18.11.2014 Views

Monitor Vol 39 08_Final_Nov08.pdf - tips

Monitor Vol 39 08_Final_Nov08.pdf - tips

Monitor Vol 39 08_Final_Nov08.pdf - tips

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Industrial Policy<br />

42<br />

Trade & Industry <strong>Monitor</strong><br />

the department of economic development and tourism of the provincial<br />

government and other stakeholders with an interest and knowledge of<br />

the sector. These SPVs function effectively as sector development organisations.<br />

The objective is not merely to develop existing firms, but critically<br />

to also enhance opportunities for new entrants – notably small firms and<br />

particularly black and female owned and managed firms.<br />

The provincial government supports SPVs that are broadly representative<br />

and that have considerable legitimacy within the sector. Ideally, membership<br />

of the SPV should be diverse and include small firms. Government<br />

can have some confidence that policy proposals that emanate from such<br />

associations are likely to have broad legitimacy within the sector. The task<br />

of government is to support those proposals that will develop the sector<br />

in a manner that accords with governmental objectives of both growth<br />

and equity.<br />

The principal role of the SPVs is to institutionalise the exchange of information<br />

between the private sector and government. The SPVs allow for<br />

government to obtain information as to firms’ future investments and the<br />

factors that are promoting and restraining investment activity. They are<br />

the institutional mechanism through which potential policies to support<br />

the sector are discussed and debated and ultimately presented to the<br />

provincial government for assistance.<br />

Moreover, the role of the SPVs is not confined to discussing policy proposals.<br />

SPVs may well engage directly in implementation. The provincial<br />

government may grant funding support for a proposal that emanates from<br />

an SPV and task that organisation with ensuring that the programme is<br />

carried out and that the funding is spent effectively. Governmental capacities<br />

are not solely limited in terms of policy formulation. Arguably, an<br />

even more critical constraint lies in government’s capacity to implement.<br />

SPVs, or other institutional forms of sector organisation, “… can carry<br />

much of the burden of industrial policy – both in its design and in its<br />

implementation, thus economising on limited governmental capacities.”<br />

(Kaplan, 2006).<br />

As regards funding, the MEDS favours a co-funding mechanism. Since<br />

many of the market failures are partial rather than total, some of the funding<br />

support can and should come from the beneficiaries themselves. Thus,<br />

in regard to training for example, since firms will gain at least some of the<br />

benefits of training expenditures, government support for training programmes<br />

can be partial. This limits the deployment of government fiscal<br />

resources. At the same time, this gives government a significant measure<br />

of security that public monies are being spent in projects to which the intended<br />

beneficiaries, who possess far more information than government<br />

as to their real development needs, are prepared to commit their own<br />

resources (Western Cape Government, Department of Economic Development<br />

and Tourism, 2005: 136).<br />

The institutional design proposed here is certainly not free of risk. The<br />

capacities required of government are still far from trivial. The danger<br />

of governmental capture, always real, may be enhanced where a close<br />

relationship is cultivated with business associations and where, in addition,<br />

government capacities are weak. But, however this is structured<br />

institutionally, in the present context in South Africa, the design and development<br />

of effective industrial policy will necessitate a major role for<br />

business.<br />

Institutional arrangements will necessarily evolve and change over time.<br />

It is of critical importance that the institutional design of industrial policy<br />

embodies feedback mechanisms and structured monitoring and evaluation,<br />

something that has been largely lacking from previous policies. This<br />

will enable governmental capacities to grow with experience - a version of<br />

learning by doing (Western Cape Government, Department of Economic<br />

Development, 2005: Chapter 6). As its own capacities enhance and develop,<br />

government will then be in a position to be more effective and also<br />

more adventurous in advancing its industrial policies.<br />

References<br />

Alves, P. and Kaplan. D. (2004) South Africa’s Declining Export Shares: The<br />

Developing Country Challenge Trade and Industry <strong>Monitor</strong> (June) vol. 30<br />

pps. 2-6.<br />

Accelerated and Shared Growth Initiative South Africa (ASGISA) (2006)<br />

Background Document. Media Briefing by the Deputy President Pumzile<br />

Mlambo- Ngcuka. A Summary. (February 6)<br />

Chang, H. J. (1996) The Political Economy of Industrial Policy Macmillan,<br />

London.<br />

Department of Economic Development, Western Cape (2005). Micro-economic<br />

Development Strategy for the Western Cape. Synthesis Report. Version<br />

1. July. Department of Economic Development, Western Cape.<br />

Department of Trade and Industry (the dti) (2002) Accelerating Growth<br />

and Development. The Contribution of the Integrated Manufacturing<br />

Strategy. DTI, Pretoria.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!