20.03.2015 Views

Market Economics | Interest Rate Strategy - BNP PARIBAS ...

Market Economics | Interest Rate Strategy - BNP PARIBAS ...

Market Economics | Interest Rate Strategy - BNP PARIBAS ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

will be strong for those currencies that have seen<br />

solid foreign inflows beforehand.<br />

When discussing inflation-fighting credentials, the<br />

ECB stands out. Only last week, the ECB’s Trichet<br />

expressed his unease at EMU HICP moving above<br />

the ECB’s 2% ceiling. Instantly, the euro rushed<br />

higher. However, in the case of the EUR, the<br />

credibility of the ECB must also be viewed in the<br />

context of outstanding credit risks, leading to nonhomogenous<br />

monetary conditions within the<br />

eurozone. Table 7 alongside has been constructed<br />

with the help of the IMF. It shows debt levels and the<br />

interest rate-growth differentials of selected EMU<br />

countries. At the start of the currency union, rates<br />

were way too loose for peripheral countries. The rule<br />

of thumb suggests that nominal GDP and rates<br />

should be at approximately the same level. The rule<br />

should particularly apply in the long term.<br />

Table 7: Public Debt and <strong>Interest</strong> <strong>Rate</strong>–Growth<br />

<strong>Rate</strong> Differential (pp)<br />

Country<br />

Debt/GDP<br />

2007 2009 2015 1/ Historical /2 Projected /1<br />

France 63.8 77.4 94.8 0.8 0.5<br />

Germany 65 72.5 81.5 2.6 1.5<br />

Greece 95.6 114.7 158.6 -1.5 2.2<br />

Ireland 24.9 64.5 94 -5.8 3.2<br />

Italy 103.4 115.8 124.7 1.4 1.7<br />

Portugal 63.6 77.1 98.4 -0.6 2.2<br />

Spain 36.1 55.2 94.4 -2.4 2.6<br />

Median 63.8 77.1 94.8 -0.6 2.2<br />

Mean 64.6 82.5 106.6 -0.8 2<br />

Source: IMF’s WEO database, <strong>BNP</strong> Paribas<br />

<strong>Interest</strong> rate-Growth rate Differential<br />

Chart 8: USD Liquidity vs. S&P 500, CRB<br />

However, before the crisis, peripheral countries<br />

enjoyed relative to their nominal GDP growth very<br />

low funding costs, which led to booming and<br />

consequently busting assets. The table shows that<br />

Ireland ran a negative interest rate-growth gap of<br />

5.6%. But now, as assets have tanked, peripheral<br />

countries are exposed to liabilities no longer covered<br />

by asset values.<br />

The funding costs of these liabilities have soared and<br />

will stay high if you believe the IMF numbers, leading<br />

to the perverse situation that monetary conditions in<br />

the recessionary countries of Europe’s periphery<br />

have tightened while booming Germany faces superloose<br />

monetary conditions. This environment will put<br />

the inflation-fighting credentials of the ECB to the<br />

test.<br />

We recall the situation from August to early<br />

November, when the ECB channelled 3mths Euribor<br />

rates up by about 60bp. At the same time, intra-EMU<br />

credit spreads widened, leaving us confident with our<br />

EURUSD 1.34 year-end call for 2010. Now as<br />

inflation is moving up and the ECB rhetoric is<br />

becoming more hawkish, we are watching credit<br />

spreads with interest. As long as credit does not pop<br />

up, the euro will strengthen, supported by<br />

expectations of a hawkish central bank reaction to<br />

rising inflation.<br />

However, recessionary peripheral economies facing<br />

already-tight monetary conditions are unlikely to cope<br />

well with monetary tightening. Inflation and the<br />

reaction of central banks must always be viewed in<br />

the context of credit; this is particularly the case for<br />

EMU.<br />

Inflation will kill the ‘quasi-China trade’<br />

Source: Reuters Ecowin Pro, <strong>BNP</strong> Paribas<br />

Third, the emergence of inflation might actually be<br />

good news for countries currently stuck in deflation or<br />

facing the threat of deflation (e.g. Japan and the US,<br />

respectively). On the other hand, inflation represents<br />

the biggest threat in countries where there has been<br />

domestically built up leverage.<br />

Above, we discussed the case of China, where<br />

inflation will either undermine the real value of<br />

household assets (in the case of deposit rates<br />

remaining below inflation) or the highly leveraged<br />

corporate sector faces rising funding costs (should<br />

the central bank take on the fight against inflation by<br />

increasing official lending rates). In our view, the<br />

inflation trade is the ‘anti quasi-China trade’ working<br />

against shares, commodities and last and not least<br />

the AUD. Inflation will bring the USD-funded carry<br />

trade to an abrupt halt, leading to a higher USD.<br />

Inflation will weaken the JPY<br />

Fourth, rising inflation globally will put the JPY under<br />

significant selling pressure. Japan has accumulated<br />

foreign currency hedged assets as hedging costs<br />

became virtually zero in a world where quantitative<br />

easing is a common policy tool. When inflation<br />

comes back and central banks tighten policy, the<br />

JPY will fall victim to the process.<br />

Hans Redeker 20 January 2011<br />

<strong>Market</strong> Mover, Non-Objective Research Section<br />

62<br />

www.Global<strong>Market</strong>s.bnpparibas.com

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!