20.03.2015 Views

Market Economics | Interest Rate Strategy - BNP PARIBAS ...

Market Economics | Interest Rate Strategy - BNP PARIBAS ...

Market Economics | Interest Rate Strategy - BNP PARIBAS ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

such shocks at the moment, such as extreme<br />

drought in Russia last year and unusually wet<br />

weather in parts of Australia now, following on from<br />

unusually cold conditions in the northern hemisphere<br />

in December. Crops are being affected and so food<br />

prices are rising faster than underlying demand and<br />

supply conditions would suggest.<br />

The traditional approach to such shocks is to argue<br />

that, while such effects may last for many months, if<br />

next year’s crops are more normal, the food price<br />

shocks may diminish or reverse. Against this, some<br />

believe that global warming is making extreme<br />

conditions more likely (e.g. the melting of sea ice in<br />

the Barents and Kara seas due to global warming<br />

may be responsible, by changing local wind systems,<br />

for the intense cold spell in Western Europe in<br />

December). There is some probability of this being<br />

correct, so our assumption is food inflation due to<br />

shocks may lessen next year. But there are unlikely<br />

to be significant falls in food prices.<br />

The output gap<br />

The output gap is a little like virtue – it’s somewhat<br />

difficult to define and tougher to measure, but you<br />

tend to find out from consequences when it’s not<br />

present.<br />

In order to calculate the global output gap, we have<br />

taken figures for the past and for forecast periods<br />

from the IMF’s WEO. We calculated the output gap<br />

using a Hodrick-Prescott filter. The results are shown<br />

in Chart 2.<br />

The chart shows a number of striking things:<br />

• The disinflationary trend in the 1990s was<br />

probably greatly helped by output being below<br />

trend;<br />

• The last burst of global inflation in 2007/2008<br />

was associated with output above trend;<br />

• The financial crisis resulted in a considerable<br />

loss of output relative to potential – about 5% on<br />

a global basis. However, output was about 2½%<br />

above potential before the crisis and so the<br />

output gap that emerged was quite small;<br />

• On the basis of IMF forecasts, output should be<br />

about potential in 2011; and<br />

• IMF growth forecasts suggest that output will be<br />

significantly above potential in coming years – by<br />

the most since the early 1980s, in fact.<br />

While the relationship between the output gap and<br />

inflation is not particularly tight on a global basis, in<br />

recent years changes in the output gap have seemed<br />

to offer a good explanation of changes in the rate of<br />

Chart 3: Global Output Gap vs GDP Deflator<br />

Source: Reuters EcoWin Pro<br />

increase in the global GDP deflator (see Chart 3). In<br />

this context, the IMF’s projection of flat inflation from<br />

here but an increase in output relative to potential<br />

seems like dreaming.<br />

Our perspective is that there may be some<br />

shortcomings with the output gap estimates. The<br />

method of filtering may imply a more permanent loss<br />

of capacity than has in fact occurred, for example.<br />

However, the increases we are seeing in inflationary<br />

pressures in a number of traded commodities and in<br />

some emerging markets suggest that, globally,<br />

capacity has closed enough to generate hotspots of<br />

inflation, with a threat of this spreading.<br />

If the IMF’s forecast for global growth is right, a<br />

substantial excess of global demand over supply<br />

looks likely to emerge. This will be spread unevenly –<br />

excess demand being most prevalent in emerging<br />

markets, persisting alongside excess supply in G10<br />

economies. This unevenness will reduce the level of<br />

output at which inflation becomes a problem (prices<br />

are more likely to be rigid downwards than upwards).<br />

The upshot from the output gap analysis is that there<br />

is at least a significant risk that inflation will become a<br />

significant problem on a global basis, even if this is<br />

not yet our main scenario.<br />

Monetary policy<br />

People often think of monetary policy being<br />

summarised by the level of interest rates. <strong>Interest</strong><br />

rates are a very useful instrument of policy, but as we<br />

have seen with QE in the US, by no means the only<br />

one. Monetary policy has many aspects and<br />

transmission channels – the level of real and nominal<br />

rates today, expectations of rates tomorrow, the<br />

exchange rate, credit spreads and equity and other<br />

asset prices. We have always been partial to our<br />

financial and monetary conditions index (FMCI). At<br />

Paul Mortimer-Lee 20 January 2011<br />

<strong>Market</strong> Mover<br />

5<br />

www.Global<strong>Market</strong>s.bnpparibas.com

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!