10.03.2015 Views

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

The Advantages of Fiscal Leadership in an Economy 95<br />

the government leadership with an independent central bank that directs<br />

monetary policy exclusively towards the achievement of the inflation target<br />

(i.e., δ = λ cb = 0). The third column gives the minimum loss associated<br />

with a simultaneous decision-making version of the same game. In each<br />

case, the deficit rule is soft for the Eurozone countries (λ g 2<br />

= 0.25); medium<br />

strength for the United States, Canada, and Switzerland (λ g 2<br />

= 0.5); and<br />

harder for Sweden, the United Kingdom and New Zealand (λ g 2<br />

= 1). The<br />

deficit ratio targets are 0% in all countries (a balanced budget in the medium<br />

term), but the propensity to spend, s, out of any remaining deficit or any<br />

endogenous budget improvements is one.<br />

Evidently, complete dependence in monetary policy is extremely unfavorable,<br />

although the magnitude of the loss varies considerably from country<br />

to country. The losses in Column 3 (Table 3) appear to be relatively small<br />

in comparison. However, when these figures are converted into “growth-rate<br />

equivalents”, I find these losses to be significant. A growth-rate equivalent<br />

is the loss in output growth that would produce the same welfare loss, if all<br />

other variables remain fixed at their optimized values. 25<br />

The figures in Column 4 are more interesting. They show that the losses<br />

associated with simultaneous decision-making are equivalent to having permanent<br />

reductions of up to 20% in the level of national income. That is,<br />

France, Italy, and the Netherlands could have expected to have grown about<br />

15%–20% more, had they adopted fiscal leadership with deficit targets; and<br />

Sweden, the United Kingdom, and New Zealand around 3%–5% less, had<br />

they not done so. Similarly, fiscal leadership with debt targeting would<br />

be worth 10%–20% extra GDP in the United States, and Canada. These<br />

are significant gains and significantly larger than could be expected from<br />

international policy co-ordination itself (Currie et al., 1989).<br />

Thus, the immediate effect of introducing a stability pact deficit rule<br />

has been to increase the costs of an unco-ordinated (simultaneous moves)<br />

regime dramatically. This reveals the weakness of the deficit rule as a<br />

25 Currie et al. (1989). To obtain these figures, I compute the marginal rates of transformation<br />

around each government’s indifference curve to find the change in output growth, dy t , that<br />

would yield the welfare losses in Column 3. Formally,<br />

dy t =<br />

dEL g t<br />

[λ g 2 {(b − θ)y t − τ t }(b − θ) − λ g 1 ]<br />

using Eq. (9). The minimum value of dy t is, therefore, attained when tax revenues τ t grow at<br />

the same rate as the re-payment target (b − θ)y t . These are the losses reported in Column 4.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!