08.01.2015 Views

6 slides per page

6 slides per page

6 slides per page

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Capital Structure<br />

Managerial Finance, 2008<br />

Konan Chan<br />

Capital Structure and the Pie<br />

• The value of a firm is defined to be the sum of the<br />

value of the firm’s debt and the firm’s equity.<br />

V = B + S<br />

• If the goal of the firm’s<br />

management is to make the firm<br />

as valuable as possible, then the<br />

firm should pick the debt-equity<br />

ratio that makes the pie as big as<br />

possible.<br />

S B<br />

Value of the Firm<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 2<br />

Leverage Effect Example<br />

Current Proposed<br />

Assets $5,000,000 $5,000,000<br />

Debt $0 $2,500,000<br />

Equity $5,000,000 $2,500,000<br />

Debt/Equity Ratio 0 1<br />

Share Price $10 $10<br />

Shares Outstanding 500,000 250,000<br />

Interest rate 10% 10%<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 3<br />

Example<br />

Current Capital Structure: No Debt<br />

Recession Expected Expansion<br />

EBIT $300,000 $650,000 $1,000,000<br />

Interest 0 0 0<br />

Net Income $300,000 $650,000 $1,000,000<br />

ROE 6.00% 13.00% 20.00%<br />

EPS $0.60 $1.30 $2.00<br />

Proposed Capital Structure: Debt = $2.5 million<br />

EBIT $300,000 $650,000 $1,000,000<br />

Interest 250,000 250,000 250,000<br />

Net Income $50,000 $400,000 $750,000<br />

ROE 2.00% 16.00% 30.00%<br />

EPS $0.20 $1.60 $3.00<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 4<br />

Leverage Effect<br />

EPS and EBIT<br />

• When increase financial leverage by more debt<br />

– Let’s ignore tax here for simplicity<br />

– In good year, we have more left-over after paying interests;<br />

in bad year, we have less left-over<br />

– ROE changes from 6%-20% to 2%-30% range<br />

– EPS changes from $.6-$2 to $.2-$3 range<br />

• The variability in both ROE and EPS increases when<br />

financial leverage is increased<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 5<br />

$3.5<br />

$3.0<br />

$2.5<br />

$2.0<br />

$1.5<br />

EPS<br />

$1.0<br />

Break-even Point:<br />

EPS = $1; EBIT = $500,000<br />

$0.5<br />

Current<br />

Proposed<br />

$0.0<br />

$300,000 $650,000 $1,000,000<br />

EBIT<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 6<br />

1


Capital Structure Theory<br />

• Modigliani & Miller Propositions<br />

– No tax (MM,1958)<br />

– With corporate tax (MM, 1963)<br />

– With both corporate and <strong>per</strong>sonal tax (Miller, 1977)<br />

• Trade-off theory<br />

• Pecking order theory (Myers and Majluf, 1984)<br />

• Free cash flow theory (Jensen, 1986)<br />

• Market timing (Baker and Wurgler, 2002)<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 7<br />

Homemade Leverage<br />

Current Capital Structure<br />

• Investor borrows $500 and<br />

uses $500 of her own to buy<br />

100 shares of stock<br />

• Payoffs:<br />

– Recession: 100(0.60) -<br />

.1(500) = $10<br />

– Expected: 100(1.30) - .1(500)<br />

= $80<br />

– Expansion: 100(2.00) -<br />

.1(500) = $150<br />

• Mirrors the payoffs from<br />

purchasing 50 shares from the<br />

firm under the proposed<br />

capital structure<br />

Proposed Capital Structure<br />

• Investor buys $250 worth of<br />

stock (25 shares) and $250<br />

worth of bonds paying 10%.<br />

• Payoffs:<br />

– Recession: 25(.20) + .1(250) =<br />

$30<br />

– Expected: 25(1.60) + .1(250) =<br />

$65<br />

– Expansion: 25(3.00) + .1(250) =<br />

$100<br />

• Mirrors the payoffs from<br />

purchasing 50 shares under the<br />

current capital structure<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 8<br />

MM Propositions (no tax)<br />

• MM proposition I<br />

– Capital structure does affect not firm value or WACC<br />

– WACC keeps the same for any debt ratio<br />

• MM proposition II<br />

– Given proposition I, WACC keeps the same<br />

– WACC = R B (B/V) + R S (S/V) = R 0 where V=B+S<br />

– R S = R 0 + (B/S)(R 0 - R B )<br />

– the expected return on equity increases with the debt-equity<br />

ratio<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 9<br />

Cost of capital: R (%)<br />

MM Proposition II (No Taxes)<br />

B<br />

RS<br />

= R 0<br />

+ × ( R 0<br />

− R B<br />

)<br />

S<br />

R B<br />

R 0 R<br />

WACC<br />

B S<br />

= × RB<br />

+ × RS<br />

B + S B + S<br />

R B<br />

Debt-to-equity Ratio<br />

B<br />

S<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 10<br />

L<br />

Example: MM w/o Tax<br />

• Suppose required return on assets = 16%, cost of debt<br />

= 10%, debt/assets = 45%<br />

• What is the cost of equity<br />

– R S = 16% + (16% - 10%)(.45/.55) = 20.91%<br />

• Suppose the cost of equity is 25%, what is the debtto-equity<br />

ratio What is equity/assets<br />

– 25% = 16% + (16% - 10%)(B/S)<br />

– B/S = (25% - 16%) / (16% - 10%) = 1.5<br />

– S/V = 1 / 2.5 = 40%<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 11<br />

Tax Shield<br />

• Compare unlevered (U) with levered firm (L: 4 million debt,<br />

r B<br />

= 10% )<br />

U L<br />

EBIT 1,000,000 1,000,000<br />

Interests (r B * B) 0 -400,000<br />

EBT 1,000,000 600,000<br />

Taxes (T C = 0.35) -350,000 -210,000<br />

Earnings 650,000 390,000 (EBIT - r B B)(1-T C )<br />

Total cash flows 650,000 790,000<br />

• The difference between 790,000 and 650,000 is 140,000<br />

(T C<br />

r B<br />

B = 0.35 * 0.1 * 4,000,000)<br />

• T C<br />

r B<br />

B: tax shield from debt - the advantage of using debt<br />

(disadvantage of equity financing)<br />

EBIT(1-T C ) + T C r B B<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 12<br />

2


MM Theory with Taxes<br />

• If tax shield is <strong>per</strong>petual,<br />

PV of tax shield = B * R B * T C / R B = T C * B<br />

• Value of levered firm (V L )<br />

= unlevered firm value (V U ) + PV of tax shield<br />

= EBIT(1- T C ) / R 0 + T C * D<br />

• More debt is better, because the interest deduction<br />

generates extra value (save tax)<br />

• R WACC = (S/V)R S + (B/V)(R B )(1-T C )<br />

• R S = R 0 + (R 0 – R B )(B/S)(1-T C )<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 13<br />

MM Propositions (with corp. tax)<br />

• MM proposition I (with tax)<br />

– Capital structure does matter<br />

EBIT (1 −TC<br />

) TC<br />

RBB<br />

– VL =<br />

+ = VU<br />

+ TC<br />

B<br />

R0<br />

RB<br />

• MM proposition II<br />

– The cost of equity is positively related to leverage<br />

– R<br />

S<br />

B<br />

= R0 + ( 1−TC<br />

)( r0<br />

− RB<br />

)<br />

S<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 14<br />

Cost of capital: R<br />

(%)<br />

The Effect of Financial Leverage<br />

B<br />

RS<br />

= R 0<br />

+ × ( R 0<br />

− R B<br />

)<br />

S<br />

B<br />

RS<br />

= R0 + × ( 1−TC<br />

) × ( R0<br />

− RB<br />

)<br />

SL<br />

R 0<br />

R B<br />

B<br />

L<br />

R<br />

WACC<br />

=<br />

B + S<br />

L<br />

× RB<br />

× (1 −TC<br />

) + ×<br />

B + SL<br />

L<br />

S<br />

R<br />

S<br />

Example - MM with Tax<br />

• Suppose EBIT is 25 million, tax rate 35%, debt $75<br />

million, cost of debt 9%, unlevered cost of capital 12%<br />

• V U = 25(1-.35) / .12 = $135.42 million<br />

• V L = 135.42 + 75(.35) = $161.67 million<br />

• S = 161.67 – 75 = $86.67 million<br />

• R S = 12% + (12%-9%)(75/86.67)(1-.35) = 13.69%<br />

• R WACC = (86.67/161.67)(13.69%) +<br />

(75/161.67)(9%)(1-.35) = 10.05%<br />

Debt-to-equity<br />

ratio (B/S)<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 15<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 16<br />

Example - MM with Tax<br />

• Suppose that the firm changes its capital structure so<br />

that the debt-to-equity ratio becomes 1.<br />

• What will happen to the cost of equity under the new<br />

capital structure<br />

– R S = 12% + (12% - 9%)(1)(1-.35) = 13.95%<br />

• What will happen to the weighted average cost of<br />

capital<br />

– R WACC = .5(13.95%) + .5(9%)(1-.35) = 9.9%<br />

Miller Theory<br />

• Allow both corporate and <strong>per</strong>sonal tax to exist<br />

⎛ (1 − TC<br />

)(1 − TS<br />

) ⎞<br />

V<br />

⎜<br />

⎟<br />

L<br />

= VU<br />

+ B 1−<br />

⎝ (1 − TB<br />

) ⎠<br />

• The cost of equity is positively related to leverage<br />

B ⎛ (1 − TC<br />

)(1 − TS<br />

) ⎞<br />

rS<br />

= r0 +<br />

( r0<br />

rB<br />

)<br />

S<br />

⎜<br />

(1 TB<br />

)<br />

⎟ −<br />

⎝ − ⎠<br />

• In some cases, capital structure will not matter; i.e.,<br />

back to original MM propositions w/o tax<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 17<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 18<br />

3


MM in Reality and Trade-off<br />

• In reality, no firm takes the extreme step of using<br />

100% debt financing as implied by MM with tax<br />

• MM ignored the costs of bankruptcy in their analysis<br />

of MM with taxes<br />

• By including the cost of bankruptcy, there is a tradeoff<br />

between the benefits of debt financing (tax<br />

shields) against costs of debt financing (increased<br />

risk of bankruptcy)<br />

• Firm value = unlevered firm value + PV tax shield -<br />

PV of financial distress costs<br />

Costs of Financial Distress<br />

• Direct costs<br />

– Legal and administrative costs (lawyers, accountants,<br />

professional witness, …etc.)<br />

– About 3% of market value (Warner, 1977)<br />

• Indirect costs<br />

– Impaired ability to conduct business (lost sales)<br />

– Agency costs of debt (over-investment (Jensen and<br />

Meckling, 1976), under-investment (Myers and Majluf,<br />

1984))<br />

– Costly managerial efforts<br />

– Employee’s unwillingness to work (wage reduction, search<br />

new jobs)<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 19<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 20<br />

Trade-off Theory<br />

• Trade-off between the benefits (tax shields) and costs<br />

(financial distress) of using debt<br />

• There exists an optimal level of debt which maximizes the<br />

firm value<br />

Firm Value<br />

V U<br />

PV(costs of financial distress)<br />

B*<br />

V L = V U + T C B<br />

PV(tax shields)<br />

Debt<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 21<br />

Factors Affect Trade-off<br />

• Growth<br />

– high growth firms should use less debt<br />

– because their growth potential will be easily destroyed by<br />

financial distress<br />

• Types of assets<br />

– firms with more intangible assets should have less debt<br />

(high-tech. vs. airlines) because firms with tangible assets<br />

can sell assets to recover from financial distress<br />

• Uncertainty of o<strong>per</strong>ating income<br />

– firms with more uncertain o<strong>per</strong>ating income should have<br />

less debt (software vs. utilities) because these firms have a<br />

high probability of ex<strong>per</strong>iencing financial distress<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 22<br />

Pecking Order Theory<br />

• Theory<br />

– Firms heavily rely on internally generated funds<br />

– When needs external financing is necessary, debt is the<br />

primary way to get financing<br />

– Equity is the last resort to finance projects<br />

• Rationale<br />

– Information asymmetry causes difficulty in pricing equity<br />

– Firm will issue over-valued shares only and thus investors<br />

discount shares<br />

– Firms prefer to use internally generated funds<br />

– Bonds are safer than equity because valuation of bonds is<br />

less affected by information asymmetry<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 23<br />

Implications from Pecking Order<br />

• Theory<br />

– No defined target (optimal) capital structure<br />

– Most profitable firms generally borrow less is not because they have<br />

low target debt ratios but because they don’t need outside money<br />

– Less profitable firms issue debt because debt financing is first on the<br />

pecking order of external financing<br />

– Firms will avoid external financing, if with enough internal funds<br />

• Financial slack<br />

– Cash buildup, low debt level, and ready access to debt financing<br />

– Financial slack is valuable because it avoids the costs of financial<br />

distress and external financing during bad times<br />

– It’s more valuable if firms with more positive NPV projects<br />

– Explains why growth firms have low debt ratios<br />

– Time the issues in good times to reserve financial slack<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 24<br />

4


Agency Costs<br />

• What is the agency relationship<br />

– The relationship between the principal and agent<br />

– The agent is hired by the principal to act on behalf of the<br />

principal<br />

– Examples: stockholders and the manager, investors and<br />

fund manager, landlord and tenant<br />

• Is there any problem<br />

– Will the agent always act in the interests of the principal<br />

Why<br />

– Conflict of interests ⇒ agency costs<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 25<br />

Types of Agency Problems<br />

• Agency problem between stockholders and the manager<br />

(agency costs of equity)<br />

– Shirking<br />

– Perquisites<br />

– Over-investment<br />

– Wasting free cash flows (free cash flows are cash flows in excess of<br />

that required to fund all positive NPV projects)<br />

• Agency problem between stockholders and bondholders<br />

(agency costs of debt)<br />

– Over-investment (risk-shifting/asset substitution)<br />

– Under-investment (pass out positive NPV projects)<br />

– Milking the pro<strong>per</strong>ty (cash in and run)<br />

– Bait and switch (promise to do safe project,but invest in risky project)<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 26<br />

Over-Investment Problem<br />

• When a firm is in financial distress, and there is a<br />

risky project (high payoff with very small chance)<br />

• What will the shareholders do<br />

Over-Investment (Risk-Shifting)<br />

• Stockholders have only limited liabilities<br />

• Given financial distress, shareholders will be<br />

forced to give up the ownership<br />

• If head I win, if tail you lose:<br />

– Stockholders shift the project risks to bondholders. So,<br />

stockholders gain at the expense of bondholders<br />

• Financial distress leads stockholders to take high<br />

risks<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 27<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 28<br />

Under-Investment Problem<br />

• The firm is in financial distress and has a safe<br />

positive project, but it is short of cash<br />

• What will shareholders do Raise money to take the<br />

project or not<br />

Under-Investments<br />

• Stockholders and bondholders share the benefits of<br />

positive NPV projects<br />

• So, shareholders will pass up the positive NPV<br />

project<br />

• Financial distress destroys the investment policy<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 29<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 30<br />

5


Ways to Reduce Agency Costs:<br />

• Align interests of the manager and stockholders<br />

– The threat of firing<br />

– (Hostile) Takeover<br />

– Managerial compensation<br />

– Leveraged buyouts (LBOs): pro and con<br />

• Align interests of the stockholders and bondholders<br />

– Protective covenants<br />

– Consolidation of debt<br />

– Strip financing<br />

RJR Nabisco LBOs:<br />

Stock price Bond value<br />

• Oct. 27, 1988 (before ann.) $56 $5.0 billion<br />

• Oct. 28, 1988 (after ann.) $75 $4.4 billion<br />

• Nov. 30, 1988 (final bid) $109<br />

• KKR won the bid (25 billion in total), even though<br />

the management bid $3 more<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 31<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 32<br />

Free Cash Flow Theory<br />

• Managers have incentives to not distribute free cash<br />

flows and cause their firms to grow beyond the<br />

optimal size<br />

• The use of debt and corporate market control<br />

(takeovers, LBOs) can help to reduce the agency<br />

costs of free cash flows<br />

– benefits of using debt<br />

– ways to reduce the agency cost of equity<br />

• Example: Oil industry in 80’s<br />

Agency Cost of Equity<br />

• An individual will work harder for a firm if he is one of the<br />

owners than if he is one of the “hired help.”<br />

• While managers may have motive to partake in <strong>per</strong>quisites,<br />

they also need opportunity. Free cash flow provides this<br />

opportunity.<br />

• The free cash flow hypothesis says that an increase in<br />

dividends should benefit the stockholders by reducing the<br />

ability of managers to pursue wasteful activities.<br />

• The free cash flow hypothesis also argues that an increase in<br />

debt will reduce the ability of managers to pursue wasteful<br />

activities more effectively than dividend increases.<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 33<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 34<br />

Market Timing Theory<br />

Market Value Debt Ratios, 2002<br />

• Managers “time” the market and issue equity when<br />

the market price is high<br />

– Loughran and Ritter (1995) find issuers under<strong>per</strong>form after<br />

equity issuance<br />

• The market timing has long and <strong>per</strong>sistent effect on<br />

capital structure<br />

– Capital structure is the outcome of managers’ past attempt<br />

to issue equity opportunistically<br />

Company<br />

Microsoft<br />

Intel<br />

ExxonMobil<br />

Merck<br />

Procter & Gamble<br />

Boeing<br />

Walt Disney<br />

Debt/Assets<br />

0<br />

0<br />

0.04<br />

0.08<br />

0.12<br />

0.27<br />

0.27<br />

LT debt/capital<br />

0<br />

0<br />

0.03<br />

0.04<br />

0.07<br />

0.24<br />

0.25<br />

M/B<br />

5.54<br />

4.03<br />

3.72<br />

7.18<br />

10.13<br />

3.65<br />

1.92<br />

American Electric Power<br />

0.54<br />

0.36<br />

1.62<br />

Delta Air Lines<br />

0.77<br />

0.75<br />

0.82<br />

General Motors<br />

0.84<br />

0.83<br />

4.12<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 35<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 36<br />

6


Country<br />

Leverage Ratios<br />

Total debt to<br />

total asset<br />

(Book value %)<br />

LT debt to total<br />

assets<br />

(Book value %)<br />

LT debt to total<br />

capital<br />

(Market value %)<br />

United States 58% 37% 28%<br />

Japan 69 53 29<br />

Germany 73 38 23<br />

France 71 48 41<br />

Italy 70 47 46<br />

UK 54 28 35<br />

Canada 56 39 35<br />

India 67 34 35<br />

South Korea 73 49 64<br />

Capital Structure Patterns Worldwide<br />

• Capital structures have strong industry patterns<br />

– High: utilities, transport, and capital-intensive manufacture<br />

– Low: service, mining, most rapidly growing or high-tech<br />

– The industry's asset mix and variability affect capital structure<br />

• Capital structures vary across countries<br />

– US, UK, Canadian firms have lower book debt ratios than firms<br />

in Japan, France, and Italy<br />

– US & German firms have lower market value debt ratios<br />

– Leverage in developing countries is less than developed ones<br />

– Historical, institutional, & cultural factors may play a part<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 37<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 38<br />

Capital Structure Patterns Worldwide<br />

• Leverage ratios are inversely related to the <strong>per</strong>ceived costs of<br />

financial distress.<br />

– Both across industries & across countries, the more costly is financial<br />

distress, the less debt will be used.<br />

– Companies rich in collateralizeable assets have higher leverage than<br />

firms rich in growth options.<br />

• Within industries, leverage is inversely related to profitability<br />

– In all industries, the most profitable firms typically borrow the least<br />

• Taxes influence capital structures, but they cannot explain the<br />

differences in leverage across industries and countries<br />

– Increased corporate tax rates yield increased debt usage<br />

– It’s not clear firms in US use more debt now<br />

Capital Structure Patterns Worldwide<br />

• Existing shareholders consider leverage-increasing events<br />

"good news" and leverage-decreasing events "bad news"<br />

– Stock prices rise when leverage-increasing events announced, but fall<br />

for leverage-decreasing events.<br />

• Corporations that are forced away from a preferred capital<br />

structure tend to return to that structure over time<br />

– Has occurred frequently, particularly for US firms that have taken on<br />

large amounts of new debt to finance takeovers.<br />

– More generally, corporations like to o<strong>per</strong>ate within target leverage<br />

zones, and will issue new equity when debt ratios get too high and<br />

will issue debt if they fall too low.<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 39<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 40<br />

Negative news for Equity offerings<br />

Positive news for leverage-increasing<br />

Security type<br />

Common stock<br />

Preferred stock<br />

Convertible preferred stock<br />

Straight bonds<br />

Convertible bonds<br />

Two-day announcement<strong>per</strong>iod<br />

abnormal return<br />

-3.14%<br />

-0.19%<br />

-1.44%<br />

-0.26%<br />

-2.07%<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 41<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 42<br />

7


Rajan and Zingales (1995)<br />

US Financing Pattern<br />

90<br />

Historical US financing patterns<br />

60<br />

30<br />

0<br />

-30<br />

79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02<br />

Internal Debt Equity<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 43<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 44<br />

Junk Bonds<br />

• Low-grade bonds, with high default risks, but offer high<br />

yield.<br />

• Prior to 1970, most junk bonds are “Fallen Angels”.<br />

• From late 1970, Michael Milken of Drexel Burnham Lambert<br />

changed the market by creating the demand and supply of the<br />

junk bonds.<br />

• Junk bonds grew rapidly from 1984 to 1989, changing the<br />

corporate finance in 80s.<br />

• Small firms can get a huge amount of financing through junk<br />

bonds, where they were not allowed to do so in the past<br />

• Threat of hostile takeover, wave of mergers and acquisitions,<br />

popularity of share repurchases<br />

LBOs<br />

• The acquisition by a small group of investors<br />

financed primarily with debt.<br />

• Going private transaction, usually with very high<br />

debt ratio after LBOs.<br />

• Top ten LBOs happened in 1986-1989.<br />

• Too much money was chasing too few good deals<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 45<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 46<br />

The Development<br />

• The increasing defaulted events in late 80s increased<br />

the burden of DBL.<br />

• Milken was charged for securities fraud, and DBL<br />

filed bankruptcy in 1990.<br />

• Junk bond market collapsed in 1990, so as the<br />

decline of LBOs.<br />

Junk Bonds and M&A<br />

Amount<br />

Junk Bonds Issues<br />

160000<br />

80%<br />

140000<br />

70%<br />

120000<br />

60%<br />

100000<br />

50%<br />

80000<br />

40%<br />

60000<br />

30%<br />

40000<br />

20%<br />

20000<br />

10%<br />

0<br />

0%<br />

80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99<br />

Amount M&A%<br />

Year<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 47<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 48<br />

8


Junk Bonds and Default<br />

Amount<br />

Junk Bonds Issues<br />

800<br />

12%<br />

700<br />

10%<br />

600<br />

8%<br />

500<br />

400<br />

6%<br />

300<br />

4%<br />

200<br />

2%<br />

100<br />

0<br />

0%<br />

80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99<br />

New issues Default<br />

Year<br />

Testing Trade-off<br />

• Supportive<br />

– Significant negative relationship between R&D and debt<br />

– Leverage is positively related to tangibility of assets, but<br />

negatively related to growth opportunity. Leverage is also<br />

positively related to sales (firm size)<br />

• Against<br />

– Profitability is negatively related to leverage<br />

– Stock prices increase for leverage-increasing<br />

announcements, and stock prices decrease for leveragedecreasing<br />

announcements<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 49<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 50<br />

Testing Pecking Order<br />

• Supportive<br />

– Inverse relationship between profitability and financial<br />

leverage within industries<br />

– Stock prices increase for leverage-increasing<br />

announcements, and stock prices decrease for leveragedecreasing<br />

announcements<br />

– Leverage is positively related to firm size<br />

• Against<br />

– Cannot explain the inter-industry differences in debt ratios<br />

– Leverage is positively related to tangibility of assets<br />

Testing Free Cash Flow<br />

• Supportive<br />

– Stock prices increase for leverage-increasing<br />

announcements, and stock prices decrease for leveragedecreasing<br />

announcements<br />

• Against<br />

– Leverage is positively related to tangibility of assets<br />

– Profitability is negatively related to leverage<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 51<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 52<br />

Testing Market Timing<br />

• (M/B) efwa is the weighted average of historical<br />

market-to-book ratios, giving more weight when<br />

firms issue more equity<br />

Graham and Harvey (2001)<br />

• Survey on 392 corporate managers (CFOs) to see if<br />

theories match practice<br />

• For each question, managers rate their answers from<br />

0~4<br />

– 0 means they never care about it<br />

– 4 means it’s important<br />

– Summarized by <strong>per</strong>centage of CFOs answer 3 or 4<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 53<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 54<br />

9


Survey on Debt Issue Decision<br />

Trade-Off in Practice<br />

• CFOs think that the corporate tax advantage of debt<br />

is moderately important (rating: 2.07, 45%)<br />

– It’s more important for large, higher levered, dividendpaying,<br />

manufacturing, regulated, public firms<br />

• Distress is not very important (rating: 1.24, 21%)<br />

• Almost 60% CFOs think flexibility and credit rating<br />

are important factors in raising debt, an evidence<br />

saying that they want to avoid distress<br />

• Earnings volatility is important when making debt<br />

decisions (rating: 2.32, 48%)<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 55<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 56<br />

Target Debt Ratio<br />

Trade-Off in Practice<br />

• Targets that are tight or somewhat strict are more<br />

common for<br />

– large firms (55%) than for small firms (36%)<br />

– investment-grade (64%) than speculative firms (41%)<br />

– regulated (67%) than unregulated firms (43%)<br />

• Given large investment-grade firms represent the big<br />

portion of the economy, the evidence fairly strongly<br />

supports the trade-off theory<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 57<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 58<br />

Pecking Order in Practice<br />

• Financial flexibility is the most important item about<br />

corporate debt decisions (rating: 2.59, 59%)<br />

• Insufficient internal funds is important in debt<br />

issuance decisions (rating: 2.13, 47%)<br />

• Flexibility is more important for dividend-paying<br />

firms, which are thought to have less information<br />

asymmetry<br />

• No strong evidence that firms issue equity because<br />

recent profits are insufficient to fund activities, or<br />

because the ability to obtain funds from debt is<br />

diminished<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 59<br />

Pecking Order in Practice<br />

• The importance of financial flexibility (financial<br />

slack) and insufficient internal fund to security<br />

issuance decisions is generally consistent with the<br />

pecking-order model<br />

• But, the desire for flexibility and the claim of<br />

insufficient funds are not driven by information<br />

asymmetry, the factors behind the pecking order<br />

theory<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 60<br />

10


Survey on Equity Issue Decision<br />

Pecking Order and Equity Issue<br />

• Undervaluation is important when firms avoid to<br />

issue equity, consistent with pecking order<br />

• But, large, dividend-paying firms are more likely to<br />

think this is important than small, nondividendpaying<br />

firms<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 61<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 62<br />

Agency Cost in Practice<br />

• Jensen (1986) argue that when a firm has ample free<br />

cash flow, its managers tend to waste<br />

• Firms can use debt to commit to pay out free cash<br />

flow and discipline management to work efficiently<br />

• Little evidence that firms discipline managers in this<br />

way. It is important to note, that<br />

– managers might be unwilling to admit to using debt in this<br />

manner<br />

– <strong>per</strong>haps a low rating on this question reflects an<br />

unwillingness of firms to adopt Jensen’s solution more<br />

than a weakness in Jensen’s argument<br />

Managerial Finance Konan Chan 63<br />

11

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!