Corporate governance and earnings management ... - CEREG

Corporate governance and earnings management ... - CEREG Corporate governance and earnings management ... - CEREG

cereg.dauphine.fr
from cereg.dauphine.fr More from this publisher
10.01.2015 Views

This philosophy was also reflected in the first US regulations. In 1917, a memorandum entitled “Uniform Accounting” issued by the American Institute of Accountants (predecessor to the American Institute of Certified Public Accountants) was accepted by the Federal Trade Commission and Federal Reserve Board, for application by companies wishing to obtain a loan. It recommends that goodwill should be “shown as a deduction from net worth” (AIA, 1917). While this treatment was only compulsory for financial statements produced for the purposes of a loan, it still reveals the state of mind at the time (see below). But the standard (pure) static approach had not lost all its influence: there were still authors, and not just minor ones, who preferred rapid amortization of goodwill and in fact most intangibles. One of them was Hatfield, whose position remained unchanged (1927). Others were in favor of recognition at cost with no systematic amortization (Dickinson, 1917, pp. 79- 80; Freeman, 1921, p. 263; Bliss, 1924, p. 350; Esquerré, 1927, p. 130). This view had considerable support from the tax administration through the 1918 Revenue Act, which did not include goodwill in its list of intangible items for which a systematic allowance for obsolescence is possible, and the Revenue Act of 1928 which stipulated that “no deduction for depreciation, including obsolescence, is allowable in respect of goodwill” (Catlett & Olson, 1968, p. 57). There was an increasing trend recommending recording goodwill at cost, followed by systematic amortization over the useful life or a period corresponding to the period on which discounting to present value was based. Heading the line in this school were Gilman (1916, p. 195), Paton and Stevenson (1922, p. 531), Yang (1927, p. 196) and Paton and Littleton (1940, p. 92). Under this flood of contradictory opinions, it may seem tempting to conclude like Saliers (1923, p. 580) that all opinions are equal. But some opinions appeared more widespread than others. It is undeniable that supporters of speedy amortization soon found themselves in the minority, and their views were not taken up by the emerging regulations. 30

It is also clear that supporters of recording at cost (or even at actuarial value) were in a difficult position and found themselves on the defensive. Esquerré (1927, p. 130) was forced to observe that “in some mysterious way the intangible asset goodwill has become very objectionable to business people. To them it is symptomatic of insufficiency of real values”. But despite all this, the United States were already taking a less static approach than the Germans (see below): a German writing a thesis on treatment of goodwill in “Anglo-Saxon” countries at the time considered from his outsider’s point of view that charging goodwill to equity was an “Anglo-saxon” specificity (Mildebrath, 1931, p. 97). Of course, a significant event of this period was the serious economic crisis of 1929 in American industry, which had several consequences in terms of treatment of goodwill. Its main impact was to reinforce the positions of those who saw goodwill as an unstable, if not undesirable, item: not only was it noted that, as in the previous period, “financiers frequently deduct all intangible values from the net worth section of the balance sheet when a loan is being contemplated” (Walker, 1938b, p. 259), but companies themselves appeared to be continuing such drastic measures in their accounts. A 1931-32 study of listed companies’ financial statements showed that of the 86 balance sheets showing goodwill as a separate item, 31 of them listed goodwill at $1.00 (Fjeld, 1936, p. 333). While it was true, as one of the commentators pointed out, that “the practice could have been the result of either a write-up, a write-down, or of amortization of the cost of purchased goodwill until only a nominal valuation remained” (Hughes, 1982, p. 99), another study undertaken a little later confirmed a clear trend in favor of writing down goodwill and recording it at a nominal value (Avery, 1942, p. 356, 363). In general, as Canning (1929, p. 43) or Nobles et al. (1941, p. 198) underline, there was at the time a “popular practice of writing off”; hence, rapid amortization techniques, either charging to expenses or even more often, when goodwill was too large for the profits to “bear”, charging to equity, could very plausibly have been widespread. 31

It is also clear that supporters of recording at cost (or even at actuarial value) were in a<br />

difficult position <strong>and</strong> found themselves on the defensive. Esquerré (1927, p. 130) was forced<br />

to observe that “in some mysterious way the intangible asset goodwill has become very<br />

objectionable to business people. To them it is symptomatic of insufficiency of real values”.<br />

But despite all this, the United States were already taking a less static approach than the<br />

Germans (see below): a German writing a thesis on treatment of goodwill in “Anglo-Saxon”<br />

countries at the time considered from his outsider’s point of view that charging goodwill to<br />

equity was an “Anglo-saxon” specificity (Mildebrath, 1931, p. 97).<br />

Of course, a significant event of this period was the serious economic crisis of 1929 in<br />

American industry, which had several consequences in terms of treatment of goodwill. Its<br />

main impact was to reinforce the positions of those who saw goodwill as an unstable, if not<br />

undesirable, item: not only was it noted that, as in the previous period, “financiers frequently<br />

deduct all intangible values from the net worth section of the balance sheet when a loan is<br />

being contemplated” (Walker, 1938b, p. 259), but companies themselves appeared to be<br />

continuing such drastic measures in their accounts. A 1931-32 study of listed companies’<br />

financial statements showed that of the 86 balance sheets showing goodwill as a separate<br />

item, 31 of them listed goodwill at $1.00 (Fjeld, 1936, p. 333). While it was true, as one of the<br />

commentators pointed out, that “the practice could have been the result of either a write-up, a<br />

write-down, or of amortization of the cost of purchased goodwill until only a nominal<br />

valuation remained” (Hughes, 1982, p. 99), another study undertaken a little later confirmed a<br />

clear trend in favor of writing down goodwill <strong>and</strong> recording it at a nominal value (Avery,<br />

1942, p. 356, 363).<br />

In general, as Canning (1929, p. 43) or Nobles et al. (1941, p. 198) underline, there was at<br />

the time a “popular practice of writing off”; hence, rapid amortization techniques, either<br />

charging to expenses or even more often, when goodwill was too large for the profits to<br />

“bear”, charging to equity, could very plausibly have been widespread.<br />

31

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!