Exchange rate policy and macroeconomic adjustment 8 - Columbia ...

Exchange rate policy and macroeconomic adjustment 8 - Columbia ... Exchange rate policy and macroeconomic adjustment 8 - Columbia ...

globalcenters.columbia.edu
from globalcenters.columbia.edu More from this publisher
18.02.2015 Views

Exchange rate policy and macroeconomic adjustment8 China’s exchange rate policy and what it means for the dollar Geng Xiao The debate over the exchange rate between the renminbi (RMB) and the US dollar is usually framed in terms of global imbalances: excessive US consumption beyond its savings on the one hand and excessive Chinese production and savings beyond its own spending on the other. This quickly leads to the view that the United States should export and save more and China should import and spend more. The debate centres on how to achieve this rebalancing. The focus in the West is on short-term appreciation of the renminbi, while the emphasis in China is on longer-term structural and institutional reform (Xiao 2008). 1 Leaders in the United States would like the renminbi to appreciate significantly and quickly to encourage an expansion of US exports and employment. Chinese leaders, however, regard the pressure to revalue the renminbi and various protectionist trade policies from the West as unfair, and believe they threaten China’s development. 2 What accounts for this considerable gap between the views of China and the West? What is the economic rationale for China’s insistence on a stable renminbi? The argument for a sustained appreciation of the renminbi is rooted not only in short-term concerns about China’s large current account surplus, but in longerterm trends of China’s economic fundamentals, including high growth, rapid urbanisation and industrialisation, low national debt and low fiscal deficits. These trends are the result of three decades of reform in China that have opened the country to trade with the rest of the world and led to strong productivity gains. Based on the experience of other fast-growing industrialising economies, these forces will increase Chinese wages, the value of the renminbi and China’s price level—over time. 1 Some of the key results are summarised and restated in this chapter. 2 On 30 November 2009, in his meeting with European leaders, Chinese Premier, Wen Jiabao, said some countries on the one hand demanded renminbi appreciation and on the other hand adopted various trade protection meaures. 153

<strong>Exchange</strong> <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>macroeconomic</strong><br />

<strong>adjustment</strong>8<br />

China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> what it<br />

means for the dollar<br />

Geng Xiao<br />

The debate over the exchange <strong>rate</strong> between the renminbi (RMB) <strong>and</strong> the US<br />

dollar is usually framed in terms of global imbalances: excessive US consumption<br />

beyond its savings on the one h<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> excessive Chinese production <strong>and</strong><br />

savings beyond its own spending on the other. This quickly leads to the view<br />

that the United States should export <strong>and</strong> save more <strong>and</strong> China should import <strong>and</strong><br />

spend more. The debate centres on how to achieve this rebalancing. The focus<br />

in the West is on short-term appreciation of the renminbi, while the emphasis in<br />

China is on longer-term structural <strong>and</strong> institutional reform (Xiao 2008). 1<br />

Leaders in the United States would like the renminbi to appreciate significantly<br />

<strong>and</strong> quickly to encourage an expansion of US exports <strong>and</strong> employment. Chinese<br />

leaders, however, regard the pressure to revalue the renminbi <strong>and</strong> various<br />

protectionist trade policies from the West as unfair, <strong>and</strong> believe they threaten<br />

China’s development. 2 What accounts for this considerable gap between the<br />

views of China <strong>and</strong> the West? What is the economic rationale for China’s<br />

insistence on a stable renminbi?<br />

The argument for a sustained appreciation of the renminbi is rooted not only in<br />

short-term concerns about China’s large current account surplus, but in longerterm<br />

trends of China’s economic fundamentals, including high growth, rapid<br />

urbanisation <strong>and</strong> industrialisation, low national debt <strong>and</strong> low fiscal deficits.<br />

These trends are the result of three decades of reform in China that have opened<br />

the country to trade with the rest of the world <strong>and</strong> led to strong productivity<br />

gains. Based on the experience of other fast-growing industrialising economies,<br />

these forces will increase Chinese wages, the value of the renminbi <strong>and</strong> China’s<br />

price level—over time.<br />

1 Some of the key results are summarised <strong>and</strong> restated in this chapter.<br />

2 On 30 November 2009, in his meeting with European leaders, Chinese Premier, Wen Jiabao, said some<br />

countries on the one h<strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>ed renminbi appreciation <strong>and</strong> on the other h<strong>and</strong> adopted various trade<br />

protection meaures.<br />

153


China: The Next Twenty Years of Reform <strong>and</strong> Development<br />

China’s stance<br />

China views its renminbi peg with the US dollar as a crucial link for its trade<br />

<strong>and</strong> investment flows with US <strong>and</strong> world markets. China is concerned that a<br />

premature end to this nominal link with the dollar would bring about financial<br />

instabilities such as speculative capital inflows, associated asset bubbles <strong>and</strong><br />

short-term nominal shocks to employment <strong>and</strong> business in the external sector.<br />

China has not forgotten how the large appreciation of the Japanese yen brought<br />

about by the 1985 Plaza Accord created massive asset bubbles that burst in 1989,<br />

creating a two-decade-long period of sustained deflation without eliminating<br />

Japan’s trade surplus.<br />

China is also wary of how currency appreciation might encourage destabilising<br />

capital inflows. From 2005 to 2008, the renminbi appreciated steadily against<br />

the United States dollar by over 5 per cent a year <strong>and</strong> China’s stock-market<br />

index increased from about 1500 to 6000 before falling to 2000 because of large<br />

speculative capital inflows especially from Hong Kong. If China were to use<br />

renminbi appreciation to reach a balance in trade <strong>and</strong> to stop speculative capital<br />

inflows, the renminbi could overshoot its equilibrium level, leading to bubbles<br />

<strong>and</strong> deflation.<br />

Another reason for not having predictable renminbi appreciation relates to<br />

China’s outward investment. For a country with a large net surplus savings<br />

<strong>and</strong> trade surplus, a well-functioning financial system should support orderly<br />

private or non-state capital outflows of the same order of magnitude as the trade<br />

surplus. Private firms <strong>and</strong> financial institutions would, however, be reluctant<br />

to buy dollar assets if they were likely to continually depreciate in terms of<br />

the renminbi. Because fear of dollar depreciation—<strong>and</strong> the near-zero short-term<br />

interest <strong>rate</strong>s in the United States—reduces outward investment by privatesector<br />

investors, the People’s Bank of China (PBOC) has to finance virtually all<br />

of China’s trade surplus by building up official exchange reserves, making its<br />

monetary control difficult. 3<br />

In any case, it is not clear that nominal renminbi appreciation is necessary.<br />

The real exchange <strong>rate</strong> between the renminbi <strong>and</strong> the US dollar should be selfadjusting.<br />

This is because the change in China’s price level relative to that in<br />

the United States (the ‘real exchange <strong>rate</strong>’) is technically the sum of renminbi<br />

appreciation against the dollar <strong>and</strong> China’s extra inflation above US inflation.<br />

This real exchange <strong>rate</strong> is determined largely by China’s productivity growth.<br />

If China appreciates its currency in excess of its productivity gains, it will<br />

3 See a series of articles by Ronald McKinnon about the exchange-<strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> in Japan <strong>and</strong> China—<br />

particularly McKinnon et al. (2009).<br />

154


<strong>Exchange</strong> <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>macroeconomic</strong> <strong>adjustment</strong><br />

experience deflation. If, however, China refuses nominal appreciation against<br />

its productivity gains, the country will experience some structural inflation<br />

related to the increase of wages <strong>and</strong> prices in the non-tradable sector, which will<br />

keep the real exchange <strong>rate</strong> compatible with its productivity changes. If China<br />

experiences inflation higher than its productivity gains, the renminbi will face<br />

depreciation pressure.<br />

Indeed, if China makes the mistake of continually appreciating the renminbi<br />

against the dollar—ostensibly to reflect its higher productivity growth in<br />

manufacturing—then wage growth could well slow by roughly the amount<br />

of the anticipated exchange appreciation. Manufacturing firms would risk<br />

bankruptcy if they raised wages in the face of an ever-higher renminbi. Indeed,<br />

in Japan’s very high growth phase in the 1950s <strong>and</strong> 1960s, when the yen was<br />

fixed at 360 to the dollar, Japanese wages grew very rapidly—at about the same<br />

pace as domestic productivity growth in manufacturing. Then, when Japan<br />

was forced by the US government to appreciate in the 1970s <strong>and</strong> afterwards,<br />

wage growth slumped to virtually zero <strong>and</strong> remains at zero today. 4 China does<br />

not want to repeat Japan’s experience of deflationary stagnation by allowing<br />

excessive renminbi appreciation.<br />

It should also be noted that recent research by Hong Qiao (2007) has shown that<br />

currency appreciation has an ambiguous impact on the net trade balance. Qiao’s<br />

(2007) research is clearly consistent with Japan’s experiences <strong>and</strong> supports<br />

China’s current exchange-<strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong>.<br />

When it comes to rebalancing, what really matters is the real exchange <strong>rate</strong>:<br />

the relative price levels between economies in international currency, which<br />

determine the relative costs of production, exports <strong>and</strong> imports of trading<br />

partners. Hence, if China pegs the renminbi to the dollar, it can still achieve a<br />

rapid increase in its real exchange <strong>rate</strong> against the United States by having an<br />

inflation <strong>rate</strong> 5 percentage points higher than that of the United States. Many<br />

formerly fast-growing industrialising economies—such as Japan, South Korea,<br />

Taiwan <strong>and</strong> Hong Kong—kept inflation about 5–8 per cent during their fastgrowth<br />

phases as a way to make nominal wages <strong>and</strong> general price levels converge<br />

towards global st<strong>and</strong>ards.<br />

Hence, both inflation <strong>and</strong> nominal appreciation can adjust the real exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong>. The Chinese approach to exchange-<strong>rate</strong> stability thus far has focused on<br />

inflation first <strong>and</strong> appreciation second, which makes the longer-term objectives of<br />

creating employment, productivity gains, wage growth <strong>and</strong> price liberalisation<br />

the priorities rather than addressing trade imbalances through <strong>adjustment</strong>s for<br />

exchange-<strong>rate</strong> change.<br />

4 See detailed analysis in McKinnon (2006).<br />

155


China: The Next Twenty Years of Reform <strong>and</strong> Development<br />

Policy alternatives<br />

Given the fact that China is cautious about using large nominal appreciation to<br />

rebalance the Chinese <strong>and</strong> global economies—at least for the time being—it is<br />

important to consider some alternative <strong>policy</strong> options. A widely held view in<br />

China is that the rebalancing should focus on reducing the net savings surplus<br />

by shifting disposable income to households, paying corpo<strong>rate</strong> dividends,<br />

increasing governments’ fiscal spending, <strong>and</strong> so on—<strong>and</strong> not simply on<br />

adjusting the exchange <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

China is well known for its high savings <strong>rate</strong>, which reached about 55 per<br />

cent of gross domestic product (GDP), with a current account surplus of about<br />

10 per cent of GDP, during 2007–08. One of the key sources of China’s high<br />

national savings <strong>rate</strong> is its state-owned enterprises (SOEs), as corpo<strong>rate</strong> savings<br />

contribute about half of China’s national savings (Prasad 2009). Historically,<br />

these large SOEs could not pay high salaries or wages to their employees due to<br />

tight control by the government. They did not distribute dividends. Even after<br />

they were reformed into a modern corpo<strong>rate</strong> format in the 1990s, the primary<br />

focus was on reducing losses, not sharing dividends. They also did not gene<strong>rate</strong><br />

private purchasing power when the prices of their shares increased, which<br />

created huge capital gains with, as it happens, only small wealth effects on<br />

consumption. The high savings of SOEs are prone to investment in sectors with<br />

tendencies to overcapacity. Hence, privatisation <strong>and</strong> deregulation are necessary<br />

to reduce savings <strong>and</strong> inefficient investment by the large SOEs. 5<br />

While China clearly must increase its current consumption, consumption is<br />

ultimately limited by income. China has a long way to go in raising the wages<br />

<strong>and</strong> productivity of its workforce. Right now, household income accounts for<br />

only 35 per cent of national income. The low disdposable income is especially<br />

acute for migrant workers, who do not receive high-quality education in rural<br />

villages. Their wages were stagnant at a level of about US$120–200 a month for<br />

the first several decades of reform due to steady high underemployment for<br />

unskilled labour.<br />

Chinese savings are also high because the average Chinese household is faced<br />

with a very high return on investment, such as in residential property. In one<br />

of our studies (Sun et al. 2009) of the comparative long-term return on capital<br />

for China, Japan <strong>and</strong> the United States, we found that China’s return on capital<br />

is about 20 per cent, compared with about 10 per cent for Japan <strong>and</strong> 5 per cent<br />

for the United States in the past three decades. Moreover, Chinese households<br />

save to meet very high future expenditures, such as college education for their<br />

single child <strong>and</strong> medical <strong>and</strong> retirement expenditures.<br />

5 For more on China’s SOEs, see the discussion by Xiao et al. (2009).<br />

156


Addressing the West’s concerns<br />

<strong>Exchange</strong> <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>macroeconomic</strong> <strong>adjustment</strong><br />

Chinese <strong>and</strong> foreign observers alike have expressed concerns about inefficient<br />

investment in China’s export-manufacturing sector <strong>and</strong> in some local<br />

government-sponsored projects. As a result, China’s central government has<br />

recently tightened monitoring <strong>and</strong> control of all new projects, especially those<br />

likely to lead to overcapacity. The Chinese authorities have not, however,<br />

changed their overall stimulus <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> continue to focus on generating more<br />

efficient investment, employment <strong>and</strong> imports so as to contribute positively to<br />

global rebalancing <strong>and</strong> global recovery.<br />

For those who worry about China’s US$2.2 trillion foreign exchange reserves, it<br />

is worth looking at a case that illust<strong>rate</strong>s China’s need for foreign exchange. The<br />

number of self-financed Chinese students studying abroad increased from 102<br />

247 in 2002 to 161 600 in 2008, which is a compound <strong>rate</strong> of about 8 per cent a<br />

year. If we assume the number of such students will increase 8 per cent a year<br />

for the next 10 years, the number of students studying abroad will reach 348<br />

882 by 2018. If each outgoing student spends four years overseas, with US$60<br />

000 in expenditure per annum for tuition, living expenses <strong>and</strong> travel, the total<br />

accumulated expenditure for those Chinese students going abroad will reach<br />

US$606.8 billion—amounting to about 30 per cent of China’s current foreign<br />

exchange reserves. It is no secret that even high <strong>and</strong> middle-income Chinese<br />

parents need to save for many years or decades to pay for their children’s<br />

expensive overseas education.<br />

Price distortions <strong>and</strong> global rebalancing<br />

One of the key factors driving the global imbalances has been cheap money,<br />

which, together with weak regulation of high-risk investment, led to property<br />

<strong>and</strong> stock-market bubbles in the United States <strong>and</strong> other economies. The<br />

bubbles brought temporary capital gains that reduced Americans’ savings <strong>and</strong><br />

increased their consumption to levels beyond their sustainable income. This<br />

is well known now; but what has been overlooked in the public discussion<br />

is that this same cheap money also flowed into China through foreign direct<br />

investment (FDI) <strong>and</strong> other capital flows. Cheap foreign money, combined with<br />

cheap Chinese l<strong>and</strong>, energy <strong>and</strong> natural resources, has led to huge overcapacity<br />

in China’s manufacturing sector, driving down the prices of made-in-China<br />

products.<br />

The United States’ current zero-interest-<strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> might be necessary for<br />

the US economy now, but it is likely to create a carry trade as a by-product—<br />

that is, where investors borrow currencies with low interest <strong>rate</strong>s <strong>and</strong> invest<br />

157


China: The Next Twenty Years of Reform <strong>and</strong> Development<br />

in currencies with high interest <strong>rate</strong>s to make profits when the interest <strong>rate</strong><br />

differential is larger than the anticipated exchange <strong>rate</strong> change. This brings<br />

capital flows into China in anticipation of higher investment returns compared<br />

with the United States. If managed well, China can combine this foreign capital<br />

<strong>and</strong> its own savings to improve the efficiency of its investment, so as to allow<br />

higher levels of domestic investment for future domestic consumption. This<br />

would certainly help global rebalancing.<br />

Rising Chinese household income <strong>and</strong> large official reserves mean that there will<br />

be rising dem<strong>and</strong> for diversification by Chinese investors into foreign assets.<br />

Over time, the amount of cross-border capital flows could be much larger than<br />

the amount of trade flows. To facilitate these future cross-border capital flows,<br />

it would be helpful for China to maintain a stable exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> large<br />

foreign exchange reserves—both of which are critical in reducing the Chinese<br />

<strong>and</strong> foreign investors’ uncertainty that would result from a volatile exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong>. Having a stable exchange <strong>rate</strong> to facilitate cross-border investment is<br />

also important for the large number of US multinational corporations with<br />

extensive <strong>and</strong> growing investments in China that gene<strong>rate</strong> high value-added<br />

complementary jobs in the United States.<br />

The future for China <strong>and</strong> the dollar<br />

The biggest challenge for Chinese <strong>policy</strong>makers now is how to deal with the<br />

property <strong>and</strong> stock-market bubbles being formed by cheap money in China<br />

<strong>and</strong> around the world. As asset prices <strong>and</strong> the consumer price index (CPI)<br />

rise, it is important for China to raise its interest <strong>rate</strong>—as India has done very<br />

successfully—to keep the real interest <strong>rate</strong> at a stable <strong>and</strong> positive level. A<br />

higher interest <strong>rate</strong> would attract greater capital inflows. It is therefore necessary<br />

for China to improve its capital-control mechanisms, to allow orderly crossborder<br />

capital flows for more efficient investments with higher returns both<br />

domestically <strong>and</strong> internationally, while limiting the speculative flow of capital<br />

<strong>and</strong> the inefficient <strong>and</strong> low-return investments.<br />

So what does China’s <strong>policy</strong> stance mean for the dollar? There are some clear<br />

implications.<br />

Given the institutional <strong>and</strong> structural constraints in China, it does not seem<br />

likely that nominal renminbi appreciation will become a key <strong>policy</strong> variable<br />

in rebalancing China <strong>and</strong> the global economy in the near future. This means it<br />

will be difficult for the United States to pursue a weak-dollar <strong>policy</strong>. Without<br />

depreciation against the renminbi, any further depreciation of the dollar against<br />

the euro <strong>and</strong> yen would do little to help global rebalancing—<strong>and</strong> could instead<br />

cause shocks to the European <strong>and</strong> Japanese economies.<br />

158


<strong>Exchange</strong> <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>macroeconomic</strong> <strong>adjustment</strong><br />

Given the huge potential for cross-border investment <strong>and</strong> debt financing<br />

between the United States <strong>and</strong> China, a stable renminbi–dollar exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

seems to fit both countries’ long-term national interest. If the United States<br />

<strong>and</strong> China can coope<strong>rate</strong> effectively in maintaining the stability of the exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> orderly cross-border flows of capital, there is little reason to believe<br />

the dollar-based international currency system will collapse in the foreseeable<br />

future.<br />

In the longer term—certainly after 2020 <strong>and</strong> perhaps during 2025–35—the<br />

renminbi is likely to become an international currency when it becomes fully<br />

convertible <strong>and</strong> the Chinese economy completes its structural <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

transformation into a fully modernised market economy with a more democratic<br />

political system. By that time, the integration of the US, European, Japanese<br />

<strong>and</strong> Chinese economies will be so deep that the dollar, euro, yen <strong>and</strong> renminbi<br />

are likely to become leading reserve currencies of the world, with fully floating<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong>s.<br />

Rebalancing the world economy can be accomplished without revaluing the<br />

renminbi. For this to happen without major dislocations, however, structural<br />

<strong>and</strong> institutional reforms must occur both in China <strong>and</strong> in the United States.<br />

Higher inflation in China <strong>and</strong> deflation or lower inflation in the United States<br />

can bring about the needed <strong>adjustment</strong> in real, rather than nominal, exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong>s. This implies a stronger dollar, but also requires de-leveraging in the<br />

United States, including reduction of US fiscal deficits.<br />

Challenges in the next two decades<br />

During the next 20 years of reform <strong>and</strong> development, the key <strong>macroeconomic</strong><br />

challenge is to determine how to manage the exchange <strong>rate</strong>, interest <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

inflation <strong>rate</strong> in order to facilitate sustainable, stable, efficient <strong>and</strong> harmonious<br />

growth of China’s real economy in the context of a world economy in which the<br />

weight of the Western economies will shrink relative to the emerging market<br />

economies.<br />

To appreciate the extent of this challenge, it is essential to recognise that China’s<br />

high growth in the past 30 years is a story largely of rapid productivity growth<br />

<strong>and</strong> catching up. The productivity story is likely to continue for the next two<br />

decades if China continues its market-oriented reform <strong>and</strong> its trend of rapid<br />

industrialisation <strong>and</strong> urbanisation. As a result, China’s non-tradable goods<br />

prices—such as wages for unskilled labour <strong>and</strong> property prices—are likely to<br />

continue to rise (see the chapter in this volume by Ross Garnaut), relative to the<br />

prices of tradable goods, which are set by global markets.<br />

159


China: The Next Twenty Years of Reform <strong>and</strong> Development<br />

In the next two decades, rising non-tradable goods prices in China will lead<br />

to a gradual but steady convergence of China’s price levels towards those in<br />

Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> the United States, through structural inflation or structural<br />

renminbi appreciation—or both. It is essential for China’s <strong>policy</strong>makers <strong>and</strong><br />

Chinese people to tole<strong>rate</strong> the structural inflation <strong>and</strong>/or currency appreciation<br />

associated with this productivity catch-up.<br />

More importantly, since inflation <strong>and</strong> currency appreciation can cause<br />

distortions, shocks <strong>and</strong> income redistribution, it is necessary for <strong>policy</strong>makers<br />

to use appropriate <strong>policy</strong> mixes to mitigate potential dislocation that might be<br />

created in the <strong>adjustment</strong> process.<br />

For example, when structural inflation emerges, it will be critical to raise<br />

nominal interest <strong>rate</strong>s so as to avoid asset bubbles that are caused by negative<br />

real interest <strong>rate</strong>s as well as to protect the value of bank deposits held by the lowincome<br />

households who cannot afford to invest or speculate in property markets<br />

in order to hedge against the structural inflation. Since 1991, China’s urban<br />

residential real estate prices have grown on average about 9 per cent a year, but<br />

the mortgage <strong>rate</strong> is only about 5 per cent <strong>and</strong> the one-year fixed-deposit <strong>rate</strong><br />

is only about 2 per cent. The structural inflation in property <strong>and</strong> low mortgage<br />

<strong>and</strong> deposit <strong>rate</strong>s implies a very serious problem of negative real interest <strong>rate</strong>s in<br />

terms of investing in property. This is the root of China’s property bubbles <strong>and</strong><br />

the associated huge income redistribution from depositors (usually the poor) to<br />

mortgage holders (usually the rich).<br />

If China cannot maintain a positive real interest <strong>rate</strong>, its boom <strong>and</strong> bust cycles<br />

in the property sector are likely to continue, leading to serious inefficiency<br />

in investment as well as social instability. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, if China does<br />

raise interest <strong>rate</strong>s to a level higher than its structural inflation, it then needs<br />

adequate capital control to deal with speculative capital inflows.<br />

The importance of keeping the real interest <strong>rate</strong> positive cannot be<br />

overemphasised for China in the next two decades, as China’s key challenge<br />

in <strong>macroeconomic</strong> <strong>adjustment</strong> is to improve its investment <strong>and</strong> consumption<br />

efficiency so that it can absorb more of its current account surplus. Otherwise,<br />

China will face serious international trade protection pressure.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, this chapter shows that it is not necessary for China to<br />

rely only on nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> flexibility to facilitate its rising price level<br />

if it can instead tole<strong>rate</strong> higher structural inflation <strong>and</strong> the associated real<br />

appreciation. In fact, it is much easier for China to implement a flexible exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong> regime when it allows reasonable structural inflation. With inflation, there<br />

will be potential for the currency to depreciate when inflation runs beyond<br />

productivity growth. So, a mixture of inflation <strong>and</strong> nominal appreciation could<br />

160


<strong>Exchange</strong> <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>macroeconomic</strong> <strong>adjustment</strong><br />

create a regime in which the market exchange <strong>rate</strong>s could go up or down—<br />

reducing the incentive for massive speculative holdings of the renminbi, which<br />

has become one of the key drivers of China’s foreign exchange reserve bubble.<br />

It should also be pointed out that when China pegs its renminbi to the US<br />

dollar, it should not worry too much about runaway inflation since the peg has<br />

the stabilisation function. If the inflation <strong>rate</strong> goes beyond China’s underlying<br />

productivity growth, the market will expect the renminbi to depreciate, which<br />

will lead to capital outflows <strong>and</strong> the tightening of money supply. Given China’s<br />

huge foreign exchange reserves, it is easy for China to defend its peg <strong>and</strong> avoid<br />

runaway inflation.<br />

As soon as China starts to tole<strong>rate</strong> reasonable structural inflation <strong>and</strong> the<br />

associated real appreciation, the pressure for nominal appreciation will be<br />

reduced.<br />

This chapter has also highlighted the fact that the exchange <strong>rate</strong> is a price not<br />

just for trade but for assets. In fact, the volume of the asset markets is much<br />

bigger than that of trade. Maintaining stable exchange <strong>rate</strong>s for facilitating stable<br />

<strong>and</strong> efficient cross-border capital flows could be more important than using the<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> to balance trade. It could be more productive to use trade policies<br />

such as reducing the transaction costs for imports to balance China’s trade.<br />

References<br />

McKinnon, R. 2006, ‘China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong> trap: Japan redux?’, American<br />

Economic Review, vol. 6, no. 2, pp. 427–31.<br />

McKinnon, R. Lee, B. <strong>and</strong> Wang, Y. D. 2009, The global credit crisis <strong>and</strong> China’s<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong>, Stanford Center for International Development Working Paper<br />

no. 391, Stanford University, Calif.<br />

Prasad, E. 2009, ‘Rebalancing growth in Asia’, Finance & Development, vol. 46,<br />

no. 4, pp. 19–22.<br />

Qiao, H. 2007, ‘<strong>Exchange</strong> <strong>rate</strong>s <strong>and</strong> trade balances under the dollar st<strong>and</strong>ard’,<br />

Journal of Policy Modeling, vol. 29, no. 5, pp. 765–82.<br />

Sun, W., Yang, X. <strong>and</strong> Xiao, G. 2009, Investment <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> FDI: a comparative<br />

analysis of return to capital among China, US <strong>and</strong> Japan, Paper presented at<br />

the joint symposium of US–China Advanced Technology Trade <strong>and</strong> Industrial<br />

Development, Beijing, 23–24 October.<br />

161


China: The Next Twenty Years of Reform <strong>and</strong> Development<br />

Xiao, G. 2008, ‘China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> monetary policies: structural <strong>and</strong><br />

institutional constraints <strong>and</strong> reform options’, Asian Economic Papers, vol. 7,<br />

no. 3, pp. 31–49.<br />

Xiao, G., Yang, X. <strong>and</strong> Janus, A. 2009, ‘State-owned enterprises in China: reform<br />

dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts’, in R. Garnaut, L. Song <strong>and</strong> W. T. Woo (eds), China’s<br />

New Place in a World in Crisis: Economic, geopolitical <strong>and</strong> environmental<br />

dimensions, ANU E Press, Canberra, pp. 155–78.<br />

Acknowledgments<br />

This chapter consists of two sections. Section one is a reprint of an article by the<br />

author published on 13 January 2010 at ‘What Matters’ web forum hosted by<br />

the McKinsey Quarterly (). Section two<br />

includes additional comments prepared specially for this chapter. The author<br />

is g<strong>rate</strong>ful to the McKinsey Quarterly for permission to include the previously<br />

published contents in this chapter. The author would also like to thank Ronald<br />

McKinnon, Andrew Sheng, Pieter Bottelier, Wing Thye Woo, Jeffrey Sachs, Barry<br />

Bosworth, Harry Broadman, David Dollar, David Loevinger, David Meale, David<br />

Skilling, Jonathan Woetzel, Kenneth Lieberthal, Cheng Li, Xingdong Chen,<br />

Chunlai Chen, Min Zhu, Qiren Zhou <strong>and</strong> Hong Liang for helpful comments <strong>and</strong><br />

discussions on this work. Jonathan Delikat <strong>and</strong> Will Hobbs provided excellent<br />

research assistance.<br />

162


4<br />

Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d<br />

by trade disputes<br />

China’s post WTO blues<br />

Wing Thye Woo <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

The escalation of friction between China <strong>and</strong> its trading partners<br />

China’s current account in the balance of payments has been in surplus since<br />

1994 <strong>and</strong> it has shown a clear upward trend, reaching US$184 billion in 2006, or<br />

9 per cent of gross domestic product (GDP). As China’s capital account is also<br />

in persistent surplus because of the large inflows of foreign direct investment<br />

(FDI) <strong>and</strong> capital controls on outflows, its foreign exchange reserves reached<br />

US$1.07 trillion in 2006—the largest in the world. China also became the secondlargest<br />

holder of US Treasury securities, holding as much as US$353.6 billion,<br />

trailing only Japan, which holds US$648.8 billion.<br />

At the time of writing (June 2007), China’s overall trade surplus, the China–US<br />

trade surplus <strong>and</strong> the China–EU trade surplus continued to soar, 1 causing a<br />

marked escalation in concern about China’s unfair trading practices <strong>and</strong> the gross<br />

undervaluation of the renminbi. In February 2007, the US Trade Representative<br />

(USTR) had filed a case with the World Trade Organization (WTO) against<br />

prohibited subsidies in China. This action was followed by two more WTO cases<br />

against China in April 2007—challenging market access restrictions on products<br />

of copyright-intensive industries <strong>and</strong> challenging weaknesses in the legal regime<br />

for protection <strong>and</strong> enforcement of copyrights <strong>and</strong> trademarks. 2<br />

In order to appreciate adequately the high intensity of the sound <strong>and</strong> the fury<br />

of the anti-China rhetoric—<strong>and</strong> the global character of these criticisms—it is<br />

worthwhile to quote a number of news reports from the barrage of press articles<br />

on the trade imbalance issue that appeared on 13 June 2007. 3<br />

45


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

The Financial Times (2007a) reported<br />

Peter M<strong>and</strong>elson, the EU trade commissioner…called various aspects of<br />

China’s trade <strong>policy</strong> ‘illogical, indefensible’ <strong>and</strong> ‘unacceptable <strong>and</strong> accused<br />

[China] of doing nothing to rein in rampant counterfeiting…Mr M<strong>and</strong>elson<br />

also refused to grant China market economy status…[because it had] fulfilled<br />

[only] one of five criteria. 4<br />

The Straits Times (2007) of Singapore reported<br />

Peter M<strong>and</strong>elson proclaimed that the…[EU] trade deficit with China was no<br />

longer ‘tolerable’ <strong>and</strong> warned that relations with Beijing were now at a ‘crossroads’…[Trade<br />

is] so skewed that the EU now exports more to Switzerl<strong>and</strong>…<br />

than to the entire Chinese market.<br />

USA Today (2007) reported that<br />

[a]fter years of inconclusive skirmishing, trade tensions between the United<br />

States <strong>and</strong> China are about to intensify. ‘We are competing not only with a<br />

country with low wages but with very high <strong>and</strong> heavy subsidies <strong>and</strong> a rigging<br />

of their currency,’ says Rep. S<strong>and</strong>er Levin, D-Mich., chairman of the House<br />

trade subcommittee. ‘I hate the term trade war because it is always used<br />

when you try to get a fair break…Sometimes pressure works.’<br />

In confirmation of the growing perception of—<strong>and</strong> deepening dissatisfaction<br />

about—unfair Chinese trading practices, the media on 13 June 2007 also<br />

contained reports on the actions being undertaken by the Bush administration<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Chinese government to forestall protectionism.<br />

The St<strong>and</strong>ard (2007) of Hong Kong reported<br />

US lawmakers plan to introduce legislation today seeking to pressure<br />

China to raise the value of the yuan to stem a ballooning trade imbalance…<br />

Sponsored by Democratic senator Charles Schumer, the bill will lay out<br />

the US response whenever countries ‘unfairly undervalue their currency’.<br />

Currently, there are half a dozen measures before the US Congress aimed<br />

at China, including proposals to apply sanctions unless it allows the yuan to<br />

appreciate by at least 10 per cent.<br />

The Wall Street Journal (2007b) reported<br />

[t]urning aside growing congressional anger over the US trade deficit with<br />

China, President George Bush’s administration today will reject dem<strong>and</strong>s<br />

that it formally accuse Beijing of ‘manipulating’ its currency to give Chinese<br />

companies an edge over American businesses. ‘There might be an initial sigh<br />

of relief in the markets that the Treasury has not taken a more confrontational<br />

line, but protectionist pressures are only likely to build’, Julian Jessop, chief<br />

46


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

international economist at Capital Economics in London, warned clients in<br />

a note yesterday. Meanwhile Beijing took steps yesterday apparently aimed,<br />

at least in part, at defusing US concerns. Chinese authorities permitted an<br />

unusually large rise in its tightly controlled currency.<br />

The International Herald Tribune (2007) reported that ‘the yuan had the biggest<br />

gain since the end of a dollar link in July 2005. The yuan rose 0.26 per cent to<br />

7.6436 against the dollar…[yielding a cumulative gain of] 8.3 per cent since…July<br />

2005.’<br />

Events then moved quickly. On 14 June 2007, Senators Max Baucus<br />

(Democrat from Montana), Charles E. Grassley (Republican from Iowa), Charles<br />

E. Schumer (Democrat from New York) <strong>and</strong> Lindsey Graham (Republican from<br />

South Carolina) introduced legislation ‘to punish China if it did not change its<br />

<strong>policy</strong> of intervening in currency markets to keep the exchange value of the<br />

currency, the yuan, low’ (New York Times 2007).<br />

On 19 June 2007, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) adopted a new<br />

country surveillance framework that set out<br />

…a catch-all obligation on countries not to adopt policies that undermine the<br />

stability of the international system, <strong>and</strong> lists a set of objective criteria that<br />

will be used to indicate whether a country is complying with its commitments.<br />

Warning lights will include large-scale currency intervention, the<br />

accumulation of reserves <strong>and</strong> ‘fundamental exchange <strong>rate</strong> misalignment’—a<br />

term that mirrors language in a bill before the US Congress that would<br />

impose penalties on nations that fail to correct such misalignments. Rodrigo<br />

Rato, managing director of the IMF, said: ‘This decision is good news for the<br />

IMF reform programme <strong>and</strong> good news for the cause of multilateralism…<br />

[because this new framework] gives clear guidance to our members on how<br />

they should run their exchange <strong>rate</strong> policies, on what is acceptable to the<br />

international community <strong>and</strong> what is not’ (Financial Times 2007b).<br />

The above developments were warnings that China, Europe <strong>and</strong> the United<br />

States could be marching towards a trade war. In this chapter, we examine the<br />

reasons for the trade friction with China <strong>and</strong> propose policies to reduce that<br />

friction. Our discussion will focus on four questions<br />

1 What are the problems caused by trade imbalances?<br />

2 What are the problems revealed by the appearance of trade imbalances?<br />

3 Is a large yuan appreciation the best cure for trade friction?<br />

4 What is to be done?<br />

47


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

What are the problems caused by trade imbalances?<br />

It is not uncommon to encounter allegations that the US–China trade deficit<br />

represents the export of unemployment from China to the United States. A<br />

recent study by Robert Scott (2007), of the Economic Policy Institute, used<br />

an input–output model to arrive at the claim that the bilateral trade deficit of<br />

US$49.5 billion in 1997 caused the loss of 597,300 jobs that year <strong>and</strong> the 2006<br />

bilateral trade deficit of US$235.4 billion caused the loss of 2,763,400 jobs—<strong>and</strong><br />

that every state had suffered a net loss of jobs from the rise in the bilateral trade<br />

deficit during 1997–2006. The alleged job losses in 2006 from the bilateral trade<br />

deficit implied that the 2006 unemployment <strong>rate</strong> was 1.21 percentage points<br />

higher than if the bilateral trade balance had been zero. 5<br />

There are two major problems with the Scott (2007) study. First, the overall<br />

unemployment <strong>rate</strong> in the United States did not grow in line either with the<br />

widening overall US trade deficit or with the widening US–China trade deficit.<br />

The average unemployment <strong>rate</strong> of 4.9 per cent in the 1998–2006 period was<br />

lower than the average unemployment <strong>rate</strong>s in the previous periods of 1980–88<br />

<strong>and</strong> 1989–97, which were 7.5 per cent <strong>and</strong> 6 per cent respectively. In reality, the<br />

US economy was a highly successful job-creation machine in the 1997–2006<br />

period.<br />

Second, in the face of the strong dem<strong>and</strong> for labour in the US economy<br />

during the period of growing trade deficit, a substantial amount of the so-called<br />

job losses could have been voluntary departures by workers—rather than<br />

involuntary displacement of workers—from import-competing industries that<br />

paid low wages or had potentially low wage growth in the future.<br />

The more sophisticated complaint against the growing trade deficit is that<br />

the displacement of workers adds to the downward pressure on US wages<br />

created by globalisation. This downward wage pressure comes from the post<br />

1990 integration of the labour force in the former Soviet Union, India <strong>and</strong><br />

China into the international division of labour. The number of workers already<br />

engaged in the international division of labour was 1.08 billion in 1990, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

combined labour force of the former Soviet Union, India <strong>and</strong> China was 1.23<br />

billion (Table 1). The division of labour in 1990 was certainly an unnatural one<br />

because half of the world’s workforce had been kept out of it voluntarily by the<br />

autarkic policies of the former Soviet Union, India <strong>and</strong> China.<br />

The economic isolation of the Soviet bloc started crumbling when the<br />

new non-communist Solidarity government of Pol<strong>and</strong> began marketisation<br />

<strong>and</strong> internationalisation of its economy on 1 January 1990. The economic<br />

transition <strong>and</strong> political disintegration of the Soviet bloc became irreversible<br />

when President Boris Yeltsin replaced Mikhail Gorbachev as the unambiguous<br />

48


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

leader of Russia in August 1991 <strong>and</strong> implemented market-oriented reforms in<br />

January 1992. 6<br />

For the Chinese élite, the events in the Soviet Union confirmed that there did<br />

not exist a third way in the capitalism versus socialism debate. In early 1992,<br />

Deng Xiaoping led a successful campaign to put China firmly on the path of<br />

convergence to a private market economy (Sachs <strong>and</strong> Woo 2000, 2003). Today,<br />

under the heading of a socialist market economy with Chinese characteristics,<br />

the Chinese constitution gives private property the same legal status as public<br />

property, <strong>and</strong> the Chinese Communist Party accepts capitalists as members.<br />

In 1991, India faced a balance-of-payments crisis, <strong>and</strong> it responded by going<br />

well beyond administration of the st<strong>and</strong>ard corrective <strong>macroeconomic</strong> medicine<br />

of fiscal monetary tightening <strong>and</strong> exchange-<strong>rate</strong> devaluation into comprehensive<br />

<strong>adjustment</strong>s of microeconomic incentives. The trade regime was deregulated<br />

significantly, restrictions on foreign investment were relaxed, reform of the<br />

banking sector <strong>and</strong> the capital markets was initiated, <strong>and</strong> divestment of public<br />

enterprises <strong>and</strong> tax reforms were announced (Acharya 2004).<br />

A decade after the start of internationalisation, the number of workers<br />

involved in the international economic system had increased to 2.67 billion in<br />

2000 (with 1.36 billion workers from the former Soviet Union, India <strong>and</strong> China)<br />

(Table 4.1). The Heckscher-Ohlin model would predict that this doubling of world<br />

labour—achieved by bringing in cheaper labour from the former Soviet Union,<br />

India <strong>and</strong> China—would lower the relative price of labour-intensive goods <strong>and</strong><br />

hence reduce real wages in industrialised economies. 7<br />

The fact that US capital could now move abroad to set up production facilities<br />

in the economies of the former Soviet Union, India <strong>and</strong> China to service the<br />

Table 4.1 The distribution of the global labour force, 1990 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

(million persons)<br />

Non-SIC a countries<br />

sic countries<br />

Total Industrialised Developing China India Soviet bloc<br />

economies economies<br />

1990 2,315 403 680 687 332 213<br />

2000 2,672 438 851 764 405 214<br />

a SIC— former Soviet Union, India <strong>and</strong> China.<br />

Source: Freeman, R., 2004. Doubling the global work force: the challenge of integrating China,<br />

India, <strong>and</strong> the former Soviet Bloc into the world economy, Harvard University, 8 November<br />

(unpublished). Our figure for ‘total’ in 2002 is different from that in Freeman (2004).<br />

49


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

US market provided another channel (besides the cross-border movement of<br />

goods) for globalisation to depress US wage <strong>rate</strong>s. It is important to note that<br />

the imposition of a very high US tariff would not only drastically curb imports<br />

from the former Soviet Union, India <strong>and</strong> China, it would also radically reduce<br />

this type of FDI flow from the United States to the former Soviet Union, India<br />

<strong>and</strong> China.<br />

The inconvenient fact is, however, that the US real wage has not fallen.<br />

One possible explanation to reconcile the theoretical prediction with the<br />

real outcome is the remarkably high US productivity growth since the late<br />

1980s, perhaps enabled in large part by the information <strong>and</strong> communications<br />

technology revolution. This productivity growth was high enough to prevent<br />

the real wage from declining but not enough to keep it growing at the same<br />

<strong>rate</strong> as GDP growth—<strong>and</strong> the economic impact of globalisation is manifested<br />

in a diminished labour share of GDP.<br />

While the Heckscher-Ohlin model does provide a coherent mechanism<br />

for globalisation to lower the labour share of US income <strong>and</strong> to widen the<br />

distribution of US wages, the inconvenient truth is that China cannot be blamed<br />

as the most influential factor in these two wage outcomes, even though China<br />

accounted for 764 million of the combined labour force of the former Soviet<br />

Union, India <strong>and</strong> China of 1.38 billion in 2000. China is not the main culprit<br />

because there have been three other, independent developments that have<br />

had important consequences for US wages.<br />

First, there have been technological innovations that have substituted capital<br />

for labour—for example, fewer secretaries are needed because answering<br />

machines can now convert messages into voice files <strong>and</strong> email them to the<br />

travelling professionals. Technological innovations have also transformed<br />

many of what were traditionally non-tradable services into tradable services,<br />

allowing jobs to be outsourced to foreign service providers. For example, the<br />

information <strong>and</strong> communications technology revolution has allowed offshore<br />

call centres to h<strong>and</strong>le questions from US customers, offshore accountants to<br />

process US-based transactions <strong>and</strong> offshore medical technicians to read the<br />

X-rays of US patients. 8<br />

Second, there have been institutional changes that attenuated the labour<br />

share of income. Union membership has declined, reducing the bargaining<br />

power of labour. There has also been an upward shift in the compensation<br />

norms for high-level executives, often using vehicles such as stock options,<br />

which in effect make them co-owners of the company. This could reflect a<br />

combination of a shift in social attitudinal norms <strong>and</strong> more collusion between<br />

managers <strong>and</strong> their boards. 9<br />

50


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

Third, there was increased immigration into the United States (before 2001),<br />

especially a disproportionate inward immigration of low-skilled labour. 10<br />

Based on a partial review of the literature, our assessment is that the<br />

pressure that is preventing US wages (especially of unskilled labour) from<br />

rising in line with GDP growth can be roughly decomposed among the various<br />

factors as follows<br />

• 70–80 per cent of the downward wage pressure is from labour-substituting<br />

technological innovations, <strong>and</strong> wage-weakening institutional changes<br />

• 5–10 per cent of the downward wage pressure is from inward<br />

immigration<br />

• 15–20 per cent of the downward pressure is from import competition<br />

<strong>and</strong> the relocation of manufacturing activities abroad.<br />

In short, the popular outcry in the United States <strong>and</strong> the European Union<br />

against China’s trade surpluses is misplaced. Even if China’s trade balance were<br />

zero, the pains of structural <strong>adjustment</strong> <strong>and</strong> income redistribution caused by<br />

technological innovations, institutional changes, globalisation <strong>and</strong> immigration<br />

would still be there. The additional pain from the incremental structural<br />

<strong>adjustment</strong> caused by the widening trade deficit is minor in comparison.<br />

What are the problems revealed by the appearance of trade<br />

imbalances?<br />

Before discussing the economic problems in China <strong>and</strong> the United States that<br />

gene<strong>rate</strong>d the trade imbalances, we should mention a troubling basic data<br />

issue: there is strong disagreement about the size of the US–China trade deficit.<br />

Figure 4.1 shows that the Chinese figure for the bilateral deficit in 2006 (US$145<br />

billion) was only 57.7 per cent of the US figure (US$251 billion). 11 The huge gap<br />

between these two estimates in 2006 was a huge improvement in accuracy<br />

from the past in two ways. First, the gap was usually much larger in previous<br />

years: for example, the 1993 Chinese estimate of the trade deficit was only 25.6<br />

per cent of the US estimate. Second, the recent period is one in which the two<br />

countries could agree whether the bilateral balance was in surplus or in deficit!<br />

Throughout the 1983–92 period, the Chinese data showed China to be running<br />

a deficit in its trade with the US but the US data showed a surplus.<br />

Given these wildly different measures of the size of the bilateral trade<br />

imbalance, it is only to be expected that each side would regard the bilateral<br />

trade imbalance with a different degree of concern. The primary reason for the<br />

discrepancy between the Chinese <strong>and</strong> US estimates is the different national<br />

treatment of US–China trade that goes through Hong Kong. 12 Drawing on the<br />

51


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

work of Feenstra et al. (1999) for the analysis in this chapter, we will measure<br />

the US–China trade balance as the simple average between the US estimate<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Chinese estimate, as reported in the IMF’s Direction of Trade Statistics<br />

database. 13<br />

Figure 4.2 displays three items: China’s overall trade balance, the China–US<br />

trade balance <strong>and</strong> the China–EU trade balance. China has been running a<br />

surplus on its US trade since 1986, a surplus on its EU trade since 1997 <strong>and</strong> a<br />

surplus on its overall trade since 1994. Since 1986—except for the four years<br />

associated with an economic downturn in China (1990, 1991, 1997 <strong>and</strong> 1998)—the<br />

bilateral surplus with the United States exceeded China’s overall trade surplus,<br />

meaning that China was running massive deficits in its trade with some of its<br />

other trading partners.<br />

The changing configuration of China’s bilateral trade balances reflects<br />

mainly the steady expansion of production networks into China. In this new<br />

geographical division of the production of components <strong>and</strong> of the production<br />

stages in manufacturing, China usually makes the cheaper components<br />

<strong>and</strong> assembles the final products by combining the domestically produced<br />

components with imported components. The fast transfer of manufacturing <strong>and</strong><br />

assembly operations to China from Japan, Taiwan <strong>and</strong> South Korea translates<br />

directly into high growth in the China–US trade surplus because this transfer<br />

reduces the Japan–US trade surplus <strong>and</strong> the South Korean–US trade surplus<br />

correspondingly. In short, the China–US trade deficit could be reduced by<br />

transferring the assembly operations of Korean, Taiwanese, Japanese <strong>and</strong><br />

European production networks to Vietnam, but the Vietnam–US trade deficit<br />

would then increase, leaving the overall US trade balance unchanged.<br />

China’s chronic <strong>and</strong> growing overall trade surplus reveals a deep-seated<br />

problem in its economy: its dysfunctional financial system. This problem is<br />

revealed by the aggregate-level accounting identity that the overall current<br />

account balance (of which, in China, the overall trade account is the biggest<br />

part) is determined by the fiscal position of the government, <strong>and</strong> by the savingsinvestment<br />

decisions of the state-controlled enterprise (SCE) sector <strong>and</strong> the<br />

private sector. 14 Specifically,<br />

CA = (T – G) + (S SCE – I SCE ) + (S private – I private ) (1)<br />

where CA is the current account in the balance of payments.<br />

CA = (X – M) + R (2)<br />

52


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

Figure 4.1<br />

US–China trade deficit: discrepancy between US <strong>and</strong><br />

Chinese data, 1980–2006 (US$ million)<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

2002<br />

2004<br />

2006<br />

-10,000.0<br />

-60,000.0<br />

US$ million<br />

-110,000.0<br />

-160,000.0<br />

-210,000.0<br />

-260,000.0<br />

Official US estimate<br />

Official Chinese estimate<br />

Source: International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2007. Direction of Trade Statistics, 9 May, Statistics<br />

Department, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.<br />

Figure 4.2<br />

China trade account balance, 1980–2006 (US$ million)<br />

180,000<br />

Overall trade surplus China-EU surplus China-US surplus<br />

130,000<br />

US$ million<br />

80,000<br />

30,000<br />

-20,000<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

2002<br />

2004<br />

2006<br />

Source: International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2007. Direction of Trade Statistics, 9 May, Statistics<br />

Department, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.<br />

53


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

where X is the export of goods <strong>and</strong> non-factor services, M is the import of<br />

goods <strong>and</strong> non-factor services, R is the net factor earnings from abroad (that is,<br />

export of factor services), T is state revenue, G is state expenditure (including<br />

state investment), S SCE are the savings of the SCEs, I SCE is investment of<br />

the SCEs, S private is savings of the private sector <strong>and</strong> I private is private-sector<br />

investment.<br />

The Chinese fiscal position (T–G) has for the past decade been a small deficit,<br />

so it was not the cause for the swelling current account surpluses in the 2000s.<br />

The current account surplus exists because the sum of savings by SCEs <strong>and</strong> the<br />

private sector exceeds the sum of their investment expenditures. The current<br />

account surplus has exp<strong>and</strong>ed steadily because the non-government savings<br />

<strong>rate</strong> has been rising steadily. We will argue later that there is a link between the<br />

existence of the current account surplus <strong>and</strong> the growth of the surplus.<br />

Why has China’s financial system failed to translate the savings into<br />

investments? Such an outcome was not always the case. Before 1994, the<br />

voracious absorption of bank loans by SCEs to invest recklessly kept the current<br />

account mostly negative <strong>and</strong> the creation of non-performing loans high. When<br />

the government implemented stricter controls on the state-owned banks from<br />

1994 onwards (for example, by removing top bank officials whenever their bank<br />

lent more than its credit quota or allowed the non-performing loan ratio to<br />

increase too rapidly), the state-owned banks slowed the growth of loans to SCEs.<br />

This cut-back created an excess of savings because the state-owned bankdominated<br />

financial sector did not then channel the released savings (which<br />

were also increasing) to finance the investment of the private sector. This failure<br />

in financial intermediation by the state-owned banks is quite underst<strong>and</strong>able.<br />

Firstly, the legal status of private enterprises was, until recently, lower than that<br />

of state-owned enterprises; <strong>and</strong>, secondly, there was no reliable way to assess<br />

the balance sheets of the private enterprises, which were naturally eager to<br />

escape taxation. The upshot was that the residual excess savings leaked abroad<br />

in the form of the current account surplus. Inadequate financial intermediation<br />

has made developing China a capital-exporting country!<br />

This perverse current account outcome is not new. Taiwan had exactly this<br />

problem until the mid 1980s when all Taiwanese banks were state owned <strong>and</strong><br />

were ope<strong>rate</strong>d according to the civil service regulation that the loan officer had<br />

to repay any bad loan that he had approved. The result was a massive failure<br />

in financial intermediation, which caused Taiwan’s current account surplus to<br />

be 21 per cent of GDP in 1986. The reason why China has not been producing<br />

the gargantuan current account surpluses seen in Taiwan in the mid 1980s is<br />

because of the large amount of SCE investments.<br />

54


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

Why is the savings <strong>rate</strong> of the non-government sector rising? The combined<br />

savings of the state-owned enterprise <strong>and</strong> non-state-owned enterprise sector<br />

rose from 20 per cent in 1978 to 30 per cent in 1987, <strong>and</strong> then went above 45 per<br />

cent after 2004. In discussions on the rise of the savings <strong>rate</strong>, a common view<br />

is that the rise reflects the uncertainty about the future that many state-owned<br />

enterprise workers feel in the face of widespread privatisation of loss-making<br />

state-owned enterprises. We find this explanation incomplete because it seems<br />

that there has also been a rise in the rural savings <strong>rate</strong> even though rural<br />

residents have little to fear about the loss of jobs in the state-owned enterprise<br />

sector because none of them are employed there. 15<br />

We see two general changes that have caused urban <strong>and</strong> rural savings <strong>rate</strong>s<br />

to rise significantly. The first is increased worries about the future. The steady<br />

decline in state subsidies to medical care, housing, loss-making enterprises<br />

<strong>and</strong> education, <strong>and</strong> mismanagement of pension funds by the state, have led<br />

people to save more to insure against future bad luck (for example, sickness,<br />

job loss), to buy their own lodging, build up nest eggs for retirement <strong>and</strong> invest<br />

in their children.<br />

The second change is the secular improvement in the official Chinese<br />

attitude towards market capitalism. Given the high <strong>rate</strong> of return to capital, this<br />

increasingly business-friendly attitude of the Communist Party of China has<br />

no doubt encouraged rural <strong>and</strong> urban residents to save for investment: that is,<br />

greater optimism about the future has spawned investment-motivated saving. 16<br />

Our investment-motivated savings hypothesis is not new. According to Jeffrey<br />

Williamson (1988), the historical record of Western Europe <strong>and</strong> North America<br />

shows that ‘investment dem<strong>and</strong> seems to have been the driving force behind<br />

private saving <strong>and</strong> accumulation, past <strong>and</strong> present’.<br />

In our explanations for the existence <strong>and</strong> the growth of the current account<br />

surpluses, there is a common element: China’s financial system. The fact is that<br />

savings behaviour is not independent of the sophistication of the financial system.<br />

An advanced financial system will have a variety of financial institutions that<br />

enable pooling of risks by providing medical insurance, pension insurance <strong>and</strong><br />

unemployment insurance; <strong>and</strong> transform savings into education loans, housing<br />

loans <strong>and</strong> other types of investment loans to the private sector. Ceteris paribus, the<br />

more sophisticated a financial system, the lower the savings <strong>rate</strong>—a proposition<br />

that finds formal statistical support in Liu <strong>and</strong> Woo (1994) <strong>and</strong> Woo <strong>and</strong> Liu (1995).<br />

China gene<strong>rate</strong>s the current account surplus because of inadequate financial<br />

intermediation, <strong>and</strong> the surplus grows over time because the dysfunctional<br />

financial system fails to pool risks to reduce uncertainty-induced savings <strong>and</strong><br />

fails to provide loans to reduce investment-motivated saving (Figure 4.2).<br />

55


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

The overall US trade balance has been in deficit at least since 1980, <strong>and</strong> it<br />

has always been much bigger than the US–China trade balance (Figure 4.3).<br />

This pattern of imbalances suggests three conclusions. First, the US–China<br />

trade deficit is only 22.4 per cent of the overall US trade deficit, so even if the<br />

bilateral trade balance were brought to zero by tariffs aimed at China, the overall<br />

trade deficit would still be large. Second, the bilateral trade deficit surplus is<br />

created by the same factors that are causing the overall trade deficit: the large<br />

annual budget deficit created by the tax cuts enacted by the Bush administration<br />

in 2001 <strong>and</strong> the post 2001 growth in defence expenditure. Third, the highly<br />

sophisticated US financial system (which pioneered the sub-prime mortgage<br />

market <strong>and</strong> corpo<strong>rate</strong> junk bonds to enable consumption <strong>and</strong> investment) has<br />

lowered the US private savings <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

Clearly, the sustained nature of the overall US trade deficit was possible only<br />

because foreign lenders had faith in the growth prospects of the US economy,<br />

<strong>and</strong> because the East Asian central banks were willing to hold an increasing<br />

amount of US financial instruments. The paradox is why the US Congress is<br />

so concerned about trade deficits when foreigners have such confidence in the<br />

economic future of the United States. Both groups cannot be right.<br />

Figure 4.3<br />

US trade imbalance, 1980–2006 (US$ million)<br />

1980<br />

1982<br />

1984<br />

1986<br />

1988<br />

1990<br />

1992<br />

1994<br />

1996<br />

1998<br />

2000<br />

2002<br />

2004<br />

2006<br />

0<br />

-150,000<br />

US$ million<br />

-300,000<br />

-450,000<br />

-600,000<br />

-750,000<br />

-900,000<br />

Overall trade balance<br />

US-China trade balance<br />

Source: International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2007. Direction of Trade Statistics, 9 May, Statistics<br />

Department, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.<br />

56


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

Is a large yuan appreciation the cure for trade friction?<br />

China has been under foreign pressure at least since 2002 to appreciate the yuan<br />

significantly. In December 2002, Haruhiko Kuroda <strong>and</strong> Masahiro Kawai (2002)<br />

from Japan’s Ministry of Finance called for a yuan appreciation in order to stop<br />

China exporting its price deflation to the rest of the world. In September 2003,<br />

US Treasury Secretary, John Snow, declared that China should appreciate the<br />

yuan as part of its international responsibility to eliminate imbalances in the<br />

global balance of payments. 17 In September 2003, Morris Goldstein <strong>and</strong> Nicholas<br />

Lardy (2003) of the Institute for International Economics in Washington, DC,<br />

claimed that an immediate yuan appreciation of 15–25 per cent would benefit<br />

China because it would remove ‘the incentive for further speculative capital<br />

inflow <strong>and</strong> reserve accumulation. No longer would the foreign component of<br />

the money supply be working at cross-purposes with the needs of domestic<br />

stabilization.’<br />

In March 2007, Goldstein (2007) offered the opinion to the US Congress<br />

that the<br />

…renminbi (RMB) is now grossly undervalued—on the order of 30 percent<br />

or more against an average of China’s trading partners <strong>and</strong> 40 percent or<br />

more against the US dollar…[The] US Treasury has refused to label China<br />

as a ‘currency manipulator’ despite overwhelming evidence to the contrary<br />

<strong>and</strong> the managing director of the International Monetary Fund continues to<br />

reject the role of global umpire for exchange <strong>rate</strong> policies that was laid out for<br />

the Fund in its charter. China should deliver right away a meaningful ‘down<br />

payment’ of a 10–15 per cent appreciation of the RMB from its current level.<br />

Failure by China to drastically reduce its large-scale, one-way intervention in<br />

the exchange market should result in a finding of ‘currency manipulation’ in<br />

the Treasury’s May 2007 report to the US Congress…Finally, the IMF should<br />

return to its roots by taking up in earnest the role that its founders set out for<br />

it as the global umpire for exchange <strong>rate</strong> policies.<br />

We will use the format of question <strong>and</strong> answer to analyse the question posed<br />

in the title of this part of the paper <strong>and</strong> to assess the validity of the above<br />

assertions.<br />

Did China export deflation, as Kuroda <strong>and</strong> Kawai (2003) claimed?<br />

The fundamental problem with Kuroda <strong>and</strong> Kawai’s claim is that it is impossible<br />

to blame Japan’s deflation on China’s deflation because the timing is wrong.<br />

Japan’s deflation started with the bursting of the stock market cum real estate<br />

bubble in 1992, which was well before China’s trade account surpluses started to<br />

soar in the 2000s. If anything, trade with China since 2003 has been an important<br />

57


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

stimulus to Japanese economic recovery. Sustained high Chinese investment<br />

spending has sucked in large amounts of intermediate inputs, machinery <strong>and</strong><br />

capital equipment from Japan.<br />

Would a yuan appreciation reduce global imbalances, as Bergsten<br />

(2007) claimed?<br />

There is little doubt that a large appreciation of the yuan against the US<br />

dollar—say, 40 per cent, as suggested by Goldstein (2007)—could eliminate the<br />

US–China trade deficit as well as China’s overall trade surplus. But this move<br />

would only hurt China <strong>and</strong> would not ‘save’ the world. Ceteris paribus, in the<br />

aftermath of a 40 per cent yuan appreciation, foreign companies producing in<br />

China for the G7 markets would move their operations to other Asian economies<br />

(such as Vietnam <strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong>) <strong>and</strong> export from there, <strong>and</strong> G7 importers would<br />

start importing the same goods from other Asian countries instead. In the<br />

absence of a collective appreciation of all Asian currencies, a yuan appreciation<br />

would only reconfigure the geographical distribution of the global imbalances,<br />

not eliminate them.<br />

How could a collective regional appreciation against the US dollar be<br />

achieved?<br />

It would be naive to assume that Asian currencies tend to move closely together<br />

when one of them moves a large amount, such as 40 per cent. The last time<br />

the Asian currencies moved together by a large amount was during the Asian<br />

financial crisis of 1997–98, <strong>and</strong> China did not join in despite many predictions to<br />

the contrary. Should the US government now exp<strong>and</strong> its currency appreciation<br />

campaign serially to other East Asian countries <strong>and</strong> undertake a ‘surge’ in<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> activism on any country that pushes back? For many reasons,<br />

this would not be a desirable international economic st<strong>rate</strong>gy for the United<br />

States. 18<br />

Would a large, simultaneous collective appreciation of the Asian<br />

currencies be an unambiguous gain for the United States?<br />

We are not sure. Immediate cessation of the foreign financing of the US savings<br />

gap would translate into an immediate zero current account balance, <strong>and</strong><br />

this would require an immediate increase in US exports <strong>and</strong>/or an immediate<br />

decrease in US imports. Exports would increase quickly only if there were<br />

substantial excess production capacity or if there were a substantial drop in<br />

domestic dem<strong>and</strong> that freed up the domestic goods for sale abroad. Imports<br />

58


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

would decrease quickly only if there were excess production capacity (to<br />

enable replacement of imports) or if there were a substantial drop in domestic<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> that reduced the use of consumer goods <strong>and</strong> inputs. Since there is no<br />

substantial excess production capacity in the US economy today, the immediate<br />

elimination of the current account deficit would require a huge drop in domestic<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>, which would have its origin in a large negative wealth shock, possibly<br />

in the form of a stock market collapse or an inflationary spike. 19<br />

Would the absence of a yuan appreciation cause high inflation in<br />

China, as Goldstein <strong>and</strong> Lardy (2003) claimed?<br />

The growth of Chinese money supply has not slowed drastically despite the<br />

heightening of anti-inflation rhetoric by the Chinese government in response<br />

to the continued high growth of investment expenditure. Has the Chinese<br />

government lost control of its money supply, as a number of analysts have<br />

warned? Not at all. The speculative inflows <strong>and</strong> growth in foreign exchange<br />

reserves cannot exp<strong>and</strong> the money supply without the agreement of the People’s<br />

Bank of China (PBC). As well as sterilisation through open-market operations,<br />

China has the use of credit quotas on bank lending. The fact is that all Chinese<br />

banks are state controlled, <strong>and</strong> their high-ranking executives are appointed by<br />

the state. Given the choice between maximising bank profits or heeding orders<br />

from the prime minister’s office, the bank chiefs can always be counted on to<br />

choose the latter. There is no question about the Communist Party of China<br />

losing control of the money supply since 2002.<br />

Money supply growth in 2005–07 did not slow markedly because China chose<br />

not to enforce the credit quotas stringently. First, the inflation <strong>rate</strong>, although<br />

rising, is still low. Second, it is good politics to have a booming economy in the<br />

period leading up to the important seventeenth Party Congress in November<br />

2007, which will ratify important personnel appointments for the next five<br />

years.<br />

What is the correct level for the exchange <strong>rate</strong>?<br />

The Economist magazine constructs a purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong> based on the prices of Big Mac hamburgers sold in different countries.<br />

In 2006, it cost 10.4 yuan to buy a Big Mac in China <strong>and</strong> US$3.15 in the United<br />

States, so the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> was 3.3 yuan per US dollar in 2006, compared<br />

with the actual (nominal) exchange <strong>rate</strong> of 8 yuan per US dollar. Is it, therefore,<br />

meaningful to say that the Chinese exchange <strong>rate</strong> was undervalued by almost<br />

60 per cent in 2006? The answer is no, because the prices of the hamburgers<br />

59


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

included non-tradable inputs, <strong>and</strong> the prices of non-tradables were lower in<br />

China than in the United States. In general, the prices of non-tradables are lower<br />

in developing economies than in industrialised economies because labour costs<br />

are lower in the former. With economic development, the prices of non-tradables<br />

in the developing economies will rise to bring the price ratio of non-tradables<br />

to tradables closer to the price ratio in the industrialised economy.<br />

To see that the gap between the usual PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> the actual<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> reflects the development gap between the two countries, we<br />

first make the following definitions<br />

a) Defining the consumer price index in China <strong>and</strong> the United States<br />

CPI of China, CPI C = (1-a) P C T + a PC N<br />

CPI of the United States, CPI U = (1-a) P U T + a PU N<br />

(3)<br />

where CPI is the consumer price index, C is China, U is the United States,<br />

P i is the price of the tradable good in country ‘i’, T Pi is the price of the<br />

N<br />

non-tradable good in country ‘i’, <strong>and</strong> ‘a’ is the weight of non-tradable<br />

goods in the price index.<br />

b) Defining the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

e PPP = CPI C / CPI U (4)<br />

We next state the equilibrium conditions.<br />

a) Goods arbitrage<br />

P C T = eactual P U T (5)<br />

where e actual is the actual (nominal) exchange <strong>rate</strong> expressed as the<br />

number of yuan per US dollar.<br />

b) Relationship between prices of tradables <strong>and</strong> non-tradables within each<br />

country<br />

for developing China, P C T = d PC N<br />

for industrialised United States, P U T = f PU N (6)<br />

60


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

c) The difference between the industrialised <strong>and</strong> the developing economy<br />

is that the relative price of non-tradables is higher in the former.<br />

d > f > 0 (7)<br />

We can now derive the following relationship between the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> the actual exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

e PPP = CPI C / CPI U<br />

e PPP = [(1-a+af)/(1-a+ad)] e actual<br />

e PPP < e actual (8)<br />

The above exercise shows that it is conceptually difficult to determine the<br />

‘correctness’ of a country’s exchange <strong>rate</strong> on the basis of PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong>s.<br />

The actual (nominal) exchange <strong>rate</strong> of a developing economy will always be<br />

undervalued in relation to the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong>, <strong>and</strong> it is ludicrous to dem<strong>and</strong><br />

that the government of the developing economy set its exchange <strong>rate</strong> equal to<br />

the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> (because this is not a sustainable <strong>policy</strong>).<br />

One meaningful definition of the ‘correct exchange <strong>rate</strong>’ is that it is the<br />

‘market-clearing exchange <strong>rate</strong>’: the exchange <strong>rate</strong> that is gene<strong>rate</strong>d by the<br />

foreign exchange markets in the absence of intervention by any central bank.<br />

The fact that the People’s Bank of China has been accumulating foreign<br />

reserves during every period means that the yuan is undervalued according to<br />

this definition. What would happen, however, if China were to go further in its<br />

marketisation of foreign exchange transactions by removing its capital controls?<br />

Diversification of asset portfolios by private Chinese agents would surely result<br />

in a great outflow of funds, possibly causing the yuan to depreciate. In such a<br />

case, the present exchange <strong>rate</strong> of 8 yuan per US dollar would be overvalued<br />

compared with the ‘complete free-market exchange <strong>rate</strong>’. Of course, no one<br />

knows whether the complete free-market exchange <strong>rate</strong> would be higher or<br />

lower than 8 yuan per US dollar.<br />

Suppose the value of the complete free-market exchange <strong>rate</strong> was 6.5 yuan<br />

per US dollar <strong>and</strong> the market-clearing exchange <strong>rate</strong> with controls on capital<br />

outflows was 4.5 yuan per US dollar—<strong>and</strong> suppose the government stops<br />

intervention immediately <strong>and</strong> then removes capital controls a few years later,<br />

after it has strengthened the supervision, management <strong>and</strong> technical capability<br />

61


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

of the domestic financial institutions. One plausible result of this particular twostep<br />

market liberalisation (which we call Option A) would be appreciation to 4.5<br />

yuan per dollar on cessation of foreign exchange market intervention followed<br />

by depreciation to 6.5 yuan per dollar on removal of the capital controls.<br />

Suppose China adopts another form of two-step liberalisation (Option<br />

B), incremental appreciation of the yuan <strong>and</strong> removal of the capital controls<br />

after a few years. Option B is better than Option A because the exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong> overshooting in Option A creates an unnecessary to-<strong>and</strong>-fro movement<br />

in resources. As mentioned, the removal of capital controls could very well<br />

cause the yuan to depreciate past 8 yuan per dollar, say, to 9.5 yuan per dollar,<br />

meaning that Option A would result in very severe exchange <strong>rate</strong> overshooting<br />

compared to Option B.<br />

In effect, the Chinese government has been implementing a form of Option<br />

B since July 2005. In our opinion, the Chinese government has chosen a speed<br />

of exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>adjustment</strong> that is too slow, causing the yuan to depreciate<br />

significantly against the euro. We recommend that the Chinese government<br />

increases the speed of the yuan appreciation, but not in the form of an immediate<br />

discrete 10–15 per cent appreciation as advocated by Goldstein (2007). 20<br />

In our opinion, the instinctive calls by some economists for the use of the<br />

exchange-<strong>rate</strong> mechanism to solve China’s external imbalance is only partially<br />

correct. Given China’s capital controls, a freely floating currency regime could<br />

mean a value for the yuan that would be greatly over-appreciated compared<br />

with what its value would be under free capital flows, <strong>and</strong> could therefore<br />

reduce economic growth significantly. 21 Freeing capital flows is not, however,<br />

an option at this time. Given the weakness of the balance sheets of China’s<br />

state-owned banks <strong>and</strong> the considerable embezzlement of state assets that<br />

has occurred—<strong>and</strong> the experience of the East Asian financial crisis—we advise<br />

against allowing the free movement of capital in the short term.<br />

The correct way to think about exchange-<strong>rate</strong> management is to analyse<br />

the issue within the context of overall <strong>macroeconomic</strong> management <strong>and</strong> not<br />

just in regard to its impact on the balance of payments. It is likely that there are<br />

alternative combinations of <strong>macroeconomic</strong> policies that would produce results<br />

superior to the one gene<strong>rate</strong>d by appreciating the yuan alone. The general point<br />

is that because the balance of payments is only one of the main outcomes of<br />

concern 22 <strong>and</strong> the exchange <strong>rate</strong> is only one of the ways to affect the balance<br />

of payments, 23 it is seldom the optimum to concent<strong>rate</strong> exclusively on one<br />

<strong>policy</strong> target (which does not dominate the other <strong>policy</strong> targets in importance)<br />

<strong>and</strong> then to employ only one <strong>policy</strong> tool (which is chosen idiosyncratically) to<br />

achieve that target.<br />

62


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

What is to be done?<br />

The real source of the anxieties that have given rise to the present US obsession<br />

with yuan appreciation is not the large trade imbalances but the large amount<br />

of structural <strong>adjustment</strong> necessitated by the acceleration of globalisation <strong>and</strong><br />

of labour-saving technological progress. Dollar depreciation <strong>and</strong> trade barriers<br />

will slow the process of structural <strong>adjustment</strong> but will not stop it because<br />

the main driver of structural <strong>adjustment</strong> in the United States is technological<br />

progress. The optimal solution is a <strong>policy</strong> package that emphasises multilateral<br />

action to achieve several important objectives. It is bad economics <strong>and</strong> bad<br />

politics to dwell on just one region (China alone must change), to dwell on just<br />

one instrument (yuan appreciation alone) <strong>and</strong> to dwell entirely on one target<br />

(external imbalance).<br />

We start by stating what should be done in the United States. Congress<br />

should quicken the reduction in fiscal imbalance, <strong>and</strong> exp<strong>and</strong> trade <strong>adjustment</strong><br />

programs, especially those that upgrade the skills of younger workers. The<br />

Trade Adjustment Assistance (TAA) program still functions inadequately after<br />

its overhaul in 2002. Lael Brainard (2007) reported that<br />

[p]articipation has remained surprisingly low, thanks in part to confusing<br />

Department of Labor interpretations <strong>and</strong> practices that ultimately deny<br />

benefits to roughly three-quarters of workers who are certified as eligible<br />

for them. TAA has helped fewer than 75,000 new workers per year, while<br />

denying more than 40 per cent of all employers’ petitions. And remarkably,<br />

the Department of Labor has interpreted the TAA statute as excluding the<br />

growing number of services workers displaced by trade. Between 2001 <strong>and</strong><br />

2004, an average of only 64 per cent of participants found jobs while they<br />

participated in TAA. And earnings on the new job were more than 20 per cent<br />

below those prior to displacement.<br />

The TAA program is in clear need of further improvement. Brainard’s (2007)<br />

proposal for the establishment of wage insurance is an excellent way to bring<br />

the US social safety net more in line with the type of structural <strong>adjustment</strong>s<br />

driven by globalisation <strong>and</strong> technological changes.<br />

What is to be done in China? The obvious short-term <strong>policy</strong> package has<br />

three components. First, the steady process of yuan appreciation begun in July<br />

2005 should be quickened—<strong>and</strong> should be used more aggressively as an antiinflation<br />

instrument. Second, import liberalisation should be accele<strong>rate</strong>d (for<br />

example, commitments made in negotiations for WTO membership, such as<br />

intellectual property rights protection, should be implemented) <strong>and</strong> exp<strong>and</strong>ed<br />

beyond WTO specifications.<br />

63


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

The third component of the short-term <strong>policy</strong> package is to have an<br />

expansionary fiscal <strong>policy</strong> (such as rural infrastructure investments) to soak up<br />

excess savings, with an emphasis on import-intensive investments (for example,<br />

buying aeroplanes <strong>and</strong> sending students abroad). There must be time limits put<br />

on the exp<strong>and</strong>ed public works <strong>and</strong> SCE investments because, in the long term,<br />

increased public investments could follow an increasingly rent-seeking path<br />

that is wasteful (for example, building a second big bridge to a low-populated<br />

isl<strong>and</strong> to benefit a politically connected construction company, as happened<br />

in Japan), <strong>and</strong> the increased SCE investments could convert themselves into<br />

non-performing loans at the state-owned banks.<br />

It is now common to hear calls for China to rebalance its growth path<br />

by reducing savings to increase consumption. This advice on increasing<br />

consumption cannot be wrong, however, consumption in China today is largely<br />

under the control of individual families <strong>and</strong> firms. They have probably already<br />

tried their best to optimise their consumption given all the constraints they<br />

face, <strong>and</strong> are unlikely to welcome the government telling them how to spend<br />

their money.<br />

Since the health insurance <strong>and</strong> social security networks in China are in<br />

their infancy, many Chinese people are choosing to save a great deal of money<br />

as a hedge against severe illness. In the absence of student-loan programs,<br />

families are also choosing to save a great deal for their children’s education.<br />

Many middle-class Chinese families have bought property in anticipation of<br />

capital gains but have refrained from moving into the new property because<br />

roads, subways <strong>and</strong> schools for many newly developed residential communities<br />

are underdeveloped. These are their best choices given the structural <strong>and</strong><br />

economic constraints on Chinese society. As a result, the consumption of<br />

Chinese households remains low <strong>and</strong> savings <strong>rate</strong>s remain high. All of these<br />

factors beg the question, ‘how can China increase domestic consumption?’.<br />

In the context of the above examples, the answers are quite straightforward:<br />

build an integ<strong>rate</strong>d health insurance system; create student-loan <strong>and</strong> scholarship<br />

programs; <strong>and</strong> build more roads, subways <strong>and</strong> schools. 24 The optimal solution<br />

to the problem of excess saving is not, however, for the government to absorb<br />

it by increasing its budget deficit but to establish an improved mechanism<br />

for coordinating private savings <strong>and</strong> private investments. Establishment of a<br />

modern financial system will not only achieve this objective, it will enhance<br />

welfare <strong>and</strong> lower the savings <strong>rate</strong> by pooling risks through vehicles such as<br />

medical <strong>and</strong> pension insurance. In a nutshell, China’s main challenge today<br />

is to develop smoothly functioning financial, planning <strong>and</strong> regulatory systems<br />

that can employ the remaining rural surplus labour (as indicated by an average<br />

64


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

wage of about US$120 per month for 480 million rural <strong>and</strong> migrant workers)<br />

<strong>and</strong> surplus capital, which now shows up in China’s sustained current account<br />

surplus <strong>and</strong> rising foreign exchange reserves.<br />

The most important priority for financial-sector development is the appearance<br />

<strong>and</strong> growth of competitive domestic private banks. As China is required by its<br />

WTO accession agreement to allow foreign banks to compete against its stateowned<br />

banks on an equal basis by 2007, it would be akin to self-loathing not to<br />

allow the formation of truly private banks of domestic origin. There is no reason to<br />

favour foreign private banks over domestic private banks, <strong>and</strong> there is no reason<br />

why China should not allow its best financial minds to compete with—<strong>and</strong> achieve<br />

the same glorious success as—the best foreign financial minds.<br />

We therefore recommend that after the recapitalisation of the big four state<br />

banks, at least two of them should be broken into several regional banks, <strong>and</strong><br />

the majority of these regional banks should be privatised. At the same time,<br />

laws on the establishment of new banks should be loosened, <strong>and</strong> interest <strong>rate</strong>s<br />

deregulated. It is crucial, however, that financial-sector liberalisation proceeds<br />

no faster than the development of the financial regulatory ability of the state.<br />

Even then, the danger of substituting a financial crash for financial repression<br />

is real. A modern financial system requires a modern system of supervision<br />

<strong>and</strong> prudential regulation for its proper functioning.<br />

It would be a good idea to sell a few of the regional state banks to foreign<br />

banks. This would facilitate the transfer of modern banking technology to<br />

Chinese banks. The more local staff the foreign bankers train, the larger is the<br />

pool of future managers for Chinese-owned banks. An accele<strong>rate</strong>d process<br />

of promoting the growth of sound domestic private financial institutions <strong>and</strong><br />

allowing the entry of foreign financial institutions would shorten the time<br />

needed for Shanghai to assume its rightful place among the major international<br />

financial centres, <strong>and</strong> to contribute to more efficient intermediation of the<br />

world’s savings.<br />

An important part of financial reform should be promotion of the development<br />

of sound rural financial institutions. The government can usefully draw on the<br />

wealth of international experience with various schemes in developing economies<br />

to direct investment credit to rural areas. In particular, we wish to draw attention<br />

to the successful Indonesian experience of establishing a self-sustaining <strong>and</strong><br />

profitable banking system (the ‘Unit Desa’ system) in the countryside to provide<br />

a starting point for discussing how to accele<strong>rate</strong> financial development in rural<br />

China. 25 China should allow the appearance of new small-scale rural financial<br />

institutions that will mobilise local savings to finance local investments as quickly<br />

as adequate prudential supervision can be put into place.<br />

65


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

The widespread international attention on the value of the yuan is possibly<br />

the first time in international monetary history that the value of the currency<br />

of a developing economy has so greatly exercised the finance ministries <strong>and</strong><br />

central banks of the largest industrialised economies for such a sustained<br />

period. This anomalous situation reveals two noteworthy points about China’s<br />

return to the international stage: it shows the significant economic impact<br />

that China is already having on the world; <strong>and</strong> it portends that the anticipated<br />

continued fast growth of China in the next two decades will not only force<br />

more structural <strong>adjustment</strong>s in other countries, it will require China to assume<br />

a broader ‘global system’ perspective in resolving disputes caused by crossborder<br />

spillovers from its policies. The most important <strong>and</strong> obvious area for<br />

collaboration between China <strong>and</strong> industrialised economies at this point is<br />

working together to further liberalise the multilateral free-trade system, <strong>and</strong>,<br />

at the minimum, to prevent it being eroded.<br />

As China continues to grow rapidly, there is the unfortunate possibility that<br />

the range of international disputes could exp<strong>and</strong>—possibly in the medium<br />

term—to include international concerns about China’s public health readiness<br />

<strong>and</strong> environmental protection. Hopefully, the world will be more multilateral in<br />

its approach to the solution of these issues rather than insisting on a unilateral<br />

solution by China, as in the present case of the yuan.<br />

Notes<br />

1 At the end of May, the National Development <strong>and</strong> Reform Commission predicted that ‘China’s<br />

trade surplus will swell to between US$250 billion to US$300 billion this year, driven by price<br />

competitiveness <strong>and</strong> strong external dem<strong>and</strong>. The surplus for the first four months of this year<br />

totaled US$63.3 billion, up 88% from the same period of last year’ (Wall Street Journal 2007a).<br />

In mid June, it was revealed that China’s overall trade surplus had widened to US$22.45 billion<br />

in May 2007, which was a 33 per cent gain on April’s figure (St<strong>and</strong>ard 2007).<br />

2 Details of these three WTO cases are found in USTR 2007a, 2007b <strong>and</strong> 2007c.<br />

3 Neither the date nor the sample of newspapers was selected r<strong>and</strong>omly. These were the<br />

newspapers that were on the Singapore Airlines flight from Singapore to San Francisco (via<br />

Hong Kong) on the day of our travel.<br />

4 The article also reported that Peter M<strong>and</strong>elson ‘wants greater access for European companies<br />

to China <strong>and</strong> a crackdown on piracy—threatening extra tariffs or import quotas if not. He also<br />

wants the renminbi pegged to a basket of currencies.’<br />

5 The US civilian labour force in 2006 was 151.4 million (United States President 2007:Table<br />

B-35).<br />

6 For details <strong>and</strong> analysis of the economic transition in the former Soviet bloc <strong>and</strong> China, see<br />

the papers in Woo et al. 1997.<br />

7 More accu<strong>rate</strong>ly, the wage of the formerly isolated worker in the former Soviet Union, India <strong>and</strong><br />

China would rise while the wage for the worker in the industrialised economy would fall.<br />

66


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

8 There is a large empirical literature on the relative impact of technological changes <strong>and</strong><br />

globalisation on the US wage <strong>rate</strong>; notable contributions include Sachs <strong>and</strong> Shatz (1994) <strong>and</strong><br />

Feenstra <strong>and</strong> Hanson (1996 <strong>and</strong> 1998).<br />

9 Akerlof (2007) is a recent discussion on ‘norms’ <strong>and</strong> their economic consequences.<br />

10 Borjas (1994) <strong>and</strong> Ottaviano <strong>and</strong> Peri (2005) are good discussions of this topic.<br />

11 The data are from the Direction of Trade Statistics database maintained by the International<br />

Monetary Fund (IMF 2007).<br />

12 See Feenstra et al. 1999 for the details of the different national treatments. This study reestimated<br />

the export <strong>and</strong> import data of China–US trade, <strong>and</strong> reduced the gap between the<br />

two estimates: for example, the US$29 billion gap between the two official figures in 1996<br />

was reduced to US$5 billion after revision of the data.<br />

13 The simple average of the Direction of Trade Statistics data was closer than the simple average<br />

of the official data to the simple average of the revised data of Feenstra et al. (1999); the latter<br />

two are reported in Feenstra et al. (1999:Table 1).<br />

14 The SCE category covers companies that are classified as state-owned companies <strong>and</strong> joint<br />

ventures <strong>and</strong> joint-stock companies that are controlled by third parties (for example, legal<br />

persons), who are answerable to the state.<br />

15 The Economist Intelligence Unit (2004:23) reported that ‘farmers’ propensity to save seems<br />

to have increased’.<br />

16 Liu <strong>and</strong> Woo (1994) <strong>and</strong> Woo <strong>and</strong> Liu (1995) contain formal modelling <strong>and</strong> econometric support<br />

for the investment-motivated saving hypothesis.<br />

17 See, for example, Financial Times (2003).<br />

18 For one thing, serial exchange-<strong>rate</strong> activism <strong>and</strong> the surge of it are unlikely to be more<br />

successful than the expansion of the war from Afghanistan to Iraq <strong>and</strong> the surge of US military<br />

effort in Iraq in 2007.<br />

19 Considerations like this might be the reason why Goldstein <strong>and</strong> Lardy (2003) <strong>and</strong> Goldstein<br />

(2007) advocated a two-step st<strong>rate</strong>gy of yuan appreciation: a modest appreciation followed<br />

by incremental appreciation.<br />

20 Our analysis therefore leads us to agree with the three recent <strong>policy</strong> positions of the US<br />

Treasury: that China must increase the pace of reform in financial services market (Paulson<br />

2007), that China has not engaged in currency manipulation, <strong>and</strong> that China should increase<br />

the <strong>rate</strong> of yuan appreciation.<br />

21 In Robert Mundell’s opinion, ‘China’s growth <strong>rate</strong> could fall by half <strong>and</strong> foreign direct investment<br />

(FDI) could slow to a crawl if the country were to ab<strong>and</strong>on its long-st<strong>and</strong>ing support of pegging<br />

the currency’ (quoted in South China Morning Post 2003).<br />

22 The inflation <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> unemployment would be among the other key concerns.<br />

23 Other ways include monetary <strong>and</strong> fiscal policies.<br />

24 Xiao (forthcoming) discusses this issue more fully <strong>and</strong> emphasises the problem of<br />

distinguishing productive investments from non-productive investments.<br />

25 Indonesia is similar to China in key economic <strong>and</strong> institutional features: a geographically<br />

vast <strong>and</strong> heavily populated economy, <strong>and</strong> a rural financial system dominated by branches of<br />

a state bank (Bank Rakyat Indonesia <strong>and</strong> Agricultural Bank of China respectively). See Woo<br />

(2005).<br />

67


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

References<br />

Acharya, S., 2004. ‘Why did India reform?’, Business St<strong>and</strong>ard, 24 February.<br />

Available from http://www.rediff.com/money/2004/feb/24guest1.htm<br />

Akerlof, G.A., 2007. ‘The missing motivation in <strong>macroeconomic</strong>s’, Presidential<br />

Address to the American Economic Association Meeting in Chicago, University<br />

of California at Berkeley.<br />

Bergsten, C.F., 2007. The dollar <strong>and</strong> the renminbi, Statement to the Hearing on<br />

US Economic Relations with China: st<strong>rate</strong>gies <strong>and</strong> options on exchange <strong>rate</strong>s<br />

<strong>and</strong> market access, Subcommittee on Security <strong>and</strong> International Trade <strong>and</strong><br />

Finance, Committee on Banking, Housing <strong>and</strong> Urban Affairs, United States<br />

Senate, Washington, DC, 23 May.<br />

Borjas, G.J., 1994. ‘The economics of immigration’, Journal of Economic<br />

Literature, 32(4):1,667–717.<br />

Brainard, L., 2007. Meeting the challenge of income instability, Testimony<br />

to Joint Economic Committee Hearing, 28 February, Washington,<br />

DC. Available from http://jec.senate.gov/Documents/Hearings/<br />

02.28.07%20Income%20Instability/Testimony%20-%20Brainard.pdf<br />

Feenstra, R.C. <strong>and</strong> Hanson, G.H., 1996. ‘Globalization, outsourcing, <strong>and</strong> wage<br />

inequality’, American Economic Review, LXXXVI:240–5.<br />

——, 1998. The impact of outsourcing <strong>and</strong> high-technology capital on wages:<br />

estimates for the United States, 1979–1990, Department of Economics,<br />

University of California, Davis (unpublished).<br />

Feenstra, R.C., Hai, W., Woo, W.T. <strong>and</strong> Yao, S., 1999. ‘Discrepancies in<br />

international data: an application to China–Hong Kong entrepot trade’,<br />

American Economic Review, 89(2):338–43.<br />

Financial Times, 2003. ‘Snow calls on Beijing to let currency float’, Financial<br />

Times, 2 September.<br />

——, 2007a. ‘Surplus fuels EU–China war of words’, Financial Times, 13 June.<br />

——, 2007b. ‘IMF set to scrutinise exchange <strong>rate</strong> policies’, Financial Times, 19<br />

June.<br />

Freeman, R., 2004. Doubling the global work force: the challenge of integrating<br />

China, India, <strong>and</strong> the former Soviet Bloc into the world economy, Harvard<br />

University (unpublished).<br />

Goldstein, M., 2007. Assessing progress on China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong> policies,<br />

Testimony to the Hearing on Risks <strong>and</strong> Reform: the role of currency in<br />

the US–China relationship, Committee on Finance, US Senate, 28 March,<br />

Washington, DC.<br />

Goldstein, M. <strong>and</strong> Lardy, N., 2003. ‘Two-stage currency reform in China’, Asian<br />

Wall Street Journal, 12 September.<br />

68


Facing protectionism gene<strong>rate</strong>d by trade disputes<br />

International Herald Tribune, 2007. ‘Yuan gain is biggest since end of peg’,<br />

International Herald Tribune, 13 June.<br />

International Monetary Fund (IMF), 2007. Direction of Trade Statistics, 9<br />

May, Statistics Department, International Monetary Fund, Washington,<br />

DC. Available from http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/longres.<br />

cfm?sk=20954<br />

Kuroda, H. <strong>and</strong> Kawai, M., 2002. ‘Time for a switch to global reflation’, Financial<br />

Times, 1 December.<br />

Liu, L.Y. <strong>and</strong> Woo, W.T., 1994. ‘Saving behavior under imperfect financial markets<br />

<strong>and</strong> the current account consequences’, Economic Journal, May.<br />

New York Times, 2007. ‘4 in Senate seek penalty for China’, New York Times,<br />

14 June.<br />

Ottaviano, G.I.P. <strong>and</strong> Peri, G., 2005. Rethinking the gains from immigration: theory<br />

<strong>and</strong> evidence from the US, NBER Working Papers 11672, National Bureau of<br />

Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.<br />

Paulson, H.M., 2007. ‘Prepared remarks by Treasury Secretary Henry M.<br />

Paulson, Jr. on the growth <strong>and</strong> future of China’s financial markets’, HP-301,<br />

7 March, The Department of the Treasury, Washington, DC. Available from<br />

http://www.treas.gov/press/releases/hp301.htm<br />

Sachs, J.D. <strong>and</strong> Shatz, H.J., 1994. ‘Trade <strong>and</strong> jobs in US manufacturing’,<br />

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1:1–84.<br />

Sachs, J.D. <strong>and</strong> Woo, W.T., 2000. ‘Underst<strong>and</strong>ing China’s economic performance’,<br />

Journal of Policy Reform, 4(1):1–50.<br />

——, 2003. ‘China’s growth after WTO membership’, Journal of Chinese<br />

Economics <strong>and</strong> Business Studies, 1(1):1–31.<br />

Scott, R.E., 2007. Costly trade with China: millions of US jobs displaced with net<br />

job loss in every state, EPI Briefing Paper, No. 188, 2 May, Economic Policy<br />

Institute, Washington, DC.<br />

South China Morning Post, 2003. ‘Ab<strong>and</strong>oning peg will slash growth 50 pc in<br />

China’, South China Morning Post, 15 September.<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard, 2007. ‘US lawmakers turn up yuan heat’, St<strong>and</strong>ard (Hong Kong), 13<br />

June.<br />

Economist Intelligence Unit, 2004. Country Report: China, December, Economist<br />

Intelligence Unit, Paris.<br />

The Straits Times, 2007. ‘EU’s ties with China at crucial crossroads’, The Straits<br />

Times, 13 June.<br />

United States, Office of the President, 2007. Economic Report of the President,<br />

Washignton, DC. Available from http://www.gpoaccess.gov/eop/index.<br />

html<br />

69


China—Linking Markets for Growth<br />

United States Trade Representative (USTR), 2007a. WTO Case Challenging<br />

Chinese Subsidies, 2 February. Available from http://www.ustr.gov/assets/<br />

Document_Library/Fact_Sheets/2007/asset_upload_file143_10465.pdf<br />

——, 2007b. WTO Case Challenging Market Access Restrictions in China on<br />

Products of Copyright-Intensive Industries, 9 April. Available from http://www.<br />

ustr.gov/assets/Document_Library/Fact_Sheets/2007/asset_upload_file971_<br />

11063.pdf<br />

——, 2007c. WTO Case Challenging Weaknesses in China’s Legal Regime for<br />

Protection <strong>and</strong> Enforcement of Copyrights <strong>and</strong> Trademarks, 9 April. Available<br />

from http://www.ustr.gov/assets/Document_Library/Fact_Sheets/2007/<br />

asset_upload_file908_11061.pdf<br />

USA Today, 2007. ‘Tensions push US to get even with China’, USA Today, 13<br />

June.<br />

Wall Street Journal, 2007a. ‘China says trade surplus isn’t likely to shrink soon’,<br />

Wall Street Journal, 30 May.<br />

——, 2007b. ‘Bush, resisting Congress, won’t slap China on yuan’, The Wall<br />

Street Journal (Asia edition), 13 June.<br />

Williamson, J., 1988. ‘Comments on Reflections on Development’, in G. Ranis<br />

<strong>and</strong> T.P. Schultz (eds), The State of Development Economics: progress <strong>and</strong><br />

perspectives, Basil Blackwell, New York:24–30.<br />

Woo, W.T., 2005. ‘China’s rural enterprises in crisis: the role of inadequate<br />

financial intermediation’, in Y. Huang, A. Saich <strong>and</strong> E. Steinfeld (eds),<br />

Financial Sector Reform in China, Harvard University Asia Centre, Cambridge,<br />

MA.:67–91.<br />

——, 2006, ‘The structural nature of internal <strong>and</strong> external imbalances in China’,<br />

Journal of Chinese Economic <strong>and</strong> Business Studies, 4(1):1–20.<br />

Woo, W.T. <strong>and</strong> Liu, L.Y., 1995. ‘Investment-motivated saving <strong>and</strong> current account<br />

malaise’, Asia-Pacific Economic Review, 1(2):55–68.<br />

Woo, W.T., Sachs, J. <strong>and</strong> Parker, S. (eds), 1997. Economies in Transition: Asia <strong>and</strong><br />

Europe, Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press, Cambridge, MA.<br />

Xiao, G., (forthcoming). ‘What is special about China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

external imbalance? A structural <strong>and</strong> institutional perspective’, Asian<br />

Economic Papers.<br />

70


8<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Position of China: Structural <strong>and</strong><br />

Institutional Factors <strong>and</strong> their<br />

Implications<br />

Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

Global capital flows into developing economies have been driven<br />

by two fundamental factors: profit opportunities in the<br />

emerging economic frontiers <strong>and</strong> the physical <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

barriers to international capital mobility. Advancement in transportation<br />

<strong>and</strong> communication technology has greatly reduced the<br />

physical costs of cross-border mobility of capital <strong>and</strong> goods while<br />

the spread of global development knowledge has also led to new<br />

profit opportunities in less developed economies, such as China.<br />

Since the early 1980s, China has emerged as a major global<br />

development frontier, following its open-door policies <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

reforms initiated by Deng Xiaoping. Since that time, the barriers to<br />

foreign trade <strong>and</strong> investment in China have declined steadily,<br />

leading to China’s accession to the World Trade Organisation in late<br />

2001 – after one-<strong>and</strong>-a-half decades of tough negotiations. By the<br />

end of 2002, only a year after joining the WTO, China overtook the<br />

US in FDI inflows, becoming the most attractive FDI destination in<br />

the world, receiving $52.7 billion in FDI.<br />

China’s recent dramatic achievement seems to suggest that<br />

today’s global economy is unprecedented in terms of openness <strong>and</strong><br />

the amount of foreign capital flows into developing countries.<br />

113<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


114<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Unfortunately, this optimistic impression is not confirmed by facts.<br />

Foreign capital flows into developing countries today are far below<br />

historical record achieved before World War I. The gross value of<br />

foreign capital stock in developing countries increased from 8.6% of<br />

their GDP in 1870 to a peak of 32.4% in 1914. This ratio dropped<br />

to 4.4% in 1950 due to the interruption to the global trade <strong>and</strong><br />

investment during the war <strong>and</strong> by 1973, recovered only to 10.9%<br />

<strong>and</strong> 21.7% by 1998 (Maddison 2001, p. 28). Hence, in spite of<br />

technological advances during the last century, the world is actually<br />

less open for capital flows to less developed countries than one<br />

hundred years ago.<br />

Capital flows among developed countries are much freer than<br />

between developed <strong>and</strong> developing countries because of better<br />

protection of property rights <strong>and</strong> less capital control in the<br />

developed economies. High capital mobility among developed<br />

economies has led to a dramatic change in the holding of net foreign<br />

assets among developed countries during the last decade. For<br />

example, from 1989 to 1998, Japan’s holding of net foreign assets<br />

increased from $294 to $1.153 billion while the US obligation in net<br />

foreign liabilities jumped from $49 to $1.537 billion (Maddison<br />

2001, p. 137). Clearly, Japan has exported a substantial amount of<br />

capital to the US in search of better risk-adjusted return <strong>and</strong> in<br />

preparation for its aging population, even while the <strong>policy</strong><br />

environment in Japan, such as the volatility of the exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

the secular appreciation of the yen, is unfavourable to Japanese<br />

investment in foreign assets.<br />

In the last decade, foreign direct investment in China increased<br />

from about $3 billion in 1990 to $52.7 billion in 2002. As impressive<br />

as this is, on a per capita basis, China’s FDI inflow in 2001 was still<br />

below the average of FDI inflows to the rest of developing<br />

countries. Per capita FDI inflows in 2001 was only $37 for China,<br />

compared to an average of $120 for the world <strong>and</strong> $42 for all the<br />

rest of developing countries.<br />

Foreign invested enterprises in China have contributed to more<br />

than half of China’s exports. China has been generating current<br />

account surpluses for the last nine years. Since current account<br />

surplus simply means net savings or net export of capital, China is<br />

taking in FDI on the one h<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> exporting capital to capital-rich<br />

economies like the United States on the other h<strong>and</strong>. How can we<br />

reconcile these seemingly inconsistent patterns of capital flows?<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

115<br />

Is China attracting too much FDI? What happened to China’s<br />

investment in US bonds? What is the impact of foreign portfolio<br />

investment on the stability of the Chinese financial markets <strong>and</strong><br />

other Asian regional markets? Is China generating global deflation?<br />

How serious is China’s impact on its competitors? Is China saving<br />

too much? Should China revaluate its currency? Is China becoming<br />

a growth engine for the world? These are questions we examine in<br />

this chapter.<br />

The next section presents the basic facts on the patterns of global<br />

capital flows <strong>and</strong> the position of China. Section 2 explains the<br />

uniqueness of China’s economic conditions in attracting capital<br />

inflows. Section 3 assesses the impact of China’s rapid integration<br />

into the global economy on the rest of the world. Throughout our<br />

analysis, we emphasise structural <strong>and</strong> institutional factors such as the<br />

gaps in development, population structure, <strong>and</strong> financial <strong>and</strong> legal<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> their effects on the patterns of global capital flows<br />

<strong>and</strong> global economic development. Section 4 concludes.<br />

1 Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

In this section, we first summarise the pattern of global trade <strong>and</strong><br />

foreign direct investment based on the extensive information from<br />

the WTO <strong>and</strong> the World Investment Report of UNCTAD. Then<br />

we review global portfolio investment using detailed IMF <strong>and</strong> US<br />

Treasury surveys. Our purpose here is to provide a concise <strong>and</strong><br />

comparative background to determine China’s position in the global<br />

capital market.<br />

US Trade Deficits with China <strong>and</strong> the Asian Region<br />

Global merch<strong>and</strong>ise trade increased from $124 billion in 1948 to<br />

12.7 trillion in 2000, an increase of more than 100 times over a<br />

period of half-century. Western Europe <strong>and</strong> North America have<br />

maintained about 40% <strong>and</strong> 20% of the global trade respectively<br />

throughout this period. Asia’s share has risen from about 14% to<br />

about 24% at the costs of Latin America, Africa, <strong>and</strong> other regions.<br />

During the last two decades from 1982 to 2001, the growth <strong>rate</strong><br />

for global merch<strong>and</strong>ise trade varied from -5.8% in 1982 to 19.5% in<br />

1995, averaging about 6.1% a year. The global trade in commercial<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


116<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

services was relatively stable at a level of about 23% of the<br />

merch<strong>and</strong>ise trade (see Table 1.1 1 ).<br />

In 2000, Asia’s share of global exports (at 26.7%) is 3.9% higher<br />

than its share of imports (at 22.8%) while North America’s share of<br />

exports (at 17.1%) is 6.1% lower than its share of imports (at 23.2%)<br />

due to exceptional export performance in Japan, Asia’s newly<br />

industrialising trading economies <strong>and</strong> China. From 1948 to 2000,<br />

Japan increased its share of global export from 0.4% to 7.7% <strong>and</strong> six<br />

Asian traders (see Table 1.2) increased their share from 3% to<br />

10.5%. In the last quarter of the 20th century, China increased its<br />

share of global exports from 1.2% in 1983 to 4.3% in 2001, with a<br />

strong momentum for further gains of market share in the future<br />

(see Table 1.2).<br />

In 2001, the US current account deficit (net capital import)<br />

reached $393.4 billion. On the other side, current account surplus<br />

(net capital export) was $87.8 billion for Japan, $57.1 billion for the<br />

six Asian traders, $17.4 billion for China, <strong>and</strong> $39.6 for transition<br />

economies (see Table 4.7). Except for Japan, many countries with a<br />

current account surplus (net capital exporters) are not capital-rich<br />

economies. In 2000, according to the IMF, the US absorbed 64% of<br />

global net capital exports (i.e. the sum of the current account<br />

surpluses of the rest of the world).<br />

Who is financing the net capital import to the United States?<br />

Table 4.10 shows the exports, imports <strong>and</strong> balance of goods account<br />

for the US in 2002. The US goods deficit, which is the major part of<br />

its current account deficit, is as high as $484 billion. The US goods<br />

account deficit is financed by <strong>and</strong> distributed among the rest of the<br />

world: 18% by North America, 18% by Western Europe, 14.5% by<br />

Japan, <strong>and</strong> 21.3% by China. The importance of China in US trade<br />

deficits is at the centre of the globalisation debate. Is China taking<br />

away jobs from American workers or financing American<br />

consumers? Is China generating global deflation? Is China saving<br />

too much? Should China revaluate its currency? We discuss these<br />

questions later.<br />

Due to rapid regional integration of production through the socalled<br />

supply chain management, China’s strong export performance<br />

is intimately related to the export activities of its neighbours.<br />

This modern management model, pioneered by Hong Kong<br />

1<br />

All tables <strong>and</strong> graphs are at the end of this chapter.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

117<br />

entrepreneurs, sepa<strong>rate</strong>s the whole value-added chain into different<br />

parts <strong>and</strong> searches for the best deals in distribution <strong>and</strong> production<br />

among global providers of production <strong>and</strong> services. This innovation<br />

makes our traditional concept of “made-in-China” or “made-in-<br />

Japan” much less relevant as many parts of final goods <strong>and</strong> services<br />

are produced or provided by countries other than the one where<br />

final goods are exported.<br />

Table 4.9 <strong>and</strong> Graph 5.2 show the rising US current account<br />

deficits with the greater China, including Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> Taiwan.<br />

It is clear that the part of trade deficits attributable to Hong Kong<br />

<strong>and</strong> Taiwan are either declining or stabilising while the part due to<br />

China is rising rapidly. This is largely because the production of<br />

final goods has been rapidly relocated to China from Hong Kong,<br />

Taiwan <strong>and</strong> other Asian economies over the last decade. But the key<br />

components or high value-added parts of the supply chain are still<br />

kept in the more developed Asian economies. If this part of the<br />

contribution to the production of final goods is excluded, China’s<br />

own value added in exports to the US would be very small. This<br />

point needs to be remembered as we attempt to assess China’s<br />

impact on the world. About two-thirds of China’s FDI is coming<br />

from its neighbours such as Hong Kong, Macao, Taiwan, Japan,<br />

Singapore <strong>and</strong> Korea, in part for the purpose of assembling final<br />

products to be exported to North America <strong>and</strong> Europe.<br />

Steady FDI Flows into China<br />

Foreign direct investment is much more volatile than foreign trade,<br />

but it is becoming increasingly important in recent decades for both<br />

developed <strong>and</strong> developing countries. The growth <strong>rate</strong> for global<br />

FDI fluctuated widely from 56.7% in 1999 to -50.7% in 2001,<br />

averaging about 16.3% in the last two decades. As a result of rapid<br />

FDI growth, global FDI flows as a percentage of global merch<strong>and</strong>ise<br />

trade increased from about 1.5% in the early 1980s to between 6%<br />

<strong>and</strong> 12% in the last five years. But the scale of global FDI flows is<br />

still much smaller than the global service trade, which is about 23%<br />

of merch<strong>and</strong>ise trade. At its peak in 2000, global FDI reached $1.5<br />

trillion, or about 15% of the United States’ GDP (Table 1.1).<br />

Most of global FDI, especially FDI among developed countries,<br />

is through mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions (M&A) rather than green-field<br />

investment. In 2001, M&A amounted to as much as 80% of global<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


118<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

FDI. Among all the M&A in 2001, 83.5% was conducted in the<br />

developed countries, 31.1% in the US alone, <strong>and</strong> only 5.8% in Asia<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Pacific region.<br />

Developed countries are key hosts of FDI with their share of<br />

global FDI at levels ranging from 60% to 80%. At the regional<br />

level, North America has been exp<strong>and</strong>ing its market share at the<br />

costs of European countries although the latter have been picking<br />

up in the late 1990.<br />

Graph 5.1 shows the trend since 1979 of FDI inflows to US,<br />

China, Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific region, <strong>and</strong> all developing countries<br />

excluding China. The US has been dominating the global FDI<br />

inflows with its share ranging from 11.2% or $19 billion in 1992 to<br />

26% or $283 billion in 1999. Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific region have<br />

increased their market share from 15.2% in 1991 to 24.3% in 1996,<br />

but the Asian financial crisis depressed their share to only 9% in<br />

2000.<br />

China’s share of global FDI increased from a low base of 1.7% in<br />

1990 to a peak of 13% in 1994. After 1994, China’s share of global<br />

FDI declined steadily to only 2.7% in 2000 largely due to massive<br />

M&A activities in the developed economies during the tech bubble.<br />

After the burst of the tech bubble, global FDI dropped 50% in 2001<br />

but China’s FDI was growing steadily, contributing to a recovery of<br />

China’s share in global FDI to 6.4%, which is consistent with its<br />

trade expansion to 4.3% of the global export by 2001.<br />

FDI into China has exceeded $40 billion since 1996 <strong>and</strong> has been<br />

growing steadily every year since 1990. This puts pressure on other<br />

developing countries, especially its Asian neighbours. As shown in<br />

Table 1.3, the Asia-7, including India, Indonesia, Malaysia,<br />

Philippines, Republic of Korea, Singapore, <strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong>, with more<br />

population than China, only had $33 billion FDI inflows at their<br />

peak year of 1997. After the Asian financial crisis in 1997-1998, the<br />

Asia-7’s FDI inflows declined dramatically to only $18 billion by<br />

2001. The Asian financial crisis however did not slow FDI flows into<br />

the developing economies as a whole. FDI into developing economies<br />

excluding China recorded a steady growth from $34 billion in<br />

1990 to $147 billion in 1997, <strong>and</strong> peaked at $197 billion in 2000,<br />

<strong>and</strong> then fell to $158 billion in 2001.<br />

In 2001, per capita FDI inflows are $120 for the world, $420 for<br />

the developed economies, $42 for the developing economies<br />

excluding China, $37 for China, <strong>and</strong> only $12 for the Asia-7.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

119<br />

Apparently China is winning the competition for FDI inflows <strong>and</strong><br />

its neighbours are very much concerned about this trend.<br />

Table 1.6 shows inward FDI stocks for selected regions <strong>and</strong><br />

countries over the period from 1980 to 2001. Global FDI stock<br />

increased from $636 billion in 1980 to $6258 billion in 2000, an<br />

increase of almost ten times. During the same period, the world<br />

trade volume only increased about three-folds from $4 trillion in<br />

1980 to $12.5 trillion in 2000. This clearly shows the increasing<br />

importance of FDI in the world economy <strong>and</strong> the exp<strong>and</strong>ing scope<br />

<strong>and</strong> depth of globalisation.<br />

However, the access to foreign capital is unequal with 5 billion<br />

out of a 6.1 billion world population in the developing countries<br />

receiving only $2.1 trillion out of $6.8 trillion in the FDI stock by<br />

2001. In 2001, per capita FDI stock is $1,118 for the world, $3,763<br />

for the developed economies, $478 for all developing economies<br />

excluding China, $309 for China, <strong>and</strong> only $220 for the Asia-7.<br />

The developed economies provided most of the global FDI stock<br />

but its share is declining from 95.8% in 1980 to 87.8% in 2001. In<br />

the last decade, Hong Kong emerged as a major financial centre for<br />

facilitating capital flows into China. Hong Kong’s outward FDI<br />

stock increased from $2.3 billion in 1985 to $375 billion in 2001,<br />

exceeding Japan’s $300 billion. In 2001, Hong Kong captured 5.7%<br />

of global FDI outward stock, compared with only 4.6% for Japan. A<br />

significant part of Hong Kong’s outward FDI into China is “roundtripping”<br />

Chinese capital, perhaps as much as one-quarter (World<br />

Bank, 2002, p. 41).<br />

The pattern of global FDI flows raises a few core questions. Is<br />

China attracting too much FDI? Is China hurting its Asian<br />

neighbours <strong>and</strong> competitors? These questions can only be discussed<br />

meaningfully after examining many special development conditions<br />

in China.<br />

Two-Way Flows in Cross-Border Portfolio Investment<br />

Based on the recent Global Portfolio Investment Survey by the IMF<br />

(Table 2.1), the derived portfolio investment liabilities for the world<br />

in 2001 are $12.5 trillion, about twice the amount of the global FDI<br />

stock <strong>and</strong> almost equal to the sum of global merch<strong>and</strong>ise exports <strong>and</strong><br />

imports. The IMF survey is so far the best estimate on the stock of<br />

global portfolio investment. Compared to IMF’s last survey for<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


120<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

1997, the global portfolio investment stock doubled in only four<br />

years. The top three targets for portfolio investment stock are very<br />

stable, including the US, UK <strong>and</strong> Germany, sharing 24.5%, 10%,<br />

<strong>and</strong> 9.2% of the global total respectively. Japan fell from the fourth<br />

place in 1997 to the sixth in 2001, now behind France <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. Japan’s share dropped from 6.5% in 1997 to 4.2% in<br />

2001, reflecting its weakening economy (see Table 2.1).<br />

China made little progress in attracting foreign portfolio<br />

investment during 1997 to 2001. The derived amount of foreign<br />

portfolio investment in China increased slightly from $19.3 to<br />

$20.1, reflecting its stagnant “B shares” market, which is a tiny<br />

experimental stock market designed for foreign investors with share<br />

prices quoted <strong>and</strong> traded in foreign exchange.<br />

In March 2001, China opened its “B share” market to domestic<br />

residents with foreign exchange savings. This opening caused a brief<br />

surge in prices <strong>and</strong> many foreign investors took profits <strong>and</strong> dumped<br />

many shares to domestic residents. At the end of 2002, China<br />

announced its plan to allow the Qualified Foreign Institutional<br />

Investors (QFII) to invest in its “A share” market designed for<br />

domestic investors with RMB savings. The Chinese authorities are<br />

also studying actively the mechanism of Qualified Domestic<br />

Institutional Investors (QDII), which would allow Chinese residents to<br />

invest in overseas securities markets, including Hong Kong markets,<br />

where many Chinese companies are listed but their shares cannot be<br />

sold to Chinese residents through legal channels. Compared to<br />

China’s inward FDI stock of $395 billion, its foreign portfolio<br />

investment stock of about $20 billion is insignificant. However, the<br />

potential for foreign investment in China’s securities market is bright<br />

as its stock market capitalisation is almost the same as that of Hong<br />

Kong at $463 billion at the end of 2002, compared to $2 trillion in<br />

Japan <strong>and</strong> $11 trillion in the US. China’s financial sector is still<br />

underdeveloped <strong>and</strong> is the major bottleneck for China’s sustainable<br />

growth <strong>and</strong> development as will be discussed further in the next<br />

section. But with China’s commitment to WTO <strong>and</strong> its recent efforts<br />

on modernising its financial regulation <strong>and</strong> development, it is just a<br />

matter of time, perhaps as long as another decade, for China’s foreign<br />

portfolio investment to catch up with its FDI <strong>and</strong> foreign trade.<br />

To underst<strong>and</strong> the potential foreign portfolio investment in<br />

China, it is useful to take a look at the experiences of China’s more<br />

developed neighbours. This is possible by examining the bilateral<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

121<br />

long-term securities investment data collected <strong>and</strong> maintained by<br />

the US Treasury. Since the US is the largest player as assets <strong>and</strong><br />

liabilities holder in cross-border portfolio investment, the picture we<br />

get from this data set should be illustrative. Some of the findings,<br />

such as China’s huge investment in US bonds, are not only<br />

surprising as new development but also have important implications<br />

for building global capital market order.<br />

Graph 6.1 shows the cross-border gross purchases <strong>and</strong> sales of<br />

stocks <strong>and</strong> bonds between the US <strong>and</strong> the rest of the world. Clearly<br />

the rest of the world traded much more US stocks <strong>and</strong> bonds than<br />

the US traded the rest of the world’s stocks <strong>and</strong> bonds. In the most<br />

recent period, the monthly gross purchases of US bonds by the rest<br />

of the world are in the range of $600 to $800 billion. The monthly<br />

gross purchases of US stocks by the rest of the world are in the<br />

range of $200 to $400 billion. The monthly gross purchases of<br />

foreign bonds or stocks by US residents, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, have<br />

never exceeded $200 billion. A similar pattern can be seen in Graph<br />

6.3 for the cross-border trading of stocks <strong>and</strong> bonds between the US<br />

<strong>and</strong> Asia. Asia’s love with US bonds went back to the 1980s. Asian<br />

countries have accumulated large amounts of net holdings of US<br />

bonds, led by Japan <strong>and</strong> followed now by China.<br />

Table 2.2 to 2.5 show the summary trends on cross-border<br />

trading of long-term securities between the US <strong>and</strong> major Asian<br />

economies. The transaction data reported monthly are added up to<br />

get the annual numbers. The net purchases are derived by<br />

subtracting the gross sales from gross purchases. During the ten<br />

years from 1988 to 1997, Asia’s net purchases of US bonds reached<br />

$415 billion, compared to $1.447 billion by the rest of the world. In<br />

2001, Asia’s net purchases of US bonds were as high as $147 billion,<br />

compared to $405 billion by the rest of the world. China’s net<br />

purchases of US bonds in 2001 were as much as Japan’s at about<br />

$52 billion. Both Japan <strong>and</strong> China have increased their net<br />

purchases of US bonds after the Asian financial crisis. During the<br />

ten years from 1988 to 1997, China’s net purchases of US bonds<br />

were only 11.5% of the Asia total. But it increased to 23% in 1999,<br />

19% in 2000, <strong>and</strong> 35.2% in 2001. Given China’s $280 billion official<br />

reserves <strong>and</strong> about $260 non-official reserves foreign exchange<br />

credit in the banking system, China’s increased net purchases of US<br />

bonds are inevitable. But it is still surprising to know that China’s<br />

share is as much as 35.2% of the Asia total.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


122<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 4.8 also shows a summary account of China’s balance of<br />

payments since 1982. Two items are related to China’s capital<br />

outflows. One is the current account surplus <strong>and</strong> the other is the<br />

errors <strong>and</strong> omissions. China’s accumulated current account surplus<br />

since 1982 reached $135 billion while the accumulated errors <strong>and</strong><br />

omissions since 1982 were even higher at $140 billion, both at about<br />

12% of GDP. Table 4.8 also shows China’s external debt at the end<br />

of 2001 was only about $170 billion or 14.7% of GDP. Clearly<br />

China is putting a lot of official <strong>and</strong> private savings in US dollars.<br />

Why? A simple explanation is property rights! Like other foreign<br />

investors in US assets, the Chinese government <strong>and</strong> the Chinese<br />

people certainly believe that the property rights of their US<br />

investment are well protected. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, China also<br />

provides better protection for property rights in FDI in China than<br />

on domestic assets. Hence, on the whole, both sides are happy <strong>and</strong><br />

better protection of property rights enhances value <strong>and</strong> productivity<br />

of capital.<br />

It is interesting to note that the private foreign bank lending to<br />

China is not as important as FDI. This can be seen from the<br />

changes in cross-border banking capital flows between Hong Kong<br />

<strong>and</strong> Mainl<strong>and</strong> China during the last decade. As shown in Graph 5.3<br />

<strong>and</strong> Table 4.11, Hong Kong used to be an important centre in Asia<br />

for making syndicated loans to China <strong>and</strong> other Asian economies.<br />

From 1994 to 1999, Hong Kong was a net lender of banking capital<br />

to Mainl<strong>and</strong> China. After 2000, however, Hong Kong turned into a<br />

net borrower of banking capital from Mainl<strong>and</strong> China. Since 1997,<br />

there has been a steady decline in Mainl<strong>and</strong>’s gross banking<br />

liabilities to Hong Kong from more than $50 billion in 1997 to less<br />

than 20 billion after 2001. This was triggered by the bankruptcy of<br />

the GITIC (Guangdong International Trust <strong>and</strong> Investment<br />

Corporation), which borrowed from foreign banks in Hong Kong<br />

with the implicit underst<strong>and</strong>ing that the Chinese government would<br />

guarantee the loans. The Chinese government, however, decided<br />

not to use its money to save this regional state-owned holding<br />

company in order to avoid moral hazard problem in similar cases for<br />

other companies <strong>and</strong> in the future. After the GITIC bankruptcy,<br />

foreign banks became very cautious in extending syndicated loans to<br />

China.<br />

During the Asian financial crisis in 1997, Hong Kong suffered a<br />

huge withdrawal of foreign banking capital. Hong Kong’s foreign<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

123<br />

banking funds fell from $630 billion in June 1997 to $250 billion<br />

by April 2002, a drop of 60%. Among the total withdrawal of<br />

$380 billion, $251 is by Japan (see Table 4.11). In spite of fluctuations<br />

in capital flows, Hong Kong’s banks have been extremely resilient<br />

during <strong>and</strong> after the crisis with NPLs staying no more than 5%.<br />

During the Asian financial crisis, short-term capital flows were<br />

blamed as a driver for financial market instability. Hence, there have<br />

been calls for caution on liberalisation of capital accounts <strong>and</strong><br />

portfolio investment. The role of foreign investors in the stability of<br />

local markets becomes an interesting topic. Graphs 6.3 to 6.8<br />

examine this issue using data after the Asian financial crisis <strong>and</strong> show<br />

a strong negative correlation between the size of trading by foreign<br />

investors <strong>and</strong> the level of the local stock market turnover. What it<br />

means is that, at least, during the non-crisis period, the participation<br />

of foreign investors in the Asian local stock markets enhances the<br />

local market stability: the lower the local turnover, the higher the<br />

share of trading by the US investors. This pattern appears in Japan,<br />

Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, Korea, <strong>and</strong> even the tiny “B share”<br />

market of Mainl<strong>and</strong> China. It appears that the US investment,<br />

probably helped by their institutional investors, is more rational<br />

than that of the local investors.<br />

2 China’s Structural <strong>and</strong> Institutional Conditions for FDI<br />

In spite of the large volume of literature on China’s foreign trade<br />

<strong>and</strong> investment by scholars (Lardy, 2002), investment bank<br />

economists (Lehman Brothers, 2002 <strong>and</strong> Goldman Sachs, 2003),<br />

<strong>and</strong> international organisations (OECD, 2002), in our view, the<br />

implications of recent development in China relating to its foreign<br />

trade <strong>and</strong> investment are not appreciated properly in their scale,<br />

scope <strong>and</strong> depth. This is partly due to China’s many unique<br />

development conditions as well as an inclination to use the st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

equilibrium tools of economics to deal with intrinsically a<br />

disequilibrium problem of development with unlimited supply of<br />

cheap labour in China <strong>and</strong> other developing economies. This<br />

section examines this Lewis type dual-sector development issue in<br />

order to answer many of the questions raised in the previous<br />

questions. The Lewis model of dual-sector development has many<br />

new implications when the cross-border mobility of capital <strong>and</strong><br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


124<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

capitalist institutions become possible for a country as large as onefifth<br />

of the world in terms of population.<br />

Development Gaps <strong>and</strong> Unlimited Supply of Labour<br />

China is large with one-fifth of the world’s population. China’s<br />

labour force is larger than the sum in all developed economies.<br />

China’s total GDP at purchasing power parity prices is about $5<br />

trillion, or roughly half of the United States’ GDP at current prices.<br />

However, China’s GDP at current prices is much smaller, about<br />

one-fourth of Japan’s <strong>and</strong> one-tenth of US’s. However, for some<br />

manufacturing products, China’s market share can be more than<br />

50% of the global total. The size of China allows it to enjoy<br />

economies of scale <strong>and</strong> scope. China can afford to have all major<br />

global auto producers set up joint-venture production bases inside<br />

China. However, China’s size in monetary terms is limited by the<br />

extremely low market prices its labour <strong>and</strong> products have to face<br />

now <strong>and</strong> for the next decade or so, a fact of life due to its effectively<br />

unlimited supply of labour.<br />

As shown in Table 3.4, in global context, China’s population is<br />

mature, not too young <strong>and</strong> not too old, with 70% in working age of<br />

15 to 65. China currently has only 7% population above age 65 <strong>and</strong><br />

23% under age 15.<br />

China’s population compares favourably with both the aging<br />

population in the developed economies <strong>and</strong> the less than mature<br />

population in developing economies. The share of working age<br />

population in China is among the highest at 70%, compared with<br />

only 60% in other less developed countries <strong>and</strong> 67% in developed<br />

countries.<br />

The old age population in the developed countries reaches 15%,<br />

or eight percent higher than in China. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the<br />

population under 15 in other less developed countries is as high as<br />

36%, or 13 percent higher than in China.<br />

Compared with both the developed <strong>and</strong> the other less developed<br />

countries, China’s population structure in the past two decades <strong>and</strong><br />

next two decades is particularly favourable for rapid growth in<br />

China, independent of other <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> institutional factors. China’s<br />

advantage in population structure during these decades is further<br />

enhanced by globalisation <strong>and</strong> the sustained prosperity in the<br />

developed economies after World War II. Large amounts of<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

125<br />

retirement savings from the aging <strong>and</strong> rich economies accumulated<br />

in the last half-century need to be invested in young, growing <strong>and</strong><br />

productive economies such as China.<br />

China’s population structure today is almost the same as Japan’s<br />

in 1975. Japan’s outst<strong>and</strong>ing growth performance during the one<strong>and</strong>-half<br />

decades since 1975 could suggest that China should have at<br />

least one more decade to enjoy the favourable population structure<br />

for growth. However, Japan’s lost decade since 1990 also reminds<br />

China of the challenges ahead. China has a window of opportunities<br />

to reform its financial <strong>and</strong> legal system in the next decade to deal<br />

with its future aging problem.<br />

China is poor <strong>and</strong> has effectively unlimited supply of cheap,<br />

mature <strong>and</strong> educated labour at least for the next one or two decades.<br />

China’s per capita GDP at purchasing power parity prices of 2000 is<br />

$3,920, slightly higher than the average for other less developed<br />

countries at $3,470, but well below the level of $22,060 for the<br />

developed countries. If using per capita GDP as a rough estimate for<br />

average wage, China’s average wage at PPP would be about $1.86 an<br />

hour ($3,920/[12mX22dX8h]). Since China’s GDP per capita at<br />

current prices is only about $1,000, China’s average wage at current<br />

prices would be only $0.47 an hour, compared to $10 an hour for<br />

the developed economies under the same assumption.<br />

At an average wage of less than half a dollar an hour, China has<br />

added 150 million non-farm jobs over the last two decades <strong>and</strong><br />

reduced the number of people with income less than $1 a day by<br />

150 million. This number, i.e. 150 million, is as large as the entire<br />

population of Western Europe <strong>and</strong> its Western Offshoots (including<br />

US, Canada, <strong>and</strong> Australia) in 1820 <strong>and</strong> is more than twice the<br />

net migration to the Western Offshoots during the 129 years from<br />

1870 to 1998 (Maddison 2001, p. 28). With this unprecedented<br />

achievement in employment creation, China still needs to create at<br />

least the same amount (150 million) of non-farm jobs perhaps over<br />

the next one to two decades.<br />

China’s case clearly fits well into W. Arthur Lewis’s dual-sector<br />

economic development model of unlimited supply of labour except<br />

that the Lewis model has never been applied seriously to an<br />

economy as large <strong>and</strong> as open as the Chinese economy today. Also,<br />

China has made great progress not only in providing primary<br />

education for most of school age kids but also in higher education.<br />

China produces more engineers in one year than Taiwan <strong>and</strong> Hong<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


126<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Kong could do in ten to twenty years. Hence, China has not only<br />

unlimited supply of cheap labour but also unlimited cheap talents.<br />

This is confirmed by the fact that it is now more <strong>and</strong> more difficult<br />

for China’s college graduates to find good jobs. China’s top<br />

executive MBA programmes are as expensive as Hong Kong’s.<br />

China’s overseas students have been putting pressures on their<br />

classmates from other foreign countries.<br />

Cross-Border Mobility of Capital <strong>and</strong> Capitalist Institutions<br />

China’s economy is open, in many ways much more open than<br />

today’s Japanese economy. China attracted much more FDI flows<br />

<strong>and</strong> stocks than Japan. In 2001, Japan, with its half a century long<br />

rapid economic growth <strong>and</strong> development, attracted only $49 per<br />

capita in FDI flows <strong>and</strong> $395 per capita in FDI stock, compared to<br />

the world average of $120 in flow <strong>and</strong> $1,118 in stock <strong>and</strong> China’s<br />

$37 in flow <strong>and</strong> $309 in stock. At official exchange <strong>rate</strong>s, China’s<br />

foreign trade is more than 40% of GDP while Japan’s is about 20%.<br />

China allows a large amount of processing trade, which requires a<br />

large amount of imported components. Large scale processing trade<br />

is only possible for very open economies with close to zero<br />

transaction costs, including tariffs <strong>and</strong> other taxes. China has<br />

committed itself to this close to zero transaction costs for processing<br />

trade since early 1980s, drawing lessons from its successful<br />

neighbours of newly industrialised Asian traders.<br />

China’s experiences in opening up its economy have effectively<br />

relaxed two crucial assumptions in international trade <strong>and</strong> development<br />

theories: the mobility of capital <strong>and</strong> the replication of capitalist<br />

institutions. Capital is mobile across the Chinese borders on a large<br />

scale now as our review in the previous sections show. Traditional trade<br />

theories based on factor immobility needs to be modified to take<br />

capital mobility into account. For example, capital-intensive industries<br />

such as auto <strong>and</strong> IC manufacturing can be profitable in China because<br />

of the capital <strong>and</strong> technology brought in by FDI <strong>and</strong> MNCs. The<br />

development of these capital-intensive industries is not constrained by<br />

the lack of capital. Instead, it is determined by the total costs of<br />

internationally linked supply chains <strong>and</strong> the global dem<strong>and</strong>, including<br />

the dem<strong>and</strong> from China itself. Supply chain management theory <strong>and</strong><br />

global market equilibrium may be more important than the simple<br />

application of traditional trade, investment, <strong>and</strong> macro theories.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

127<br />

China’s imitation of capitalist economic institutions is also<br />

unprecedented in scale, scope, depth, <strong>and</strong> speed, ranging from<br />

central banks, modern public corporations, labour markets, stock<br />

markets, <strong>and</strong> social security systems. The transfer of capitalist<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> practices is facilitated greatly by the existence of<br />

mature market economies in the overseas Chinese communities in<br />

Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> Taiwan as well as large amount of returning<br />

overseas students <strong>and</strong> overseas Chinese business communities. In<br />

this regard, the recent success <strong>and</strong> failure of Japan, Korea <strong>and</strong> other<br />

Asian economies in development <strong>and</strong> modernisation also set useful<br />

examples for China.<br />

It is now possible for MNCs to combine unlimited supply of<br />

Chinese cheap labour <strong>and</strong> cheap talents with advanced international<br />

capital, technology <strong>and</strong> capitalist institutions by relocating some<br />

major parts of their production <strong>and</strong> research in China. MNCs not<br />

only benefit from access to China’s domestic markets but also gain<br />

international competitiveness when they export some of their<br />

products from their China bases. Since China allows MNCs to have<br />

complete control on their China operations, they can get around<br />

China’s underdeveloped financial <strong>and</strong> legal systems, at least for their<br />

day-to-day operation. In other words, their risks of operation in<br />

China are much lower than in other places in the region.<br />

China’s rapid improvement in infrastructure over the last two<br />

decades is also an important factor in attracting FDI. This is<br />

especially relevant for a few key economic centres along the eastern<br />

coast, including the Pearl River Delta region around Guangdong<br />

<strong>and</strong> Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> the Yangtze River Delta region around<br />

Shanghai. China now has more telephone lines than the US. Its<br />

highway length is second only to that in the US <strong>and</strong> will form a<br />

complete national network connecting all major cities across China<br />

after the current five-year plan. Satellites are used not only for<br />

television but also for clearing <strong>and</strong> settlements in banking <strong>and</strong><br />

securities transactions. Hong Kong has the world’s busiest seaport<br />

<strong>and</strong> airport, h<strong>and</strong>ling 60% of China’s container shipments.<br />

However, major port development planned in Shanghai <strong>and</strong><br />

Guangzhou are likely to increase their capacity to Hong Kong’s<br />

current level in one or two decades. This rapid improvement in<br />

infrastructure is coordinated by China’s forward-looking planning<br />

authorities <strong>and</strong> led by innovative local leaders. China’s population<br />

structure <strong>and</strong> its low level of development also allow fast catching up<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


128<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

of investment in infrastructure. China’s obsession with infrastructure<br />

investment is also encouraged by a generation of leaders<br />

with engineering backgrounds who see investment in infrastructure<br />

as much more valuable than investment in loss-making state-owned<br />

enterprises. China’s government-directed infrastructure projects<br />

may not make profits but will certainly facilitate the mobility of<br />

labour, goods, <strong>and</strong> capital across China’s vast western, inl<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

coastal regions. They have laid a good physical foundation for<br />

China’s further integration with the global market economy.<br />

However, in the near future, China’s financial <strong>and</strong> legal systems<br />

will come under great pressure to price the risks <strong>and</strong> returns for<br />

millions of large <strong>and</strong> small projects, which would challenge even the<br />

best bankers in the world. In spite of great achievements in<br />

legislation, the legal system is still weak in the enforcement of<br />

property rights <strong>and</strong> contracts. This weakness directly affects the<br />

robustness <strong>and</strong> efficiency of China’s banking sector <strong>and</strong> capital<br />

markets.<br />

China’s financial system is efficient in generating savings but is<br />

not effective in allocating them to productive investment. China’s<br />

banking deposits increased from about 30% to 160% over the last<br />

two decades. However, about 20% to 30% of these deposits have<br />

difficulty finding productive investment outlets. A substantial part of<br />

China’s surplus deposits ended up in government bonds. The local<br />

governments are then forced to invest these funds in infrastructure<br />

projects in order to keep the economy growing at 8% a year.<br />

The flood of savings in China’s banking system is partly due to a<br />

loose monetary <strong>policy</strong> during the early 1990s <strong>and</strong> after the Asian<br />

financial crisis. China’s money supply (M2) increased ten times from<br />

1990 to 2001 while its nominal GDP rose only five times during the<br />

same period. Hence, China’s money supply is growing twice as fast<br />

as its nominal GDP. China’s NPLs is in the range of 25% to 55% of<br />

GDP by the official <strong>and</strong> private estimations. However, China’s<br />

banking system is still stable for a number of reasons. First, the<br />

government is still the owner of most banks in China <strong>and</strong> is<br />

determined to reform its state-owned banks. So, the Chinese people<br />

do not feel any risks to their bank deposits. Second, the Chinese<br />

economy, although growing at 8% a year, still has ample surplus<br />

labour <strong>and</strong> other unemployed resources, which are looking for<br />

employment opportunities following two decades of a gradual but<br />

steady loosening of migration policies <strong>and</strong> control of private<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

129<br />

enterprises. Third, China’s capital account is not open for its<br />

domestic RMB deposit holders.<br />

The traditional equilibrium model may not be useful for<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing China’s <strong>macroeconomic</strong> conditions because of<br />

China’s disequilibrium in the labour markets with unlimited supply<br />

of labour. Unlike the situations in Japan <strong>and</strong> the newly industrialised<br />

Asian economies, where the supply of labour quickly hit the limits<br />

with wages shooting up, China’s market wages for the unskilled<br />

labour in major manufacturing centres such as Guangdong have<br />

been stagnant at a subsistence level of around $100 a month for<br />

more than a decade.<br />

China’s weak <strong>and</strong> inefficient financial system is creating a puzzle<br />

of co-existence of surplus labour <strong>and</strong> capital. For 16 out of the 21<br />

years since 1982, China ran current account surpluses, including the<br />

last 9 years. The accumulated sum since 1982 of China’s current<br />

account surpluses <strong>and</strong> the errors <strong>and</strong> omissions reached 23.8% of<br />

GDP in 2001. As China reforms its financial system <strong>and</strong> opens up its<br />

financial sector under the WTO commitment, the efficiency <strong>and</strong><br />

speed of China’s integration into the world economy will be<br />

improved steadily. This implies that more <strong>and</strong> more of China’s<br />

labour will work directly or indirectly for the global market<br />

although their wages will be kept from rising due to ample surplus<br />

labour. This trend of development in China is determined by the<br />

interaction between China’s structural <strong>and</strong> institutional features <strong>and</strong><br />

prompts us to further examine the role of China as a world factory<br />

<strong>and</strong> as a regional competitor in the next section.<br />

3 Implications for the Rest of the World<br />

To appreciate the impact of China’s development <strong>and</strong> integration<br />

into the global economy, it is useful to review the history of global<br />

capitalist development as articulated by Angus Maddison. For<br />

thous<strong>and</strong>s of years before 1000, the global economy was stagnant<br />

but living st<strong>and</strong>ards as measured by GDP per capita were pretty<br />

much equal across regions. During the first millennium, per capita<br />

GDP of the world declined slightly from $444 to $435 (at the 1990<br />

international prices for this <strong>and</strong> all other numbers cited from<br />

Maddison, 2001) while world population increased only from 231 to<br />

268 million.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


130<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

During the period from 1000 to 1820, global economic growth<br />

picked up but slowly. Although the world population increased from<br />

268 million to 1 billion, average per capita GDP for the world<br />

increased only from $435 to $667. The world started to diverge in<br />

development <strong>and</strong> income during this period. By 1820, the first<br />

world, including Western Europe, Western Offshoots, <strong>and</strong> Japan,<br />

increased their per capita GDP to $21,470 while the rest of the<br />

world, or the third world, only had a per capita GDP level of $573.<br />

From 1820 to 1998, a great divergence in development <strong>and</strong><br />

inequality in income emerged between the first <strong>and</strong> the third world.<br />

The share of population in the first world declined from 16.8% to<br />

14.2% but its share of GDP increased from 28.5% to 53.4%. By<br />

1998, world population reached 5.9 billion with 5.1 billion in the<br />

third world, including 1.2 billion in China.<br />

The above are the global conditions under which W. Arthur<br />

Lewis developed his dual-sector theory on economic development<br />

under unlimited supply of labour (Lewis, 1954). Lewis pointed out<br />

that the non-capitalist traditional sector in the rural area provides a<br />

reservoir for unlimited supply of labour at a fixed urban wage<br />

slightly higher than the subsistence rural wage. The urban wage is<br />

checked not only by the surplus labour in the rural area but also by<br />

rising unemployment in the urban area. This is exactly the condition<br />

we see in China now. China’s leaders have been working hard to<br />

raise the income for peasants. But that is a mission impossible with<br />

the Lewis type development reality.<br />

Lewis also points out that the capitalist modern sector is able to<br />

gene<strong>rate</strong> profits <strong>and</strong> net savings for investment in capital that is<br />

critical for sustained growth. He cites the evidences from Britain<br />

where net savings increased from 5% before 1780 to 7% in early<br />

1800s, <strong>and</strong> 12% around 1870. Similar rises of net savings are also<br />

observed in the US between 1840s <strong>and</strong> 1890s, <strong>and</strong> in Asia after<br />

World War II. Consistent with the Lewis dual-sector model,<br />

Britain’s Manchester, US’s New Engl<strong>and</strong>, New York, <strong>and</strong> Chicago,<br />

Japan’s Tokyo <strong>and</strong> Osaka, <strong>and</strong> cities in Asia’s newly industrialised<br />

economies have become the world factories one by one over time.<br />

Now, the centre of global manufacturing is once again on the move<br />

towards low costs economies. This time it goes to China’s<br />

Guangdong <strong>and</strong> Shanghai, where access to unlimited supply of<br />

labour is facilitated by low transportation <strong>and</strong> declining transaction<br />

costs.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

131<br />

China as a World Factory: Changes in Global Relative Prices<br />

There is little disagreement on the trend that China will become a<br />

world factory. Instead, the debates are on the impact of that trend on<br />

the rest of the world. In our view, the single most important impact<br />

of China’s outst<strong>and</strong>ing development performance is on changes in<br />

global relative prices. There is no doubt that new labour supply to<br />

the global market will lead to a secular fall in the prices of labourintensive<br />

manufacturing products.<br />

Before China’s opening up, the world economy was largely a<br />

capitalist open market economy dominated by the developed<br />

economies. The majority of the third world population, including<br />

those in China, were not very relevant to this global market. Let’s use<br />

the population of age 15 to 65 in Table 3.4 to estimate the impact of<br />

China’s opening on the labour supply in the world market. The<br />

world’s working population at age 15 to 65 is 896 million in China,<br />

2,242 million in other less developed countries, <strong>and</strong> 802 million in<br />

more developed countries. Let’s assume for simplicity that about onequarter<br />

of the labour force in China (224 million) <strong>and</strong> other less<br />

developed countries (560 million) are working for the world market<br />

now while the rest are effectively isolated from the world market.<br />

Then, the total labour force working for the world market today<br />

would be 1,586 million (224m+560m+802m). Since China’s labour<br />

force was entirely outside of the global market twenty years ago,<br />

China’s opening has added 224 million to the 1,363 million<br />

(560m+802m) labour force that have already been integ<strong>rate</strong>d into the<br />

global market. That is a net addition of about 16.4% over two<br />

decades. If China’s past success in integrating its labour into the global<br />

market can be continued <strong>and</strong> replicated in other developing countries,<br />

the world market would certainly have no shortage of labour.<br />

It is clear that the additional supply of China’s labour force to the<br />

global market has concent<strong>rate</strong>d in the manufacturing export sector.<br />

This means the global prices for manufacturing products have to<br />

fall dramatically. For example, the prices of televisions in the US<br />

have been dropping by 8% a year since 1988. The deflation in<br />

manufacturing products has started from the traditional labourintensive<br />

products such as toys, plastics, clothing but has been<br />

spreading to less labour-intensive products such as electronics <strong>and</strong><br />

machinery as China advances in its production <strong>and</strong> technology<br />

capability.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


132<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

As the Say’s law predicts, supply creates dem<strong>and</strong>, if there is a<br />

perfect market. China’s opening leads to growth in income <strong>and</strong><br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for final products. But it is clearly impossible for China to<br />

consume all of its manufacturing products such as televisions,<br />

DVDs, motorcycles, <strong>and</strong> bicycles. Because of China’s extremely low<br />

level of per capita wealth, the Chinese people’s savings <strong>rate</strong> has been<br />

as high as 40.3%, compared to 16.5% in the US, 20.3% in the<br />

European Union, 26% in developing countries, <strong>and</strong> 27.3% in Japan.<br />

China’s high savings depress its domestic current dem<strong>and</strong>. Hence,<br />

export is the most convenient way out <strong>and</strong> China’s export<br />

significantly depresses global prices on some specific products such<br />

as toys, televisions, <strong>and</strong> bicycles.<br />

China’s impact on deflation in the manufacturing products,<br />

however, is not going to cause a global deflation because the weight<br />

of manufacturing products made in China is too small in the total<br />

expenditure basket of the developed economies. China’s exports,<br />

which usually incorpo<strong>rate</strong> a high proportion of imported<br />

components, are only about 4.3% of the world total in 2001. There<br />

is a long way to go before China has a direct impact on global<br />

deflation.<br />

This is partly due to terms-of-trade effect. The more China<br />

exports, the lower the product prices, <strong>and</strong> the lower the share of<br />

China’s exports in the total expenditure of the developed economies,<br />

other things given.<br />

Anderson <strong>and</strong> Hu (2003) highlighted that China’s net export of<br />

manufacturing goods is negligible for causing global deflation in<br />

manufacturing prices. This is true but the large deflation effects on<br />

specific products are hidden within the net manufacturing exports.<br />

The export value is likely to be depressed because of falling prices<br />

on China’s export while the import value is likely to be high, partly<br />

due to stronger dem<strong>and</strong> from China for key components which<br />

China can not produce.<br />

In monetary terms, China’s impact on the rest of the world is<br />

small. But in terms of specific product prices <strong>and</strong> welfare, or the socalled<br />

consumer surplus, China’s contribution to the increase of the<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards of livings in both developed <strong>and</strong> developing countries is<br />

huge but invisible in statistics. Today’s lucky kids around the world<br />

can testify to this with their made-in-China toys. Without China’s<br />

production, most toys may cost five to ten times more.<br />

As we have emphasised, China’s impact is on changes in global<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

133<br />

relative prices. The deflation in manufacturing sector is accompanied<br />

by inflation in commodity <strong>and</strong> skills, which are needed to<br />

support the rapid increase in the volume of manufacturing goods<br />

<strong>and</strong> the rising living st<strong>and</strong>ards in China <strong>and</strong> elsewhere. China has<br />

turned from a net exporter of oil to a net importer <strong>and</strong> its imports of<br />

oil have increased steadily in the last decade to about 60 million tons<br />

a year by 2001. China’s net commodity imports since 1990s have<br />

tripled. China’s tuition for top rank executive MBA programmes is<br />

as high as in Hong Kong or even in the US.<br />

Changes in global relative prices are followed by structural<br />

changes in the global economy. The most important change is the<br />

shift of manufacturing to China. However, China is only becoming<br />

a platform for global manufacturing in order to take advantage<br />

of China’s favourable labour supply <strong>and</strong> domestic markets. It is<br />

clear that this competition is not between China <strong>and</strong> the foreign<br />

manufacturers. Instead, it is a competition among foreign manufacturers<br />

themselves with China only participating as a supply of<br />

labour <strong>and</strong> domestic markets. Foreign invested firms produce half of<br />

China’s exports with only a small part of the value-added going to<br />

China’s labour <strong>and</strong> with a high proportion of imported components.<br />

FDI in China concent<strong>rate</strong>d mainly in a few clusters of manufacturing<br />

bases in the coastal region (see Table 4.5). The unskilled<br />

labour for the export industry is, however, largely coming from poor<br />

<strong>and</strong> remote western <strong>and</strong> inl<strong>and</strong> regions of China.<br />

China’s development <strong>and</strong> integration with the capitalist world<br />

economy is not a miracle if we compare it with the industrialisation<br />

in the UK, the US, Japan, <strong>and</strong> the newly industrialised Asian<br />

economies. But the size <strong>and</strong> structure of China’s population <strong>and</strong> the<br />

mobility of capital <strong>and</strong> capitalist institutions – made possible by<br />

today’s advances in technology <strong>and</strong> development knowledge – make<br />

China’s case special, especially for many of its neighbours.<br />

China as a Regional Competitor: Benefits Versus Costs<br />

For many Asians, it is amazing that China weathered through the<br />

Asian financial crisis with few changes in its high growth <strong>rate</strong> of<br />

around 8%. Many are wondering whether China’s growth is at the<br />

costs of others by siphoning off market shares in foreign trade,<br />

investment <strong>and</strong> domestic jobs. There is no doubt that China has<br />

become a major competitor in the world market, especially for its<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


134<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Asian neighbours. The competitive pressure from China can best be<br />

seen from Table 1.6 on the share of global inward FDI stock. China<br />

increased its share from only 1% in 1980 <strong>and</strong> 1985 to 5.8% in 2001<br />

while the Asia-7, which has more population than China, did not<br />

gain much from 4.2% in 1980 to 4.8% in 2001. China’s per capita<br />

inward FDI stock reached $309 by 2001, moving towards Japan’s<br />

$395, <strong>and</strong> well above Asia-7’s $220. However, China’s per capita<br />

FDI stock is still less than the average for all developing countries,<br />

which is at $478. Table 1.3 shows per capita inward FDI flows <strong>and</strong><br />

gives similar pattern.<br />

China’s competitiveness in labour-intensive manufactures is well<br />

recognised <strong>and</strong> attracted 60% of China’s total FDI as shown in<br />

Table 4.3. However, FDI is also significant in the non-labourintensive<br />

real-estate sector that has 12% of China’s FDI. The<br />

services sector also attracted substantial FDI.<br />

What is particularly relevant for our discussion in this section is<br />

the concentration of China’s FDI in a few clusters of coastal super<br />

cities, which have critical mass for global scale production,<br />

distribution <strong>and</strong> financing.<br />

Table 4.5 ranks China’s 31 provincial level regions by their FDI<br />

inflows in 2001 <strong>and</strong> provides a number of indicators for the<br />

provincial economies. The provinces <strong>and</strong> cities are then divided into<br />

three groups by their ranking in FDI inflows: the top-9, the middle-<br />

12, <strong>and</strong> the bottom-10. The top-9 includes, in descending order of<br />

the share of average FDI during 2000-2001, Guangdong (25.7%),<br />

Jiangsu (14.9%), Shanghai (9.3%), Fujian (8.5%), Sh<strong>and</strong>ong (7.6%),<br />

Liaoning (5.4%), Zhejiang (4.8%), Tianjin (4.6%), <strong>and</strong> Beijing<br />

(3.8%). Many foreign visitors are impressed by the physical changes<br />

in the cities such as Shanghai <strong>and</strong> Beijing but the real stars of<br />

productive investment <strong>and</strong> manufacturing capacity in China are<br />

Guangdong <strong>and</strong> Jiangsu, where l<strong>and</strong> prices have not been driven up<br />

to international levels as in Hong Kong, Shanghai <strong>and</strong> Beijing while<br />

access to finance, research <strong>and</strong> other services provided by the big<br />

cities is still convenient.<br />

The concentration of economic activities in the top-9 is<br />

impressive, if not surprising. This group has about one-third of<br />

China’s population but produced half of China’s GDP, attracted<br />

three-quarters of China’s FDI, <strong>and</strong> gene<strong>rate</strong>d 90% of China’s<br />

foreign trade.<br />

The middle-12 includes mostly inl<strong>and</strong> provinces while the<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

135<br />

bottom-10 consists of all western provinces, the poorest region of<br />

China. The middle-12 has half of China’s population <strong>and</strong> one-third<br />

of China’s GDP but only attracted one-seventh of China’s FDI <strong>and</strong><br />

8% of China’s foreign trade. The bottom-10 has 18% of China’s<br />

population, 10% of GDP, 3% of foreign trade, <strong>and</strong> 1.8% of FDI.<br />

Given the diversity of China’s regions, it is natural to ask which<br />

parts of China we would like to compare with its neighbouring<br />

countries. With China’s huge population, it is also important to<br />

compare FDI per capita.<br />

In 2001, China’s top-9 attracted $97 per capita in FDI, much<br />

higher than the Asia-7 of $12. But the Asia-7 did much better than<br />

China’s middle-12 at $10 per capita <strong>and</strong> bottom-10 at $4 per capita.<br />

Both China’s inl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> western regions face similar concerns as<br />

the Asia-7 countries. They are working hard to improve their<br />

investment environment as well as lobby for more support from<br />

China’s central government. China’s central government is also<br />

working very hard to help the less developed regions, particularly<br />

through the “Go West” st<strong>rate</strong>gy. The central government has<br />

invested heavily in highways, railroads, airports <strong>and</strong> other<br />

infrastructural works in the western regions but their effects on<br />

attracting FDI did not gene<strong>rate</strong> the intended results. Instead, the<br />

poor people in the western <strong>and</strong> inl<strong>and</strong> regions continue to rush to<br />

the eastern coast for jobs, riding on the new roads built by the<br />

government. These unintended results, however, may be better than<br />

the plan, as the migrant labourers send remittances, knowledge, <strong>and</strong><br />

even skills they learnt in the big cities back to their hometowns.<br />

For the Asia-7, labour mobility to China’s eastern coast is out of<br />

question except for a few highly skilled professionals. But intraindustry<br />

trade is exp<strong>and</strong>ing as can be seen from the rising trade<br />

volume for the six Asian traders (Taiwan, Hong Kong, Korea,<br />

Malaysia, Singapore, <strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong>, re-export excluded; see Table<br />

1.2). While China’s share of global export increased from 2.5% in<br />

1993 to 4.0% in 2000, the six Asian traders’ share increased from<br />

9.7% to 10.5%. During the same period, Asia as a whole increased<br />

slightly its share of global exports from 26.3% to 26.7% with a<br />

significant decrease in Japan’s share from 10% to 7.7% <strong>and</strong> Australia<br />

<strong>and</strong> New Zeal<strong>and</strong>’s share from 1.5% to 1.2%.<br />

There is no doubt that China’s export growth is much faster than<br />

its neighbours’ as shown in Table 4.1. During 1990-2000, China’s<br />

export growth was 14.9%, compared to 8.4% for the export growth<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


136<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

in Asia. But it is due to two factors. First, China started from a very<br />

low share of only 2.5% of global trade in 1993. Even in 2001,<br />

China’s share of global exports was only 4.3%. Second, as discussed<br />

in the previous section, China’s exports include many components<br />

imported from Asian <strong>and</strong> Western economies. The value-added<br />

from China is small.<br />

Table 4.2 compares the market share in global manufactures<br />

exports in 1990 <strong>and</strong> 2000. This table should ease the concerns by<br />

China’s competitors in Asia a bit as it shows clearly that they can<br />

grow with China at the costs of more developed economies in terms<br />

of market shares in manufacture export. From 1990 to 2000, the<br />

developed economies lost 11 percentage points of market share in<br />

global manufactures exports. Asia’s gain is as high as 7.3 percentage<br />

points. China gained 2.3 percentage points while the six Asian<br />

traders gained 3.1 percentage points, more than the gain by China.<br />

The rest of Asia excluding China <strong>and</strong> the six Asian traders also<br />

gained 1.3 percentage points.<br />

Hence, China is not only a regional competitor but also an<br />

important partner in terms of the integration of Asia’s global-scale<br />

manufacturing. China not only has an unlimited supply of labour<br />

<strong>and</strong> talents but also large markets for consumer products <strong>and</strong><br />

manufacturing equipments <strong>and</strong> parts, which are all opportunities for<br />

its neighbours. Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> Taiwan are the first in seizing the<br />

opportunities, followed by the US, Europe, <strong>and</strong> Japan.<br />

The competitive pressures from China will not go away until<br />

most of China’s surplus labour is absorbed by the exp<strong>and</strong>ing modern<br />

sector. The key is how to best position oneself in the increasingly<br />

competitive global economy. The pressure to force China to revalue<br />

its currency would not affect China’s export competitiveness, simply<br />

because the real wage in China is not set by the nominal exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong>. China’s wages are extremely flexible at the low end. The real<br />

wage for unskilled labour is determined by the subsistence-level<br />

income in China’s rural areas. The reliable <strong>and</strong> sustainable way for<br />

China’s real wage to increase is to help China to develop its poor<br />

regions in the western <strong>and</strong> inl<strong>and</strong> provinces.<br />

However, a revaluation in RMB is likely to put large deflation<br />

pressure in the coastal regions’ real estate <strong>and</strong> services sectors as<br />

these modern sectors are already substantially integ<strong>rate</strong>d with the<br />

world economy. The price structure there, except for the wage of<br />

unskilled migrant labour, are much more sensitive to changes in<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

137<br />

nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>s. In particular, large amount of assets <strong>and</strong><br />

liabilities concent<strong>rate</strong>d in the more advanced regions of China are<br />

denominated in foreign exchange. Any attempt to adjust the<br />

currently fixed exchange <strong>rate</strong> of RMB would be equivalent to<br />

redistribution of wealth among holders of foreign exchange assets<br />

<strong>and</strong> liabilities, similar to redistribution among creditors <strong>and</strong> debtors<br />

during inflation or deflation. Given China’s sustained surplus in<br />

current account <strong>and</strong> rising official <strong>and</strong> private foreign exchange<br />

reserves, it is entirely creditable for China to maintain the current<br />

fixed exchange <strong>rate</strong> regime. Then, China can leave any <strong>adjustment</strong>s<br />

in real wages <strong>and</strong> other prices to domestic price <strong>adjustment</strong>s. Given<br />

China’s disequilibria in many markets, including the labour markets,<br />

China’s fixed exchange <strong>rate</strong> provides an anchor <strong>and</strong> a reference for<br />

gradually rationalising China’s price structure. Partly due to the<br />

fixed exchange <strong>rate</strong>, China’s price structure today is largely consistent<br />

with the requirement of a market economy.<br />

As discussed in the previous section, China’s current account<br />

surplus implies that China is exporting capital, which does not seem<br />

consistent with China’s unlimited supply of labour. Would a<br />

revaluation of RMB help to turn China’s current account surplus<br />

into balance or deficit? Not really! China’s excessive savings are not<br />

due to exchange <strong>rate</strong>s but are a result of its underdeveloped financial<br />

system, which is not able to identify good projects <strong>and</strong> enforce<br />

lending contracts. Revaluation of RMB would depress the best parts<br />

of the Chinese economy <strong>and</strong> lead to less lending <strong>and</strong> more surplus<br />

savings, <strong>and</strong> hence more current account surplus, just like what<br />

happened in Japan when the yen appreciated. So, for those who<br />

would like to see a reduction in current account surplus in China or<br />

Japan, they need to help China <strong>and</strong> Japan reform their financial<br />

system, <strong>and</strong> not tamper with the exchange <strong>rate</strong>s. After all, we all<br />

have learnt from the Keynesian <strong>and</strong> Monetarist debates about the<br />

neutrality of money <strong>and</strong> monetary <strong>policy</strong> in the long run. <strong>Exchange</strong><br />

<strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> is only part of the monetary <strong>policy</strong>. The role of China in<br />

the region <strong>and</strong> in the global financial system is real, not just a<br />

monetary phenomenon. The aging populations in Japan, Europe<br />

<strong>and</strong> the US also need real returns from their savings, not nominal or<br />

monetary illusions.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


138<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

4 Conclusion<br />

This paper reviews global capital flows <strong>and</strong> the position of China.<br />

We have found that the rapid FDI inflows into China, following its<br />

economic opening <strong>and</strong> reform, are essentially driven by two factors:<br />

China’s unlimited supply of labour <strong>and</strong> talents <strong>and</strong> China’s declining<br />

barriers for cross-border mobility of capital <strong>and</strong> capitalist institutions.<br />

The combination of China’s unlimited supply of labour with<br />

foreign capital under capitalist institutions is transforming China into<br />

a world factory much like what happened before in Europe, America,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Asia. The consequences of this are also similar to what we have<br />

seen in the past: a decline of prices for labour-intensive manufacturing<br />

products <strong>and</strong> a relative rise in the prices for raw materials <strong>and</strong> skills.<br />

The catching up of China in economic development provides<br />

competitive pressures as well as productive opportunities for the<br />

world <strong>and</strong> especially for its neighbours. The aging populations in<br />

the developed countries also need to rely on the much younger <strong>and</strong><br />

mature population in China <strong>and</strong> Asia to secure good returns on their<br />

retirement savings.<br />

However, due to the underdeveloped financial system in China<br />

<strong>and</strong> other developing economies, global savings have refused to flow<br />

into these developing economies with growth potential. Even China<br />

is having a net export of savings as the Chinese government <strong>and</strong><br />

people are accumulating foreign assets, especially US bonds <strong>and</strong><br />

stocks. The global savings <strong>and</strong> capital flows, although driven by<br />

structural factors such as the costs of labour, are hindered by<br />

institutional factors, such as the quality of domestic banks <strong>and</strong><br />

capital markets in the less developed countries. This flight to quality<br />

is partly responsible for the tech bubbles in the US <strong>and</strong> lies at the<br />

heart of volatility in global capital flows.<br />

The solution to these global mismatches in capital flows lies not<br />

in manipulating exchange <strong>rate</strong>s <strong>and</strong> other monetary tools, which<br />

cannot change the real wages <strong>and</strong> potential competitiveness of<br />

developing economies like China. Instead, developed economies<br />

need to focus on real development problems in the developing<br />

countries, which have more than 80% of the world’s population.<br />

FDI is successful in China largely because foreign investments do<br />

not rely on the domestic financial system <strong>and</strong> foreign investors have<br />

complete control over the companies they establish.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

139<br />

China has not yet become an engine of growth for the global<br />

economy in cash terms. However, in terms of GDP measured by<br />

PPP or the welfare of the global population or the global consumer<br />

surplus, China is becoming an engine of growth for the world. This<br />

is why we need to study China’s success <strong>and</strong> its problems seriously<br />

since they have profound implications for all of us.<br />

References<br />

Anderson, Jonathan <strong>and</strong> Fred Hu (2003), The Five Myths about China<br />

<strong>and</strong> the World, Goldman Sachs.<br />

International Monetary Fund (2002), World Economic Outlook, IMF,<br />

Washington D.C., September.<br />

International Monetary Fund (2003), Global Portfolio Investment<br />

Survey, IMF, Washington D.C.<br />

Lewis, W. Arthur (1954), Economic Development with Unlimited<br />

Supply of Labour, The Manchester School.<br />

Lardy, Nicholas R. (2002), Integrating China into the Global Economy,<br />

Brookings Institute Press, Washington D.C.<br />

Maddison, Angus (2001), The World Economy: A Millennial<br />

Perspective, OECD Development Centre, Paris.<br />

National Bureau of Statistics (2002), Statistical Yearbook of China,<br />

China Statistical Press.<br />

Newton, Alastair <strong>and</strong> Robert Subbaraman (2002), China: Gigantic<br />

Possibilities, Present Realities, Lehman Brothers, New York.<br />

OECD(2002), China in the World Economy: The Domestic Policy<br />

Challenges, OECD, Paris.<br />

Population Reference Bureau (2002), 2002 World Population Data<br />

Sheet, Washington D.C.<br />

US Treasury, “Treasury International Capital System website”,<br />

http://www.treas.gov/tic/index.html.<br />

UNCTAD (2002), World Investment Report 2002, UNCTAD, New<br />

York/Geneva.<br />

World Bank (2002), Global Development Finance, The World Bank,<br />

Washington D.C.<br />

World Trade Organisation (2001), Annual Report, 2001, WTO,<br />

Geneva.<br />

World Trade Organisation (2002), Annual Report, 2002, WTO,<br />

Geneva.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


140<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 1.1. Global Trade <strong>and</strong> Investment, 1982-2001<br />

(in billions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991<br />

Level<br />

FDI 59 51 60 58 86 140 164 193 203 160<br />

M&A 116 140 156 81<br />

Service Trade 805 775 800 783 902 1,069 1,218 1,336 1,601 1,673<br />

Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Trade 3,780 3,684 3,889 3,931 4,326 5,050 5,737 6,156 6,982 6,982<br />

Growth<br />

FDI -13.2 17.0 -4.3 50.1 61.8 17.1 17.6 17.6 5.3 -21.0<br />

M&A<br />

Service Trade -2.4 -3.7 3.2 -2.2 15.3 18.5 13.9 9.7 19.8 4.5<br />

Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Trade -5.8 -2.5 5.6 1.1 10.1 16.7 13.6 7.3 13.4 0.0<br />

As percentage of Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Trade<br />

FDI 1.6 1.4 1.5 1.5 2.0 2.8 2.9 3.1 2.9 2.3<br />

M&A 2.0 2.3 2.2 1.2<br />

Service Trade 21.3 21.0 20.6 19.9 20.9 21.2 21.2 21.7 22.9 24.0<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

141<br />

Table 1.1. (continued)<br />

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 Average<br />

1982-<br />

2001<br />

Level<br />

FDI 171 228 260 331 386 478 694 1,088 1,492 735 351.9<br />

M&A 79 83 127 187 227 305 532 766 1,144 594 206.2<br />

Service Trade 1,863 1,897 2,077 2,387 2,536 2,627 2,662 2,713 2,872 2,870 1,773.4<br />

Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Trade 7,484 7,464 8,485 10,142 10,585 10,950 10,797 11,204 12,538 12,601 7,638.3<br />

Growth<br />

FDI 6.9 32.9 14.1 27.3 16.8 23.8 45.3 56.7 37.1 -50.7 16.3<br />

M&A -1.8 4.8 53.0 46.8 21.7 34.3 74.4 44.1 49.3 -48.1 27.8<br />

Service Trade 11.4 1.8 9.5 14.9 6.3 3.6 1.3 1.9 5.9 -0.1 6.7<br />

Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Trade 7.2 -0.3 13.7 19.5 4.4 3.5 -1.4 3.8 11.9 0.5 6.1<br />

As percentage of Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Trade<br />

FDI 2.3 3.0 3.1 3.3 3.6 4.4 6.4 9.7 11.9 5.8 3.8<br />

M&A 1.2 1.1 1.5 1.8 2.1 2.8 4.9 6.8 9.1 4.7 1.9<br />

Service Trade 24.0 25.4 24.5 23.5 24.0 24.0 24.7 24.2 22.9 22.8 22.8<br />

Source: UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2002, website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


142<br />

Table 1.2 World Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Trade by Region, 1948-2000<br />

(in billions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

1948 1953 1963 1973 1983 1993 2000<br />

World export in value 58.0 84.0 157.0 579.0 1835.0 3641.0 6186.0<br />

Export Share<br />

World 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

North America 27.3 24.2 19.3 16.9 15.4 16.8 17.1<br />

Latin America 12.3 10.5 7.0 4.7 5.8 4.4 5.8<br />

Western Europe 31.5 34.9 41.4 45.4 38.9 43.7 39.5<br />

C./E. Europe/Baltic<br />

States/CIS 6.0 8.1 11.0 9.1 9.5 2.9 4.4<br />

Africa 7.3 6.5 5.7 4.8 4.4 2.5 2.3<br />

Middle East 2.0 2.7 3.2 4.1 6.8 3.4 4.2<br />

Asia 13.6 13.1 12.4 14.9 19.1 26.3 26.7<br />

Japan 0.4 1.5 3.5 6.4 8.0 10.0 7.7<br />

China 0.9 1.2 1.3 1.0 1.2 2.5 4.0<br />

India 2.2 1.3 1.0 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.7<br />

Australia <strong>and</strong><br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> 3.7 3.2 2.4 2.1 1.4 1.5 1.2<br />

Six East Asian traders* 3.0 2.7 2.4 3.4 5.8 9.7 10.5<br />

World import in value 66.0 84.0 163.0 589.0 1881.0 3752.0 6490.0<br />

Import Share<br />

World 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

North America 19.8 19.7 15.5 16.7 17.8 19.8 23.2<br />

Latin America 10.6 9.3 6.8 5.1 4.5 5.2 6.0<br />

Western Europe 40.4 39.4 45.4 47.4 40.0 42.9 39.6<br />

C./E. Europe/Baltic<br />

States/CIS 5.8 7.6 10.3 8.9 8.4 2.9 3.7<br />

Africa 7.6 7.0 5.5 4.0 4.6 2.6 2.1<br />

Middle East 1.7 2.0 2.3 2.8 6.3 3.2 2.6<br />

Asia 14.2 15.1 14.2 15.1 18.5 23.4 22.8<br />

Japan 1.0 2.9 4.1 6.5 6.7 6.4 5.8<br />

China 1.1 1.7 0.9 0.9 1.1 2.8 3.5<br />

India 3.1 1.4 1.5 0.5 0.7 0.6 0.8<br />

Australia <strong>and</strong><br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> 2.6 2.4 2.3 1.6 1.4 1.5 1.3<br />

Six East Asian traders* 3.0 3.4 3.1 3.7 6.1 9.9 9.5<br />

Note:<br />

* Asia six: Taiwan, Hong Kong, Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, <strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong>;<br />

Significant re-exports excluded.<br />

Source: WTO.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

143<br />

Table 1.3 FDI Inflows in Selected Regions, 1990-2001<br />

(in billions of dollars)<br />

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 Popu- 2001 FDI<br />

lation Inflows<br />

(million) per capita<br />

Total World 203 160 171 228 260 331 386 478 694 1,088 1,492 735 6,125 120<br />

Developed countries 165 113 107 137 145 203 220 268 484 838 1,227 503 1,197 420<br />

United States 48 23 19 51 45 59 84 103 174 283 301 124 287 433<br />

Japan 2 1 3 0 1 0 0 3 3 13 8 6 127 49<br />

Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific 25 24 33 59 69 76 94 106 96 103 134 102<br />

China 3 4 11 28 34 36 40 44 44 40 41 47 1,281 37<br />

Hong Kong, China 3 1 4 7 8 6 10 11 15 25 62 23 7 3358<br />

Taiwan Province of China 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 2 0 3 5 4 23 183<br />

Greater China sub-total 8 7 16 35 43 44 53 58 59 68 108 74 1,310 56<br />

India 0 0 0 1 1 2 3 4 3 2 2 3 1,050 3<br />

Indonesia 1 1 2 2 2 4 6 5 0 -3 -5 -3 217 -15<br />

Malaysia 3 4 5 6 5 6 7 6 3 4 4 1 24 23<br />

Philippines 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 2 80 22<br />

Republic of Korea 1 1 1 1 1 2 2 3 5 9 9 3 48 66<br />

Singapore 6 5 2 5 9 9 9 11 6 12 5 9 4 2050<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> 3 2 2 2 1 2 2 4 5 4 3 4 63 60<br />

Asia-7 sub-total 13 14 13 17 20 26 31 33 24 29 20 18 1,486 12<br />

Developing countries 38 44 59 83 109 113 153 191 188 225 238 205 5,018 41<br />

All developing countries<br />

minus China 34 40 48 56 75 77 113 147 144 185 197 158 3,737 42<br />

Source: UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2002, website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


144<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 1.4 Share of Global FDI Inflows by Selected Regions, 1990-2001<br />

(in percentages)<br />

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001<br />

Total World 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Developed countries 81.2 70.6 62.7 60.3 55.7 61.5 57.0 56.0 69.7 77.0 82.3 68.4<br />

United States 23.9 14.2 11.2 22.3 17.4 17.8 21.9 21.6 25.1 26.0 20.2 16.9<br />

Japan 0.9 0.9 1.6 0.0 0.3 0.0 0.1 0.7 0.5 1.2 0.6 0.8<br />

Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific 12.2 15.2 19.4 26.0 26.5 23.0 24.3 22.2 13.9 9.5 9.0 13.9<br />

China 1.7 2.7 6.5 12.1 13.0 10.8 10.4 9.3 6.3 3.7 2.7 6.4<br />

Hong Kong, China 1.6 0.6 2.3 3.0 3.0 1.9 2.7 2.4 2.1 2.3 4.2 3.1<br />

Taiwan Province of China 0.7 0.8 0.5 0.4 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.0 0.3 0.3 0.6<br />

Greater China sub-total 4.0 4.2 9.3 15.5 16.6 13.2 13.6 12.1 8.5 6.2 7.2 10.0<br />

Singapore 2.7 3.1 1.3 2.1 3.3 2.7 2.2 2.2 0.9 1.1 0.4 1.2<br />

Republic of Korea 0.4 0.7 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.6 0.6 0.8 0.9 0.6 0.4<br />

India 0.1 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.5<br />

Indonesia 0.5 0.9 1.0 0.9 0.8 1.3 1.6 1.0 -0.1 -0.3 -0.3 -0.4<br />

Malaysia 1.3 2.5 3.0 2.5 1.8 1.8 1.9 1.3 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.1<br />

Philippines 0.3 0.3 0.5 0.5 0.6 0.4 0.4 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.2<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> 1.3 1.3 1.2 0.8 0.5 0.6 0.6 0.8 0.7 0.3 0.2 0.5<br />

Asia-7 sub-total 6.6 8.9 7.6 7.3 7.7 8.0 8.0 6.9 3.4 2.6 1.4 2.5<br />

Developing countries 18.5 27.7 34.6 36.6 41.9 34.0 39.5 40.0 27.0 20.7 15.9 27.9<br />

All developing countries minus China 16.8 25.0 28.1 24.5 28.8 23.2 29.1 30.7 20.7 17.0 13.2 21.5<br />

Source: UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2002, website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

145<br />

Table 1.5 Shares in M&A Sales by Selected Regions <strong>and</strong> Countries<br />

(in percentages)<br />

1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001<br />

Total World 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Developed countries 91.7 86.2 81.4 87.0 87.9 82.6 76.1 83.4 88.7 92.3 83.5<br />

United States 35.0 20.0 24.1 35.2 28.5 30.0 26.8 39.4 32.9 28.4 31.1<br />

Japan 0.2 0.3 0.1 0.6 0.3 0.8 1.0 0.8 2.1 1.4 2.6<br />

Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific 2.7 4.6 8.8 3.7 3.8 5.9 7.1 3.0 3.8 1.9 5.8<br />

China 0.2 0.3 0.7 0.6 0.2 0.8 0.6 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.4<br />

Hong Kong, China 0.7 2.1 6.4 1.3 0.9 1.4 2.4 0.2 0.5 0.4 1.7<br />

Taiwan Province of China 0.2 0.0 0.2 0.1 0.4<br />

Greater China sub-total 3.2 0.3 1.1 0.7 2.6<br />

Singapore 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.5 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2<br />

Republic of Korea 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.1 0.6<br />

India 0.2 0.1 0.6 0.3 0.1 0.3 0.1 0.2 0.2 0.0 0.2<br />

Indonesia 0.1 0.5 0.2 0.7 0.6 0.2 1.4 0.4 0.2 0.0 0.3<br />

Malaysia 0.8 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.7 1.3 0.6 0.6<br />

Philippines 0.3 0.3 0.4 0.3 0.7 0.3 0.1 0.1 0.4 0.1 0.8<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> 0.1 0.6 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.6 0.3 0.2 0.2<br />

Asia-7 sub-total 1.6 1.8 2.1 1.5 2.7 2.2 2.6 1.2 3.0<br />

Developing countries 7.2 10.3 17.2 11.8 8.8 15.7 22.0 15.5 9.7 6.2 14.4<br />

Source: UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2002, website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


146<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table1.6 FDI Inward Stock by Selected Regions <strong>and</strong> Countries, 1980-2001<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2001 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2001 Popu- Inward<br />

lation FDI<br />

(million) Stock<br />

per capita<br />

Total World 635,534 913,182 1,871,594 2,911,725 6,258,263 6,845,723 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 6,125 1,118<br />

Developed countries 389,715 568,670 1,382,978 2,021,303 4,124,261 4,504,122 61.3 62.3 73.9 69.4 65.9 65.8 1,197 3,763<br />

United States 83,046 184,615 394,911 535,553 1,214,254 1,321,063 13.1 20.2 21.1 18.4 19.4 19.3 287 4,597<br />

Japan 3,270 4,740 9,850 33,508 50,323 50,319 0.5 0.5 0.5 1.2 0.8 0.7 127 395<br />

Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific 161,196 228,970 317,663 570,625 1,246,700 1,329,431 25.4 25.1 17.0 19.6 19.9 19.4<br />

China 6,251 10,499 24,762 137,435 348,346 395,192 1.0 1.1 1.3 4.7 5.6 5.8 1,281 309<br />

Hong Kong, China 124,286 129,750 148,183 174,063 429,036 451,870 19.6 14.2 7.9 6.0 6.9 6.6 7 66,451<br />

Taiwan Province of China 2,405 2,930 9,735 15,736 27,924 32,033 0.4 0.3 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.5 23 1,424<br />

Greater China sub-total 132,942 143,179 182,680 327,234 805,306 879,095 20.9 15.7 9.8 11.2 12.9 12.8 1,310 671<br />

Singapore 1,177 1,075 1,668 5,652 18,916 22,319 0.2 0.1 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.3 1,050 21<br />

Republic of Korea 10,274 24,971 38,883 50,601 60,638 57,361 1.6 2.7 2.1 1.7 1.0 0.8 217 264<br />

India 5,169 7,388 10,318 28,732 52,748 53,302 0.8 0.8 0.6 1.0 0.8 0.8 24 2,185<br />

Indonesia 1,281 2,601 3,268 6,086 12,440 14,232 0.2 0.3 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 80 178<br />

Malaysia 1,327 2,160 5,864 9,991 62,786 47,228 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.3 1.0 0.7 48 976<br />

Philippines 6,203 13,016 28,565 59,582 95,714 104,323 1.0 1.4 1.5 2.0 1.5 1.5 4 24,839<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> 981 1,999 8,209 17,452 24,468 28,227 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.4 0.4 63 451<br />

Asia-7 sub-total 26,412 53,210 96,774 178,095 327,709 326,991 4.2 5.8 5.2 6.1 5.2 4.8 1,486 220<br />

Developing countries 245,819 344,463 484,954 849,915 2,002,173 2,181,249 38.7 37.7 25.9 29.2 32.0 31.9 5,018 435<br />

All developing countries<br />

minus China 239,568 333,964 460,193 712,480 1,653,827 1,786,057 37.7 36.6 24.6 24.5 26.4 26.1 3,737 478<br />

Source: UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2002, website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

147<br />

Table 1.7 FDI Outward Stock in Selected Regions <strong>and</strong> Countries, 1980-2001<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2001 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2001 Popu- Inward<br />

lation FDI<br />

(million) Stock<br />

per capita<br />

Total World 521,486 691,745 1,721,462 2,854,853 6,086,428 6,552,011 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 6,125 1,070<br />

Developed countries 499,428 656,276 1,630,443 2,577,550 5,316,292 5,751,947 95.8 94.9 94.7 90.3 87.3 87.8 1,197 4,805<br />

United States 215,375 238,369 430,521 699,015 1,293,431 1,381,674 41.3 34.5 25.0 24.5 21.3 21.1 287 4,807<br />

Japan 19,610 43,970 201,440 238,452 278,445 300,115 3.8 6.4 11.7 8.4 4.6 4.6 127 2,356<br />

Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific 6,206 11,699 47,813 185,931 583,524 603,290 1.2 1.7 2.8 6.5 9.6 9.2<br />

China - 131 2,489 15,802 25,804 27,579 0.0 0.1 0.6 0.4 0.4 1,281 22<br />

Hong Kong, China 148 2,344 11,920 78,833 365,803 374,780 0.0 0.3 0.7 2.8 6.0 5.7 7 55,115<br />

Taiwan Province of China 97 204 12,888 25,144 49,187 54,667 0.0 0.0 0.7 0.9 0.8 0.8 23 2,430<br />

Greater China sub-total 2,679 27,297 119,779 440,794 457,026 0.0 0.4 1.6 4.2 7.2 7.0 1,310 349<br />

Singapore 235 250 281 495 1,311 2,068 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1,050 2<br />

Republic of Korea - 55 77 1,295 2,339 2,464 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 217 11<br />

India 197 1,374 2,671 11,143 18,688 18,955 0.0 0.2 0.2 0.4 0.3 0.3 24 777<br />

Indonesia 171 171 155 1,220 1,965 2,126 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 80 27<br />

Malaysia 127 461 2,301 7,787 50,552 40,825 0.0 0.1 0.1 0.3 0.8 0.6 48 844<br />

Philippines 3,718 4,387 7,808 35,050 53,009 63,225 0.7 0.6 0.5 1.2 0.9 1.0 4 15,054<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> 13 14 404 2,173 2,439 2,610 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.0 0.0 63 42<br />

Asia-7 sub-total 6,712 13,698 59,163 130,304 132,274 0.9 1.0 0.8 2.1 2.1 2.0 1,486 89<br />

Developing countries 22,058 35,469 90,404 270,925 751,632 776,065 4.2 5.1 5.3 9.5 12.3 11.8 5,018 155<br />

All developing countries<br />

minus China 22,058 35,338 87,915 255,123 725,828 748,486 4.2 5.1 5.1 8.9 11.9 11.4 3,737 200<br />

Source: UNCTAD, World Investment Report 2002, website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


148<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 2.1 Derived Portfolio Investment Liabilities in Selected Countries,<br />

Year-End 1997 <strong>and</strong> 2001<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

Equity Securities Long-term Debt Securities Short-term Debt Securities TOTAL Share in TOTAL<br />

Investment in: 1997 2001 1997 2001<br />

United States 427,579 997,821 886,325 1,653,419 36,192 417,850 1,350,096 3,069,090 22.18 24.46<br />

United Kingdom 313,962 705,331 232,378 395,148 7,099 153,795 553,439 1,254,346 9.09 10.00<br />

Germany 143,058 271,367 446,255 798,524 2,437 81,488 591,750 1,151,378 9.72 9.18<br />

France 163,195 388,422 105,150 332,358 2,222 55,209 270,567 775,990 4.44 6.19<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 164,443 285,897 116,817 368,280 1,938 37,417 283,199 691,594 4.65 5.51<br />

Japan 241,804 333,581 144,855 157,246 7,382 36,553 394,041 527,380 6.47 4.20<br />

Hong Kong SAR of China 62,952 79,056 9,884 8,829 1,188 505 74,024 88,390 1.22 0.70<br />

Korea, Republic of 6,085 51,666 31,259 22,650 706 2,018 38,050 76,334 0.62 0.61<br />

Singapore 19,316 35,850 4,918 7,330 129 1,236 24,363 44,417 0.40 0.35<br />

Taiwan Province of China 9,302 38,808 2,545 2,004 21 65 11,868 40,877 0.19 0.33<br />

Russian Federation 10,937 10,753 17,530 14,831 1,687 318 30,154 25,902 0.50 0.21<br />

Malaysia 14,645 11,508 10,541 9,526 417 293 25,603 21,327 0.42 0.17<br />

China, P.R. 4,618 13,210 14,112 5,504 610 1,457 19,340 20,103 0.32 0.16<br />

India 10,396 13,252 4,404 1,793 203 214 15,003 15,260 0.25 0.12<br />

Philippines 4,658 3,452 7,206 8,823 98 332 11,962 12,607 0.20 0.10<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> 4,526 7,684 8,108 3,837 276 349 12,909 11,870 0.21 0.09<br />

Indonesia 4,258 3,800 5,226 1,607 870 79 10,354 5,486 0.17 0.04<br />

Total value of investment 2,567,784 5,134,498 3,421,999 6,373,367 98,430 1,038,297 6,088,217 12,546,226 100.00 100.00<br />

Source: IMF, Global Portforlio Investment Survey, 2003.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

149<br />

Table 2.2 Net Purchases of Foreign Stocks by US Residents<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

All-ex-US Asia Japan Hong Singa- Taiwan Korea China<br />

Kong pore<br />

Amount<br />

1988-1997 349,729 127,033 80,211 19,773 4,625 202 8,737 1,400<br />

1998 -6,212 8,594 3,694 1,385 929 487 1,907 8<br />

1999 -15,640 46,873 46,134 -2,777 -149 1,767 1,965 222<br />

2000 13,088 -11,198 -16,461 3,254 -3,038 767 2,057 251<br />

2001 50,113 27,523 19,938 4,823 -2,487 2,949 2,006 -40<br />

As percengate of Asia Total<br />

1988-1997 275.3 100.0 63.1 15.6 3.6 0.2 6.9 1.1<br />

1998 -72.3 100.0 43.0 16.1 10.8 5.7 22.2 0.1<br />

1999 -33.4 100.0 98.4 -5.9 -0.3 3.8 4.2 0.5<br />

2000 116.9 -100.0 -147.0 29.1 -27.1 6.8 18.4 2.2<br />

2001 182.1 100.0 72.4 17.5 -9.0 10.7 7.3 -0.1<br />

Source: US Treasury website.<br />

Table 2.3 Net Purchases of Foreign Bonds by US Residents<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

All-ex-US Asia Japan Hong Singa- Taiwan Korea China<br />

Kong pore<br />

Amount<br />

1988-1997 302,824 15,001 -865 -10,045 -2,532 -7,619 9,627 -825<br />

1998 17,349 -4,602 -1,952 -2,452 -2,445 -815 3,161 -1,716<br />

1999 5,676 -3,912 -2,497 -1,458 -334 -2,173 -719 -336<br />

2000 4,054 -13,290 -4,509 -984 -893 -2,762 -1,365 -1,808<br />

2001 -30,393 -15,654 178 -3,298 -293 -3,792 -1,856 -4,033<br />

As percengate of Asia Total<br />

1988-1997 2018.7 100.0 -5.8 -67.0 -16.9 -50.8 64.2 -5.5<br />

1998 377.0 -100.0 -42.4 -53.3 -53.1 -17.7 68.7 -37.3<br />

1999 145.1 -100.0 -63.8 -37.3 -8.5 -55.5 -18.4 -8.6<br />

2000 30.5 -100.0 -33.9 -7.4 -6.7 -20.8 -10.3 -13.6<br />

2001 -194.2 -100.0 1.1 -21.1 -1.9 -24.2 -11.9 -25.8<br />

Source: US Treasury website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


150<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 2.4 Net Purchases of US Stocks by Foreign Residents<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

All-ex-US Asia Japan Hong Singa- Taiwan Korea China<br />

Kong pore<br />

Amount<br />

1988-1997 115,571 9,615 6,617 1,031 8,828 409 -29 28<br />

1998 50,020 -13,781 -1,171 -2,223 -8,438 -69 -84 1<br />

1999 107,522 3,379 5,723 -156 -852 37 -78 204<br />

2000 174,890 21,683 2,070 215 10,788 -147 -160 -103<br />

2001 116,386 22,516 6,788 675 13,078 261 -76 3<br />

As percengate of Asia Total<br />

1988-1997 1202.0 100.0 68.8 10.7 91.8 4.3 -0.3 0.3<br />

1998 363.0 -100.0 -8.5 -16.1 -61.2 -0.5 -0.6 0.0<br />

1999 3182.1 100.0 169.4 -4.6 -25.2 1.1 -2.3 6.0<br />

2000 806.6 100.0 9.5 1.0 49.8 -0.7 -0.7 -0.5<br />

2001 516.9 100.0 30.1 3.0 58.1 1.2 -0.3 0.0<br />

Source: US Treasury website.<br />

Table 2.5 Net Purchases of US Bonds by Foreign Residents<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

All-ex-US Asia Japan Hong Singa- Taiwan Korea China<br />

Kong pore<br />

Amount<br />

1988-1997 1,447,448 415,223 202,793 52,694 36,900 22,701 2,900 47,890<br />

1998 227,771 45,092 21,432 9,223 9,935 -2,996 15,812 3,519<br />

1999 242,639 74,155 37,643 6,844 -7,417 -483 11,273 17,053<br />

2000 282,938 82,474 49,936 10,181 -4,574 -5,240 5,839 15,656<br />

2001 405,413 147,141 51,873 29,274 389 9,930 533 51,784<br />

As percengate of Asia Total<br />

1988-1997 348.6 100.0 48.8 12.7 8.9 5.5 0.7 11.5<br />

1998 505.1 100.0 47.5 20.5 22.0 -6.6 35.1 7.8<br />

1999 327.2 100.0 50.8 9.2 -10.0 -0.7 15.2 23.0<br />

2000 343.1 100.0 60.5 12.3 -5.5 -6.4 7.1 19.0<br />

2001 275.5 100.0 35.3 19.9 0.3 6.7 0.4 35.2<br />

Source: US Treasury website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

151<br />

Table 3.1 Corpo<strong>rate</strong> tax comparison among Asian countries<br />

(in percentages)<br />

Regular<br />

Preferential <strong>rate</strong> for foreign<br />

investment<br />

Korea 27<br />

Singapore 22<br />

Hong Kong 16<br />

China 33 15<br />

USA 35<br />

Germany 25<br />

Japan 30<br />

Source: Joongang Daily, March 5, 2003, p. 3.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


152<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 3.2 Foreign <strong>Exchange</strong> Reserve to GDP Ratio<br />

1990 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Average<br />

Singapore 73.5 79.3 81.8 83.2 84.5 89.2 89.5 86.8 83.5<br />

Hong Kong 33.8 37.7 39.8 41.4 54.3 55.1 60.9 66.2 48.7<br />

Taiwan 44.5 37.2 33.6 31.0 28.5 33.6 36.6 34.0 34.9<br />

Malaysia 21.8 32.6 26.2 26.1 27.6 33.0 37.6 31.8 29.6<br />

Yemen 12.7 17.3 17.8 17.2 16.3 18.6 16.7<br />

Venezuela 17.1 14.5 12.1 18.0 16.3 12.5 12.1 10.7 14.2<br />

Norway 12.4 14.0 14.4 16.0 14.7 11.6 12.9 12.2 13.5<br />

Swiss 12.8 12.3 11.0 13.5 14.5 13.9 14.1 12.5 13.1<br />

China 7.4 9.3 10.5 12.8 15.5 15.0 15.6 15.3 12.7<br />

Indonesia 6.9 6.8 6.8 8.0 11.9 18.8 16.8 21.0 12.1<br />

Korea 5.7 6.1 6.6 6.7 7.4 14.1 17.4 23.4 10.9<br />

Saudi Arabia 8.2 4.9 5.6 9.1 9.2 9.9 10.8 10.4 8.5<br />

Spain 10.0 8.2 5.7 9.9 12.9 9.1 5.5 5.2 8.3<br />

Austria 5.5 7.8 7.6 9.8 9.4 9.4 7.1 7.0 8.0<br />

Denmark 7.8 5.3 5.6 7.5 11.1 7.5 12.7 0.9 7.3<br />

group average 7.8 7.1 6.3 9.1 11.1 8.7 8.4 4.4 7.9<br />

Sweden 7.6 10.5 8.9 7.1 4.2 5.3 5.8 6.3 7.0<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 6.8 9.1 7.2 4.9 6.4 6.3 5.6 6.0 6.5<br />

Brazil 1.7 9.0 7.5 7.8 6.5 5.6 6.5 5.8 6.3<br />

Mexico 3.8 2.3 6.3 6.0 7.2 8.1 6.4 6.2 5.8<br />

India 0.4 6.0 5.2 5.2 6.3 6.5 7.1 5.3<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 5.7 8.9 7.5 6.1 6.0 4.3 1.7 1.9 5.2<br />

Belgium 5.7 5.2 5.3 5.9 6.1 6.0 3.5 3.5 5.2<br />

France 5.3 5.2 4.9 5.0 5.1 4.2 3.9 3.8 4.7<br />

Japan 2.3 2.3 3.6 4.7 5.2 4.6 5.5 7.8 4.5<br />

Australia 5.3 3.0 3.1 3.4 4.4 3.8 4.9 4.6 4.1<br />

Italy 5.5 3.0 2.9 3.5 4.7 2.0 1.7 2.1 3.2<br />

Canada 2.8 1.9 2.1 3.0 2.5 3.4 3.6 4.1 2.9<br />

Great Britain 3.3 3.6 3.5 2.9 2.2 1.9 2.1 2.8 2.8<br />

Germany 2.3 1.1 0.9 1.0 1.4 1.7 1.7 1.7 1.5<br />

USA 0.9 0.6 0.7 0.5 0.4 0.0 0.3 0.3 0.5<br />

Average 11.3 12.2 11.8 12.6 13.4 13.8 14.1 14.1 12.9<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

153<br />

Table 3.3 GDP by Country (at current price <strong>and</strong> official exchange <strong>rate</strong>)<br />

1990 Rank 1999 Rank 1990 1999 2000 2001<br />

USA 1 1 5,743.8 9,268.6 9,872.9 10,082.2<br />

Japan 2 2 2,970.1 5,015.0 4,454.6 4,172.5<br />

Germany 3 3 1,503.6 1,991.5 1,891.0 1,845.3<br />

United Kingdom 6 4 983.6 1,448.3 1,397.6 1,423.7<br />

France 4 5 1,195.4 1,355.7 1,308.9 1311<br />

Italy 5 6 1,094.0 1,112.9 1,084.7<br />

China 10 7 387.8 991.1 1,080.1 1,139.8<br />

Canada 7 8 573.8 675.7 703.9 705.6<br />

Spain 8 9 492.0 565.6 563.9<br />

Brazil 9 10 442.9 538.8 555.9<br />

Mexico 15 11 247.0 482.3 567.5<br />

India 11 12 306.0 450.0 0.0<br />

Korea 14 13 253.7 424.2 408.9 422.2<br />

Australia 12 14 294.8 397.7 361.1 357.1<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 13 15 283.5 375.3 373.2<br />

Taiwan 19 16 162.7 290.5 313.9 282.4<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> 17 17 228.4 242.9 247.1<br />

Belgium 18 18 193.8 237.1 230.8<br />

Sweden 16 19 229.8 231.3 218.4<br />

Austria 20 20 158.4 198.0 191.7<br />

Denmark 22 21 129.1 166.2 163.6<br />

Hong Kong 26 22 72.6 158.0 162.5<br />

Indonesia 24 23 106.1 156.7 134.5<br />

Norway 23 24 115.5 148.4 158.6<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 27 25 59.0 148.3 165.5<br />

Saudi Arabia 25 26 104.7 142.9 173.3<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 21 27 134.8 121.0 122.5<br />

Venezuala 28 28 48.6 96.5 117.8<br />

Singapore 31 29 37.5 85.3 91.9 85.6<br />

Malaysia 29 30 42.8 78.9 89.9<br />

Nigeria 33 31 32.4 34.5 36.5<br />

Kuwait 34 32 18.2 29.8 38.0<br />

Romania 30 33 38.3 29.6 30.7<br />

Yemen 32 34 33.6 0.0 0.0<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


154<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 3.4 Global Population by Region <strong>and</strong> Age<br />

(in millions of habitants <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

Habitants Share in Region Total<br />

All Below 15 15 to 65 Above 65 Below 15 15 to 65 Above 65<br />

China 1,281 295 896 90 23 70 7<br />

Less developed countries<br />

excluding China 3,737 1,345 2,242 149 36 60 4<br />

More developed countries 1,197 215 802 180 18 67 15<br />

East Asia 1,512 333 1,058 121 22 70 8<br />

U.S. 287 60<br />

190 37 21 66 13<br />

Western Europe 184 31 123 29 17 67 16<br />

Japan 127<br />

18 87 23 14 68 18<br />

Source: Population Reference Bureau, World Population Data Sheet, 2002.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

155<br />

Table 4.1 China in World Trade<br />

(in percentages)<br />

Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Exports Merch<strong>and</strong>ise Imports<br />

World Total Growth World Total Growth<br />

in 2000 1990-2000 in 2000 1990-2000<br />

World 100.0 6.0 100.0 6.0<br />

Asia 26.7 8.4 22.8 7.6<br />

Japan 7.7 5.2 5.9 4.9<br />

China 4.0 14.9 3.5 15.5<br />

Hong Kong 3.3 n.a. 3.3 n.a.<br />

Commercial Service Commercial Service<br />

Exports<br />

Imports<br />

World Total Growth World Total Growth<br />

in 2000 1990-2000 in 2000 1990-2000<br />

World 100.0 6.0 100.0 6.0<br />

Asia 21.1 9.0 25.4 7.0<br />

Japan 4.7 5.0 8.1 3.0<br />

China 2.1 18.0 2.5 24.0<br />

Hong Kong 2.9 0.09 1.8 0.09<br />

Source: WTO.<br />

Table 4.2 Share in World Exports of Manufactures, 1990 <strong>and</strong> 2000<br />

(in percentages)<br />

1990 2000 Gain/Loss<br />

World 100.0 100.0<br />

Developed countries 80.4 69.4 -11.0<br />

Developing countries 17.5 27.4 9.9<br />

Asia 12.6 19.9 7.3<br />

China 1.9 4.7 2.8<br />

Asia-Six* 9.1 12.2 3.1<br />

Other Asia 1.6 2.9 1.3<br />

Note:<br />

* Asia Six: Taiwan, Hong Kong, Korea, Malaysia, Singapore <strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong>;<br />

Significant re-exports excluded.<br />

Source: WTO.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


156<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 4.3 Foreign Direct Investment in China by Sector<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

Sector 1999 2000 2001 1999 2000 2001<br />

Manufacturing 22,603 25,844 30,907 56.1 63.5 65.9<br />

Electric Power, Gas <strong>and</strong><br />

Water Production <strong>and</strong> Supply 3,703 2,242 2,273 9.2 5.5 4.8<br />

Wholesale & Retail Trade<br />

<strong>and</strong> Catering Services 965 858 1,169 2.4 2.1 2.5<br />

Transport, Storage, Post <strong>and</strong><br />

Telecommunication services 1,551 1,012 909 3.8 2.5 1.9<br />

Farming, Forestry, Animal<br />

Husb<strong>and</strong>ry <strong>and</strong> Fishery 710 676 899 1.8 1.7 1.9<br />

Mining <strong>and</strong> Quarrying 557 583 811 1.4 1.4 1.7<br />

Construction 917 905 807 2.3 2.2 1.7<br />

Scientific Research <strong>and</strong><br />

Polytechnical Services 110 57 120 0.3 0.1 0.3<br />

Health Care, Sports <strong>and</strong><br />

Social Welfare 148 106 119 0.4 0.3 0.3<br />

Education, Culture <strong>and</strong> Arts,<br />

Radio, Film <strong>and</strong> Television 61 54 36 0.2 0.1 0.1<br />

Banking <strong>and</strong> Insurance 98 76 35 0.2 0.2 0.1<br />

Geological Prospecting <strong>and</strong><br />

Water Conservancy 5 5 10 0.0 0.0 0.0<br />

Other Sectors 753 1,453 1,051 1.9 3.6 2.2<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

157<br />

Table 4.4 China’s FDI Inflows by Source Country, 1995-2001<br />

(in billions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001<br />

Level<br />

Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> Macao 20.5 21.3 21.0 18.9 16.7 15.9 17.0<br />

Japan 3.1 3.7 4.3 3.4 3.0 2.9 4.4<br />

Taiwan 3.2 3.5 3.3 2.9 2.6 2.3 3.0<br />

Singapore 1.9 2.2 2.6 3.4 2.6 2.2 2.1<br />

Korea 1.0 1.4 2.1 1.8 1.3 1.5 2.2<br />

Neighboring Countries 29.7 32.0 33.4 30.5 26.2 24.7 28.7<br />

USA 3.1 3.4 3.2 3.9 4.2 4.4 4.4<br />

Virgin Isl<strong>and</strong> 0.3 0.5 1.7 4.0 2.7 3.8 5.0<br />

Great Britain 0.9 1.3 1.9 1.2 1.0 1.2 1.1<br />

Germany 0.4 0.5 1.0 0.7 1.4 1.0 1.2<br />

Others 3.2 3.9 4.1 5.2 4.9 5.6 6.5<br />

Total 37.5 41.7 45.3 45.5 40.3 40.7 46.9<br />

Share of total<br />

Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> Macao 54.7 51.0 46.5 41.6 41.4 38.9 36.3<br />

Japan 8.3 8.8 9.6 7.5 7.4 7.2 9.3<br />

Taiwan 8.4 8.3 7.3 6.4 6.5 5.6 6.4<br />

Singapore 4.9 5.4 5.8 7.5 6.5 5.3 4.6<br />

Korea 2.8 3.3 4.7 4.0 3.2 3.7 4.6<br />

Neighboring Countries 79.1 76.7 73.8 67.0 64.9 60.7 61.1<br />

USA 8.2 8.2 7.2 8.6 10.5 10.8 9.4<br />

Virgin Isl<strong>and</strong> 0.8 1.3 3.8 8.9 6.6 9.4 10.7<br />

Great Britain 2.4 3.1 4.1 2.6 2.6 2.8 2.2<br />

Germany 1.0 1.2 2.2 1.6 3.4 2.6 2.6<br />

Others 8.5 9.4 9.0 11.4 12.1 13.7 13.9<br />

Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Source: National Bureau of Statistics, Statistical Yearbook of China, 2002.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


158<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 4.5 FDI <strong>and</strong> Trade Patterns by Province <strong>and</strong> Ranked by Provincial FDI Amount in 2001<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

Province Population GDP (2001, FDI Population GDP share FDI share Trade share Trade FDI as share FDI GDP<br />

(2001, million) current (2001) share (2001) (2001) (2000-2001 (2000-2001 contribution of Fixed per capita per capita<br />

price) average) average) by FIEs Capital (2001) (2001,<br />

(2000-2001 Formation current<br />

average) (2001) price)<br />

National Total 1,276 1,286 46,367 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 50.4 23.7 36 1,008<br />

Guangdong 78 128 11,932 6.1 10.0 25.7 36.1 53.6 75.0 153 1,648<br />

Jiangsu 74 115 6,915 5.8 8.9 14.9 10.5 62.1 49.6 94 1,558<br />

Shanghai 16 60 4,292 1.3 4.6 9.3 11.7 60.8 49.7 266 3,696<br />

Fujian 34 51 3,918 2.7 4.0 8.5 4.8 61.4 80.9 114 1,490<br />

Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 90 114 3,521 7.1 8.8 7.6 6.2 49.8 27.5 39 1,258<br />

Liaoning 42 61 2,516 3.3 4.7 5.4 4.2 59.6 32.0 60 1,446<br />

Zhejiang 46 81 2,212 3.6 6.3 4.8 7.0 31.0 16.7 48 1,762<br />

Tianjin 10 22 2,133 0.8 1.7 4.6 3.6 79.2 51.3 212 2,208<br />

Beijing 14 34 1,768 1.1 2.7 3.8 5.3 31.7 26.8 128 2,479<br />

Top 9 by FDI 404 666 39,207 31.7 51.8 84.6 89.4 54.0 43.3 97 1,647<br />

Hubei 60 56 1,189 4.7 4.4 2.6 0.8 29.3 14.3 20 940<br />

Hunan 66 48 810 5.2 3.7 1.7 0.6 17.5 15.9 12 728<br />

Hebei 67 67 670 5.2 5.2 1.4 1.1 29.9 6.6 10 1,003<br />

Sichuan 86 53 582 6.8 4.1 1.3 0.6 21.0 7.1 7 617<br />

Hainan 8 7 467 0.6 0.5 1.0 0.3 45.8 35.1 59 826<br />

Henan 96 68 457 7.5 5.3 1.0 0.7 18.0 5.7 5 711<br />

Jiangxi 42 26 396 3.3 2.0 0.9 0.4 15.5 14.5 9 626<br />

Guangxi 48 27 384 3.8 2.1 0.8 0.4 23.2 11.6 8 561<br />

Shaanxi 37 22 352 2.9 1.7 0.8 0.5 14.3 6.1 10 607<br />

Heilongjiang 38 43 341 3.0 3.3 0.7 0.8 11.4 4.3 9 1,126<br />

Jilin 27 24 338 2.1 1.9 0.7 0.7 40.1 8.5 13 910<br />

Anhui 63 40 337 5.0 3.1 0.7 0.7 26.4 7.0 5 626<br />

Middle 12 by FDI 637 482 6,322 49.9 37.4 13.6 7.7 24.4 11.4 10 756<br />

Chongqing 31 21 256 2.4 1.6 0.6 0.4 16.1 8.3 8 681<br />

Shanxi 33 21 234 2.6 1.7 0.5 0.6 11.5 5.9 7 655<br />

Inner Mongolia 24 19 107 1.9 1.4 0.2 0.5 7.9 3.6 5 784<br />

Gansu 26 13 74 2.0 1.0 0.2 0.2 9.0 2.1 3 502<br />

Yunnan 43 25 65 3.4 1.9 0.1 0.4 10.1 1.3 2 583<br />

Qinghai 5 4 36 0.4 0.3 0.1 0.0 6.6 2.6 7 693<br />

Guizhou 38 13 28 3.0 1.0 0.1 0.2 7.0 0.9 1 344<br />

Xinjiang 19 18 20 1.5 1.4 0.0 0.5 4.3 0.4 1 954<br />

Ningxia 6 4 17 0.4 0.3 0.0 0.1 11.6 1.5 3 639<br />

Tibet 3 2 - 0.2 0.1 - 0.0 3.2 0.0 - 636<br />

Bottom 10 by FDI 226 139 838 17.7 10.8 1.8 2.9 8.7 2.7 4 614<br />

Source: National Bureau of Statistics, Statistical Yearbook of China, 2002.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

159<br />

Table 4.6 China’s External Borrowing in 2000<br />

(in thous<strong>and</strong>s of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

Borrower / Foreign Interna- Foreign Buyer’s Borrowing Issuing Delayed Savings by Lease Portion of Trade Total Share in<br />

Type of Loan Govern- tional Banks Credit by Bonds Payment Foreigners Hard Credit Total<br />

ment financial exporters, (Usance?) Currency<br />

institutions foreign Payment<br />

companies related with<br />

<strong>and</strong> Counterindividuals<br />

trade<br />

State Council, Ministries 1,655,869 2,679,027 43,935 603,039 4,981,869 29.3<br />

Chinese Banks 712,225 593,240 1,130,712 5,919 336,999 176,839 49,764 117 3,005,815 17.7<br />

Chinese Non-Banking<br />

Financial Institutions 182,602 4,522 249,900 284 591 437,899 2.6<br />

Foreign Invested Enterprises 1,668 77,601 800,517 157,978 2,314,315 76,998 59,498 31,262 154 3,519,989 20.7<br />

Chinese Enterprises 596 89,457 9,432 25,054 13,709 976,296 10,328 1,124,871 6.6<br />

Foreign Financial Institutions 1,581,144 20,036 103,375 1,704,556 10.0<br />

Others 57,947 2,460 8,718 4,821 1,378 75,324 0.4<br />

Trade Credit 2,370,358 2,756,627 3,348,841 1,305,105 2,354,006 1,266,935 274,903 153,424 1,009,643 10,482 2,161,000 17,011,323 100.0<br />

Share in total 13.9 16.2 19.7 7.7 13.8 7.4 1.6 0.9 5.9 0.1 12.7 100.0<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


160<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 4.7 Population, GDP, Savings <strong>and</strong> Current Account Surplus by Selected Regions <strong>and</strong> Countries, 2001<br />

(percentages <strong>and</strong> billions of dollars)<br />

Population GDP at PPP GDP (PPP) per Saving Investment Net Lending Current<br />

(% of World) (% of World) capita as % of the (% of GDP) (% of GDP) (% of GDP) Account<br />

World Average Balance<br />

($ bn)<br />

China 21.0 12.1 58 40.3 37.9 2.4 17.4<br />

India 16.7 4.7 28 20.3 22.9 -2.6 -0.1<br />

Developing Asia 52.2 22.2 43 32.3 30.3 2.0 39.4<br />

Developing countries 78.0 37.6 48 26.8 26.2 0.6 39.6<br />

Countries in transition 6.6 6.2 94 24.0 21.0 3.0 11.8<br />

Newly industrialized Asian Countries 1.3 3.3 254 29.0 23.9 5.1 57.1<br />

Japan 2.1 7.3 348 27.3 25.2 2.1 87.8<br />

European Union 6.2 19.9 321 20.3 20.2 0.1 3.2<br />

United States 4.6 21.4 465 16.5 19.1 -2.6 -393.4<br />

Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook, September 2002 <strong>and</strong> World Bank website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

161<br />

Table 4. 8 China’s Balance of Payments, 1982-2001<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991<br />

Current Account Balance 5,674 4,240 2,030 -11,417 -7,035 300 -3,803 -4,317 11,997 13,270<br />

FDI into China 430 636 1,258 1,659 1,875 2,314 3,194 3,393 3,487 4,366<br />

Net Errors & Omissions 279 117 -932 92 -863 -1,371 -1,011 90 -3,134 -6,748<br />

Reserve Assets Change -6,291 -4,137 -95 2,353 1,954 -4,931 -2,318 503 -12,118 -14,554<br />

GDP in dollars at average<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> 304,423 294,247 321,277 400,000 448,913 389,259 406,443<br />

Accumulated CA since 1982 527 -6,508 -6,208 -10,011 -14,328 -2,331 10,939<br />

Accumulated FDI since 1982 3,983 5,858 8,172 11,366 14,759 18,246 22,612<br />

Accumulated capital flight<br />

(E&O) since 1982 444 1,307 2,678 3,689 3,599 6,733 13,481<br />

Accumulated official foreign<br />

exchange reserves 6,986 8,901 8,220 2,644 2,072 2,923 3,372 5,550 11,093 21,712<br />

External debt 15,830 21,480 30,200 40,000 41,300 52,550 60,560<br />

Accumulated CA since 1982<br />

as % of GDP 0.2 -2.2 -1.9 -2.5 -3.2 -0.6 2.7<br />

Accumulated FDI since 1982<br />

as % of GDP 1.3 2.0 2.5 2.8 3.3 4.7 5.6<br />

Accumulated capital flight<br />

(E&O) since 1982 as % of GDP 0.1 0.4 0.8 0.9 0.8 1.7 3.3<br />

Official reserves as % of GDP 0.9 0.7 0.9 0.8 1.2 2.8 5.3<br />

External debt as % of GDP 5.20 7.30 9.40 10.00 9.20 13.50 14.90<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


162<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 4. 8 (continued)<br />

1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001<br />

Current Account Balance 6,401 -11,903 7,658 1,618 7,242 29,717 29,324 15,667 20,519 17,405<br />

FDI into China 11,156 27,515 33,787 35,849 40,180 44,236 43,752 38,752 38,399 44,241<br />

Net Errors & Omissions -8,252 -9,804 -9,775 -17,812 -15,566 -16,952 -16,576 -14,804 -11,893 -4,856<br />

Reserve Assets Change 2,102 -1,767 -30,527 -22,481 -31,643 -35,724 -6,426 -8,505 -10,548 -47,325<br />

GDP in dollars at average<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> 481,389 601,223 542,749 701,250 818,873 903,241 960,789 992,353 1,079,481 1,157,211<br />

Accumulated CA since 1982 17,340 5,437 13,095 14,713 21,955 51,672 80,996 96,663 117,182 134,588<br />

Accumulated FDI since 1982 33,768 61,283 95,070 130,919 171,099 215,335 259,087 297,840 336,238 380,479<br />

Accumulated capital flight<br />

(E&O) since 1982 21,733 31,537 41,312 59,124 74,690 91,642 108,218 123,023 134,916 139,771<br />

Accumulated official foreign<br />

exchange reserves 19,443 21,199 51,620 73,597 105,029 139,890 144,959 154,675 165,574 212,165<br />

External debt 69,320 83,570 92,810 106,590 116,280 130,970 146,040 151,830 145,730 170,110<br />

Accumulated CA since 1982<br />

as % of GDP 3.6 0.9 2.4 2.1 2.7 5.7 8.4 9.7 10.9 11.6<br />

Accumulated FDI since 1982<br />

as % of GDP 7.0 10.2 17.5 18.7 20.9 23.8 27.0 30.0 31.1 32.9<br />

Accumulated capital flight<br />

(E&O) since 1982 as % of GDP 4.5 5.2 7.6 8.4 9.1 10.1 11.3 12.4 12.5 12.1<br />

Official reserves as % of GDP 4.0 3.5 9.5 10.5 12.8 15.5 15.1 15.6 15.3 18.3<br />

External debt as % of GDP 14.40 13.90 17.10 15.20 14.20 14.50 15.20 15.30 13.50 14.70<br />

Source: National Bureau of Statistics, Statistical Yearbook of China, 2002 <strong>and</strong> People’s Bank of China website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

163<br />

Table 4.9 US Current Account Deficits with Greater China<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

Amount Share of Greater China Total<br />

China Taiwan Hong Kong Greater China Taiwan Hong Kong Greater<br />

China China<br />

1985 -6 -11,697 -5,610 -17,313 0 68 32 100<br />

1986 -1,665 -14,267 -5,861 -21,792 8 65 27 100<br />

1987 -2,796 -17,209 -5,871 -25,876 11 67 23 100<br />

1988 -3,490 -12,585 -4,550 -20,625 17 61 22 100<br />

1989 -6,235 -12,978 -3,431 -22,644 28 57 15 100<br />

1990 -10,431 -11,175 -2,805 -24,411 43 46 11 100<br />

1991 -12,691 -9,841 -1,141 -23,673 54 42 5 100<br />

1992 -18,309 -9,346 -716 -28,371 65 33 3 100<br />

1993 -22,777 -8,934 319 -31,391 73 28 -1 100<br />

1994 -29,505 -9,597 1,745 -37,357 79 26 -5 100<br />

1995 -33,790 -9,682 3,940 -39,532 85 24 -10 100<br />

1996 -39,520 -11,447 4,102 -46,865 84 24 -9 100<br />

1997 -49,695 -12,263 4,829 -57,129 87 21 -8 100<br />

1998 -56,927 -14,960 2,387 -69,501 82 22 -3 100<br />

1999 -68,677 -16,073 2,124 -82,626 83 19 -3 100<br />

2000 -83,833 -16,097 3,133 -96,797 87 17 -3 100<br />

2001 -83,096 -15,253 4,381 -93,968 88 16 -5 100<br />

2002 -103,115 -13,805 3,283 -113,637 91 12 -3 100<br />

Source: US Census Bureau website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


164<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Table 4.10 US Exports, Imports <strong>and</strong> Balance of Goods in 2002<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

Amount Share of the Total<br />

Balance Exports Imports Balance Exports Imports<br />

Total Balance of Payments Basis -484,353 682,586 1,166,939 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

North America -86,962 258,360 345,322 18.0 37.9 29.6<br />

Western Europe -89,218 157,080 246,298 18.4 23.0 21.1<br />

Eastern Europe/FSR -8,283 6,599 14,883 1.7 1.0 1.3<br />

Pacific Rim Countries -215,005 178,561 393,567 44.4 26.2 33.7<br />

Australia 6,606 13,084 6,478 -1.4 1.9 0.6<br />

China<br />

Japan<br />

-103,115 22,053 -70,055 125,168 21.3 3.2 10.7<br />

51,440 121,494 14.5 7.5 10.4<br />

Newly Industrialized Countries(NICS) -22,073 69,823 91,896 4.6 10.2 7.9<br />

Hong Kong 3,283 12,612 9,328 -0.7 1.8 0.8<br />

Korea -12,979 22,596 35,575 2.7 3.3 3.0<br />

Singapore 1,429 16,221 14,793 -0.3 2.4 1.3<br />

Taiwan -13,805 18,394 32,199 2.9 2.7 2.8<br />

Other Pacific Rim(3) -26,369 22,162 48,531 5.4 3.2 4.2<br />

South/Central America -17,902 51,643 69,544 3.7 7.6 6.0<br />

OPEC -34,482 18,852 53,334 7.1 2.8 4.6<br />

Other Countries -36,397 28,956 65,353 7.5 4.2 5.6<br />

Source: US Census Bureau website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

165<br />

Table 4.11 Cross-Border Banking Capital Flows in Hong Kong, 1997-2002<br />

(in millions of dollars <strong>and</strong> percentages)<br />

Period<br />

Outside Banking Outside Banking Net Outside<br />

Claims on HK Liabilities to HK Banking<br />

(HK Gross (HK Gross Liabilities to HK<br />

Borrowing) Lending) (Net HK Lending)<br />

1997-06 629,554 640,490 10,936<br />

All Outside 2002-04 249,541 389,987 140,446<br />

Hong Kong Change -380,013 -250,504 129,509<br />

Change in % -60.4 -39.1 1184.2<br />

Japan<br />

Singapore<br />

UK<br />

US<br />

1997-06 309,067 361,423 52,357<br />

2002-04 57,942 81,484 23,542<br />

Change -251,125 -279,939 -28,814<br />

Change in % -81.3 -77.5 -55.0<br />

1997-06 48,863 37,597 -11,266<br />

2002-04 24,214 39,700 15,486<br />

Change -24,649 2,103 26,753<br />

Change in % -50.4 5.6 -237.5<br />

1997-06 50,679 28,231 -22,448<br />

2002-04 18,753 60,207 41,454<br />

Change -31,926 31,976 63,902<br />

Change in % -63.0 113.3 -284.7<br />

1997-06 24,974 23,606 -1,368<br />

2002-04 12,491 31,806 19,315<br />

Change -12,482 8,201 20,683<br />

Change in % -50.0 34.7 -1511.7<br />

1997-06 40,087 50,105 10,018<br />

Mainl<strong>and</strong> 2002-04 39,312 16,651 -22,661<br />

China Change -776 -33,454 -32,679<br />

Change in % -1.9 -66.8 -326.2<br />

Source: Hong Kong Monetary Authority website.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


166<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Figure 5.1 FDI Inflows, 1979-2001<br />

(in billions of dollars)<br />

350<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

1979<br />

1980<br />

1981<br />

1982<br />

1983<br />

1984<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

United States Asia <strong>and</strong> the Pacific China All developing countries minus China<br />

Figure 5.2 US Current Account Deficits with Greater China<br />

(in billions of dollars)<br />

-140<br />

-120<br />

-100<br />

-80<br />

-60<br />

-40<br />

-20<br />

0<br />

20<br />

1985<br />

1986<br />

1987<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

China Taiwan Hong Kong<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

167<br />

Figure 5.3 Banking Capital Flows between Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> Mainl<strong>and</strong><br />

China<br />

(in billions of dollars)<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

-10<br />

-20<br />

-30<br />

1994-03<br />

1994-09<br />

1995-03<br />

1995-09<br />

1996-03<br />

1996-09<br />

1997-03<br />

1997-09<br />

1998-03<br />

1998-09<br />

1999-03<br />

1999-09<br />

2000-03<br />

2000-09<br />

2001-03<br />

2001-09<br />

2002-03<br />

Mainl<strong>and</strong> China Banking Claims on HK (HK Gross Borrowing from Mainl<strong>and</strong> China)<br />

Mainl<strong>and</strong> China Banking Liabilities on HK (HK Gross Lending to Mainl<strong>and</strong> China)<br />

Net Mainl<strong>and</strong> China Banking Liabilities to HK (Net HK Lending to Mainl<strong>and</strong> China)<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

168<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Figure 6.1 Cross-Border Trading between US <strong>and</strong> the Rest of the World<br />

(in billions of dollars)<br />

Foreign Stocks by US Residents<br />

Foreign Bonds by US Residents<br />

800<br />

700<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

0<br />

-100<br />

Gross Sales<br />

Gross Purchases<br />

Net Purchases<br />

800<br />

700<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

0<br />

-100<br />

Gross Sales<br />

Gross Purchases<br />

Net Purchases<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

US Stocks by Foreign Residents<br />

US Bonds by Foreign Residents<br />

800<br />

700<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

0<br />

-100<br />

Gross Sales<br />

Gross Purchases<br />

Net Purchases<br />

800<br />

700<br />

600<br />

500<br />

400<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

0<br />

-100<br />

Gross Sales<br />

Gross Purchases<br />

Net Purchases<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

169<br />

Figure 6.2 Cross-Border Trading between US <strong>and</strong> Asia<br />

(in billions of dollars)<br />

Asia Stocks by US Residents<br />

150<br />

120<br />

90<br />

60<br />

Gross Sales<br />

Gross Purchases<br />

Net Purchases<br />

30<br />

0<br />

-30<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

US Stocks by Asia Residents<br />

150<br />

120<br />

90<br />

60<br />

Gross Sales<br />

Gross Purchases<br />

Net Purchases<br />

30<br />

0<br />

-30<br />

Asia Bonds by US Residents<br />

150<br />

120<br />

90<br />

60<br />

Gross Sales<br />

Gross Purchases<br />

Net Purchases<br />

30<br />

0<br />

-30<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

US Bonds by Asia Residents<br />

150<br />

120<br />

90<br />

Gross Sales<br />

Gross Purchases<br />

Net Purchases<br />

60<br />

30<br />

0<br />

-30<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


170<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Figure 6.3 The Lower the Local Turnover, the Higher the Share of<br />

Trading by US Residents, The Case of Japan<br />

(in percentages <strong>and</strong> billions of dollars)<br />

Ratio of Gross Purchases by US Residents over Market Turnover in Japan<br />

Japan Stock Market Monthly Turnover<br />

18.0%<br />

350<br />

16.0%<br />

14.0%<br />

12.0%<br />

300<br />

250<br />

10.0%<br />

8.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

billions of dollars<br />

0.0%<br />

0<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

18.0%<br />

16.0%<br />

Share of Gross Purchases of Japan Stocks<br />

by US Residents<br />

14.0%<br />

12.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

8.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

Actual during Oct1988-Apr2002<br />

Fitted using sample from Oct1998-Apr2002<br />

0 50 100 150 200 250 300 350<br />

Monthly Stock Market Turnover in Japan<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

171<br />

Figure 6.4 The Lower the Local Turnover, the Higher the Share of<br />

Trading by US Residents, The Case of Hong Kong<br />

(in percentages <strong>and</strong> billions of dollars)<br />

Ratio of Gross Purchases by US Residents over Market Turnover in Hong Kong<br />

Hong Kong Stock Market Monthly Turnover<br />

45.0%<br />

90<br />

40.0%<br />

80<br />

35.0%<br />

70<br />

30.0%<br />

60<br />

25.0%<br />

20.0%<br />

15.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

billions of dollars<br />

5.0%<br />

10<br />

0.0%<br />

0<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

40.0%<br />

Share of Gross Purchases by US Residents<br />

35.0%<br />

Actual during 1997-April 2002<br />

Fitted using sample from 1997-April 2002<br />

30.0%<br />

25.0%<br />

20.0%<br />

15.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90<br />

Monthly Stock Market Turnover in Hong Kong<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


172<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Figure 6.5 The Lower the Local Turnover, the Higher the Share of<br />

Trading by US Residents, The Case of Mainl<strong>and</strong> China<br />

(in percentages <strong>and</strong> billions of dollars)<br />

Ratio of Gross Purchases by US Residents over Market Turnover in Mainl<strong>and</strong> China<br />

Mainl<strong>and</strong> China Stock Market Monthly Turnover<br />

200.0%<br />

18<br />

180.0%<br />

160.0%<br />

140.0%<br />

120.0%<br />

100.0%<br />

80.0%<br />

60.0%<br />

40.0%<br />

20.0%<br />

16<br />

14<br />

12<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

billions of dollars<br />

0.0%<br />

0<br />

1995-07<br />

1996-01<br />

1996-07<br />

1997-01<br />

1997-07<br />

1998-01<br />

1998-07<br />

1999-01<br />

1999-07<br />

2000-01<br />

2000-07<br />

2001-01<br />

2001-07<br />

2002-01<br />

Share of Gross Purchases by US Residents<br />

7.0%<br />

6.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

3.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

1.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

Actual during Apr2000-April 2002<br />

Fitted using sample from Apr2000-April 2002<br />

-1.0%<br />

0 2 4 6 8 10 12<br />

Monthly Turnover in the B Shares Markets of Mainl<strong>and</strong> China<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

173<br />

Figure 6.6 The Lower the Local Turnover, the Higher the Share of<br />

Trading by US Residents, The Case of Singapore<br />

(in percentages <strong>and</strong> billions of dollars)<br />

Ratio of Gross Purchases by US Residents over Market Turnover in Singapore<br />

Singapore Stock Market Monthly Turnover<br />

45.0%<br />

25<br />

40.0%<br />

35.0%<br />

20<br />

30.0%<br />

25.0%<br />

20.0%<br />

15.0%<br />

15<br />

10<br />

billions of dollars<br />

10.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

5<br />

0.0%<br />

0<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

Share of Gross Purchases by US<br />

Residents<br />

45.0%<br />

40.0%<br />

35.0%<br />

30.0%<br />

25.0%<br />

20.0%<br />

15.0%<br />

10.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

Actual during Jan1998-Apr2002<br />

Fitted using sample from Jap1998-Apr2002<br />

0 5 10 15 20 25<br />

Monthly Stock Market Turnover in Singapore<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


174<br />

Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China<br />

Figure 6.7 The Lower the Local Turnover, the Higher the Share of<br />

Trading by US Residents, The Case of Taiwan<br />

(in percentages <strong>and</strong> billions of dollars)<br />

Ratio of Gross Purchases by US Residents over Market Turnover in Taiwan<br />

Taiwan Stock Market Monthly Turnover<br />

4.5%<br />

200<br />

4.0%<br />

180<br />

3.5%<br />

3.0%<br />

2.5%<br />

2.0%<br />

1.5%<br />

1.0%<br />

0.5%<br />

160<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

billions of dollars<br />

0.0%<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

0<br />

Share of Gross Purchases by US Residents<br />

4.50%<br />

4.00%<br />

3.50%<br />

3.00%<br />

2.50%<br />

2.00%<br />

1.50%<br />

1.00%<br />

0.50%<br />

0.00%<br />

Actual during Jan1998-Apr2002<br />

Fitted using sample from Jan1998-Apr2002<br />

-0.50%<br />

- 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160<br />

Monthly Stock Market Turnover in Taiwan<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

175<br />

Figure 6.8 The Lower the Local Turnover, the Higher the Share of<br />

Trading by US Residents, The Case of Korea<br />

(in percentages <strong>and</strong> billions of dollars)<br />

Ratio of Gross Purchases by US Residents over Market Turnover in Korea<br />

Korea Stock Market Monthly Turnover<br />

12.0%<br />

120<br />

10.0%<br />

100<br />

8.0%<br />

80<br />

6.0%<br />

4.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

billions of dollars<br />

0.0%<br />

0<br />

1988<br />

1989<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

6.0%<br />

5.0%<br />

Actual during Jan1999-Apr2002<br />

Fitted using sample from Jan1999-Apr2002<br />

Share of Gross Purchases by US<br />

Residents<br />

4.0%<br />

3.0%<br />

2.0%<br />

1.0%<br />

0.0%<br />

0 20 40 60 80 100 120<br />

Monthly Stock Market Turnover in Korea<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


9<br />

Comment on Young Rok Cheong<br />

<strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

Li-Gang Liu*<br />

T<br />

his overview paper is very thought-provoking. It has raised<br />

many important issues facing the Chinese <strong>and</strong> world<br />

economies. The authors have painstakingly compiled a wealth of<br />

data, as indicated in 38 tables <strong>and</strong> charts, to provide evidence for<br />

their argument. The paper raises many interesting issues – each of<br />

which would be sufficient for a paper itself; but it is also styled so<br />

well that we can underst<strong>and</strong> these complex issues with ease.<br />

Let me give a quick review of key points of the paper. Essentially,<br />

the authors raise nine questions.<br />

The first one is how to reconcile the fact that China is exporting<br />

capital <strong>and</strong>, at the same time, importing a large amount of capital.<br />

The answer they provide is that China used its trade surplus to<br />

finance its main customers, mainly the US customers.<br />

The second question is whether China is attracting too much<br />

FDI. The answer appears to be ‘yes’.<br />

The third question is what happens to China’s investment in US<br />

bonds. The authors’ figure indicates that China has become the<br />

second largest bondholder of the US treasury. Indeed, by 2001,<br />

China purchased the same amount of bonds as Japan.<br />

* The discussant was formerly a senior research fellow at the Asian<br />

Development Bank Institute in Tokyo. He now is an assistant professor of Public<br />

Policy <strong>and</strong> Finance at the School of Public Policy of the George Mason<br />

University in Arlington, Virginia, USA.<br />

176<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Li-Gang Liu<br />

177<br />

The fourth question is: What is the impact of foreign portfolio<br />

investment on the stability of the Chinese stock markets? At this<br />

moment, the impact is negligible given that China’s capital account<br />

is closed, but we may expect more impact in the near future as the<br />

Qualified Foreign Institutional Investors (QFII) plan to allow<br />

foreign institutional investors to set up joint-venture mutual funds<br />

in the Chinese stock market.<br />

Fifth, they ask if China is generating global deflation. The<br />

answer is ‘yes’ in the labour-intensive manufacturing products but<br />

‘no’ in overall manufactured products since China’s share in world<br />

trade is still rather small, around 4 percent in 2000.<br />

Sixth, they are interested in determining the seriousness of<br />

China’s impact on its competitors. As Geng Xiao mentioned in his<br />

presentation, there are both benefits <strong>and</strong> costs of China’s emergence<br />

in the world economy. Perhaps the rational st<strong>rate</strong>gy is for other<br />

countries to respond proactively <strong>and</strong> deal with the challenge of the<br />

emergence of the Chinese economy.<br />

Seventh, they raise the issue of whether China is saving too<br />

much. Their answer is affirmative. Demographics <strong>and</strong> growth can<br />

explain this phenomenon. However, Chinese savings are not well<br />

utilised. The existing financial system is the root problem.<br />

Eight, given large capital inflows <strong>and</strong> domestic savings, they ask<br />

a hotly debated question: Should China revalue its currency? Their<br />

qualified answer is, ‘No, but perhaps some domestic price <strong>adjustment</strong><br />

should be used.’<br />

The last question they entertain is whether China has become a<br />

growth engine for the world. From the paper the answer is not that<br />

clear. Although China has become a major trading nation in the<br />

world <strong>and</strong> its GDP size in PPP is the third largest in the world, it is<br />

not obvious that China is an engine of global growth at this<br />

moment.<br />

Having recapped the key points of the paper, I would like to<br />

make the following observations <strong>and</strong> comments.<br />

The first one concerns the sustainability of the current trade-FDI<br />

pattern in China. There is a big difference between ‘made in China’<br />

<strong>and</strong> ‘made by China’. At present, more than 50 percent of Chinese<br />

exports is conducted in the form of processed trade: China imports<br />

intermediate components, mainly from Japan, South Korea, <strong>and</strong><br />

Taiwan, <strong>and</strong> then assembles them for exports. The assembled<br />

products are then disproportionately exported to the US market.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


178<br />

Comment on Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

This pattern of triangular trade has allowed China’s powerful<br />

exporting neighbours, South Korea, Taiwan, <strong>and</strong> to some extent,<br />

Japan, to divert their previously US-bound exports to China,<br />

thereby reducing their trade surplus with the US. If this triangular<br />

feature of the China-US trade were to be taken into consideration,<br />

the adjusted real trade balance between China <strong>and</strong> the US would be<br />

far smaller than the current number since China’s value-added in<br />

the processed trade has been rather minimal, mostly in the form of<br />

low wages of the assembly workers. Indeed, this feature is evidenced<br />

by the fact that although China has a large trade surplus with the<br />

US, it runs a similarly large trade deficit with South Korea, Taiwan<br />

<strong>and</strong> Japan. Therefore, China’s global trade surplus is small,<br />

accounting for only 2 percent of its GDP per year. As the US-China<br />

trade deficit balloons, it is not surprising that China has become a<br />

new target of US trade policies, similar to Japan <strong>and</strong> other East<br />

Asian economies in the 1980s. Thus, it is very doubtful whether the<br />

current pattern is sustainable <strong>and</strong> whether China can continue to<br />

export its trade surplus to the US. At this moment, China’s trade-to-<br />

GDP ratio is close to 50 percent <strong>and</strong> the US current account deficit<br />

is historically high, possibly reaching 7 percent of its GDP by the<br />

end of this year. One would have to wonder whether this size of US<br />

current account deficits could be maintained. There will have to be<br />

some kind of <strong>adjustment</strong> on both sides.<br />

Second, I am puzzled by the fact that the wage <strong>rate</strong>s in the export<br />

sector have been rather stagnant over the last ten years despite an<br />

impressive improvement in the sophistication of Chinese exports.<br />

The authors mention that FDI-funded firms are the main drivers of<br />

China’s export growth contributing to 50 percent of China’s exports.<br />

Indeed, China has become the largest FDI recipient in the world for<br />

the first time this year. Then it is puzzling that the wage <strong>rate</strong>s in the<br />

exporting sector have not gone up much over the last ten years.<br />

Empirical evidence indicates that, normally, a country with a large<br />

amount of FDI like China would experience a rapid growth of wages<br />

in the export sector. The authors mention that in Guangdong<br />

province, over the last ten years, the average wage for manufacturing<br />

workers is only 100 dollars per month. I suspect that this rather<br />

stagnant wage pattern has a direct connection with the ongoing<br />

restructuring in the state-owned enterprise sector <strong>and</strong> the unlimited<br />

supply of labour from China’s vast rural area. Because of these two<br />

factors, the wages in the export sector have not led to an overall<br />

178<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Li-Gang Liu<br />

179<br />

domestic wage growth, as is usually observed in a country with large<br />

inflows of FDI. However, without wage growth, it will be difficult<br />

for China to raise domestic dem<strong>and</strong>. This is perhaps why China’s<br />

growth is so dependent on export growth, as indicated by its tradeto-GDP<br />

ratio.<br />

If you look at the nominal GDP among China, the US <strong>and</strong> Japan<br />

over the last 30 years, China’s GDP in nominal US dollars as a share<br />

of United States’ GDP has not changed much; it stayed more or less<br />

below 10 percent of United States’ nominal GDP. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, if you look at Japan, its GDP as a share of United States’<br />

GDP has converged to the size of the US GDP until the bubble<br />

collapsed in the 1990s.<br />

It is quite puzzling that although China has experienced quite<br />

high growth, it has not grown much in terms of nominal value of<br />

US dollars. This seems to indicate that the wealth from FDIgene<strong>rate</strong>d<br />

income is located overseas rather than within China. I<br />

wonder whether this is because the net value added in China’s<br />

exports has been minimal, mainly in the form of cheap labour<br />

income.<br />

The third issue I would like to comment on is whether there is an<br />

FDI diversion from ASEAN to China. This is a controversial issue,<br />

especially among Asian countries. However, I want to put this in<br />

perspective by asking whether the current trend of high FDI in<br />

China is a cyclical issue or a permanent phenomenon. If you look at<br />

the overall FDI flows to less-developed countries, excluding China,<br />

over the last several years, they have increased. Why have ASEAN<br />

countries received less FDI from the rest of the world? I think<br />

domestic factors play the major role. ASEAN countries were hit by<br />

the financial crisis of 1997-98 <strong>and</strong> the recovery from the crisis was<br />

further exacerbated by the September 11th terrorist attacks in the<br />

US. In addition, Islamic countries such as Indonesia <strong>and</strong> Malaysia<br />

may have suffered from a higher investment premium. Western<br />

investors may view these countries as quite risky, so they prefer not<br />

to move their assets to these countries for the time being.<br />

If we look at the adjusted per capita flows <strong>and</strong> stock figures of<br />

FDI, as the two authors mention, 25 percent of FDI from Hong<br />

Kong to China is round-tripped FDI. That is, Chinese money or<br />

investment is first taken to Hong Kong or other offshore facilities<br />

<strong>and</strong> is then taken back to China in order to enjoy tax incentives,<br />

favourable l<strong>and</strong> use concessions, better property protections, <strong>and</strong><br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


180<br />

Comment on Young Rok Cheong <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao<br />

other types of subsidies. If these tax incentives are going to be<br />

phased out with China’s WTO commitment, I feel that such capital<br />

flight may not return. After the dust has settled in the ASEAN<br />

economies, perhaps such capital from China will go to Malaysia or<br />

Indonesia, rather than go back to China.<br />

The fourth issue I would like to discuss is an interesting <strong>and</strong><br />

rather controversial one, that is, the prediction of the Lewis model<br />

the authors used: If the Lewis model is applicable, China is going to<br />

contribute to world deflation, or wage deflation at least. According<br />

to the authors, currently 224 million of Chinese would be<br />

participating in the world market, while two-thirds of the<br />

population are still waiting in line. If we think those people are<br />

waiting in line to get into the labour-intensive industry only, perhaps<br />

that kind of prediction could materialise. However, if we qualify this<br />

assumption by assuming that China will continue to grow with<br />

industrialisation <strong>and</strong> urbanisation, the non-tradable service sector<br />

will increase to a normal size as we have seen in most of the<br />

industrialised countries, <strong>and</strong>, as a result, the immiserising impact of<br />

Chinese export growth on the rest of the world will not take place.<br />

Thus, the participation ratio of Chinese workers in the world<br />

economy will be much lower than the authors’ prediction, <strong>and</strong> it is<br />

likely that a majority of people in China will engage in the nontradable<br />

service sector rather than compete internationally. Also, as I<br />

mentioned, China cannot maintain a 50 percent trade-to-GDP ratio<br />

forever. This ratio is obviously unsustainable for a continent-sized<br />

country like China.<br />

However, the issue is, as China’s nominal GDP ratio to Japan<br />

<strong>and</strong> the US shows, that China’s terms of trade have been flat over<br />

the years, despite the fact that it has been climbing the value-added<br />

product ladder. Perhaps the average wage rigidity, due to a lack of<br />

active bargaining power of the workers in the foreign-owned firms,<br />

might be the reason why wages cannot go up. And perhaps because<br />

of this problem, the income inequality in China in the 1990s has<br />

become worse. The problem is that local governments have great<br />

incentives to attract FDI, so in a sense, they tend to collude with<br />

foreign investors <strong>and</strong> the interests of workers may have been<br />

ignored here.<br />

What is the <strong>policy</strong> implication then? Wing Thye Woo has<br />

mentioned that one should try to increase the income of the rural<br />

sector. I think we should go a bit further <strong>and</strong> also look at the wage<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Li-Gang Liu<br />

181<br />

issue of FDI-funded firms. The question is whether the bargaining<br />

power of workers can be increased so that their wages can be<br />

increased through the bargaining process. In fact, this will be one of<br />

the solutions if China wants to sustain its growth by creating<br />

sustainable domestic dem<strong>and</strong> in the future. Almost 90 years ago,<br />

when Henry Ford offered his workers a wage of 5 dollars a day, a<br />

much higher wage than usual, he had an economic insight not<br />

apparent to most people at the time. If a majority of his workers<br />

could not afford to buy his Model-T automobiles, who would<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> them after productivity <strong>and</strong> efficiency were improved so<br />

immensely that the mass production of cars was no longer a fantasy?<br />

His insight proved to be right.<br />

Today, the world is facing a similar challenge: integrating large,<br />

populous <strong>and</strong> poor developing countries into the world market. If<br />

this succeeds, it will boost their manufacturing capacities because of<br />

their large pool of semi-skilled industrial workers <strong>and</strong>, at the same<br />

time, it will directly impact the welfare of industrial workers of the<br />

developed world. To address this challenge, the wage <strong>rate</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

income of those developing countries will have to go up so that their<br />

own large internal markets can dem<strong>and</strong> some of the goods<br />

produced. Besides waiting for the labour market alone to adjust the<br />

wage <strong>rate</strong>s in developing countries, this process can also be<br />

facilitated if governments in both developed <strong>and</strong> developing<br />

countries collectively pay attention to <strong>and</strong> enforce their labour laws<br />

so as to allow wage bargaining between workers <strong>and</strong> capitalists to<br />

take place. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the beneficiaries from the<br />

globalisation process, mostly the transnational corporations, will<br />

have to share some of their profits with the industrial workers in the<br />

developing countries. Similar to the insight of Henry Ford, it may<br />

be a difficult <strong>policy</strong> for some to accept at the moment. But for the<br />

sake of global prosperity, such measures will prove to be beneficial<br />

for everyone. Presumed as a champion for the welfare of workers<br />

<strong>and</strong> peasants, the Chinese government can play a decisive role in<br />

initiating a global movement that will benefit its own millions of<br />

industrial workers <strong>and</strong> peasants at home.<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


10<br />

Floor Discussion of “China’s Role<br />

in the Region <strong>and</strong> in the Global<br />

Financial System”<br />

The Park <strong>and</strong> Wang Paper<br />

Masaru Yoshitomi, former dean of the Asian Development Bank<br />

Institute (ADBI), wondered whether China’s economic boom<br />

would eventually end in a financial crisis <strong>and</strong> what could be done to<br />

prevent such a crisis from occurring. “The main reason for the<br />

Chiang Mai Initiative is that we want to prevent a crisis similar to<br />

the capital account crises that struck Asia in 1997, <strong>and</strong> to better<br />

manage such a crisis when it would occur. First of all, we have to<br />

underst<strong>and</strong> the real nature of the capital account crises of 1997. At<br />

the ADBI we have just released a report 1 that develops a set of <strong>policy</strong><br />

recommendations for China on how to sequence its financial<br />

liberalisation, given that the sequencing order of financial<br />

liberalisation was clearly the missing link when the World Bank<br />

published its Asian miracle report in 1993 <strong>and</strong> only four years later<br />

the Asian crisis erupted.<br />

The ADBI found that there was a huge gap between the new<br />

risks arising from financial liberalisation <strong>and</strong> deregulation (changing<br />

the incentives of borrowers <strong>and</strong> lenders), on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

pre-existing, old kind of institutions including prudential regulation<br />

<strong>and</strong> supervision, on the other h<strong>and</strong>. The old regulatory frameworks<br />

1<br />

ADBI, “Policy Proposals for Sequencing the PRC’s Domestic <strong>and</strong> External<br />

Financial Liberalization”, October 2002.<br />

182<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Floor Discussion<br />

183<br />

<strong>and</strong> institutions were clearly not prepared for managing the new<br />

risks under liberalisation because they had no idea about how to do<br />

capital account liberalisation. That is quite natural because under<br />

the old, regulated financial markets we did not need such concepts at<br />

all.<br />

The capital account crisis did, in fact, happen in the 1990s in<br />

Asia, <strong>and</strong> it might happen in the future in China as well. I have come<br />

to the conclusion that big financial crises usually occur after a real<br />

economic boom with some technological improvements. In this<br />

decade, the Chinese economy will continue to boom at least until we<br />

have the Olympics in 2008, <strong>and</strong> probably until 2010 when we have<br />

the World Expo, financed by the banks <strong>and</strong> so on. The WTO<br />

accession will liberalise financial services transactions in China by<br />

inviting all kinds of financial institutions. So at the end of this<br />

decade, there is likely to be a risky combination of a continued<br />

economic boom together with a real estate bubble financed by the<br />

banks, not by the securities market like in Japan in the 1980s.<br />

The de facto capital account liberalisation in China will probably<br />

end up in a capital account crisis because such crises tend to take<br />

place, not every year but every ten or fifteen years. In order to<br />

prevent a crisis from occurring in China, besides implementing the<br />

kind of <strong>policy</strong> recommendation on the sequencing order of financial<br />

liberalisation that we at the ADBI have suggested, we may also need<br />

the arrangements beyond the Chiang Mai Initiative that Yung Chul<br />

Park <strong>and</strong> Yunjong Wang have suggested in their paper. In my later<br />

panel presentation I will talk more about the kind of recommendations<br />

we have made in our ADBI report.” (See Chapter 17 of this<br />

volume.)<br />

Xie Ping, of the central bank of China, thought that it was not<br />

yet clear to the Chinese government how regional financial<br />

cooperation beyond the Chiang Mai agreement should be<br />

developed. “It is not clear because China receives too many different<br />

suggestions. One day the ADB makes a suggestion, one day the<br />

World Bank, one day the IMF, <strong>and</strong> another day the BIS. It has been<br />

suggested, for example, that we create an Asian bond market, <strong>and</strong><br />

that such a market would be very useful for the Asian countries<br />

including China. In the context of the Chiang Mai Initiative, last<br />

year we agreed on currency swaps with Japan, Thail<strong>and</strong>, Korea <strong>and</strong><br />

some other countries, amounting to about 10 or 20 billion dollars.<br />

Some people say that this amount is very small <strong>and</strong> that, if China<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


184<br />

China’s Role in the Region <strong>and</strong> in the Global Financial System<br />

would face a financial crisis, it would be absolutely nothing. So<br />

maybe this currency swap agreement is just symbolic. It may just<br />

mean that China participates actively in efforts at East Asian<br />

financial cooperation. Also, we have been discussing this Asian<br />

Monetary Fund proposal for a very long time. Some people are<br />

upset with it <strong>and</strong> are saying, ‘You cannot do this!’, while others are<br />

saying, ‘This is a good idea’. There are so many people with<br />

different opinions about the Asian Monetary Fund.<br />

Last week Professor Mundell from <strong>Columbia</strong> University, was in<br />

Beijing for a week. I met with him <strong>and</strong> he suggested to me that in<br />

the next 10 years, Asia should be united with one currency, <strong>and</strong> that<br />

this currency should be based on the Chinese yuan <strong>and</strong> the Japanese<br />

yen. He also thought that the Chinese yuan should be fully<br />

convertible before the 2008 Olympic Games. He gave us, the central<br />

bank, a lot of suggestions.”<br />

Wing Thye Woo, of the University of California, said that in<br />

every regional or global arrangement there is always an issue of<br />

economic power involved. “Look at Japan’s experience in the IMF.<br />

For many years, the Japanese tried to enlarge the capital base of the<br />

IMF to increase Japan’s voting power, but the Americans <strong>and</strong> the<br />

others resisted it. So any kind of regional financial institution set up<br />

now in Asia would mean locking in the present distribution of<br />

economic power. The president of such an institution would<br />

possibly be a Japanese, the executive vice-president a Chinese, the<br />

deputy vice-president a Korean. But let us say that we wait 20 years<br />

from now, perhaps the president <strong>and</strong> the next 5 executive vicepresidents<br />

would be all Chinese. So what’s the incentive for China<br />

to lock-in the present status-quo distribution of power?<br />

Another question is why China should be in favour of a regional<br />

bloc when its trade relationship is global in nature. It should be in<br />

favour of an Asian bloc only if this would be a building block toward<br />

multilateralism. Then the Chinese would be more enthusiastic about<br />

it. If you look at China’s aspirations for the future, I think it would<br />

see its interests better served by a multilateral world rather than a<br />

regional bloc; <strong>and</strong> if it has to be a regional bloc, it should be seen as<br />

a bargaining chip to push the multilateral agenda. That’s why I think<br />

the Chiang Mai Initiative has no life beyond monetary cooperation.”<br />

Geng Xiao, of the University of Hong Kong, agreed with Wing<br />

Thye Woo on the economic power issue in the Chiang Mai<br />

Initiative. “The difficulty of the Chiang Mai Initiative sort of effort<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Floor Discussion<br />

185<br />

is that, at present, there are no credible leaders. Japan has a problem<br />

with its financial system, <strong>and</strong> nobody knows how to fix it. China is<br />

basically free-riding on the US system, pegged with the US dollar<br />

<strong>and</strong> trading with the US. So it is indeed very important to go back<br />

to fundamentals, as Yoshitomi <strong>and</strong> the ADBI people have done, <strong>and</strong><br />

look at the so-called Asian miracle. If you look at Japan, Korea,<br />

Singapore, Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> all of these countries, they are all special<br />

cases of Asia in the sense that they are all small countries with a<br />

limited amount of labour supply <strong>and</strong> when the growth starts, the<br />

labour supply hits the limit <strong>and</strong> then wages go up. But in Asia, which<br />

has 50 percent of the world’s population, the typical Asian situation<br />

is the case of unlimited supply of labour, fitting into the traditional<br />

Lewis model, the dual sector model. When China started growing,<br />

we had a huge population at subsistence level wages <strong>and</strong> an<br />

unlimited supply of labour, <strong>and</strong> that had an immediate effect on the<br />

ten years of growth. If you look at the Asian countries, we have all<br />

these successful economies of Japan, Korea, Taiwan, <strong>and</strong> now China,<br />

<strong>and</strong> you always see these huge current account surpluses, which<br />

mean that these countries are exporting capital, are having huge<br />

savings. But at the same time we have a huge surplus of labour in<br />

Asia. This means that we have a surplus labour economy exporting<br />

capital to the capital-rich US economy instead of investing it in the<br />

unlimited supply of labour economies in Asia. If capital <strong>and</strong> labour<br />

combine in Asia, these two things will continue to drive Asian<br />

growth. But the problem now is that the capital cannot go to Asia, it<br />

can only go to the US, <strong>and</strong> from the US it goes back to Asia through<br />

FDI. So we are actually free-riding on the US system, largely<br />

because the US financial system is the most competitive system in<br />

the world.<br />

So in this sense, we have to go back to these fundamentals, to<br />

assess whether the free-riding on the US system is the best solution<br />

for Asia. Hong Kong is the typical case, it is just free-riding, <strong>and</strong><br />

there is no monetary <strong>policy</strong>. If Japan would resolve its banking<br />

problem, the Japanese interest <strong>rate</strong> would rise, which would help to<br />

better allocate resources because at a 0 percent interest <strong>rate</strong>, this<br />

capital just does not know where to go, it just goes to the US.<br />

We are all without choice just investing in the US, but at the<br />

same time we have so many resources in terms of labour, in terms of<br />

oil in Indonesia, all kind of resources. We have technology in Japan<br />

<strong>and</strong> in Taiwan, <strong>and</strong> we have financial markets in Hong Kong, but we<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


186<br />

China’s Role in the Region <strong>and</strong> in the Global Financial System<br />

are not using it. Last year, even Hong Kong had capital flight to the<br />

US. In Asia there is no leader, we are still relying on the US. But we<br />

have to ask ourselves whether that is the best solution.”<br />

Yung Chul Park was not sure that China would face a financial<br />

crisis in the next 10 to 15 years. “Whether China is going to be the<br />

next epicentre of a financial crisis within the next ten years or so<br />

depends upon a couple of assumptions. The first is, to what extent<br />

China is going to borrow from abroad, from the global market. The<br />

second is, to what extent China is going to borrow from other Asian<br />

countries. In the next 10 to 15 years, I don’t think China is going to<br />

borrow so much from outside. Since the savings <strong>rate</strong> is still very<br />

high, China will continue to run a current account surplus for some<br />

time. But the foreign debt of China will not go up to the level of<br />

Korea or Thail<strong>and</strong> or Indonesia, so the foreign debt-to-GDP ratio<br />

will remain very low.<br />

I am more concerned about domestic financial turbulence in<br />

China because of this non-performing loan problem <strong>and</strong> the<br />

bankruptcy of the state-owned banks. And this domestic instability<br />

may spill over to other East Asian countries <strong>and</strong> that might be<br />

something to worry about even though I think the spillover would be<br />

relatively small. So I am not as much worried about the possibility of<br />

China getting into a serious financial crisis as Yoshitomi.”<br />

Li-Gang Liu, of the ADBI, was puzzled about the leadership<br />

issue in Asian financial cooperation that Park <strong>and</strong> Wang raised at the<br />

end of their paper. “I am not sure that the analogy of Germany <strong>and</strong><br />

France, as leaders in European integration, necessary applies to<br />

China <strong>and</strong> Japan as leaders of Asian integration. In terms of<br />

economic size, China is just one-fifth of the Japanese economy. Also,<br />

if the rest of the Asian countries are further advanced in terms of<br />

financial services liberalisation, capital account liberalisation <strong>and</strong><br />

domestic financial liberalisation, why can’t they start some kind of a<br />

financial cooperation framework? China can always join at a later<br />

stage. The IMF system started without Russia, <strong>and</strong> the WTO did<br />

not have China as a member for many years, so why should the<br />

other countries, if they are willing to go ahead, wait for China?”<br />

Zdeněk Drábek, of the WTO, thought however that Chinese<br />

cooperation was of key importance. “Since the stability of the<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> in the region is important, the Chinese role in that<br />

context is important. It would be very useful for Korea, for Thail<strong>and</strong>,<br />

for Indonesia to know whether the Chinese are going to devalue their<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Floor Discussion<br />

187<br />

currency or not. So in that sense monetary cooperation with the<br />

Chinese is not premature but highly important.”<br />

In his reply to the comments, Yunjong Wang stressed that the<br />

basic aim of the Chiang Mai Initiative (CMI) <strong>and</strong> the Asian<br />

Monetary Fund (AMF) is to prevent financial crisis <strong>and</strong> manage the<br />

crisis better. “In terms of crisis prevention, we need two things: one<br />

is the swap facility <strong>and</strong> the other is the monitoring <strong>and</strong> surveillance<br />

system. Regarding the facility, the current CMI just links to the<br />

IMF, so if we are really satisfied with the current Chiang Mai swap<br />

scheme, we should probably be happy with the way in which the<br />

IMF deals with crisis prevention <strong>and</strong> management as well. Then we<br />

don’t need to go any further. But if we are dissatisfied with the role<br />

of the IMF <strong>and</strong> the current scheme of the CMI, then we should<br />

think about what kind of elements could be introduced to better<br />

prevent the crisis. Regarding the monitoring <strong>and</strong> surveillance<br />

system, the main task is to identify the emerging problems in East<br />

Asia. The <strong>policy</strong> dialogue has already started, but that’s not enough,<br />

we need a secretariat to detect <strong>and</strong> initiate a discussion about the<br />

emerging issues.<br />

Probably ASEAN+3 will just have to forget about exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

coordination, because it is too early. Currency union <strong>and</strong> currency<br />

unification is a delicate political issue. In terms of exchange stability,<br />

European countries have a different past, they started with the fixed<br />

exchange system, <strong>and</strong> they didn’t need to care too much about<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> stability. The Bretton Woods system guaranteed<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> stability through various ways, <strong>and</strong> for two decades<br />

the European countries had quite stable exchange <strong>rate</strong>s <strong>and</strong> also<br />

capital controls.<br />

In East Asia there are now different degrees of capital market<br />

opening. Geng Xiao talked about China’s free riding, but I think<br />

that China’s monetary <strong>policy</strong> is independent because China has a<br />

restrictive capital market opening. Hong Kong has a currency board<br />

system <strong>and</strong> its capital market is open, so it is very sensitive to US<br />

monetary <strong>policy</strong>. But China can maintain an independent monetary<br />

<strong>policy</strong>.<br />

Talking about currency unification, there is indeed this fact of<br />

status quo in economic power. It is a very important factor. If we<br />

pursue monetary unification, political will is important. Political<br />

scientists are trying to explain why the East Asian countries have no<br />

particular political will. European leaders have a kind of new<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


188<br />

China’s Role in the Region <strong>and</strong> in the Global Financial System<br />

functionalistic vision underpinning the European system. In Europe<br />

there is a lot of interaction between the countries <strong>and</strong> the spillover<br />

effects are large, so there is a natural need for <strong>policy</strong> coordination.<br />

But in East Asia we still have a relatively low degree of intraregional<br />

trade. It is increasing but it is still low. We also have<br />

minimal financial integration among the countries, but that is a less<br />

important factor. The most important factor is that countries have<br />

different <strong>policy</strong> objectives. For China, economic development is a<br />

more important issue than regional integration, <strong>and</strong> Japan may have<br />

yet another <strong>policy</strong> objective. Different political instruments are<br />

required for these different <strong>policy</strong> objectives. My conclusion is that<br />

it is probably still too early to say much about a high level of<br />

economic integration in East Asia.”<br />

The Cheong <strong>and</strong> Xiao Paper<br />

Robert McCauley, of the BIS, wondered whether the Lewis model,<br />

in the modern monetary world, would be the right way of looking at<br />

wages <strong>and</strong> employment in China. “The current world is quite<br />

different from the employment model when potential growth was<br />

reasonably well defined. For example, if the renmimbi were to<br />

revalue, would that mean that the nominal wage would simply go<br />

down more or less in proportion to the devaluation?”<br />

Geng Xiao explained that in the Lewis model, the real wage is<br />

determined by subsistence labour <strong>and</strong> the unemployment <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

“There is a lot of unskilled labour in China, <strong>and</strong> labourers are<br />

competing with each other to find a job. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, the wage<br />

level has to be higher than their incomes in the countryside <strong>and</strong>, on<br />

the other h<strong>and</strong>, they have to face the unemployment in the cities. So<br />

these two conditions more or less determine the wage <strong>rate</strong>. Chinese<br />

people have lived so many years of endurance <strong>and</strong> frustration in real<br />

income that they can deal with low wages. An exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

revaluation would probably have an effect on real wages, but not too<br />

much. On the longer time horizon of 5, 10, 20 years, wages are hard<br />

to change, largely because you have so many people coming out of<br />

the countryside who are looking for a job. Wages will go up largely<br />

when things become cheaper <strong>and</strong> the living st<strong>and</strong>ard increases. Food<br />

has become cheaper for everybody in China, including the people in<br />

the countryside, <strong>and</strong> that has increased their living st<strong>and</strong>ards.”<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Floor Discussion<br />

189<br />

Masaru Yoshitomi wondered how one could reconcile the fact<br />

that income in China has increased <strong>and</strong>, at the same time, a large<br />

part of the population still lives at a subsistence level. “How does the<br />

Lewis model apply to China? On the one h<strong>and</strong>, we are hearing that<br />

the income of people in China has increased over the past 20 years<br />

<strong>and</strong> that it will continue to increase in the next 20 years. But, on the<br />

other h<strong>and</strong>, Geng Xiao insists that the Lewis model applies because<br />

the wage level will continue to be based on wages at the subsistence<br />

level. How do you reconcile these two sort of conflicting facts?”<br />

Young Rok Cheong thought the explanation was quite simple.<br />

“These facts go together because there is a large inequality in<br />

income in different areas. Look at the per capita GDP in the cities,<br />

<strong>and</strong> at the difference between the top rich 9 cities <strong>and</strong> the rest. The<br />

gap is widening.”<br />

Yoshitomi insisted: “But the question is: Have the wages of the<br />

labourers who mig<strong>rate</strong>d to the coastal areas remained constant over<br />

the past 20 or 30 years? And are the wages in the coastal areas still<br />

determined by the subsistence level in the very remote areas in<br />

China? That is what I’m asking.”<br />

Cheong explained: “You will be surprised to know that wages for<br />

the workers in Guangdong in assembling lines in foreign investment<br />

enterprises are actually lower than probably in the whole nation<br />

because the competition in the labour market is so perfect that<br />

labourers are coming from all over China. If you want to find a job<br />

you go to the coastal cities. The wages there are not higher than in<br />

the interior cities.”<br />

Yoshitomi continued: “What kind of immigrants are they? Are<br />

they coming into the cities from relatively near or from remote<br />

areas?”<br />

Cheong: “Both, they are coming from the Western part of<br />

China, <strong>and</strong> they are coming from within the province. Many of the<br />

migrating workers are not seeking the job by themselves but are<br />

being sent by provincial governments. They organise the provision<br />

of cheap labour, as cheapest as possible, <strong>and</strong> export the labourers to<br />

the coastal areas. I visited many companies <strong>and</strong> they have their own<br />

dormitories <strong>and</strong> maintain a very low level of wages.”<br />

Geng Xiao added that for skilled labour, wages are increasing<br />

rapidly in China. “The wage income of the professors <strong>and</strong> the<br />

technicians is going up very fast, every year. The gap between skilled<br />

<strong>and</strong> unskilled labour is increasing rapidly. Wages for unskilled<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


190<br />

China’s Role in the Region <strong>and</strong> in the Global Financial System<br />

labour, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, remain low because you have plenty of<br />

supply. For example, when you advertise for a waitress, there are<br />

hundreds of people applying. How can you then increase the wage?<br />

Even in Hong Kong the wage for unskilled labour has not changed<br />

much, it is still the same as 10 years ago.”<br />

Charles Adams thought that at the time Lewis developed his<br />

model, he did not make a distinction between product wages <strong>and</strong><br />

consumption wages <strong>and</strong> that the subsistence argument is about the<br />

consumption wages. Second, he found it very odd to be talking<br />

about China’s exporting deflation. “At best it is an issue of relative<br />

prices. But in the case of the US, manufacture prices have been<br />

rising less rapidly than service prices for a long time, <strong>and</strong> well before<br />

China was potentially on the scene. So I suspect it has something to<br />

do with differential productivity. And just to make a provocative<br />

point: while it seems that one can make the case that the RMB does<br />

not need to appreciate vis-à-vis the US dollar, one can also make the<br />

case that the RMB should appreciate against the rest of Asia. What<br />

would happen if the US dollar weakened against the other Asian<br />

currencies <strong>and</strong> the RMB did not change?”<br />

Geng Xiao said that his quick answer would be that most Asian<br />

economies are pegged to the US dollar, “so when the US dollar<br />

changes everyone just follows”.<br />

Adams observed that there might be a de facto pegging, but on<br />

paper, most countries were floating. “So if we see <strong>adjustment</strong>s in<br />

other Asian currencies, then there will be an issue about the cross<strong>rate</strong><br />

between those currencies <strong>and</strong> the RMB. So all I’m asking you is,<br />

if you think on that margin, what would be your answer?”<br />

Xiao: “According to economic theory it is very simple: you just<br />

don’t mess with the exchange <strong>rate</strong>. The issue of prices <strong>and</strong> price<br />

changes is confusing in China because the country is not an<br />

equilibrium economy. The exchange <strong>rate</strong> is about inflation; it is<br />

about the price. In China, there are many sectors <strong>and</strong> many regions,<br />

all fragmented, <strong>and</strong> they are all trying to find equivalent prices. So<br />

the exchange <strong>rate</strong> is used as an anchor.”<br />

Adams: “I may be old-fashioned, but nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

changes have quite a profound effect on real exchange <strong>rate</strong>s, for a<br />

sustained period, in many countries.”<br />

Xiao: “That is true, but exchange <strong>rate</strong> fluctuations in China<br />

would also have a huge wealth impact in the sense that China’s<br />

holding of foreign assets are huge. I did some rough calculations:<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Floor Discussion<br />

191<br />

once you change the exchange <strong>rate</strong> by, say, 10 to 20 percent, there is<br />

going to be a redistribution of wealth in China of the range of 7 to 8<br />

percent of GDP. That is why I doubt whether China should have<br />

floating exchange <strong>rate</strong>s. The monetary system in China relies so<br />

heavily on the US dollar, 45 percent of China’s central bank assets<br />

are in US dollars, <strong>and</strong> 24 percent of China’s GDP is in US dollars.<br />

So if you mess with the exchange <strong>rate</strong>, you will stimulate huge<br />

speculations of people who will be trying to make money out of the<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> changes. That’s why the exchange <strong>rate</strong> in China<br />

should remain fixed. By remaining fixed, the renmimbi remains<br />

credible – at least, as long as China continues to have a surplus. And<br />

a fixed <strong>rate</strong> substantially reduces the risks for traders, producers,<br />

foreign investors <strong>and</strong> Chinese people. So, in my view, the current<br />

monetary system is the best for China. I don’t believe in the<br />

traditional IMF recipe because that is only right for an economy<br />

based on an equilibrium model. It is better to give China an<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> anchor, so that it can fully employ its labour force.<br />

Once that is realised, we can talk about floating <strong>and</strong> all the other<br />

traditional arguments coming into effect. But first China has to<br />

address the basic question of development.”<br />

Xiao stressed that China’s trade-to-GDP ratio of 45 percent was<br />

rather meaningless because of the minimal value-added in China’s<br />

exports, <strong>and</strong> that China would remain a very attractive country for<br />

foreign investors. “As a percentage of GDP, the value-added is very<br />

small <strong>and</strong> China’s GDP, in PPP terms, is highly undervalued. It is<br />

the opposite in Japan. Japan’s exports are only 10 percent of GDP<br />

because its GDP, in PPP terms, is overvalued. I don’t think that the<br />

potential of FDI into China is going to decline, largely because once<br />

every major multinational corporation has production facilities in<br />

China, you gene<strong>rate</strong> an economy of scale <strong>and</strong> scope that is going to<br />

have its own momentum. Look at what happened earlier in history<br />

in Manchester, New York, Chicago, Tokyo, Osaka – they have all<br />

become major manufacture centres of the world. The same is now<br />

happening in Shanghai <strong>and</strong> in Guangdong.”<br />

Yunjong Wang shared Xiao’s view that China would continue to<br />

attract foreign investors, because of its own large population <strong>and</strong><br />

that of neighbouring India. “I cannot see a turning point in foreign<br />

investment in the near future. India, with its large English speaking<br />

population, is trying to establish special economic zones along its<br />

coast. Just like China, India also has an unlimited supply of unskilled<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


192<br />

China’s Role in the Region <strong>and</strong> in the Global Financial System<br />

labour. The two countries together may have 1 billion unskilled<br />

labourers. That is going to attract a lot of capital. But we should be<br />

careful. There are still many foreign investors who do not want to<br />

invest in the western part of China. To attract foreign capital, you<br />

need a good infrastructure <strong>and</strong> a good working discipline. Foreign<br />

factories are mostly concent<strong>rate</strong>d on the coastal line <strong>and</strong> this might<br />

create growing inequality, undermining social cohesion <strong>and</strong> stability.<br />

However, both India <strong>and</strong> China have an enormous potential for<br />

foreign investments.”<br />

Geng Xiao emphasised that the competitive pressure of China in<br />

the world is just there, not only because of the Lewis model <strong>and</strong> the<br />

unlimited supply of labour, but also because of the mobility of<br />

institutions <strong>and</strong> of capital. “The successes of Shanghai <strong>and</strong> Hong<br />

Kong are tremendously important. You cannot believe how many<br />

people are focused on China, <strong>and</strong> how much advice is given to<br />

China. Look at the whole world, look at the major US <strong>and</strong><br />

European corporations, or at the major international, US <strong>and</strong><br />

European institutions, they all have China experts who study China,<br />

advise China, <strong>and</strong> think about China. All the high techs are in Hong<br />

Kong. So this is real. If China continues its success, the implications<br />

for the whole world are tremendous. It is so simple, I mean, 1000 or<br />

500 years ago we spent most of our time on getting food <strong>and</strong> shelter,<br />

but today one hour is for food <strong>and</strong> the other time is for<br />

entertainment. In a way, this relative price <strong>adjustment</strong> is good news,<br />

it means that now, in principle, it should be easy for everyone in the<br />

world to have a decent basic life. We have the technology, the<br />

knowledge <strong>and</strong> the institutions to realise that.”<br />

Zdeněk Drábek wondered about the importance of FDI for<br />

China’s growth. “How important is the foreign sector? What is really<br />

driving the growth? I would think that most of the aggregate dem<strong>and</strong><br />

is domestic <strong>and</strong> that most of the investment must be domestic<br />

investment. So I don’t think that foreign investment is the engine of<br />

economic growth in China. What is much more important is what the<br />

government is doing. I think that the fiscal <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> the investments<br />

by state enterprises are driving this big investment drive in China.”<br />

Young Rok Cheong agreed. “The magic is not just FDI or the<br />

unlimited supply of labour. The magic is to put everything together.<br />

The Chinese government is a very stable government <strong>and</strong> very<br />

open-minded to foreigners. And indeed, the infrastructure investments<br />

are huge <strong>and</strong> unprecedented in China.”<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


Floor Discussion<br />

193<br />

Cheong ended the discussion with three <strong>policy</strong> suggestions. “The<br />

first is that the Chinese government can <strong>and</strong> should allow the<br />

market to work. The market is working at the global level <strong>and</strong> it<br />

should also work at the national level. Second, once China fully<br />

employs all its surplus labour, it can apply the traditional recipes<br />

of economic equilibrium theory. China’s labour force provides<br />

competitive pressure to other countries, but it also harbours<br />

domestic risks, social risks. Third, the development of the domestic<br />

financial system in China is of key importance for sustained growth.<br />

Economic growth is facilitated by the protection of property rights,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the protection of property rights in China is coming through in<br />

the wrong way, through the foreign investment enterprises. Only<br />

when the foreigners came in, the government started to secure<br />

property rights <strong>and</strong> apply other st<strong>and</strong>ards of international practice<br />

in, for instance, the hiring of workers. Property rights protection is<br />

going to be the key for China to have success in the next stage. The<br />

financial sector is a derivative of the real sector <strong>and</strong> anything that<br />

goes wrong will be reflected in the financial sector. So by tracing the<br />

road for the financial sector in China, we can trace the road for<br />

maintaining growth <strong>and</strong> development.”<br />

From: China’s Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy - Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth,<br />

FONDAD, December 2003, www.fondad.org


State-owned<br />

enterprises in China<br />

Reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts9<br />

Xiao Geng, Xiuke Yang <strong>and</strong> Anna Janus<br />

Introduction<br />

Large-scale SOE reform in China has been going on since 1978. In spite of<br />

the Chinese Government’s efforts towards privatisation <strong>and</strong> its commitment<br />

to market-oriented development, SOEs remain a dominant part of the<br />

Chinese economy, especially among certain st<strong>rate</strong>gically important<br />

sectors, such as infrastructure construction, telecommunications, financial<br />

services, energy <strong>and</strong> raw materials. The question of how this apparent<br />

paradox can be resolved—<strong>and</strong> what the explanation might imply for<br />

our underst<strong>and</strong>ing of China—is the main focus for this chapter. Many<br />

questions arise in this context: should the Chinese Government continue<br />

its trend of privatising SOEs or should it continue to keep control of the<br />

largest <strong>and</strong> most important SOEs? Is there a set of implicit objectives in<br />

government policies that can explain China’s SOE reform dynamics in the<br />

past <strong>and</strong> predict future trends?<br />

SOE reform in China has been unique in many ways. Unlike the abrupt<br />

approach to privatisation adopted in Russia, which was followed by a<br />

collapse of the economies in all former Soviet Union partner countries in<br />

the last decade of the twentieth century, the more gradual approach taken<br />

in China has entailed a steady expansion of SOE assets <strong>and</strong> profits, as well<br />

as an accumulation of power <strong>and</strong> influence among SOEs. Unlike in India,<br />

which has to cope with high urban unemployment <strong>and</strong> poor industrial<br />

infrastructure, in China, the privatisation of SOEs has coincided with<br />

large-scale improvement of infrastructure <strong>and</strong> still relatively low urban<br />

unemployment.<br />

This chapter reviews the relative performance of large <strong>and</strong> mediumsized<br />

enterprises during the reform period in a comprehensive <strong>and</strong><br />

systematic way in order to reveal possible underlying patterns <strong>and</strong> trends.<br />

For this purpose, we have used three sets of data: sector-level annual<br />

155


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

survey data for China’s large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises<br />

from 1995 to 2005, collected by the National Bureau of Statistics; firmlevel<br />

survey data for China’s top-500 enterprises, published by the China<br />

Enterprise Confederation; <strong>and</strong> the Fortune Global 500 data published<br />

by Fortune Magazine. For our analysis, we have used the novel approach<br />

of grouping SOEs by sector into two categories: the competitive <strong>and</strong><br />

the st<strong>rate</strong>gic markets. This distinction was made based on the specific<br />

characteristics of the industry sectors. The competitive market contains<br />

sectors that relate to the manufacturing of consumer products. Sectors in<br />

this market have undergone intensive privatisation. The st<strong>rate</strong>gic market<br />

contains sectors such as infrastructure construction, financial services,<br />

energy <strong>and</strong> raw materials, where there are still government-imposed<br />

market entry barriers. Many government documents <strong>and</strong> research papers<br />

have cited such a distinction when discussing industrial <strong>policy</strong>, although<br />

there has been no official classification of which industries belong to<br />

competitive markets <strong>and</strong> which to st<strong>rate</strong>gic markets. The distinction we<br />

make in this chapter helps us unveil an implicit objective function behind<br />

the facts of SOE transformation in China. The analytical framework in this<br />

chapter also highlights the impacts of reforms on enterprise performance<br />

as well as on the Chinese economy <strong>and</strong> society. The results of this study<br />

show a comprehensive picture of SOE transformation <strong>and</strong> provide a useful<br />

foundation for consideration of future reforms.<br />

We begin with a review of the advancement of SOE transformation<br />

since the beginning of the reforms <strong>and</strong> an assessment of the current state<br />

of SOEs in China. We then explore the characteristic dynamics of SOE<br />

transformation in the main part of our chapter. Possible <strong>policy</strong> implications<br />

are then outlined.<br />

Progress of SOE reforms in China<br />

Background of SOE reform<br />

Under heavy influence from the Soviet Union, China gave birth to the<br />

SOEs about 50 years ago after the establishment of the People’s Republic of<br />

China <strong>and</strong> the socialist industrialisation that came soon after. In less than<br />

10 years, China nationalised virtually all private industrial enterprises<br />

during the 1950s. Before 1978—the year that marked the beginning<br />

of market-oriented transformation—China ope<strong>rate</strong>d its SOEs under a<br />

centrally planned economy. Since 1978, Chinese authorities have initiated<br />

156


State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

intensive reforms <strong>and</strong> privatisation of SOEs. At the macro level, the SOE<br />

reforms can be seen as a st<strong>rate</strong>gic <strong>adjustment</strong> of the nationalised <strong>and</strong><br />

centralised economy towards a more market-oriented economy; at the<br />

micro level, the reforms are intended to transform the Chinese SOEs into<br />

modern corporations. Specifically, SOE reforms fall into three successive<br />

phases.<br />

The first phase, from 1978 to 1984, concent<strong>rate</strong>d on increasing<br />

managerial autonomy in order to motivate the Chinese SOEs to pursue<br />

profit <strong>and</strong> growth. By loosening its hold on the planned economy, the<br />

Chinese Government to some degree began to weaken the link between<br />

the State <strong>and</strong> enterprises. Managers were essentially allowed to sell<br />

surplus production at market prices for a profit, once the planned quotas<br />

for production were met. The most important innovations during this<br />

period were the delegation of managerial autonomy from government<br />

bureaucracy to enterprise managers <strong>and</strong> the introduction of a dual-price<br />

system (the existing planned price for within-the-quota output <strong>and</strong> the<br />

new market price for above-the-quota output).<br />

The second phase, from 1985 to 1993, focused on separating company<br />

ownership <strong>and</strong> management by introducing a ‘contract responsibility’<br />

system. Managers signed a contract with the relevant government agencies<br />

<strong>and</strong> became the legal representatives of the SOE, consequently being held<br />

responsible for the company’s profits <strong>and</strong> losses. The idea of reform during<br />

this period was to transform SOEs into truly independent economic<br />

entities that were responsible for their own profits <strong>and</strong> losses, as well<br />

as to establish independent legal entities that shared certain rights <strong>and</strong><br />

obligations. The result was that the management teams tended to pursue<br />

short-term interests rather than long-term profitable growth because they<br />

had the rights only to ope<strong>rate</strong> SOEs but no clear property rights. The<br />

main problem of the ‘responsibility system’ is that the managers can easily<br />

share profits with the government <strong>and</strong> employees but are not practically<br />

capable of assuming losses <strong>and</strong> liabilities that might follow from their<br />

managerial decisions, since they do not own any significant amount of<br />

assets or property.<br />

The third phase, starting from 1993 <strong>and</strong> continuing into the present,<br />

emphasised transforming SOEs into modern corporations. The main<br />

elements of reform during this period include the policies of ‘grasping<br />

the large <strong>and</strong> letting go the small’, severing the link between the State<br />

<strong>and</strong> labour, as well as changing the State’s position towards shareholders<br />

157


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

under mixed ownership (state <strong>and</strong> non-state ownership). During this<br />

period, privatisation took place on a large scale, notably among small<br />

SOEs. Some of the largest SOEs are even being listed on the young Chinese<br />

stock markets <strong>and</strong> the Hong Kong Stock <strong>Exchange</strong>, usually with the State<br />

still holding about two-thirds of the shares in the listed companies.<br />

Current state of Chinese SOEs<br />

Even after more than two decades of market-oriented reforms, SOEs<br />

still play a prominent role in the Chinese economy. To examine the most<br />

relevant trends, our focus here will be on SOEs among large <strong>and</strong> mediumsized<br />

enterprises in China.<br />

In 2005, there were 3999 SOEs among all large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized<br />

industrial enterprises (25 per cent of the total), centralising assets of<br />

RMB6.09 trillion (58 per cent of the total) <strong>and</strong> generating a total profit of<br />

RMB268 billion (48 per cent of the total) (Table 9.1).<br />

Table 9.1<br />

Structure <strong>and</strong> performance of SOEs in large <strong>and</strong> mediumsized<br />

industrial enterprises, 2005<br />

Ownership No. SOEs Assets (RMB billion) Profit (RMB billion) ROA (%)<br />

State 3999 6090 268 4.40<br />

Collective 1331 343 23 6.62<br />

Private 5584 1110 68 6.13<br />

Foreign 5272 2880 203 7.05<br />

Total 16 186 10 423 562 5.39<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Source: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2005, China Statistical Yearbook 2005, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

Table 9.2<br />

Structure <strong>and</strong> performance of top-500 Chinese<br />

enterprises in 2007, by ownership (per cent)<br />

Ownership No. SOEs Assets Profit Employees Taxes ROA<br />

State 69.8 93.6 87.9 89.3 92.7 1.4<br />

Collective 5.8 4.2 2.2 2.4 1.7 0.8<br />

Private 17.8 1.7 7.1 7.0 3.9 6.1<br />

Foreign 6.6 0.5 2.8 1.3 1.7 8.5<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Source: A Report on the Development of China’s Enterprises 2007, Enterprise Management<br />

Publishing House, Beijing, Chapter 12, p. 88.<br />

158


State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

In 2007, of the top-500 Chinese enterprises, an astounding 69.8 per<br />

cent were SOEs, accounting for 94 per cent of asset value <strong>and</strong> creating<br />

88 per cent of the total profit (Table 9.2). SOEs are not only economically<br />

dominant, they are still socially relevant too, employing 89.3 per cent of<br />

the workforce <strong>and</strong> contributing 92.7 per cent of overall taxes.<br />

In 2007, of the top-500 Chinese manufacturing enterprises, almost 50<br />

per cent were SOEs, creating 61 per cent of the total profit (Table 9.3).<br />

Table 9.3<br />

Structure <strong>and</strong> performance of top-500 Chinese<br />

manufacturing enterprises in 2007, by ownership (per cent)<br />

Ownership No. SOEs Profit ROA<br />

State 49.8 61.1 3.2<br />

Collective 7.8 7.8 6.2<br />

Private 29.4 21.4 6.4<br />

Foreign 13.0 9.7 7.9<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Source: A Report on the Development of China’s Enterprises 2007, Enterprise Management<br />

Publishing House, Beijing, Chapter 13, p. 126.<br />

In 2007, of the top-500 Chinese service-sector enterprises, SOEs were<br />

even more dominant, accounting for 94 per cent of assets, 92 per cent of<br />

profit <strong>and</strong> 61 per cent of the number of firms (Table 9.4).<br />

Table 9.4<br />

Structure <strong>and</strong> performance of top-500 Chinese enterprises<br />

in the service industry in 2007, by ownership (per cent)<br />

Ownership No. SOEs Assets Profit ROA<br />

State 61.4 93.6 92.4 0.8<br />

Collective 11.4 5.4 1.1 0.2<br />

Private 23.2 0.8 5.3 5.3<br />

Foreign 4.0 0.1 1.2 8.3<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Source: A Report on the Development of China’s Enterprises 2007, Enterprise Management<br />

Publishing House, Beijing, Chapter 14, p. 137.<br />

Meanwhile, Chinese SOEs are also becoming a globally noticeable force.<br />

In 2007, there were 22 Chinese SOEs listed in the Fortune Global 500 <strong>and</strong><br />

China ranked sixth in the number of firms by country. The contributions<br />

of the 22 Chinese SOEs in the Fortune Global 500 include employment of<br />

13 per cent of the workforce, 3.6 per cent of overall profit <strong>and</strong> 3.8 per cent<br />

of total revenue (Table 9.5).<br />

159


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

Table 9.5<br />

Structure <strong>and</strong> performance of Fortune Global 500 in<br />

2007, by country (per cent)<br />

Country No. firms Assets Revenue Profit No. employees ROA<br />

United States 32.4 25.5 35.1 38.5 34.1 2.7<br />

Japan 13.4 9.4 11.5 7.0 9.4 1.3<br />

France 7.6 10.9 8.7 7.4 9.7 1.2<br />

Germany 7.4 9.5 8.8 5.7 8.9 1.1<br />

Britain 6.6 12.1 7.4 8.3 6.1 1.2<br />

China 4.4 4.7 3.8 3.5 13.0 1.4<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Source: ‘Fortune Global 500’, Fortune Magazine, 23 July 2007.<br />

In addition, the Chinese SOEs accounted for three of the top-five<br />

largest employers in the world in 2006 (Table 9.6) <strong>and</strong> three of the top-five<br />

enterprises in Asia in terms of revenue (Table 9.7).<br />

Table 9.6<br />

Top-five enterprises in Asia in 2006, by revenue<br />

Company Country Revenue ($million)<br />

Toyota Motors Japan 204 746.4<br />

Sinopec China 131 636<br />

China National Petroleum China 110 520.2<br />

State Grid China 107 185.5<br />

Honda Motors Japan 94 790.5<br />

Source: ‘Fortune Global 500’, Fortune Magazine, 23 July 2007.<br />

Table 9.7 Top-five biggest employers in the world, 2006<br />

Company Country No. employees<br />

Wal-Mart Stores United States 1 900 000<br />

State Grid China 1 504 000<br />

China National Petroleum China 1 086 966<br />

US Postal Service United States 796 199<br />

Sinopec China 681 900<br />

Source: ‘Fortune Global 500’, Fortune Magazine, 23 July 2007.<br />

For the SOE reforms in the past 30 years, however, revenues <strong>and</strong> profits<br />

have consistently run ahead of deeper enterprise transformation such<br />

as improvement of operating efficiency <strong>and</strong> enhancement of industrial<br />

productivity. The return on assets (ROA) of Chinese SOEs in the top-500<br />

Chinese enterprises was only 1.4 per cent in 2007—lagging far behind<br />

non-state enterprises (NSEs) in China, such as private-owned enterprises<br />

160


State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

(6.08 per cent) <strong>and</strong> foreign-funded enterprises (8.48 per cent) (Table 9.2).<br />

As for return on equity (ROE), it is only 10.07 per cent for the heavily<br />

SOE-dominated top-500 Chinese enterprises—performing far worse than<br />

the Fortune Global 500 average of 16.13 per cent (Table 9.8).<br />

Table 9.8<br />

Performance of top-500 Chinese <strong>and</strong> global companies<br />

(per cent)<br />

ROA<br />

ROE<br />

Top-500 Chinese enterprises 1.82 10.07<br />

Fortune Global 500 companies 1.79 16.13<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

ROE = return on equity<br />

Sources: A Report on the Development of China’s Enterprises 2007, Enterprise Management<br />

Publishing House, Beijing; ‘Fortune Global 500’, Fortune Magazine, 23 July 2007.<br />

Clearly, apart from increasing revenues <strong>and</strong> profits, Chinese SOEs<br />

still show major deficiencies in regard to efficiency <strong>and</strong> productivity. As<br />

a major economic force in China, they are also quickly becoming more<br />

relevant on a global scale. There appears therefore to be a continuing<br />

need for reform <strong>and</strong> enhanced policies for SOEs in China. In order for<br />

China’s economic transformation to be successful, we have to recognise<br />

accu<strong>rate</strong>ly what is happening in the Chinese SOEs. For this purpose, this<br />

chapter attempts to shed some light on the underlying characteristics of<br />

SOE reform in China.<br />

The dynamics of SOE reform in China<br />

Our analytical approach<br />

In order to highlight the special characteristics of SOE reform in China,<br />

this chapter uses sector-level annual survey data from China’s large <strong>and</strong><br />

medium-sized industrial enterprises during 1995–2005, which are collected<br />

at the firm level <strong>and</strong> maintained at the National Bureau of Statistics<br />

(NBS) in China. The sector-level data allow us to compare enterprise<br />

performance across ownership, industry <strong>and</strong> time. The NBS survey covers<br />

all of the large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises in 38 sectors<br />

(Appendix 9.1). In addition to differentiating firms by ownership <strong>and</strong> by<br />

sector (as other studies have done), this chapter groups the 38 sectors into<br />

two overall categories: the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market <strong>and</strong> the competitive market<br />

(Appendices 9.2 <strong>and</strong> 9.3). The st<strong>rate</strong>gic market, including the sectors of<br />

161


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

infrastructure construction, energy <strong>and</strong> raw materials, has been providing<br />

critical infrastructure support for the Chinese national economy, whereas<br />

the competitive market, including sectors related to personal services <strong>and</strong><br />

the manufacturing of consumer products, is essential to improving the<br />

living st<strong>and</strong>ards of the Chinese people. Such a distinction allows us to<br />

systematically interpret reform processes <strong>and</strong> to derive considerations <strong>and</strong><br />

st<strong>rate</strong>gies for future SOE reform.<br />

Special characteristics of SOE reform in China<br />

The transformation of SOEs has been characterised on the one h<strong>and</strong> by a<br />

rapid decline in the number of SOEs <strong>and</strong> on the other h<strong>and</strong> by a steady<br />

accumulation <strong>and</strong> expansion of state-owned assets as well as profits in<br />

large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises.<br />

The number of Chinese SOEs in large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial<br />

enterprises was 15 107 in 1995 <strong>and</strong> diminished to 3999 in 2005—a loss<br />

of 73.5 per cent—<strong>and</strong> the number of all industrial SOEs fell from 118 000<br />

in 1995 to 27 500 in 2005, a loss of 76.7 per cent (Table 9.9). The sharp<br />

decrease in the number of SOEs shows how dramatically privatisation has<br />

taken place in the course of reforms.<br />

Table 9.9 The number of industrial SOEs in China, 1995–2005<br />

Year<br />

No. industrial SOEs<br />

(all sizes)<br />

No. industrial SOEs<br />

(large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized)<br />

1995 118 000 15 107<br />

2000 53 500 9144<br />

2005 27 500 3999<br />

Sources: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 1995, China Statistical Yearbook 1995, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2000, China Statistical Yearbook<br />

2000, China Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2005, China Statistical<br />

Yearbook 2005, China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

162<br />

The state-owned assets in large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial<br />

enterprises, however, steadily accumulated from RMB3.89 trillion in 1995<br />

to RMB6.09 trillion in 2005 (Table 9.10), with a compound annual growth<br />

<strong>rate</strong> of 4.6 per cent for 10 years. At the same time, the profit gene<strong>rate</strong>d<br />

from large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized state-owned industrial enterprises also<br />

soared—from RMB70.8 billion in 1995 to RMB268 billion in 2005, with a<br />

compound annual growth <strong>rate</strong> as high as 14.2 per cent—indicating that the<br />

privatisation <strong>and</strong> transformation of SOEs during this period contributed<br />

to a dramatic increase in state-owned profits <strong>and</strong> assets, which enhanced<br />

the government’s financial, political <strong>and</strong> social net asset value.


State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

Table 9.10 Assets <strong>and</strong> profits of SOEs in large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized<br />

industrial enterprises<br />

Year Assets (RMB billion) Profit (RMB billion) ROA (%)<br />

1995 3890 70.8 1.82<br />

2000 4640 87.4 1.88<br />

2005 6090 268 4.40<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Sources: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 1995, China Statistical Yearbook 1995, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2000, China Statistical Yearbook<br />

2000, China Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2005, China Statistical<br />

Yearbook 2005, China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

Starting with these observations, we explore two key hypotheses about<br />

SOE reform in China.<br />

Hypothesis 1<br />

SOEs are more likely to be privatised when they are losing profit in the<br />

competitive market.<br />

If we examine the competitive market <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market<br />

sepa<strong>rate</strong>ly (Table 9.11), we can see that the number of SOEs in the<br />

competitive market has diminished dramatically from 12 128 in 1995 to<br />

1975 in 2005 (a loss of 83.7 per cent). However, the amount of state-owned<br />

assets in the competitive market remained relatively stable (falling from<br />

RMB1819 billion in 1995 to RMB1423 billion in 2005).<br />

Table 9.11 The number <strong>and</strong> performance of SOEs in the competitive<br />

market<br />

Year No. SOEs Assets (RMB billion) Profit (RMB billion) ROA (%)<br />

1995 12 128 1819 9 0.51<br />

2000 6872 1902 7 0.38<br />

2005 1975 1423 27 1.89<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Sources: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 1995, China Statistical Yearbook 1995, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2000, China Statistical Yearbook<br />

2000, China Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2005, China Statistical<br />

Yearbook 2005, China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

At the same time, the change in the number of SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic<br />

market was less extreme—from 2979 in 1995 to 2024 in 1995 (a loss of only<br />

32 per cent)—yet there was a remarkable increase in state-owned assets,<br />

from RMB1.99 trillion to RMB4.66 trillion (Table 9.12).<br />

163


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

Table 9.12 The number <strong>and</strong> performance of SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic<br />

market<br />

Year No. SOEs Assets (RMB billion) Profit (RMB billion) ROA (%)<br />

1995 2979 1985 62 3.10<br />

2000 2272 2642 80 3.03<br />

2005 2024 4664 241 5.17<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Sources: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 1995, China Statistical Yearbook 1995, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2000, China Statistical Yearbook<br />

2000, China Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2005, China Statistical<br />

Yearbook 2005, China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

Looking more closely at the competitive market (Table 9.11), it is<br />

striking to see that the ROA of SOEs was as low as 0.5 per cent in 1995,<br />

0.4 per cent in 2000 <strong>and</strong> 1.9 per cent in 2005—lagging far behind the ROA<br />

achieved by SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market, which was 3.1 per cent in 1995,<br />

3.0 per cent in 2000 <strong>and</strong> 5.2 per cent in 2005 (Table 9.12). The ROA of<br />

SOEs in the competitive market was also significantly lower than the ROA<br />

of NSEs—4.6 per cent in 1995, 6.26 per cent in 2000 <strong>and</strong> 7.04 per cent<br />

in 2005 (Table 9.14).<br />

The above empirical evidence shows privatisation has been rather<br />

instrumental in the ab<strong>and</strong>onment of less-profitable <strong>and</strong> less-efficient SOEs<br />

<strong>and</strong> thus reducing financial, social <strong>and</strong> political liabilities arising from<br />

loss-making SOEs.<br />

Hypothesis 2<br />

When SOEs are profitable in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market, their sector’s state<br />

monopoly is more likely to be maintained.<br />

Looking more closely at the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market, the number of SOEs has<br />

remained relatively stable during the reform period, while the number<br />

of assets accumulated in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market has soared remarkably.<br />

Moreover, the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market was also immensely profitable, with a rise<br />

in total profit from RMB61.5 billion in 1995 to RMB241.2 billion in 2005<br />

(Table 9.12). Enterprises in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market had an average ROA of 5.17<br />

per cent in 2005 compared with 1.89 per cent in the competitive market.<br />

The government’s strong grip on the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market is obvious from the<br />

proportion of state-owned assets to total assets in the respective sectors.<br />

In the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market, state-owned assets accounted for 56 per cent of<br />

total assets, while in the competitive market the number was only 15 per<br />

164


State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

cent in 2005 (Table 9.13). The st<strong>rate</strong>gic market comprises various sectors<br />

in which SOEs still hold monopolies, such as infrastructure <strong>and</strong> energy,<br />

<strong>and</strong> it becomes evident from our analysis that SOEs in this market have<br />

been consistently maintained. From the view of the government, reforms<br />

of SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market have led to an increase in profit <strong>and</strong> asset<br />

value <strong>and</strong> a strengthening of social <strong>and</strong> political assets.<br />

Table 9.13 Total assets in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic <strong>and</strong> competitive markets<br />

in 2005 (RMB billion)<br />

State-owned assets Total assets State-owned assets (%)<br />

Total 6086.7 17 632.5 34.5<br />

The st<strong>rate</strong>gic market 4663.7 8338.9 55.9<br />

The competitive market 1423 9293.6 15.3<br />

Source: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2005, China Statistical Yearbook 2005, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

General implications<br />

If we combine the preceding observations from the competitive market <strong>and</strong><br />

the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market, we can see how SOE reforms have left the government<br />

fundamentally better off. In the competitive market, the number of lessefficient<br />

<strong>and</strong> less-profitable SOEs was dramatically reduced, while in the<br />

st<strong>rate</strong>gic market SOEs were guarded <strong>and</strong> profits soared. At the same time,<br />

this course of reforms has significant wider implications.<br />

Impact on NSEs: infrastructural support <strong>and</strong><br />

price controls<br />

SOE reforms have successfully created room for non-state enterprises<br />

(NSEs) to grow. Assets in NSEs have soared from RMB1264.6 billion in<br />

1995 to RMB11 545.8 billion in 2005, with profit rising from RMB58.2<br />

billion in 1995 to RMB812.6 billion in 2005 (Table 9.14).<br />

The dominance of SOEs in China’s st<strong>rate</strong>gic market has contributed<br />

to this success in two distinct ways. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, SOEs still hold<br />

state monopolies over critical sectors such as infrastructure. By centrally<br />

coordinating <strong>and</strong> pursuing its efforts in these regards, the Chinese<br />

Government has managed to provide an extensive <strong>and</strong> ever-growing<br />

infrastructure network as one of the pillars of overall economic growth.<br />

165


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

Table 9.14 Performance of NSEs in large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial<br />

enterprises<br />

Year Assets (RMB billion) Profit (RMB billion) ROA (%)<br />

1995 1264.6 58.2 4.60<br />

2000 3584.2 224.4 6.26<br />

2005 11 545.8 812.6 7.04<br />

ROA = return on assets<br />

Sources: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 1995, China Statistical Yearbook 1995, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2000, China Statistical Yearbook<br />

2000, China Statistics Press, Beijing; National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2005, China Statistical<br />

Yearbook 2005, China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

The growth in infrastructure is outst<strong>and</strong>ing: in the area of transportation<br />

routes, the length of railways in operation extended from 59 700 kilometres<br />

in 1995 to 77 100km in 2006 (up 28 per cent). The length of highways<br />

extended from 1.16 million km in 1995 to 3.46 million in 2006 (up 200 per<br />

cent) <strong>and</strong> the length of civil aviation routes extended from 1.13 million km<br />

in 1995 to about 2.11 million km in 2006 (up 87 per cent). Postal delivery<br />

routes, which were about 1.9 million km in length in 1995, extended to 3.4<br />

million km at the end of 2006 (up 79 per cent). As for telecommunications,<br />

the capacity of mobile telephone exchanges extended from 8 million<br />

subscribers in 1995 to 610 million subscribers in 2006 (up 7525 per cent),<br />

<strong>and</strong> broadb<strong>and</strong> subscriber ports extended from 18 million ports in 2003 to<br />

65 million ports in 2006 (up 260 per cent) (see Appendices 9.4–7 for details<br />

on infrastructure growth).<br />

Another channel through which the dominant position of SOEs in the<br />

st<strong>rate</strong>gic market has contributed to NSE growth is by upholding price controls.<br />

Since SOEs still hold monopolies in these st<strong>rate</strong>gically relevant sectors, the<br />

prices of energy, water <strong>and</strong> resources are kept artificially low. On the one<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, this serves Chinese consumers. On the other, private <strong>and</strong> other nonstate<br />

enterprises also benefit notably from this favourable price environment.<br />

The implicit subsidisation of the private sector, however—including<br />

many foreign-invested enterprises—through lower than market prices in<br />

key inputs implies that China is subsidising global consumers of madein-China<br />

products. It has also attracted many energy-intensive <strong>and</strong><br />

environmentally harmful industrial activities to China. On the whole, the<br />

price controls that followed from the tight control by the government of<br />

SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market have led to significant hidden social costs. It<br />

will be interesting to see how long China can sustain the price control <strong>and</strong><br />

the implicit subsidies to domestic <strong>and</strong> international firms <strong>and</strong> consumers.<br />

166


Distorted distribution of wealth<br />

State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

SOE transformation has so far increased state-owned assets <strong>and</strong> profits.<br />

The resulting wealth distribution seems unbalanced, as state-owned assets<br />

are centralised within the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market. While about 51 per cent of all<br />

SOEs are included in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market, the assets accumulated here<br />

amount to RMB4664 billion, or 77 per cent of total state-owned assets in<br />

large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises. At the same time, profit<br />

gene<strong>rate</strong>d from SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market amounts to RMB241 billion,<br />

which equals 90 per cent of the total profit gene<strong>rate</strong>d from large <strong>and</strong><br />

medium-sized SOEs (Table 9.15).<br />

Table 9.15 Structure <strong>and</strong> performance of SOEs in st<strong>rate</strong>gic <strong>and</strong><br />

competitive markets, 2005 (per cent)<br />

Total St<strong>rate</strong>gic market Competitive market<br />

No. SOEs 100 51.61 49.39<br />

Assets 100 76.62 23.38<br />

Profit 100 89.97 10.03<br />

Source: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2005, China Statistical Yearbook 2005, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

The centralisation of assets <strong>and</strong> profits in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market <strong>and</strong> the<br />

strengthened monopoly position of SOEs in the most profitable sectors of<br />

the Chinese economy, as well as the low efficiency <strong>and</strong> low productivity<br />

of SOEs, all indicate a distorted allocation of wealth. This is prone to<br />

hinder innovation <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurship in China’s largest companies <strong>and</strong><br />

most important sectors, as well as encumbering enterprise efficiency <strong>and</strong><br />

industrial productivity.<br />

Impact on China’s consumption <strong>and</strong> savings<br />

Retaining profitable SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market also has major implications<br />

for China’s <strong>macroeconomic</strong> balance. Since SOE dividends are not paid out<br />

to shareholders, a major source of wealth <strong>and</strong> income is held back. As<br />

a result, household consumption is about only 37 per cent of GDP <strong>and</strong><br />

household income is about 45 per cent of national income (Table 9.16).<br />

High savings held by SOEs <strong>and</strong> the government (through high taxation)<br />

are among the key reasons for China’s low consumption <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> large<br />

current account surplus.<br />

167


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

Table 9.16 China’s household income <strong>and</strong> consumption, 2007<br />

(RMB billion) Percentage of GDP (%)<br />

Household income 11 198 45<br />

Household consumption 9332 37<br />

Note: Household income is estimated using data on per capita income of rural <strong>and</strong> urban<br />

households multiplied by the respective population estimates.<br />

Source: National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 2008, China Statistical Yearbook 2008, China<br />

Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

Concentration of SOEs among top-500 Chinese<br />

companies<br />

After several stages of reform, Chinese SOEs still dominate among large<br />

enterprises in China to a remarkable degree. SOEs account for 70 per cent<br />

of the Chinese top-500 enterprises, 94 per cent of assets <strong>and</strong> 88 per cent of<br />

profits. The Chinese SOEs also contribute 93 per cent of the taxes gene<strong>rate</strong>d<br />

from, <strong>and</strong> employ 89 per cent of the total workforce in the Chinese top-<br />

500 enterprises (Table 9.2). Although the Chinese SOEs perform worse<br />

than non-state enterprises such as collective-owned enterprises, privateowned<br />

enterprises <strong>and</strong> foreign-funded enterprises, they still dominate<br />

among large manufacturing enterprises. In the manufacturing sector, SOEs<br />

account for about 50 per cent of firms, contributing 61 per cent of the<br />

total profit gene<strong>rate</strong>d from the top-500 Chinese manufacturing enterprises<br />

(Table 9.3). In the service sector, SOEs account for 61 per cent of firms, 93<br />

per cent of assets <strong>and</strong> 92 per cent of profits among the top-500 Chinese<br />

enterprises in the service industry (Table 9.4).<br />

Even globally, Chinese SOEs are becoming more <strong>and</strong> more significant.<br />

The number of Chinese enterprises in the Fortune Global 500 increased<br />

from 15 in 2005 to 22 in 2007 <strong>and</strong> China ranked sixth in 2007 in the<br />

number of firms by country (Table 9.17).<br />

Table 9.17 The number of Chinese enterprises in the Fortune<br />

Global 500<br />

Year<br />

No. of Chinese enterprises<br />

2005 15<br />

2006 19<br />

2007 22<br />

Note: All of the Chinese enterprises in the Fortune Global 500 are SOEs.<br />

Source: ‘Fortune Global 500’, Fortune Magazine, 23 July 2007.<br />

168


Some <strong>policy</strong> implications<br />

State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

To address the apparent shortcomings of past SOE reforms, we propose<br />

full privatisation as part of a large-scale reform of China’s financial sector. 1<br />

Reforms should focus on limiting the role of the State <strong>and</strong> increasing<br />

the global competitiveness of Chinese enterprises. We present several<br />

recommendations for such a scenario:<br />

• all large SOEs under central or local-government control should be<br />

listed within a short period—that is, five to 10 years<br />

• for SOEs that are already listed, state ownership should be reduced to<br />

a minority shareholder level—for example, below 30 per cent—within<br />

three to five years<br />

• state-owned shares should be limited to less than 50 per cent for all<br />

new initial public offerings (IPOs)<br />

• listed SOEs should be required to have a plan to further reduce state<br />

ownership—for example, to below 30 per cent—within three to five<br />

years after their IPO.<br />

Majority state ownership is neither necessary to represent the interests<br />

of the State nor advantageous in improving the competitiveness of the<br />

listed company. The interest of the State can still be maintained through<br />

one golden share that gives the State veto power against any decisions by<br />

the board that are potentially harmful to the national interest or national<br />

security.<br />

Summary <strong>and</strong> conclusion<br />

By using various statistical data, this chapter examines the transformation<br />

of SOEs during the reform period from 1995 to 2005, which has been<br />

characterised on the one h<strong>and</strong> by a sharp decline in the number of firms<br />

<strong>and</strong> on the other h<strong>and</strong> by a steady accumulation of state-owned assets.<br />

The results of this study show that it is the competitive market where<br />

there is a sharp decline in the number of SOEs <strong>and</strong> the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market<br />

where there is a steady accumulation of state-owned assets. We have shown<br />

how Chinese SOEs are more likely to be privatised when they are losing<br />

profit. When they are more profitable, their sector’s monopoly position is<br />

more likely to be strengthened, which leads us to the conclusion that the<br />

privatisation of SOEs in China has been driven by an implicit objective<br />

of the government to maximise financial, social <strong>and</strong> political assets <strong>and</strong><br />

minimise financial, social <strong>and</strong> political liabilities.<br />

169


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

Moreover, we point out that this specific course of reform has affected<br />

China’s <strong>macroeconomic</strong> environment in a number of ways. NSEs have<br />

benefited from the continuing monopoly position of SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic<br />

market in the sense that they can take advantage of a vast system of<br />

basic infrastructure, as well as of lasting price controls on energy <strong>and</strong><br />

resources. The over-concentration of SOEs in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market seems<br />

to have served specific government purposes to bolster the nation’s<br />

economic growth. Low efficiency <strong>and</strong> productivity in these sectors still<br />

hinder innovation <strong>and</strong> entrepreneurship in China’s largest companies <strong>and</strong><br />

in China’s most important sectors. Apart from this domestic problem of a<br />

distorted distribution of wealth, the global impacts of the ever-growing<br />

Chinese SOEs will not be ignored abroad. Therefore, there will be a further<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for transformation of the Chinese SOEs with pressure coming from<br />

domestic consumers <strong>and</strong> politics, as well as from international competition<br />

<strong>and</strong> international politics.<br />

References<br />

A Report on the Development of China’s Enterprises 2007, Enterprise<br />

Management Publishing House, Beijing.<br />

‘Fortune Global 500’, Fortune Magazine, 23 July 2007.<br />

National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) 1995, China Statistical Yearbook 1995,<br />

China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

—— 2000, China Statistical Yearbook 2000, China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

—— 2005, China Statistical Yearbook 2005, China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

—— 2008, China Statistical Yearbook 2008, China Statistics Press, Beijing.<br />

Ten <strong>policy</strong> recommendations to build Shanghai into a top international<br />

financial center within a decade, Brookings-Tsinghua Center Working<br />

Paper, Brookings-Tsinghua Center, Beijing.<br />

Endnotes<br />

1. See Ten <strong>policy</strong> recommendations to build Shanghai into a top international financial center<br />

within a decade, Brookings-Tsinghua Center Working Paper, Brookings-Tsinghua Center,<br />

Beijing.<br />

170


State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

Appendix 9.1 List of industry codes <strong>and</strong> the full<br />

industry name<br />

06 Coal mining <strong>and</strong> dressing (CMD)<br />

07 Petroleum <strong>and</strong> natural gas extraction (PNGE)<br />

08 Ferrous metals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing (FMMD)<br />

09 Non-ferrous metals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing (NFMMD)<br />

10 Non-metal minerals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing (NMMD)<br />

13 Food processing (FPc)<br />

14 Food production (FPd)<br />

15 Beverage production (BP)<br />

16 Tobacco processing (TP)<br />

17 Textile industry (TI)<br />

18 Garments <strong>and</strong> other fibre products (GOFP)<br />

19 Leather, furs, down <strong>and</strong> related products (LFDRP)<br />

20 Timber, bamboo, cane, palm fibre <strong>and</strong> straw (TBCPFS)<br />

21 Furniture manufacturing (FM)<br />

22 Papermaking <strong>and</strong> paper products (PPP)<br />

23 Printing <strong>and</strong> recording medium reproduction (PRMR)<br />

24 Cultural, educational <strong>and</strong> sporting goods (CESG)<br />

25 Petroleum processing <strong>and</strong> coking (PPC)<br />

26 Raw chemical materials <strong>and</strong> chemicals (RCMC)<br />

27 Medical <strong>and</strong> pharmaceutical products (MPP)<br />

28 Chemical fibre (CF)<br />

29 Rubber products (RP)<br />

30 Plastic products (PP)<br />

31 Non-metal mineral products (NMP)<br />

32 Smelting <strong>and</strong> pressing of ferrous metals (SPFM)<br />

33 Smelting <strong>and</strong> pressing of non-ferrous metals (SPNFM)<br />

171


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

34 Metal products (MP)<br />

35 Ordinary machinery manufacturing (OMM)<br />

36 Special purposes equipment manufacturing (SPEM)<br />

37 Transport equipment manufacturing (TEM)<br />

39 Electric equipment <strong>and</strong> machinery (EEM)<br />

40 Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications equipment (ETE)<br />

41 Apparatus <strong>and</strong> instruments (AI)<br />

42 Cultural, office machinery <strong>and</strong> other manufacturing (COMOM)<br />

43 Recycling industry (RI)<br />

44 Electric power, steam <strong>and</strong> hot water (EPSHW)<br />

45 Gas production <strong>and</strong> supply (GPS)<br />

46 Tap water production <strong>and</strong> supply (TWPS)<br />

172


State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

Appendix 9.2 List of sectors in the st<strong>rate</strong>gic market<br />

06 Coal mining <strong>and</strong> dressing (CMD)<br />

07 Petroleum <strong>and</strong> natural gas extraction (PNGE)<br />

08 Ferrous metals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing (FMMD)<br />

09 Non-ferrous metals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing (NFMMD)<br />

10 Non-metal minerals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing (NMMD)<br />

16 Tobacco processing (TP)<br />

25 Petroleum processing <strong>and</strong> coking (PPC)<br />

27 Medical <strong>and</strong> pharmaceutical products (MPP)<br />

32 Smelting <strong>and</strong> pressing of ferrous metals (SPFM)<br />

33 Smelting <strong>and</strong> pressing of non-ferrous metals (SPNFM)<br />

44 Electric power, steam <strong>and</strong> hot water (EPSHW)<br />

45 Gas production <strong>and</strong> supply (GPS)<br />

46 Tap water production <strong>and</strong> supply (TWPS)<br />

173


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

Appendix 9.3 List of sectors in the competitive market<br />

13 Food processing (FPc)<br />

14 Food production (FPd)<br />

15 Beverage production (BP)<br />

17 Textile industry (TI)<br />

18 Garments <strong>and</strong> other fibre products (GOFP)<br />

19 Leather, furs, down <strong>and</strong> related products (LFDRP)<br />

20 Timber, bamboo, cane, palm fibre <strong>and</strong> straw (TBCPFS)<br />

21 Furniture manufacturing (FM)<br />

22 Papermaking <strong>and</strong> paper products (PPP)<br />

23 Printing <strong>and</strong> recording medium reproduction (PRMR)<br />

24 Cultural, educational <strong>and</strong> sporting goods (CESG)<br />

26 Raw chemical materials <strong>and</strong> chemicals (RCMC)<br />

28 Chemical fibre (CF)<br />

29 Rubber products (RP)<br />

30 Plastic products (PP)<br />

31 Non-metal mineral products (NMP)<br />

34 Metal products (MP)<br />

35 Ordinary machinery manufacturing (OMM)<br />

36 Special purposes equipment manufacturing (SPEM)<br />

37 Transport equipment manufacturing (TEM)<br />

39 Electric equipment <strong>and</strong> machinery (EEM)<br />

40 Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications equipment (ETE)<br />

41 Apparatus <strong>and</strong> instruments (AI)<br />

42 Cultural, office machinery <strong>and</strong> other manufacturing (COMOM)<br />

43 Recycling industry (RI)<br />

174


State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

Appendix 9.4 Length of transportation routes (10 000km)<br />

Year Length of<br />

railways in<br />

operation<br />

Length of<br />

national<br />

electrified<br />

railways<br />

Length of<br />

highways<br />

Length of<br />

expressways<br />

Length of<br />

navigable<br />

inl<strong>and</strong><br />

waterways<br />

Length of<br />

civil aviation<br />

routes<br />

Length of<br />

international<br />

aviation routes<br />

Length of<br />

petroleum <strong>and</strong><br />

gas pipelines<br />

1995 5.97 0.97 115.70 0.21 11.06 112.90 34.82 1.72<br />

1996 6.49 1.01 118.58 0.34 11.08 116.65 38.63 1.93<br />

1997 6.60 1.20 122.64 0.48 10.98 142.50 50.44 2.04<br />

1998 6.64 1.30 127.85 0.87 11.03 150.58 50.44 2.31<br />

1999 6.74 1.40 135.17 1.16 11.65 152.22 52.33 2.49<br />

2000 6.87 1.49 140.27 1.63 11.93 150.29 50.84 2.47<br />

2001 7.01 1.69 169.80 1.94 12.15 155.36 51.69 2.76<br />

2002 7.19 1.74 176.52 2.51 12.16 163.77 57.45 2.98<br />

2003 7.30 1.81 180.98 2.97 12.40 174.95 71.53 3.26<br />

2004 7.44 1.86 187.07 3.43 12.33 204.94 89.42 3.82<br />

2005 7.54 1.94 334.52 4.10 12.33 199.85 85.59 4.40<br />

2006 7.71 2.34 345.70 4.53 12.34 211.35 96.62 4.82<br />

175


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

Appendix 9.5 Number of berths in major coastal ports<br />

Year Total For productive use For non-productive use<br />

Length of<br />

quay line (km)<br />

No. berths<br />

(unit)<br />

10 000-tonne<br />

class<br />

Length of<br />

quay line (km)<br />

No. berths<br />

(unit)<br />

10 000-tonne<br />

class<br />

Length of<br />

quay line (m)<br />

No. berths<br />

(unit)<br />

2003 281 2562 650 257 2238 650 24 008 324<br />

2005 379 3641 769 341 3110 769 37 951 531<br />

2006 418 3804 883 382 3291 883 35 257 513<br />

176


Appendix 9.6 Postal delivery routes<br />

State-owned enterprises in China: reform dynamics <strong>and</strong> impacts<br />

(‘000 km) Length of postal routes Highway routes Railway routes<br />

Year<br />

1995 1 886 819 183<br />

1996 2 119 917 184<br />

1997 2 363 874 186<br />

1998 2 854 931 190<br />

1999 2 979 989 190<br />

2000 3 073 1 070 185<br />

2001 3 103 1 074 180<br />

2002 3 081 1 113 178<br />

2003 3 270 1 137 191<br />

2004 3 336 1 195 196<br />

2005 3 406 1 230 200<br />

2006 3 369 1 231 205<br />

177


China’s New Place in a World in Crisis<br />

Appendix 9.7 Main communication capacity of telecommunications<br />

Year Capacity of longdistance<br />

telephone<br />

exchanges (circuit,<br />

thous<strong>and</strong>s)<br />

Capacity of local-office<br />

telephone exchanges<br />

(10 000 lines)<br />

Capacity of mobile<br />

telephone exchanges<br />

Length of long-distance<br />

optical cable lines<br />

(‘000 km)<br />

Broadb<strong>and</strong> subscribers<br />

port of Internet (10 000<br />

ports)<br />

1995 3 519 7204 797 107 -<br />

1996 4 162 9291 1536 130 -<br />

1997 4 368 11 269 2586 151 -<br />

1998 4 492 13 824 4707 194 -<br />

1999 5 032 15 346 8136 240 -<br />

2000 5 635 17 826 13 986 287 -<br />

2001 7 036 25 566 21 926 399 -<br />

2002 7 730 28 657 27 400 488 -<br />

2003 8 694 35 083 33 698 594 1802<br />

2004 12 630 42 347 39 684 695 3578<br />

2005 13 716 47 196 48 242 723 4875<br />

2006 14 423 50 280 61 032 722 6486<br />

- zero<br />

178


Preliminary draft: 8 October 2004<br />

Not for publication or quotation<br />

without written permission from authors<br />

Stanford Center for International Development (SCID) conference<br />

China’s Policy Reform: Progress <strong>and</strong> Challenges<br />

Stanford University<br />

14-16 October 2004<br />

Property Rights <strong>and</strong> “Original Sin” in China:<br />

Transaction Costs, Wealth Creation, <strong>and</strong> Property Rights Infrastructure<br />

By Andrew SHENG, XIAO Geng, <strong>and</strong> WANG Yuan 1<br />

1. Introduction<br />

This is one of a series of papers by the authors examining how China can reform its capital <strong>and</strong><br />

financial markets by drawing lessons from the experiences of Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> other market<br />

economies. The first paper was presented in this conference series at Stanford last year <strong>and</strong><br />

examined the development experiences in other economies 2 . The second paper, presented in<br />

Beijing <strong>and</strong> Shanghai looked at the need for a property rights infrastructure as a pre-condition for<br />

efficient capital market development <strong>and</strong> good corpo<strong>rate</strong> governance 3 . This paper presents for the<br />

first time in English a Chinese version of a paper on property rights disputes in China presented in<br />

Beijing, Shanghai, <strong>and</strong> Hong Kong 4 . An overview of the role of property rights infrastructure<br />

(PRI) <strong>and</strong> the function of efficient markets was presented recently in Beijing 5 . There is a further<br />

paper, as yet unpublished, that examines the historical reasons why China did not evolve its own<br />

property rights infrastructure 6 .<br />

1 Andrew SHENG <strong>and</strong> WANG Yuan work for the Securities <strong>and</strong> Futures Commission, Hong Kong. XIAO Geng<br />

works for the University of Hong Kong. The paper reflects entirely the authors’ personal view <strong>and</strong> does not represent<br />

the views of their employers. Xiao Geng would like to acknowledge the financial support for this research from Hong<br />

Kong’s University Grants Committee (Project No: AOE/H-05/99) <strong>and</strong> the Stanford Center for International<br />

Development. The authors would like to thank Wu Jinglian, Gao Xiqing, Zhang Jun, Liang Zhiping, Zhou Qiren,<br />

Liang Hong, Gaik-Looi Tan <strong>and</strong> seminar participants in Beijing, Shanghai <strong>and</strong> Hong Kong for helpful comments <strong>and</strong><br />

discussions.<br />

2 Sheng, Xiao <strong>and</strong> Wang (2003b).<br />

3 Sheng, Xiao <strong>and</strong> Wang (2004b).<br />

4 Sheng, Xiao <strong>and</strong> Wang (2003a).<br />

5 Sheng (2004).<br />

6 Sheng, Xiao <strong>and</strong> Wang (2004d).<br />

1


China’s economic reform has now advanced to a stage in which more attention should be turned<br />

to developing an integ<strong>rate</strong>d property rights infrastructure so as to derive lasting benefits to the<br />

economy. Hong Kong, which has a well functioning PRI including very effective regulatory <strong>and</strong><br />

anti-corruption institutions, could serve as a live knowledge base for building <strong>and</strong> maintaining a<br />

modern PRI in China. The historical experiences of U.S. <strong>and</strong> other matured economies could also<br />

provide useful lessons for China.<br />

2. What is a Property Rights Infrastructure?<br />

A market is actually a property rights delineation, transfer <strong>and</strong> protection system. It depends on<br />

an infrastructure, comprising information <strong>and</strong> accounting services, legal <strong>and</strong> regulatory services<br />

<strong>and</strong> the judicial system, together with other supporting institutions, that gives legal protection of<br />

property rights. The concept, role <strong>and</strong> functions of PRI are discussed elsewhere in detail. 7 The<br />

PRI comprises three broad categories of institutions/ processes:<br />

(i) Institutions/processes for delineation of property rights:<br />

• Central registry of property rights for l<strong>and</strong>, property, shares, <strong>and</strong> other assets. The formal<br />

record of property rights is crucial in reducing the costs of enforcing property rights <strong>and</strong> of<br />

resolving property rights disputes.<br />

• Accounting <strong>and</strong> legal process to define property rights in complicated forms of assets such<br />

as shares, bonds, options, <strong>and</strong> other ownership instruments.<br />

(ii) Institutions/processes for exchange of property rights:<br />

• Trading process such as retail <strong>and</strong> wholesale markets, auction houses, stock exchanges,<br />

futures markets, banks <strong>and</strong> insurance companies.<br />

• Regulated intermediaries to facilitate complicated financial <strong>and</strong> non-financial transactions,<br />

including lawyers, accountants, auditors, credit rating agencies, credit bureaus, sponsors<br />

<strong>and</strong> other information service providers. These intermediaries are used for identifying,<br />

providing <strong>and</strong> verifying information about the value <strong>and</strong> quality of property rights, which<br />

is indispensable for due diligence when the property rights are traded.<br />

• Clearing, settlement <strong>and</strong> payment systems to complete financial <strong>and</strong> non-financial<br />

transactions safely, timely, efficiently, <strong>and</strong> conveniently.<br />

(iii) Institutions/processes for protection, enforcement, adjudication, <strong>and</strong> fine-tuning of property<br />

rights:<br />

• The general rules of the game that forms the legal <strong>and</strong> economic system of a market<br />

economy: laws, regulations, st<strong>and</strong>ards, codes, <strong>and</strong> norms that protect property rights of all<br />

participants across space <strong>and</strong> time.<br />

• Independent <strong>and</strong> transparent judiciary to adjudicate disputes over property rights <strong>and</strong> finetune<br />

property rights as necessary.<br />

• Enforcement infrastructure including police, regulators, <strong>and</strong> armed forces that can enforce<br />

the judicial decisions <strong>and</strong> protect property rights firmly <strong>and</strong> fairly at a cost that is lower<br />

than the benefits to the society <strong>and</strong> the market.<br />

7 Sheng, Xiao <strong>and</strong> Wang (2004c).<br />

2


• M<strong>and</strong>atory disclosure regimes to ensure that important information about property rights,<br />

such as the financial statements of listed companies, are independently verified <strong>and</strong><br />

accountable so as to facilitate self, regulatory <strong>and</strong> market disciplines on the corpo<strong>rate</strong><br />

sector.<br />

• Active <strong>and</strong> independent public watchdogs such as media, consumer councils, councillors/<br />

parliamentarians, <strong>and</strong> other civil society organizations to promote proper conduct <strong>and</strong><br />

behaviour <strong>and</strong> accountability through public pressures <strong>and</strong> reputations.<br />

• A well-functioning government with effective checks <strong>and</strong> balances that can provide basic<br />

political <strong>and</strong> social order.<br />

A well-functioning PRI helps to build <strong>and</strong> maintain proper market behaviour <strong>and</strong> good credit<br />

culture <strong>and</strong> is the foundation for good governance in corporations, government agencies, market<br />

regulators <strong>and</strong> other market participants. The ultimate result of strong PRI will be reflected in the<br />

quality of corpo<strong>rate</strong> decision-making <strong>and</strong> government <strong>policy</strong>-making that is essential for risk<br />

management at all levels. Specifically good PRI leads to good capital market, which then provide<br />

low-cost financing to good corporations.<br />

3. “Original Sin” <strong>and</strong> Relationship with Property Rights<br />

Since its opening up st<strong>rate</strong>gy was implemented in 1979, China has enjoyed rapid growth <strong>and</strong><br />

unprecedented wealth creation. China’s economy has exp<strong>and</strong>ed at around 8% per annum for<br />

more than two decades. From a position where most property was owned by the state, the sale of<br />

state-owned enterprises to the private sector, the leasing of l<strong>and</strong> use rights to individuals <strong>and</strong><br />

foreign firms, as well as the establishment of the stock market have resulted in the emergence of<br />

private sector wealth. The private sector has exp<strong>and</strong>ed to a scale which is now as large as<br />

accounting for about three quarters of the employment, two thirds of GDP, one half of industrial<br />

<strong>and</strong> residential property value, one third of stock market capitalisation, <strong>and</strong> one fifth of bank<br />

loans. China’s constitution now protects private property rights.<br />

This rapid emergence of private sector wealth happened in China before the pre-conditions for a<br />

robust <strong>and</strong> efficient property rights infrastructure was firmly established. The resulting uncertainty<br />

about property rights has led to many disputes on the legitimacy <strong>and</strong> clarity of ownership. How<br />

did the private sector obtain this wealth? Was it through corrupt practices, tax evasion,<br />

smuggling, fraud or other illegal activities? The lack of clarity in ownership of property rights for<br />

the private sector is commonly called “original sin” within China, as the entrepreneurs or owners<br />

of private business are unable to explain clearly the origin of such accumulated wealth.<br />

The concern on “original sin” has created huge moral <strong>and</strong> political debates. At one extreme, there<br />

is moral outrage over such illegally gotten wealth that should be confiscated <strong>and</strong> those responsible<br />

charged criminally. At the other extreme, there are calls for amnesty in the same way that some<br />

Western countries give tax amnesties to enable past defaulters to start afresh. This paper does not<br />

attempt to get into the moral or political issues, but uses a Coasian new institutional economics<br />

framework of transactions costs to examine the economic dimensions of “original sin” <strong>and</strong> its<br />

3


possible resolution. It concludes that there is ample Western experience in dealing with this but<br />

all requires the pre-condition of a robust PRI.<br />

One of the key difficulties in dealing with “original sin” <strong>and</strong> the associated property rights<br />

disputes lies in the confusion about the substantive differences between two types of economic<br />

behaviour: criminal wealth transfer activities <strong>and</strong> non-criminal property rights disputes. The<br />

confusion of the two creates dilemmas in government <strong>policy</strong>-making, judicial decisions, <strong>and</strong><br />

enforcement actions. To analyse the problem of “original sin” in China objectively <strong>and</strong> find<br />

constructive solutions, some clear <strong>and</strong> useful principles to distinguish the two categories of<br />

behaviour are needed.<br />

Applying new institutional economics, 8 this paper develops an analytic framework to distinguish<br />

“original sin” of criminal nature from non-criminal property rights disputes based on two<br />

principles: the transaction cost principle <strong>and</strong> the wealth creation principle. Our analysis suggests:<br />

• When transaction costs are high <strong>and</strong> there is net wealth creation, the conflicts between the<br />

private businessmen <strong>and</strong> the state/public should be treated as property rights disputes <strong>and</strong><br />

should be dealt with according to principles similar to the “liability rule” as applied to the<br />

non-criminal cases in the western legal system. The persons inflicting harms or losses to<br />

others should pay damages but should not be punished.<br />

• When transaction costs are low <strong>and</strong> there is no net wealth creation, the conflicts should be<br />

treated as criminal cases <strong>and</strong> should be dealt with according to principles similar to the<br />

“property rule” as applied to the criminal cases in the western legal system. The persons<br />

inflicting harm or losses to others should be punished <strong>and</strong> pay damages.<br />

The above economic <strong>and</strong> legal principles on dealing with “original sin” <strong>and</strong> property rights<br />

disputes could be useful in guiding the design <strong>and</strong> implementation of reforms in China’s judicial<br />

system, which is one of the key pillars for well-functioning PRI. These conceptual principles<br />

could also contribute to current debates in China on the issues of reform of state-owned<br />

enterprises <strong>and</strong> state asset management <strong>and</strong> the improvement of corpo<strong>rate</strong> governance 9 .<br />

4. Wealth Creation, Wealth Transfer, <strong>and</strong> Social Cost<br />

We need to define a few key concepts before developing the analytic framework for studying<br />

“original sin” <strong>and</strong> property rights disputes. Let’s sepa<strong>rate</strong> conceptually the costs related to<br />

“original sin” into two parts: Wealth Transfer (α) <strong>and</strong> Social Cost (β). Let’s also sepa<strong>rate</strong><br />

conceptually the Private Sector Value Added (ε) from the “original sin” related Wealth Transfer<br />

(α).<br />

Wealth Transfer (α): Transfer of wealth <strong>and</strong> benefits related to private taking of stateowned<br />

assets or other stealing <strong>and</strong> rent-seeking activities.<br />

8 Werin (2003).<br />

9 Sheng, Xiao, <strong>and</strong> Wang (2004b).<br />

4


Social Cost (β): The money, time, <strong>and</strong> other resources spent on getting α. β is a social<br />

cost, or a waste of society’s resources, from wealth transfer activities. It is a burden on the<br />

society <strong>and</strong> increases the cost of doing business.<br />

Private Sector Value Added (ε): The net creation of wealth from the legitimate business of<br />

the private sector.<br />

In the above definition, α could involve both state-owned <strong>and</strong> privately owned enterprises <strong>and</strong><br />

it can lead to quasi-fiscal costs such as non-performing loans in the state banks <strong>and</strong> unfunded<br />

pension liabilities for the government. This transfer is clearly inequitable <strong>and</strong> discourages<br />

legitimate wealth creation activities. But the wealth transfer itself is just redistribution <strong>and</strong><br />

would not directly destroy wealth. It is difficult to avoid α when property rights are not<br />

defined clearly <strong>and</strong> when there is too much unnecessary regulation. α, if getting out of control,<br />

may become a threat to social stability.<br />

Now let’s look at a simplified national income account. We break national income into net state<br />

sector income <strong>and</strong> net private sector income.<br />

Net State Sector Income = Tax Revenues + State Sector Value Added − α;<br />

Net Private Sector Income = ε + α − β;<br />

National Income = Tax Revenues + State Sector Value Added + ε − β;<br />

Since Wealth Transfer α is simply a transfer from the state sector to private sector, it does not<br />

appear in the consolidated National Income equation. In other words, the size of α does not affect<br />

directly the size of National Income. 10 To increase National Income, it is necessary to reduce<br />

social cost β.<br />

But β is closely related to α. α is what motivates “original sin”-related activities such as stealing,<br />

tunnelling, asset stripping <strong>and</strong> other rent seeking. These activities then will gene<strong>rate</strong> Social Cost<br />

β. If there are no effective measures to stop people from rent-seeking, the competition among<br />

people who are trying to get Wealth Transfer α would increase Social Cost β to the extent that β<br />

could be greater than α.<br />

Hence, to increase National Income, we need to minimize not only β but also α. If there are no<br />

state assets <strong>and</strong> no regulation-induced opportunities for wealth redistribution, α would be zero <strong>and</strong><br />

β would also fall to zero automatically. One must recognize that “original sin” involves two<br />

parties: the state sector <strong>and</strong> the private sector. Opportunities for committing “original sin” exist<br />

because of discretionary authority by government officials. The greater the market distortion<br />

caused by laws <strong>and</strong> administrative rules, the greater the opportunity for wealth transfer (i.e. larger<br />

α).<br />

10 For simplicity, we assume here there are no income effects.<br />

5


The “original sin” problem in China is complicated because wealth transfer-related criminal<br />

activities are often mixed up with non-criminal property rights disputes. Conceptually the total<br />

accumulated wealth of private businessmen in China can be represented by ∑(ε + α), which<br />

includes both ∑ε <strong>and</strong> ∑α. While ∑ε is conceptually “clean” of criminal activities, ∑α is often<br />

related to illegal or “extra-legal” gains from private usage of state-owned assets, evasion of<br />

taxation, smuggling, gambling, vice, fraud in IPOs, <strong>and</strong> market manipulation etc.<br />

However, in reality, it is difficult to measure ∑ε <strong>and</strong> ∑α sepa<strong>rate</strong>ly without a well-functioning<br />

PRI. A transparent <strong>and</strong> equitable “due process” is needed to unravel the historical legacy of<br />

“original sin” <strong>and</strong> this cannot be done purely by administrative or political means because of the<br />

moral issues <strong>and</strong> perceived inequities this brings. This is the dilemma in resolving the “original<br />

sin” of private entrepreneurs in China. There is a national interest in promoting ∑ε as it creates<br />

employment, growth, <strong>and</strong> tax revenues, but there is also public “bad” with respect to ∑α as it is<br />

related to rent-seeking, unfair practices <strong>and</strong> corruption. Depending on which component of ∑(ε<br />

+ α) is larger, you can have dramatically different views on the “original sin” problem in China.<br />

The analytic framework we propose here however provides a more objective <strong>and</strong> constructive,<br />

<strong>and</strong> perhaps less emotional approach to look at the issue. We regard the “original sin” in China as<br />

a problem of co-existence <strong>and</strong> conceptual confusion between criminal wealth transfer activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> non-criminal/civil property rights disputes.<br />

Clearly China needs to develop institutions that are able to distinguish ∑ε from ∑α. Good<br />

systems for property rights registration <strong>and</strong> accounting would make it easier to measure ∑ε.<br />

Given the complexity of both criminally oriented “original sin” <strong>and</strong> non-criminal property rights<br />

disputes, China needs a strong, independent, <strong>and</strong> transparent judicial system to resolve the two<br />

categories of conflicts through non-political, routine, <strong>and</strong> case-by-case processes. The judiciary in<br />

the western legal <strong>and</strong> economic system plays this function routinely without much interaction<br />

with its executive <strong>and</strong> legislative arms of government.<br />

The lawyers <strong>and</strong> judges in the common law tradition have to identify which categories of the law<br />

would apply to each case (criminal or non-criminal laws such as tort). Facts have to be sorted out<br />

before they move to next stage of adjudication. Hence, problems of original sin have to be<br />

resolved on a case-by-case basis, <strong>and</strong> cannot be resolved on the basis of “broad principles”. This<br />

is where experienced lawyers <strong>and</strong> judges are needed to sepa<strong>rate</strong> the criminal elements from civil<br />

cases. Clearly China can learn a lot from the development experiences of the legal <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

system in the mature Western market economies.<br />

Putting aside the difficulties of developing PRI in general <strong>and</strong> a well-functioning judiciary in<br />

particular, we still need some clear principles on how to make proper distinctions between<br />

“original sin” of criminal nature <strong>and</strong> the non-criminal property rights disputes. Traditionally, we<br />

use the existing legal <strong>and</strong> regulatory rules as the only criteria when investigating corruption,<br />

criminal behaviour <strong>and</strong> property rights disputes. But this approach has a serious problem: the<br />

existing rules may be outdated <strong>and</strong> inconsistent with efficiency <strong>and</strong> equity principles. In fact,<br />

6


China’s reform in the past decades is clearly a history of how the outdated rules inherited from the<br />

central planning era are changed gradually over time. To move from such a regime to a full<br />

market-based regime where property rights are clearly delineated <strong>and</strong> protected would require a<br />

clear institution-building path that involves a clear vision on how the PRI can <strong>and</strong> should be built.<br />

5. Property Rule versus Liability Rule: The Transaction Costs Principle<br />

We need to distinguish “original sin” of criminal nature from non-criminal property rights<br />

disputes conceptually in order to differentiate the two categories of behaviour more effectively in<br />

practice. A problem with property rights enforcement in China is that historically, the system is<br />

based on criminal sanctions, which is not necessarily the most appropriate in market-based<br />

property disputes.<br />

The Western legal tradition distinguishes between civil <strong>and</strong> criminal cases, through what is now in<br />

economic terms called the property rule <strong>and</strong> liability rule. Swedish economist Lars Werin in his<br />

survey of law <strong>and</strong> economics literature provides the following definition on property rule <strong>and</strong><br />

liability rule based on the concept of transaction costs 11 :<br />

Property Rule: “If a person wants to expose someone else to the risk of harm or loss under<br />

circumstances where the transaction costs associated with a voluntary agreement are low,<br />

then he should buy the right to do so from the other person. If he inflicts a harm or loss<br />

without having bought this right, he will be punished, provided the court finds a<br />

sufficiently close connection between the harm or loss <strong>and</strong> his act. He may also have to<br />

pay damages to the victim.”<br />

Liability Rule: “If a person wants to expose someone else to the risk of harm or loss under<br />

circumstances where the transaction costs associated with a voluntary agreement are high,<br />

then he may do it. If he inflicts a harm or loss, he will have to pay damages to the victim,<br />

provided the court finds a sufficiently close connection between the harm or loss <strong>and</strong> his<br />

act. A court determines the size of the damages, in principle calculated so as to correspond<br />

to the harm or loss. The acting person will not be punished.”<br />

Many judges in the Western legal system apply the property rule <strong>and</strong> liability rule in their<br />

adjudication, without totally underst<strong>and</strong>ing the economic concept of transaction costs, as<br />

expounded by Nobel Laureate Ronald Coase.<br />

In the context of transitional economies, where property rights need to move from statedominated<br />

holdings to private holdings, it is important to underst<strong>and</strong> that the lower the total<br />

transactions costs (including taxes <strong>and</strong> rent-seeking activity costs), the greater the ability of the<br />

market to function efficiently. In many emerging markets, such wealth transfers as theft, fraud,<br />

false accounting, corruption <strong>and</strong> the like result in huge unreported transaction costs. Accordingly,<br />

the move towards efficient market economies requires the building of PRI that reduces transaction<br />

costs.<br />

11 Werin (2003), pg 204.<br />

7


The transaction costs principle being articulated explicitly in the property rule <strong>and</strong> liability rule<br />

can be abstracted from common sense practices through a simple example:<br />

• A person stealing some medicine from a drugstore would face criminal charges of<br />

stealing. The reason is there is an open market with zero transaction costs for the person<br />

to buy the medicine, but he preferred to steal it for personal use at a loss to the drugstore.<br />

• If, however, the person rushed into the drugstore, <strong>and</strong> without paying, took <strong>and</strong> used the<br />

medicine in order to save life of some other person on the street, he may not only not be<br />

punished for stealing, but could be rewarded for being a public-spirited hero. The<br />

transaction costs of paying immediately for the medicine were high relative to the urgency<br />

of saving a human life.<br />

6. The Wealth Creation Principle<br />

The Western legal tradition, which ope<strong>rate</strong>d on the basis of the need to protect individual property<br />

rights, including against interference from the state, has intuitively ope<strong>rate</strong>d on the basis of<br />

lowering market transaction costs. When transaction costs are low, people would prefer to use the<br />

market to obtain the resources they want in order to minimize the total costs to the society. When<br />

transaction costs are high, using the market to obtain resources may be too costly, hence there<br />

may be an incentive to engage in criminal activities, i.e. steal or cheat. Hence, the transaction<br />

costs principle ultimately is consistent with the wealth creation principle. Lars Werin uses the<br />

wealth creation principle to describe the judge-made law in the common law tradition: 12<br />

• “Property rights <strong>and</strong> rules on rights of transfer instituted by judge-made law tend<br />

systematically to produce incentives that promote efficiency, that is, encourage wealthincreasing<br />

acts <strong>and</strong> counteract wealth-decreasing acts, with no direct consideration of<br />

the consequences for the distribution of wealth.”<br />

• “Property rights <strong>and</strong> restrictions on rights of transfer instituted by politically-based law<br />

are of two kinds. They either concern “constitutional” <strong>and</strong> “night watch” matters, basic<br />

to any society <strong>and</strong> which require a purely political decision process; they then tend to<br />

be efficiency promoting. Or else they are framed so as to promote distributional<br />

objectives, with no regard to efficiency. The latter category dominates.”<br />

The above analysis suggests that any market reforms, including the building of the PRI, would<br />

require a clear vision or social objective of reducing transaction costs <strong>and</strong> maximizing wealthcreation<br />

risk-taking by the private sector. This implies that the appropriate institutional<br />

framework, such as the judicial <strong>and</strong> regulatory structure (<strong>and</strong> in enforcement work), should be<br />

built with these objectives in mind.<br />

What the above analysis suggests is that whilst economists can explain these conceptual issues,<br />

the resolution of these complex property rights disputes lies in the realm of law <strong>and</strong> regulation.<br />

This is why we conclude that China needs to focus on developing a well-functioning PRI <strong>and</strong><br />

especially an effective judicial system that is specialized in h<strong>and</strong>ling these complicated cases. The<br />

function of PRI is not just to resolve “original sin” <strong>and</strong> property rights disputes. As the historical<br />

12 Werin (2003), pg 61.<br />

8


issues are resolved, the gap between the actual practices <strong>and</strong> the existing laws <strong>and</strong> rules will be<br />

narrowed, reducing the probability of new “original sin” from emerging. Each society has to go<br />

through this stage of development when it is modernizing its legal <strong>and</strong> economic system.<br />

7. Historical Lessons from U.S.<br />

Finally, it is important to point out that the presence of “original sin” happens in all societies.<br />

Each dealt with this problem through its own evolving legal, economic <strong>and</strong> political systems.<br />

Entrepreneurs with “original sin” will want to legitimize themselves in order to preserve their<br />

wealth. As Hern<strong>and</strong>o de Soto correctly pointed out 13 , the United States confronted this problem<br />

in the 19 th century. The U.S. opened up new frontier territory, e.g. the Wild West, before proper<br />

title deeds were registered <strong>and</strong> law <strong>and</strong> order were imposed. As a result, most settlers became<br />

illegal squatters or miners. In this extra-legal situation, the lawlessness or extra-legality at the<br />

grass-root level conflicted with actual laws in the established society:<br />

“The crucial change had to do with adapting the law to the social <strong>and</strong> economic needs of the<br />

majority of the population. Gradually, Western nations became able to acknowledge that<br />

social contracts born outside the official law were a legitimate source of law <strong>and</strong> to find ways<br />

of absorbing these contracts 14 .”<br />

English common law, which the U.S. was originally based on, did not have means of h<strong>and</strong>ling<br />

transfers of dubious property titles, such as squatting rights. The common law protected<br />

established l<strong>and</strong>lords against illegal squatters. However, in a situation of mass migration into new<br />

l<strong>and</strong>s with unclear title <strong>and</strong> boundaries, the squatters in the U.S. became the majority, <strong>and</strong> their<br />

rights had to be legitimised. This situation is not unlike the mass migration of rural labour into<br />

China’s urban areas where the property title has not yet been made clear, since all l<strong>and</strong> belonged<br />

to the state. It is also conceptually equivalent to the situation where entrepreneurial individuals<br />

created net wealth for society by using state-assets, that were inefficiently managed under stateowned<br />

enterprises. If there are any disputes over such property rights, how should we deal with it?<br />

In America’s Wild West, attempts by the established l<strong>and</strong>lords to enforce their rights created huge<br />

squatter/homestead owners’ rebellion <strong>and</strong> disorder. When the squatters became the majority, new<br />

laws were passed to legalize their extra-legality. The legal device to legitimise their newly<br />

accumulated wealth ∑(ε + α) was the concept of “pre-emption”, which was an innovation to<br />

allow a squatter to buy the l<strong>and</strong> that he had improved on (e.g. pay ∑α to the original l<strong>and</strong> owner<br />

to legitimize ∑ε) 15 . By legitimising extra-legal activities, the frontier states could then collect tax<br />

revenues <strong>and</strong> enforce property rights to l<strong>and</strong>. This was a win-win situation for all concerned.<br />

In other words, faced with the conflicts between the existing l<strong>and</strong>owners <strong>and</strong> the extra-legal<br />

activities of the squatters, who became a strong political force by sheer numbers, “American<br />

politicians thus had three choices. They could continue to try to thwart or ignore extra-legal<br />

13 This section draws heavily from de Soto (2000), Chapter 5, The Missing History of US History.<br />

14 de Soto (2000), pg 106.<br />

15 Op cit, pg 120.<br />

9


activities, grudgingly make concessions, or become champions of extralegal rights 16 .” The U.S.<br />

Congress gradually consolidated the diffuse <strong>and</strong> conflicting l<strong>and</strong> laws that were out of touch with<br />

reality on the ground into a more consistent property rights system that recognized “the two great<br />

principles of equity in [American] statutory law: The right of occupants … to their improvements<br />

<strong>and</strong> the right of settlers on privately owned l<strong>and</strong>, unchallenged for seven years <strong>and</strong> paying taxes<br />

thereon, to a firm <strong>and</strong> clear title to their l<strong>and</strong> no matter what adverse titles may be outst<strong>and</strong>ing. 17 ”<br />

Indeed, “it took the [U.S.] politicians some time before they awakened to the fact that alongside<br />

the official law, extralegal social contracts for property had taken shape <strong>and</strong> that they constituted<br />

an essential part of the nation’s property rights system. To establish a comprehensive legal<br />

system that could be enforced throughout the nation, they would have to catch up with the way<br />

people were defining, using <strong>and</strong> distributing property rights 18 .” For example, in addressing illegal<br />

mining on state l<strong>and</strong>, the U.S. Mining Law of 1866, which legalized individual mining, was “an<br />

explicit recognition that value added to assets was something the law needed to encourage <strong>and</strong><br />

protect 19 .”<br />

To sum up, “the recognition <strong>and</strong> integration of extralegal property rights was a key element in the<br />

United States becoming the most important market economy <strong>and</strong> producer of capital in the<br />

world 20 .” “The American experience is very much like what is going on in Third World <strong>and</strong><br />

former communist countries. The official law has not been able to keep up with popular<br />

initiatives, <strong>and</strong> government has lost control.” For law to be obeyed, it must respond to the needs<br />

of the people. “In the long <strong>and</strong> arduous process of integrating extralegal property rights [into a<br />

new formal property law system], American legislators <strong>and</strong> jurists created a system much more<br />

conducive to a productive <strong>and</strong> dynamic market economy 21 .”<br />

Even today, the method to resolve “original sin” in the US is evolving <strong>and</strong> innovating. The U.S.<br />

courts use “plea bargaining”, or a legal settlement of their past sins by bargaining for a lower fine,<br />

to recognize <strong>and</strong> resolve economic misconduct quickly <strong>and</strong> efficiently. This is fiscally efficient<br />

because it takes considerable tax resources to investigate <strong>and</strong> determine the scale of “original sin”.<br />

For example, in the investigation of securities analyst misconduct after the technology bubble, the<br />

U.S. Courts settled for a US$1.4 billion fine on 10 investment banks, which did not admit the<br />

liability involved but acknowledged that they had to pay for their misconduct. This was a legal<br />

device to settle economic issues of disputes over property rights that harmed society that is largely<br />

consistent with the liability rule.<br />

The experience of other Asian economies shows that if corruption <strong>and</strong> market misconduct cannot<br />

be stopped, businesses will begin to legitimize themselves by taking over politics. The Asian<br />

experience is that business cartels may choose to “backward integ<strong>rate</strong>” into political parties in<br />

16 Op cit, pg 130.<br />

17 Op cit, pg 130.<br />

18 Op cit, pg 136.<br />

19 Op cit, pg 146<br />

20 Op cit. pg 148.<br />

21 Op cit. pg 150.<br />

10


order to achieve “regulatory capture”. This has created the unhealthy “crony-capitalism” that was<br />

one of the causes of the Asian financial crisis.<br />

Hern<strong>and</strong>o de Soto sums up the situation very well: “Today in many developing <strong>and</strong> former<br />

communist nations, property law is no longer relevant to how the majority of people live <strong>and</strong><br />

work. How can a legal system aspire to legitimacy if it cuts out 80 percent of its people? The<br />

challenge is to correct this legal failure. The American experience shows that this is a threefold<br />

task: We must find the real social contracts on property, integ<strong>rate</strong> them into the official law, <strong>and</strong><br />

craft a political st<strong>rate</strong>gy that makes reform possible 22 .”<br />

The historical experiences of U.S. are consistent with both the transaction costs principle <strong>and</strong><br />

wealth creation principles. Outdated laws make property rights unclear <strong>and</strong> transaction costs high<br />

<strong>and</strong> they should not stop entrepreneurs from creating new wealth. China can learn from the U.S.<br />

experience by focusing on resolving the historical conflicts with clear principles <strong>and</strong> practical<br />

reform action.<br />

8. Next Steps<br />

Historian Ray Huang described the process of China’s modernization <strong>and</strong> the establishment of a<br />

market economy in China as completing three parts of the Chinese word “ 立 ” (e.g. meaning<br />

“st<strong>and</strong>ing up” in English), which consists of (1) the superstructure (the central bureaucracy), (2)<br />

the connecting networks <strong>and</strong> channels (property rights infrastructure), <strong>and</strong> (3) the grass-root<br />

organizations <strong>and</strong> individuals. 23 According to Huang, China has already built up the upper <strong>and</strong><br />

bottom parts but still needs to develop the middle part, e.g. the connecting networks <strong>and</strong> channels<br />

between the central bureaucracy <strong>and</strong> the grass-root organizations <strong>and</strong> individuals in order to make<br />

China mathematically manageable. Put in another way, China needs to build an effective<br />

property rights infrastructure to resolve property rights disputes <strong>and</strong> deter/reduce corruption <strong>and</strong><br />

rent-seeking activities related to “original sin”.<br />

The concept of PRI can be likened to a highway. A PRI is an institutional highway for the flow of<br />

wealth <strong>and</strong> the creation <strong>and</strong> exchange of property rights. Recurring symptoms of economic <strong>and</strong><br />

financial crisis, such as bad loans, corruption, commercial fraud, poor corpo<strong>rate</strong> governance,<br />

market manipulation <strong>and</strong> property rights disputes are rooted in the flaws of the PRI. When an<br />

accident happens in the institutional highway, the immediate reaction is to blame drivers or cars.<br />

Any investigation will look at the driver (the individual), the vehicle (the enterprise), the traffic<br />

rules (policies <strong>and</strong> regulations), <strong>and</strong> even whether traffic police were on the beat. But they often<br />

forget two fundamental factors: the quality of the highway (property rights infrastructure) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

brightness of street lamps (transparency), both of which are necessary conditions for a market<br />

economy. In other words, the design of the PRI is a pre-condition for a well-functioning market<br />

economy.<br />

22 Op cit. pg. 151.<br />

23 Huang (1999), Chinese edition, page 3.<br />

11


In 2000, China had one lawyer per 11,000 citizens, compared with one per 300 in the US, one per<br />

700 in the UK, <strong>and</strong> one per 6,300 in Japan. Similarly, China had one accountant per 9,650<br />

persons, compared with 412 in Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> 166 in US. In 2001, China had 28% employment<br />

in the service sector, considerably less than above 70% in U.S., France, U.K., Singapore <strong>and</strong><br />

Hong Kong. China today therefore has considerable way to go towards building capacity in its<br />

service (or property delineation, transfer <strong>and</strong> protection) sector.<br />

The United States spend over US$1 trillion on regulatory activities, which is roughly 10% of<br />

GDP. Above-the-line transaction costs are expensive, since legal, accounting <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

costs are high. However, the market works, because below-the-line transaction costs are relative<br />

low compared to many emerging markets, where such costs are estimated at more than 10% of<br />

GDP, although they spend considerably less on regulatory activities. What is unseen is the “lost<br />

opportunity” in wealth creation <strong>and</strong> growth, which is held back by costly wealth transfers or<br />

criminal activities.<br />

The advantage of the judge-made common law system in a market economy is that this is a<br />

pragmatic <strong>and</strong> empirical system that is truly “feeling the stones, as you cross the river.” The<br />

market place or social system throws up every day very special <strong>and</strong> complex situations of<br />

property disputes that are tested at different levels of courts. The written law requires objective<br />

interpretation. When new situations or knowledge arises, judges have to make a decision on the<br />

legal or social principles that define such issues. The accumulation of knowledge of cases <strong>and</strong><br />

their judicial decisions forms an empirical base for society to resolve conflicts, build stable<br />

expectations <strong>and</strong> make decisions that have social legitimacy.<br />

The robustness <strong>and</strong> durability of common law system in resolving conflicts lies in its transparency<br />

<strong>and</strong> legitimacy. Every judge knows that he needs to know the law <strong>and</strong> the precedent decisions<br />

made by his predecessors. The opposing sides must present both the evidence <strong>and</strong> the legal<br />

principles for the judge to decide. If the judge makes an error of judgement, it can be appealed to<br />

a higher court, to clarify matters of legal principle.<br />

The Chinese judiciary has made considerable progress in recent years in evolving case law<br />

precedents. However, considerable resources must be devoted to this area in order to match the<br />

urgent need to complement the rapid progress to a market system.<br />

The National People’s Congress has also made considerable progress in adapting new laws. But,<br />

copying law is easy. During last two decades, China has copied considerable best-practice<br />

legislations from advanced economies, such as contract law, company law, securities law, <strong>and</strong><br />

banking laws. The problem lies in enforcement. The current judicial system is not yet able to<br />

apply these laws efficiently <strong>and</strong> fairly since the judges have very limited independence from the<br />

local party <strong>and</strong> government bureaucracy. Some judges, who came from such background as<br />

retired army officers or party officials, have little professional trainings in the legal principles.<br />

The Chinese bureaucracy is efficient in providing basic social <strong>and</strong> economic order but it attempts<br />

to define <strong>and</strong> enforce property rights through administrative instruments. For a market economy<br />

12


to function efficiently, an independent judiciary <strong>and</strong> regulatory structure [key components of PRI]<br />

is vital.<br />

China needs to review the development of the accounting profession to strengthen audit <strong>and</strong><br />

disclosure quality. Areas such as a national credit reference agency, national network of property<br />

title registry, <strong>and</strong> market-based rating agencies, professional valuation agencies, <strong>and</strong> related<br />

infrastructure <strong>and</strong> services are all urgently needed to build the PRI.<br />

After a quarter of century of reforms, China has reached the stage of economic development<br />

where the <strong>macroeconomic</strong> conditions provide a favourable opportunity for the next stage of<br />

reform: construction of a robust PRI to allow more efficient <strong>and</strong> orderly exchange <strong>and</strong> protection<br />

of property rights. China is no longer in shortage of savings <strong>and</strong> funds. Indeed, arguably it is<br />

suffering from an excess of savings. China’s advantage as a latecomer to the market economy is<br />

that there is already enough experience <strong>and</strong> “software” to bring in the people, processes <strong>and</strong><br />

experiences, so that a sustainable <strong>and</strong> equitable market economy can be built to global st<strong>and</strong>ards.<br />

Since Hong Kong is already an international financial centre with a PRI competitive <strong>and</strong><br />

transparent by world st<strong>and</strong>ards, Hong Kong can bring in a wealth of market experience in<br />

building the PRI to facilitate China’s transition to a fully competitive market economy that<br />

ope<strong>rate</strong>s on global st<strong>and</strong>ards. Building PRI will take time <strong>and</strong> political will. China should not<br />

under-use <strong>and</strong> under-estimate the value of the Hong Kong PRI in its reform efforts. How to build<br />

a modern <strong>and</strong> institutional property rights infrastructure is an important but complex task. Further<br />

research <strong>and</strong> discussion are needed before a clear action plan could be mapped out.<br />

13


Reference<br />

De Soto, Hern<strong>and</strong>o. (2000). The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West <strong>and</strong><br />

Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books,<br />

Huang, Ray. (1990). China: A Macro History. New York: M.E.Sharpe.<br />

Huang, Ray. (1999). Broadening the Horizons of Chinese History. Chinese edition, Taibei: New<br />

Century Publisher. English edition, ME Sharpe, New York.<br />

Sheng, Andrew. (2004). “Optimal Financial Structure for Economic Growth: Lessons from Other<br />

East Asian Economies.” Paper presented at Beijing University CCER Tenth Anniversary<br />

conference, 16-17 September 2004.<br />

Sheng, Andrew, Geng Xiao <strong>and</strong> Yuan Wang. (2003a) “China’s Financial Reform: Property Rights<br />

Infrastructure <strong>and</strong> the Resolution of ‘Original Sin’.” In Chinese. Presented Shanghai<br />

Institute of Law <strong>and</strong> Economics, Beijing, 13 December 2003.<br />

(http://www.econ.hku.hk/~xiaogeng/research/Paper/031213%20Beijing%20SILE%20semi<br />

nar%20paper.pdf).<br />

──────. (2003b). “The Future of Capital Markets in Developing Countries: Implications for<br />

China’s Equity Markets.” Paper presented at Stanford Center for International<br />

Development conference China’s Market Reforms, Stanford, 19 September 2003.<br />

(http://www.econ.hku.hk/~xiaogeng/research/Paper/030919-Stanford.pdf).<br />

──────. (2004a). “A New Institutional Economic Analysis of ‘Original Sin’.” In Chinese.<br />

Perspectives, 4(2), 1-4.<br />

(http://www.oycf.org/Perspectives/Chinese/Chinese_14_04302004/1a_shen_final.pdf).<br />

──────. (2004b). “Corpo<strong>rate</strong> Governance, Capital Market, <strong>and</strong> Property Rights Infrastructure:<br />

The Experiences of Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> Lessons for China.” Paper presented at Shanghai<br />

Academy of Social Science & 1990 Institute conference State-owned Enterprise<br />

Governance in China, Shanghai, 28-29 May 2004.<br />

(http://www.econ.hku.hk/~xiaogeng/research/Paper/CorpGov&PRI-English.pdf).<br />

──────. (2004c). “China’s Financial Reform <strong>and</strong> Property Rights Infrastructure.” Forthcoming<br />

in October 2004 issue of Perspectives.<br />

(http://www.econ.hku.hk/~xiaogeng/research/Paper/FinancialReform&PRI-<br />

Perspectives.pdf).<br />

──────. (2004d). “The Property Rights Micro-Foundations of Macro-History: Ray Huang’s<br />

Analysis of Market Reform in China.” Unpublished manuscript.<br />

(http://www.econ.hku.hk/~xiaogeng/research/Paper/MacroHistory&PRI.pdf).<br />

Werin, Lars. (2003). Economic Incentives <strong>and</strong> Legal System: An Introductory Survey, London:<br />

World Scientific.<br />

14


1<br />

F E B R U A R Y 2 0 1 0<br />

Is the renminbi the next<br />

global currency?<br />

Geng Xiao, director of the Brookings-Tsinghua Center for<br />

Public Policy, discusses how divergent growth <strong>rate</strong>s<br />

of the Chinese <strong>and</strong> US economies will erode the hegemony<br />

of dollar—but not right away.


2<br />

The US dollar’s run as the world’s stable currency has stumbled with the recent<br />

financial crisis. Waiting in the wings is the renminbi. But according to economist Geng<br />

Xiao, it’s still in China’s—<strong>and</strong> the world’s—best interest not to dump the dollar just yet.<br />

In this video interview, Geng Xiao, director of the Brookings-Tsinghua Center for Public<br />

Policy, explains why China needs time to push through difficult economic reforms at home<br />

before it can allow its currency to float freely against the dollar. McKinsey Publishing’s<br />

Clay Ch<strong>and</strong>ler conducted the interview with Xiao in Hong Kong.<br />

The Quarterly: The United States has long held that the currency of China is<br />

undervalued, that it gives an unfair advantage to Chinese exporters, <strong>and</strong> that it costs<br />

Americans jobs. Authorities in China beg to differ; they say that it helps to preserve<br />

stability. Can you help us to underst<strong>and</strong> the arguments on both sides of this debate?<br />

Geng Xiao: There’s no argument about the imbalance: China has the trade surplus, US<br />

has the trade deficit. So both sides want to improve that. But the question is how. From the<br />

American perspective, the emphasis is on the short-term <strong>adjustment</strong> through price <strong>and</strong><br />

through the exchange <strong>rate</strong>. So the US wants a quick <strong>adjustment</strong> in RMB exchange <strong>rate</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

that means appreciation so it can correct the trade imbalances.<br />

But the Chinese put more emphasis on medium- <strong>and</strong> long-term structural <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

change. So that’s the debate. It’s very difficult for the exchange <strong>rate</strong> to correct the trade<br />

balance. And on the other h<strong>and</strong>, there are some negative consequences of the exchange<strong>rate</strong><br />

uncertainty.<br />

Foreign investors, including American investors, want to invest in RMB assets because of<br />

the expectation of RMB appreciation. This is what we call “hot money.” And these capital<br />

flows are creating a lot of bubbles in the property market, in the stock market.<br />

And that creates difficulties for China’s central bank in terms of monetary <strong>policy</strong> making.<br />

So you can see that there are a lot of concerns from the Chinese side about using the<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> to correct the trade balance. Some prices are so high in China. Some are<br />

so low. So you need a benchmark. China needs a benchmark so that the price can be<br />

compared to the global price, to the price structure, which is compatible with efficiency.<br />

So that’s why price reform is more important than exchange-<strong>rate</strong> change. <strong>Exchange</strong>-<strong>rate</strong><br />

change would not really change the inefficiencies in the use of energy, for example, because<br />

people will still waste energy. Even though you change the exchange <strong>rate</strong>, the internal<br />

subsidies are still there. So I think the point is that China needs to eliminate a lot of these<br />

structural distortions, structural inefficiencies. And then if there’s little distortion, I think<br />

a floating exchange <strong>rate</strong> will apply <strong>and</strong> will be useful for China.


3<br />

The Quarterly: What are these reforms <strong>and</strong> how long will they take?<br />

Geng Xiao: China has already started a lot of its reforms. But it’s going to take anywhere<br />

from 5 to 10 years’ time, really, for China to correct its distortions—l<strong>and</strong> reform, reform<br />

of the energy sector, state-owned-enterprise reform, <strong>and</strong> social welfare. During the last<br />

30 years, most of the tradable-goods prices have become more or less consistent with the<br />

global price structure. Only the nontradable sectors still have a different price structure<br />

compared to the global price structure.<br />

So the nontradables are the key. And you have to underst<strong>and</strong>, nontradable prices in China<br />

have to be lower than in the United States because China still is a developing country <strong>and</strong><br />

still has low productivity. Only when the productivity of China’s nontradable sector reaches<br />

that of the United States will the two countries’ price structures converge. And that is a<br />

long process.<br />

It actually is in America’s interest to allow China to carry out structural <strong>and</strong> institutional<br />

reforms instead of exchange-<strong>rate</strong> change. Let me explain why. China is not really<br />

competing with the United States. Even if you change the exchange <strong>rate</strong>, it will have very<br />

little impact on US trade deficit because the US is going to buy from some other countries.<br />

US people should realize that in the past, the US production was largely for American<br />

consumers. But because of the global financial crisis, American consumers are not<br />

consuming.<br />

So in the future, the US needs to produce for consumers from emerging markets, like<br />

China. That’s the key. They need to think about what to sell to Chinese consumers—not just<br />

Chinese consumers in China but also Chinese consumers who will go out <strong>and</strong> spend in the<br />

United States.<br />

The Quarterly: China is now sitting on a stash of something like $2 trillion in foreigncurrency<br />

reserves. How much larger can this get?<br />

Geng Xiao: If China actually followed the advice of the US <strong>and</strong> allowed the RMB to<br />

continue to appreciate, I would say that China will continue to increase its foreignexchange<br />

reserves, because that bubble, that expectation gene<strong>rate</strong>d by the holding of RMB,<br />

nobody can predict. It can be $4 trillion, you know, $6 trillion.<br />

I think as time goes on, China can do a lot in terms of diversification. But there’s a limit,<br />

because if there is expectation on RMB appreciation, you will get even more reserves. And<br />

most of the reserves start with the US dollar, because that’s the most liquid, the most<br />

stable currency. So I don’t see that there’s any way that China can significantly reduce its<br />

holding of the dollar assets, because the world is just basically dominated by the dollar.<br />

In that sense, you know, I don’t think there’s much choice for China. But if pushed hard,


4<br />

China can always do more. And even marginally, a little bit more is going to have a big<br />

impact in the market.<br />

I think the worst scenario is that China allows this RMB appreciation expectation to<br />

continue. So more <strong>and</strong> more people try to hold RMB. And that gene<strong>rate</strong>s more <strong>and</strong> more<br />

foreign-exchange reserves.<br />

And then China also wants to diversify from the dollar to other assets. All this is going to<br />

create a huge amount of disturbance, not just in the market but also pressures on the US<br />

Treasury. And that’s entirely unnecessary. I think the most effective way is for China to<br />

tole<strong>rate</strong> mode<strong>rate</strong> inflation, which would certainly allow real appreciation of the Chinese<br />

currency, which would contribute to the rebalancing of the global economy <strong>and</strong> also would<br />

encourage Chinese people to hold the dollar, because the RMB will have much higher<br />

inflation than the dollar.<br />

And China, when its economy is growing 10, 15 percent a year, I think a 5 percent or 7<br />

percent inflation <strong>rate</strong> is entirely normal. And once that happens, I think China will have,<br />

actually, a shortage of foreign-exchange reserves because people will want to hold dollar<br />

assets. And they will want to invest overseas. And that is going to create a balance. Right<br />

now, though, it is not a balance. It’s a [temporary] solution. Everybody wants to dump US<br />

dollars <strong>and</strong> hold RMB. And not just Chinese. The entire world, everybody in the world,<br />

wants to hold RMB. And that’s really a danger.<br />

The Quarterly: Does a global financial crisis have any bearing on China’s ability to<br />

diversify out of US dollars?<br />

Geng Xiao: Well, I think it’s not in China’s interest to dump the dollars that they are<br />

holding. Because that would hurt China as a whole. China is a net holder of dollar assets.<br />

And I think more importantly, China actually benefits tremendously from the two-way<br />

capital flows, you know, the US investment in China, which helps to improve China’s<br />

investment efficiency. The problem is that the US has this authority as a global currency.<br />

But US monetary <strong>policy</strong> is entirely focused on the domestic <strong>policy</strong>, in the domestic<br />

unemployment.<br />

So, that creates an intrinsic problem. In principle, US monetary <strong>policy</strong> should take care of<br />

global stability. The interest <strong>rate</strong> for the global economy cannot be zero. But, effectively, if<br />

the US is adopting a zero-interest-<strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong>, the whole world is going to be flooded with<br />

cheap money. That’s the fundamental problem. China is having difficulty dealing with that<br />

problem because US interest <strong>rate</strong>s are zero. And China is flooded with hot money. But for<br />

China, there aren’t many alternatives.


5<br />

Related thinking<br />

“How corpo<strong>rate</strong> China is<br />

evolving”<br />

“Is China recession proof?”<br />

“The looming deleveraging<br />

challenge”<br />

“Economic Conditions<br />

Snapshot, December<br />

2009: McKinsey Global<br />

Survey results”<br />

The Quarterly: So, what do you foresee for the US dollar? Will it continue in its current<br />

role as the dominant global currency? Or is that role soon to come to an end?<br />

Geng Xiao: Well, if you look at the history, I think this will happen, definitely. It’s just<br />

a matter of time. In the past, we had the gold st<strong>and</strong>ard. We had the pound. We have the<br />

dollar. And just think about it, if the Chinese economy continues its growth at the current<br />

pace, the Chinese economy will be the biggest in the world. And if you think about the<br />

reforms in China in 10, 20 years’ time, China will be able to finish all the reforms. And the<br />

Chinese economy would be a modern market economy, <strong>and</strong> the RMB will become one of<br />

the important reserve currencies, just like the US dollar.<br />

The Quarterly: Professor Xiao, thank you so much for joining us <strong>and</strong> sharing<br />

your views.<br />

Copyright © 2010 McKinsey & Company. All rights reserved.


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary<br />

Policies: Structural <strong>and</strong> Institutional<br />

Constraints <strong>and</strong> Reform Options<br />

Geng Xiao<br />

Brookings–Tsinghua Center for<br />

Public Policy <strong>and</strong> Senior Fellow<br />

Brookings Institution<br />

School of Public Policy <strong>and</strong><br />

Management<br />

Tsinghua University<br />

Beijing, China 100084<br />

gxiao@brookings.edu<br />

gxiao@tsinghua.edu.cn<br />

Abstract<br />

This paper argues that declining transaction costs in exporting on<br />

the one h<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the structural <strong>and</strong> institutional barriers to importing<br />

<strong>and</strong> consumption on the other h<strong>and</strong> are the main causes<br />

for China’s rising current account surplus. Reforms in China’s planning,<br />

financial, <strong>and</strong> regulatory systems are more important than<br />

<strong>adjustment</strong> in nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> for balancing China’s trade<br />

<strong>and</strong> for China’s surplus capital to hire more of its surplus labor.<br />

Although structural inflation <strong>and</strong> currency appreciation are necessary<br />

for China’s price level to catch up step-by-step with those in<br />

the advanced economies, the pace of inflation <strong>and</strong> appreciation<br />

need to be compatible with China’s underlying productivity<br />

growth. An “inflation first <strong>and</strong> appreciation second” approach<br />

would help China avoid the risks of both deflation <strong>and</strong> runaway<br />

inflation. The United States <strong>and</strong> China can have win–win results if<br />

both focus on the real constraints behind their external imbalances.<br />

1. Introduction<br />

The objective of this paper is to clarify some of the confusion<br />

related to the debate on China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> to identify the real barriers to greater ºexibility in<br />

China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong>. 1 To my mind, there is no doubt that<br />

1 The literature on China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> is exp<strong>and</strong>ing rapidly.<br />

Anderson (2005) provides the most comprehensive review<br />

<strong>and</strong> related statistics. McKinnon (2005) gives the most comprehensive<br />

analysis on why China should adopt a ªxed exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong> regime. A large number of articles <strong>and</strong> congressional testimonies<br />

advise China to appreciate its currency aggressively, including<br />

Goldstein (2007), Goldstein <strong>and</strong> Lardy (2005), Cline<br />

(2005), <strong>and</strong> Makin (2007). Some experts, such as Prasad (2007),<br />

Williamson (2003), <strong>and</strong> Yu (2007) discussed the usefulness of a<br />

ºexible exchange <strong>rate</strong> regime for more independent monetary<br />

polices in China. Bhagwati (2007), Koivu <strong>and</strong> Garcia-Herrero<br />

Asian Economic Papers 7:3<br />

© 2008 The Earth Institute at <strong>Columbia</strong> University <strong>and</strong> the Massachusetts<br />

Institute of Technology


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

on the issues of exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> global imbalance, China, the United States, <strong>and</strong><br />

the world can have a win–win solution. However, this can only come from a stronger<br />

mutual underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the real constraints facing each side <strong>and</strong> from each<br />

side helping the other.<br />

China’s main challenge today is to develop smoothly functioning ªnancial, planning,<br />

<strong>and</strong> regulatory systems that can employ the remaining rural surplus labor <strong>and</strong><br />

surplus capital—that now show up as a sustained current account surplus <strong>and</strong> rising<br />

foreign exchange reserves—in an efªcient, harmonious, <strong>and</strong> environmentally<br />

friendly way. What is special for China (<strong>and</strong> perhaps a few other Asian economies)<br />

is the co-existence of both surplus (i.e., under-employed) labor <strong>and</strong> surplus capital.<br />

Despite its extremely low capital stock per person, China actually maintains surplus<br />

capital, which it is exporting to capital-rich countries, such as the United States, to<br />

ªnance their excessive consumption. If anything, we should focus on this issue<br />

rather than the renminbi exchange <strong>rate</strong>, which is a distraction from the root problems.<br />

Why does the surplus capital in China not lead to the hiring of more surplus labor,<br />

<strong>and</strong> thereby to increased wages, income, <strong>and</strong> consumption among Chinese workers?<br />

If that were to happen rapidly, it would naturally lead to the reduction of China’s<br />

global current account surplus <strong>and</strong> to the appreciation of China’s exchange <strong>rate</strong>. It is<br />

a pity that economists in developed countries tend to ignore this basic question because<br />

it does not exist in their world of general equilibrium with full employment of<br />

labor <strong>and</strong> capital. The question is assumed away in the neoclassical production<br />

function framework where there are no transaction costs in getting capital <strong>and</strong> labor<br />

to work together. Too much attention has been put on the role of prices, interest<br />

<strong>rate</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> exchange <strong>rate</strong>s in correcting market disequilibrium. In China, both before<br />

<strong>and</strong> since the advent of market-oriented reforms, hidden transaction costs have been<br />

the single most important barrier to growth, development, <strong>and</strong> prosperity.<br />

The rapid rise in China’s global current account surplus <strong>and</strong> the slow appreciation<br />

of the renminbi has led to a strong Washington consensus: China should be pressed<br />

hard to raise the value of its currency in order to reduce its global current account<br />

surplus <strong>and</strong> its current account surplus with the United States. In U.S. congressional<br />

hearings on 28 March 2007, Peterson Institute for International Economics scholar<br />

Morris Goldstein claimed that China’s currency was under-valued by about 40 per-<br />

(2007), Roach (2007), Woo (2006), <strong>and</strong> Woo <strong>and</strong> Xiao (2007) provided analysis on why exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> alone might not be able to eliminate China’s external imbalance. Dooley,<br />

Folkerts-L<strong>and</strong>au, <strong>and</strong> Garber (2005), Sheng <strong>and</strong> Ng (2007), <strong>and</strong> Truman (2007) discussed the<br />

issue of developing a new international monetary system that could take into account the<br />

large current account surplus in China.<br />

32 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

cent against the dollar. He suggested, “China should deliver right away a meaningful<br />

‘down payment’ of a 10–15 percent appreciation of the renminbi from its current<br />

level.” In my view, the current single-minded focus on the renminbi exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

by the Washington elite is unlikely to be helpful in addressing the imbalances in<br />

China’s trading patterns. If the suggested change is so good for China, why has<br />

China not already adopted the approach that the Washington elite are advising?<br />

What has stopped Chinese <strong>policy</strong>makers from doing something that is supposedly<br />

both good <strong>and</strong> important for China, the United States, <strong>and</strong> the world? Has the<br />

Washington elite really considered carefully the constraints faced by Chinese<br />

<strong>policy</strong>makers? Moreover, as rightly pointed out by Stephen S. Roach of Morgan<br />

Stanley in his congressional testimony on 28 March 2007 (Roach 2007):<br />

You in the Congress need to ask yourselves an important hypothetical question:<br />

How would you feel if you got your way on the Chinese currency <strong>adjustment</strong><br />

but found that after three or four years the pressures bearing down on American<br />

workers had only intensiªed? (p. 1)<br />

In some ways, the current situation in U.S.–Chinese economic relations can be compared<br />

to that of United States–European economic relations in the immediate postwar<br />

period when the Marshall Plan was designed to restore the European economy<br />

in order to beneªt both Europeans <strong>and</strong> Americans. In this context, the speech by<br />

U.S. Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson (Paulson 2007) in Shanghai on “The Growth<br />

<strong>and</strong> Future of China’s Financial Markets” is comparable to the Marshall Plan by being<br />

the “Paulson Plan” for China. I certainly believe that the cooperative spirit of the<br />

Marshall Plan, if applied to China, would be much more productive than the current<br />

Washington consensus to pressure China to appreciate its exchange <strong>rate</strong>. The fact is,<br />

as I will explain in detail, China currently faces unprecedented challenges <strong>and</strong> opportunities<br />

not dissimilar to those of post-war reconstruction in Europe. Without the<br />

help <strong>and</strong> cooperation of the United States <strong>and</strong> other developed nations, China is unlikely<br />

to be able to proceed smoothly in its economic, social, <strong>and</strong> political modernization.<br />

2. China’s export competitiveness: Low labor costs <strong>and</strong> declining transaction<br />

costs<br />

The stylized facts about China <strong>and</strong> its global imbalances in trade <strong>and</strong> capital ºows<br />

are well known: the United States has run global current account deªcits in most of<br />

the last 25 years. 2 In 2006, its current account deªcit reached US$ 857 billion, or<br />

2 Cheong <strong>and</strong> Xiao (2003) reviews capital ºows into China in the context of global trade <strong>and</strong><br />

foreign direct investment.<br />

33 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

6.5 percent of GDP. The huge U.S. deªcits have been ªnanced mainly by the current<br />

account surpluses of Japan, China, <strong>and</strong> oil-exporting countries.<br />

In 2006 China’s global current account surplus jumped to a record high of US$ 184<br />

billion, or about 9 percent of GDP. As a result, China’s foreign exchange reserves<br />

have reached US$ 1.07 trillion, the largest in the world. China also became the second-largest<br />

holder of U.S. Treasury securities, holding as much as US$ 353.6 billion,<br />

trailing only Japan, which holds US$ 648.8 billion. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the Chinese<br />

currency was basically pegged to the U.S. dollar from 1994 to 2005. Starting in July<br />

2005, the renminbi was de-linked from the dollar <strong>and</strong> has since been under a managed<br />

ºoat with reference to a basket of currencies. However, from July 2005 to<br />

March 2007, the renminbi appreciated only about 7 percent.<br />

Low wages are not the only, nor even the most important, factor in explaining<br />

China’s recent increase in export competitiveness. Wages in India, Indonesia, <strong>and</strong><br />

many parts of Africa are probably much lower than in China today <strong>and</strong> China’s<br />

wages are increasing steadily, especially for skilled labor. Why then do foreign investors<br />

still prefer to invest in China? Why do China’s exports continue to exp<strong>and</strong><br />

as the wages of its workers increase? The reason is declining transaction costs in<br />

China.<br />

The concept of transaction costs is crucial in explaining many myths in the debate<br />

about China’s currency. Unlike the costs of inputs, which are determined by supply<br />

<strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> in a market, transaction costs are synthetic <strong>and</strong> determined by how<br />

well a society’s political, social, <strong>and</strong> economic institutions function. For example, before<br />

China’s reforms began in 1979, when foreign trade <strong>and</strong> investment by private<br />

individuals <strong>and</strong> ªrms were prohibited, the transaction costs of foreign trade <strong>and</strong> investment<br />

in China were artiªcially set at a prohibitively high level.<br />

Even though transaction costs are sometimes hidden, they are part of the real cost of<br />

doing business, <strong>and</strong> when they are high, they reduce the competitiveness of the<br />

economy. No country in the world worried about China’s export competitiveness<br />

before 1979 even though the average wage for factory workers was only US$ 24 dollars<br />

a month (under the ofªcial exchange <strong>rate</strong> of 1.5 yuan per dollar) compared with<br />

the current monthly wage for migrant workers of about US$ 120 dollars (under the<br />

2006 exchange <strong>rate</strong> of 8 yuan per dollar).<br />

Unfortunately, none of the experts testifying before the U.S. Senate Finance Committee<br />

on 28 March 2007 touched upon declining transaction costs in their analyses of<br />

China’s export competitiveness. Morgan Stanley’s Stephen Roach said, “China competes<br />

not just on the basis of its currency but also from the st<strong>and</strong>point of cheap labor<br />

34 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

costs, modern infrastructure, access to state-of-the-art technology, <strong>and</strong> increasing investment<br />

in human capital <strong>and</strong> basic research.” (p. 1) He was right in highlighting<br />

many factors affecting China’s export competitiveness other than currency, but even<br />

Roach missed the important factor of declining transaction costs in China’s export<br />

<strong>and</strong> foreign-invested sectors.<br />

Declining transaction costs are particularly signiªcant for China’s export <strong>and</strong> foreign-invested<br />

sectors due to the globalization of the production process, characterized<br />

by supply chain management technology <strong>and</strong> the active role of multinational<br />

corporations. Thanks to the information technology (IT) revolution, the supply<br />

chain management technology championed by Hong Kong trading companies is<br />

now able to identify rapidly consumer preferences for a great variety of goods<br />

across vast geographical areas. Modern logistics infrastructure allows companies to<br />

sign contracts with low-cost producers around the world for each part of the supply<br />

chain, <strong>and</strong> deliver the products on time to consumers overseas. In effect, international<br />

supply chain technology has reduced the transaction costs of exporting from<br />

China.<br />

Unfortunately, the international supply chain system does not yet work as smoothly<br />

for imports into China as for exports from China. Exports from China involve only a<br />

small part of the international supply chain, usually the labor-intensive processing<br />

or manufacturing part. As a result of China’s open-door <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> the efforts of<br />

multinational corporations located there, exporters can now h<strong>and</strong>le this part of the<br />

production process efªciently, using China for reliable low-cost labor <strong>and</strong> production<br />

facilities. In particular, such exporters do not need to worry about consumer<br />

ªnancing or supplier credit because these concerns are all h<strong>and</strong>led outside of China<br />

through international ªnancial markets in New York, London, or Hong Kong.<br />

In contrast, the transaction costs of importing to China are very high. The supply<br />

chain has to ascertain Chinese consumer dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> then ªnd the lowest-cost supplier.<br />

Consumer dem<strong>and</strong> in China, however, is affected by many factors outside the<br />

control of the international supply chain, including lack of efªcient consumer<br />

ªnancing, the absence of a functioning social safety net, a shortage of medical insurance,<br />

the weaknesses of the pension system, an absence of basic urban <strong>and</strong> rural infrastructure<br />

for individual consumption, lack of basic regulations <strong>and</strong> enforcement<br />

of environmental protection, shortfalls in the regulation of product quality, <strong>and</strong><br />

weak protection of intellectual property rights. Hence, the international supply<br />

chain faces tremendous obstacles when it comes to importing goods into China.<br />

Clearly many of China’s domestic economic challenges have also hindered the<br />

growth of imports <strong>and</strong> are at the root of China’s sustained global current account<br />

surplus.<br />

35 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

Although a change in the exchange <strong>rate</strong> can directly affect the relative cost of labor,<br />

it cannot affect transaction costs very much. In my view, thanks to China’s continued<br />

reform <strong>and</strong> opening, including its accession to the World Trade Organization,<br />

transaction costs in China’s export sector will continue to fall in the near future; this<br />

will further enhance the competitiveness of China’s export sector even as labor costs<br />

in China are rising steadily due to expected currency appreciation, inºation, <strong>and</strong><br />

other causes. In other words, if we take into account the rapidly declining transaction<br />

costs for exports in China, the hypothetical question raised by Stephen Roach<br />

earlier could become a real risk.<br />

In summary, China is likely to gain even more export competitiveness in the future<br />

due to the declining transaction costs of exporting. In order for China to balance its<br />

trade, it has to work hard to reduce the transaction costs for imports. 3 <strong>Exchange</strong> <strong>rate</strong><br />

<strong>adjustment</strong>s would not be as effective in addressing the trade imbalance as reducing<br />

the hidden barriers <strong>and</strong> constraints on imports.<br />

3. What is the “correct” level for China’s nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>?<br />

Many economists would regard the purchasing power parity (PPP) exchange <strong>rate</strong>,<br />

which is a hypothetical benchmark exchange <strong>rate</strong> derived from the law of one price<br />

for the same bundle of goods, as the best theoretical deªnition of the “right” level<br />

for the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>. When we buy the same bundle of goods in China using<br />

renminbi <strong>and</strong> in the United States using dollars, the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> is the<br />

amount of renminbi divided by the amount of dollars spent on the sample bundle of<br />

goods in the two locations.<br />

The usefulness of this benchmark PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> is obvious, but the problem is<br />

how to select the same bundle of representative goods in both countries. For tradable<br />

goods such as computers <strong>and</strong> cameras it is easy to ªnd the same bundle <strong>and</strong>,<br />

surprisingly, the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> calculated using only tradable goods is likely to<br />

be equal to the prevailing nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>. For example, if you were to buy a<br />

Dell notebook computer in both Shanghai <strong>and</strong> New York today, the amount of<br />

renminbi spent in Shanghai divided by the amount of dollars spent in New York is<br />

likely to be close to 8 yuan per dollar. Any discrepancy from this ratio should be less<br />

than the cost of ordering <strong>and</strong> shipping the notebook computer between the two locales.<br />

If it were not, somebody would be able to make a fortune by buying comput-<br />

3 For a review on the transaction costs on imports into China, see USTR (2007), which examines<br />

various barriers to imports into China, although the USTR report did not use the concept<br />

of transaction costs in its analysis <strong>and</strong> did not trace the root of the problem to China’s<br />

weakness in planning, ªnancial sector development, <strong>and</strong> regulation.<br />

36 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

ers in one place <strong>and</strong> selling them in the other. In other words, claims that China’s<br />

nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> is under-valued are nonsensical unless they are based on a<br />

PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> derived from buying a bundle of goods that also includes nontradable<br />

goods.<br />

The Economist calculates a PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> based on a McDonald’s restaurant Big<br />

Mac, which is a non-tradable good because it must be consumed where it is purchased.<br />

According to The Economist, in 2006, a Big Mac cost 10.4 yuan in China <strong>and</strong><br />

US$ 3.15 in the United States, implying a PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> of about 3.3 yuan to a<br />

dollar, which suggests that the renminbi was under-valued by almost 60 percent<br />

considering China’s nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> of 8 yuan per dollar in 2006.<br />

So why does a Big Mac in China cost 60 percent less than in the United States? The<br />

answer is simple: the costs of non-tradable goods such as labor <strong>and</strong> rent used in producing<br />

a Big Mac are much lower in China than in the United States. In fact, the<br />

prices of non-tradable goods in a developing country are generally lower than the<br />

prices of non-tradable goods in a developed country. Hence, given the different<br />

stages of economic development prevailing in China <strong>and</strong> the United States, it<br />

should be expected that the actual nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> of the renminbi would be<br />

under-valued compared to the Big Mac PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong>. In fact, using the Big<br />

Mac PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> as a benchmark, the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>s of most Asian<br />

economies are similarly under-valued.<br />

This exercise shows that it is exceptionally difªcult to claim convincingly that a<br />

country’s nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> is under- or over-valued. The intellectual basis for<br />

such a claim is questionable at best because of the theoretical difªculties in deªning<br />

the “correct” nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

4. The transitory <strong>and</strong> lasting effects created by changes in the nominal<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

Although it is difªcult to deªne the “correct” level for China’s nominal exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong>, it is still possible <strong>and</strong> important to analyze the effects of changes in the nominal<br />

exchange <strong>rate</strong> on the economy. In the short-run, changes in the nominal exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong> will immediately redistribute wealth between exporters <strong>and</strong> importers <strong>and</strong><br />

thereby affect their competitiveness. However, in theory, the nominal revaluation<br />

will have only temporary effects on the competitiveness of importers <strong>and</strong> exporters<br />

through a redistribution of income <strong>and</strong> will have no lasting effects on competitiveness<br />

after the economy adjusts to the shock.<br />

37 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

To illust<strong>rate</strong> how this economic logic functions, suppose China were to revalue its<br />

currency by 15 percent tomorrow. This would immediately redistribute a large sum<br />

of wealth from exporters to importers in the short-run, artiªcially reducing the competitiveness<br />

of China’s exporters by 15 percent, <strong>and</strong> increasing the competitiveness<br />

of importers to China by 15 percent. However, the effects on the Chinese economy<br />

will not stop after this 15 percent revaluation. Many exporting ªrms will have to<br />

close down, which may lead to deºation in China. The deºation would continue until<br />

it has produced a 15 percent decline in the price level exactly matching the revaluation.<br />

After the deºation, wages <strong>and</strong> other costs will be 15 percent lower <strong>and</strong> exporting<br />

ªrms will regain the competitiveness they had lost. Importers to China<br />

would ªnd that the prices of domestically produced substitutes had dropped by<br />

15 percent, offsetting their 15 percent gain in advantage from the revaluation.<br />

In reality, things are much more complicated. Fortunately, we can consult the experience<br />

of Japan, which allowed its currency to appreciate steadily <strong>and</strong> signiªcantly for<br />

many years during the 1980s <strong>and</strong> 1990s, with little effect on reducing or eliminating<br />

its current account surplus. What Japan got from the appreciation of the yen was little<br />

more than a decade of deºation! If Japan had held its nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> constant<br />

throughout 1990s, it would most likely have faced inºation, but excessive appreciation<br />

of the yen eliminated the necessity for inºation <strong>and</strong> even required some<br />

deºation to compensate.<br />

The argument that changes in the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> would have a lasting effect<br />

on current account balances is misleading. If a country could gain real competitiveness<br />

through the nominal devaluation of its currency, economic growth <strong>and</strong> development<br />

would be easy <strong>and</strong> would have occurred a long time ago in many developing<br />

countries. Lasting improvements in competitiveness are determined by factor<br />

costs, transaction costs, technological progress, infrastructure, human capital, <strong>and</strong><br />

other real variables, but not by the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>. Sustained current account<br />

imbalances have very little to do with the level of the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

Current account imbalances are the results of the savings <strong>and</strong> investment gaps (Liu<br />

<strong>and</strong> Woo 1994).<br />

5. The Balassa–Samuelson effect <strong>and</strong> structural inºation<br />

In order to underst<strong>and</strong> the economic role of currency appreciation, we go back to<br />

the point I made in our discussion of the Big Mac exchange <strong>rate</strong> that the prices of<br />

non-tradable goods in China are lower than in the United States. Because the prices<br />

of tradable goods in China equal the prices of tradable goods in the United States<br />

due to price arbitrage, the result of the lower prices of non-tradable goods in China<br />

38 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

is that the general price level in China is lower than the general price level in the<br />

United States.<br />

Bela Balassa <strong>and</strong> Paul Samuelson have found that because the productivity growth<br />

in the non-tradable goods sector is generally substantially lower than the productivity<br />

growth in the tradable goods sector during the economic development process,<br />

there is the secular trend of the prices of non-tradable goods rising relative to the<br />

prices of tradable goods. In an open economy, where the prices of tradable goods are<br />

ªxed by the value of the exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> by the prices of foreign substitutes, the<br />

Balassa–Samuelson effect of a relative rise in the prices of non-tradable goods is<br />

achieved by either inºation (rise in the absolute price level of non-tradable goods)<br />

or currency appreciation (fall in the absolute price level of tradable goods), or by a<br />

combination of inºation-cum-appreciation. Hence, in a growing economy with a<br />

ªxed exchange <strong>rate</strong> regime, there is an inherent structural inºation to accommodate<br />

the Balassa–Samuelson effect.<br />

The implication of this discussion is that, as long as China keeps its exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

ªxed, the process of economic development would naturally gene<strong>rate</strong> structural<br />

inºation to bring the general price level in China up to the general price level in the<br />

United States. 4 The underlying mechanism is that rising productivity in China’s<br />

tradable sector (manufacturing) would raise the wages of engineers. This development<br />

would then entice workers from the non-tradable sector, such as hair stylists<br />

or barbers, to shift to the manufacturing sector. As a result, if there is no surplus labor<br />

in the economy, wages for hair stylists will also rise even though there has been<br />

no productivity gain in haircutting. Increases in wages for all sectors will either lead<br />

to inºation or require appreciation of the currency to accommodate the increase in<br />

the general level of prices stemming from the rising productivity in the manufacturing<br />

sector.<br />

According to this theory, productivity growth in the tradable goods sector is the<br />

driver of structural inºation <strong>and</strong> currency appreciation. However, before inºation<br />

<strong>and</strong> currency appreciation can take off signiªcantly, the economy ªrst needs to reach<br />

a state of full employment. This process has worked smoothly previously in economies<br />

like Japan, Korea, <strong>and</strong> Hong Kong, which achieved full employment after industrialization<br />

started.<br />

4 The gap in price levels between China <strong>and</strong> the United States can be measured by the difference<br />

between China’s nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> for GDP. In 2006, the<br />

gap was 67.5 percent based on China’s nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> of 8 yuan per dollar <strong>and</strong> the<br />

2.6 yuan per dollar PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> for GDP as calculated by the World Bank.<br />

39 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

From 1950 to 1960, Japan’s average inºation <strong>rate</strong> was 5.3 percent, exceeding the<br />

2.6 percent average for the United States. From 1960 to 1971, Japan’s average<br />

inºation <strong>rate</strong> was about 5.5 percent, exceeding the 3.4 percent average U.S. inºation.<br />

Following high inºation during the ªrst oil crisis in the early 1970s, however, Japan’s<br />

central bank started to clamp down very hard on inºation. As a result, from<br />

1979 to 1993, Japan’s inºation <strong>rate</strong> averaged about 2.3 percent, which was below the<br />

average U.S. <strong>rate</strong> of 4.7 percent. With inºation under control, the only alternative<br />

way to accommodate the continued growth in domestic price levels was through<br />

yen appreciation. The yen, previously pegged to the dollar at 360 yen per dollar,<br />

started to appreciate in 1971 <strong>and</strong> then after the 1984 Plaza Accord rose to approximately<br />

100–120 yen per dollar in the 1990s. The Plaza Accord, in which a U.S.-led<br />

coalition forced Japan to appreciate its currency, would not have been necessary if<br />

Japan had allowed its domestic inºation to exceed the <strong>rate</strong> in the United States during<br />

the 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s. However, the government-engineered appreciation of the<br />

yen in the 1990s was so excessive that it led to a decade of deºation in Japan.<br />

The story in Hong Kong is much simpler but is also consistent with the Balassa–<br />

Samuelson theory. With the Hong Kong dollar pegged to the U.S. dollar, Hong<br />

Kong’s inºation <strong>rate</strong>, brought about by strong productivity growth, averaged about<br />

3 percentage points above the average U.S. inºation <strong>rate</strong> from 1980 to 2000. Annual<br />

inºation in Hong Kong was around 10 percent for a number of years in the 1990s.<br />

The productivity gains brought about by developments in supply chain management<br />

technology in the international trade sector <strong>and</strong> by the rapid development of<br />

the Hong Kong ªnancial sector pushed up prices in all sectors because labor, l<strong>and</strong>,<br />

<strong>and</strong> capital were all at full employment. The unemployment <strong>rate</strong> in Hong Kong at<br />

the peak of the 1990s business cycle was as low as 2 percent.<br />

The story for China is a bit complicated, but still appears to be consistent with the<br />

Balassa–Samuelson theory. A number of studies (Xiao <strong>and</strong> Tu 2005; Xiao 2006; Lu<br />

2007, Xiao <strong>and</strong> Weiss 2007) have shown that rapid labor productivity growth in<br />

China’s industrial sector has occurred <strong>and</strong> is continuing. This productivity growth<br />

has led to a steady increase in the wages of urban workers. High <strong>and</strong> rising urban<br />

wages attracted as many as 119 million workers from China’s rural areas to its<br />

coastal cities in recent years. However, due to the large pools of rural <strong>and</strong> migrant<br />

labor, which may amount to as many as 481 million people, the wages of rural <strong>and</strong><br />

migrant workers have risen slowly until recently. As a result, inºation has been low<br />

<strong>and</strong> currency appreciation slow during the last decade despite China’s tremendous<br />

growth <strong>rate</strong>s.<br />

40 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

In the next decade or two, however, as China’s baby boom generation starts aging<br />

<strong>and</strong> the economy continues to grow rapidly, China is likely to get closer <strong>and</strong> closer<br />

to full employment. When this happens, China will probably experience rapid structural<br />

inºation <strong>and</strong>/or currency appreciation similar to that experienced by Japan<br />

<strong>and</strong> Hong Kong. The key underlying assumption of this model, of course, is continued<br />

productivity growth in the manufacturing sector.<br />

6. China should adopt an inºation-ªrst <strong>and</strong> appreciation-second st<strong>rate</strong>gy<br />

It is clear from the previous section that inºation <strong>and</strong> currency appreciation are substitutes<br />

because they are equivalent ways of facilitating a rise in a country’s domestic<br />

price level. So, the people who are pushing China to revalue the renminbi by 15<br />

to 40 percent are really asking China to raise its domestic price level upward by 15<br />

to 40 percent. Why not just recommend to Chinese <strong>policy</strong>makers a 15 to 40 percent<br />

inºation?<br />

A large currency appreciation affects all members of society immediately through a<br />

forced redistribution of wealth, followed by forced wage <strong>and</strong> price <strong>adjustment</strong>s.<br />

Inºation, on the other h<strong>and</strong>, is an aggregation of price <strong>adjustment</strong>s in each market<br />

where rational individuals <strong>and</strong> companies make decisions about how to respond to<br />

changes in wages <strong>and</strong> prices; <strong>and</strong>, hence, in my opinion, causes much less shock to<br />

the society.<br />

In my view, China should be encouraged to run a stable but low <strong>rate</strong> of inºation to<br />

accommodate the structural inºation from the Balassa–Samuelson effect. The<br />

inºation <strong>rate</strong> should be about 5 percent a year, to facilitate the steady approach of its<br />

domestic price level to the level in more developed economies. This structural<br />

inºation st<strong>rate</strong>gy also has the advantage of deterring currency speculation, as speculators<br />

would need to worry about inºation in China whenever they bet on appreciation<br />

of the renminbi. 5 When structural inºation, which is different from pure monetary<br />

inºation, is expected to surpass 5 percent, China should also add currency<br />

appreciation as an additional instrument to absorb pressure for increases in domestic<br />

prices. The extent of currency appreciation should be determined by the market,<br />

5 Furthermore, speculators <strong>and</strong> investors can still bet on real estate, which will rise in value<br />

with both inºation <strong>and</strong> appreciation. But the catch-up in property prices should be viewed as<br />

a leading indicator for the catch-up in the overall price level <strong>and</strong> should not concern the Chinese<br />

authorities too much as long as property investors are required to make sizable down<br />

payments.<br />

41 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

in the sense that appreciation should not be so extensive as to push inºation below<br />

3 percent.<br />

The most useful way to consider the question of how fast the renminbi should appreciate<br />

is to examine the combination of inºation <strong>and</strong> renminbi appreciation to determine<br />

China’s domestic price level relative to that of the United States. We approach<br />

an underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the best pace for renminbi appreciation in the coming<br />

years by also considering a realistic pace for convergence between price levels in<br />

China <strong>and</strong> other countries.<br />

For simplicity, let us assume that China will maintain an inºation <strong>rate</strong> exactly the<br />

same as the U.S. <strong>rate</strong>. Using this assumption, we can then calculate the number of<br />

years needed for the price level in China to catch up to the level in the United States,<br />

assuming also a constant annual <strong>rate</strong> of renminbi appreciation. The result from this<br />

simple arithmetic shows that it will take 57 years for China’s price level to match<br />

that of the United States if the currency appreciates at 2 percent a year, 38 years with<br />

appreciation at 3 percent a year, 23 years at 5 percent, 15 years at 8 percent, <strong>and</strong><br />

8 years if the currency appreciates at a <strong>rate</strong> of 15 percent a year. As pointed out previously,<br />

the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> is just one of two variables that ªgures in the determination<br />

of domestic price levels; the other variable is the inºation <strong>rate</strong>. If its currency<br />

appreciates too fast, China will experience deºation; if it appreciates too<br />

slowly, China will experience inºation.<br />

Moreover, in 2006 China’s domestic price level was 32.5 percent that of the United<br />

States. China’s domestic price level, which determines the costs of goods made in<br />

China for American consumers, is determined by the underlying growth of productivity<br />

in China, not by China’s premier, not by the governor of China’s central bank,<br />

<strong>and</strong> not by congresspersons in Washington. This point cannot be emphasized<br />

enough if we want to discuss China’s currency <strong>policy</strong> scientiªcally <strong>and</strong> objectively.<br />

Now let’s ask: how long would it take for China’s domestic price level to reach the<br />

U.S. price level based on past experiences in price level convergence among developed<br />

<strong>and</strong> developing countries? The answer could very well range from 15 to<br />

38 years. This timeframe for convergence, in turn, would imply annual renminbi appreciation<br />

ranging from 3 to 8 percent, assuming inºation in China is no higher than<br />

inºation in the United States. In my view, it is not possible for China’s domestic<br />

price level to reach that of the United States’ level within 15 years. For this judgment<br />

to make any sense, China’s average annual currency appreciation plus its extra<br />

inºation could not exceed 8 percent. Hence, on average, 4 percent per year extra<br />

42 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

inºation <strong>and</strong> 4 percent per year currency appreciation would probably be the best<br />

we could expect for China in the next two decades.<br />

The actual pace of inºation <strong>and</strong> appreciation in China at the present is far below this<br />

“limit.” In 2006, China’s inºation <strong>rate</strong> was only 1.5 percent, much lower than the 2.5<br />

percent inºation <strong>rate</strong> in the United States. In fact, relative to the Unites States, China<br />

had deºation in 2006! At the same time, the average <strong>rate</strong> of currency appreciation<br />

was around 3 percent. So in 2006 relative to the United States, China’s domestic<br />

price level increased only about 2 percent (1.5 2.5 3 2) <strong>and</strong> stood at 32.5 percent<br />

of that of the United States. At this pace, it will take 57 years for the price level<br />

in China to catch up to the U.S. level. No wonder so many in Washington are getting<br />

impatient about China’s currency <strong>policy</strong>! However, although it is easy to complain<br />

about China’s slow <strong>adjustment</strong>, it is difªcult to ªnd a solution to speed up the convergence<br />

of China’s price level.<br />

7. Why has China’s inºation <strong>rate</strong> been so low <strong>and</strong> at the same time its<br />

currency appreciation <strong>rate</strong> also so slow?<br />

The structural constraints associated with China’s surplus labor pool are the main<br />

causes for the slow catch-up in China’s price level, although difªculties in <strong>macroeconomic</strong><br />

policies also play an important role. In 2006, inºation in China was<br />

1.5 percent while it was 2.5 percent in the United States, 2.2 percent in Korea,<br />

5.5 percent in India, 7.9 percent in Pakistan, 13.1 percent in Indonesia, 7.5 percent in<br />

Vietnam, <strong>and</strong> 6.2 percent in the Philippines. It seems fair to say that in the global<br />

context, China experienced deºationary pressure in 2006 even though its economy<br />

grew 10.7 percent.<br />

Surprisingly, although China recorded one of the lowest inºation <strong>rate</strong>s in the world<br />

in 2006, both the Chinese government <strong>and</strong> international organizations like the Asian<br />

Development Bank (ADB), the World Bank, <strong>and</strong> the IMF have urged China to<br />

tighten monetary <strong>policy</strong> to restrain investment. In contrast, the ADB, among other<br />

organizations, recommended that other Asian economies with much higher<br />

inºation <strong>rate</strong>s raise investment, especially in infrastructure, which is the exact <strong>policy</strong><br />

China followed in the past.<br />

According to a survey by the Ministry of Agriculture, total employment in China<br />

was 764 million in 2006. Of this total, only 283 million jobs belonged to the urban<br />

sector. The number of migrant workers reached 119 million in 2006, an increase of<br />

7 million over the previous year, <strong>and</strong> their average monthly wage was about<br />

958 yuan, or US$ 120 dollars. Subtracting the 283 million urban jobs <strong>and</strong> 119 million<br />

43 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

migrant workers from total employment of 764 million, suggests China still has<br />

362 million rural workers. Combining the number of rural workers with the 119 million<br />

migrant workers yields 481 million unskilled workers who currently earn an<br />

average of US$ 120 dollars a month or less. Many of these workers are likely underemployed<br />

<strong>and</strong> would be eager to shift to a job that paid a higher wage.<br />

These 481 million unskilled workers face two choices: stay in the villages or mig<strong>rate</strong><br />

to urban regions to ªnd a job in the industrial or service sector. If they stay in the villages,<br />

they can maintain a st<strong>and</strong>ard of living more or less the same as that of an average<br />

Chinese peasant, which is barely above subsistence. If they mig<strong>rate</strong> to the cities,<br />

they have to compete with other migrants for the limited number of urban jobs.<br />

Fierce competition in the unskilled labor markets, which are linked nation-wide<br />

through the newly completed inter-province highway system, mobile phones, bus<br />

<strong>and</strong> rail routes, as well as informal township associations, has driven wages for unskilled<br />

labor down to a level close to the subsistence income of the average peasant.<br />

None would envy the position of rural or migrant Chinese workers.<br />

In recent years, the Chinese government has tried hard to increase wages for migrant<br />

workers as well as incomes of peasants. Wages for migrant workers increased<br />

as much as 12 percent in 2006 after the government’s effort to raise the minimum<br />

wage. Shenzhen, the special economic zone next to Hong Kong, increased its minimum<br />

wage by 17 percent last year. Nevertheless, the income of rural residents in<br />

China increased only 1.2 percent in 2006. As explained previously, the incomes of<br />

migrant workers <strong>and</strong> rural residents are closely linked due to their freedom to move<br />

between urban <strong>and</strong> rural jobs. In order to raise the income of one group, it is necessary<br />

to raise the income of both.<br />

This huge pool of unskilled workers is what is slowing the growth of wages in<br />

China, <strong>and</strong> this pool of underutilized labor is what ultimately dampens inºationary<br />

pressures in China. If the Chinese economy were to slow down, for example as a result<br />

of a 15 percent revaluation of the renminbi, China could easily see deºation <strong>and</strong><br />

massive unemployment due to the competition of 481 million unskilled workers<br />

who are surviving barely above subsistence. 6<br />

6 It must be pointed out that the low wages of unskilled workers have also adversely affected<br />

the environment <strong>and</strong> public health; the vast number of unskilled workers may encourage<br />

low-cost production that gene<strong>rate</strong>s huge environmental <strong>and</strong> public health damage when the<br />

government <strong>and</strong> industries with low proªt-margins do not have enough resources <strong>and</strong> incentives<br />

to take necessary precautions <strong>and</strong> preventive measures. Although it is difªcult to<br />

get reliable data, from my own experience in visiting many rural enterprises, I conclude that<br />

for many of these enterprises the costs of pollution <strong>and</strong> energy-inefªcient technology could<br />

be much greater than the thin proªts <strong>and</strong> low wages they gene<strong>rate</strong>. Unfortunately, the central<br />

44 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

Why did international organizations like the ADB recommend that one economy,<br />

such as India, increase investment when inºation is high, while recommending that<br />

another economy, such as China, reduce investment when inºation is low? The typical<br />

answer is that “China is special,” that it has over-capacity, <strong>and</strong> that therefore it<br />

should reduce investment <strong>and</strong> increase consumption.<br />

The advice to increase consumption cannot be wrong. However, consumption in<br />

China today is largely under the control of individuals <strong>and</strong> ªrms. They have probably<br />

already tried to optimize their consumption given all the constraints they face,<br />

<strong>and</strong> are unlikely to welcome the government telling them how to spend their<br />

money.<br />

8. China’s real challenges in managing external balances<br />

To accele<strong>rate</strong> the catch-up in China’s domestic price level, the international community<br />

should encourage China to adopt a loose monetary <strong>policy</strong>, which means less<br />

sterilization of its rising foreign exchange reserves. A loose monetary <strong>policy</strong> is necessary<br />

to accommodate steady structural inºation, <strong>and</strong> a low <strong>and</strong> stable inºation<br />

<strong>rate</strong> is a necessary condition for facilitating an orderly renminbi appreciation that<br />

would not risk deºation. However, in order to convince China to adopt a loose<br />

monetary <strong>policy</strong>, it is necessary to help China to develop a robust ªnancial, planning,<br />

<strong>and</strong> regulatory system that can distinguish productive from unproductive investments.<br />

Chinese leaders are trying to change China’s growth model from export-led to consumption-led<br />

development, but they need help from the international community.<br />

For example, health insurance <strong>and</strong> social security networks in China are in their infancy,<br />

<strong>and</strong> therefore, many Chinese people choose to save a great deal as a hedge<br />

against uncontrollable expenses. In the absence of student-loan programs, families<br />

also choose to save a great deal for their children’s education. Betting on capital<br />

gains, many middle-class Chinese families decide to buy property in new residential<br />

communities, but refrain from moving until roads, subway networks, schools, <strong>and</strong><br />

other infrastructure are completed. These are the best choices given the structural<br />

<strong>and</strong> economic constraints of Chinese society. As a result of the individual best<br />

choices available to Chinese households, consumption remains low <strong>and</strong> savings<br />

government has not yet found an effective way to limit the low-efªciency activities that provide<br />

socially costly employment for the pool of unskilled labor. China needs to ªnd ways immediately<br />

to identify <strong>and</strong> stop these value-subtracting industries before they permanently<br />

damage the environment <strong>and</strong> the people.<br />

45 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

<strong>rate</strong>s remain high. All of this begs the question, how can China best increase domestic<br />

consumption?<br />

In the context of these examples, the answers are quite straightforward: build an integ<strong>rate</strong>d<br />

health insurance system; create student loan or scholarship programs; <strong>and</strong><br />

build more roads, subways, <strong>and</strong> schools. All these solutions, not surprisingly, require<br />

investment. These are productive investments, <strong>and</strong> productive public investments<br />

are fundamentally different from investments that gene<strong>rate</strong> unproductive<br />

over-capacity. These productive investments will free up the consumption power of<br />

Chinese households, which currently is held back to hedge against potential negative<br />

future eventualities.<br />

What China needs, then, is a set of <strong>macroeconomic</strong> policies that increase productive<br />

investment <strong>and</strong> consumption while reducing unproductive investments. Unfortunately,<br />

this is almost impossible, because the <strong>macroeconomic</strong> instruments available<br />

to the government, such as control over the money supply, the exchange <strong>rate</strong>, interest<br />

<strong>rate</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> bank reserve ratios, do not distinguish productive from nonproductive<br />

investment. Without much choice, the Chinese government was forced<br />

to go back to its old tools: administrative controls, industrial <strong>policy</strong>, <strong>and</strong> political<br />

discipline including an anti-corruption campaign.<br />

Unfortunately, China’s National Bureau of Statistics cannot distinguish productive<br />

from unproductive investment. When reported statistics suggested the overall investment<br />

<strong>rate</strong> was too high, the Chinese government put a brake on investment, depressing<br />

both productive <strong>and</strong> unproductive investment. When investment, especially<br />

productive investment, is constrained, imports do not grow fast enough to<br />

keep up with exports. As discussed previously, investment in the supply chain system<br />

that supports China’s exports has been carried out largely by foreign-invested<br />

companies <strong>and</strong> is not affected by the Chinese government’s <strong>macroeconomic</strong> control<br />

policies. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, imports depend heavily on domestic consumption <strong>and</strong><br />

domestic investment. Hence, China developed a large current account surplus because<br />

the government failed to allow enough productive investment.<br />

9. Conclusion<br />

The essential function of a good modern ªnancial, planning, <strong>and</strong> regulatory system<br />

is to reduce the transaction costs between capital <strong>and</strong> labor so that they can work<br />

productively together. Without this system, China will not be able to employ productively<br />

<strong>and</strong> fully its 481 million rural <strong>and</strong> migrant workers. Instead, China creates<br />

hundreds of socially costly rural enterprises, which gene<strong>rate</strong> more pollution <strong>and</strong> so-<br />

46 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

cial instability than they gene<strong>rate</strong> in proªts <strong>and</strong> wages. China’s imports will not be<br />

able to balance off its exports, which will continue costing the United States <strong>and</strong><br />

other nations jobs while encouraging protectionism. China’s potential purchasing<br />

power will be locked up in its foreign exchange reserves instead of becoming productive<br />

investment <strong>and</strong> consumption. It is for this reason that I regard Treasury Secretary<br />

Paulson’s Shanghai speech on China’s ªnancial sector reform as a “Marshall<br />

Plan” draft that could bring a win–win result for China <strong>and</strong> the United States in the<br />

21st century.<br />

The strength of the ªnancial sector in the United States contrasts sharply with its<br />

weakness in China. With a strong ªnancial sector, average Americans can afford to<br />

maintain a low savings <strong>rate</strong> since they can secure capital gains on their investments<br />

in property <strong>and</strong> capital markets. With a weak ªnancial sector, Chinese consumers<br />

have to maintain a high savings <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> lower consumption (<strong>and</strong> lower st<strong>and</strong>ard of<br />

living). China’s surplus capital cannot be used to hire all its own people productively.<br />

Americans today worry about the competition from China just as Hong Kong<br />

did a decade ago. People in Hong Kong today, however, realize that when China is<br />

growing productively, there will be more work than all of Hong Kong’s labor pool<br />

can h<strong>and</strong>le. I have no doubt that if the United States can help China ªx its ªnancial<br />

sector, China will create enormous dem<strong>and</strong> for U.S. goods <strong>and</strong> services, with consequent<br />

beneªts <strong>and</strong> employment opportunities for the people of the United States.<br />

Supply creates dem<strong>and</strong> only if we have an efªcient ªnancial sector <strong>and</strong> if the transaction<br />

costs are decreasing toward zero.<br />

How to build a robust ªnancial, planning, <strong>and</strong> regulatory system in China with help<br />

from the international community is a topic beyond the scope of this paper. However,<br />

efforts by the United States <strong>and</strong> the international community to increase consumption<br />

in China should focus on this broad fundamental issue, not simply on a<br />

renminbi exchange <strong>rate</strong> revaluation.<br />

References<br />

Anderson, Jonathan. 2005. The Complete RMB H<strong>and</strong>book (3rd edition). Asian Economic Perspectives,<br />

25 July. Hong Kong: UBS Investment Research.<br />

Bhagwati, Jagdish. 2007. U.S. Trade Policy: The China Question. Testimony before U.S. Senate<br />

Finance Committee in Congressional Hearing regarding Opportunities <strong>and</strong> Challenges in the<br />

U.S.–China Economic Relationship, 27 March, Washington, DC.<br />

Cheong, Y. R., <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao. 2003. Global Capital Flows <strong>and</strong> the Position of China. In China’s<br />

Role in Asia <strong>and</strong> the World Economy: Fostering Stability <strong>and</strong> Growth, edited by Jan Joost Teunissen,<br />

pp. 113–175. The Hague: FONDAD.<br />

47 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

Cline, William R. 2005. The Case for a New Plaza Agreement. Policy Briefs, Number PB05-4,<br />

Washington DC: Institute for International Economics.<br />

Dooley, Michael, David Folkerts-L<strong>and</strong>au, <strong>and</strong> Peter Garber. 2005. International Financial Stability:<br />

Asia, Interest Rates, <strong>and</strong> the Dollar. Global Markets Research 27. New York: Deutsche Bank.<br />

Goldstein, Morris. 2007. A (Lack of) Progress Report on China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate Policies,<br />

pp. 15–16. No. WP07-5, Washington D.C.: Peterson Institute for International Economics.<br />

———. 2007. Assessing Progress on China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate Policies. Testimony before the U.S.<br />

Senate Finance Committee in Congressional Hearing regarding Risks <strong>and</strong> Reforms: The Role of<br />

Currency in the U.S.–China Relationship, 28 March, Washington, DC.<br />

Goldstein, Morris, <strong>and</strong> Nicholas R. Lardy. 2005. China’s Role in the Revived Bretton Woods<br />

System: A Case of Mistaken Identity. Working Paper Series, No. WP05-2. Washington DC: Institution<br />

for International Economics.<br />

Koivu, Tuuli, <strong>and</strong> Alicia Garcia-Herrero. 2007 Can the Chinese Trade Surplus Be Reduced<br />

Through <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate Policy? BOFIT Discussion Paper No. 6/2007. Hong Kong: BOFIT.<br />

Liu, Liang-Yun, <strong>and</strong> Wing Thye Woo. 1994. Saving Behavior under Imperfect Financial Markets<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Current Account Consequences. Economic Journal 104 (424):512–527.<br />

Lu, Feng. 2007. The Return on Capital in China: Evidences, Causes, <strong>and</strong> Policy Implications.<br />

Paper presented at CCER China Economic Monitor Workshop, 11 January, Beijing.<br />

Makin, John H. 2007. China’s Risky Currency Policy. Testimony before the U.S. Senate Finance<br />

Committee in Congressional Hearing regarding Risks <strong>and</strong> Reforms: The Role of Currency in<br />

the U.S.–China Relationship, 28 March, Washington, DC.<br />

McKinnon, Ronald. 2005. <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate or Wage Changes in International Adjustment? Japan<br />

<strong>and</strong> China versus the United States. 2005 ZEW Discussion Paper No. 05-64 2005.<br />

———. 2005. China’s New <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate Policy: Will China Follow Japan into a Liquidity<br />

Trap? Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper No. 05-02. Stanford.<br />

Paulson, Henry. 2007. On the Growth <strong>and</strong> Future of China’s Financial Markets. Prepared remarks<br />

by U.S. Treasury Secretary, 7 March, Shanghai.<br />

Prasad, Eswar S. 2007. <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate Flexibility in China: Why It Really Matters <strong>and</strong> How to<br />

Make Progress. Testimony before the U.S. Senate Finance Committee in Congressional Hearing<br />

regarding Risks <strong>and</strong> Reforms: The Role of Currency in the U.S.–China Relationship, 28 March,<br />

Washington, DC.<br />

Roach, Stephen S. 2007. The China Fix. Testimony before the U.S. Senate Finance Committee in<br />

Congressional Hearing regarding Risks <strong>and</strong> Reforms: The Role of Currency in the U.S.–China<br />

Relationship, 28 March, Washington, DC.<br />

Sheng, Andrew, <strong>and</strong> Allen Ng. 2007. The External Wealth of China: An Investigation from International<br />

Balance Sheet Perspective. WP01/2008, Hong Kong Institute for Monetary Research.<br />

Truman, Edwin M. 2005. A Revived Bretton Woods System? Implications for Europe <strong>and</strong> the<br />

United States. Speech at the Conference Revived Bretton Woods System: A New Paradigm for<br />

Asian Development? 4 February, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.<br />

48 Asian Economic Papers


China’s <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> Monetary Policies<br />

U.S. Trade Representative (USTR). 2007. National Trade Estimate Report on Foreign Trade Barriers:<br />

China. Ofªce of the U.S. Trade Representative: Washington DC.<br />

Williamson, John. 2003. The Reminbi <strong>Exchange</strong> Rate <strong>and</strong> the Global Monetary System. Lecture<br />

delivered at the Central University of Finance <strong>and</strong> Economics, 29 October, Beijing.<br />

Woo, Wing Thye. 2006. The Structural Nature of Internal <strong>and</strong> External Imbalances in China.<br />

Journal of Chinese Economic <strong>and</strong> Business Studies 4 (1):1–20.<br />

Woo, Wing Thye, <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao. 2007. Facing Protectionism Gene<strong>rate</strong>d by Trade Disputes:<br />

China’s Post-WTO Blues. In China Linking Markets for Growth. Asia Paciªc Press, Canberra.<br />

Xiao, Geng. 2006. Non-Performing Debts in Chinese Enterprises: Patterns, Causes, <strong>and</strong> Implications<br />

for Banking Reform. Asian Economic Papers 4 (3):61–113.<br />

Xiao, Geng, <strong>and</strong> Zhengge Tu. 2005. Productivity Growth in China’s Large <strong>and</strong> Medium-Sized<br />

Industrial Firms: Patterns, Causes, <strong>and</strong> Implications. Paper presented at International Workshop<br />

on Competition, Innovation <strong>and</strong> Productivity: Empirical Evidence from Firm Level Data,<br />

19–20 December, Nice, Sophia-Antipolis, France.<br />

Xiao, Geng, <strong>and</strong> John Weiss. 2007. Development in North East People’s Republic of China: An<br />

Analysis of Enterprise Performance: 1995–2002. China Economic Review 18 (2):170–189.<br />

Yu, Yongding. 2007. Global Imbalances: China’s Perspective. Paper presented at IIE Conference<br />

on Global Imbalances, 8 February, Washington, DC.<br />

49 Asian Economic Papers


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Nonperforming Debts in Chinese<br />

Enterprises: Patterns, Causes, <strong>and</strong><br />

Implications for Banking Reform *<br />

Geng Xiao<br />

The University of Hong Kong<br />

Hong Kong, SAR, China<br />

xiaogeng@hku.hk<br />

Abstract<br />

Given the domination of bank financing, nonperforming debts<br />

(NPDs) in large Chinese enterprises are a proxy for nonperforming<br />

loans (NPLs) in China’s major banks. Using a firm-level survey<br />

of more than 20,000 large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises<br />

conducted by the National Bureau of Statistics of China,<br />

this paper estimates both the level <strong>and</strong> ratio of NPDs across<br />

ownership type, industry, <strong>and</strong> region for the period 1995–2002.<br />

The results show that NPD ratios have been falling since 2000 as<br />

a result of the rapid expansion of better-performing non-state enterprises<br />

(NSEs), the improved performance of state-owned enterprises<br />

(SOEs), <strong>and</strong> the exit of poor-performing enterprises<br />

(which has been facilitated by asset management companies <strong>and</strong><br />

other merger <strong>and</strong> acquisition activities). SOEs, however, are still<br />

much more likely than NSEs to gene<strong>rate</strong> NPDs. This paper provides<br />

useful tools <strong>and</strong> sector information for assessing enterprise<br />

debt risks <strong>and</strong> draws lessons for banking reform in China.<br />

1. Introduction<br />

Since early 2004, the newly established China Banking<br />

Regulatory Commission (CBRC) has announced quarterly<br />

* This paper was presented at the Asian Economic Panel meeting<br />

in Hong Kong on 12–13 April 2004, <strong>and</strong> at the Hong Kong Monetary<br />

Authority workshop on 8 July 2004. The author would like<br />

to acknowledge research collaboration with the Industry <strong>and</strong><br />

Transportation Department of the National Bureau of Statistics<br />

(NBS) of China. Xing Junling <strong>and</strong> Yu Xiaoyun provided extensive<br />

technical support at NBS. Tu Zhengge provided excellent<br />

research assistance. The author would like to thank the Research<br />

Grant Council of Hong Kong <strong>and</strong> the University Grant Council<br />

of Hong Kong for ªnancial support (project nos. HKU7167/98H<br />

<strong>and</strong> AOE/H05/99). This research work also beneªted from a<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

Asian Economic Papers 4:3<br />

© 2006 The Earth Institute at <strong>Columbia</strong> University <strong>and</strong> the Massachusetts<br />

Institute of Technology<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 61


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

statistics on the ratio of nonperforming loans (NPLs) for China’s major banking institutions.<br />

It reported a sharp decline in the NPL ratio from above 24 percent in 2002<br />

to 19.6 percent in June 2003, 17.8 percent in December 2003, 13.3 percent in June <strong>and</strong><br />

December 2004, <strong>and</strong> only 8.7 percent in June 2005. During the 2-year period between<br />

June 2003 <strong>and</strong> June 2005, the outst<strong>and</strong>ing amount of NPLs in China dropped from<br />

RMB2.538 trillion to RMB1.276 trillion, a decrease of RMB1.262 trillion. This is<br />

clearly a dramatic turnaround in terms of banking sector performance. Are the<br />

ofªcial statistics reliable? What happened to the quality of bank loans <strong>and</strong> debt in<br />

China’s enterprises? These questions motivate this paper. Outside observers interpreted<br />

the ofªcial reports cautiously because they did not underst<strong>and</strong> how China’s<br />

banks calculated their NPL ratios. Most analysts <strong>and</strong> commentators would still estimate<br />

China’s NPL ratio to be at a much higher level than the ofªcial ªgure—usually<br />

two to three times that of the ofªcial NPL ratio. For example, UBS, an investment<br />

bank <strong>and</strong> global asset management ªrm, (Anderson 2005) estimates that China’s<br />

NPLs fell from about 50–55 percent in 1997–98 to about 25–30 percent by the end of<br />

2004. These market estimations of NPL ratios are usually based on <strong>macroeconomic</strong><br />

data because it is difªcult to get reliable <strong>and</strong> representative microeconomic data<br />

from Chinese banks.<br />

This paper attempts to develop an alternative approach to the study of NPLs in<br />

China using ªrm-level microeconomic data. As a result of the limited development<br />

of stock markets <strong>and</strong> enterprise bond markets in China, banks are still the major<br />

holders of enterprises’ long-term <strong>and</strong> short-term debt. In recent years, Chinese<br />

banks have exp<strong>and</strong>ed rapidly in the business of consumer loans, especially mortgage<br />

loans. The outst<strong>and</strong>ing amounts of consumer loans rose from below 1 percent<br />

in 1998 to above 10 percent in 2004. Because the quality of consumer loans is generally<br />

much better than that of enterprise loans, the quality of bank loans depends<br />

largely on the quality of the bank lending to enterprises. The quality of enterprise<br />

debt is directly linked to the proªtability of the enterprises. The ability to pay the interest<br />

<strong>and</strong> principal of loans derives ultimately from proªtability <strong>and</strong> cash income<br />

ºows of the enterprises. This is especially true if we are examining a large group of<br />

enterprises, in which the variations in the enterprise-speciªc timing of cash income<br />

ºows <strong>and</strong> the structures of ªnancing within the group will be averaged out statistically<br />

through the law of large numbers, making the proªtability of each enterprise<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

seed fund for st<strong>rate</strong>gic research in corpo<strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> ªnancial law <strong>and</strong> <strong>policy</strong> from The University<br />

of Hong Kong. The author is also g<strong>rate</strong>ful to Wing Thye Woo, Dwight Perkins, Jeffrey Sachs,<br />

Alan Siu, Richard Wong, Sung Yun Wing, Zhang Weiying, Erh-Cheng Hua, Ren Ruoen, Peng<br />

Wensheng, <strong>and</strong> Guonan Ma for comments <strong>and</strong> suggestions. The author takes responsibility<br />

for any errors.<br />

62 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 62


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

the single most important contribution to the quality of the enterprise group’s portfolio<br />

of debts.<br />

This paper uses the proªtability conditions of each enterprise to measure <strong>and</strong> characterize<br />

the quality of the enterprise group’s portfolio of debts. It uses both reported<br />

proªtability <strong>and</strong> imputed proªtability (the latter is derived from the components of<br />

value-added) to give two alternative estimates of the quality of debt portfolios for<br />

different groups of enterprises classiªed by ownership, industry, <strong>and</strong> region. The<br />

method is applied to a comprehensive annual survey of all the large <strong>and</strong> mediumsized<br />

industrial enterprises in China conducted by the National Bureau of Statistics<br />

of China. Information about the survey data can be found in tables A.1 to A.6 in the<br />

appendix. The survey sample includes more than 20,000 enterprises <strong>and</strong> covers the<br />

period from 1995 to 2002 (see table A.6). In 2002, the sample enterprises had 26 million<br />

employees in total, which is about 16.7 percent of China’s total industrial employment.<br />

These enterprises incurred RMB5.7 trillion in debt, an amount equal to<br />

43.6 percent of the total loans in China’s ªnancial institutions. The sample enterprises<br />

contributed about 19.2 percent of China’s GDP. Clearly these enterprises are<br />

the most important leaders in the Chinese industrial sector. Aggregate ªnancial information<br />

about the sample enterprises has been regularly reported in the Statistical<br />

Yearbook of China.<br />

The contribution of this paper is the methodology of using the disaggregated ªrmlevel<br />

data to study the enterprise proªtability of the enterprises <strong>and</strong> the quality of<br />

their debts. The paper derives both the level <strong>and</strong> ratio of NPD across enterprise<br />

groups by ownership, industry, <strong>and</strong> region for the period 1995–2002. The results<br />

show that NPDs have indeed been falling as a result of both the rapid expansion of<br />

better-performing non-state enterprises (NSEs) <strong>and</strong> improvements in the performance<br />

of state-owned enterprises (SOEs), as well as rapid exit of poor-performing<br />

state-owned enterprises, which has been facilitated by newly established asset management<br />

companies that specialize in dealing with NPLs. The micro-level evidence<br />

uncovered here is largely consistent with the CBRC reports on falling NPLs <strong>and</strong><br />

NPL ratios in China’s banking sector. This study, however, provides a more transparent,<br />

simpler, <strong>and</strong> more objective method of estimating NPDs <strong>and</strong> allows outsiders<br />

to examine the detailed causes <strong>and</strong> dynamics of the changing patterns of NPDs<br />

in Chinese enterprises. In particular, it was found that the SOEs had consistently<br />

gene<strong>rate</strong>d higher NPD ratios than the NSEs, providing a challenge as well as an opportunity<br />

for future banking reform.<br />

Section 2 deªnes our concepts of NPDs; section 3 shows the patterns of NPD <strong>and</strong><br />

NPD ratios across enterprises’ ownership type, industry, <strong>and</strong> region; <strong>and</strong> section 4<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

63 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 63


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

examines the trend of NPD ratios during the period 1995–2002 <strong>and</strong> provides scenarios<br />

of the future of NPD ratios in China. Section 5 uses panel data regressions to<br />

identify the impacts of various factors on the proªtability <strong>and</strong> debt quality of the enterprises.<br />

Section 6 addresses the sample-selection bias in the measure of NPD ratios<br />

resulting from the exit of poor-performing enterprises from the sample over the<br />

study period. Section 7 discusses the implications of the empirical results for banking<br />

reform in China.<br />

2. Defining <strong>and</strong> estimating NPDs<br />

In recent years, the CBRC has been trying hard to monitor <strong>and</strong> supervise the NPLs<br />

in China’s banking institutions. It developed detailed rules on the reporting of the<br />

amount of NPLs <strong>and</strong> the NPL ratios. The purpose is to manage <strong>and</strong> reduce ªnancial<br />

risk by monitoring both the changing distribution of NPLs <strong>and</strong> the changing NPL<br />

ratios of individual banks <strong>and</strong> bank branches. This is clearly necessary <strong>and</strong> useful.<br />

Poor governance of banks is a sufªcient condition for creating NPLs, even when the<br />

enterprise sector is doing well.<br />

The efforts of the CBRC <strong>and</strong> the individual banks to reduce NPLs, however, are only<br />

necessary conditions. Ultimately, the quality of China’s banking assets <strong>and</strong> enterprise<br />

debts depends directly on the proªtability of China’s enterprises. For example,<br />

in the short run it is easy for banks to reduce NPL ratios, or even the amount of<br />

NPLs, by simply exp<strong>and</strong>ing the total amount of loans. New loans are much less<br />

likely to have repayment problems in the short run, but they could create more bad<br />

loans in the future if they are extended to potentially loss-making enterprises. New<br />

loans can help existing loss-making enterprises continue to pay their interest on old<br />

loans, thereby also shifting the underlying risks to the future. The problem is especially<br />

serious when the economy is booming. These are the main reasons why the reliability<br />

of NPL statistics as reported by China’s banks can vary considerably, depending<br />

on how they are calculated. Outsiders are unable to completely underst<strong>and</strong><br />

how the NPLs <strong>and</strong> NPL ratios in China’s banks are actually calculated because the<br />

decisions in each individual case require judgments that are too complex for outsiders<br />

to assess. This is why analysts <strong>and</strong> commentators rely more on the study of<br />

China’s <strong>macroeconomic</strong> conditions, such as business cycles <strong>and</strong> sector performance,<br />

to gauge the level of NPLs in China. Based on their personal impressions <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong>ings<br />

about the Chinese economy, they report NPL ratios that are usually<br />

two to three times larger than the ofªcial ratio.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

This paper attempts to develop an objective measure of the quality of enterprise<br />

debts in China. Proªtability is the only criterion used in measuring the quality of<br />

these debts. The concept <strong>and</strong> its implementation are straightforward. If the enter-<br />

64 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 64


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

prises are making proªts, the quality of their debts (more speciªcally their total liabilities)<br />

are termed “performing.” If they are making losses, their debts are regarded<br />

as “nonperforming.” The amount of NPD for a speciªc enterprise group is then the<br />

sum of the total liabilities in the loss-making enterprises for that group. The NPD ratio<br />

for the group is simply the ratio of the sum of total liabilities in the loss-making<br />

enterprises divided by the sum of total liabilities in both the loss-making <strong>and</strong> proªtmaking<br />

enterprises in the group. These simple deªnitions of NPD <strong>and</strong> the NPD ratio<br />

make our NPD statistics objective, easy to measure, <strong>and</strong> easy to underst<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Our concept of the NPD ratio, however, is not applicable to an individual enterprise,<br />

because according to our deªnition, an enterprise cannot have part of its total debt<br />

be performing <strong>and</strong> the other part be nonperforming: all the debts in any given enterprise<br />

have the same quality. For instance, one enterprise cannot have 70 percent of<br />

its debts performing <strong>and</strong> 30 percent nonperforming. For an individual enterprise,<br />

losses might occur in the ªrst few years, but the ªrm would make proªts in the future.<br />

After a close examination by its creditors, such a ªrm would be considered to<br />

have high-quality debt. Our deªnition of NPD would not be fair to this particular<br />

enterprise. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, a currently proªtable enterprise might become a loss<br />

maker. Then its debt quality would be bad upon close examination. Our assessment,<br />

based only on current proªtability, might not do justice to this particular enterprise.<br />

The difference between current proªtability <strong>and</strong> longer-term proªtability, however,<br />

could be seen as a r<strong>and</strong>om distribution for a large group of enterprises, such as<br />

groups in our sample sepa<strong>rate</strong>d by time, ownership, industry, <strong>and</strong> region. With a<br />

sizable group, the variability in the timing of cash ºows, proªt streams, payments to<br />

creditors, <strong>and</strong> other proªtability-related variables for enterprises within the group<br />

would offset each other, leaving the average NPD ratio for the group a much more<br />

reliable <strong>and</strong> accu<strong>rate</strong> measure of the quality of the group’s portfolio of debts. This is<br />

why our concept of the NPD ratio is useful only for measuring debt quality for<br />

groups of enterprises. This study would be very useful as complementary research<br />

to the traditional method of estimating NPLs.<br />

For our method to be useful, it needs to be applied to a representative sample with<br />

sizable groups of enterprises. The annual survey of large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial<br />

enterprises conducted by China’s National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) is a suitable<br />

data set for our method. The NBS data are in fact census data, not really sample<br />

data, because the survey covers all large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises in<br />

China. In 2002, China had more than 180,000 industrial enterprises with sales above<br />

RMB5 million. The NBS sample includes only about 21,000–23,000 large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized<br />

industrial enterprises out of a total of 180,000 ªrms. Many small industrial<br />

enterprises are not included in our study, but most of them have limited access<br />

to bank ªnance under the current ªnancial system in China.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

65 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 65


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

One major weakness of using our method for the NBS data is sample selection bias.<br />

The group of enterprises included in the NBS survey each year is not always the<br />

same. About 20 percent of the group consists of enterprises that enter <strong>and</strong> exit the<br />

survey sample each year as a result of changes in their size classiªcation or organizational<br />

changes such as mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisition, privatization, reorganization, <strong>and</strong><br />

bankruptcy. The proªtability of exiting ªrms is not necessarily the same as that of<br />

the new entries. This means that we are studying only the largest <strong>and</strong> most dynamic<br />

frontier industrial enterprises in China <strong>and</strong> leaving out the poor-performing ones.<br />

We will address this issue in section 6 <strong>and</strong> show the impact of this sample selection<br />

bias on the estimated ratio of NPD.<br />

Our sample covers not only SOEs but also other types of enterprises in all industries<br />

<strong>and</strong> regions, including rural <strong>and</strong> urban collectives, private enterprises, domestic<br />

mixed-ownership corporations, foreign-invested enterprises, <strong>and</strong> enterprises with<br />

investment from Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan. Our sample does not include<br />

nonindustrial enterprises, however, such as China Telecom, a big service sector ªrm.<br />

It is entirely possible that the enterprises not included in our sample have worse<br />

performance records than the enterprises in the NBS sample. If that is the case, the<br />

NPD ratios for the entire Chinese enterprise sector would be higher than the ratios<br />

reported in this study. Also, if the banking institutions in China are performing<br />

worse than the enterprises in the NBS sample, as a consequence of their own weak<br />

governance, the overall NPL situation of the Chinese economy as a whole would be<br />

worse than that for the sample enterprises used in this study. In addition, we cannot<br />

directly compare the NPL ratios reported by the CBRC with the NPD ratios estimated<br />

in our study because they are deªned differently. The NPD ratios here are designed<br />

to examine the trend <strong>and</strong> the cross-sectional patterns of the quality of Chinese<br />

enterprise debts.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

During the period from 1995 to 2002, the sample enterprises created about 16–25<br />

percent of China’s industrial employment <strong>and</strong> 33–43 percent of China’s industrial<br />

value added (see table A.6). Most signiªcantly, the sample enterprises contributed<br />

about 14–19 percent of China’s GDP. Their total liabilities, one of the key variables<br />

we examine in this paper, amount to about 43–65 percent of China’s total banking<br />

loans during the 1995–2002 period. Of course, not all of the total liabilities in the<br />

sample enterprises correspond to loans from banks. But even assuming that 60 percent<br />

of the total liabilities in the sample are related to various bank loans, the statistical<br />

analysis in the paper provides an in-depth study of the quality of about 27–29<br />

percent of China’s total loans. In summary, although the members of the sample enterprises<br />

group are changing each year, as a whole they form a stable club of China’s<br />

elite industrial enterprises. The performance of this elite group of enterprises is<br />

66 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 66


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

much more representative of the performance of China’s industrial economy than,<br />

for example, the performance of China’s listed companies or any small sample of<br />

Chinese enterprises. Given the growing importance of China’s industrial sector for<br />

both the domestic <strong>and</strong> global economy, our analysis in this paper ªlls a crucial gap<br />

in underst<strong>and</strong>ing the dynamics of China’s industrial reform <strong>and</strong> development.<br />

Tables 1, 2, <strong>and</strong> 3 show the distribution of the total liabilities for the sample enterprises<br />

by ownership, industry, <strong>and</strong> region. The objective is to ªnd out how much of<br />

these debts are located in proªt-making <strong>and</strong> loss-making enterprises <strong>and</strong> then calculate<br />

the amounts <strong>and</strong> ratios of the NPD. There are two underlying forces affecting<br />

the NPD ratios: the shifting distribution of debts across enterprise groups with different<br />

proªtability <strong>and</strong> the changing proªtability of each group.<br />

Table 1 shows the distribution of total liabilities (or total debts) across ownership<br />

types. The share of total debts by SOEs fell sharply, from 76.4 percent in 1995 to 48.2<br />

percent in 2002, to the beneªt of domestic mixed-ownership corporations <strong>and</strong> private<br />

enterprises. The total debt for SOEs increased from RMB2.5 trillion in 1995 to<br />

RMB3.2 trillion in 1998, immediately before the Asian ªnancial crisis, <strong>and</strong> then fell<br />

to RMB2.8 trillion in 2002. The total debt for collectives followed the same pattern as<br />

that for SOEs, rising from RMB227 billion in 1995 to RMB287 billion in 1998 <strong>and</strong><br />

then falling to RMB219 billion in 2002. The shifting of debt toward private, mixed,<br />

foreign, or overseas Chinese enterprises was steady <strong>and</strong> rapid throughout the 1995–<br />

2002 period, without any interruption resulting from the Asian ªnancial crisis in<br />

1998–99. For the 8 years from 1995 to 2002, total debt in the sample enterprises increased<br />

by RMB2,436 billion. Of this net increase, RMB246 billion ended up in the<br />

SOEs, RMB1,411 billion went to mixed-ownership enterprises, RMB467 billion to<br />

foreign enterprises, <strong>and</strong> RMB95 billion to private enterprises. The drastic changes in<br />

the distribution of total debt are strong evidence of the rapid but quiet privatization<br />

<strong>and</strong> opening up of the most dynamic part of China’s industrial sector. In the next<br />

section, we will show that the redistribution of total debt from SOEs toward the<br />

better-performing NSEs contributed to the larger part of the observed fall in average<br />

NPD ratios for the sample enterprises.<br />

How were ªnancial resources allocated among the Chinese industrial enterprises<br />

during 1995–2002, which can be characterized as a period of high growth <strong>and</strong> steady<br />

reform? Which industries <strong>and</strong> regions were getting more ªnancial resources for their<br />

elite industrial enterprises? Tables 2 <strong>and</strong> 3 provide the answer. The two tables give<br />

us detailed information about credit allocation among China’s large <strong>and</strong> mediumsized<br />

industrial enterprises <strong>and</strong> illust<strong>rate</strong> the changing l<strong>and</strong>scape of Chinese enterprise<br />

ªnancing. In tables 2 <strong>and</strong> 3 the total debt for each industry or region are sorted<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

67 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 67


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

Table 1. Distribution of total liabilities by ownership, 1995–2002 (RMB billion)<br />

Change in total<br />

liabilities during<br />

1995–2002 as percentage<br />

of total in 1996<br />

Change in total<br />

liabilities during<br />

1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Amount of debt for<br />

Private 0 1 2 11 18 31 61 95 95 9,500.0%<br />

Collective 227 268 285 287 284 254 221 219 8 3.0%<br />

Mixed 231 279 380 514 690 1,033 1,424 1,642 1,411 505.7%<br />

Foreign 152 232 285 329 371 400 561 619 467 201.3%<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 164 190 214 276 297 305 359 389 225 118.4%<br />

State-owned 2,512 2,737 3,035 3,193 3,145 2,940 2,703 2,758 246 9.0%<br />

Total 3,286 3,707 4,201 4,610 4,805 4,963 5,329 5,722 2,436 65.7%<br />

Share of debt for<br />

Private 0.0% 0.0% 0.0% 0.2% 0.4% 0.6% 1.1% 1.7% 1.7%<br />

Collective 6.9% 7.2% 6.8% 6.2% 5.9% 5.1% 4.1% 3.8% 3.1%<br />

Mixed 7.0% 7.5% 9.0% 11.1% 14.4% 20.8% 26.7% 28.7% 21.7%<br />

Foreign 4.6% 6.3% 6.8% 7.1% 7.7% 8.1% 10.5% 10.8% 6.2%<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 5.0% 5.1% 5.1% 6.0% 6.2% 6.1% 6.7% 6.8% 1.8%<br />

State-owned 76.4% 73.8% 72.2% 69.3% 65.5% 59.2% 50.7% 48.2% 28.2%<br />

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

68 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 68


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

by their amount in 2002, to make it easy to look for the winners <strong>and</strong> losers. The last<br />

two columns show the amount of change <strong>and</strong> the growth <strong>rate</strong> for total debts during<br />

the 1995–2002 period.<br />

As shown in table 2, the top ªve industries in 2002, ranked by the level of their total<br />

debts, were electric power, steam <strong>and</strong> hot water; transport equipment manufacturing;<br />

smelting <strong>and</strong> pressing of ferrous metals; electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications<br />

equipment; <strong>and</strong> raw chemical materials <strong>and</strong> chemicals. The top ªve industries together<br />

attracted RMB2.692 trillion in debt, or 47 percent of the total debt for the<br />

whole sample. The net gains in debt for the top ªve industries during 1995–2002<br />

amounted to RMB1.465 trillion, or 60 percent of the gains by the whole sample.<br />

China’s ªnancial risks are heavily inºuenced by the performance of the above ªve<br />

sectors.<br />

From the last column of table 2, the top ªve industries ranked by the growth of their<br />

total debts during 1995–2002 were tap water production <strong>and</strong> supply; electric power,<br />

steam, <strong>and</strong> hot water; electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications equipment; papermaking<br />

<strong>and</strong> paper products; <strong>and</strong> gas production <strong>and</strong> supply.<br />

Clearly, the above leading industries, which have attracted investment in the last<br />

decade, are largely related to industrial infrastructure, intermediate inputs, raw materials,<br />

production equipment, <strong>and</strong> utilities. Rapid development of these industries<br />

would lay a solid foundation for China’s further industrialization. In this sense,<br />

China’s enterprise ªnance looks increasingly driven by market forces. Of course, a<br />

risk-based regulation st<strong>rate</strong>gy would require extra attention to be paid to the sectors<br />

with heavy concentrations of investment. As we will see in the next section, some of<br />

the above sectors with rapid growth in enterprise debts do have high NPD ratios,<br />

especially the SOE-dominated utilities sector.<br />

From table 3 we see that the top ªve regions ranked by the level of their total enterprise<br />

debts in 2002 are Guangdong, Jiangsu, Sh<strong>and</strong>ong, Shanghai, <strong>and</strong> Liaoning.<br />

These regions are clearly becoming China’s new industrial centers. In section 5, we<br />

will examine region-speciªc enterprise performance, which is relevant for assessing<br />

debt risks across regions. Xiao (2005) examines enterprise performance in the northeast<br />

region of China in detail, <strong>and</strong> Xiao <strong>and</strong> Tu (2005) study China’s industrial productivity<br />

growth using the same set of data.<br />

In the next section, we will show how much of the total debt shown in tables 1–3 is<br />

located in loss-making enterprises. Proªtability of enterprises becomes the crucial<br />

variable for our study. Reported proªts, however, present several problems. First, it<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

69 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 69


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

Table 2. Distribution of total liabilities by industry, 1995–2002, by total liability in 2002 (RMB billion)<br />

Change in total liabilities<br />

during 1995–<br />

2002 as percentage of<br />

total in 1995<br />

Change in total<br />

liabilities during<br />

1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[44] Electric power 296 317 361 521 614 719 802 934 638 215.5%<br />

[37] Transport equipment 229 276 324 360 385 400 440 491 262 114.4%<br />

[32] Pressing ferrous 331 356 396 416 440 407 417 443 112 33.8%<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications 145 167 198 229 251 286 366 424 279 192.4%<br />

[26] Raw chemicals 226 264 326 365 369 388 380 400 174 77.0%<br />

[17] Textile 258 274 287 275 244 234 230 234 24 9.3%<br />

[40] Electric equipment 136 164 185 195 194 195 218 226 90 66.2%<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery 157 180 194 207 202 205 209 222 65 41.4%<br />

[06] Coal mining 129 147 168 182 206 209 217 215 86 66.7%<br />

[31] Nonmetal products 138 166 186 195 201 195 209 215 77 55.8%<br />

[36] Special equipment 148 161 176 187 186 191 184 192 44 29.7%<br />

[25] Petroleum processing 101 113 163 180 180 184 178 173 72 71.3%<br />

[33] Pressing nonferrous 95 101 116 132 140 140 153 162 67 70.5%<br />

[07] Petroleum extract 151 157 164 170 160 158 149 153 2 1.3%<br />

[27] Medical 59 73 81 91 97 105 121 133 74 125.4%<br />

[22] Papermaking 53 65 72 73 80 88 121 125 72 135.8%<br />

[15] Beverage 73 83 99 103 108 111 111 114 41 56.2%<br />

[13] Food processing 87 107 112 114 106 101 103 111 24 27.6%<br />

[16] Tobacco 70 76 82 72 71 74 109 108 38 54.3%<br />

[28] Chemical fiber 62 71 76 83 91 83 75 73 11 17.7%<br />

[34] Metal products 46 53 59 62 63 59 65 68 22 47.8%<br />

[14] Food production 37 41 42 46 48 48 56 65 28 75.7%<br />

[30] Plastic 31 38 43 46 48 49 55 61 30 96.8%<br />

[29] Rubber 36 43 48 50 51 49 52 51 15 41.7%<br />

[46] Tap water 14 15 23 27 30 34 39 46 32 228.6%<br />

[42] Instruments 29 32 37 34 35 34 40 40 11 37.9%<br />

[18] Garments 18 23 24 26 29 33 38 39 21 116.7%<br />

[10] Nonmetal mining 16 16 18 19 23 28 23 29 13 81.3%<br />

[23] Printing 14 17 19 20 22 23 27 27 13 92.9%<br />

[19] Leather 16 19 21 21 21 21 23 24 8 50.0%<br />

[45] Gas production 10 13 13 16 18 20 19 23 13 130.0%<br />

[12] Timber logging 19 20 22 23 22 22 22 22 3 15.8%<br />

[20] Timber 10 12 16 16 18 19 21 22 12 120.0%<br />

[09] Nonferrous mining 18 18 19 19 19 19 20 21 3 16.7%<br />

[43] Other manufacturing 9 11 11 10 12 11 13 13 4 44.4%<br />

[08] Ferrous mining 6 7 8 11 9 8 8 10 4 66.7%<br />

[24] Cultural 5 8 8 9 9 9 8 10 5 100.0%<br />

[21] Furniture 4 4 5 5 5 5 6 6 2 50.0%<br />

Total 3,282 3,708 4,202 4,610 4,807 4,964 5,327 5,725 2,443 74.4%<br />

Note: See appendix 2 for full industry names corresponding to industry codes.<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

70 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 70


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 3. Distribution of total liabilities by region, 1995–2002, by total liability in 2002, (RMB billion)<br />

Change of total liabilities<br />

during 1995–<br />

2002 as percentage of<br />

total in 1995<br />

Change of total<br />

liabilities during<br />

1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[44] Guangdong 299 348 414 436 434 468 509 559 260 87.0%<br />

[32] Jiangsu 226 269 300 320 328 369 456 503 277 122.6%<br />

[37] Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 262 295 336 354 416 436 455 490 228 87.0%<br />

[31] Shanghai 231 273 323 337 347 334 349 376 145 62.8%<br />

[21] Liaoning 293 310 346 362 320 323 335 354 61 20.8%<br />

[50] Sichuan Chongqing 183 199 233 240 319 295 303 325 142 77.6%<br />

[13] Hebei 143 166 184 199 213 224 249 257 114 79.7%<br />

[41] Henan 133 156 165 204 210 219 234 254 121 91.0%<br />

[42] Hubei 135 164 182 217 219 233 229 253 118 87.4%<br />

[23] Heilongjiang 149 149 167 190 183 191 189 195 46 30.9%<br />

[33] Zhejiang 121 143 153 157 159 166 170 187 66 54.5%<br />

[12] Tianjin 108 110 119 156 155 144 153 175 67 62.0%<br />

[22] Jilin 115 136 153 155 159 170 163 173 58 50.4%<br />

[11] Beijing 98 113 132 166 154 157 187 169 71 72.4%<br />

[61] Shaanxi 78 89 99 101 134 133 142 156 78 100.0%<br />

[35] Fujian 47 55 54 55 62 66 135 149 102 217.0%<br />

[43] Hunan 78 86 99 112 119 124 140 149 71 91.0%<br />

[34] Anhui 81 92 108 108 113 131 129 145 64 79.0%<br />

[14] Shanxi 78 89 100 129 129 135 126 133 55 70.5%<br />

[53] Yunnan 58 64 68 75 76 75 103 114 56 96.6%<br />

[62] Gansu 54 59 79 93 83 84 88 94 40 74.1%<br />

[45] Guangxi 60 62 71 80 85 90 89 90 30 50.0%<br />

[36] Jiangxi 58 68 72 78 87 88 90 88 30 51.7%<br />

[15] Inner Mongolia 51 55 63 71 78 72 83 87 36 70.6%<br />

[54] Tibet Qinghai Ningxia 34 34 43 56 57 63 55 79 45 132.4%<br />

[52] Guizhou 44 40 47 59 63 74 72 78 34 77.3%<br />

[65] Xinjiang 58 68 75 79 79 80 80 78 20 34.5%<br />

[46] Hainan 12 15 19 20 23 20 15 16 4 33.3%<br />

Total 3,287 3,707 4,204 4,609 4,804 4,964 5,328 5,726 2,439 74.2%<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

71 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 71


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

is difªcult to check the consistency of reported proªts with enterprises’ other<br />

ªnancial variables because of China’s complicated accounting regulations. In other<br />

words, we do not know how reported proªts are calculated from other ªnancial<br />

variables reported in the NBS survey. Second, it is widely reported that enterprises<br />

sometimes manage their proªt numbers for many purposes, including legal or illegal<br />

tax evasion. For this paper, it seems useful to develop an alternative measure of<br />

proªtability, one that is based on a consistent set of ªnancial variables available from<br />

the NBS survey. Because the main purpose of the NBS survey is to calculate the<br />

value-added of industrial enterprises, it is possible to develop a measure of an enterprise’s<br />

proªtability or potential proªtability based on the reconstructed components<br />

of its value-added.<br />

We use the following variables available from the NBS survey to deªne the imputed<br />

proªtability of the sample enterprises:<br />

VA value-added, including value-added taxes <strong>and</strong> ªnancial changes<br />

W wages <strong>and</strong> other employee compensation expenses<br />

FC ªnancial charges, mainly interest payments<br />

D current depreciations<br />

T all tax payments, including those for value-added taxes<br />

TA total assets<br />

We can classify enterprises into eight proªtability groups:<br />

[4]: if VA ≤ 0<br />

[3]: if VA W ≤ 0 <strong>and</strong> VA 0<br />

[2]: if VA W FC ≤ 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W 0<br />

[1]: if VA W FC D ≤ 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W FC 0<br />

[1]: if VA W FC D T ≤ 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W FC D 0<br />

[2]: if VA W FC D T 0 <strong>and</strong> (VA W FC D T)/TA ≤ .05<br />

[3]: if (VA W FC D T)/TA .05 <strong>and</strong> (VA W FC D T)/TA ≤ .15<br />

[4]: if (VA W FC D T)/TA .15<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

Table 4 shows the number of enterprises in each of the eight proªtability groups<br />

over the period from 1995 to 2002. This imputed proªtability by group allows us to<br />

sepa<strong>rate</strong> the NPDs into more disaggregated groups according to the qualitative <strong>and</strong><br />

quantitative extent of loss making. Chinese banks are in the process of changing<br />

from four loan classiªcation categories (normal, overdue, doubtful, <strong>and</strong> poor) to the<br />

international st<strong>and</strong>ard of ªve categories (normal, special mention, subst<strong>and</strong>ard,<br />

doubtful, <strong>and</strong> loss). Unlike the classiªcation of bank loans, the proªtability<br />

72 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 72


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 4. Number of enterprises <strong>and</strong> share of total enterprises, by profitability, 1995–2002<br />

Average<br />

1995–2002<br />

Profitability 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[4]: if VA 0 867 1,006 969 901 569 458 450 602 728<br />

[3]: if VA W 0 <strong>and</strong> VA 0 2,995 2,977 3,102 3,085 2,503 2,260 1,963 1,928 2,602<br />

[2]: if VA W FC 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W 0 2,152 2,199 1,988 1,749 1,307 955 811 698 1,482<br />

[1]: if VA W FC D 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W FC 0 1,815 1,757 1,839 1,943 1,841 1,684 1,740 1,724 1,793<br />

[1]: if VA W FC D T 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W FC D 0 3,059 2,644 2,705 2,579 2,399 2,396 2,396 2,138 2,540<br />

[2]: if VA W FC D T 0 <strong>and</strong> (VA W FC D T) /TA 0.05 5,095 5,106 5,336 5,284 5,292 5,129 5,225 4,985 5,182<br />

[3]: if (VA W FC D T)/TA 0.05 <strong>and</strong> (VA W FC D T) /TA 0.15 4,371 4,327 4,297 4,253 4,490 4,579 5,208 5,365 4,611<br />

[4]: if (VA W FC D T)/TA 0.15 2,189 2,958 2,721 2,499 3,062 3,277 4,105 4,780 3,199<br />

Total 22,543 22,974 22,957 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220 22,136<br />

[4]: if VA 0 3.8% 4.4% 4.2% 4.0% 2.7% 2.2% 2.1% 2.7% 3.3%<br />

[3]: if VA W 0 <strong>and</strong> VA 0 13.3% 13.0% 13.5% 13.8% 11.7% 10.9% 9.0% 8.7% 11.8%<br />

[2]: if VA W FC 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W 0 9.5% 9.6% 8.7% 7.8% 6.1% 4.6% 3.7% 3.1% 6.7%<br />

[1]: if VA W FC D 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W FC 0 8.1% 7.6% 8.0% 8.7% 8.6% 8.1% 7.9% 7.8% 8.1%<br />

[1]: if VA W FC D T 0 <strong>and</strong> VA W FC D 0 13.6% 11.5% 11.8% 11.6% 11.2% 11.6% 10.9% 9.6% 11.5%<br />

[2]: if VA W FC D T 0 <strong>and</strong> (VA W FC D T) /TA 0.05 22.6% 22.2% 23.2% 23.7% 24.7% 24.7% 23.9% 22.4% 23.4%<br />

[3]: if (VA W FC D T) /TA 0.05 <strong>and</strong> (VA W FC D T) /TA 0.15 19.4% 18.8% 18.7% 19.1% 20.9% 22.1% 23.8% 24.1% 20.8%<br />

[4]: if (VA W FC D T)/TA 0.15 9.7% 12.9% 11.9% 11.2% 14.3% 15.8% 18.7% 21.5% 14.5%<br />

100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%<br />

Note: VA value-added, including value-added taxes <strong>and</strong> financial changes; W wages <strong>and</strong> other employee compensation expenses; FC financial charges, mainly interest payments; D current depreciations;<br />

T all tax payments including value-added taxes; TA total assets.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

73 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 73


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

classiªcation proposed here reveals the underlying economic conditions, for<br />

example:<br />

• Enterprises in proªtability group [4] create negative value-added. They should<br />

be closed immediately according to economic principles. The quality of their<br />

debts is the worst among the eight groups by proªtability.<br />

• Enterprises in group [3] have positive value-added but cannot pay all of their<br />

wage bills. In economics, they cannot even cover their variable costs. They should<br />

also be closed as soon as possible to avoid incurring new losses. The quality of<br />

their debts will worsen every day as the losses accumulate.<br />

• Enterprises in group [2] can pay their wage bills but cannot pay all of their<br />

ªnancial charges. The quality of their debts is poor, but because their investment<br />

is sunk, such ªrms may have reasons to continue operations in the short run to<br />

maintain employment while waiting for a turnaround after reorganization.<br />

• Enterprises in group [1] can pay their wage bills <strong>and</strong> ªnancial charges but cannot<br />

cover all of their depreciation charges. The quality of their debts will fall as<br />

capital is depleted.<br />

We will leave the more detailed analysis of NPDs based on the above proªtability<br />

classiªcations for a sepa<strong>rate</strong> paper. Here we focus on the big picture ªrst <strong>and</strong> classify<br />

enterprises in the ªrst four groups as loss making <strong>and</strong> the last four groups as<br />

proªt making, based on imputed proªtability.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

Table 5 shows the number of enterprises making proªts or losses based on both reported<br />

<strong>and</strong> imputed proªts over the period from 1995 to 2002. The number of lossmaking<br />

enterprises by imputed proªtability was stable at about 8,000 (34–35 percent)<br />

during 1995–98 <strong>and</strong> fell rapidly afterward to 4,952 (22.3 percent) in 2002. The<br />

number of loss-making enterprises by reported proªtability was 6,937 (30.8 percent)<br />

in 1995 <strong>and</strong> rose sharply to 8,987 (40.3 percent) in 1998, then dropped to 6,295 (or<br />

28.3 percent) in 2002. In the next section, we will use both imputed <strong>and</strong> reported<br />

proªtability to estimate the amount <strong>and</strong> ratio of NPD. Although the two proªtability<br />

measurements are different in concept <strong>and</strong> measurement, both are useful for<br />

assessing the quality of enterprise debt. Imputed proªtability is more useful for<br />

comparing enterprise performance across groups because it is based on a consistent<br />

set of reported ªnancial variables, but it is different from actually reported<br />

proªtability. Imputed proªts can be larger than reported proªts for several reasons.<br />

First, when output is not sold or is still in inventory, some of the value-added might<br />

not turn into actual proªts. Second, reported proªts are likely to be lower than imputed<br />

proªts as a result of legal or illegal tax evasion or proªt hiding. In other re-<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

74 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 74


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 5. Number <strong>and</strong> share of enterprises making profits or losses, 1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Average<br />

1995–2002<br />

Based on imputed profits<br />

Number of enterprises<br />

Making profits 14,714 15,035 15,059 14,615 15,243 15,381 16,934 17,268 15,531<br />

Making losses 7,829 7,939 7,898 7,678 6,220 5,357 4,964 4,952 6,605<br />

Total 22,543 22,974 22,957 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220 22,136<br />

Share<br />

Making profits 65.3% 65.4% 65.6% 65.6% 71.0% 74.2% 77.3% 77.7% 70.2%<br />

Making losses 34.7% 34.6% 34.4% 34.4% 29.0% 25.8% 22.7% 22.3% 29.8%<br />

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%<br />

Based on reported profits<br />

Number of enterprises<br />

Making profits 15,606 15,088 14,476 13,306 14,328 15,144 15,510 15,925 14,923<br />

Making losses 6,937 7,886 8,481 8,987 7,135 5,594 6,388 6,295 7,213<br />

Total 22,543 22,974 22,957 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220 22,136<br />

Share<br />

Making profits 69.2% 65.7% 63.1% 59.7% 66.8% 73.0% 70.8% 71.7% 67.4%<br />

Making losses 30.8% 34.3% 36.9% 40.3% 33.2% 27.0% 29.2% 28.3% 32.6%<br />

Total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%<br />

lated papers (Liu <strong>and</strong> Xiao 2004; Cai, Liu, <strong>and</strong> Xiao 2005), we examine the issue of<br />

proªt disguising in detail.<br />

3. Estimated level <strong>and</strong> ratio of NPD<br />

Using the method developed in section 2, we report the main NPD statistics for the<br />

whole sample as well as for groups classiªed by ownership, industry, <strong>and</strong> region.<br />

Table 6 shows the amount of NPD as well as the NPD ratio for the whole sample<br />

during the 1995–2002 period. There are two sets of NPD statistics in the table: the<br />

upper part is derived from imputed proªts <strong>and</strong> the lower part from reported proªts.<br />

The amount <strong>and</strong> ratio of NPD are calculated sepa<strong>rate</strong>ly for three categories of debts:<br />

total liabilities, long-term liabilities, <strong>and</strong> short-term liabilities. They are similar in<br />

size <strong>and</strong> trend, with the NPD ratio for short-term liabilities declining slightly faster<br />

than the ratio for long-term liabilities.<br />

According to imputed proªtability, the NPD ratio for the whole sample was stable at<br />

around 27–30 percent during 1995–99 but declined rapidly afterward to only 18.4<br />

percent in 2002, with the amount of NPD at about RMB1 trillion.<br />

According to reported proªtability, the NPD ratio for the whole sample was 24.1<br />

percent in 1995, rising to 34.3 percent in 1998 <strong>and</strong> then falling to 22.9 percent in 2002,<br />

with the amount of NPDs at about RMB1.3 trillion. According to the CBRC, China’s<br />

NPL ratio fell sharply to 19.6 percent, with the amount of NPLs at RMB2.5 trillion<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

75 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 75


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

Table 6. Amount of nonperforming debt <strong>and</strong> nonperforming debt ratio for whole sample, 1995–2002<br />

Change in<br />

1998–2002<br />

Change in<br />

1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Based on imputed profits<br />

Amount of nonperforming debt (RMB billion)<br />

Within total liabilities 914 1,095 1,204 1,371 1,315 1,128 1,091 1,051 137 320<br />

Within long-term liabilities 308 370 389 470 472 395 365 343 35 127<br />

Within short-term liabilities 605 724 812 895 836 727 716 709 104 186<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio (percent)<br />

Within total liabilities 27.8 29.5 28.7 29.7 27.4 22.7 20.5 18.4 9.5 11.4<br />

Within long-term liabilities 26.6 29.5 28.2 30.3 29.2 24.2 21.9 19.9 6.7 10.4<br />

Within short-term liabilities 28.5 29.6 29.1 29.5 26.5 22.2 19.8 17.9 10.6 11.6<br />

Based on reported profits<br />

Amount of nonperforming debt (RMB billion)<br />

Within total liabilities 792 1,002 1,167 1,580 1,427 1,185 1,392 1,311 519 269<br />

Within long-term liabilities 282 327 368 556 504 411 441 408 126 148<br />

Within short-term liabilities 509 674 793 1,014 916 759 930 891 382 123<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio (percent)<br />

Within total liabilities 24.1 27.0 27.8 34.3 29.7 23.9 26.1 22.9 1.2 11.4<br />

Within long-term liabilities 24.4 26.1 26.7 35.9 31.1 25.1 26.5 23.7 0.7 12.3<br />

Within short-term liabilities 24.0 27.5 28.4 33.4 29.0 23.2 25.8 22.5 1.5 11.0<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

76 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 76


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 7. Amount of nonperforming debt <strong>and</strong> nonperforming debt ratio, estimated from<br />

imputed profitability, by ownership, 1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Amount of nonperforming debt estimated<br />

from imputed profitability (RMB billion)<br />

Private 0 0 0 2 2 4 5 7<br />

Collective 53 55 60 50 47 32 25 22<br />

Mixed 39 63 90 107 165 191 207 178<br />

Foreign 36 69 77 94 74 63 98 94<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 26 32 37 68 54 53 53 49<br />

State-owned 761 876 938 1,049 972 786 702 701<br />

Total 915 1,095 1,202 1,370 1,314 1,129 1,090 1,051<br />

Nonperforming ratio estimated from<br />

imputed profitability (percent)<br />

Private 0.0 0.0 0.0 18.2 11.8 12.9 8.2 7.4<br />

Collective 23.3 20.6 21.1 17.4 16.5 12.6 11.3 10.0<br />

Mixed 16.9 22.5 23.7 20.8 23.9 18.5 14.5 10.8<br />

Foreign 23.7 29.7 27.0 28.7 20.0 15.8 17.5 15.2<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 15.9 16.8 17.3 24.6 18.2 17.4 14.8 12.6<br />

State-owned 30.3 32.0 30.9 32.9 30.9 26.7 26.0 25.4<br />

Total 27.8 29.5 28.6 29.7 27.4 22.7 20.5 18.4<br />

Share of nonperforming debt estimated<br />

from imputed profitability (percent)<br />

Private 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.1 0.2 0.4 0.5 0.7<br />

Collective 5.8 5.0 5.0 3.6 3.6 2.8 2.3 2.1<br />

Mixed 4.3 5.8 7.5 7.8 12.6 16.9 19.0 16.9<br />

Foreign 3.9 6.3 6.4 6.9 5.6 5.6 9.0 8.9<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 2.8 2.9 3.1 5.0 4.1 4.7 4.9 4.7<br />

State-owned 83.2 80.0 78.0 76.6 74.0 69.6 64.4 66.7<br />

Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

by the middle of 2003. Given the different deªnitions of NPL <strong>and</strong> NPD, the results<br />

for the NPD statistics look consistent with the CBRC statistics for NPLs. In the next<br />

section, we will further examine the trend of NPD ratios for the whole sample.<br />

We compare the NPD statistics for different types of enterprises by ownership,<br />

where NPD is derived from both imputed proªtability (table 7) <strong>and</strong> reported<br />

proªtability (table 8). These tables show that NPD ratios vary signiªcantly across<br />

types of enterprises by ownership <strong>and</strong> that SOEs have much higher NPD ratios than<br />

NSEs. In 2002, the NPD ratio for SOEs was 25.4 percent by imputed proªtability <strong>and</strong><br />

25.8 percent by reported proªtability. The NPD ratio for private enterprises was 7.4<br />

percent by imputed proªtability <strong>and</strong> 15.8 percent by reported proªtability. The NPD<br />

ratio for domestic mixed-ownership enterprises was 10.8 percent by imputed<br />

proªtability <strong>and</strong> 20.2 percent by reported proªtability.<br />

From the NPD statistics in tables 7 <strong>and</strong> 8, it is possible to decompose the fall of the<br />

average NPD ratio for the whole sample into two parts: one resulting from improvement<br />

in NPD ratios in each type of enterprise <strong>and</strong> the other resulting from the redistribution<br />

of debts from SOEs to the better-performing NSEs.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

77 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 77


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 8. Amount of nonperforming debt <strong>and</strong> nonperforming debt ratio, estimated from<br />

reported profitability, by ownership 1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Amount of nonperforming debt estimated<br />

from reported profitability (RMB billion)<br />

Private 0 0 0 4 4 7 12 15<br />

Collective 53 67 74 84 69 52 48 42<br />

Mixed 28 37 69 136 172 214 296 332<br />

Foreign 44 82 102 136 107 98 177 139<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 29 45 52 89 74 63 77 71<br />

State-owned 638 770 869 1,131 999 752 782 712<br />

Total 792 1,001 1,166 1,580 1,425 1,186 1,392 1,311<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio estimated from<br />

reported profitability (percent)<br />

Private 0.0 0.0 0.0 36.4 23.5 22.6 19.4 15.8<br />

Collective 23.3 25.0 26.1 29.3 24.3 20.5 21.7 19.2<br />

Mixed 12.2 13.3 18.2 26.5 24.9 20.7 20.8 20.2<br />

Foreign 28.9 35.3 35.8 41.3 28.9 24.5 31.6 22.4<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 17.7 23.7 24.3 32.4 24.9 20.7 21.4 18.2<br />

State-owned 25.4 28.1 28.6 35.4 31.8 25.6 28.9 25.8<br />

Total 24.1 27.0 27.8 34.3 29.7 23.9 26.1 22.9<br />

Share of nonperforming debt estimated<br />

from reported profitability (percent)<br />

Private 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.3 0.3 0.6 0.9 1.1<br />

Collective 6.7 6.7 6.3 5.3 4.8 4.4 3.4 3.2<br />

Mixed 3.5 3.7 5.9 8.6 12.1 18.0 21.3 25.3<br />

Foreign 5.6 8.2 8.7 8.6 7.5 8.3 12.7 10.6<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 3.7 4.5 4.5 5.6 5.2 5.3 5.5 5.4<br />

State-owned 80.6 76.9 74.5 71.6 70.1 63.4 56.2 54.3<br />

Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Let us assume that R i t is the NPD ratio in year t for enterprise group i <strong>and</strong> S i t is the<br />

share of debts for group i in year t. Then the NPD ratio for the whole sample in year<br />

t can be calculated from the following formula:<br />

2002 1995 2002 1995<br />

NPD ratio Σ i<br />

05 . ∗ ( R i<br />

+ R i<br />

) ∗( S i<br />

− S i<br />

) +<br />

2002 1995 2002 1995<br />

NPD ratio Σ 05 . ∗Σ<br />

( R − R ) ∗ ( S + S ),<br />

i i i i i i<br />

where i private enterprises, collective enterprises, mixed enterprises, foreign enterprises,<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, or Taiwanese enterprises (HK-M-Taiwan), or SOEs.<br />

The change in NPD for the whole sample from 1995 to 2002 can be presented equivalently<br />

in the following formats:<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

R 2002 R 1995 2002 2002 1995 1995<br />

ΣiRi ∗Si − ΣiRi ∗Si<br />

R 2002 R 1995 2002 1995 2002 1995<br />

Σ i<br />

05 . ∗ ( R i<br />

+ R i<br />

) ∗( S i<br />

− S i<br />

) +<br />

R 2002 R 1995 2002 1995 1995 2002<br />

Σ i<br />

05 . ∗( R i<br />

− R i<br />

) ∗ ( S i<br />

+ S i<br />

).<br />

The ªrst term in the above equation is the ªrst component of the change in the NPD<br />

ratio for the whole sample during 1995–2002 that can be attributed to the shift of the<br />

78 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 78


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

total liabilities across ownership groups while holding the individual ownership<br />

group’s NPD ratio at its average level for 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2002. Using statistics from tables<br />

1, 7, <strong>and</strong> 8, this ªrst component is 3.86 percent for the imputed-proªtability<br />

method <strong>and</strong> 2.33 percent for the reported-proªtability method.<br />

The second term in the NPD equation is the component of change in the NPD ratio<br />

for the whole sample during 1995–2002 that can be attributed to the fall in individual<br />

ownership groups’ NPD ratio while holding constant the distribution of total liabilities<br />

across ownership groups at its average level for 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2002. This second<br />

component is 4.74 percent for the imputed-proªtability method <strong>and</strong> 1.13 percent<br />

for the reported-proªtability method.<br />

Hence, according to the imputed-proªtability method, the NPD ratio for the whole<br />

sample fell from 27.8 percent in 1995 to 18.4 percent in 2002, a drop of 9.4 percentage<br />

points. Out of these 9.4 percentage points, 3.86 percentage points can be attributed<br />

to the shift of ªnancial resources from SOEs to the better-performing NSEs, which<br />

have lower NPD ratios than SOEs.<br />

According to the reported-proªtability method, the NPD ratio for the whole sample<br />

fell only slightly, from 24.1 percent in 1995 to 22.9 percent in 2002, a drop of only 1.2<br />

percentage points. The decomposing of this 1.2 percentage points shows that the<br />

shift of ªnancial resources from SOEs to the better-performing NSEs led to a 2.33-<br />

percentage-point drop in the NPD ratio for the whole sample, whereas the changes<br />

in the NPD ratios for individual ownership groups led to an increase of 1.13 percentage<br />

points in the NPD ratio for the whole sample.<br />

Clearly, the decline in the NPD ratio is more signiªcant according to the imputedproªtability<br />

method, compared to the reported-proªtability method. As previously<br />

noted, we are not clear how reported proªts are calculated because of large variations<br />

in accounting <strong>and</strong> proªt-reporting practices across types of enterprises, but we<br />

know exactly how imputed proªts are calculated from the ªnancial variables that<br />

are used for measuring GDP. We think both measures are useful. The NPD statistics<br />

derived from imputed proªtability can be used for comparing the underlying performance<br />

of different groups of enterprises, <strong>and</strong> the NPD statistics from reported<br />

proªtability better reºect the actual outcomes that creditors are going to face when<br />

they deal with enterprises.<br />

Tables 9–12 present NPD statistics by industry for 1995–2002. The results shown in<br />

tables 9 <strong>and</strong> 10 are derived using imputed proªtability, <strong>and</strong> the results in tables 11<br />

<strong>and</strong> 12 are derived from reported proªtability. Tables 13–16 present NPD statistics<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

79 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 79


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 9. Amount of nonperforming debt by industry, estimated from imputed profitability,<br />

1995–2002, by nonperforming debt in 2002 (RMB billion)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[44] Electric power 52 86 80 143 188 169 174 177<br />

[26] Raw chemicals 52 65 92 127 108 88 97 89<br />

[06] Coal mining 63 76 77 81 112 102 67 77<br />

[36] Special equipment 69 74 86 103 98 93 83 76<br />

[37] Transport equipment 63 81 90 101 96 93 103 72<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications 47 52 60 64 54 56 52 60<br />

[31] Nonmetal products 42 56 72 65 59 49 48 51<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery 52 71 74 81 74 65 62 51<br />

[17] Textile 113 124 106 105 72 47 44 44<br />

[40] Electric equipment 39 51 58 53 52 45 48 40<br />

[22] Papermaking 13 13 22 28 21 19 25 27<br />

[28] Chemical fiber 17 22 21 33 26 22 24 24<br />

[32] Pressing ferrous 75 70 85 81 85 62 35 23<br />

[27] Medical 13 20 19 20 15 11 13 19<br />

[46] Tap water 7 7 12 9 10 12 13 19<br />

[13] Food processing 32 42 41 42 32 21 17 18<br />

[33] Pressing nonferrous 28 35 36 47 28 22 22 16<br />

[42] Instruments 15 17 19 17 14 13 14 16<br />

[14] Food production 13 13 16 14 11 8 12 14<br />

[34] Metal products 16 19 23 27 22 18 13 14<br />

[45] Gas production 9 12 11 10 10 13 13 14<br />

[15] Beverage 11 12 13 14 12 13 9 13<br />

[07] Petroleum extract 3 4 13 0 13 11 18 12<br />

[25] Petroleum processing 3 9 7 15 18 8 17 10<br />

[10] Nonmetal mining 7 5 7 7 6 6 7 9<br />

[29] Rubber 9 9 9 11 18 9 9 9<br />

[30] Plastic 12 12 14 16 14 10 7 9<br />

[09] Nonferrous mining 5 6 6 9 6 5 6 7<br />

[12] Timber logging 4 4 6 7 9 8 7 7<br />

[20] Timber 5 4 6 8 7 6 5 6<br />

[18] Garments 4 5 4 7 5 4 6 5<br />

[23] Printing 4 4 6 5 6 6 6 5<br />

[08] Ferrous mining 5 4 1 5 2 2 1 3<br />

[19] Leather 6 5 5 7 4 5 3 3<br />

[43] Other manufacturing 3 2 3 3 3 3 3 3<br />

[24] Cultural 1 2 1 3 2 3 2 2<br />

[16] Tobacco 1 1 1 3 1 2 3 1<br />

[21] Furniture 2 1 1 1 2 2 2 1<br />

Total 915 1,095 1,203 1,372 1,315 1,131 1,090 1,046<br />

Note: See appendix 2 for full industry names corresponding to industry codes.<br />

by region during 1995–2002. Tables 13 <strong>and</strong> 14 are derived from imputed proªtability,<br />

<strong>and</strong> tables 15 <strong>and</strong> 16 are derived from reported proªtability. Tables 9–16 are sorted<br />

by the results in the last column (for 2002) so that readers can easily see the best <strong>and</strong><br />

worst performers in the quality of enterprise debts by region.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

The information here shows the big picture on the quality of enterprise debts across<br />

industry <strong>and</strong> region <strong>and</strong> can be used by <strong>policy</strong>makers, as well as by banks, investors,<br />

<strong>and</strong> enterprises as a benchmark against which to check the performance of<br />

their own debt portfolios. This information is a public good <strong>and</strong> contributes to more<br />

scientiªc management of debt risks in China. Bankers from Shanghai <strong>and</strong><br />

Guangdong might want to know the NPD statistics in their regions. Ofªcials in<br />

charge of utilities might want to know how bad that sector’s enterprise debts are<br />

80 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 80


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 10. Nonperforming debt ratios by industry, estimated from imputed profitability,<br />

1995–2002, by nonperforming debt ratio in 2002 (percent)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[45] Gas production 90.0 92.3 84.6 58.8 58.8 68.4 72.2 60.9<br />

[46] Tap water 50.0 43.8 50.0 34.6 32.3 34.3 33.3 41.3<br />

[36] Special equipment 46.3 46.0 48.9 55.1 52.7 48.9 45.1 39.6<br />

[42] Instruments 51.7 53.1 51.4 50.0 40.0 38.2 35.0 39.0<br />

[06] Coal mining 49.2 51.7 45.8 44.5 54.6 48.8 30.9 35.8<br />

[09] Nonferrous mining 27.8 35.3 31.6 47.4 33.3 26.3 30.0 35.0<br />

[28] Chemical fiber 27.4 31.0 28.0 39.8 28.9 26.5 32.0 32.9<br />

[12] Timber logging 21.1 20.0 27.3 30.4 40.9 34.8 33.3 31.8<br />

[10] Nonmetal mining 41.2 33.3 38.9 36.8 27.3 21.4 30.4 31.0<br />

[08] Ferrous mining 83.3 57.1 12.5 45.5 25.0 22.2 12.5 30.0<br />

[20] Timber 55.6 33.3 37.5 50.0 38.9 31.6 23.8 28.6<br />

[31] Nonmetal products 30.4 33.7 38.7 33.3 29.5 25.1 23.0 23.8<br />

[43] Other manufacturing 30.0 20.0 27.3 30.0 25.0 27.3 25.0 23.1<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery 33.1 39.7 38.1 39.1 36.6 31.7 29.5 23.0<br />

[26] Raw chemicals 23.0 24.6 28.3 34.8 29.3 22.7 25.5 22.3<br />

[22] Papermaking 24.5 20.3 30.6 38.4 26.3 21.6 20.7 21.6<br />

[14] Food production 35.1 31.7 38.1 29.8 22.9 16.7 21.1 21.5<br />

[34] Metal products 34.8 35.8 39.0 43.5 34.9 30.5 20.0 20.6<br />

[24] Cultural 20.0 25.0 12.5 33.3 22.2 33.3 25.0 20.0<br />

[44] Electric power 17.6 27.1 22.2 27.4 30.6 23.5 21.7 19.0<br />

[17] Textile 44.0 45.3 36.9 38.2 29.5 20.0 19.1 18.8<br />

[23] Printing 28.6 25.0 31.6 25.0 26.1 26.1 22.2 18.5<br />

[29] Rubber 25.0 21.4 18.8 22.0 35.3 18.4 17.3 18.0<br />

[40] Electric equipment 28.5 31.1 31.4 27.2 26.8 23.1 22.0 17.7<br />

[21] Furniture 50.0 25.0 20.0 20.0 40.0 40.0 33.3 16.7<br />

[13] Food processing 36.4 39.3 36.6 36.5 30.2 20.8 16.5 16.2<br />

[30] Plastic 38.7 31.6 32.6 34.8 29.2 20.4 12.7 15.0<br />

[37] Transport equipment 27.5 29.3 27.7 28.1 24.9 23.3 23.4 14.7<br />

[27] Medical 22.0 27.4 23.5 22.2 15.5 10.5 10.7 14.3<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications 32.2 31.1 30.3 27.9 21.5 19.6 14.2 14.2<br />

[18] Garments 23.5 21.7 16.7 25.9 16.7 12.5 16.2 13.2<br />

[19] Leather 37.5 26.3 23.8 33.3 19.0 23.8 13.0 12.5<br />

[15] Beverage 15.1 14.5 13.1 13.7 11.1 11.7 8.1 11.4<br />

[33] Pressing nonferrous 29.5 34.7 30.8 35.6 20.0 15.7 14.4 9.9<br />

[07] Petroleum extract 2.0 2.5 7.9 0.0 8.1 7.0 12.1 7.8<br />

[25] Petroleum processing 3.0 7.9 4.3 8.3 10.0 4.3 9.6 5.8<br />

[32] Pressing ferrous 22.7 19.7 21.5 19.5 19.3 15.2 8.4 5.2<br />

[16] Tobacco 1.4 1.3 1.2 4.2 1.4 2.7 2.8 0.9<br />

Total 27.9 29.6 28.6 29.8 27.4 22.8 20.5 18.3<br />

Note: See appendix 2 for full industry names corresponding to industry codes.<br />

compared with those of other industries. These patterns of NPD ratios at the aggregate<br />

levels by ownership, industry <strong>and</strong> region are useful for illustrating the overall<br />

quality <strong>and</strong> distribution of enterprise debts in China as well as for contributing to<br />

informed <strong>policy</strong> debates.<br />

4. Patterns of NPDs<br />

By applying a simple regression method to the disaggregated NPD ratios, we can<br />

summarize the variability in NPD ratios for two relevant dimensions: one is the declining<br />

trend in NPD ratios <strong>and</strong> the other is the gap in NPD ratios across ownership<br />

type, industry, <strong>and</strong> region. Tables 17–19 show the results of six regressions using the<br />

group NPD ratios reported in tables 7 <strong>and</strong> 8, 9 <strong>and</strong> 11, <strong>and</strong> 13 <strong>and</strong> 15, respectively. In<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

81 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 81


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 11. Amount of nonperforming debt by industry, estimated from reported profitability,<br />

1995–2002, by nonperforming debt in 2002 (RMB billion)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[44] Electric power 83 39 76 119 161 147 173 183<br />

[26] Raw chemicals 39 51 103 174 158 123 134 140<br />

[37] Transport equipment 57 68 89 106 114 117 108 117<br />

[25] Petroleum processing 4 22 16 76 39 86 98 76<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications 31 41 53 60 54 35 59 73<br />

[31] Nonmetal products 43 64 83 88 74 54 70 72<br />

[17] Textile 104 135 128 135 88 51 74 69<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery 36 52 58 72 64 59 68 65<br />

[36] Special equipment 50 57 68 88 81 76 86 65<br />

[40] Electric equipment 30 41 52 61 52 42 62 45<br />

[28] Chemical fiber 11 20 16 34 27 17 32 32<br />

[33] Pressing nonferrous 18 35 35 68 46 21 33 32<br />

[13] Food processing 29 52 53 68 51 28 29 31<br />

[22] Papermaking 13 17 26 32 27 23 40 30<br />

[15] Beverage 18 21 22 29 27 25 27 29<br />

[32] Pressing ferrous 45 61 69 68 81 41 43 25<br />

[06] Coal mining 29 33 31 79 99 78 67 23<br />

[27] Medical 12 17 24 23 15 14 17 20<br />

[34] Metal products 15 21 26 30 27 21 19 19<br />

[14] Food production 12 15 17 18 13 12 17 18<br />

[30] Plastic 11 12 14 17 14 13 13 15<br />

[46] Tap water 4 5 10 12 9 9 11 15<br />

[16] Tobacco 5 6 7 6 5 8 25 14<br />

[42] Instruments 10 12 15 17 14 9 11 13<br />

[10] Nonmetal mining 7 6 6 7 6 7 5 11<br />

[29] Rubber 11 11 10 13 19 18 15 11<br />

[45] Gas production 4 10 9 8 8 10 8 10<br />

[07] Petroleum extract 28 40 6 22 7 2 3 9<br />

[18] Garments 3 5 7 8 6 5 9 8<br />

[20] Timber 4 5 7 8 7 6 8 8<br />

[19] Leather 5 6 6 6 5 5 5 7<br />

[09] Nonferrous mining 7 8 6 9 6 3 5 6<br />

[12] Timber logging 3 5 8 7 7 8 7 6<br />

[23] Printing 3 3 5 5 4 3 4 4<br />

[08] Ferrous mining 5 3 2 2 3 3 2 3<br />

[43] Other manufacturing 2 3 3 3 4 3 3 3<br />

[21] Furniture 1 1 2 1 1 1 2 1<br />

[24] Cultural 1 1 1 2 1 1 1 1<br />

Total 793 1,004 1,169 1,581 1,424 1,184 1,393 1,309<br />

Note: See appendix 2 for full industry names corresponding to industry codes.<br />

each of the six regressions, the independent variables include a time trend (year)<br />

<strong>and</strong> a categorical variable (ownership, industry, or region). Each categorical variable<br />

has the “whole sample” dummy to match the NPD ratio for the whole sample. The<br />

regression equations can be written as<br />

NPD ratio f (year, categorical variable).<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

We use weighted regressions to discount the impact of the NPD ratios in the early<br />

years. (The weights used are listed in the footnotes of tables 17, 18, <strong>and</strong> 19.) The regression<br />

coefªcients for the time trend variable (year) indicate how fast the NPD ratio<br />

would fall every year based on the variability of the NPD ratios reported for each<br />

group in the relevant tables. In principle, the declining trend of NPD ratios for all<br />

82 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 82


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 12. Nonperforming debt ratios by industry, estimated from reported profitability,<br />

1995–2002, by nonperforming debt ratio in 2002 (percent)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[25] Petroleum processing 4.0 19.3 9.8 42.2 21.7 46.7 54.7 43.9<br />

[28] Chemical fiber 17.7 28.2 21.1 41.0 29.7 20.5 42.1 43.8<br />

[45] Gas production 40.0 76.9 69.2 50.0 44.4 50.0 44.4 41.7<br />

[10] Nonmetal mining 43.8 37.5 33.3 35.0 27.3 25.9 21.7 37.9<br />

[20] Timber 40.0 41.7 43.8 50.0 41.2 31.6 38.1 36.4<br />

[26] Raw chemicals 17.3 19.3 31.6 47.7 42.8 31.7 35.3 34.9<br />

[36] Special equipment 33.8 35.6 38.6 47.1 43.5 39.8 46.7 33.9<br />

[31] Nonmetal products 31.2 38.3 44.9 45.4 37.0 27.7 33.5 33.6<br />

[46] Tap water 26.7 31.3 43.5 44.4 29.0 26.5 28.2 32.6<br />

[42] Instruments 34.5 37.5 40.5 51.5 40.0 26.5 27.5 31.7<br />

[08] Ferrous mining 71.4 37.5 25.0 18.2 33.3 37.5 25.0 30.0<br />

[17] Textile 40.3 49.3 44.6 49.1 35.9 21.8 32.0 29.5<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery 22.8 28.9 29.9 34.8 31.7 28.8 32.5 29.4<br />

[19] Leather 31.3 31.6 28.6 28.6 23.8 22.7 21.7 29.2<br />

[09] Nonferrous mining 38.9 47.1 31.6 47.4 33.3 15.8 25.0 28.6<br />

[34] Metal products 31.9 38.9 44.1 48.4 42.9 35.6 29.2 28.4<br />

[13] Food processing 33.3 48.6 47.7 59.1 48.1 28.0 28.2 27.9<br />

[14] Food production 32.4 36.6 40.5 39.1 27.1 24.5 30.4 27.7<br />

[12] Timber logging 15.8 25.0 36.4 30.4 31.8 34.8 31.8 26.1<br />

[15] Beverage 24.7 25.3 22.2 28.4 25.2 22.5 24.5 25.4<br />

[30] Plastic 35.5 31.6 32.6 37.0 29.2 26.5 23.6 24.6<br />

[22] Papermaking 24.5 26.2 36.1 43.8 33.8 26.4 33.1 24.0<br />

[37] Transport equipment 24.9 24.6 27.4 29.4 29.6 29.2 24.5 23.8<br />

[29] Rubber 30.6 25.6 20.8 25.5 37.3 36.7 28.8 21.6<br />

[43] Other manufacturing 22.2 27.3 27.3 33.3 33.3 27.3 23.1 21.4<br />

[18] Garments 17.6 21.7 29.2 29.6 20.7 15.2 23.7 20.5<br />

[40] Electric equipment 22.1 25.0 28.1 31.3 26.8 21.5 28.4 19.9<br />

[33] Pressing nonferrous 18.9 34.7 30.2 51.5 32.9 15.1 21.4 19.8<br />

[44] Electric power 28.0 12.3 21.1 22.8 26.2 20.5 21.6 19.6<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications 21.4 24.6 26.6 26.2 21.5 12.2 16.1 17.2<br />

[21] Furniture 25.0 33.3 40.0 20.0 20.0 20.0 33.3 16.7<br />

[27] Medical 20.3 23.6 29.3 25.3 15.5 13.3 14.0 15.0<br />

[23] Printing 21.4 17.6 25.0 23.8 18.2 13.0 14.8 14.8<br />

[16] Tobacco 7.0 7.9 8.5 8.3 7.0 10.8 22.9 13.0<br />

[24] Cultural 16.7 12.5 12.5 22.2 11.1 11.1 12.5 11.1<br />

[06] Coal mining 22.5 22.3 18.5 43.4 48.1 37.3 30.9 10.7<br />

[07] Petroleum extract 18.5 25.5 3.7 12.9 4.4 1.3 2.0 5.9<br />

[32] Pressing ferrous 13.6 17.1 17.5 16.3 18.4 10.1 10.3 5.6<br />

Total 24.1 27.1 27.8 34.3 29.6 23.9 26.1 22.9<br />

Note: See appendix 2 for full industry names corresponding to industry codes.<br />

the groups is related to the improvement of the general market environment of the<br />

Chinese economy as a result of reform <strong>and</strong> opening. The regression coefªcients for<br />

the categorical variable indicate the average gap between the NPD ratio of that particular<br />

category <strong>and</strong> the NPD ratio of the base category (which is indicated by a zero<br />

value for the coefªcient <strong>and</strong> a blank value for the t-statistics in the tables) after removing<br />

the inºuence of the declining trend in NPD ratio. The negative sign means<br />

“lower than” the NPD ratio of the base category.<br />

For example, table 17 shows that based on the NPD ratios estimated from imputed<br />

proªtability (reported in table 7), the NPD ratio for a particular group is likely to decline<br />

on average by 1.5 percentage points each year. For private enterprises, NPD ratios<br />

in a given year are likely to be 21.3 percentage points lower than those for SOEs<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

83 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 83


Table 13. Amount of nonperforming debt by region, estimated from imputed profitability,<br />

1995–2002, by nonperforming debt in 2002 (RMB billion)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[31] Shanghai 70 94 95 98 92 78 69 81<br />

[44] Guangdong 64 90 113 131 106 90 86 80<br />

[41] Henan 23 39 37 63 61 64 69 72<br />

[23] Heilongjiang 60 58 56 69 71 62 56 58<br />

[21] Liaoning 105 117 115 110 87 63 75 57<br />

[50] Sichuan Chongqing 71 71 109 88 127 124 104 57<br />

[12] Tianjin 52 32 38 61 53 24 39 56<br />

[42] Hubei 27 53 39 36 34 36 35 46<br />

[13] Hebei 33 45 41 42 47 45 49 45<br />

[37] Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 47 48 50 64 69 58 44 45<br />

[11] Beijing 27 45 67 99 68 64 55 42<br />

[22] Jilin 36 35 38 39 35 32 39 41<br />

[32] Jiangsu 39 49 57 57 59 51 49 40<br />

[61] Shaanxi 37 49 49 46 48 38 46 38<br />

[14] Shanxi 24 33 29 50 44 33 24 35<br />

[54] Tibet Qinghai Ningxia 12 18 23 18 14 11 11 34<br />

[43] Hunan 29 28 33 37 35 34 30 32<br />

[52] Guizhou 16 15 15 28 25 28 26 31<br />

[34] Anhui 26 27 26 35 31 44 14 23<br />

[45] Guangxi 18 18 23 20 21 17 16 22<br />

[15] Inner Mongolia 17 16 14 27 46 25 34 21<br />

[53] Yunnan 9 11 20 24 23 17 20 21<br />

[35] Fujian 7 10 11 11 6 8 34 20<br />

[62] Gansu 12 22 29 30 28 26 15 15<br />

[36] Jiangxi 20 26 29 30 32 19 18 12<br />

[33] Zhejiang 19 25 24 37 25 18 17 11<br />

[65] Xinjiang 9 13 14 16 21 17 15 11<br />

[46] Hainan 4 7 9 5 8 2 4 3<br />

Total 913 1,094 1,203 1,371 1,316 1,128 1,093 1,049<br />

Table 14. Nonperforming debt ratios by region, estimated from imputed profitability, 1995–<br />

2002, by nonperforming debt ratio in 2002 (percent)<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[54] Tibet Qinghai Ningxia 35.3 52.9 53.5 31.6 24.6 17.7 20.0 42.5<br />

[52] Guizhou 36.4 37.5 31.9 47.5 39.7 37.8 36.1 40.3<br />

[12] Tianjin 48.1 29.4 32.2 39.1 34.2 16.6 25.5 32.0<br />

[23] Heilongjiang 40.0 38.9 33.7 36.3 38.8 32.6 29.5 29.7<br />

[41] Henan 17.3 25.0 22.3 30.9 29.0 29.2 29.5 28.3<br />

[14] Shanxi 30.4 37.1 29.0 38.5 34.1 24.4 19.0 26.5<br />

[11] Beijing 27.6 39.8 51.1 59.6 44.2 40.8 29.6 24.9<br />

[45] Guangxi 30.5 29.5 32.9 24.7 24.7 18.9 18.0 24.4<br />

[61] Shaanxi 47.4 55.7 50.0 45.1 35.8 28.6 32.4 24.2<br />

[15] Inner Mongolia 33.3 28.6 22.2 38.6 59.0 34.7 41.0 24.1<br />

[22] Jilin 31.3 25.5 24.8 25.2 22.0 18.8 23.9 23.7<br />

[31] Shanghai 30.3 34.3 29.4 29.1 26.5 23.4 19.8 21.6<br />

[43] Hunan 36.7 32.6 33.3 33.0 29.4 27.4 21.3 21.5<br />

[46] Hainan 33.3 43.8 50.0 25.0 34.8 10.5 25.0 18.8<br />

[53] Yunnan 15.5 17.5 29.4 32.4 30.3 22.7 19.2 18.4<br />

[42] Hubei 20.0 32.3 21.4 16.7 15.5 15.5 15.3 18.2<br />

[13] Hebei 23.1 27.1 22.2 21.1 22.1 20.0 19.7 17.6<br />

[50] Sichuan Chongqing 38.8 35.7 46.8 36.7 39.8 42.0 34.3 17.5<br />

[21] Liaoning 35.8 37.7 33.3 30.5 27.2 19.5 22.3 16.1<br />

[34] Anhui 32.1 29.7 24.1 32.4 27.4 33.8 10.9 16.0<br />

[62] Gansu 22.2 37.3 37.2 32.6 33.3 31.0 16.9 16.0<br />

[44] Guangdong 21.4 25.9 27.3 30.0 24.4 19.3 16.9 14.3<br />

[65] Xinjiang 15.8 19.1 18.9 20.3 26.3 21.3 18.5 13.9<br />

[36] Jiangxi 34.5 38.2 40.3 38.5 36.8 21.3 20.0 13.6<br />

[35] Fujian 14.9 18.2 20.0 20.0 9.7 12.1 25.2 13.3<br />

[37] Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 17.9 16.3 14.8 18.1 16.6 13.3 9.7 9.2<br />

[32] Jiangsu 17.3 18.2 19.1 17.8 18.0 13.8 10.7 8.0<br />

[33] Zhejiang 15.8 17.5 15.7 23.6 15.6 10.8 10.0 5.9<br />

Total 27.8 29.5 28.7 29.8 27.4 22.7 20.5 18.3<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

84 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 84


Table 15. Amount of nonperforming debt by region, estimated from reported profitability,<br />

1995–2002, by nonperforming debt in 2002 (RMB billion)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[21] Liaoning 89 87 95 117 77 46 94 114<br />

[44] Guangdong 68 121 137 170 151 118 131 111<br />

[50] Sichuan Chongqing 61 60 71 94 129 101 91 88<br />

[32] Jiangsu 41 54 63 83 74 64 96 73<br />

[31] Shanghai 34 50 63 82 72 47 63 69<br />

[12] Tianjin 28 33 41 66 55 57 55 67<br />

[37] Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 46 45 51 68 67 56 72 63<br />

[22] Jilin 35 42 64 78 57 46 52 62<br />

[42] Hubei 33 54 60 77 73 79 65 62<br />

[23] Heilongjiang 47 59 58 104 69 74 74 56<br />

[43] Hunan 24 31 45 54 37 48 41 55<br />

[13] Hebei 28 30 40 54 47 48 64 53<br />

[61] Shaanxi 31 34 38 49 53 46 48 45<br />

[41] Henan 34 44 45 51 51 55 69 43<br />

[62] Gansu 16 16 17 41 36 11 31 40<br />

[35] Fujian 9 10 8 11 9 10 38 36<br />

[36] Jiangxi 19 24 26 35 36 32 32 31<br />

[54] Tibet Qinghai Ningxia 14 17 21 26 21 25 10 30<br />

[45] Guangxi 14 27 31 35 30 23 25 29<br />

[14] Shanxi 15 20 24 54 53 38 35 28<br />

[15] Inner Mongolia 18 16 16 30 36 24 30 28<br />

[34] Anhui 21 22 25 52 49 25 33 26<br />

[53] Yunnan 8 9 15 21 25 19 24 26<br />

[65] Xinjiang 10 36 16 21 25 22 28 26<br />

[11] Beijing 11 18 37 40 39 37 51 22<br />

[33] Zhejiang 19 22 28 38 26 20 23 14<br />

[52] Guizhou 15 13 20 18 16 11 11 11<br />

[46] Hainan 4 8 11 8 12 4 6 4<br />

Total 792 1,002 1,166 1,577 1,425 1,186 1,392 1,312<br />

Table 16. Nonperforming debt ratios by region, estimated from reported profitability, 1995–<br />

2002, by nonperforming debt ratio in 2002 (percent)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[62] Gansu 29.1 27.1 21.5 44.6 42.9 13.1 35.2 43.0<br />

[12] Tianjin 25.9 30.0 34.5 42.6 35.5 39.6 35.9 38.5<br />

[54] Tibet Qinghai Ningxia 41.2 50.0 48.8 45.6 36.8 39.7 18.2 38.0<br />

[43] Hunan 30.8 36.0 45.5 48.6 31.1 38.7 29.1 37.2<br />

[22] Jilin 30.2 30.7 41.8 50.3 35.8 27.1 31.9 35.8<br />

[36] Jiangxi 32.8 35.3 36.1 44.3 41.4 36.0 35.6 35.2<br />

[65] Xinjiang 17.5 52.2 21.3 26.9 31.6 27.5 35.0 32.9<br />

[45] Guangxi 23.7 43.5 44.3 43.2 35.3 25.3 27.8 32.2<br />

[21] Liaoning 30.4 28.0 27.5 32.3 24.1 14.3 28.1 32.2<br />

[15] Inner Mongolia 34.6 28.6 25.4 42.9 45.6 32.9 36.1 31.8<br />

[61] Shaanxi 39.7 38.6 38.4 48.5 39.6 34.6 33.8 28.8<br />

[23] Heilongjiang 31.3 39.6 34.9 54.7 37.7 38.7 38.9 28.6<br />

[50] Sichuan Chongqing 33.3 30.2 30.5 39.0 40.4 34.2 30.0 27.1<br />

[46] Hainan 36.4 53.3 61.1 40.0 50.0 20.0 37.5 25.0<br />

[42] Hubei 24.4 32.9 33.0 35.5 33.5 34.1 28.5 24.5<br />

[35] Fujian 19.1 18.2 14.8 20.4 14.5 15.2 28.1 24.0<br />

[53] Yunnan 13.8 14.1 22.1 28.0 33.3 25.3 23.3 22.8<br />

[14] Shanxi 19.0 22.7 24.0 41.9 41.4 27.9 27.8 21.2<br />

[13] Hebei 19.6 18.1 21.7 27.1 22.1 21.4 25.8 20.6<br />

[44] Guangdong 22.8 34.8 33.1 39.0 34.8 25.2 25.7 19.9<br />

[31] Shanghai 14.7 18.2 19.5 24.4 20.7 14.1 18.1 18.4<br />

[34] Anhui 25.9 24.2 23.1 48.1 43.0 19.2 25.8 17.9<br />

[41] Henan 25.6 28.0 27.3 25.1 24.3 25.1 29.5 16.9<br />

[32] Jiangsu 18.1 20.1 21.1 25.9 22.6 17.3 21.1 14.5<br />

[52] Guizhou 34.1 32.5 41.7 30.5 25.0 14.9 15.3 14.3<br />

[11] Beijing 11.2 16.1 28.2 24.1 25.3 23.4 27.3 13.0<br />

[37] Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 17.6 15.3 15.2 19.2 16.1 12.8 15.8 12.9<br />

[33] Zhejiang 15.7 15.4 18.3 24.2 16.4 12.0 13.5 7.5<br />

Total 24.1 27.0 27.8 34.2 29.7 23.9 26.1 22.9<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

85 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 85


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

Table 17. Regression summarizing trend <strong>and</strong> cross-ownership patterns of nonperforming debt ratios (dependent variable nonperforming debt ratio)<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio estimated<br />

from reported profitability<br />

as shown in table 8<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio<br />

estimated from imputed profitability<br />

as shown in table 7<br />

Independent variables Coefficient t-statistic Coefficient t-statistic<br />

Intercept 2,996.8 10.9 1,092.6 2.0<br />

Year 1.5 10.7 0.5 1.9<br />

Ownership private enterprises 21.3 18.2 13.9 5.9<br />

Ownership collective enterprises 18.2 15.5 10.7 4.6<br />

Ownership mixed-ownership domestic enterprises 18.3 15.7 16.3 7.0<br />

Ownership foreign-invested enterprises 13.3 11.4 5.1 2.2<br />

Ownership enterprises with investment from Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 13.6 11.7 6.9 3.0<br />

Ownership whole sample 12.4 10.6 11.0 4.7<br />

Ownership state-owned enterprises 0 0<br />

Number of observations 56 56<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.906 0.538<br />

Note: Regression equation: NPD ratio f(year, ownership). Weighted least-squares regression with weights of 100 to 2002, 95 to 2001, 90 to 2000, 85 to 1999, 80 to 1998, 75 to 1997, 70 to 1996, <strong>and</strong> 65 to<br />

1995.<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

86 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 86


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 18. Regression summarizing trend <strong>and</strong> cross-industry patterns of nonperforming debt ratios (dependent<br />

variable nonperforming debt ratio)<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio<br />

based on imputed profitability<br />

as shown in table 9<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio<br />

based on reported profitability<br />

as shown in table 11<br />

Independent variables Coefficient t-statistic Coefficient t-statistic<br />

Intercept 3,571.4 15.7 1,754.7 6.4<br />

Year 1.8 15.6 0.9 6.3<br />

[07] Petroleum extract 25.3 11.1 17.3 6.3<br />

[44] Electric power 13.9 6.1 13.1 4.8<br />

[16] Tobacco 26.6 11.7 13.0 4.7<br />

[24] Cultural 7.1 3.1 8.5 3.1<br />

[27] Medical 15.6 6.9 7.8 2.9<br />

[23] Printing 1.2 0.5 7.5 2.7<br />

[18] Garments 9.5 4.2 5.3 1.9<br />

[21] Furniture 7.3 3.2 4.6 1.7<br />

[43] Other manufacturing 8.2 3.6 4.0 1.5<br />

Industry whole sample 8.4 3.7 4.0 1.5<br />

[26] Raw chemicals 8.4 3.7 3.0 1.1<br />

[10] Nonmetal mining 3.2 1.4 2.1 0.8<br />

[15] Beverage 18.0 7.9 1.4 0.5<br />

[40] Electric equipment 5.4 2.4 1.0 0.4<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications 1.0 0.4 0.6 0.2<br />

[25] Petroleum processing 15.5 6.8 0.5 0.2<br />

[22] Papermaking 11.3 5.0 0.1 0.0<br />

[46] Tap water 0.0 0.0<br />

[19] Leather 5.9 2.6 0.0 0.0<br />

[06] Coal mining 8.6 3.8 0.2 0.1<br />

[33] Pressing nonferrous 6.9 3.0 0.6 0.2<br />

[09] Nonferrous mining 7.3 3.2 0.7 0.3<br />

[08] Ferrous mining 1.3 0.6 1.4 0.5<br />

[29] Rubber 7.2 3.2 1.8 0.6<br />

[37] Transport equipment 0.3 0.1 2.1 0.8<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery 1.0 0.4 3.3 1.2<br />

[30] Plastic 4.9 2.1 3.8 1.4<br />

[34] Metal products 1.2 0.5 4.2 1.5<br />

[32] Pressing ferrous 4.9 2.1 4.4 1.6<br />

[31] Nonmetal products 6.8 3.0 4.6 1.7<br />

[28] Chemical fiber 3.5 1.5 4.6 1.7<br />

[12] Timber logging 4.7 2.1 4.6 1.7<br />

[14] Food production 4.8 2.1 5.1 1.8<br />

[17] Textile 5.0 2.2 5.4 2.0<br />

[42] Instruments 9.5 4.2 5.5 2.0<br />

[36] Special equipment 6.9 3.0 6.9 2.5<br />

[13] Food processing 4.9 2.2 8.7 3.1<br />

[20] Timber 2.6 1.1 8.7 3.2<br />

[45] Gas production 35.0 15.4 22.1 8.0<br />

Number of observations 312 312<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.850 0.610<br />

Note: Regression equation: NPD ratio f(year, industry). Weighted least-squares regression with weights of 100 to 2002, 95 to 2001,<br />

90 to 2000, 85 to 1999, 80 to 1998, 75 to 1997, 70 to 1996, <strong>and</strong> 65 to 1995. See appendix 2 for full industry names corresponding to industry<br />

codes.<br />

in that year. The NPD ratio for the whole sample for a given year is likely to be 12.4<br />

percent lower than the NPD ratio for SOEs in that year.<br />

The regression results shown in tables 17–19 can be used to make rough predictions<br />

about NPD ratios for a particular group in the future. But these rough predictions<br />

are based only on the pattern of NPD ratios during 1995–2002. Figures 1 <strong>and</strong> 2 show<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

87 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 87


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 19. Regression summarizing trend <strong>and</strong> cross-region patterns of nonperforming debt<br />

ratios (dependent variable nonperforming debt ratio)<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio<br />

based on imputed profitability<br />

as shown in<br />

table 13<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio<br />

based on reported profitability<br />

as shown in<br />

table 15<br />

Independent variables Coefficient t-statistic Coefficient t-statistic<br />

Intercept 4,537.3 16.1 2,022.1 5.5<br />

Year 2.2 16.0 1.0 5.4<br />

[37] Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 24.9 10.2 28.2 8.9<br />

[33] Zhejiang 24.1 9.9 25.1 8.0<br />

[35] Fujian 18.5 7.6 22.3 7.0<br />

[32] Jiangsu 24.0 9.9 21.1 6.7<br />

[11] Beijing 5.4 2.2 20.6 6.5<br />

[31] Shanghai 10.8 4.4 19.3 6.1<br />

Region whole sample 17.6 7.2 19.3 6.1<br />

[13] Hebei 15.7 6.5 18.8 5.9<br />

[15] Inner Mongolia 16.5 6.8 14.4 4.6<br />

[41] Henan 17.6 7.2 14.0 4.4<br />

[14] Shanxi 7.8 3.2 12.5 3.9<br />

[53] Yunnan 6.0 2.5 10.4 3.3<br />

[34] Anhui 19.1 7.8 9.5 3.0<br />

[44] Guangdong 13.2 5.4 9.3 2.9<br />

[50] Sichuan Chongqing 7.3 3.0 9.1 2.9<br />

[42] Hubei 14.8 6.1 7.2 2.3<br />

[21] Liaoning 4.3 1.8 6.1 1.9<br />

[12] Tianjin 4.0 1.7 5.0 1.6<br />

[54] Tibet Qinghai Ningxia 4.5 1.9 4.9 1.6<br />

[22] Jilin 4.3 1.8 4.0 1.3<br />

[23] Heilongjiang 4.9 2.0 3.5 1.1<br />

[45] Guangxi 14.0 5.8 3.3 1.0<br />

[36] Jiangxi 8.1 3.3 2.7 0.8<br />

[46] Hainan 7.7 3.2 2.1 0.7<br />

[62] Gansu 3.4 1.4 2.1 0.7<br />

[52] Guizhou 2.4 1.0 1.5 0.5<br />

[43] Hunan 3.7 1.5 1.0 0.3<br />

[61] Shaanxi 1.4 0.6 0.6 0.2<br />

[65] Xinjiang 0.0 0.0<br />

Number of observations 232 232<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.790 0.629<br />

Note: Regression equation: NPD ratio f(year, region). Weighted least-squares regression with weights of 100 to 2002, 95 to 2001, 90<br />

to 2000, 85 to 1999, 80 to 1998, 75 to 1997, 70 to 1996, <strong>and</strong> 65 to 1995.<br />

the actual <strong>and</strong> predicted value of NPD ratios using the regression coefªcients in tables<br />

17–19 when the categorical variable is set to the whole sample. Figure 1 is based<br />

on imputed proªtability <strong>and</strong> shows a much faster <strong>rate</strong> of decline in NPD ratios than<br />

ªgure 2, which is based on reported proªtability.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

A more sophisticated method for assessing likely NPD ratios in future years for the<br />

whole sample is to build a few likely scenarios based on alternative assumptions<br />

about the possible NPD ratios for individual groups <strong>and</strong> the possible distribution of<br />

total liabilities. Table 20 outlines nine scenarios for the NPD ratios for the whole<br />

sample by the year 2007 by providing speciªc alternative assumptions about the<br />

possible NPD ratios for each group of enterprises <strong>and</strong> about the possible distribu-<br />

88 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 88


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Figure 1. Predicting nonperforming debt ratios: Imputed proªtability <strong>and</strong> weighted<br />

regression<br />

Figure 2. Predicting nonperforming debt ratios: Reported proªtability <strong>and</strong> weighted<br />

regression<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

89 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 89


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

Table 20. Scenarios for nonperforming debt ratio of the whole sample by 2007 (percent)<br />

Optimistic case: Two years faster<br />

than predicted by trend<br />

Likely case: As predicted<br />

by trend<br />

Pessimistic case: Two years<br />

slower than predicted by trend<br />

Alternative assumptions about<br />

distribution of total liabilities<br />

Alternative assumptions about value of<br />

nonperforming debt ratios<br />

Private 2.9 3.7 4.5<br />

Collective 2.6 1.8 1.0<br />

Mixed 38.0 44.2 50.4<br />

Foreign 13.5 15.3 17.1<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 7.7 8.3 8.9<br />

State-owned 36.2 28.2 20.2<br />

Optimistic case: 2002 nonperforming debt ratios<br />

estimated from imputed profitability<br />

Private 7.4 16.8 15.8 14.7<br />

Collective 10.0<br />

Mixed 10.8<br />

Foreign 15.2<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 12.6<br />

State-owned 25.4<br />

Weighted average for all 18.4<br />

Likely case: 2002 average nonperforming debt ratio<br />

(average over nonperforming debt statistics from both<br />

imputed <strong>and</strong> reported profitability)<br />

Private 11.6 19.6 18.9 18.3<br />

Collective 14.6<br />

Mixed 15.5<br />

Foreign 18.8<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 15.4<br />

State-owned 25.6<br />

Weighted average for all 20.6<br />

Pessimistic case: 2002 nonperforming debt ratio<br />

estimated from reported profitability<br />

Private 15.8 22.4 22.1 21.8<br />

Collective 19.2<br />

Mixed 20.2<br />

Foreign 22.4<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 18.2<br />

State-owned 25.8<br />

Weighted average for all 22.9<br />

90 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 90


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

tion of total liabilities across groups. These simulated scenarios can facilitate <strong>policy</strong><br />

debates by showing the magnitude of reforms necessary to achieve various speciªc<br />

objectives. For example, table 20 shows that to lower the overall NPD ratio to 14.7<br />

percent by the year 2007, it is necessary for individual groups to achieve NPD ratios<br />

in the optimistic case (e.g., 2002 NPD ratios estimated from imputed proªtability)<br />

<strong>and</strong> for the distribution of total liabilities also to achieve the optimistic case, in<br />

which the SOE sector share of total liabilities falls to 20.2 percent. The nine scenarios<br />

in table 20 are built for illustrative purposes. The alternative assumptions are subjective<br />

<strong>and</strong> debatable but are all based on the patterns of NPD statistics estimated in<br />

this paper.<br />

5. Explaining profitability <strong>and</strong> quality of debts<br />

The NPD statistics for each group of enterprises reºect the total effects from all factors<br />

that might cause NPD. For example, a major factor that might contribute to a<br />

high NPD ratio for SOEs is that many enterprises in the utilities industry are SOEs<br />

<strong>and</strong> the utilities industry as a whole is not proªtable because of heavy price regulation<br />

by the government. In this case, the high NPD ratio for the group of SOEs actually<br />

reºects both ownership <strong>and</strong> industry risks. The purpose of this section is to use<br />

regression analysis to isolate different sources of bad debt risks. Because we have<br />

classiªed enterprise debts by their proªtability, we need to explain what factors are<br />

driving enterprise proªtability <strong>and</strong> returns on assets.<br />

Tables 21 <strong>and</strong> 22 summarize the characteristics of the key variables used in the<br />

proªtability regressions. Table 23 reports the results of four panel data regressions:<br />

two logistic regressions explaining the imputed <strong>and</strong> reported proªtability <strong>and</strong> two<br />

linear regressions explaining the imputed <strong>and</strong> reported return on total assets. The<br />

explanatory variables for the four regressions are the same: log(capital/labor ratio);<br />

ratio of liability to total assets; log(employees); market share; industry concentration;<br />

<strong>and</strong> dummy variables for ownership, year, industry, <strong>and</strong> region. The<br />

coefªcients <strong>and</strong> their st<strong>and</strong>ard errors indicate the size <strong>and</strong> the statistical signiªcance<br />

of the impact of the explanatory variables on proªtability.<br />

Some common patterns emerge in all four regressions:<br />

• The ratio of liability to total assets has a signiªcantly negative impact on<br />

proªtability, implying that the more the enterprise borrows, the less the proªts or<br />

the lower the returns on assets.<br />

• Market share has a positive impact on proªtability.<br />

• State ownership has a negative impact on proªtability.<br />

• Proªtability improves signiªcantly during 2000–2002.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

91 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 91


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

Table 21. Summary statistics for key variables in profitability regressions, 1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Total<br />

Number of observations for<br />

Return on total assets with reported profit 22,543 22,974 22,957 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220 177,086<br />

Return on total assets with imputed profit 22,393 22,815 22,813 22,129 21,296 20,555 21,730 21,999 175,730<br />

Capital/labor ratio (RMB thous<strong>and</strong> per person) 22,295 22,724 22,708 22,046 21,240 20,505 21,641 21,972 175,131<br />

Asset/liability ratio 22,479 22,904 22,848 22,187 21,354 20,633 21,792 22,069 176,266<br />

Employment 22,543 22,974 22,957 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220 177,086<br />

Market share (percentage of three-digit industry sales total) 22,543 22,974 22,957 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220 177,086<br />

Industry concentration (percentage by top four enterprises in two-digit industry sales total)<br />

22,543 22,974 22,957 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220 177,086<br />

Median for<br />

Return on total assets with reported profit (percent) 0.27 0.14 0.09 0.04 0.18 0.38 0.53 0.82 0.23<br />

Return on total assets with imputed profit (percent) 3.42 3.56 3.40 3.22 4.51 5.38 6.59 7.31 4.58<br />

Capital/labor ratio (RMB thous<strong>and</strong> per person) 27.4 36.5 41.6 49.4 57.9 63.6 70.0 75.5 49.2<br />

Asset/liability ratio 0.713 0.711 0.711 0.711 0.690 0.682 0.651 0.635 0.690<br />

Employment 877 823 793 715 654 620 560 520 701<br />

Market share (percentage of three-digit industry sales total) 0.207 0.192 0.182 0.185 0.199 0.201 0.192 0.185 0.193<br />

Industry concentration (percentage by top four enterprises<br />

in two-digit industry sales total)<br />

10.4 11.1 11.6 12.1 12.4 13.1 11.7 12.3 11.6<br />

Mean for<br />

Return on total assets with reported profit (percent) 0.16 0.54 0.64 0.89 0.34 1.29 1.69 2.03 0.41<br />

Return on total assets with imputed profit (percent) 5.04 6.07 5.74 5.58 7.72 8.91 10.65 11.61 7.63<br />

Capital/labor ratio (RMB thous<strong>and</strong> per person) 51.4 65.9 74.1 95.0 118.3 130.0 152.4 165.6 105.8<br />

Asset/liability ratio 0.706 0.709 0.711 0.714 0.694 0.687 0.657 0.642 0.690<br />

Employment 1,696 1,633 1,593 1,502 1,428 1,361 1,237 1,189 1,458<br />

Market share (percentage of three-digit industry sales total) 0.838 0.831 0.823 0.839 0.867 0.907 0.881 0.869 0.856<br />

Industry concentration (percentage by top four enterprises<br />

in two-digit industry sales total)<br />

11.4 12.0 13.0 13.4 13.5 13.8 13.9 14.1 13.1<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard deviation for<br />

Return on total assets with reported profit (percent) 8.30 9.24 8.36 8.53 8.42 8.46 9.99 8.97 8.86<br />

Return on total assets with imputed profit (percent) 13.73 16.25 15.16 14.27 15.27 16.06 17.99 19.51 16.29<br />

Capital/labor ratio (RMB thous<strong>and</strong> per person) 123.6 162.6 154.9 242.8 358.3 346.6 430.6 447.8 308.4<br />

Asset/liability ratio 0.23828 0.25137 0.26388 0.28025 0.27605 0.28080 0.28693 0.28883 0.27218<br />

Employment 5,215 4,908 4,719 4,482 4,401 3,947 3,599 3,560 4,404<br />

Market share (percentage of three-digit industry sales total) 3.2 3.2 3.2 3.1 3.1 3.4 3.4 3.4 3.3<br />

Industry concentration (percentage by top four enterprises<br />

in two-digit industry sales total)<br />

7.5 7.5 7.6 7.1 6.9 7.1 6.2 6.1 7.1<br />

92 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 92


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 22. Median of key variables for profitability regressions by ownership, 1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Total<br />

Percentage return on total assets<br />

with reported profit for<br />

Private 1.78 4.84 0.36 0.03 1.00 1.03 1.38 1.72 1.34<br />

Collective 0.69 0.50 0.34 0.28 0.51 0.67 0.72 0.91 0.52<br />

Mixed 2.07 1.46 0.89 0.52 0.88 1.10 1.24 1.33 1.11<br />

Foreign 1.70 0.83 0.77 0.54 1.65 2.93 2.99 3.61 2.08<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 1.31 1.01 0.89 0.43 0.87 1.35 1.55 1.95 1.26<br />

State-owned 0.14 0.05 0.02 0.00 0.03 0.09 0.06 0.09 0.05<br />

Total 0.27 0.14 0.09 0.04 0.18 0.38 0.53 0.82 0.23<br />

Percentage return on total assets<br />

with imputed profit for<br />

Private 11.25 17.44 9.65 7.39 12.01 11.34 12.93 13.98 12.67<br />

Collective 7.44 8.24 7.17 7.52 8.60 9.46 10.57 10.97 8.41<br />

Mixed 7.13 6.78 6.36 6.06 7.11 7.83 8.83 9.43 7.85<br />

Foreign 5.80 6.31 6.09 5.49 8.15 9.93 11.01 11.24 8.66<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 6.57 6.75 6.23 5.41 6.99 8.19 8.86 9.69 7.61<br />

State-owned 2.14 2.01 1.86 1.34 2.18 2.53 2.80 2.87 2.14<br />

Total 3.42 3.56 3.40 3.22 4.51 5.38 6.59 7.31 4.58<br />

Capital/labor ratio (RMB thous<strong>and</strong><br />

per person) for<br />

Private 26 54 49 48 52 51 52 56 52<br />

Collective 25 30 33 40 44 45 49 52 37<br />

Mixed 33 39 42 46 52 57 62 67 54<br />

Foreign 71 91 114 134 144 145 149 145 129<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 63 79 82 98 109 108 107 103 96<br />

State-owned 26 35 40 47 55 62 68 74 44<br />

Total 27 36 42 49 58 64 70 75 49<br />

Liability/total assets ratio for<br />

Private 0.531 0.653 0.722 0.724 0.686 0.693 0.667 0.654 0.671<br />

Collective 0.708 0.718 0.723 0.717 0.707 0.712 0.690 0.686 0.711<br />

Mixed 0.646 0.636 0.650 0.672 0.664 0.660 0.653 0.644 0.654<br />

Foreign 0.574 0.553 0.554 0.538 0.534 0.516 0.479 0.472 0.517<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 0.638 0.622 0.625 0.614 0.603 0.589 0.544 0.520 0.583<br />

State-owned 0.731 0.733 0.737 0.747 0.732 0.732 0.718 0.704 0.732<br />

Total 0.713 0.711 0.711 0.711 0.690 0.682 0.651 0.635 0.690<br />

Median employment per firm for<br />

Private 500 453 718 429 391 394 383 367 384<br />

Collective 643 599 565 511 490 461 437 408 528<br />

Mixed 1,010 972 897 820 748 711 645 606 725<br />

Foreign 408 387 376 350 321 332 320 320 341<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 446 390 387 360 364 360 343 340 363<br />

State-owned 1,014 975 946 873 829 793 753 729 894<br />

Total 877 823 793 715 654 620 560 520 701<br />

Market share (percentage of threedigit<br />

industry sales total) for<br />

Private 0.159 0.285 0.283 0.118 0.147 0.148 0.148 0.141 0.146<br />

Collective 0.206 0.190 0.175 0.193 0.192 0.185 0.161 0.146 0.185<br />

Mixed 0.361 0.310 0.253 0.212 0.221 0.213 0.198 0.183 0.214<br />

Foreign 0.450 0.402 0.399 0.419 0.406 0.396 0.355 0.318 0.381<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 0.339 0.331 0.341 0.341 0.329 0.343 0.312 0.277 0.318<br />

State-owned 0.185 0.169 0.156 0.149 0.158 0.155 0.145 0.143 0.160<br />

Total 0.207 0.192 0.182 0.185 0.199 0.201 0.192 0.185 0.193<br />

Industry concentration (percentage<br />

by top four enterprises in twodigit<br />

industry sales total) for<br />

Private 12.6 9.5 8.6 10.8 11.7 11.0 11.6 11.1 11.6<br />

Collective 9.9 8.5 9.7 10.8 10.6 11.3 11.6 11.1 10.5<br />

Mixed 10.5 11.3 11.6 11.7 12.4 12.9 11.7 12.3 11.8<br />

Foreign 10.5 11.3 13.3 12.5 13.8 13.1 14.0 12.3 12.4<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 9.9 10.6 11.6 12.1 12.4 12.1 13.1 12.3 11.7<br />

State-owned 10.4 11.1 11.6 12.1 12.4 13.4 13.1 12.5 11.7<br />

Total 10.4 11.1 11.6 12.1 12.4 13.1 11.7 12.3 11.6<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

93 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 93


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

Table 23. Profitability regressions<br />

Return on total<br />

assets by reported<br />

profitability<br />

Return on total<br />

assets by imputed<br />

proªtability<br />

Reported proªtability<br />

(1 proªt, 0 loss)<br />

Imputed profitability<br />

(1 profit, 0 loss)<br />

Dependent variable B SE Exp(B) B SE Exp(B) B SE B SE<br />

Constant 2.174*** 0.120 8.797 2.430*** 0.118 11.353 0.142*** 0.008 0.014*** 0.004<br />

Log(capital/labor ratio) 0.005 0.007 1.005 0.063*** 0.007 0.939 0.012*** 0.000 0.001*** 0.000<br />

Liability/assets ratio 1.730*** 0.023 0.177 3.156*** 0.026 0.043 0.116*** 0.001 0.115*** 0.001<br />

Log(employees) 0.029*** 0.007 1.029 0.080*** 0.007 1.084 0.003*** 0.000 0.003*** 0.000<br />

Market share 0.109*** 0.005 1.115 0.175*** 0.006 1.191 0.004*** 0.000 0.002*** 0.000<br />

Industry concentration 0.001 0.003 0.999 0.005 0.003 1.005 0.001*** 0.000 0.000*** 0.000<br />

Private 0.106*** 0.003 0.029*** 0.001<br />

Collective 0.450*** 0.059 0.637 0.215*** 0.049 0.806 0.070*** 0.001 0.022*** 0.001<br />

Mixed 0.534*** 0.059 0.586 0.094*** 0.048 0.910 0.047*** 0.001 0.017*** 0.001<br />

Foreign 0.763*** 0.061 0.466 0.940*** 0.051 0.391 0.065*** 0.002 0.017*** 0.001<br />

0.757*** 0.061 0.469 0.658*** 0.051 0.518 0.053*** 0.002 0.015*** 0.001<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong><br />

Taiwan<br />

State-owned 1.235*** 0.057 0.291 0.585*** 0.047 0.557 0 . 0 .<br />

1995 0.390*** 0.025 0.677 0.061*** 0.025 1.062 0.049*** 0.002 0.005*** 0.001<br />

1996 0.397*** 0.024 0.673 0.118*** 0.024 0.889 0.038*** 0.001 0.012*** 0.001<br />

1997 0.394*** 0.024 0.674 0.236*** 0.024 0.790 0.040*** 0.001 0.014*** 0.001<br />

1998 0.412*** 0.024 0.662 0.393*** 0.023 0.675 0.041*** 0.001 0.016*** 0.001<br />

1999 0.231*** 0.024 0.794 0.111*** 0.024 0.895 0.027*** 0.001 0.008*** 0.001<br />

2000 0.093*** 0.025 0.911 0.225*** 0.025 1.252 0.018*** 0.001 0.001*** 0.001<br />

2001 0.016 0.025 1.016 0.005 0.024 0.995 0.007*** 0.001 0.001*** 0.001<br />

2002 0 0 .<br />

Logistic Logistic General linear model General linear model<br />

Regression method<br />

Nagelkerke R 2 0.189 0.251<br />

Adjusted R 2 0.181 0.218<br />

Number of observations 177,086 177,086 172,985 174,317<br />

Note: Coefficients for industry <strong>and</strong> region dummies are omitted in this table but are used to calculate pure industry <strong>and</strong> region profitability index in next table.<br />

***Estimated coefficient is significant at level of 1 percent.<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

94 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 94


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 24. Industry-specific profitability indexes for large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises, by ISPI5, 1995–2002<br />

ISPI6<br />

([ISPI3 ISPI4]/2)<br />

ISPI5<br />

([ISPI1 ISPI2]/2)<br />

ISPI4<br />

(estimated from<br />

imputed return<br />

on total assets)<br />

ISPI3<br />

(estimated from<br />

reported return<br />

on total assets)<br />

ISPI2<br />

(estimated from<br />

imputed profitability)<br />

ISPI1<br />

(estimated from<br />

reported profitability)<br />

Industry<br />

[16] Tobacco 3.196 8.018 1.030 1.301 5.607 1.166<br />

[07] Petroleum extract 1.314 3.714 1.060 1.142 2.514 1.101<br />

[44] Electric power 2.451 1.764 1.019 1.021 2.107 1.020<br />

[15] Beverage 1.548 2.654 1.006 1.065 2.101 1.036<br />

[27] Medical 1.903 2.064 1.021 1.039 1.984 1.030<br />

[22] Papermaking 1.353 1.508 1.007 1.008 1.431 1.008<br />

[26] Raw chemicals 1.510 1.333 1.007 1.001 1.422 1.004<br />

[25] Petroleum processing 0.833 1.783 0.999 1.052 1.308 1.026<br />

[23] Printing 1.628 0.942 1.003 0.974 1.285 0.989<br />

[33] Pressing nonferrous 1.230 1.174 1.002 1.001 1.202 1.002<br />

[13] Food processing 1.095 1.277 0.999 1.039 1.186 1.019<br />

[40] Electric equipment 1.283 1.021 1.004 0.996 1.152 1.000<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications 1.396 0.851 1.008 0.986 1.124 0.997<br />

[18] Garments 1.173 0.960 0.999 1.006 1.066 1.003<br />

[31] Nonmetal products 1.007 1.122 0.993 0.971 1.065 0.982<br />

[12] Timber logging 1.034 1.048 1.005 0.974 1.041 0.990<br />

[37] Transport equipment 1.119 0.943 1.001 0.985 1.031 0.993<br />

[17] Textile 1.044 1.016 0.992 0.978 1.030 0.985<br />

[19] Leather 1.061 0.897 0.995 1.004 0.979 0.999<br />

[14] Food production 0.935 1.007 0.995 1.005 0.971 1.000<br />

[32] Pressing ferrous 0.858 1.061 0.994 0.998 0.960 0.996<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery 1.088 0.832 0.997 0.961 0.960 0.979<br />

[29] Rubber 0.780 0.984 0.992 0.990 0.882 0.991<br />

[43] Other manufacturing 0.927 0.838 0.996 0.999 0.882 0.998<br />

[30] Plastic 0.913 0.812 0.995 0.967 0.862 0.981<br />

[24] Cultural 0.937 0.777 0.998 0.974 0.857 0.986<br />

[10] Nonmetal mining 0.882 0.829 0.995 0.968 0.856 0.982<br />

[28] Chemical fiber 0.856 0.852 0.996 0.996 0.854 0.996<br />

[34] Metal products 0.883 0.748 0.993 0.972 0.816 0.982<br />

[20] Timber 0.827 0.793 0.992 0.990 0.810 0.991<br />

[36] Special equipment 0.853 0.651 0.995 0.960 0.752 0.978<br />

[09] Nonferrous mining 0.898 0.602 1.010 0.964 0.750 0.987<br />

[21] Furniture 0.768 0.688 0.990 0.977 0.728 0.984<br />

[06] Coal mining 0.797 0.551 0.996 0.953 0.674 0.974<br />

[42] Instruments 0.748 0.554 0.997 0.957 0.651 0.977<br />

[08] Ferrous mining 0.430 0.676 0.991 0.973 0.553 0.982<br />

[46] Tap water 0.454 0.571 0.966 0.942 0.513 0.954<br />

[45] Gas production 0.159 0.132 0.962 0.907 0.146 0.935<br />

Note: ISPI industry-specific profitability index. The indexes in this table are derived from the coefficients of industry dummies in the profitability regressions reported in table 23. For easy comparison, each profitability<br />

index is normalized by the sample average. An index value that is greater than one indicates profitability that is better than the sample average. See appendix 2 for full industry names corresponding to industry<br />

codes.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

95 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 95


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

It should be noted that the above are independent impacts by each explanatory variable<br />

after the impacts of other explanatory variables, including the impact of industry<br />

<strong>and</strong> region variables, are controlled for.<br />

The impacts of ownership on proªtability revealed by each of the four regressions<br />

are the following:<br />

• The logistic regression on imputed proªtability implies that, compared to private<br />

enterprises, the odds that collective, mixed, foreign, HK-M-Taiwan, <strong>and</strong> SOEs will<br />

be proªtable are 0.637, 0.586, 0.466, 0.469, <strong>and</strong> 0.291, respectively. In other words,<br />

the SOEs have the lowest probability of making proªts compared with the other<br />

groups.<br />

• The logistic regression on reported proªtability shows similar results but with less<br />

dramatic quantitative impacts except for the foreign-invested <strong>and</strong> HK-M-Taiwan–<br />

invested enterprises. As compared to private enterprises, the odds that collective,<br />

mixed, foreign, HK-M-Taiwan, <strong>and</strong> SOEs will be proªtable are 0.806, 0.910, 0.391,<br />

0.518, <strong>and</strong> 0.557, respectively. The foreign-invested <strong>and</strong> HK-M-Taiwan–invested<br />

enterprises seem less proªtable than the SOEs when measured by reported<br />

proªts. This is likely attributable to the different tax <strong>and</strong> accounting system for the<br />

externally invested enterprises. For example, the multinational corporations are<br />

likely to use various accounting practices to transfer proªts to their overseas entities.<br />

The imputed proªts would be more useful when comparing enterprise performance<br />

across ownership in China because they are derived from the consistent<br />

framework of calculating value-added <strong>and</strong> would not be affected by differences in<br />

tax <strong>and</strong> accounting systems across ownership sectors.<br />

• The linear regression on imputed proªtability shows that the return on total assets<br />

for private, collective, mixed, foreign, <strong>and</strong> HK-M-Taiwan enterprises will be 10.6,<br />

7, 4.7, 6.5, <strong>and</strong> 5.3 percentage points higher, respectively, than that for SOEs.<br />

• The linear regression on reported proªtability shows that the return on total<br />

assets for private, collective, mixed, foreign, <strong>and</strong> HK-M-Taiwan enterprises will<br />

be 2.9, 2.2, 1.7, 1.7, <strong>and</strong> 1.5 percentage points higher, respectively, than that for<br />

SOEs.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

Tables 24 <strong>and</strong> 25 use the industry <strong>and</strong> region dummies in the four proªtability regressions<br />

to construct industry- <strong>and</strong> region-speciªc proªtability indexes (ISPI <strong>and</strong><br />

RSPI, respectively). These tables can be used as benchmarks for assessing the pure<br />

industry-speciªc or region-speciªc risks of enterprise debts in China. They summarize<br />

the independent impacts of industry <strong>and</strong> location on the quality of industrial<br />

enterprise debts averaged over 1995–2002.<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

96 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 96


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 25. Region-specific profitability indexes for large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises, by RSPI5, 1996–2002<br />

RSPI6<br />

(RSPI3 RSPI4]/2)<br />

RSPI5<br />

([RSPI1 RSPI2]/2)<br />

RSPI4<br />

(estimated from<br />

imputed return<br />

on total assets)<br />

RSPI3<br />

(estimated from<br />

reported return<br />

on total assets)<br />

RSPI2<br />

(estimated from<br />

imputed profits)<br />

RSPI1<br />

(estimated from<br />

reported profits)<br />

Region<br />

[37] Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 2.829 2.105 1.023 1.047 2.467 1.035<br />

[32] Jiangsu 1.532 1.799 1.009 1.040 1.666 1.024<br />

[13] Hebei 1.746 1.445 1.014 1.030 1.595 1.022<br />

[33] Zhejiang 1.622 1.496 1.014 1.005 1.559 1.010<br />

[41] Henan 1.346 1.700 1.009 1.032 1.523 1.021<br />

[34] Anhui 1.035 1.623 1.001 1.030 1.329 1.016<br />

[15] Inner Mongolia 1.103 1.316 1.002 1.014 1.210 1.008<br />

[31] Shanghai 1.432 0.858 1.007 0.989 1.145 0.998<br />

[35] Fujian 1.253 1.011 1.007 1.015 1.132 1.011<br />

[14] Shanxi 1.082 1.028 1.002 1.001 1.055 1.002<br />

[42] Hubei 0.827 1.279 1.004 1.032 1.053 1.018<br />

[45] Guangxi 0.764 1.327 0.996 1.009 1.045 1.003<br />

[36] Jiangxi 0.901 1.140 1.000 1.003 1.021 1.001<br />

[44] Guangdong 0.913 0.969 0.998 1.006 0.941 1.002<br />

[23] Heilongjiang 0.905 0.939 0.998 0.997 0.922 0.997<br />

[50] Sichuan Chongqing 0.908 0.886 0.993 0.994 0.897 0.993<br />

[11] Beijing 1.341 0.445 0.996 0.961 0.893 0.979<br />

[54] Tibet Qinghai Ningxia 0.825 0.833 0.990 0.983 0.829 0.987<br />

[53] Yunnan 0.885 0.764 0.997 0.978 0.824 0.988<br />

[22] Jilin 0.809 0.816 0.994 0.994 0.812 0.994<br />

[12] Tianjin 0.815 0.738 1.004 0.970 0.776 0.987<br />

[46] Hainan 0.721 0.812 0.996 0.975 0.766 0.985<br />

[61] Shaanxi 0.766 0.760 0.992 0.990 0.763 0.991<br />

[43] Hunan 0.660 0.857 0.989 0.989 0.758 0.989<br />

[62] Gansu 0.686 0.794 0.984 0.982 0.740 0.983<br />

[52] Guizhou 0.727 0.735 0.994 0.986 0.731 0.990<br />

[21] Liaoning 0.774 0.662 0.993 0.974 0.718 0.983<br />

[65] Xinjiang 0.705 0.695 0.992 0.973 0.700 0.983<br />

Note: RSPI region-specific profitability index. The indexes in this table are derived from the coefficients of region dummies in the profitability regressions reported in table 23. For easy comparison, each<br />

profitability index is normalized by the sample average. An index value that is greater than one indicates profitability better than the sample average.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

97 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 97


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

ISPI1, ISPI2, ISPI5, RSPI1, RSPI2, <strong>and</strong> RSPI5 (see tables 24 <strong>and</strong> 25) are derived from<br />

the industry or region dummies in the logistic regressions but are normalized by the<br />

sample average. Compared with the sample average, the odds that a speciªc industry<br />

or region will be proªtable can be calculated by multiplying the sample average<br />

by the index value. For example, the index value of ISPI5 given in table 24 for the tobacco<br />

industry is 5.607. Thus the odds that the tobacco industry will be proªtable,<br />

are 5.607 times those that the average industry will be proªtable, when other factors<br />

inºuencing proªtability are held constant.<br />

ISPI3, ISPI4, ISPI6, RSPI3, RSPI4, <strong>and</strong> RSPI6 are derived from the industry or region<br />

dummies in the linear regressions but are also normalized by ªrst subtracting the<br />

average return of all industries or regions <strong>and</strong> then adding one. This makes the index<br />

value equal to one for the average of all industries or regions. The index value<br />

minus one is the additional return a speciªc industry or region has over the average<br />

return on total assets. For example, the index value of ISPI6 in table 24 is 1.166 for<br />

the tobacco industry. This means that the tobacco industry’s return on total assets is<br />

likely to be higher than the average return on total assets for all industries by a ratio<br />

of 0.166 (1.166 1), or 16.6 percent.<br />

Hence, tables 24 <strong>and</strong> 25 help us determine which industries <strong>and</strong> regions are more<br />

proªtable for the large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises when the inºuences<br />

of other factors such as types of ownership <strong>and</strong> capital intensity are removed. The<br />

two tables are sorted by ISPI5 <strong>and</strong> RSPI5 from high to low proªtability. The top ªve<br />

industries by industry-speciªc proªtability are tobacco processing; petroleum <strong>and</strong><br />

natural gas extraction; electric power, steam, <strong>and</strong> hot water; beverage production;<br />

<strong>and</strong> medical <strong>and</strong> pharmaceutical products. The top ªve regions by region-speciªc<br />

proªtability are Sh<strong>and</strong>ong, Jiangsu, Hebei, Zhejiang, <strong>and</strong> Henan.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

The proªtability regressions in table 23 can also be used to assess the proªtability or<br />

debt quality of a particular enterprise if we know the value for that enterprise of the<br />

explanatory variable. The predicted value from the logistic regressions is the probability<br />

of making proªts. Of course, the prediction using the regression equation<br />

only helps to assess non-enterprise-speciªc risks that are summarized by the explanatory<br />

variables in the regressions. In the real world <strong>and</strong> for a speciªc enterprise, the<br />

enterprise-speciªc risks are clearly most important <strong>and</strong> cannot be analyzed using<br />

the statistical results presented here. It is usually the case, however, that practitioners<br />

know the ªrm-speciªc risks very well but ªnd it difªcult to assess non-ªrmspeciªc<br />

risks. Our study helps reveal non-ªrm-speciªc information <strong>and</strong> thus can<br />

contribute to better <strong>policy</strong> <strong>and</strong> more effective business st<strong>rate</strong>gy.<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

98 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 98


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

6. Exit of poor-performing enterprises <strong>and</strong> its impact on the NPD ratio<br />

The analysis in the previous sections is affected by a sample selection bias that results<br />

from the way the National Bureau of Statistics in China deªnes the sample of<br />

large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises. As pointed out earlier, about 20 percent<br />

of ªrms enter <strong>and</strong> exit this sample every year, <strong>and</strong> the enterprises in the sample<br />

make up a very dynamic group that accu<strong>rate</strong>ly reºects the current state of China’s<br />

large industrial enterprise sector. Such change in the sample, however, creates a<br />

problem for measuring the NPD ratio: it is possible that the exiting enterprises have<br />

higher NPD ratios than the new entries.<br />

Table 26 shows the number of enterprises by proªtability <strong>and</strong> entry-exit status for<br />

the 1995–2002 period. The entry-exit status of a sample enterprise for a particular<br />

period t is deªned as one of the following four exclusive groups: 1<br />

• “exit” group: the enterprise was in the sample at t 1 <strong>and</strong> t, but not at t 1<br />

• “new” group: the enterprise was in the sample at t <strong>and</strong> t 1, but not at t 1<br />

• “stay” group: the enterprise was in the sample at t 1, t, <strong>and</strong> t 1<br />

• “once” group: the enterprise was in the sample at t, but not at t 1 <strong>and</strong> t 1<br />

As shown in table 26, among the proªt-making enterprises in 1996, 1,177 enterprises<br />

appeared in the sample of 1995 <strong>and</strong> 1996 but did not show up in the sample of 1997,<br />

<strong>and</strong> hence they belong to the “exit” group; 2,802 enterprises did not appear in the<br />

sample of 1995 but appeared in the sample of 1996 <strong>and</strong> 1997, <strong>and</strong> hence they fall into<br />

the “new” group; 10,540 enterprises appeared in the sample of 1995, 1996, <strong>and</strong> 1997,<br />

<strong>and</strong> hence they are in the “stay” group; 516 enterprises did not appear in 1995 <strong>and</strong><br />

1997 but showed up in 1996, <strong>and</strong> hence they are put into the “once” group.<br />

Table 26 tells us that both proªt-making <strong>and</strong> loss-making enterprises are actively entering<br />

<strong>and</strong> exiting the sample every year. The dynamics of this life-death process<br />

reºect how lively China’s enterprise reform <strong>and</strong> restructuring has been. But we<br />

would expect that the “exit” group would have more loss-making enterprises than<br />

the “new” or “stay” group. The bottom part of table 26 presents information to al-<br />

1 Because we do not have data for 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2003, the entry-exit status for 1995 <strong>and</strong> 2003 may<br />

differ slightly from the deªnition here. For 1995, we have information on ªrms that exited or<br />

stayed in 1996, but we do not have information on ªrms that were new in 1995 or appeared<br />

only in 1995. For 2002, we have information on ªrms that were new or stayed in 2002, but we<br />

have no information on ªrms that exited or appear only in 2002. The unavailable information<br />

is indicated by blank entries in the table.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

99 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 99


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 26. Number of enterprises by profitability <strong>and</strong> entry-exit status, 1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Number of profit-making enterprises<br />

Exit 2,485 1,177 2,434 1,648 1,335 2,608 1,258<br />

New 2,802 1,533 2,408 2,523 1,160 3,890 2,300<br />

Stay 12,229 10,540 10,493 9,849 11,017 11,235 11,221 14,968<br />

Once 516 599 710 368 378 565<br />

Whole sample 14,714 15,035 15,059 14,615 15,243 15,381 16,934 17,268<br />

Number of loss-making enterprises<br />

Exit 1,651 1,048 1,745 1,722 943 1,182 649<br />

New 981 574 838 642 360 864 687<br />

Stay 6,178 5,642 5,293 4,674 4,474 3,631 3,258 4,265<br />

Once 268 286 444 161 184 193<br />

Whole sample 7,829 7,939 7,898 7,678 6,220 5,357 4,964 4,952<br />

Number of enterprises<br />

Exit 4,136 2,225 4,179 3,370 2,278 3,790 1,907<br />

New 3,783 2,107 3,246 3,165 1,520 4,754 2,987<br />

Stay 18,407 16,182 15,786 14,523 15,491 14,866 14,479 19,233<br />

Once 784 885 1,154 529 562 758<br />

Whole sample 22,543 22,974 22,957 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220<br />

Share of loss-making enterprises (percent)<br />

Exit 39.9 47.1 41.8 51.1 41.4 31.2 34.0<br />

New 25.9 27.2 25.8 20.3 23.7 18.2 23.0<br />

Stay 33.6 34.9 33.5 32.2 28.9 24.4 22.5 22.2<br />

Once 34.2 32.3 38.5 30.4 32.7 25.5<br />

Whole sample 34.7 34.6 34.4 34.4 29.0 25.8 22.7 22.3<br />

Note: “Exit” group enterprise was in sample at t 1 <strong>and</strong> t but not at t 1; “new” group enterprise was in sample at t <strong>and</strong> t 1<br />

but not at t 1; “stay” group enterprise was in sample at t 1, t, <strong>and</strong> t 1; “once” group enterprise was in sample at t, but not<br />

at t 1 or t 1.<br />

low us to assess this expectation. The share of loss-making enterprises in the “exit”<br />

group is much higher than their share in the other groups, particularly during 1998–<br />

99. In 1998, the share of loss-making ªrms is 51.1 percent for the “exit” group, 25.8<br />

percent for the “new” group, 32.2 percent for the “stay” group, <strong>and</strong> 38.5 percent for<br />

the “once” group. Clearly the group that is exiting the sample has a much higher<br />

share of poor-performing ªrms than the group that is entering the sample. This is a<br />

good trend for the economy, but it creates biased estimates of NPD ratios, because<br />

the NPDs of the exiting enterprises are entirely ignored in the analysis of the previous<br />

sections.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

Unlike table 26, which shows the distribution in the number of enterprises by entryexit<br />

status, table 27 shows the distribution of the amounts of performing <strong>and</strong><br />

nonperforming debts by entry-exit status. For example, table 27 shows that the<br />

amount of NPDs that exited the sample with the exit of enterprises rose from<br />

RMB157 billion in 1995 to RMB200 billion in 1998, <strong>and</strong> then fell to RMB92 billion in<br />

2001. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the amount of performing debt that entered the sample<br />

with the entry of new enterprises rose steadily from RMB311 billion in 1996 to<br />

RMB400–800 billion after 1997. The exit of bad ªrms <strong>and</strong> the entry of good ªrms are<br />

clearly driving forces in improving the debt quality of the Chinese enterprise sector.<br />

100 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 100


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 27. Liabilities/debts by profitability <strong>and</strong> entry-exit status, 1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Amount of performing debt based on<br />

imputed profits (RMB billion)<br />

Exit 327 204 384 272 396 512 298<br />

New 311 248 503 429 418 780 483<br />

Stay 2,043 2,044 2,295 2,335 2,587 2,812 3,088 4,190<br />

Once 52 70 129 78 92 71<br />

Whole sample 2,370 2,611 2,997 3,239 3,490 3,834 4,237 4,673<br />

Amount of nonperforming debt based<br />

on imputed profits (RMB billion)<br />

Exit 157 116 193 200 154 174 92<br />

New 130 96 145 151 81 168 115<br />

Stay 757 826 881 971 990 848 803 936<br />

Once 23 34 54 20 25 27<br />

Whole sample 914 1,095 1,204 1,370 1,315 1,128 1,090 1,051<br />

Total liabilities (RMB billion)<br />

Exit 484 320 577 472 550 686 390<br />

New 441 344 648 580 499 948 598<br />

Stay 2,800 2,870 3,176 3,306 3,577 3,660 3,891 5,126<br />

Once 75 104 183 98 117 98<br />

Whole sample 3,284 3,706 4,201 4,609 4,805 4,962 5,327 5,724<br />

Nonperforming debt ratio based on<br />

imputed profits (percent)<br />

Exit 32.4 36.3 33.4 42.4 28.0 25.4 23.6<br />

New 29.5 27.9 22.4 26.0 16.2 17.7 19.2<br />

Stay 27.0 28.8 27.7 29.4 27.7 23.2 20.6 18.3<br />

Once 30.7 32.7 29.5 20.4 21.4 27.6<br />

Whole sample 27.8 29.5 28.7 29.7 27.4 22.7 20.5 18.4<br />

Note: “Exit” group enterprise was in sample at t 1 <strong>and</strong> t but not at t 1; “new” group enterprise was in sample at t <strong>and</strong> t 1<br />

but not at t 1; “stay” group enterprise was in sample at t 1, t, <strong>and</strong> t 1; “once” group enterprise was in sample at t, but not<br />

at t 1 or t 1.<br />

From table 27 it is clear that the NPD ratio for the “exit” group is much higher than<br />

that for the “new,” “stay,” <strong>and</strong> “once” groups. For example, in 1998 the NPD ratio<br />

for the “exit” group was 42.4 percent, close to twice the NPD ratio for the “new”<br />

group (22.4 percent) <strong>and</strong> much higher than that for the “stay” group (29.4 percent).<br />

The implication of the above evidence is that the dynamics of entry <strong>and</strong> exit is contributing<br />

signiªcantly to the fall in the NPD ratio for the sample. Clearly, the analysis<br />

in the previous sections underestimated the level of the NPD ratios. The number<br />

of bad ªrms exiting the sample, however, is more than the number of bad ªrms entering<br />

the sample for every one of the eight years. This means that the trend of declining<br />

NPD, as revealed in the previous sections, is still valid, although some bias<br />

<strong>and</strong> distortions exist in the level of estimated NPD. The rest of this section attempts<br />

to identify the size of the NPD ratio bias that resulted from the entry-exit dynamics<br />

of the sample enterprises.<br />

If the “exit” group of enterprises had remained in the sample while the same NPD<br />

ratio <strong>and</strong> the same amount of total debts were maintained, then the NPD ratio of the<br />

enlarged hypothetical sample would certainly have been pushed higher. Table 28 at-<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

101 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 101


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

tempts to estimate how much higher the NPD ratio of the enlarged hypothetical<br />

sample would have been if the “exit” group had stayed in the sample for one, two,<br />

or three years. The variables in table 28 are deªned as follows:<br />

R(t) NPD ratio for the original sample for period t, from row 4 of table 6.<br />

L(t) total liabilities or debts of the original sample for period t, from row 7 of table<br />

1.<br />

Rx(t) NPD ratio for the “exit” group for period t, from row 16 of table 27.<br />

Lx(t) total liabilities/debts for the “exit” group for period t, from row 11 of table<br />

27.<br />

R(t, T) NPD ratio for the hypothetically enlarged sample, with the original “exit”<br />

group remaining in the sample for T periods:<br />

R(t, T) [R(t) * L(t) Σ j Rx(t j) * Lx(t j)]/[L(t) Σ j Lx(t j)],<br />

where j 1, 2, . . . , T. dR(t, T) R(t, T) R(t), the difference, in percentage points,<br />

in the estimated NPD ratios between the enlarged hypothetic sample <strong>and</strong> the original<br />

sample.<br />

In table 28, rows 1–4 simply replicate results we have from previous tables, as noted<br />

above. Rows 5–10 construct the NPD ratio <strong>and</strong> the total debts of the “exit” group for<br />

the periods t 1, t 2, <strong>and</strong> t 3. These 10 rows of data are used to calculate the<br />

NPD ratio for the enlarged hypothetical sample in which the “exit” group of enterprises<br />

are retained for one, two, or three periods. The results of these calculations<br />

are shown in rows 11–13. The longer the “exit” group is retained in the enlarged<br />

sample, the higher the NPD ratio for the enlarged sample. Rows 14–16 show the<br />

percentage-point difference in the NPD ratio between the enlarged hypothetical<br />

sample (i.e., including the “exit” group) <strong>and</strong> the original sample. This is the estimated<br />

sample selection bias. As shown in table 28, on average, over 1998–2002, the<br />

NPD ratio would have increased about two percentage points if the “exit” group of<br />

enterprises had remained in the sample for three more years.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

As shown in row 16 of table 28, the increase in the NPD ratio in this counterfactual<br />

experiment is particularly signiªcant for the years 1999 to 2001, largely as a result of<br />

more active restructuring of SOEs during this period. We know that during the period<br />

from 1999 to 2000, Chinese authorities transferred RMB1.4 trillion in bad loans<br />

from the four big state-owned banks to four asset management companies to facilitate<br />

the bankruptcies <strong>and</strong> restructuring of SOEs. The exit of poor-performing enterprises<br />

<strong>and</strong> their debts from our sample was also very signiªcant around 1998. In<br />

fact, as shown in row 6 of table 27, from 1995 to 2000, RMB0.994 trillion in NPDs<br />

(based on the imputed-proªts method of this paper) exited from our sample,<br />

102 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 102


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table 28. Reduction of nonperforming debt ratio resulting from exit of poor-performing<br />

enterprises, 1995–2002<br />

Row Variable Definition of variable 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Average<br />

during<br />

1998–2002<br />

1 R(t) Nonperforming debt ratio for 27.8% 29.5% 28.7% 29.7% 27.4% 22.7% 20.5% 18.4% 23.7%<br />

original sample in t<br />

2 L(t) Total debts for original sample 3,286 3,707 4,201 4,610 4,805 4,963 5,329 5,722<br />

3 Rx(t) Nonperforming debt ratio for 32.4% 36.3% 33.4% 42.4% 28.0% 25.4% 23.6%<br />

“exit” group in t<br />

4 Lx(t) Total liabilities/debts for 484 320 577 472 550 686 390<br />

“exit” group in t<br />

5 Rx(t 1) Nonperforming debt ratio for 32.4% 36.3% 33.4% 42.4% 28.0% 25.4% 23.6% 30.6%<br />

“exit” group in t 1<br />

6 Lx(t 1) Total debts for “exit” group in<br />

484 320 577 472 550 686 390<br />

t 1<br />

7 Rx(t 2) Nonperforming debt ratio for<br />

32.4% 36.3% 33.4% 42.4% 28.0% 25.4% 33.1%<br />

“exit” group in t 2<br />

8 Lx(t 2) Total debts for “exit” group in<br />

484 320 577 472 550 686<br />

t 2<br />

9 Rx(t 3) Nonperforming debt ratio for<br />

32.4% 36.3% 33.4% 42.4% 28.0% 34.5%<br />

“exit” group in t 3<br />

10 Lx(t 3) Total debts for “exit” group in<br />

484 320 577 472 550<br />

t 3<br />

11 R(t, 1) Nonperforming debt ratio of<br />

29.9% 29.2% 30.1% 28.7% 23.3% 21.0% 18.7% 24.4%<br />

enlarged sample with “exit”<br />

group staying hypothetically<br />

for one period<br />

12 R(t, 2) Nonperforming debt ratio of<br />

29.5% 30.5% 29.2% 24.8% 21.6% 19.4% 25.1%<br />

enlarged sample with “exit”<br />

group staying hypothetically<br />

for two periods<br />

13 R(t, 3) Nonperforming debt ratio of<br />

30.7% 29.5% 25.5% 23.0% 20.0% 25.7%<br />

enlarged sample with “exit”<br />

group staying hypothetically<br />

for three periods<br />

14 dR(t, 1) dR(t, 1) R(t) 0.3% 0.5% 0.4% 1.3% 0.5% 0.6% 0.3% 0.6%<br />

15 dR(t, 2) dR(t, 2) R(t) 0.9% 0.8% 1.8% 2.0% 1.1% 1.0% 1.4%<br />

16 dR(t, 3) dR(t, 3) R(t) 0.9% 2.2% 2.8% 2.5% 1.7% 2.0%<br />

Note: Exit group enterprise was in sample at t 1 <strong>and</strong> t but not at t 1.<br />

amounting to about 70 percent of the bad loans carved out by the four asset management<br />

companies. The declining trend of NPD ratios observed in the sample during<br />

1995–2002 is clearly helped by the exit of these poor-performing enterprises <strong>and</strong><br />

their NPDs. But as shown in row 13 of table 28, even if the “exit” group of enterprises<br />

had been included in the sample, the estimated NPD ratio for the hypothetically<br />

enlarged sample would still have declined very signiªcantly, from 30.7 percent<br />

in 1998 to 20.0 percent in 2002, consistent with the trend we discovered in the previous<br />

sections.<br />

The NPDs of “exiting” enterprises will continue to burden China’s banks unless the<br />

banks can transfer the NPLs to China’s asset management companies (which have<br />

been established to manage NPLs). So it is important to examine the impact of exiting<br />

poor-performing ªrms on estimated NPD ratios. It is also important, however,<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

103 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 103


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

to keep in mind that past NPDs are sunk costs, <strong>and</strong> what matters the most for economic<br />

growth in China is the future trend of NPD ratios. Our NPD estimation<br />

method is more meaningful for projecting the future NPD trend because our sample<br />

consists of a truly dynamic group of the more active Chinese industrial enterprises,<br />

<strong>and</strong> these ªrms more accu<strong>rate</strong>ly represent the current state of the Chinese industrial<br />

sector.<br />

7. Implications for banking reform<br />

This paper investigates empirically the quality of debts in the most dynamic group<br />

of enterprises in China. We uncover a large amount of independent, consistent, <strong>and</strong><br />

statistically signiªcant micro-level evidence that shows that the quality of enterprise<br />

debts in China improved during 1995–2002, especially after 1998. Because of the<br />

transparency <strong>and</strong> scientiªc methods used in this research, the evidence looks much<br />

more convincing than the <strong>macroeconomic</strong> statistics announced by China’s ªnancial<br />

authorities.<br />

The fall in NPD ratios for our sample enterprises is brought about by the shift of<br />

ªnancial resources from SOEs to NSEs, improvement in the proªtability of SOEs<br />

<strong>and</strong> NSEs, <strong>and</strong> the exit of poor-performing enterprises from the sample of the large<br />

<strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises. Both enterprise restructuring <strong>and</strong> the timing<br />

of business cycles have contributed to the recent improvement in enterprise<br />

proªtability in China <strong>and</strong> the fall in NPD ratios. But the beneªts of reform dividends<br />

<strong>and</strong> business cycle timing could be uncertain in the future.<br />

China can continue, however, to beneªt from the shift of ªnancial resources from<br />

SOEs to better-performing NSEs, because the gaps in performance between the two<br />

are still very large. The gaps in proªtability across industries <strong>and</strong> regions in China<br />

are also large, showing the need for better risk management <strong>and</strong> more efªcient allocation<br />

of ªnancial resources. The analysis in this paper could contribute to better assessment<br />

of various risks relating to ownership, industry, <strong>and</strong> region.<br />

The rising share of ªnancial resources allocated to NSEs <strong>and</strong> the declining NPD ratios<br />

for all types of enterprises provide excellent opportunities for pushing banking<br />

reforms in China now. If China’s banks can establish good corpo<strong>rate</strong> governance<br />

<strong>and</strong> risk management, there seem to be enough good NSEs to lend to.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

Most of the major banks in China, however, are still state-owned. In light of the<br />

strong evidence that SOEs are performing much worse than NSEs, priorities for<br />

banking reform would seem to be the development of good private banks, the pri-<br />

104 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 104


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

vatization of state-owned banks, <strong>and</strong> the encouragement of more foreign or jointventure<br />

banks to establish themselves in China. If China fails to develop non-state<br />

banks, there is a high risk that it will continue to have high NPL ratios, even when<br />

its NPD ratio is falling as a result of the privatization of enterprises. This is because<br />

SOEs could create NPLs in spite of the good performance of China’s enterprise<br />

sector.<br />

Appendix 1. Data cleaning<br />

The NBS survey covers more than 20,000 large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises<br />

in China. It contains some observations that are unusable because of incomplete<br />

data reporting or the classiªcation of small enterprises that were considered<br />

large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized historically on the basis of their design production capacity.<br />

The classiªcation st<strong>and</strong>ard for the size of industrial enterprises was ªrst issued in<br />

April 1988 by several government agencies, including the State Planning Commission,<br />

National Bureau of Statistics, Ministry of Finance, Ministry of Labor, <strong>and</strong> State<br />

Economic Commission. The st<strong>and</strong>ard includes detailed speciªcations based on measurements<br />

of output quantity or capacity in technical-quantity terms instead of<br />

value terms. The st<strong>and</strong>ard is clearly a legacy of the centrally planned economy <strong>and</strong><br />

is being phased out at present. It now only applies to state-owned industrial enterprises.<br />

For private enterprises, the National Bureau of Statistics is using sales as the<br />

sole variable in determining enterprise size.<br />

In this study, observations that satisfy one or more of the following screening conditions<br />

for industrial enterprises are regarded as unusable, <strong>and</strong> consequently such enterprises<br />

are deleted from the usable sample:<br />

1. Net value of ªxed assets RMB100,000<br />

2. Intermediate inputs RMB100,000<br />

3. Number of employees 30<br />

4. Gross value of industrial inputs at current price RMB100,000<br />

5. Sales RMB100,000<br />

6. Total assets RMB100,000<br />

7. Total assets liquid assets 0<br />

8. Total assets gross ªxed assets 0<br />

9. Total assets net value of ªxed assets 0<br />

10.Accumulated depreciation current depreciation 0<br />

11. Missing data for total assets, number of employees, gross value of industrial output<br />

at current price, net value of ªxed assets, or sales<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

105 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 105


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

After the unusable observations are deleted, only about 5 percent or less of the sample<br />

enterprises have sales values less than RMB5 million. Tables A.1, A.2, <strong>and</strong> A.3<br />

show the distribution of usable <strong>and</strong> unusable observations in the sample by ownership,<br />

industry, <strong>and</strong> region, respectively. Because the unusable observations are<br />

evenly distributed across ownership, industry, <strong>and</strong> region, we believe that excluding<br />

them from the usable sample does not create much bias in our analysis.<br />

Table A.4 shows summary statistics for key size variables (i.e., sales, output, assets,<br />

liabilities, labor, <strong>and</strong> value-added) for the sample with the unusable observations removed.<br />

Table A.5 shows the same set of size variables at selected percentiles. Table<br />

A.6 examines the weight of the sample within the context of the Chinese economy.<br />

Clearly, the sample represents an important part of the Chinese economy, <strong>and</strong> this<br />

makes statistical analysis of the sample important <strong>and</strong> valuable for both<br />

<strong>policy</strong>makers <strong>and</strong> practitioners.<br />

Appendix 2. List of industry codes <strong>and</strong> the full industry names<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

[06] Coal mining <strong>and</strong> dressing<br />

[07] Petroleum <strong>and</strong> natural gas extraction<br />

[08] Ferrous metals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing<br />

[09] Nonferrous metals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing<br />

[10] Nonmetal minerals mining <strong>and</strong> dressing<br />

[12] Logging <strong>and</strong> transport of timber <strong>and</strong> bamboo<br />

[13] Food processing<br />

[14] Food production<br />

[15] Beverage production<br />

[16] Tobacco processing<br />

[17] Textile industry<br />

[18] Garments <strong>and</strong> other ªber products<br />

[19] Leather, furs, down, <strong>and</strong> related products<br />

[20] Timber, bamboo, cane, palm ªber <strong>and</strong> straw<br />

[21] Furniture manufacturing<br />

[22] Papermaking <strong>and</strong> paper products<br />

[23] Printing <strong>and</strong> record medium reproduction<br />

[24] Cultural, educational, <strong>and</strong> sports goods<br />

[25] Petroleum processing <strong>and</strong> coking<br />

[26] Raw chemical materials <strong>and</strong> chemicals<br />

[27] Medical <strong>and</strong> pharmaceutical products<br />

[28] Chemical ªber<br />

[29] Rubber products<br />

106 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 106


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

[30] Plastic products<br />

[31] Nonmetal mineral products<br />

[32] Smelting <strong>and</strong> pressing of ferrous metals<br />

[33] Smelting <strong>and</strong> pressing of nonferrous metals<br />

[34] Metal products<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery manufacturing<br />

[36] Special purposes equipment manufacturing<br />

[37] Transport equipment manufacturing<br />

[40] Electric equipment <strong>and</strong> machinery<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecom equipment<br />

[42] Instruments, cultural, <strong>and</strong> ofªce machinery<br />

[43] Other manufacturing<br />

[44] Electric power, steam, <strong>and</strong> hot water<br />

[45] Gas production <strong>and</strong> supply<br />

[46] Tap water production <strong>and</strong> supply<br />

Table A.1 Distribution of usable <strong>and</strong> unusable observations by ownership, 1995–2002<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

Data quality<br />

Poor<br />

Private 2 1 2 3 9 14 26 54<br />

Collective 60 72 93 66 58 77 86 89<br />

Mixed 23 24 39 73 82 145 178 158<br />

Foreign 41 67 64 43 42 65 65 98<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 31 36 34 28 43 59 60 89<br />

State-owned 307 525 583 901 538 626 674 615<br />

Total 464 725 815 1,114 772 986 1,089 1,103<br />

Poor (percent)<br />

Private 28.6 6.7 5.6 1.7 2.8 2.7 2.6 4.0<br />

Collective 1.5 1.7 2.2 1.8 1.7 2.6 3.5 4.0<br />

Mixed 1.8 1.7 1.9 2.4 2.2 3.2 3.1 2.5<br />

Foreign 3.9 4.9 4.0 2.7 2.1 3.1 2.4 3.2<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 3.2 3.1 2.7 1.9 2.7 3.7 2.6 3.4<br />

State-owned 2.0 3.4 3.9 6.7 4.8 6.3 7.7 7.9<br />

Total 2.0 3.1 3.4 4.8 3.5 4.5 4.7 4.7<br />

Good<br />

Private 5 14 34 176 307 498 958 1,302<br />

Collective 4,008 4,199 4,116 3,577 3,350 2,899 2,394 2,138<br />

Mixed 1,233 1,406 2,064 2,934 3,592 4,381 5,619 6,135<br />

Foreign 1,000 1,305 1,525 1,579 1,924 2,048 2,610 2,935<br />

Hong Kong, Macau, <strong>and</strong> Taiwan 936 1,115 1,222 1,454 1,524 1,552 2,211 2,495<br />

State-owned 15,361 14,935 14,350 12,573 10,766 9,360 8,106 7,215<br />

Total 22,543 22,974 23,311 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220<br />

Total<br />

Private 7 15 36 179 316 512 984 1,356<br />

Collective 4,068 4,271 4,209 3,643 3,408 2,976 2,480 2,227<br />

Mixed 1,256 1,430 2,103 3,007 3,674 4,526 5,797 6,293<br />

Foreign 1,041 1,372 1,589 1,622 1,966 2,113 2,675 3,033<br />

HK-M-Taiwan 967 1,151 1,256 1,482 1,567 1,611 2,271 2,584<br />

State-owned 15,668 15,460 14,933 13,474 11,304 9,986 8,780 7,830<br />

Total 23,007 23,699 24,126 23,407 22,235 21,724 22,987 23,323<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

107 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 107


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table A.2 Distribution of unusable observations by industry, 1995–2002 (percent)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[06] Coal mining 0.4 0.3 1.0 1.0 0.7 3.2 1.8 3.7<br />

[07] Petroleum extract 0.0 0.0 4.0 7.1 3.0 2.6 2.6 0.0<br />

[08] Ferrous mining 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 2.2 7.1 0.0<br />

[09] Nonferrous mining 3.0 2.5 2.5 3.7 2.3 2.9 3.7 3.3<br />

[10] Nonmetal mining 1.4 0.9 2.8 3.4 0.0 2.8 5.1 5.4<br />

[12] Timber logging 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.0 4.0 4.3 5.4<br />

[13] Food processing 2.3 2.7 3.7 5.0 3.6 5.4 6.9 6.5<br />

[14] Food production 3.6 6.6 7.3 5.9 3.9 5.8 5.4 5.7<br />

[15] Beverage 1.6 3.1 3.2 3.6 2.5 3.6 3.4 4.5<br />

[16] Tobacco 0.7 4.2 0.0 0.0 0.0 1.4 1.4 1.4<br />

[17] Textile 2.5 3.0 3.8 6.0 3.8 3.8 4.4 4.8<br />

[18] Garments 2.8 1.5 1.8 1.6 1.3 2.0 2.0 3.1<br />

[19] Leather 2.6 4.5 2.8 6.3 5.0 6.5 4.9 4.3<br />

[20] Timber 7.4 1.5 1.3 5.2 5.3 4.9 4.1 5.4<br />

[21] Furniture 3.1 5.6 1.3 3.1 2.7 1.4 2.3 2.3<br />

[22] Papermaking 2.6 3.3 3.0 6.7 4.4 6.1 5.1 4.6<br />

[23] Printing 1.1 1.3 2.5 1.3 2.3 1.6 2.3 1.6<br />

[24] Cultural 9.4 8.9 0.9 2.7 2.7 7.1 3.7 3.2<br />

[25] Petroleum processing 0.0 2.6 2.6 0.8 0.0 2.5 3.8 5.6<br />

[26] Raw chemicals 2.4 2.7 2.2 4.2 2.5 4.3 4.9 5.1<br />

[27] Medical 1.6 2.4 1.8 3.9 3.4 3.8 4.1 2.9<br />

[28] Chemical fiber 2.4 1.1 4.7 3.7 2.4 4.6 3.4 5.3<br />

[29] Rubber 4.7 3.4 3.4 4.4 3.2 3.1 4.2 6.1<br />

[30] Plastic 2.6 3.6 2.9 2.1 2.8 4.4 4.6 5.1<br />

[31] Nonmetal products 2.0 3.2 3.2 5.2 3.0 4.0 4.7 4.2<br />

[32] Pressing ferrous 0.4 3.5 3.2 8.5 2.6 5.4 6.8 5.7<br />

[33] Pressing nonferrous 1.1 2.3 1.4 2.2 3.2 1.9 3.0 2.8<br />

[34] Metal products 0.9 1.9 3.1 4.2 2.0 4.4 3.8 4.4<br />

[35] Ordinary machinery 0.5 1.0 1.9 2.2 1.8 2.6 2.4 2.6<br />

[36] Special equipment 0.9 1.7 1.3 1.9 2.1 2.8 3.2 3.8<br />

[37] Transport equipment 1.6 2.5 2.2 3.6 2.9 3.3 3.3 2.6<br />

[40] Electric equipment 1.8 2.6 1.9 3.1 1.7 3.4 2.5 3.8<br />

[41] Electronic <strong>and</strong> telecommunications 1.8 2.4 3.0 3.0 2.1 2.9 4.3 2.8<br />

[42] Instruments 0.6 1.6 1.3 4.4 2.1 2.8 3.9 5.1<br />

[43] Other manufacturing 3.0 4.2 3.8 2.8 2.1 3.7 3.8 5.9<br />

[44] Electric power 4.7 14.2 18.6 22.8 19.5 20.3 18.4 16.8<br />

[45] Gas production 2.9 2.9 7.6 4.7 7.1 6.2 9.8 4.8<br />

[46] Tap water 1.1 1.5 1.0 1.9 1.9 1.4 2.6 1.7<br />

Total 2.0 3.1 3.4 4.8 3.5 4.5 4.7 4.7<br />

Note: See appendix 2 for full industry names corresponding to industry codes.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

108 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 108


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table A.3 Distribution of unusable observations by region, 1995–2002 (percent)<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

[11] Beijing 4.6 3.0 2.6 4.4 5.9 9.5 3.9 4.1<br />

[12] Tianjin 4.4 5.9 13.9 13.1 9.3 18.2 18.5 22.3<br />

[13] Hebei 1.5 2.1 2.1 4.2 3.4 4.7 7.9 8.9<br />

[14] Shanxi 1.6 1.9 3.1 5.1 2.5 4.4 8.1 8.6<br />

[15] Inner Mongolia 1.1 5.1 7.1 7.6 7.7 9.1 9.1 9.6<br />

[21] Liaoning 2.3 3.2 2.9 8.1 2.0 2.6 4.4 4.3<br />

[22] Jilin 2.2 6.1 7.8 11.2 12.5 10.6 11.3 10.2<br />

[23] Heilongjiang 2.7 4.3 5.5 10.2 7.9 8.2 11.4 9.0<br />

[31] Shanghai 5.4 5.5 5.4 3.6 1.1 1.2 0.4 1.2<br />

[32] Jiangsu 0.6 0.6 1.3 0.9 0.8 1.0 0.8 1.0<br />

[33] Zhejiang 0.5 1.7 1.5 1.9 4.3 4.7 4.5 3.1<br />

[34] Anhui 0.8 1.2 0.4 3.7 1.8 2.7 3.5 3.6<br />

[35] Fujian 2.1 1.7 2.5 4.2 1.9 3.3 2.5 2.5<br />

[36] Jiangxi 1.6 1.9 1.7 5.6 4.8 8.2 4.4 5.3<br />

[37] Sh<strong>and</strong>ong 1.5 2.3 2.7 2.6 2.1 2.4 2.6 2.6<br />

[41] Henan 1.1 7.5 7.7 8.2 5.3 8.1 10.4 12.2<br />

[42] Hubei 2.6 3.3 3.6 5.7 3.2 4.0 6.1 5.0<br />

[43] Hunan 2.2 4.2 2.3 5.1 1.3 2.0 2.0 2.4<br />

[44] Guangdong 2.8 2.5 2.2 2.7 2.7 2.9 2.5 3.2<br />

[45] Guangxi 0.7 5.6 1.6 2.8 0.7 2.2 1.5 2.8<br />

[46] Hainan 18.1 10.7 3.5 8.1 5.8 7.6 10.9 7.8<br />

[50] Sichuan Chongqing 1.7 2.7 1.8 5.1 4.9 6.4 5.8 3.6<br />

[52] Guizhou 0.8 6.9 11.0 10.0 14.2 15.3 16.0 8.9<br />

[53] Yunnan 0.9 0.0 1.2 2.9 1.1 2.6 1.5 2.3<br />

[54] Tibet Qinghai Ningxia 0.0 0.6 2.7 6.2 2.4 0.6 4.4 2.8<br />

[61] Shaanxi 1.5 1.3 0.6 4.7 2.1 2.5 2.3 1.4<br />

[62] Gansu 1.4 1.0 6.9 7.4 8.7 9.2 8.8 10.3<br />

[65] Xinjiang 1.5 1.6 1.4 3.7 0.6 4.0 2.2 1.8<br />

Total 2.0 3.1 3.4 4.8 3.5 4.5 4.7 4.7<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

109 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 109


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table A.4 Summary statistics for sales, output, assets, liabilities, labor, <strong>and</strong> value-added for<br />

the cleaned sample (RMB million)<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

Number of<br />

enterprises<br />

Mean<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviation<br />

Median<br />

Minimum<br />

Maximum<br />

Sales<br />

1995 22,543 136 630 45 0.109 39,930 3,071,530<br />

1996 22,974 144 681 44 0.100 43,738 3,308,847<br />

1997 22,957 155 761 44 0.103 50,760 3,560,393<br />

1998 22,293 163 772 44 0.101 50,611 3,629,511<br />

1999 21,463 188 871 50 0.107 61,211 4,032,923<br />

2000 20,738 234 1,219 57 0.112 92,279 4,843,396<br />

2001 21,898 257 1,213 63 0.109 78,984 5,624,020<br />

2002 22,220 292 1,329 69 0.101 72,843 6,495,292<br />

Total 177,086 195 966 51 0.100 92,279 34,565,913<br />

Gross value of<br />

industrial output<br />

1995 22,543 136 616 46 0.101 40,214 3,073,253<br />

1996 22,974 147 685 48 0.130 44,349 3,378,619<br />

1997 22,957 157 762 48 0.113 51,693 3,607,608<br />

1998 22,293 165 767 48 0.100 51,646 3,681,858<br />

1999 21,463 190 874 54 0.106 63,918 4,068,673<br />

2000 20,738 230 1,171 61 0.150 92,617 4,775,290<br />

2001 21,898 255 1,177 67 0.140 79,422 5,573,291<br />

2002 22,220 288 1,275 71 0.100 73,633 6,388,539<br />

Total 177,086 195 943 54 0.100 92,617 34,547,132<br />

Total assets<br />

1995 22,543 229 1,047 79 0.829 65,931 5,161,722<br />

1996 22,974 256 1,199 85 0.831 75,366 5,872,942<br />

1997 22,957 291 1,388 92 0.701 83,704 6,690,180<br />

1998 22,293 329 1,522 99 0.701 90,322 7,323,630<br />

1999 21,463 369 1,684 105 1.350 91,485 7,918,937<br />

2000 20,738 397 1,763 111 1.770 85,791 8,239,931<br />

2001 21,898 420 1,846 113 0.741 86,018 9,196,855<br />

2002 22,220 446 1,882 115 0.835 85,809 9,909,926<br />

Total 177,086 341 1,564 98 0.701 91,485 60,314,123<br />

Total liabilities<br />

1995 22,543 146 595 56 0.028 29,785 3,285,112<br />

1996 22,974 161 658 60 0.016 27,652 3,706,920<br />

1997 22,957 183 788 64 0.016 31,269 4,201,084<br />

1998 22,293 207 859 69 0.098 33,133 4,609,115<br />

1999 21,463 224 895 71 0.022 32,958 4,804,740<br />

2000 20,738 239 957 74 0.010 46,409 4,962,981<br />

2001 21,898 243 908 72 0.001 33,647 5,328,350<br />

2002 22,220 258 990 71 0.016 43,050 5,723,794<br />

Total 177,086 207 840 66 0.001 46,409 36,622,096<br />

Number of employees<br />

1995 22,543 1,696 5,215 877 30 254,078 38,223,099<br />

1996 22,974 1,633 4,908 823 30 197,048 37,513,117<br />

1997 22,957 1,593 4,719 793 30 193,076 36,581,069<br />

1998 22,293 1,502 4,482 715 30 193,110 33,490,764<br />

1999 21,463 1,428 4,401 654 30 194,410 30,656,548<br />

2000 20,738 1,361 3,947 620 30 161,654 28,225,561<br />

2001 21,898 1,237 3,599 560 30 147,722 27,079,491<br />

2002 22,220 1,189 3,560 520 30 137,962 26,426,284<br />

Total 177,086 1,458 4,404 701 30 254,078 258,195,933<br />

Reported value-added<br />

1995 22,543 43 332 11 424 32,912 958,256<br />

1996 22,974 44 348 11 3,241 34,809 1,016,728<br />

1997 22,957 47 382 12 6,738 39,565 1,080,121<br />

1998 22,293 51 398 12 5,939 41,525 1,131,106<br />

1999 21,463 60 479 14 1,954 53,645 1,288,589<br />

2000 20,738 73 690 16 12,140 79,063 1,520,978<br />

2001 21,898 80 660 18 1,796 78,355 1,741,547<br />

2002 22,220 91 652 20 2,339 72,057 2,012,908<br />

Total 177,086 61 510 14 12,140 79,063 10,750,232<br />

Sum<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

110 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 110


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

Table A.5 Size of sales, output, assets, liabilities, labor, <strong>and</strong> value-added at selected<br />

percentiles for the cleaned sample (RMB million)<br />

Percentiles<br />

5 10 25 50 75 90 95<br />

Sales<br />

1995 6 10 20 45 101 233 418<br />

1996 5 9 19 44 102 245 438<br />

1997 4 8 19 44 105 264 488<br />

1998 4 7 18 44 107 286 530<br />

1999 6 9 21 50 125 325 614<br />

2000 6 10 23 57 146 387 739<br />

2001 6 11 25 63 162 444 838<br />

2002 6 11 27 69 181 505 983<br />

Gross value of industrial output<br />

1995 7 10 22 46 104 236 403<br />

1996 6 10 21 48 110 250 440<br />

1997 5 9 21 48 112 266 489<br />

1998 5 9 20 48 115 288 536<br />

1999 7 11 24 54 131 333 606<br />

2000 6 11 25 61 151 388 730<br />

2001 7 12 27 67 169 444 836<br />

2002 7 12 29 71 186 505 956<br />

Total assets<br />

1995 22 28 44 79 167 378 676<br />

1996 23 29 46 85 180 414 745<br />

1997 22 29 48 92 198 474 888<br />

1998 23 30 50 99 218 538 1,007<br />

1999 24 32 54 105 239 603 1,144<br />

2000 23 31 54 111 259 672 1,304<br />

2001 22 31 54 113 271 725 1,445<br />

2002 21 30 54 115 282 775 1,589<br />

Total liabilities<br />

1995 12 17 29 56 115 245 424<br />

1996 12 18 31 60 125 268 471<br />

1997 12 18 33 64 137 301 542<br />

1998 12 19 34 69 151 345 641<br />

1999 12 18 35 71 160 381 709<br />

2000 11 18 35 74 169 412 784<br />

2001 9 16 32 72 170 429 848<br />

2002 9 15 31 71 176 459 910<br />

Number of employees<br />

1995 211 306 520 877 1,515 2,858 4,631<br />

1996 186 271 475 823 1,457 2,806 4,584<br />

1997 168 248 445 793 1,429 2,767 4,595<br />

1998 141 208 388 715 1,340 2,656 4,429<br />

1999 126 187 348 654 1,257 2,566 4,258<br />

2000 116 173 323 620 1,208 2,497 4,143<br />

2001 103 150 288 560 1,129 2,332 3,815<br />

2002 92 134 260 520 1,079 2,257 3,778<br />

Reported value-added<br />

1995 2 1 4 11 26 64 121<br />

1996 2 0 4 11 29 69 131<br />

1997 2 0 4 12 30 74 141<br />

1998 2 1 4 12 31 80 159<br />

1999 0 2 5 14 37 95 183<br />

2000 0 2 6 16 43 115 215<br />

2001 1 2 7 18 49 131 247<br />

2002 0 2 7 20 54 147 289<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

111 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 111


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

Table A.6 Weights of sample enterprises in Chinese economy<br />

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002<br />

(1) Number of enterprises in sample 22,543 22,974 23,311 22,293 21,463 20,738 21,898 22,220<br />

165,080 162,033 162,885 171,256 181,557<br />

(2) Number of all industrial state-owned enterprises plus non-state<br />

industrial enterprises with annual sales above RMB5 million<br />

(3) Reported value added for all enterprises in sample (RMB billion) 958 1,017 1,080 1,131 1,289 1,521 1,742 2,013<br />

(4) Total industrial value added in China (RMB billion) 2,472 2,908 3,241 3,339 3,509 3,905 4,238 4,654<br />

(3)/(4) Sample value added/China’s industrial value added 38.8% 35.0% 33.3% 33.9% 36.7% 39.0% 41.1% 43.3%<br />

(5) China’s GDP (RMB billion) 5,848 6,789 7,446 7,835 8,207 8,947 9,731 10,479<br />

(3)/(5) Sample value added/China’s GDP 16.4% 15.0% 14.5% 14.4% 15.7% 17.0% 17.9% 19.2%<br />

(6) Number of employees for all enterprises in the sample (million) 38 38 37 34 31 28 27 26<br />

(7) Number of employees in all industrial enterprises (million) 157 162 166 166 164 162 163 158<br />

(6)/(7) Sample employment/China’s industrial employment 24.4% 23.1% 22.1% 20.2% 18.7% 17.4% 16.6% 16.7%<br />

(8) Urban employees in China (million) 191 198 202 216 224 232 239 248<br />

(6)/(8) Sample employment/China’s urban employment 20.0% 18.9% 18.1% 15.5% 13.7% 12.2% 11.3% 10.7%<br />

(9) Total employment in China (million) 679 689 696 706 714 721 730 737<br />

(6)/(9) Sample employment/China’s employment 5.6% 5.4% 5.3% 4.7% 4.3% 3.9% 3.7% 3.6%<br />

(7)/(9) China’s industrial employment/China’s employment 23.0% 23.5% 23.8% 23.5% 23.0% 22.5% 22.3% 21.4%<br />

(10) Total liabilities for all enterprises in sample (RMB billion) 3,286 3,707 4,201 4,610 4,805 4,963 5,329 5,722<br />

(11) Total loans in China (RMB billion) 5,054 6,116 7,491 8,652 9,373 9,937 11,231 13,129<br />

(10)/(11) Sample total liabilities/Total loans in China (%) 65.0% 60.6% 56.1% 53.3% 51.3% 49.9% 47.4% 43.6%<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

112 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 112


Nonperforming Debts in Chinese Enterprises<br />

References<br />

Anderson, Jonathan. 2005. How to Think about China (Part 3): Which Way Out for the Banking<br />

System? Asian Economic Perspectives, 9 May. UBS Investment Research.<br />

Cai, Hongbin, Qiao Liu, <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao. 2005. Does Competition Encourage Unethical Behavior?<br />

The Case of Corpo<strong>rate</strong> Proªt Hiding in China. Hong Kong Institute of Economics <strong>and</strong><br />

Business St<strong>rate</strong>gy Working Paper no. 1126. Hong Kong: The University of Hong Kong.<br />

China Banking Regulatory Commission (CBRC). Statistics. Available at http://www.cbrc<br />

.gov.cn<br />

Liu, Qiao, <strong>and</strong> Geng Xiao. 2004. Look Who Are Disguising Proªts: An Application to Chinese<br />

Industrial Firms. Hong Kong Institute of Economics <strong>and</strong> Business St<strong>rate</strong>gy Working Paper no.<br />

1095. Hong Kong: The University of Hong Kong.<br />

Xiao, Geng. 2005. What Is Special about Enterprise Performance in North-East People’s Republic<br />

of China? Dynamics of Privatization, Proªtability <strong>and</strong> Productivity during the Reform Era.<br />

Hong Kong Institute of Economics <strong>and</strong> Business St<strong>rate</strong>gy Working Paper no. 1133. Hong Kong:<br />

The University of Hong Kong.<br />

Xiao, Geng, <strong>and</strong> Zhengge Tu. 2005. China’s Industrial Productivity Revolution: A Stochastic<br />

Frontier Production Function Analysis of China’s Large <strong>and</strong> Medium-Sized Industrial Enterprises<br />

during 1995–2002. Paper presented at the Western Economic Association International<br />

<strong>and</strong> Hong Kong Economic Association conference, 15 January, Hong Kong.<br />

1 LINE SHORT<br />

REGULAR<br />

1 LINE LONG<br />

113 Asian Economic Papers<br />

Asian Economic Papers (ASEP) 4:3<br />

Job No. 1055<br />

page 113


The economic challenges ahead for China<br />

By Xiao Geng, China Daily, September 8, 2010<br />

China's key <strong>macroeconomic</strong> challenge over the next two decades is to determine how to manage<br />

its exchange, interest <strong>and</strong> inflation <strong>rate</strong>s to facilitate sustainable, stable <strong>and</strong> efficient economic<br />

growth as the Western economies shrink in size relative to emerging market economies.<br />

To appreciate the magnitude of this challenge, one must realize that China's high economic growth<br />

<strong>rate</strong> in the past 30 years has largely been a story of rapid productivity growth <strong>and</strong> catching up.<br />

This is likely to continue for the next two decades as it continues to implement market-oriented<br />

reform alongside rapid industrialization <strong>and</strong> urbanization.<br />

In this context, the price of China's non-tradable goods - such as wages for unskilled labor <strong>and</strong><br />

property prices - is likely to continue to rise compared with the prices of tradable goods, which are<br />

set by global markets. In the next two decades, China's price levels will gradually but steadily<br />

converge toward those in the United States through structural inflation or structural revaluation of<br />

the yuan - or both.<br />

Since the inflation <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> currency revaluation, necessarily associated with productivity catch-up,<br />

can cause distortions, shocks <strong>and</strong> income redistribution, the critical challenge for Chinese<br />

<strong>policy</strong>makers is to mitigate any potential dislocation created in the <strong>adjustment</strong> process.<br />

There are two key policies that China can pursue.<br />

First, when structural inflation emerges, it would be critical for China to raise nominal interest<br />

<strong>rate</strong>s. This will avoid the asset bubbles caused by negative real interest <strong>rate</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> will protect the<br />

value of bank deposits held by low-income households which cannot afford to hedge against<br />

structural inflation by investing or speculating in property markets.<br />

By way of example, China's urban residential real estate prices have risen on average by about 9<br />

percent a year since 1991, but the mortgage <strong>rate</strong> is only about 5 percent <strong>and</strong> the one-year<br />

fixed-deposit <strong>rate</strong> is only about 2 percent. Such structural inflation in property <strong>and</strong> low mortgage<br />

<strong>and</strong> deposit <strong>rate</strong>s imply a very serious problem of negative real interest <strong>rate</strong>s in terms of property<br />

investment. These negative real interest <strong>rate</strong>s are at the root of China's property bubbles <strong>and</strong><br />

associated huge income redistribution from depositors (usually poor) to mortgage holders (usually<br />

the rich).<br />

If China cannot maintain a positive real interest <strong>rate</strong>, the boom <strong>and</strong> bust cycles in its property<br />

sector are likely to continue, leading to serious inefficiency in investment <strong>and</strong> social instability.<br />

Conversely, if China does raise interest <strong>rate</strong>s to a level higher than its structural inflation, it will<br />

need adequate capital control mechanisms to deal with speculative capital inflows.<br />

But this problem is solvable, <strong>and</strong> brings us to the second <strong>policy</strong> point; China must permit


easonable structural inflation.<br />

Specifically, China need not rely solely on nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> flexibility to facilitate its rising<br />

price levels. Instead, it can tole<strong>rate</strong> higher structural inflation <strong>and</strong> the associated real revaluation of<br />

the yuan.<br />

In fact, by allowing for reasonable structural inflation, China can implement a flexible exchange<br />

<strong>rate</strong> regime more easily. With inflation, there will be potential for the currency to devalue when<br />

inflation runs beyond productivity growth.<br />

Furthermore, a mixture of inflation <strong>and</strong> nominal appreciation would create a regime in which the<br />

market exchange <strong>rate</strong>s could go up or down. This would reduce the incentive for massive<br />

speculative holdings of the yuan. Such speculative holdings have become a key driver of China's<br />

foreign exchange reserve bubble.<br />

Since the yuan's peg to a currency or basket of currencies has a stabilizing function, when China<br />

pegs the yuan to the US dollar, it need not worry much about runaway inflation. If the inflation<br />

<strong>rate</strong> goes beyond China's underlying productivity growth, the market will expect the yuan to<br />

depreciate, which will lead to capital outflows <strong>and</strong> the tightening of money supply.<br />

There is one final point to be made.<br />

While the debate over the yuan's exchange <strong>rate</strong> is often framed in terms of global trade imbalances,<br />

the exchange <strong>rate</strong> is a price not just for trade but for assets. In fact, asset markets are much larger<br />

than trade markets. Thus, maintaining stable exchange <strong>rate</strong>s to facilitate stable <strong>and</strong> efficient capital<br />

flows between the US <strong>and</strong> China is more important than using the exchange <strong>rate</strong> to correct global<br />

trade imbalances. In any case, using trade policies may be a more productive way of correcting<br />

China's trade imbalances.<br />

In sum, given China's huge foreign exchange reserves, it will be easy for it to defend the yuan's<br />

peg <strong>and</strong> avoid runaway inflation. And, as soon as China starts tolerating reasonable structural<br />

inflation <strong>and</strong> the associated increase in its real exchange <strong>rate</strong>, the pressure for nominal<br />

reevaluation of the yuan will be reduced.<br />

The author is director of <strong>Columbia</strong> University Global Center for East Asia based in Beijing <strong>and</strong> a<br />

non-resident senior fellow at the John L. Thornton China Center of Brookings Institution.


Alternatives to revaluating the yuan<br />

http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/opinion/2010-03/25/content_9638821.htm<br />

Page 1 of 3<br />

2010/3/26<br />

Op-Ed Contributors<br />

Alternatives to revaluating the yuan<br />

By Xiao Geng (China Daily)<br />

Updated: 2010-03-25 07:48<br />

Editor's note: According to the author, it’s not the appropriate time to revaluate yuan in<br />

consideration of national interests of both US <strong>and</strong> China. But he suggests some<br />

structural <strong>and</strong> institutional reforms as alternative options.<br />

The debate on how to correct the trade imbalance between the United States <strong>and</strong> China is<br />

focused on increase: How to increase US exports <strong>and</strong> savings <strong>and</strong> how to increase Chinese<br />

imports <strong>and</strong> consumption.<br />

A big part of the debate, especially in the US, is focused on China's currency, which US leaders<br />

allege is undervalued. The Americans want China to revalue the yuan considerably in the hope<br />

that it would lead to an increase in US exports <strong>and</strong> employment.<br />

Chinese leaders differ. They regard the US pressure to revaluate the yuan <strong>and</strong> Washington's<br />

protectionist measures as unfair <strong>and</strong> detrimental to China's development. They place emphasis<br />

upon structural <strong>and</strong> institutional reform to increase Chinese consumption <strong>and</strong> make domestic<br />

investment more efficient.<br />

Related readings:<br />

Tagging the yuan as a scapegoat is<br />

unfair<br />

Yuan revaluation talk heats up<br />

Raise yuan at the right time<br />

industrialization, low national debt <strong>and</strong> low fiscal deficits.<br />

Why is there such a considerable gap between<br />

Chinese <strong>and</strong> US views?<br />

The US dem<strong>and</strong> for the revaluation of the yuan is<br />

based upon its short-term concern over China's large<br />

current account surplus <strong>and</strong> long-term worry over<br />

China's high growth, rapid urbanization <strong>and</strong><br />

China, on its part, is worried that a revaluated yuan or a premature end to its link with the US<br />

dollar would cause financial instability through speculative capital inflow, asset bubbles <strong>and</strong><br />

nominal shocks to employment <strong>and</strong> business in its exports sector. China fears that a currency<br />

revaluation could destabilize capital inflows <strong>and</strong> discourage private Chinese firms <strong>and</strong> financial<br />

institutions from buying dollar assets, especially if their values could continually to fall in yuan<br />

terms.<br />

Beijing has not forgotten how the large increase in the value of the Japanese yen brought about<br />

by the 1985 Plaza Accord created massive asset bubbles, which burst in 1989 <strong>and</strong> led to a two<br />

decade-long deflation without eliminating Japan's trade surplus.<br />

But a nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>adjustment</strong> is not China's only tool for correcting trade imbalances.<br />

If China pegs the yuan to the dollar, it can still use inflation to achieve a rapid increase in its price<br />

level relative to that in the US, or a real revaluation of the yuan against the dollar. Relative price<br />

levels between economies tend to take into account the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> adjust price<br />

levels for the gap in inflation <strong>rate</strong>s between two economies.<br />

Because of these two factors the Chinese approach to exchange <strong>rate</strong> stability thus far has<br />

focused on inflation first <strong>and</strong> appreciation second. This puts priority on creating employment,<br />

increasing wages <strong>and</strong> productivity, <strong>and</strong> price liberalization rather than addressing trade<br />

imbalances through <strong>adjustment</strong>s of the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

Given that the Chinese approach is likely to remain constant, it is important to consider some<br />

alternative <strong>policy</strong> options, particularly certain structural <strong>and</strong> institutional reforms.<br />

First, to reduce savings <strong>and</strong> inefficient investment, China needs to privatize <strong>and</strong> deregulate large<br />

State-owned enterprises (SOEs). China's savings <strong>rate</strong> reached the high of about 55 percent of<br />

GDP in 2007-2008, with a current account surplus of about 10 percent of GDP. Corpo<strong>rate</strong><br />

savings amount to about half of the national savings, <strong>and</strong> a major contributing factor is the<br />

savings of China's SOEs.


Alternatives to revaluating the yuan<br />

http://www.chinadaily.com.cn/opinion/2010-03/25/content_9638821.htm<br />

Page 2 of 3<br />

2010/3/26<br />

The SOEs are not allowed to pay high salaries to their employees <strong>and</strong> do not distribute<br />

dividends, <strong>and</strong> they do not gene<strong>rate</strong> purchasing power when the prices of their shares increase.<br />

This has created huge capital gains with no wealth effects on consumption. In addition, the highsavings<br />

of SOEs are often invested in overcapacity sectors.<br />

Household income still accounts for only 35 percent of China's national income, <strong>and</strong> the country<br />

will not be able to significantly raise the wages <strong>and</strong> productivity of its workforce in the near<br />

future. To improve domestic consumption, therefore, China must create an investment<br />

environment conducive to investment in sectors with large domestic consumption potential. In<br />

sum, investment at present is the most important variable for eliminating China's current account<br />

surplus, <strong>and</strong> for absorbing its savings internally.<br />

Especially now, it is important that investments be made more efficiently. In the past few years<br />

cheap money, or a low interest <strong>rate</strong>, has often led to inefficient investment in China's exports<br />

manufacturing sector, driving down prices of "made in China" products. Since the US' current<br />

zero interest <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong> is likely to bring capital flows into China in the hope of higher investment<br />

return, the current availability of cheap money is likely to continue. Because of this it is important<br />

that China improve its capital control mechanisms to allow orderly cross-border capital flows for<br />

more efficient investments with higher returns both domestically <strong>and</strong> internationally, while limiting<br />

the speculative flow of capital <strong>and</strong> inefficient investments.<br />

Another overlooked problem contributing to the global imbalance is factor price distortion in the<br />

Chinese economy. This must be addressed if the global economy is to be righted. Price<br />

distortions are caused by a number of factors, including local governments' offering of cheap<br />

l<strong>and</strong> as part of efforts to attract foreign invested enterprises, weak property rights, rudimentary<br />

carbon-emission st<strong>and</strong>ards, weak enforcement of environmental protection laws, <strong>and</strong> a lack of a<br />

social safety net, which makes the cost of labor low now, but has hidden social liabilities for the<br />

future.<br />

Given the huge potential of cross-border investment <strong>and</strong> debt financing between the US <strong>and</strong><br />

China, a stable yuan-dollar exchange <strong>rate</strong> suits both countries' long-term national interests. And<br />

in the long-term, certainly after 2020 <strong>and</strong> perhaps between 2025 <strong>and</strong> 2035, the yuan is likely to<br />

become a fully convertible currency. But for that to happen, the Chinese economy must first<br />

complete its structural <strong>and</strong> institutional transformation into a fully modernized market economy<br />

with a more democratic political system. Until then, the US <strong>and</strong> China should look for long-term<br />

<strong>policy</strong> options that are realistic <strong>and</strong> beneficial to both countries.<br />

The author is director of the Brookings-Tsinghua Center for Public Policy in Beijing <strong>and</strong> senior<br />

fellow of the Brookings Institution in Washington DC.


Wall Street Journal Asia February 9, 2010<br />

Geng Xiao: Beijing's Property-Price Dilemma<br />

Bolder action—including increasing the interest <strong>rate</strong> on deposits—is needed to keep a bubble<br />

from forming.<br />

By GENG XIAO<br />

Average prices for urban residential property in China have increased to $523 per square meter<br />

($48.59 per square foot) in 2008 from $111 in 1991, or about 9% annually. Throughout this<br />

period, there have been warnings that sustained investment <strong>and</strong> speculation could lead to a<br />

boom <strong>and</strong> bust—especially given uncertain government <strong>policy</strong>. But before <strong>policy</strong> makers can fix<br />

the problem, they have to underst<strong>and</strong> what has gone wrong.<br />

In the long run, China's economic growth will inevitably drive prices higher. A property's value is<br />

the present discounted value of the rents it can gene<strong>rate</strong> in the future. Since rents are impossible<br />

to predict with certainty, markets guess based on assumptions about future economic<br />

development. The urbanization <strong>rate</strong>—one proxy for China's level of productivity since industrial<br />

activity is concent<strong>rate</strong>d in cities—is only around 46% now, so productivity growth will likely<br />

continue for another decade or more.<br />

Inflation expectations are another factor pushing prices higher. Investors view property as a<br />

hedge against rising prices, so the worse inflation expectations are, the more investors will pay<br />

for "insurance." However, this dem<strong>and</strong> drives property prices beyond the inflation trend if supply<br />

cannot keep pace with dem<strong>and</strong>. Policy makers have contributed to that excess dem<strong>and</strong> by<br />

keeping bank deposit <strong>rate</strong>s near zero, which has made property a better outlet for household<br />

savings for the past two decades. The situation will worsen if the central bank fails to raise<br />

deposit interest <strong>rate</strong>s fast enough if inflation picks up.<br />

Finally, actual <strong>and</strong> expected currency appreciation has encouraged overseas Chinese to bet on<br />

property in major mainl<strong>and</strong> cities. Not only do these properties seem to be on an upward trend,<br />

but yuan appreciation further boosts returns in dollar terms. Real estate-related investment<br />

accounted for 10% to 15% of China's foreign direct investment between 2006 <strong>and</strong> 2009. The<br />

ownership of high-end residential real estate by foreigners <strong>and</strong> overseas Chinese in big cities was<br />

around 20%, by some estimates.<br />

Preventing a property bubble will be difficult in the face of these trends. When the government<br />

tried to control the real-estate boom around 2005, it restricted both high-end property supply<br />

<strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>. The State Council asked all new residential development projects in May 2006 to<br />

allocate 70% of their floor space to flats smaller than 90 square meters to reduce the number of<br />

luxury flats. In July 2006, it also restricted the investment on residential property by foreign<br />

investors <strong>and</strong> overseas Chinese, allowing them to buy only one property to live in themselves.


But total dem<strong>and</strong> remained strong <strong>and</strong> pushed up prices. Reducing supply is easier than cutting<br />

market dem<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Efforts to boost supply at the lower end of the property spectrum might help. High-end property<br />

is concent<strong>rate</strong>d only in major cities such as Shenzhen, Shanghai <strong>and</strong> Beijing. These cities have<br />

relatively high per-capita income, rapidly modernizing city infrastructure <strong>and</strong> particularly large<br />

concentrations of non-local <strong>and</strong> cash-rich residents <strong>and</strong> enterprises. The price for luxury property<br />

in these cities is high compared to the incomes of local residents, but is still 30% to 50% below<br />

those in cities such as Hong Kong, Tokyo, London <strong>and</strong> New York. The convergence of prices for<br />

high-end residential <strong>and</strong> commercial property among these cities means local residents with<br />

much lower wages can no longer afford to buy a decent home.<br />

Few developers, however, are enthusiastic about building low-price housing without heavy<br />

subsidies. So central <strong>and</strong> local governments have subsidized lending <strong>rate</strong>s, rolled out<br />

administrative controls <strong>and</strong> tax rules <strong>and</strong> lowered down-payment requirements while increasing<br />

taxes on luxury development. The goal is to shift construction away from bubble-prone, high-end<br />

projects. Though these policies create some cases of inefficiency, corruption <strong>and</strong> uncertainty<br />

about future property prices, recently they have started to cool down property markets.<br />

Yet that alone will not be enough to prevent a serious bubble. Investors <strong>and</strong> speculators are still<br />

betting on an upward trend in property prices. They know neither the central nor local<br />

governments want a collapse of property markets; about one-third of local government revenues<br />

come from l<strong>and</strong> sales, <strong>and</strong> property development is regarded as a pillar of the economy. Recent<br />

macro statistics also reflect a high probability that consumer-price inflation will be as high as 5%<br />

in coming years. Moreover, given the Federal Reserve's zero interest <strong>rate</strong> <strong>policy</strong>, Chinese<br />

authorities are likely to be cautious in raising their interest <strong>rate</strong> or the value of yuan, to avoid<br />

attracting speculative inflows of overseas money. This means China is likely to experience a low<br />

or even negative real interest <strong>rate</strong> for the next few years, reinforcing property's appeal as an<br />

investment.<br />

Policy makers can't put off dealing with the drivers for property dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the low interest <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

Authorities need to balance strong domestic dem<strong>and</strong>-driven growth fueled by cheaper credit <strong>and</strong><br />

potential property, <strong>and</strong> stock market bubbles if credit becomes too cheap. The key is to raise the<br />

interest <strong>rate</strong> to deter domestic speculative forces while managing cross-border capital flows so<br />

they are invested in more efficient projects outside property speculation <strong>and</strong> stock markets.<br />

Mr. Xiao is Senior Fellow at the Brookings Institution <strong>and</strong> Director of the Brookings-Tsinghua<br />

Center in Beijing.


Inflation First, Appreciation Second:<br />

China’s Practical Choice<br />

Xiao Geng Brookings Website July 30, 2007<br />

Starting in July 2005, the RMB was de-linked from the dollar <strong>and</strong> has since been under a<br />

managed float with reference to a basket of currencies. However, from July 2005 to March<br />

2007, the RMB appreciated only about 7%. In particular, China’s global current account<br />

surplus in 2006 jumped to a record high of $184 billion, or about 9% of GDP. As a result,<br />

China’s foreign exchange reserves have reached $1.07 trillion, the largest in the world. China<br />

has also become the second-largest holder of U.S. bonds.<br />

More Related Content »<br />

The rapid rise in China’s global current account surplus <strong>and</strong> the slow appreciation of the RMB<br />

has led to a strong Washington consensus: China should be pressed hard to raise the value of<br />

its currency so as to reduce its global current account surplus as well as its current account<br />

surplus with the United States. In Congressional hearings on 28 March 2007, Institute for<br />

International Economics scholar Morris Goldstein held that China’s currency is now grossly<br />

under-valued on the order of 40 percent against the US dollar, saying that, “China should<br />

deliver right away a meaningful‘down payment’of a 10-15 percent appreciation of the RMB<br />

from its current level.”<br />

In my view, the current single-minded focus on the RMB exchange <strong>rate</strong> by Washington elites is<br />

unlikely to be helpful in addressing the imbalances of China’s trading patterns.<br />

Barriers to China’s Fixable Rate Adjustment<br />

On the issues of China’s <strong>rate</strong> <strong>and</strong> global imbalance, China, the U.S., <strong>and</strong> the world can reach a<br />

win-win approach to resolve the issues, but that is built on the basis of a mutual underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

of difficulties the other party faces <strong>and</strong> mutual assistance. China currently faces<br />

unprecedented challenges <strong>and</strong> opportunities not entirely dissimilar to those of post-war<br />

reconstruction in Europe. Without the help <strong>and</strong> cooperation of the U.S. <strong>and</strong> other developed<br />

nations, China is unlikely to be able to h<strong>and</strong>le this crucial step in its economic, social <strong>and</strong><br />

political modernization.<br />

The special phenomenon, the coexistence of surplus labor <strong>and</strong> surplus capital, appears in<br />

China <strong>and</strong> other Asia countries. China’s main challenge today is to develop<br />

smoothly-functioning financial, planning, <strong>and</strong> regulatory systems that can employ the<br />

remaining rural surplus labor <strong>and</strong> surplus capital. These surpluses now show up now as<br />

China’s sustained current account surplus <strong>and</strong> rising foreign exchange reserves, <strong>and</strong> instead<br />

should be utilized in an efficient, harmonious, <strong>and</strong> environmentally-friendly way.


In China, hidden transaction cost has been the single most important barrier to national growth,<br />

development <strong>and</strong> prosperity before <strong>and</strong> after the advent of market-oriented reforms. Low<br />

wage is neither the single factor nor even the most important factor pushing the<br />

advance of China’s export competitiveness. No countries in the world worried about<br />

China’s export competitiveness before 1979, even though at that time the average wage for<br />

factory workers was only 24 dollars a month (under the official exchange <strong>rate</strong> of 1.5<br />

yuan/dollar), as compared with the current monthly wages of about $120/month for migrant<br />

workers (under the exchange <strong>rate</strong> of 8 yuan/dollar in 2006). The declining transaction costs of<br />

exporting <strong>and</strong> the exp<strong>and</strong>ing market play more important roles in China’s export<br />

competitiveness.<br />

In fact, international supply chain management has largely decreased China’s export costs<br />

<strong>and</strong> has had significant effects on this sector <strong>and</strong> also that of foreign investment. However,<br />

exports from China involve only labor-intensive processing <strong>and</strong> manufacturing. At the same<br />

time, the international supply chain faces tremendous obstacles when importing goods into<br />

China, so these transaction costs are very high. The supply chain has to start by ascertaining<br />

consumer dem<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> then find the lowest-cost producer. Consumer dem<strong>and</strong> in China,<br />

however, is affected by many factors outside of the international supply chain’s control,<br />

including China’s lack of efficient consumer financing, the absence of a functioning social<br />

safety net, a shortage of medical insurance, the weaknesses of the pension system, an<br />

absence of basic urban <strong>and</strong> rural infrastructures for individual consumption, a lack of basic<br />

regulations <strong>and</strong> enforcement of environmental protection, shortfalls in the effective regulation<br />

of product quality, <strong>and</strong> a near-total breakdown in the effective protection of intellectual property<br />

rights. Clearly, many of the domestic challenges involved in economic structures <strong>and</strong><br />

institutions that China faces have hindered the growth of China’s imports but not<br />

exports <strong>and</strong> are at the root of China’s sustained global current account surplus.<br />

While the relative cost of labor can be affected directly by a change in the exchange <strong>rate</strong>,<br />

transaction costs cannot be affected very much by such a change. In my view, thanks to<br />

China’s continued reform <strong>and</strong> opening, including the benefits from the accession to the World<br />

Trade Organization, China’s export competitiveness is likely to grow greater in the future<br />

because of the declining transaction costs of exporting, even if labor costs rise from RMB<br />

appreciation, inflation <strong>and</strong> other events.<br />

In order for China to balance its trade, it has to work hard on reducing the transaction costs for<br />

imports. Since the barriers to imports are primarily in the realm of hidden transactions<br />

costs, not in price, an emphasis on exchange <strong>rate</strong> <strong>adjustment</strong> would not be as effective<br />

as a focus on reducing the barriers <strong>and</strong> constraints facing imports into China.<br />

Only Adjusting Rates Is Not Enough<br />

Unfortunately, in the public <strong>policy</strong> debate, <strong>rate</strong>s, especially the nominal <strong>rate</strong>, are thought to be<br />

the most important factors affecting competitiveness <strong>and</strong> trade imbalances, which is a<br />

misunderst<strong>and</strong>ing in both theory <strong>and</strong> practice.


The implication is that as long as China maintains free trade, China’s nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

will always be consistent with the PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> based on tradable goods because of the<br />

possibility of market arbitrage. In other words, claims that China’s nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> is<br />

undervalued are nonsensical unless they are based on a PPP exchange <strong>rate</strong> derived from<br />

buying a bundle of goods that also includes non-tradable goods.<br />

Japan allowed its currency to appreciate steadily <strong>and</strong> significantly for many years during the<br />

1990s with little effect on reducing or eliminating Japan’s current account surplus. What Japan<br />

got from the appreciation of the yen was little more than a decade of deflation. If Japan had<br />

held its nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> constant throughout the 1990s, it most likely would have faced<br />

inflation during that period. But too great an appreciation of the yen eliminated the necessity<br />

for inflation <strong>and</strong> even required some deflation to compensate the excessive appreciation of<br />

yen. Clearly the argument that changes in the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> will have a lasting<br />

effect on current account balances is misleading. If a country can gain real<br />

competitiveness through nominal devaluation of its currency, economic growth <strong>and</strong><br />

development would be easy <strong>and</strong> should have been accomplished a long time ago for<br />

many developing countries. What we know from basic economic principle <strong>and</strong> real world<br />

experiences is that the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> is only a benchmark for domestic price levels.<br />

Changes in the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> will have lasting effects only on the domestic price level,<br />

not on competitiveness. Lasting improvements in competitiveness are determined by factor<br />

costs, transaction costs, technological progress, infrastructure, human capital <strong>and</strong> other real<br />

variables, but not the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>. Moreover, we should realize that sustained<br />

current account imbalances have very little to do with the level of the nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong>.<br />

Current account imbalances are fundamentally about surpluses or deficits of capital, about<br />

savings <strong>and</strong> investment gaps, <strong>and</strong> about consumption <strong>and</strong> saving behaviors.<br />

China Should Adopt an Inflation-First <strong>and</strong> Appreciation-Second St<strong>rate</strong>gy<br />

Inflation <strong>and</strong> currency appreciation are substitutes that are equivalent in terms of facilitating<br />

the rise of a country’s domestic price level. To an American consumer, the effects of China’s<br />

suffering 15% inflation or an appreciation in the RMB-dollar exchange <strong>rate</strong> by 15% are the<br />

same. The U.S. consumer faced with a 15% increase in his costs of buying goods made from<br />

China would not really care where the increased costs come from: inflation in China or an<br />

appreciation of the RMB.<br />

Those who are pushing China to revalue the RMB by 15% or 40% are really asking<br />

China to adjust upwards its domestic price level by 15% or 40%. But why not just<br />

recommend to Chinese <strong>policy</strong>-makers 15% or 40% inflation? We can see immediately<br />

the difficulties in engineering inflation as high as 15% to 40% in China.<br />

Although inflation <strong>and</strong> currency appreciation play the same function in raising the domestic<br />

price level, they work through very different economic mechanisms. Structural inflation, which<br />

accommodates domestic price level changes, works through individual markets with much<br />

less shock to the society than sudden <strong>and</strong> large exchange <strong>rate</strong> changes.


To speed up the growth of China’s domestic price levels, China can of course use inflation,<br />

currency appreciation, or even both at the same time. In my view, China should be<br />

encouraged to run a stable but low <strong>rate</strong> of inflation first, say about 5% a year, so as to match<br />

the steady growth of its domestic price levels with those in more developed economies. When<br />

structural inflation, which is different from pure monetary inflation, is expected to reach beyond<br />

5%, China should also add currency appreciation as an additional instrument to further absorb<br />

the pressure for increases in domestic price levels. The extent of currency appreciation should<br />

be determined by the market in the sense that appreciation would not be so excessive as to<br />

push inflation down below 3%.<br />

This inflation-first <strong>and</strong> appreciation-second st<strong>rate</strong>gy would avoid the risks of both<br />

deflation <strong>and</strong> excessive inflation. It will also be able to deter currency speculation as<br />

speculators would need to worry about inflation in China whenever they bet on the<br />

appreciation of RMB. Speculators <strong>and</strong> investors can still bet on real estate, which will rise in<br />

value with both inflation <strong>and</strong> appreciation, but the catch-up of prices in property should be<br />

viewed as a leading indicator for the catch-up of overall price levels in China <strong>and</strong> should not<br />

concern the Chinese authorities too much as long as investors are required to make sizable<br />

down-payments for their properties.<br />

Overall, price levels in China are far low than those in the US, but some luxuries <strong>and</strong> costly<br />

services are exceptions. The gap in price levels between China <strong>and</strong> the U.S. can be<br />

measured by the difference between China’s nominal exchange <strong>rate</strong> (8 yuan/dollar in<br />

2006) <strong>and</strong> the PPP exchange for GDP as calculated by the World Bank (2.6 yuan/dollar<br />

in 2006). This gap is as much as 67.5%.<br />

In my view, it is not possible for China’s domestic price level to reach that of the U.S. within 15<br />

years. If this common-sense judgment holds true, then China’s average annual currency<br />

appreciation plus its extra inflation could not possibly exceed 8%. Hence, 4% per year extra<br />

inflation <strong>and</strong> 4% per year currency appreciation would probably be the best we can<br />

hope for in China.<br />

The actual pace of inflation <strong>and</strong> RMB appreciation in China at the present is far from this “limit.”<br />

In 2006, China’s inflation <strong>rate</strong> was only 1.5%, much lower than the inflation <strong>rate</strong> in the U.S. of<br />

2.5%. In fact, relative to the U.S., China had deflation in 2006! The average <strong>rate</strong> of RMB<br />

appreciation in 2006 was around 3%. So in 2006 China’s domestic price level increased only<br />

about 2% (1.5% - 2.5% + 3% = 2%) relative to that in the U.S. At this pace, it will take China 57<br />

years to catch up to the U.S. price level. No wonder so many in Washington are getting<br />

impatient about China’s currency <strong>policy</strong>! However, while it is easy to complain about China’s<br />

slow <strong>adjustment</strong>, it is difficult to find a solution to speed up China’s price level catch-up.<br />

The International Community Should Encourage China to Adopt a Loose Monetary<br />

Policy<br />

The structural constraint of the large pool <strong>and</strong> surplus of unskilled labor is the main reason for<br />

price increases <strong>and</strong> the RMB’s slow appreciation. According to the Asian Development Bank,


in 2006, inflation reached 2.2% in Korea, 5.5% in India, 7.9% in Pakistan, 13.1% in Indonesia,<br />

7.5% in Vietnam, <strong>and</strong> 6.2% in the Philippines. It seems fair to say that in the global context<br />

China experienced deflationary pressure in 2006 even though China’s growth <strong>rate</strong> was 10.7%.<br />

Surprisingly both the Chinese government <strong>and</strong> international organizations like the ADB, World<br />

Bank <strong>and</strong> International Monetary Fund have urged China to tighten monetary <strong>policy</strong> so as to<br />

restrain investment when China actually recorded one of the lowest inflation <strong>rate</strong>s in the world<br />

in 2006. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the ADB, among others, recommended that other Asian<br />

economies, many of which have much higher inflation <strong>rate</strong>s than China in 2006, raise<br />

investment, especially in infrastructure. The typical answer is that “China is special,” that China<br />

has over-capacity, <strong>and</strong> that therefore China should reduce investment <strong>and</strong> increase<br />

consumption.<br />

The advice on increasing consumption cannot be wrong. However, consumption in China<br />

today is largely under the control of individual families <strong>and</strong> firms. They have probably already<br />

tried their best to optimize their consumption given all the constraints they face, <strong>and</strong> are<br />

unlikely to welcome the government telling them how to spend their money. Since the health<br />

insurance <strong>and</strong> social security networks in China are in their infancy, many Chinese people<br />

choose to save a great deal of money as a hedge against severe illness. In the absence of<br />

student-loan programs, families also choose to save a great deal for their children’s education.<br />

As roads, subways <strong>and</strong> schools for many newly developed residential communities are<br />

underdeveloped, many middle class Chinese families are deciding to buy property, betting on<br />

the capital gains but refraining from moving into the new property until the road <strong>and</strong>/or subway<br />

networks are completed.<br />

In the context of the above examples, the answers are quite straight forward: build an<br />

integ<strong>rate</strong>d health insurance system; create student-loan or scholarship programs; <strong>and</strong> build<br />

more roads, subways, <strong>and</strong> schools. All these solutions, not surprisingly, require investment.<br />

But these are productive investments, <strong>and</strong> productive public investments are fundamentally<br />

different from the investment that gene<strong>rate</strong>s unproductive over-capacity, since these<br />

investments will free up the consumption power of Chinese households, which are currently<br />

held back as a hedge against potential negative future eventualities.<br />

Because of the difficulties in distinguishing productive investment from unproductive<br />

investment, the central bank of China faces a dilemma: if it adopts a loose monetary <strong>policy</strong>, it<br />

will have to deal with over-capacity as unproductive investment exp<strong>and</strong>s out of control; if it<br />

adopts a tighter monetary <strong>policy</strong>, it will have to deal with a current account surplus when<br />

imports <strong>and</strong> productive investment cannot grow fast enough to keep up with the expansion of<br />

exports.<br />

To speed up China’s catch-up in domestic price level the international community should<br />

encourage China to adopt a loose monetary <strong>policy</strong>, which means less sterilization of its rising<br />

foreign exchange reserves. This move would accommodate steady structural inflation, <strong>and</strong> a<br />

low <strong>and</strong> stable inflation <strong>rate</strong> is a necessary condition for facilitating an orderly RMB<br />

appreciation that would not risk deflation. But to convince China to adopt a loose monetary


<strong>policy</strong>, it is necessary to help China to develop a robust financial planning <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

system that can distinguish productive from unproductive investments.<br />

The strength of the financial sector in the U.S. contrasts sharply with the weakness of that of<br />

China. With a strong financial sector, the average American can afford to maintain a low<br />

savings <strong>rate</strong> since they can secure capital gains on their investments in property <strong>and</strong> capital<br />

markets. With a weak financial sector, the Chinese consumer has to maintain a high saving<br />

<strong>rate</strong>s, lower consumption (<strong>and</strong> hence a lower st<strong>and</strong>ard of living), <strong>and</strong> thus China cannot use its<br />

surplus capital to utilize productively all its people.<br />

Americans today worry about competition from China just as Hong Kong people did a decade<br />

ago. But today, people in Hong Kong realize that as China’s economy grows, more work<br />

opportunities come than all of Hong Kong’s labor pool can h<strong>and</strong>le. I have no doubt that if<br />

America helps China fix its financial sector, China will create an enormous dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

American goods <strong>and</strong> services, consequently giving similar benefits <strong>and</strong> employment<br />

opportunities for the American people. The U.S. <strong>and</strong> the international community should make<br />

efforts for that solution instead of a narrow-minded focus on simple RMB exchange <strong>rate</strong><br />

revaluation.


Sustainable Growth<br />

By Xiao Geng<br />

Far Eastern Economic Review, page 54-55, Vol. 168<br />

The year will be one of little significance for China’s macro economy, which means 8% growth<br />

with few shocks.<br />

Given the many challenges facing China, why such strong confidence? The answer may be<br />

obvious to business executives in China, but it has taken economists a lot of research effort to<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>. The country's most important firms are in the middle of a quiet productivity<br />

revolution that is going to transform not just Chinese enterprises <strong>and</strong> cities, but also eventually<br />

the global economic l<strong>and</strong>scape.<br />

In the past few years, too much attention has been paid to China's macro-economy, largely due<br />

to exciting business cycles. However, hidden behind the headlines are deep structural <strong>and</strong><br />

institution al changes: ever intensifying market competition, on-going inflows of FDI, rapid<br />

expansion of both exports <strong>and</strong> imports, quiet but steady privatization, chaotic but breathtaking<br />

improvement in the regulatory environment, <strong>and</strong> finally the transformation of urban<br />

infrastructure in many leading cities.<br />

A key question linking the macro- <strong>and</strong> microeconomics of China's development is the effects of<br />

these changes on productivity. If there is no productivity improvement, china's high growth is<br />

simply borrowed prosperity, driven by the expansion of investment in the past <strong>and</strong> the rise of<br />

non-performing loans in the future. Many observers have rightly pointed out that China's<br />

statistics so far show no impressive productivity growth. But China is too big <strong>and</strong> too diverse for<br />

the data to show what is really happening.<br />

Working closely with researchers at the National Bureau of Statistics of China, my colleagues <strong>and</strong><br />

I discovered that the average annual growth of total factor productivity in China's large <strong>and</strong><br />

medium-sized industrial enterprises sector is as high as 6.8%, with a steep rising trend during<br />

1996-2002. This productivity revolution is driven mainly by frontier technological catching up. In<br />

another words, the high growth in China is sustainable if the productivity gaps between the best<br />

<strong>and</strong> the average are narrowed in the future through intensifying competition, privatization <strong>and</strong><br />

improvements in the regulatory environment.<br />

We also found that the debt quality of the large <strong>and</strong> medium-sized industrial enterprises<br />

improved sharply after 1998 due to improving profitability as well as a shift of debt capital from<br />

less profitable to more profitable firms. While the over all improvement in enterprise profitability<br />

is likely to be associated with business cycles, the better allocation of debt capital observed in our<br />

study is clearly linked to better performance of banking <strong>and</strong> debt markets.<br />

In a sepa<strong>rate</strong> study on China's FDI inflows, we also found that the round tripping FDI (e.g. FDI<br />

suspected to be domestic capital or unverifiable to be foreign origin) accounts on average for


about 40% of China's total FDI inflows during the last decade. During the same period, China's<br />

total capital flight, including that due to misinvoicing of imports <strong>and</strong> exports, was actually larger<br />

than China's total FDI inflows. These findings indicate that FDI in China, although important in<br />

bringing advanced technology, is not important quantitatively as a capital input in supporting<br />

China's growth. Because China's high growth is not dependent on net inflows of foreign capital, it<br />

is more sustainable.<br />

The huge technological gaps between China <strong>and</strong> the advanced economies, between the best <strong>and</strong><br />

worst firms within the country, <strong>and</strong> between the coastal <strong>and</strong> inl<strong>and</strong> regions are all driving forces<br />

for rapid productivity growth. Competition in each industry will be as fierce as ever <strong>and</strong> the race<br />

between ever-rising volumes of market transactions <strong>and</strong> slowly improving market <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

infrastructure will intensify. In the middle of this productivity revolution, it is wise for the<br />

government to minimize macro shocks so as to allow the market forces to play out in spreading<br />

frontier technology, allocating inputs <strong>and</strong> finding equilibrium prices. The government on the<br />

other h<strong>and</strong> should focus on the Ionger-term objective, improving the market <strong>and</strong> regulatory<br />

infrastructure so property rights can be delineated clearly, exchanged efficiently <strong>and</strong> enforced<br />

fairly.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!