10.03.2015 Views

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

116 Chirstophe Deissenberg and Pavel Ševčík<br />

equilibrium E M as well as the Skiba point π s to the left. In other words,<br />

if the firms react quickly to profit differences, the regulator will follow a<br />

policy that leads to the upper equilibrium E U even if the initial proportion<br />

of Bs is small. Indeed, the high speed of reaction of the firms means that the<br />

accumulated costs incurred by the regulator on the way to E U will be small<br />

and easily compensated by the gains around and at E U . Moreover, R does<br />

not have to make Bs much better off than NBs to insure a fast reaction. As a<br />

result, for β large, the equilibrium E U is characterized by a large proportion<br />

of Bs and thus insures high stationary gains to all actors.<br />

Not surprisingly, an increase of the discount factor ρ has the opposite<br />

effect. Impatient regulators want to build up confidence, only if the initial<br />

proportion of Bs is high. The resulting equilibrium value π U will be relatively<br />

low, since the time and efforts needed now for an additional increase<br />

in the stock of Bs weighs heavily compared to the expected future benefits.<br />

An increase of the prediction cost δ finally, shifts E M to the left and<br />

E U to the right: It is easier for R to incite the firms to use the B strategy,<br />

favoring the convergence to equilibrium with a large number of believers.<br />

The scenario with two stable equilibria separated by a Skiba point can<br />

change qualitatively, when the parameter values are sufficiently altered.<br />

For small values of β and/or δ and/or for large values of ρ, the equilibrium<br />

E U collides with E M and disappears. Only one (stable) equilibrium<br />

remains, E L . Thus, in the long-run, the proportion of believers tends to zero.<br />

On the other hand, for large values of δ trying to outguess the regulator is<br />

never optimal. The only remaining equilibrium is the one where everybody<br />

is a believer.<br />

6. Conclusion<br />

The starting point of this paper is a static situation, where standard rational<br />

behavior by all agents leads to a Pareto-inferior outcome, although<br />

there is no fundamental conflict of interest either among the different firms<br />

or between the firms and the regulator, and although the firms are perfectly<br />

informed and perfectly predict the regulator’s actions. In addition<br />

to the environmental problem studied here, such a situation is common for<br />

instance in monetary economics, in disaster relief, patent protection, capital<br />

levies, or default on debt.<br />

The present paper and previous work strongly suggest that, in such a<br />

situation, the existence of believers who take the announcements of a macroeconomic<br />

regulator at face value typically, Pareto-improve the economic

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!