12.11.2014 Views

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

sidered two major commercial banks,<br />

one regional rural bank and one private<br />

commercial bank from the southern<br />

states of Tamil Nadu and Kerala. <strong>The</strong><br />

estimated transaction cost was 3.68 percent<br />

of the loan amount if the loan was<br />

delivered through a direct lending<br />

channel. <strong>The</strong> literature on micro-credit<br />

(see (Ghatak, 2000) and (de Aghion<br />

and Gollier, 2000)) argues that group<br />

lending to the poor through Non-Governmental<br />

Organization (NGO) and<br />

Self Help Group (SHG) may be an efficient<br />

method of credit delivery system.<br />

In 1991, the RBI initiated the policy of<br />

encouraging direct linkages between<br />

the banks and NGO and SHG due to<br />

the presence of high transaction costs.<br />

Puhazhendhi (1995) estimated the financial<br />

intermediation of NGO and<br />

SHG reduced transaction costs by between<br />

21 and 41 percent relative to the<br />

direct lending channel. In spite of these<br />

efforts transaction costs remain high<br />

even after a decade of reform. <strong>The</strong> estimated<br />

opportunity cost of existing<br />

high transaction costs in India is<br />

still high. 8<br />

Though heading in the right direction,<br />

prudential norms are yet to reach<br />

global standards. <strong>The</strong> pace of restructuring<br />

nationalized banks through privatization<br />

is slow. This is mainly because<br />

nationalized banks’ balance<br />

sheets are weak due to accumulated<br />

NPA over the past three decades. <strong>The</strong><br />

government needs to clean up balance<br />

sheets by recapitalization and other<br />

measures in order to make these banks<br />

more attractive to investors. Given recent<br />

trends on the magnitude of NPA<br />

(Table 5) the cost of restructuring appears<br />

to be very high, particularly since<br />

it is already running very high deficits.<br />

Such liabilities on the government to<br />

revive the banking sector (contingent<br />

liabilitie000s), are significant in the<br />

case of India. <strong>The</strong> impact of contingent<br />

liabilities is now examined.<br />

4.2. Contingent Liabilities<br />

<strong>The</strong> financial sector in transition and<br />

developing economies is characterized<br />

by poor regulatory and enforcement<br />

systems, and inadequate disclosure of<br />

information which may lead to a high<br />

incidence of NPA. When the banking<br />

sector is in stress, out of legal obligation<br />

or political compulsion the central government<br />

has to rescue the banks. Such<br />

public financing by government represents<br />

its contingent liabilities and can<br />

potentially lead to a large increase in<br />

public debt. Because of their uncertain<br />

nature these contingent liabilities are<br />

unbudgeted and, hence, are hidden fiscal<br />

risks. Contingent liabilities are also<br />

important because the government cannot<br />

achieve its long-run objective of a<br />

sound fiscal system without addressing<br />

the problem. Explicit contingent liabilities<br />

are specific obligations which the<br />

government has to settle under a contract<br />

or a law. <strong>The</strong>se include obligations<br />

issued to state governments and public<br />

sector banks, etc. <strong>The</strong> government can<br />

foresee such guarantees and includes<br />

them in its budget constraint. 9<br />

However, contingent liabilities or implicit<br />

liabilities are uncertain and their<br />

realization is dependent on the probability<br />

of particular events. Sometimes,<br />

these events could be totally exogenous<br />

to government policy, e.g., an earthquake<br />

or any other natural disaster.<br />

Most of the time, these liabilities are a<br />

result of government policy. One interesting<br />

example is a guarantee extended<br />

by government to foreign creditors of<br />

domestic banks. <strong>The</strong>se guarantees may<br />

lead to moral hazard problems in the<br />

banking sector as banks may take high<br />

risks, eventually leading to default on<br />

foreign loanswww, and pressure on the<br />

government to bail them out because of<br />

It is argued that under current ineffi ciencies in the banking<br />

sector, any efforts by government to ensure macroeconomic<br />

stabilization or restructuring will involve an offsetting<br />

effect, adversely affecting the initial policy objectives,<br />

which will transmit mainly through the financial sector<br />

public expectations or political compulsion<br />

(For a detailed model see (Sharma,<br />

2004)). One relevant case study in this<br />

regard is the crisis in the UTI mutual<br />

fund discussed in section 5.<br />

Contingent implicit liabilities are<br />

normally calculated after the event occurs,<br />

as they are dependent on the probability<br />

of the triggering event, the actual<br />

loss and the amount government<br />

pays to bail out the system. (Polackova,<br />

1999) notes the financial systems represent<br />

the most serious contingent implicit<br />

liability. For example the cost of<br />

resolving past banking crises varies<br />

from around 1 percent of GDP (Thailand<br />

1983-87) to around 55 percent of<br />

GDP (Argentina 1980-82) depending<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

127

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!