Corporate governance and earnings management ... - CEREG

Corporate governance and earnings management ... - CEREG Corporate governance and earnings management ... - CEREG

cereg.dauphine.fr
from cereg.dauphine.fr More from this publisher
10.01.2015 Views

But subsequently, no doubt for budgetary reasons (Prospert, 1934, p. 71), the tax administration, in an instruction of March 30, 1918, refused all systematic (and a fortiori rapid) amortization of goodwill, arguing that “the value of goodwill generally increases… except in rare cases of depreciation” (Brière, 1934, p. 181). From 1918 to September 1925, the French tax administration’s position was as follows: all amortization was impossible, unless it could be proved (generally this was very difficult for taxpayers) that the goodwill had really lost value. As we shall see, this position was based on doctrine inspired by ideas from the actuarial view. In 1925, the administration took a more hardline position. A ministerial decision of September 15 ruled that no amortization (or provision) would now be allowed, and this was confirmed in article 29 of the Instruction of January 31, 1928. How can this extreme position be explained The main reason is that under pressure from taxpayers, the administration came to accept that capital gains on business transfers should be tax-free 2 . In exchange for this concession, capital losses would no longer be deductible, even when proven (Brière, 1934, p. 64-67). This radical system only lasted three years, from 1925 to 1928. In 1928 the matter was brought before the courts by disgruntled taxpayers. In response to their complaints, the Conseil d’Etat finally allowed amortization of goodwill on condition that the loss of value was “effective”, “permanent” and affected the goodwill “in its entirety” 3 . This decision was confirmed four years later in a very interesting ruling which stipulated that goodwill was “not a start-up cost” but “an asset” 4 . The administration had to give way to the judges and acknowledge that amortization was possible if the overall effective loss of value was demonstrable. In fact, the issue ceased to be relevant when the laws of March 28, 1933 and decree of July 20, 1934 reintroduced the 2 (Ministerial decision of September 15, 1925 confirmed by a Direction Générale circular of September 19, 1925 and a circular of June 29, 1925 issued by the Direct Contributions department). 3 Conseil d’Etat, Aug. 3, 1928, comment Brière, 1934, p. 185. 4 Conseil d’Etat, Jan. 8, 1932, Gazette du Palais, Feb. 23, 1932. 38

“balance sheet approach” and systematic taxation of all capital gains, including gains on sales of goodwill. There was no longer any reason to oppose the possibility of depreciating goodwill. From then on, and practically from 1928 to the modern day, the French tax administration’s position remained almost constantly as follows: - goodwill is an asset (but start-up costs are not); - goodwill cannot be systematically amortized; - goodwill can be reduced in exceptional circumstances. b) The influence of the tax administration on French doctrine We shall consider tax and commercial doctrine separately. Tax doctrine Most major specialists in taxation defended the stand taken by the tax administration. This was the case for Lecerclé (1922), Besson, Bocquet, Durand and Bourrel (quoted in Brière, 1934, p. 26-36). Lecerclé (1922), who appears to have been one of the leaders in this school of thought, reflects the thinking of the time: goodwill can only be amortized “in very exceptional cases” if there is a regular, constant decline in the value of the business (Brière, 1934, p. 176). Commercial doctrine Supporters of the static doctrine naturally found themselves on the defensive against tax theorists. For supporters of the actuarial approach, on the other hand, such as Charpentier and Hamelin (1933), convictions were strengthened. Some authors, including major names, remained faithful to the static approach. Batardon, for example (1931, p. 185-187), continued to group goodwill together with start-up costs and called for rapid amortization, at least for limited liability companies. Prospert (1934) also 39

But subsequently, no doubt for budgetary reasons (Prospert, 1934, p. 71), the tax<br />

administration, in an instruction of March 30, 1918, refused all systematic (<strong>and</strong> a fortiori<br />

rapid) amortization of goodwill, arguing that “the value of goodwill generally increases…<br />

except in rare cases of depreciation” (Brière, 1934, p. 181).<br />

From 1918 to September 1925, the French tax administration’s position was as follows: all<br />

amortization was impossible, unless it could be proved (generally this was very difficult for<br />

taxpayers) that the goodwill had really lost value. As we shall see, this position was based on<br />

doctrine inspired by ideas from the actuarial view. In 1925, the administration took a more<br />

hardline position. A ministerial decision of September 15 ruled that no amortization (or<br />

provision) would now be allowed, <strong>and</strong> this was confirmed in article 29 of the Instruction of<br />

January 31, 1928.<br />

How can this extreme position be explained The main reason is that under pressure from<br />

taxpayers, the administration came to accept that capital gains on business transfers should be<br />

tax-free 2 . In exchange for this concession, capital losses would no longer be deductible, even<br />

when proven (Brière, 1934, p. 64-67).<br />

This radical system only lasted three years, from 1925 to 1928. In 1928 the matter was<br />

brought before the courts by disgruntled taxpayers. In response to their complaints, the<br />

Conseil d’Etat finally allowed amortization of goodwill on condition that the loss of value<br />

was “effective”, “permanent” <strong>and</strong> affected the goodwill “in its entirety” 3 . This decision was<br />

confirmed four years later in a very interesting ruling which stipulated that goodwill was “not<br />

a start-up cost” but “an asset” 4 .<br />

The administration had to give way to the judges <strong>and</strong> acknowledge that amortization was<br />

possible if the overall effective loss of value was demonstrable. In fact, the issue ceased to be<br />

relevant when the laws of March 28, 1933 <strong>and</strong> decree of July 20, 1934 reintroduced the<br />

2 (Ministerial decision of September 15, 1925 confirmed by a Direction Générale circular of September 19, 1925<br />

<strong>and</strong> a circular of June 29, 1925 issued by the Direct Contributions department).<br />

3 Conseil d’Etat, Aug. 3, 1928, comment Brière, 1934, p. 185.<br />

4 Conseil d’Etat, Jan. 8, 1932, Gazette du Palais, Feb. 23, 1932.<br />

38

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!