14.11.2014 Views

Authors Iain Begg | Gabriel Glöckler | Anke Hassel ... - The Europaeum

Authors Iain Begg | Gabriel Glöckler | Anke Hassel ... - The Europaeum

Authors Iain Begg | Gabriel Glöckler | Anke Hassel ... - The Europaeum

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

flexible labour regulation than countries like Finland or Germany, where<br />

the value of capitalisation is less and information networks between banks<br />

and firms’ management are more dense. 8<br />

Different institutional complementarities, however, do not imply a<br />

different capacity to cope with globalisation pressures. On the contrary,<br />

different economies will develop responses depending on their countryspecific<br />

comparative advantage. In other words, the VoC predicts<br />

that countries will react differently to similar pressures, meaning that<br />

globalisation is unlikely to result in convergence towards a single economic<br />

model. 9 Another important result of the VoC is that there appears to be no<br />

systematic difference between LMEs and CMEs in terms of overall income<br />

levels and growth rates. However, LMEs tend to have higher participation<br />

rates in the labour market and a more unequal income distribution,<br />

compared to CMEs. Additionally, the two ideal-types of capitalist<br />

economies will tend to specialise in different patterns of innovation and<br />

competition and therefore in different industrial sectors.<br />

In LMEs, the higher degree of flexibility and mobility with market-based<br />

modes of firm relations incentivises radical forms of innovation, and<br />

strategies based on price competition. In CMEs, in contrast, cooperation<br />

between capital and labour lends itself to incremental forms of process<br />

and product innovation, as well as quality-based competition strategies.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se diametrically opposed incentives result in different comparative<br />

advantages so that, in the traded sector, CMES and LMEs tend to specialise<br />

in different industries and to develop patents on different categories of<br />

goods.<br />

Under this framework, policymakers must pay due regard to the<br />

implications of economic reform for different spheres of the political<br />

economy. To put it simply, the interplay between institutions implies that<br />

a limited number of combinations are both feasible and optimal.<br />

Lisbon through the looking glass<br />

<strong>The</strong> VoC approach, it is important to recognise, would be ambivalent about<br />

the very idea of the Lisbon Strategy. According to this school of political<br />

economy, the competitive advantage of economies blossoms from the<br />

bottom up rather than thriving from the top down, leaving little room for<br />

government intervention. As such, attempts by EU policymakers to “build<br />

a knowledge-based economy” and, latterly, to foster “growth and jobs”<br />

would smack of government overreach for proponents of VoC. Similarly,<br />

the focus on national economies as a key unit of analysis means that<br />

118<br />

After the crisis: A new socio-economic settlement for the EU

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!