Financial sector development - Sida

Financial sector development - Sida Financial sector development - Sida

tanzaniagateway.org
from tanzaniagateway.org More from this publisher
18.02.2015 Views

along with growth. This approach highlights the importance of the quality of investments, not just the investment rate as such. Some empirical findings suggest that investments in equipment (machinery) are more important for growth than so called structural investment. In fact, some low-quality investment might waste resources in the economy and, thereby, be detrimental to growth in the long run although temporarily boosting the growth rate. The risk that such investments are undertaken is higher in economies with large distortions in the working of market forces, e.g. high barriers to market competition or foreign trade, price distortions, administrative investment regulations or skewed credit schemes. Another line of research suggests that public investment may be instrumental for growth, although the type of public investment is of importance (infrastructure investments may be growth promoting, while investments in state industry are not necessarily so). The discussion leads to a complex picture of the investment and growth relationship. Technological change, and not physical capital accumulation per se, seems to be a crucial ingredient in the growth process. The technological change factor depends to a large extent on factors such as human capital investments, innovation climate, and entrepreneurship. The driving forces behind these qualities of economic life are found in the institutional framework of an economy, i.e. the rules, formal (laws) and informal (norms and conventions), constraining economic action. A general requirement for economic activity is clear and stable rules of the game. These include transparent and enforceable legislation, and limited risks of unpredictable changes in enterprise conditions. Well-defined and enforceable property rights may reduce the risk of expropriation (either through nationalisation or heavy taxation), a risk which most likely has a very negative impact on entrepreneurs' willingness to invest. Another particular growth promoting institution is a framework for efficient intermediation of financial resources, since a major obstacle to the entrepreneurs' ability to realize their ideas, is lack of capital. 3.2 Investment and savings In a closed economy, national savings and domestic investments are equal by definition. In a fully open economy, i.e. an economy where capital can flow freely, across the borders, the expected rates of return internationally will determine where people's savings are placed. In view of the substantial reduction in barriers to capital flows in recent decades, it can be expected that the correlation between savings and investments within countries has been reduced. This notion is challenged by empirical findings, and to some extent also theoretically. The correlation between domestic savings and investments, despite capital mobility, have been shown to be very strong in a large number of countries (the Feldstein- Horioka puzzle). The most straight-forward explanation is to claim that capital is not as mobile as believed for various reasons (political risk, currency premiums, "home-country bias", etc). Another type of explanation turns on domestic capital immobility: firms' and households' tendency to finance investments from their own savings. Indeed, a very large proportion of all investments made, in particular in developing countries, are self-financed. Firms and households retain a substantial share of their profits/surpluses and invest them in their own businesses. Self-financing may be beneficial for the firm or the household: it internalizes information and incentives, which may substantially reduce a number of transaction costs. The drawback of self-finance is that it may not provide sufficient resources to fully realize the investment opportunities. There is, thus, a role for the financial system to reallocate resources from savers to investors. 14

3.3 Driving forces behind savings Whereas there is a positive correlation between the income level of a country and the savings rate, at least up to a certain level of income, there is no clear evidence that the income distribution of a country affects the savings rate. Possibly this may be because saving is driven by many different motives, which may affect different groups of the population in various ways, depending on the specific conditions in each country. People save for several reasons. First, there is the income smoothing motive. According to the permanent income hypothesis, the consumer distinguishes between permanent and temporary income, and will save temporary income increases (or dissave - i.e. borrow or use up the savings in case of temporary income reductions) so that consumption remains equal to the individual’s permanent income. Also, people behave differently over their lifecycle: dissaving when young, saving in mid-life and again dissaving during retirement. These hypotheses may explain how saving adapt to a given income stream, but they have difficulties, among other things, in explaining the positive correlation between savings and growth. Another reason for saving is the precautionary motive. The individual may save for "the rainy day": if unemployment strikes, if the harvest goes bad, if the children will not provide for you as old. Precautionary saving depends on the individual's opportunity to insure himself. In the developed world, there are formal insurance companies as well as social transfer systems which reduce uncertainties about future income. In developing countries, a substitute may be the extended family, which may guarantee that the individual will be provided for in case of health problems, old age or bad luck, thus reducing this savings motive. Partly related to both of these two arguments is the bequest motive: people save for the future generation. Some empirical studies suggest that bequests are more important for the wealthy than the poor. Bequests may still be important in developing countries, and among poor, for example manifested in keeping the small farm within the family (and not sell it off at old age, as suggested by the life-cycle hypothesis). It should be noted that a bequest may not only be a sign of altruism, but may also be control motivated (the bequestor makes sure he is able to influence decisions until his death), or have a precautionary motive. In conjunction with these arguments, demography obviously affects aggregate saving, although relationships are ambiguous. High fertility rates may have a negative effect on saving, if people have many children as a substitute for saving for their old age. Reductions in mortality rates may have a positive effect on saving, because investments in education are more profitable (people live longer). Moreover, a growing population may mean a growing labor force which causes growing incomes and growing savings. On the other hand, there is a fairly robust negative relationship between dependency ratios (the proportion of young and old people to the number of people active on the labor market) and savings rates. Another category of savings motives are sociological. For example, consumption habits may lag behind income changes. This explanation would fit empirical findings of the savings and growth correlation. Urbanisation may also affect savings, although it is unclear in what direction. On the one hand, urban life may bring more investment opportunities, 15

3.3 Driving forces behind savings<br />

Whereas there is a positive correlation between the income level of a country and the<br />

savings rate, at least up to a certain level of income, there is no clear evidence that the<br />

income distribution of a country affects the savings rate. Possibly this may be because<br />

saving is driven by many different motives, which may affect different groups of the<br />

population in various ways, depending on the specific conditions in each country.<br />

People save for several reasons. First, there is the income smoothing motive. According to<br />

the permanent income hypothesis, the consumer distinguishes between permanent and<br />

temporary income, and will save temporary income increases (or dissave - i.e. borrow or<br />

use up the savings in case of temporary income reductions) so that consumption remains<br />

equal to the individual’s permanent income. Also, people behave differently over their lifecycle:<br />

dissaving when young, saving in mid-life and again dissaving during retirement.<br />

These hypotheses may explain how saving adapt to a given income stream, but they have<br />

difficulties, among other things, in explaining the positive correlation between savings and<br />

growth.<br />

Another reason for saving is the precautionary motive. The individual may save for "the<br />

rainy day": if unemployment strikes, if the harvest goes bad, if the children will not provide<br />

for you as old. Precautionary saving depends on the individual's opportunity to insure<br />

himself. In the developed world, there are formal insurance companies as well as social<br />

transfer systems which reduce uncertainties about future income. In developing countries,<br />

a substitute may be the extended family, which may guarantee that the individual will be<br />

provided for in case of health problems, old age or bad luck, thus reducing this savings<br />

motive.<br />

Partly related to both of these two arguments is the bequest motive: people save for the<br />

future generation. Some empirical studies suggest that bequests are more important for the<br />

wealthy than the poor. Bequests may still be important in developing countries, and among<br />

poor, for example manifested in keeping the small farm within the family (and not sell it off<br />

at old age, as suggested by the life-cycle hypothesis). It should be noted that a bequest<br />

may not only be a sign of altruism, but may also be control motivated (the bequestor makes<br />

sure he is able to influence decisions until his death), or have a precautionary motive.<br />

In conjunction with these arguments, demography obviously affects aggregate saving,<br />

although relationships are ambiguous. High fertility rates may have a negative effect on<br />

saving, if people have many children as a substitute for saving for their old age. Reductions<br />

in mortality rates may have a positive effect on saving, because investments in education<br />

are more profitable (people live longer). Moreover, a growing population may mean a<br />

growing labor force which causes growing incomes and growing savings. On the other<br />

hand, there is a fairly robust negative relationship between dependency ratios (the<br />

proportion of young and old people to the number of people active on the labor market) and<br />

savings rates.<br />

Another category of savings motives are sociological. For example, consumption habits<br />

may lag behind income changes. This explanation would fit empirical findings of the<br />

savings and growth correlation. Urbanisation may also affect savings, although it is unclear<br />

in what direction. On the one hand, urban life may bring more investment opportunities,<br />

15

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!