strong>of</strong> Socialist International and held its socialist responsibilities as a top priority.<br />

17. H. WILSON, Purpose in Politics, Selected Speeches, Wei<strong>de</strong>nfeld and Nicholson, London, 1964, p.100.<br />

18. 60th Annual Conference <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party (Blackpool: 1961), p.216.<br />

19. M. NEWMAN, Socialism and European Unity, Junction Books, London, 1983 p.163.<br />

20. GMWU Journal, 25(8), August 1962, as quoted in L.J. ROBINS, The Reluctant Party, UK: G.W. &<br />

A. Hesketh, Ormskirk, 1979, p.23.


The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe 125<br />

A memorandum from the Tra<strong>de</strong>s Union Conference (TUC) articulated the overriding<br />

question facing the Party: “Would going into the Community help this country<br />

and the six already in the EEC to work together for their own economic expansion<br />

and rising living standards”? 21 The answer to that question was not clear.<br />

Barbara Castle, on the Left <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party and a member <strong>of</strong> the anti-EEC<br />

Britain and the Common Market Committee, was certain that entering the Community<br />

would not help Britain. In a 1962 article entitled, ‘Planning and the Common<br />

Market: The Anti-Socialist Community’, she wrote:<br />

“In the context <strong>of</strong> the economic philosophy which inspired the Community this means, in<br />

effect, that [Britain] would be <strong>de</strong>barred from pursuing even the cautious and experimental<br />

Socialist policy to which the whole <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party is committed”. 22<br />

Richard Clements, the editor <strong>of</strong> the Left-wing paper, Tribune, outlined the paper’s<br />

opinion <strong>of</strong> the EEC in 1961:<br />

“The Common Market […] is a baited trap. If Macmillan and the Conservatives had<br />

got Britain pinned down and immobilized into the capitalist-oriented EEC, then their<br />

task in Britain would have been easier”. 23<br />

Hugh Gaitskell, the lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the Party, had indicated some lukewarm support for Europe,<br />

caught as he was, between the anti-European left and the pro-European revisionist<br />

right. However, he shied away from openly endorsing the i<strong>de</strong>a, and at the 1962 Party Conference,<br />

to the surprise <strong>of</strong> his revisionist friends, he effectively came down against Europe. 24<br />

In an effort to unify the party, Gaitskell presented Five Conditions for entry but in 1962, it<br />

was already clear that the Conservative negotiators would not succeed in attaining them. 25<br />

Because Labour and the Six could not be reconciled, general opinion, and even opinion<br />

within the Labour Party, recognised that Labour was thus 'against' entry to the EEC. 26<br />

21. L.J. ROBINS, The Reluctant Party, op.cit., p.15.<br />

22. B. CASTLE, Planning and the Common Market: The Anti-Socialist Community, in: New Statesman 13<br />

March, 1962, as quoted in M. NEWMAN, Socialism and European Unity, op.cit., pp.170-171.<br />

23. R. CLEMENTS, Editorial, Tribune June 1971, as quoted in T. NAIRN, The Left Against Europe?,<br />

in: New Left Review, vol.75(Oct.1972), p.55.<br />

24. Gaitskell was seen as something <strong>of</strong> a revisionist, as he had become a central figure in Friends <strong>of</strong> Socialist<br />

Commentary, which promoted links between revisionist groups. (See T. JONES, Remaking the Labour<br />

Party, Routledge, London, 1996, p.26.) One theory for his more negative stance towards Europe at the<br />

1962 Conference is his experience meeting European and Commonwealth socialists in 1962. His meeting<br />

with the Europeans at the Socialist International was marked by clashes and disagreements; in contrast,<br />

when he met with the Commonwealth Socialist lea<strong>de</strong>rs in September 1962, the conference was pleasant,<br />

harmonious and productive. L.J. Robins credits these experiences with reinforcing Gaitskell’s and the Labour<br />

Party’s commitment to the Commonwealth, at the expense <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>. (See L.J. ROB-<br />

INS, The Reluctant Party, op.cit., p.28.)<br />

25. Gaitskell outlined his major points <strong>of</strong> concern: 1) safeguarding the interests <strong>of</strong> the EFTA countries,<br />

2) retaining the freedom to plan the British economy, 3) retaining the system <strong>of</strong> planned production<br />

in agriculture (that Labour created after the war), 4) retaining the right to maintain an in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt<br />

foreign policy, and 5) providing for the interests <strong>of</strong> the Commonwealth countries.<br />

26. George Brown, the Labour Foreign Secretary in the Wilson Government, wrote in his memoirs,<br />

“In the years <strong>of</strong> opposition, when Mr. Macmillan was trying to negotiate British entry, Labour feeling,<br />

on the whole, was hostile […] the bulk <strong>of</strong> the Party was Anti-Common Market”. G. BROWN,<br />

In My Way, St. Martin’s Press, New York, 1971, p.216.


126<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

Gaitskell had managed to unify the Party behind a stance advocating conditional entry<br />

and promoting nationalism. 27 His sud<strong>de</strong>n <strong>de</strong>ath robbed the Party <strong>of</strong> an able lea<strong>de</strong>r,<br />

and perhaps <strong>of</strong> the promise <strong>of</strong> future Party unity. Nonetheless, initially, un<strong>de</strong>r the new<br />

lea<strong>de</strong>r Harold Wilson, the Labour Party appeared to maintain a general unanimity on<br />

the subject <strong>of</strong> the Five Conditions. The 1964 Labour Election Manifesto did not mention<br />

the EEC. It outlined Labour's approach to Europe in one sentence:<br />

“Though we shall seek to achieve closer links with our European neighbours, the<br />

Labour Party is convinced that the first responsibility <strong>of</strong> a British Government is still<br />

to the Commonwealth”. 28<br />

The Labour Left saw the EEC as “a Conservative exercise in economic escapism”;<br />

they believed that economic recovery would be through national planning.<br />

The 1964 Manifesto presented Labour's economic plans, including a reintroduction<br />

<strong>of</strong> a planned economy, the re-establishment <strong>of</strong> public ownership <strong>of</strong> the iron<br />

and steel industries, as well as an extensive regional policy <strong>de</strong>signed to help the less<br />

<strong>de</strong>veloped or <strong>de</strong>clining areas within the UK. At the first Labour Conference following<br />

the election, 29 there was little mention <strong>of</strong> entry to the EEC and the Common<br />

Market - the subject was confined to the speech <strong>of</strong> George Brown, the Foreign Secretary:<br />

“In view <strong>of</strong> the difficulties now within the Common Market we cannot talk<br />

airily <strong>of</strong> 'going into Europe' without <strong>de</strong>fining what that means”. 30<br />

In the <strong>journal</strong>, Common Market, an article appeared in 1965 that, after <strong>de</strong>scribing<br />

the Labour Government's attitu<strong>de</strong> toward the EEC, <strong>de</strong>clared: “any direct Labour<br />

initiative to join the Common Market can therefore be dismissed as overwhelmingly<br />

unlikely.” 31 And in fact, the Prime Minister, Labour lea<strong>de</strong>r Harold<br />

Wilson, emphatically stated in April 1965 that<br />

“there is no question whatever <strong>of</strong> Britain either seeking or being asked to seek entry<br />

into the Common Market in the immediately foreseeable future. So far as this Government<br />

are concerned, the conditions we laid down still apply”. 32<br />

27. He could not, at this point, seem to unify the Party around one vision <strong>of</strong> socialism. He was unable to convince<br />

the Party that the much vaunted Clause IV <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party Constitution had outlived its usefulness,<br />

and the right-left split over that issue foreshadowed the factionalism <strong>of</strong> the 1970s and 1980s. See T.<br />

NAIRN, The Left Against Europe?, op.cit.; and T. JONES, Remaking the Labour Party, op.cit.<br />

28. Labour Manifesto 1964, in: F.W.S. CRAIG (ed.), British Election Manifestos 1959-1987, Al<strong>de</strong>rshot:<br />

Parliamentary Research Services, 1990, p.56.<br />

29. A comment at this Conference foreshadows a future split between the lea<strong>de</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> the Government<br />

and the rank and file <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party. No longer were Party and Government viewed as a unified<br />

entity. The split would occur five years later over the EEC. The Rt. Hon. R. J. Gunter, M.P.<br />

and Chairman <strong>of</strong> the Conference remarked: "You know, the Labour Government is not the Labour<br />

Party, and the Labour Party is not the Labour Government. We all know this is so. The Government<br />

no more dictates to the Party than the Party dictates to the Government. The Labour Party exists as<br />

a party so that we may progress towards a Socialist society, and for that we must have Labour governments".<br />

64th Annual Conference …, op.cit., p.112.<br />

30. Ibid., p.181. George Brown was personally pro-Europe, as were some other ministers; however,<br />

he was not at this point able to push for <strong>integration</strong> against a strong anti-Europe majority.<br />

31. A Look across the Channel, in: Common Market 5, no.2(1965), p.28. Prior to 1966, all articles in<br />

the Common Market <strong>journal</strong> reflected the opinions <strong>of</strong> the Editorial Board.<br />

32. Hansard’s Parliamentary Debates, HOUSE OF COMMONS, 5 th Series, 711(1965): 623.


The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe 127<br />

However, by 1967, Wilson was prepared to support an application for entry that<br />

overlooked most <strong>of</strong> the original Labour conditions. What occurred between<br />

1965-1967 to change Harold Wilson’s mind, and split the Party on Europe?<br />

A Faction <strong>of</strong> the Party Turns to Europe – 1965-1967<br />

Harold Wilson, elected to lead a government with a four-seat majority in 1964, was<br />

neither pro- nor anti-Europe. There have been suggestions that the application for<br />

entry in 1967 was done to appease the pro-Europeans in the knowledge that <strong>de</strong><br />

Gaulle would veto the effort. 33 However, there are indications that a legitimate shift<br />

towards Europe was occurring in a faction <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party. Traditional analysis<br />

points to the economy as the overwhelming rationale for the change in attitu<strong>de</strong><br />

towards the EC. The benefits outlined in the Manifesto did not materialise, and the<br />

economy entered a downward spiral. In addition, EFTA was not as successful as its<br />

creators had hoped and efforts to create a linkage between the EFTA countries and<br />

the EEC were rejected by the Six. 34 Thus, this failure <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party to<br />

achieve its aims through national planning, coupled with the perceived inefficacy <strong>of</strong><br />

EFTA, is thought to have led to the renewed interest in the EEC. In addition to the<br />

economic reasons, however, there is evi<strong>de</strong>nce <strong>of</strong> changes on the European level<br />

which also influenced members <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party to turn towards Europe. Specifically,<br />

the work <strong>of</strong> the new Commission pointed to an emerging promise <strong>of</strong> something<br />

more compatible with the socialist goals <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party.<br />

The lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> this first Commission was Walter Hallstein, who was a <strong>de</strong>dicated<br />

'European' and expan<strong>de</strong>d the role and power <strong>of</strong> the Commission within the Community.<br />

Initially, it appeared that the Commission was only interested in achieving<br />

liberal economic aims – an agenda that did not inclu<strong>de</strong> full employment or other<br />

Labour priorities. The immense challenge <strong>of</strong> beginning <strong>de</strong>regulation and the harmonisation<br />

<strong>of</strong> industry necessary for the Common Market <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d tough action<br />

from the Hallstein Commission in its first few years. The expansion <strong>of</strong> the institutions’<br />

jurisdiction over certain social policies could have created more opposition<br />

from the Labour Party; however, the increased focus and the ‘left <strong>of</strong> centre’ thinking<br />

on social issues (complementary to the Labour i<strong>de</strong>ology) were essential new elements<br />

<strong>of</strong> the institutions in the late 1960s.<br />

33. A. THORPE, A History <strong>of</strong> the British Labour Party, Macmillan Press Ltd, London, 1997, p.170.<br />

34. Wilson himself led the British <strong>de</strong>legation to the Vienna Conference where it was hoped<br />

EEC-EFTA ‘bridge-building’ would be successful. However, it was not only the rejection <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Six that weakened EFTA. “In 1962 part <strong>of</strong> Labour’s attack on the Conservative Government had<br />

been based upon support for EFTA as an alternative European grouping which had no supranational<br />

or restrictive political aspects. However, in October 1964 the Labour Government, which had<br />

inherited a massive balance <strong>of</strong> payments <strong>de</strong>ficit, itself weakened the organisation by imposing a 15<br />

per cent surcharge on EFTA imports in clear contravention <strong>of</strong> the EFTA treaty”. M. NEWMAN,<br />

Socialism and European Unity, op.cit., p.204.


128<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

The Commission introduced ‘new i<strong>de</strong>as’ into the European <strong>de</strong>bate, beginning<br />

with the Medium-Term Policy Programme, drawn up to cover the years 1966-1974,<br />

which was <strong>de</strong>scribed as “an exercise in dirigisme”. 35 In fact, as early as 1964, the<br />

Commission Reports show a marked increase in their discussions <strong>of</strong> social policy<br />

and social harmonisation – a turn from the capitalist enterprise to which Labour objected.<br />

In that same year, the Commission attempted to create a measure <strong>of</strong> social<br />

harmonisation in the area <strong>of</strong> wages and tra<strong>de</strong> unions. 'Initiative 1964' was <strong>de</strong>vised<br />

to call “the member States' attention to the need for increasing the close collaboration<br />

in or<strong>de</strong>r to promote the levelling upwards <strong>of</strong> living and working conditions”. 36<br />

A law on collective bargaining was in its second reading stage, and business and<br />

tra<strong>de</strong> unions were to participate in a task force to make changes in a wages policy.<br />

In addition, a social policy for agriculture was announced, and advisory committees<br />

were formed on the social problems <strong>of</strong> farmers, and paid farm-workers. 37<br />

The most important change, vis-à-vis the Labour Party’s attitu<strong>de</strong>, was the introduction<br />

<strong>of</strong> the concept <strong>of</strong> ‘Regional Policy’, mentioned for the first time in the June<br />

1965 Report. The Commission stated that “social policy and regional policy are<br />

closely linked. A balance must be sought between mobility <strong>of</strong> labour between sectors<br />

or regions, which is essential for a dynamic economy, and the social and economic<br />

disadvantages which could arise from excessive inter-regional migration”. 38<br />

This section <strong>of</strong> the Report and the work the Commission had been doing directly<br />

addressed one <strong>of</strong> Labour's fears about the EEC, incorporated un<strong>de</strong>r the condition <strong>of</strong><br />

retaining the freedom to plan the economy. The social policy <strong>of</strong> the Commission in<br />

the area <strong>of</strong> employment had consisted <strong>of</strong> an extensive retraining and relocation programme.<br />

Funds were pooled by the Six, and the Commission directed them to specific<br />

areas within individual countries for unemployment relief. However, prior to<br />

the change in the Commission’s priorities, most <strong>of</strong> the money went to relocating<br />

workers - almost twice as much for relocation than for retraining. This new Community<br />

regional policy was a closer articulation <strong>of</strong> Labour’s policy preference, outlined<br />

in its 1964 and 1966 election manifestos: that money was better spent encouraging<br />

industry in the poorer regions, rather than relocating those workers.<br />

Another new policy introduced in 1965, in line with existing Labour policies,<br />

was the formation <strong>of</strong> a committee <strong>de</strong>signed to distribute the money <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Development Fund to projects originating in the less-<strong>de</strong>veloped EEC Associated<br />

Countries. Funds were provi<strong>de</strong>d for infrastructure, as well as public institutions,<br />

such as schools and hospitals. This programme provi<strong>de</strong>d on a Community level<br />

much <strong>of</strong> what the Labour Government was interested in providing to its Commonwealth.<br />

In the 1964 Labour manifesto, the Government promised to create a Ministry<br />

<strong>of</strong> Overseas Development in or<strong>de</strong>r to provi<strong>de</strong> funding and aid to the <strong>de</strong>veloping<br />

countries <strong>of</strong> the world. In 1966, Labour claimed that it had “increased the flow <strong>of</strong><br />

35. M. CINI, The European Commission, Manchester University Press, Manchester, 1996, p.45.<br />

36. Eighth General Report on the Activities <strong>of</strong> the Community (The EEC Commission: June 1965),<br />

p.251.<br />

37. Seventh General Report on the Activities <strong>of</strong> the Community (The EEC Commission: June 1964).<br />

38. Eighth General Report …, op.cit., p.164.


The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe 129<br />

external aid to <strong>de</strong>veloping nations both insi<strong>de</strong> and outsi<strong>de</strong> the Commonwealth” and<br />

proposed to “make our aid more effective by helping recipient countries to plan<br />

their <strong>de</strong>velopment and to select worthwhile projects on which to spend our aid”. 39<br />

During 1967 a faction <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party, including Prime Minister Wilson,<br />

began to see opportunities for social policies within the European framework. Harold<br />

Wilson believed Europe could advance his domestic agenda: “The question is<br />

whether any proposed surren<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> sovereignty will advance or retard our progress<br />

to the kind <strong>of</strong> world we all want to see”. 40 The TUC also saw benefits on the European<br />

level, and when invited to join the tra<strong>de</strong> union centre <strong>of</strong> the Six (ECTUS), the<br />

TUC sent two representatives to their Executive Committee. 41<br />

In retrospect, the political shift <strong>of</strong> the Community is apparent; that it was noted<br />

by Labour lea<strong>de</strong>rs and contemporary <strong>journal</strong>s at the time reaffirms its importance:<br />

“It is evi<strong>de</strong>nt that EEC members like France remain free to practise a high <strong>de</strong>gree <strong>of</strong><br />

economic planning. In the Common Market's own practice, the trend is toward more<br />

central control <strong>of</strong> national economic life along lines attractive or at least acceptable<br />

to Socialism. Many young Labour MPs and Ministers have 'discovered' the European<br />

institutions, and have found them less dangerous than they imagined”. 42<br />

The Labour lea<strong>de</strong>rship <strong>of</strong>ficially recognised the leeway allowed by the European<br />

institutions after Wilson's trip to meet with the Heads <strong>of</strong> Government <strong>of</strong> the Six.<br />

The meetings were arranged to assess the possibility <strong>of</strong> safeguarding British interests<br />

in an application for EEC membership, and were conducted from January to<br />

March 1967. During the series <strong>of</strong> meetings, which also inclu<strong>de</strong>d a February visit to<br />

the EEC Commission itself, Wilson began to un<strong>de</strong>rstand the difference between the<br />

Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome and its practical application within the Community. 43 In his memoirs,<br />

Wilson <strong>de</strong>scribed his discussion with the Italian Ministers about an important<br />

Labour issue, regional policy:<br />

“We then turned to regional policies. The answers we received, both on the freedom<br />

we require for existing regional policies and on our plans to extend them, were reassuring.<br />

It was important to us that we should be able to report that in the matter <strong>of</strong><br />

regional policies, Community practice allowed a great <strong>de</strong>al <strong>of</strong> latitu<strong>de</strong>”. 44<br />

In other countries as well, Wilson was told that the laws <strong>of</strong> the Community in<br />

practice could allow for many <strong>of</strong> Labour's requirements.<br />

39. Labour Manifesto 1966, op.cit., p.99.<br />

40. H. WILSON, Purpose in Politics, op.cit., p.110.<br />

41. L.J. ROBINS, The Reluctant Party, op.cit., p.65.<br />

42. P. LEWIS, Britain in Transition, in: Common Market 6, nos.9-10(1966), pp.181-182.<br />

43. Upon returning from Europe, George Brown, the Foreign Secretary, said <strong>of</strong> himself and Wilson:<br />

“I'd long ago discovered that the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome, like the Bible, takes account <strong>of</strong> any possible sin,<br />

provi<strong>de</strong>s the antidote and thereby <strong>of</strong>fers ways and means <strong>of</strong> obtaining sanctity afterwards. On our<br />

tour <strong>of</strong> Europe the Prime Minister also learned this. We found that other people bound by the Treaty<br />

<strong>of</strong> Rome had managed to provi<strong>de</strong> for all their private troubles, and it was pretty obvious that we<br />

could provi<strong>de</strong> for ours, even within the terms <strong>of</strong> the Treaty”. G. BROWN, op.cit., p.221.<br />

44. H. WILSON, A Personal Record, Little, Brown and Co., Boston, 1971, p.332.


130<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

In the ensuing Parliamentary <strong>de</strong>bate over application to the EEC, Wilson articulated<br />

many <strong>of</strong> these examples and arguments to support his case for entry. No less<br />

than three times in his speech on 2 May 1967 did he refer to the “practical working<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Community”, and on 8 May he reiterated the importance <strong>of</strong> the nature <strong>of</strong> the<br />

institutions rather than the articles <strong>of</strong> the Treaty. “My experience with the working<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Community, the actual practical working, and what we have learned in our<br />

discussions about its working, ren<strong>de</strong>r unfoun<strong>de</strong>d the fears and anxieties which I<br />

certainly had and very fully expressed, based on a literal reading <strong>of</strong> the Treaty <strong>of</strong><br />

Rome and regulations ma<strong>de</strong> un<strong>de</strong>r it”. 45 Wilson’s comments attest to the fact that it<br />

was not Labour's (or his) i<strong>de</strong>ology that was changing, but rather that Labour's i<strong>de</strong>ological<br />

convictions could be accommodated within the EEC.<br />

Other Members <strong>of</strong> Parliament also embraced this new view <strong>of</strong> the EEC allowing<br />

them i<strong>de</strong>ological constancy. Labour MP Eric Heffer encapsulated the vision <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Community:<br />

“We have the opportunity within our grasp as a Labour and Socialist movement to<br />

influence the future <strong>of</strong> Europe for all time. […] I believe that we can get a Socialist<br />

United States <strong>of</strong> Europe”. 46<br />

He elaborated at the 1967 Labour Party Conference:<br />

“We must fight for a Socialist United States <strong>of</strong> Europe […] I believe that the way to<br />

get there is first to get into the EEC, to fight for its expansion and to fight to turn it<br />

into a Socialist economic community”. 47<br />

Unfortunately for the future <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party, there never existed a consensus<br />

position on Europe within the Party. Compoun<strong>de</strong>d by economic and political concerns,<br />

the split within the party ran <strong>de</strong>ep. At the 1967 Labour Party Conference,<br />

votes in all areas un<strong>de</strong>r discussion were very close, as the effects <strong>of</strong> joining or not<br />

joining the Common Market overshadowed all policies. One motion <strong>de</strong>monstrates<br />

both the split within the Party and some <strong>of</strong> the factors influencing the move towards<br />

Europe. The motion in question was carried by 3,350,000 for, and 2,697,000<br />

against; it read:<br />

“This Conference welcomes the Government’s <strong>de</strong>cision to apply for membership <strong>of</strong><br />

the European Economic Community and to negotiate satisfactory terms for British<br />

entry. Conference is encouraged by the support <strong>of</strong> our Socialist and Tra<strong>de</strong>s Union<br />

colleagues in the Six for the entry <strong>of</strong> Britain and other E.F.T.A. countries and is convinced<br />

that British membership would be a vital step towards European unity”. 48<br />

The Labour Party entered the 1970s divi<strong>de</strong>d on the question <strong>of</strong> Europe, with rising<br />

left-right tension approaching a dangerous precipice. Wilson as party lea<strong>de</strong>r was confronted<br />

with the task <strong>of</strong> unifying the party - one that he could not accomplish.<br />

45. Hansard’s Parliamentary Debates, HOUSE OF COMMONS, 5 th Series, 746(1967): 321-322.<br />

46. Hansard’s Parliamentary Debates, HOUSE OF COMMONS, 5 th Series, 746(1967): 1154-1156.<br />

47. Labour Party Conference Report, 1967, pp.280-281 as quoted in M. NEWMAN, Socialism and<br />

European Unity, op.cit., p.216.<br />

48. F.W.S. CRAIG (ed.), Conservative and Labour Party Conference Decisions 1945-1981, Parliamentary<br />

Research Services, Chichester, 1982, p.237.


The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe 131<br />

Divi<strong>de</strong>d over Europe – 1967-1987<br />

During the 1970s and early 1980s, the Labour Party was weak and riddled with<br />

infighting on the issue <strong>of</strong> entry, and later, <strong>of</strong> remaining in the EEC. The Conservatives<br />

orchestrated the successful entry <strong>of</strong> 1 January 1973, and Labour remained<br />

opposed to entry, refusing to participate in Community institutions until after the<br />

1975 referendum on remaining in the EEC. Renegotiations and the referendum<br />

failed to unify the party as was hoped, and the anti-Europe faction continued to<br />

voice concerns similar to those <strong>of</strong> the party in the 1950s and 1960s. Finally, in<br />

1983, after a bitter Conference <strong>de</strong>bate, Labour advocated in its election manifesto<br />

complete withdrawal from the Community.<br />

The division within the Labour Party, forged during the 1967 application un<strong>de</strong>r<br />

Wilson, critically impaired the Party’s ability to get elected. In fact, Party membership<br />

was in <strong>de</strong>cline, and within the last two years <strong>of</strong> the Wilson government, the<br />

party lost over ten by-elections. 49 Even after losing the 1970 election to the Conservatives<br />

by a large margin, Labour remained unable to unite on the subject <strong>of</strong> Europe.<br />

Tom Nairn, on the Labour Left, rearticulated the question asked in 1962 by<br />

the TUC in his 1972 essay ‘The Left against Europe?’. He wrote:<br />

“We know, in<strong>de</strong>ed, that the Common Market is inten<strong>de</strong>d to strengthen the sinews and<br />

the world-position <strong>of</strong> European capitalism and its various ruling classes. What we do<br />

not know – and on the basis <strong>of</strong> this analysis, cannot ever know – is whether, or in<br />

what ways, it may also strengthen the position and enlarge the real possibilities <strong>of</strong><br />

the European working classes and European social revolutionaries”. 50<br />

He also framed the European discussion in relation to the <strong>de</strong>eper <strong>de</strong>bate within<br />

the Labour Party – that <strong>of</strong> the nature <strong>of</strong> socialism. The revisionists in the Labour<br />

Party i<strong>de</strong>ntified themselves with the social <strong>de</strong>mocratic movements <strong>of</strong> the Continent<br />

and were in favour <strong>of</strong> entering the EEC, based on arguments <strong>of</strong> promoting socialism<br />

through the Community. 51 Those on the Left <strong>of</strong> the Party did not accept the<br />

type <strong>of</strong> socialism promoted by the revisionists, and thus refused to accept their related<br />

views on the positive social aspects <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>. 52 This <strong>de</strong>bate <strong>of</strong><br />

i<strong>de</strong>as and i<strong>de</strong>ologies would continue throughout the 1970s and the 1980s and cause<br />

a severe split within the Party.<br />

The Conservative Prime Minister Edward Heath brought Britain into the Common<br />

Market in 1973. In the vote, 69 Labour MPs, led by the pro-European revisionist Roy<br />

Jenkins, voted for membership, flouting the <strong>de</strong>mands <strong>of</strong> the Labour lea<strong>de</strong>rship who im-<br />

49. K. JEFFREYS, The Labour Party since 1945, Macmillan Press Ltd., London, 1993, p.71.<br />

50. T. NAIRN, The Left Against Europe?, op.cit., p.111.<br />

51. Alan Day credited the European social <strong>de</strong>mocrats with becoming “the pace-setters <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>”.<br />

He also claimed that Continental, and by extension, British social <strong>de</strong>mocrats believed<br />

that there was time and opportunity to mould Europe into a socialist concept. See A. DAY, Socialists<br />

and European Unity, in: Socialist Commentary, August 1971.<br />

52. Byron Criddle commented in Socialists and European Integration that “the socialists’ espousal <strong>of</strong><br />

the European cause has gone hand in hand with retreat from traditional socialist i<strong>de</strong>ology into social<br />

<strong>de</strong>mocratic revisionism”. As quoted in A. DAY, op.cit., p.7.


132<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

posed a three-line whip against membership. Even though the terms <strong>of</strong> entry were negotiated<br />

by the Conservatives, these Labour MPs believed that it did not<br />

“automatically make them into ‘Tory Terms’; that is, terms which in their nature<br />

must by opposed by members <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party. The Labour Committee for<br />

Europe says these are terms that can honourably be supported by Socialists”. 53<br />

Notwithstanding the rhetoric <strong>of</strong> the pro-Europeans, the majority <strong>of</strong> the Parliamentary<br />

Labour Party voted no, and animosities <strong>de</strong>epened.<br />

Many members <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party remained i<strong>de</strong>ologically opposed to the i<strong>de</strong>a<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Common Market, even though Britain had joined. To the “guardians <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Party’s ‘ultimate purpose’”, in other words, the Left-wing traditionalist socialists,<br />

“there was still little to choose between the collaborationist Social Democratic Europe<br />

<strong>of</strong> the revisionists and the capitalist-dominated Europe <strong>of</strong> the Conservative<br />

Party”. 54 One Labour MP, Eric Deakins, <strong>de</strong>clared: “I am not merely against Britain's<br />

membership <strong>of</strong> the Common Market. Even if we were not in, I should be<br />

against the Common Market's very existence”. 55<br />

In the more mo<strong>de</strong>rate press, however, the benefits <strong>of</strong> the EEC, as noted in the<br />

1965-1967 period, were still being reported. In a 1973 issue <strong>of</strong> Political Quarterly,<br />

for example, an article discusses the increased attention paid to social policy within<br />

the Community. It reviews the 1971 progress report on the actions taken by Community<br />

institutions, Report on the Development <strong>of</strong> the Social Situation in the Community.<br />

A key element <strong>of</strong> the actions taken in 1971 by the Community inclu<strong>de</strong>d the<br />

reform <strong>of</strong> the European Social Fund “to allow the Community to promote schemes<br />

itself directly instead <strong>of</strong> through national governments.” 56 This and other achievements<br />

were touted as successes for socialism on the European stage.<br />

Harold Wilson, still the lea<strong>de</strong>r <strong>of</strong> the party, attempted to create and maintain cohesiveness<br />

in the party by throwing the European issue into the hands <strong>of</strong> the British<br />

public. The major elements <strong>of</strong> the 1974 Labour campaign strategy were the commitments<br />

to renegotiating the terms <strong>of</strong> entry and to a referendum on joining. The<br />

renegotiation process was a balancing act between the lea<strong>de</strong>rship, which, while not<br />

enthusiastic, was nonetheless committed to Europe, those on the pro-European<br />

Right, and the Party's Left, which was strongly against any involvement.<br />

The outlined renegotiation objectives in the Labour manifesto inclu<strong>de</strong>d the traditional<br />

concerns for the Commonwealth and <strong>de</strong>veloping countries, as well as a <strong>de</strong>mand<br />

for changes in the Common Agricultural Policy and the Community Budget.<br />

After Labour won the 1974 election, in an opening statement to the Council <strong>of</strong><br />

Ministers, the Foreign Secretary, James Callaghan, reiterated that Britain “reserved<br />

the right to withdraw from the Community if satisfactory terms could not be<br />

53. The Labour Party and the European Communities, Labour Committee for Europe, Sept., 1971 as<br />

quoted in L.J. ROBINS, The Reluctant Party, op.cit., p.88.<br />

54. L.J. ROBINS, The Reluctant Party, op.cit., p.69.<br />

55. Hansard’s Parliamentary Debates, HOUSE OF COMMONS, 5 th Series, 865(1973): 306.<br />

56. E. WISTRICH, Social Policy in the Community, in: Political Quarterly vol.44, no.2(April-June<br />

1973), p.212.


The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe 133<br />

agreed.” 57 The renegotiated terms passed Parliament on 9 April 1975, though not<br />

because <strong>of</strong> Labour support. The Government had to rely on Opposition support,<br />

which it received: its own members were split - 137 Labour MPs voting for, 145<br />

against, with 33 abstentions.<br />

The renegotiated terms were almost immaterial at the start <strong>of</strong> the referendum campaign,<br />

as most <strong>of</strong> “the opponents <strong>of</strong> membership were opposed whatever the terms”. 58<br />

The referendum itself was also a question <strong>of</strong> intraparty factionalism, as the Left hoped<br />

to use the issue <strong>of</strong> EC membership in or<strong>de</strong>r to secure control <strong>of</strong> the lea<strong>de</strong>rship positions,<br />

by gaining support from the many members <strong>of</strong> the party who were against entry but not<br />

necessarily in favour <strong>of</strong> radical leftist economic policy. 59 The Left called for a national<br />

referendum on the issue <strong>of</strong> membership, expecting that with a withdrawal vote it could<br />

consolidate its position within the party. The mainstream element <strong>of</strong> the party, represented<br />

by Prime Minister Wilson, 60 also thought that the EC <strong>de</strong>bate would provi<strong>de</strong> it<br />

with a chance to strengthen its power – by “outmanoeuvring the left”. 61 Thus Wilson<br />

co-opted the Left’s strategy <strong>of</strong> holding a referendum. 62<br />

Wilson, in an attempt to hold the party together, waived Cabinet responsibility<br />

during the referendum campaign, paradoxically allowing the Left and the Right <strong>of</strong><br />

the Party to criticise each other with impunity. Neil Kinnock, writing in the leftist<br />

Tribune, sc<strong>of</strong>fed at the i<strong>de</strong>a that socialism could be better achieved by going into<br />

Europe and attacked Roy Jenkins and other revisionists:<br />

“Somehow the vocabulary <strong>of</strong> radical – even revolutionary – socialism has a hollow<br />

ring when it comes from such conventionally Right-wing, or to use current terminology,<br />

‘mo<strong>de</strong>rate’ mouths”. 63<br />

In response the Right-wing attacked the ‘Labourism’ <strong>of</strong> the Left-wing, which was<br />

not ‘socialism’ and was blocking “the way to the establishment <strong>of</strong> social <strong>de</strong>mocracy on<br />

the European mo<strong>de</strong>l”. 64 Labour lea<strong>de</strong>rship hoped that the referendum <strong>de</strong>cision in favour<br />

<strong>of</strong> entry, on the high turnout <strong>of</strong> about 65%, would help to put the membership issue<br />

to rest. However, to the Labour Left, the issue was far from settled.<br />

After the referendum, the Labour Party sent representatives to the European<br />

Parliament (EP), which the Conservative Party had done from the time <strong>of</strong> British<br />

accession in 1973. Some pro-European Labour Members <strong>of</strong> the European Parlia-<br />

57. S. GEORGE, An Awkward Partner: Britain in the European Community, Clarendon Press, Oxford,<br />

1990, p.79.<br />

58. S. GEORGE, op.cit., p.88.<br />

59. G. BROWN, op.cit., p.76.<br />

60. Although Wilson was initially the Left’s candidate in the early 1960s, by his third term as PM in 1974,<br />

he had become much more centrist, and a supporter, though now lukewarm, <strong>of</strong> entry to the EC.<br />

61. G. BROWN, op.cit., p.77.<br />

62. For a thorough analysis <strong>of</strong> the referendum campaign, see J. SMITH, The 1975 Referendum, in:<br />

Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History, vol.1(1999), Nomos, Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, 1999, pp.41-56;<br />

and, D. BUTLER and U. KITZINGER, The 1975 Referendum, Macmillan, London, 1999.<br />

63. N. KINNOCK, Socialism and Sovereignty, in: Tribune, 2 May, 1975.<br />

64. S. FIELDING, Labourism and locating the British Labour Party within the European Left, in:<br />

Working Papers in Contemporary History and Politics, No.11, University <strong>of</strong> Salford, Salford,<br />

1996, p.7.


134<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

ment (MEPs) took advantage <strong>of</strong> the opportunities presented, and began to pursue<br />

socialist aims. Michael Stewart became a vice-chairman <strong>of</strong> the Socialist Group, the<br />

largest political grouping in the EP, and John Evans pushed to expand the Regional<br />

Fund. 65 These efforts, and some successes, notwithstanding, the Labour Left refused<br />

to see the European Community as a route to broa<strong>de</strong>r socialism.<br />

Only the implementation <strong>of</strong> radical reforms (outlined in the 1979 general election<br />

manifesto) could reconcile the Labour Left to the EC. Even a newly-elected<br />

MEP, Alf Lomas, spoke at the Conference in negative overtones on the subject:<br />

“If we do not achieve these fundamental changes within a reasonable period <strong>of</strong> time,<br />

then we should reconsi<strong>de</strong>r the whole issue. A reasonable period <strong>of</strong> time, in my opinion,<br />

is no longer than one term <strong>of</strong> the Assembly, and if we do not get these changes<br />

then we should recommend withdrawal”. 66<br />

Labour's goodwill and effort towards achieving these <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d reforms were<br />

limited, as only one year later the Conference <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d that the <strong>de</strong>mands were incapable<br />

<strong>of</strong> being fulfilled. The Conference “urged the Labour Party to inclu<strong>de</strong> the<br />

withdrawal <strong>of</strong> the United Kingdom from the EEC as a priority in the next general<br />

election manifesto”. 67 I<strong>de</strong>ological opposition still ran <strong>de</strong>ep within the party: John<br />

Shelmerdine stated at the 1980 Conference:<br />

“Let us face it, the Common Market is a club for capitalism. The only way we need<br />

to tra<strong>de</strong> is through an international socialism. Our fight is not just with one country<br />

or another; it is with capitalism”. 68<br />

Labour did in<strong>de</strong>ed continue to fight against capitalism, as expressed through the<br />

EEC, until i<strong>de</strong>ology compatible with the Labour i<strong>de</strong>als <strong>of</strong> socialism became a viable<br />

option within the EEC institutions.<br />

In 1981, the National Executive Committee (NEC) <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party agreed<br />

to a policy, Withdrawal from the EEC, which was passed with 6,213,000 votes for,<br />

and only 782,000 against. The statement clearly articulated the view held by most<br />

on the Labour Left, and echoed the earliest criticisms <strong>of</strong> the EEC <strong>of</strong> the 1950s:<br />

“[EEC membership] has seriously hin<strong>de</strong>red, and could prevent altogether, Britain<br />

adopting a coherent socialist strategy for industrial and economic regeneration.<br />

Withdrawal is thus not a substitute for Labour’s alternative economic, industrial and<br />

social strategy. It is a necessary condition for its success”. 69<br />

The hard-line approach to European affairs drove the pragmatists and the<br />

pro-Marketeers from the party.<br />

In 1981, Roy Jenkins, and other MPs, mostly revisionists and pro-Europeans,<br />

formed the Social Democratic Party (SDP) which entered into an ‘Alliance’ with<br />

65. C. JACKSON, The First British MEPs: Styles and Strategies, in: Contemporary European History,<br />

vol.2, no.2(1993), p.186.<br />

66. 78th Annual Conference <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party (Brighton: 1979), p.324.<br />

67. 79th Annual Conference <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party (Blackpool: 1980), p.126. This quotation is an excerpt<br />

<strong>of</strong> Composite 15 at that Conference, which was carried by a vote <strong>of</strong> 2 to 1.<br />

68. 79th Annual Conference …, op.cit., p.127.<br />

69. M. NEWMAN, Socialism and European Unity, op.cit., p.247.


The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe 135<br />

the Liberal Party. 70 The Alliance attracted membership away from the Labour Party,<br />

and showed itself in by-elections to be capable <strong>of</strong> contesting both Conservative<br />

and Labour 'safe seats'. 71 Ignoring the Alliance threat, and with the most articulate<br />

pro-Europeans out <strong>of</strong> the Party, the Labour Party held fast to its strong anti-European<br />

rhetoric for the 1983 campaign. In 1982 there was not a single discussion concerning<br />

Europe at the Labour Annual Conference, except a casual remark by<br />

Michael Foot reaffirming the Party's commitment to withdrawal. On election day, 9<br />

June 1983, Labour lost further 31 seats on top <strong>of</strong> its 1979 loss, leaving the Party<br />

with 209 seats, and the Conservatives with 397. Labour was <strong>de</strong>cimated.<br />

Confronted with such failure, and faced with a round <strong>of</strong> elections for the European<br />

Parliament, the Labour Party <strong>de</strong>ci<strong>de</strong>d to accept the Community and Britain’s<br />

membership for the duration <strong>of</strong> the upcoming European Parliamentary session,<br />

1984-1989, and retain merely the ‘option’ to withdraw. 72 However, during the 1986<br />

and 1987 Labour Party Conferences there was no <strong>de</strong>bate or even comment on the<br />

state <strong>of</strong> European affairs. After the third straight loss to the Conservatives in 1987,<br />

the Labour Party was <strong>of</strong>ficially unelectable.<br />

The Final Transformation: Labour Reunifies as the Party for Europe – 1987-1994<br />

Labour’s failures in the 1983 and 1987 elections <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong>d a radical change in<br />

policy – and in the late 1980s the Party launched a thorough Policy Review. Not<br />

only a result <strong>of</strong> electoral failure, the Policy Review was also <strong>de</strong>signed to confront<br />

the perceived inefficacy <strong>of</strong> traditional Labour economic policies. The Presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong><br />

France, François Mitterrand had attempted to create a socialist state in France during<br />

the years 1981-1984. His experiment failed badly and forced a reversal <strong>of</strong> policy.<br />

“From this experience, European socialists generally drew the conclusion that a<br />

new strategy had to be <strong>de</strong>vised which would operate on a European scale.” 73 As<br />

these events overtook them, anti-Marketeers began to re-evaluate their positions;<br />

the Policy Review was not, however, as some claim, merely a response to Thatcherism.<br />

It also coinci<strong>de</strong>d with changes on the European stage which promoted European<br />

policies that more closely mirrored Labour’s traditional domestic aims.<br />

70. Although the Liberal Party had been consistently pro-Europe since the 1950's, until the SDP-Liberal<br />

Alliance, they had never provi<strong>de</strong>d enough <strong>of</strong> electoral threat to force the major parties to consi<strong>de</strong>r<br />

seriously their impact in a campaign.<br />

71. In November 1981, Shirley Williams won a by-election victory for the SDP in the Conservative<br />

seat <strong>of</strong> Crosby. In February <strong>of</strong> 1983 the Liberals won the traditional Labour seat <strong>of</strong> Bermondsey.<br />

72. In 1979 European Parliamentary elections amounted to a “<strong>de</strong>ep-dilemma – how [could] a pr<strong>of</strong>oundly<br />

anti-EEC party go out and ask for Votes to send its representatives to the European Parliament”?<br />

Ph. WEBSTER, The Campaign in the UK, in: D. WOOD (ed.), The Times Gui<strong>de</strong> to the<br />

1979 European Parliament, Times Books, London, 1979, p.42.<br />

73. S. GEORGE and B. ROSAMOND, The European Community, in: M. SMITH and J. SPEAR<br />

(eds.), The Changing Labour Party, Routledge, London, 1992, p.178.


136<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

Jacques Delors, the Presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the Commission, began to wi<strong>de</strong>n the mandate <strong>of</strong><br />

the EC as early as 1986, in the Commission’s programme for that year. He stated that<br />

“The Commission can only welcome incorporation <strong>of</strong> the social dimension in the<br />

Luxembourg Treaty. Beginning this year it promises to translate these aims into proposals<br />

to <strong>de</strong>monstrate to the people <strong>of</strong> Europe that the creation <strong>of</strong> a vast economic<br />

area, based on the market and business co-operation, is inconceivable - I would say<br />

unattainable - without some harmonisation <strong>of</strong> social legislation”. 74<br />

After Labour’s 1987 general election <strong>de</strong>feat, this new European social dimension<br />

provi<strong>de</strong>d Labour with the only means <strong>of</strong> achieving its social aims against the<br />

backdrop <strong>of</strong> Thatcherite Britain.<br />

While the Thatcher Government was attempting to un<strong>de</strong>rmine the tra<strong>de</strong> unions in<br />

the UK, Jacques Delors was visiting the European Tra<strong>de</strong> Union Confe<strong>de</strong>ration (ETUC)<br />

to garner support for his proposals for “l'espace social” 75 and a “social charter”. In Britain<br />

during these years, the Conservatives were privatising British Telecom and British<br />

Gas, and cutting back on pensions and benefits and other elements <strong>of</strong> the welfare state.<br />

With an overall majority in the House <strong>of</strong> Commons <strong>of</strong> 144 seats, the Conservatives left<br />

Labour without much recourse at the national level in the area <strong>of</strong> social policy. The Policy<br />

Review recognised the constraints to Labour on a national level, and Europe, and<br />

the EC, is portrayed as an opportunity, rather than an obstacle. 76<br />

The increased opportunities in Europe and the plurality position within the European<br />

Parliament <strong>of</strong> the Socialist Group provi<strong>de</strong>d the 32 Labour MEPs with more<br />

<strong>of</strong> a chance <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>feating the Conservatives than the 209 MPs had in London. This<br />

fact was noted at the time as <strong>de</strong>monstrated in an article in Political Quarterly: “It is<br />

clear that the aims and interests <strong>of</strong> European Labour movements have more influence<br />

over EC <strong>de</strong>cisions than the British movement can bring to bear on the Thatcher<br />

administration”. 77 A Labour MEP, Barry Seal, elaborated:<br />

“Comra<strong>de</strong>s, <strong>de</strong>cisions are being ma<strong>de</strong> in the Common market every day […] the<br />

<strong>de</strong>cisions that affect Britain cannot be changed by Westminster. This is where the<br />

Labour members <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament come in”. 78<br />

A key example was in the 1987 <strong>de</strong>bate in the European Parliament on the Baron Crespo<br />

von Wogau report, which consi<strong>de</strong>red the Commission's Paper: 'The Single Act: A<br />

New Frontier for Europe'. The report generally supported the Commission’s plans, and<br />

highlighted the importance <strong>of</strong> the creation <strong>of</strong> the espace social, as well as the efforts to<br />

create economic cohesion between countries or within a country by supplementing the<br />

Structural Funds with other programmes. In Westminster, such an effort would have been<br />

74. Bulletin <strong>of</strong> the European Communities (Brussels: The Commission), vol. 19, no. 2 (1986), 12.<br />

75. L’espace social, conceptualised by Delors, is a vague term for a new area <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong> which<br />

would focus on workers’ rights and social issues. It is the i<strong>de</strong>a behind what would become the Social<br />

Charter, or a charter <strong>of</strong> basic social rights introduced by Delors in 1989.<br />

76. M. SMITH, A return to revisionism? The Labour Party’s Policy Review, in: M. SMITH and J.<br />

SPEAR (eds.), The Changing Labour Party, op.cit., pp.64-65.<br />

77. J. GRAHL and P. TEAGUE, The British Labour Party and the European Community, in: Political<br />

Quarterly, vol.59, no.1(Jan-March, 1988), p.75.<br />

78. 79th Annual Conference …, op.cit., p.152.


The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe 137<br />

immediately quashed; however, in the European Parliament, the report was passed by 255<br />

to 38, with the 63 abstentions including the British Conservative MEPs. 79<br />

It is apparent that the EP presented a broad opportunity for political and policy<br />

achievement for the Labour Party, and after a time serving in the EP, Labour MEPs<br />

and Party members realised its potential. 80 Speaking for the NEC, Tony Clarke encapsulated<br />

the new Labour attitu<strong>de</strong>: “Each vote for a Labour Euro candidate is a<br />

vote for Labour and is a vote against Thatcher and her divisive policies for Britain<br />

and Europe”. 81 By 1988, a vocal portion <strong>of</strong> the Conference was drawing attention<br />

to the possibilities in Europe, perhaps partially spurred on by the visit <strong>of</strong> Jacques<br />

Delors to the Tra<strong>de</strong>s Union Conference earlier in the year.<br />

In 1988, Jacques Delors addressed the annual conference <strong>of</strong> the TUC. He spoke <strong>of</strong><br />

issues directly affecting the unions and their members: a social Community that would<br />

benefit workers, not merely employers; a voice in policy-making; protection for the<br />

rights <strong>of</strong> the members. 82 This last concept, <strong>of</strong> workers’ rights, resonated with many in<br />

the tra<strong>de</strong> union movement; the related i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> social citizenship had been discussed in<br />

the Labour press since the mid-1980s. Michael Mann wrote that “policy should be built<br />

on top <strong>of</strong> a simple, more universal, more radical un<strong>de</strong>rstanding <strong>of</strong> citizen rights, to enhance<br />

the power <strong>of</strong> the ordinary person and family against the power <strong>of</strong> big capital”. 83<br />

At the 1988 Party Conference, Neil Kinnock picked up this theme <strong>of</strong> European<br />

workers’ rights. The Financial Times reported:<br />

“[The] social dimension is anathema to Mrs. Margaret Thatcher, Labour argues […]<br />

in sharp contrast, Labour’s ‘social Europe’ as <strong>de</strong>fined by Mr. Kinnock, means ensuring<br />

the highest standards <strong>of</strong> working conditions and workers’ rights”. 84<br />

The Party was primed for the emergence <strong>of</strong> the Social Charter.<br />

The concept <strong>of</strong> a ‘social charter’ suited the Party, as in the 1970s Labour had advocated<br />

its own ‘Social Contract’ as an essential tenet <strong>of</strong> its Manifesto, Let Us Work Together.<br />

85 However, the European Social Charter, drafted in 1980 and an element <strong>of</strong> the<br />

79. EUROPEAN COMMISSION (Brussels), Bulletin <strong>of</strong> the European Communities vol.20,<br />

no.5(1987), p.118. It is worthwhile to mention that <strong>of</strong>ten the divisions came down on national lines,<br />

rather than the broa<strong>de</strong>r political alliances; therefore, examples <strong>of</strong> clear Labour versus Conservative<br />

voting are difficult to pinpoint.<br />

80. Ben Rosamond highlights the importance <strong>of</strong> the links built between the Labour Party and the Confe<strong>de</strong>ration<br />

<strong>of</strong> Socialist Parties. See B. ROSAMOND, Labour and the European Community:<br />

Learning to be European?, in: Politics, vol.10, no.2(1990), pp.41-48.<br />

81. 79th Annual Conference …, op.cit., p.140.<br />

82. S. GEORGE and B. ROSAMOND, The European Community, op.cit., p.179.<br />

83. M. MANN, Socialism can Survive: Social Change and the Labour Party, in: Fabian Tract 502,<br />

The Fabian Society, London, March 1985, p.20.<br />

84. Another critical element <strong>of</strong> this Conference <strong>de</strong>bate was the remission <strong>of</strong> a resolution <strong>de</strong>manding change to<br />

the 1972 European Communities Act. The Act, passed un<strong>de</strong>r the 1970 Conservative Government in tan<strong>de</strong>m<br />

with the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Accession to the Communities, accepted the primacy <strong>of</strong> European Council Directives<br />

in Britain. The Labour Party had, since the law’s inception, been fighting to change it and return power<br />

to the British Parliament. By 1988, most <strong>of</strong> the controversial laws being passed on the European level<br />

and 'forced' on the British Parliament were social measures that Thatcher and the Conservative MPs did<br />

not like. Labour capitalised on this uninten<strong>de</strong>d consequence and thus no longer advocated repeal or<br />

amendment to the European Communities Act.


138<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

‘1992’ Programme which would later be ad<strong>de</strong>d as a protocol to the Maastricht Treaty,<br />

was a much wi<strong>de</strong>r and far-reaching document, allowing for greater reform within Britain.<br />

86 Margaret Thatcher called it ‘socialism through the back door’. 87 Labour was<br />

quick to see the potential benefits <strong>of</strong> such a charter, and prepared a policy document in<br />

support entitled, The Social Charter: How Britain Benefits. This document highlighted<br />

the similarities between Labour’s aims and those <strong>of</strong> the Commission. 88<br />

There was great excitement about the Charter, Delors and Europe in general.<br />

Ken Coates, a Labour MEP, wrote <strong>of</strong> Delors: “Sud<strong>de</strong>nly, a new prophet had arisen<br />

in Brussels. Was it possible that all those causes which had been lost during the<br />

Great Waste since 1979, all those social Goods, could now, after ten corrosive<br />

years, be recovered in the European Community”? 89 All <strong>of</strong> the Policy Review documents<br />

had a European dimension, “suggesting that the EC [was seen] not only as<br />

a separate policy area, but also as a factor in the formulation <strong>of</strong> all other policy”. 90<br />

Even on the local level, Europe was having a direct impact, changing the attitu<strong>de</strong>s<br />

<strong>of</strong> Labour councils and councillors. Authorities could apply directly to Community<br />

structural funds, such as the Social and Regional Funds, to support local<br />

projects. In fact, the links with the Commission and the Community were shown in<br />

several surveys to have a direct effect on the attitu<strong>de</strong>s towards Europe <strong>of</strong> Labour<br />

councillors. Labour lea<strong>de</strong>rs with local government backgrounds were among those<br />

pushing for Labour to take a bigger role in Europe. 91<br />

By the time that the Maastricht Treaty came into force in November 1993, the<br />

extension <strong>of</strong> European Community responsibility to inclu<strong>de</strong> workers’ rights, as<br />

well as public health policies and education, had created a social awareness in the<br />

community which resonated with the left <strong>of</strong> centre governments in Europe, and<br />

with the entire Labour Party. The Major Government refused to participate in the<br />

dialogue on the Social Charter, and did not agree to adopt the finished product.<br />

Tony Blair’s campaign promised that Britain would sign this Charter, and many <strong>of</strong><br />

New Labour’s reforms within Britain have been direct results <strong>of</strong> implementing European<br />

directives. Thus, Europe has finally become “part and parcel” <strong>of</strong> Labour’s<br />

British domestic policy. Moreover, as Prime Minister, Blair has taken a lead in setting<br />

the agenda for the European Council meetings that discuss employment and<br />

social policy. Nonetheless, though social policy may have helped convert the<br />

Labour Party to Europe, it has not yet converted the European Union to socialism.<br />

85. H. PELLING, A Short History <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party, Macmillan Press, London, 1978, p.160.<br />

86. P. ALCOCK, The Labour Party and the Welfare State, in: M. SMITH and J. SPEAR (eds.), The<br />

Changing Labour Party, op.cit., p.149.<br />

87. Thatcher called it “a socialist charter – <strong>de</strong>vised by socialists in the Commission and favoured predominately<br />

by socialist member states”. M. THATCHER, The Downing Street Years, Harper Collins,<br />

New York, 1994, p.750.<br />

88. B. ROSAMOND, The Labour Party, Tra<strong>de</strong> Unions and Industrial Relations, in: M. SMITH and<br />

J. SPEAR (eds.), The Changing Labour Party, op.cit., pp.97-98.<br />

89. J. HUGHES, The Social Charter and the Single European Market, Spokesman, Nottingham,<br />

1991, pp.vii-viii.<br />

90. S. GEORGE and B. ROSAMOND, The European Community, op.cit., p. 171.<br />

91. See J. GRAHL and P. TEAGUE, British Labour Party …, op.cit., pp.83-85.


139<br />

Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen<br />

Andrea CIAMPANI – La CISL tra integrazione europea e mondializzazione. Pr<strong>of</strong>ilo<br />

storico <strong>de</strong>l «sindacato nuovo» dalla Conferenza di Londra al Trattato di Amsterdam,<br />

Edizioni Lavoro, Roma, 2000, 204 p. – ISBN 88-7910-934-0 – 50.000 Lit.<br />

This book, written by Andrea Ciampani (University <strong>of</strong> Padua) for the fiftieth birthday <strong>of</strong> the<br />

CISL, the Italian tra<strong>de</strong> union set up by Giulio Pastore in May 1950 two years after the<br />

CGIL's break up, is an example <strong>of</strong> European scholars' recent but growing interest in the role<br />

played by pressure groups and non-institutional actors in the international system and the<br />

European <strong>integration</strong> process.<br />

The analysis <strong>of</strong> the CISL's international pr<strong>of</strong>ile appears particularly difficult, not only<br />

because it is not supported by a selected bibliography, but mainly because it looks like a<br />

hybrid where European Integration History coexists with other subjects like Economic History<br />

and Industrial Relations.<br />

Via a careful analysis <strong>of</strong> the documents collected at the International Institute <strong>of</strong> Social<br />

History in Amsterdam, the author efficaciously investigates the different levels at which the<br />

CISL operates: national, European, and international, in an intricate labyrinth where the<br />

three i<strong>de</strong>ntities <strong>of</strong>ten appear to be overlapping. This complex articulation is not only the<br />

result <strong>of</strong> the CISL's own <strong>history</strong>, but also <strong>of</strong> the Italian post-war <strong>history</strong>, which has been<br />

strongly influenced by international <strong>de</strong>velopment as well as by the Cold War.<br />

In the first part <strong>of</strong> his book Ciampani <strong>de</strong>als with the CISL's origins, focussing on the historical<br />

<strong>de</strong>bate <strong>de</strong>veloped with regard to the various splits which completely changed the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

labour movement in Italy and France, ousting the united antifascist tra<strong>de</strong> unions established after<br />

World War II. The author stresses that even though the Marshall Plan was the catalyst <strong>of</strong> the Italian<br />

CGIL's break up due to its implications with organised labour, internal factors also played an<br />

important role, as did the disputes among the various labour wings with regard to adopting different<br />

programs for Italian reconstruction. Since its birth, the CISL, through Giulio Pastore, its first<br />

Secretary, and Mario Romani, Director <strong>of</strong> the Ufficio Studi, has <strong>de</strong>veloped a pronounced international<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>ile. It took part in the establishment <strong>of</strong> the new international labour organisation, the<br />

International Confe<strong>de</strong>ration <strong>of</strong> Free Tra<strong>de</strong> Unions (ICFTU), formed by all the Western «free»<br />

labour organisations which had left the Communist oriented World Fe<strong>de</strong>ration <strong>of</strong> Tra<strong>de</strong> Unions<br />

in 1949, and it has played an active role in Europe since the creation <strong>of</strong> the European Coal and<br />

Steel Community (ECSC) in 1952.<br />

In the 1950's the links with the American labour organisations, in particular the American<br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ration <strong>of</strong> Labour (AFL), as well as its efforts to become a reliable interlocutor for the<br />

US programs in Italy, have influenced the i<strong>de</strong>ntity <strong>of</strong> the CISL. It tried to establish a «new»<br />

form <strong>of</strong> tra<strong>de</strong> unionism, free from both the political parties and the State along the lines <strong>of</strong><br />

the American mo<strong>de</strong>l, something that was completely new to the Italian tradition <strong>of</strong> labour<br />

organisations, strongly tied as they were to political parties.<br />

During the 1960's, in spite <strong>of</strong> the strong repercussions caused by internal political factors<br />

like the question <strong>of</strong> the opening to the left, the CISL consolidated its international approach.<br />

In 1965 Bruno Storti, the CISL's Secretary, was appointed Presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the ICFTU, a symbol<br />

for the overwhelming role played by European tra<strong>de</strong> unions on the international scene. As a<br />

consequence the CISL promoted a series <strong>of</strong> international initiatives with the intention <strong>of</strong><br />

radically changing its image and becoming a tra<strong>de</strong> union seriously engaged in supporting<br />

the establishment <strong>of</strong> new <strong>de</strong>mocratic organisations all over the world, like in Somalia and<br />

the Middle East.


140<br />

Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen<br />

On the European scene, the 1960's were characterised by the CISL’s change <strong>of</strong> attitu<strong>de</strong>, passing<br />

from its enthusiastic support <strong>of</strong> the European Community to a more critical approach. This<br />

was partly the result <strong>of</strong> the condition <strong>of</strong> inferiority which the Rome Treaties assigned to the<br />

labour movement. The Treaties were worked mainly out by governments, political lea<strong>de</strong>rs and<br />

the management, with little possibility <strong>of</strong> participation for tra<strong>de</strong> unions and, more seriously, paying<br />

little attention to the <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> an integrated policy in the social field. This condition<br />

became more than evi<strong>de</strong>nt in the absence <strong>of</strong> tra<strong>de</strong> union representatives sitting in European institutions.<br />

No labour representative took part in the Messina negotiations and in spite <strong>of</strong> the continuous<br />

requests for being represented in the Commission, only the Economic and Social Committee,<br />

a consultative body with no <strong>de</strong>cision-making power, allotted one third <strong>of</strong> its seats to tra<strong>de</strong><br />

union representatives. In spite <strong>of</strong> this limited success, the CISL believed that the creation <strong>of</strong> a<br />

Common Market could provi<strong>de</strong> the solution to Italian unemployment and for this reason it<br />

started a propaganda campaign among its members, asking for the setting up <strong>of</strong> a European<br />

Social Fund, seen as an instrument for financing pr<strong>of</strong>essional training. The author stresses how<br />

during the 1960's the CISL consolidated its European i<strong>de</strong>ntity through the <strong>de</strong>bate with other<br />

European tra<strong>de</strong> unions, taking part in Jean Monnet’s Committee for the United States <strong>of</strong> Europe<br />

and starting a dialogue with the Commissioner Lionello Levi Sandri with the aim <strong>of</strong> promoting a<br />

European social policy and supporting Italian workers who travelled abroad. The real turning<br />

point in the question <strong>of</strong> labour movement representation in Europe came about with the establishment<br />

<strong>of</strong> the European Tra<strong>de</strong> Union Confe<strong>de</strong>ration in 1973, which also comprised the European<br />

Christian unions and, since 1974, the Communist CGIL, marking a leap forward in the new<br />

role played by the European labour movements in Brussels.<br />

During the 1970's internal political factors became prepon<strong>de</strong>rant: Ciampani points out<br />

how the Italian labour movement tried to loosen its ties with the political parties. After the<br />

violent protests which took place in 1968, the question <strong>of</strong> promoting the unification <strong>of</strong> the<br />

three Italian labour organisations became the focus <strong>of</strong> their activity, and in 1971 the<br />

CGIL-CISL and UIL agreed on a common program. Even though real unity <strong>of</strong> action met<br />

with many obstacles and actually was never achieved, the three organisations tried to find a<br />

“gentlemen's agreement” signing a pact for unity <strong>of</strong> action in 1972 and working towards<br />

common goals during that period.<br />

The last part <strong>of</strong> the book, focussing on the 1980's and 1990's, is particularly interesting as<br />

the links between internal and international factors become more complex with the radical<br />

changes that occurred in the international system forcing the CISL, as well as all the European<br />

labour movements, to start an internal <strong>de</strong>bate regarding the new role played by the<br />

tra<strong>de</strong> unions in a globalised system. The fall <strong>of</strong> the Berlin Wall, the German unification, the<br />

collapse <strong>of</strong> the Soviet Union and the end <strong>of</strong> the Cold War had obvious consequences in the<br />

social field, as the role played by the labour movement changed radically.<br />

On the European scene, the '80s and '90s appear more successful for the labour movement's<br />

goals. Ciampani points out the role played by the new Presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the European<br />

Commission, Jacques Delors, in promoting a new dialogue with the social actors, with the<br />

aim <strong>of</strong> setting up a social space in Europe. For the first time the European Community<br />

acknowledged the right <strong>of</strong> the social parties to negotiate among themselves. This acceleration<br />

was to lead to the Social Chart approved by the Strasbourg European Council in 1989,<br />

which, <strong>de</strong>spite lacking any real binding value, reinforced labour's participation in the European<br />

<strong>de</strong>cision-making process. The election <strong>of</strong> Emilio Gabaglio, as the European Tra<strong>de</strong><br />

Union Confe<strong>de</strong>ration Secretary during the Maastricht Treaty negotiations was particularly<br />

significant as it gave the CISL an extraordinary opportunity to play a role in working out the<br />

Maastricht Treaty articles on the establishment <strong>of</strong> a European social policy.<br />

In general, Ciampani's book is a pioneering work which opens the way to a new series <strong>of</strong><br />

European studies, focussing on the role played by non-governmental actors in shaping the<br />

European Union’s <strong>history</strong>. In this context the CISL's case appears particularly interesting not


Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen 141<br />

only for the pronounced international pr<strong>of</strong>ile <strong>de</strong>veloped by the Italian tra<strong>de</strong> union since its<br />

origins, but also because it casts light on a series <strong>of</strong> initiatives which clearly <strong>de</strong>monstrate<br />

how since the 1970's Italy has tried to find a space among its European partners, in particular<br />

France and Germany, by promoting the <strong>de</strong>velopment <strong>of</strong> a social policy. In this context the<br />

role played by the CISL in close cooperation with the Italian government appears particularly<br />

significant.<br />

Maria Eleonora Guasconi<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Urbino<br />

Dimitris N. CHRYSSOCHOOU – Theorizing European Integration, Sage, London,<br />

2001, 240 p. – ISBN 0-7619-6286-7 – paperback: 16.99 £.<br />

In his book Theorizing European Integration, Dimitris Chryssochoou aims at nothing less than a<br />

reformulation <strong>of</strong> what European <strong>integration</strong> research should be aiming at: In place <strong>of</strong> the dominance<br />

<strong>of</strong> the “microcosm <strong>of</strong> sector-specific analyses” (p.2), future scholarship on the European<br />

Union should be more open and geared towards a re-thinking <strong>of</strong> the epistemology <strong>of</strong> EU studies<br />

by asking “what constitutes legitimate questions and answers for <strong>integration</strong> scholarship” (p.2)?<br />

Chryssochoou’s major contention is that existing theories <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong> are too narrowly<br />

focused and conceptually confined to “grasp the distinctive nature <strong>of</strong> the European polity<br />

and its complex … governance structures” (p.1). He claims that this insufficiency in extant<br />

European <strong>integration</strong> theorizing is mainly the result <strong>of</strong> the “raw positivism <strong>of</strong> self-styled<br />

‘social scientists’ confining the art <strong>of</strong> theorizing to a narrow set <strong>of</strong> verifiable or falsifiable<br />

hypotheses” (p.6). Yet, what should <strong>integration</strong> theory do or seek to achieve instead?<br />

Chryssochoou has an answer ready at hand. In or<strong>de</strong>r to gain a <strong>de</strong>eper un<strong>de</strong>rstanding <strong>of</strong> the<br />

emerging Euro-polity, its constitutive ‘civic spheres’ and ‘political spaces’, researchers have<br />

to free themselves from the cages <strong>of</strong> “‘strict’ science” advocated by ‘KKV’-type scholars<br />

(p.8). 1 Although much <strong>of</strong> Chryssochoou’s book is about existing theories <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong><br />

which he presents at length – half <strong>of</strong> the volume is <strong>de</strong>dicated to a review <strong>of</strong> theories from the<br />

functionalism and fe<strong>de</strong>ralism <strong>of</strong> the Community’s ‘formative’ years to the present new-institutionalism<br />

<strong>de</strong>bate – he is critical and sceptical about the contributions these theories are<br />

capable <strong>of</strong> making in or<strong>de</strong>r to meet two key challenges <strong>of</strong> the evolving European polity, the<br />

‘<strong>de</strong>mocratic <strong>de</strong>ficit’ and the lack <strong>of</strong> a transnational civic sphere. In the final chapters <strong>of</strong> the<br />

book he proposes to remedy this situation.<br />

First, Chryssochoou advances an alternative characterization <strong>of</strong> the EU polity, based on<br />

Lijphart’s theory <strong>of</strong> consociationalism, illuminating key features <strong>of</strong> European governance<br />

which other characterizations, such as the fe<strong>de</strong>ral or confe<strong>de</strong>ral state analogy, do not grasp.<br />

According to him, the EU can best be <strong>de</strong>picted as a ‘confe<strong>de</strong>ral consociation’ possessing<br />

key elements <strong>of</strong> a consociational polity: a power-sharing ‘governing’ coalition <strong>of</strong> member<br />

states, some form <strong>of</strong> proportional representation in the <strong>de</strong>cision-making institutions, a (qualified)<br />

right <strong>of</strong> mutual veto, and segmental autonomy <strong>of</strong> the constituent (national) parts. He<br />

justifies the attribute <strong>of</strong> a ‘confe<strong>de</strong>ral’ polity through the existence <strong>of</strong> “equally sovereign<br />

<strong>de</strong>moi, each with its own distinctive national i<strong>de</strong>ntity, political tradition, social structure and<br />

civic culture” (p.141). Especially in the more recent treaty amending bargains, the confe<strong>de</strong>ral<br />

nature <strong>of</strong> the polity poses an increasing challenge to EU governance. Given the increasing<br />

asymmetry between and politicization <strong>of</strong> an elite-controlled process <strong>of</strong> further policy<br />

<strong>integration</strong> and a concomitant compromising <strong>of</strong> the principles <strong>of</strong> “ruler accountability and<br />

1. G. King, R. O. Keohane and S. Verba, Designing Social Inquiry. Scientific Inference in Qualitative<br />

Research, Princeton University Press, Princeton, 1994.


142<br />

responsible government” resulting in a <strong>de</strong>mocratic <strong>de</strong>ficit, the EU’s legitimacy <strong>de</strong>ficit is<br />

exacerbated in the absence <strong>of</strong> European ‘civic sphere’ or ‘<strong>de</strong>mos’ (p.164).<br />

Chryssochoous’s analysis <strong>of</strong> the ina<strong>de</strong>quacies <strong>of</strong> extant <strong>integration</strong> theories to ask (and<br />

answer) the question about how these pressing legitimacy concerns can be solved, leads him, in a<br />

second step, to issue a plea for more engagement in ‘metatheorizing’. He claims that existing<br />

<strong>integration</strong> theories are “trapped in the legacy <strong>of</strong> functionalist-driven, task-oriented and problem-solving<br />

mo<strong>de</strong>s <strong>of</strong> collective action” and are hence inapt to ask and answer the ‘right’ questions<br />

“<strong>of</strong> polity, <strong>de</strong>mocracy, i<strong>de</strong>ntity and legitimate governance within the evolving ‘EU or<strong>de</strong>r’”<br />

(p.172). What Chryssochoou calls for is a ‘normative turn’ in European <strong>integration</strong> theorizing,<br />

which <strong>de</strong>notes the elaboration <strong>of</strong> a “‘system <strong>of</strong> i<strong>de</strong>as’ that attaches a priori importance to questions<br />

<strong>of</strong> bringing the Union closer to its citizens” (p.173). Hence, presently dominant questions in<br />

EU scholarship, such as how to explain outcomes and processes, should cease to be a main concern<br />

for future research. What is important, claims Chryssochoou, is to improve the EU’s<br />

grass-root support, i.e. to find and to construct the EU’s “civic core” and, in or<strong>de</strong>r to achieve this<br />

goal, reflect about “in whose name are publicly binding <strong>de</strong>cisions taken in Brussels, or what<br />

really makes for the polity’s ‘constituting authority’?” (p.174)<br />

Although Chryssochoou’s book addresses interesting and pressing problems <strong>of</strong> EU governance,<br />

i.e. the <strong>of</strong>ten alleged lop-si<strong>de</strong>dness between ‘output-’ and ‘input-legitimacy’ 2 and<br />

the lack <strong>of</strong> a European transnational civic sphere, his reflections on how these twin-problems<br />

should be tackled and solved are, unfortunately, <strong>de</strong>legated to no more than a quarter <strong>of</strong><br />

his book. Furthermore, his thoughts on these problems are neither convincing nor do they<br />

lead to the advancement <strong>of</strong> a coherent research agenda. Two main <strong>de</strong>ficiencies that un<strong>de</strong>rscore<br />

this seemingly harsh statement spring readily to mind.<br />

First, Chryssochoou’s ‘jump’ from the alleged ina<strong>de</strong>quacy <strong>of</strong> existing theories <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong><br />

to the conclusion that more ‘metatheorizing’ should be done, lacks the foundation upon which an<br />

enterprise <strong>of</strong> this type could be justified. At no place in the book does he advance a coherent set<br />

<strong>of</strong> criteria according to which he intends to compare, contrast and criticize existing theories <strong>of</strong><br />

<strong>integration</strong>. Half <strong>of</strong> the volume provi<strong>de</strong>s a good literature review; however, it is not evi<strong>de</strong>nt how<br />

this review adds to the general argument <strong>of</strong> the book. The author explores at the outset the somewhat<br />

trivial point that theories help us or<strong>de</strong>r and un<strong>de</strong>rstand the world in manifold ways, i.e.<br />

through <strong>de</strong>duction, induction, normative claims etc. But, for various reasons, no social scientist<br />

would probably disagree with the assertion that theories are important. Chryssochoou’s presentation<br />

<strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong> theories illuminates how historical context and theory formation continue to<br />

fuel one another, although, one may ask, for what purpose? If the fundamental objective <strong>of</strong> the<br />

presentation <strong>of</strong> these different ‘theories’ is to <strong>de</strong>monstrate their ina<strong>de</strong>quacy to ask and answer<br />

questions that relate to the problem <strong>of</strong> the Community’s <strong>de</strong>mocratic cre<strong>de</strong>ntials, then Chryssochoou<br />

has undoubtedly succee<strong>de</strong>d in beheading ‘theory strawmen’. Yet, he failed to explicitly<br />

recognize that some <strong>of</strong> the approaches reviewed are explanatory theories (that can be tested),<br />

some normative and prescriptive, others – by social science standards – rather i<strong>de</strong>ologies than<br />

theories. Hence, it is about as fair to accuse explanatory theory <strong>of</strong> being blind to providing<br />

answers to allegedly normative questions, as it is to accuse a football team to do badly in basketball.<br />

If we accept that theory has different purposes, as the author ma<strong>de</strong> more or less explicit in<br />

the first chapter, why should so much space be <strong>de</strong>dicated to <strong>integration</strong> theories which Chryssochoou<br />

belittles for their ‘too narrow focus’? The main criticism here is that Chryssochoou does<br />

not <strong>de</strong>liver on what he seemingly sets out to do when he tells the rea<strong>de</strong>r about the value <strong>of</strong> theorizing<br />

in general: Theory evaluation has to follow certain rules and standards <strong>of</strong> comparison –<br />

where are they?<br />

2. Scharpf, W.Fritz, Economic Integration, Democracy and the Welfare State, in: Journal <strong>of</strong> European<br />

Public Policy, 4,1(1997), pp.18-36.


Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen 143<br />

Secondly, Chryssochoou’s plea for the use <strong>of</strong> metatheory in re<strong>de</strong>fining the European <strong>integration</strong><br />

research agenda is equally groun<strong>de</strong>d on weak foundations. Based on his characterization <strong>of</strong><br />

the European polity as a ‘confe<strong>de</strong>ral consociation’, he shows that one <strong>of</strong> the key problems that<br />

troubles the present and future EU, the problem <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>mocratic legitimacy, has to be put at<br />

center-stage. Yet, why should this problem be approached through ‘metatheorizing’? Chryssochoous’s<br />

claim for metatheory is based on two assumptions. First, the problem <strong>of</strong> transnational<br />

<strong>de</strong>mocracy-building to overcome the challenges to <strong>de</strong>mocratic legitimacy can only be addressed<br />

in the context <strong>of</strong> constructing a European civic sphere or <strong>de</strong>mos; and second, theories <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong><br />

are too narrowly confined as to be capable <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>aling with these questions. The first assumption<br />

is based on an i<strong>de</strong>al-typical characterization <strong>of</strong> the EU as a ‘confe<strong>de</strong>ral consociation’ and<br />

forms part <strong>of</strong> a larger <strong>de</strong>bate about a ‘<strong>de</strong>mos-requirement’ for the workings <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>mocracy, a<br />

<strong>de</strong>bate which he does not even hint at in the book. However, why should the rea<strong>de</strong>r be convinced<br />

about the ‘civic sphere’ or ‘<strong>de</strong>mos-requirement’ for the construction <strong>of</strong> a legitimate and viable<br />

European polity when Chryssochoou does not provi<strong>de</strong> compelling arguments why we should follow<br />

this assumption? He <strong>de</strong>finitely has a case when he claims that the ‘input’-si<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>mocratic<br />

legitimacy is heavily bur<strong>de</strong>ned, but he fails to <strong>de</strong>liver on the implications – he simply assumes<br />

that European <strong>de</strong>mocracy has to be European <strong>de</strong>mos-cracy. Consequently, the second assumption<br />

– that extant theories <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong> neither ask the right questions nor provi<strong>de</strong> any answers to the<br />

<strong>de</strong>mos-cracy-problem– is a corollary <strong>of</strong> the first. However, only if we accept the ill-foun<strong>de</strong>d first<br />

assumption does the second make sense.<br />

Theorizing and metatheorizing/‘self-reflection’ on the European polity should follow criteria<br />

which are clearly <strong>de</strong>fined and transparent. Chryssochoou’s book has ma<strong>de</strong> a valid and<br />

important point when affirming that <strong>de</strong>mocratic legitimacy in the EU is un<strong>de</strong>r stress – but he<br />

has provi<strong>de</strong>d a nonconvincing argument as to why explanatory theory and positivist science<br />

should not be able to address and <strong>de</strong>al with the question <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong>mocratic legitimacy. Furthermore,<br />

even if we were to accept that we need more metatheorizing, Chryssochoou’s book<br />

ends merely on a plea to do just that with little in the way <strong>of</strong> suggestions as to how to<br />

metatheorize, and which rules to follow.<br />

Berthold Rittberger<br />

Nuffield College<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Oxford<br />

Wolfram KAISER – Using Europe, Abusing the Europeans. Britain and European Integration,<br />

1945-63, Macmillan, London, 1999, 312 p. – ISBN 0-333-77635-6 – paperback:<br />

18.99 £.<br />

When Wolfram Kaiser's Using Europe, Abusing the Europeans. Britain and European Integration,<br />

1945-63 was originally published in 1996 it was lau<strong>de</strong>d on its dust jacket as 'indispensible',<br />

'outstanding' and 'an important contribution to British <strong>history</strong>'. At that time, the<br />

book <strong>de</strong>served such commendations as it was the first archive-based study <strong>of</strong> Britain's reaction<br />

to the formation <strong>of</strong> the European Economic Community (EEC). It has since held a notable<br />

position in what has become a rich and dominant area <strong>of</strong> research and teaching, enough<br />

for it to be reprinted with a new preface in 1999. Kaiser's subject – essentially British policy<br />

from the Messina Conference <strong>of</strong> June 1955 to <strong>de</strong> Gaulle's veto <strong>of</strong> Britain's first application<br />

in January 1963 – gained him a place in the historiography, but it was his argumentative<br />

style and uncompromising judgements which motivated other historians to engage with his<br />

work. To <strong>de</strong>termine whether the dust jacket endorsements <strong>of</strong> Using Europe remain valid,<br />

Kaiser's arguments have to be analysed, particularly in light <strong>of</strong> subsequent research. These<br />

may be divi<strong>de</strong>d into those specific to 1955-63 and those concerning the wi<strong>de</strong>r <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong><br />

Britain and European <strong>integration</strong>.


144<br />

Kaiser <strong>of</strong>fers numerous contentions about 1955-63 but there are four which are most significant.<br />

The first is that in 1955 the British were complacent, arrogant and un<strong>de</strong>restimated<br />

the Six but did not 'miss a bus' at Messina (pp.27, 54-60). The criticisms ranged by Kaiser<br />

about Britain's <strong>de</strong>cision making and diplomacy in 1955 were not entirely original although<br />

they were based on a more <strong>de</strong>tailed analysis than that <strong>of</strong> preceding accounts. Kaiser has no<br />

sympathy for Foreign Office attitu<strong>de</strong>s, especially for the then Foreign Secretary, Harold<br />

Macmillan, to whom he attributes personal responsibility for Britain's disastrous diplomacy<br />

(pp.48-49). Although the failed diplomacy cannot be gainsaid, Kaiser's views on Macmillan<br />

may be disputed; if Macmillan is to be criticised then it ought to be for his non-involvement<br />

rather than his involvement. As to Kaiser's rejection <strong>of</strong> Miriam Camps' view that Britain<br />

missed a bus in 1955 – questioning whether there was a bus to catch and adding that Britain<br />

was heading along a different road (pp.54-60) – whilst these are germane points to raise,<br />

they are speculative and suggest little more than the unpredictability <strong>of</strong> events for Britain<br />

and the Six in 1955. Kaiser is on stronger ground in his second major argument which<br />

explains how British attitu<strong>de</strong>s towards European <strong>integration</strong> evolved over 1956-57 to produce<br />

Plan G, Britain's proposal for a European industrial Free Tra<strong>de</strong> Area (FTA) (pp.60-87).<br />

Nevertheless, Kaiser's treatment <strong>of</strong> the FTA is ultimately negative and others, such as Ellison,<br />

Moravcsik and Schaad, have <strong>of</strong>fered more positive interpretations.<br />

Kaiser's third and most significant argument is that Britain's first application for EEC membership<br />

in 1961 was 'the result <strong>of</strong> a dual “appeasement” strategy' to maintain strong<br />

Anglo-American relations, particularly the nuclear link, and to hold the Conservative Party<br />

together whilst splitting the Labour Party (pp.XXXII and pp.108-173). Without doubt this is an<br />

interesting explanation, if a rather contrived one. Yet that US pressure was dominant in Macmillan's<br />

mind, and that an EEC application was seen as a diplomatic counter to secure the <strong>de</strong>al eventually<br />

agreed at Nassau, un<strong>de</strong>rplays the other motives for the first application and overplays its<br />

potential by-products. Furthermore, it could be argued that the domestic political context <strong>of</strong> the<br />

application was not as straightforward as Using Europe suggests although extensive research on<br />

this subject has yet to be produced. Nevertheless, the work <strong>of</strong> Bange, Deighton, Ellison, Griffiths<br />

and Ward, Ludlow, Tratt, Hugo Young and John Young, amongst others, <strong>of</strong>fer contrary interpretations<br />

to Kaiser's on the motives for the first application.<br />

Kaiser's fourth main argument consi<strong>de</strong>rs the fate <strong>of</strong> Britain's first application. Here, he<br />

focuses on high politics, particularly the relations between <strong>de</strong> Gaulle and Macmillan, and<br />

the issue <strong>of</strong> nuclear diplomacy (pp.174-203). Although his account is far less <strong>de</strong>veloped in<br />

terms <strong>of</strong> evi<strong>de</strong>nce than his treatment <strong>of</strong> the motives for the application, it nevertheless has<br />

merit. Yet Ludlow's research on the conditional nature <strong>of</strong> the application and on the Brussels<br />

negotiations themselves, along with the work <strong>of</strong> others, <strong>de</strong>monstrates that Kaiser tells only<br />

one version <strong>of</strong> this story. Ludlow's concentration on the ebb and flow <strong>of</strong> the negotiations and<br />

their technicalities and the attitu<strong>de</strong>s <strong>of</strong> the Community and the Six suggests that Britain<br />

failed to exploit opportunities for success prior to the strengthening <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong> Gaulle's power<br />

after 1962. The first application's <strong>de</strong>mise, according to Ludlow, was thus a significant failure<br />

for the British, contrary to Kaiser's view that on the 'diplomatic level' it was 'a full success'<br />

(p.203). Whatever view is taken <strong>of</strong> <strong>de</strong> Gaulle's veto in January 1963 it cannot be <strong>de</strong>nied that<br />

it left the British government in the position which it had worked to avoid since the Messina<br />

Conference <strong>of</strong> June 1955.<br />

Clearly, Using Europe is important in that Kaiser's arguments about 1955-63, <strong>de</strong>spite the<br />

criticisms that may be ma<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong> them, are significant and have generated historical <strong>de</strong>bate.<br />

Can the same be said <strong>of</strong> Kaiser's assertions about 'Britain and Europe' when he ventures outsi<strong>de</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> 1955-63, especially as his epilogue covers 1963-1996 and the 1999 reprint's preface<br />

comments on 1997-98? Using Europe does not make enough <strong>of</strong> its own historiographical<br />

criticisms <strong>of</strong> the 'awkward partner' school and the British Son<strong>de</strong>rweg thesis as <strong>de</strong>picted in<br />

the introduction (see pp.XXIX-XXXI). That Kaiser himself ultimately succumbs to 'round-


Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen 145<br />

ing up the usual suspects' (p.XXX), criticising the British for their arrogance and un<strong>de</strong>restimation<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Six and not <strong>of</strong>fering a thorough-going comparative perspective leaves him to a<br />

<strong>de</strong>gree hoist by his own petard. Neither does Using Europe distinguish itself by engaging<br />

significantly with the research <strong>of</strong> the noteworthy historians <strong>of</strong> the field, primarily Alan Milward<br />

and John Young. The 1999 preface might have been employed by Kaiser to comment<br />

on the literature since 1996 and to place his book amongst it but instead he focuses on party<br />

politics and Britain's relationship with the EU from 1996 to 1998. Perhaps his <strong>de</strong>cision to do<br />

so reflects his own belief that it is here that his work is <strong>of</strong> greater effect?<br />

Despite being for the most part a diplomatic <strong>history</strong>, Using Europe also <strong>de</strong>velops arguments<br />

about the domestic political context, particularly party political, <strong>of</strong> British foreign<br />

policy. This is the strength <strong>of</strong> the epilogue and <strong>of</strong> the 1999 preface where Kaiser comments<br />

on how Britain's European policy has consistently been driven by, and un<strong>de</strong>rmined by, party<br />

politics, especially <strong>of</strong> the Conservative kind. In this Kaiser returns briefly to the points<br />

raised in his introduction and states that 'Unintentionally, the Son<strong>de</strong>rweg thesis <strong>of</strong> British<br />

postwar <strong>history</strong> adopts the myth, created by the British political elite, <strong>of</strong> British exceptionalism'<br />

(p.211). Dismissing the premise that Britain's choices can be explained by its difference<br />

from other Western European countries, a view restated recently by John Young, Kaiser<br />

argues that British diplomacy set it apart from the early EEC. Moreover, he believes that this<br />

had, and has, party political motivation: 'What is arguably even more relevant to un<strong>de</strong>rstanding<br />

Britain's relationship with its European partners was – and is more than ever in the 1990s<br />

– the enormous influence <strong>of</strong> party political controversies and tactics' (p.218). Whilst this<br />

draws Kaiser's thesis together, and explains why he chose the title he did for his book, perhaps<br />

it does not <strong>of</strong>fer the revision <strong>of</strong> the awkward partner school that he suggests as he is<br />

forced to admit that 'Seen over the entire postwar period, [party political controversies and<br />

tactics] have been far more divisive [in Britain] than in any other member state' (p.218).<br />

Thus, Kaiser's main contribution to the historiographical <strong>de</strong>bate, apart from his arguments<br />

about 1955-63, is that he adds domestic politics to the list <strong>of</strong> factors which explain why Britain<br />

has found it so difficult to integrate with Europe.<br />

James Ellison<br />

Queen Mary, University <strong>of</strong> London<br />

George PETRAKOS, Stoyan TOTEV (ed.) – The Development <strong>of</strong> the Balkan Region,<br />

Ashgate, Al<strong>de</strong>rshot, 2001, 520 p. – ISBN 0-7546-1225-2 – 65,00 £.<br />

Ce livre n’a rien d’un recueil d’articles. Les douze auteurs se sont livrés sous la direction <strong>de</strong><br />

George Petrakos et Stoyan Totev à une réflexion appr<strong>of</strong>ondie sur les limites et l’avenir du<br />

développement économique dans la région <strong>de</strong>s Balkans. La pério<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> transition <strong>de</strong>puis dix<br />

ans en Europe a soulevé beaucoup <strong>de</strong> questions, restées sans une réponse claire et convaincante.<br />

Par exemple, pourquoi les pays balkaniques sont-ils tellement différents en termes<br />

d’efficacité économique par rapport aux pays <strong>de</strong> l’Europe Centrale? Pourquoi ces pays là<br />

semblent-ils échouer dans leurs efforts <strong>de</strong> transition vers l’économie du marché? Est-ce que<br />

l’échec <strong>de</strong>s politiques intérieures ou les conditions initiales désavantageuses et l’environnement<br />

géographique défavorable sont-ils responsables <strong>de</strong> cette médiocre efficacité? En plus,<br />

quelle réponse politique a été donnée par l’Union européenne aux questions susmentionnées<br />

et qu’est-ce qu’on peut faire actuellement? Voilà quelques questions cruciales qui se posent<br />

dans ce livre pour l’ensemble <strong>de</strong>s pays balkaniques.<br />

Dans ce volume, les auteurs essayent <strong>de</strong> faire une analyse comparative <strong>de</strong>s problèmes d’efficacité<br />

économique et d’adaptation structurelle dans les pays <strong>de</strong>s Balkans. Ce livre, composé <strong>de</strong><br />

seize articles au total, est divisé en <strong>de</strong>ux parties. La première partie est constituée d’un travail <strong>de</strong><br />

recherche comparative sur <strong>de</strong>s questions politiques et analytiques. Dans cette partie du volume


146<br />

on fait l’analyse <strong>de</strong> la performance économique et <strong>de</strong>s structures <strong>de</strong> l’industrie et du commerce<br />

dans les pays balkaniques, <strong>de</strong>s relations commerciales inter-balkaniques et <strong>de</strong> la coopération économique,<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’évolution et <strong>de</strong> la distribution <strong>de</strong>s investissements directs étrangers, <strong>de</strong> la réforme<br />

structurelles en ce qui concerne les privatisations, <strong>de</strong> l’efficacité <strong>de</strong> l’industrie balkanique, <strong>de</strong> la<br />

désintégration ou intégration dans les Balkans et <strong>de</strong>s politiques <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne pour la<br />

reconstruction et le développement <strong>de</strong> la région.<br />

La <strong>de</strong>uxième partie du volume est composée <strong>de</strong>s étu<strong>de</strong>s <strong>de</strong> cas et <strong>de</strong>s recherches sur les<br />

différents pays <strong>de</strong> la région. Après avoir démontré la problématique générale du développement<br />

économique <strong>de</strong> la région, les auteurs se lancent dans l’analyse <strong>de</strong>s facteurs spécifiques<br />

qui influencent les divers pays <strong>de</strong>s Balkans. Le cas <strong>de</strong> la Bulgarie, <strong>de</strong> l’Albanie et <strong>de</strong> la Roumanie,<br />

pays en phase d’une longue et difficile transition économique, montre bien les contradictions<br />

<strong>de</strong> ce processus: les possibilités et les conditions pour une coopération et une<br />

intégration régionale et leurs limites en termes d’adaptation structurelle. L’expérience <strong>de</strong> la<br />

Grèce, pays membre <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne, indique clairement le rôle important <strong>de</strong> la<br />

géographie dans les relations commerciales et le développement économique. Dans le cas<br />

grecque, la proximité géographique est un <strong>de</strong>s facteurs importants qui conditionnent fortement<br />

l’orientation <strong>de</strong>s investissements directs étrangers, comme p.ex. en direction <strong>de</strong> Bulgarie,<br />

d'Albanie, <strong>de</strong> Roumanie ou <strong>de</strong> la FYROM.<br />

Au début du nouveau millénaire les pays balkaniques, à l’exception <strong>de</strong> la Grèce, qui a<br />

honoré les critères <strong>de</strong> convergence pour faire partie <strong>de</strong> l’Union Economique et Monétaire,<br />

ont eu moins <strong>de</strong> chance que les autres ex-pays démocratie populaires <strong>de</strong> l’Est européen.<br />

Pour certains pays balkaniques, toute la pério<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s années 90 a été, dans le meilleur <strong>de</strong>s<br />

cas, une ère <strong>de</strong> crise prolongée ou, dans le pire <strong>de</strong>s cas, un cauchemar. Si les indications présentées<br />

à travers les différents articles <strong>de</strong>vaient persister dans le futur, les pays balkaniques<br />

seraient décrochés davantage encore par les pays développés <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne, en<br />

constituant un noyau périphérique européen encore plus faible. Voilà quelques observations<br />

pessimistes <strong>de</strong>s auteurs <strong>de</strong> ce livre.<br />

Dans le livre présenté ici la perspective s’appr<strong>of</strong>ondit et s’élargit au terme <strong>de</strong> recherches<br />

basées sur <strong>de</strong> nombreuses sources comme en témoignent les notes abondantes qui accompagnent<br />

chaque article. A n’en pas douter, cet ouvrage intéressant et riche incite à la réflexion. Il constitue<br />

un apport important à la recherche et nourrit un débat sur l’avenir <strong>de</strong>s Balkans.<br />

Petrit Nathanaili<br />

Université <strong>de</strong> Tirana<br />

Jason G. HARTELL and Johan F.M. SWINNEN (eds.) – Agriculture and East-West<br />

European Integration, Ashgate Publishing Ltd., Al<strong>de</strong>rshot, 2000, pp.V-XIX, 264 –<br />

ISBN 0-7546-1201-5 – 39,95 £.<br />

Cette étu<strong>de</strong> évalue les conséquences qu’entraînera l’adhésion <strong>de</strong>s pays <strong>de</strong> l’Europe centrale et<br />

orientale (PECO) à l’Union européenne dans le domaine <strong>de</strong> l’agriculture. Elle relève<br />

quelques-unes <strong>de</strong>s incertitu<strong>de</strong>s et <strong>de</strong>s contraintes fondamentales, les effets économiques et les<br />

coûts d’adaptation qu’engendrera l’intégration <strong>de</strong> ces pays dans l’Union. Le premier chapitre<br />

donne une vue d’ensemble thématique <strong>de</strong> la région en général et arrive à la conclusion que<br />

l’adoption <strong>de</strong> la politique agricole commune par les pays PECO aboutira à une augmentation<br />

substantielle <strong>de</strong> la production agricole, entraînant <strong>de</strong>s conséquences macro-économiques considérables<br />

dans tous les pays candidats à l’adhésion.<br />

Après cette analyse générale, l’étu<strong>de</strong> <strong>of</strong>fre un examen plus détaillé et plus précis pour<br />

sept <strong>de</strong>s pays candidats. Les perspectives qui s'ouvrent aux Etats baltes sont plutôt partagées:<br />

la région possè<strong>de</strong> une gran<strong>de</strong> abondance <strong>de</strong> terres et vient d’entamer le processus du


Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen 147<br />

rétablissement <strong>de</strong> la propriété privée. Cependant, à un accroissement <strong>de</strong> la production dans<br />

certains secteurs (par exemple le secteur laitier), correspond une situation moins encourageante<br />

dans secteur céréalier où la compétitive souffre <strong>de</strong>s conditions défavorables du climat<br />

et du sol. Les Etats baltes <strong>de</strong>vraient améliorer tout aussi bien la qualité <strong>de</strong>s produits que<br />

l’efficacité <strong>de</strong>s métho<strong>de</strong>s <strong>de</strong> production.<br />

La politique agricole tchèque par contre s’écarte <strong>de</strong> façon frappante <strong>de</strong>s objectifs <strong>de</strong> la<br />

Politique Agricole Commune (PAC) <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne. Ainsi, la République tchèque<br />

ne se soucie guère du maintien <strong>de</strong> la parité <strong>de</strong>s revenus entre le secteur agricole et le secteur<br />

industriel – une priorité dans l’Union européenne -, tout comme elle ne prévoit pas <strong>de</strong> ressources<br />

<strong>de</strong>stinées à compenser le secteur agricole pour <strong>de</strong>s désavantages comparés. La<br />

République tchèque dispose néanmoins <strong>de</strong> ressources à meilleur marché que l’Union européenne,<br />

pratique un système d’agriculture efficace et jouit <strong>de</strong> certains avantages en termes<br />

<strong>de</strong> plus gran<strong>de</strong> mobilité <strong>de</strong> facteurs comme la main-d’œuvre et le capital en l'occurrence.<br />

L’Union européenne est le principal partenaire commercial <strong>de</strong> la République en ce qui concerne<br />

les produits agricoles: elle fournit quelques 50% <strong>de</strong>s importations dont le pays a<br />

besoin et acquiert 40% <strong>de</strong> ses exportations agricoles.<br />

L’importance du secteur agricole en Pologne avait suscité la crainte que l’adhésion <strong>de</strong> ce<br />

pays à l’Union européenne, n’entraîne un accroissement substantiel <strong>de</strong> la production et ne<br />

ren<strong>de</strong> plus préoccupantes encore les distorsions du marché communautaire. Mais les conditions<br />

climatiques et pédologiques sont moins favorables en Pologne qu’en Union européenne.<br />

En outre, le pays continue à importer <strong>de</strong>s produits agricoles en gran<strong>de</strong>s quantités. La<br />

peur que l’adhésion polonaise ne provoque une surproduction substantielle s’est avérée<br />

injustifiée. Il y a même <strong>de</strong>s signes indiquants que les prix entre la Pologne et l’Union européenne<br />

ont convergé <strong>de</strong>puis le début <strong>de</strong>s années 1990, bien qu’il subsiste <strong>de</strong>s écarts pour<br />

certains produits (sucre, bœuf, lait, beurre).<br />

Seule la Slovénie ne pose pas <strong>de</strong> problèmes. Alors que la situation géographique <strong>de</strong> ce<br />

pays vallonné et montagneux entrave la production agricole, la Slovénie est le plus proche<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne en termes <strong>de</strong> politique agricole: une prédominance d’exploitations<br />

familiales, un fort lobby et <strong>de</strong>s prix élevés. Le processus d’adaptation à la PAC est en cours.<br />

Le secteur agricole <strong>de</strong> la Slovénie n’est pas libéralisé comme en Pologne ou en Estonie, et il<br />

y a <strong>de</strong>s craintes que les prix chutent. Mais en fait, on ne s’attend point à <strong>de</strong>s difficultés<br />

d’adaptation majeures.<br />

Ce qui n’est pas vrai pour la Bulgarie, dont la politique agricole, tout comme le niveau<br />

<strong>de</strong>s prix, diffèrent sensiblement <strong>de</strong>s réalités agricoles <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne. Tandis qu’en<br />

Union européenne les agriculteurs sont subventionnés, et même fortement, les agriculteurs<br />

bulgares sont effectivement taxés. De plus, les relations commerciales entre les <strong>de</strong>ux régions<br />

restent faibles: Le commerce agro-alimentaire entre la Bulgarie et l’Union européenne est<br />

encore instable, en partie à cause <strong>de</strong> fortes fluctuations <strong>de</strong> l’économie bulgare.<br />

Dans les quatre <strong>de</strong>rniers chapitres (7 à 10), les auteurs tirent quelques conclusions pru<strong>de</strong>ntes.<br />

Il y a eu un mouvement <strong>de</strong> migration considérable <strong>de</strong>s pays <strong>de</strong> l’Europe <strong>de</strong> l’Est vers<br />

l’Union européenne. Il s'en est suivi un accroissement <strong>de</strong> l’<strong>of</strong>fre <strong>de</strong> la main-d’œuvre agricole<br />

en Europe <strong>de</strong> l’Ouest, tandis qu’en Europe orientale, la production agricole a baissé. Certes,<br />

les politiques agricoles <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne et <strong>de</strong>s PECO ont convergé dans une certaine<br />

mesure, mais il subsiste <strong>de</strong>s différences notables entre ces <strong>de</strong>ux régions en ce qui concerne<br />

le choix <strong>de</strong>s instruments et le niveau <strong>de</strong> protection. A l’exception <strong>de</strong> la Slovénie (et sauf certains<br />

produits comme le lait dans d’autres pays candidats) le niveau <strong>de</strong> protection est toujours<br />

beaucoup plus bas dans les pays <strong>de</strong> l’Europe centrale et orientale. «Une ré-nationalisation»<br />

<strong>de</strong> la politique agricole commune, au moins en partie, pourrait constituer une solution<br />

possible pour affronter quelques-uns <strong>de</strong>s futurs défis. Etant donné que les PECO jouiront du<br />

statut <strong>de</strong> bénéficiaires nets alors que les pays membres actuels <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne<br />

<strong>de</strong>viendront dans une plus large mesure <strong>de</strong>s contributeurs nets à la PAC, l'évolution en cours


148<br />

encouragera le transfert <strong>de</strong> revenus entre pays, voir même entre régions, <strong>de</strong> l’Ouest vers<br />

l’Est. La préférence actuelle en Union européenne pour une politique agricole hautement<br />

protectionniste pourrait par conséquent diminuer.<br />

Les réflexions développées dans Agriculture and East-West European Integration reposent<br />

sur <strong>de</strong>s donnes antérieures à l'adoption <strong>de</strong> l’«Agenda 2000» par le sommet <strong>de</strong> Berlin en<br />

mars 1999. Puisque lesdites réformes décidées par le sommet <strong>de</strong> Berlin en mars sont néanmoins<br />

tout, sauf radicales, les conclusions <strong>de</strong> l'ouvrage restent toujours pertinentes. Par<br />

ailleurs, un <strong>de</strong>s attraits majeurs <strong>de</strong> l’étu<strong>de</strong> consiste en le double fait <strong>de</strong> donner au lecteur,<br />

primo, <strong>de</strong>s informations <strong>de</strong> base ainsi qu’un aperçu <strong>de</strong> l’état actuel du secteur agricole dans<br />

les Etats candidats et, secundo, d'ouvrir une perspective intéressante grâce à une analyse<br />

comparative qui, il est vrai ne concerne pas tous les pays candidats à l’adhésion. Le livre<br />

<strong>of</strong>fre par<strong>de</strong>ssus le marché une multitu<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> données statistiques et servira autant l’étudiant<br />

en agroéconomie que les passionnés <strong>de</strong> la PAC. Sans parler, bien entendu, <strong>de</strong> tous ceux,<br />

directement ou indirectement, concernés par le processus <strong>de</strong> l’élargissement.<br />

Gisela Hendriks<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Kent at Canterbury<br />

Massimiliano GUDERZO – Interesse nazionale e responsabilità globale. Gli Stati Uniti,<br />

l'Alleanza atlantica e l'integrazione europea negli anni di Johnson (1963-1969), Firenze,<br />

Aida-Il Maestrale, 2000, 611 p. – ISBN 88-8329-013-5 – 33 €.<br />

Il est <strong>de</strong>s livres dont la publication marque presque instantanément l'historiographie, pour le<br />

moins variée et désormais abondante, <strong>de</strong> l'intégration européenne. L'ouvrage volumineux <strong>de</strong><br />

Massimiliano Gu<strong>de</strong>rzo, pr<strong>of</strong>esseur associé <strong>d'histoire</strong> <strong>de</strong>s relations internationales à l'université<br />

d'Urbino, figure assurément au nombre <strong>de</strong> ceux-là. En effet, alors que les relations entre<br />

l'Europe en construction et les États-Unis ont déjà donné lieu à <strong>de</strong>s recherches fécon<strong>de</strong>s<br />

pour la pério<strong>de</strong> qui court <strong>de</strong> l'immédiat après-guerre jusqu'aux années <strong>de</strong> la prési<strong>de</strong>nce Kennedy,<br />

rares encore sont les travaux consacrés à la politique européenne <strong>de</strong> l'administration<br />

Johnson trop souvent occultée dans la littérature par la guerre du Viêt-nam et par ses<br />

répercussions immédiates sur la politique intérieure américaine. Voilà une lacune magistralement<br />

comblée. Les sources exploitées sont nombreuses (papiers Lyndon Johnson, documents<br />

diplomatiques américains et européens, archives communautaires et militaires,<br />

Mémoires et sources orales, …) et la bibliographie se révèle très soli<strong>de</strong>.<br />

A défaut <strong>de</strong> l'analyse détaillée qu'interdisent les dimensions forcément limitées imparties<br />

à cette recension, on se limitera à survoler les principaux thèmes abordés au fil <strong>de</strong> l'ouvrage.<br />

Prêtant une attention toute particulière au processus décisionnel et à la policy-making dans<br />

la conduite <strong>de</strong>s relations étrangères <strong>de</strong>s États-Unis (Maison-Blanche, Secrétariat d'État, Pentagone,<br />

Trésor) l'auteur passe au crible la politique atlantique américaine au cours <strong>de</strong>s<br />

années soixante et pointe la concordance répétée entre la recherche <strong>de</strong> l'intérêt national et la<br />

conscience, au titre <strong>de</strong> superpuissance occi<strong>de</strong>ntale, d'une responsabilité globale dans le contexte<br />

<strong>de</strong> la Guerre froi<strong>de</strong>. Il montre aussi combien cette duplicité ne pouvait inévitablement<br />

qu'entraîner <strong>de</strong>s malentendus avec un partenaire européen <strong>de</strong> plus en plus désireux d'affirmer<br />

sa position économique, politique et militaire mondiale et, en ce faisant, tenté <strong>de</strong> traiter<br />

d'égal à égal avec les États-Unis malgré les soubresauts répétés du processus d'intégration.<br />

Dans un premier temps, le Pr<strong>of</strong>. Gu<strong>de</strong>rzo se penche sur l'année 1963, en<strong>de</strong>uillée par<br />

l'assassinat <strong>de</strong> John F. Kennedy, pour examiner la portée du «grand <strong>de</strong>ssein» atlantique du<br />

prési<strong>de</strong>nt démocrate en faveur d'un partnership américano-européen et décrypter les réactions<br />

<strong>de</strong> Washington face au projet gaullien d'Europe européenne et indépendante, au renforcement<br />

<strong>de</strong> l'axe Paris-Bonn et à l'opposition française à l'entrée du Royaume-Uni dans la<br />

Communauté économique européenne (CEE). Accordant une attention soutenue aux ques-


Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen 149<br />

tions <strong>de</strong> défense, l'auteur analyse ensuite l'origine et la portée stratégique du projet américain<br />

<strong>de</strong> force multilatérale nucléaire (MLF) et s'attar<strong>de</strong> sur l'attitu<strong>de</strong> adoptée par les stratèges<br />

<strong>de</strong> la Maison-Blanche à l'égard <strong>de</strong>s velléités françaises <strong>de</strong> développer unilatéralement une<br />

force <strong>de</strong> frappe nucléaire nationale. Il précise ensuite les raisons qui ont conduit les<br />

États-Unis à développer une nouvelle doctrine stratégique <strong>de</strong> riposte graduée mieux adaptée<br />

à la menace soviétique en cas d'escala<strong>de</strong> nucléaire. Mais les Européens, qui réclament un<br />

nouveau partage <strong>de</strong>s responsabilités atomiques au sein <strong>de</strong> l'Alliance, ne parviennent pas à<br />

s'entendre sur les moyens <strong>de</strong> la réformer. Dès lors, toujours plus isolée compte tenu <strong>de</strong> ses<br />

ambitions d'indépendance nationale, la France s'engage dans ce qui apparaît bien comme<br />

une logique <strong>de</strong> rupture et déci<strong>de</strong>, en 1966, <strong>de</strong> retirer ses forces du comman<strong>de</strong>ment militaire<br />

intégré <strong>de</strong> l'Alliance atlantique. A cet égard, le livre fourmille d'éléments qui mettent en<br />

lumière, parfois au jour le jour, la complexité <strong>de</strong>s relations, y compris personnelles, entre<br />

Johnson et De Gaulle. «Débarrassés» <strong>de</strong> l'épine française, les États-Unis réactivent alors<br />

leurs relations privilégiées avec la Gran<strong>de</strong>-Bretagne et avec l'Allemagne fédérale qui, <strong>de</strong><br />

facto, dominent les débats au sein du Nuclear Planning Group (NPG) immédiatement créé.<br />

La RFA, qui a fini par renoncer à la MLF et par accepter le principe d'un accord <strong>de</strong> non-prolifération<br />

atomique, se trouve alors enfin associée aux décisions occi<strong>de</strong>ntales en matière<br />

d'armement nucléaire. Un an plus tard, le rapport Harmel saura lui aussi consacrer le lea<strong>de</strong>rship<br />

américain, présent et futur, au sein <strong>de</strong> la coalition atlantique.<br />

Au total, sur fond <strong>de</strong> crise <strong>de</strong> l'Otan, <strong>de</strong> la transformation <strong>de</strong>s relations Est-Ouest et <strong>de</strong>s<br />

péripéties qui secouent les relations franco-américaines, le livre met particulièrement bien<br />

en lumière les difficultés <strong>de</strong> l'administration Johnson à composer avec les solidarités et les<br />

antagonismes intra-européens et, dès lors, à conduire une politique à la fois collective et différenciée<br />

à l'égard <strong>de</strong>s Six malgré une approche <strong>de</strong> consultation multilatérale entre les Occi<strong>de</strong>ntaux.<br />

Il décrit aussi avec nuance les efforts menés par la Commission Hallstein (tan<strong>de</strong>m<br />

J. Rey-R. Marjolin) pour personnifier l'Europe <strong>de</strong>s Six et pour participer aux négociations<br />

commerciales multilatérales au sein du GATT (Kennedy Round) en qualité d'interlocuteur<br />

unique. Le Marché commun apparaît alors comme un rival commercial. Mais la diplomatie<br />

américaine sait aussi tirer habilement pr<strong>of</strong>it <strong>de</strong> l'évolution <strong>de</strong>s rapports <strong>de</strong> force franco-allemands,<br />

qu'il s'agisse du dossier <strong>de</strong> l'adhésion du Royaume-Uni aux Communautés européennes,<br />

<strong>de</strong> l'accès <strong>de</strong>s produits agricoles américains au marché européen ou <strong>de</strong> la tourmente<br />

monétaire <strong>de</strong> novembre 1968.<br />

Particulièrement <strong>de</strong>nse, l'ouvrage <strong>de</strong> Massimiliano Gu<strong>de</strong>rzo <strong>of</strong>fre un panorama détaillé<br />

<strong>de</strong>s relations USA-Europe analysées surtout du point <strong>de</strong> vue américain et stratégique.<br />

L'auteur démontre que la guerre du Viêt-nam n'a pas empêché la Maison-Blanche <strong>de</strong> s'impliquer<br />

activement dans les affaires du mon<strong>de</strong> et <strong>de</strong> l'Europe qui, au cours <strong>de</strong>s années soixante,<br />

est elle-même en butte à <strong>de</strong>s luttes internes qui ne facilitent pas le dialogue qu'elle veut<br />

nouer avec les États-Unis, notamment sur le terrain militaire et commercial. L'unité européenne<br />

et atlantique sont au cœur du propos. Mais Gu<strong>de</strong>rzo retrace aussi l'action personnelle<br />

du prési<strong>de</strong>nt Johnson en matière <strong>de</strong> politique internationale examinée notamment sous<br />

l'angle conceptuel <strong>de</strong> la peacekeeping et <strong>de</strong> la peacemaking. Enfin, il passe au crible les<br />

efforts poursuivis par l'administration démocrate en faveur <strong>de</strong> l'unité européenne bien perçue<br />

par les Américains comme un gage essentiel <strong>de</strong> leurs propres sécurité et prospérité. Et <strong>de</strong><br />

s'interroger, pour conclure, sur la capacité, passée et à venir, <strong>de</strong>s Européens à se doter<br />

eux-mêmes <strong>de</strong>s moyens nécessaires pour assurer leur défense et ainsi contre-balancer la<br />

suprématie américaine.<br />

Étienne Deschamps<br />

Université catholique <strong>de</strong> Louvain, Louvain-la-Neuve


150<br />

Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen<br />

Institut für Zeitgeschichte on behalf <strong>of</strong> Auswärtiges Amt (ed.) – Akten zur Auswärtigen<br />

Politik <strong>de</strong>r Bun<strong>de</strong>srepublik Deutschland, 1951, ed. by Matthias Jaroch; 1952, ed. by<br />

Martin Koopmann and Joachim Wintzer, R. Ol<strong>de</strong>nbourg Verlag, München, 1999, LVIII,<br />

816 p. – ISBN 3-486-56418-8; 2000, LVIII and 842 p. – ISBN 3-486-56480-3. – 64,80 €<br />

(each volume).<br />

In the early 1950s West German foreign policy had to face a serious dilemma: on the one<br />

hand, Chancellor A<strong>de</strong>nauer, who since March 1951 was acting as foreign minister, too, tried<br />

to reduce West Germany’s <strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>ncy on the Western Allies; on the other hand, he <strong>de</strong>sperately<br />

nee<strong>de</strong>d – and asked for – Allied support, especially after the Stalin proposals <strong>of</strong> spring<br />

1952 concerning the unification <strong>of</strong> Germany. Thus A<strong>de</strong>nauer, at the same time, had to avoid<br />

the impression on the part <strong>of</strong> the Western powers that West Germany might again turn to traditional<br />

power politics, and on the part <strong>of</strong> the German people that he was some sort <strong>of</strong> a puppet<br />

on Allied strings. How successful he and his government in Bonn were in managing this<br />

problem is, amongst many other topics, documented in the two volumes.<br />

These volumes – a first one, <strong>de</strong>aling with the years 1949/1950, was published in 1997 –<br />

are the first steps towards filling the gap between 1949 and 1963, the starting point <strong>of</strong> the<br />

“<strong>of</strong>ficial” edition project concerning the foreign policy <strong>of</strong> the Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Republic <strong>of</strong> Germany.<br />

They, too, may be read in addition to the documentation on the talks between A<strong>de</strong>nauer and<br />

the Allied High Commission, published in two volumes in 1989 and 1990. As was the case<br />

with the former volumes, a summary <strong>of</strong> their content is not provi<strong>de</strong>d, but abstracts for each<br />

document and a <strong>de</strong>tailed in<strong>de</strong>x are valuable tools for searching certain topics. The annotations<br />

by the editors concentrate on more or less “technical” aspects like the references <strong>of</strong> a<br />

certain document to others or to other record groups, the importance <strong>of</strong> documents within<br />

the <strong>de</strong>cision making process or its political and organisational background. The main source<br />

<strong>of</strong> documentation in these two volumes have been the archives <strong>of</strong> the German foreign ministry;<br />

furthermore, they contain some records <strong>of</strong> the papers <strong>of</strong> Herbert Blankenhorn, head <strong>of</strong><br />

the political <strong>de</strong>partment <strong>of</strong> the Auswärtiges Amt, and the Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Chancellery kept by the<br />

Bun<strong>de</strong>sarchiv Koblenz, <strong>of</strong> the Bun<strong>de</strong>sarchiv/Militärarchiv in Freiburg and <strong>of</strong> the A<strong>de</strong>nauer<br />

papers, kept by the Stiftung Bun<strong>de</strong>skanzler-A<strong>de</strong>nauer-Haus in Rhöndorf near Bonn.<br />

The altogether 469 documents, including memoranda, notes, minutes and correspon<strong>de</strong>nce,<br />

cover a wi<strong>de</strong> range <strong>of</strong> topics: the West German contribution to the common Western <strong>de</strong>fence<br />

against the “communist threat”, the European Defence Community (EDC), the ratification <strong>of</strong> the<br />

treaty on the European Coal and Steel Community (ECSC), the “contractual agreements”<br />

between the Three Powers and the Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Republic and the termination <strong>of</strong> the occupation statute,<br />

the establishment <strong>of</strong> diplomatic relations with other countries, the negotiations on the settlement<br />

<strong>of</strong> Germany’s foreign <strong>de</strong>bts, the restitution negotiations with Israel, the problem <strong>of</strong> German<br />

reunification, the Saar question, and arms production, to mention only the most important. Surprisingly,<br />

there are only a few entries concerning the Organisation for European Economic<br />

Co-operation and the European Payments Union, which were without doubt <strong>of</strong> high importance<br />

for the <strong>integration</strong> <strong>of</strong> West Germany into the West European economic and political setting. One<br />

may won<strong>de</strong>r whether this fact reflects the attitu<strong>de</strong> towards the OEEC <strong>of</strong> A<strong>de</strong>nauer and his administration<br />

or <strong>of</strong> those who selected the documents.<br />

Among the most interesting topics rank the Soviet Union’s proposals regarding a unified,<br />

but neutralised Germany and the reactions <strong>of</strong> the Western powers, as well as <strong>of</strong> the Fe<strong>de</strong>ral<br />

Republic and the German Democratic Republic (GDR). It becomes clear that not only the<br />

Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Chancellor and his supporters were afraid <strong>of</strong> the potential consequences, but also<br />

the GDR government. Ulbricht and other leading politicians <strong>of</strong> the Socialist Unity Party<br />

(SED) feared that they might be “sacrificed cold-heartedly”, if the Soviet Union succee<strong>de</strong>d<br />

in keeping West Germany out <strong>of</strong> the “aggressive block” dominated by the United States. So<br />

A<strong>de</strong>nauer’s rigid refusal to explore the Soviet <strong>of</strong>fer was received with great relief by the East


Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen 151<br />

German government. Amongst A<strong>de</strong>nauer’s motives for the rejection <strong>of</strong> the Soviet proposals<br />

the non-recognition <strong>of</strong> the O<strong>de</strong>r-Neiße as Germany’s final Eastern bor<strong>de</strong>r ranked very high.<br />

One may speculate about the chances to unify at least the Fe<strong>de</strong>ral Republic and the GDR at<br />

that time, if A<strong>de</strong>nauer would have been willing to renounce the Eastern parts <strong>of</strong> the former<br />

German Reich.<br />

As far as European <strong>integration</strong> is concerned, the formation <strong>of</strong> a <strong>de</strong>fence community is the<br />

problem most frequently <strong>de</strong>alt with in the documents. The West Germans stressed the necessity<br />

to be treated on equal terms and to establish some sort <strong>of</strong> political framework for the<br />

EDC and the ECSC as well. Although there can be no doubt regarding the Fe<strong>de</strong>ral government’s<br />

willingness to integrate West Germany into the emerging European community,<br />

French anxiety seemed not to have disappeared until the signing <strong>of</strong> the ECSC treaty. To control<br />

the Germans counted, after all, amongst the predominant causes <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong><br />

– a fact that A<strong>de</strong>nauer had already “forgotten” in spring 1952, when he only mentioned the<br />

aggressive politics <strong>of</strong> the Soviet Union as an impetus to unify Europe.<br />

The two volumes are a valuable and indispensable source for anyone who is interested in<br />

the beginnings <strong>of</strong> West German foreign policy. The documents <strong>de</strong>monstrate in <strong>de</strong>tail what<br />

kind <strong>of</strong> obstacles had to be cleared and how “Bonn” step by step got used to a new style <strong>of</strong><br />

foreign policy and to its new role in European and international politics.<br />

Priv.Doz. Dr. Werner Bührer<br />

Technische Universität München<br />

Marie-Thérèse BITSCH (ed.) – Le couple France-Allemagne et les institutions<br />

européennes. Une postérité pour le plan Schuman? Proceedings <strong>of</strong> the symposium held at<br />

the Institute <strong>of</strong> high European studies <strong>of</strong> Strasbourg (Strasbourg University III – Robert<br />

Schuman), 25 -27 May 2000, Brussels, Bruylant, 2001, 609 p. – ISBN 2-8027-1500-3 –<br />

85,00 €.<br />

On the occasion <strong>of</strong> the 50th anniversary <strong>of</strong> the <strong>de</strong>claration <strong>of</strong> 9 May 1950, the Institute <strong>of</strong><br />

high European studies <strong>of</strong> the Strasbourg University III – Robert Schuman, organized, from<br />

25 to 27 May 2000, a scientific symposium with the purpose <strong>of</strong> studying the posterity <strong>of</strong> this<br />

founding proclamation <strong>of</strong> the European Community. Following the tradition established by<br />

Raymond Poi<strong>de</strong>vin who has set up and run for long years the Research Centre for the <strong>history</strong><br />

<strong>of</strong> international relations <strong>of</strong> the Institute, this symposium gathered French and German historians<br />

specialists in the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> Europe and connected the subjects <strong>of</strong> Franco-German<br />

relations and European construction.<br />

Without recounting the genesis and the immediate results <strong>of</strong> the Schuman plan, already<br />

known by the works <strong>of</strong> Raymond Poi<strong>de</strong>vin 1 and Pierre Gerbet 2 or by the symposium organized<br />

on that subject by Klaus Schwabe, 3 the 25 contributions collected by Marie-Thérèse<br />

Bitsch look back, over a period <strong>of</strong> 50 years, on the evolution <strong>of</strong> the Franco-German relations<br />

with regard to the Community construction. The contributions are divi<strong>de</strong>d into five large<br />

parts that successively take up the “first options” leading from the Schuman plan to the treaties<br />

<strong>of</strong> Rome (with in particular an assessment <strong>of</strong> the i<strong>de</strong>as <strong>of</strong> Walter Hallstein), the “pros-<br />

1. R. POIDEVIN, Robert Schuman, homme d’Etat, Paris, Imprimerie Nationale, 1986, 520 p. by the<br />

same author, in collaboration with Dierk SPIERENBURG, Histoire <strong>de</strong> la Haute Autorité <strong>de</strong> la CE-<br />

CA, Bruxelles, Bruylant, 1993, 919 p.<br />

2. P. GERBET, La genèse du plan Schuman. Des origines à la déclaration du 9 mai 1950, Lausanne,<br />

Centre <strong>de</strong> recherches européennes, 1962, 40 p.<br />

3. K. SCHWABE (editorship), Die Anfänge <strong>de</strong>s Schuman-Plans 1950-1951, Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, Nomos,<br />

1988, 475 p.


152<br />

Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen<br />

pects <strong>of</strong> institutional evolution in the sixties”, “the standpoint <strong>of</strong> the dynamic forces” ma<strong>de</strong><br />

up <strong>of</strong> political parties, the tra<strong>de</strong> unions and business circles, the “position <strong>of</strong> the lea<strong>de</strong>rs <strong>of</strong><br />

the seventies”, finally the “relaunch <strong>of</strong> the eighties and nineties”. The great variety <strong>of</strong> themes<br />

that recall the political aspects as well as social and monetary questions, and the particular<br />

importance attached to the personal contributions <strong>of</strong> the French and German political lea<strong>de</strong>rs,<br />

who were increasingly embodying the relation between the two countries, answer the<br />

general question on the adaptation <strong>of</strong> the “Franco-German couple” to the evolution <strong>of</strong> the<br />

European project. This <strong>of</strong>ten hackneyed expression finds here its true justification, each <strong>of</strong><br />

the actors taking a constant interest in the European policy <strong>of</strong> the other and each <strong>of</strong> them<br />

conceiving his own European policy according to the interests and concern <strong>of</strong> his neighbour.<br />

This study <strong>of</strong> the Franco-German relations with regard to the European construction<br />

reveals a certain number <strong>of</strong> permanent features, beyond the evolutions and transformations<br />

that give a certain rhythm to the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the two partners.<br />

The European construction is in the first place a matter <strong>of</strong> pragmatism and realism, rather<br />

than <strong>of</strong> lyricism or vision. The Schuman <strong>de</strong>claration and Chancellor A<strong>de</strong>nauer’s response to<br />

it at that time were only partly attributable to the power <strong>of</strong> a visionary project or to the<br />

necessity <strong>of</strong> reconciliation, but embraced also France’s and Germany’s immediate interests<br />

at the beginning <strong>of</strong> the fifties. The contributions <strong>de</strong>voted to the politicians, consi<strong>de</strong>red the<br />

most European political lea<strong>de</strong>rs (Valéry Giscard d’Estaing, Helmut Schmidt, François Mitterrand<br />

and Helmut Kohl) emphasize the pragmatism <strong>of</strong> their European proposals. To each<br />

<strong>of</strong> them could apply Willy Brandt’s affirmation in 1971 quoted by Andreas Wilkens, according<br />

to which the German chancellor refused “institutional perfectionism” and “<strong>integration</strong>ist<br />

abstractions” preferring a step-by-step policy, “the possible and practical steps that we can<br />

take right now”. Michèle Weinachter, in her study on Valéry Giscard d’Estaing, recalls that<br />

the ancient presi<strong>de</strong>nt <strong>of</strong> the Republic affirmed his support <strong>of</strong> fe<strong>de</strong>ralism only after 1981. The<br />

election <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament by universal suffrage, <strong>of</strong>ten presented together with the<br />

creation <strong>of</strong> the EMS as one <strong>of</strong> France’s important contributions to the European construction,<br />

is <strong>de</strong>scribed by people around the Presi<strong>de</strong>nt as the “least evil” in the face <strong>of</strong> the feared<br />

reinforcement <strong>of</strong> the prerogatives <strong>of</strong> the European Parliament. But this pragmatism also<br />

picked out by Georges Saunier for the years 1981-1985 during which the relaunch projects<br />

were being prepared, doesn’t work just one-way. It doesn’t alone put a damper on the most<br />

daring advances <strong>of</strong> the Community construction; it also protects its achievements in the<br />

name <strong>of</strong> well un<strong>de</strong>rstood national interests, particularly at the economic level. Pierre Gerbet<br />

thus shows the importance <strong>of</strong> Presi<strong>de</strong>nt Pompidou’s action in favour <strong>of</strong> economic <strong>integration</strong>,<br />

even if he basically remained loyal to the <strong>de</strong> Gaullian conception <strong>of</strong> the Europe <strong>of</strong><br />

States, <strong>de</strong>spite some astonishing references to prospective transfers <strong>of</strong> sovereignty in favour<br />

<strong>of</strong> a European government.<br />

Pragmatism at work in the European policy pursued by France and Germany neither<br />

rules out difficulties nor the will to go ahead. Differences <strong>of</strong> opinion between François Mitterrand<br />

and Helmut Kohl, whether about the part <strong>of</strong> the WEU analyzed by Elisabeth du Réau<br />

or concerning the institutional reform <strong>of</strong> Europe, studied by Hanns-Jürgen Küsters at the<br />

time <strong>of</strong> reunification, prove that the Franco-German relations are not self-evi<strong>de</strong>nt according<br />

to François Mitterrand’s own words in 1994, that they evolve continuously and that crises or<br />

friction cannot always be avoi<strong>de</strong>d. Even then, it still must be stressed, that oppositions are<br />

not fixed and could never be reduced to the simple contrast between centralizing France,<br />

<strong>de</strong>sperately <strong>de</strong>fending national sovereignty, and fe<strong>de</strong>ral Germany whose constitutional tradition<br />

might make it more accessible to the process <strong>of</strong> Community <strong>integration</strong>. If basically the<br />

i<strong>de</strong>a <strong>of</strong> supranationality meets with less resistance in Germany than in France, Wolf Gruner<br />

nevertheless shows that from the beginning <strong>of</strong> the <strong>de</strong>bates on the ratification <strong>of</strong> the ECSC<br />

treaty within the Bun<strong>de</strong>srat there is to be found a certain distrust <strong>of</strong> Community <strong>integration</strong><br />

on the part <strong>of</strong> the German Län<strong>de</strong>r. These reservations have known an important <strong>de</strong>velopment


Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen 153<br />

in 1992 with the insertion <strong>of</strong> a new article 23 in the Constitution that aims at protecting the<br />

rights <strong>of</strong> the Län<strong>de</strong>r and at giving them a share in working out Germany’s Community policy.<br />

The reservations are still tangible today in the recent European proposals ma<strong>de</strong> by the<br />

Christian Democrat Union (CDU) and the Christian Social Union (CSU), originating from<br />

Bavaria that advocates reducing and clarifying the powers <strong>of</strong> the European Union. Thus, in<br />

the continuation <strong>of</strong> the work <strong>of</strong> Georges-Henri Soutou on the “uncertain alliance”, 4 the proceedings<br />

<strong>of</strong> the symposium contribute to <strong>de</strong>mythifying the i<strong>de</strong>alized, almost pious image <strong>of</strong><br />

the Franco-German couple. At the same time, France’s and Germany’s European commitment<br />

seems like the main point <strong>of</strong> contact between both countries, their most solid anchorage<br />

in 50 years <strong>of</strong> basic transformations.<br />

The necessity <strong>of</strong> cooperating that drives on the political lea<strong>de</strong>rs <strong>of</strong> the two countries also<br />

urges on part <strong>of</strong> the civil society. One <strong>of</strong> the interests <strong>of</strong> the symposium was to make room<br />

for economic, social and unionist actors <strong>of</strong>ten missing in the historical works on the Community<br />

construction. The studies <strong>of</strong> Sylvie Lefèvre and Werner Bührer on the business circles<br />

and the French and German fe<strong>de</strong>rations <strong>of</strong> employers (the CNPF= French National<br />

Employers’union) and the BDI, the confe<strong>de</strong>ration <strong>of</strong> German industrialists, emphasize that<br />

<strong>de</strong>spite divergent economic traditions, marked either by the mercantile system after Colbert<br />

or by liberalism, they were in agreement on European <strong>integration</strong> in the name <strong>of</strong> economic<br />

mo<strong>de</strong>rnization. The interest <strong>of</strong> German and French tra<strong>de</strong> unions, except for the communist<br />

CGT (Confédération Générale du Travail = French Tra<strong>de</strong> Union, close to the French communist<br />

party), is well brought out in the contributions <strong>of</strong> Cédric Guinand and Sylvain Schirmann.<br />

For the powerful German DGB (Deutscher Gewerkschaftsbund = Fe<strong>de</strong>ration <strong>of</strong> German<br />

Tra<strong>de</strong> Unions), as well as for the French organizations CFTC (Confédération Française<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Travailleurs Chrétiens, Christian tra<strong>de</strong> union) and FO (Force ouvrière), it is a question<br />

<strong>of</strong> bringing an influence to bear on the Community institutions with a view to give the workers’<br />

interests more weight. These organizations rapidly support the Community construction,<br />

in which they see a means to improve the protection <strong>of</strong> their members, even if at the<br />

beginning they expressed reservations towards the European Economic Community that<br />

was less willing to lend an ear to tra<strong>de</strong> unions than the ECSC. Nevertheless, the structuring<br />

<strong>of</strong> European tra<strong>de</strong> unionism doesn’t turn out to be less laborious as the national means <strong>of</strong><br />

expressing claims remain predominant.<br />

The panorama outlined by the contributions <strong>of</strong> the symposium on 50 years <strong>of</strong> a vivid<br />

Franco-German cooperation on European level bring <strong>de</strong>finitively out the present lifelessness<br />

<strong>of</strong> the relations between the two states, the lack <strong>of</strong> confi<strong>de</strong>nce prevailing between their lea<strong>de</strong>rs,<br />

the diverging evolution <strong>of</strong> their policies. The lessons learned in these 50 years induce to<br />

be optimistic, but the theme <strong>of</strong> the symposium, that refers to the posterity <strong>of</strong> the <strong>de</strong>claration<br />

<strong>of</strong> May 1950, doesn’t spare the question: a temporary crisis before the nth relaunch or the<br />

end <strong>of</strong> an adventure initiated by the Schuman plan?<br />

Rémi Decout-Paolini<br />

Ancien élève <strong>de</strong> l’École normale supérieure<br />

Agrégé <strong>de</strong> l’université en histoire<br />

4. G.-H. SOUTOU, L’alliance incertaine. Les rapports politico-stratégiques franco-allemands,<br />

1954-1996, Paris, Fayard, 1996, 497p.


154<br />

Book reviews – Comptes rendus – Buchbesprechungen<br />

Wilfried LOTH/Wolfgang WESSELS (ed.). – Theorien europäischer Integration.<br />

Opla<strong>de</strong>n, Leske und Budrich, 2001, 294 p. – ISBN 3-8100-2886-X – 24,90 €.<br />

Cet ouvrage arrive à point nommé, et non seulement en raison <strong>de</strong> la création récente <strong>de</strong> la<br />

«Convention pour la réforme <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne». Si la discussion urgente et nécessaire<br />

sur l’avenir <strong>de</strong> l’Europe, entamée là et ailleurs, doit être menée à son terme avec succès, la<br />

politique et la science ont en effet besoin d’un «forum <strong>de</strong> discussion commun» réclamé par<br />

les éditeurs (p.7). Wilfried Loth et Wolfgang Wessels ne se contentent pourtant pas «<strong>de</strong> mettre<br />

en ordre ces éléments et <strong>de</strong> les examiner en vue <strong>de</strong> détecter leurs points forts et faibles»<br />

(p.13). Ils veulent en outre créer une base pour les recherches interdisciplinaires.<br />

L’ouvrage, issu d’un congrès du Centre Culturel organisé à Essen, en septembre 1999, en<br />

coopération avec le cercle <strong>de</strong> travail «Intégration Européenne», présente dans sa première<br />

partie une vue d’ensemble sur l’état actuel <strong>de</strong>s travaux scientifiques relatifs à l’intégration<br />

européenne dans les différentes disciplines scientifiques. Dans un premier temps, Wolfgang<br />

Wessels évoque dans un bref sommaire la diversité dans la discussion sur la science <strong>de</strong><br />

l’intégration en politologie. Wim Kösters, assisté <strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>ux collaborateurs, développe en<br />

détail <strong>de</strong>s éléments <strong>de</strong> la théorie d’intégration économique. Wilfried Loth présente ensuite<br />

<strong>de</strong>s apports historiques sur l’interprétation <strong>de</strong> l’unification européenne. Armin von Bogdandy<br />

présente à son tour <strong>de</strong>s conceptions juridiques sur le processus d’intégration européenne,<br />

alors que Maurizio Bach dresse un sommaire <strong>de</strong>s idées théoriques pour l’analyse <strong>de</strong><br />

l’intégration européenne du point <strong>de</strong> vue <strong>de</strong> la sociologie.<br />

Dans la <strong>de</strong>uxième partie, l’ouvrage contient <strong>de</strong>s essais exemplaires sur l’évolution interdisciplinaire<br />

<strong>de</strong> la théorie <strong>de</strong> l’intégration européenne. Richard Münch décrit le phénomène<br />

<strong>de</strong> l’unification européenne comme un processus <strong>de</strong> changement institutionnel et culturel.<br />

Manfred Zuleeg analyse les aspects supranationaux du droit et <strong>de</strong> la procédure <strong>de</strong> l’Union<br />

européenne. Philipp C. Schmitter et Jose I. Torreblanca se consacrent aux effets <strong>de</strong> l’élargissement<br />

à l’Est sur la transformation <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne. Pour finir, Klaus Busch présente<br />

l’évolution d’un modèle synoptique d’explication <strong>de</strong> théories d’intégration politiques.<br />

D'une façon impressionnante, les contributions <strong>de</strong>s experts montrent comment les hypothèses<br />

<strong>de</strong> départ, les questions et les métho<strong>de</strong>s divergent non seulement entre elles, mais<br />

également au sein même <strong>de</strong>s différentes disciplines. Malgré certains points <strong>de</strong> départ, le chemin<br />

vers une théorie d’intégration commune semble être encore très laborieux.<br />

Priv.-Doz. Dr. Ulrich Lappenküper<br />

Universität Bonn


155<br />

Abstracts – Résumés – Zusammenfassungen<br />

Milène Wegmann<br />

Neo-liberal Conceptions <strong>of</strong> a European Fe<strong>de</strong>ration, 1918–1945<br />

From 1918 to 1945 neo-liberal fe<strong>de</strong>ralists advocated an institutionally foun<strong>de</strong>d ”liberal fe<strong>de</strong>ration” <strong>of</strong> states<br />

as the ”logical consummation <strong>of</strong> the liberal programme” (von Hayek) and the <strong>de</strong>sirable alternative to<br />

the socialist international planning. They maintained the thesis that economic systems and political structures<br />

were strongly inter<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt. Customs unions being introduced as measures <strong>of</strong> liberal tra<strong>de</strong> policy<br />

could be accepted (Röpke) and even un<strong>de</strong>rstood as a synonym <strong>of</strong> ”fe<strong>de</strong>ration” (Einaudi, von Hayek,<br />

Robbins). Freedom and or<strong>de</strong>r ought to be secured by means <strong>of</strong> a framework <strong>of</strong> legal regulation within the<br />

fe<strong>de</strong>ration and by an international system <strong>of</strong> law in the worldwi<strong>de</strong> inter-state relations. After the neo-liberal<br />

fe<strong>de</strong>ralists had analyzed the economic aspects <strong>of</strong> fe<strong>de</strong>ral unions from 1918-1939, they turned during<br />

the Second World War to the extra-economic conditions <strong>of</strong> a fe<strong>de</strong>ration <strong>of</strong> states and recognized social<br />

and cultural <strong>integration</strong> as <strong>of</strong> primordial importance. They consi<strong>de</strong>red the social and cultural <strong>integration</strong><br />

as a prerequisite for an economic <strong>integration</strong> and emphasized the necessity <strong>of</strong> an institutional framework.<br />

The essential features common to the different conceptions <strong>of</strong> a neo-liberal fe<strong>de</strong>ration resulted from the<br />

discourse <strong>of</strong> the neo-liberal economists: the relation <strong>of</strong> correspon<strong>de</strong>nce between the political and the economic<br />

structure <strong>of</strong> society, the cosmopolitan and liberal-internationalist orientation <strong>of</strong> the conceptions <strong>of</strong><br />

fe<strong>de</strong>ration, the primacy <strong>of</strong> social and cultural <strong>integration</strong> over economic <strong>integration</strong> and the rejection <strong>of</strong><br />

laissez-faire in international relations.<br />

Les conceptions néo-libérales d'une fédération européenne (1918-1945)<br />

Entre 1918 et 1945 les fédéralistes néo-libéraux défen<strong>de</strong>nt la conception d'une «fédération libérale»<br />

institutionnalisée en laquelle ils repèrent à la fois «l'aboutissement du programme économique libéral»<br />

(von Hayek) et l'alternative préférable à la planification internationale socialiste. Ils défen<strong>de</strong>nt la thèse<br />

<strong>de</strong> l'interdépen<strong>de</strong>nce <strong>de</strong>s structures économiques et politiques. Pour autant qu'elles soient conçues<br />

comme mesures d'une politique économique libérale, les unions douanières peuvent être acceptées<br />

(Röpke); elles <strong>de</strong>viendraient même synonyme du terme «fédération» (Einaudi, von Hayek, Robbins).<br />

La liberté et l'ordre <strong>de</strong>vraient être assurés au sein <strong>de</strong> la fédération par un cadre <strong>de</strong> règles légales et, au<br />

niveau mondial, dans les relations entre Etats, moyennant un système <strong>de</strong> droit international. Après<br />

avoir analysé entre 1918 et 1939 les aspects économiques <strong>de</strong>s unions fédérales, les fédéralistes<br />

néo-libéraux consacrent leurs étu<strong>de</strong>s pendant la Secon<strong>de</strong> Guerre mondiale à l'examen <strong>de</strong>s conditions<br />

autres qu'économiques, en l'occurrence sociales et culturelles, dont ils reconnaissent l'importance primordiale,<br />

voire leur indispensabilité à l'intégration économique et à la formation d'une fédération entre<br />

Etats. Aussi insistent-ils sur la nécessité d'introduire un cadre institutionnel. Les caractéristiques essentielles<br />

unissant les visions néo-libérales d'une fédération d'Etats plongent leurs racines dans les débats<br />

<strong>de</strong>s économistes néo-libéraux: interdépen<strong>de</strong>nce <strong>de</strong>s structures économiques et politiques, orientation<br />

cosmopolite et libérale-internationaliste <strong>de</strong>s conceptions <strong>de</strong> fédération d'Etats, subordination <strong>de</strong> l'intégration<br />

économique à l'intégration sociale et culturelle ainsi que renonciation au «laissez faire» en<br />

matière <strong>de</strong> relations internationales.<br />

Neoliberale Europa-Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte. 1918–1945<br />

Die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten vertraten von 1918 bis 1945 eine institutionell abgesicherte „liberale<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration“ von Staaten als „Vollendung <strong>de</strong>s liberalen Wirtschaftsprogramms“ (von Hayek) und<br />

wünschenswerte Alternative zur sozialistischen internationalen Planung. Sie verfochten die These, daß<br />

Wirtschaftsformen und politische Strukturen in einem engen Zuordnungsverhältnis stün<strong>de</strong>n. Zollunionen<br />

for<strong>de</strong>rten keinen Wi<strong>de</strong>rspruch heraus (Röpke), solange sie als Maßnahmen liberaler Han<strong>de</strong>lspolitik<br />

eingesetzt wür<strong>de</strong>n, und wur<strong>de</strong>n gera<strong>de</strong>zu als Synonym für „Fö<strong>de</strong>ration“ verstan<strong>de</strong>n (Einaudi, von<br />

Hayek, Robbins). Freiheit und Ordnung sollten durch einen Rahmen gesetzlicher Regelungen in <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ration und durch ein internationales Rechtssystem in <strong>de</strong>n weltweiten zwischenstaatlichen Bezie-


156<br />

Abstracts – Résumés – Zusammenfassungen<br />

hungen gesichert sein. Nach<strong>de</strong>m die neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisten zwischen 1918 und 1939 die wirtschaftlichen<br />

Aspekte von fö<strong>de</strong>rativen Zusammenschlüssen untersucht hatten, wandten sie sich im<br />

Zweiten Weltkrieg <strong>de</strong>n außerökonomischen Bedingungen einer Staatenfö<strong>de</strong>ration zu und erkannten<br />

<strong>de</strong>r gesellschaftlichen und kulturellen Integration eine primordiale Be<strong>de</strong>utung zu. Sie erachteten die<br />

soziale und kulturelle Integration als Vorbedingung für eine ökonomische Integration und wiesen auf<br />

die Notwendigkeit einer institutionellen Absicherung hin. Die wesentlichen Merkmale, welche die<br />

neoliberalen Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte miteinan<strong>de</strong>r teilten, sind aus <strong>de</strong>m gemeinsamen Diskurs <strong>de</strong>r neoliberalen<br />

Wirtschaftswissenschafter hervorgegangen: das Zuordnungsverhältnis von Wirtschaftsformen<br />

und politischen Strukturen, die kosmopolitische und liberal-internationalistische Ausrichtung <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>rationskonzepte, <strong>de</strong>r Primat <strong>de</strong>r sozialen und kulturellen Integration vor <strong>de</strong>r ökonomischen Integration<br />

und die Absage an das laissez faire in <strong>de</strong>n internationalen Beziehungen.<br />

Bertrand Vayssière<br />

The Italian Origins <strong>of</strong> European Fe<strong>de</strong>ralism during the Second World War.<br />

The study <strong>of</strong> the especially strong fe<strong>de</strong>ralist current within the Resistance in Italy, enables to un<strong>de</strong>rstand<br />

the very particular conditions <strong>of</strong> the emergence as well as the specificities <strong>of</strong> this i<strong>de</strong>ological movement,<br />

that broke with the political traditions <strong>of</strong> the pre-war years and laid down as a prerequisite the setting up<br />

<strong>of</strong> a European political framework. Actually, the first activists in the literal sense <strong>of</strong> a current until then<br />

without militants gathered in Italy. They could very quickly refer to a real programme <strong>of</strong> action, a structured<br />

political training and they were willing to carry the ”good news” beyond the bor<strong>de</strong>rs, i.e. to Switzerland,<br />

where first contacts were established during the war and from where the diffusion <strong>of</strong> this i<strong>de</strong>a,<br />

that used to be confined to certain resistance circles <strong>of</strong> the peninsula, set <strong>of</strong>f. Certainly, this first diffusion,<br />

accelerated by the effects <strong>of</strong> liberation, induced a great optimism within the ranks <strong>of</strong> these militants <strong>of</strong> a<br />

new kind who saw in the political, economic and social conditions emerging in the post-war years, the<br />

opportunity to rebuild a more just and coherent whole at European scale. But liberation was also the<br />

occasion to recognize the gap, that may exist between utopia and reality: The Italian fe<strong>de</strong>ralism, battle-tried<br />

and well-disciplined, then had to take into account the existence <strong>of</strong> other currents from different<br />

countries, until then undreamt-<strong>of</strong>, as well as the opposition <strong>of</strong> political parties con<strong>de</strong>mned a bit quickly<br />

and finally an international situation that questioned the prerequisite to all hopes expressed in the Resistance<br />

movement: the possibility <strong>of</strong> establishing a unique and in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>nt European framework.<br />

Les origines italiennes du fédéralisme européen pendant la Secon<strong>de</strong> Guerre mondiale.<br />

L’étu<strong>de</strong> du courant fédéraliste au sein <strong>de</strong> la Résistance en Italie, particulièrement fort dans ce pays, permet<br />

<strong>de</strong> comprendre les conditions très particulières <strong>de</strong> son émergence, ainsi que les spécificités <strong>de</strong> ce<br />

mouvement idéologique, qui rompt avec les traditions politiques d’avant-guerre et pose comme préalable<br />

l’institution d’un cadre politique européen. L’Italie est en effet un pays où se sont regroupés les premiers<br />

activistes, au sens propre du terme, d’un courant jusqu’ici sans militants, qui peuvent très tôt se réclamer<br />

d’un véritable programme d’action, d’une formation politique structurée, et désireux <strong>de</strong> porter «la bonne<br />

parole» par-<strong>de</strong>là les frontières. En l’occurrence, c’est en Suisse, en pleine pério<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong> guerre, qu’ont été<br />

établis les premiers contacts et lancée la diffusion d’une idée qui restait cantonnée à certains milieux<br />

résistants <strong>de</strong> la péninsule. Certes, cette première diffusion, accélérée par les effets <strong>de</strong> la Libération,<br />

prédispose à un grand optimisme dans les rangs <strong>de</strong> ce militantisme d’un nouveau genre qui voit, dans les<br />

conditions politiques, économiques et sociales qui se <strong>de</strong>ssinent dans l’après-guerre, l’occasion <strong>de</strong> rebâtir<br />

un ensemble plus juste et plus cohérent, à l’échelle européenne. Mais la Libération est également l’occasion<br />

<strong>de</strong> vérifier le hiatus qui peut exister entre l’utopie et la réalité: le fédéralisme italien, aguerri et discipliné,<br />

doit alors tenir compte <strong>de</strong> l’existence d’autres courants, jusque-là insoupçonnés, issus <strong>de</strong> pays<br />

divers, ainsi que <strong>de</strong> la résistance <strong>de</strong> partis politiques un peu vite condamnés, et enfin d’une situation internationale<br />

qui remet en cause le préalable à tous les espoirs exprimés dans la Résistance: la possibilité<br />

d’instaurer un cadre européen unique et indépendant.<br />

Der italienische Ursprung <strong>de</strong>s europäischen Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus während <strong>de</strong>m Zweiten Weltkrieg<br />

Das Studium <strong>de</strong>s in <strong>de</strong>r italienischen Resistenz ganz beson<strong>de</strong>rs stark ausgeprägten Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus erlaubt<br />

ein besseres Verständnis, sowohl <strong>de</strong>r beson<strong>de</strong>ren Rahmenbedingungen seines Aufschwungs, als auch <strong>de</strong>r


Abstracts – Résumés – Zusammenfassungen 157<br />

i<strong>de</strong>ologischen Eigenheiten einer Bewegung die mit <strong>de</strong>n politischen Traditionen <strong>de</strong>r Vorkriegszeit bricht<br />

und die Schaffung eines politischen Rahmens für Europa zur Grundvoraussetzung erhebt. Italien ist in<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Tat jenes Land in <strong>de</strong>m sich die ersten Aktivisten (im wahrsten Sinne <strong>de</strong>s Wortes) einer bis dahin ohne<br />

Militanten gebliebenen Bewegung versammelten, eine strukturierte Formation bil<strong>de</strong>ten und über ein<br />

regelrechtes Aktionsprogramm verfügten, <strong>de</strong>ssen „frohe Botschaft“ sie über die Lan<strong>de</strong>sgrenzen hinaus<br />

tragen wollten. Der Schweiz fällt hierbei eine zentrale Rolle zu. Mitten im Krieg wer<strong>de</strong>n hier die ersten<br />

Kontakte geknüpft um eine bislang auf bestimmte Schichten <strong>de</strong>r italienischen Resistenz beschränkte I<strong>de</strong>e<br />

weiter zu verbreiten. Die Liberation för<strong>de</strong>rt diese Entfaltung in erheblichem Maß. Sie entfacht in <strong>de</strong>n<br />

Reihen <strong>de</strong>s neuen Militantismus größte H<strong>of</strong>fnung in die sich abzeichnen<strong>de</strong>n politischen, wirtschaftlichen<br />

und sozialen Grundvoraussetzungen eines gerechteren und kohärenteren Neuanfangs auf europäischer<br />

Ebene. Die Liberation gibt aber auch Gelegenheit <strong>de</strong>n Hiatus zwischen Utopie und Realität zu überprüfen:<br />

<strong>de</strong>r abgehärtete und disziplinierte italienische Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus muss damals <strong>de</strong>r Existenz an<strong>de</strong>rer<br />

Geistesströmungen aus verschie<strong>de</strong>nsten Län<strong>de</strong>rn Rechnung tragen und <strong>de</strong>m Wi<strong>de</strong>rstand mancher doch<br />

etwas voreilig verurteilter Parteien entgegentreten. Schließlich gibt die internationale Lage Anlass zur<br />

Sorge. All diese Entwicklungen lassen Zweifel an <strong>de</strong>r großen H<strong>of</strong>fnungen <strong>de</strong>r Resistenzler aufkommen:<br />

die Möglichkeit einen einzigen und unabhängigen europäischen Rahmen aufzustellen.<br />

Seung-Ryeol Kim<br />

France‘s Agony between “Vocation Européenne et Mondiale”: The Union Française as an<br />

Obstacle in the French Policy <strong>of</strong> Supranational European Integration, 1952-1954<br />

In contrast to the Atlantic and European dimension <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>, historians have neglected problems<br />

that were related with the colonies <strong>of</strong> European powers. Although the problems regarding colonies did<br />

not originally concern supranational <strong>integration</strong>, they always affected the unification process. In contrast to<br />

Great Britain, France planned and stimulated two supranational functional Communities (ECSC and EDC)<br />

in spite <strong>of</strong> its world power status. France thought that it could harmonize the construction <strong>of</strong> supranational<br />

European <strong>integration</strong>, mainly directed towards the monitoring <strong>of</strong> Germany, with the world power status<br />

mainly based on retaining the colonial system. However, during the negotiations for the European political<br />

Community (EPC), the Pool Vert and the process <strong>of</strong> the ratification <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty (1952-1954), France<br />

was confronted with a serious problem. It seemed that the EPC which was to be a ‚ro<strong>of</strong> organization‘ for the<br />

ECSC and the EDC would lead in the near future to a fe<strong>de</strong>ration, a framework in which France’s world<br />

power status could be dissolved. In view <strong>of</strong> this terrible prospect, a number <strong>of</strong> people in France who had<br />

advocated the ECSC and the EDC as control bodies over West Germany recoiled from the EPC project.<br />

This issue played a great role in France‘s rejection <strong>of</strong> the Pool Vert and the ratification <strong>of</strong> the EDC treaty.<br />

The study shows that supranational European <strong>integration</strong> and the retaining <strong>of</strong> world power status based on<br />

the colonial system was very difficult to be harmonized and that, in this sense, the breakdown <strong>of</strong> the French<br />

colonial system contributed to the success <strong>of</strong> the EEC negotiations (1955-1957).<br />

La France entre “vocation européenne et vocation mondiale”: l'Union Française,<br />

un obstacle au principe <strong>de</strong> la supranationalité européenne (1952-1954)<br />

Les dimensions européenne et atlantique du processus d'intégration <strong>de</strong> l'Europe sont bien connues. En<br />

revanche, les historiens ont négligé les problèmes en rapport avec les colonies <strong>de</strong>s puissances<br />

européennes. Quoiqu'initialement ces problèmes ne concernaient point l'intégration supranationale, il<br />

n'en reste pas moins qu'ils ont toujours affecté la marche vers l'unification. A l'opposé <strong>de</strong> la Gran<strong>de</strong>-Bretagne,<br />

la France, malgré son statut <strong>de</strong> puissance mondiale, fait figure <strong>de</strong> moteur <strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>ux communautés<br />

fonctionnelles à caractère supranational: la CECA et la CED. Paris croyait pouvoir harmoniser la construction<br />

d'une Europe supranationale essentiellement <strong>de</strong>stinée à contrôler <strong>de</strong> près l'Allemagne d'une part<br />

avec ses préoccupations <strong>de</strong> gran<strong>de</strong> puissance visant au maintien <strong>de</strong> l'empire colonial d'autre part. Hélas,<br />

au cours <strong>de</strong>s négociations pour la communauté politique européenne (CPE) et le Pool Vert, ainsi qu'au fil<br />

<strong>de</strong>s procédures <strong>de</strong> ratification <strong>de</strong> la CED (1952-1954), le Quai d'Orsay se heurta à une sérieuse difficulté:<br />

appelée à coiffer la CECA et la CED, la communauté politique pouvait facilement aboutir dans un avenir<br />

rapproché à une fédération européenne qui menacerait <strong>de</strong> remettre en question la position française <strong>de</strong><br />

gran<strong>de</strong> puissance. Cette perspective inquiétante amena finalement la plupart <strong>de</strong>s Français qui jadis avaient<br />

initié la CECA et la CED comme instruments <strong>de</strong> surveillance <strong>de</strong> la RFA à abandonner le projet <strong>de</strong> la<br />

communauté politique. Ce revirement jouait également un grand rôle dans le rejet français du Pool Vert<br />

et le refus <strong>de</strong> ratifier le traité CED. La présente étu<strong>de</strong> montre qu'il était en effet très difficile <strong>de</strong> concilier


158<br />

Abstracts – Résumés – Zusammenfassungen<br />

une politique <strong>de</strong> puissance fondée sur les territoires d'outre-mer et l'intégration européenne supranationale.<br />

Aussi le déclin du système colonial français après 1954 a-t-il contribué au succès <strong>de</strong>s négociations<br />

pour la création <strong>de</strong> la CEE (1955-1957).<br />

Zwischen europäischer Berufung und Berufung zur Weltmacht: die Union Française, und<br />

Frankreichs supranationale Europapolitik, 1952-1954<br />

Im Gegensatz zur atlantischen und europäischen Dimension <strong>de</strong>r Integrationsgeschichte Europas wur<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Probleme im Zusammenhang mit <strong>de</strong>n Kolonien europäischer Staaten von <strong>de</strong>n Historikern eher<br />

vernachlässigt. Obwohl diese Probleme nicht ursprünglich die supranationale Integration betrafen,<br />

beeinflußten sie diese doch stets. An<strong>de</strong>rs als Großbritannien, bil<strong>de</strong>te Frankreich trotz seiner Weltmachtstellung<br />

die treiben<strong>de</strong> Kraft bei <strong>de</strong>r Entstehung funktionaler Gemeinschaften – <strong>de</strong>r EGKS und<br />

<strong>de</strong>r EVG – welche auf <strong>de</strong>m Prinzip <strong>de</strong>r Supranationalität fußten. Paris glaubte bei<strong>de</strong>s, die supranationale<br />

europäische Integration als Instrument <strong>de</strong>r Überwachung Deutschlands und die Weltmachtpolitik<br />

mit ihrem erklärten Ziel <strong>de</strong>r Aufrechterhaltung <strong>de</strong>s Kolonialsystems, in Einklang bringen zu können.<br />

Im Laufe <strong>de</strong>r Verhandlungen zur europäischen politischen Gemeinschaft (EPG) und zum Pool Vert,<br />

bzw. während <strong>de</strong>r Ratifizierungsprozedur <strong>de</strong>s EVG-Vertrags (1952-1954), wur<strong>de</strong> das Quai d'Orsay<br />

jedoch mit einer ernsten Schwierigkeit konfrontiert. Es schien als ob die politische Gemeinschaft, die<br />

eine Art ‚Dachorganisation‘ für die EGKS und die EVG bil<strong>de</strong>n sollte, in naher Zukunft zur Entstehung<br />

einer Fö<strong>de</strong>ration, und damit zur Auflösung <strong>de</strong>s französischen Weltmachtstatus führen könnte. Angesichts<br />

dieser beängstigen<strong>de</strong>n Zukunftsperspektive drängte nun ein großer Teil jener Franzosen die<br />

seinerzeit die EGKS und die EVG als Kontrollorgan Deutschlands befürwortet hatten, auf eine<br />

Absage <strong>de</strong>s EPG-Projekts. Ihre Furcht spielte auch eine wichtige Rolle bei <strong>de</strong>r französischen Ablehnung<br />

<strong>de</strong>s Pool Vert und <strong>de</strong>s EVG-Vertrags. Diese Studie zeigt, wie schwierig es war, supranationale<br />

europäische Integrationspolitik mit <strong>de</strong>m Festhalten an <strong>de</strong>r alten Weltmachtposition zu vereinbaren,<br />

genauso wie umgekehrt das Auseinan<strong>de</strong>rbröckeln eben jenes Kolonialsystems schließlich seinen Teil<br />

zum Erfolg <strong>de</strong>r EWG-Verhandlungen (1955-57) beitrug.<br />

Lise Rye Svartvatn<br />

In Quest <strong>of</strong> Time, Protection and Approval:<br />

France and the Claims for Social Harmonization in the European Economic Community,<br />

1955-56<br />

During the negotiations that led to the Treaty <strong>of</strong> Rome, France called for a harmonization <strong>of</strong> working regulations,<br />

claiming that the diversity in existing national regulations caused unequal terms <strong>of</strong> competition.<br />

This article aims to explain why social harmonization was a persistent French <strong>de</strong>mand. It argues that the<br />

claims were launched in or<strong>de</strong>r to gain time for a government that was unable to take a stand on the proposed<br />

common market. Furthermore, it suggests that the claims were sustained in or<strong>de</strong>r to secure continued<br />

protection for French industry, which was necessary if sufficient support for French membership <strong>of</strong><br />

the common market was to be obtained.<br />

En quête pour gagner du temps, une meilleure protection et un appui suffisant:<br />

la France, la CEE et l'harmonisation européenne dans le domaine social (1955-1956)<br />

Tout au long <strong>de</strong>s négociations aboutissant au Traité <strong>de</strong> Rome, Paris n'a cessé <strong>de</strong> revendiquer une harmonisation<br />

<strong>de</strong>s conditions <strong>de</strong> travail en prétextant que la diversité <strong>de</strong>s réglementations nationales faussait la<br />

compétition européenne. La présente contribution tache d'expliquer la persistance <strong>de</strong> cette <strong>de</strong>man<strong>de</strong><br />

française par trois considérations majeures. D'une part, la France cherchait à gagner du temps parce que<br />

son gouvernement ne voulait pas se prononcer sur le marché commun proposé par les partenaires<br />

européens. D'autre part, l'harmonisation sociale est revendiquée pour assurer à l'industrie française<br />

l'indispensable protection, et au gouvernement, un appui suffisant pour rallier l'opinion publique à une<br />

adhésion au marché commun.


Abstracts – Résumés – Zusammenfassungen 159<br />

Die EWG-Verhandlungen und Frankreichs For<strong>de</strong>rung nach Harmonisierung im sozialen<br />

Bereich: ein Spiel um Zeit, Schutz und die nötige Unterstützung zu gewinnen. 1955-1956<br />

Frankreich berief sich während <strong>de</strong>n Vertragsverhandlungen zur Einführung <strong>de</strong>s Gemeinsamen Marktes<br />

stets auf die <strong>de</strong>n Wettbewerb verfälschen<strong>de</strong>n unterschiedlichen Bestimmungen <strong>de</strong>s nationalen Arbeitsrechts<br />

um seine For<strong>de</strong>rung nach mehr Harmonisierung im Sozialbereich zu untermauern. Der vorliegen<strong>de</strong><br />

Aufsatz erläutert die Hintergrün<strong>de</strong> dieser französischen Hartnäckigkeit. Zum einen ist sie bedingt<br />

durch <strong>de</strong>n Willen Zeit zu gewinnen, weil die Regierung in Paris sich nicht klar zur geplanten EWG<br />

aussprechen wollte. Darüber hinaus ging es ihr um die Einführung zusätzlicher Schutzmaßnahmen zu<br />

Gunsten <strong>de</strong>r französischen Industrie, bzw. die Notwendigkeit in <strong>de</strong>r öffentlichen Meinung die erfor<strong>de</strong>rliche<br />

Unterstützung für Frankreichs Beteiligung am Gemeinsamen Markt zu gewinnen.<br />

Juhana Aunesluoma<br />

An Elusive Partnership: Europe, Economic Co-operation and British Policy towards<br />

Scandinavia, 1949-1951<br />

The British and the Scandinavians have <strong>of</strong>ten been seen to have drawn a sense <strong>of</strong> unity from the fact that<br />

they all were in the 1950s, for various reasons, unable to participate in such integrative experiments as the<br />

ECSC or later in the EEC. The similarities in their behaviour have led to assumptions that even more<br />

wi<strong>de</strong>-ranging convergence <strong>of</strong> interests between the British and the Scandinavians has existed since<br />

Europe's economic reconstruction began in the 1940s.<br />

British and Scandinavian scepticism towards new forms <strong>of</strong> economic and political co-operation in<br />

Europe in the 1950s was embed<strong>de</strong>d in national circumstances and preferences, but was coupled with<br />

their shared feeling <strong>of</strong> the feasibility <strong>of</strong> an intergovernmental alternative towards economic co-operation<br />

in Europe. What is argued in the article is, that this basic convergence <strong>of</strong> interests in the early phase <strong>of</strong><br />

European <strong>integration</strong> brought the British, Danish, Swedish and Norwegian governments together into<br />

regular consultations within a specifically established body, Uniscan, which sought to facilitate a <strong>de</strong>gree<br />

<strong>of</strong> co-ordination <strong>of</strong> policies and eventually paved the way for the speedy establishment <strong>of</strong> EFTA in 1959,<br />

when the alternative to create a wi<strong>de</strong>r free tra<strong>de</strong> area had been exhausted.<br />

None the less, before EFTA realised the original vision outlined in 1949, attempts towards <strong>de</strong>eper<br />

Anglo-Scandinavian economic co-operation beyond the consultative remit <strong>of</strong> Uniscan proved unsuccessful.<br />

In spite <strong>of</strong> similar thinking about the most fruitful approach to <strong>integration</strong> policies in Europe, co-ordinated<br />

policy-making and the <strong>de</strong>finition <strong>of</strong> collective bargaining positions within and towards different<br />

international organisations was found difficult.<br />

The article discusses the potential and the ramifications <strong>of</strong> Anglo-Scandinavian co-operation in<br />

the post-Second World War international economy and in the early years <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>, with<br />

particular attention to British policy-making. What emerges is the preference <strong>of</strong> the Labour government<br />

in particular to <strong>de</strong>velop economic, political and institutional ties with the Scandinavians, but that<br />

these fell short <strong>of</strong> the earlier plans <strong>of</strong> wi<strong>de</strong>spread liberalisation and co-ordination among the group.<br />

Un partenariat difficile à saisir: l'Europe, la coopération économique et la politique britannique<br />

face à la Scandinavie. 1949-1951<br />

A cause <strong>de</strong> leur refus, pour diverses raisons, <strong>de</strong> participer aux expériences intégratives <strong>de</strong> la CECA,<br />

respectivement <strong>de</strong> la plus tardive CEE, les Britanniques et les Scandinaves sont souvent considérés<br />

comme ayant développé durant les années 1950 une espèce <strong>de</strong> sens commun. Les similitu<strong>de</strong>s au niveau<br />

<strong>de</strong> leur comportement ont même fait supposer une très large convergence d'intérêts, et ce, <strong>de</strong>puis les<br />

débuts <strong>de</strong> la reconstruction dans la secon<strong>de</strong> moitié <strong>de</strong>s années quarante.<br />

La méfiance britannique et scandinave envers les nouvelles formes <strong>de</strong> la coopération économique et<br />

politique développées dans l'Europe <strong>de</strong>s années 1950 est certes conditionnée par <strong>de</strong>s circonstances et <strong>de</strong>s<br />

préférences nationales, mais, d'un autre côté, elle est aussi l'expression du sentiment commun qu'il existe,<br />

en-<strong>de</strong>hors <strong>de</strong> la coopération économique pratiquée par les Six, une alternative intergouvernementale faisable.<br />

Ce point commun élémentaire amena les gouvernements britannique, danois, suédois et norvégien<br />

à se consulter régulièrement pendant la phase précoce <strong>de</strong> l'intégration européenne au sein d'un organisme<br />

spécifique, l'Uniscan, qui aspirait à faciliter la coordination <strong>de</strong>s politiques et qui, finalement, préparait la<br />

voie à la rapi<strong>de</strong> constitution <strong>de</strong> l'AELE en 1959, lorsque l'alternative <strong>de</strong> créer une vaste aire <strong>de</strong> libre<br />

échange avait été abandonnée.


160<br />

Abstracts – Résumés – Zusammenfassungen<br />

Pourtant, avant même que l'AELE ne concrétise enfin la vision originale déjà esquissée en 1949,<br />

d'autres efforts briguant un appr<strong>of</strong>ondissement <strong>de</strong> la coopération anglo-scandinave au-<strong>de</strong>là <strong>de</strong>s attributions<br />

purement consultatives d'Uniscan avaient échoué. En dépit <strong>de</strong> l'unicité <strong>de</strong>s vues en ce qui concerne<br />

l'approche la plus bénéfique en matière d'intégration européenne, une coordination <strong>de</strong>s politiques ainsi<br />

qu'une définition commune <strong>de</strong>s positions à adopter face aux différentes organisations internationales<br />

s'avérait difficile.<br />

Le présent article discute les potentialités et les ramifications <strong>de</strong> la coopération anglo-scandinave<br />

dans le système économique international <strong>de</strong> l'après-Deuxième Guerre mondiale et <strong>de</strong>s débuts <strong>de</strong> la construction<br />

européenne. Ce faisant, il voue une attention particulière à la politique britannique. Il apparaît<br />

ainsi que, surtout le cabinet travailliste, accorda la préférence au développement <strong>de</strong>s liens économiques,<br />

politiques et institutionnels avec les Scandinaves, ce qui cependant ne répondait guère aux plans initiaux<br />

d'une vaste libéralisation et coordination au sein du groupe.<br />

Eine schwer <strong>de</strong>finierbare Partnerschaft: Europa, die wirtschaftliche Zusammenarbeit und<br />

die britische Skandinavienpolitik (1949-1951)<br />

Wegen ihrer, aus verschie<strong>de</strong>nsten Grün<strong>de</strong>n, ablehnen<strong>de</strong>n Haltung gegenüber <strong>de</strong>m integrativen Experiment<br />

<strong>de</strong>r EGKS, bzw. <strong>de</strong>r späteren EWG, dichtete man <strong>de</strong>n Briten und <strong>de</strong>n Skandinaviern <strong>of</strong>t die<br />

Entfaltung eines Sinns für Gemeinsamkeit an. Die Ähnlichkeiten in ihrem Verhalten führte sogar zur<br />

Annahme, es habe seit Beginn <strong>de</strong>s Wie<strong>de</strong>raufbaus nach <strong>de</strong>m Zweiten Weltkrieg zwischen Briten und<br />

Skandinaviern eine weitreichen<strong>de</strong> Interessenkonvergenz gegeben.<br />

Die britische und skandinavische Skepsis gegenüber <strong>de</strong>n neuen Formen <strong>de</strong>r wirtschaftlichen und<br />

politischen Zusammenarbeit im Europa <strong>de</strong>r frühen Fünfzigerjahre war zwar durch nationale Umstän<strong>de</strong><br />

und Präferenzen geprägt; - sie war aber auch gekoppelt mit <strong>de</strong>r gemeinsam aufgefaßten Meinung, dass<br />

an<strong>de</strong>re, durchaus machbare Alternativen zur wirtschaftlichen Kooperation in Europa bestan<strong>de</strong>n. Diese<br />

elementare Einhelligkeit veranlasste die Regierungen in Großbritannien, Dänemark, Schwe<strong>de</strong>n und Norwegen<br />

regelmäßige Konsultationen im Rahmen eines eigens dafür geschaffenen Gremiums – die Uniscan<br />

– abzuhalten. Dieses Forum sollte die Koordinierung <strong>de</strong>r Politiken vorantreiben und ebnete auch<br />

schließlich <strong>de</strong>n Weg zur raschen Entstehung <strong>de</strong>r EFTA im Jahre 1959, als die Alternative einer größeren<br />

Freihan<strong>de</strong>lszone aufgegeben wur<strong>de</strong>.<br />

Allerdings, noch bevor die EFTA das ursprüngliche, bereits 1949 ins Auge gefasste Ziel verwirklichen<br />

konnte, waren Versuche die wirtschaftliche Kooperation über die beraten<strong>de</strong> Rolle <strong>de</strong>r Uniscan<br />

hinaus zu vertieften gescheitert. Trotz aller Gemeinsamkeit, insbeson<strong>de</strong>re mit Rücksicht auf die in<br />

ihren Augen wohl bessere europäische Integrationspolitik, gelang es <strong>de</strong>n Briten und <strong>de</strong>n Skandinaviern<br />

nur schwer eine einheitliche Haltung gegenüber <strong>de</strong>n internationalen Organisationen einzunehmen.<br />

Der vorliegen<strong>de</strong> Aufsatz untersucht die Möglichkeiten und die Verzweigungen einer englisch-skandinavischen<br />

Zusammenarbeit im Rahmen <strong>de</strong>r internationalen Nachkriegswirtschaft und <strong>de</strong>n<br />

frühen Jahren <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Vereinigung. Dabei wird beson<strong>de</strong>rs <strong>de</strong>r britischen Politik ein großes<br />

Augenmerk geschenkt. Es wird <strong>de</strong>utlich, dass insbeson<strong>de</strong>re die Laborregierung <strong>de</strong>r Entwicklung wirtschaftlicher,<br />

politischer und institutioneller Bindungen mit <strong>de</strong>n Skandinaviern <strong>de</strong>n Vorzug gab, diese aber<br />

nicht <strong>de</strong>n ursprünglichen Plänen einer großzügigen Liberalisierung und Koordination innerhalb <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Gruppe entsprachen.<br />

Erin Delaney<br />

The Labour Party's Changing Relationship to Europe.<br />

The Expansion <strong>of</strong> European Social Policy<br />

In 1950, the National Executive <strong>of</strong> the Labour Party stated that European <strong>integration</strong> could not be reconciled<br />

with a socialist agenda; however, by 1994, the Labour Party <strong>de</strong>clared that Europe, and the European<br />

Community, were an integral part <strong>of</strong> its ‘socialist’ domestic policy. Traditional analysis has cited the reasons<br />

for this change as a combination <strong>of</strong> numerous factors, including: intraparty factionalism; economic<br />

pressure; tension between the lea<strong>de</strong>rship and rank-and-file members; and the role <strong>of</strong> the two-party system.<br />

The EC is one factor that has been relatively ignored in the explanations for this policy change, as<br />

has its potential to exert discreet and discernible influence on policy in general.<br />

The aim <strong>of</strong> this article is to <strong>de</strong>monstrate that <strong>de</strong>velopments within the Community, specifically in the<br />

area <strong>of</strong> social policy, affected the Labour Party’s policy towards the EC. Beginning in 1950, this article


Abstracts – Résumés – Zusammenfassungen 161<br />

traces the changes in Labour’s policy, and relates them to the concurrent changes in the Community,<br />

using a variety <strong>of</strong> primary resources, including Party documents, aca<strong>de</strong>mic and political <strong>de</strong>bate in <strong>journal</strong>s<br />

and newspapers and personal memoirs.<br />

Les développements <strong>de</strong> la politique sociale européenne et l'attitu<strong>de</strong> changeante du Labour Party<br />

britannique face à l'Europe<br />

En 1950 encore, le comité exécutif national du Labour Party britannique déclarait qu'une intégration<br />

européenne s'avérerait incompatible avec son agenda; en 1994 pourtant, le même parti proclamait que<br />

l'Europe et la Communauté européenne font partie intégrante <strong>de</strong> son propre programme politique 'socialiste'.<br />

Les analyses classiques attribuent ce revirement à une combinaison <strong>de</strong> différentes raisons parmi<br />

lesquelles on distingue notamment la lutte <strong>de</strong>s factions au sein du parti, les pressions économiques, les<br />

tensions entre les lea<strong>de</strong>rs et la base <strong>de</strong>s militants ainsi que le poids du système bipartite anglais. La CE<br />

par contre est un facteur d'explication relativement ignoré, en l'occurrence son potentiel d'exercer une<br />

influence judicieuse et visible sur la politique en général.<br />

Le but <strong>de</strong> la présente contribution est <strong>de</strong> démontrer que les développements <strong>de</strong> la politique communautaire,<br />

notamment dans le domaine social, ont affecté l'approche du Labour Party face à la CE. En se<br />

servant <strong>de</strong> diverses sources primaires – <strong>de</strong>s documents du parti, les débats académiques et politiques<br />

reproduits dans les journaux, <strong>revue</strong>s ou mémoires – l'article retrace à partir du début <strong>de</strong>s années 1950 le<br />

changement d'attitu<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s travaillistes en le mettant en relation avec les évolutions au sein <strong>de</strong> la Communauté.<br />

Die Entwicklung <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Sozialpolitik und<br />

die verän<strong>de</strong>rte Haltung <strong>de</strong>r Labour Party gegenüber Europa<br />

Obwohl das nationale Exekutivkomitee <strong>de</strong>r britischen Labour Partei 1950 noch verkün<strong>de</strong>te, die<br />

europäische Integration sei unvereinbar mit <strong>de</strong>m sozialistischen Programm, erklärte dieselbe Partei 1994,<br />

dass Europa und die Gemeinschaft nun integraler Bestandteil parteieigener 'sozialistischer' Politik wären.<br />

Herkömmliche Analysen geben eine Kombination mehrerer Grün<strong>de</strong> für diesen Wan<strong>de</strong>l an: parteiinterne<br />

Querelen; wirtschaftlicher Druck, Spannungen zwischen <strong>de</strong>r Parteispitze und <strong>de</strong>r Basis; <strong>de</strong>r Einfluss <strong>de</strong>s<br />

englischen Zweiparteiensystems. Die EG, und insbeson<strong>de</strong>re ihr Potential einen bestimmten und erkennbaren<br />

Einfluss auf die allgemeine Politik auszuüben, wer<strong>de</strong>n dabei allerdings als Erklärungsfaktor relativ<br />

<strong>of</strong>t ignoriert.<br />

Ziel <strong>de</strong>s vorliegen<strong>de</strong>n Aufsatzes ist es zu beweisen, dass bestimmte Entwicklungen innerhalb <strong>de</strong>r EG<br />

– insbeson<strong>de</strong>re im Bereich „Soziales“ – sich auf die Europapolitik <strong>de</strong>r Labour Partei auswirkten. Beginnend<br />

mit <strong>de</strong>m Jahr 1950, zeichnet <strong>de</strong>r Aufsatz anhand diverser Primärquellen (parteiinterne Dokumente,<br />

aka<strong>de</strong>mische und politische Debatten in Zeitungen, Zeitschriften und Memoiren) die Wechsel im europapolitschen<br />

Labourprogramm auf und stellt diese in direkte Verbindung mit <strong>de</strong>n Verän<strong>de</strong>rungen innerhalb<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Gemeinschaft.


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

Zivilgesellschaft und Staat<br />

in Europa<br />

Die Untersuchung von sechs europäischen Staaten<br />

zeigt, wie sehr die Kulturen unterschiedliche Vorstellungen<br />

davon entwickelt haben, was ein Staat ist<br />

und welche Rolle er zu übernehmen hat. Wie Staat<br />

und Gesellschaft zueinan<strong>de</strong>r stehen, gestaltet sich<br />

dabei in je<strong>de</strong>m Land an<strong>de</strong>rs aus. Legitimation und<br />

Ausmaß staatlichen Han<strong>de</strong>lns entspricht jeweils verschie<strong>de</strong>nen<br />

theoretischen Voraussetzungen und Erwartungen.<br />

Die Verhaltensformen <strong>de</strong>r Individuen<br />

o<strong>de</strong>r Gruppen innerhalb dieses Spannungsverhältnisses<br />

erklären sich in diesem Zusammenhang.<br />

Der Band ist ein wertvoller Beitrag zur Diskussion <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Aufgaben und Ziele von Staat und Zivilgesellschaft<br />

sowie <strong>de</strong>ren Verhältnis zueinan<strong>de</strong>r, zumal sich gravieren<strong>de</strong><br />

Verän<strong>de</strong>rungen in diesem Spannungsfeld<br />

ergeben. Er bietet ebenso weitreichen<strong>de</strong> Impulse für<br />

die Diskussion über die sich wan<strong>de</strong>ln<strong>de</strong>n politischen<br />

und gesellschaftlichen Strukturen im Bereich <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen<br />

Union und <strong>de</strong>ren östlicher Nachbarschaft.<br />

Er richtet sich gleichermaßen an Lehren<strong>de</strong> und Lernen<strong>de</strong><br />

in Politik- und Sozialwissenschaft sowie auch<br />

an in Politik und Publizistik Tätige.<br />

Günther Ammon/Michael Hartmeier (Hrsg.)<br />

Zivilgesellschaft und Staat<br />

in Europa<br />

Ein Spannungsfeld im Wan<strong>de</strong>l<br />

Deutschland, Frankreich, Italien, Spanien, Ukraine,<br />

Weißrußland<br />

Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Günther Ammon/Michael Hartmeier<br />

(Hrsg.)<br />

Zivilgesellschaft und Staat<br />

in Europa<br />

Ein Spannungsfeld im Wan<strong>de</strong>l<br />

Deutschland, Frankreich, Italien,<br />

Spanien, Ukraine, Weißrußland<br />

2001, 133 S., brosch.,<br />

24,– €, 42,20 sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7251-6<br />

NOMOS


163<br />

Notices – Informations – Mitteilungen<br />

Conference on ”Actors and Policies in the European Integration<br />

from the implementation <strong>of</strong> the Rome Treaties to the creation <strong>of</strong> the<br />

‘snake’ (1958-1972)”<br />

Florence, 28, 29 and 30 November 2002<br />

Historical research on the European <strong>integration</strong> has mainly focussed its attention on<br />

the period between the 1940s and the 1960s, but from the 1960s, with the creation<br />

and strengthening <strong>of</strong> the European institutions, the historical analyses <strong>de</strong>aling only<br />

with the policies pursued by the national governments , diplomacies, etc. seem no<br />

longer completely satisfactory in or<strong>de</strong>r to fully un<strong>de</strong>rstand the European <strong>integration</strong><br />

process. Not only the European Commission or the European Parliament tried to<br />

assert themselves as autonomous actors, which could work out ‘European’ policies<br />

in<strong>de</strong>pen<strong>de</strong>ntly from the governments <strong>of</strong> the ”six”, but also interest groups and political<br />

forces began to organise themselves as European entities. Such an important<br />

<strong>de</strong>velopment seems to <strong>of</strong>fer to the historians an opportunity to further a new<br />

approach to the History <strong>of</strong> the European <strong>integration</strong>. To that end the next conference<br />

organised by the Liaison Committee <strong>of</strong> Historians will focus its attention on<br />

those topic.<br />

The conference, which will held in Florence in November 2002, will be organised<br />

into five sections:<br />

1. Institutional actors, national governments and EC <strong>de</strong>cision-making process<br />

2. The Birth and Consolidation <strong>of</strong> a European political world<br />

3. Interest and pressure groups<br />

4. The EC ‘internal’ policies<br />

5. The EC ‘external’ policies<br />

Form information contact:<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>. Antonio Varsori –<br />

Dipartimento di Studi sullo Stato –<br />

Facoltà di Scienze Politiche –<br />

Via Laura 48 – 50121 FIRENZE –<br />

ITALY –<br />

e-mail: varsori@unifi.it


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

Jahrbuch <strong>de</strong>s Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus<br />

2001<br />

Die Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisierungs-, Regionalisierungs- und Dezentralisierungsprozesse<br />

in <strong>de</strong>n Mitgliedstaaten <strong>de</strong>r<br />

EU und in <strong>de</strong>n Beitrittskandidaten haben spürbar an<br />

Dynamik gewonnen. Auch in <strong>de</strong>r Bun<strong>de</strong>srepublik ist<br />

eine Diskussion um die Zukunft <strong>de</strong>s Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus entbrannt.<br />

Fragen <strong>de</strong>r Territorialglie<strong>de</strong>rung und -organisation<br />

kommt in Europa eine immer größere Be<strong>de</strong>utung<br />

zu.<br />

Das Jahrbuch vermittelt Lesern in Politik und Verwaltung,<br />

Forschung und Lehre sowie europapolitisch<br />

Interessierten einen umfassen<strong>de</strong>n Überblick über die<br />

aktuellen Entwicklungen in Wissenschaft und politischer<br />

Praxis.<br />

Die Beiträge <strong>de</strong>s vorliegen<strong>de</strong>n zweiten Ban<strong>de</strong>s greifen<br />

aktuelle Themen <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus- und Regionalismusforschung<br />

auf und behan<strong>de</strong>ln zentrale Fragen<br />

<strong>de</strong>r bun<strong>de</strong>s<strong>de</strong>utschen Diskussion. In Län<strong>de</strong>rberichten<br />

wer<strong>de</strong>n neue Entwicklungen in <strong>de</strong>n EU-Mitgliedstaaten,<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Schweiz, Polen, <strong>de</strong>r Tschechischen Republik,<br />

Ungarn sowie <strong>de</strong>n Vereinigten Staaten von Amerika<br />

behan<strong>de</strong>lt. Abschließend widmen sich einige Beiträge<br />

Formen regionaler und kommunaler Kooperation<br />

und <strong>de</strong>r Rolle <strong>de</strong>r Regionen in <strong>de</strong>r EU.<br />

Die Herausgeber konnten abermals über dreißig<br />

namhafte Experten aus Wissenschaft und Verwaltung<br />

gewinnen.<br />

Band 2<br />

Europäisches Zentrum für Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus-Forschung Tübingen<br />

Jahrbuch <strong>de</strong>s Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus<br />

2001<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus, Subsidiarität und Regionen in Europa<br />

Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Europäisches Zentrum für<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus-Forschung Tübingen<br />

Jahrbuch <strong>de</strong>s Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus<br />

2001<br />

Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus, Subsidiarität und<br />

Regionen in Europa<br />

2001, 543 S., geb.,<br />

76,– €, 129,– sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7288-5<br />

NOMOS


165<br />

Contributors - Auteurs - Autoren<br />

Contributors - Auteurs - Autoren<br />

AUNESLUOMA Juhana, D.Phil, Lecturer <strong>of</strong> Contemporary History, Department<br />

<strong>of</strong> Social Science History, P.O.Box 54,<br />

00014 University <strong>of</strong> Helsinki, Finnland<br />

Tel: +358-9-191 24939<br />

E-mail: juhana.aunesluoma@helsinki.fi<br />

DELANEY Erin, PhD Candidate, Centre <strong>of</strong> International Studies,<br />

University <strong>of</strong> Cambridge; Chercheuse à L’Institut d’étu<strong>de</strong>s Européennes,<br />

L’Université Libre <strong>de</strong> Bruxelles,<br />

Adresse personnelle: 2, Rue Jacques Jordaens, 1000 Bruxelles<br />

Tel: +32 2 650 3676<br />

E-mail: e<strong>de</strong>laney@post.harvard.edu<br />

SEUNG-RYEOL Kim, Dr. phil. Lecturer at the Korea University in South Korea<br />

Personal address: Shilim 1-Dong, Kwanak-Ku Seoul South-Korea, 1625-16<br />

Tel: +82 2 857 0848<br />

Mobile: +82 16 892 0848<br />

E-mail: mark.kim@gmx.<strong>de</strong><br />

SVARTVATN Lise Rye is a Research Fellow at the Norwegian University<br />

<strong>of</strong> Science and Technology (NTNU), Department <strong>of</strong> History,<br />

N-7491 Trondheim, Norway<br />

Tel: 0047-73550563<br />

Fax: 0047-73596441<br />

E-mail: lise.svartvatn@hf.ntnu.no<br />

VAYSSIERE Bertrand, ancien élève <strong>de</strong> l’Institut d’Etu<strong>de</strong>s Politiques<br />

<strong>de</strong> Paris (1990-1992), maître <strong>de</strong> conférences à l’université <strong>de</strong> Pau et <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Pays <strong>de</strong> l’Adour UFR Lettres, Langues et Sciences Humaines,<br />

avenue du Doyen Poplawski, BP 1160, 64013 PAU ce<strong>de</strong>x, France.<br />

Adresse personnelle: 50, rue Adolphe Coll, 31300 Toulouse.<br />

E-mail: bertrand.vayssiere@wanadoo.fr<br />

WEGMANN Milène, ist Dr. phil. <strong>de</strong>r Universität Bern, Schweiz<br />

Persönliche Adresse: Beethovenstrasse 28,<br />

CH - 3073 Muri-Gümligen b. Bern, Schweiz<br />

Tel: +41 33 251 20 23<br />

E-mail: mawegmann@freesurf.ch


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

Grenzüberschreiten<strong>de</strong><br />

Zusammenarbeit zwischen<br />

<strong>de</strong>n Regionen in Europa<br />

Die europäische Integration stellt nicht nur einen<br />

Prozess dar, <strong>de</strong>r durch die zunehmen<strong>de</strong> Dynamik<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Supranationalität die Mitglieds- und Kandidatenlän<strong>de</strong>r<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Union miteinan<strong>de</strong>r<br />

verbin<strong>de</strong>t, son<strong>de</strong>rn auch eine Entwicklung, die einen<br />

massiven Transfer von traditionellen nationalen<br />

Aufgaben sowohl nach oben wie nach unten<br />

erfor<strong>de</strong>rlich macht. Gera<strong>de</strong> vor <strong>de</strong>m Hintergrund<br />

dieses Zwangs zur strukturellen Kompetenzverlagerung<br />

ergeben sich die Be<strong>de</strong>utungen <strong>de</strong>r grenzüberschreiten<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Zusammenarbeit für <strong>de</strong>n gesamten<br />

Integrationsprozess. Aufbauend auf<br />

grundlegen<strong>de</strong>n Darstellungen zum rechtlichen<br />

Rahmen regionaler Zusammenarbeit innerhalb<br />

<strong>de</strong>r EU und zum allgemeinen Charakter <strong>de</strong>r Grenzen<br />

zwischen <strong>de</strong>n Regionen in Europa bietet <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Sammelband eine Analyse dieser regionalen Zusammenarbeit<br />

in ausgewählten Regionen und<br />

Politikfel<strong>de</strong>rn. Untersucht wer<strong>de</strong>n z.B. Bildungspolitik,<br />

Innen- und Rechtspolitik, Umweltschutz,<br />

Strukturpolitik und Verkehrspolitik sowie die Regionen<br />

Saar-Lor-Lux, Neiße-Nisa-Nysa und das<br />

Rheineinzugsgebiet. In einem beson<strong>de</strong>ren Teil<br />

wer<strong>de</strong>n Probleme und Perspektive <strong>de</strong>r regionalen<br />

Zusammenarbeit in Europa aus <strong>de</strong>r Sicht verschie<strong>de</strong>ner<br />

nationaler und europäischer Institutionen<br />

beleuchtet.<br />

Schriften <strong>de</strong>s<br />

Zentrum für Europäische Integrationsforschung<br />

Center for European Integration Studies<br />

Xuewu Gu (Hrsg.)<br />

Grenzüberschreiten<strong>de</strong><br />

Zusammenarbeit zwischen<br />

<strong>de</strong>n Regionen in Europa<br />

Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Xuewu Gu (Hrsg.)<br />

Grenzüberschreiten<strong>de</strong><br />

Zusammenarbeit zwischen<br />

<strong>de</strong>n Regionen in Europa<br />

2002, 219 S., geb.,<br />

44,– €, 76,– sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7777-1<br />

(Schriften <strong>de</strong>s Zentrum für Europäische<br />

Integrationsforschung (ZEI), Bd. 39)<br />

NOMOS


167<br />

Books received – Livres reçus – Eingegangene Bücher<br />

AUCHET Marc, BOURGUIGNON Annie. – Aspects d’une dynamique<br />

régionale: Les pays nordiques dans le contexte <strong>de</strong> la Baltique. Nancy,<br />

Presses Universitaires <strong>de</strong> Nancy, 2001, 312 p. – ISBN 2-86480-3. – 22,87 €.<br />

BARNAVI Elie, GOOSSENS Paul (éds.). – Les frontières <strong>de</strong> l’Europe. Bruxelles,<br />

Éditions De Boeck, 2001, 271 p. – ISBN 2-8041-3938-7. – 995,00 BEF.<br />

BITSCH Marie-Thérèse. – Le couple France-Allemagne et les institutions<br />

européennes. Bruxelles, Bruylant, 2001, 609 p. – ISBN 2-8027-1500-3. –<br />

85,00 €.<br />

BITSCH Marie-Thérèse. – Histoire <strong>de</strong> la construction européenne: <strong>de</strong> 1945 à nos<br />

jours. Bruxelles, Editions Complexe, 2001, 356 p. – ISBN 2-87027-881-0. –<br />

21,19 €.<br />

BOSSUAT Gérard. – Les ai<strong>de</strong>s américaines, économiques et militaires à la<br />

France, 1938 – 1960, Une nouvelle image <strong>de</strong>s rapports <strong>de</strong> puissance. Paris,<br />

Comité pour l’histoire économique et financière <strong>de</strong> la France, 2001, 406 p. –<br />

ISBN 2-11-091050-X. – Prix 22,87 €.<br />

BOSSUAT Gérard. – Les fondateurs <strong>de</strong> l’unité européenne. Paris, Belin, 2001,<br />

320 p. – ISBN 2701129621 – Prix 19,70 €.<br />

BOURMEYSTER Alexandre. – L’Europe au regard <strong>de</strong>s intellectuels russes.<br />

Toulouse, Editions Privat, 2001, 127 p. – ISBN 2-7089-6934-X. – 11,89 €.<br />

BÖSCH Frank. – Die A<strong>de</strong>nauer-CDU. Gründung, Aufstieg und Krise einer<br />

Erfolgspartei 1945 – 1969. München, Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt GmbH,<br />

2002, 576 p. – ISBN 3-421-05438-X. – 39,80 €.<br />

COFFEY Peter. – The euro, an essential gui<strong>de</strong>. London and New York, Continuum,<br />

2001, 260 p. – ISBN 0-8264-4766-X (Hb.). – 60,00 £. – ISBN 0-8264-4767-8<br />

(Pp.). – 15,99 £.<br />

CONWAY Martin, GOTOVITCH José. – Europe in Exile. European Exile<br />

Communities in Britain 1940 – 45. New-York – Oxford, Berghahn Books,<br />

2001, 281 p. – ISBN 1-57181-759-X (hb.). – 47,00 £. – 1-57181-503-1 (pb.).<br />

– 17,00 £.<br />

DEN JYSKE HISTORIKER. – Mø<strong>de</strong>t med <strong>de</strong>n europaeiske jungle. National<br />

strategi og i<strong>de</strong>ntitet i dansk europapolitik 1945 – 2000. Aarhus, Aarhus<br />

Universitet, 2001, 178 p. – ISBN 87-7023-778-6. – 125 kr.<br />

DUCHENNE Geneviève. – Visions et Projets Belges pour l’Europe. De la Belle<br />

Époque aux Traités <strong>de</strong> Rome (1900 – 1957). Bruxelles, P.I.E. Peter Lang,<br />

2001, 302 p. – ISBN 90-5201-963-3. – 26,30 €.


168<br />

Books received – Livres reçus – Eingegangene Bücher<br />

DUMOULIN Michel – DUCHENNE Geneviève. – L’Europe et la Mediterranée.<br />

Bruxelles, P.I.E. Peter Lang AG, 2001, 329 p. – ISBN 90-5201-967-3. – 30,10 €.<br />

DU RÉAU Elisabeth. – L’Idée d’Europe au XX e siècle. Des mythes aux réalités.<br />

Bruxelles, Editions Complexe, 2001, 371 p. – ISBN 2-87027-882-9. – 21,19 €.<br />

DU RÉAU Elisabeth. – L’élargissement <strong>de</strong> l’union européenne. Quels Enjeux?<br />

Quels Défis? Paris, Presses <strong>de</strong> la Sorbonne Nouvelle, 2001, 232 p. –<br />

ISBN 2-87854-219-3. – 18,30 €.<br />

FARELL Mary, FELLA Stefano, NEWMAN Michael. – European Integration<br />

in the 21 st Century. Unity in Diversity? London, Sage Publications, 2002,<br />

232 p. – ISBN 0-7619-7218-8 (hb.). – 50,00 £. – ISBN 0-7619-7219-6 (pb.). –<br />

16,99 £.<br />

GOLDMANN Kjell. – Transforming the European Nation-State. Dynamics <strong>of</strong><br />

Internationalization. London, Sage Publications, 2001, 224 p. –<br />

ISBN 0-7619-6362-X (hb.). – 55,00 £. – ISBN 0-7619-6327-8 (pb.). – 17,99 £.<br />

GRAML Hermann. – Zwischen Stresemann und Hitler. Die Außenpolitik <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Präsidialkabinette Brüning, Papen und Schleicher. München, Ol<strong>de</strong>nbourg,<br />

2001, 239 p. – ISBN 3-486-64583-8. – 24,80 €.<br />

GRUNEWALD Michel – BOCK Manfred. – Le discours européen dans les<br />

<strong>revue</strong>s alleman<strong>de</strong>s. (1945–1955) – Der Europadiskurs in <strong>de</strong>n <strong>de</strong>utschen<br />

Zeitschriften. (1945-1955). Bern, Peter Lang AG, 2001, 472 p. –<br />

ISBN 3-906758-26-5. – 99,00 SFR.<br />

HAFTENDORN Helga. – Deutsche Außenpolitik zwischen Selbstbeschränkung<br />

und Selbstbehauptung. München, Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt, 2001, 524 p. –<br />

ISBN 3-421-05219-0. – 29,80 €.<br />

HIMMLER Norbert. – Zwischen Macht und Mittelmaß. Großbritanniens<br />

Außenpolitik und das En<strong>de</strong> <strong>de</strong>s Kalten Krieges. Berlin, Duncker & Humblot<br />

GmbH., 2001, 296 p. – ISBN 3-428-10123-5. – 34,00 €.<br />

HUBEL Helmut. – EU Enlargement and Beyond: The Baltic States and Russia.<br />

Berlin, Arno Spitz, 2002, 487 p. – ISBN 3-8305-0271-0. – 60,00 €.<br />

KAVAKAS Dimitrios. – Greece and Spain in European Foreign Plicy. The influence<br />

<strong>of</strong> southern member states in common foreign and security policy.<br />

Al<strong>de</strong>rshot, Ashgate, 2001, 238 p. – ISBN 0-7546-1821-8 (Hb.). – 45,00 £.<br />

KIPPING Matthias. – La France et les origines <strong>de</strong> l’Union européenne. Intégration<br />

économique et compétitivité internationale. Paris, Comité pour<br />

l’histoire économique et financière <strong>de</strong> la France, 2002, 411 p. –<br />

ISBN 2-11-091056-9. – 27,00 €.<br />

KUSTERER Hermann. – Le Général et le Chancelier. Paris, Economica, 2001,<br />

427 p. – ISBN 2-7178-4338-8. – 30,00 €.


Books received – Livres reçus – Eingegangene Bücher 169<br />

LAVENEX Sandra. – The Europeanisation <strong>of</strong> Refugee Policies. Between<br />

human rights and internal security. Al<strong>de</strong>rshot, Ashgate, 2001, 235 p. –<br />

ISBN 0-7546-1803-X. – 42,50 £.<br />

MAGNUSSON Lars & STRATH Bo (eds.). – From the Werner Plan to the<br />

EMU. In Search <strong>of</strong> a Political Economy for Europe. Bruxelles, P.I.E. Peter<br />

Lang, 2001, 490 p. – ISBN 90-5201-948-7. – 64,00 SFR.<br />

MAURHOFER Roland. – Die schweizerische Europapolitik vom Marshallplan<br />

zur EFTA 1947 bis 1960. Bern, Verlag Paul Haupt, 2001, 490 p. –<br />

ISBN 3-258-06383-4. – 49,00 €.<br />

MELCHIONNI Maria Grazia. – L’I<strong>de</strong>ntità Europea alla fine <strong>de</strong>l XX Secolo.<br />

Roma, Università <strong>de</strong>gli Studi di Roma, 2001, 468 p.<br />

MINISTÈRE DE L’ÉCONOMIE, DES FINANCES ET DE L’INDUSTRIE. – Le rôle <strong>de</strong>s<br />

ministères <strong>de</strong>s Finances et <strong>de</strong> l’Economie dans la construction<br />

européenne (1957-1978). Actes du colloque tenu à Bercy les 26, 27 et 28<br />

mai 1999. Tomes I et II. Paris, Comité pour l’histoire économique et financière<br />

<strong>de</strong> la France, 2002, 572 p. et 270 p. – ISBN2-11-091048-8. – 39,00 €.<br />

MONAR Jörg, WESSELS Wolfgang. – The European Union after the Treaty <strong>of</strong><br />

Amsterdam. London, Continuum, 2001, 350 p. – ISBN 0-8264-4769-4<br />

(hb.). – 65,00 £. – ISBN 0-8264-4770-8 (pp.). – 18,99 £.<br />

MÜLLER-BRANDECK-BOCQUET Gisela (Hrsg.) – Europäische Aussenpolitik.<br />

GASP- und ESVP-Konzeptionen ausgewählter EU-Mitgliedstaaten.<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, Nomos, 2002, 149 p. – ISBN 3-7890-7743-7. – 25,00 €.<br />

MÜLLER-PETERS Anke, PEPERMANS Roland, KIELL Guido,<br />

FARHANGMEHR Minoo. – The Psychology <strong>of</strong> European Monetary<br />

Union: A Cross-National Study <strong>of</strong> Public Opinion Towards the Euro. Santiago<br />

<strong>de</strong> Compostela, Grafinova S.A., 2001. 562 p. – ISBN 84-607-2896-X.<br />

NICOL Danny. – EC Membership and the Judicalization <strong>of</strong> British Politics.<br />

Oxford, University Press, 2001, 287 p. – ISBN 0-19-924779-X. – 37,45 £.<br />

PAPADEMETRIOU Demetrios G. – WALLER MEYERS Deborah (Eds.). –<br />

Cought in the Middle: Bor<strong>de</strong>r Communities in an Era <strong>of</strong> Globalization.<br />

Washington, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, 2001, 340 p. –<br />

ISBN 0-87003-185-6. – 24,95 $<br />

QUERMONNE Jean-Louis. – L’Europe en quête <strong>de</strong> légitimité. Paris, Presses <strong>de</strong><br />

Sciences PO, 2001, 126 p. – ISBN 2-7246-0822-4. – 12,00 €.<br />

RECK Brigitte. – Flexibilität in <strong>de</strong>r Europäischen Union. Entstehung und Entwicklung<br />

eines alternativen Integrationsmo<strong>de</strong>lls. Stuttgart, Ibi<strong>de</strong>m-Verlag,<br />

2001, 130 p. – ISBN 3-89821-134-7. – 29,90 €.


170<br />

Books received – Livres reçus – Eingegangene Bücher<br />

RENNE Barbara. – Die Europäische Wirtschafts- und Währungsunion<br />

zwischen Anspruch und Wirklichkeit. Ist die EWWU <strong>de</strong>s Maastrichter Vertrages<br />

ziel- und funktionsadäquat verfaßt? Bern, Peter Lang AG., 2001,<br />

148 p. – ISBN 3-631-38325-8. – 48,00 SFR.<br />

SCHWARZ Hans-Peter (Hrsg.). – Akten zur Auswärtigen Politik <strong>de</strong>r Bun<strong>de</strong>srepublik<br />

Deutschland 1953. Band I und II. München, Ol<strong>de</strong>nbourg, 2001,<br />

1254 p. – ISBN 3-486-56560-5. – 99,80 €.<br />

SCHWARZ Hans-Peter (Hrsg.). – Akten zur Auswärtigen Politik <strong>de</strong>r Bun<strong>de</strong>srepublik<br />

Deutschland 1971. Band I, II und III. München, Ol<strong>de</strong>nbourg,<br />

2002, 2153 p. – ISBN 3-486-56618-0. – 178,00 €.<br />

SPILLMANN Kurt R. – WENGER Andreas. – Russia’s Place in Europe. A<br />

Security Debate. Bern, Peter Lang AG., 1999, 251 p. – ISBN 3-906762-21-1 –<br />

23,50 €.<br />

TONRA Ben. – The Europeanisation <strong>of</strong> National Foreign Policy. Dutch, Danish<br />

and Irish Foreign Policy in the European Union. Al<strong>de</strong>rshot, Ashgate,<br />

2001, 314 p. – ISBN 0-7546-1261-9. – 47,50 £.<br />

TORREBLANCA José I. – The Reuniting <strong>of</strong> Europe. Promises, negotiations<br />

and compromises. Al<strong>de</strong>rshot, Ashgate, 2001, 376 p. – 1-84014-527-7 (Hb.).<br />

– 49,95 £.<br />

UNIVERSITÉ CATHOLIQUE DE LOUVAIN. – Annales d’étu<strong>de</strong>s européennes <strong>de</strong><br />

l’UCL 2001. Bruxelles, Bruylant, 2001, 398 p. – ISBN 2-8027-1523-2. –<br />

82,00 €.<br />

VANHOONACKER Sophie. – The Bush Administration (1889 – 1993) and the<br />

Development <strong>of</strong> a European Security i<strong>de</strong>ntity. Al<strong>de</strong>rshot, Ashgate, 2001,<br />

284 p. – ISBN 0-7546-1664-9. – 39,95 £.<br />

WILHELM Justus. – Deutschland, Polen und die Politik in <strong>de</strong>r Nato, 1989 bis 1997.<br />

Bern, Peter Lang AG., 2001,310 p. – ISBN 3-631-37868-8. – 72,00 SFR.


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

Die Konstruktion Europas<br />

Ist <strong>de</strong>r Verlauf <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Integration nur von<br />

materiellen Interessen bestimmt o<strong>de</strong>r spielen auch<br />

I<strong>de</strong>en eine Rolle? Zur Beantwortung dieser Frage<br />

wird zunächst eine konstruktivistische Theorie <strong>de</strong>r Bildung<br />

staatlicher Präferenzen entwickelt. Der zweite<br />

Teil bietet eine methodisch reflektierte, systematisch<br />

vergleichen<strong>de</strong> Untersuchung europapolitischer Vorstellungen<br />

(»Verfassungsi<strong>de</strong>en«) in Deutschland,<br />

Frankreich und Großbritannien seit 1950. Der dritte<br />

Teil analysiert ihre politische Wirksamkeit anhand<br />

<strong>de</strong>r Verhandlungen zum Amsterdamer Vertrag. Ergebnis<br />

ist, daß in Bereichen, wo objektive Interessenlagen<br />

unklar sind, I<strong>de</strong>en auch in zwischenstaatlichen<br />

Verfassungskonferenzen eine wesentliche<br />

Rolle spielen.<br />

Das Buch wen<strong>de</strong>t sich an Leser, die an <strong>de</strong>n Wurzeln<br />

<strong>de</strong>r gegenwärtigen Debatte um die EU-Verfassung<br />

interessiert sind wie auch an Wissenschaftler, die im<br />

Bereich Theorien <strong>de</strong>r internationalen Beziehungen<br />

arbeiten.<br />

Markus Jachtenfuchs ist Pr<strong>of</strong>essor für Politikwissenschaft<br />

an <strong>de</strong>r International University Bremen.<br />

Weltpolitik im 21. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rt<br />

Markus Jachtenfuchs<br />

Die Konstruktion Europas<br />

Verfassungsi<strong>de</strong>en und institutionelle Entwicklung<br />

Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Markus Jachtenfuchs<br />

Die Konstruktion Europas<br />

Verfassungsi<strong>de</strong>en und<br />

institutionelle Entwicklung<br />

i. Vb., 2002, 302 S., brosch.,<br />

20,– €, 35,20 sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7906-5<br />

(Weltpolitik im 21. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rt, Bd. 9)<br />

NOMOS


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

Jahrbuch <strong>de</strong>s Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus<br />

2001<br />

Die Fö<strong>de</strong>ralisierungs-, Regionalisierungs- und Dezentralisierungsprozesse<br />

in <strong>de</strong>n Mitgliedstaaten <strong>de</strong>r<br />

EU und in <strong>de</strong>n Beitrittskandidaten haben spürbar an<br />

Dynamik gewonnen. Auch in <strong>de</strong>r Bun<strong>de</strong>srepublik ist<br />

eine Diskussion um die Zukunft <strong>de</strong>s Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus entbrannt.<br />

Fragen <strong>de</strong>r Territorialglie<strong>de</strong>rung und -organisation<br />

kommt in Europa eine immer größere Be<strong>de</strong>utung<br />

zu.<br />

Weltpolitik im 21. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rt<br />

Thomas Gehring<br />

Die Europäische Union als komplexe<br />

internationale Organisation<br />

Wie durch Kommunikation und Entscheidung<br />

soziale Ordnung entsteht<br />

Das Jahrbuch vermittelt Lesern in Politik und Verwaltung,<br />

Forschung und Lehre sowie europapolitisch<br />

Interessierten einen umfassen<strong>de</strong>n Überblick über die<br />

aktuellen Entwicklungen in Wissenschaft und politischer<br />

Praxis.<br />

Die Beiträge <strong>de</strong>s vorliegen<strong>de</strong>n zweiten Ban<strong>de</strong>s<br />

greifen aktuelle Themen <strong>de</strong>r Fö<strong>de</strong>ralismus- und Regionalismusforschung<br />

auf und behan<strong>de</strong>ln zentrale<br />

Fragen <strong>de</strong>r bun<strong>de</strong>s<strong>de</strong>utschen Diskussion. In<br />

Län<strong>de</strong>rberichten wer<strong>de</strong>n neue Entwicklungen in<br />

<strong>de</strong>n EU-Mitgliedstaaten, <strong>de</strong>r Schweiz, Polen, <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Tschechischen Republik, Ungarn sowie <strong>de</strong>n Vereinigten<br />

Staaten von Amerika behan<strong>de</strong>lt. Abschließend<br />

widmen sich einige Beiträge Formen<br />

regionaler und kommunaler Kooperation und <strong>de</strong>r<br />

Rolle <strong>de</strong>r Regionen in <strong>de</strong>r EU.<br />

Die Herausgeber konnten abermals über dreißig<br />

namhafte Experten aus Wissenschaft und Verwaltung<br />

gewinnen.<br />

Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Thomas Gehring<br />

Die Europäische Union<br />

als komplexe internationale<br />

Organisation<br />

Wie durch Kommunikation und Entscheidung<br />

soziale Ordnung entsteht<br />

2002, 322 S., brosch.,<br />

20,– €, 35,20 sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7877-8<br />

(Weltpolitik im 21. Jahrhun<strong>de</strong>rt, Bd. 8)<br />

NOMOS


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

Developing Local Governance<br />

Networks in Europe<br />

There has recently been a major rush <strong>of</strong> reforms at<br />

local government level throughout Europe. This cutting<br />

edge book provi<strong>de</strong>s both a conceptual overview<br />

<strong>of</strong> this trend and an empirical analysis <strong>of</strong> the<br />

new "local governance networks” which are emerging<br />

in Europe.<br />

This book examines the changing relationships between<br />

public, private and voluntary actors at local level<br />

through case studies in eleven countries and reports<br />

from two multi-country comparative studies. It<br />

also provi<strong>de</strong>s a research agenda for comparative local<br />

governance.<br />

This is the first book in the ‘Local Governance in Europe’<br />

series from the Study Group on Local Governance<br />

(http://www.uwe.ac.uk/bbs/sglg/) un<strong>de</strong>r<br />

the auspices <strong>of</strong> the European Group <strong>of</strong> Public Administration<br />

(EGPA).<br />

The book will be essential reading for researchers<br />

and stu<strong>de</strong>nts <strong>of</strong> public administration, management<br />

and political science as well as for change agents at<br />

local level.<br />

Tony Bovaird (Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Strategy and Public<br />

Services Management) and Elke Löffler (Senior<br />

Research Associate) work at Bristol Business School<br />

(University <strong>of</strong> the West <strong>of</strong> England). Salvador<br />

Parrado-Díez is a Senior Lecturer at the Spanish<br />

Distance Learning University (UNED) in Madrid.<br />

Local Governance in Europe 1<br />

Tony Bovaird / Elke Löffler / Salvador Parrado-Díez<br />

Developing Local Governance<br />

Networks in Europe<br />

Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Tony Bovaird/Elke Löffler/<br />

Salvador Parrado-Díez (eds.)<br />

Developing Local Governance<br />

Networks in Europe<br />

2002, 250 pp.,<br />

42,– €, 73,– sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7826-3<br />

(Local Governance in Europe, Vol. 1)<br />

NOMOS


NOMOS Aktuell<br />

Die Beziehungen zwischen <strong>de</strong>r<br />

EU und <strong>de</strong>n Mercosur-Staaten<br />

Die Einzelbeiträge <strong>de</strong>s Tagungsbands beleuchten<br />

aus wirtschafts-, rechts- und politikwissenschaftlicher<br />

Perspektive eine Reihe spezifischer<br />

Rahmendingen, die für die gegenwärtigen und<br />

künftigen EU-MERCOSUR-Beziehungen von beachtlicher<br />

Prägewirkung sind. Thematische<br />

Schwerpunkte sind die seit <strong>de</strong>m zweiten Weltkrieg<br />

in Südamerika eingetretenen Entwicklungen<br />

hinsichtlich <strong>de</strong>r sozio-ökonomischen Rahmenbedingungen<br />

(Hartmut Sangmeister), <strong>de</strong>r<br />

ordnungspolitischen Leitvorstellungen und <strong>de</strong>r<br />

regionalen Integrationsansätze (Fe<strong>de</strong>rico Fo<strong>de</strong>rs)<br />

sowie <strong>de</strong>r Beziehungen Südamerikas zur<br />

EU (Klaus Bo<strong>de</strong>mer), <strong>de</strong>n USA (Wolf Grabendorff)<br />

und zu Südost-Asien (Manfred Mols).<br />

Außer<strong>de</strong>m wer<strong>de</strong>n Konzept und bisheriger <strong>integration</strong>spolitischer<br />

»aquis« <strong>de</strong>s MERCOSUR<br />

thematisiert (Ulrich Wehner). Schließlich wird<br />

untersucht, welche potentiellen Implikationen<br />

von <strong>de</strong>r EU-Osterweiterung und von <strong>de</strong>r EU-<br />

AKP-Kooperation für die Mercosur-Staaten sowie<br />

für die EU-MERCOSUR-Beziehungen ausgehen<br />

(Peter Nunnenkamp).<br />

Schriftenreihe <strong>de</strong>s Arbeitskreises<br />

Europäische Integration e.V. 48<br />

Wulfdiether Zippel (Hrsg.)<br />

Die Beziehungen zwischen <strong>de</strong>r<br />

EU und <strong>de</strong>n Mercosur-Staaten<br />

Stand und Perspektiven<br />

Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n<br />

Wulfdiether Zippel (Hrsg.)<br />

Die Beziehungen zwischen <strong>de</strong>r<br />

EU und <strong>de</strong>n Mercosur-Staaten<br />

Stand und Perspektiven<br />

2002, 155 S., brosch.,<br />

25,– €, 43,80 sFr,<br />

ISBN 3-7890-7726-7<br />

(Schriftenreihe <strong>de</strong>s Arbeitskreises<br />

Europäische Integration e.V., Bd. 48)<br />

NOMOS


Annual subscription: 38,– € including postage and<br />

packing<br />

Single issues: 21,– €<br />

Payments can be ma<strong>de</strong><br />

– by cheques payable to NOMOS Verlag<br />

– by bank transfers to Stadtsparkasse Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n,<br />

account no 5 002 266, bank clearing number<br />

(Bankleitzahl 66 250 030) in the name <strong>of</strong> NOMOS.<br />

Please ensure you quote the Journal <strong>of</strong> European<br />

Integration History when instructing your bank and<br />

enclose a copy <strong>of</strong> your instructions to the bank with<br />

your or<strong>de</strong>r.<br />

– by credit card (VISA, Masters, Eurocard).<br />

Subscriptions and or<strong>de</strong>rs should be sent to: NOMOS<br />

Verlagsgesellschaft, D-76520 Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n, Germany.<br />

Inquiries concerning advertisements should be<br />

sent to the Editorial Secretariat, Centre d’étu<strong>de</strong>s et <strong>de</strong><br />

recherches européennes Robert Schuman, 4 rue Jules<br />

Wilhelm, L-2728 Luxembourg.<br />

JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN<br />

INTEGRATION HISTORY<br />

REVUE D’HISTOIRE DE<br />

L’INTÉGRATION EUROPÉENNE<br />

ZEITSCHRIFT FÜR GESCHICHTE DER<br />

EUROPÄISCHEN INTEGRATION


JOURNAL OF EUROPEAN INTEGRATION HISTORY<br />

The purpose <strong>of</strong> The Journal <strong>of</strong> European Integration History is to encourage the<br />

analysis and un<strong>de</strong>rstanding <strong>of</strong> different aspects <strong>of</strong> European <strong>integration</strong>, especially<br />

since 1945, in as wi<strong>de</strong> a perspective as possible. The Journal publishes the<br />

conclusions <strong>of</strong> research on diplomatic, military, economic, technological, social<br />

and cultural aspects <strong>of</strong> <strong>integration</strong>. Numbers <strong>de</strong>voted to single themes as well as<br />

to diverse subjects are published in English, French or German. Each number<br />

inclu<strong>de</strong>s reviews <strong>of</strong> important, relevant publications.<br />

REVUE D’HISTOIRE DE L’INTÉGRATION EUROPÉENNE<br />

L’objectif <strong>de</strong> la Revue d’histoire <strong>de</strong> l’intégration européenne est <strong>de</strong> promouvoir l’analyse<br />

et la compréhension <strong>de</strong>s différents aspects <strong>de</strong> l’intégration européenne<br />

particulièrement <strong>de</strong>puis 1945, mais sans exclusive. La Revue publie les résultats <strong>de</strong>s<br />

recherches sur les aspects diplomatiques, militaires, économiques, technologiques,<br />

sociaux et culturels <strong>de</strong> l’intégration. Les numéros à thème ou ceux ouverts à diverses<br />

perspectives sont publiés dans l’une <strong>de</strong>s langues suivantes: anglais, français, allemand.<br />

Chaque numéro comprend <strong>de</strong>s comptes rendus d’ouvrages importants.<br />

ZEITSCHRIFT FÜR GESCHICHTE DER<br />

EUROPÄISCHEN INTEGRATION<br />

Die Zeitschrift für Geschichte <strong>de</strong>r europäischen Integration bietet ein Forum zur<br />

Erforschung <strong>de</strong>s europäischen Integrationsprozesses in allen Aspekten: <strong>de</strong>n politischen,<br />

militärischen, wirtschaftlichen, technologischen, sozialen und kulturellen.<br />

Ihren Schwerpunkt bil<strong>de</strong>n Beiträge zu <strong>de</strong>n konkreten Einigungsprojekten seit<br />

1945, doch wer<strong>de</strong>n auch Arbeiten zu <strong>de</strong>n Vorläufern und Vorbereitungen<br />

publiziert. Die Zeitschrift erscheint zweimal im Jahr. Neben Themenheften stehen<br />

„<strong>of</strong>fene“ Ausgaben, und je<strong>de</strong>smal wer<strong>de</strong>n auch Besprechungen wichtiger Neuerscheinungen<br />

veröffentlicht. Die Beiträge eines internationalen Autorenkreises<br />

erscheinen in englischer, französischer o<strong>de</strong>r <strong>de</strong>utscher Sprache.<br />

2002, Volume 8, Number 1<br />

NOMOS Verlagsgesellschaft<br />

Ba<strong>de</strong>n-Ba<strong>de</strong>n

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!