15.01.2015 Views

Answer Key

Answer Key

Answer Key

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

EconS425 - Homework #3 (Due on March 7 th , 2013)<br />

1. Exercise 2 from Chapter 7 in Shy (page 165)<br />

Solution:<br />

a) Given a low reservation price (a low B), we’ll attempt to find a monopoly equilibrium<br />

where not all the market is served. Figure 7.2 illustrates the location of the two<br />

indifferent consumers, one on each side of the firm. The indifferent consumer (on<br />

each side) is determined by the reservation utility, that is, B a p 0 , or,<br />

Solution-Figure 7.2: Single-firm location model<br />

a B p . Hence, the monopoly chooses p that solves<br />

max =p 2a 2 p( B p)<br />

p<br />

The solution is given by<br />

2<br />

p M B , a B , and =p 2a<br />

<br />

B<br />

2 2 2<br />

1<br />

Now, it is easy to verify that 0B<br />

1 implies that 0 a<br />

, hence, not all the<br />

2<br />

market is served.<br />

b) When substituting B 1 into the solution for ‘a’ found in the previous subquestion,<br />

we get that the indifferent consumers lie “outside” the city. This implies that for<br />

B 1, the monopoly can increase the price and still having the entire street<br />

purchase the product. Thus, the monopoly will pick the highest possible price<br />

subject to having the consumers living at the edges of town purchase the product.<br />

1<br />

Formally, set p to satisfy B p 0. Hence,<br />

2<br />

M 1 1 M 1<br />

p B , a , and B <br />

2 2 2<br />

2. A unit circle representing the dimension of “mouth feel” in breakfast cereals has 200<br />

consumers spread uniformly along it. All consumers buy either one package of cereal a<br />

week or none at all (in which case they eat bread) and incur disutility c = 200 from each<br />

unit distance by which a brand deviates from their favorite mouth feel. They derive<br />

utility v = 20 from eating bread.<br />

1<br />

Instructor: Ana Espinola


a. What is the equation for the demand curve facing cereal makers (Distinguish<br />

the monopolistic and competitive segments, but ignore the super-competitive<br />

segment.)<br />

Solution:<br />

The equation for the monopolistic segment of the demand curve is<br />

2 L<br />

qm<br />

( v p ) 40 2 p<br />

c<br />

and for the competitive segment<br />

L c 200<br />

qc<br />

( p p)<br />

p p<br />

c n n<br />

b. What is the symmetric equilibrium under free entry if the cereal makers’ costs<br />

are C(q) = 128 +4q<br />

Solution:<br />

Checking first whether the zero-profit equilibrium lies on the monopolistic<br />

segment of the demand curve, we note that if C(q) = 218 + 4q, monopoly profits<br />

are<br />

( p m) q F 2( p 4)(20 p) 128<br />

m<br />

m<br />

Setting the derivative of these profits with respect to p equal to zero, we find<br />

that p $12 . Hence, q 16 and $0 , so that this is indeed the zero-profit<br />

m<br />

m<br />

equilibrium. Dividing the number of consumers, 200, by the number of units<br />

each firm sells, 16, we find that n ≤ 12.<br />

c. What if fixed costs fall to 100<br />

Solution:<br />

With lower fixed costs, monopolistic cereal makers earn non-zero profits, so that<br />

we have to look at the competitive segment of the demand curve for<br />

equilibrium. Competitive profits are<br />

200<br />

<br />

c<br />

( p m) qc<br />

F ( p 4)( p p) 100<br />

n<br />

Setting the derivative of these profits with respect to p equal to zero and using<br />

that, in the symmetric equilibrium, p p and profits are zero, we find that<br />

p $14 q 10 $0 and n=20 at the equilibrium.<br />

c<br />

c<br />

3. On an atoll in the Pacific island group Saloponesia there is just one street, Ring Street,<br />

along which all people live—one islander per unit distance—and along which all shops<br />

are located. The island group used to be a French colony, which may explain the<br />

islanders’ custom of walking to a nearby bakery every day to buy a fresh chocolate<br />

croissant. Their attachment to this custom is not unbounded, however. Depending upon<br />

the opportunity cost of their time spent walking, they may find croissants too expensive.<br />

In that case they stay home and eat corn flakes instead. Each of the bakers runs exactly<br />

one bakery and, when not baking, plays Bertrand.<br />

2<br />

Instructor: Ana Espinola


a. Set up a model (adopting simplifying assumptions where appropriate) to analyze<br />

this croissant market, and describe the equilibrium if it is given that there are<br />

some islanders who eat corn flakes.<br />

Solution:<br />

One way of setting up the model that omits the u and v-terms in the Salop model<br />

(which cancel out anyway) is as follows. Let customers’ opportunity cost of<br />

walking be c per unit distance (c/2 going and c/2 coming back). If they live at a<br />

distance d from a bakery charging p for a croissant, their perceived cost of<br />

buying from that bakery is p + cd. If this cost exceeds that of buying from the<br />

nearest bakery in the other direction from where they live, they buy from that<br />

bakery instead. If the cost of buying from either bakery exceeds their reservation<br />

price p u , they eat corn flakes.<br />

Assume that the bakeries are identical. In a symmetric equilibrium, they will then<br />

locate at equal distances from each other on Ring Street. As a result, if there are<br />

some islanders who eat corn flakes, the market areas of the bakeries are not<br />

touching, and each bakery is therefore a local monopoly.<br />

If a bakery is a local monopoly, the length xm<br />

of its market in either direction is<br />

defined by<br />

u<br />

p cx p<br />

Beyond this distance no customer buys from it. Given that there is one islander<br />

per unit distance along Ring Street, its daily sales are<br />

u<br />

2( p p)<br />

qm<br />

2xm<br />

(1)<br />

c<br />

and its profits, assuming that each bakery has the same cost function C (q) = F +<br />

mq, are<br />

u<br />

2( p p)<br />

<br />

m<br />

( p m)<br />

F<br />

(2)<br />

c<br />

Setting the derivative of these profits with respect to p equal to zero, we find<br />

that it sets<br />

u<br />

p m<br />

p (3)<br />

2<br />

Substituting equation (3) into (1) and (2) yields<br />

u<br />

p m<br />

qm<br />

(4)<br />

c<br />

And<br />

u 2<br />

( p m)<br />

<br />

m<br />

F<br />

(5)<br />

2c<br />

Assuming there is free entry into the croissant market, the monopolist bakers<br />

cannot be making positive profits in equilibrium. (Strictly speaking, we follow<br />

Salop’s assumption that bakeries relocate without cost when entry occurs, each<br />

time redistributing themselves evenly around the circle). From setting profits in<br />

(5) to zero and rearranging, we find that<br />

m<br />

3<br />

Instructor: Ana Espinola


u<br />

p c 2Fc<br />

Substituting this expression back into (3) and (4) yields expressions for the<br />

equilibrium price and sales.<br />

4. Exercise 1 and 3 from Chapter 8 in Shy (pages 213-214)<br />

Exercise 1 from Chapter 8<br />

Solution:<br />

a) I4 20 20 20 10 70<br />

b)<br />

I <br />

HH<br />

2 2<br />

4 10 3 20 1600<br />

c) i. After the merger of firms 1 and 2,<br />

I <br />

HH<br />

2 2 2 2<br />

20 10 10 3 20 1800<br />

ii. I HH<br />

1800 1600 200<br />

iii. The merger may be challenged by the FTC or the Justice Department since the<br />

postmerger I<br />

HH<br />

exceeds 1, 000 and I HH<br />

200 100<br />

Exercise3 from Chapter 8<br />

Solution:<br />

a) We look for a Nash equilibrium in prices. The X-seller takes pY<br />

as given and solves<br />

<br />

max X pXQ pX ( pX 2 pY<br />

) , yielding pX<br />

pY<br />

pX<br />

2<br />

The Y-seller takes pX<br />

as given and solves<br />

pX<br />

max Y pY 2Q 2 pY ( pX 2 pY<br />

) , yielding pY<br />

<br />

pY<br />

4<br />

Hence,<br />

2<br />

N N N 2 N N N<br />

pX , pY , pS , Q , X <br />

<br />

Y<br />

<br />

3 6 3 3 9<br />

b) We define a system as one unit of X bundled with two units of Y. Then, the merged<br />

firm chooses a system price p that solves<br />

S<br />

2<br />

<br />

max S pS ( pS<br />

) , yielding pS QS and <br />

S<br />

<br />

pS<br />

2 4<br />

c) To make a welfare judgment on the gains from this merger it is sufficient to compare<br />

prices and profit levels. Before the merger, the price of one system is<br />

0 2<br />

1<br />

pS pX 2pY pS<br />

which is the price after the merger. Also, before the<br />

3 2<br />

2 2<br />

2<br />

1<br />

merger, aggregate profit is <br />

X<br />

Y <br />

S<br />

which is the profit after the<br />

9 4<br />

merger takes place. Since the system price falls and industry profit increases, the<br />

merger is welfare improving.<br />

4<br />

Instructor: Ana Espinola

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!