10.03.2015 Views

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

Economic Models - Convex Optimization

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The Advantages of Fiscal Leadership in an Economy 85<br />

discretionary revenues, τ t . All the other variables are as previously defined.<br />

We may regard large values of λ g 2 , say λg 2 > max[1,λg 1<br />

], as defining a<br />

“hard” debt or deficit rule; and smaller values, λ g 2 < min[1,λg 1<br />

], as a “soft”<br />

debt or deficit rule.<br />

The objectives of the central bank, however, may be quite different from<br />

those of the government. We model them as follows:<br />

L cb<br />

t<br />

= 1 2 (π −ˆπ)2 − (1 − δ)λ cb y t − δλ g 1 y t<br />

+ δλg 2<br />

2 [(b − θ)y t − τ t ] 2 (10)<br />

where 0 ≤ δ ≤ 1, and λ cb is the weight, which the central bank assigns<br />

to the output growth. The parameter δ measures the degree to which the<br />

central bank is forced to take the government’s objectives into account.<br />

The closer δ is to 0, the greater is the independence of the central bank in<br />

making its choices. And the lower is λ cb is, the greater is the degree of its<br />

conservatism in making these choices.<br />

In Eq. (9), we have defined the government’s inflation target as ˆπ. The<br />

fact that the same inflation target appears in Eq. (10) would be correct for<br />

the cases where the bank has the instrument independence, but not target<br />

independence. However, it is easy to relax this assumption and allow the<br />

central bank to choose its own target, as the ECB does. But, as I show in<br />

Hughes Hallett (2005), there is no advantage in doing so since the government<br />

would simply adjust its parameters to compensate. Hence, only if the<br />

bank is free to choose the value of λ cb as well, do we get an extra advantage.<br />

Yet, even this will not be enough to outweigh the advantages to be gained<br />

from fiscal leadership — for the reasons noted in Section 5.<br />

A second feature is that Eqs. (9) and (10) specify symmetric inflation<br />

targets around ˆπ. Symmetric inflation targets are particularly emphasized<br />

as being required of both monetary policy and the fiscal authorities (HMT,<br />

2003). We have, therefore, specified both to be features of the government<br />

and the central bank objective functions here. However, it is not clear that<br />

symmetry has been a feature of the European policy making in practice.<br />

Indeed, the ECB has acquired a reputation for being more concerned to<br />

tighten monetary policy when π> ˆπ, than it is to loosen it when π< ˆπ.<br />

Consequently, rather than symmetry in the output-gap target, we have<br />

asymmetric penalties, which tighten the fiscal constraints in recessions,<br />

but weaken them in a boom when the debt and deficits would be falling<br />

anyway. On one hand, this might not be ideal, since it introduces an element<br />

of pro-cyclicality; on the other hand, it brings the rule closer to reality.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!