12.11.2014 Views

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

THE<br />

INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

<strong>2007</strong><br />

<strong>Volume</strong> 4 | <strong>Quarterly</strong> <strong>Issue</strong>: 31st <strong>Dec</strong>ember <strong>2007</strong><br />

www.iipmthinktank.com<br />

www.gidf.org<br />

REIMAGINING INDIA:<br />

MORE MARKET,<br />

RETHINK<br />

EDIFY<br />

DELINEATE<br />

LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

INSIDE THIS ISSUE<br />

Development Agenda<br />

<strong>The</strong> Visible Hand<br />

Free Exchange<br />

India Re-examined<br />

Progress Within Limits<br />

<strong>The</strong> Other Path<br />

A New Beginning<br />

A N I I P M T H I N K T A N K<br />

&<br />

G R E A T I N D I A N D R E A M F O U N D A T I O N P R E S E N T A T I O N


THE GREAT INDIAN DREAM<br />

“Let us together dream of a country where poor are<br />

not just merely reduced to statistics but where there are<br />

no poor. Let there be a day when small children are<br />

taken to a poverty museum like science museum where<br />

they shiver at the plight of the way people used to live in<br />

the last millennium. Let this dream take the form of a<br />

revolution and as long as our dreams keep outweighing<br />

our memories, India would remain a young and dynamic<br />

nation on this path to global equality. And for this let the<br />

wait not be for eternity. Let us together achieve this in<br />

the next 25 years.”<br />

Prof. Arindam Chaudhuri<br />

<strong>The</strong> Great Indian Dream, 2003, Macmillan India,New Delhi<br />

“A Society where man is at the centre of all activities,<br />

a society where exploitation of man by man has been<br />

abolished, where he is cared for as an in a family, where<br />

“to each according to his need’ is practised, a society where<br />

non bureaucratic National Economic Planning is given<br />

due importance for sustainable optimum growth, where<br />

adequate social safety net is a reality and yet market’s<br />

advantages are fully taken care of for creativity and<br />

entrepreneurship, such a society can be truly described as<br />

humane society and the vision as “Humanism”.<br />

Dr. M K Chaudhuri<br />

<strong>The</strong> Great Indian Dream, 2003, Macmillan India,New Delhi<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate


ethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

4 edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate<br />

CREDITS<br />

Founder<br />

Dr. M. K. Chaudhuri<br />

Editor-in-Chief<br />

Arindam Chaudhuri<br />

Managing Editor<br />

Prasoon.S. Majumdar<br />

Deputy Editor<br />

M.N.V.V.K. Chaitanya<br />

Consulting Editor<br />

Prashanto Banerji<br />

Research Fellows<br />

Pathikrit Payne<br />

Sray Agarwal<br />

Akram Hoque<br />

Tanaya Bose<br />

Group Design Director<br />

Satyajit Datta<br />

Senior Designer<br />

Amit Sharma<br />

Designer<br />

Dinesh Chandelkar<br />

Saurabh Mishra<br />

Production Manager<br />

Gurudas Mallik Thakur<br />

Production Supervisors<br />

Digember Singh Chauhan<br />

Soumyajeet Gupta<br />

Chief Marketing Advisor<br />

Amit Saxena<br />

Marketing & Sales<br />

Neha Malhotra<br />

Principal Offices<br />

Satbari, Chandan Haula, Chattarpur, Bhatimines Road, New Delhi - 110074<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, Junction of , 32nd Road & S.V. Road, Bandra (W), Mumbai - 400 050<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, 419 100ft. Road, Koramngala, Bangalore - 560 034<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, 893/4, Bhandarkar Road, <strong>Dec</strong>can Gymkhana, Pune - 411 004<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, 145, Marshall’s Road, Egmore, Chennai - 600 008<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower , 19, Inqulab Society, gulbai Tekra, Off C.G. Road, Ahmedabad - 380 015<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, 6-3-252/2, Erramanzil, Banjara Hills, Hyderabad - 500 082<br />

We are keen to hear from anyone, who would like to share their experiences concerning Indian<br />

economic issues, or would like to know more about<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Publications. You can e-mail us on m.chaitanya@iipm.edu & neha.malhotra@iipm.edu<br />

Or alternatively please call Neha Malhotra at 9818825794<br />

Additional <strong>Think</strong>ing<br />

www.iipmthinktank.com<br />

www.iipm.edu<br />

www.iipmpublications.com<br />

www.arindamchaudhuri.com<br />

www.thesundayindian.com<br />

www.thedailyindian.com<br />

www.businessandeconomy.org<br />

www.gidf.org<br />

www.planmanconsulting.com<br />

Printed by:<br />

Rolleract Press Servies, C-163, Ground Floor,<br />

Naraina industrial Area, Phase-I, New Delhi - 16<br />

Disclaimer :<br />

All efforts have been taken to ensure the veracity of the information contained in the research, however <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong><br />

<strong>Think</strong> Tank expressly disclaims any and all warranties, express or implied, including without limitation warranties of<br />

merchantability and fitness for a particular purpose, with respect to any service or material. In no event shall <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong><br />

<strong>Think</strong> Tank be liable for any direct, indirect, incidental, punitive, or consequential damages of any kind whatsoever<br />

with respect to the and materials, although the reader may freely use the research and material provided, <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong><br />

<strong>Think</strong> Tank retains all trademark right and copyright on all the text and graphics.


PARADIGM PRISM<br />

“<strong>The</strong>re is no knowledge, no light, no<br />

wisdom that you are in possession of, but<br />

what you have received it from some source.”<br />

Who we are?<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank, an independent, India-centric research body, is inspired by<br />

Dr. M.K. Chaudhuri’s vision of India as an economic powerhouse in the 21st century; a modern<br />

nation state where poverty becomes history and the underprivileged are not consigned to<br />

the dustbin of amnesia. <strong>The</strong> national presence (across 7 nodes, New Delhi, Mumbai, Chennai,<br />

Pune, Bangalore, Hyderabad, & Ahmedabad) makes our understanding of the economy superior,<br />

where in many research fellows and scholars, embark on research assignments and network<br />

with global intelligentsia.<br />

What we believe?<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank is wholly free of ideology and looks at the Indian developmental paradigms,<br />

purely modelled upon the basis of ‘objective reality’ by opting for prescriptive economics. We<br />

start with real-life problems, lay down solutions and examine them in real-life context (through<br />

G.I.D Foundation) and observe what we learn about people and other variables in the systems<br />

in India as we opine that there is much more to boundary between the humanity and the world<br />

of ideas. We passionately believe in the credo that we constantly seek to follow: rethink, edify<br />

and delineate. This enduring commitment has helped us foster and broaden the parameters of<br />

public policy debate and alternatives. Toward that goal, it strives to achieve greater involvement<br />

of the intelligent, concerned change agents (reform minded politicians, public servants, socially<br />

responsible firms and citizens) in questions of policy and the ideation. Furthermore, we ardently<br />

believe that the managers of tomorrow that are being groomed at <strong>IIPM</strong> today will play a decisive<br />

role in India’s renewed tryst with destiny.<br />

What we do?<br />

-Brigham Young<br />

As a premier ‘ideas organisation’, <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank is committed to enhance public<br />

awareness of policy issues in economics and management and to engineer solutions that will<br />

fulfill the Great Indian Dream. By publishing the findings of its research, and through the active<br />

participation of its senior researchers in the media and policy, it aims to bring new knowledge<br />

to the attention of policy makers. Every year, <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank commissions and publishes<br />

socio-economic three quarterly reviews and an annual review, on a wide range of policy<br />

issues including education, health, poverty, unemployment, agriculture, industry, services, FDI,<br />

external trade, infrastructure and environment. All these outputs meet the highest standards of<br />

scholarship, are accessible to a broad readership, and explore policy alternatives consistent<br />

with the philosophy of ours. <strong>The</strong> central theme of our issues are devoted to assess where the<br />

critical predicaments are, analysing what needs to be done to annul the element of development<br />

deterrents in the economy and offer concrete proposals on how to accelerate welfare<br />

everywhere towards achieving inclusive development. <strong>The</strong> India Economy Review is a small<br />

manifestation of that vision. More than 3,000 students (7 nodes of <strong>IIPM</strong>) have—and continue<br />

to—spent endless hours conducting primary and secondary research on strategic issues that<br />

confront India. This research is then analysed by many scholars across the 7 campuses. Brand<br />

new insights and policy recommendations that are provided by this core team are then crafted,<br />

honed and polished by member Economics Research Group (ERG). This massive effort is<br />

spearheaded and led by the renowned economist and management guru, Prof. Arindam<br />

Chaudhuri. We trust that the untiring efforts of <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank are a modest, yet<br />

significant contribution to the policy reinvention that is poised to transform India.<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate


ethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate<br />

THE FUTURE IS HERE<br />

“<strong>The</strong> great aim of education is not<br />

knowledge but action.”<br />

-Herbert Spencer<br />

Since its incorporation (1973), <strong>IIPM</strong> has been an institution with privileged traditions, in the<br />

diversity of its fraternity, its global outlook, its world class research and its commitment to alternative<br />

national economic planning process.<br />

It can be said, without much oversimplification that there are no ‘underdeveloped economies’.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are only ‘under managed’ countries. Japan 140 years was ago was an underdeveloped<br />

country by every material measurement. But it very quickly produced management of great<br />

competence, indeed of excellence. <strong>The</strong> policy inference is that ‘management’ is the prime mover<br />

and ‘development’ is the consequence. At <strong>IIPM</strong>, every one considers that development is a matter<br />

of human energies rather than economic wealth. And the generation and direction of these human<br />

energies is the task of ‘management’. Accordingly, we formed <strong>The</strong> Great Indian Dream. Unlike<br />

any other dream, this is one dream which each one of us are determined to realise and that too in<br />

our own lifetimes. Each bit of cynicism and condemnation from pessimists makes us evolve even<br />

stronger and determined.<br />

All our endeavours and initiative is towards realisation of this dream, where in we produce<br />

committed ‘bare foot’ managers and entrepreneurs who are needed by nation, on an insistent<br />

basis. As an educational institute, we aim at initializing a three dimensional personality in <strong>IIPM</strong>ites,<br />

viz.<br />

Pursuit of knowledge in economics and management<br />

Commitment to economic, social, political and technological upliftment of masses and<br />

Cultivation of taste for literature, fine arts and etc.<br />

Economists often have limited access to the practical problems facing senior managers, while<br />

senior managers often lack the time and motivation to look beyond their own industry to the<br />

larger issues of the global economy. It has set before it the twin tasks: to reorient education and<br />

research towards the needs of both the private and public sectors and to establish the link between<br />

the National Economic Planning and the development of private enterprises in Indian economy.<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> dares to look beyond, and understands that what we teach today, other adopt tomorrow.<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong>’s service output (education, research and consulting,) is a unique combination of two distinct<br />

disciplines: economics and management. Through this integration, <strong>IIPM</strong> helps guide business and<br />

policy leaders in shaping the Indian and global economy, bringing together the practical insights<br />

of industry with broader national and global perspectives.<br />

A hall mark of <strong>IIPM</strong> is that it is armed with the comparative advantage of engaging the<br />

committed, passionate and brightest management post graduates and undergraduates, who<br />

pursued the education at <strong>IIPM</strong> and subsequently joined it, to realise the dream. <strong>IIPM</strong> alumni, spread<br />

across the globe, holding crucial decision-making positions in the corporate sector, are bonded by<br />

the one ideology of making a positive difference, turning that ideology into a movement itself.<br />

<strong>The</strong> India Economy Review is another humble initiative towards the realisation of the same and<br />

more distinctly, engaging the broader publics and pertinent stakeholders.


FROM THE EDITOR’S DESK<br />

planning for competition, not by planning against competition<br />

Dear reader,<br />

After being shackled for nearly five<br />

decades, a <strong>size</strong>able class of ingenious private<br />

entrepreneurs have been fully liberated,<br />

at least in some economic spheres.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y are now exhibiting their true potential<br />

and international competitiveness as<br />

is reflected in the popular media. In this<br />

context, after perusing all those informative,<br />

yet disparate nuggets and given the<br />

fact that India boasts of a deep financial<br />

services sector, long standing and diversified<br />

private participation (relative to<br />

China, Brazil and other emerging economies),<br />

vibrant entrepreneurial class and<br />

Anglo-Saxon legal institutions, it may<br />

seem surprising that India still painfully<br />

needs a much more market-orientation<br />

across all levels. <strong>The</strong>re is still exists a robust<br />

economic reasoning which asserts<br />

that the state should disentangle all obstacles<br />

and disengage the past planning<br />

follies to release the creative, social and<br />

economic energies of the fast growing<br />

‘bottom millions’. Consider this: According<br />

to the Heritage Foundation’s Index of<br />

Economic Freedom (<strong>2007</strong>), India is only<br />

55.6 percent free. This score makes it the<br />

world’s 104th freest economy!<br />

In this issue of IER, many empirical<br />

research studies profess that, among<br />

other positive outcomes, economic freedom<br />

promotes national growth and poverty<br />

reduction. Furthermore, different<br />

research papers outline the processes and<br />

policy implications of business freedom,<br />

financial freedom and investment freedom<br />

in several areas, which specifically<br />

and importantly includes<br />

basic education,<br />

labour markets<br />

and financial markets.<br />

Unlike most other issues,<br />

IER this time<br />

covers not only business<br />

and economics,<br />

but also deals with<br />

important research<br />

submissions that falls<br />

outside the realm of traditional economics-<br />

such as intellectual property, ecology<br />

and environment, economic history and<br />

politics This issue, we have some original<br />

research and novel analysis about<br />

• Public governance, market, deprivation<br />

and the political system.<br />

• India’s growing ecological footprint<br />

• <strong>The</strong> international trade in higher education<br />

and implications for India.<br />

Prasoon.S.Majumdar<br />

Managing Editor<br />

M.N.V.V.K.Chaitanya<br />

Deputy Editor<br />

• Why poor parents are choosing ‘More<br />

Market, Less Government’ in education,<br />

and what we should do about it?<br />

• Accountable governance and pro-poor<br />

markets for poverty reduction<br />

• Reforms in the Indian banking sector<br />

and policy reversal<br />

• Economic freedom in India’s product<br />

and labour markets<br />

Above all, after reading all the opinions<br />

featured here in this issue, we at the<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank are of the firm opinion<br />

that, if we get a state that reflects more of<br />

what this country is actually about, India<br />

can indeed turn the century and its market--<br />

around, in the very near future. <strong>The</strong><br />

impressive response in areas that have<br />

been reformed in the recent past must<br />

give policymakers confidence that further<br />

liberalisation will eventually deliver additional<br />

growth dividends and foster the<br />

process of pulling millions of people out<br />

of poverty.<br />

Best,<br />

Prasoon.S.Majumdar<br />

M.N.V.V.K. Chaitanya


SEARCH, SIEVE, SCHEME...<br />

“Research is formalised curiosity. It is poking<br />

and prying with a purpose.”<br />

Zora Neale Hurston<br />

In economics, like in everyday existence, it is<br />

imperative to hear, perceive and consider what<br />

others have to say. Each issue of <strong>The</strong> IER brings<br />

together a selection of important contributions on a<br />

particular theme, authored by some of the brightest<br />

minds in different areas of Indian economics. <strong>The</strong><br />

provocation for publishing these issues arises from<br />

the fact that over the years economic journals have<br />

become copious, exclusive and expensive. Most of<br />

the journals and a good many of the books have gone<br />

beyond the cerebral and financial reach of general<br />

students and other scholars. It is for them that these<br />

issues are primarily being raised and debated here.<br />

Much about India is transparent enough. One does<br />

not require detailed criteria, cunning calibration or<br />

probing analysis to pinpoint India’s problems and<br />

recognise its antecedents. <strong>The</strong>re is in fact much that<br />

is perceptible about India. But not everything about<br />

India is even if simplistic is so simple. <strong>The</strong> learned<br />

reader would appreciate the fact that India is like an<br />

elephant that looms too large to be grasped within a<br />

distinct structure and paradigm the constituent parts<br />

of which would fail to reveal the entirety. Obviously and<br />

observably, no suggested solution to any protracted<br />

and complex socio-economic problem will satisfy<br />

all sides and stake-holders evenly. Consequently,<br />

there exists an enormous diversity in economic<br />

thinking and perspectives, as is also reflected in the<br />

viewpoints of different expert contributors in this<br />

issue. <strong>The</strong> intended outcome of this exercise is to<br />

facilitate the invention, improvement, deliberation<br />

and dissemination of innovation in economic thinking<br />

and national economic planning, insisting merely on<br />

well-grounded, open and unbiased debates, without<br />

predetermined outcomes. It is impossible to do justice<br />

to the entire field of Indian economics in a single<br />

issue. <strong>The</strong> topics selected for this issue are those<br />

which are of critical and immediate importance to<br />

India. Majority of them were freshly and exclusively<br />

written. Encapsulated, it is a constructive attempt<br />

aimed at helping India actualise its promises and<br />

potential. <strong>The</strong> editors hope that this issue of IER<br />

will proffer the reader a flavour of dynamism and<br />

excitement and persuade her/him to participate<br />

in the journey towards realising ‘<strong>The</strong> Great Indian<br />

Dream’. At the same time, it illuminates the terrible,<br />

practical problems of India and Bharat.<br />

HAPPY READING...<br />

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank likes to thank all the internal faculty who have been instrumental in coordinating<br />

with many authors all across India and according their unstinted support. <strong>The</strong> assistance of Prof.<br />

R.Krishnan and Syed Ahmed (<strong>IIPM</strong> Chennai), Mr. Tareque Laskar (<strong>IIPM</strong> Bangalore), Mr. Sudipto<br />

Chatterjee (<strong>IIPM</strong> Ahmedabad), Prof.Jayanta Chakraborti and Ms. Bindiya Naik (<strong>IIPM</strong> Pune), has been<br />

more valuable than, perhaps, they realise. Ms. Vareen Gadhoke Ray at Planman Media, particularly, did<br />

all that it was possible to do for this issue of IER.


(F)ACT SHEET<br />

INDIA’S FUTURE: Redesigning Development Agenda<br />

Liberalism As <strong>The</strong> Basis Of Human Rights And Dignity<br />

Christopher LINGLE 12<br />

India’s Future – Knowledge And Learning<br />

Societies Or Mere Markets And State<br />

Lawrence Surendra 16<br />

State And Market Conundrum In <strong>The</strong> Indian<br />

Context –A Need For Debates<br />

Pradeep Banerjee 24<br />

Larger Market Role, Reduced Government Interventions–<br />

Is It A Misnomer?<br />

Anandajit Goswami 32<br />

THE VISIBLE HAND: Government’s Role<br />

Governance, Market, Deprivation And <strong>The</strong> Political System<br />

Amal Sanyal 36<br />

<strong>The</strong> Economics Of Social Unrest – Its Causes And Cure<br />

Nilanjan Banik 42<br />

More Market, Less Government: A Recipe For Disaster For <strong>The</strong><br />

Water Sector<br />

Shripad Dharmadikary 46<br />

Inclusive Growth In India: A Case Of Structural And Agrarian<br />

Challenges<br />

D.M. Diwakar 52<br />

Market Economy And <strong>The</strong> State Of Regional<br />

Disparities In India<br />

Anu Singh 62<br />

Accountable Governance And Pro-poor Markets For Effective<br />

Poverty Reduction<br />

Anindo Banerjee 68<br />

Food Security In India: <strong>Issue</strong>s And Implications<br />

Anajani Sinha 74<br />

FREE EXCHANGE: More Markets<br />

Why Poor Parents Are Choosing ‘More Market, Less Government’<br />

In Education, And What We Should Do About It?<br />

James Tooley 80<br />

International Trade In Higher Education: What Should India Do?<br />

Stephen P. Heyneman 86<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate


ethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

10 edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate<br />

Water Resources In Gujarat And Role Of Water Markets In<br />

Breaking Gridlock In Water Scarcity – A Replicable Policy<br />

Prescription At National Level<br />

Jharna Pathak 94<br />

Commodity Futures: A Catalyst For Agricultural Development<br />

V. Shunmugam & D.G. Prasad 102<br />

Overseas Investment By Indian Firms: Recent Trends<br />

And Patterns<br />

Deepika Wadhwa 108<br />

Indian Banking Reforms And Policy Reversal: A Vicious Cycle<br />

Anurag Sharma 116<br />

Indian Corporate Bond Market: <strong>The</strong> Road Ahead<br />

Pramod K. Yadav & Ritesh Agarwal 132<br />

QUO VADIS: India Reexamined<br />

Just How Free Are India’s Labour And Product Markets?<br />

Paul Conway, Richard Herd & Sean Dougherty 138<br />

Going For Growth Through Economic Reforms: <strong>The</strong> Case Of India<br />

Rok Spruk 146<br />

India’s Unique Pattern Of Development: Quo vadis?<br />

Kalpana Kochhar 154<br />

PROGRESS WITHIN LIMITS: Environmental Economics<br />

India’s Growing Ecological Footprint: Exploring Past And<br />

Future Changes<br />

T R Manoharan 164<br />

A NEW BEGINNING: Law And Public Policy<br />

<strong>The</strong> First Sale Doctrine Before <strong>The</strong> U.S. Supreme Court:<br />

Intellectual Property Implications For India<br />

Shubha Ghosh 168<br />

SOTTO VOCE: Economic Exposition<br />

Liberty And Prohibition: A Governance Dilemma<br />

Ali Mehdi 172<br />

THE OTHER PATH: Reimagining India<br />

An Alternative Integrated Development Perspective For <strong>The</strong><br />

Peripheral Regions: <strong>The</strong> Case Of Barak Valley In Northeast India<br />

Baharul Islam 174<br />

THE ‘OTHER’ INDIA: Tenancy Reforms<br />

Tenancy Reforms in Orissa: A Critical Perspective<br />

Mrutyunjay Dash 182


CALL FOR PAPERS<br />

IER is a quarterly journal featuring contents of academic and professional interest that are of utility to managers,<br />

policy makers, politicians, consultants, teachers and students in the areas of Economics and Management. It<br />

is a multidisciplinary platform for sharing and disseminating knowledge in the issues of education, health,<br />

poverty, unemployment, agriculture, industry, service, FDI, international trade, infrastructure and environment,<br />

pertaining to Indian economy. We passionately believe in the credo that we constantly seek to follow: rethink,<br />

edify and delineate. This enduring commitment has helped us foster and broaden the parameters of public<br />

policy debate and alternatives. Toward that goal, we strive to achieve greater involvement of the intelligent,<br />

concerned change agents (reform minded politicians, public servants, academicians, socially responsible firms,<br />

civil society organizations and citizens) in questions of policy and the ideation. In order to further augment value<br />

and provision a broad perspective to Indian economic problems, your knowledge and expertise in the above<br />

mentioned fields would be highly valuable to IER. We would like the possibility of receiving a write-up from you,<br />

on a topic of your expertise and interest as per the under-mentioned guidelines.<br />

Guidelines For Contributors<br />

Content: Articles should be in the areas of education, health, poverty, unemployment, agriculture, industry,<br />

service, FDI, international trade, infrastructure and environment, pertaining to Indian economy, which are<br />

of contemporary interest and value to the esteemed and intellectual readers. <strong>The</strong> journal seeks to present<br />

an eclectic approach supported by empirical research or practical applications as necessary. Contents that<br />

demonstrate clear and bold thinking, fresh and useful ideas and solutions, accessible and jargon-free expression,<br />

and unmistakable authority and proficiency are those most likely to meet our reader’s needs.<br />

Reviewing Process: Each article is reviewed by the Economics Research Group (ERG). If found suitable, the<br />

same may be sent for another round of review before final acceptance. With prior information and consent,<br />

the editors reserve the right to modify and improve the manuscripts to meet IER’s standards of presentation<br />

and style. <strong>The</strong> editors also have full right to accept or reject an article for publication. Editorial decisions will be<br />

communicated within a period of 2 weeks of the receipt of the submission.<br />

Word Length: Articles should be of 2,500 to 3,000 words including abstract and references.<br />

Headings And Sub-Headings: Headings should be typed in capital and underlined; sub-headings should be<br />

typed in upper and lower case and underlined.<br />

References: References to other publications should follow the Harvard style.<br />

Figures, Charts And Diagrams: Use of figures, charts and diagrams should be kept to the minimum and text<br />

should indicate where the same will appear. All tables, charts, graphs should be typed on separate sheets. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

should be numbered as Table-1, Table 2, etc. <strong>The</strong> graphs must have the minimum amount of descriptive text and<br />

the axes should be labeled with variable written out in full, along the length of axes.<br />

Abstract And Key Words: An abstract within 100 words and three key words should be submitted.<br />

Author’s Bio-data And Photograph: A brief bio-data with full postal and e-mail addresses and a coloured<br />

photograph should be sent along with the articles.<br />

Copyright: Authors should warrant that their work is not an infringement of any existing copyright and will<br />

indemnify the publisher against any breach of warranty. <strong>The</strong> articles published in IER will become the legal<br />

copyright of the publisher. <strong>The</strong> articles appearing in IER are the personal responsibility of the authors themselves<br />

and do not reflect the views of the editor, principal or the Economics Research Group (ERG) or the sponsoring<br />

organization. <strong>The</strong> author(s) will receive a complementary copy of IER in which their articles are published; they<br />

will also receive ten reprints of their articles for their personal use.<br />

Submission: <strong>The</strong> submission should be sent to M.N.V.V.K. Chaitanya at m.chaitanya@iipm.edu


Christopher LINGLE,<br />

Professor of Economic at<br />

Universidad Francisco<br />

Marroquin in Guatemala<br />

Liberalism As <strong>The</strong> Basis Of<br />

Human Rights And Dignity<br />

"Of all the varieties of virtues,<br />

liberalism is the most beloved."<br />

-Aristotle<br />

I<br />

dealism and an abiding concern<br />

for mankind tend to preoccupy<br />

young intellectuals throughout<br />

the world. Ironically, despite the successes<br />

in promoting human development,<br />

Liberalism remains relatively<br />

underappreciated by the youth in<br />

most countries.<br />

This problem is compounded in India<br />

by legal arrangements that make it<br />

impossible to form political organizations<br />

that identify with Liberal ideals.<br />

As it is, modifications to the preamble<br />

of the Constitution made during the<br />

Emergency specify that: “India is a<br />

sovereign, secular, socialist republic.”<br />

At the same time, an amendment<br />

was made to the relevant section in the<br />

Representation of the People Act, 1950<br />

to require all recognized and registered<br />

parties to swear to uphold the<br />

Constitution. <strong>The</strong> courts have ruled<br />

variously on whether or not the Preamble<br />

is to be deemed a part of the Constitution.<br />

<strong>The</strong> current view on this is<br />

that since all parties must stand for<br />

Socialism, no party can legally register<br />

to espouse Classical Liberalism as a<br />

political platform. Attempts to challenge<br />

this ban on political speech of<br />

Liberals languish in the court system.<br />

One might consider the level of outrage<br />

that would lead to a rapid hearing<br />

if socialist or communist parties were<br />

banned. And the strongest voice to remove<br />

such limits would almost certainly<br />

be led by Liberals! Another<br />

problem is that opponents of the Liberal<br />

view effectively create a veil of<br />

good intentions to obscure the obvious<br />

flaws and failings of Socialism. Meanwhile,<br />

critiques of Liberalism make the<br />

unfounded assertion that it offers few<br />

answers for solving social problems<br />

within the larger community.<br />

To counter this latter tactic, Liberals<br />

must make clear representations of the<br />

social benefits of Liberalism. One area<br />

that might be fruitful is to articulate<br />

the Liberal basis of the concept of socalled<br />

human rights. It turns out that<br />

Human rights did not formally appear<br />

12 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

in international law until 1948 when<br />

the Universal <strong>Dec</strong>laration of Human<br />

Rights (UDHR) was signed. This document<br />

enshrines principles of equality<br />

and justice, and the sanctity of a person’s<br />

rights regardless of their ethnicity,<br />

religion or gender. <strong>The</strong> first sentence<br />

of the 1948 <strong>Dec</strong>laration states<br />

that “inherent human dignity” should<br />

be recognized. As such, a balanced application<br />

of human rights principles<br />

would not impose social responsibilities<br />

that come into conflict with<br />

personal rights.<br />

But some attempts to curb assaults<br />

on the dignity of human beings have<br />

contributed to the continuing problems<br />

that offend a collective sense of justice.<br />

Indeed, many of the most vocal supporters<br />

of so-called human rights actually<br />

promote legal concepts that inadvertently<br />

support the sort of misconduct<br />

they wish to see ended. In particular,<br />

demands for human rights in terms of<br />

social or collective rights undermine<br />

the universality intended by the drafters<br />

of the UDHR. For example, government<br />

officials frequently engage in<br />

populist promises that define rights<br />

based on economic or social characteristics.<br />

In modern times, there has been<br />

an emergence of identity politics<br />

whereby leaders of group-based movements<br />

claim they represent the interests<br />

of groups defined by ethnicity,<br />

class, religion, gender, sexual orientation<br />

or other criteria.<br />

A focus on group “rights” divides<br />

communities into distinctive and separate<br />

political classes that are in conflict<br />

with the interests and rights of other<br />

groups. Demands for an assignment of<br />

rights as a matter of law tend to be<br />

based on a perception of some historical<br />

oppression or victimhood. In the<br />

first instance, assignment of particular<br />

rights contradicts a notion of universal<br />

rights wherein all humans possess<br />

equal rights regardless of differences<br />

race or ethnicity. And basing human<br />

rights upon collective concepts of<br />

“fundamental” social rights leads to<br />

zero or negative-sum policy outcomes<br />

with some groups benefiting and others<br />

losing. One common intrusion to<br />

individual liberties relating is the imposition<br />

of limits on the exercise of<br />

private property rights and the freedom<br />

of exchange. In this regard, the<br />

excesses of protectionism and unlawful<br />

expropriation are legendary. <strong>The</strong>re is<br />

an unfortunate tendency for few objections<br />

being raised when the assets of<br />

private corporations are nationalized.<br />

But this indifference overlooks the fact<br />

that acts that diminish economic<br />

freedoms provide the logic and mechanisms<br />

for reducing civic and political<br />

freedoms. Those wishing to support<br />

human rights should consider that<br />

rights and dignity of humans are best<br />

preserved through rigorous support for<br />

individual rights and the Rule of Law.<br />

As it is, proponents of collective or<br />

group rights that ignore the key role of<br />

individuals as bearers of rights guaranteed<br />

to autonomous humans undermine<br />

the Rule of Law.<br />

Indeed, the assertion of group rights<br />

over individual rights provided the basis<br />

for the injustices of apartheid in<br />

South Africa and genocide in other<br />

parts of the world. <strong>The</strong> assignment of<br />

group rights in the case of apartheid is<br />

a worst-case scenario of abuses arising<br />

from the violation of these generality<br />

conditions. But other extreme acts<br />

arising out of the exclusivity of ethnic<br />

nationalism had destructive consequences<br />

in the Balkans and plague<br />

other parts of the world.<br />

References to social or collective or<br />

group rights mask the fact that assignment<br />

of such rights may involve empowerment<br />

or possessions that require<br />

the action or aid of others. In the process<br />

of activating such group rights, the<br />

rights of other individuals will be violated<br />

by imposing obligation upon<br />

them. Rights that impose obligations<br />

necessarily attenuate the freedom of<br />

choice and action of others. In such an<br />

order, human beings are treated as objects<br />

or servants of the community<br />

Rights that impose obligations necessarily attenuate the<br />

freedom of choice and action of others. In such an order,<br />

human beings are treated as objects or servants of the<br />

community rather than valued as unique individuals<br />

rather than valued as unique individuals.<br />

Whereas the assignment and enforcement<br />

of individual rights encourages<br />

coordination and cooperation,<br />

collectivized rights involve conflict<br />

and require coercion. As it turns out,<br />

many of the countries that suffer most<br />

from communal violence and sectarianism<br />

are those that have imple<br />

mented policies that define rights of<br />

minorities. Clearly, this approach has<br />

not worked.<br />

A collectivistic approach to human<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

13


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

rights as group rights also violates the<br />

generality requirement of jurisprudence<br />

associated with Kant’s categorical<br />

imperative. Under a Kantian system,<br />

justice is served when rights are<br />

applied generally without particular,<br />

arbitrary preferences for either individuals<br />

or groups.<br />

What is at stake is the choice of a<br />

system that serves as the means for attaining<br />

and measuring social justice.<br />

On the one hand, private property<br />

rights might be seen as essential for<br />

safeguarding most other civil rights.<br />

On the other hand, these rights might<br />

be the most effective incentive to inspire<br />

individual effort that may lead to<br />

general prosperity of the community.<br />

A focus on “social” or communitarian<br />

rights tends to lead to reliance<br />

upon a politicization of the economic<br />

position (income and wealth) of individuals<br />

in the community. Politicizing<br />

such outcomes in pursuit of a special<br />

sense of social justice is open to exploitation<br />

by special interest groups or<br />

power elites of other groups or specific<br />

individuals within the community.<br />

It also allows envy and politics to brew<br />

up a ghastly stew. Anchoring human<br />

rights to a (more or less inviolable)<br />

concept of private property reduces<br />

the number of politicized decisions affecting<br />

peoples’ lives. This would be<br />

less exploitative and also less arbitrary<br />

and probably more stable since community<br />

actions are justified by mutual<br />

consent and voluntary exchange among<br />

individuals. Despite well-intentioned<br />

attempts to create or promote a broad<br />

sense of community, democracy allows<br />

the interests of special groups to dominate<br />

the interests of the wider community.<br />

Mechanisms that rely upon<br />

For greater harmony in the future, political initiatives<br />

and the relentless expansion of restrictions and bureaucracy<br />

that contribute to dehumanization should be<br />

replaced by individual initiatives<br />

majority rule to determine the distribution<br />

of wealth or goods tends to reinforce<br />

an increased sense of collective<br />

identity as a means to avoid, to deflect<br />

or to harness as well as to direct<br />

the policies.<br />

In the end, politicization arising out<br />

of attempts to enforce collective rights<br />

can be seen as the principal cause of<br />

the powerlessness of individuals. Expansion<br />

in the nature and direction of<br />

state intervention replaces the rights<br />

of the individual, except as a member<br />

of a group.<br />

In the United States of America, increased<br />

political divisiveness has<br />

emerged as more collective action has<br />

been mandated. Despite emphasizing<br />

multi-cultural studies in American<br />

universities, one result has been demands<br />

for a restoration of “separate<br />

but equal” facilities for different<br />

groups. More troubling is what seems<br />

to be a growing intolerance of diversity<br />

due to resentment of members of<br />

groups who are perceived as recipients<br />

of preferential treatment. Members of<br />

groups identified as historical victimizers<br />

begin to imagine that they are<br />

being victimized and captive to an insubstantial<br />

logic of retribution. Certain<br />

members of the Hindu community in<br />

India are making such claims against<br />

the Muslim population.<br />

Defining human rights in collective<br />

or group terms invites an increased<br />

politicization of life outcomes, something<br />

to be avoided given India’s ethic<br />

and religious diversity. Unfortunately,<br />

populist politicians seldom search for<br />

private solutions to solve problems or<br />

conflicting interests in a private manner.<br />

For greater harmony in the future,<br />

political initiatives and the relentless<br />

expansion of restrictions and bureaucracy<br />

that contribute to dehumanization<br />

should be replaced by individual initiatives.<br />

As such, the best way serve<br />

humane ends is to ground the concept<br />

of human rights in a Liberal order<br />

where individual rights are protected<br />

within a Rule of Law.<br />

14 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


10 WEBSITES TO IMPROVE YOUR LIFE<br />

INVITATION<br />

PRICE RS.50<br />

ONLY!<br />

GET MORE FROM TECHNOLOGY<br />

JANUARY, 2008<br />

Intel vs AMD<br />

<strong>The</strong> battle intensifies<br />

in 2008<br />

•WordPerfect Office X3 •Zoho<br />

•OpenOffice.org •Google Docs Beta<br />

Best Office<br />

Alternatives<br />

•Lotus Symphony Beta<br />

•iWork<br />

•<strong>Think</strong>Free Online<br />

Best products of<br />

the year <strong>2007</strong>


Lawrence Surendra,<br />

Planning Commission of India Chair in<br />

Economics, Department of Studies in<br />

Economics and Cooperation,<br />

University of Mysore<br />

India’s Future – Knowledge And Learning<br />

Societies Or Mere Markets And State<br />

"Economics is not a body of concrete<br />

wealth but an engine for<br />

the discovery of concrete truth."<br />

-Alfred Marshall<br />

<strong>The</strong> Central Statistical Organization<br />

in its estimate released on<br />

May 21, <strong>2007</strong>, estimated GDP at<br />

factor cost at 1999 – 2000 prices as<br />

Rs.28,482 billion. India’s GDP at factor<br />

cost increased from US$20 billion in<br />

1950-51 to US$828 billion in 2006-07.<br />

GDP at current market prices was estimated<br />

at US$912 billion in 2006-07. With<br />

increasing integration, share of merchandise<br />

trade (imports + exports) increased<br />

from 12.2 percent of GDP in 1950-51 to<br />

33.6 percent in 2006-07. Inclusion of<br />

services will increase this share further.<br />

As per the World Economic Outlook<br />

(April <strong>2007</strong>), India accounted for 6.3<br />

percent of global GDP measured in terms<br />

of Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) and<br />

1.3 percent export of goods and services.<br />

In terms of PPP, India’s GDP in 2006 was<br />

valued at around US$ four trillion, nearly<br />

five times the GDP valued at current<br />

nominal exchange rate.<br />

<strong>The</strong> figures in terms economic growth<br />

are impressive with the Finance Minister<br />

aiming for a growth rate of above 10 percent<br />

(around 12 percent) next year. Ambitious<br />

but very much in the realm of<br />

possibility, if the Finance Minister plays<br />

his hands well. For those who directly or<br />

indirectly benefit by this growth, especially<br />

the middle and upper middle classes,<br />

this is news to cheer and feel gratified,<br />

in the sense of feeling a sense of pleasure<br />

and comfort. <strong>The</strong> latter sense of gratification<br />

leads not only to the desire for<br />

greater and greater gratification but also<br />

leads to over-confidence and arrogance;<br />

signs of the latter are plenty and all it requires<br />

is to read the papers in the metros.<br />

This arrogance around a growing economy<br />

also leads to all kinds of fanciful assumptions<br />

about the role of state and<br />

markets and a kind of evangelical zeal<br />

about markets. For those who will benefit<br />

little or nothing by this growth and<br />

for the many who may even become or<br />

already are, victims of the rapid economic<br />

growth, they may still hope that there<br />

would be some protections for them and<br />

that they still remain constitutionally<br />

citizens of India with equal opportunities<br />

16 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

and rights. <strong>The</strong> fact that the economy<br />

and its growth happens within the framework<br />

of a solemnly constituted nation<br />

bound by constitutional obligations,<br />

could give the poor and disadvantaged<br />

reasons to hope and aspire for an inclusive<br />

growth, something that the Finance<br />

Minister has also recently been referring<br />

to and on more than one occasion. If inclusive<br />

growth is not to become a mantra<br />

but serious policy, then it has important<br />

implications for the future of India as we<br />

know it. <strong>The</strong> future of India as a nation,<br />

as an idea that has so important a place<br />

in the comity of nations globally, will<br />

critically depend on how economic policy<br />

in our country deals with India’s large<br />

scale mass poverty. That remains and<br />

will remain the Indian economy’s most<br />

central problem; how economic policy<br />

deals with it, will be what makes or breaks<br />

economic growth and political stability;<br />

in the ultimate analysis our ability to<br />

break the poverty trap is what will determine<br />

whether we pull through as a society<br />

or descend gradually into chaos and<br />

anarchy. This reality needs to be stated<br />

upfront before entering into any discussion<br />

about state and markets.<br />

<strong>The</strong> State And Economists<br />

Faster growth rates in the economy has<br />

led to calls for an entirely market based<br />

economic growth model and to even assume<br />

that, the state is and can no longer<br />

be the primum mobilum of development.<br />

If that is so, then how does one deal with<br />

the question of the state when it comes to<br />

thorny problems such as poverty alleviation,<br />

social exclusion and gross societal<br />

inequalities that are a drag on the overall<br />

development of a nation. Often there is a<br />

scare tactic that is mounted about the<br />

dangers of a dirigistic state and which the<br />

Indian state hardly is, especially after the<br />

reforms of the 1990s and from the VIII<br />

Plan onwards. Once, the distinction between<br />

accepting a role for the state in<br />

development and that of a dirigistic state<br />

is deliberately blurred, it is easier to<br />

equate the two and call all state involvement<br />

as dirigistic and then try to figure<br />

out in the push for market friendly economic<br />

reforms how to reduce the role of<br />

the state. This then becomes a false debate.<br />

More critical than raising false<br />

clashes between state and market in the<br />

new millennium, is whether the state in<br />

developing societies such as India has a<br />

developmental role, if so how does then<br />

one define it and shape it? <strong>The</strong>re is no<br />

point in putting questions arising out of<br />

the 19th century and early 20th century<br />

problems that developed states have gone<br />

through and more so when most states,<br />

including the Indian state in an age of<br />

globalization are bending over backwards<br />

to be market and corporate friendly.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is nothing in our ‘karma’ that says,<br />

we have to go through the routes other<br />

societies have gone through. Pluralistic<br />

and sensible approaches to economic<br />

policy making and economic reform in<br />

particular requires a profound understanding<br />

that economic policy making<br />

especially in open and still vibrant democracies<br />

as ours, is related to good governance<br />

as a public good and multiplier<br />

of economic efficiency. Good governance<br />

in a society of diverse groups, interests<br />

and pulls and pressures is an art. In a developmental<br />

strategy sense, governance<br />

is central to economic policy. For this the<br />

state has a critical role in the management<br />

of the political economy of the large<br />

economies as ours and with such large<br />

and varied socio-economic problems,<br />

agro-eco systems and federal political<br />

structure. Good governance is an important<br />

and critical public good and for<br />

which the state cannot be seen as an adversary<br />

by the market. Undermining the<br />

state has serious consequences for markets<br />

as well. <strong>The</strong> State can very well be<br />

undermined from within the State by<br />

market forces. Instead of tired debates<br />

about state versus markets, what we need<br />

is serious debate on better policy and<br />

polity, involving state and markets.<br />

Once, the distinction between accepting a role for the<br />

state in development and that of a dirigistic state is deliberately<br />

blurred, it is easier to equate the two and call all<br />

state involvement as dirigistic<br />

Better policy and polity that works to the<br />

welfare of the nation as a whole than satisfy<br />

the greed of a few be it business<br />

or politicians.<br />

Economics and economic growth is<br />

part of the complexity of social systems<br />

and their inbuilt injustices, contradictions<br />

and handicaps. To think that the<br />

problems of economic growth can be unraveled<br />

without reference to the social<br />

system, would mean that when the social<br />

system starts unraveling itself, it will<br />

sweep in its wake, all traces of economics<br />

development. This is an issue that many<br />

economists have tried to skirt. It may be<br />

fashionable amidst the greed and individualism<br />

in the wake of the benefits<br />

brought to the leisure classes as a result<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

17


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

of globalization, for media gurus to triumphantly<br />

embrace the market as the<br />

panacea for all our ills. But it requires<br />

some humility to recognize that economic<br />

policy making, doing economics and<br />

shaping public policy in the context of<br />

poor and developing societies as ours,<br />

requires also a deep sense of humanity.<br />

A central issue in discussing the role of<br />

the state and economic growth is the issue<br />

about balanced growth, to avoid<br />

growing disparities between states, between<br />

regions and between different sectors<br />

of the population. For example, one<br />

of the major points of criticism by market<br />

friendly economic reformers’ is that<br />

policy and theoretical approaches, based<br />

on ‘balanced growth’, has been the bane<br />

of earlier economic policy making. Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty one of our foremost<br />

economists and who engaged in policy<br />

with that deep sense of humanity, in dismissing<br />

the debate about ‘balanced and<br />

unbalanced growth’ as semantic, refers<br />

ence to discussions of trade as a major<br />

engine for growth and like Amartya Sen,<br />

he recognizes “cycles of optimism and<br />

pessimism in trade led growth”. As Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty says, “the point I<br />

am driving at is that it was not much due<br />

to the alleged doctrine of ‘market failures’<br />

in the sense indicated by fundamental<br />

theorems of welfare economics that<br />

policy-makers in both developed and developing<br />

countries agreed to a theory of<br />

state-directed industrialization, but from<br />

a growth perspective based on data on<br />

massive agrarian overpopulation in<br />

South and Eastern Europe. Obviously<br />

the extension of this argument to deal<br />

<strong>The</strong> need to forge the new consensus that Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravorty made a plea for in the 1980s is ironically<br />

even more relevant now in the end of the first decade of<br />

the new millennium<br />

to the problem of surplus labour as a<br />

more serious conceptual and policy issue<br />

to deal with, especially in rural areas.<br />

Economist of the intellectual caliber of<br />

Sukhamoy Chakravarty, in addressing<br />

such critical issues as that of surplus labour<br />

also dealt with the problem of the<br />

state. With regard to debate about the<br />

state he points to the compatibility or<br />

otherwise between the planning principle<br />

and the principle of comparative advantage.<br />

A dichotomy which he says has<br />

been misleadingly drawn. This has refer-<br />

with countries like India was done later,<br />

although it was present in a general way<br />

from the beginning”. So much for the arguments<br />

about socialist inspired penchant<br />

for state involvement in economic<br />

planning and growth. In connection with<br />

the extension of the argument on surplus<br />

labour to underdeveloped areas, he refers<br />

to the UN Expert Group Report of<br />

1951 on 'Measures for the Economic Development<br />

of Underdeveloped Areas.<br />

'Chakravarty says, “this report reflected<br />

the emergence of a ‘development consensus’<br />

which lasted for nearly twenty five<br />

years”. He then refers to the breakdown<br />

of the consensus – “more prominently in<br />

the 1980s, based on criticisms which were<br />

first voiced by a resurgent neo-classicism<br />

on the one hand, and a ‘radical critique’<br />

of the left on the other”. This he says<br />

does not imply a demise of the sub-discipline<br />

of ‘development economics’, but,<br />

“the need to forge a new consensus” (emphasis<br />

added). <strong>The</strong> need to forge the new<br />

consensus that Sukhamoy Chakravorty<br />

made a plea for in the 1980s is ironically<br />

even more relevant now in the end of the<br />

first decade of the new millennium.<br />

We must consider ourselves very fortunate,<br />

that our nation has been blessed<br />

with a whole number of good, intellectually<br />

honest economists. In the context of<br />

looking at the perspectives of economic<br />

theory and policy, there is much that we<br />

can glean from the insightful writings of<br />

economists like the late Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty, (who along with Amartya<br />

Sen) belongs to that unique class of intellectually<br />

honest economists who have not<br />

done their economics only to pander to<br />

the tunes of the times. Economists who<br />

always did their theoretical and practical<br />

policy work, not only standing above<br />

vested interest pulls and pushes but also<br />

with a deep sense of humanity unconcerned<br />

whether that got them applause<br />

from the galleries or not. Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty’s contributions in the context<br />

of the discussion on state and markets<br />

are several and relate to the role of<br />

knowledge, the significance of coordination<br />

failure and surplus labour, the need<br />

to go beyond ‘the market failure’ or stages<br />

of growth argument, the impact of<br />

economic organizations from the viewpoint<br />

of “ensuring creativity, growth and<br />

18 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

equity”, the interdependence between<br />

agriculture and industry and the dilemma<br />

between the need for widening the<br />

market and the prevention of the abuse<br />

of monopoly power.<br />

Especially with regard to the abuse of<br />

monopoly power, let us also for example<br />

and for a moment keep in view economists<br />

and others who act like petty salesmen<br />

for the Commerce Ministry concept<br />

of SEZs. <strong>The</strong>se economists, both within<br />

state institutions and belonging to dubious<br />

NGOs, who on the one hand are the<br />

loudest ones to run the State down while<br />

singing the paens of the market, are the<br />

same ones on the other hand who are encouraging<br />

the worst abuses of monopoly<br />

power and the dismantling of the constitutional<br />

state in the name of SEZs. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

can be no greater irony than this. SEZs<br />

are best described as state encouraged<br />

rapacity by market players who cannot<br />

function in a market more even handedly<br />

regulated by the state and by a state<br />

that stands by the Indian Constitution<br />

and its protections for the rights of all<br />

citizens, be they poor peasants or workers.<br />

Those professing an almost evangelistic<br />

deal to have “growth at any cost”<br />

are oblivious to the principle that any<br />

abuse of monopoly power by the state in<br />

the name of the market, is a sure recipe<br />

that can take any nation however great it<br />

may be, including India, down a vortex of<br />

social instability and violence. This is the<br />

reality that is stares before us not only in<br />

the aftermath of Nandigram but in places<br />

like Mangalore, where fraud and deception<br />

is sought to used to divest people<br />

of productive agricultural land and create<br />

social tension and conflict. Finance<br />

Minister Chidambaram’s note of caution<br />

at the recent Indian Economic Forum<br />

that growth cannot be only for the top<br />

ten percent is not only a welcome note of<br />

caution but also an indication that<br />

policy making at the highest level is<br />

recognizing the larger objectives of<br />

economic growth.<br />

Such caution seems absent at the Commerce<br />

Ministry and most statements that<br />

emanate from the Commerce Ministry,<br />

including that of the Commerce Secretary<br />

seems not only totally oblivious to<br />

ground realities but a very unbalanced<br />

approach to economic growth priorities.<br />

While it is a matter of very deep concern<br />

as regards the long term implications for<br />

India of the SEZ route to rapid economic<br />

growth, the fact is that the disastrous<br />

nature of its implementation could actually<br />

bring down the government and the<br />

Congress Party to which belongs Mr.<br />

Kamal Nath the Commerce Minister<br />

whose Ministry seems to be recklessly<br />

spearheading the SEZ concept. Though<br />

all this may not happen before huge economic<br />

and social costs have accrued to<br />

the nation in terms of not only the accentuated<br />

conflicts it is going to engender<br />

but also in terms of the loss of revenues<br />

in terms of the state and loss of income<br />

and livelihood for thousands of people.<br />

In a globalised world where sovereignty<br />

is also at stake, the Commerce Ministry<br />

can try to run rough shod over all other<br />

Ministries including the Finance Ministry.<br />

However, what such deepening fissures<br />

in economic governance shows is<br />

the possibilities that exist for sections of<br />

the market to use one instrumentality of<br />

state, in this case the Commerce Ministry,<br />

to undermine the state as a whole<br />

and thereby society, showing the hollowness<br />

of arguments pitting market versus<br />

the state. In the end the greed and rapacity<br />

of the market can take both state and<br />

market together down.<br />

<strong>The</strong> challenge for the academic as well<br />

as working economist, for any person<br />

concerned about and engaged with public<br />

policy, is how even in these circumstances<br />

to focus on long term issues for<br />

the country as a whole. In the Indian<br />

context, what seems in my mind and<br />

echoing Sukhamoy Chakravarty, a key<br />

issue that is of great relevance for the immediate<br />

and the long term, is “a proper<br />

formulation of the role of knowledge as<br />

A key issue that is of great relevance for the immediate<br />

and the long term is “a proper formulation of the role of<br />

knowledge as a productive factor” and “institutional arrangements<br />

necessary for transition to a ‘learning society’<br />

a productive factor” and “institutional<br />

arrangements necessary for transition to<br />

a ‘learning society’ ".<br />

Knowledge And <strong>The</strong> Learning<br />

Society<br />

Chakravarty refers to Simon Kuznets<br />

who was of the conclusion that in the final<br />

analysis, it was the growth of knowledge<br />

which was the most decisive characteristic<br />

of modern economic growth.<br />

Here Kuznets was not referring to technology<br />

alone but as Chakravarty puts it,<br />

“also of basic sciences which are increasingly<br />

having profound impacts on transformations<br />

in the sphere of production<br />

that are leading to changes in the international<br />

economy”. He warns us that a<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

19


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

systematic underinvestment in science “is<br />

likely to be the result if the growth of science<br />

is left to competitive market forces”.<br />

He then refers to the “dilemma of ‘knowledge”,<br />

which he describes as that which,<br />

“pertains to the lack of compatibility between<br />

institutions which lead to the widest<br />

possible diffusion and utilization of<br />

knowledge and those which are particularly<br />

relevant for its creation in the very<br />

first instance”.<br />

If you need active, democratic, broader<br />

socially based, natural resource sustaining<br />

and future oriented policy, you<br />

need to create the intellectual environment<br />

for it. This then means better and<br />

more funding for research, in both the<br />

social sciences and natural sciences, especially<br />

in our universities. It is commendable<br />

that the 11th plan visualizes a<br />

massive investment in a whole new generation<br />

of advanced higher education<br />

institutions but existing universities do<br />

not adequately figure in the plan. <strong>The</strong><br />

Finance Minister allocating sums in his<br />

annual budget to Universities is also a<br />

good and welcome sign.<br />

<strong>The</strong> second theme that I would like to<br />

pick up and highlight from Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty’s prodigious output of his<br />

intellectual labour for economics and the<br />

country, is that relating to social learning,<br />

social innovation and questions regarding<br />

when do societies really become<br />

‘learning societies’. To a certain extent,<br />

in my view, it relates to the larger noninstitutional<br />

aspects of knowledge, unlike<br />

above where I partly referred to the<br />

institutional conditions for ‘knowledge’<br />

and ‘learning’. <strong>The</strong>re is also the other<br />

aspect of our ability to learn from other<br />

societies. In referring to the question of<br />

‘learning society’, we are dealing with<br />

broader questions of Human Resources<br />

Development and which are critical and<br />

particularly relevant where we stand today<br />

in our nation’s history. Knowledge in<br />

the perspective of Chakravarty needs to<br />

be seen as a public good. One could say,<br />

that in spite of all the middle class parlour<br />

talk and fashion for criticizing Nehruvian<br />

– Mahalanobis (N-M) strategy,<br />

it did give us a higher initial level of<br />

knowledge to start with. Chakravarty<br />

while objective and critical of the N-M<br />

strategy shows its validity and contribution<br />

also. On the second aspect, that of<br />

knowledge being widely shared, this is<br />

where we as a highly caste-ridden and<br />

hierarchical society, have had our problems<br />

and also by and large inherited so-<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is an extra-ordinarily rich harvest of ideas from<br />

Sukhamoy Chakravarty’s writings and how we can go<br />

beyond the dichotomies of market and state, to address<br />

urgent and needed tasks of creating ‘a learning society’<br />

cially serious failures also.<br />

Other than these broad based requirements<br />

and aspects related to creating a<br />

dynamic learning society, that can be<br />

self-sustaining and sustainable, in an<br />

economic, ecological and social sense,<br />

there are other related aspects. Some of<br />

this is related to problems such as technology,<br />

its adaptation, innovation, use<br />

and dissemination. Chakravarty is of the<br />

view that while TNCs do bring technology,<br />

we have to seriously consider whether<br />

it will in fact “lead to a significant<br />

accretion of technical knowledge appropriate<br />

to Indian conditions”. So the creation<br />

and promotion of the conditions for<br />

a learning society, is not just to import<br />

and imitate but also to adapt and contextualize.<br />

Chakravarty with reference to<br />

technology adaptation says how it is,<br />

“more appropriate to the factor endowments<br />

of developing countries deserve<br />

very close considerations”; then adds a<br />

very important qualifier, “it would be<br />

most inappropriate to leave questions of<br />

adaptation to technologists alone” and<br />

the overall macro-economic framework<br />

must be also made conducive to the process<br />

of adaptation. Finally, his other related<br />

and important point, that “given<br />

the contemporary trends in technology,<br />

it is important to allow for a theory of<br />

‘knowledge’ production and dissemination”.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is an extra-ordinarily rich<br />

harvest of ideas and practical policy options<br />

from Sukhamoy Chakravarty’s writings<br />

and how we can go beyond the dichotomies<br />

of market and state, to address<br />

urgent and needed tasks of creating ‘a<br />

learning society’. Time and space does<br />

not allow us to go, into further discussion<br />

and elaboration in this area. In sum, one<br />

can only say that we need to see how to<br />

bring ‘knowledge’ and ‘learning’, as two<br />

very critical aspects of not just economic<br />

growth, but for economic, social and cultural<br />

progress in large and complex developing<br />

societies as ours. It would be a<br />

mockery and travesty to reduce such<br />

unique, rich and diverse societies as ours,<br />

to narrow and limited frameworks of<br />

‘state versus market’.<br />

Comparative Development And<br />

Governance<br />

<strong>The</strong> renowned, ecological and environ-<br />

20 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

mental economist, Herman Daly in his<br />

writings points to the current dilemmas<br />

of economic planning under globalization<br />

wherein comparative advantage has<br />

become absolute advantage, in a situation<br />

of greater integration of economies<br />

and the attempts by powerful countries<br />

to have absolute advantage as regards<br />

trade and investment. Sukhamoy Chakravarty,<br />

with great perspicacity already in<br />

the 1980s pointed to two necessary directions<br />

of theoretical efforts for development<br />

economics in developing countries.<br />

Firstly he had called for “a deeper study<br />

of economic organization from the point<br />

of view of ensuring creativity, growth and<br />

equity” and went on to add that “earlier<br />

discussion of the market versus the Plan<br />

was much too crude”. Secondly and<br />

which is very relevant to our discussion<br />

here, is that “we should possibly reorient<br />

the study of international economics<br />

from its preoccupation with problems of<br />

comparative advantage based on internationally-immobile<br />

primary factors,<br />

towards a study of processes based on<br />

internationalization of capital, changes<br />

in income distribution and the resulting<br />

variations in sectoral productivity levels<br />

which give rise to the emergence of a<br />

process of uneven world economic<br />

growth”. Sukhamoy Chakravarty’s reference<br />

to uneven growth on a world scale<br />

has much relevance even within our<br />

country, in the context of current economic<br />

growth patterns and growth models<br />

dependent and unleashed by globalization,<br />

which in turn are producing very<br />

uneven growth across the country. Thus,<br />

producing income inequalities not only<br />

between groups and individuals but also<br />

between states and regions as a whole<br />

and which has serious implications for<br />

national growth as a whole.<br />

Amartya Sen, similarly has argued (including<br />

in his joint book with Dreze),<br />

“that the success of liberalization and<br />

closer integration with the world economy<br />

may be severely impaired by India’s<br />

backwardness in basic education, elementary<br />

health care, gender inequality<br />

and limitations of land reforms”. He goes<br />

on to say, “While Manmohan Singh (previously<br />

as Finance Minister) did initiate<br />

the correction of governmental over-activity<br />

in some fields, the need to correct<br />

governmental under-activity in other areas<br />

has not really been addressed”. Amartya<br />

Sen’s states that Manmohan Singh,<br />

considered to be the architect of India’s<br />

economic reforms, “stood solidly for<br />

critical scrutiny of the empirical picture,<br />

rather than a large reliance on theory”<br />

and adds that “it would be in the tradition<br />

of his (Manmohan Singh’s) research<br />

to point out that the relevant picture includes<br />

– in the context of the east and<br />

south-east Asian success stories – not<br />

just an orientation towards exports but<br />

also widespread public efforts in basic<br />

education, public health care, female independence,<br />

land reforms, and other<br />

components of social infrastructure”.<br />

Amartya Sen points out that the South-<br />

East Asian and East Asian countries<br />

share conditions “that are particularly<br />

favourable to widespread participation<br />

of the population in economic change.<br />

<strong>The</strong> relevant features include high rates<br />

of literacy, a fair degree of female empowerment,<br />

and quite radical land reforms”.<br />

He then goes to ask the basic<br />

questions that many market-oriented<br />

economists have not had the courage or<br />

honesty to ask, or have even been deeply<br />

uncomfortable when faced with these<br />

questions. Amartya Sen asks, “Can we<br />

expect in India results similar to those<br />

that the more socially egalitarian countries<br />

have achieved, given that half of the<br />

Indian population (and two-thirds of the<br />

women) are still illiterate, that the female<br />

empowerment is very little achieved in<br />

most parts of India, that credit is very<br />

hard to secure by the rural poor, and that<br />

land reforms remain only partially and<br />

We need to seriously study ‘comparative development’<br />

between us and other economies especially in East and<br />

South East Asia to make the correct conclusions<br />

about the role of state and markets<br />

unevenly executed?”<br />

In the foregoing arguments that I have<br />

put forward buttressed by the views of<br />

eminent economists like Amartya Sen,<br />

the point I am emphasizing is that<br />

progress in economic development and<br />

growth cannot be achieved just by putting<br />

up the state against the market, both have<br />

a role and in many instances have even a<br />

synergetic role to play. I go further and<br />

advocate that we need to seriously study<br />

‘comparative development’ between us<br />

and other economies especially in East<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

21


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

and South-East Asia to make the correct<br />

conclusions about the role of state and<br />

markets and to have the pragmatic approach<br />

to use both. Instead what we have<br />

today is simplistic journalistic comparisons<br />

to other economies and often to<br />

only advance the point that in other cases<br />

cited, they have been more market<br />

friendly than the Indian state has been.<br />

What one witnesses, especially in the<br />

popular press and in TV business programmes,<br />

are almost illiterate comparisons<br />

by journalists to other countries and<br />

societies in East and South-East Asia<br />

without any reference to their history or<br />

a deeper understanding of these societies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> comparisons are like frozen in<br />

time and are snapshots of the present<br />

without any reference to how they have<br />

come there. Unfortunately academics<br />

also, instead of making up for their lack<br />

of knowledge of Asian societies, in an<br />

incestuous manner quote these journalistic<br />

comparisons when for example there<br />

is opposition to the entry of TNCs to the<br />

retail trade or to the coercive attempts to<br />

deprive people of their land and force<br />

SEZs down the throat of unsuspecting<br />

citizens. In contrast what we seriously<br />

and urgently need is the building of institutional<br />

capacity to study comparative<br />

development between India and other<br />

developing countries especially in the<br />

Asia and Pacific region and focused on<br />

different aspects of economy, society,<br />

social policy and in general the shaping<br />

of public policy. In a sense the old institutional<br />

arrangements that exist in most<br />

of our universities in the form of area<br />

studies and associated centres and departments<br />

may have to be revisited and<br />

both existing capacity strengthened as<br />

well as new capacity created.<br />

An important dimension of generating<br />

knowledge on comparative development<br />

is to link with governance and understanding<br />

governance related issues. Keeping<br />

in line with what has been said earlier<br />

in this paper about the centrality of governance<br />

to ensure growth that can be socially,<br />

culturally and ecologically sustained,<br />

research and studies need to be<br />

done not only comparing India and Asian<br />

countries but also comparisons within<br />

India between regions and states. Keynes<br />

had held that, “the theory of economics<br />

does not furnish a body of settled conclusions<br />

immediately applicable to policy<br />

Unfortunately academics, instead of making up for their<br />

lack of knowledge of Asian societies, in an incestuous<br />

manner quote journalistic simplistic comparisons down the<br />

throat of unsuspecting citizens<br />

and it is a method rather than a doctrine,<br />

an apparatus of the mind, a technique of<br />

thinking”. Comparative development, in<br />

contemporary times, almost two decades<br />

after the emergence of globalization, is “a<br />

technique of thinking’. Keynes was only<br />

echoing Marshall who in his Principle of<br />

Economics had long ago held the view,<br />

“economics is not a body of concrete<br />

wealth but an engine for the discovery of<br />

concrete truth”. Economists and social<br />

scientists in our country have much work<br />

to do to study and learn from other societies<br />

and in order to ensure that economic<br />

progress and development in our country,<br />

means a full human life for all our citizens<br />

not a situation of vulgar wealth mocking<br />

the inhuman conditions of existence that<br />

is the day to day reality for a very large<br />

number of our citizens. Only then India<br />

will be truly and respected for its greatness<br />

and the extraordinary cultural and<br />

philosophical wealth that it possesses.<br />

Otherwise, we will continued to be seen<br />

as a nation of hypocrites (even if no one<br />

for politeness does not say this to our face)<br />

and no amount of nationalistic jingoism<br />

and fanatical cultural nationalism will<br />

change our image or the situation we are<br />

in as a nation. It is therefore time that<br />

middle class intelligentsia, academics and<br />

intellectuals in India came to grips with<br />

this reality than delude themselves with<br />

false images of greatness.<br />

References<br />

• Sukhamoy Chakravarty, ‘Writings on<br />

Development, with an Introduction by<br />

Mihir Rakshit’, Oxford University<br />

Press, Delhi, 1997<br />

• Dreze, Jean and Amartya Sen, ‘India:<br />

Economic Development and Social<br />

Opportunity’, Oxford University Press,<br />

Delhi, 1995<br />

• Dreze, Jean and Amartya Sen (eds),<br />

‘Indian Development: Regional Perspectives’,<br />

Oxford University Press,<br />

Delhi, 1996<br />

• Amartya Sen, ‘<strong>The</strong>ory and Practice of<br />

Development’, in ‘Indias economic Reforms<br />

and Development-Essays for<br />

Manmohan Singh’, Isher Judge Ahluwalia<br />

and I.M.D.Little (eds), Oxford<br />

University Press, 1998<br />

• Amaresh Bagchi, ‘Role of Planning and<br />

the Planning Commission in the New<br />

Indian Economy: case for a Review’,<br />

Economic and Political Weekly, Bombay,<br />

November 3, <strong>2007</strong>.<br />

22 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


D A R E T O D R E A M : S T R A T E G I C A L L Y ! I N N O V A T I V E L Y !<br />

Strategicw w<br />

July-September <strong>2007</strong>, <strong>Volume</strong> 1 <strong>Issue</strong> 3<br />

Innovators<br />

www.iipm.edu<br />

w . i i p m p u b l i c a t i o n s . c o m<br />

Rs.100<br />

Radical knowledge<br />

Re-structuring<br />

INSIDE THIS ISSUE<br />

20 STRATEGIC CHOICES: ANEEL KARNANI<br />

PROFESSOR OF STRATEGY, UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN<br />

How Indian firms can make better strategic choices &<br />

execute them to achieve true competitive advantages<br />

32<br />

ILLUSION & REALITY: ANDREW LIKIERMAN<br />

DEAN, LONDON BUSINESS SCHOOL<br />

How the success of an organisation is not reflected by<br />

its sheer <strong>size</strong>; rather it’s linked to shareholders’ returns<br />

40<br />

PR AND COMMUNICATION SYSTEM: DAVID NORDFORS<br />

SEMIOR RESEARCH SCHOLAR, STANFORD UNIVERSITY<br />

How communicators & journalists are “attention workers”<br />

driving the “innovation communication system”<br />

48<br />

ENTREPRENEURSHIP: ELIZABETH R. THORNTON<br />

PROFESSOR OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP, BABSON COLLEGE<br />

Unveiling the rich<br />

secrets behind those<br />

unanticipated strategic<br />

master-strokes<br />

Explaining the risks and returns behind many<br />

entrepreneurial motives to start their own businesses<br />

56 INDIA’S PATH TO INNOVATION: DR. DAN STEINBOCK<br />

DIRECTOR, ICT RESEARCH INSTITUTE<br />

On how India’s future depends on the private sector<br />

players becoming the highly-active innovation drivers<br />

AN AN <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> INTELLIGENCE UNIT UNIT PUBLICATION


Pradeep Banerjee,<br />

Independent Consultant,<br />

Bangalore<br />

State And Market Conundrum In <strong>The</strong> Indian<br />

Context – A Need For Debates<br />

"Freedom is hammered out on<br />

the anvil of discussion, dissent<br />

and debate."<br />

-Hubert H. Humphrey<br />

A<br />

concern about the economy is<br />

one that has many a participant.<br />

<strong>The</strong> concern is expressed<br />

in the many debates that refer<br />

to this concern and it does so in a myriad<br />

of ways. It ranges from the animated<br />

to the scholarly, from the simple to the<br />

complex, and from the informed to the<br />

expected. <strong>The</strong>se discussions, then, have<br />

moved out of the confines of the political<br />

class and the academicians. It has<br />

moved in to include members of the<br />

larger civil society. In a manner of<br />

speaking, the debates have become a<br />

part of the discourse of the many participants.<br />

A favoured point in discussions<br />

and debates about the economy is<br />

that about the market. <strong>The</strong>se debates<br />

and discussions are more about the manner<br />

that markets envelope the society,<br />

and also about the manner in which<br />

markets relate to the individual. In some<br />

ways markets have come to be associated<br />

with helping men in their ‘desire of bettering<br />

(their) condition’. 1 That is a probable<br />

reason based on which markets<br />

have almost assumed a proxy for the<br />

economy. Markets, then, are structures<br />

that hold the interest of many. <strong>The</strong> grip<br />

on the interest accrues from a recognition<br />

that markets and human societies<br />

have moved in tandem over long periods<br />

of time now. It is the ubiquitous presence<br />

of the market that makes it an immediate<br />

point of reference. Markets<br />

existed before economists adopted analytical<br />

tools to work on this ubiquitous<br />

item of every day occurrence. Markets<br />

have been analyzed to understand their<br />

dynamics. Markets have been identified<br />

at a spatial level that on immediate reckoning<br />

looms large as structural constructs.<br />

So there are global markets<br />

where the sheer <strong>size</strong> is at once baffling.<br />

And then there are country level markets<br />

that operate using methods and<br />

processes to draw lines of conventions<br />

and lines of practice to retain an identity<br />

that is independent of the global<br />

mind sweep. <strong>The</strong> hierarchy of markets<br />

includes local markets and these local<br />

markets themselves may be larger than<br />

24 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

what can be provided for in a cognitive<br />

mind set of an individual. <strong>The</strong> calibration<br />

of markets using hierarchy, however,<br />

as the defining attribute, does not quiet<br />

capture all that what make up for markets.<br />

Markets as constructs have evolved<br />

and have changed with time moving<br />

from points at which barter was entered<br />

into to places where the magnitude is at<br />

once large and complex. <strong>The</strong> pattern of<br />

thinking and arriving at explanations<br />

that have accompanied these transformations<br />

have similarly changed course.<br />

What causes them and why these are<br />

useful to transactions in society, therefore,<br />

remain important issues. And these<br />

have been so for some time now if we<br />

exclude the antiquity from the purview.<br />

Arriving At A Framework Handy<br />

Enough For A Debate<br />

<strong>The</strong> market is not an island floating in a<br />

sea of societal events. <strong>The</strong> market is<br />

probably more like an iceberg that has<br />

a ninth of it unseen. <strong>The</strong>se are not institutions<br />

that occur in relative isolation.<br />

Instead these occur when commerce<br />

clearly engages the society as an activity<br />

that a society needs to engage itself<br />

with. Accordingly, and for instance, ‘the<br />

“Spirit” of Capitalism’, in a manner that<br />

Weber approached the issue and elaborated<br />

upon it, probably has a lot to do<br />

with the issue of markets. Weber was of<br />

course concerned with commerce, and<br />

the manner in which this activity<br />

emerged from after being confined to<br />

ethical pits for a long time and particularly<br />

during the Middle Ages and up to<br />

the beginnings of the modern period. As<br />

regards markets, these were accepted as<br />

a part of commerce for these went alongside<br />

commerce. Weber was writing in<br />

the 1890s and he referred to the term<br />

‘economic order’ to which both the individual<br />

and the enterprise had to comply<br />

with. If the modern period is identified<br />

with a pervasiveness of the economic<br />

order and in which compliance comes in<br />

as given, it was not so earlier. ‘<strong>The</strong> capitalist<br />

spirit’ Weber wrote, ‘has had to<br />

prove itself in a hard struggle against a<br />

world of hostile forces.’ 2 On matters related<br />

to the establishment of commerce,<br />

then, we would need to go an earlier author.<br />

Adam Smith in his <strong>The</strong> Wealth of<br />

Nations wrote of the manner in which<br />

feudalism underwent erosion. <strong>The</strong> erosion<br />

had to do with the establishment<br />

and the consequent spread of commerce<br />

and manufacture. <strong>The</strong> observations of<br />

Smith are relevant in yet another manner.<br />

<strong>The</strong> spread of commerce and manufacture<br />

brought in certain fundamental<br />

changes in the society. And finally it<br />

brought in the first hints of the involvement<br />

of the ruling elite in this spread.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Chapter was entitled tellingly “How<br />

the Commerce of Towns Contributed to<br />

the Improvement of the Country”. In it<br />

Smith wrote, ‘commerce and manufactures<br />

gradually introduced order and<br />

good government, and with them, the<br />

liberty and security of individuals.’ 3 <strong>The</strong><br />

rationale for the coming in of peace over<br />

that of warfare that were carried on by<br />

manor lords between themselves was<br />

traced to the declining influence of these<br />

manor lords over the sovereign. <strong>The</strong> surplus<br />

could now be expended on manufactories<br />

that commerce helped deliver<br />

for consumption. And Smith, who was a<br />

votary for individual efforts, once again<br />

empha<strong>size</strong>d on the ‘desire of bettering<br />

(their) condition’. Smith wrote that, ‘<strong>The</strong><br />

natural efforts of every individual to better<br />

his own condition, when suffered to<br />

exert itself with freedom and security, is<br />

so powerful a principle, that it is alone,<br />

and without any assistance, not only capable<br />

of carrying on the society to wealth<br />

and prosperity, but of surmounting a<br />

hundred impertinent obstructions with<br />

which the folly of human laws too often<br />

encumber its operations.’ 4 Smith had his<br />

reservations about commerce and those<br />

who practiced it, and yet he was emphatic<br />

on the impact that commerce and<br />

manufacturing had on society. On the<br />

whole the impact was good. <strong>The</strong>re is a<br />

primacy of economics in his statement<br />

Markets have almost assumed a proxy for the economy.<br />

Markets, then are structures that hold the interest of many.<br />

<strong>The</strong> grip on the interest accrues from a recognition<br />

that markets and human societies have moved in<br />

tandem over long periods of time now<br />

for he points out that the momentum<br />

generated could surmount the hindrances<br />

to progress. It is of these and similar<br />

hindrances that the referencing by Weber<br />

highlighted.<br />

<strong>The</strong> intermixing of politics and economics<br />

was clearly seen by others too<br />

and the emerging viewpoint clarified<br />

that the expansion of economics went<br />

along with an expansion of the political<br />

landscape. Of the many who wrote on<br />

this issue, Adam Fergusson (1723-1816),<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

25


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

yet another Scot and identified with the<br />

Scottish Enlightenment, was articulate<br />

on the issue. In his An Essay on the History<br />

of Civil Society (1767), Fergusson<br />

wrote that, ‘It has been found, that, except<br />

in a few singular cases, the commercial<br />

and political arts have advanced<br />

together.’ 5 Fergusson maintained that<br />

the incidence of commerce was quiet<br />

engaged with the ways of nations and<br />

pointed out that, ‘In some nations the<br />

spirit of commerce, intent on securing<br />

its profits, has led the way to political<br />

wisdom’. 6 <strong>The</strong> point that was being made<br />

by Fergusson was received well and the<br />

text of the Essay on the History of Civil<br />

Society ‘found many enthusiastic readers<br />

in London, where it went through<br />

seven editions in Fergusson’s lifetime.’ 7<br />

It was an endorsement of the general acceptance<br />

of these thoughts and explanations<br />

about the working of the economy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> schools of German Philosophy<br />

tors who debated on a host of areas that<br />

were at once connected with the enquiries<br />

that Smith and Fergusson were working<br />

on. <strong>The</strong> transition was clearly visible<br />

and so much so that until the seventeenth<br />

century, the term economy did<br />

not quiet signify much and that university<br />

chairs were set up for studies in ethics<br />

and not that for economics. Smith<br />

himself was appointed as a professor of<br />

moral philosophy in 1752 and published<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>The</strong>ory of the Moral Sentiments in<br />

1759, years earlier to <strong>The</strong> Wealth of Nations<br />

which was published in 1776. <strong>The</strong><br />

transition was notable enough and<br />

It was reasoned that if the interests of these contending<br />

actors (Commercial class and State) were so intense, the<br />

resultant interactions could well be inimical to either of<br />

them and could therefore be a source of stress in the<br />

society. Hence, came the idea of civil society<br />

would also remain indebted to Fergusson<br />

for the term civil society, a term that<br />

would also be used here in connection<br />

with the market and the State.<br />

<strong>The</strong> contributions of Smith and Fergusson<br />

were important. <strong>The</strong>y helped<br />

recognize the reasons for commerce and<br />

further enabled recognition of an additional<br />

two domains that were relevant to<br />

matters of manufactories and commerce.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se were those of markets and that of<br />

States. <strong>The</strong>re were many more contribu-<br />

Watson points out that when Smith died<br />

‘after a life of intellectual adventure and<br />

social prudence’, a local newspaper complained<br />

in its obituary (4 August 1790)<br />

that he had ‘converted his chair of moral<br />

philosophy at Glasgow University into<br />

one of trade and finance’.’ 8 And while<br />

earlier in Britain ‘men argued that human<br />

nature rather than the state should<br />

govern economics’, matters changed<br />

course and the role of the state became<br />

clearer so much so that, ‘We should not<br />

forget that state intervention in the<br />

eighteenth century was very important<br />

to economic development and Smith<br />

never disagreed with this.’ 9 <strong>The</strong> debates<br />

initiated by thinkers such as Smith and<br />

Fergusson, among the many others, had<br />

initiated major long term changes. And<br />

if the stage was set for expansion of commercial<br />

trade and manufactories, their<br />

momentum was quiet clearly induced by<br />

debates that took place during these periods.<br />

Changes during the next period of<br />

the nineteenth century and those thereafter<br />

are testimony to the expansion that<br />

had been achieved by these nations.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Third Actor – Inclusion Of<br />

<strong>The</strong> Civil Society As Part Of<br />

<strong>The</strong> Triad<br />

<strong>The</strong> growth of these economies brought<br />

into sharp focus a number of developments<br />

that claimed for attention. <strong>The</strong><br />

rise of the commercial class with its<br />

members quiet clearly interested in their<br />

private interests and that of the State<br />

could expectedly raise the requirements<br />

of boundaries determining their spheres<br />

of operation. It was reasoned that if the<br />

interests of these contending actors were<br />

so intense, as it appeared to be, the resultant<br />

interactions could well be inimical<br />

to either of them and could therefore<br />

be a source of stress in the society. It is<br />

as an outcome of this concern that the<br />

idea of civil society came to be articulated.<br />

If the term civil society has been<br />

an old one, it is with John Locke (1632-<br />

1704), the Scottish Enlightenment<br />

group, and Georg Hegel (1770-1831) that<br />

the term came to be positioned more<br />

firmly and done so in the contextual format<br />

that includes the State and the market.<br />

Seligman observes that ‘what stood<br />

26 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

at the core of all attempts to articulate<br />

a notion of civil society in that period,<br />

and since, has been the problematic relation<br />

between the private and the public;<br />

the individual and the social; public ethics<br />

and individual interests; and individual<br />

passions, and public concerns.’ 10<br />

<strong>The</strong> organization of society being an endeavor<br />

of immediate concern, the inclusion<br />

of civil society as a building block is<br />

as relevant and in this context plays a<br />

normative role. Civil society as a normative<br />

ideal emerged, as Seligman points<br />

out to ‘as the result of a crisis in social<br />

order and a breakdown of existing paradigms<br />

of the idea of order.’ 11 <strong>The</strong> stress<br />

points and crisis refers to that between<br />

the State and individual interests. <strong>The</strong><br />

role of civil society has been assessed in<br />

these contexts, and to discharge which<br />

role civil society ‘is most usefully thought<br />

as identifying a set of human capacities,<br />

moral and political.’ 12 This is an effective<br />

expression to hold on to for assessing<br />

the impact of civil society when<br />

functioning as a part of the triad formed<br />

by the State, the market and the<br />

civil society.<br />

Spread Of Markets, Influence<br />

Of States And <strong>The</strong> Colonial<br />

Period In India<br />

It is a point that is made that the state of<br />

the economy in the earlier part of the<br />

eighteenth century in India was not so<br />

different as compared to that in Britain<br />

and other European countries. It is observed<br />

that the ‘economies of India,<br />

China, and other Asian regions in the<br />

early eighteenth century were not so different<br />

– hardly less sophisticated than in<br />

Europe’ and that ‘the economies of Britain<br />

and Europe accelerated after 1750,<br />

quickly outstripping those of India, China,<br />

Japan and the rest of Asia.’ 13 <strong>The</strong><br />

stirrings of the early differences began<br />

at some time during the seventeenth and<br />

the eighteenth centuries. <strong>The</strong> case study<br />

of India is an illustration of what occurred<br />

as a response to the emergent<br />

State and interactions between the State,<br />

the market and the civil society.<br />

<strong>The</strong> pre-colonial history of India has<br />

a continuity that is easily segregated<br />

from that of the beginnings of the arrival<br />

of commercial class from Britain<br />

and other European nation states to India<br />

in search of markets. This early history<br />

of travelers, merchants and those of<br />

the East India Company officials are<br />

that of commercial interests in search of<br />

markets. In various ways the State in<br />

Britain and those in other nations too<br />

emerged as supporters that enabled a<br />

deepening of interests. It is, however,<br />

the cessation of the Company rule and<br />

the initiation of the colonial rule by the<br />

State in Britain that the changes came<br />

into much sharper focus. This is expected<br />

inasmuch as the rule by the colonial<br />

State was qualitatively different from<br />

that by commercial interests in the form<br />

of the Company supported though the<br />

Company was by the State. Accordingly,<br />

while the early stages, and that prior to<br />

the proclamation transferring power to<br />

the State of Britain of the territory of<br />

India, offers a fascinating story of the<br />

manner in which the commercial class<br />

established its presence in the country,<br />

it is the firming up of the relationships<br />

under the State that is of relevance here.<br />

<strong>The</strong> response of the civil society to the<br />

colonial State was at once sharp and often<br />

provocative. Dadabhai Naoroji, the<br />

forefront spokesperson of the economic<br />

drain theory and who estimated the<br />

drain to be to the extent of ‘30,000,000<br />

to 40,000,000 a year’ did not find any<br />

issues with the ‘operations of economic<br />

laws’ as a cause behind this sorry state<br />

of India. Instead, he identified the British<br />

State and its policies that were the<br />

cause. Writing in 1880, Dadabhai pointed<br />

out that, ‘It is not the pitiless operations<br />

of economic laws, but it is the<br />

thoughtless and pitiless action of the<br />

British policy; … in short, it is the pitiless<br />

perversion of economic laws by the<br />

sad bleeding to which India is subjected,<br />

that is destroying India.’ 14 <strong>The</strong> point<br />

Dadabhai Naoroji, the forefront spokesperson of the economic<br />

drain theory and who estimated the drain to be to<br />

the extent of ‘30,000,000 to 40,000,000 a year’ did not<br />

find any issues with the ‘operations of economic laws’ as a<br />

cause behind this sorry state of India<br />

about the overreach by the State was not<br />

restricted to identifying that it was the<br />

role of the State, and the manner in<br />

which the State denuded the economy<br />

causing, that were the reason for the severe<br />

handicap faced by the populace of<br />

the country over which the State presided.<br />

A further issue was raised, and it<br />

was about the operation and influence<br />

of the colonial State as against that of<br />

the pre-colonial State. Dadabhai pointed<br />

out that under the suzerainty of the<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

27


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

‘native despot the people keep and enjoy<br />

what they produce, though at times they<br />

suffer some violence in the back. Under<br />

the British Indian despot the man is at<br />

peace, there is no violence; his substance<br />

is drained away, unseen, peaceably and<br />

subtly – he starves in peace, and peaceably<br />

perishes in peace, with law and order!”<br />

15 This was a clear recognition of<br />

the differences among the type of States,<br />

and it was a rendition of practices that<br />

each of these States had on the economy.<br />

Dadabhai, a civil society member, was<br />

elaborating on the overreach by the<br />

State and the manner in which its hegemony<br />

overshadowed the development<br />

of indigenous commercial class. <strong>The</strong> focus<br />

of the drain theory was not on the<br />

underdevelopment of the commercial<br />

class per se. <strong>The</strong> State and Commercial<br />

interest were locked into a symbiotic relationship<br />

such as to benefit the British<br />

economy. <strong>The</strong> loss to the peripheral<br />

economy was a consequence. <strong>The</strong> indigenous<br />

commercial class moved forward<br />

instead on a stunted road.<br />

If the State arose as a means to reduce<br />

the violence among interacting individuals<br />

and groups, the colonial State quiet<br />

well performed on this attribute of Statehood.<br />

Dadabhai clearly recognized this<br />

at the empirical level and wrote about<br />

this while elaborating on the arrival of a<br />

more peaceful time over that which prevailed<br />

earlier. <strong>The</strong> peaceful time that<br />

the Colonial State brought in augmented<br />

an increase in economic produce in the<br />

form of raw material that the colonizing<br />

economy required as inputs to its produce.<br />

<strong>The</strong> peripheral economy also provided<br />

the market that the Commercial<br />

interests of the class in that economy<br />

required. <strong>The</strong> peace that came in was<br />

required for the market and yet there<br />

was no getting away from the fact that<br />

the Colonial State while engaged in doing<br />

so was engendering growth of the<br />

markets for the colonizing State. Dadabhai<br />

wrote that, ‘<strong>The</strong>re is security of life<br />

and property in one sense or way, i.e.,<br />

the people are secure from any violence<br />

from each other or from Native despots.’<br />

And yet this did not secure the economy<br />

from the drain that the colonial State<br />

had established. Accordingly, ‘What is<br />

secure, and well secure, is that England<br />

is perfectly safe and secure …to carry<br />

away from India, and to eat up in India,<br />

<strong>The</strong> State and Commercial interest were locked into a<br />

symbiotic relationship such as to benefi t the British<br />

economy. <strong>The</strong> loss to the peripheral economy was a<br />

consequence. <strong>The</strong> indigenous commercial class moved<br />

forward instead on a stunted road<br />

her property at the present rate of<br />

30,000,000 to 40,000,000 a year.’ 16<br />

So clear were the State and Market<br />

relationship recognized that other members<br />

of the civil society too expressed<br />

their dissension with the practices that<br />

emerged out of this relationship. Writing<br />

in the Indian People on 27 th of February<br />

1903, Sachidanand Sinha, pointed out<br />

that the effective administration practiced<br />

during the governance of Lord<br />

Curzon was more an outcome necessitated<br />

by the requirements of commerce.<br />

‘Trade cannot thrive without efficient<br />

administration’, wrote Sinha and adding<br />

that the ‘latter is not worth attending to<br />

in the absence of profits of the former.’<br />

Consequently, it is ‘always with the assent<br />

and often to the dictates of the<br />

Chambers of Commerce (that) the Government<br />

of India is carried on’. 17<br />

This is not a place for arriving at exhaustive<br />

details of the manner in which<br />

the colonial State worked around to address<br />

the requirements of the markets.<br />

Suffice it note that the thesis of Sate and<br />

market reinforcing each other is quiet<br />

clearly observable during this period<br />

and that the members of the Indian civil<br />

society had been able to identify this<br />

relationship. It was recognition of this<br />

relationship that brought the civil society<br />

to debate about the relationship and<br />

so as to arrive at what was required to<br />

change the coordinates of the relationship.<br />

It was the cohesion of the civil society,<br />

which over the years gathered<br />

members of the commercial class that<br />

prompted the building of alternative<br />

viewpoints of the manner that the economy<br />

should function. <strong>The</strong> subsequent<br />

participation by political parties as a<br />

joint effort brought in the transition<br />

from the colonial State to a State that<br />

was part of the Indian scenario. This<br />

constitutes the second issue that merits<br />

recognition and it is that of the civil society<br />

playing an important role in influencing<br />

the changeover from the earlier<br />

State mode to that of yet another one.<br />

Post-Colonialism And <strong>The</strong><br />

Search For New Paradigms<br />

<strong>The</strong> triad of State, market and civil society<br />

as it were during the colonial pe-<br />

28 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

riod came in for significant changes after<br />

the colonial period came to their end. In<br />

the Indian instance, their build up were<br />

influenced by the colonial forces. <strong>The</strong><br />

market that was more local in the precolonial<br />

period was not quiet so at the<br />

start of the post-colonial period. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

was the availability of a market economy<br />

enabled to a significant degree by a network<br />

of railway connection. <strong>The</strong> availability<br />

of a market economy is an important<br />

distinction, for it helps to make a<br />

transition from where an economy is to<br />

where it wants to reach in a manner that<br />

is akin to a transformation of the economy.<br />

In the Indian instance, Jha points<br />

out that the country at the start of its<br />

post-colonial journey was, among other<br />

countries, the one that was ‘best placed<br />

to make a transition quickly because it<br />

was the only country with a fully developed<br />

national market economy.’ 18 And<br />

yet at the end of about six decades of<br />

economic management, the changes in<br />

the economy is seemingly short of that<br />

which can be viewed as one of transformation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> economic transformation<br />

of India, it is contended, ‘has run into<br />

difficulties because it has gone too slow’,<br />

leading to an outcome that Jha refers to<br />

as ‘the paradox of India’s slow transition’.<br />

19 <strong>The</strong> presence of markets at this<br />

point in time came along with the presence<br />

of the indigenous commercial class<br />

too. As regards the State and the civil<br />

society, the changes recorded by these<br />

two actors require further exploration.<br />

<strong>The</strong> explanation lies in the specific historical<br />

experiences that the State and<br />

civil society underwent in the country.<br />

<strong>The</strong> dimensions of the market are<br />

easier to discern; it is not so with that of<br />

the State and the civil society. <strong>The</strong> involvement<br />

of the civil society in the colonial<br />

period with the colonial State gave<br />

rise to an important development unique<br />

in its own way and quiet different from<br />

that which the European instances<br />

record. In this case, there was a formation<br />

of a ‘we’ that was distinctly different<br />

from the State. It was the norm that nationalist<br />

movements would recruit their<br />

support of interested parties from<br />

among the intending participants in<br />

their cause. <strong>The</strong> goal was the removal of<br />

the colonial State. Towards this, the participation<br />

that was sought was from an<br />

increasing number of participants and<br />

even from those who were not quiet covered<br />

by the colonial State. <strong>The</strong> practitioners<br />

of nationalism, in other words,<br />

were making a case of representing the<br />

indigenous populace in all their domains<br />

of practice, be it economic or be it otherwise.<br />

<strong>The</strong> change from a colonial State<br />

to a nation State was carried out under<br />

the controlling interest of nationalism.<br />

This led to the formation of a State that<br />

was different from the colonial State.<br />

Characterizing this State, Kaviraj points<br />

out that the ‘secret of the immense power<br />

of the nation-states was not the inheritance<br />

from colonialism but from their<br />

nationalist mobilization.’ 20 <strong>The</strong> range of<br />

activities that the State could now command<br />

over was large and it now had the<br />

advantage of being a representative<br />

State that could speak for all. Note that<br />

this was distinct from the European instances<br />

where attempts were consistently<br />

made to sustain different domains<br />

for the State, the market and the civil<br />

society. <strong>The</strong> contributions of theorists<br />

who tried to find solutions to the problem<br />

of one of the actors in an overreach<br />

situation over the other the other two,<br />

and covered in the earlier part of this<br />

essay, were directed to this end. In the<br />

evolving model that had emerged in a<br />

post-colonial State, the overreach by the<br />

State was at the cost of the civil society.<br />

An outcome of the influence of the nation State during<br />

the post colonial period, upon most matters that<br />

the nationalists had embedded their positions on in the<br />

colonial period, was that the State took on contingent<br />

responsibilities in a number of activities<br />

An outcome of the influence of the nation<br />

State during the post colonial period<br />

on most matters that the nationalists<br />

had embedded their positions on in<br />

the colonial period was that the State<br />

took on contingent responsibilities in a<br />

number of activities. This meant a<br />

squeezing of the markets that the commercial<br />

classes in the society would have<br />

endorsed targeting for their growth. A<br />

large spread of influence and an inclusive<br />

control over economic activities can<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

29


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

mean a slow down in pushing the economic<br />

agenda. A lesser reliance on market<br />

forces of the type that emerges as<br />

with a market economy and coupled with<br />

an intensifying bureaucratization of<br />

processes can bring in a slow down making<br />

the transition that much more difficult<br />

to execute. Bhagwati points out to<br />

the overhang of the State leading to ‘the<br />

inability to trust the market when scarcities<br />

are acute and the tasks are challenging’.<br />

21 <strong>The</strong> impact of this overhang on<br />

the market had certain long term effects<br />

for the practices of the State in the economic<br />

sphere. A ‘combination of industrial<br />

licensing and controls at home with<br />

import and exchange controls externally,<br />

effectively cut off rigours of competition<br />

from all sources and made the creation<br />

of a rentier, as against an entrepreneurial,<br />

economy more likely.’ 22 An overhang<br />

of this type has an adverse impact on the<br />

creation of the market and on agents, or<br />

entrepreneurs, who constitute an important<br />

part of the market. <strong>The</strong> movement<br />

from early post-colonial period and into<br />

latter day envisages the highs and the<br />

lows of the State and its influence on the<br />

economy and the polity. This has not<br />

been a period of the routine; it has instead<br />

been a period that can be characterized<br />

by the term ‘change’.<strong>The</strong> economy<br />

progressed from early reaching of<br />

high notches as at the end of the early<br />

plans, to a leveling of the growth and<br />

whereby the economy was described as<br />

one that was inflicted by a Hindu rate of<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> economy periodically recorded<br />

weaknesses in its ability to deliver<br />

as much as was demanded of it. In<br />

a manner of speaking the overstretched<br />

State which depended on large scale<br />

controls to be able to deliver the promises<br />

that were made now faced road<br />

blocks in its way forward. <strong>The</strong> liberaliza-<br />

<strong>The</strong> process of debate is augmentative. <strong>The</strong> need is to<br />

engage the State by the civil society. Debates are expected<br />

to enhance an understanding of the way that the intricate<br />

relationships between the triad of actors and also to help<br />

determine the way forward from the current relationship<br />

tion of the 1990s and thereafter, accordingly,<br />

focused on dismantling the economic<br />

controls that had been instituted<br />

during the course of the journey after<br />

independence. <strong>The</strong> growth rates that<br />

have been realized, and the prospects<br />

that have come to be expected, has<br />

prompted a re-look yet again at what<br />

could be the best solution for moving<br />

forward. <strong>The</strong> market has expectedly become<br />

an arena to be looked into with<br />

more than usual interest.<br />

Debates Are Contributive<br />

We started with the observation that the<br />

debate on the market has progressed<br />

beyond the confines of the few. It now<br />

includes the many instead, and this for<br />

the simple reason that the market concerns<br />

all. Markets, then, turn out to be<br />

constructs that are influenced by the<br />

manner in which economic activities are<br />

handled in society. Markets have that<br />

quality which encourages the many to<br />

arrive at answers about its construct.<br />

This happens because of the relationship<br />

that individuals have with the market.<br />

This is important because it also<br />

brings in the role of democracy and following<br />

the adoption of which there is an<br />

influence by members of society who opt<br />

for a political governance of the type<br />

that is shaped by this political mode of<br />

participation. It is about the influence<br />

that civil society has on the political terrain<br />

and also about the influence that<br />

civil society can have on that terrain.<br />

<strong>The</strong> influence that matters in the context<br />

that has been drawn out here is that on<br />

the State and Market relationship and it<br />

is here that the influence could be one<br />

of moving forward such that the outcome<br />

is that of consensual gain. <strong>The</strong><br />

political influence that leads to the<br />

putting up of a confrontationist barrier<br />

is of negative consequence. It is here<br />

that the process of debate is augmentative.<br />

<strong>The</strong> need is to engage the State by<br />

the civil society. <strong>The</strong> debates are expected<br />

to enhance an understanding of the<br />

way that the intricate relationships between<br />

the triad of actors, namely, the<br />

State, the market and the civil society<br />

works and also to help determine the<br />

way forward from the current status of<br />

existing relationship. A preponderant<br />

30 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

reliance on the market can be debilitative<br />

as much as one on the role of the<br />

State to work as the redeemer in view of<br />

its spread and involvement in a majority<br />

of human spheres of activities. A civil<br />

society that is built on representing sectional<br />

interests is yet again a handicap.<br />

<strong>The</strong> rationale for debates into and about<br />

the interacting relationships is expected<br />

to yield a better perspective about actions<br />

to be taken. In a maturing political<br />

economy, these debates are important<br />

given that ‘these debates form parts of<br />

a collective reflection on the nature of<br />

the conditions which political democracy<br />

requires to take root and flourish.’<br />

23<br />

<strong>The</strong> market, as it stands, is but a construct.<br />

Taken by itself the market could<br />

be amoral. It is constructed best, and<br />

functions so, when it is mediated by the<br />

State in terms of the coordinates set up<br />

by the civil society. To say so is not to<br />

reduce the entirety of the State, market<br />

and civil society complex as an outcome<br />

of an instrumentalist intervention.<br />

For doing so is not even a good<br />

theoretical exercise, leave alone a matter<br />

of practice.<br />

<strong>The</strong> State and market conundrum is<br />

an intricate issue and particularly so in<br />

an economy that has had a past of the<br />

type that India has. It is that debates<br />

would address complex body made up<br />

by the State, the market and the civil<br />

society the necessary enabling momentum<br />

to take those steps that would address<br />

needs of the society. That is why<br />

there is a need for debates. And as we<br />

have seen, there have been instances of<br />

such debates influencing the society.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Indian instance is not exempt<br />

from this.<br />

References<br />

1.<br />

Adam Smith in his ‘An Inquiry into<br />

the Nature and Causes of the Wealth<br />

of Nations’ pointed out that ‘an augmentation<br />

of fortune is the means by<br />

which the greater part of men propose<br />

and wish to better their conditions.’<br />

2.<br />

Weber, Max., ‘<strong>The</strong> Protestant Ethic<br />

and the “Spirit” of Capitalism and<br />

Other Writings’, Penguin Books, New<br />

York, 2002, p.15.<br />

3.<br />

Hirschman, A., ‘<strong>The</strong> Passions and the<br />

Interests – Political Arguments for<br />

Capitalism before Its Triumph’, Princeton<br />

University Press, Princeton,<br />

New Jersey, 1997, p.100.<br />

4.<br />

Ibid., p.103<br />

5.<br />

Ibid, p. 120.<br />

6<br />

. Ibid, p. 120.<br />

7.<br />

Watson, P., ‘Ideas – A History from<br />

Fire to Freud’, Widenfield & Nicolson,<br />

London, 2005, p.539.<br />

8.<br />

Ibid., p. 541. Watson herein refers to<br />

the work of Ian Simpson Ross, ‘<strong>The</strong><br />

Life of Adam Smith’, Oxford: <strong>The</strong> Oxford<br />

University Press, 1995.<br />

9.<br />

Ibid., p.541. In this elaboration,<br />

Watson refers to the work of Paul<br />

Langford, ‘A Polite and Commercial<br />

People’, Oxford University Press, Oxford,<br />

1989.<br />

10.<br />

Seligman, A., “Civil Society as Idea<br />

and Ideal”, in Chambers, S and Kymlicka,<br />

W’, (edited)., ‘Alternative Conceptions<br />

of Civil Society’, Princeton<br />

University Press, Princeton, 2002, pp.<br />

13-14.<br />

11.<br />

Ibid., p.14.<br />

12.<br />

Khilnani, S., “<strong>The</strong> development of<br />

civil society”, in Kaviraj, S and Khilnani,<br />

S, (edited)., ‘Civil Society – History<br />

and Possibilities’, Cambridge<br />

University Press, Foundation Books,<br />

2002, p. 25.<br />

13.<br />

Pomeranz, C., ‘<strong>The</strong> Great Divergence:<br />

China, Europe and the making of the<br />

Modern World Economy’, Princeton<br />

University Press, Princeton, 2000,<br />

quoted in Watson, P., Ibid.’ p.570.<br />

Also see Frank, Andre Gunder., Review<br />

of ‘<strong>The</strong> Great Divergence’, Journal<br />

of Asian Studies, at www.rrojasdatabank.org/agfrank/pomeranz.html,<br />

accessed on 19th November <strong>2007</strong>.<br />

14.<br />

Naoroji, Dadabhai., ‘Poverty and Un-<br />

British Rule in India’, p.216 and quoted<br />

in Chandra, B, Mukherjee, M,<br />

Mukherjee, A, Panikkar, K. N, and<br />

Mahajan, S., ‘India’s Struggle for Independence<br />

– 1857 – 1947, Penguin<br />

Books, 1991, New Delhi, p.97.<br />

15.<br />

Naoroji, Dadabhai., ‘Speeches’, p.389<br />

and quoted in Chandra, B et al., Op.<br />

cit., p.100.<br />

16.<br />

Naoroji, Dadabhai., ‘Poverty and Un-<br />

British Rule in India’, pp.224-25, Op.<br />

cit., p.99.<br />

17.<br />

Chandra, B et al., Op. cit., p.99.<br />

18.<br />

Jha, Prem Shankar., ‘<strong>The</strong> Perilous<br />

Road to the Market – <strong>The</strong> Political<br />

Economy of Reform in Russia, India<br />

and China’, Rupa and Company, New<br />

Delhi, 2002, p. 165.<br />

19<br />

. Ibid., p.165<br />

20.<br />

Kaviraj, S., “In Search of Civil Society”,<br />

in Kaviraj, S and Khilnani, S, (edited).,<br />

Op. cit., p. 314.<br />

21<br />

. Bhagwati, Jagdish., ‘India in Transition<br />

– Freeing the Economy’, Oxford<br />

University Press, New Delhi, 1994,<br />

page. 51.<br />

22<br />

. Ibid., p. 61.<br />

23<br />

.Kaviraj, S., “In Search of Civil<br />

Society”, in Kaviraj, Sudipta and<br />

Khilnani, Sunil, (edited)., Op. cit.,<br />

page. 323.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

31


Anandajit Goswami,<br />

Associate Fellow, <strong>The</strong> Energy<br />

and Resources Institute (TERI),<br />

New Delhi<br />

Larger Market Role, Reduced<br />

Government Interventions – Is It A Misnomer?<br />

"Liberty is the only thing you<br />

cannot have unless you are<br />

willing to give it to others."<br />

-William Allen White<br />

<strong>The</strong> above title highlights some basic<br />

facets of the reformist changes that<br />

have taken place in India during<br />

the liberalization period. <strong>The</strong> “India Shining”<br />

campaign marked by stupendous<br />

growth rates of the economy owing to diversified<br />

market led reforms has created a notion<br />

of reimagination of India fraught by<br />

greater role of the market with less government<br />

intervention. But it is absolutely imperative<br />

to look onto other dimensions of<br />

the growth story before such a reimagination<br />

of India is well established. <strong>The</strong> following<br />

sections of this article would dwell upon<br />

some of those dimensions.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Growth Story<br />

We all know that the growth of the Indian<br />

economy has not followed the classical<br />

growth pattern as stated by many growth<br />

theorists like Solow where the growth of the<br />

economy starts from agriculture sector followed<br />

by its transmission to the manufacturing<br />

and services sector. In India’s case the<br />

larger part of the growth has been a result<br />

of service led growth. <strong>The</strong> growth in agriculture<br />

sector started with green revolution<br />

in Indian economy. <strong>The</strong>re after there has<br />

been a leap frogging jump in the growth pattern<br />

towards service sector during the period<br />

from 1990s till now without a subsequent<br />

growth in manufacturing sector. <strong>The</strong><br />

manufacturing growth has stagnated at the<br />

same time. According to recent estimates<br />

the share of service sector has increased to<br />

more than 50 percent of the GDP of the Indian<br />

economy whereas the sectoral share for<br />

agriculture in the GDP has dropped down<br />

to 16 percent. 1 Another factor that has contributed<br />

to the growth of Indian economy is<br />

the opening up of the economy through<br />

larger exports and imports. This has been<br />

evident in the double digit (close to 20 percent)<br />

growth rate in the export of principal<br />

commodities from India in the recent years.<br />

<strong>The</strong> trade policy (2004–2009) 2 of India also<br />

highlights the point of the growth of Indian<br />

economy by meeting export targets. Statistics<br />

show that our current account is in a<br />

deficit due to huge imports, which is balanced<br />

by capital account surplus. This has<br />

been triggered mainly by large amount of<br />

32 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

foreign institutional investments in the Indian<br />

economy. However at the back of all<br />

these shining stories, the cause for worry lies<br />

in another fact. Statistics show that although<br />

Indian GDP has grown at a rate of 7 percent<br />

– 8 percent and is hinting to touch a doubledigit<br />

figure of 10 percent 3 in recent times,<br />

the employment elasticity of the Indian<br />

economy has not grown proportionately<br />

with respect to the growth in GDP. Thus<br />

although income of the country has grown<br />

by one unit it has not increased the employment<br />

potential by one unit. Thus the growth<br />

has created inequality in the Indian economy<br />

which is a serious question at the backdrop<br />

of the service led growth. Studies also<br />

show that the sectoral inequality (Goswami<br />

A, Chakraborty P <strong>2007</strong>) across the Indian<br />

economy has also increased during the period<br />

of 1990–2003. So the question is in spite<br />

of market led reforms leading to growth in<br />

the economy why the growth has not been<br />

chanellised to tackle important developmental<br />

factors like growing inequality? <strong>The</strong><br />

next section highlights some of the factors<br />

which have contributed to this gloomy side<br />

of the India Shining Story.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Developmental Side<br />

<strong>The</strong> startling facts regarding development<br />

come with certain important numbers. Data<br />

shows that in spite of moving in a growth<br />

trajectory India’s ranking in Human Development<br />

Index is 126. 4 This is much lower<br />

than the rank, which many other developing<br />

countries with which India’s growth is being<br />

compared. Development has many dimensions<br />

like poverty, nutrition, fertility rates,<br />

mortality rates, access to safe water and<br />

sanitation. Statistics shows that although<br />

poverty rate (Head Count Ratio) in India is<br />

going down, the malnutrition index is going<br />

up. 5 <strong>The</strong> moot question is whether it is due<br />

to lack of access to public services and goods<br />

like safe water and sanitation or is it because<br />

of lifestyle changes. <strong>The</strong> infant mortality<br />

rates are still quite low in certain states like<br />

Orissa in India. <strong>The</strong> primary school drop<br />

out rates have not decreased to a large extent<br />

in some states and it has failed in some<br />

instances in Rajasthan largely due to institutional<br />

failures. <strong>The</strong> teacher attendances<br />

in primary schools have not improved in<br />

many rural parts of India. <strong>The</strong> mid–day<br />

meal programme has failed in some states<br />

like Rajasthan owing to corruption and governance<br />

failures. <strong>The</strong>se governance failures<br />

are reflected in the fact that according to the<br />

recent IFPRI report India stands out at 94<br />

in the Hunger Index and is below African<br />

countries like Burkina Faso, Zimbabwe<br />

whose ranks are 92 and 93 respectively. 6<br />

Some of the neighbouring countries of India<br />

like Srilanka (with a rank 69) are above India<br />

in the Hunger Index. Other than this, the<br />

Transparency International Report quotes<br />

India’s rank in corruption index as 74 7 that<br />

is quite dismal in comparison to many other<br />

growing developing countries like Taiwan.<br />

India has been very poor in implementation<br />

of contract also which is reflected in its position<br />

beyond 150 in the “Implementation of<br />

Contract Index”. 8 This shows that as a country<br />

we have been not been capable of implementing<br />

designed contracts. <strong>The</strong> next question<br />

is as a country, whether we have the<br />

economic freedom to implement contracts<br />

even in today’s context of booming GDP<br />

growth. As Prof. Amartya Sen brought out<br />

the concept of “Freedom for Development”,<br />

if on those lines one considers India’s development<br />

then the facts are not too striking.<br />

This is because India’s ranking in the “Economic<br />

Freedom Index” stands out at 104 9<br />

which is not an optimistic picture considering<br />

the growth and development of many<br />

other developing countries. Other than this,<br />

a World Bank report also shows that it takes<br />

much more time in opening and closing<br />

business in India in comparison to other<br />

countries of South Asia like Pakistan. This<br />

reduces the ranking of the country in the<br />

economic freedom index. According to a<br />

report 10 India ranked 69 in 2005 amongst<br />

141 countries by the rankings of “Economic<br />

Freedom of the World Report <strong>2007</strong>”. This<br />

index gives a relative picture of the countries<br />

in terms of how policies and institutions of<br />

countries stand out in economic freedom.<br />

Economic freedom according to this index<br />

includes indicators like “personal choice,<br />

voluntary exchange, freedom to compete<br />

and security of privately owned property”.<br />

Although India’s position has improved<br />

Statistics show that although GDP has grown at a rate of<br />

7-8% and is hinting to touch a double-digit fi gure of 10%<br />

in recent times, the employment elasticity of the Economy<br />

has not grown proportionately w.r.t. GDP growth<br />

from 89 (in 1990) to 69 (in 2005) in the ranking,<br />

it still leaves scope for lot of improvement.<br />

Domestic institutional structures will<br />

have a critical role to play in such upliftment<br />

of India’s ranking. <strong>The</strong> reason for highlighting<br />

these facts is that all the above-mentioned<br />

factors play a role towards the development<br />

of the country. A consideration of<br />

these factors is also important while moving<br />

in the service driven growth path of Indian<br />

economy. A large outcome of the index<br />

rankings of India is a result of the governance<br />

failures within the country. As the<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

33


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

country grows it would be more important<br />

to build up institutions within India which<br />

are functional and proactive. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

has a very critical role to play in building<br />

up action oriented efficient institution<br />

structures and in implementing them. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

institutions have to facilitate the functioning<br />

of the market in an efficient way in certain<br />

segments of the economy to promote the<br />

growth of the Indian economy. This has to<br />

be facilitated by sound governance framework<br />

in Indian economy to address the developmental<br />

dimensions of India along its<br />

growth path. <strong>The</strong> next section briefly highlights<br />

the governance aspect.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Governance Aspect<br />

With regard to governance structure the<br />

important issue to ponder about is the role<br />

of the government market driven economy.<br />

In context of India, the role of government<br />

has to be efficient provisioning of public<br />

ment. This needs efficient functioning of<br />

the departments and the bodies associated<br />

with the basic infrastructure services. However<br />

the expenses for such provision of infrastructure<br />

and health care services should<br />

also be met through collection of taxes. <strong>The</strong><br />

tax collection policy has to be well targeted<br />

and progressive. This would mean that people<br />

with higher income would pay higher<br />

Market oriented growth is not a solution to the mitigation<br />

of this problem of conflicts. <strong>The</strong> role of a debating, progressive<br />

society holds the key towards this conflict resolution<br />

and for which government has to take a proactive role<br />

goods, services like safe, wider road networks,<br />

hospital services, water and sanitation<br />

services. In certain cases of such provisioning<br />

public private partnerships could be<br />

tried out in the form of concession, management<br />

contracts. <strong>The</strong> efficient functioning of<br />

these partnerships would again depend to a<br />

large extent on the nature and extent of implementation<br />

of such contracts, reduction of<br />

corruption in the process of awarding contracts.<br />

Efficient delivery of basic infrastructure<br />

services like safer roads, water and<br />

quality health care could tackle many of the<br />

developmental dimensions of the economy,<br />

which is lying at a dismal state at the mo-<br />

taxes for the provisioning of the infrastructure<br />

services for development. <strong>The</strong> key towards<br />

the success of this is the implementation<br />

mechanism which has to be monitored<br />

and reviewed from time to time. An accountability<br />

framework has to be brought in<br />

the governance structure for trickling down<br />

of growth of Indian economy towards development.<br />

This trickling down in simpler<br />

terms would mean provision of basic services<br />

like road, health care, water, information<br />

network to the rural areas of India.<br />

Along with that this would also mean provision<br />

of finance to the rural people for generation<br />

of economic activities and income<br />

for them.<br />

<strong>The</strong> growth of self-help groups and microfinance<br />

with favorable interest rate structure<br />

along with a reduction of intermediaries<br />

and informal lending could be one possible<br />

step in this direction. Larger penetration of<br />

banks, ATMs by allowing large number of<br />

players in banking segment could also be<br />

another step in this direction. However, this<br />

would need the support system of a governance<br />

framework, which would facilitate the<br />

efficient players to operate in the system.<br />

Market led growth thereby doesn’t necessarily<br />

mean a lesser government intervention as<br />

market led growth could often create a larger<br />

need for regulating the costs of growth so<br />

that growth could percolate and transit towards<br />

development of the society. Thus the<br />

importance of the government increases in<br />

that case with a change in its governance<br />

framework and operational structure. If this<br />

doesn’t happen then it could be termed as a<br />

failure of the governance framework, which<br />

could create disparities in the society<br />

through larger conflicts across sections of<br />

the society. <strong>The</strong> type and extent of these<br />

conflicts would vary from place to place and<br />

from region to region. <strong>The</strong>se could range<br />

from conflicts having their origin in caste<br />

discrimination (like the ones prevalent in<br />

Bihar) to conflicts, hatred originating from<br />

one section of the society, which has been<br />

deprived of the fruits of growth and development<br />

(like the ones in the North-Western<br />

parts of Andhra Pradesh, North-Eastern<br />

states of India). <strong>The</strong>re could be many other<br />

forms, but the two has been cited to bring<br />

out the role of the failure of governance<br />

framework in the development of a country<br />

even with the presence of a market driven<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> caste driven conflict (ones in<br />

Bihar) could be because of corruption and<br />

the political system as well as an ineffective<br />

education system. <strong>The</strong> resource scarcity and<br />

developmental needs driven conflict (ones<br />

in Andhra Pradesh, North-Eastern states of<br />

India) could be because of a lack of governance<br />

framework to enable efficient distribution<br />

of resources between regions across<br />

India. Conflict resolution is an integral part<br />

of development of a country. It arises because<br />

of domestic failures and exists because<br />

of ineffective implementation of stated policies,<br />

contracts. Market oriented growth is<br />

not a solution to the mitigation of this problem<br />

of conflicts. <strong>The</strong> role of a debating, pro-<br />

34 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

gressive society holds the key towards this<br />

conflict resolution and for which government<br />

has to take a proactive role through an<br />

efficient functioning of the governance<br />

framework. However in this regard one<br />

should mention the role of an important arm<br />

of the governance framework of India viz.<br />

the Administrative Services. It is absolutely<br />

essential in India to create an accountability<br />

system for the civil servants of the country.<br />

Such accountability could be created by efficient<br />

reviewing and monitoring of the performance<br />

of the civil servants. <strong>The</strong> civil society<br />

has to take a proactive role in<br />

questioning the role of the civil servants of<br />

the country on a regular basis by monitoring<br />

of the performance of the civil servants,<br />

which has to be target oriented. One could<br />

also think of incorporation of efficient managers<br />

in different arms of governance of the<br />

country. <strong>The</strong> governance framework could<br />

be led by these managers and the research<br />

inputs for further direction for managers<br />

could come from civil society. <strong>The</strong>se are<br />

some of the roads, which have to be traversed<br />

in modification of the existing governance<br />

regime in India to translate the<br />

growth story of India into a larger developmental<br />

story also.<br />

Conclusion<br />

Thus it is clear from the above stated analysis<br />

that if India has to be reimagined it has<br />

to be done in a holistic way. Such a reimagination<br />

would include an efficient functioning<br />

of market along with an effective functioning<br />

of the government through reduction<br />

of corruption and rent seeking activities. It<br />

would also mean an effective governance<br />

framework which would mean government<br />

with a target oriented role towards reduction<br />

of corruption, hunger, death rates, school<br />

drop outs etc. It would also mean a proactive<br />

government, which contributes towards<br />

creation of a well debated progressive society<br />

through a reduction in conflicts across<br />

states of India. Thus given the paradigm of<br />

development in which India is moving, the<br />

time is apt to imagine future India with an<br />

efficient role of market in certain segments<br />

of the economy along with proactive, efficient,<br />

accountable government functioning<br />

to create a trickle down effect of the growth<br />

towards its development.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

www.oecd.org/dataoecd/17/52/39452196.pdf<br />

2<br />

www.foreigntradepolicy.com/main_<br />

policy.htm<br />

3<br />

Emerging Structure of Indian Economy:<br />

Implications of Growing Inter -<br />

Sectoral Imbalances, T. S. Papola<br />

Director, Institute for Studies in Industrial<br />

Development, New Delhi, Presidential<br />

Address, 88 th Conference of <strong>The</strong> Indian<br />

Economic Association, Andhra<br />

University, Vishakhapatnam, <strong>Dec</strong>ember<br />

27-29, 2005; isidev.nic.in/pdf/presAdd_<br />

IEA05.pdf<br />

4<br />

http://hdr.undp.org/en/statistics/<br />

5<br />

Jha P & Negre M Indian Economy in the<br />

Era of Contemporary Globalisation:<br />

Some Core Elements of the Balance<br />

Sheet, www.macroscan.com/anl/may07/<br />

pdf/Indian_Economy.pdf<br />

6<br />

<strong>The</strong> Challenge of Hunger <strong>2007</strong> Global<br />

Hunger Index: Facts, determinants, and<br />

trends; Measures being taken to reduce<br />

acute undernourishment and chronic<br />

hunger, Bonn, October <strong>2007</strong>, published<br />

by Welt Hunger Hilfe, International Food<br />

Policy Research Institute, Concern<br />

7<br />

www.transparency.org/publications/gcr<br />

8<br />

www.adb.org/Documents/Fact_Sheets/<br />

IND.asp<br />

9<br />

www.heritage.org/research/ features/index/country.cfm?id=India<br />

- 15k -<br />

10<br />

“India ranks 69th in global economies<br />

freedom index”, 4 sep, <strong>2007</strong>, Economic<br />

Times. economictimes.indiatimes.com/<br />

articleshow/2337548.cms<br />

References<br />

• <strong>The</strong> Economic Times. economictimes.<br />

indiatimes.com/articleshow/2337548.cms;<br />

“India ranks 69 th in global economies<br />

freedom index”, 4 Sep, <strong>2007</strong>, accessed on<br />

1 st October <strong>2007</strong><br />

• Goswami, A. Chakraborty, P, Inequality<br />

in Indian Economy, Studies in Indian<br />

Economy, Vol. II/ edited by K. R. Gupta;<br />

New Delhi, Atlantic Pub., <strong>2007</strong><br />

• Jha P & Negre M Indian Economy in the<br />

Era of Contemporary Globalisation:<br />

Some Core Elements of the Balance<br />

Sheet , www.macroscan.com/anl/may07/<br />

pdf/Indian_Economy.pdf, accessed on 1 st<br />

Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• http://hdr.undp.org/en/statistics/ accessed<br />

on 30th October <strong>2007</strong><br />

• Welt Hunger Hilfe, International Food<br />

Policy Research Institute, Concern , <strong>The</strong><br />

Challenge of Hunger <strong>2007</strong> Global Hunger<br />

Index: Facts, determinants, and<br />

trends; Measures being taken to reduce<br />

acute undernourishment and chronic<br />

hunger, Bonn, October <strong>2007</strong>,<br />

• www.oecd.org/dataoecd/17/52/39452196.<br />

pdf accessed on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• www.foreigntradepolicy.com/main_policy.htm<br />

accessed on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• www.transparency.org/publications/gcr<br />

accessed on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• www.adb.org/Documents/Fact_Sheets/<br />

IND.asp accessed on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• www.heritage.org/research/ features/index/country.cfm?id=India<br />

- 15k – accessed<br />

on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

35


Amal Sanyal,<br />

Associate Professor,<br />

Lincoln University,<br />

Canterbury, New Zealand<br />

Governance, Market, Deprivation<br />

And <strong>The</strong> Political System<br />

"<strong>The</strong> care of human life and<br />

happiness, and not their destruction,<br />

is the first and only<br />

object of good government."<br />

-Thomas Jefferson<br />

A<br />

lot has changed in our economic<br />

institutions in the last<br />

two decades. <strong>The</strong>se changes<br />

have not made much impression on water,<br />

housing, healthcare and power for<br />

low income people, or on poverty. I<br />

strongly believe that these issues are<br />

similarly handled in pre- and post-reform<br />

and that this is a matter of the political<br />

system, which has not changed across the<br />

periods. To these issues it is extraneous<br />

if we have a globally integrated fullfledged<br />

market economy or an importsubstituting<br />

economy run by administered<br />

production and pricing. To address<br />

them properly we need governments to<br />

act pro-actively against deprivation. A<br />

necessary condition is to have governments<br />

formed with competent and<br />

public-minded persons. <strong>The</strong> present political<br />

system is not capable of producing<br />

such governments. We need a thorough<br />

political reform, not economic, to get<br />

such governments.<br />

I am not competent to discuss the political<br />

system or its reform possibilities.<br />

Given that this issue of the journal focuses<br />

on market reform, I explore if certain<br />

market reforms can play a catalytic<br />

role in reducing deprivation by either<br />

inducing change in the political system<br />

or in spite it. We can get such effects to<br />

a degree by ridding the government of a<br />

variety of governance tasks, i.e. by letting<br />

markets produce these services. My suggestions<br />

do not arise from an economist’s<br />

habit of preaching ‘market’ for the sake<br />

of the economy. Rather, it is a sort of<br />

preaching ‘market’ for the sake of the<br />

political system. I will focus entirely on<br />

market reforms in the provision of governance.<br />

Though I will mainly examine<br />

possible effects on the political system<br />

and deprivation, I will also elaborate on<br />

more general economic effects.<br />

<strong>The</strong> abstract notion of governance in<br />

practical terms involves production of<br />

services for individuals or communities.<br />

Depending on jurisdiction, central, state<br />

and local governments provide them.<br />

Principles are laid down by the legislature<br />

and production and delivery are<br />

36 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

managed by the executive. At the point<br />

of delivery it is handled by government<br />

offices and workers. Leaving aside defence,<br />

judicial service and policing, we<br />

are left with a bewildering variety of<br />

services that touch our everyday life.<br />

Need for them has appeared gradually<br />

with the evolution of governance and it<br />

was expedient for the government of the<br />

day to start producing them. But taking<br />

stock today, there is no strategic, technical<br />

or logistical reason why they can not<br />

be produced outside the government. On<br />

the other hand there is an important<br />

connection between these services and<br />

the political system. As I reason below<br />

their marketisation can improve our political<br />

system significantly. Further, for<br />

one class of services marketisation can<br />

directly alleviate deprivation, i.e. in spite<br />

of the political system.<br />

We expect three types of gain from<br />

these changes. More important are social<br />

and political. <strong>The</strong>re are of course<br />

economic benefits, though they come<br />

with adverse side effects which need to<br />

be addressed. In the social area, delegation<br />

can produce a significant dent on<br />

corruption. As long as government is the<br />

sole producer and provider, the delivery<br />

person can seek private money for service<br />

or speed. Replacing government by<br />

markets in governance can disable a<br />

large field of rent-seeking. Leaving that<br />

paid to police, bribes the public pays are<br />

to local, state and central government<br />

workers for governance services of this<br />

kind. <strong>The</strong>y can be mostly eliminated by<br />

moving them to the market and keeping<br />

the markets competitive. Improvement<br />

in the political system can come as a direct<br />

result of mitigation of corruption.<br />

Note that service at a government office<br />

can be as easily sped up by bribe as<br />

by show of political power. Those with<br />

right political affiliation easily jump<br />

service queues. Also, politicians reward<br />

people by getting their work done or<br />

sped up in return for vote or allegiance.<br />

This kind of favour is extremely valuable<br />

because certain services are indispensable<br />

for business, property, jobs, pension,<br />

healthcare, litigation, reputation or even<br />

freedom. Government workers who<br />

oblige politicians in this game expect reciprocation.<br />

Generally the return is<br />

through rewards related to their career—promotions,<br />

suitable placements<br />

and protection. This creates a second<br />

round effect on work culture as promotion<br />

gets detached from merit. It reinforces<br />

poor governance and allegiance<br />

to the political system.<br />

Through repeated feedback the nexus<br />

intensifies the corruption of politics. <strong>The</strong><br />

nexus itself becomes a stable feature<br />

rather than occasional. Given this stable<br />

relation, politics and political affiliation<br />

have emerged as the surest way of ‘getting<br />

things done’. Politics is now widely<br />

perceived as a tool for benefiting oneself<br />

rather than the community, country or<br />

nation. This image of politics leads to<br />

adverse selection in politics. Relatively<br />

competent people--- sure about their<br />

ability--- tend to stay away to avoid the<br />

stigma. At the same time those who have<br />

the taste and the ability to manipulate,<br />

subvert and criminalise tend to join politics.<br />

Obviously, we do not choose from<br />

among the best of Indians when we vote<br />

in elections. This leads to governments<br />

formed of the less competent and the<br />

corrupt. Reform that snaps the tie between<br />

politics and provision can have<br />

noticeable effect on the nature of our<br />

politics. We can also expect some direct<br />

effects on deprivation in spite of the<br />

apathy of the political system. Services<br />

like forestation, land recovery, bunding,<br />

dredging and de-silting of rivers, arid<br />

area programs etc. have direct impact on<br />

income and quality of life below and<br />

around the poverty line. <strong>The</strong>se services<br />

are under-produced in the present system<br />

and their production can be significantly<br />

increased by marketisation.<br />

On the economic side, we expect improvement<br />

in efficiency. Inefficiency of<br />

the present system shows as poor quality,<br />

Improvement of effi ciency would reduce cost and<br />

generate either taxpayers’ saving or release budgetary<br />

resource for worthwhile projects. <strong>The</strong>se overall gains<br />

will be attended with dislocation for some<br />

failure to deliver in time or to deliver at<br />

all. Cost far exceeds what is technically<br />

required. Part of the resources are<br />

drained through bureaucratic and political<br />

delay, inappropriate technology<br />

and overstaffing. Improvement of efficiency<br />

would reduce cost and generate<br />

either taxpayers’ saving or release budgetary<br />

resource for worthwhile projects.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se overall gains will be attended with<br />

dislocation for some. <strong>The</strong> most pronounced<br />

short run effect is that the government<br />

has to persuade some employees<br />

to retire. Some retirees would find<br />

employment in new outfits and others’<br />

retirement has to be financed from cost<br />

saving. If we go for this variant of reform,<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

37


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

then the resource saving should be properly<br />

accounted and used strictly for alleviating<br />

adverse side effects.<br />

Model For delegation<br />

For ease of discussion I will arrange governance<br />

services into three groups. First<br />

are the services for individuals that are<br />

provided on demand. As far as the consumer<br />

is concerned, these are like any<br />

other private good that she or he uses<br />

exclusively. Getting a passport, a driving<br />

licence, a variety of registration, certification<br />

and so on are of this category. <strong>The</strong><br />

second group consists of services that are<br />

public goods by nature. Once produced<br />

and in place, any one can dip into their<br />

benefit and it is not possible to deny anyone<br />

access. Hence governance involves<br />

producing these services for whoever is<br />

interested and not for any one in particular.<br />

Examples are roads, bridges, street<br />

lighting and road maintenance and so<br />

on. People are quite aware of the usefulness<br />

of these services, but are prone to<br />

understate how much they would be willing<br />

to pay. <strong>The</strong> reason is so called ‘free<br />

riding’ – why pay if they can’t stop me<br />

from using it? <strong>The</strong> third group is a special<br />

class of public goods type services<br />

whose benefit most may not be aware of.<br />

Or, even if they are aware, most people<br />

put a low priority on them because the<br />

benefit appears distant and dispersed. I<br />

will call them pro-active governance<br />

services because the public may not generally<br />

press for them as they do for other<br />

public goods like roads or bridges. Some<br />

of these services may be directed at individuals<br />

but most are not directed to anyone<br />

in particular. When serving individuals,<br />

they produce large scale<br />

externality benefits. An example is a program<br />

of immunisation against a contagious<br />

disease. It saves an immunised<br />

person from the disease even as it reduces<br />

the chance of others getting it.<br />

More generally these services are not<br />

directed and are produced for the benefit<br />

of everyone at present and in the future.<br />

Examples are services like foresta-<br />

Services that are public goods by nature are thought to be an<br />

area where markets would fail to produce the right amount at<br />

the right cost even if markets are competitive to the hilt<br />

tion, dredging and cleaning of rivers,<br />

reforestation of hill sides, creating buffers<br />

at arid zones and so on.<br />

<strong>The</strong> three groups of services lend<br />

themselves to marketisation in different<br />

degrees and are amenable to different<br />

business models. <strong>The</strong>ir impact on corruption<br />

and the political system vary.<br />

Some have more impact on the political<br />

system while others have more<br />

positive and attending adverse side effects<br />

upon the economy.<br />

Individually Demanded Services<br />

Provision of an individually demanded<br />

service can be most easily transferred to<br />

markets. Unlike for public goods, its demand<br />

is easy to recognise. Because demand<br />

arises from the need of an individual<br />

who benefits from it alone, it can<br />

be priced. Also generally these services<br />

are not free under our present system.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y are either sold at a price or a fee is<br />

charged. <strong>The</strong>refore they can be sold like<br />

any item of consumption by private sellers.<br />

However, unlike a consumption item,<br />

some services are conditional on not only<br />

the price but also characteristics of the<br />

applicant or buyer. Suppose a registration<br />

service can not be sold to persons<br />

below 18 years. <strong>The</strong> selling organisation<br />

has to carry out the necessary verification.<br />

In fact part of the price accounts<br />

for the cost of verification of the applicant.<br />

Like clerks in government offices<br />

who currently provide these services,<br />

sellers are to be provided with relevant<br />

rules. <strong>The</strong>se rules should be made public,<br />

displayed prominently at service<br />

shops and should be mandated to be<br />

available on demand.<br />

What are the potential objections to<br />

this possibility? First, will the price remain<br />

reasonable? Yes, if firms are allowed<br />

to enter this business freely, their<br />

competition should keep price close to<br />

the cost of production and provision. In<br />

the present system government offices<br />

producing these services are over-staffed.<br />

It is easy to see that the cost of providing<br />

them would be significantly lower for private<br />

firms. <strong>The</strong> government often subsidises<br />

the price, which means that part of<br />

the true cost and whole of the cost of inefficiency<br />

of government offices is passed<br />

to the government budget for the tax<br />

payer to bear. Tax payers would be spared<br />

this in the suggested scenario. What if<br />

38 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

the market price turns out to be higher<br />

than what poorer applicants can bear? If<br />

the government means to help, sellers<br />

can be required to sell at lower price to<br />

some applicants and get the difference<br />

reimbursed by the government. Sellers<br />

will be required to verify an applicant’s<br />

claim to the subsidy as per guideline.<br />

What is the incentive of a seller to do the<br />

extra work rather than pass on to the next<br />

applicant? If a seller is not keen to service<br />

these applicants it will simply lose<br />

some business. Poorer buyers will move<br />

to other sellers.<br />

What do we gain by upsetting the<br />

present system? First, as I suggested<br />

above, is to reduce the space for rentseeking.<br />

It not only reduces the burden<br />

of bribes in an ordinary household’s<br />

budget, but cleans the environment of<br />

governance. As rent-seeking abates, the<br />

grip of politics on service provision too<br />

falls to that extent. <strong>The</strong> effect on political<br />

life can be easily appreciated. Second,<br />

resource spent on providing this<br />

item will come down close to what is necessary<br />

with present technology of provision<br />

and verification. This gain actually<br />

means saving of resources, which should<br />

be earmarked for supporting loss of government<br />

job and hardship. Private firms<br />

are also expected to innovate processes<br />

in order to increase profit margin. This<br />

would bring in improvement in speed<br />

and quality for service users.<br />

Universal Services Or Public<br />

Goods<br />

Services that are public goods by nature<br />

are thought to be an area where markets<br />

would fail to produce the right amount<br />

at the right cost even if markets are competitive<br />

to the hilt. Because people can<br />

not be excluded from such a service once<br />

it is produced, it is difficult to get them<br />

pay the right price -- that is price commensurate<br />

with the benefit. Knowing<br />

that the service is going to be available<br />

any way, no one would be too keen to pay<br />

the deserving price, however much someone<br />

needs it. If such a service were to be<br />

produced by private sellers, they would<br />

find much less than the true demand in<br />

the market. Production will be less than<br />

requirement. Because there is no way of<br />

getting the right price paid, these services<br />

are usually funded from taxes.<br />

However many services that are traditionally<br />

known as public goods have<br />

ceased to be really so. We now have technology<br />

to prevent using many of these<br />

services even when they are available to<br />

others. Toll gates at the ends of a bridge<br />

are now common. We also have toll gates<br />

at the end of newly-built highways. In<br />

many countries gates are operated electronically<br />

to prevent users from skipping<br />

the toll and employees from stealing toll<br />

money. We have the technology to separate<br />

payers and non-payers in much more<br />

complicated situation than the bridge or<br />

the highway example. In London any vehicle<br />

entering the central business district<br />

with many entry and exit points is<br />

automatically billed for entry in working<br />

hours. This is done without obstructing<br />

traffic flow. As soon as we have a lowcost<br />

way to exclude non-payers, the service<br />

becomes like a private good and we<br />

could be better off by delegating them to<br />

market operation. Several state governments<br />

have invited private firms to build<br />

roads and bridges and collect tolls for a<br />

stipulated number of years. A common<br />

uneasiness about marketisation of these<br />

services comes from the belief that tolls<br />

or similar fees are an encroachment on<br />

our private budgets. “Why should we pay<br />

for using roads and bridges at all?”—it is<br />

asked. <strong>The</strong> fact of the matter is that we<br />

pay and have always paid for similar services<br />

through taxes. Paying a road charge<br />

at the toll gate is definitely fairer than<br />

that because those who do not use a road<br />

do not have to pay.<br />

Much of this is happening in India as I<br />

remarked earlier. <strong>The</strong> point here is that<br />

this model can be extended over a larger<br />

variety of government services. Maintenance<br />

of public places, government offices<br />

and buildings, railway stations and<br />

property, tourist routes and spots, places<br />

Majority of the services that are traditionally known as<br />

public goods have ceased to be really so. We now have<br />

technology to prevent using many of these services<br />

even when they are available to others<br />

of historical interest and so on can be<br />

brought under this mode of operation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> basic toll-gate model of business of<br />

course requires adaptation depending on<br />

the service. Several imaginative improvisations<br />

are already in use in various<br />

countries. For example, in some instances<br />

the government may not want to<br />

charge individuals though it is possible.<br />

<strong>The</strong> government may decide to waive<br />

tolls along the road to a pilgrimage or<br />

not to charge visitors of historical and<br />

educational sites. In this case the government<br />

itself pays the bill to the business<br />

that produces the service. Users do ‘buy’<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

39


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

entry tickets or toll stamps to keep account<br />

of the number of uses. But they buy<br />

it for free, and the bill is paid by the government.<br />

A useful improvement is to allow<br />

a market for these businesses, which<br />

lets an investor sell off, say a toll service,<br />

to a buyer with obligations and rights of<br />

the original contract. This facilitates entry<br />

and exit, allow firms to specialise in<br />

specific services by acquiring similar<br />

business in different places. Can we gain<br />

anything for the political system from<br />

marketisation of these services? Since<br />

these services are not individually demanded,<br />

there is no scope for bribes<br />

from individual buyers and hence no effect<br />

on the political system along the<br />

route discussed earlier. <strong>The</strong>se services<br />

however are a source of significant political<br />

corruption. Public goods are often<br />

gifted to a community before elections.<br />

Secondly when a sanctioned service gets<br />

delayed or stopped on the way it can be<br />

started or re-started only with lobbying.<br />

For urgent service local business or communities<br />

often collectively pay into party<br />

funds as part of lobbying. To stop these<br />

occurrences, of course marketisation<br />

alone is not enough. Whether a project<br />

or a service is taken up will continue to<br />

depend on the political system and hence<br />

on lobbying. But stoppage of work and<br />

allied corruption can be avoided to a<br />

large extent. Economic advantage of<br />

marketisation of these services merits<br />

separate mention. First, to match our<br />

current economic growth investment<br />

needed for infrastructure is beyond the<br />

government’s means. If the government<br />

insists on doing by itself the task will be<br />

either delayed or have to be done by borrowing.<br />

<strong>The</strong> cost of borrowing is raised<br />

from tax payers while in the suggested<br />

alternative it is substituted by toll paying<br />

users. Toll rates can be reduced as much<br />

as possible through competitive bids<br />

Pro-active services are particularly recommended for<br />

delegation to markets. While their impact on the political<br />

system could be marginal, they could help alleviate<br />

deprivation in spite of the political system<br />

from interested firms. Secondly, it is<br />

easier to assure quality of construction<br />

and subsequent maintenance under the<br />

market system. <strong>The</strong>y are to form part of<br />

the deal with the government who should<br />

enforce them strictly with penalty provisions.<br />

Because of the contractual nature<br />

of the obligation, there is no haziness<br />

about accountability when construction<br />

or maintenance is poor. This contrasts<br />

starkly with government provision, where<br />

it is nearly impossible to fi x responsibility<br />

for failure because of multiple agencies,<br />

hierarchical decisions and change<br />

of governments.<br />

Pro-active Services<br />

<strong>The</strong>se tasks are important and urgent<br />

but government organisations do a poor<br />

job. <strong>The</strong> primary reason is that assigned<br />

organisations do not have to face customers<br />

because there are no identifiable<br />

customers. Neither they nor the government<br />

or political parties are subject to<br />

any pressure for quantum, quality or<br />

speed. <strong>The</strong>se services are particularly<br />

recommended for delegation to markets.<br />

While their impact on the political<br />

system could be marginal, they could<br />

help alleviate deprivation in spite of the<br />

political system. At present markets for<br />

these services exist only in an odd, theoretical<br />

way. <strong>The</strong>re are no private buyers<br />

willing to pay. <strong>The</strong> government assumes<br />

a dual personality as both buyer and<br />

producer. It does not help because the<br />

government is only a buying agent, not<br />

a true buyer. It is expected to buy on behalf<br />

of a billion people who do not press<br />

for the services and billions more who<br />

are not even born. <strong>The</strong>re is no economic<br />

or political mechanism to keep the<br />

government interested. <strong>The</strong> result is too<br />

little production and poor quality.<br />

Whatever little is produced is produced<br />

indifferently. Inefficiency of government<br />

services is compounded here because of<br />

buyer apathy.<br />

Inviting private firms creates a group<br />

seriously interested in them--- as hotly<br />

interested as commercial firms are in<br />

their line of business. Firms specialising<br />

in these services take on the job of demand<br />

creation as part of their business<br />

agenda. <strong>The</strong>y produce media campaigns<br />

to generate public awareness of the urgency<br />

of the services and organise special<br />

interest groups that press on the<br />

political system. Some of these services<br />

40 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

like immunisation, social forestry, reforestation<br />

of hill sides or de-silting of waterways<br />

etc. have a direct impact on the<br />

livelihood and quality of life of the poor.<br />

By generating pressure from the demand<br />

side on the political system, marketisation<br />

can help to produce more of<br />

them and make a difference. We also<br />

gain from the supply side. Since producers<br />

are to make a profit at the end of the<br />

day, every rupee of taxpayer drawn into<br />

the work has to work efficiently. It may<br />

appear puzzling that there should be<br />

any scope for profit in these services. If<br />

the government were to do the job it is<br />

not expected to make a profit out of it.<br />

Taxpayers would then just pay for the<br />

cost. However that cost contains, as experience<br />

tells, not only the technically<br />

required cost but that of inappropriate<br />

technical and political choices, of bureaucratic<br />

delays, of coalition politics<br />

and above all of general inefficiency. For<br />

the same amount of money budgeted for<br />

a project, the suggested system promises<br />

to meet the stipulated quality and<br />

complete it in time with a profit to spare<br />

for the producers. In a sense the profit<br />

is hidden in the present system. It is enjoyed<br />

by bureaucrats and government<br />

workers not in cash but in kind. It takes<br />

the form of the luxury of slack work environment<br />

and unaccountability. It is<br />

this hidden profit that motivates private<br />

firms as much as it motivates some government<br />

workers to prefer jobs in these<br />

areas. <strong>The</strong> latter take it in kind while<br />

private business would convert it to cash<br />

profit. But the winner would be the public<br />

who would get more services, done in<br />

time at lower cost. To get this going we<br />

need to initiate a market-like environment<br />

by announcing that these services<br />

will be bought on the market. This will<br />

spawn an industry producing these services<br />

that will not only efficiently produce<br />

better quality service but also generate<br />

a demand side awareness to sustain the<br />

industry. United States, North Europe<br />

and Pacific countries like Japan, Australia<br />

and New Zealand have made big<br />

strides in the technology of environment<br />

protection and nurturing in the last decade.<br />

<strong>The</strong> business model generates ample<br />

incentive for cost-cutting, improvement<br />

of technology and research. A<br />

switch to this model could help us to<br />

make significant difference to the lives<br />

of lower income people and also reduce<br />

resource costs in the long run.


Nilanjan Banik,<br />

Associate Professor, Institute for<br />

Financial Management and<br />

Research (IFMR),Chennai<br />

<strong>The</strong> Economics Of Social Unrest –<br />

Its Causes And Cure<br />

"Injustice anywhere is a threat<br />

to justice everywhere."<br />

-Martin Luther King Jr.<br />

"Naxalite faction vows to avenge Nandigram<br />

killings"<br />

26 May <strong>2007</strong>, Times of India.<br />

Newspaper headlines, such as these,<br />

are not hard to find these days.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Naxalite movement takes its<br />

name from a peasant uprising which took<br />

place in May 1967 at Naxalbari – a place on<br />

the north-eastern tip of India situated in the<br />

state of West Bengal. Many believe that<br />

these fearsome Naxals are now in Nandigram.<br />

Although to a layman what is happening<br />

in Nandigram carries more political<br />

connotation there are some economics behind<br />

it. <strong>The</strong> purpose of this article is to examine<br />

the economics of social unrest.<br />

Nandigram is a case in point but the following<br />

arguments in general will have a broader<br />

implication for India as a whole. As is<br />

known, recently the Naxals have also expanded<br />

their area of operations (from their<br />

old pockets in West Bengal, Bihar and Andhra<br />

Pradesh in the 1970s) to new guerilla<br />

zones in other states like Orissa, Maharashtra,<br />

Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand, Madhya<br />

Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh. So what goes<br />

into making a militant? Actually, it is the<br />

socially deprived group of people who takes<br />

arm against the administration. Does the<br />

people are more socially deprived now than<br />

what they were before? We are considering<br />

the period before and after reforms. This<br />

benchmark is because of less militant activities<br />

during the period before reforms.<br />

Although there were few reforms during<br />

early 1980s, the all encompassing process<br />

of reforms started during 1991. We are defining<br />

reforms in terms of globalization and<br />

liberalization. Surprisingly, incidence of<br />

anti-government activities was less during<br />

the period before reforms. Surprising because<br />

then the average Indian in terms of<br />

economic well-being was worse off compared<br />

to what the people are now. For example,<br />

India’s GDP grew at an average rate<br />

of 3.5 percent until mid-1970s; it increased<br />

to 5.5 percent during the 1980s; and further<br />

to around six percent during the 1990s.<br />

During the last three years, Indian economy<br />

has recorded a growth rate of around nine<br />

percent per annum.<br />

42 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1: Poverty In India<br />

Population below Poverty Line (As per Expert Group Methodology) in India<br />

Sector 1973-74 1977-78 1983 1978-88 1993-94 1999-2000<br />

Population (Millions)<br />

Rural 261.3 264.3 252 231.9 244 193.2<br />

Urban 60 64.6 70.9 75.2 76.3 67<br />

Total 321.3 328.9 322.9 307.1 320.3 260.2<br />

Poverty Ratio (%)<br />

Rural 56.4 53.1 45.7 39.1 37.3 27.1<br />

Urban 49 45.2 40.8 38.2 32.4 23.6<br />

Total 54.9 51.3 44.5 38.9 36 26.1<br />

Source: Rural Development Statistics 2002-03, National Institute of Rural Development<br />

A reflection of this higher growth rate other hand, share of services sector in GDP<br />

also got reflected in terms of higher percapita<br />

income and lower poverty numbers. 1950-51 to 55 percent during 2006-<strong>2007</strong>.<br />

has increased from 29.80 percent during<br />

Measured in constant US 2005 dollars India’s<br />

per-capita GDP has increased from mained more or less constant at around 27<br />

<strong>The</strong> share of manufacturing sector has re-<br />

215 during 1975 to 293 during 1988 and further<br />

to 546 during 2005. Like wise, the pov-<br />

Now let us concentrate on the number of<br />

percent during post reforms era.<br />

erty number (measured in terms of head people who are earning their livelihood<br />

count ratio) has fallen from 42 percent during<br />

1987 to the present level of 26.1 percent. cent of the Indian population earns their<br />

from these three sectors. Around, 58.6 per-<br />

Measured by these numbers reforms have livelihood from agricultural and agricultural<br />

related allied activities compared to<br />

increased overall economic well-being.<br />

So where lie the problem? How can we less than 10 percent of the population earning<br />

their livelihood from organized services<br />

explain this anomaly of a rise in social unrest?<br />

<strong>The</strong> answer to this apparent puzzle lies sector (Table 4). What does it means? In<br />

in examining impact of reforms on income simple words, if the national income is Rs<br />

distribution. Reforms entail unequal payoff 100 then agricultural and allied activities<br />

to economic agents. People with more skill are contributing 18.5 percent of the national<br />

income, that is, Rs 18.5 compared to Rs<br />

stand to gain more compared to people with<br />

less skill sets (read, less productive people). 55 generated by the services sector. Income<br />

And this has resulted in more skewed income<br />

distribution (read, right skewed dentributing<br />

Rs 18.5 to 58.6 people (employed<br />

inequality becomes evident as it is like dissity<br />

function) leading to social unrest. <strong>The</strong> in agricultural sector) compared to distributing<br />

Rs 55 to less than 10 people (employed<br />

following two boxes will help us to analyze<br />

this scenario better.<br />

in organized service sector) or 23 people<br />

Looking at sectoral GDP share, we find (employed in both organized and unorganized<br />

service sector). What is more worrying<br />

that the share of agriculture has fallen from<br />

56.90 percent during 1950-51 to 18.5 percent<br />

during 2006-<strong>2007</strong> (Table 2). On the more as going by the latest data<br />

is that this inequality is going to increase<br />

agricultural<br />

sector is growing at an annual rate of 2.6<br />

percent compared to services growing at<br />

a rate of 11 percent. If the present trend<br />

continues, then share of agriculture in national<br />

income is to become a single digit<br />

number within the next 15 years<br />

– contributing more to inequality in<br />

income distribution.<br />

Table-2 complements Table-1 by throwing<br />

some more additional information. <strong>The</strong><br />

share of income generated by the agricultural<br />

sector is more volatile (measured by<br />

the variance of the growth rates) compared<br />

to manufacturing, services and overall GDP.<br />

Uncertainties associated with income have<br />

two specific outcomes: postponement of<br />

investment decision and migration. As is<br />

evident from Table-4 because of fluctuating<br />

agricultural income level of investment<br />

is also least in the agricultural sector. Postponement<br />

of investment decisions have<br />

bearing on future income and reduce future<br />

expected earning from the sector. This is<br />

one way to contribute to the burgeoning<br />

disparity in earnings across sectors. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

is another way and that has to do with migration.<br />

Uncertainty associated with volatile<br />

income leads to migration. As ‘expected’<br />

return in the urban sector (dominated by<br />

the services sector) is higher than ‘actual’<br />

return in the agricultural sector, migration<br />

happens. However, many migrating labors<br />

lack adequate skills for finding<br />

meaningful employment in the services<br />

sector. Consequently, these unemployed<br />

people find add to a higher skewed<br />

income distribution.<br />

Now let us examine why are the workers<br />

in the services sector, especially in the organized<br />

services sector, like, banking, telecommunication,<br />

teaching, medical, legal,<br />

etc., are making so much money relative to<br />

the agriculture workers. For that one has to<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

43


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 2: Reforms And Income Generation<br />

Components 1950-51 1960-61 1970-71 1980-81 1990-91 1995-96 2004-05 2006-07<br />

Agriculture and<br />

allied activities<br />

56.90 46.74 46.07 38.86 31.27 28.24 21.13 18.5<br />

(2.6%)!<br />

Industry 14.28 19.46 20.65 24.50 27.64 28.12 27.15 26.4<br />

(10.4%)<br />

Services 29.80 34.30 33.66 36.64 41.10 43.64 51.72 55<br />

(11%)<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (2006) and Central Statistical Organization (2006)<br />

examine the productivity data. <strong>The</strong> growth<br />

theory literature tells us that more productive<br />

countries tend to prosper more compared<br />

to the less productive ones. If market<br />

is determining the pay-off, same kind of<br />

argument holds true within a country but<br />

across its laborers. So it makes sense to look<br />

at labor productivity data in India. Figure 1<br />

gives a glimpse of sector wise labor productivity<br />

growth in India. Output per worker in<br />

the services sector grew at a rate of seven<br />

percent during 1993-99, compared to only<br />

2.7 percent during the previous decade. <strong>The</strong><br />

performance of the labor productivity in the<br />

manufacturing sector was more modest<br />

growing from 3.1 percent to 4.5 percent during<br />

the same period. Agriculture sector was<br />

the lagging sector, with output per worker<br />

rising only to 2.4 percent during 1993-99,<br />

compared to 1.5 percent during the previous<br />

decade. As wages are linked to productivity<br />

it is little surprising to figure out why<br />

people in the services sector making more<br />

money compared to the other sector.<br />

<strong>The</strong> fact that services is the fastest growing<br />

sector (that is, demand for skilled labors<br />

are always there) and requires only skilled<br />

labors (less in numbers in India); wage rate<br />

in the services sector is much higher than<br />

in the agricultural sector. <strong>The</strong> average per<br />

day return of agricultural worker varies between<br />

Rs 25 (read Indian Rupees; Rs 39.5<br />

is one US dollar) in States, like, Bihar, Mi-<br />

zoram, Manipur, Arunachal Pradesh, etc.<br />

to an average of around Rs 125 per day in<br />

States, like, Haryana, Punjab, Kerala,<br />

Tamil Nadu, Gujarat, etc. Although spatial<br />

inequalities exist for agricultural sector;<br />

income inequality becomes large considering<br />

inter-sector inequality, i.e. inequality<br />

between services and agricultural sectors.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se days the average salaries for a standard<br />

Business School graduates ranges between<br />

five lacs to seven lacs, per annum.<br />

Quite evidently these are much higher figures<br />

compared to an average agricultural<br />

earning. So what needs to be done? From<br />

the demand side perspective government is<br />

Table 3: Uncertainty In Agricultural Income<br />

spending money on schemes like, minimum<br />

rural employment guarantee<br />

scheme in 200 most<br />

backward districts in India<br />

with the objective of providing<br />

100 days of guaranteed<br />

unskilled wage employment<br />

to each rural<br />

household opting for it. <strong>The</strong>se schemes are<br />

to be spread to other districts as well. However,<br />

such demand management policies<br />

sometime can be self defeating. For instance,<br />

if these people are hired for building<br />

a road and the project never gets completed<br />

then the money allocated for the<br />

purpose will add on to inflation. A better<br />

1971-72 to<br />

1980-81<br />

way to address this problem associated with<br />

income inequality will be to address long<br />

term supply management policies. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are two major problems. First has to do<br />

with skill formation. Workers can be trained<br />

giving vocational education. <strong>The</strong> experiences<br />

of some South-East Asian economies<br />

show that one reason these economies fared<br />

well on the distributional aspect of income<br />

1981-82 to<br />

1990-91<br />

1991-92 to<br />

2004-05<br />

GDP<br />

Growth (Mean) 3.16 5.64 5.83<br />

Coff. of Variation 137.75 39.05 31.84<br />

Agriculture and Allied Service<br />

Growth (Mean) 1.83 3.55 2.58<br />

Coff. of Variation 475.21 150.74 188.74<br />

Industry<br />

Growth (Mean) 4.05 7.11 5.81<br />

Coff. of Variation 88.91 28.22 51.85<br />

Services<br />

Growth (Mean) 4.42 6.72 7.78<br />

Coff. of Variation 34.03 17.16 23.04<br />

Source: National Account Statistics<br />

44 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 1: Sector Wise Factor Productivity<br />

Average Annual Percent Change<br />

7<br />

6<br />

5<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

Labor And Total Factor Productivity Growth In India<br />

Output Per Worker<br />

Total Factor Productivity<br />

1960-73 1973-83 1983-93 1993-99 1999-2004<br />

Source: Bosworth, Collins and Virmani (2006)<br />

Table 4: Capital Formation And Employment sion. A better provision<br />

of services<br />

Investment (as a % of 1993-94 1999-2000 2004-2005<br />

total investment)<br />

especially in the<br />

Agricultural and Allied 8.42 8.48 6.63<br />

education sector<br />

will usher in an<br />

Industry 50.09 51.44 54.06<br />

even income distribution.<br />

<strong>The</strong> sec-<br />

Services 41.19 40.08 39.31<br />

Employment Ratios (as a % of total employment)<br />

ond major problem<br />

Agricultural and Allied 60.39 56.70 58.60<br />

is associated with<br />

Industry 15.83 17.57 18.50<br />

volatile agricultural<br />

Services 23.78 25.73 22.90<br />

income. As we have<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (2006) and Central Statistical Organization (2006)<br />

seen volatile agricultural<br />

is because the governments put emphasis<br />

on vocational education. Growth in these<br />

economies is primarily driven by increase<br />

labor force participation. It would make<br />

sense to impart adequate training so that<br />

labors from countryside have necessary<br />

skills to find employment in the services<br />

and manufacturing sectors. Government<br />

expenditure should be directed towards<br />

sectors, like primary education, where social<br />

return is higher than the private return.<br />

For the sector, like higher education and<br />

also vocational education, government can<br />

encourage private participation. Private<br />

participation brings in accountability and<br />

hence efficiency in the way of service provi-<br />

output contributes to rural poverty<br />

affecting the distribution of income. It also<br />

leads to increase migration which in turn is<br />

contributing to inequality. A reason for<br />

volatility in agricultural production is because<br />

of lack of adequate infrastructure.<br />

Because of lack of cold storage facilities,<br />

irrigation system, dams and roads network<br />

connecting to market considerable portion<br />

of agricultural produce depends on weather.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is a loss of agricultural output either<br />

because of flood or because of drought.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are not enough man made tanks and<br />

canals which can store water during flood<br />

and supply water during drought.<br />

To reduce this volatility there is a need<br />

to build rural infrastructure. A proper<br />

infrastructural investment in rural sector,<br />

such as irrigation and drainage, storage,<br />

soil conservation, water management systems<br />

and road networks connecting the<br />

rural markets with their urban counterpart,<br />

is necessary to reduce this fluctuation<br />

in agricultural output. Demand management<br />

policies like introduction of crop<br />

insurance, futures trading in agricultural<br />

commodities and greater accessibility to<br />

credit will complement these supply side<br />

measures. None of these exists at this<br />

point of time. It’s a little wonder why the<br />

people in the country side feel deprived<br />

and with further reforms the level of desperation<br />

is growing. Finally, referring<br />

back to our issue about Nandigram what<br />

started the flare in Nandigram was lack of<br />

well defined property rights. Initially, it<br />

was the marginal farmers or share croppers<br />

(working on other’s lands) who were<br />

up in arms against the government. <strong>The</strong><br />

land owners were happy with the price<br />

offered by the government for acquiring<br />

their land. However, there exist no property<br />

rights which spell out how the money<br />

is going to get distributed from the land<br />

owners to these share croppers or the<br />

land less laborers. <strong>The</strong> seed of unrest<br />

could have been solved by addressing<br />

this issue.<br />

End Notes<br />

1 Bosworth, B., Collins, S. and Virmani,<br />

A. (2006), ‘Sources of growth in the Indian<br />

economy’, paper presented to the<br />

Indian Policy Forum, New Delhi, July.<br />

2 Bhanumurthy N. R. and A. Mitra<br />

(2004), ‘Economic growth, poverty, and<br />

inequality in Indian States in the prereform<br />

and reform periods’, Asian Development<br />

Review, Vol. 21, pp. 79-99.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

45


Shripad Dharmadikary<br />

Manthan Adhyayan Kendra,<br />

Badwani, Madhya Pradesh<br />

More Market, Less Government<br />

A Recipe For Disaster For <strong>The</strong> Water Sector<br />

"We never know the worth of<br />

water till the well is dry."<br />

-Thomas Fuller<br />

An article published some time<br />

back argued that in Rajasthan,<br />

petrol was freely available<br />

to anyone who wanted it, while millions<br />

of people faced great difficulty in<br />

obtaining water, even though water is far<br />

more abundant in the state than petrol.<br />

This phenomenon was attributed by the<br />

author to the fact that while the management<br />

of water was entirely controlled by<br />

the government, the supply and management<br />

of petrol was by private players and<br />

operated on market principles. Since<br />

last 16 years, the call to harness the power<br />

of the market (and of private enterprise)<br />

for the better performance of<br />

various sectors of the economy has been<br />

growing stronger. In 1991, the introduction<br />

of the policies of Liberalisation,<br />

Privatisation and Globalisation (LPG)<br />

in the country initiated the process of<br />

the opening up of the financial sector on<br />

one hand, and on the other, the transformation<br />

of sectors hitherto owned and<br />

managed by the government or by other<br />

public agencies into market based operations<br />

and private ownership and<br />

management. While some of the important<br />

sectors where wide-ranging reforms<br />

were introduced included power, telcom<br />

and insurance, the process began later,<br />

and in a fragmented way for other sectors.<br />

<strong>The</strong> water sector can be put in the<br />

latter category.<br />

Water Markets In India<br />

It is not as if water markets or trade have<br />

not existed in India. In the British times,<br />

several large irrigation schemes were<br />

owned and operated privately, with the<br />

company selling water on a commercial<br />

basis. For example, the Orissa Canal<br />

Scheme, first proposed by Sir Arthur<br />

Cotton in 1858, was started in 1865, with<br />

the East India (Orissa) Irrigation and<br />

Canal Company (EIICC) financing the<br />

project and selling all the water to the<br />

Government, who in turn was to collect<br />

the water charges from farmers, and<br />

pass on the profits to the EIICC after<br />

deducting administrative expenses 1 . In<br />

many parts of the country, for example<br />

46 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

in North Gujarat, thriving groundwater<br />

markets exist, as farmers extract groundwater<br />

using tubewells and sell it primarily<br />

to other farmers for irrigation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> ‘tanker economy’ is very well established,<br />

with highly developed networks<br />

of tanker owners supplying water<br />

to industries, colonies, commercial establishments<br />

and even households on a<br />

regular or need-based basis. In cities<br />

like Ahemdabad, regular home delivery<br />

of bottled drinking water is a common<br />

feature. Last but not the least, the bottled<br />

water industry has become a thriving<br />

multi-crore rupees business. For all<br />

this, water remains largely in the public<br />

domain. <strong>The</strong> British experiments with<br />

private irrigation were not very successful<br />

and canal irrigation has been essentially<br />

a public sector endeavour in independent<br />

India. While groundwater is<br />

largely in the private domain, with the<br />

landowners having unrestricted right to<br />

pump out as much water as they want<br />

from their lands – it is largely operated<br />

on an individual and unorganised basis.<br />

Tankers and other supplies to households,<br />

colonies etc. operate more like<br />

informal markets. Even otherwise, these<br />

water markets have formed a small part<br />

of the huge water economy and even a<br />

smaller part of the vast water system.<br />

This is so for a good reason.<br />

Water As A Social Responsibility<br />

Water is a biological necessity for survival.<br />

Water is also the foundation of the<br />

livelihoods of millions of people – agriculture,<br />

fishing, dairying, cattle rearing<br />

being some of the occupations that depend<br />

critically on water. Water is a critical<br />

input into the development process,<br />

apart from the being an essential requirement<br />

for industry and manufacturing.<br />

Thus, water has a vital social significance<br />

apart from its commercial<br />

value. Indeed, water is a basic, fundamental<br />

human right. Due to all this, the<br />

production and provision of water has<br />

long been considered a social and moral<br />

responsibility of the community and the<br />

Government. This is all the more so in<br />

India - since the income and resource<br />

distribution in India is heavily skewed<br />

and iniquitous, and we have large sections<br />

of populations who cannot afford<br />

to bear the cost of even the minimum<br />

necessary supplies of water. This makes<br />

low-priced provision of water services<br />

essential. This is also the reason that<br />

the sector has been heavily subsidised,<br />

and has remained in the public domain<br />

till now.<br />

A New Regime<br />

In the last decade or so, it is being argued<br />

that the water sector must be operated<br />

on market based principles and the<br />

Government must change its role to only<br />

that of a regulator, with the private sector<br />

being allowed into the sector.<br />

Several reasons are being advanced<br />

for this. <strong>The</strong> many serious problems of<br />

the water sector and its abysmal performance<br />

in delivering services is being attributed<br />

primarily to the inefficiency and<br />

corruption of the government system –<br />

qualities that are believed to be largely<br />

inherent to public sector. <strong>The</strong> public sector<br />

is also generally considered as deficient<br />

in modern technology, lacking<br />

management skills and badly administered.<br />

Further, the lack of internal resource<br />

generation due to below-cost supply<br />

is leading to deficiency of resources<br />

with the Government to invest in the<br />

needs of the sector.<strong>The</strong> achievements of<br />

Tankers and other supplies to households, etc. operate<br />

more like informal markets. Even otherwise, these water<br />

markets have formed a small part of the huge water economy<br />

and even a smaller part of the vast water system<br />

the telcom sector, now operating on<br />

market based principles with a large<br />

number of private players is also being<br />

cited as evidence that these polices can<br />

improve access and service levels. Thus,<br />

“More Market, Less Government” is the<br />

mantra being advocated for the water<br />

sector also. As this approach gets translated<br />

into new policies, laws and programs,<br />

some important questions need<br />

to be answered – will this work? What<br />

will be the consequences of such an approach<br />

in the water sector? Is this the<br />

correct policy choice? In some ways, the<br />

cart has already been put before the<br />

horse. While these serious questions<br />

have not been fully debated, far-reaching<br />

transformations in the sector have<br />

already been set in motion.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se transformations can be seen as<br />

an extension of the LPG regime into the<br />

water sector. As with the initial set of<br />

reforms in 1991, the changes in the water<br />

sector are also being driven by the World<br />

Bank and other international financial<br />

a g e n c i e s l i k e t h e A s i a n D e ve l o p m e nt B<br />

ank. Water has been among the last of<br />

the sectors to be opened up to the reforms<br />

process; however, we just note this<br />

without going into the reasons for<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

47


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

the same.<br />

<strong>The</strong> process to aggressively bring LPG<br />

policies into the water sector was initiated<br />

around the mid-1990s with a key<br />

knowledge activity. Around this time,<br />

the World Bank began a comprehensive<br />

and wide-ranging review of India’s water<br />

sector – called the India Water Resources<br />

Management Sector Review.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Water Sector Review 1998 was a<br />

“sector-wide program undertaken in<br />

partnership between the Government of<br />

India and the World Bank, also with<br />

contributions from the Governments of<br />

U.K., Denmark and the Netherlands.” 2<br />

<strong>The</strong> purpose was “collectively assessing<br />

and establishing a Reform Agenda and<br />

Action plan for India’s Water Sector.” 3<br />

In 1996, a series of missions visited<br />

India, and then the World Bank team,<br />

with inputs from the Government of India,<br />

and many consultants, finalised five<br />

specialists reports 4 , dealing with<br />

(1) Intersectoral Water Allocation,<br />

Planning and Management<br />

(2) Groundwater Regulation and<br />

Management<br />

(3) Irrigation<br />

(4) Rural Water Supply and Sanitation<br />

(5) Urban Water Supply & Sanitation<br />

A sixth report, synthesising all the<br />

above was also prepared 5 . <strong>The</strong>se were<br />

first published as World Bank reports in<br />

the year 1998.<br />

This Review identified two broad issues<br />

that needed to be addressed –<br />

“Mechanisms ....for integrated treatment<br />

of surface and groundwater... and<br />

for efficiently and equitably allocating<br />

scare water resources between competing<br />

uses...[that is, inter-sector allocations].<br />

Second, reforms to improve service<br />

delivery in the water sub-sectors<br />

(i.e. irrigation, urban water supply, rural<br />

water supply...)”.<br />

For both these broad objectives, the<br />

measures suggested consisted essentially<br />

of transforming the sector to operate<br />

on commercial and market basis, and<br />

the privatisation of various activities.<br />

This agenda is being rolled out through<br />

a number of different measures. <strong>The</strong> key<br />

One of the far reaching recommendations made by the<br />

World Bank was the introduction of tradable water rights<br />

or water entitlements. <strong>The</strong> idea is this – that all (or at least<br />

some) people have a defined water entitlement<br />

mechanism to further this approach has<br />

been a series of Water Sector Restructuring<br />

loans given by the World Bank to<br />

a number of states, for example in Madhya<br />

Pradesh, Maharashtra, Rajasthan<br />

etc. 6 <strong>The</strong> reforms package implemented<br />

through the conditionalities in these<br />

loans is often supported by other loans,<br />

grants and technical assistance from<br />

Asian Development Bank, or agencies<br />

like British Government’s development<br />

assistance agency DFID.<br />

<strong>The</strong> reforms processes have the following<br />

common elements:<br />

• Unbundling (separation of source,<br />

‘transmission’ and ‘distribution’)<br />

• Independent regulator to set tariffs<br />

and decide other issues<br />

• Steeply increasing tariffs, de-politicisation<br />

of tariffs<br />

• Full cost recovery<br />

• Elimination of subsidies<br />

Cutting off supplies for non-payment<br />

• Dismantling public / community supplies<br />

like public taps, stand posts<br />

• Retrenchment<br />

• Privatisation and PPPs<br />

• Allocation of water to highest value<br />

use through market mechanism<br />

<strong>The</strong> net result of these policies is the<br />

conversion of the sector into a market.<br />

Not only is the service provision within<br />

a sub-sector (for example irrigation) to<br />

be carried out on a commercial basis, on<br />

market principles, but the inter-sectoral<br />

allocation also is to be done through<br />

market mechanisms. What are the implications?<br />

Let us examine the inter-sectoral<br />

allocation in more detail.<br />

Tradable Water Rights For Inter-<br />

Sectoral Allocation<br />

One of the far reaching recommendations<br />

made by the World Bank in the<br />

Water Sector Review 1998 was the introduction<br />

of tradable water rights or water<br />

entitlements. <strong>The</strong> idea is this – that all<br />

(or at least some) people have a defined<br />

water entitlement. <strong>The</strong>re is also a<br />

developed market of such entitlements,<br />

in which these can be sold or bartered.<br />

<strong>The</strong> economic logic is that this trading<br />

will ensure that water is allocated to the<br />

highest value user – thus ensuring<br />

efficiency of use. This is being justified<br />

as an easy way (where political resistance<br />

will be least) of inter-sectoral<br />

allocations.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Water Sector Resources Stra<br />

tegy of the World Bank, adopted in<br />

2003, states 7 :<br />

“....those requiring additional resources<br />

(such as cities) will be ...able to meet<br />

48 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

their needs by acquiring the rights of<br />

those who are using water for low-value<br />

purposes.<br />

“....there are strong incentives for<br />

those using water for low-value purposes<br />

to voluntarily give up their rights,<br />

making reallocation politically attractive<br />

and practical.”<br />

<strong>The</strong> Water Sector Review 1998’s Report<br />

on Intersectoral Allocation gives<br />

the example of Chennai. It says 8 :<br />

“As in all parts of the world, the value<br />

of water for irrigated foodcrops is a fraction<br />

of the value for urban and domestic<br />

purposes. Rough calculations suggest<br />

that the value of water in irrigation in<br />

Tamil Nadu is less than Rs. 0.5/cubic<br />

meter. Even if Metrowater could pay several<br />

times this amount, it could obtain<br />

additional water….<br />

“<strong>The</strong> potential for voluntary inter-sectoral<br />

transfer of water to urban users<br />

from irrigation provide a promising low<br />

cost alternative...”<br />

Thus, the Bank argues that in a water<br />

market, the farmer would find it more<br />

profitable to sell his share of water to the<br />

city (or an industry, or a golf course)<br />

than to grow crops.<br />

One of the first ‘trials’ of this approach<br />

is taking place in Maharashtra. <strong>The</strong> Maharashtra<br />

Water Resources Regulatory<br />

Authority Act (MWRRA) 2005 came<br />

into force on 8th June 2005. Maharashtra<br />

soon became the first, and so far the<br />

only, state to set up the Water Resources<br />

Regulatory Authority - more or less<br />

on the lines of the regulatory commissions<br />

set up for electricity in various<br />

states - with objectives that include fi x-<br />

ing the rates for use of water for agriculture,<br />

industrial, drinking and other purposes<br />

and several related matters.<br />

Among the functions of the Authority is<br />

the mandate to develop a framework for<br />

trading in water entitlements. <strong>The</strong> Authority<br />

is to determine the distribution<br />

of entitlements between various users,<br />

and then these entitlements can be<br />

“transferred, bartered, bought or sold<br />

on annual or seasonal basis within a<br />

market system” 9 to be created by the Authority.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Authority has already begun<br />

the exercise of setting up entitlements in<br />

six irrigation projects in Maharashtra on<br />

a pilot basis, inlcuding tow major projects.<br />

Will such an exercise lead to a rational<br />

and efficient allocation of water?<br />

While the economic argument that water<br />

will be allocated to the highest valueadding<br />

user looks attractive, there are<br />

likely to be serious implications. For example,<br />

if a farmer finds it more profitable<br />

to sell his share of water to industry<br />

or a near by city – and this happens on a<br />

large scale, what are the implications for<br />

food security? What would happen to<br />

associated rural economic activity? For<br />

example, agricultural residues provide<br />

fodder for cattle, but if a farmer does not<br />

cultivate his land, what happens to the<br />

cattle? Another important question is<br />

related to the conversion of livelihood to<br />

cash. <strong>The</strong> farmer, by cultivating his land,<br />

gets the output in the form of grain,<br />

food, milk and some cash. By selling his<br />

water right, this is likely to be largely<br />

Market driven inter-sector allocation poses more serious<br />

broader concerns. Water is not just an economic commodity<br />

– it is essentially an ecological, natural entity, and<br />

water as an ecological system is vast and complex<br />

converted to cash. This has the danger<br />

of being spent on careless consumptive<br />

expenditure, or worse, on liquor and<br />

other addictions. More cash can also<br />

mean that women will have lesser<br />

control on the household income as cash<br />

is more likely to be controlled by<br />

the men.<br />

Apart from these individual-related<br />

issues, market driven inter-sector allocation<br />

poses even more serious broader<br />

concerns. First of all, water is not just an<br />

economic commodity – it is essentially<br />

an ecological, natural entity, and water<br />

as an ecological system is vast and complex.<br />

Water – and water bodies like rivers,<br />

lakes etc. – have many cultural, social<br />

and religious associations. Thus,<br />

there are many externalities associated<br />

with water, and it is simply not possible<br />

for market mechanisms to address these.<br />

Consider (as is happening in several<br />

places like Chennai) if a farmer wants to<br />

sell his groundwater to the city instead<br />

of farming. But unrestricted withdrawals<br />

by the farmer could affect the wells<br />

of the neighbouring farmers. Or, consider<br />

whether the waters of a river that<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

49


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

has a religious ghat and temple could be<br />

sold for industrial or other purposes? In<br />

fact, this raises another serious issue –<br />

who would be entitled to sell such a<br />

right? For a market to operate there<br />

have to be tradable commodities and<br />

some understanding of ‘ownership’. But<br />

can what is essentially a community resource<br />

– like a river, lake or rainwater<br />

– can such an entity be subjected to a<br />

market regime?<br />

It is because of these very important<br />

externalities and social and human aspects<br />

that water, and in particular the<br />

sectoral allocation of water needs to be<br />

outside the market system. This is the<br />

reason why the priorities for allocation<br />

of water between sectors are prescribed<br />

by policy rather than left to the market.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Water Policy of the Government of<br />

India, approved in 2002, specifies in its<br />

Clause 5 that<br />

“In the planning and operation of systems,<br />

water allocation priorities should<br />

be broadly as follows:<br />

• Drinking water<br />

• Irrigation<br />

• Hydro-power<br />

• Ecology<br />

• Agro-industries and non-agricultural<br />

industries<br />

• Navigation and other uses.”<br />

Several states too have developed their<br />

own policies which also lay down these<br />

priorities. A market based inter-sectoral<br />

allocation of water is inherently in contradiction<br />

to the allocation based on<br />

criteria of social and environmental<br />

need and equity. This is all the more so<br />

in a country like India where there is<br />

vast inequity in the distribution of income<br />

and where conservation of ecology<br />

is not a luxury but rather a necessity as<br />

it supports the livelihoods of millions.<br />

Last, but not the least, is that by definition,<br />

a market based system allocates<br />

resources to those who have purchasing<br />

power. This not only means that the poor<br />

will be disadvantaged, but that there is<br />

a real danger of concentration of (water)<br />

recourses in the hands of the economically<br />

powerful. <strong>The</strong>re are very few places<br />

where such a market based allocation<br />

of water has been tried out. Chile is one<br />

such country where this system was put<br />

in place in the early 1980s. Indeed, the<br />

World Bank is using Chile as a model to<br />

justify the implementation of this in India.<br />

But the Bank’s own study (which it<br />

seems to have ignored) says 10 :<br />

“According to some reports, the establishment<br />

of tradable water rights in Chile<br />

has encouraged efficient agricultural use<br />

and increased agricultural productivity<br />

per unit of water… Recent reports indicate,<br />

however, that the model encountered<br />

problems as well as successes….<br />

Although benefits have accrued, significant<br />

negative impacts have been felt by<br />

farmers unfamiliar with legal processes<br />

or lacking the money to participate in<br />

markets for water (the poor). Significant<br />

conflicts have also emerged between different<br />

groups of users, and many social<br />

and environmental externalities have yet<br />

to be addressed….”<br />

And 11 :<br />

“<strong>The</strong> main disadvantage, or risk, of<br />

the new system is monopolisation of water<br />

rights. A couple of power companies<br />

and a single individual have been accused<br />

of accumulating some 70 percent<br />

of all water rights in Chile”<br />

This clearly shows how real the danger<br />

of the monopolisation of the resource<br />

are when it is left to market forces, as<br />

well as the inability of market forces to<br />

handle social, ecological and equity related<br />

externalities.<br />

Intra-Sector Marketisation<br />

<strong>The</strong> same issues come up in context of<br />

market based operations within a sector<br />

like bringing in private players for service<br />

delivery of irrigation or urban waters, or<br />

transforming these sectors into purely<br />

commercial operations. <strong>The</strong>re is massive<br />

evidence from all over the world that this<br />

has led to very serious impacts on the<br />

economically poor sections of the society.<br />

This is well documented and a subject<br />

in its own right, so we may only mention<br />

a few things here 12 .<br />

<strong>The</strong> reforms package of full cost recovery,<br />

elimination of subsidies, disconnections<br />

on non-payment (often due to unaffordability),<br />

privatisation and so on may<br />

remove ‘economic ‘distortions’ and lead<br />

to better financial sustainability – the two<br />

major arguments for the justification of<br />

reforms– but this is at the cost of social<br />

responsibility. Where this package has<br />

been implemented, tariffs have often shot<br />

up, and the poor have been disconnected<br />

as they have been unable to pay the high<br />

price for water. For example, in Guinea,<br />

on privatisation of the water supply, water<br />

rates shot up 6-7 times, and more than<br />

10,000 connections, one-third of the total,<br />

were disconnected due to non-payment.<br />

Access of the poor to water has<br />

been the first casualty in many cases of<br />

water sector privatisation and reforms.<br />

Farmers in India are already caught in<br />

a vicious economic pincer grip of rising<br />

prices of inputs and lack of commensurate<br />

prices for their products. Rising water<br />

tariffs in the irrigation sector – a sure<br />

consequence of marketisation - are like-<br />

50 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ly to skew further the economics of agriculture<br />

that is already leading to large<br />

scale suicides of farmers. Moreover, it is<br />

likely to have a casacading effect on prices<br />

of essentials like foodgrains.<br />

In Indore, an Asian Development<br />

Bank (ADB) loan for Urban Water Supply<br />

has put a condition that all public<br />

standposts must be phased out and the<br />

city Municipal Corporation has taken an<br />

in-principle decision that this should be<br />

done unless the person (who happens to<br />

have a standpost in front of the house)<br />

agrees to pay the bills. <strong>The</strong> logic is that<br />

public stand posts are a source of leakage<br />

and do not yield revenue. Removing<br />

standposts certainly fits into the process<br />

of making the system more market oriented<br />

– no supply without payment – but<br />

impacts the poor very hard.<br />

Less Market, More Accountable<br />

Government<br />

It is difficult to escape the conclusion<br />

that the marketisation of the system can<br />

only be at the cost of social responsibility.<br />

‘More Market’ in the water sector is<br />

likely to hit hard the most vulnerable sections<br />

of the society, and those living on<br />

the margins are likely to be pushed out<br />

even from there. It is also likely to have a<br />

deleterious impact on livelihoods of<br />

farmers and a cascading effect on millions<br />

of other poor as food prices too<br />

could be affected. Further, the market<br />

cannot handle the many critically important<br />

externalities – social, ecological,<br />

cultural and religious- associated with<br />

water. Commodification and marketisation<br />

of water will also create the dangers<br />

of monopolistic control on this vital resource.<br />

Thus, the advocacy of ‘More<br />

Market’ in the water sector is a sure recipe<br />

for disaster. However, this does in any<br />

way mean, automatically, that business as<br />

usual is fine or that more ‘governmentas-usual’<br />

is the answer. For there is no<br />

denying that the myriad problems of the<br />

water sector – lack of access, inequity,<br />

deteriorating quality, destruction of environment,<br />

displacement due to dams<br />

etc. – are in many ways due to the gross<br />

inefficiency, corruption and mismanagement<br />

by the public agencies handling<br />

water resources. However, water, with its<br />

vital necessity for our very daily survival<br />

as well as its central role in livelihood,<br />

economy, society and culture has to be<br />

under public control. But this public control<br />

has to be really ‘public’ –that is, by<br />

the community at large and not just by<br />

the Government or bureaucratic agencies.<br />

What we need is an accountable,<br />

responsible, transparent and participatory<br />

system of managing water –<br />

Less Markets, More Accountable<br />

Public Systems.<br />

Endnotes<br />

1<br />

D’souza 2006 Page 128-129<br />

2<br />

World Bank 1999a Page ix<br />

3<br />

ibid<br />

4<br />

World Bank 1999b to 1999f<br />

5<br />

World Bank 1999a<br />

6<br />

Since water is primarily a state subject,<br />

the reforms have to take place at the<br />

state level.<br />

7<br />

World Bank 2004<br />

8<br />

World Bank 1999b Page 133-134<br />

9<br />

Maharashtra Water Resources Regulatory<br />

Authority Act (MWRRA)<br />

2005, Clause 11 (i)<br />

10<br />

World Bank 1999c Page 29<br />

11<br />

World Bank 1999d Page 108<br />

l2<br />

For more information, see for example<br />

Water: Private, Limited <strong>Issue</strong>s in Privatisation,<br />

Corporatisation and Commercialisation<br />

of Water Sector in India,<br />

Manthan Adhyayan Kendra 2006,<br />

available at www.manthan-india.org<br />

References<br />

• D’souza Rohan (2006): ‘Drowned and<br />

Dammed – Colonial Capitalism and<br />

flood control in Eastern India’, Oxford<br />

University Press, New Delhi.<br />

• Dwivedi Gaurav, Rehmat and Shripad<br />

Dharmadhikary (<strong>2007</strong>): ‘Water: Private,<br />

Limited’, Manthan Adhyayan<br />

Kendra, Badwani, Madhya Pradesh.<br />

• World Bank (1999a): ‘Initiating and<br />

Sustaining Water Sector Reforms: A<br />

Synthesis’, World Bank, Washington<br />

D.C. and Allied Publishers Limited,<br />

Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999b): ‘Inter-Sectoral<br />

Water Allocation, Planning and Management’,<br />

World Bank, Washington<br />

D.C. and Allied Publishers Limited,<br />

Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999c): ‘Groundwater<br />

Regulation and Management’, World<br />

Bank, Washington D.C. and Allied<br />

Publishers Limited, Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999d): ‘<strong>The</strong> Irrigation<br />

Sector’, World Bank, Washington D.<br />

C. and Allied Publishers Limited,<br />

Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999e): ‘Rural Water<br />

Supply and Sanitation’, World Bank,<br />

Washington D.C. and Allied Publishers<br />

Limited, Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999f): ‘Urban Water<br />

Supply and Sanitation’, World Bank,<br />

Washington D.C. and Allied Publishers<br />

Limited, Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (2004): ‘Water Resources<br />

Sector Strategy’, World Bank, Washington<br />

D.C.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

51


D.M.Diwakar,<br />

Professor of Economics<br />

Giri Institute of Development Studies<br />

(GIDS), Lucknow<br />

Inclusive Growth In India: A Case Of<br />

Structural And Agrarian Challenges<br />

"To forget how to dig the<br />

earth and tend the soil is to<br />

forget ourselves."<br />

-Mahatma Gandhi<br />

Measures of economic reforms<br />

in India were expected to<br />

deliver goods and services to<br />

attain higher growth rate of the economy<br />

and provide better employability to accommodate<br />

underemployed, unemployed<br />

and marginalized sections of the<br />

society into mainstream of development.<br />

But realisations over the years have not<br />

been in conformity with the expectations.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is common agreement<br />

among the experts across the board that<br />

economy has attained higher growth<br />

rates but reforms measures are yet to<br />

prove effective towards distributive justice<br />

with higher growth. Latest Human<br />

Development Report indicates further<br />

sliding down to the rank of 128. Indian<br />

agriculture irrespective of the <strong>size</strong> of<br />

holdings, which is mainstay for majority<br />

of the masses, has been experiencing<br />

worst forms of crises culminated and<br />

manifested in starvation and tragic suicides<br />

of its producers, who have been<br />

feeding the nation. Besides unregistered<br />

starvation in backward regions in absence<br />

of employment at least at subsistence<br />

level, even diversified and prosperous<br />

agriculture of Punjab, petty cotton<br />

growers of Maharashtra, Andhra and<br />

Karnataka are also not spared from this<br />

trap. Expert Group on agrarian crisis<br />

underlines suicides as a disturbing symptom<br />

of deep-rooted crises that Indian<br />

agriculture has been confronting. Broadly<br />

two dimensions of agrarian crises –<br />

low growth with declining productivity<br />

and high dependence of population on<br />

lower farm income have been the root<br />

causes. Reflecting a little further stagnation,<br />

increasing risk in production and<br />

marketing, collapse of the extension<br />

system, growing institutional vacuum,<br />

and the lack of alternative livelihood<br />

opportunities, etc., are inter alia main<br />

factors behind agrarian crisis (Radhakrishna,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>).<br />

Challenges of the syndrome of fatigue<br />

at the front of technology, institution,<br />

policy and governance (Narayanamoorthy,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>; Behera and Mishra, <strong>2007</strong>)<br />

have been debated at length. Mounting<br />

52 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

criticisms loaded with adverse results of<br />

reforms undermining human face compelled<br />

planners and policy makers to<br />

incorporate such policies that may appear<br />

addressing the crises and concerns<br />

of marginalisation. Hence the Eleventh<br />

Five Year Plan has been claimed to focus<br />

on faster inclusive growth (GOI, 2006)<br />

to address the issues of exclusions. This<br />

exercise is an attempt to underline challenges<br />

on the way to achieve the targets<br />

of inclusive growth. It is not possible to<br />

do justice with all the factors in one exercise<br />

and therefore, this exercise is intended<br />

to analyse a few important dimensions<br />

of agrarian challenges towards<br />

achieving the objectives of inclusive<br />

growth. This paper is divided in four<br />

parts. Part one examines growth performance<br />

of agricultural economy. Part two<br />

deals with indebtedness and credit markets<br />

and institutions. Part three concentrates<br />

on farmers despair and part four<br />

consolidates discussion and reflects on<br />

possible imperatives and options in<br />

this regard.<br />

1. <strong>Dec</strong>elerating Growth<br />

Share of the agricultural sector declined<br />

from 59.2 percent of Gross Domestic<br />

Product (GDP) in 1950-51 to 27.36 percent<br />

in 1999-2000, This figure has further<br />

fallen to 18.5 percent in 2006-07<br />

(Economic Survey, GOI, <strong>2007</strong>:1). Contribution<br />

of agriculture to GDP has been<br />

declining not only because the other sectors<br />

are growing fast but also because of<br />

continued neglect of this sector leading<br />

to decline in rural income. However,<br />

over 56.5 percent of the workforce and<br />

63.9 percent of the rural workforce – 39.8<br />

percent self employed and 24.1 percent<br />

agricultural labour are still directly dependent<br />

on this sector for their livelihood<br />

(National Sample Survey Organisation<br />

(NSSO), 61 st Round, 2006:27).<br />

Out of self-employed workforce majority<br />

of holdings are of marginal and small<br />

farmers. On an average, this sector grew<br />

at the rate of 2.54 percent during 1950-<br />

51 to 2003-04. During pre-Green Revolution<br />

(1950-51 to 1964-65) agriculture<br />

grew by 2.54 percent. Interestingly average<br />

growth rate in post -Green Revolution<br />

period until 1980 was only 2.05 percent,<br />

which was slightly lower than<br />

earlier period. Growth rate of agriculture<br />

in 1980s was the highest at 3.08 percent<br />

and later in last one decade (1993-<br />

94 to 2003-04) this sector suffered<br />

deceleration and grew only by 2.38 percent<br />

(Bhalla, 2005: p.2). During Ninth<br />

and Tenth Five Year Plan, agriculture<br />

grew only by 2 and 1.7 percent respectively<br />

(GOI, 2006:4).<br />

In pre–Green Revolution period<br />

growth rates of all principal crops, in<br />

terms of their area production and yield<br />

were 1.58, 3.15, 1.21 percent, food grains<br />

1.35, 2.82, 1.36 percent and non food<br />

grains 2.44, 3.74, 0.89 percent respectively.<br />

Post-Green Revolution data of<br />

growth rates suggest that area and production<br />

of all principal crops had lower<br />

rate of growth but yield registered higher<br />

rate of growth than that of pre-Green<br />

Revolution period. So far non-food<br />

grains are concerned, growth rates of<br />

area and production witnessed deceleration.<br />

However productivity registered<br />

increasing trend from 0.89 percent to<br />

1.59 percent. In case of food grains area<br />

declined, production registered lower<br />

rate of growth and yield rate increased.<br />

Statisticall, the comparison of 1980s<br />

with 1990s suggests that, in case of all<br />

principal crops, cultivable area increased<br />

in 1990s and production and productivity<br />

parameters registered deceleration.<br />

In the case of food grains, area declined,<br />

production and productivity encountered<br />

lower rate of growth than 1980s.<br />

So far non-food grains are concerned<br />

area, production and productivity indicated<br />

an increasing trend with deceleration,<br />

i.e., lower rate of growth than<br />

1980s. However there was an evidence<br />

of recovery in terms of area and productivity<br />

of food grains, and area production<br />

and productivity in non-food grains<br />

during 2000-01 to 2006-07. As a result,<br />

there was a sign of recovery in area production<br />

and productivity of all principal<br />

crops. However, in terms of the growth<br />

According to NSSO data, over 56.5% of the workforce<br />

and 63.9% of the rural workforce – 39.8% self employed<br />

and 24.1% agricultural labour are still directly dependent<br />

on agriculture sector for their livelihood<br />

rates of production it was still lower than<br />

the growth rates of the production of<br />

1980s (GOI, 2006a).<br />

Expansion of irrigation network, use<br />

of modern technology - HYV seeds,<br />

chemical fertilizer, pesticides combined<br />

- cropping pattern changed remarkably.<br />

Cropping intensity also improved to the<br />

level of 134 percent. But percentage coverage<br />

of food grains did not change significantly<br />

until 1980-81. Coverage of<br />

total cereals hardly changed and remained<br />

at the level of about 75 percent.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

53


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

During 1990-91 to 2000-01 it remained<br />

around 65 percent. Coverage of oil seeds,<br />

fruits and vegetables almost doubled and<br />

area under HYV increased from 1.2 percent<br />

of GCA to 41.17 percent. Paddy<br />

coverage of HYV has increased from<br />

0.56 percent in 1966-67 to 17.34 percent<br />

in 1998-99, wheat from 0.34 to 12.61 percent,<br />

jowar from 0.12 to 4.89 percent,<br />

bajra from 0.04 to 3.76 and maize 0.13 to<br />

1.89 percent of GCA. Important factors<br />

inter alia for such poor performance was<br />

continued neglect of agriculture towards<br />

structural inequity, prevailing non-development<br />

syndrome in infrastructure,<br />

lack of adequate budgetary allocation of<br />

resources for investment. Agricultural<br />

investment to GDP witnessed declining<br />

trend over the years. During 1985-86 it<br />

was 2.3 percent at 1993-94 prices, which<br />

declined to 1.6 percent in 1989-90 and<br />

continued to decline further to 1.4 percent<br />

in 1999-2000 and 1.3 percent in<br />

2003-04. Even at prices of 1999-2000 the<br />

level of investment in 2003-04 was 1.9<br />

percent and remained stagnated at 1.9<br />

percent only for three consecutive years,<br />

i.e., up to 2005-06 (GOI, 2006-07). This<br />

clearly indicated a decline in investment<br />

in real terms. Realisation at the level of<br />

the Planning Commission of the Government<br />

of India suggests that private<br />

investment cannot be sustained without<br />

sustained public investment. Thus, syndrome<br />

of non-development left this sector<br />

under performed. Much hope is<br />

pinned on Bharat Nirman Yojana to expand<br />

irrigation network. But the provision<br />

made under this scheme in the budget<br />

of current financial year does not<br />

appear consistent with targets. With this<br />

speed the target of covering additional<br />

10 million hectare under irrigation will<br />

take at least 17 years.<br />

Cost of cultivation increased significantly<br />

with the increasing use of modern<br />

technology across the states (Diwakar,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>). Variation in terms of percentage<br />

rate of change in cost of cultivation since<br />

1991 at least for a few major commodities<br />

suggests that lower range of the cost<br />

of cultivation for paddy increased from<br />

over 73 percent in 97-98 to<br />

117 percent in 2002-03 and<br />

about 173 percent in 2004-<br />

05. Upper range of cost increased<br />

by over 92 percent<br />

in 97-98 to about 149 percent<br />

in 2002-03 and 124 percent<br />

40% of the farmers did not like to continue with agriculture.<br />

About 27% were reluctant to continue in this occpation<br />

precisely because of non-viability. Interstate variations<br />

were even higher than that of all India fi gures<br />

in 2004-05. Lower range of cost of cultivation<br />

of wheat increased by 105 percent<br />

in 1997-98 compared to 1990-91, 132<br />

percent in 2002-03 and 170 percent by<br />

2004-05. Upper range of variation increased<br />

from 85 percent to 106 percent.<br />

Lower range of cost of cultivation for<br />

cotton increased by 149 percent in 97-98<br />

to 184 percent in 2002-03 and upper<br />

range by 235 and 167 percent respectively.<br />

Cost of cultivation for other crops<br />

can similarly worked out to assess the<br />

trend and variation of specific crop<br />

across the states. Difference in cost and<br />

price structure is another dimension for<br />

examination of the viability of the crops.<br />

For example, farm harvest price/cost of<br />

cultivating cotton ratio in 1997-98 in<br />

Haryana, was 0.8633 with respect to<br />

Desi and 0.9656 for American cotton<br />

and in Punjab 0.5515 and 0.6914 respectively.<br />

In Maharashtra price–cost ratio<br />

was 0.9452. Thus, farmers of these states<br />

were not in a position to recover even<br />

cost from the returns. In case of paddy<br />

Andhra Pradesh however, was getting<br />

Rs.445 price per quintal against cost of<br />

cultivation Rs.436.77. Escalating cost of<br />

production with poor returns from agriculture<br />

amidst uncertainty of monsoon,<br />

risk of crop failures, absence<br />

of effective insurance<br />

cover, and almost<br />

non-existence of extension<br />

services pushed farmers<br />

into unprecedented hardships.<br />

Terms of trade remained<br />

against agriculture<br />

even after termination of industrial protection<br />

and devaluation of rupee in 1991<br />

(Bhalla, 2005). Data also suggest that<br />

about 40 percent of the farmers did not<br />

like to continue with agriculture (NSSO,<br />

2005:59 th Round). About 27 percent were<br />

reluctant to continue in this occupation<br />

precisely because of non-viability. Interstate<br />

variations were even higher than<br />

that of all India figures. About 36 percent<br />

of the farmers of Bihar, West Bengal,<br />

34 percent of Orissa, 30 percent of<br />

Haryana and Jharkhand, 29 percent of<br />

Maharashtra, and even 28 percent of the<br />

farmers of Punjab – agriculturally one of<br />

the most developed regions and Kerala,<br />

one of the most developed states in terms<br />

of social development indicators of the<br />

country and Karnataka, and 30 percent<br />

farmers of Haryana did not like agricul-<br />

54 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ture occupation. Encountering deceleration<br />

resulted into lower farm income<br />

and widening gap between agricultural<br />

and non-agricultural income. <strong>The</strong>refore<br />

major challenge is not simply to attain<br />

higher growth target in agriculture,<br />

which has been projected at 4 percent,<br />

but to include agricultural labourers and<br />

marginal and small farmers participating<br />

in the growth process effectively. In<br />

order to make them to participate in the<br />

growth process institutional, infrastructure<br />

and technological constraints need<br />

to be addressed on priority basis. This<br />

sector by and large is dependant on vagaries<br />

of monsoon and unprotected from<br />

the risks of crop failures despite expansion<br />

of significant network of irrigation.<br />

Rising cost of cultivation, embedded<br />

with insufficient infrastructure support<br />

and slowing down of employment and<br />

income, left farmers trapped in the syndrome<br />

of indebtedness and despair. Performance<br />

of agriculture remained dismal<br />

with some minor exceptions, thanks<br />

to the unpredictable monsoon and governmental<br />

indifference towards this sector.<br />

As a result, employment in rural<br />

sector grew at declining rate (Bhalla,<br />

2005). Data from NSS rounds suggest<br />

that there was significant decline in employment<br />

in primary sector for both<br />

males and females (NSSO, 60:506).<br />

Findings are supporting the apprehensions<br />

that National Rural Employment<br />

Guarantee Scheme with this speed cannot<br />

deliver the jobs to rural workforce,<br />

.as implementation reports from different<br />

states is adding frustrations only.<br />

Another disturbing factor is decelerating<br />

real wage rates in agriculture and nonagriculture<br />

(Sharma, 2005). But the<br />

question is whether these were substantial<br />

to offset the decelerating impacts of<br />

primary sector on the income of rural<br />

economy. <strong>Dec</strong>elerating growth rate suggests<br />

that this sector could not generate<br />

sufficient capital and investment even<br />

through private sector. Limited benefits<br />

of expansion of the post -Green Revolution<br />

technology could increase production<br />

and productivity but that also could<br />

not be sustained. Moreover, the gains<br />

could not be transferred significantly to<br />

the rural poor in particular and farm<br />

sector at large in general. Rather due to<br />

lack of effective infrastructure and extension<br />

services, modern technology<br />

added confusions in absence of effective<br />

extension services, increased cost of production,<br />

and created environmental<br />

complications and imbalances added<br />

with greater intensity of exploitation of<br />

poor farmers through usury network of<br />

non-institutional credit market in absence<br />

of effective institutional credit<br />

support.<br />

2. Indebtedness, Credit Markets<br />

And Institutions<br />

Rural indebtedness is an indicative of<br />

deficiency of rural income to carry out<br />

necessary activities for livelihood support.<br />

<strong>Dec</strong>elerating growth in agriculture<br />

and increasing income gap between agriculture<br />

and non-agriculture forced a<br />

great majority of farmers and agricultural<br />

labourers to borrow. Findings of<br />

the Royal Commission (which stated<br />

that 'farmers are born in debt, they live,<br />

die in debt and transfer debt liability to<br />

next generation') still hold good. <strong>The</strong><br />

worsening state of farmer's despair is a<br />

matter of serious social concern. In order<br />

to address the deficient need of the<br />

farmers many players – formal as well as<br />

informal - have been operating in the<br />

credit market. NSSO survey report suggests<br />

that about 48.6 percent of the farmers’<br />

households were indebted with an<br />

average outstanding loan amount of<br />

Rs.12,585. Out of indebted farmers<br />

households, 31.3 percent were from the<br />

category of landless and below marginal<br />

farmers, 29.8 percent were from marginal<br />

farmers and 18.8 percent from<br />

small farmers category. Thus, altogether<br />

80 percent of the indebted households<br />

were from the poorest lot in terms of<br />

land in possession. Prevalent rate of indebtedness<br />

of landless labour households<br />

of rural area were 45.3 percent,<br />

About 48.6% of the farmers’ households were indebted<br />

with an average outstanding loan amount of Rs. 12585.<br />

Altogether 80% of the indebted households were from the<br />

poorest lot in terms of land in possession<br />

who owed on an average Rs.6,121. With<br />

the increasing <strong>size</strong> of land in possession<br />

prevalent rate of indebtedness increased<br />

and so was the amount of loan. Considering<br />

per farmer loan amount by Monthly<br />

Per-capita Expenditure (MPCE), extent<br />

of indebtedness was higher in lower<br />

consumption bracket. With the increase<br />

in monthly per capita expenditure percentage<br />

of indebtedness decreased.<br />

However, amount of loan per farmer remained<br />

positive with the increasing<br />

monthly per capita expenditure. Indebtedness<br />

by social groups suggest that<br />

spread of indebtedness and loan amount<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

55


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

was lowest in STs and second lowest in<br />

SCs. OBCs reported higher spread of<br />

indebtedness and amount of loan than<br />

SCs but lower spread and higher amount<br />

of loan than general category of<br />

social group.<br />

State wise distribution of farmers’ indebtedness<br />

suggests that Andhra<br />

Pradesh registered highest incidence of<br />

debts with 82 percent followed by Tamil<br />

Nadu (74.5 percent), Punjab (65.4 percent),<br />

Kerala (64.4 percent) and Karnataka<br />

(61.6 percent). Uttaranchal reported<br />

lowest percentage of farmers with<br />

loan. In terms of per farmer amount of<br />

loan, Punjab carried the highest burden<br />

of loan amount at Rs.41,576 followed by<br />

Kerala (33,907). Haryana stood at third<br />

with Rs.26,007 followed by Andhra<br />

Pradesh (Rs.23,965), Tamil Nadu<br />

(Rs.23,963), Rajasthan (Rs.18,372),<br />

Karnataka (Rs.18,135) and Maharashrtra<br />

(Rs.16,973). Among social groups of<br />

STs, per farmer loan amount was highest<br />

in Punjab (Rs.1,18,495), followed by<br />

Haryana (Rs.23,555), Tamil Nadu<br />

(Rs.21,023) and Andhra Pradesh<br />

(Rs.12,760). In case of SCs, per farmer<br />

loan amount was highest in Rajasthan<br />

(Rs.16,708) followed by Haryana<br />

(Rs.13,341), Kerala (Rs.13308), Tamil<br />

Nadu 12,786 and Andhra Pradesh<br />

(Rs.12,720). For OBCs per farmer loan<br />

amount was highest in Kerala<br />

(Rs.33,116), followed by Tamil Nadu<br />

(Rs.27,355), Haryana (Rs.26,226),<br />

Andhra Pradesh (Rs.23,697), and Rajasthan<br />

(Rs.22,009). In general category<br />

also per farmer loan amount was highest<br />

in Kerala (Rs.38,013) followed by<br />

Andhra Pradesh (Rs.37,802), Haryana<br />

(Rs.31,548), Gujarat, Karnataka and<br />

Tamil Nadu.<br />

Amount of loan taken was generally<br />

utilized for production and consumption<br />

purposes. Data suggest that 30.6 percent<br />

of loan amount was spent for capital expenditure<br />

in farm business followed by<br />

current capital expenditure (27.8 percent).<br />

Non-farm business consumed 6.7<br />

percent. Thus, altogether 65 percent<br />

loan amount was directly used for production<br />

purposes. Another 15 percent<br />

was spent for social development and<br />

remaining 20 percent was on marriage<br />

and other ceremonial occasions and on<br />

consumption expenditure. Medical<br />

treatment and other expenditure could<br />

eat significant proportion in some of<br />

Near landless and marginal households took 56.7 % and<br />

47.2 % of loan amount respectively from informal usury<br />

networks. State wise variations suggest that non-institutional<br />

share of loan fi nance was higher in many states<br />

the states.<br />

Rural credit market has both formal<br />

and informal players. Formal players are<br />

government, cooperatives, commercial<br />

banks, whereas informal credit market<br />

is run by and large by moneylenders - often<br />

farmer, traders including dealers of<br />

inputs, other professionals, friends and<br />

relatives, and others operate as moneylenders.<br />

NSS data suggest that commercial<br />

banks remained major player in providing<br />

credit to farmers (35.6 percent)<br />

followed by cooperatives (19.6 percent)<br />

and government (2.5 percent). Altogether<br />

57.7 percent of credit taken by farmers<br />

was provided through institutional arrangements.<br />

Remaining 42.3 percent<br />

credit market was controlled by informal<br />

players. <strong>The</strong>se players may be categorized<br />

in one bracket of moneylenders<br />

with a few individual exceptions. It is<br />

evident from data in reference that credit<br />

extended by cooperatives and commercial<br />

banks emerged positively directed<br />

towards increasing <strong>size</strong> of holdings<br />

whereas credit extended by moneylenders<br />

had inverse direction. Landless<br />

households took 47.3 percent loan from<br />

moneylenders alone. Adding extended<br />

informal usury network it came to 77<br />

percent. Near landless and marginal<br />

households took 56.7 percent and 47.2<br />

percent of loan amount respectively from<br />

informal usury networks. State wise<br />

variations suggest that non-institutional<br />

share of loan finance was higher in many<br />

states. Non-institutional finance controlled<br />

greater credit market to the tune<br />

of 68 percent in Andhra Pradesh followed<br />

by Rajasthan, Assam Bihar and<br />

Punjab. Although Maharashtra provided<br />

83 .8 percent credit through institutional<br />

sources farmers were not free from<br />

distress and suicides. This suggests that<br />

provision of institutional credit is although<br />

important it alone cannot be sufficient<br />

to rescue the farmers from the<br />

syndrome of despair.<br />

Flow of institutional credit amount to<br />

agriculture over the years increased<br />

many folds by cooperatives, commercial<br />

and regional rural banks in terms of<br />

short, medium and long terms loan. But<br />

the question of distributional aspects of<br />

credit remained to be addressed effectively.<br />

Total credit extended by cooperatives<br />

was to the tune of Rs.24.23 crore in<br />

1950-51 to Rs.15,957 crore in 1998-99<br />

56 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

and 33,174 crore by <strong>Dec</strong>ember 2006<br />

(GOI, <strong>2007</strong>:171). Credit volume extended<br />

by commercial banks and regional<br />

rural banks were even higher than cooperatives<br />

although initials were the same.<br />

<strong>The</strong>ir initial credit amount was to the<br />

tune of Rs.24.23 crore in 1950-51, which<br />

further got increased to Rs.36,860 crore<br />

in 1998-99 and in <strong>Dec</strong>ember 2006, it<br />

stands at 1, 16, 169 crores. Provisional<br />

estimates, projection and targets indicated<br />

increasing volume of credit. <strong>The</strong><br />

share of agriculture in total bank credit<br />

had steadily increased under the impulse<br />

of bank nationalization and reached 18<br />

percent towards the end of<br />

the 1980s. But thereafter,<br />

agriculture suffered severe<br />

neglect of institutional<br />

credit delivery mechanism<br />

in the post reform period.<br />

<strong>The</strong> achievement has been<br />

almost completely reversed<br />

and the agricultural credit share dipped<br />

to less than 10 percent in the late 90s – a<br />

ratio that had prevailed in the early<br />

1970s. Even the number of farm loan accounts<br />

with scheduled commercial banks<br />

has declined in absolute terms from<br />

27.74 million in March 1992 to 20.84 million<br />

in March 2003 (Shetty, Economic<br />

and Political Weekly, July 17, 2004).<br />

Similarly per hectare credit in rupees to<br />

agriculture in recent years increased<br />

from 1,940 in 1998-99 to 4,578 in 2003-<br />

04, but annual growth rate of per hectare<br />

credit to agriculture, which was 25.5<br />

percent in 1999-00 over previous year,<br />

slipped down to 14.2 percent in the year<br />

2000-01. After witnessing partially recovery<br />

(17.4 percent) in 2001-02, growth<br />

of per hectare credit registered lower<br />

rate ( at 14.1 percent) in 2002-03 (Lok<br />

Sabha.2005). This also partially explains<br />

as to why moneylenders were dominating<br />

the credit market, wherein appropriating<br />

surpluses through exorbitant interest<br />

rates (Bhalla, 2005:6).<br />

3. Farmers In Despair<br />

Vagaries of monsoon added with rising<br />

costs and uncertainty of access to reliable<br />

technology, market and public credit<br />

institutions amidst unprotected risks<br />

with non-profitable agriculture aggravated<br />

the syndrome of frustration among<br />

farmers across the states of India irrespective<br />

of level of development of agriculture.<br />

Initially anticipating<br />

better returns farmers invested<br />

capital mobilising<br />

through public and private<br />

institutions and stayed in<br />

production for couple of<br />

years to make their fortunes.<br />

Richer lots of farmers could stay<br />

for couple of years because of their staying<br />

power and relatively better access to<br />

credit and inputs even if they suffered<br />

losses. Unfortunately many of them specially<br />

farmers from smaller farm <strong>size</strong><br />

could not sustain growing burden of<br />

loans from moneylenders, traders, dealers<br />

of inputs for many years. Because of<br />

loss of face before the community consequent<br />

upon mounting burden of debts,<br />

failures of credit, insurance and procurement<br />

delivery mechanisms and agencies,<br />

they were forced to commit suicides.<br />

Various studies and reports have been<br />

conducted on this serious problem. Indira<br />

Gandhi Institute Of Development<br />

Research (IGIDR) has brought a comprehensive<br />

study on suicides of farmers<br />

(Mishra 2006:41) for the government of<br />

Maharashtra. Study found various reasons<br />

for suicides. About 86.5 percent<br />

suicides were because of indebtedness,<br />

73.9 percent for deteriorating economic<br />

status, and 40.5 percent because of crop<br />

failures. Loss of face in community (because<br />

of non-payment of loan, inability<br />

to marry their marriageable sisters and<br />

daughters, etc.), were the other reasons.<br />

About 91 percent of suicides were committed<br />

by males. As per police records,<br />

number of suicides in Maharashtra in<br />

2004 alone was 4147. Study reported that<br />

number of suicides increased from 11866<br />

to 14729 between 1995 to 2004.Study<br />

suggests that suicides in females registered<br />

decline after 1999. Another study<br />

<strong>The</strong> central issue of farmers’ suicides is the debt trap.<br />

Small and marginal farmers are not eligible for availing<br />

institutional credit and crop insurance. Thus, they land at<br />

the doorsteps of the usurious moneylenders<br />

(Mohanty, 2005) revealed that cash crop<br />

growers, small and marginal farmers of<br />

Amaravati and Yavatmal districts were<br />

trapped in debt anticipating better returns<br />

from cultivation and committed<br />

suicides.<br />

Kisan Sabha estimates that more than<br />

5,000 farmers committed suicide in<br />

Andhra Pradesh since 1998, more than<br />

3000 committed suicide in Maharashtra,<br />

about 1,000 farmers committed suicide<br />

in Punjab from 1998 to the present, and<br />

about 5,000 committed suicide in Karnataka<br />

over the same period. It is estimated<br />

that 488 farmers committed sui-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

57


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

cide in Wayanad District in Kerala<br />

between 2001 and 2005.” (People’s Democracy,<br />

Vol.30, No. 09, Feb 26, 2006).<br />

Another study (Ridyasagar, and Sunianchandra,<br />

2003) argued that “<strong>The</strong> central<br />

issue of farmers’ suicides is the debt trap.<br />

Small and marginal farmers, especially<br />

those, who lease in land from others, are<br />

not eligible for availing institutional<br />

credit and crop insurance. Thus, they<br />

land at the doorsteps of the usurious<br />

moneylenders. This debt trap is tightening<br />

because of the drastic shifts in the<br />

cropping pattern that is market driven.”<br />

Seeds, fertilizer and pesticide dealers<br />

are at the centre of a growing controversy<br />

in Andhra Pradesh. <strong>The</strong>y are the<br />

new moneylenders to a peasantry<br />

strapped for credit. “<strong>The</strong> banks have<br />

given no loans in the past seven years,”<br />

says Malla Reddy, General Secretary of<br />

the Andhra Pradesh Ryuthu Sangham<br />

(APRS). “So many farmers are forced to<br />

depend on sources like these for credit.<br />

<strong>The</strong> same man advises them on what to<br />

buy and then sets the rates for the purchase.”<br />

With the seed dealers charging<br />

hefty interest rates on their credit sales,<br />

the problem gets more acute. <strong>The</strong> series<br />

of reports filed by P. Sainath which appeared<br />

in the Hindu and India Together<br />

is indeed an eye opener. <strong>The</strong> <strong>Dec</strong>can<br />

Herald dated August 11, 2005 reported<br />

that Movement Against State Repression<br />

(MASR) claims that about 40000<br />

farmers committed suicides in Punjab<br />

alone since 1988 whereas state government<br />

admitted only 2116 cases. Rising<br />

cost of cultivation, lack of market security,<br />

exorbitant rate of interests charged<br />

by moneylenders, dishonouring contracts<br />

etc. were inter alia a few important<br />

reasons. After 1996 loan amounts increased<br />

four times but public institutions’<br />

share was merely 20 percent. Despande<br />

and Prabhu (2005) found that<br />

most of the suicides were driven by debt.<br />

Delivery mechanism of institutional<br />

credit and its defined connivance with<br />

local middle men and functionaries often<br />

hatches conspiracy to confiscate the<br />

land of the poor marginal and small<br />

farmers and forcing them to<br />

commit suicide. Suicide<br />

committed by Manasa Ram<br />

of Maraucha Ishwari Singh<br />

Village (Suratganj Block in<br />

Barabanki district of Uttar<br />

Pradesh) is an example of<br />

Near landless and marginal households took 56.7 % and<br />

47.2 % of loan amount respectively from informal usury<br />

networks. State wise variations suggest that non-institutional<br />

share of loan fi nance was higher in many states<br />

many such cases. However, efforts of social<br />

activists foiled this conspiracy and<br />

the confiscation got cancelled later. Tenant<br />

farmers have seldom access to institutional<br />

credit in absence of ownership<br />

of land as collateral security and therefore<br />

they are forced to be trapped in<br />

usurious exploitative network. <strong>The</strong>y often<br />

sell their crops at pre-decided tied<br />

price to the input dealers or at best at<br />

farm harvest price to petty traders.<br />

Kisan Sabha deliberated upon this serious<br />

crisis and noted: “While every such<br />

death is a tragic individual reality for<br />

grieving families and loved ones, there<br />

are important common features to the<br />

farmers’ suicides. <strong>The</strong>se farmers invested<br />

heavily in inputs – biological inputs,<br />

electricity, machinery, and other components<br />

of fixed and variable costs. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

costs have risen sharply in the period of<br />

liberalisation, and are especially onerous<br />

when the farmer invests in seeds<br />

produced by private companies, particularly<br />

multinational corporations. <strong>The</strong><br />

farmers were often the victims of plain<br />

cheating – they were sold spurious seed<br />

and other inputs by unscrupulous traders.<br />

Since 1991, farmers have had to witness<br />

the massive withdrawal of the formal<br />

sector credit from the<br />

countryside, and have had<br />

to borrow from the informal<br />

sector at usurious rates<br />

of interest for their production<br />

and consumption<br />

needs. Finally, when they<br />

reaped a harvest, neo liberalism<br />

and the new trade regime robbed<br />

them of prices that could even cover<br />

their costs, let alone earn them a livelihood.<br />

Where the output itself is destroyed<br />

by pest, disease or natural disaster,<br />

the farmer was un-indemnified by<br />

any system of insurance, and inadequately<br />

compensated, if at all, by the<br />

state. It is the stark reality that, for many<br />

in our society and in such a situation,<br />

suicide appears as the alternative of last<br />

resort” (People’s Democracy, vol.30, no.<br />

09, Feb 26, 2006). Market driven farm<br />

diversification, not necessarily designed<br />

differently but for the interests of corporate<br />

sectors, exploited farm land, thereby<br />

undermining ecological and fertility<br />

balance. Globalisation and new trade<br />

regime has made farmers condition vulnerable<br />

and exposed to uncertainty<br />

58 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

(Vidyasagar and Chandra, 2003, CSD,<br />

NIRD). <strong>The</strong>re is every possibility of<br />

worsening condition of poor farmers<br />

further with the emphasis on investment<br />

through corporate contract farming.<br />

Unless means of production is reoriented<br />

in favour of producers and meaningful<br />

employment and employability of<br />

poor cultivators are ensured through<br />

public sector initiatives for infrastructure<br />

development and input and output<br />

markets are regulated in the interest of<br />

producers it will be difficult to rescue<br />

farmers from the syndrome of distress<br />

and despair leading towards suicides.<br />

4. Policy Imperatives And Options<br />

We have discussed a few dimensions of<br />

agrarian crises rooted in the syndrome<br />

of decelerating growth of agriculture<br />

amidst rising costs and inadequate infrastructure<br />

leading to deficient employment<br />

and income for the livelihood of<br />

rural workers specially small and marginal<br />

cultivators and agricultural labourers.<br />

It emerged from the analysis that<br />

decelerating growth with inadequate infrastructure,<br />

technological support and<br />

institutional arrangements forced majority<br />

of the peasants in the debt trap. Majority<br />

of indebted households were from<br />

the poorest lot in terms of <strong>size</strong> of land<br />

possession and monthly per capita consumption<br />

expenditure. However, rate of<br />

indebtedness and amount of loan was<br />

directly related with increasing <strong>size</strong> of<br />

land possession and households with<br />

higher MPCE. Contrary to belief major<br />

amount of loan utilized were for capital<br />

expenditure and current expenditure of<br />

farm and non-farm business instead of<br />

consumption purposes. However, significant<br />

amount of loan was spent on essential<br />

consumption expenditure, marriage<br />

and other ceremonial occasions<br />

also. Expenditure on education and<br />

health was the least. So far sources of<br />

loan were concerned with formal sector<br />

- commercial bank remained the major<br />

player followed by cooperative societies.<br />

Moneylender was yet significantly present<br />

in the rural borrowing market and<br />

other informal sources, i.e., traders,<br />

friends and relatives, professionals and<br />

others were not different than moneylenders<br />

with a few individual exceptions.<br />

Institutional credit remained favourable<br />

for increasing <strong>size</strong> of land possessions<br />

but mostly in poor states. Banks remained<br />

effective after nationalisation<br />

until 1980s but its performance declined<br />

significantly in late 90s. Per hectare<br />

credit to agriculture was also declined.<br />

Analysis suggests that the geneses of indebtedness<br />

were rooted in continued<br />

neglect of agriculture resulted in decelerated<br />

growth syndrome. <strong>Dec</strong>lining investment<br />

and inadequate infrastructure<br />

acted as a drag on institutional and technological<br />

transformation and modernisation<br />

with ecological balance. Poor support<br />

system for technological transfer<br />

and updating, credit, input, insurance<br />

and marketing with dependence on vagaries<br />

of monsoon resulted in crop failures<br />

and lower returns leading to misery,<br />

distress and despair.<br />

In this sort of syndrome, cultivators<br />

were often not in a position to repay the<br />

loan(s). <strong>The</strong>y hardly sustained the loss<br />

<strong>The</strong> central issue of farmers’ suicides is the debt trap.<br />

Small and marginal farmers are not eligible for availing<br />

institutional credit and crop insurance. Thus, they land at<br />

the doorsteps of the usurious moneylenders<br />

of face before the community and committed<br />

suicides. Thus, most of the unfortunate<br />

suicides were debt driven. Credit<br />

needs have been grown considerably<br />

over the time following commercialisation<br />

and modernization. However, average<br />

household borrowing in rural India<br />

has not been excessive. Inadequacy of<br />

institutional credit delivery network,<br />

poor performance of credit cooperatives,<br />

regional rural banks, and commercial<br />

banks, to meet their farm lending<br />

targets, and high cost of rural banking,<br />

etc., have aggravated further (Radhakrishna,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>). Consecutive failures<br />

of governance (in terms of effective policies<br />

and their effectual implementation)<br />

were witnessed. Instead of correcting<br />

aforesaid those lapses the economy has<br />

been moving in a different direction in<br />

the interest of the rich and corporate<br />

sectors with a faster pace of reforms. Interestingly<br />

despite symptoms of all the<br />

negative indications against the poor,<br />

contradictory policies for reforms have<br />

been put in place with a lip service to the<br />

poor. Unless poor producers are brought<br />

in the mainstream of production, control<br />

over the means of production and distribution<br />

on sustainable basis this process<br />

of marginalization, distress and despair,<br />

which has emerged out sharply in the era<br />

of reforms and globalisation of markets,<br />

may not be checked. Lowering the rate<br />

of interest on institutional loans and<br />

Right to Work may have positive effects<br />

subject to effective implementation<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

59


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

which is always doubtful. However, Right<br />

to Work on ad hoc basis cannot be continued<br />

for long. Sustainable employment<br />

generation led growth process for poor<br />

producers need to be put in place. This<br />

needs stronger and active role of State,<br />

which has been narrowing down during<br />

reform process. State has compromised<br />

with anti-poor development players. Unskilled<br />

labour force has hardly any space<br />

in the reform led labour market. Meaningful<br />

employment for skilled and unskilled<br />

workforce and initiatives to create<br />

institutions and opportunities to<br />

speed up skill transformation to enter<br />

into the job market is the prime tasks<br />

which market can seldom perform for<br />

poor having no purchasing power. And<br />

civil society cannot rest in peace if the<br />

idle hands do not get employment.<br />

<strong>The</strong>refore, pro-poor activism of civil<br />

society and effective mobilisation and<br />

resistance of peasants and social activists<br />

have become an imperative for all<br />

peace loving people to create pressure<br />

upon the state to perform pro-poor role<br />

inorder to achieve growth, with<br />

meaningful employment and actionable<br />

social justice.<br />

Reference<br />

• Behera, B. and Mishra, P., (<strong>2007</strong>): Acceleration<br />

of Agricultural Growth in<br />

India: Suggestive Policy Framework,<br />

Economic and Political Weekly, vol.<br />

42, No. 42. October 20-26.<br />

•. Bhalla, G.S., (2005): <strong>The</strong> State of the<br />

Indian Farmers, G. Parthasarathi Memorial<br />

Lecture in 88th Annual Conference<br />

of the Indian Economic Association,<br />

<strong>Dec</strong>ember 28, 2005.<br />

• Despande, R.S., and Prabhu, Nagesh,<br />

(2005): Farmers Distress – Proof beyond<br />

Questions, Economic and Political<br />

Weekly, Vol.40, No. 44 and 45, November<br />

4.<br />

• Diwakar, D.M., (<strong>2007</strong>): Contours of<br />

Agrarian Crises in India, Uttar<br />

Pradesh-Uttaranchal Economic Association<br />

(UPUEA) Economic Journal,<br />

Annual Conference Number.<br />

• Government of India (2006): Towards<br />

Faster and More Inclusive Growth: An<br />

Approach to the 11th Five Year Plan,<br />

Planning Commission, New Delhi, November<br />

2006.<br />

• Government of India (2006a): Agriculture<br />

at a Glance 2006, Ministry of Agriculture,<br />

New Delhi.<br />

• Government of India (<strong>2007</strong>): Economic<br />

Survey, Ministry of Finance, New<br />

Delhi.<br />

• Lok Sabha Starred Question No. 611,<br />

dated on 09.05.2005.<br />

• Mishra, Srijit, (2006): Farmers’ Suicide<br />

in Maharashtra, Economic and Political<br />

Weekly,Vol.41,No. 16, April 22-28,<br />

pp. 1538-45,see also, Suicide Mortality<br />

Rates across States of India, in the<br />

same issue p. 1567.<br />

• Mohanty, B.B., (2005): We are Like the<br />

Living Dead: Farmer Suicides in Maharashtra,<br />

Western India, Journal of<br />

Peasant Studies, Vol.32, No.2, April,<br />

pp. 243-276.<br />

• Narayanamoorthy, A., (<strong>2007</strong>): <strong>Dec</strong>eleration<br />

in Agricultural Growth: Technology<br />

Fatigue or Policy Fatigue? Economic<br />

and Political Weekly, Vol.42,<br />

No.25, June 23.<br />

• National Sample Survey Organisation<br />

(2005): Indebtedness of Farmer Households<br />

in India, NSS Report No. 498,<br />

59 th Round, January-<strong>Dec</strong>ember 2003.<br />

• National Sample Survey Organisation<br />

(NSSO) (2006): Employment and Unemployment<br />

Situation in India, 2004-<br />

05, Report No. 515 -I<br />

• People’s Democracy, Vol.30, No. 09,<br />

February 26 th , 2006.<br />

• Rao, Nageswara, <strong>The</strong> Hindu, September<br />

11, 2005.<br />

• Radhakrishna, R. (<strong>2007</strong>): Expert Group<br />

Report on Agrarian Crisis<br />

in India, Government of India,<br />

New Delhi.<br />

• RBI’s Basic Statistical Returns of<br />

Scheduled Commercial Banks in India,<br />

various <strong>Issue</strong>s.<br />

• Sharma, H.R., (2005): Recent Trends<br />

in Wage Earnings of Agricultural Labourers<br />

State Level Analysis for Different<br />

Social Groups, Arth Vijnana,<br />

Vol. XLVII, Nos. 3-4, September-<strong>Dec</strong>ember,<br />

pp. 329-344.<br />

• Shetty, S.L. (2004): Distributional <strong>Issue</strong>s<br />

in Bank Credit, Multi-pronged<br />

Strategy for Correcting Past Neglect,<br />

Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.<br />

Xxxix, no. 29, July 17.<br />

•Sainath,P.,IndiaTogether, accessible at<br />

http://indiatogether.com/agriculture/<br />

suicides.htm; Sainath, P. (<strong>2007</strong>): Farming-<br />

it ‘s what they do, <strong>The</strong> Hindu, May<br />

24, <strong>2007</strong>, p.11; Suicides are about the<br />

living, not dead, <strong>The</strong> Hindu, May 21,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>, p.p.13.; Vidarbha: Packaging an<br />

anniversary, <strong>The</strong> Hindu, August 31,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>; it’s official: distress up, suicides<br />

appalling, India Together, 22 November<br />

2006, courtesy <strong>The</strong> Hindu, p.11;<br />

When farmers die, India Together,<br />

http://www.indiatogether.org/2004/<br />

june/psa-farmdie.htm<br />

• Vidyasagar, R. and Sunianchandra, K.,<br />

(2003): Study on Farmers’ Suicides<br />

in Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka,<br />

CSD, National Institute of Rural<br />

Development.<br />

60 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


I.T. = Business Growth<br />

At Planman Technologies we don’t believe in mindless application of I.T.<br />

because, I.T. is not about having systems to enable employees to e-mail<br />

and chat more effectively nor is it just about being connected. We help you<br />

apply I.T. to grow your Business.<br />

Planman is a 360° Business Growth Consulting firm. We enable you to<br />

take intellect driven growth decisions and apply I.T. only to increase your<br />

ROI and Beat <strong>The</strong> Competition In A Wrinkle Free Manner!<br />

To us, I.T. = Business Growth.<br />

To understand how we can help your business grow E-MAIL TO<br />

growth@planmantechnologies.com<br />

www.planmanconsulting.com<br />

www.planmantechnologies.com<br />

O UTREACH • OUTPERFORM • OUTSHINE


Anu Singh,<br />

Professor of Economics, Alliance<br />

Business Academy, Bangalore<br />

Market Economy And <strong>The</strong> State Of Regional<br />

Disparities In India<br />

"By definition, a government<br />

has no conscience. Sometimes<br />

it has a policy, but<br />

nothing more."<br />

-Albert Camus<br />

Economic and social regional<br />

disparities in India among different<br />

segments of the society<br />

have been the major force behind adopting<br />

planning process in India. With the<br />

establishment of planning commission<br />

in March 1950, India launched the process<br />

of state led ‘growth with social justice’<br />

its prime concern of over all development<br />

of India and of all its states. <strong>The</strong><br />

first three decades of planned development<br />

involves massive investments in<br />

backward regions, moreover various<br />

public policies encouraged private investments<br />

in regions which are not very<br />

economically sound. Capital and other<br />

subsidies were seen as the best way of<br />

addressing regional imbalance through<br />

capital formation as well as income and<br />

employment generation. It’s considered<br />

to be the responsibility of the government,<br />

in promoting balanced development<br />

in which all states should get opportunity<br />

to develop evenly through<br />

direct investment in public sector units.<br />

In spite of these commendable efforts<br />

and policy interventions, considerable<br />

level of regional disparities remained at<br />

the end of the Seventies. <strong>The</strong> accelerated<br />

economic growth since the early<br />

Eighties appears to have aggravated regional<br />

disparities. In 1991 after the balance<br />

of payment crises Indian government<br />

followed the policy regime of<br />

Liberalization, Privatization and Globalization<br />

(LPG), which resulted in a<br />

tremendous increase in GDP and per<br />

capita Income. India today is the fourth<br />

largest economy, in the world in Purchasing<br />

Power Parity (PPP) dollars, after<br />

the US, China and Japan, and has<br />

the third largest GDP in the entire continent<br />

of Asia. It is also the second largest<br />

among emerging nations. India is<br />

also one of the select three markets in<br />

the world which proffers high prospects<br />

for growth and earning potential in<br />

practically all areas of business. <strong>The</strong> reforms<br />

generated results are quite commendable<br />

at all India level and demonstrated<br />

very great picture of our nation.<br />

But the question is whether these<br />

62 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

achievements like increase in GDP, per<br />

capita income, foreign direct investment<br />

and foreign exchange reserves are sufficient<br />

conditions for the over all development<br />

of the nation and its nationals.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se on-going economic reforms with<br />

stabilization and deregulation policies<br />

as their central pieces seem to have further<br />

widened the regional disparities.<br />

<strong>The</strong> impact of globalization and privatization<br />

is not uniform across economies<br />

and also across different sections of the<br />

population within an economy. Market<br />

economy is not meant for the equal distribution<br />

of wealth, it is an uneven process<br />

with unequal distribution of benefits<br />

and losses, both across the countries and<br />

within a country across different income<br />

groups: the rich get richer and everyone<br />

else gets poorer, many absolutely and<br />

the rest in relation to the rapidly growing<br />

wealth of the rich. It has distorted<br />

investment priorities, for wealth gets directed<br />

into areas wherein it will earn the<br />

largest profit and not into spaces that<br />

most people really need (accordingly,<br />

public health, education and other basic<br />

social services receive little attention).<br />

II. Analyzing Growth Across<br />

Select Indian States<br />

Economic reforms among other things,<br />

implied that private sector would be the<br />

principal engine of economic growth.<br />

Most of the restrictions on private investment<br />

have been removed. Mounting<br />

debt burden of the government has imposed<br />

a cap on public investment. As a<br />

result, while there was significant increase<br />

in the quantum of private investment,<br />

there was a sharp fall in the public<br />

investment over the last decade. This<br />

has created even more imbalance among<br />

different states throughout India.<br />

For studying the effects of LPG on<br />

regional growth and regional imbalances<br />

among different states we have<br />

taken indicators which have direct<br />

bearing on social and economic development<br />

of the nation or region. <strong>The</strong><br />

scope of our analysis in this article is<br />

restricted to a comparative analysis of<br />

the eight major States in respect to few<br />

key parameters which have an intrinsic<br />

bearing on social, human and economic<br />

development. For the purpose of this<br />

article, we have divided these states<br />

into two groups; forward and backward.<br />

Forward states category consists<br />

of Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka Maharashtra,<br />

and Tamil Nadu, the backward<br />

states group comprises of Bihar, Madhya<br />

Pradesh, Orissa, Rajasthan and<br />

Uttar Pradesh. <strong>The</strong> parameters taken<br />

to analyze the situation are per capita<br />

income, percentage share of poor and<br />

per capita consumption expenditure.<br />

In order to analyze the nature of the<br />

private players or the market mechanism<br />

we have collected cumulative figures of<br />

total cases of foreign direct investments<br />

done in these states. <strong>The</strong> most important<br />

indicator of the economic development<br />

of a society is the Per-capita Annual Income<br />

(PCI) generated by it. PCI is an<br />

indicator of the level of economic development<br />

and it measures the inequality<br />

in the income distribution among different<br />

regions. Per capita Gross State Domestic<br />

Product (GSDP) as a percentage<br />

of per capita GDP of the country for forward<br />

and backward group of States are<br />

presented in the Table-1. It shows the<br />

growth in per capita incomes of the two<br />

groups of States over the last two and<br />

half decades, especially from 1991. All<br />

the States in the forward group, have<br />

improved their relative position over the<br />

last two and half decades. One important<br />

point is worth mentioning is that the<br />

Per capita incomes of the three states in<br />

the forward group category except Maharashtra<br />

were below the national aver-<br />

Table 1: Per-capita GSDP As A Percentage Of GDP<br />

States 1981-82 1990-91 1999-2000 2005-2006<br />

Forward Group<br />

Andhra Pradesh 87.4 92.5 97.9 101.9<br />

Karnataka 92.8 95.4 105.8 106.1<br />

Maharashtra 143 144.7 147.4 144.2<br />

Tamil Nadu 92.8 100 122.3 116.5<br />

Backward Group<br />

Bihar 58.8 53.5 36.4 30.6<br />

Madhya Pradesh 80.8 78.1 78.2 60.8<br />

Orissa 75 66.9 66.7 NA<br />

Rajasthan 76.6 79.3 85.1 69.5<br />

Uttar Pradesh 75.8 70.6 59.4 51.6<br />

All India 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: http://mospi.nic.in/<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

63


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

age in the eighties, but by the year 2005,<br />

all have gone above the national average.<br />

This is basically due to the increasing<br />

share of private investment in these<br />

states and in stark contrast, states in the<br />

backward group experienced relative<br />

deterioration in terms of per capita income<br />

and this specific deterioration was<br />

more marked after the reforms. Table-1<br />

also shows the degree of disparity in per<br />

capita income among these states,<br />

wherein Bihar and Uttar Pradesh have<br />

the greatest degree of disparity, in comparison<br />

to the forward states. <strong>The</strong> differences<br />

in per capita income between<br />

forward and backward states were minimum<br />

in 1980-81 and maximum in<br />

2005-2006.<br />

Percentage Of Poor<br />

<strong>The</strong> percentage of poverty is worth to<br />

discuss while analyzing regional disparities<br />

in India. <strong>The</strong> overall percentage of<br />

poverty has decreased from 51.3 percent<br />

in 1977-78 to 38.9 in 1987-88 and reached<br />

to the level of 36.0% in 1993-94. Now in<br />

2004-05 fewer Indians were living in<br />

poverty than in 1999-2000, with official<br />

data showing poverty declined by 4.3 per<br />

cent during this period. Poverty in India<br />

has declined to 21.8 per cent in 2004-05<br />

from 26.1 per cent in 1999-2000.While<br />

there has been great progress in reducing<br />

poverty, it has been far from even,<br />

and these data masks large regional differences.<br />

Based on NSS data, Orissa was<br />

the poorest state with 39.9 per cent of<br />

people living below poverty line followed<br />

by Jharkhand (34.8 per cent) and Bihar<br />

(32.5 per cent). Poverty levels were low<br />

in Chandigarh (3.8 per cent people living<br />

below poverty line), Jammu and<br />

Kashmir (4.2 per cent) and Punjab<br />

(5.2 percent).<br />

Among the other major states, percentage<br />

of people living below poverty<br />

line was 15 per cent in Assam, 12.5 per<br />

cent in Gujarat, 9.9 per cent in Haryana,<br />

17.4 per cent in Karnataka, 11.4 per cent<br />

in Kerala, 32.4 per cent in Madhya<br />

Pradesh, 17.5 per cent in Rajasthan, 17.8<br />

per cent in Tamil Nadu and 20.6 per cent<br />

in West Bengal. National trends in poverty<br />

reduction have been dominated by<br />

rapid growth in Forward states only<br />

other regions have seen little or no<br />

change. This is clearly presented in Table-2<br />

which is showing the<br />

percentage of poverty share<br />

among different states of<br />

India. <strong>The</strong> main beneficiaries<br />

of the overall decline in<br />

poverty in the country have<br />

been the fast growing States<br />

in the forward group. In<br />

contrast, the share of the poor in the<br />

States in the backward group has gone<br />

up significantly. As the table indicates,<br />

Table-2 Percentage Share Of Poor<br />

each one of the States in this group has<br />

now increasing share of poor from 1980s<br />

to 2000. <strong>The</strong>se show that economic<br />

growth of forward states is more than<br />

the backward states due to market<br />

mechanism.<br />

Average Monthly Per-capita<br />

Consumption Expenditure<br />

After 15 years of reforms Average<br />

Monthly Per Capita consumption Expenditure<br />

among different states is still<br />

showing wide disparities. For the forward<br />

states, it seems the formula of more<br />

market and less government<br />

is working well, but<br />

for poor states it is working<br />

in opposite direction,<br />

where government gives<br />

incentives to establish industries<br />

in these backward<br />

states, industrialist are<br />

only interested in profit maximization.<br />

All the states in the forward categories<br />

have PCCE more than Rs.1000, whereas<br />

States 1983-84 1987-88 1993-94 1999-2000<br />

Forward Group<br />

Andhra Pradesh 5.1 5.22 4.81 4.57<br />

Karnataka 4.64 5.17 4.88 4.01<br />

Maharashtra 9.01 9.65 9.53 8.76<br />

Tamil Nadu 8.05 7.53 6.31 5.01<br />

Backward Group<br />

Bihar 14.31 13.71 15.4 16.36<br />

Madhya Pradesh 8.61 8.61 9.32 11.47<br />

Orissa 5.62 5.4 5.01 6.5<br />

Rajasthan 3.93 4.65 4.01 3.14<br />

Uttar Pradesh 17.24 17.47 18.87 20.36<br />

All India 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: Planning Commission, Government of India.<br />

64 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

all the states in backward categories are<br />

having PCCE which is less than Rs.1000.<br />

<strong>The</strong> lowest among them is Bihar with<br />

only Rs.696.27 and highest PCCE is<br />

earned in Uttar Pradesh (Rs.964.02). In<br />

comparison to backward states, the lowest<br />

PCCE stands at Rs.1018.55 and highest<br />

at Rs.1148.27 (Maharashtra).<br />

Total Cases Of Foreign Direct<br />

Investment<br />

FDI influences growth by increasing total<br />

factor productivity and, more generally,<br />

the efficiency of resource use in the<br />

recipient economy. Technology transfers<br />

through FDI generate positive externalities<br />

in the host country. FDI contributes<br />

to export growth, productivity<br />

growth and finance for balance of payments;<br />

it supports increase in national<br />

income. FDI increases employment and<br />

contributes to economic growth. FDI<br />

has increased manifold over the past two<br />

decades. FDI brings private overseas<br />

funds into the country for investments.<br />

Under the new Industrial Policy Resolution<br />

the industrial policy reforms have<br />

substantially reduced the industrial licensing<br />

requirements, removed restrictions<br />

on expansion and facilitated easy<br />

access to foreign technology and foreign<br />

direct investment. Foreign Direct Investment<br />

in India is allowed on automatic<br />

route in almost all sectors. Table-<br />

3 will help us in explaining the much<br />

widening of regional imbalance<br />

throughout India. As it is evident from<br />

the table, the cumulative numbers of<br />

FDI cases are lowest in the state of Bihar(27),<br />

followed by Orissa (91) and<br />

highest in the state of Maharashtra with<br />

3743 and seconded only by Karnataka,<br />

with 2147 cases. That means the total<br />

Table-3 Total Cases Of FDI In Select States Of India<br />

Total Cases of FDI<br />

States Aug 1991-<strong>Dec</strong> 2004<br />

Forward Group Number Investment in Rs Cr<br />

Andhra Pradesh 1026 11634.44<br />

Karnataka 2147 19096.39<br />

Maharashtra 3743 37107.79<br />

Tamil Nadu 2066 22651.29<br />

Total FG 90489.91<br />

Backward Group<br />

Bihar 27 739.71<br />

Madhya Pradesh 170 9271<br />

Orissa 91 8229.31<br />

Rajasthan 241 2911.21<br />

Uttar Pradesh 536 4836.56<br />

Total BG 25987.79<br />

Source: http://eaindustry.nic.in/handbk0305/chap143.pdf<br />

gap between the highest and the lowest regions of the country. This has enabled<br />

is almost 3716 cases and this depicts the the developed regions to achieve accelerated<br />

economic growth during the<br />

clear case of wide regional inequalities.<br />

Again, the total investment in aforementioned<br />

backward states is only 28.7% of which were unable to attract any signifi-<br />

1990s. Backward regions of the country,<br />

the forward states. Ever since reforms cant private, experienced decelerated<br />

started, a great majority of FDI is directed<br />

only into select states which al-<br />

<strong>The</strong> issue of regional balance has been<br />

economic growth during this period.<br />

ready had good standard of living. <strong>The</strong> an integral component of almost every<br />

flow of private investment, both domestic<br />

and foreign, has been extremely bining<br />

and a strategy of State-led industri-<br />

Five Year Plan. <strong>The</strong> adoption of planased<br />

in favour of the more developed alization, with Plans and policies designed<br />

to facilitate more investments in<br />

the relatively backward areas were intended<br />

to lead to a more balanced<br />

growth in the country. It was expected<br />

that, over time, inter-state disparities<br />

would be minimized. An analysis of<br />

these trends, especially the more recent<br />

trends (after 1991), leads to the inevitable<br />

inference that, regional disparities<br />

still persist and in some indicators it has<br />

widened more especially after reform<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

65


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

period. Also, there are others parameters<br />

like number of bank branches<br />

and credit deposit ratio which are showing<br />

the same trend of accentuating<br />

inequality.<br />

Policy Payoffs!<br />

Thus, it is clear from the above discussion<br />

that mere free market forces and<br />

mechanisms will not help in improving<br />

the overall condition of Indian economy.<br />

Government has to work side by side and<br />

even equally with the private sector, in<br />

addition to the policy incentives aimed<br />

at private bodies for attracting the requisite<br />

investments in backward regions.<br />

But as reflected in the data, they did not<br />

work properly because of other reasons<br />

like poor social capital and weak economic<br />

conditions in backward states.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is, arguably, a greater need for<br />

higher levels of investment in social<br />

services and infrastructure, specifically<br />

in relatively backward states as compared<br />

to the more developed counterparts.<br />

<strong>The</strong> state governments of the<br />

backward regions tend to be fiscally<br />

weaker and are therefore unable to find<br />

enough resources to meet the huge investment<br />

requirements needed to catch<br />

up. <strong>The</strong>refore, if possible government<br />

should concentrate in developing backward<br />

regions and let private bodies concentrate<br />

on forward states and areas. In<br />

addition to this macro policy approach,<br />

there are several other direct and indirect<br />

measures which the state can think<br />

over. It will require Herculean tasks on<br />

the part of the Centre and the leadership<br />

in the concerned regions to ensure that<br />

the gap does not widen further.<br />

In order to reap the maximum benefits<br />

from FDI, there is a need to establish a<br />

transparent, broad and effective enabling<br />

policy environment for investment<br />

and to direct these capital flows into the<br />

areas where it is required most.<br />

References<br />

• http://planningcommission.nic.in/<br />

midterm/english-pdf/chapter-18.<br />

pdf<br />

• http://rbidocs.rbi.org.in/rdocs/Publications/PDFs/81450.pdf<br />

• http://www.iht.com/articles/<strong>2007</strong>/04/19/news/fdi.php<br />

• http://www.mospi.nic.in/mospi_<br />

nsso_rept_pubn.htm<br />

• http://www.nyu.edu/projects/ollman/docs/china_speech2_content.<br />

php<br />

• http://www.rba.gov.au/PublicationsAndResearch/Conferences/2002/<br />

kishore.pdf<br />

• http://www.rediff.com/money/<strong>2007</strong>/mar/21poor.htm<br />

Our Weapons of Mass Instruction<br />

66 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE GREAT INDIAN DREAM<br />

“Many ideas grow better when transplanted into another<br />

mind than in the one where they sprang up.”<br />

-Oliver Wendell Holmes<br />

When Great Indian Dream got released in August 2003, it created<br />

scores of academic debates and ideological dissent among<br />

many leaders. After inquiring into fallacies in national economic<br />

planning, specifically resource mobilisation strategies, it proffers<br />

an alternate plan, reconciling key social developmental imperatives,<br />

economic challenges and political constraints. <strong>The</strong> futuristic<br />

and unconventional economic wisdom inherent in it has been<br />

gaining a lot of acceptance and appreciation from many thought<br />

leaders in all walks of life. Accrediting their three decade old research<br />

at <strong>IIPM</strong>, the authors’ talk of potential growth rates over<br />

14%, since then. <strong>The</strong>ir observations were disregarded. But nowadays,<br />

every national and international think-tank, including the PM<br />

talks about a 10%. <strong>The</strong> Election Commission took a leaf out of<br />

this book and ordered enquiry into the rigging process in West<br />

Bengal. Many politicians were defamed and intelligentsia was<br />

provoked. Veteran lawyer, Ram Jethmalani used it for his campaigns<br />

in opposition to Atal Bihari Vajpayee. As on <strong>Dec</strong>ember<br />

2005, the tax component is almost 55 per cent in petrol and for<br />

diesel, the tax component in the price is almost 34 per cent, in line<br />

with the resource mobilisation strategies of the authors. It is indeed<br />

very assuring to find that in the last two years as it hit book stands,<br />

tolerant of a few minor deviations, the compelling socioecononomic<br />

recommendations mentioned in it remain convincingly<br />

well-founded. <strong>The</strong> ideology integral to this book has turned<br />

into a movement called ‘GID Foundation’ (GIDF), stirring a social<br />

revolution, as it supports developmental initiatives in more than<br />

2000 villages across 12 states and supporting an estimated 25,<br />

00,000 people residing primarily in the remote/backward areas.<br />

Effectual ideas relating to all social sectors are featured in the<br />

book are being executed to restore pride to the ‘betrayed India’.<br />

Reminds one about Sigmund Freud’s associable observation:<br />

‘Thought is action in rehearsal’.


Anindo Banerjee,<br />

Head, Programme Initiatives, Praxis -<br />

Institute for Participatory Practices,<br />

Patna<br />

Accountable Governance And Pro-poor Markets<br />

For Effective Poverty Reduction<br />

"Adam Smith, the father of modern economics,<br />

is often cited as arguing for the “invisible hand”<br />

and free markets: fi rms, in the pursuit of profi ts,<br />

are led, as if by an invisible hand, to do what is<br />

best for the world. But unlike his followers, Adam<br />

Smith was aware of some of the limitations of<br />

free markets, and research since then has further<br />

clarifi ed why free markets, by themselves, often<br />

do not lead to what is best. As I put it in my<br />

new book, Making Globalization Work, the<br />

reason that the invisible hand often seems invisible<br />

is that it is often not there."<br />

ALTMAN Daniel, Managing Globalization.<br />

In: Q & A with Joseph E. Stiglitz,<br />

Columbia University and <strong>The</strong> International<br />

Herald Tribune (IHT),<br />

October 11, 2006<br />

In the month of October, when<br />

over twenty five thousand landless<br />

agricultural labourers hailing<br />

from various dalit 1 and tribal communities<br />

of India marched to New Delhi<br />

to press for their land rights and succeeded<br />

in securing a vital policy decision<br />

towards constitution of a highpowered<br />

‘National Land Reforms<br />

Council’ headed by the Prime Minister,<br />

they heralded a historic assertion<br />

against increasing market-led appropriation<br />

of vital resources like land,<br />

water, mines and forests. Given that<br />

the last two decades have witnessed<br />

countless instances of dispossession of<br />

the poor in developing economies<br />

from critical life-support systems,<br />

mostly at the behest of market-forces<br />

actively aided by agencies of the State,<br />

the issues concerning the role and obligations<br />

of market forces and agencies<br />

of the State towards poverty reduction<br />

need to be examined cautiously, with<br />

an eye on the impacts of contemporary<br />

trends and policies on the well-being<br />

of poor communities.<br />

Markets And <strong>The</strong> Poor<br />

<strong>The</strong> experiences of several African<br />

governments during the eighties and<br />

the nineties relating to policies aimed<br />

at overcoming acute fiscal imbalances<br />

are a good pointer to the potential impact<br />

of ungoverned market forces on<br />

critical sectors such as agriculture.<br />

Measures administered to this effect<br />

on the advice of international financial<br />

institutions like the World Bank included<br />

withdrawal of the public sector<br />

from sectors like agriculture, de-control<br />

of prices, reduction of farm subsidies<br />

and increased privatization. <strong>The</strong><br />

outcomes were equally radical: the<br />

drastic steps immediately affected<br />

over seventy percent of the poor in the<br />

region by drastically suppressing food<br />

production. A recently concluded evaluation<br />

2 of World Bank’s role in African<br />

agriculture attributed the crisis to the<br />

68 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

inability of market forces to step in<br />

and jump-start agricultural growth.<br />

According to Professor Jeffery Sachs<br />

of Columbia University, “<strong>The</strong> whole<br />

thing was based on the idea that if you<br />

take away the government for the poorest<br />

of the poor, markets will somehow<br />

solve the problems, but markets can’t<br />

step in and won’t step in when people<br />

have nothing. And if you take away<br />

help, you leave them to die.” 3<br />

<strong>The</strong> example of sub-Saharan Africa<br />

clearly illustrates the criticality of the<br />

role of a pro-poor ‘welfare state’ in<br />

safeguarding the survival needs of the<br />

poorest of the poor, who do not offer<br />

any investment incentives to profitseeking<br />

market forces.<br />

According to the United Nations-<br />

Millennium Development Goals<br />

(MDGs) report of <strong>2007</strong>, the share of<br />

the poorest fifth of populations in developing<br />

regions in national consumption<br />

decreased from 4.6 to 3.9 percent<br />

between 1990 and 2004. Widening income<br />

inequality is of particular concern<br />

in Eastern Asia, where the share<br />

of consumption among the poorest<br />

people declined dramatically during<br />

this period. Inequality is the highest in<br />

Latin America, the Caribbean and in<br />

sub-Saharan Africa, where the poorest<br />

fifth of the people account for only<br />

about three percent of national income,<br />

despite increased involvement<br />

of market forces in local economies.<br />

Internationally, 46 countries of the<br />

world have become poorer today than<br />

they were in 1990, according to Human<br />

Development Report 2004.<br />

Nearly 1300 million people live in<br />

absolute poverty, earning less than one<br />

dollar a day, while about 3000 million<br />

people, more than a half of the world’s million people are officially registered<br />

population live on less than two dollars as unemployed, besides an additional<br />

a day. According to the International 700 million underemployed people.<br />

Labour Organization (ILO), over 120 Instances of poverty, which often are<br />

Growing Inequality In <strong>The</strong> World<br />

Share Of Poorest Quintile In National Consumption,<br />

1990 And 2004 (Percentage)<br />

Latin America & the Caribbean<br />

2.8<br />

2.7<br />

3.4<br />

1990<br />

3.4<br />

2004<br />

Eastern Asia<br />

7.1<br />

4.5<br />

Western Asia<br />

5.9<br />

5.4<br />

South-Eastern Asia<br />

6.2<br />

6.1<br />

CIS<br />

7.9<br />

6.2<br />

Northern Africa<br />

6.2<br />

6.3<br />

Southern Africa<br />

7.2<br />

6.7<br />

Transition Countries Of South-Eastern Europe<br />

8.3<br />

7.8<br />

Developing Regions<br />

4.6<br />

3.9<br />

0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0 6.0 7.0 8.0 9.0<br />

Source: UN MDG Report <strong>2007</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

69


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

a complex interplay of social, political<br />

and economic factors, can be addressed<br />

only by interventions that hit<br />

hard at the root causes of inequalities,<br />

rather than by the quirks of unregulated<br />

markets that by design are tailored<br />

to suit the conditions of the rich<br />

and the powerful. Given the enormous<br />

amounts of power, influence and resources<br />

that the latter tend to have at<br />

their disposal, often catalyzed by increasing<br />

overlap of political and business<br />

interests in most modern economies,<br />

the only chance for the poorest<br />

people rests on systems of governance<br />

that can be held to account and at least<br />

be subjected to a floor test of popularity<br />

based on electoral performance of<br />

alternative political ideologies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> message of the poorest people<br />

is loud and clear: governments must<br />

protect them from the vagaries of market!<br />

<strong>The</strong>ir verdict has been communicated<br />

clearly on many an occasion,<br />

evident in the electoral defeat of the<br />

‘India Shining’ campaign in India. <strong>The</strong><br />

resurrection of the ‘Aam Aadmi’ (i.e.<br />

the ‘common man’) as a reference<br />

point of current development policies,<br />

at least rhetorically, has been compelled<br />

by lessons learnt from many of<br />

these recent trends. Yet, the poorest of<br />

the poor in countries like India continue<br />

to face unprecedented challenges<br />

to their existence. <strong>The</strong> markets are<br />

pushing them hard to extinction, by<br />

encroaching upon some of their commonest<br />

avenues of survival, notably<br />

retail trade, artisan-crafts, common<br />

property resources and most alarmingly,<br />

agriculture.<br />

One needs to delve into the basic<br />

Food grain off-take through the PDS declined from 17<br />

million tonnes per year in the early nineties to 12 million<br />

tonnes per year around the end of the decade, endangering<br />

the food security of millions of the poor<br />

character and orientation of markets<br />

to assess their potential role in poverty<br />

reduction. Markets operate on the<br />

laws of supply and demand, and thereby<br />

play a role in fixation of prices and<br />

wages. <strong>The</strong>oretically speaking, the<br />

price of a product or service is directly<br />

proportional to the rarity of its supply,<br />

its quality, the cost of production, and<br />

inversely proportional to the bargaining<br />

power of the buyer and degree of<br />

regulation of unfair practices. For<br />

markets to be favourable entities for<br />

the poor (when participating in markets<br />

as sellers), the latter ought to be<br />

able to vie with competing forces towards<br />

suppressing the cost of production,<br />

acquiring greater market share to<br />

limit the range of suppliers and towards<br />

investing adequately in optimizing<br />

the quality of the product. Such<br />

possibilities are likely to be highly infeasible,<br />

given their limited economic<br />

abilities. Similarly, as buyers of products<br />

or users of services, their bargaining<br />

power is often limited on account<br />

of their limited ability to promise continuity<br />

as buyers or users, limited creditworthiness<br />

and lack of effective<br />

mechanisms to hold sellers/service<br />

providers accountable. Profit-seeking<br />

markets are more likely to serve clients<br />

that can offer greater economic returns<br />

to producers and therefore are<br />

likely to exclude the poor. <strong>The</strong> only<br />

ways to offset this fundamental likelihood<br />

of exclusion is to either regulate<br />

the markets in order that the poor are<br />

compulsorily served on pro bono terms<br />

as a principle of policy, or to create<br />

alternative providers that by mandate<br />

serve the poor. This necessitates a<br />

role for a pro-poor welfare state<br />

or non-profit organizations in<br />

serving the needs and interests of<br />

the poor.<br />

India was one of the fastest growing<br />

economies in the world during the<br />

nineties. <strong>The</strong> decade also witnessed an<br />

unprecedented scale of entry of market<br />

forces in various sectors of the<br />

economy. Yet, despite a significant<br />

spurt in macroeconomic growth, the<br />

rate of reduction of rural poverty in<br />

India was halted during the 1990s. Estimates<br />

show that the incidence of poverty,<br />

which between 1972-1973 and<br />

1989-1990 fell from 55.4 percent to<br />

34.3 percent in rural India, never went<br />

below the 1989-90 level in subsequent<br />

70 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

NSSO rounds undertaken up to 1997<br />

(Please refer to the diagram) iv . Though<br />

the rate of decline of rural poverty<br />

picked up again during the subsequent<br />

years (from 1999-2004), the rate of<br />

GDP growth was in fact less during<br />

this phase than during 1993–1999. <strong>The</strong><br />

average per-capita expenditure in rural<br />

areas was not even ten percent<br />

higher in 1999-2000 than in 1993-1994,<br />

and rural poverty actually went up in<br />

some of the poorer states, such as Assam<br />

and Orissa. Also, food grain offtake<br />

through the public distribution<br />

system declined from 17 million tonnes<br />

per year in the early nineties to 12 million<br />

tonnes per year around the end of<br />

the decade 5 , endangering the food security<br />

of millions of the poor in the<br />

country at the time when the GDP<br />

growth was unprecedented.<br />

<strong>The</strong> State vis-à-vis <strong>The</strong> Poor<br />

<strong>The</strong> Eleventh Five-Year Plan of India<br />

underscores the challenge of providing<br />

employment to 70 million additional<br />

people by 2011-12. It is also a well-established<br />

fact that the incidence of<br />

It is a well-established fact that the incidence of unemployment<br />

is substantially higher in the ‘below poverty line’<br />

category, and particularly high amongst the Scheduled<br />

Castes (SCs) and Scheduled Tribes(STs)<br />

unemployment is substantially higher<br />

in the ‘Below Poverty Line’ category,<br />

and particularly high amongst the<br />

scheduled castes and tribes therein (as<br />

indicated by successive National Sample<br />

Surveys). A critical question therefore<br />

is: what strategies and preparedness<br />

does the State have to meet this<br />

challenge, which is important to be addressed<br />

to prevent the nation’s slide<br />

into anarchy? Do markets provide a<br />

Trends In <strong>The</strong> Poverty Ratio (1972 - 1997)<br />

60<br />

55<br />

55.36<br />

Rural<br />

Urban<br />

50<br />

50.6<br />

45<br />

40<br />

35<br />

30<br />

45.67<br />

45.31<br />

40.5<br />

38.81<br />

35.65<br />

34.29<br />

39.23 39.06<br />

36.6<br />

34.3<br />

36.2<br />

33.4<br />

43.47<br />

36.43<br />

33.73<br />

32.76<br />

41.02<br />

36.66<br />

33.5<br />

30.51<br />

37.15<br />

35.78<br />

29.99<br />

25<br />

28.04<br />

Oct 72-Sep 73<br />

Jul 77- Jun 78<br />

Jan 83- <strong>Dec</strong> 83<br />

Jul 86-Jun 87<br />

Jul 87-Jun 88<br />

Jul 88-Jun 89<br />

Jul 89-Jun 90<br />

Jul 90-Jun 91<br />

Jan 92-<strong>Dec</strong> 92<br />

Jun 93-Jun 94<br />

Jul 94-Jun 95<br />

Jul 95-Jun 96<br />

Jan 97-<strong>Dec</strong> 97<br />

Percent Population<br />

(Source: "<strong>The</strong> Poverty Puzzle" by C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh, Macroscon, Feb. 22, 2000)<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

71


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

solution, or do they further endanger<br />

the chances of survival of the poor?<br />

Can democratic governments be allowed<br />

to forego their duties towards a<br />

majority of their trustees who vote<br />

them into power?<br />

Of late, various governments in India<br />

have been offering unprecedented<br />

incentives to the private sector with an<br />

eye on macro-economic growth. For<br />

instance, policies relating to establishment<br />

of Special Economic Zones<br />

(SEZs) include significant supports to<br />

private entrepreneurs in the form of<br />

facilitation of land acquisition, tax rebates<br />

and friendlier administrative<br />

mechanisms, amongst others. However,<br />

many of the provisions jeopardize<br />

the long-term interests of the poor in<br />

many ways and the much-touted objective<br />

of inclusive growth hasn’t come<br />

into effect. For instance, one of the<br />

largest Special Economic Zones in India<br />

proposed to be set up by Reliance<br />

Industries Limited in Maharashtra<br />

across three tehsils of Raigad district<br />

threatens to displace nearly 35,000<br />

farmers based over 25,000 hectares of<br />

agricultural land. <strong>The</strong> threat to the<br />

livelihoods of the farmers likely to lose<br />

ownership of land are sought to be offset<br />

merely by providing monetary compensation<br />

without any thoughts about<br />

the limited livelihood-choices available<br />

to them, consequent pressure on<br />

limited urban infrastructure, or the<br />

implications for a large number of nonowner<br />

dependents of farmland, e.g.<br />

sharecroppers or wage labourers.<br />

In similar developments across the<br />

country, as many as 396 SEZs have<br />

been accorded formal clearance by the<br />

government (by October <strong>2007</strong>), of<br />

which 149 have already been notified.<br />

When households displaced by SEZs<br />

or big projects migrate to cities, their<br />

survival becomes even more arduous,<br />

thanks to modern urban policies that<br />

increasingly shut out spaces from the<br />

reach of the poor. <strong>The</strong> commonest<br />

Markets, unless regulated with a pro-poor orientation, can<br />

eliminate the poor rather than contributing to poverty<br />

reduction, given the inherent tendencies of supply-side<br />

domination and profi t maximization<br />

coping avenues for the poor, e.g. participation<br />

in retail trade, accessing<br />

state-run basic services, or opting for<br />

low-investment livelihoods (e.g. rag<br />

picking or plying rickshaws) are made<br />

increasingly inaccessible by policies<br />

that allow entry of big business houses<br />

in retail trade, enhance the cost<br />

of basic services by allowing their<br />

privatization, or block public spaces<br />

for the poor.<br />

Another area of concern relates to<br />

increasing privatization of common<br />

property resources in the country,<br />

bearing life-threatening implications<br />

for a large number of poor communities.<br />

<strong>The</strong> operations of mining companies<br />

in various forest-rich areas of<br />

states like Chhattisgarh and Jharkhand<br />

have destroyed the age-old forestbased<br />

livelihoods of many tribal families.<br />

In Orissa, the state government<br />

has already committed several rivers<br />

and reservoirs for use by industry for<br />

water-intensive activities. In Chhattisgarh<br />

too, industries have been permitted<br />

to draw water from rivers like Kelo<br />

and Sheonath. Kelo, a tributary of Mahanadi<br />

river, happens to be an important<br />

source of livelihood for over sixty<br />

village communities settled alongside<br />

its 98 kilometer long stretch across<br />

Raigarh district of Chhattisgarh,<br />

whose lives have been badly affected<br />

due to severe decline in the stock of<br />

river water. During a People’s Tribunal<br />

held in Kolkata in January <strong>2007</strong>, Santwana<br />

Dey – an elderly woman hailing<br />

from a farmer household based in Bejiberia<br />

village of Singur where the<br />

Government of West Bengal acquired<br />

land for handing over to Tata Motors<br />

in lieu of promises of jobs in a car factory<br />

and offers of monetary compensation,<br />

raised a fundamental issue: ‘no<br />

one can dictate what should my family<br />

do for a living; we have a right to pursue<br />

occupations that we are capable of and<br />

cannot be forced to work in a car factory,<br />

which we have no inkling about!’<br />

Santwana’s straightforward assertion<br />

in the Tribunal underscored a legiti-<br />

72 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

mate contention of millions of marginalized<br />

citizens of the country – regarding<br />

their right to work, and<br />

particularly the right to avail of work<br />

of a suitable and gainful nature, in<br />

keeping with the directive of the constitution<br />

of India (Article 41; Directive<br />

Principles of State Policy) calling upon<br />

the State to make effective provisions,<br />

within the limits of its economic capacity<br />

and development, for securing<br />

the right to work. In a country where<br />

the rate of growth of the <strong>size</strong> of labour<br />

force exceeds the rate of growth of employment,<br />

and where over ninety percent<br />

of the workforce is employed in<br />

the unorganized sector, the challenge<br />

of creating gainful employment opportunities<br />

for a large segment of socially<br />

and economically disadvantaged citizens<br />

remains the greatest trial of relevance<br />

of our welfare state. <strong>The</strong> performance<br />

of the State with respect to<br />

its duties towards the poorest of the<br />

poor people might have been inadequate<br />

and often inefficient, but it has<br />

undoubtedly been critical. No other<br />

agency has the scale and depth of presence<br />

amongst the poor like agencies of<br />

the State. <strong>The</strong>re are important policies<br />

favouring affirmative action for the<br />

socially marginalized, employment<br />

guarantees, relief from disasters, decentralized<br />

governance, right to information,<br />

provisions against atrocities<br />

and social security benefits for especially-challenged<br />

people and affordable<br />

basic services. However, bureaucracies<br />

managing a State’s performance<br />

have often failed to administer the<br />

pro-poor provisions effectively and<br />

have eluded any kind of accountability<br />

to the people. In many states, they<br />

have also undermined the status and<br />

potential of Panchayati Raj institutions<br />

by assuming sweeping powers over decisions<br />

relating to local development.<br />

Holding functionaries of the State accountable<br />

is the greatest need of the<br />

hour, not reducing the role of<br />

the State.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Way Forward<br />

For poverty reduction to be effective<br />

and viable in the long run, the State<br />

needs to play a far more efficient and<br />

accountable role than it is today, without<br />

withdrawing itself from the obligation<br />

of poverty reduction. Markets can<br />

be made a supportive channel towards<br />

creation of more development opportunities<br />

for the people, through regulations<br />

that bring about a level playing<br />

field. A two-pronged strategy, where<br />

the State assumes full responsibility<br />

for efficient and accountable delivery<br />

of crucial basic services and entitlements,<br />

and also enables poor communities<br />

to effectively engage with markets<br />

can significantly contribute to the<br />

wellbeing of the poor. Facilitating<br />

meaningful participation of the poor<br />

in contemporary markets would call<br />

for support towards value addition and<br />

sale of economic products of the poor;<br />

storage of goods; establishment of efficient<br />

institutions for managing procurements,<br />

forward movements and<br />

linkages; price control and equitable<br />

incentives, amongst other things. Local<br />

institutions of governance need to<br />

be freed from the control of bureaucracy<br />

and capacitated to play an effective<br />

regulatory role towards safeguarding<br />

the strategic needs of the poor,<br />

based on principles of equity and<br />

social justice.<br />

Markets, unless regulated with a<br />

pro-poor orientation, can eliminate<br />

the poor rather than contributing to<br />

poverty reduction, given the inherent<br />

tendencies of supply-side domination<br />

and profit maximization. <strong>The</strong> poor<br />

have little say in the functioning of<br />

market forces, but have some stake and<br />

control in the governments they elect.<br />

<strong>The</strong> only way in which the poor can<br />

safeguard their interests in a market is<br />

by electing pro-poor governments that<br />

eliminate anti-poor market forces and<br />

regulate supplies of essential goods<br />

and services in order that they remain<br />

accessible and affordable to the poor.<br />

Good governance is the right of every<br />

citizen, and ensuring the same through<br />

effective mechanisms of accountability<br />

of government functionaries is the<br />

greatest need of the hour.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

‘Dalit’ literally means ‘oppressed’<br />

and refers to socially marginalized<br />

communities living in India.<br />

2<br />

Evaluation undertaken by <strong>The</strong> Independent<br />

Evaluation Group of the<br />

World Bank, titled “Assessment<br />

of the Bank’s assistance to agricultural<br />

development in Sub-Saharan<br />

Africa during FY 1991-06”<br />

3<br />

Ref. report titled ‘World Bank Neglects<br />

African Farming, Study Says’,<br />

published in the New York<br />

Times, October 15 <strong>2007</strong><br />

4<br />

Ref. ‘<strong>The</strong> Poverty Puzzle’ by C.P.<br />

Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh,<br />

Macroscan, February 22, 2000<br />

5<br />

Ref. ‘Hunger amidst Plenty’ by Jean<br />

Drèze, India Together, <strong>Dec</strong>ember 3,<br />

<strong>2007</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

73


Anjani Sinha<br />

Managing Director & CEO,<br />

National Spot Exchange Limited,<br />

Mumbai<br />

Food Security In India:<br />

<strong>Issue</strong>s And Implications<br />

"annam na nindyat. tadvratam."<br />

(Do not look down upon anna. That is<br />

the inviolable discipline of life for the one<br />

who knows.)<br />

"annam na paricaksita. tadvratam."<br />

(Do not neglect anna. That is the<br />

inviolable discipline of life for the one<br />

who knows.)<br />

"annam bahu kurvita. tadvratam."<br />

(Multiply anna many-fold. Ensure an<br />

abundance of food all around. That is the<br />

inviolable discipline of life for the one<br />

who knows.)<br />

-<strong>The</strong> Taittiriyopanisad<br />

1. Concept<br />

Food Security refers to the scenario in<br />

which every citizen of the country has access<br />

to sufficient and affordable good<br />

quality food. <strong>The</strong> concept has evolved<br />

during the last three decades to include<br />

not only food availability, but also economic<br />

access to food and biological absorption<br />

of food in the body. It is considered<br />

in terms of availability of foods, its<br />

quality, its accessibility and affordability<br />

for general mass. Thus we can say that<br />

there are four pillars of food secu<br />

rity - Availability, Affordability, Accessi<br />

bility and Quality of food in terms of<br />

balanced diet.<br />

2. Objectives And Focus<br />

2.1 India’s food security policy has a<br />

laudable objective to ensure availability<br />

of food grains to common mass at an affordable<br />

price. It has enabled the poor to<br />

have access to food where none existed.<br />

When India got Independence, the then<br />

Prime Minister Late Sri Jawaharlal Nehru<br />

said, “Everything else can wait but<br />

not agriculture.”<br />

2.2 Historically, India’s food security<br />

policy has focused essentially on growth<br />

in agriculture production, fixing minimum<br />

support price for procurement and maintaining<br />

buffer stocks of rice and wheat to<br />

ensure food security.<br />

3. Concerns<br />

3.1 As a matter of fact, concern on<br />

food security has always haunted the<br />

scholars and policy makers right from<br />

Malthusian <strong>The</strong>ory way back in eighteenth<br />

century. This is mainly because of limited<br />

and declining natural resources and ever<br />

increasing population.<br />

3.2 Recently, Government of India<br />

has taken a policy decision to allocate Rs.<br />

48.82 billion for National Food Security<br />

Mission (NFSM). <strong>The</strong> primary objective<br />

is to raise the production of rice, wheat<br />

and pulses during the 11 th Five-Year Plan<br />

period (<strong>2007</strong>-12) and ensure food security<br />

in the country. Assuming requirement of<br />

175 kg cereals and 11 kg of pulses per<br />

capita per annum, India needs 265 million<br />

74 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Per-capita Per Day Availability Of Foodgrains<br />

In India Since 1971<br />

Period Cereals Pulses Food Grains<br />

1971-1975 393 44 437<br />

1981-1985 417 39 456<br />

1991-1995 445 37 482<br />

2001-2005 414 32 446<br />

Projected Growth Rate And Demand For<br />

Various Food Commodities Towards 2011-12<br />

Food Item<br />

Projected<br />

Growth<br />

Rate (%)<br />

tons of cereals production and 17 million<br />

tons of pulses production by the end of<br />

2050. Achieving this level of production is<br />

not a big task as India currently produces<br />

around 210 million tons of food grains.<br />

But, it needs a serious planning and<br />

effective implementation.<br />

3.3 Adequate per capita availability of<br />

food is a function of food production on<br />

one hand, and growth in population and<br />

purchasing power, on the other. Nature of<br />

food security varies across population categories<br />

and geography. Food production<br />

is the result of interaction of human being’s<br />

crop production technique and management<br />

of the natural resources such as<br />

Demand:<br />

Million<br />

Tonnes<br />

Food grains 2.21 251.7<br />

Milk and milk products 3.18 100.39<br />

Meat 4.65 5.36<br />

Eggs: Billion 4.62 35.77<br />

Fish 4.58 5.91<br />

Oilseeds 2.94 49.2#<br />

Vegetables 2.51 92.93<br />

Fresh Fruits 3.46 29.43<br />

Sugar and gur 1.88 22.49<br />

# Assume 40% dependence on import for edible oil<br />

Source: NACP–ICAR In House Estimates<br />

Note: Projected demand includes export in the same ratio as n the base scenario<br />

2003-04 for foodgrains and in 2004-05 for others.<br />

land, water, weather and climatic<br />

condition. <strong>The</strong> guiding<br />

principle should be optimal<br />

utilization of scarce<br />

resources. Thus it is important<br />

to know the natural<br />

Resources, understand the<br />

level of technology utilization,<br />

and understand effect<br />

of modern production technology<br />

on the natural resources,<br />

limitation of total<br />

efforts towards production<br />

increase and understanding<br />

of the scope of overall utilization<br />

of scientific knowledge<br />

in our present agriculture.<br />

It is also important<br />

that natural resources<br />

should continue to be available<br />

without deterioration<br />

over a long period of time.<br />

3.4 <strong>The</strong> natural resources,<br />

which we have, are limited<br />

especially land and<br />

water. Fertility of land is<br />

declining. Soil health has<br />

been declining because of excessive usage<br />

of fertilizer and pesticide. Organic contents<br />

and microenvironment of the soil has<br />

undergone noticeable changes impacting<br />

productivity. <strong>The</strong>re is change in weather<br />

pattern and climatic condition. Frequency<br />

of erratic rain, floods and droughts has<br />

increased considerably.<br />

3.5 Level of technology utilization in<br />

Indian agriculture is highly uneven and<br />

biased to certain pockets of the county.<br />

Green revolution helped India to transform<br />

itself from food deficit to food surplus<br />

country. But unfortunately, green<br />

Revolution has not percolated across all<br />

the states. Application of modern production<br />

techniques is still limited to some<br />

pockets, like the states of Punjab and<br />

Haryana. High variation in production<br />

and productivity in different states is the<br />

result of varying level of technology integration<br />

in our agriculture production.<br />

3.6 <strong>The</strong> long term sustainability of<br />

agriculture and consistent growth in production<br />

and productivity matching with<br />

population growth is a big question mark.<br />

It has been noticed that in various parts of<br />

Punjab and Haryana, water level has gone<br />

down to such levels that water extraction<br />

has become economically unviable. Nitrogen<br />

contents of water has increased, there<br />

is presence of pesticides residue in drinking<br />

water. Heavy and unscientific method<br />

of fertilizer application has taken a toll on<br />

the soil quality. <strong>The</strong>re is adverse impact on<br />

the local microclimate because of intensive<br />

agriculture and similar crop cycle over<br />

a long period of time. Higher contents of<br />

fertilizer and pesticides in ground water<br />

not only affect productivity, but it also severely<br />

affects the food quality. Situation<br />

Food production is the result of interaction of human being’s<br />

crop production technique and management of the<br />

natural resources. <strong>The</strong> guiding principle must be<br />

optimal utilization of scarce resources<br />

demands to take corrective as well as preventive<br />

actions to maintain agriculture<br />

growth sustainable in the long run.<br />

3.7 In India average per capita land<br />

holding is less than 0.16 hectare. Average<br />

farm holding with farmers is 1.6 acre. Now<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

75


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

let us take the case of a typical farmer. His<br />

crop production decision is guided by his<br />

immediate needs. <strong>The</strong> decisions of seeds<br />

selection, fertilizer, pesticides etc are<br />

based on his own feeling or fellow farmers’<br />

advice that may be scientific or unscientific.<br />

Crop cycle is decided not on the basis<br />

of scientific procedure but the personal<br />

requirements of the farmer. Hence, the<br />

concern is how to transform sustenance<br />

agriculture into agri-business.<br />

4. Strategy To Combat<br />

<strong>The</strong> Concerns<br />

4.1 Though the Government and<br />

different agencies have done commendable<br />

job to transform India from food<br />

starved to food surplus nation, still due<br />

to lack of effective extension services,<br />

the impact in a number of States has<br />

been less than desirable levels. <strong>The</strong><br />

States of UP, Bihar and West Bengal<br />

cities, service industry has penetrated in<br />

our day to day life in such a manner, that<br />

we are dependent upon one or the other<br />

service provider for our daily needs. Examples<br />

are newspaper vendor, milk supplier,<br />

etc. without whom the daily routine<br />

does not start in cities. But, in agriculture,<br />

it is not so. A farmer does sowing, irrigation,<br />

pesticide treatment, harvesting and<br />

marketing of produce – all activities himself.<br />

He knows agriculture very well, but<br />

his knowledge is confined to old techniques.<br />

He does not get any professional<br />

training to use modern techniques. In<br />

most cases, he is dependent upon the vendor<br />

only for advisory services also. For<br />

example, he asks the pesticide vendor how<br />

much quantity of pesticide he should use<br />

to treat his farms. <strong>The</strong>re are cases where<br />

only one liter of pesticide is sufficient, if<br />

properly applied, but, the pesticide vendor<br />

sells a 5 liters container advising him to<br />

Crop cycle is decided not on the basis of scientifi c procedure<br />

but the personal requirements of the farmer.<br />

Hence, the concern is how to transform sustenance<br />

agriculture into agri-business<br />

have very fertile land, but productivity is<br />

lower than the national average. Here<br />

lies the potential to be tapped. Major<br />

constraints in these areas are limited use<br />

of modern agriculture production technique<br />

by farmers in absence of effective<br />

extension activities. <strong>The</strong> productivity of<br />

rice and wheat grown in these areas is<br />

quite low. Hence, by focusing on these<br />

states, we can achieve remarkable success<br />

in ensuring food security.<br />

4.2 Another strategy to ensure food<br />

security is launching of professional commercial<br />

services at village levels to provide<br />

various agri solutions to the farmers. In<br />

apply the same frequently, because the<br />

main interest of the vendor could be to sell<br />

pesticide. If there is a service agency locally<br />

available, which is run by a qualified<br />

agriculture graduate, and he provides an<br />

end to end solution for pesticide treatment<br />

at a fee, the farmer may save money because<br />

of reduction in input cost, yield may<br />

improve because of non application of excessive<br />

pesticide and still the agriculture<br />

graduate can run the service unit in a profitable<br />

manner. We can apply this theory<br />

for all activities associated with agriculture-sowing,<br />

harvesting, processing and<br />

so on. A well qualified professional having<br />

expertise in mangoes can provide excellent<br />

services in mango growing area about<br />

plucking of mangoes scientifically, identifying<br />

such mangoes which are totally matured.<br />

This will give confidence to the<br />

marginal farmer that he himself is the<br />

owner of his land, he himself is in possession<br />

of his land, though he is a marginal<br />

farmer who otherwise cannot buy new machines<br />

and agricultural equipments as it is<br />

not viable for marginal holding, still he can<br />

avail all the modern facilities at his doorstep.<br />

Hence, the second mantra for ensuring<br />

food security in Indian context, considering<br />

the fragmented holding and<br />

marginal farmers, is organizing extensive<br />

application of professional but commercial<br />

services at farm level in the form of either<br />

independent small ventures run by agriculture<br />

graduates or by big corporate<br />

launching such service on a large scale.<br />

4.3 Nature has bestowed us with<br />

enough resources. <strong>The</strong> Ganges belt is so<br />

fertile that it can feed wheat to the entire<br />

world, if it is utilized properly. Similarly,<br />

soil in other area is most ideal for cotton<br />

production. In order to ensure comprehensive<br />

and sustained growth, what is important<br />

is to have a national level unbiased<br />

scientific crop planning, based on agro<br />

climatic conditions, soil type, soil condition,<br />

method of available irrigation, potential<br />

of irrigation, infrastructure requirement,<br />

existence of infrastructure,<br />

suitability of various crops to be grown in<br />

that area, seed variety selection, fertilizer<br />

dosage determination, application of pesticides<br />

and plant nutrient, crop monitoring,<br />

scientific method of problem identification<br />

and suitable solution, food habits in<br />

the area. India is divided in 15-agro climatic<br />

zones. Each zone has got its own<br />

potential and limitation. Crop production<br />

76 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

planning based on the resources availability<br />

in these zones is required to be done to<br />

use the resources judiciously. Planning<br />

should be based on scientific study coupled<br />

with commercial planning, with farmers’<br />

interest in mind. If his land is suitable<br />

for a specific cash crop, which will give<br />

him better return on investment, he should<br />

be induced to do so, even if it means he has<br />

to buy food grains from the market. Under<br />

this planning, the country as a whole has<br />

to evaluate, which crop we should produce<br />

here and which crop we should import, so<br />

that overall return on agriculture improves.<br />

Similarly, if water is deficient in an<br />

area, farmers should not cultivate sugarcane<br />

there. Instead of thinking in terms<br />

of quintals per hectare, we have to start<br />

thinking in terms of Rupees per hectare.<br />

This will be the real transformation of sustenance<br />

agriculture into agri business.<br />

Hence, the third mantra is national level<br />

integrated crop planning, with focus on<br />

farmers’ return on investment.<br />

4.4 Information is key to success. Authentic<br />

and timely information reduces<br />

uncertainty in business. India is one of the<br />

leading countries in respect of Information<br />

technology. But, if we look at Indian<br />

agriculture or even information relating<br />

to Indian agriculture, we do not find IT<br />

application working anywhere. We know<br />

from USDA data what is happening in US,<br />

but we do not know what is happening in<br />

our own villages. Authentic information<br />

can be generated only if we have robust<br />

information system coupled with robust<br />

connectivity backbone upto village level.<br />

For this purpose, if the entire agricultural<br />

land in the country is mapped on computer<br />

software and latest technology for database<br />

designing and data mining is used,<br />

it will prove to be the most powerful tool<br />

to help agriculture. If the village level representative<br />

is required to feed data on<br />

daily basis regarding sowing, crop pattern,<br />

harvesting on daily basis relating to all<br />

land holding in his area and all such data<br />

travels to a central server, where it is processed<br />

to generate consolidated reports, we<br />

will get the most valuable information<br />

about Indian agriculture on daily basis.<br />

This information will be most useful for<br />

the farmers also, because they will know<br />

in how much area, onion is already sown<br />

and so, whether he should do onion cultivation<br />

or shift to some other crop. Today,<br />

if price of a commodity is higher in a year,<br />

lot of farmers will cultivate the same commodity<br />

next year, which leads to glut; fall<br />

in price and resultant loss. A number of<br />

companies will be interested to buy data,<br />

because their business is connected with<br />

agriculture and hence, the entire venture<br />

can be run in a profitable manner. Looking<br />

at the outstanding success of telecom<br />

revolution in our country, it is not a difficult<br />

target. Hence, the forth important<br />

strategy should be to develop real time<br />

database system to track agriculture after<br />

mapping each and every land holding cultivated<br />

in our country.<br />

4.5 <strong>The</strong> area under cultivation in our<br />

country is consistently under pressure. Urbanization,<br />

industrialization, housing for<br />

increasing population are taking a toll on<br />

the land under cultivation. But, still India<br />

has a lot of barren and wasteful land, which<br />

is not under cultivation. Such land is wasteful<br />

due to variety of reasons. Somewhere<br />

land is not fit for agriculture because it is<br />

full of stones and hilly layers. Somewhere<br />

it is not cultivable because of poor rainfall<br />

and lack of irrigation facilities. If through<br />

comprehensive planning we can convert at<br />

least a part of such wasteful land into agriculture<br />

land, it will ease the food security<br />

threat. In Rajasthan, agriculture has<br />

progressed very well after creating irrigation<br />

facilities through canalization. In<br />

Kutch area, similar wonders have been<br />

achieved by using Narmada water through<br />

canalization. Similarly, area covered with<br />

stony layers not fit for agriculture can be<br />

developed for poultry. Hence, the next<br />

In Rajasthan, agriculture has progressed very well after<br />

creating irrigation facilities through canalization. In Kutch<br />

area, similar wonders have been achieved by using<br />

Narmada water through canalization<br />

strategy for solving food security problem<br />

should be to convert wasteful land into agriculture<br />

wherever possible.<br />

4.6 If land resources are limited and<br />

population is continuously increasing, fundamentally<br />

there will always be a mismatch<br />

in the long run. <strong>The</strong> production of food<br />

grains has a degree of inelasticity in the<br />

long run because of long crop period and<br />

seasonality factors. Compared to that, in<br />

the same area production of fruits and vegetables<br />

can be increased manifold by using<br />

better techniques, multi-layer cropping,<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

77


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

etc. <strong>The</strong> idea is to increase production of<br />

fruits and vegetables manifold if production<br />

of food grains cannot be increased<br />

significantly. Human food habits also keep<br />

on changing, with change in socio economic<br />

factors. If fruits and vegetables are<br />

commercially within reach of lower middle<br />

class people, it will ease the pressure<br />

on cereals. However, this will also need<br />

good investment in rural infrastructure,<br />

cold chain, transportation and<br />

marketing support.<br />

4.7 In order to ensure food security,<br />

another important strategy should be to<br />

strengthen marketing infrastructure and<br />

make the farming more remunerative. If<br />

production increases, but marketing infrastructure<br />

is not strong to tackle load of<br />

increased production, it will be a big disaster.<br />

In case of absence of strong marketing<br />

infrastructure, increase in production<br />

will lead to glut at arrival centers, which<br />

means unremunerative prices to the farmers<br />

and in such case, increase in production<br />

cannot be sustained. <strong>The</strong> solution lies<br />

in improving marketing efficiency by reducing<br />

cost of intermediation and bringing<br />

in price transparency. This can be achieved<br />

through developing electronic spot markets<br />

with facilities for deliveries at various<br />

arrival centers and developing a robust<br />

structured market, which can be relied<br />

upon by buyers located anywhere in the<br />

country for sourcing deliveries. <strong>The</strong> Exchange<br />

will, guarantee payment to the sellers<br />

against deliveries and delivery of quality<br />

certified material to the buyers. Hence,<br />

electronic national level spot exchange is<br />

the next strategy to ensure food security.<br />

4.8 Now, we have Warehousing Development<br />

and Regulation Act in place.<br />

This will certainly promote investment in<br />

rural infrastructure in terms of warehousing,<br />

cold storage, etc. We know that around<br />

Futures market has helped in discovering correct price<br />

levels and improving farmers’ realization. In Uttar Pradesh,<br />

Mentha farmers are now getting Rs.500 per kg; while<br />

earlier they were getting only Rs.300-350 per kg<br />

15% of total production goes as post harvest<br />

losses. Even bringing the storage loss<br />

to 5% will have large effects on our food<br />

security. However, marketability of warehouses<br />

is also crucial, because it is a capital<br />

intensive project and unless people use it,<br />

private investment in rural warehouses will<br />

not be viable in a big way. Marketability of<br />

warehouses means a platform, where warehouse<br />

receipts can be negotiated. If a<br />

farmer or trader knows that by keeping<br />

goods in a designated warehouse, he can<br />

sell his produce on a national level electronic<br />

platform, he will certainly choose to<br />

keep his produce in such designated scientific<br />

rural warehouses. But, for this purpose<br />

national level electronic spot exchange<br />

has to come up, where warehouse<br />

receipts representing quality certified farm<br />

produce can be traded. This will create a<br />

business model for institutional investors<br />

for creating rural infrastructure. In absence<br />

of this, we may find big shopping<br />

malls coming up in cities, but creating<br />

warehouses and cold storage in rural area<br />

may not be achieved, unless we also have<br />

a viable business model enhancing marketability<br />

of warehouses at national level.<br />

Hence, strengthening rural infrastructure<br />

and linking them to modern market is next<br />

strategy to ensure food security.<br />

4.9 Futures market has helped in discovering<br />

correct price levels for various<br />

commodities and hence improving farmers’<br />

realization. In U.P., Mentha farmers<br />

are now getting Rs.500 per kg; while earlier<br />

they were getting only Rs. 300- 350 per<br />

kg. As a result, area under cultivation has<br />

doubled. Production has also increased<br />

from 18000 MT to 32000 MT per annum.<br />

But, futures market will be more helpful<br />

to the farmers, if there is also an electronic<br />

spot market, so that farmers can use<br />

futures market for price discovery and spot<br />

market for price realization. For developing<br />

electronic spot market, the most important<br />

requirement is amendment in<br />

APMC law and recognition of the concept<br />

of E Trading, E Markets or Electronic<br />

Spot Exchanges under the APMC Act.<br />

Presently, the scenario is that sale and purchase<br />

of farm produce outside the principal<br />

yard and sub yard is illegal. A farmer<br />

is not allowed to sell more than head load<br />

to a person not holding APMC license,<br />

otherwise the buyer can be prosecuted.<br />

Futures markets and spot markets will<br />

help ensure food security by making farming<br />

remunerative and improving farmers’<br />

realization thereby strengthening rural<br />

economy. Hence, amendment in APMC<br />

Act, promoting alternative marketing<br />

channels, recognizing E Trading and E<br />

Market as national level platforms, giving<br />

the farmers a choice to sell wherever he<br />

desires, are important steps towards ensuring<br />

food security. In order to ensure<br />

food security, we have to make farming<br />

remunerative and attractive. Developing<br />

alternative channels for marketing of agriculture<br />

produce and giving freedom to<br />

farmers to sell wherever they get the highest<br />

price is key to achieve this goal.<br />

78 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

1 0 j a n 2 0 0 8<br />

YEAR-END SPECIAL<br />

only Rs. 10<br />

i nd i a ’ s mo s t i nf l uen t i a l bus i ne s s and ec onomy m a g a z i n e<br />

India’s No. 1<br />

Business & Economy<br />

Magazine<br />

India’s most<br />

Disruptive<br />

Dynasties<br />

<strong>The</strong>y were kings in<br />

several sectors. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

spotted opportunities in<br />

new sectors, controlled by<br />

strong players. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

gatecrashed, and caused<br />

massive disruptions.<br />

Finally, they changed the<br />

rules of the game<br />

Vijay Mallya, UB Group


James Tooley,<br />

President,<br />

<strong>The</strong> Education Fund,<br />

Orient Global,Singapore<br />

Why Poor Parents Are Choosing ‘More Market, Less<br />

Government’ In Education And What We Should Do About It?<br />

"Freedom necessarily means<br />

that many things will be done<br />

which we do not like. Our<br />

faith in freedom does not rest<br />

on the foreseeable results in<br />

particular circumstances but<br />

in the belief that it will, on<br />

balance, release more forces<br />

for the good than the bad."<br />

-Friedrich Hayek<br />

I’ve moved to India because something<br />

extraordinary is happening<br />

in education, and I want to be a<br />

part of it. Most excitingly, it concerns<br />

the education of the less well-off in society,<br />

rather than the rich. <strong>The</strong> accepted<br />

wisdom says that the poor need<br />

governments to provide their education<br />

– in most developing countries,<br />

governments supplemented by hefty<br />

international aid. But government<br />

education for the poor in India isn’t<br />

working well. Visiting a government<br />

school for the poor here is not an edifying<br />

experience. Where there should<br />

be ten teachers, you’ll often only find<br />

two or three present. <strong>The</strong>y won’t all be<br />

teaching either. Children– bright-eyed,<br />

eager young children – will often be<br />

seating on the floor, doing nothing.<br />

Nor will there be sanitation facilities<br />

in many schools. I know one government<br />

school in the slums behind the<br />

Charminar in Hyderabad where the<br />

children have an arrangement to use a<br />

neighbour’s toilet, and avail themselves<br />

of drinking water from him too. In another,<br />

they have to wait until they get<br />

home (which sometimes stops them<br />

coming to school altogether). In a<br />

third, a well-known foundation has<br />

provided computers and a television to<br />

transform teaching. <strong>The</strong> television is<br />

in the headteacher’s office, still in its<br />

box; the computers are in a locked<br />

room. Reason: the school has no electricity.<br />

This too is commonplace. I’m<br />

not the only one to feel that the poor<br />

deserve much more than what government<br />

education apparently has to offer.<br />

It would all be deeply depressing if it<br />

wasn’t for the fact that the poor, in<br />

huge numbers, are already embracing<br />

an alternative. Private schools are blossoming<br />

in the slums and low-income<br />

areas of urban India, and in rural India<br />

too. <strong>The</strong>se low-cost private schools are<br />

run by entrepreneurs from the communities.<br />

Perhaps a woman has started a<br />

nursery, then been persuaded to extend<br />

it further when parents report<br />

that their children are happy with her.<br />

80 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Or a husband and wife team starts a<br />

school as a joint business, seeing the<br />

success of other schools in the neighbourhood.<br />

Visit these schools, and<br />

you’ll find the vast majority of teachers<br />

present and teaching, and a vibrant atmosphere<br />

of learning taking place.<br />

And the market for these schools seems<br />

huge: I first discovered for myself these<br />

low cost private schools in poor areas<br />

of the Old City of Hyderabad a few<br />

years back. From the roof of one, I<br />

could see five or six other private<br />

schools, all vying for the same customers.<br />

‘More Market, Less Government’<br />

in education already seemed to be the<br />

impulse of poor parents across India.<br />

How many schools are there? What<br />

proportion of children are they serving?<br />

How good are these low cost private<br />

schools? What is their business<br />

model – and does it have implications<br />

for the way the sector can be enhanced?<br />

<strong>The</strong>se were the questions that leapt out<br />

at me when I first found these schools<br />

for myself. I procured funding from<br />

the John Templeton Foundation to<br />

conduct detailed research – in India,<br />

and also in Nigeria, Ghana, Kenya and<br />

China, for the phenomenon of low cost<br />

private schools turns out to be something<br />

that is widespread across the developing<br />

world. My research teams<br />

explored selected, officially designated<br />

‘poor’ areas, such as slums and shanty<br />

towns in metropolitan cities in these<br />

countries, and poor areas in the rural<br />

hinterlands surrounding these cities.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y researched remote villages in impoverished<br />

North-West China, and<br />

rural communities in south India. <strong>The</strong><br />

teams combed these poor areas, going<br />

down every alleyway in the slums, visiting<br />

every settlement in the rural areas,<br />

asking of people on market stalls and<br />

in the streets, to find where the poor<br />

were being educated. <strong>The</strong>y found large<br />

numbers of schools – 918 in the ‘notified’<br />

slums of three zones of Hyderabad,<br />

India, for instance.<br />

What the research teams found<br />

points to an extraordinary grassroots<br />

educational revolution that is taking<br />

place – in India and across the developing<br />

world. In poor urban areas surveyed,<br />

a large majority of school children<br />

were found to be in ‘budget’<br />

private schools. For instance, in the<br />

slums of Hyderabad, India, 65 percent<br />

of schoolchildren were in private unaided<br />

schools. <strong>The</strong>se schools charge<br />

very low fees, affordable to parents on<br />

poverty-line and minimum-wages. In<br />

Hyderabad, mean monthly fees at 4th<br />

grade were Rs.78.17 ($1.74) in unrecognized<br />

and Rs.102.55 ($2.28) in recognized<br />

private schools in the slums –<br />

about 4.2 percent and 5.5 percent<br />

respectively of the monthly wage for a<br />

breadwinner on a typical minimum<br />

wage of about Rs.78/-per day (Government<br />

of India, 2005, assuming 24 working<br />

days per month).<br />

Private schools for the poor are not<br />

just an urban phenomenon either. In<br />

the deprived district of Mahbubnagar,<br />

in Andhra Pradesh, I found around<br />

three-fifths of schools were government,<br />

only a tiny number private aided,<br />

and well over a third were private unaided.<br />

But breaking these figures into<br />

schools in the small towns and rural<br />

areas proper, I could see that small<br />

town Andhra Pradesh is rather similar<br />

to the metropolitan areas: Just as in<br />

urban Hyderabad, the vast majority of<br />

schools – nearly two-thirds – were private<br />

unaided in the small towns of<br />

Mahbubnagar. In the rural areas proper,<br />

however, government schools were<br />

in a majority – around fourth-fifths,<br />

with private unaided schools making<br />

up the remaining fifth. Development<br />

experts who are aware of the existence<br />

of this low cost private sector appear<br />

uniformly to worry about their low<br />

quality: <strong>The</strong> Oxfam Education Report,<br />

for instance, notes that private schools<br />

for the poor are of ‘inferior quality’,<br />

offering ‘a low-quality service’ that will<br />

In Hyderabad, mean monthly fees at 4th grade were<br />

Rs. 78.17 ($1.74) in unrecognized and Rs.102.55 ($2.28)<br />

in recognized private schools in the slums – about 4.2<br />

percent and 5.5 percent respectively of the monthly wage<br />

for a breadwinner on a typical minimum wage<br />

‘restrict children’s future opportunities.’<br />

(Watkins, 2000, p. 230). Nambissan<br />

(2003) notes that in Calcutta, ‘the<br />

mushrooming of privately managed<br />

unregulated pre-primary and primary<br />

schools… can have only deleterious<br />

consequences for the spread of education<br />

in general and among the poor in<br />

particular’ (p. 52), for the quality of the<br />

private schools is ‘often suspect’ (p. 15,<br />

footnote 25). Significantly, such concerns<br />

about low quality of private provision<br />

must be read in the context of<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

81


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

the reported low standard of government<br />

provision. <strong>The</strong> Oxfam Education<br />

Report prefaces the remarks quoted<br />

above with the observation that ‘there<br />

is no doubting the appalling standard<br />

of provision in public education systems’<br />

(Watkins, 2000, p. 230). Indeed,<br />

the low quality of government schools<br />

for the poor is one reason given for the<br />

‘mushrooming’ of the private schools:<br />

Venkatanarayana (2004) notes that the<br />

‘failure of public school in terms of<br />

meeting parents’ expectations/aspirations’<br />

has led to a ‘growing demand’ for<br />

private schools in rural Andhra<br />

Pradesh, India (p. 40).<br />

Are the low cost private schools as<br />

bad as the development experts think?<br />

I looked at the issue of quality in detail.<br />

My researchers tested around<br />

24,000 children in the global sample,<br />

taken from stratified random samples<br />

of schools within these poor communities.<br />

Children were tested in key curriculum<br />

subjects, and questionnaires<br />

given to children, their parents, teachers<br />

and school managers, and IQ tests<br />

to children and their teachers, to elicit<br />

data to control for a wide range of<br />

background variables, including peergroup<br />

variables. <strong>The</strong> results from Delhi<br />

were typical. In mathematics, mean<br />

scores of children in government<br />

schools were 24.5 percent, while those<br />

in private unrecognised schools were<br />

42.1 percent and private recognised<br />

were 43.9 percent. That is, children in<br />

unrecognised private schools achieved<br />

nearly 18 percentage points higher in<br />

Low cost private schools are accountable to the parents –<br />

who can withdraw their children if they’re not satisfi ed; the<br />

entrepreneurs knows this, and knows he or she will feel<br />

the pinch for each parents who doesn’t pay fees, so<br />

makes sure things go well within the school<br />

maths than children in government<br />

schools (a 72 percent advantage!),<br />

while children in recognised private<br />

schools were over 19 percentage points<br />

higher than children in government<br />

schools (a 79 percent advantage). In<br />

English, the performance difference<br />

was much greater (children in unrecognised<br />

schools gaining 35 percentage<br />

points higher, while children in recognised<br />

schools were 41 percentage<br />

points higher). However, these differences<br />

might be expected, given that<br />

government schools are not providing<br />

what parents want, English medium.<br />

(On the other hand, they might not be<br />

expected, given an oft-repeated criticism<br />

that private schools are Englishmedium<br />

in name only, that this is just<br />

another way they pull the wool over ignorant<br />

poor parents’ eyes. What we<br />

found showed that the private schools<br />

were in fact getting their children to a<br />

much higher English standard than<br />

what children might pick up in the environment,<br />

through radio, television<br />

and advertisements, for instance –<br />

which is perhaps what the tests were<br />

measuring for children in government<br />

schools). But in any case, if more private<br />

schools are English medium, this<br />

might lead us to expect that government<br />

schools would be superior in<br />

achievement in Hindi: the opposite was<br />

true. Children in private unrecognised<br />

schools achieved on average 22 percentage<br />

points higher than children in<br />

government schools (an 83 percent advantage).<br />

In recognised private schools,<br />

children scored on average 24 percentage<br />

points higher (an 89 percent advantage.)<br />

Controlling for relevant background<br />

variables, the differences<br />

between government and private<br />

schools were reduced but still hugely<br />

significant: In Hyderabad, for instance,<br />

a child attending a private unrecognised<br />

school would be predicted to<br />

gain 16.1 percentage points higher in<br />

mathematics than the same child attending<br />

a government school. In a private<br />

recognised school, the difference<br />

in scores would be 17.3 percentage<br />

points. In English, the advantages<br />

would be even greater –16.9 percentage<br />

points higher in an unrecognised<br />

school, and 18.9 percentage points in a<br />

recognised school. In Urdu, after controlling<br />

for the background variables,<br />

there turned out to be no statistically<br />

significant difference between government<br />

and either type of private school.<br />

More market, less government in education<br />

– this appears to be how poor<br />

parents see the way forward. And they<br />

are doing it for a good reason – the low<br />

cost private schools are better than the<br />

government alternative. Presumably<br />

they’re better because they’re accountable<br />

to the parents – who can withdraw<br />

their children if they’re not satisfied;<br />

the entrepreneurs knows this, and<br />

knows he or she will feel the pinch for<br />

each parents who doesn’t pay fees, so<br />

keeps a close eye on his teachers and<br />

makes sure things go well within the<br />

82 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

school. Better, however, but perhaps<br />

not good enough. For whatever the advantages<br />

of the low cost private schools<br />

that I’ve outlined above, clearly their<br />

quality could be improved – and noone<br />

acknowledges this more, in my experience,<br />

than the private school entrepreneurs<br />

themselves. <strong>The</strong>y are hungry<br />

for new ideas in curriculum and pedagogy.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y are hungry for investment<br />

in infrastructure and technology. But<br />

this is where something rather exciting<br />

opens up for us. We can see the low<br />

cost private education sector as a new<br />

frontier for investment. <strong>The</strong> key relevant<br />

finding of my research is that the<br />

vast majority of the private schools in<br />

the poor areas are run as businesses,<br />

not charities, dependent more or less<br />

entirely on fee income and, very importantly,<br />

making a reasonable profit.<br />

In Hyderabad for instance, 91 percent<br />

unrecognized and 82 percent recognized<br />

private schools were entirely dependent<br />

on student fee income, receiving<br />

no outside funding at all. Profit<br />

margins, my research showed, could be<br />

in the region of 20-40 percent of fee<br />

income. Because the private schools<br />

for the poor are run as businesses, this<br />

provides at least three ways forward for<br />

investors to help in improving quality<br />

– each of which is prompted by the observation<br />

that school proprietors are<br />

hungry for improvement and innovation.<br />

Why? Because whatever the critics<br />

of private schools for the poor may<br />

claim, many care about children’s education.<br />

On its own, this might be<br />

enough for some to invest. But, the<br />

power of the market means that it’s<br />

coupled with another major incentive:<br />

proprietors know that they are in an<br />

increasingly competitive market. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

need parents to know that their school<br />

is special, to maintain or increase market<br />

share. If school improvements seem<br />

to have demonstrably better outcomes,<br />

they’ll want them for their schools.<br />

So we can, first, help school proprietors<br />

improve their infrastructure<br />

through providing loans, through existing<br />

or purpose-created non-banking<br />

finance organizations. Typical projects<br />

would include refurbishing or building<br />

new classrooms and buying land. Second,<br />

investors can conduct research<br />

and development to find out what works<br />

to improve desired curriculum and<br />

pedagogical outcomes in low cost education.<br />

Investors can then partner with<br />

local entrepreneurs to ensure that the<br />

improved methods are made available,<br />

suitably packaged, at a price acceptable<br />

to school entrepreneurs.<br />

And this leads to a third exciting<br />

possibility. In '<strong>The</strong> Fortune at the Bottom<br />

of the Pyramid', Prof. C.K. Prahalad<br />

challenges the ‘dominant assumption’<br />

that the poor are not bothered<br />

about brand-names: ‘On the contrary’,<br />

his findings suggest, ‘the poor are very<br />

brand-conscious’ (2005, p. 13). In private<br />

education, brand names could be<br />

important to help solve the genuine<br />

information problem that exists – and<br />

this provides a third major opportunity<br />

for investors to enter the education<br />

market. How can poor parents<br />

judge if one private school in their<br />

community is better than another, and<br />

that it is adequately serving the educational<br />

needs of their children? Typically,<br />

my research showed parents using<br />

a variety of informal methods, such<br />

as visiting several schools to see how<br />

committed teachers and the proprietor<br />

appear. Or they talk to friends, comparing<br />

notes about how frequently exercise<br />

books are marked and homework<br />

checked. Importantly, I found<br />

that if parents choose one private<br />

school, but subsequently discover that<br />

another seems better, they have little<br />

In private education, brand names could be important to<br />

help solve the genuine information problem that exists –<br />

and this provides a third major opportunity for investors to<br />

enter the education market<br />

hesitation in moving their child to<br />

where they think they will get a better<br />

education. And school proprietors<br />

know all of this, so make sure teachers<br />

turn up and teach, and invest any surpluses<br />

in school improvement, to ensure<br />

parental satisfaction. So there is<br />

an information problem, but there are<br />

ways around it.<br />

However, in other markets, brand<br />

names provide a safer way of overcoming<br />

parallel information asymmetries.<br />

Buying into trusted brands would be<br />

one way of overcoming the information<br />

problem too, for poor parents wanting<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

83


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

the best education for their children.<br />

One possibility would be for investors<br />

to assist expansion-minded proprietors<br />

accessing loan capital. Or it could involve<br />

creating a specialised education<br />

investment fund, to provide equity to<br />

education companies that run chains<br />

of budget private schools. Suitable exit<br />

strategies could be worked out for the<br />

investment fund, perhaps by giving advice<br />

on how to list on local stock markets,<br />

or to get other investors on board.<br />

A further possibility could involve investors<br />

engaging in a joint venture with<br />

local educational entrepreneurs to set<br />

up a chain themselves. Investment in<br />

initial R&D would be required, to create<br />

the standards for a demonstrable<br />

and truly replicable model of private<br />

education for the poor. But here’s the<br />

rub: although it is possible to envisage<br />

creating chains of private schools here<br />

in India as things stand now, the regulatory<br />

environment certainly doesn’t<br />

make life easy for investors and innovators.<br />

<strong>The</strong> problem is profit. It all<br />

seems to go back to the Unnikrishnan<br />

Supreme Court Judgement of 1993<br />

(Unnikrishnan vs. State of Andhra<br />

Pradesh., 1993, in Padala Rama Reddi<br />

(1993) <strong>The</strong> Andhra Pradesh Education<br />

Code, Hyderabad, pp. 399-400). <strong>The</strong><br />

judgement reads: ‘Education has never<br />

been commerce in this country. Making<br />

it one is opposed to the ethos, tradition<br />

and sensibilities of this nation.’<br />

Moreover, ‘Commercialisation of education<br />

cannot and should not be permitted<br />

… Both in the light of our tradition<br />

and from the standpoint of interest<br />

of general public, commercialisation is<br />

positively harmful, it is opposed to<br />

public policy.’<br />

It’s hard to read these statements<br />

now in the light of the activities of successful<br />

businesses such as NIIT and<br />

Aptech and think that they make much<br />

Although it is possible to envisage creating chains of private<br />

schools here in India as things stand now, the regulatory<br />

environment certainly doesn’t make life easy for investors<br />

and innovators.<strong>The</strong> problem is profi t<br />

sense. <strong>The</strong>se certainly are commercial<br />

companies, and their business is clearly<br />

education. So they seem to show<br />

that, in point of fact, there is a very fine<br />

Indian ethos and tradition of the ‘business<br />

of education’. Usefully, the Unnikrishnan<br />

judgement was partially<br />

revoked in 2002. In the Supreme Court<br />

on October 31 st 2002 (TMA Pai Foundation<br />

versus State of Karnataka), it<br />

was pointed out that it is ‘no secret that<br />

the examination results at all levels of<br />

unaided private schools, notwithstanding<br />

the stringent regulations of the governmental<br />

authorities, are far superior<br />

to the results of the government-maintained<br />

schools’ (Para 61, p. 40). So<br />

clearly, the judgement said, Unni<br />

Krishnan needs reconsideration if it is<br />

having a dampening effect on private<br />

education entrepreneurs. However,<br />

did this reconsideration mean that Unnikrishnan’s<br />

rejection of profit is also<br />

superseded? It is not clear to me. <strong>The</strong><br />

new judgement reads: in ‘setting up a<br />

reasonable fee structure, the element<br />

of profiteering is not as yet accepted in<br />

Indian conditions’ (Para. 53, p. 34).<br />

However, ‘Reasonable surplus to meet<br />

cost of expansion and augmentation of<br />

facilities does not, however amount to<br />

profiteering’ (p. 128). Does this allow<br />

for-profit education? Or not? It seems<br />

that it may still be a grey area – and<br />

grey areas like this can breed corruption<br />

and inefficiency. To make matters<br />

worse, the sentiments behind Unnikrishnan<br />

are there in the regulations<br />

of the examination boards. <strong>The</strong> CBSE<br />

for instance says that only schools that<br />

are run ‘as a community service and<br />

not as a business’ are able to be affiliated<br />

to the board. And they are there<br />

in many state regulations too, that only<br />

allow schools to be registered if they<br />

are run by non-profit educational societies<br />

or trusts, but not by companies.<br />

All this means that if investors want<br />

to invest in education, it’s not straightforward.<br />

Of course it’s possible. Forprofit<br />

companies can contract with<br />

educational societies and trusts to provide<br />

management and educational inputs.<br />

But these means are cumbersome,<br />

open to regulatory risk, and in<br />

any case obtuse: for the regulations<br />

want to protect us from something that<br />

in other areas of our lives seems whol-<br />

84 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ly desirable. <strong>The</strong> profit motive is accepted<br />

as beneficial in most areas of<br />

our lives, in spurring innovation, improving<br />

quality and extending access.<br />

For instance, would anyone deny that<br />

the mobile phone revolution has accomplished<br />

each of these, and that<br />

profit was a key factor underlying each?<br />

<strong>The</strong> same could be true of the delivery<br />

of education – the profit motive could<br />

spur new methods of learning, which<br />

improve learner outcomes, and help<br />

reach those who currently don’t have<br />

access to quality education. Allowing<br />

the profit motive into education – and<br />

hence allowing masses of investment<br />

into this area – would be wholly beneficial<br />

to education in India. If only India<br />

could break away from this regulatory<br />

morass, then the future could be golden.<br />

If the entrepreneurial spirit that<br />

Indians daily show in the field of education<br />

could be harnessed, rather than<br />

damped down (as it is by current regulations),<br />

then the emerging chains of<br />

private schools, including low cost<br />

schools, funded by investment from<br />

within India and overseas, could have<br />

an extraordinary impact. And this impact<br />

could be felt not only in India but<br />

on the rest of the world too. American<br />

brand names like McDonald’s and<br />

Starbucks are predominant in the current<br />

wave of globalisation. In the next<br />

wave, there could be the educational<br />

equivalents of these chains – offering<br />

standardised delivery of high quality<br />

educational experiences – emanating<br />

from India to take on the rest of the<br />

world. I find that prospect pretty exciting.<br />

Which is why, as I say, I’ve come to<br />

India to see if I can be a part of this<br />

educational revolution.<br />

References<br />

• Nambissan, Geetha, B. (2003) Educational<br />

deprivation and primary school<br />

provision: a study of providers in the<br />

city of Calcutta, IDS Working Paper<br />

187, (Brighton, Institute of Development<br />

Studies).<br />

• Prahalad, C.K. (2005) <strong>The</strong> Fortune at<br />

the Bottom of the Pyramid, Wharton<br />

School Publishing, Upper Saddle<br />

River, NJ.<br />

• Tooley, James, Dixon, Pauline and<br />

Gomathi, S.V., (<strong>2007</strong>) Private Schools<br />

and the Millennium Development<br />

Goal of Universal Primary Education:<br />

A census and comparative survey in<br />

Hyderabad, India, Oxford Review of<br />

Education 33(5).<br />

• Tooley, James and Dixon, Pauline,<br />

(2006) ‘De Facto’ Privatisation of<br />

Education and the Poor: Implications<br />

of a Study from sub-Saharan Africa<br />

and India, Compare 36(4), 443-462<br />

• Tooley, James (2006), Backing the<br />

Wrong Horse: How Private Schools<br />

Are Good for the Poor, <strong>The</strong> Freeman,<br />

May, 8-13.<br />

• Tooley, James (2005) Private schools<br />

for the poor, Education Next: A Journal<br />

of Opinion and Research, Fall,<br />

Vol. 5 (4), 22-32.<br />

• Venkatanarayana, M. (2004) Educational<br />

Deprivation of Children in A.<br />

P: Levels and Trends, Disparities and<br />

Associate Factors, Working Paper<br />

362, Centre for Development Studies<br />

(www.cds.edu), August.<br />

• Watkins, K. (2000), <strong>The</strong> Oxfam Education<br />

Report. (Oxford, Oxfam in<br />

Great Britain).<br />

TECH WATCH<br />

What’s in store<br />

for technology freaks in 2008<br />

INDIA’S FIRST AND NO. 1 BUSINESS AND MARKETING MAGAZINE<br />

4Ps<br />

✮ PRODUCT ✮ PRICE ✮ PLACE ✮ PROMOTION ✮<br />

BUSINESS AND<br />

MARKETING<br />

<strong>Volume</strong>-II <strong>Issue</strong>-24 4 January - 17 January 2008<br />

Why Toyota, GM,<br />

Ford & Renault<br />

love India...<br />

Power, passion, leadership skills,<br />

strategic expertise and many<br />

such qualities... they have it all;<br />

the maestros who will turn things<br />

around for India in 2008. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

are the very forces who will make<br />

2008 worthwhile for India Inc. An<br />

exclusive 4Ps B&M compilation...<br />

20<br />

...and why India loves Jaguar, Land<br />

Rover & Suzuki. <strong>The</strong> reason: India<br />

may emerge as a global player in the<br />

passenger car segment<br />

Meet the 2nd<br />

Son of the East<br />

Rendezvous with<br />

Kenji Anai,<br />

Global Head,<br />

Multifuncl. Devices,<br />

National Panasonic<br />

88 Supermodels<br />

NOW ONLY<br />

Rs.10<br />

alone can’t<br />

cast the<br />

marketing<br />

spell.<br />

You<br />

need<br />

Pill(ow) fight<br />

more! Why Dabur needs a<br />

‘new u’ look soon<br />

by Rajita<br />

Chaudhuri<br />

38<br />

Top 5:<br />

Why Airtel &<br />

Kingfisher Airlines<br />

reign supreme<br />

this fortnight<br />

4Ps<br />

BUSINESS AND<br />

MARKETING<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

85


Stephen P. Heyneman,<br />

Professor, International Education Policy,<br />

Vanderbilt University, Nashville, Tennessee<br />

International Trade in Higher Education:<br />

What Should India Do?<br />

"Higher education should be left to private enterprise<br />

and for meeting national requirements<br />

whether in the various industries, technical arts,<br />

belles-letters or fi ne arts. <strong>The</strong> State Universities<br />

should be purely examining bodies, self-supporting<br />

through the fees charged for examinations.<br />

Universities will look after the whole of the fi eld<br />

of education and will prepare and approve<br />

courses of studies in the various departments<br />

of education. No private school should be run<br />

without the previous sanction of the respective<br />

Universities. University charters should be<br />

given liberally to any body of persons of proved<br />

worth and integrity, it being always understood<br />

that the Universities will not cost the State anything<br />

except that it will bear the cost of running<br />

a Central Education Department.<strong>The</strong> foregoing<br />

scheme does not absolve the State from running<br />

such seminaries as may be required for supplying<br />

State needs."<br />

-Mahatma Gandhi, Harijan,<br />

2 October 1937<br />

At independence, India had<br />

twenty universities; today<br />

there are 348. From a rate of<br />

attendance of less than one percent,<br />

today it is 12 percent. Between 1990<br />

and 2000 the number of students in<br />

higher education grew by 113 percent.<br />

Providers are diverse. Approximately<br />

one third of the students attend nongovernment<br />

institutions and 63 percent<br />

attend institutions financed by state<br />

governments. Of the world’s most famous<br />

scientists and economists, many<br />

received their training in India. Indian<br />

higher education appears healthy. But<br />

according to some estimates India<br />

needs at least 150 new universities. Although<br />

enrollment (12 percent) is<br />

higher than at any time in India’s history,<br />

it is less than any OECD country<br />

and has even fallen behind that of China<br />

(with 16 percent). Less then 2 percent<br />

of the students in India have an<br />

opportunity to attend any of the top<br />

universities sponsored by the national<br />

government. Only $US 406 is spent/<br />

year on the typical university student<br />

in India. This includes expenditures<br />

for electronic libraries, books, research<br />

laboratories, physical infrastructure,<br />

and salaries. <strong>The</strong> typical student in<br />

China has seven times more resources<br />

at his disposal. <strong>The</strong> typical student in<br />

Malaysia has 30 times more resources<br />

available, and a student in Canada has<br />

37 times more resources available.<br />

Though overall growth in the last ten<br />

years has been rapid, universities with<br />

advanced research programs grew by<br />

only 51 percent; in the Russian Federation<br />

they grew by 113 percent, in<br />

China by 167 percent and in Malaysia<br />

by 200 percent. Though foreign universities<br />

are higher in cost, 160,000 students<br />

leave India each year seeking<br />

higher education elsewhere. Over<br />

5,000 Indian students arrive annually<br />

to study in the U.S., where the price of<br />

attending universities is higher than<br />

anywhere in the world. <strong>The</strong>y do this<br />

because they cannot find a university<br />

in India comparable in quality.<br />

86 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure I: Ranking Of Asian Universities By Size Of Bandwidth<br />

Rank Multi-Disciplinary Schools Internet Bandwidth per student (kbps) Overall Rank 2000<br />

1 Sun Yat-sen University (Taiwan) 33.53 20<br />

2 Kyungpock National University 27.76 35<br />

3 Chungnam National Unviersity 20.84 50<br />

4 Australian National University 19.58 8<br />

5 Taiwan Normal University 19.02 37<br />

6 Seoul national University 17.14 4<br />

7 Tsing Hua University(Taiwan)* 14.77 18<br />

8 Chonnam National University 14.77 1<br />

9 Tohcku University (Japan) 13.52 34<br />

10 Tianjin University (China) 11.84 2<br />

11 National University of Singapore 11.54 46<br />

12 University of Wollongong 10.81 54<br />

13 University of Adelaide 7.1 5<br />

14 Nagoya University 6.92 45<br />

15 Central University (Taiwan)* 6.88 26<br />

16 Nagoya University 6.58 11<br />

17 Central University (Taiwan)* 6.12 24<br />

18 University of Melbourne 6.06 9<br />

19 Kasetsart University 5.56 63<br />

20 Chao Toung University (Taiwan)* 5.5 28<br />

21 Monash University 5.14 30<br />

22 Chonbuk National University 5 43<br />

23 Taiwan University* 4.1 12<br />

24 Pusan National Unviersity 3.99 39<br />

25 City University of Hong Kong 3.9 27<br />

26 Hckkaido University 3.81 19<br />

27 Southeast University (China) 3.56 60<br />

28 Chung Hsing University (Taiwan)* 3.35 65<br />

29 Keio University* 3.24 22<br />

30 Hanyang University 3.16 38<br />

31 University of Western Australia 2.89 23<br />

32 Sungkyunkwan U niversity 2.83 33<br />

33 Ewha Womans University 2.46 32<br />

34 Macquarie University 2.32 56<br />

35 Ritsumeikan University 2.18 67<br />

36 Waseda University 2.13 29<br />

37 Chinese University of Hong Kong 2.1 6<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

87


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure I: Ranking Of Asian Universities By Size Of Bandwidth (Contd.)<br />

Rank Multi-Disciplinary Schools Internet bandwidth per student (kbps) Over all Rank 2000<br />

38 University of Hong Kong 2.05 3<br />

39 Korew University 2.04 414<br />

40 Cheng Kung University (Taiwan)* 1.6 16<br />

Although there are many famous Indian<br />

scientists and economists, they<br />

often teach in foreign universities.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y do this because universities in<br />

India cannot offer comparable research<br />

facilities, programs with comparable<br />

innovation, or comparable<br />

levels of remuneration. When one<br />

ranks a nation by the number of citations<br />

to its published scientific literature,<br />

citations from India in 2005<br />

ranked number 21, accounting for only<br />

1.1 percent share of the total. <strong>The</strong> scarcity<br />

of world class faculty in Indian<br />

Figure II. Asia Week: Multi-Disiplinary Ranking: Top<br />

77 Universities in Asia<br />

Country Number (Percentage) Highes Rank<br />

Korea 13(16.9) 4<br />

Japan 11(14.9) 1<br />

Australia 10(13.0) 8<br />

Taiwan 10(13.0) 12<br />

Thailand 5(6.5) 51<br />

Philippines 4(5.2) 48<br />

New Zealand 4(5.2) 21<br />

Indonesia 4(5.2) 61<br />

Hong Kong 4(5.2) 3<br />

China 4(5.2) 42<br />

Malaysia 3(3.9) 47<br />

India 2(2.6) 40<br />

Bangladesh 1(1.3) 64<br />

Singapore 1(1.3) 5<br />

Sri Lanka 1(1.3) 77<br />

Source: www.asiaweek.com/features/universities2000/school/<br />

multi.overall.html<br />

universities is one explanation for the<br />

fact that of the applications for patents<br />

India accounted for only 0.5 percent.,<br />

and of the ‘capacity to innovate’ in<br />

2005 India ranked 50. No Indian university<br />

appears in the ranking of world<br />

universities; and no university appears<br />

in the top ranked universities in Asia<br />

in terms of what is now considered a<br />

sine qua non of university quality:<br />

bandwidth (Please refer Figure -I). Of<br />

the top ranked 77 universities within<br />

Asia, the highest university in India<br />

only ranked number 40. Only two universities<br />

were even considered (See<br />

Figure-II). It is unfortunate but nevertheless<br />

it is fair to characterize universities<br />

in India as being ‘asleep’, while<br />

universities in other countries quickly<br />

pass by.<br />

In Medieval Europe it is said that<br />

plagues were accompanied by numerous<br />

theories of ‘what went wrong’.<br />

Some attributed impending catastrophe<br />

to insufficient piety. If citizens repent<br />

they said, their futures would<br />

brighten. <strong>The</strong> problems of Indian higher<br />

education are similarly accompanied<br />

by theories of ‘what went wrong’.<br />

Some theories hold that international<br />

evidence to the contrary is irrelevant<br />

and that there is nothing wrong. Others<br />

suggest that the problems can only<br />

be solved if India does more of what it<br />

has done in the past --- finance higher<br />

education largely from public tax resources,<br />

control prices, limit providers<br />

and forbid foreign competition. And<br />

then there are some theories which<br />

point to the unmitigated success of India’s<br />

entry into telecommunications.<br />

When allowed in, foreign providers<br />

quickly rejuvenated India’s ancient telecommunications<br />

sector thus making<br />

it possible for entrepreneurial spinoffs,<br />

which spurred India into high<br />

economic growth and a decline in poverty.<br />

Why couldn’t international competition<br />

not jump start the Indian<br />

higher education sector as it has other<br />

88 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure III: Pros And Cons For Opening India To International Trade In Education<br />

Cons<br />

Loss of public good character<br />

Only serves individual needs<br />

Rewards universitites independent<br />

of the broad public good<br />

Weakens public funding<br />

Eclipses the public sector by the<br />

private sector quality<br />

Pros<br />

Increased efficiency, quality and choice<br />

Consistent with human rights<br />

Breaks the monopoly of having low quality universities define what whould be learned<br />

Strengthens public funding because it would strengthen public confidence through increased<br />

accountability<br />

Strengthens the public sector due to competition<br />

sectors? <strong>The</strong>re are two paths in Indian<br />

higher education policy: to continue to<br />

protect it or to open it up to international<br />

competition with all of the impending<br />

implications. <strong>The</strong> answer will<br />

determine India’s future. So what<br />

should India do? One problem is that<br />

the arguments for and against opening<br />

India to higher education trade is generally<br />

made by two divergent groups of<br />

stakeholders. Macro-economists generally<br />

favor international competition;<br />

education policy officials generally do<br />

not. It might be useful to place each of<br />

their arguments on the table and analyze<br />

them one by one (Please do refer<br />

Figures- III and IV).<br />

Higher Education As A Public<br />

Good<br />

Those who oppose international trade<br />

in higher education will argue that<br />

higher education is a public good and<br />

that opening up India to international<br />

providers would threaten the maintenance<br />

of the public interest. Those who<br />

favor international trade will point out<br />

that overtly sectarian or philosophically<br />

dangerous providers can be controlled<br />

through the accreditation process.<br />

Further, they will argue that<br />

competition stimulates efficiency, wider<br />

choice, and higher quality (as it does<br />

in many sectors). In their view these<br />

characteristics are part of public interest.<br />

Is it in the public interest, they<br />

ask, to allow access only to low quality,<br />

inefficient and a narrow choice of professional<br />

programs?<br />

Figure IV: Pros And Cons (Contd.)<br />

Cons<br />

Leads to “Knowledge Capitalism”<br />

Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual<br />

Property Rights (TRIPS) would exclude<br />

low income scholars by maintaining<br />

high prices for curriculum<br />

materials<br />

Since knowledge is public good, reforms<br />

in education finance with decrease<br />

access to public good<br />

Threatens the “Social contract” in<br />

which the present generation finances<br />

future generations<br />

Trade jeopardizes human rights because<br />

it contradicts national commitments<br />

supporting free education<br />

Individual Vs. Social Needs<br />

Those who oppose say that international<br />

trade would serve only the needs<br />

of the individual and that service to the<br />

community, a natural part of higher<br />

education, would be lost if trade barriers<br />

were liberalized. Those who favor<br />

point out that at present human rights<br />

are being abrogated. All individuals<br />

have the right to education they might<br />

say, and if one individual wishes to<br />

study in a field provided by a foreign<br />

university, what right do we have as a<br />

Pros<br />

Leads of the strengthening of non-resourced<br />

subjects through cross-faculty<br />

resource transfer<br />

Adhering to TRIPS would increse access<br />

to high quality products by insuring incomes<br />

from their sale. Hence it would<br />

increase supply, the choice of products,<br />

and lower the real price<br />

Public goods are never free. Reforms in<br />

education finance will increase the income<br />

to public and private producers.<br />

Hence, it will increase the supply and access<br />

to a public good.<br />

Strengthens the social contract by increasing<br />

access, quality and equity<br />

(through cross-subsidization)<br />

Trade would increase human rights by<br />

allowing access to education where it is<br />

currently denied of unavailable<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

89


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

democracy to limit that access to education?<br />

<strong>The</strong> same might be true to<br />

textbooks, foreign faculty, internet<br />

facilities and the like. Limitation of<br />

education trade itself is an abrogation<br />

of human rights.<br />

Universities Would Be Rewarded<br />

Independent Of <strong>The</strong> Public<br />

Good.<br />

Those who oppose would say that universities<br />

should be rewarded for their<br />

research and teaching independent of<br />

their abilities to generate revenue; if<br />

foreign competition were allowed then<br />

Indian universities would have to follow<br />

commercial rather than intellectual<br />

incentives. Those who favor say<br />

that competition is necessary to break<br />

what is now a monopoly. If only low<br />

quality institutions are available, there<br />

is little incentive to imp<br />

rove. Instead of being a threat to intellectual<br />

incentives, foreign comp<br />

etition may be an essential ingredient<br />

to stimulate it.<br />

International Education Trade<br />

Would Weaken <strong>The</strong> Case For<br />

Public Funding<br />

Those who oppose would point out<br />

that public funding is essential for university<br />

development and if foreign<br />

competition were allowed the case for<br />

more public resources would weaken.<br />

‘Let the private sector provide the facilities’,<br />

the politicians might say, ‘Now<br />

we can allocate resources to problems<br />

other than higher education’. Those<br />

who favor argue the opposite. <strong>The</strong>y say<br />

that foreign competition would<br />

strengthen the case for public funding,<br />

not weaken it. It would strengthen the<br />

Up for consideration should be changes in the entire legal<br />

structure, which would allow the creation of endowments<br />

often from the overseas diaspora (something China has<br />

mastered) and a new tax regime which encourages donations<br />

and gifts to education from both citizens and firms<br />

case because it would increase public<br />

confidence in the higher education<br />

sector because of increased accountability.<br />

Why should the public allocate<br />

additional resources to a sector crippled<br />

by low quality and inefficiency?<br />

Wouldn’t the public be more likely to<br />

allocate resources to a sector in which<br />

it had more confidence? And wouldn’t<br />

open competition help stimulate the<br />

supply response in which they could be<br />

more confident?<br />

Public Wector Quality Would<br />

Be Eclipsed By Private Sector<br />

Quality<br />

If foreign competition were allowed,<br />

what India now thinks of higher quality<br />

would be eclipsed by foreign private<br />

providers. Imagine Oxford in Madras,<br />

or Harvard in Bangalore? For economic<br />

reasons, there is little likelihood that<br />

a high quality provider will open a<br />

multi-faculty university. Most would<br />

open programs highly specific to vocations<br />

such as engineering or business.<br />

However narrow the presence of international<br />

providers would strengthen<br />

the quality of current universities because<br />

of the competition. <strong>The</strong>y would<br />

be more likely to study the syllabi,<br />

student services, faculty productivity<br />

and other indicators of quality if there<br />

is competition than if there is not.<br />

Those who argue for international<br />

trade would say that it is essential for<br />

maintaining the quality of the current<br />

public universities.<br />

International Trade Leads To<br />

‘Knowledge Capitalism’<br />

Critics argue that trade in education<br />

would result in having knowledge pursued<br />

if it results in remuneration and<br />

ignored if it does not. <strong>The</strong>y ask if it is<br />

right for professors to be better rewarded<br />

by virtue of the fact that their<br />

subject is in higher market demand.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y ask what will happen to the pursuit<br />

of truth if it is subject to a price.<br />

Others respond by pointing to the fact<br />

that knowledge can not be immune<br />

from its market value. <strong>The</strong>re is no hiding<br />

the fact that the demand to study<br />

history is less than the demand for<br />

commerce. However, competition need<br />

not lead to a diminishment of history<br />

or other non-revenue producing subject.<br />

<strong>The</strong> major managerial challenge<br />

in any university is how to cross-subsidize<br />

faculties, or transfer resources<br />

90 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

within the institution to support under<br />

resourced but important subjects.<br />

Without cross-subsidization, a university<br />

cannot successfully compete.<br />

Hence they would argue that international<br />

trade and the success of mastering<br />

the modern art of university administration<br />

is the key ingredient<br />

preventing ‘academic capitalism’.<br />

Trade Related Aspects Of<br />

Intellectual Property Rights<br />

(TRIPS) Excludes Low-Income<br />

scholars from successfully<br />

marketing their own curricula<br />

Critics worry that international trade<br />

in education would lower access to local<br />

curricula; international property<br />

rights agreements would protect the<br />

privileged and freeze-out those who<br />

have not yet broken into the market.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y imagine that there will be an avalanche<br />

of foreign books, guidelines,<br />

and syllabi entering India, making it<br />

difficult for local students to be educated<br />

with local materials. Those who<br />

favor open trade say that adhering to<br />

agreements on intellectual property<br />

would increase access to high quality<br />

pedagogical materials because it would<br />

insure income from their sale. In turn<br />

this would increase the incentive to<br />

write new curricula, and would lead to<br />

greater supply, wider choice, and lower<br />

real prices. In their vision, Indian producers<br />

of curricula would compete successfully,<br />

placing the Indian student<br />

consumer at a distinct advantage over<br />

a circumstance in which there would<br />

be no competition.<br />

Privatization Of Education<br />

Finance Will <strong>Dec</strong>rease Access<br />

To A Public Good<br />

Critics argue that international trade<br />

in education will lead to privatization,<br />

meaning that it will lead to an increase<br />

in the proportion of higher education<br />

finance from sources other than government.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y say that the higher the<br />

privatization the lower the access to a<br />

public good. <strong>The</strong>y say that privatization<br />

helps exclude the poor since they<br />

are the ones who least can afford it.<br />

Those who argue in favor of trade<br />

point out that no public good is ‘free’.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y believe that reforms in education<br />

finance will increase the revenue<br />

for both public and private educational<br />

providers; hence, it will increase<br />

the supply and will increase access to<br />

a public good. Recent international<br />

research on stratification and higher<br />

education suggests that higher education<br />

expansion reduces inequality;<br />

greater privatization is associated<br />

with higher levels of expansion and<br />

higher levels of social equity. <strong>The</strong> opposite<br />

is also true: control of expansion<br />

is associated with<br />

a monopoly of state financing,<br />

and hence with greater inequality<br />

of access.<br />

Trade Threatens <strong>The</strong> ‘social<br />

Contract’ Between Generations<br />

If trade leads to greater privatization<br />

(higher portions of the university<br />

budget from sources other than government),<br />

students will have to pay<br />

tuition. To do that they will have to rely<br />

on the generosity of their families,<br />

<strong>The</strong> problem is that the arguments for and against<br />

opening India to higher education trade are generally made<br />

by two divergent groups of stakeholders. Macro-economists<br />

generally favor international competition;<br />

education policy offi cials generally do not<br />

hence the present generation is expected<br />

to finance the education of future<br />

generations; and the social contract is<br />

broken. Proponents of more open trade<br />

counter with a question and a statement.<br />

<strong>The</strong> question is: when did it become<br />

true that the present generation<br />

should not sacrifice to help pay for a<br />

future generation? Isn’t that how generations<br />

have been organized since the<br />

beginning? Also, for those who cannot<br />

afford the tuition there would be scholarship<br />

aid. <strong>The</strong>refore with tuition there<br />

would be more equity, and more equity<br />

would help to strengthen the social<br />

contract between generations.<br />

Trade Jeopardizes Human<br />

Rights Because It Contradicts<br />

National Commitments For<br />

Free Education<br />

Critics point to the <strong>Dec</strong>laration of Human<br />

Rights and other legal contracts<br />

associated with the United Nations to<br />

suggest that if higher education is not<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

91


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

free of private cost it constitutes an<br />

abrogation of human rights. Those who<br />

favor open trade point out that the UN<br />

statements on education apply to mandatory<br />

education but not necessarily<br />

all education. But they also say that<br />

trade would increase human rights because<br />

it would allow access to education<br />

when currently denied, unavailable,<br />

or too costly.<br />

Trade Will Lead To Education<br />

Corruption<br />

Trade leads to greater privatization,<br />

and greater privatization leads to a decline<br />

in professionalism. <strong>The</strong> profit<br />

motive is behind corruption; hence<br />

trade will lead to greater corruption<br />

of education. Proponents of open<br />

trade acknowledge the fact that education<br />

corruption is becoming more<br />

common and is a serious problem.<br />

But they point out that it occurs in<br />

local systems without any education<br />

trade. <strong>The</strong>y also point to recent evidence<br />

suggesting that having international<br />

providers in local education<br />

markets puts a break on corruption.<br />

Students tend to demand an institution<br />

free of corruption and may frequent<br />

international higher education providers<br />

in part because they adhere to<br />

standards of professional conduct in<br />

the foreign nation where they are accredited.<br />

When international providers<br />

of higher education services offer programs<br />

free of corruption local universities<br />

will have to respond with an environment<br />

similarly corruption-free.<br />

Three Universal Ambitions For<br />

Higher Education And A Universal<br />

Dilemma<br />

Today virtually every country has three<br />

ambitions for higher education. First<br />

is the demand for greater access. And<br />

in every country the portion of the age<br />

cohort with access to post secondary<br />

education of some kind is on the<br />

increase.<br />

Second is the ambition to improve<br />

quality. Over the last decade there has<br />

been a revolution in the criteria that<br />

help define quality. Higher education<br />

If foreign competition were allowed, what India now thinks<br />

of higher quality would be eclipsed by foreign private providers.<br />

Imagine Oxford in Madras, or Harvard in Bangalore?<br />

quality now requires electronic modernity<br />

in classrooms, dormitories, libraries,<br />

science laboratories, study halls.<br />

Students are often older, work part<br />

time, and live far away from campus.<br />

High quality syllabi are no longer<br />

based on textbooks but on the most upto-date<br />

information from print and<br />

electronic sources. Students in a modern<br />

university need to have access to<br />

curricular information wherever they<br />

live or travel. Classroom instruction<br />

has changed. Class time is no longer<br />

devoted to providing information for<br />

students; instead it is devoted to the<br />

analysis of information absorbed prior<br />

to class. <strong>The</strong> internet and other forms<br />

of electronic information have changed<br />

the academic library and enhanced its<br />

quality. <strong>The</strong>re is less need for faculty<br />

or students to visit the physical place.<br />

A high quality academic library used<br />

to be defined by the quantity of its<br />

‘holdings’; now it is defined by the<br />

quantity of its access to information.<br />

<strong>The</strong> difference is enormous. Every<br />

high quality academic library has<br />

enough money to join exclusive ‘information<br />

networks’ where holdings are<br />

shared with one another, for a fee.<br />

Networks of academic libraries are<br />

trans-national, and cover university<br />

libraries in Europe, Asia and North<br />

America. Access to information<br />

is what separates the excellent libraries<br />

from the mediocre. All acad<br />

emic services, both teaching and<br />

bibliographic, are delivered through<br />

broadband facilities. Universities with<br />

low bandwidth cannot compete in<br />

quality with universities with<br />

large bandwidth. A third common ambition<br />

is to improve equity, that is, to<br />

offer scholarships and fellowships to<br />

the able students from impoverished<br />

families or from disadvantaged regions.<br />

First class universities will have<br />

enough resources to offer about one<br />

third of the students’ scholarships or<br />

fellowships from their own resources.<br />

Taken together, all three ambitions are<br />

expensive and there are few countries<br />

where all three can be financed out of<br />

public resources alone. With the increase<br />

in student numbers and with<br />

92 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

rising expectations for improvements<br />

in quality and in equity, public resources<br />

are insufficient. <strong>The</strong> scarcity of public<br />

resources is likely to be permanent<br />

and this poses a dilemma: how can<br />

higher education successfully finance<br />

its own objectives, including the<br />

traditional objectives for serving the<br />

public good?<br />

Summary<br />

Many university managers welcome<br />

the freedom to compete and lobby governments<br />

into changing legislation to<br />

make it possible. No rector or university<br />

president who has visited universities<br />

in other countries is unaware of<br />

the responsibilities and privileges of<br />

university managers in less restrictive<br />

environments. Public authorities in India<br />

should not just allow foreign universities<br />

into the country and neglect<br />

to significantly reform the legal environment<br />

in which Indian universities<br />

are asked to operate. That would neither<br />

be fair nor intelligent. Up for consideration<br />

should be changes in the<br />

entire legal structure which would allow<br />

the creation of endowments often<br />

from the overseas Diaspora (something<br />

China has mastered) and a new tax regime<br />

which encourages donations and<br />

gifts to education from both citizens<br />

and firms. Great universities, even<br />

public universities, need not depend on<br />

government financial allocation, but<br />

rather generate their own revenues<br />

though careful management. It is important<br />

to remember that new university<br />

management is the key to success.<br />

Old management styles will likely fail.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are thirty programs offering<br />

PhD degrees in university management<br />

in the United States of America, with<br />

one (Vanderbilt University) which offers<br />

a doctorate in university advancement<br />

(how to raise money). Shouldn’t<br />

similar programs be available in India?<br />

But in essence India has no choice but<br />

to invite competition into higher education.<br />

No university can be competitive<br />

today unless it has access to its<br />

own resources. <strong>The</strong> best universities<br />

have to be wise in the re-allocation of<br />

the resources they raise to help preserve<br />

their public good function. To be<br />

sure, institutions will differ in how successful<br />

they are in financing their own<br />

objectives. Some are slow because they<br />

may not recognize that to be of high<br />

quality, all universities have to take<br />

finance and management into their<br />

own hands.<br />

Some could see this ‘privatization’<br />

trend as being reprehensible, and will<br />

want to call for more piety and a return<br />

to traditional sources of finance, i.e.,<br />

from greater allocations of public expenditures<br />

at the expense of other public<br />

priorities. But others see this trend<br />

as no more than a long overdue professionalization<br />

of higher education in<br />

the legitimate pursuit of excellence.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y do not see this as a threat or as<br />

‘copying of the West’, but rather as a<br />

successful model without geographic<br />

origin in which all higher education<br />

systems must participate in order to<br />

address what is now a universal dilemma<br />

of public resource inadequacy and<br />

high public demand for quality.<br />

References<br />

• Agarwal, Pawan 2006 (May). “Higher<br />

Education in India: <strong>The</strong> Need for<br />

Change,” Working Paper Number<br />

179, ICRIER, New Delhi.<br />

• 2006 (November 11th ) “Higher<br />

Education Policy: Many Contradictions,”<br />

Economic and Political<br />

Weekly. pp. 4645 – 8.<br />

• Heyneman, SP. 1980 “Investment in<br />

Education in India: Unecon<br />

omic?” World Development No. 4 p.<br />

145 – 63<br />

• 1997 “Economics of Education: Disappointments<br />

and Potential,” pp. 25<br />

– 51 in Economics of Human Behaviour<br />

edited by T. Lakshmanasamy<br />

Mumbai: Allied Publishers Ltd.<br />

• 2001 “<strong>The</strong> Growing International<br />

Market for Education Goods and<br />

Services,” International Journal of<br />

Education Development Vol. 21 No.<br />

4 (July), pp. 345 – 61.<br />

• 2006 “Global <strong>Issue</strong>s in Higher Education”<br />

2006 eJournal USA Washington<br />

D.C.: U.S. Department of<br />

State. http://usinfo.state.gov/journals/journals.htm.<br />

• Heyneman, S.P., Anderson, K. H.<br />

and Nuraliyeva, Nazym. 2008 “<strong>The</strong><br />

Cost of Corruption in Higher Education,”<br />

2008 Comparative Education<br />

Review (forthcoming)<br />

• Yossi, Shavit, Arum, Richard and<br />

Gamoran, Adam (eds.) <strong>2007</strong> Stratification<br />

in Higher Education: A<br />

Comparative Study. Stanford, California:<br />

Stanford University Press<br />

• Tilak, Jandhyala B.G. 2005 (<strong>Dec</strong>ember<br />

2 nd .) “Higher Education: A<br />

Public Good or a Commodity for<br />

Trade: Commitment to Higher Education<br />

or Commitment of Higher<br />

Education to Trade?” Barcelona<br />

(Spain): Second Nobel Laureates<br />

Meeting. Global University Network<br />

for Innovation.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

93


Jharna Pathak<br />

Assistant Professor,<br />

Gujarat Institute of Development<br />

Research, Ahmedabad<br />

Water Resources In Gujarat And Role Of Water Markets In Breaking Gridlock In<br />

Water Scarcity – A Replicable Policy Prescription At National Level<br />

"Whiskey is for drinkin'; water<br />

is for fi ghtin'."<br />

-Mark Twain<br />

Conferences like Paris <strong>Dec</strong>laration<br />

(1998), Millennium Development<br />

Goals (2000), Vision 21:<br />

Water for People (2003); and water policies<br />

like National Water Policy (1987 and<br />

2002) and Gujarat 2010 emphasises on access<br />

to hygienic conditions, safe water and<br />

sanitation as fundamental rights to be<br />

achieved for all citizens of Gujarat.<br />

As far as availability of water resources<br />

are concerned, Gujarat can be divided into<br />

three dependent hydro-geological units,<br />

namely South, North Gujarat, Saurashtra<br />

and Kachchh. South Gujarat is better<br />

placed in terms of water resource potential<br />

than other three regions. According to the<br />

available statistics, Gujarat state has experienced<br />

rising population on one hand<br />

(from 19 million in 1951 to 60 million in<br />

2001) and the declining water resources on<br />

the other hand. As a result, the state has<br />

experienced a consistent decline in per<br />

capita availability of water, from more than<br />

2000 cubic meters in 1951 to about 1200<br />

cubic meter at present (Government of<br />

Gujarat, 1999). It has been estimated that<br />

the per capita availability will decline to<br />

910 cubic meters in 2010 and to 800 cubic<br />

meters in 2025 (Patel, 1998). <strong>The</strong> corresponding<br />

figures for India are much higher,<br />

150 cubic meters in 2010 and 1500 cubic<br />

meters in 2025. Let us examine different<br />

components of the total water resource<br />

carefully like groundwater and surface<br />

water resource.<br />

a. Surface Water<br />

As regard to surface water resources, regional<br />

inequalities are high across the regions<br />

(Table-1). <strong>The</strong> table shows that south<br />

Gujarat has 54 percent of the total surface<br />

water potential and 78 percent of the total<br />

utilisable surface water potential of the<br />

state. <strong>The</strong>se percentages are much lower<br />

in the other regions. This is mainly because<br />

of the high rainfall (upto 2000 mm)<br />

and the large number of perennial rivers<br />

in South Gujarat. Saurashtra and Kachchh<br />

have 71 and 97 rivers respectively, but except<br />

for two major rivers, Bhadar and<br />

Shetrunji, all the rivers are small and more<br />

or less seasonal. In the case of South Gu-<br />

94 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1: Region-wise Potential And Development Of Surface Water<br />

In Gujarat<br />

Details<br />

South<br />

Gujarat<br />

North<br />

Gujarat<br />

Saurashtra Kachchh Total<br />

the state during 1984, 1991, and 1997 is<br />

evident in figure 1. Figure 1 shows that the<br />

potential has declined from 20 thousand<br />

mcm per year in 1984 to 16 thousand mcm<br />

Regional Details<br />

per year in 1997, implying about 21 percent<br />

No. Of Districts 7 5 6 1 19<br />

decline. Though there has been a small<br />

increase during 1991-97 (11.16 percent increase)<br />

due to the consecutive good sea-<br />

Area sq. kms 47557 38478 64337 45612 195984<br />

% Area Of State (24%) (20%) (33%) (23%) (100%)<br />

sons, the potential is still much less than<br />

No. Of Rivers 11 6 71 97 185<br />

the same in 1984. <strong>The</strong> same trend is observed<br />

among the districts also; also the<br />

Surface Water Potential<br />

Available Mm3 17510 7940 4550 2430 32430<br />

districts show a decline in the time period<br />

(%) (54%) (25%) (14%) (7%) (100%)<br />

1984-97 (except Amreli, which shows marginal<br />

Utilisable Mm3 13900 2000 1500 400 17800<br />

increase) (Please do refer Figure-2).<br />

(%) (78%) (12%) (8%) (2%) (100%) All except four districts show some increase<br />

Source: NWRD, 1991<br />

in the potential during 1991-97,<br />

jarat, there are 17 rivers and most of them<br />

are perennial. Irrigation increases productivity,<br />

stability and sustainability (Vaidyanathan<br />

(1999); Dhawan (1995). <strong>The</strong> foremost<br />

issue is the availability of irrigation<br />

potential, its creation and utilization. Ultimate<br />

Irrigation Potential (UIP) corresponds<br />

to the gross area that could theoretically<br />

be irrigated in a year on the basis<br />

of the assumed cropping pattern and the<br />

given probability of rainfall. Pushing the<br />

irrigation potential to the ultimate level<br />

resources in the state. This along with second<br />

committee on Estimation of Groundwater<br />

Resources and Irrigation Potential<br />

in 1991 and the third Committee in 1997<br />

throws light on the changing status of<br />

groundwater in the state.<br />

About 90 percent of the groundwater is<br />

used for irrigation in agriculture. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are two types of groundwater schemes:<br />

government tubewells and private tubewells.<br />

<strong>The</strong> total groundwater potential in<br />

thanks to good rainfall (GoG 1999).<br />

Government of Gujarat (1999) in their<br />

study showed the ranges of increase and<br />

decline in groundwater potential across<br />

the different talukas of districts in the<br />

state. <strong>The</strong>y stated that talukas that experienced<br />

the highest declines in groundwater<br />

potential are from North Gujarat<br />

as well as Saurashtra and Kachchh<br />

regions.<br />

Utilisable groundwater resource is equal<br />

to the total groundwater resources<br />

available may be unsustainable in some<br />

cases. Gujarat has utilized its created potential<br />

with almost full utilization (Table-<br />

Table 2: Ultimate Irrigation Potential and<br />

Utilisation (‘000 ha)<br />

minus the provision<br />

for domestic, industrial and<br />

other uses (15 percent of the<br />

2). In as much as most of the available<br />

water resources have been almost fully<br />

exploited, special attention needs to be<br />

paid to management and maximization of<br />

utilization of the available resources.<br />

Details<br />

Utilised Irrigation Potential<br />

Potential created (97-98)<br />

Potential utilised (97-98)<br />

% of potential created to<br />

utilised irrigation potential<br />

Gujarat<br />

6103<br />

3379<br />

3097<br />

55.37<br />

India<br />

139893<br />

92742<br />

82740<br />

66.29<br />

total resources). As seen from<br />

Figure-3, that the total utilisable<br />

groundwater resources<br />

for the state is also declining.<br />

<strong>The</strong> total utilisable water resources<br />

in fact follow a similar<br />

b. Groundwater Resources<br />

Government of Gujarat has started estimating<br />

groundwater resources systematically<br />

since 1984 when the first technical<br />

group was set up to estimate the resources<br />

% of potential utilised to<br />

potential created<br />

Potential used to Utilised<br />

irrigation potential<br />

Gross irrigated area (98-99)<br />

91.65<br />

50.75<br />

3379<br />

89.19<br />

59.13<br />

73007<br />

trend as that of total water resources.<br />

Government of Gujarat<br />

(1999) shows that 76 percent<br />

of the total talukas in the<br />

state register a decrease in utilisable<br />

as well as the irrigation potential of the Source: Department of Agriculture, Government of Gujarat<br />

groundwater resources<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

95


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure-1: Total Groundwater Reserves<br />

Total Groundwater Reserves (mcm/yr)<br />

21000<br />

16000<br />

11000<br />

6000<br />

1000<br />

-4000<br />

Ahmedabad<br />

Amreli<br />

Banaskantha<br />

Baroda<br />

Bhavnagar<br />

Bharuch<br />

Valsad<br />

Dangs<br />

Districts<br />

Source: Narmada and Water Resource Department, 1984, 1991 and 1997<br />

Gandhinagar<br />

Jamnagar<br />

Junagadh<br />

Kheda<br />

Kutch<br />

1984 1991 1997<br />

Panchmahals<br />

Rajkot<br />

Sabarkantha<br />

Surat<br />

Surendranagar<br />

Mehsana<br />

Gujarat<br />

Figure-2: Bar Graph Showing Absolute Percent Change In Groundwater Reserves In Gujarat<br />

Percentage Change in Groundwater<br />

Reserves (%)<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

-20<br />

-40<br />

-60<br />

Ahmedabad<br />

Amreli<br />

Banaskantha<br />

Baroda<br />

Bhavnagar<br />

Bharuch<br />

Valsad<br />

Districts<br />

Dangs<br />

Gandhinagar<br />

Jamnagar<br />

Junagadh<br />

Kheda<br />

Kutch<br />

Panchmahals<br />

1984-1991 1991-1997 1984-1997<br />

Rajkot<br />

Sabarkantha<br />

Surat<br />

Surendranagar<br />

Mehsana<br />

Gujarat<br />

Source: Narmada and Water Resource Department, 1984, 1991 and 1997<br />

in the period 1984-97. For most of the talukas<br />

the decrease has been 25-50 percent<br />

(Government of Gujarat 1999).<br />

Figure 4 showed data relating to the levels<br />

of development of groundwater in districts<br />

of Gujarat during 1984, 1991 and<br />

1997. <strong>The</strong> average level of development<br />

shows a jump from 31 percent in 1984 to<br />

76 percent in 1997, implying an increase of<br />

more than 145 percent during the period.<br />

<strong>The</strong> state as a whole thus falls into “grey”<br />

category which is a serious situation indeed.<br />

This is evident from Map 1.<br />

In short, the long term trends do not indicate<br />

any improvement in the quality<br />

of groundwater in the state. In fact,<br />

they showed negative trends indicating<br />

worsening of the quality of groundwater<br />

96 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure-3: Bar Graph Showing Percentage Change In Utilisable Groundwater Reserves In Gujarat<br />

Percentage Change in total utilisable<br />

groundwater (%)<br />

90<br />

70<br />

50<br />

30<br />

10<br />

-10<br />

-30<br />

-50<br />

Ahmedabad<br />

Amreli<br />

Banaskantha<br />

Baroda<br />

Bhavnagar<br />

Bharuch<br />

Valsad<br />

Dangs<br />

1984-1991<br />

Districts<br />

Gandhinagar<br />

Jamnagar<br />

Junagadh<br />

Kheda<br />

Kutch<br />

Panchmahals<br />

Rajkot<br />

Sabarkantha<br />

Surat<br />

1991-1997 1984-1997<br />

Surendranagar<br />

Mehsana<br />

Gujarat<br />

Source: Narmada and Water Resource Department, 1984, 1991 and 1997<br />

over time.<br />

Government of Gujarat (1999) has projected<br />

the demand and supply of water<br />

resources in the state for 2010 and 2025.<br />

Table 3 is evident of the fact that in the<br />

year 2010 as well as in 2025, South Gujarat<br />

will be the surplus region for water while<br />

North Gujarat, Saurashtra and Kachchh<br />

will be water deficient region. <strong>The</strong> shortage<br />

is expected to increase in both the regions<br />

from 35 percent in 2010 to 83 percent<br />

in 2025 in the case of North Gujarat. This<br />

growth in demand has not been matched<br />

by an increase in supply. <strong>The</strong> problem is<br />

compounded by pollution of water, which<br />

has reduced its suitability for various uses.<br />

At the same time, in traditionally water<br />

intensive sectors of the economy such as<br />

agriculture, costs of irrigation have increased<br />

significantly. Under these circumstances,<br />

it is more important than ever<br />

before to use water efficiently. It is also<br />

necessary to anticipate and address intersectoral<br />

conflicts over allocation and use<br />

of water. <strong>The</strong> standard approach so far has<br />

been to advocate reform of water pricing<br />

across sectors to reflect the scarcity value<br />

of water. This advocacy is based on theoretical<br />

and empirical evidence on the need<br />

and desirability of such reforms including<br />

willing-to-pay studies. Nevertheless, major<br />

users of water (particularly of irrigation<br />

water) have resisted these reforms so far.<br />

Water Markets<br />

In this context, economic theory tells us<br />

that markets increase economic efficiency<br />

by allocating resources to their most valuable<br />

uses. In other words, if certain conditions<br />

are met, markets provide the correct<br />

incentives and lead to efficient resource<br />

use. <strong>The</strong>refore, one way to change the incentives<br />

so that water users support the<br />

reallocation of water and to achieving a<br />

more efficient allocation of water is<br />

through water markets. <strong>The</strong>se allow water<br />

users to buy and sell water, thus changing<br />

the whole incentive structure and breaking<br />

the logjam of water pricing reforms – when<br />

water users can gain from reallocation,<br />

they would be willing to sell water or pay a<br />

higher price for new supplies. This paper<br />

explores the role of water markets, particularly<br />

in the context of India’s water supply<br />

and sanitation sector.<br />

Apart from water markets there already<br />

In Gujarat, the per capita availability will decline to 910<br />

cubic meters in 2010 and to 800 cubic meters in 2025.<br />

<strong>The</strong> corresponding fi gures for India are much higher, 150<br />

cubic meters in 2010 and 1500 cubic meters in 2025<br />

exist numerous non-market mechanisms<br />

for allocating water in most countries.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se usufructuary rights to water have<br />

evolved either explicitly through laws and<br />

regulations or implicitly through conventions.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se water rights are generally<br />

based on one of three systems: first-come,<br />

first-served allocation (also known as<br />

prior appropriation rights), allocation<br />

based on proximity to flows (or riparian<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

97


Ahmedabad<br />

Amreli<br />

Banaskantha<br />

Baroda<br />

Bhavnagar<br />

Bharuch<br />

Vaksad<br />

Dangs<br />

Gandhinagar<br />

Jamnagar<br />

Junagadh<br />

Kheda<br />

Kutch<br />

Panchmahals<br />

Rajkot<br />

Sabarkantha<br />

Surat<br />

Surendranagar<br />

Mehsana<br />

Gujarat<br />

REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

rights) and public allocation (Sampath<br />

1992, Holden and Thobani 1996, Haddad<br />

2000). Whereas queuing for water is the<br />

basic approach of the prior appropriation<br />

doctrine, the location of one’s land determines<br />

water rights under the riparian doctrine.<br />

Under this approach whoever owns<br />

land along (above) the water has the right<br />

to ownership/reasonable use of the water.<br />

Finally, public allocation involves publicly<br />

administered distribution of water. “Under<br />

this system, public authorities decide<br />

how to allocate water using guidelines or<br />

laws establishing priorities and often specify<br />

the uses to which the water can be put.”<br />

(Holden and Thobani op. cit. p. 2) Most<br />

developing countries follow variants of the<br />

last approach where essentially the rights<br />

are allocated free – though there may be<br />

a charge for water use (typically based on<br />

the amount of irrigated area), the water<br />

rights themselves are obtained without<br />

charge. <strong>The</strong> track record, however, of administered<br />

systems of water allocation has<br />

not been impressive - across different systems<br />

and states in India, governments,<br />

however experience shortage of funds to<br />

carry out necessary R&R works of the<br />

system. At many places, canals were laid<br />

at uneven level and structures were in bad<br />

shape, which results in frequent breaching<br />

of canals. Consequently, reliability of water<br />

at scheduled time was not taken care<br />

off. Given these problems, Rosegrant and<br />

Binswanger (1994) have suggested that<br />

there may be a better way to achieve efficient<br />

allocation of water by changing incentives<br />

so that users support the efforts<br />

to reallocate water. <strong>The</strong>y argue that if water<br />

markets are established where water is<br />

scarce, then users can buy and sell water<br />

or pay a higher price for new supplies.<br />

While this is well known, the important<br />

point to note here is that none of these<br />

systems fulfil the conditions for well-defined<br />

property rights to water, which in<br />

turn are essential for water markets to exist.<br />

In this context, the question could well<br />

be asked, “Why not use administered efficiency-based<br />

pricing of water as an intermediate<br />

policy between managed quantity<br />

allocation and water markets?” <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are three reasons why water markets could<br />

be preferred to administer efficiency pricing<br />

(i.e., pricing marginal units of water at<br />

their marginal cost). First is the reduction<br />

in information costs – whereas it is theoretically<br />

possible to devise and implement<br />

a system of administered prices which<br />

would lead to efficient allocation of water,<br />

the information requirements are demanding<br />

and may require experimentation<br />

by trial and error. Second and perhaps<br />

more important, if the value of prevailing<br />

usufructuary water rights (formal or informal)<br />

has already been capitalised into<br />

the value of irrigated land, then imposition<br />

of administered pricing is perceived<br />

by right holders as expropriation of those<br />

rights. In effect, this would result in a<br />

capital loss for irrigated farms. This could<br />

explain the strong resistance by these<br />

groups to establishing administered efficiency<br />

prices. Finally, the administrative<br />

solution presumes “far-seeing,incorrupti<br />

Figure-4: Bar And Line Graph Showing In Level Of Groundwater Development<br />

200<br />

150<br />

Level of development (%)<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

Source: Narmada and Water Resource Department, 1984, 1991 and 1997<br />

Districts<br />

1984 1991 1997<br />

98 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Map-1: Ground Water Categorisation<br />

Source: NWR and WSD, Government of Gujarat<br />

ble,influence-free” administrative bodies<br />

that are able to design and implement the<br />

‘correct’ prices. In practice, this may often<br />

not be the case: these bodies could be captured<br />

by interest groups or they may be<br />

short-sighted and unable to estimate future<br />

demand, or they may be unable to set<br />

and collect appropriate water charges.<br />

Advocates of administrative approaches,<br />

however, often ignore these problems focusing<br />

at the same time on imperfections<br />

of markets that supposedly reduce the efficacy<br />

of market-based solutions! In effect,<br />

if two second best states are being compared<br />

it may be difficult to order them.<br />

<strong>The</strong> numerous informal water markets<br />

existing in North Gujarat (tubewell companies)<br />

and South Gujarat (illegal water<br />

lifting from canal) suggest that water users<br />

will buy and sell water even if it is illegal or<br />

discouraged by the government.<br />

Even though water markets are believed<br />

to change incentives for water user and<br />

improve water allocation, there are number<br />

of constraints that may prevent introduction<br />

of water markets. For formal water<br />

markets to work, one key component is for<br />

users to have some type of water right or<br />

use right they can buy or sell. This may<br />

create a serious problem not only because<br />

water rights may be difficult to establish,<br />

but also because public water agencies feel<br />

they will lose a great deal of power if they<br />

allocate water rights to users. If water users<br />

have rights, this means that system operators<br />

have the responsibility to deliver<br />

water to the users more or less when the<br />

users want it. In contrast, if a government<br />

agency holds the water rights, they can dictate<br />

farmers the conditions under which<br />

they will receive water including in some<br />

cases, necessary side payments from farmers.<br />

If water rights are made tradable, this<br />

creates an even greater dilemma for government<br />

agencies. To prevent losing control<br />

over tradable water rights, Comision<br />

Nacional del Agua in Mexico and some of<br />

the water districts of western United States<br />

limit trading among water districts. A water<br />

user must obtain special government<br />

approval to sell water outside the jurisdiction<br />

and any profits from the sale must accrue<br />

to district and not the seller. This, of<br />

course, discourages interdistrict trading,<br />

but reduces the chance that trades will<br />

have third party effect. Such instances of<br />

formal water markets in India are non-existent.<br />

Experience of Mexico, Chile, United<br />

States, France, where water markets<br />

exist in one form or the other, assists in<br />

understanding organisational problems of<br />

water trading through market. First is the<br />

resistance to water trading between or<br />

among district or jurisdiction. Second is<br />

the problem of establishing water rights<br />

and giving the users more control over water.<br />

Other problems which raise the transaction<br />

cost of water trading include legal<br />

challenges by third parties who feel they<br />

In the formal water markets water rights may be very diffi<br />

cult to establish. What's more, public water agencies feel<br />

that they will lose a great deal of power if they allocate<br />

water rights/user rights to users<br />

might be damaged by a transfer, the lack<br />

of sufficient infrastructure to transfer water<br />

among potential buyers, and lack of an<br />

effective means for verifying and enforcing<br />

water rights.<br />

Establishing Water Markets<br />

Before we determine whether there is a<br />

need of reducing transaction cost and<br />

methods to do so, there is a need to understand<br />

the past experience of markets for<br />

allocating water resource. This is done<br />

with the assumption that if a country has<br />

experience with water markets, then it is<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

99


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table-3: Details Of Availability And Requirement Of Water Resources In Gujarat<br />

Details<br />

Availability Of<br />

Water (mcm)<br />

Requirement Of<br />

Water (mcm)<br />

Surplus (mcm)<br />

Deficit Of Water Resources<br />

(mcm)<br />

As Per <strong>The</strong> Year 2010<br />

South Gujarat 24750 14390 10360 -<br />

Saurashtra & Kachchh 9740 13100 - 3360 (34.49)<br />

North Gujarat 10400 17400 - 7000 (67.31)<br />

Total 44890 44890 10360 10360<br />

As Per <strong>The</strong> Year 2025<br />

South Gujarat 28187 15500 12687 -<br />

Saurashtra & Kachchh 10170 14440 - 4269 (41.97)<br />

North Gujarat 10212 18630 - 8418 (82.43)<br />

Total 48570 48570 12687 12687<br />

Source: NWR and WSD, Government of Gujarat<br />

Note: figures in parentheses indicate the percentage shortage<br />

likely that water will be one of the goods<br />

that can be allocated using market forces.<br />

At least in the case of markets for irrigation<br />

water it appears that both formal and<br />

informal systems of water system are at<br />

work. In India, other than recent intervention<br />

in Maharashtra, there is a dearth of<br />

the experience of the formal market systems.<br />

But numerous countries experience<br />

with water markets are wide ranging, with<br />

most of the formal water markets in North<br />

and South America. For example in several<br />

areas of Chile, the legalisation of water<br />

trading and recording of water use<br />

rights were sufficient to foster an active<br />

formal water markets with relatively low<br />

transaction costs. <strong>The</strong> combination of effective<br />

water user association and well developed<br />

irrigation infrastructure allowed<br />

these farmers to easily trade water<br />

throughout the system including trades<br />

with the urban section (Hearne 1995).<br />

Garrido (1997) shows the economic gains,<br />

when trading is restricted to an individual<br />

water district. In contrast, if trades are allowed<br />

among communities that are subject<br />

to different supply constraints and drought<br />

conditions, the gains from trade can be<br />

substantial. As per his estimates, inter<br />

community trading results in 50 percent<br />

gain. In their analysis of selected water<br />

markets in Chile, Hearne and Easter<br />

(1997) found trading both within and between<br />

sectors. For permanent transactions,<br />

they felt the importance of well defined<br />

water use rights.<br />

In the case of informal markets in Asia,<br />

Shah (1993) finds that in areas with dependable<br />

groundwater recharge, the selling<br />

of tubewell water has benefited a wide<br />

range of farmers by allowing them to increase<br />

crop production and income.<br />

Groundwater markets play a major role in<br />

boosting agricultural production and returns<br />

to farmers from crop production.<br />

Saleth (1997) estimates that 20 percent of<br />

14 million pump sets are likely to be involved<br />

in water trading. This means that<br />

water markets are providing water for<br />

about 6 million hectares or 15 percent of<br />

the total area irrigated by groundwater. In<br />

Pakistan, 21 percent of the total area irrigated<br />

is from groundwater. Meinzen-Dick<br />

(1997) found that water markets increased<br />

the availability of water and the reliability<br />

of supplies. Study by Pathak (<strong>2007</strong>) showed<br />

that with greater water supplies and reliability,<br />

yield and returns increased for those<br />

who purchased water particularly for those<br />

who also had access to canal water. However,<br />

the highest yields and income was<br />

still found among farmers who owned<br />

tubewells and had access to canal water.<br />

Even though groundwater markets appear<br />

to be growing rapidly and providing a more<br />

assured source of water to many farmers,<br />

a number of concerns have been raised<br />

about the performance of informal water<br />

markets. Some of the problems are the<br />

following:<br />

• high water demand and declining<br />

groundwater level.<br />

• water rights are not well defined.<br />

• lead to over drafting of aquifers whichcauses<br />

decline in groundwater supplies.<br />

• potential for monopoly pricing and discrimination.<br />

Conclusion<br />

This paper shows that water markets have<br />

100 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

been in operation in many parts of the<br />

world including India. Although informal<br />

water markets have been in existence for<br />

decades, formal markets with clearly assigned,<br />

private and transferable water<br />

rights are of relatively recent origin. In<br />

Chile, Western USA and Australia, where<br />

there are developed formal water markets,<br />

there have been significant gains from water<br />

trading, particularly from trades between<br />

agricultural and urban users as water<br />

gets reallocated to more productive<br />

uses. In many instances, water trading has<br />

alleviated water shortages. International<br />

experience also shows that formal and developed<br />

water markets strengthen the incentives<br />

for conservation and more efficient<br />

use of water. For example, farmers<br />

have responded by switching to water-saving<br />

technologies and high-value, less water<br />

intensive crops. <strong>The</strong> Indian experience<br />

with water markets has been positive, although<br />

there have been only limited gains<br />

as markets have remained informal, localised<br />

and primitive. Thus, while these markets<br />

have led to some efficiency gains and<br />

have expanded the scope for many resource-poor<br />

farmers to access irrigation,<br />

inter-sectoral water transfers have not<br />

taken place so far. <strong>The</strong> current challenge<br />

in India is therefore to establish formal<br />

water markets, which will expand the scope<br />

of trading and make inter-sectoral water<br />

transfers possible. Further, since formal<br />

water markets have a legal basis, effective<br />

regulation can be designed to address the<br />

issue of ecological sustainability. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

markets will be of significant relevance to<br />

the urban sector, which has been suffering<br />

from acute shortages of water, but has not<br />

been able to access informal markets. A<br />

formal water market has the potential to<br />

provide low cost solutions to augmentation<br />

of water supply relatively quickly. With respect<br />

to further steps, it is desirable to<br />

make an indepth analysis on various important<br />

questions like<br />

• What are the legitimate users that need<br />

to be protected in water transaction?<br />

• Should third parties have to take into<br />

account the economic losses caused by<br />

not allowing the transfer?<br />

References<br />

• Dhawan, B.D. (1995), “Groundwater<br />

depletion, Land Degradation and Irrigated<br />

Agriculture in India. New Delhi:<br />

Commonwealth Publishers<br />

• Easter, K. William, Ariel Dinar and<br />

Mark W. Rosegrant. 1998. “Water Markets:<br />

Transaction Costs and Institutional<br />

Options,” in K.W. Easter et al. (eds.),<br />

Markets for Water: Potential and<br />

• Performance, Kluwer, Dordrecht, <strong>The</strong><br />

Netherlands.<br />

• Shah, Tushaar. 1993. Groundwater Market<br />

and Irrigation Development, Mumbai,<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

• Hearne R., 1995. <strong>The</strong> Market Allocation<br />

of Natural Resources: Transaction<br />

of Water Use in Chile. Ph.D Dissertation,<br />

Department of Applied Economics,<br />

University of Minnesota.<br />

• Garrido, (1997). An Economic Analysis<br />

of Water Markets within the Spanish<br />

Agricultural Sector: Can they Provide<br />

Substantial Benefits? In K.W. Easter et<br />

al. (eds.), Markets for Water: Potential<br />

and Performance, Kluwer, Dordrecht,<br />

<strong>The</strong> Netherlands.<br />

• Government of India. (2002): “National<br />

Water Policy”, Ministry of Water Resources,<br />

New Delhi, India<br />

• Government of India. (1987): “National<br />

Water Policy”, Ministry of Water Resources,<br />

New Delhi, India<br />

• Government of Gujarat. (1999): “White<br />

Paper on Water Policy”, Ministry of<br />

Water Resources, Government of Gujarat,<br />

Gujarat.<br />

• Haddad, Brent M. 2000. Rivers of<br />

Gold: Designing Markets to Allocate<br />

Water in California, Island Press,<br />

Washington, DC.<br />

• Hearne and Easter (1997). <strong>The</strong> Economic<br />

and Financial Gains from Water<br />

Markets in Chile. In K.W. Easter et al.<br />

(eds.), Markets for Water: Potential and<br />

Performance, Kluwer, Dordrecht, <strong>The</strong><br />

Netherlands.<br />

• Holden, Paul and Mateen Thobani.<br />

1996. “Tradable Water Rights: A Property<br />

Rights Approach to Resolving Water<br />

Shortages and Promoting Investment”,<br />

Policy Research Working Paper<br />

-1627, World Bank, Washington, DC.<br />

• Meinzen-Dick (1997) Groundwater<br />

Markets in Pakistan: Institutional Development<br />

and Productivity Impacts. In<br />

K.W. Easter et al. (eds.), Markets for<br />

Water: Potential and Performance, Kluwer,<br />

Dordrecht, <strong>The</strong> Netherlands.<br />

• Pathak Jharna (<strong>2007</strong>). Irrigation Management<br />

Transfer: Problems and Policies.<br />

A Ph.D thesis submitted to Gujarat<br />

University.<br />

• Rosegrant, Mark W. and Hans P. Binswanger.<br />

1994. “Markets in Tradable<br />

Water Rights: Potential for Efficiency<br />

Gains in Developing Country Water<br />

Resource Allocation,” World Development,<br />

22(11): 1613-1625.<br />

• Sampath, R.K. 1992. “<strong>Issue</strong>s in Irrigation<br />

Pricing in Developing Countries”,<br />

World Development, 20(7): 967-977.<br />

• Vaidyanathan, A. (1999). Water Resource<br />

Management: Institutions and<br />

Irrigation Development in India. New<br />

Delhi: Oxford University Press.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

101


V. Shunmugam D.G. Prasad<br />

Chief Economist<br />

Economist<br />

Multi Commodity Exchange Of India Ltd., Mumbai<br />

Commodity Futures: A Catalyst For<br />

Agricultural Development<br />

“Everything else can wait but<br />

not agriculture.”<br />

-Pandit Jawaharlal Nehru<br />

Historically, India has been considered<br />

an agrarian society;<br />

the fact that the basics of our<br />

culture and lifestyle have been derived<br />

from it stands testimony to our historical<br />

dependence on agriculture. Of late, the<br />

relative share of agriculture during early<br />

1990s declined significantly due to its<br />

sagging growth and leaping progress in<br />

the other sectors. Currently, services<br />

sector had become the largest contributor<br />

to the GDP and the agriculture sector<br />

had become the least contributor<br />

with its share of below 20 percent. <strong>The</strong><br />

reality is India cannot afford to neglect<br />

the agriculture sector and back pedal on<br />

reforms related to this sector with about<br />

two thirds of its population still directly<br />

or indirectly dependent on it, especially<br />

with apparent imbalances in the commodities<br />

economy making the policy<br />

choices narrow for the decision makers.<br />

At this point in time the high agricultural<br />

commodities prices combined with<br />

poor supply chain efficiency in the country<br />

affecting all sections of the society<br />

especially with the common man bearing<br />

the brunt of it. Despite the reports<br />

of high commodity prices at the retail<br />

end, farmers today are still complaining<br />

about stagnant prices at the market they<br />

sell. This could lead to the risk of many<br />

shifting their profession, often abandoning<br />

farming activities.<br />

Agrarian Challenges<br />

At the current situation of limited availability<br />

of resources, the country, indeed,<br />

requires a paradigm change from increase<br />

in production to improvement in<br />

the input-use efficiency, to enhance our<br />

competency in the agriculture sector.<br />

Given the current constraints of poor<br />

realization from agriculture and hence<br />

their poor investment in technology and<br />

lack of investment in infrastructure<br />

leading to the operation of a vicious cycle<br />

in the farming sector. This is not to<br />

say that those who command resources<br />

for example the large landholders were<br />

able to overcome the operation of this<br />

vicious cycle with their sheer bargaining<br />

102<br />

THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

power and reinvestment of profits back<br />

into farming. However, a large chunk of<br />

medium, small, and marginal farmers<br />

are still to come out of the clutches of<br />

the operation of this vicious cycle. Hence<br />

the need of the hour is to provide market<br />

based solutions to these farmers that<br />

could address the problems associated<br />

with inefficient and opaque markets;<br />

poor infrastructure including input supply<br />

systems, low credibility among the<br />

lending institutions, poor infrastructure<br />

especially in terms of transportation,<br />

warehouses, standardization and quality<br />

testing facilities, low value addition and<br />

a rather weak agricultural extension system,<br />

among others. Though there are<br />

production related issues that would<br />

need to be addressed, we believe it could<br />

be effectively tackled by equipping the<br />

farmers through market based empowerment.<br />

Remedies for these challenges<br />

can be approached by classifying them<br />

into two broad categories — marketing<br />

system ills and infrastructure challenges.<br />

As for addressing the infrastructure<br />

challenges, increased private investment<br />

could well be the answer, at least for<br />

overcoming them partially in commercially<br />

profitable areas. However, in the<br />

current marketing system wherein a<br />

large number of middlemen are involved<br />

in the supply chain, prices are largely<br />

determined by traders with immediate<br />

consideration to their profits. This eventually<br />

leads to lesser returns on agriculture<br />

making private investments in agriculture<br />

least remunerative.<br />

<strong>The</strong> current marketing system in the<br />

country leads to large price spreads suppressing<br />

the prices of commodities actually<br />

offered to the producers while inflating<br />

the prices that the end consumers<br />

are made to pay which often has no relation<br />

to the value addition that the products<br />

had undergone. This could be attributable<br />

to lack of transparency in the<br />

market and an inefficient price discovery<br />

mechanism. Farmers in most of the rural<br />

areas arrive at the market uninformed<br />

of the market situation due to lack of effective/reliable<br />

market information dissemination<br />

systems. Adding to their<br />

woes, farmers more often take sowing<br />

decisions based on the prevailing prices<br />

(unaware of the future price directions),<br />

which would most often prove them<br />

wrong. Thus, remunerative prices for<br />

their produce remain ever elusive to<br />

farmers and remain a major cause of the<br />

current stagnation in agricultural<br />

growth. In other words, the lack of motivational<br />

factor i.e. dwindling returns<br />

to labor and investment is the key reason<br />

for this stagnancy. Increased profits<br />

would be possible only if farmers were<br />

provided fair prices that are reflective of<br />

their supply and demand.<br />

Reforms On Anvil: Move towards<br />

Market Based Mechanism<br />

In a perfect market, price is determined<br />

by the forces of demand and supply (fundamentals).<br />

Frequent changes in the<br />

fundamentals lead to increased price<br />

volatility. In order to make the agriculture<br />

sector more vibrant the Indian Government<br />

allowed national online futures<br />

trading in commodities during 2003.<br />

<strong>The</strong> objective was to ensure stabilization<br />

of prices of agricultural products and<br />

provide farmers with alternative markets<br />

that could equip them in taking the right<br />

decisions in sowing, harvesting, and selling<br />

of the right crop at the right market<br />

value at the right time. Emergence of<br />

futures trading in this context, following<br />

the Government’s initiative, which serves<br />

the above needs is of great significance<br />

as a remedy to the ills in the existing<br />

marketing system.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Advent Of Futures Trading<br />

Introduction of national online commodity<br />

derivatives trading would remain<br />

the most significant development in the<br />

history of Indian commodity markets as<br />

the earlier exchanges remained regional<br />

Existence of the three national exchanges had brought in<br />

revolutionary changes in the Indian commodity markets<br />

by bringing in spatial integration and temporal price discovery<br />

for commodities at the national level.<br />

both in terms of their participation and<br />

products. Currently, there are three national<br />

exchanges, and twenty two regional<br />

exchanges that are operating in the<br />

country. Existence of the three national<br />

exchanges had brought in revolutionary<br />

changes in the Indian commodity markets<br />

by bringing in spatial integration<br />

and temporal price discovery for commodities<br />

at the national level.<br />

Undoubtedly, the revival of commodity<br />

futures trading in India has led to a<br />

reduction in daily price volatility of various<br />

commodities in the domestic spot<br />

markets. Table - I provides a comparative<br />

account of price volatility of three<br />

select agri-commodities in the spot markets<br />

before and after the introduction of<br />

futures trading at the Multi Commodity<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

103


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table I: Volatility Of Spot Prices<br />

Commodity<br />

Pre MCX futures<br />

(Percentage)<br />

Exchange of India Ltd. (MCX), the<br />

country’s No. 1 commodity derivatives<br />

exchange (in <strong>2007</strong>) located in Mumbai.<br />

It was found that there has been a<br />

marked reduction in daily price volatility<br />

in all these three commodities. <strong>The</strong><br />

finding corroborates that the resurrection<br />

of futures trading has indeed contributed<br />

to increased stability in agricultural<br />

markets, which in turn has helped<br />

Indian farmers receive a stable income<br />

besides making efficient sell/store decisions.<br />

Availability of future price signals<br />

also reduced the pre and post harvest<br />

differences in prices avoiding the rush of<br />

arrivals immediately post-harvest.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Drive Behind And <strong>The</strong><br />

Benefits Of Futures Markets<br />

Virtually all agricultural commodities<br />

in India have a long supply chain with a<br />

number of middlemen performing the<br />

roles and functions of the brokers, commission<br />

agents, processors, wholesalers,<br />

retailers, etc., and thus making their<br />

marketing costlier that their production<br />

at times. In almost all the cases, the middlemen-levied<br />

charges do not really mirror<br />

the true value of the economic function<br />

they perform in taking a given<br />

commodity from farm gate to the consumer’s<br />

plate. Thus the existing markets<br />

Post MCX futures<br />

(Percentage)<br />

Wheat 4.80 3.49<br />

Tur 1.47 2.4<br />

Urad 2.58 1.8<br />

Source: Delhi Wholesale Market, CMIE, www.cmie.com/database/services<br />

Note: Daily prices were considered.<br />

Post futures period include inception of specific contracts on MCX platform<br />

till June 2006 and corresponding period before inception of futures contracts<br />

was considered for pre-futures.<br />

had a biased marketing<br />

system offering the producer<br />

the lowest while<br />

charging the consumer<br />

the highest. Obviously,<br />

such an undesirable system<br />

cannot continue for<br />

ever and the stakeholders<br />

would look for a way out<br />

— an efficient market<br />

that enables everybody to<br />

participate in a price discovery mechanism<br />

that is fully transparent and yet is<br />

capable of bringing the cost of the value<br />

chain down to the minimum. Here is<br />

where the birth of futures exchanges<br />

proved out to be the panacea for many<br />

of the above ills faced by the physical<br />

markets. <strong>The</strong>se exchanges performed<br />

the function of advance price discovery,<br />

increasing the efficiency of the markets<br />

by helping them streamline prices to reflect<br />

on the commodity fundamentals<br />

rather than reflecting the profit making<br />

initiatives of the private players in the<br />

value chain. That apart, commodity exchanges<br />

also facilitate private participation<br />

in the market related infrastructure<br />

investments. <strong>The</strong> exchanges’ efforts in<br />

providing effective collateral management,<br />

improved warehousing for<br />

agri-products, widening the network of<br />

quality certification and product standardization<br />

agencies, and providing better<br />

logistics solutions have already<br />

brought in the much needed efficiencies<br />

in the ecosystem.<br />

Commodity Exchanges As Catalysts<br />

Of Agricultural Marketing<br />

Infrastructure Development<br />

MCX took various initiatives to launch<br />

two major infrastructure projects — Na-<br />

tional Spot Exchange Ltd. (NSEL) and<br />

National Bulk Handling Corporation<br />

Ltd. (NBHC). NSEL would provide a<br />

national-level electronic platform for<br />

spot trading in agricultural commodities<br />

by integrating all the physical markets<br />

into a common national market. This<br />

initiative is meant to empower rural India<br />

to usher in the next Green Revolution<br />

by harnessing technology. <strong>The</strong> effective<br />

co-existence of the spot and<br />

futures markets in the ecosystem will<br />

surely help in coming up with fair price<br />

discovery empowering Indian farmers in<br />

several ways, including leading them to<br />

the use of improved technology, thus,<br />

catalyzing rapid growth in agricultural<br />

production. Services that NBHC – the<br />

delivery arm of MCX extend include<br />

warehousing and bulk handling of agricultural<br />

commodities by managing a<br />

chain of accredited warehouses across<br />

the country, grading and assaying, quality<br />

systems for storage and protection,<br />

offloading and disposal services, demating<br />

of warehouse receipts, etc. In a nutshell,<br />

NBHC’s existence is slowly leading<br />

to awareness in the ecosystem regarding<br />

futures trading, collateral management<br />

systems, warehouse receipt financing,<br />

quality and standards, etc., leading to an<br />

overall improvement in the ecosystem.<br />

Thus, commodity exchanges are the seed<br />

sown to provide a new direction to agricultural<br />

productivity and returns to agriproducts<br />

by improving the marketing<br />

systems of the country with participatory<br />

efforts from all the stakeholders in the<br />

system. Exchanges ensured sustained<br />

and increased returns to agricultural<br />

products through transparent and participatory<br />

price discovery process. Besides,<br />

they also create an environment<br />

104<br />

THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

where farmers have a choice — many options<br />

of selling their commodities such<br />

as spot markets and futures markets.<br />

Also, as futures trading is done at the<br />

national level in an electronic format,<br />

integration of banks and institutional<br />

traders on the commodities marketplace<br />

creates several institutional options for<br />

farmers. Thus, with the introduction of<br />

national online commodity exchanges,<br />

the seed for democratic reforms in market<br />

in its process and its infrastructure<br />

has been sown and only time and appropriate<br />

nurturing by supporting policies<br />

can tell us how far these could go.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Global Impact Of Domestic<br />

Commexes<br />

<strong>The</strong> establishment of national commodity<br />

exchanges in India is creating a nearperfect<br />

market situation, with a much<br />

wider participation from the market<br />

ecosystem during local and global market<br />

timings. Feeling the necessity for<br />

aligning themselves with the international<br />

markets in globally traded commodities<br />

where there are international<br />

linkages, the domestic commodity exchanges<br />

make use of maximum possible<br />

hours of operation unlike their equity<br />

counterparts in the country by bridging<br />

the time zones of Tokyo and New York<br />

while passing on the price signals to the<br />

European markets. In fact, given the<br />

country’s potential share in global supply<br />

and demand, India has the potential<br />

to become the price-setter in about seventeen<br />

commodities and thus, emerge as<br />

a dominant player in the global markets.<br />

Of late, with the constant strengthening<br />

of the futures market, India has started<br />

emitting price signals to linked global<br />

markets in those commodities having<br />

international linkages. In commodities<br />

such as gold, of which India is the world’s<br />

largest importer and consumer, and<br />

chana, of which the country is the largest<br />

producer/consumer,India, with the<br />

emergence of futures markets, is slowly<br />

gaining the rightful place in the world<br />

markets by setting the prices. <strong>The</strong> prices<br />

disseminated by Indian exchanges have<br />

become increasingly acceptable to the<br />

business and farmer communities as<br />

they are discovered after assimilating<br />

the information available to<br />

the participants.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Global Commodity Arena<br />

And MCX’s Role<br />

MCX has made its mark in the global<br />

commodities exchange industry by becoming<br />

the largest silver exchange (in<br />

terms of the number of contracts traded),<br />

the second largest in natural gas,<br />

the third largest bullion exchange after<br />

NYMEX & TOCOM, and also the third<br />

largest exchange in crude oil among the<br />

top 10 commodity derivatives exchanges<br />

in the world in <strong>2007</strong> with only retail, and<br />

corporate participation and without<br />

products other than futures on its platform.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Exchange believes that as India<br />

becomes a truly global economy, it<br />

would offer greater potential in commodities,<br />

as regulatory and market impediments<br />

that prevent building up of<br />

volumes in the exchanges would get dissolved<br />

and the exchanges would be left<br />

to their own to prove their mettle. <strong>The</strong><br />

price correlation in the globally traded<br />

commodities indicates that the prices<br />

discovered in the MCX had more than<br />

90 percent correlation with their international<br />

benchmarks suggesting that the<br />

prices moved in tandem with the international<br />

markets, following a right combination<br />

of domestic and international<br />

Given India's potential share in global supply and demand,<br />

India has the potential to become the price-setter in about<br />

seventeen commodities and thus, emerge as a dominant<br />

player in the global markets<br />

fundamentals. This makes the domestic<br />

online exchanges a cost-effective better<br />

alternative to the domestic participants<br />

particularly for the SME companies,<br />

with enough liquidity as found in the International<br />

benchmark exchanges. However,<br />

the potential in other commodities<br />

and for reaching out to the end-users is<br />

yet to be harnessed, pending various<br />

regulatory reforms.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Road Ahead<br />

<strong>The</strong> proposed amendments to the Forward<br />

Contracts Regulation Act is likely<br />

to originate a slew of changes in the<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

105


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

commodity derivatives ecosystem. Firstly,<br />

the functional autonomy of the Forward<br />

Markets Commission (FMC) – the<br />

regulator for the commodity markets, as<br />

proposed in the FCRA would make it<br />

more vibrant in the eyes of the market<br />

participants and policy makers and other<br />

regulators such as RBI and SEBI.<br />

This could help facilitate entry of other<br />

participants such as banks and mutual<br />

funds as their regulators namely RBI<br />

and SEBI respectively develop confidence<br />

in the functioning and regulation<br />

of the markets. Further, new products<br />

such as options will offer the stakeholders<br />

(least risk appetite) with one more<br />

instrument for risk management. This<br />

could be more suited to farmers participation<br />

as they are less risk-hungry and<br />

could help them overcome the liquidity<br />

problems that they would otherwise face<br />

in the futures instrument in meeting the<br />

daily MTM margin requirements. <strong>The</strong><br />

entry of banks, MFs and foreign institutional<br />

investors (FIIs) would enhance<br />

the liquidity and professionalism in the<br />

markets and thereby bolstering the efficiency<br />

of the Indian commodity markets,<br />

which is essentially needed at a time<br />

when the country’s market is being<br />

opened to traders and investors from<br />

across the borders. Perhaps, with banks<br />

allowed it could even facilitate farmer’s<br />

participation helping them overcome the<br />

present hurdles in their participation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> permission to launch index-based<br />

instruments following the amendment to<br />

FCRA would open the doors for exchanges<br />

to come out with derivatives<br />

such as index linked futures and options,<br />

sector based derivatives, and weather<br />

derivatives. While rocketing in the current<br />

high-growth trajectory, the domestic<br />

exchanges have also effectively adopted<br />

global best practices from the<br />

<strong>The</strong> permission to launch index-based instruments would<br />

open the doors for exchanges to come out with derivatives<br />

such as index linked futures and options, sector based<br />

derivatives, and weather derivatives<br />

benchmark exchanges to leap forward<br />

and attain higher levels of efficiency and<br />

trading volumes. In turn, these efficient<br />

marketplaces with right products and<br />

participation are likely to transform the<br />

economy’s competitiveness and help<br />

raise the global competitiveness of Indian<br />

products and services This would<br />

help India to become an efficient global<br />

manufacturing hub and shore up its performance<br />

on the external trade front.<br />

Given all the positive effects of the futures<br />

exchanges to the economy and the<br />

markets, the growth in the commodities<br />

sector has been unsupported unlike its<br />

financial derivatives counterpart.<br />

All in all, one must acknowledge that<br />

given the current trend in globalization<br />

of economies, competitiveness would<br />

remain a major factor affecting the performance<br />

of many of these economies<br />

and may even determine their survival<br />

in a more liberalized trade environment.<br />

As production determines part of the<br />

costs of the product or a service so is<br />

its marketing cost. <strong>The</strong> more efficiently<br />

commodities are marketed in an<br />

economy could solve a part of the<br />

problem that India is facing in moving<br />

up the ladder in its trading competitiveness.<br />

As goods and services becomes<br />

cheaper due to reduced cost of<br />

marketing it, such as through reduced<br />

wastages through quality production,<br />

standardization and grading, and scientific<br />

storage, paying the intermediary<br />

the right value for the services that<br />

he renders to the marketing of the<br />

commodity. Increased marketing efficiency<br />

coupled with increased production<br />

efficiency is likely to help India remain<br />

competitive. For increased market<br />

efficiency, it is necessary that there are<br />

efficient futures markets that help the<br />

producers and value chain players take<br />

effective production and marketing decisions<br />

to reduce the cost of marketing.<br />

Hence no one can deny that efficient<br />

markets are as much important as like<br />

the efficient industries or the agricultural<br />

production systems that would efficiently<br />

produce primary or the processed<br />

products to help our economy<br />

remain competitive and there is no other<br />

alternative to the commodity derivatives<br />

trading that can bring about necessary<br />

efficiency in the existing<br />

market ecosystem.<br />

106<br />

THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


AN ARINDAM CHAUDHURI & PLANMAN MEDIA PRESENTATION<br />

TSI on Tragedies Stalking South Asia’s<br />

Leading Political Families<br />

only<br />

7 J A N - 1 3 JAN2008 Rs 10<br />

SPECIAL REPORT 24<br />

THE CROSS AROUND<br />

THEIR NECK IN ORISSA<br />

t h e n a t i o n ’ s g r e a t e s t n e w s w e e k l y<br />

DESTINY’S<br />

CHILDREN<br />

TRYST 54<br />

Exclusive<br />

interview: Air<br />

Chief Fali Major<br />

A TSI EXCLUSIVE XPOSÉ 74<br />

<strong>The</strong> sexiest woman alive<br />

Charlize (angel?) <strong>The</strong>ron, in a candid<br />

conversation about her profession<br />

NO . 1 I N R EG I ONAL REACH<br />

NOW<br />

LANGUAGES!<br />

THE NEW ADDICTION OF THE<br />

SMART INDIAN<br />

For <strong>The</strong> First Time In Global Media History... A Newsweekly In 13 Languages!


Deepika Wadhwa,<br />

Research Scholar,<br />

Centre for Economic Studies<br />

and Planning, Jawaharlal<br />

Nehru University, New Delhi<br />

Overseas Investment By Indian Firms:<br />

Recent Trends and Patterns<br />

"Today, one of the engines powering the remarkable<br />

growth in India is entrepreneurship. After<br />

being shackled for a number of decades, the<br />

wings of India's large class of talented private<br />

entrepreneurs have been fully freed. After a few<br />

tentative fl utters in the early 1990s, they are<br />

now showing their true worth. Many indigenous<br />

start-ups are becoming global success stories<br />

and Indian business has done unexpectedly<br />

well in the last decade and a half – largely as a<br />

result of more effi cient use of resources, men<br />

and machines."<br />

-Kamal Nath<br />

Minister of Commerce & Industry at<br />

United States-India Business Council<br />

(USIBC) Annual Summit, June 27, <strong>2007</strong><br />

1. Introduction<br />

Last two decades have witnessed liberalisation<br />

and globalisation of many developing<br />

economies across the world.<br />

One of the key outcomes of this process<br />

has been enhanced mobility of capital<br />

across different countries. This has resulted<br />

in a significant increase in the<br />

outward Foreign Direct Investment<br />

(FDI) flows not only from the developed<br />

countries but also from several developing<br />

and transition economies, especially<br />

since the early 1990s. <strong>The</strong> value of<br />

outward FDI flows from the developing<br />

and transition economies increased<br />

from $ 12 billion in 1990 to $193 billion<br />

in 2006 (which accounted for about 16<br />

percent of the world total outward FDI<br />

flows). Likewise, the value of the outward<br />

FDI stock of developing and transition<br />

economies went up from only $146<br />

billion in 1990 to $881 billion in 2000,<br />

reaching $1.7 trillion in 2006 (14 percent<br />

of the world total outward FDI stock).<br />

In case of India too, the FDI outflows<br />

have assumed significant proportions<br />

(in absolute terms) only since the early<br />

1990s. India’s total outward FDI stock<br />

rose from $124 million in 1990 to (almost)<br />

$13 billion in 2006; still it was<br />

ranked only 16th among the developing<br />

countries in terms of the total outward<br />

FDI stock. Likewise, India’s outward<br />

FDI flows increased from a meagre $6<br />

million in 1990 to $9.7 billion in 2006. 1<br />

India’s ranking in the Outward FDI<br />

Performance Index (of UNCTAD) has<br />

improved over these years, from 82 in<br />

1990 to 56 in 2006. <strong>The</strong> ‘internationalization’<br />

of Indian firms is also reflected<br />

in the growing number of Indian companies<br />

investing abroad, which has increased<br />

from 187 in the early 1990s to<br />

1700 by the early years of the present<br />

decade. 2<br />

In this backdrop, the present paper<br />

deals with some of the important aspects<br />

of overseas investment by Indian<br />

firms over the last decade. <strong>The</strong> second<br />

section of the paper presents a brief account<br />

of the changing policy framework<br />

in India with regard to outward FDI.<br />

108 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

<strong>The</strong> third section discusses the geographical<br />

and sectoral patterns of outward<br />

FDI flows from India. <strong>The</strong> fourth<br />

section highlights some of the overseas<br />

Mergers & Acquisitions (M&As) made<br />

by Indian firms. <strong>The</strong> fifth section discusses<br />

their likely motives and the factors<br />

driving overseas investments. <strong>The</strong><br />

paper ends with concluding remarks on<br />

some policy implications of the recent<br />

surge in outward FDI from India.<br />

2. <strong>The</strong> Policy Framework<br />

<strong>The</strong> policy guidelines for outward FDI<br />

from the country have evolved over the<br />

last few decades. <strong>The</strong> evolution of India’s<br />

overseas investment policy can be<br />

traced back to 1969, when the guidelines<br />

for overseas direct investment were issued<br />

by the Government of India for the<br />

first time. <strong>The</strong>se guidelines had defined<br />

the extent of participation of Indian<br />

companies in projects abroad. Indian<br />

companies were permitted minority<br />

participation in ‘turnkey projects’ involving<br />

no cash remittances. Subsequently,<br />

these guidelines were revised<br />

in 1978 and 1986, in the pre-reform era.<br />

<strong>The</strong> main objective of outward investment<br />

policy during this era was to encourage<br />

outward investments by Indian<br />

companies as means of promoting exports<br />

of Indian capital goods, technology<br />

and consultancy services. 3<br />

However, since the onset of economic<br />

reforms in India, overseas investment<br />

policy has undergone a structural<br />

change; with the last five years witnessing<br />

a clear thrust in policy towards promotion<br />

of greater investment opportunities<br />

for Indian firms. <strong>The</strong> stated<br />

objectives of this structural change in<br />

the overseas investment policy regime<br />

were: to help promote exports from the<br />

country, strengthen its economic linkages<br />

with other countries, provide Indian<br />

firms the access to new markets<br />

and technologies, and increase the global<br />

competitiveness of Indian firms. India’s<br />

overseas investment policy was first<br />

liberalised in 1992, which marked the<br />

introduction of an Automatic Route for<br />

overseas investments and allowed cash<br />

remittances for the first time with restrictions<br />

on the total value of investments.<br />

<strong>The</strong> total value of overseas investment<br />

by an Indian firm was<br />

restricted to $2 million in a block of<br />

three years, with a cash component of<br />

only $0.5 million. In 1995, the upper<br />

limit for automatic approval was raised<br />

to $4 million; and, the Reserve Bank of<br />

India (RBI) was given the authority for<br />

approval of overseas investment proposals<br />

worth up to $15 million, 4 while overseas<br />

investments worth more than $15<br />

million were still considered and approved<br />

by the Ministry of Finance. <strong>The</strong><br />

introduction of Foreign Exchange Management<br />

Act (FEMA), in 2000, brought<br />

in further changes in the policy relating<br />

to investments abroad. <strong>The</strong> limit for<br />

overseas investment was raised to $50<br />

million annually, without any condition<br />

relating to repatriation of a part of the<br />

declared profits. In March 2002, the upper<br />

limit for automatic approval was<br />

further increased to $100 million annually,<br />

of which 50 percent could be funded<br />

in foreign exchange from any authorized<br />

dealer (i.e. a bank authorized by<br />

RBI to deal in foreign exchange or<br />

foreign securities). 5<br />

Since 2003, however, the policy regime<br />

for overseas investment has been<br />

liberalized significantly. In 2003, Indian<br />

firms were allowed to make overseas<br />

investment (annually) of up to 100 percent<br />

of their net worth under the automatic<br />

approval route. This limit was<br />

enhanced later to 200 percent in 2005<br />

and 300 percent in <strong>2007</strong>. 6 In March<br />

2006, RBI also paved the way for proprietary/<br />

unregistered partnership firms<br />

to set up joint ventures or wholly owned<br />

subsidiaries abroad. Recently, the upper<br />

limit for total overseas investment of an<br />

Indian party in all its joint ventures and/<br />

or Wholly Owned Subsidiaries abroad<br />

has been enhanced to, not exceeding<br />

400 percent of its net worth. 7<br />

As regards the implications of these<br />

policy changes in India, Nayyar (<strong>2007</strong>) 8<br />

observes that the liberalization of the<br />

overseas investment policy regime,<br />

India’s total outward FDI stock rose from $ 124<br />

million in 1990 to (almost) $ 13 billion in 2006.<br />

Still, it was ranked only 16 th among the developing<br />

countries in terms of the total outward FDI stock<br />

along with reforms in the financial sector<br />

particularly those since early 2000s,<br />

have enhanced Indian firms’ access to<br />

capital from both domestic and international<br />

financial markets. For instance,<br />

in April 2003, banks in India were permitted<br />

to provide credit and non-credit<br />

facilities to Indian Joint Ventures or<br />

Wholly Owned Subsidiaries abroad<br />

worth up to 10 percent of their unimpaired<br />

capital funds. This limit was further<br />

raised to 20 percent in November<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

109


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

2006. Besides, India has also entered<br />

into Bilateral Investment Promotion<br />

and Protection Agreements (BIPAs)<br />

with a number of countries to promote<br />

and protect foreign investment on a reciprocal<br />

basis. All these policy changes<br />

have resulted in an environment conducive<br />

to a rapid expansion of outward<br />

FDI flows from the country.<br />

3. Overseas Investment: Geographical<br />

And Sectoral Patterns<br />

India’s outward FDI has steadily increased<br />

since 1996, both in terms of<br />

number of approvals and value. Indian<br />

investment abroad has gone up from $<br />

557 million (290 approvals) in the financial<br />

year 1996-97 to $2855 million (1395<br />

approvals) in the financial year 2005-06,<br />

representing an increase of 513 percent<br />

in terms of value of investments and 380<br />

percent in terms of the number of approvals<br />

given. In the financial year<br />

2006-07 (for the period April-October<br />

2006), actual FDI outflows stood at $<br />

3320 million as compared to $ 2109 million<br />

in the corresponding period of<br />

2005-06. 9 Before we move on to a discussion<br />

of geographical and sectoral<br />

patterns of FDI outflows from India, we<br />

must pay attention to some of the limitations<br />

of the statistics on FDI outflows:<br />

these statistics relate only to approvals<br />

rather than actual FDI outflows; the<br />

FDI outflow statistics do not include investment<br />

financed by borrowing in international<br />

financial markets through<br />

special purpose vehicles (SPVs); moreover,<br />

the data on sectoral distribution of<br />

outward FDI are not disaggregated<br />

enough 10 . Nonetheless, even the currently<br />

available statistics on outward<br />

FDI from India provide valuable<br />

insights.<br />

3.1 Geographical Patterns<br />

Until mid-1980s, much of the outward<br />

Indian investment abroad has gone up from $557 million<br />

(290 approvals) in the financial year 1996-97 to $2855<br />

million (1395 approvals) in 2005-06, representing an<br />

increase of 513% in terms of value of investments and<br />

380% in terms of the no. of approvals given<br />

FDI from India was concentrated primarily<br />

in a few developing regions of<br />

Africa (Kenya and Nigeria), Southeast<br />

Asia (Malaysia, Indonesia, and Singapore)<br />

and South Asia (Sri Lanka and<br />

Nepal) 11 . In fact, in the 1980s, India had<br />

emerged as the third largest foreign direct<br />

investor among the developing<br />

countries after Hong Kong and Singapore.<br />

12 <strong>The</strong> geographical pattern of Indian<br />

outward FDI underwent noticeable<br />

changes since early 1990s, when the<br />

outward FDI flows from India (in some<br />

of the sectors, such as software and<br />

pharmaceuticals) started shifting towards<br />

the developed regions, mainly<br />

North America and European Union.<br />

Over the period from April 1996 to<br />

October 2006, the largest recipient of<br />

India’s FDI was Russia with total Indian<br />

outward FDI of $ 2831 million, which<br />

was followed by USA at $ 2768 million,<br />

Mauritius at $ 2151 million, and UK at<br />

$ 2150 million (see Table 1). More recently,<br />

in 2006-07 (during the period<br />

April-October 2006), the top three destinations<br />

of India’s outward FDI were<br />

UK, Netherlands and Mauritius. In<br />

2006-07, India became the second-biggest<br />

source of outward FDI flows to UK.<br />

While most of the investments in USA<br />

and UK have been in IT services and<br />

pharmaceuticals, those in the Russian<br />

Federation and Sudan have been mainly<br />

in oil exploration. 13 A sizable chunk<br />

of Indian outward FDI has been going<br />

to the tax havens or offshore financial<br />

centres, like Mauritius (10 percent),<br />

British Virgin Islands (4.5 percent), and<br />

Bermuda (3 percent). In fact, it has been<br />

observed that the double taxation avoidance<br />

treaty between India and Mauritius<br />

(and other such tax haven countries)<br />

has encouraged Indian firms to ‘round<br />

trip’ investment through Mauritius (and<br />

other tax haven countries) to take advantage<br />

of the tax benefits enjoyed by<br />

overseas investors. 14 Thus, the geographical<br />

spread of Indian outward FDI<br />

has expanded over the last decade,<br />

with a shift towards the developed<br />

countries.<br />

3.2 Sectoral Patterns<br />

It has been highlighted by several ob-<br />

110 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

servers [see, for instance, Kumar (1995)<br />

& Pradhan (<strong>2007</strong>) 15 ] that the bulk of<br />

India’s outward FDI during 1970s and<br />

1980s was in the manufacturing sector,<br />

primarily in light engineering, pharmaceuticals,<br />

chemicals and textiles. Along<br />

with the increasing geographical diversification<br />

of outward FDI from the<br />

country, a sectoral diversification (towards<br />

services) also started taking place<br />

in the early 1990s. Although in case of<br />

certain services like, communication<br />

and software, broadcasting and publishing,<br />

engineering and construction, and<br />

hotels and restaurants, outward FDI<br />

from India has been rising; manufacturing<br />

sector still accounts for a major<br />

chunk of total outward FDI from India.<br />

Table-2 presents the sectoral composition<br />

of outward FDI flows from India<br />

during the period from April 1999 to<br />

October 2006. In this period, the largest<br />

amount approved for overseas investment<br />

was in the manufacturing sector<br />

(at $11093 million) followed by non-financial<br />

services sector (including software<br />

development), trading sector and<br />

other activities (see Table-2). Over this<br />

A sizable chunk of Indian outward FDI has been<br />

going to the tax havens or offshore financial<br />

centres like Mauritius (10 percent), British Virgin<br />

Islands (4.5 percent), and Bermuda (3 percent)<br />

period, the share of manufacturing sector<br />

was 53 percent while that of non-financial<br />

services was 33 percent and that<br />

of trading was 5 percent. An almost<br />

similar pattern emerges for the period<br />

Table 1: Geographical Distribution Of Approved Outward FDI Flows From India<br />

(Top 15 Destinations)(Million $ )<br />

Rank Country April 1996 to<br />

March 2002<br />

2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 * Total Share<br />

(in%)<br />

1 Russia 1748.7 0.2 1.4 1076.2 1.2 3.0 2830.6 12.78<br />

2 USA 1540.8 185.3 207.1 251.4 270.3 313.4 2768.3 12.50<br />

3 Mauritius 618.3 133.4 175.6 149.4 332.7 741.4 2150.7 9.71<br />

4 U.K 410.6 34.5 138.5 71.9 158.3 1335.9 2149.6 9.71<br />

5 Netherlands 157.9 15.9 30.2 30.7 284.6 1005.5 1524.8 6.89<br />

6 Singapore 153.0 46.8 15.9 239.3 200.5 499.5 1154.9 5.22<br />

7 Sudan - 750.0 162.0 51.5 63.0 118.1 1144.7 5.17<br />

8 British Virgin Island 776.5 3.3 4.9 131.4 29.5 39.0 984.7 4.45<br />

9 Cyprus 1.9 - 0.0 1.9 13.4 701.6 718.8 3.25<br />

10 Hong Kong 445.1 14.8 16.2 73.6 88.8 41.5 679.9 3.07<br />

11 Bermuda 232.6 29.0 142.5 221.3 2.6 627.9 2.84<br />

12 UAE 110.2 12.6 32.1 41.9 141.0 205.3 543.0 2.45<br />

13 Australia 7.0 95.0 92.9 158.8 75.3 95.2 524.1 2.37<br />

14 Brazil 13.0 5.2 5.0 17.2 420.1 6.7 467.2 2.11<br />

15 Canada 5.6 2.3 0.7 0.8 3.5 397.8 410.7 1.85<br />

Total Outward Investment<br />

7543.1 1472.1 1450.9 2804.0 2859.1 6003.9 22142.9<br />

All Developed Countries<br />

(Share in%)<br />

All Developing<br />

Countries (Share in%)<br />

2608.8<br />

(35)<br />

4934.2<br />

(65)<br />

396.6<br />

(27)<br />

1075.5<br />

(73)<br />

774.0<br />

(53)<br />

676.9<br />

(47)<br />

799.6<br />

(29)<br />

2004.3<br />

(71)<br />

1015.4<br />

(36)<br />

1843.6<br />

(64)<br />

Source: Compiled from data given in the website of Department of Economic Affairs, Ministry of Finance, Government of India.<br />

Note: * April-October 2006.<br />

4073.9<br />

(68)<br />

1929.8<br />

(32)<br />

9668.4<br />

(44)<br />

12474.4<br />

(56)<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

111


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

2006-07 (April-October 2006), with the<br />

largest amount of India’s outward FDI<br />

going to the manufacturing sector at<br />

$2403 million (40 percent)<br />

followed by financial and nonfinancial<br />

services sector (37 percent),<br />

other activities (16 percent) and trading<br />

sector (7 percent), respectively. Although<br />

there has been a decline in the<br />

share of manufacturing sector in India’s<br />

total outward FDI, it still accounts for<br />

While most of the investments from developing<br />

|countries are into other developing countries and in<br />

the service sector, outward FDI from India in the<br />

recent years has been primarily in the developed<br />

countries and in the manufacturing sector<br />

more than half of the outflows of FDI<br />

from the country. In terms of its geographical<br />

and sectoral diversification of<br />

outward FDI, India presents two sharp<br />

contrasts with other developing countries.<br />

While most of the investments<br />

vice sector, outward FDI from India in<br />

the recent years has been primarily in<br />

the developed countries and in the manufacturing<br />

sector. 16<br />

4. Modes Of Outward FDI<br />

From India<br />

In the period preceding 1990s, most of<br />

the outward FDI from India was in the<br />

form of greenfield investments for establishing<br />

new joint ventures or subsidiaries<br />

overseas. Since late 1990s, however,<br />

most of the outward FDI from the<br />

country has been through Mergers and<br />

Acquisitions (M&As) abroad, which was<br />

possibly due to the fact that greater risks<br />

and time could be associated with<br />

greenfield investments abroad. We may<br />

also note here that India’s overseas in-<br />

from developing countries are into other<br />

developing countries and in the servestment<br />

was traditionally led by a small<br />

group of family-owned large business<br />

conglomerates, like Tatas, Birlas,<br />

Thapars etc., which focused mainly on<br />

the neighbouring developing countries.<br />

Since 1990s, there has been an emergence<br />

of a large number of non familyowned<br />

as well as small and medium<br />

<strong>size</strong>d Indian firms, which have chosen<br />

outward investment as an important<br />

strategy for ‘internationalization’. 17<br />

As mentioned above, the expansion of<br />

outward FDI from India over the last<br />

decade has been led mainly by M&As<br />

abroad. Indian companies have marked<br />

their presence in several industries –<br />

software and IT services, pharmaceuticals,<br />

biotechnology, automotives, hotels<br />

and hospitality, and other consumer<br />

products. Although a significant part of<br />

the Indian outward FDI stock is still in<br />

manufacturing, overseas investment in<br />

software and IT services (for instance,<br />

those by Infosys, TCS and Wipro) has<br />

grown rapidly. Pharmaceuticals companies<br />

such as Dr. Reddy’s and Ranbaxy<br />

Table 2: Sectoral Distribution Of Approved Outward FDI Flows From India (Million $)<br />

Year<br />

Manufacturing<br />

Financial services<br />

Non- financial<br />

services<br />

Trading<br />

Others<br />

Total<br />

OFDI<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

1999-00 548.8 31.2 4.3 0.2 1143.5 65.1 58.3 3.3 2.3 0.1 1757.2<br />

2000-01 370.7 26.8 16.6 1.2 876.5 63.4 89.2 6.5 29.1 2.1 1382.1<br />

2001-02 2210.9 73.1 48.6 1.6 565.5 18.7 139.2 4.6 61.3 2.0 3025.5<br />

2002-03 1056.7 71.9 1.8 0.1 280.2 19.1 69.9 4.8 61.7 4.2 1470.3<br />

2003-04 765.6 52.8 35.1 2.4 438.8 30.3 76.9 5.3 134.1 9.2 1450.5<br />

2004-05 2026.4 72.3 9.2 0.3 548.2 19.5 69.1 2.5 151.3 5.4 2804.2<br />

2005-06 1711.1 59.9 167.7 5.9 707.4 24.8 134.3 4.7 134.3 4.7 2854.8<br />

2006-07* 2402.8 39.8 5.8 0.1 2250.0 37.3 390.8 6.5 985.6 16.3 6035.0<br />

Total 11093.1 53.4 289.1 1.4 6810.1 32.8 1027.7 4.9 1559.7 7.5 20779.7<br />

Source: Same as Table 1 above. Note: * April-October 2006.<br />

112 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 3: Cross-Border Mergers And Acquisitions By Indian Firms<br />

Year Purchases Sales<br />

No. of deals Value No. of deals<br />

Value<br />

(Million $)<br />

2000 55 910 111 1219<br />

2001 35 2195 84 1037<br />

2002 35 270 66 1698<br />

2003 57 1362 83 949<br />

2004 64 863 80 1760<br />

2005 91 2649 126 4210<br />

2006 133 4740 163 6716<br />

Source: FDI Database, UNCTAD<br />

have also made <strong>size</strong>able overseas investments.<br />

Large Indian companies in industries<br />

such as steel and chemicals<br />

have also begun to ‘internationalize’ by<br />

acquiring upstream companies, for instance,<br />

in countries like, Australia and<br />

Canada. 18 In the energy sector, India’s<br />

State-owned groups, such as ONGC<br />

Videsh, Indian Oil Corporation and Oil<br />

India, have acquired stakes abroad in<br />

exploration, refining and retailing.<br />

Table 3 presents a snapshot of Indian<br />

firms’ purchases and sales in the form of<br />

cross-border Mergers and Acquisitions.<br />

It shows that the number of Indian companies<br />

investing abroad has been steadily<br />

rising and in some of the years, the<br />

value of outbound deals was more than<br />

the value of in-bound deals.<br />

Presently, systematic information on<br />

cross-border M&As by Indian companies<br />

is not available from any government<br />

agency. <strong>The</strong>refore, in this paper,<br />

we rely mainly upon a study on Indian<br />

Acquisitions Abroad by MAPE Advisory<br />

Group 19 and refer to some other<br />

sources as well. According to the said<br />

study, Indian companies acquired 244<br />

foreign companies over the period 1st<br />

January 2000 to 31st March 2006.<br />

Table 4 shows the sectoral distribution<br />

of the 244 acquisitions by Indian<br />

companies covered by the MAPE study.<br />

<strong>The</strong> software and business process outsourcing<br />

industry saw the largest deal<br />

count, followed by pharmaceuticals and<br />

automotive. In terms of the value of the<br />

acquisitions, however, Manufacturing<br />

sector dominated with more than 40<br />

percent of the acquisitions in industries<br />

such as pharmaceuticals, automotive,<br />

consumer goods, chemicals, fertilizers<br />

and metals; whereas software and business<br />

process outsourcing accounted for<br />

almost 30 percent of the total value of<br />

acquisitions during this period. <strong>The</strong><br />

largest number of Indian acquisitions<br />

was in North America and Europe accounting<br />

for (approximately) 34 percent<br />

and 40 percent of the total, respectively.<br />

This reiterates the fact that Indian companies<br />

are investing more in the developed<br />

economies. <strong>The</strong> MAPE Study<br />

also reports that a certain degree of<br />

concentration can be found among the<br />

Indian firms that made these acquisitions<br />

abroad. Out of the 244 deals, 163<br />

deals involved Indian companies which<br />

have made more than one acquisition<br />

abroad. For instance, ONGC made a<br />

total of 9 acquisitions and Ranbaxy has<br />

made 8. <strong>The</strong> other main players include<br />

United Phosphorous, Bharat Forge, Dr<br />

Reddy’s, Tatas, HCL Tech, Mahindra &<br />

Mahindra and Nicholas Piramal,<br />

among others.<br />

This outbound M&As activity by Indian<br />

firms has continued to increase.<br />

<strong>The</strong> year <strong>2007</strong> has already witnessed<br />

two major acquisitions of Tata-Corus<br />

and Hindalco-Novelis. <strong>The</strong> former acquisition<br />

by Tata Steel was worth over<br />

$12 billion, which has been the largest<br />

acquisition ever by an Indian company;<br />

whereas the latter by Aditya Birla<br />

Group’s Hindalco Industries was worth<br />

$6 billion.<br />

5. Driving Factors And Motives<br />

For Overseas Investment<br />

<strong>The</strong> recent wave of outward FDI from<br />

India has been boosted by both domestic<br />

and international factors. In some<br />

In some industries such as pharmaceuticals, import substituting<br />

industrialization regime (of the pre-1990s era) had<br />

encouraged local technology and skill development and<br />

also created capacities and abilities in Indian firms which<br />

enabled them to become cost competitive globally<br />

cases, industry specific factors have also<br />

favoured the outward FDI. As regards<br />

the domestic factors, the policy regime<br />

on outward FDI from India has been<br />

liberalized significantly since 2003; a<br />

liberalised investment regime has provided<br />

Indian firms with easy access to<br />

cheap credit from both domestic and<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

113


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 4: Acquisitions Abroad By Indian Firms<br />

(From January 2000 To March 2006)<br />

Sector Value (Million $) Number Of Deals<br />

Automotives 427.3 24<br />

Chemicals & Fertilizers 655.2 17<br />

Consumer 668.5 10<br />

Pharmaceuticals/ Healthcare 1,604.2 50<br />

Software / BPO 1,115.4 82<br />

Metals & Mining 970.5 11<br />

Oil & Gas 1,587.0 13<br />

Other 1,525.8 37<br />

Total 8,553.8 244<br />

Source: MAPE Advisory Group, 2006<br />

international market; and a booming<br />

stock market too has had a favourable<br />

impact on their capacity to invest. On<br />

the international front, a changing economic<br />

environment has left many small<br />

to medium-<strong>size</strong>d manufacturing companies<br />

in the developed economies (such<br />

as, USA and Europe) vulnerable for acquisitions,<br />

as their prevailing business<br />

model could no longer be cost<br />

competitive. At the industry level, the<br />

lowering of trade barriers and entry of<br />

multinational firms has increased competition<br />

in the Indian market; which has<br />

compelled many Indian companies to<br />

look overseas for their growth. In this<br />

new competitive environment, the strategy<br />

of ‘internationalization’ has become<br />

vital for many firms. Secondly, as Nagaraj<br />

(2006) argues, in some industries<br />

such as, pharmaceuticals, import substituting<br />

industrialization regime (of the<br />

pre-1990s era) had encouraged local<br />

technology and skill development and<br />

also created capacities and abilities in<br />

Indian firms, which enabled them to become<br />

cost competitive globally. He<br />

In their overseas investments, Indian firms must try to<br />

focus more on resource-seeking activities like exploration<br />

and development of mineral and energy resources. China,<br />

in order to sustain its rapid growth, has invested the most<br />

in exploration of oil fi elds and industrial raw materials<br />

opines that the international competitiveness<br />

of Indian firms in the pharmaceuticals<br />

sector is attributable, to some<br />

extent, to the Patents Act of 1970 that<br />

did not allow ‘product patents’ but allowed<br />

only ‘process patents’ and thus<br />

facilitated the possibilities of ‘reverse<br />

engineering’. Indian firms at present see<br />

an opportunity to produce a large number<br />

of drugs that are going off patent in<br />

the developed countries. Moreover, getting<br />

access to specialised R&D of firms<br />

in developed nations is also one of the<br />

important reasons for Indian firms’ investments<br />

abroad in sectors like<br />

pharmaceuticals. <strong>The</strong> World Investment<br />

Report 2006 identifies four specific motives,<br />

for which firms look abroad, viz.<br />

market-seeking (i.e. looking for new<br />

customers), efficiency-seeking (i.e. reducing<br />

the costs), resources-seeking (i.e.<br />

accessing key factor inputs), or created/<br />

strategic-asset-seeking (i.e. such as<br />

technology, brands, distribution networks,<br />

R&D facilities and managerial<br />

competences).<br />

As regards the Indian firms, the key<br />

motives for their cross-border M&As<br />

have been gaining market access and<br />

acquiring new technologies and competencies.<br />

For instance, the acquisition of<br />

the Anglo-Dutch company, Corus, by<br />

Tata Steel (for more than $12 billion)<br />

seems driven by this kind of a strategy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> key motive of Tata Steel could have<br />

been to gain access to European markets;<br />

since Corus, which controls about<br />

50 percent of the UK steel market (in<br />

volume terms), is likely to offer Tata<br />

Steel a direct gateway into the European<br />

markets (where Tata Steel did not<br />

have a presence until now). It would also<br />

provide Tata Steel the access to advanced<br />

technology of Corus. This acquisition<br />

has made Tata Steel the 5th<br />

largest steel producer in the world.<br />

Thus, the main motive of Indian firms<br />

has been getting access to large markets<br />

and acquiring new technologies, and in<br />

several industries, acquisition of firms<br />

in the developed countries seems to offer<br />

the Indian firms not only better technology<br />

but also a <strong>size</strong>able market.<br />

6. Conclusion<br />

Thus, the strategy of ‘internationalization’<br />

being adopted by Indian firms<br />

seems to have been driven by a host of<br />

114 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

factors, such as, a liberalized policy regime<br />

and growing competitive pressures<br />

in the domestic market, among others.<br />

As the Indian firms look out for other<br />

markets and better technologies, the<br />

firms in the developed countries seem<br />

to have offered both in case of several<br />

industries. However, there is a clear<br />

need for precaution in this regard, since<br />

Indian firms borrowing from the global<br />

financial markets for the overseas acquisitions<br />

get exposed to the volatilities of<br />

the global financial markets. In fact,<br />

some of the major acquisitions by Indian<br />

firms in the recent years have been predominantly<br />

financed by debt from the<br />

global financial markets. <strong>The</strong>re is also a<br />

strong need to reorient the motives of<br />

the overseas acquisitions by Indian firms<br />

towards the long-term development of<br />

the country. In their overseas investments,<br />

Indian firms should try to focus<br />

more on resource-seeking activities,<br />

such as exploration and development of<br />

mineral and energy resources (the acquisition<br />

of Sakhalin Oil fields in Russia<br />

by ONGC is an example of this). We<br />

may note here that China, in order to<br />

sustain its rapid growth, has invested<br />

the most in exploration of oil fields and<br />

industrial raw materials. However, it<br />

would be interesting to see how the recent<br />

weakening of Dollar influences<br />

policies governing overseas investment<br />

as well as the capacities of Indian firms<br />

in this regard.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

<strong>The</strong>se results have been computed<br />

from the UNCTAD FDI database accessed<br />

from .<br />

2<br />

UNCTAD (2006) ‘World Investment<br />

Report 2006–FDI from Developing<br />

and Transition Economies: Implications<br />

for Development’.<br />

3<br />

As has been argued by Kumar, Nagesh<br />

(1995) ‘Industrialization, Liberalization<br />

and Two Way Flows of Foreign<br />

Direct Investments: <strong>The</strong> Case of India’,<br />

Discussion Paper Series, No.<br />

9504, INTECH- <strong>The</strong> United Nations<br />

University, Netherlands.<br />

4<br />

In 1995, the task of supervision of<br />

overseas investments was transferred<br />

from Ministry of Commerce, Govt.<br />

of India to the Reserve Bank of India<br />

(RBI). This was intended to provide<br />

a single window system for overseas<br />

investment approvals.<br />

5<br />

Gopinath, Shyamala (<strong>2007</strong>) ‘Overseas<br />

Investments by Indian companies<br />

- Evolution of Policy and Trends,’<br />

Key note address at the International<br />

Conference on Indian cross-border<br />

presence/acquisitions, Mumbai, January<br />

19.<br />

6<br />

As per the Annual Policy Statement<br />

for the Year <strong>2007</strong>-08 by Dr. Y. Venugopal<br />

Reddy, Governor, Reserve<br />

Bank of India, May 14, <strong>2007</strong>.<br />

7<br />

“RBI further liberalises Forex Rules’,<br />

RBI Press Release, September<br />

<strong>2007</strong>.<br />

8<br />

Nayyar, Deepak (<strong>2007</strong>) ‘<strong>The</strong> Internationalization<br />

of Firms from India:<br />

Investment, Mergers and Acquisitions’<br />

, SLPTMD Working Paper Series,<br />

No. 004, Department of International<br />

Development, University<br />

of Oxford.<br />

9<br />

As has been reported by the Department<br />

of Economic Affairs, Ministry<br />

of Finance, Government of India.<br />

10<br />

<strong>The</strong>se limitations have been pointed<br />

out by several analysts, for instance,<br />

Nayyar (<strong>2007</strong>).<br />

11<br />

As has been observed by Nagesh Kumar<br />

(1995).<br />

12<br />

Lall, S. (1983) <strong>The</strong> New Multinationals:<br />

<strong>The</strong> Spread of Third World Enterprises,<br />

New York: John Wiley<br />

13<br />

As reported by UNCTAD in World<br />

Investment Report 2006.<br />

14<br />

UNCTAD (2004) ‘India’s Outward<br />

FDI: A Giant Awakening?’,<br />

UNCTAD/DITE/IIAB/2004/1,<br />

20th October.<br />

15<br />

Pradhan, J. P. (<strong>2007</strong>) ‘Growth of Indian<br />

Multinationals in the World<br />

Economy: Implications for Development’,<br />

Working Paper, No. <strong>2007</strong>/04,<br />

ISID, New Delhi.<br />

16<br />

Nagaraj, R. (2006) ‘Indian Investments<br />

Abroad: What Explains the<br />

Boom?, Economic and Political<br />

Weekly, Vol. XLI, No. 46, pp.<br />

4716-4718.<br />

17<br />

Pradhan, J. P. (2005) ‘Outward Foreign<br />

Direct Investment from India:<br />

Recent Trends and Patterns’, Working<br />

Paper, No. 153, Gujarat<br />

Institute of Development Research,<br />

Ahmedabad.<br />

18<br />

As reported by UNCTAD in World<br />

Investment Report 2006.<br />

19<br />

MAPE Advisory Group ( 2006)<br />

“India Inc Going Abroad: Indian<br />

Companies’ Foreign Acquisitions’,<br />

background paper for the Seminar<br />

hosted by the IIM Calcutta on<br />

India Inc Going Abroad - Investing<br />

and Managing Internationally,<br />

Bangalore, April 19. <strong>The</strong>re are two<br />

other studies on acquisitions abroad<br />

by Indian firms. First is by FICCI<br />

in 2006 and, the second is by CMIE<br />

in <strong>2007</strong>.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

115


Anurag Sharma<br />

Research Fellow,<br />

Faculty of Business and Economics,<br />

Monash University, Melbourne<br />

Indian Banking Reforms and Policy<br />

Reversal: A Vicious Cycle<br />

"In sovereignty there are no gradations. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

may be limited royalty, there may be limited<br />

consulship; but there can be no limited government.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re must, in every society, be some<br />

power or other, from which there is no appeal,<br />

which admits no restrictions, which pervades the<br />

whole mass of the community, regulates and<br />

adjusts all subordination, enacts laws or repeals<br />

them, erects or annuls judicatures, extends or<br />

contracts privileges, exempt itself from question<br />

or control, and bounded only by physical<br />

necessity.<br />

By this power, wherever it subsists, all legislation<br />

and jurisdiction is animated and maintained.<br />

From this all legal rights are emanations, which,<br />

whether equitably or not, may be legally recalled.<br />

It is not infallible, for it may do wrong; but it is<br />

irresistible, for it can be resisted only by rebellion,<br />

by an act which makes it questionable, what shall<br />

be thenceforward the supreme power."<br />

-Samuel Johnson<br />

1. Introduction<br />

In the first decade following India’s independence<br />

in 1947, the banking sector<br />

was characterized by low reserve requirements<br />

and no control on interest<br />

rates (Demetriades and Luintel, 1996).<br />

Acting pursuant to its policy of directed<br />

and concessional lending to priority<br />

sectors (agriculture, exports, small<br />

scale industry) the government assumed<br />

control of the financial sector in the<br />

1960’s by nationalizing the major banks.<br />

Liquidity requirements were raised and<br />

interest rates on lending and deposits<br />

controlled and these became a major<br />

source of inefficiencies in the banking<br />

sector, through out the 1970’s and<br />

1980’s. Concessional lending to priority<br />

sectors with weak regulatory and supervision<br />

framework led to a high incidence<br />

of Non Performing Assets (NPA)<br />

in the banking sector. In 1992-93 NPA<br />

amounted to 24 percent of the total assets<br />

of public sector banks. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

began a gradual process of financial<br />

sector reforms in the mid 1980’s.<br />

Even though the pace of reform increased<br />

following the 1991 financial<br />

crisis, they remain incomplete. Demetriades<br />

and Luintel (1996) examine the<br />

effect of various types of banking controls<br />

on financial deepening in India<br />

and conclude these controls (with the<br />

exception of the lending rate ceiling)<br />

are having a negative impact on financial<br />

deepening and thus adversely affecting<br />

economic growth.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Indian economy has experienced<br />

more than a decade of economic reform<br />

following the 1991 financial crisis. <strong>The</strong><br />

present paper focuses on a critical analysis<br />

of the reforms process with emphasis<br />

on the banking sector, to highlight<br />

those inefficiencies which can contribute<br />

to “policy reversal” by the government.<br />

Policy reversal can be described<br />

as a situation in which government policies<br />

of sound fiscal management or<br />

financial restructuring adversely affect<br />

the banking sector (due to underlying<br />

inefficiencies) so that the government<br />

is forced to revive the banking sector by<br />

116 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

using policies such as recapitalization<br />

of public sector banks, honouring contingent<br />

and reserve of not less than Rs.500000<br />

and b) Satisfy the Reserve Bank of In-<br />

the SBI and its seven independently<br />

capitalized subsidiaries. <strong>The</strong> govern-<br />

liabilities or explicit bail-out dia (RBI) that its affairs are not ment of India is the major share holder<br />

packages that serve to undermine its<br />

initial efforts and adversely affect the<br />

government exchequer. This paper provides<br />

a brief overview of the evolution<br />

of the banking sector in India. Particular<br />

conducted in a manner detrimental to<br />

the interests of depositors.<br />

Scheduled commercial banks are further<br />

split into Public Sector Banks<br />

(PSB), private sector banks, foreign<br />

in these banks. Prior to 1991, PSBs accounted<br />

for about 90% of all deposits<br />

assets and credit in the economy. Private<br />

sector banks are classified as old<br />

and new private sector banks. <strong>The</strong>re are<br />

emphasis is placed on the possibility<br />

of policy reversal. <strong>The</strong> outline of the<br />

paper is as follows: Section-1 describes<br />

Concessional lending to priority sectors with weak regulatory<br />

and supervision framework led to a high incidence of<br />

the structure of the banking sector in<br />

India and its main characteristics in the Non Performing Assets (NPA) in the banking sector. In<br />

pre-1991 period. Section-2 outlines the 1992-93 NPA amounted to 24 percent of the total assets<br />

causes and impact of the 1991 financial<br />

of public sector banks<br />

crisis focussing on the changes in exchange<br />

rate regime. Section-3 critically banks and Regional Rural Banks 23 old private sector banks. Eight private<br />

analyses the banking sector reforms after<br />

1991 and summarizes current inefficiencies<br />

in the banking sector emphasizing<br />

high transaction costs and<br />

presence of the contingent liabilities.<br />

Section-4 discusses the relevance of<br />

policy reversals in India and cites some<br />

examples. Section-5 contains the policy<br />

conclusions and other impertaives.<br />

2. Banking Sector In India<br />

Banks in India are classified under the<br />

broad categories of scheduled and nonscheduled.<br />

Scheduled banks consist of<br />

(RRB).<br />

Public sector banks consist of nationalized<br />

banks and State Bank of India<br />

(SBI) group of banks. In 1969 the Indian<br />

government nationalized existing<br />

large private sector banks under its<br />

policy of assisting India’s planned development<br />

strategy by mobilizing financial<br />

resources to strategically important<br />

sectors. Fourteen banks were nationalized<br />

in 1969 and six in 1980. <strong>The</strong> Punjab<br />

National Bank was merged with the<br />

New Bank of India in 1993 thereby reducing<br />

the total count of national<br />

sector banks opened for business<br />

after 1991 and are classified as new private<br />

sector banks. Currently there are<br />

42 foreign banks in India, although<br />

their share in the holdings of banking<br />

sector assets remains negligible due to<br />

strict regulatory and entry requirements.<br />

RRB’s operate exclusively in<br />

Figure 1: Banking Structure In<br />

India<br />

Reserve Bank of India<br />

Scheduled Commercial bank (SCB) and<br />

banks to nineteen. <strong>The</strong><br />

Banks in India<br />

Financial Institutions<br />

scheduled cooperative banks. Non SBI group comprises<br />

Scheduled Banks comprise banks that<br />

are not included in the Second Schedule<br />

of the Banking Regulation Act of<br />

Scheduled Banks<br />

Non-Scheduled Banks<br />

1965 and thus do not satisfy the following<br />

conditions: a)<br />

have paidup<br />

Scheduled Commercial Banks<br />

Scheduled Co-operative Banks<br />

capital Public Sector Banks Private Sector Banks Foreign Banks Regional Rural<br />

Banks<br />

Nationalized Banks<br />

SBI Group<br />

Old Private Sector Banks<br />

New Private Sector Banks<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

117


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

rural areas to provide credit to small<br />

farmers and entrepreneurs. <strong>The</strong>re are<br />

currently 196 RRB’s accounting for<br />

four percent of the total assets of scheduled<br />

commercial banks. India also has<br />

specialized financial institutions under<br />

the following categories: big industry,<br />

investment and credit guarantee, exim<br />

trade, capital market, agriculture and<br />

housing development. <strong>The</strong>ir geographic<br />

reach is classified as all India, statelevel<br />

and other institutions. All-India<br />

financial institutions include (a) development<br />

banks (i.e., Industrial Development<br />

Bank of India, Industrial Credit<br />

and Investment Corporation of India,<br />

Small Industrial Development Bank,<br />

Industrial Investment Bank of India,<br />

and Industrial Finance Corporation of<br />

India); (b) specialized financial institutions<br />

(such as, Export Import Bank of<br />

India, Technology Development and<br />

Information Company of India); (c) investment<br />

institutions (i.e., Unit Trust of<br />

India (UTI), Life Insurance Corporation<br />

of India, General Insurance Corporation<br />

and subsidiaries); and (d) refinance<br />

institutions (i.e., National Bank<br />

for Agriculture and Rural Development<br />

(NABARD) and National Housing<br />

Bank). <strong>The</strong> role of these financial institutions<br />

is to promote economic development<br />

in various sectors of the economy.<br />

State level institutions include<br />

state financial corporations and state<br />

industrial development corporations.<br />

Other institutions consist of the Export<br />

Credit and Guarantee Corporation of<br />

India and Deposit Insurance<br />

and Credit Guarantee Corporation.(S<br />

hirai,2002).<br />

2.1 Pre-reform Period<br />

<strong>The</strong> banking system in India prior to<br />

1991 was highly regulated and inefficient.<br />

<strong>The</strong> most significant of these distortions<br />

were:<br />

• <strong>The</strong> existence of high levels of Cash<br />

Reserve Ratio (CRR) and Statuary<br />

Liquidity Ratio (SLR): CRR is a requirement<br />

on banks to hold a certain<br />

amount of deposits in the form of deposits<br />

to RBI. It is calculated as a<br />

percentage of reserve liabilities<br />

which are defined as a difference between<br />

all liabilities exempted from<br />

the SLR requirement and net time<br />

and demand deposits. <strong>The</strong> CRR rose<br />

from around 15 percent in 1960-70 to<br />

its upper legal limit of 15 percent in<br />

Banking reforms started in the second half of the 1980’s<br />

but was only seriously implemented after the 1991 financial<br />

crisis. <strong>The</strong> role of foreign and private sector banks<br />

remained negligible due to restricted entry regulations and<br />

strict branch licensing policies<br />

1991. <strong>The</strong> high value of CRR led to<br />

low profitability for banks and higher<br />

spreads. <strong>The</strong> RBI uses CRR as a<br />

tool for monetary intervention in the<br />

economy; e.g. the RBI increased<br />

CRR in August 1993 in order to sterilize<br />

capital inflows (Shirai, 2002).<br />

SLR is a liquidity requirement 1 for<br />

banks to hold a certain amount of<br />

deposits in the form of government<br />

and eligible securities. <strong>The</strong> upper legal<br />

limit of SLR is 40 percent. SLR<br />

increased from 25 percent in 1970 to<br />

38.5 percent in 1991. Hence for some<br />

time periods overall reserve requirements<br />

exceeded 50 percent.<br />

• Prior to 1991, Indian interest rates<br />

were administered by government.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se included lending and deposits<br />

rates including rates on saving deposits.<br />

<strong>The</strong> administration of rates<br />

was politically motivated and adversely<br />

affected bank balance sheets.<br />

Joshi and Little (1996) report the average<br />

return on assets in the second<br />

half of the 1980’s was just<br />

0.15 percent.<br />

• Directed and Concessional Lending:<br />

<strong>The</strong> state pursued a policy of allocation<br />

of financial resources to the socalled<br />

“priority sectors”. <strong>The</strong>se included<br />

agriculture, small scale<br />

industries, small business and selfemployed<br />

persons. Thus policy set<br />

quantitative loan targets 2 on banks<br />

and was a major reason behind the<br />

NPA of public sector banks. At the<br />

beginning of 1992-93 NPA amounted<br />

to 24 percent of total credit. 3<br />

• Lack of competition in the banking<br />

sector: <strong>The</strong> role of foreign and private<br />

sector banks remained negligible<br />

due to restricted entry<br />

regulations and strict branch<br />

licensing policies.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se government policies were the<br />

main cause of deteriorating bank performances<br />

and diminished banks’ incentive<br />

to operate efficiently. <strong>The</strong>re was<br />

lack of a proper regulation and supervision<br />

mechanism, which allowed banks<br />

to take high risks. This situation was<br />

worsened by the presence of implicit<br />

118<br />

THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1: Progress Of Commercial Banking In India<br />

Jun-69 <strong>Dec</strong>-80 Mar-91 Mar-95 Mar-99<br />

No. of SCB 73.0 154.0 272.0 281.0 297.0<br />

Per capita Deposit (Rs.) 88.0 738.0 2368.0 4242.0 8247.0<br />

Per capita Credit (Rs.) 68.0 457.0 1434.0 2320.0 4705.0<br />

Share of Priority Sector advances<br />

in Total Non-food credit of 15.0 40.3 39.2 35.8 35.9<br />

SCB(%)<br />

Deposits (% of National Income)<br />

15.5 36.0 48.1 46.4 48.7<br />

Total Assets (Rs. Billion) 68.4 710.8 3275.2 5215.4 11516.2<br />

Source: RBI (2003a)<br />

government guarantees i.e. the<br />

existence of contingent liabilities in<br />

the system.<br />

<strong>The</strong> reform process in the banking<br />

sector started in the second half of the<br />

1980’s but was only seriously implemented<br />

after the 1991 financial crisis.<br />

Table-1 summarizes salient aspects of<br />

the progress of the commercial banking<br />

sector in India. <strong>The</strong> evolution of the financial<br />

crisis of 1991 and its impact<br />

on the Indian economy is now<br />

briefly outlined 4 .<br />

3. Financial Crisis In India<br />

Prior to 1991 some important financial<br />

characteristics of the Indian economy<br />

can be summarized as follows:<br />

• Restrictive Capital Controls: Direct<br />

Investment was restricted. Capital<br />

inflows mainly consisted of foreign<br />

aid, commercial borrowings and Non<br />

Resident Indian (NRI) deposits. Indian<br />

companies were not allowed to<br />

hold foreign equities. <strong>The</strong> foreign<br />

portfolio investment was mainly directed<br />

toward a small number of public<br />

sector bond issues.<br />

• High fiscal deficits: Fiscal deficits<br />

were consistently high (combined<br />

gross fiscal deficit of state and central<br />

government rose by 20 and 24<br />

percent respectively in 1990 and<br />

1991) and mainly financed by borrowings<br />

and financial repression<br />

rather than monetization (Jha and<br />

Sharma (2004)). As a result the inflation<br />

rate did not reach extremely high<br />

levels and was at a par with India’s<br />

trading partners.<br />

• Pegged Exchange Rate: <strong>The</strong> exchange<br />

rate was officially pegged to<br />

a basket of currencies. However the<br />

trade-weighted nominal exchange<br />

rate depreciated steadily relative to<br />

the US$ in the latter half of the<br />

1980’s leading to small frequent devaluations.<br />

<strong>The</strong> rate of nominal depreciation<br />

was faster than the relative<br />

inflation differential leading to falls<br />

in the real exchange rate.<br />

• Trade: <strong>The</strong> government strategy was<br />

highly interventionist since independence<br />

and consisted of import<br />

substitution, complex industrial licensing<br />

requirements and public<br />

ownership of heavy industry. In the<br />

second half of the 1980’s, the emphasis<br />

shifted from import substitution<br />

to export-led growth. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

began a process of gradual liberalization<br />

of trade, investment, and<br />

financial markets. Export growth<br />

was rapid due to real depreciation of<br />

the rupee. However the value of<br />

imports increased at a faster rate<br />

(mainly in the petroleum sector)<br />

because of the easing of<br />

quantitative restrictions.<br />

India’s credit rating was downgraded and outfl ows were<br />

quick. As the forex reserves declined, economy was on<br />

the brink of default by January 1991. One of the major<br />

policy shifts in response to the financial crisis was the<br />

change in exchange rate management<br />

3.1 1991 Financial Crisis<br />

• Due to a widening gap between exports<br />

and imports and downturn of<br />

capital flows the current account<br />

deficit grew steadily and was financed<br />

by external borrowings and<br />

remittances of NRI making the<br />

economy extremely vulnerable to external<br />

shocks. External debt was $69<br />

billion in 1990-91 compared with $35<br />

billion in 1984-85.<br />

• Shocks: <strong>The</strong> first external shock was<br />

the sharp increase in world oil prices<br />

due to the Gulf War increasing the<br />

value of petroleum imports from $2<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

119


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 2: Cost Of Banks’ Rescue (Rs.Billion)<br />

in terms of a foreign currency<br />

and commits to<br />

1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 2001-2002<br />

trade in unlimited<br />

Capital Infusion 57.0 52.9 8.5 15.1 27.0 4.0 18.0<br />

amounts at that rate.<br />

Cumulative Infusion 97.0* 149.9 158.4 173.5 200.5 204.5 222.5 Normally the exchange<br />

*: Includes Rs.40 billion injected prior to 1993<br />

rate is allowed to vary<br />

billion to $5.7 billion which was quite<br />

high compared to 5 percent increase<br />

in non-oil imports. Exports were also<br />

adversely affected due to the impact<br />

of the Gulf war on India’s trading<br />

partners. For example, growth of India’s<br />

single largest trading partner,<br />

the US, fell from 3.9 percent in 1989<br />

to -1 percent in 1991. This led to a<br />

sharp deterioration in the trade account.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Gulf crisis also resulted<br />

in a decline in non resident workers’<br />

remittances to India.<br />

Apart from these external factors,<br />

political uncertainty in India in 1990<br />

and 1991 led to a fall in investor confidence<br />

further widening current account<br />

imbalances and causing a loss in reserves.<br />

India’s credit rating was downgraded<br />

by credit rating agencies leading<br />

to difficulties in commercial bank financing.<br />

<strong>The</strong> outflows from the economy<br />

were quick and as the forex reserves<br />

declined, the economy was on the brink<br />

of default by January 1991. One of the<br />

major policy shifts in response to the<br />

financial crisis was a change in exchange<br />

rate management. <strong>The</strong> next section<br />

briefly outlines exchange rate policy<br />

changes from 1970 to the present.<br />

3.2. Exchange Rate Regime<br />

In India<br />

With the collapse of the Bretton Woods<br />

arrangement in 1973 most developed<br />

economies switched from a fixed exchange<br />

rate to a flexible exchange rate<br />

regime. Under a fixed exchange rate<br />

regime the central bank announces the<br />

buying and selling rates of its currency<br />

within a narrow band.<br />

One major drawback of a fixed exchange<br />

rate regime in economies with<br />

perfect capital mobility is that monetary<br />

stabilization policy becomes ineffective<br />

(Obstfeld, 1995). For example if a government<br />

attempts to increase money<br />

supply by open market purchase of domestic<br />

bonds, households will find<br />

themselves holding more money than<br />

they desire. Since interest rate parity<br />

condition holds, household will sell<br />

their excess money holdings to the central<br />

bank for foreign currency at the<br />

fixed exchange rate and invest abroad<br />

to buy the desired amount of bonds.<br />

Such a mechanism will keep interest<br />

rates unchanged and leave the government<br />

with more bonds on the cost of<br />

forex reserves. One option for government<br />

will then be to refuse to buy the<br />

excess money supply and allow the currency<br />

Table 3: Comparison Of Central Government Holdings By Major<br />

Indian Banks After Public <strong>Issue</strong><br />

to depreciate.<br />

In spite of its drawbacks a fixed exchange<br />

rate regime is preferred in some<br />

Bank Name Date of Public <strong>Issue</strong> Government Percentage<br />

holding after public<br />

developing economies especially those<br />

with limited capital mobility. This is<br />

issue (%) as of 2001<br />

due to the following perceptions: a) A<br />

State Bank of India <strong>Dec</strong>ember 1993 66.34<br />

fixed exchange rate regime removes exchange<br />

rate uncertainty thereby retain-<br />

Sate Bank of Bikaner November 1997 75.00<br />

State Bank of Baroda <strong>Dec</strong>ember 1996 66.88<br />

ing investor confidence and macroeconomic<br />

stability; b) <strong>The</strong> export import<br />

State Bank of Travancore<br />

January 1998 76.00<br />

industry can be protected from huge<br />

Bank of India February 1997 77.00<br />

swings in exchange rates by keeping it<br />

Corporation Bank October 1997 66.33<br />

stable and c) If the currency is pegged<br />

Oriental Bank October 1994 66.48<br />

to a low inflation currency it helps keep<br />

Dena Bank <strong>Dec</strong>ember 1996 71.00<br />

domestic inflation low. For example, a<br />

120 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 2: Pre- reform Exchange Rate Variability<br />

government running a very high deficit<br />

will be reluctant to adopt an expansionary<br />

monetary policy because of its ineffectiveness<br />

in a fixed rate regime.<br />

Macroeconomic stability is a priority<br />

for any economy and all governments<br />

(irrespective of exchange rate regime)<br />

tend to intervene in the forex markets<br />

in order to influence the exchange rate.<br />

<strong>The</strong> government can take direct or indirect<br />

measures to counter exchange<br />

rate movements. Direct measures involve<br />

trading in the forex market. <strong>The</strong><br />

government uses its foreign exchange<br />

reserves to affect demand and supply in<br />

the forex market. For example, if domestic<br />

currency is depreciating the government<br />

will buy excess money supply<br />

by selling forex reserves to stabilize<br />

supply demand imbalances. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

can further offset this contractionary<br />

effect in domestic money supply<br />

by a simultaneous and equal purchase<br />

of domestic currency bonds. Such intervention<br />

is called “sterilized intervention”<br />

and is preferred by most governments.<br />

Such direct measures of<br />

intervention are complemented by some<br />

indirect measures like trade and interest<br />

rate restrictions to affect the demand<br />

and supply of foreign currency.<br />

For example, variable interest rates will<br />

affect the capacity of importers. One<br />

example is an interest rate surcharge on<br />

import finance: In order to curb imports<br />

and retain forex reserves, the RBI<br />

increased the interest rate surcharge on<br />

import finance from 15 percent to 25<br />

percent in January 1996.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

121


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

in 2004. <strong>The</strong> general perception is that<br />

if the government reduces SLR the reduced<br />

demand for government bonds<br />

will lead to a rise in interest rates the<br />

government has to pay bond holders.<br />

This may adversely affect the fiscal<br />

deficit. However, banks have continued<br />

to invest around 40 percent of their deposits<br />

in government securities in spite<br />

of the reduction in SLR. This is essentially<br />

because government bonds are<br />

considered to be a risk-free investment<br />

for banks.<br />

Interest rates were deregulated in<br />

1992 leading to complete liberalization<br />

of all term deposit and lending rates,<br />

except for savings deposit rates which<br />

remain controlled. <strong>The</strong> RBI has also<br />

begun using the bank rate (the rate at<br />

which RBI lends to commercial banks<br />

Table 4: Regulatory Framework Of Indian Banking Sector<br />

Variable 1992-93 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03<br />

Capital to Risk-weighted Assets<br />

Ratio (%)<br />

Domestic banks with international<br />

4 9 9 9<br />

business<br />

Foreign banks 8 9 9 9<br />

Non-performing assets<br />

(period overdue)<br />

Sub-standard assets 4 Q 2 Q 180 days 180<br />

days*<br />

Doubtful Assets<br />

period for which remained substandard<br />

24 M 18 M 18 M 18 M@<br />

Provisioning requirements (%)<br />

Standard Assets - 0.25 0.25 0.25<br />

Sub-standard assets 10 10 10 10<br />

Doubtful Assets (unsecured portion)<br />

100 100 100 100<br />

Loss assets 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: RBI (2003d)<br />

M: Month ; Q: Quarter<br />

by rediscounting bills or eligible paper)<br />

as a reference rate for influencing the<br />

direction of interest rates in the economy<br />

(Bhide et al., 2001). <strong>The</strong> flexibility<br />

to set lending rates led the banks to use<br />

this measure to offset the cost involved<br />

in concessional lending to priority<br />

sectors. During the reform period the<br />

ceiling of 40 percent on domestic banks<br />

and 33 percent on foreign banks for priority<br />

sector lending remained but banks<br />

were allowed to set the lending rates<br />

and more profitable sectors like the<br />

software industry and venture capital<br />

were included in the definition of priority<br />

sectors. <strong>The</strong> government relaxed the<br />

norms for entry in the banking sector in<br />

<strong>The</strong> deregulation of interest rates is also incomplete. Interest<br />

rates on saving deposits and other saving schemes<br />

such as National Savings Certifi cates, public provident<br />

funds etc. remain regulated. Such rigidities reduce the<br />

effectiveness of the transmission of monetary policy<br />

order to increase competitiveness. For<br />

example the ceiling of voting rights of<br />

an individual shareholder was increased<br />

from 1 to 10 percent in 1994. <strong>The</strong> relaxed<br />

guidelines led to the entry of 8<br />

private sector banks and 26 new foreign<br />

banks in the Indian banking sector.<br />

In response to the Narsimhan Committee<br />

recommendations, the government<br />

gradually started to privatize PSB.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se banks were accumulating large<br />

amounts of NPA due to the pre-reform<br />

regulated regime. <strong>The</strong>y made an aggregate<br />

loss of Rs.35 billion and almost<br />

half of the public sector banks had negative<br />

net worth. Realizing the importance<br />

of recapitalization, the government<br />

spent in the range of 0.02 to 0.7<br />

percent of GDP each year to wipe off<br />

accumulated NPA (Table 2). This<br />

helped the banks clean up their balance<br />

sheets and make public issues of equity.<br />

As Table 3 shows, the central government<br />

still continues to hold a large<br />

share of holdings in major state-owned<br />

banks. 6 Adoption of regulatory and supervision<br />

norms: Strengthening of the<br />

regulatory and supervisory framework<br />

of the banking sector remains a key element<br />

of financial sector reform. <strong>The</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

125


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

policy focus is on streamlining banking<br />

operations, upgrading risk management<br />

systems and enhancing the level of bank<br />

compliance with accounting standards<br />

and operationalizing consolidated accounting<br />

practices (RBI, 2003b). However,<br />

progress in this direction has been<br />

gradual. <strong>The</strong> RBI notes: “Within the<br />

process of convergence with best practices,<br />

finetuning is undertaken keeping<br />

in view the country specific circumstances.”<br />

(RBI, 2003c). For example,<br />

NPA have been defined as loans in<br />

which interest has remained unpaid for<br />

four quarters in 1992-93. This period<br />

was shortened to three quarters in<br />

1993-94 and two quarters in 1994-95.<br />

<strong>The</strong> central bank now plans to further<br />

shorten the period (in March 2004) to<br />

match the international norm of one<br />

quarter. Thus NPA were underestimated<br />

by Indian accounting standards. <strong>The</strong><br />

main reason behind such a policy was<br />

the political lobbying of borrowers. A<br />

summary of some aspects of the regulatory<br />

framework used by the RBI is given<br />

in Table 4.<br />

<strong>The</strong> financial sector reform process<br />

in India can be described as a graduated<br />

approach in the direction of liberalization.<br />

Figure 5 plots major banking<br />

indicators for the pre-reform and postreform<br />

period. <strong>The</strong>re are still some<br />

weaknesses in the financial sector<br />

which contribute to its inefficiencies.<br />

Though reduced from 40 percent to 25<br />

percent, the SLR has remained at high<br />

levels. Moreover, bank investment in<br />

government bonds and securities is still<br />

around 40 percent of their assets (Bhattacharya<br />

and Patel, 2003). This is because<br />

interest rates paid by the government<br />

are more market based due to the<br />

auction mechanism of its securities such<br />

as Treasury Bills; and also because<br />

banks prefer to invest in government<br />

securities as they are relatively risk free<br />

and more liquid. Banks are reluctant to<br />

take risks in alternative markets because<br />

of stricter prudential norms and<br />

accounting standards. <strong>The</strong> high investment<br />

in government securities is convenient<br />

for government which is running<br />

high fiscal deficits. However, when<br />

economic growth accelerates, high SLR<br />

can adversely affect the credit formation<br />

role of banks. Banks will be reluctant<br />

to lay off their securities in order<br />

to satisfy increased dem-and for credit.<br />

<strong>The</strong> CRR also remains higher than its<br />

Table 5: Non Performing Assets 0f Commercial Banking Sector: 1997-2003<br />

Year Public Sector Old Private New Private Foreign Banks<br />

Banks Sector Banks Sector Banks in India<br />

1997 17.80 10.70 2.60 4.30<br />

1998 16.00 10.90 3.50 6.40<br />

1999 15.90 13.10 6.20 7.60<br />

2000 14.00 10.80 4.10 7.00<br />

2001 12.40 11.10 5.10 6.80<br />

2002 11.09 11.01 8.86 5.38<br />

2003 9.36 8.90 7.64 5.22<br />

Definition: Gross NPA/Gross Advances (%)<br />

statuary minimum of three percent.<br />

<strong>The</strong> deregulation in interest rates is<br />

also incomplete. Interest rates on saving<br />

deposits and other saving schemes<br />

such as National Savings Certificates,<br />

public provident funds etc. remain regulated.<br />

7 Such rigidities reduce the effectiveness<br />

of the transmission of monetary<br />

policy (Sharma, 2004). <strong>The</strong><br />

lending rate for advances of over<br />

Rs.200000 was subjected to a ceiling of<br />

16.5 percent in 1987-88. This was eventually<br />

removed in 1994. <strong>The</strong> Prime<br />

Lending Rate (PLR) was set as a floor<br />

rate and banks are now free to set lending<br />

rates without any upper restriction.<br />

<strong>The</strong> lending rates though, officially<br />

flexible, are affected by public sector<br />

banks which are the dominant players<br />

in the banking sector. <strong>The</strong>se banks offer<br />

rates below the PLR because of their<br />

advantage in market share and quality<br />

of borrowers. <strong>The</strong>refore other banks’<br />

lending rates do not diverge much from<br />

the rates set by PSB thereby making<br />

PLR ineffective. <strong>The</strong> banks still have to<br />

make some loans based totally on the<br />

political agenda of the government. For<br />

example banks are forced to provide<br />

concessional loans to individuals or<br />

firms belonging to scheduled caste or<br />

scheduled tribes.<br />

4.1 High Transaction Costs<br />

One of the major concerns of the banking<br />

sector is the high transaction costs<br />

involved in the lending operations of<br />

banks. Transaction costs are particularly<br />

high in rural sector areas which<br />

are one of the priority sectors defined<br />

by government. Puhazhendhi (1995)<br />

estimated the transaction costs of lending<br />

to the rural poor in India. He con-<br />

126 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

sidered two major commercial banks,<br />

one regional rural bank and one private<br />

commercial bank from the southern<br />

states of Tamil Nadu and Kerala. <strong>The</strong><br />

estimated transaction cost was 3.68 percent<br />

of the loan amount if the loan was<br />

delivered through a direct lending<br />

channel. <strong>The</strong> literature on micro-credit<br />

(see (Ghatak, 2000) and (de Aghion<br />

and Gollier, 2000)) argues that group<br />

lending to the poor through Non-Governmental<br />

Organization (NGO) and<br />

Self Help Group (SHG) may be an efficient<br />

method of credit delivery system.<br />

In 1991, the RBI initiated the policy of<br />

encouraging direct linkages between<br />

the banks and NGO and SHG due to<br />

the presence of high transaction costs.<br />

Puhazhendhi (1995) estimated the financial<br />

intermediation of NGO and<br />

SHG reduced transaction costs by between<br />

21 and 41 percent relative to the<br />

direct lending channel. In spite of these<br />

efforts transaction costs remain high<br />

even after a decade of reform. <strong>The</strong> estimated<br />

opportunity cost of existing<br />

high transaction costs in India is<br />

still high. 8<br />

Though heading in the right direction,<br />

prudential norms are yet to reach<br />

global standards. <strong>The</strong> pace of restructuring<br />

nationalized banks through privatization<br />

is slow. This is mainly because<br />

nationalized banks’ balance<br />

sheets are weak due to accumulated<br />

NPA over the past three decades. <strong>The</strong><br />

government needs to clean up balance<br />

sheets by recapitalization and other<br />

measures in order to make these banks<br />

more attractive to investors. Given recent<br />

trends on the magnitude of NPA<br />

(Table 5) the cost of restructuring appears<br />

to be very high, particularly since<br />

it is already running very high deficits.<br />

Such liabilities on the government to<br />

revive the banking sector (contingent<br />

liabilitie000s), are significant in the<br />

case of India. <strong>The</strong> impact of contingent<br />

liabilities is now examined.<br />

4.2. Contingent Liabilities<br />

<strong>The</strong> financial sector in transition and<br />

developing economies is characterized<br />

by poor regulatory and enforcement<br />

systems, and inadequate disclosure of<br />

information which may lead to a high<br />

incidence of NPA. When the banking<br />

sector is in stress, out of legal obligation<br />

or political compulsion the central government<br />

has to rescue the banks. Such<br />

public financing by government represents<br />

its contingent liabilities and can<br />

potentially lead to a large increase in<br />

public debt. Because of their uncertain<br />

nature these contingent liabilities are<br />

unbudgeted and, hence, are hidden fiscal<br />

risks. Contingent liabilities are also<br />

important because the government cannot<br />

achieve its long-run objective of a<br />

sound fiscal system without addressing<br />

the problem. Explicit contingent liabilities<br />

are specific obligations which the<br />

government has to settle under a contract<br />

or a law. <strong>The</strong>se include obligations<br />

issued to state governments and public<br />

sector banks, etc. <strong>The</strong> government can<br />

foresee such guarantees and includes<br />

them in its budget constraint. 9<br />

However, contingent liabilities or implicit<br />

liabilities are uncertain and their<br />

realization is dependent on the probability<br />

of particular events. Sometimes,<br />

these events could be totally exogenous<br />

to government policy, e.g., an earthquake<br />

or any other natural disaster.<br />

Most of the time, these liabilities are a<br />

result of government policy. One interesting<br />

example is a guarantee extended<br />

by government to foreign creditors of<br />

domestic banks. <strong>The</strong>se guarantees may<br />

lead to moral hazard problems in the<br />

banking sector as banks may take high<br />

risks, eventually leading to default on<br />

foreign loanswww, and pressure on the<br />

government to bail them out because of<br />

It is argued that under current ineffi ciencies in the banking<br />

sector, any efforts by government to ensure macroeconomic<br />

stabilization or restructuring will involve an offsetting<br />

effect, adversely affecting the initial policy objectives,<br />

which will transmit mainly through the financial sector<br />

public expectations or political compulsion<br />

(For a detailed model see (Sharma,<br />

2004)). One relevant case study in this<br />

regard is the crisis in the UTI mutual<br />

fund discussed in section 5.<br />

Contingent implicit liabilities are<br />

normally calculated after the event occurs,<br />

as they are dependent on the probability<br />

of the triggering event, the actual<br />

loss and the amount government<br />

pays to bail out the system. (Polackova,<br />

1999) notes the financial systems represent<br />

the most serious contingent implicit<br />

liability. For example the cost of<br />

resolving past banking crises varies<br />

from around 1 percent of GDP (Thailand<br />

1983-87) to around 55 percent of<br />

GDP (Argentina 1980-82) depending<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

127


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

can subsequently cause what can be<br />

termed a “policy reversal” by government.<br />

Such policy reversals can arise<br />

under several conditions some of which<br />

are:<br />

• Suppose government is running high<br />

deficits and implements a tight monetary<br />

policy by increasing interest<br />

rates. Due to the inflexibility of the<br />

banking sector in passing on interest<br />

higher incidence of NPA in balance<br />

sheets. This may force the government<br />

to revive the banking sector<br />

through measures like recapitalization<br />

which will be a direct burden on<br />

government budget. As discussed<br />

earlier, the cost of reviving banks is<br />

very high in the case of India. <strong>The</strong><br />

government indeed began a partial<br />

privatization of banks as part of its<br />

economic reform process initially<br />

providing Rs.40 billion from 1991-92<br />

to 1992-93 to 19 nationalized banks.<br />

Subsequently, the government has<br />

spent around Rs.164.5 billion at a<br />

rate of between 0.02 and 0.7 percent<br />

of GDP each year from 1993-99.<br />

Though there was a decline in NPA<br />

from 17.8 percent in 1997 to 11.4 percent<br />

in 2002 they are still very high.<br />

• A second reason for policy reversal is<br />

the existence of weak regulatory and<br />

supervisory framework in the Indian<br />

Banking sector. <strong>The</strong> UTI mutual<br />

funds crisis is an example of this (See<br />

Appendix A.1).<br />

<strong>The</strong> government began a partial privatization of banks,<br />

initially providing Rs.40 billion from 1991-92 to 1992-93<br />

to 19 nationalized banks. Subsequently, ithas spent<br />

around Rs.164.5 billion at a rate of between 0.02 and 0.7<br />

percent of GDP each year from 1993-99<br />

on the state of the financial system.<br />

Standard and Poor’s (Polackova, 1999)<br />

estimate the fiscal cost of a future<br />

banking crisis in India will be around<br />

15 percent of GDP. This is so high because<br />

of the persistent inefficiencies in<br />

the banking system even after a decade<br />

of financial reform (Bhattacharya and<br />

Patel, 2003). Bhattacharya and Patel<br />

(2003) put the estimate of government<br />

guarantees in India as around 12 percent<br />

of GDP. Hence government guarantees<br />

are a crucial part of analysis of<br />

a financial sector especially in developing<br />

economies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> overview of the reform process<br />

brings up the question of policy reversal<br />

which is covered in the next section.<br />

5. Policy Reversal<br />

Most of the financial reforms in the Indian<br />

economy were guided by “.... objectives<br />

of increasing operational efficacy<br />

of monetary policy....” (RBI, 1997,<br />

page I-9). It is argued that under current<br />

inefficiencies (especially high NPA<br />

and the large share of government ownership)<br />

in the banking sector, any efforts<br />

by government to ensure macroeconomic<br />

stabilization (say reduction<br />

in fiscal deficit) or restructuring will<br />

involve an offsetting effect, adversely<br />

affecting the initial policy objectives,<br />

which will transmit mainly through the<br />

financial sector. This offsetting effect<br />

rates rise this will lead to banking<br />

stress. This inflexibility arises mainly<br />

because of the government’s policy<br />

of directed and concessional lending<br />

to priority sectors. Because of a regulated<br />

interest rate regime, the banks<br />

cannot adjust their deposit rates<br />

much, say in the, area of savings deposits.<br />

Thus stress in the banking<br />

sector will be directly reflected in a<br />

6. Conclusion<br />

<strong>The</strong> present paper has reviewed the financial<br />

sector reform process in India<br />

focussing on the banking sector. It can<br />

be safely concluded that financial sector<br />

reform in India is incomplete. <strong>The</strong><br />

banking sector remains inefficient because<br />

of several factors viz. high reserves<br />

and liquidity requirements, a<br />

poor regulatory and supervisory framework,<br />

the presence of implicit government<br />

guarantees, high transaction costs<br />

etc. <strong>The</strong>se inefficiencies can adversely<br />

affect the long-term policy objectives<br />

of a sound fiscal system and can even<br />

lead to policy reversals.<br />

128 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

APPENDIX<br />

A.1 UTI Crisis<br />

<strong>The</strong> section is compiled from the www.<br />

rediff.com archives. UTI mutual fund<br />

commenced operation on July 1964. It<br />

was established by the central government<br />

to channel community savings into<br />

productive uses in order to speed up industrial<br />

growth. To quote then Finance<br />

Minister T.T. Krishnamachari “the trust<br />

would be open to any person or institutions<br />

to purchase the units offered by the<br />

trust. However, this institution as we see<br />

it, is intended to cater to the needs of individual<br />

investors, and even among them<br />

as far as possible, to those whose means<br />

are small.” <strong>The</strong> main objective of the<br />

UTI was to invest retail savings in the<br />

capital market and pass the benefits back<br />

to small investors. UTI had a monopoly<br />

in the funds industry until 1986. Subsequently,<br />

PSBs sponsored funds entered<br />

the market and in 1993 there were 8 mutual<br />

funds. After 1993 private sector mutual<br />

funds were allowed. <strong>The</strong> funds industry<br />

has grown at a compounded<br />

average rate of 27 percent from an asset<br />

base of Rs.250 million in 1964 to its current<br />

<strong>size</strong> of Rs.900 billion. <strong>The</strong> share of<br />

UTI is around Rs.600 billion. UTI invests<br />

about a quarter of this through the<br />

US-64 fund, India’s largest, and accounts<br />

for about 15 percent of the domestic mutual<br />

fund industry’s assets in a year. <strong>The</strong><br />

mutual funds (particularly UTI) are very<br />

popular among small investors and became<br />

even more attractive in 1996 when<br />

the mutual fund dividend returned by<br />

equity-oriented schemes was exempted<br />

from tax. In mid 2002, the UTI bank decided<br />

to skip a dividend for its flagship<br />

US-64 scheme for the year 2001-02. This<br />

was because the NAV of the scheme had<br />

eroded sharply and was much lower than<br />

its face value of Rs.10. On 1st August,<br />

2002 the NAV of US-64 was Rs.5.80.<br />

This was the first time the UTI had<br />

skipped paying a dividend for the US-64<br />

scheme, since its inception in 1964. <strong>The</strong><br />

UTI Board decided to skip a dividend as<br />

the government had been providing budgetary<br />

support to unit holders, to bridge<br />

the gap between the NAV and repurchase<br />

price of 2001. In the period January-June<br />

2002 the SEBI reported that the UTI had<br />

redemption/repurchase to the tune of<br />

over Rs.63 billion against a mobilization<br />

of just Rs.6.3 billion. All the Minimum<br />

Income Plan (MIP) schemes of the UTI<br />

showed negative reserves on 30 June<br />

2002. According to a report by SEBI, 35<br />

out of 63 schemes (whose unaudited results<br />

were available) had negative reserves.<br />

For the MIP schemes, negative<br />

reserves totalled up to Rs.30 billion.<br />

MIP97(III) had egative reserves of<br />

Rs.2.6 billion and MIP97(IV) had negative<br />

reserves of Rs.2.5 billion. For the<br />

three years between 1999 and 2002, UTI<br />

consistently lost market share in terms of<br />

net assets. On 31 March 1999, UTI had<br />

a 77 percent market share with assets at<br />

Rs.531.45 billion out of total Rs.681.93<br />

billion. <strong>The</strong>se figures dropped dramatically<br />

over the following years and on 30<br />

June 2002 the market share of UTI was<br />

46 percent with assets amounting to<br />

Rs.463.96 billion out of total Rs.1007.03<br />

billion. UTI’s investments make up 11<br />

percent of the value of all stocks traded<br />

on the Bombay Stock Exchange.<br />

<strong>The</strong> collapse of UTI began in 1999.<br />

<strong>The</strong> UTI mutual fund scheme was ailing,<br />

the government had issued a Special Securities<br />

Scheme for Rs.33 billion by taking<br />

over a large percentage of public sector<br />

scrips which had a considerably lower<br />

book value. <strong>The</strong> government continued<br />

to pay interest of 11.2 percent to the trust<br />

until 2002. UTI had not paid any dividend<br />

to the government until then. However,<br />

things did not turn out as planned<br />

and due to harsh market conditions, especially<br />

with the tech meltdown, US- 64<br />

holdings fell by Rs.10 billion during January<br />

to November 2001. <strong>The</strong> problem<br />

was aggravated because unlike most open<br />

ended schemes US-64 did not declare its<br />

NAV on a daily basis. In 2001-02, the<br />

government provided a cash support of<br />

Rs.3 billion to US-64 following the sudden<br />

freezing of sale and repurchase of<br />

units on 2nd July 2001. In 2002, the central<br />

government doled out Rs.5 billion<br />

and promised another Rs.5 billion for the<br />

US-64 scheme to meet the difference between<br />

its net assets value and the administered<br />

repurchase price. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

planned to work out a tax concession<br />

package to enthuse investors to remain<br />

with the scheme after May 2003. A committee<br />

was set up to investigate the matter<br />

and make recommendations. <strong>The</strong><br />

committee revealed certain weaknesses<br />

in investments made by UTI.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se were:<br />

• Bad investments, including in firms it<br />

had been warned against investing in<br />

by its own internal advisory team. For<br />

example, UTI lost Rs 328 million investing<br />

in an Internet company against<br />

the advice of their own<br />

research department.<br />

• All 19 individual investment decisions<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

129


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

of the trust were imprudent and turned<br />

out to be in error.<br />

Apart from these investment inconsistencies,<br />

the stock scam in 2001 revealed<br />

the unhealthy nexus among the UTI (and<br />

possibly other mutual funds as well), local<br />

operators and promoters/corporates.<br />

It was believed the UTI mutual fund was<br />

the backbone of purchases in the infotech<br />

sector supported by the infamous operator<br />

Ketan Parikh. <strong>The</strong> tech meltdown of<br />

2001 resulted in sharp redemption for the<br />

scheme in early 2002. In mid 2002, the<br />

UTI decided to skip a dividend for its<br />

flagship US-64 scheme for the 2001-2002<br />

year. This was because the Net Asset<br />

Value (NAV) of the scheme has eroded<br />

sharply and was much lower than the face<br />

value of Rs.10. On 1st August 2002, the<br />

NAV of US-64 was only Rs.5.80. <strong>The</strong><br />

RBI was reported as contemplating a repurchase<br />

arrangement with UTI. This<br />

behavior of the RBI was an attempt to<br />

insulate the guilds market from the UTI<br />

crisis which was already having an impact<br />

on the equity market. Even some commercial<br />

banks such as the Bank of India,<br />

and State Bank of India started extending<br />

loans against UTI’s US-64 scheme<br />

at a steep discount. However, many<br />

other banks adopted a wait and<br />

watch policy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Finance inister, Yashwant Sinha<br />

was initially reluctant to provide any sort<br />

of government support to UTI. In a press<br />

conference he was quoted as saying, “We<br />

cannot go on spending government money<br />

for bailouts. A budgetary support is<br />

not a desirable option at the moment.”<br />

However this policy could not be sustained.<br />

A majority of public sector banks<br />

rejected the proposal of buying stocks<br />

held under its flagship US-64 scheme.<br />

However, these banks were willing to extend<br />

clean loans to UTI for a short period,<br />

provided the central government gave<br />

a “comfort letter” ensuring timely payment<br />

of the interest and principal amount.<br />

However, the finance minister was not<br />

keen on providing a “sovereign guarantee”<br />

to public sector banks in lieu of loans<br />

extended to UTI. <strong>The</strong> chairman of UTI,<br />

Mr. M. Damodaran was quoted as saying<br />

that “<strong>The</strong>re were problems on two fronts<br />

- liquidity and solvency. <strong>The</strong> liquidity can<br />

be taken care of by the banks line of<br />

credit. But, to address the solvency issue,<br />

the government will have to step in at the<br />

second stage, if the market does not pick<br />

up by that time- That is, the government<br />

will have to bail out UTI.” M. Damodaran<br />

said that, in the wake of a problem<br />

regarding the solvency issue, if the government<br />

was not forthcoming with funding,<br />

UTI would dump its illiquid stocks<br />

in the market.<br />

A report by global consultancy firm<br />

Mckinsey declared that UTI may need<br />

$500 million to stay solvent. Mckinsey<br />

argued that, given the high fiscal deficit,<br />

recapitalization from government funds<br />

would not be easy. Also, funds raised<br />

from the capital market would not be sufficient.<br />

After a series of meetings between<br />

UTI chairman, M. Damodaran and Secretary<br />

of the Department of Economic<br />

Affairs and later with Finance Minister<br />

Y. Sinha, the government decided to provide<br />

cash assistance to UTI of Rs.5 billion.<br />

Officials said the liabilities to the<br />

center would be provided for either in the<br />

budget or the final supplementary demand<br />

for grants and will be in the nature<br />

of a contingent liability on the government.<br />

Financial analysts began suggesting<br />

the government would have to bail<br />

out the country’s largest mutual fund operator<br />

for another year. In the light of a<br />

negative reserve of about Rs.37 billion<br />

and payment obligation for about Rs.9<br />

billion for two of its MIP schemes maturing<br />

2002 UTI had demanded around<br />

Rs.50 billion. <strong>The</strong> Cabinet Committee<br />

on Economic Affairs chaired by the<br />

Prime minister, Mr. A. B. Vajpayee, approved<br />

a bailout package of over Rs.145<br />

billion for UTI to meet the liabilities on<br />

its flagship US-64 and assured return<br />

schemes. <strong>The</strong> government also considered<br />

some tax concessions for US-64 unit<br />

holders so as to create a market, reduce<br />

redemption and keep up investment in<br />

the scheme. <strong>The</strong> Finance Minister also<br />

asserted there would be no budgetary<br />

impact as a result of the package, although<br />

it would add to the fiscal burden<br />

and contribute to public debt. <strong>The</strong> UTI<br />

case provides an interesting and important<br />

example of policy reversal in the face<br />

of financial crisis.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

“Under section 24 (b) of the Banking<br />

Regulation Act, 1949, every bank is<br />

required to maintain at the close of<br />

business every day, a minimum proportion<br />

of their Net Demand and Time<br />

Liabilities as liquid assets in the form<br />

of cash, gold and un-encumbered approved<br />

securities. <strong>The</strong> ratio of liquid<br />

assets to demand and time liabilities is<br />

known as Statutory Liquidity Ratio<br />

(SLR). Present SLR is 25 percent. <strong>The</strong><br />

RBI is empowered to increase the SLR<br />

up to 40 percent” (RBI Glossary).<br />

2<br />

In 1974, banks were required to direct<br />

33 percent of their net bank credit at<br />

concessional fixed interest rates to priority<br />

sectors. This was raised gradu-<br />

130 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ally to 40 percent in 1980.<br />

3<br />

NPA have been defined as those loans<br />

for which interest has remained unpaid<br />

for four quarters in 1992-93.<br />

4<br />

For a detailed analysis on financial crisis<br />

see Joshi and Little (1996), Cerra<br />

and Saxena (2002), Kapila and Kapila<br />

(1996) and Rangrajan (1991) among<br />

others.<br />

5<br />

For example (Kohli, 2001) reports the<br />

dates of indirect intervention done by<br />

RBI as October 1995, January and July<br />

1996, November 1997 and January,<br />

June and August 1998.<br />

6<br />

<strong>The</strong> 1998 committee on banking sector<br />

reforms recommended the minimum<br />

shareholding by the government<br />

or RBI equity in nationalized bank<br />

should be brought down to 33 percent.<br />

7<br />

In fact, few allies in the newly formed<br />

United Progressive Alliance (UPA)<br />

government are demanding a rise in<br />

the interest rates on various provident<br />

fund schemes.<br />

8<br />

To quote RBI Governor Y.V.<br />

Reddy:“<strong>The</strong> transaction costs are a<br />

drag on the economy and it is time to<br />

put emphasis on their reduction which<br />

can facilitate the growth of GDP by 2<br />

to 3 percent. (November 3, 2003, http://<br />

www.rediff.com/money/2003/nov/<br />

03cred10.htm)<br />

9<br />

Australian and New Zealand governments<br />

currently report such liabilities<br />

in their balance sheets.<br />

References<br />

• Bhattacharya, S. and U. R. Patel<br />

(2003). Reform Strategies in the<br />

Indian Financial Sector. In Conference<br />

on India’s and China’s Experience<br />

with Reform and Growth, New<br />

Delhi. International Monetary Fund<br />

and National Council of Applied<br />

Economic Research.<br />

• Bhide, M. G., A. Prasad, and S. Ghosh<br />

(2001). Emerging Challenges in Indian<br />

Banking. CREDPR Working Paper<br />

103.<br />

• Cerra, V. and S. C. Saxena (2002).<br />

What Caused the 1991 Currency Crisis<br />

in India? IMF Staff Papers 49.<br />

• de Aghion, B. A. and C. Gollier (2000).<br />

Peer Group Formation in an Adverse<br />

Selection Model. Economic Journal<br />

110, 632–43.<br />

• Demetriades, P. O. and K. B. Luintel<br />

(1996). Financial Development, Economic<br />

Growth and Banking Sector<br />

Controls: Evidence from India. <strong>The</strong><br />

Economic Journal 106, 359–374.<br />

• Ghatak, M. (2000). Screening by the<br />

Company you Keep: Joint Liability<br />

Lending and the Peer Selection Effect.<br />

Economic Journal 110, 601–31.<br />

• ha, R. and A. Sharma (2004). Structural<br />

Breaks, Unit Roots and Cointegration:<br />

A Further<br />

• Test of the Sustainability of the Indian<br />

Fiscal Deficit. Public Finance Review<br />

32.<br />

• Joshi, V. and I. M. D. Little (1996). India’s<br />

Economic Reforms: 1991-2001.<br />

Oxford: Claredon Press.<br />

• Kapila, R. and U. Kapila (1996). Understanding<br />

India’s Economic Reforms.<br />

New Delhi: Acedamic Foundation.<br />

• Kohli, R. (2001). Aspects of Exchange<br />

Rate Behavior and Management in<br />

India 1993-98. Economic and Political<br />

Weekly January 29.<br />

• Obstfeld, M. (1995). <strong>The</strong> Mirage of<br />

Fixed Exchange Rates. NBER Working<br />

Paper No. 5191.<br />

• Polackova, H. (1999). Contingent Government<br />

Liabilities: A Hidden Fiscal<br />

Risk. Finance and Development 36.<br />

• Puhazhendhi, V. (1995). Transaction<br />

Costs of Lending to the Rural Poor:<br />

Non-Governmental Organizations<br />

and Self-Help Groups of the Poor as<br />

Intermediaries for Banks in India.<br />

Banking with the Poor (BWTP) network.<br />

• Rangrajan, C. (1991). Recent Monetary<br />

Policy Measures and the Balance<br />

of Payments. Reserve Bank of India<br />

Bulletin July.<br />

• RBI (1990-2003b). Report on Currency<br />

and Finance.<br />

• RBI (1993-2003a). Trend and Progress<br />

in Banking in India.<br />

• RBI (1993-2003c). Reserve Bank of<br />

India Bulletin.<br />

• RBI (1997). Report on Currency and<br />

Finance.<br />

• RBI (2003d). Reserve Bank of India<br />

Annual Report.<br />

• Saez, L. (2001). Banking Reform in<br />

India and China. International Journal<br />

of Finance and Economics 6, 235–44.<br />

• Saggar, M. (1999). Some <strong>Issue</strong>s Relating<br />

to Exchange Rate Policy in India in<br />

the Post Liberalization Period. Ph. D.<br />

Dissertation, Indira Gandhi Institute<br />

of Development Research (IGIDR),<br />

Mumbai, India.<br />

• Sharma, A. (2004) Fiscal Deficits,<br />

Banking Crises And Adjustment Policy<br />

In A Semi-Open Economy Ph. D<br />

Dissertation, Australian National University,<br />

Canberra, Australia<br />

• Shirai, S. (2002). Banking Sector Reforms<br />

in India and China: Does India’s<br />

Experience Offer Lessons for China’s<br />

Future Reform Agenda. JBIC Discussion<br />

Paper No.2.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

131


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 3: Post-reform Exchange Rate Variability<br />

Prior to 1991, the exchange rate regime<br />

in India, was pegged to a currency <strong>The</strong> plots show the nominal exchange<br />

the currency.<br />

basket. Hence India had a fixed rate rate remained almost stable during the<br />

regime. Figure 1 plots the exchange rate two decades of the 1970’s and 1980’s.<br />

and its annual change, for rupee from <strong>The</strong> rate of change moved in a band of<br />

1970 to 1990. A positive change +/- 6 percent in the 1970’s except for<br />

indicates depreciation and a negative<br />

change indicates appreciation of percent due to the oil price<br />

1979 when the rupee depreciated by 10<br />

shock.<br />

During the 1991 financial crisis, faced<br />

with very low forex reserves the government<br />

floated the rupee, though the<br />

transition was gradual. Between 1991-<br />

93 there was a dual exchange rate regime<br />

and the rupee was subsequently<br />

floated in early 1993. International experience<br />

has shown exchange rate variability<br />

increases with a change to a<br />

more flexible rate regime. This has not<br />

been the case for India even after a decade<br />

of a floating rate regime as evident<br />

from the Figure 2 which plots the real<br />

effective exchange rate for the rupee<br />

from 1993-2002. This is essentially because<br />

a stable exchange rate remains an<br />

important objective of government exchange<br />

rate policy. Saggar (1999) notes<br />

the RBI’s intervention (measured by<br />

changes in foreign reserves) has in fact<br />

increased in the post 1993 period.<br />

<strong>The</strong> central bank has used both direct<br />

and indirect methods of market<br />

intervention. 5 <strong>The</strong> main objective of<br />

government policy is to keep the exchange<br />

rate aligned with the fundamentals<br />

of the economy like inflation. Thus<br />

the exchange rate depreciated by 1.5<br />

percent in September 1997 and the<br />

speed of depreciation was moderated<br />

by intervention sales by the RBI. In the<br />

central banks’ own words “...the conduct<br />

of exchange rate policy was guided<br />

by the need to maintain a delicate balance<br />

between the considerations of external<br />

competitiveness and price stability”<br />

(RBI, 1997, page I-9). This is also<br />

confirmed by analyzing the standard<br />

deviation of the rate of change in exchange<br />

rates, a measure of variability<br />

of the exchange rate. <strong>The</strong> standard deviation<br />

was 4.7 from 1970-80, 4.6 from<br />

1980-90 and 4.7 from 1993-2003. This<br />

122 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 4: Trends In Major Macroeconomic Indicators (1970-99)<br />

evidence clearly indicates that although<br />

the rupee has been floated, the government<br />

plays an important role in influencing<br />

demand and supply of forex reserves<br />

and thereby the exchange rate.<br />

4. Post-1991 Banking Reforms<br />

Financial sector reform was launched<br />

in 1991, based on the recommendation<br />

of the Narsimhan Committee (1991)<br />

that was set up by the government. <strong>The</strong><br />

1991 financial reforms were based on<br />

five fundamentals: Strengthening prudential<br />

norms and market discipline,<br />

appropriate adoption of international<br />

benchmarks, management of organiza-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

123


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 5: Trends In Major Banking Variables (1970-99)<br />

tional change and consolidation, technological<br />

upgrading and human resource<br />

development. Figure-3 compares<br />

major macroeconomic variables in the<br />

pre-reform and post-reform period.<br />

<strong>The</strong> banking sector reforms specifically<br />

included the following measures:<br />

<strong>The</strong> RBI reduced the CRR from 15<br />

percent in 1991 to 5.75 percent in November<br />

2001. <strong>The</strong> cash reserve ratio<br />

was further reduced to 4.5 percent in<br />

May 2004, although it remains higher<br />

than its statuary minimum level of 3<br />

percent. <strong>The</strong> SLR has been reduced<br />

from 38.5 percent in 1991 to 25 percent<br />

124 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


Pramod K.Yadav Ritesh Agarwal<br />

Doctoral Students, Indian Institute of Management (IIM)-Ahmedabad<br />

Indian Corporate Bond Market:<br />

<strong>The</strong> Road Ahead<br />

"In the age of globalization, where vast amounts<br />

of capital can be moved across the world with<br />

a mere computer keystroke, functioning bond<br />

markets are more important than ever. So is<br />

having a group of infl uential, globally known<br />

bond buyers who can alert the government if its<br />

policies are roiling markets, either by dumping<br />

its debt or speaking out. It's incredibly important<br />

that India's government and central bank continue<br />

to nurture the market's growth. India needs<br />

to take advantage of the favorable economic<br />

climate to strengthen regulation, improve transparency<br />

and bolster liquidity. It also needs to act<br />

faster to increase foreign investors' ability to move<br />

funds here. were put to productive use here.<br />

investor and business confi dence...India is<br />

stepping up efforts to do just that. For all China's<br />

advantages, bonds are one important area where<br />

India is ahead. It means markets here in Mumbai<br />

are likely to have their own Bill Gross before<br />

Shanghai does."<br />

William Pesek Jr.,<br />

International Herald Tribune,(IHT),<br />

October 11, 2004<br />

<strong>The</strong> Corporate Debt Market in<br />

India is underdeveloped, both in<br />

terms of the market participation<br />

and efficient price discovery; and the<br />

volume of fixed income securities is very<br />

small as compared to equity market.<br />

Most of the big Indian Corporate still<br />

seek bank finance and retained earnings<br />

to fulfill their funding requirements. Primary<br />

corporate debt market is dominated<br />

by non-banking finance companies and<br />

the total corporate debt market is a minuscule<br />

2 percent of the total debt market.<br />

Over the years, Indian firms have<br />

relied more on the equity market, retained<br />

earnings and bank loans to fulfill<br />

the funding requirements. To make the<br />

matter worse, the secondary market in<br />

corporate bonds has also not picked up<br />

as desired. Securities Exchange Board of<br />

India (SEBI) and the stock exchanges did<br />

realize the need of corporate bond and<br />

introduced various regulations to provide<br />

an impetus to the bond market; however<br />

none of the regulations or norm could<br />

yield the desired results. <strong>The</strong> debt market<br />

in India is broadly classified as government<br />

securities market and corporate<br />

securities market. <strong>The</strong> Indian debt market<br />

is highly skewed towards government<br />

securities market. Total outstanding debt<br />

of India has increased over the years and<br />

was around 36 percent of the GDP in<br />

2004-way below the mature financial<br />

markets (IMF,2004). <strong>The</strong> current government<br />

bond segment resulting from<br />

persistently high fiscal deficits and regulatory<br />

requirement in India is about 40<br />

percent of the GDP –at par with the well<br />

functioning financial markets. Nearly 90<br />

percent of the bonds issued in India are<br />

government bonds. <strong>The</strong> enormous <strong>size</strong> of<br />

the government bond market is not surprising<br />

considering the persistent high<br />

fiscal deficit and consequentially high<br />

public sector borrowings. Mandatory requirement<br />

on the part of banks to invest<br />

through statutory liquidity reserve<br />

(SLR,currently at 25 percent) compounds<br />

the problem. Perceived risk free nature<br />

132 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

of the government bonds leads banks to<br />

include even greater percentage of government<br />

bonds in their portfolio than the<br />

prescribed SRL of 25 percent. Government<br />

and Reserve Bank of India introduced<br />

many structural changes to improve<br />

transparency in the market<br />

dealings, method of primary auctions, allowing<br />

Primary Dealers, borrowings at<br />

market determined rates, and creating<br />

technology platforms like NDS to recognize<br />

the institutional characteristics of<br />

the market. <strong>The</strong> same kind of impetus<br />

has been lacking in the Indian corporate<br />

bond markets and as a result of this, major<br />

source of corporate funding is all but<br />

non-existent.<br />

<strong>The</strong> corporate bond market, in the<br />

sense of raising debt through public issuance<br />

in capital market, is shadowed by<br />

growing equity market and government<br />

bond market and was less than 2 percent<br />

of Indian GDP in 2004 compared to 50<br />

percent in Singapore,68 percent in South<br />

Korea, and 143 percent in USA (IMF,<br />

2004). A well developed corporate bond<br />

market facilitates the firms operating in<br />

the economy to devise their optimum for Indian debt capital markets”,<br />

capital structure and investors to have (Nov,<strong>2007</strong>), predicts that Indian bond<br />

better spectrum of asset classes to 160<br />

hedge and diversify their fixed income<br />

risks. <strong>The</strong> share of corporate<br />

140<br />

Government Debt<br />

bonds in the total bond issued has 120<br />

also decreased from 34 percent in<br />

Corporate Debt<br />

100<br />

1999-00 to a 29 percent in 2003-<br />

80<br />

04. <strong>The</strong> weak status of corporate<br />

bond market was mainly due to 60<br />

dominance of government securities<br />

and structure of the market<br />

itself where government was borrowing<br />

at pre-decided coupon<br />

rates from a group of investors<br />

such as banks. <strong>The</strong> public sector<br />

Debt As Percentage Of GDP<br />

40<br />

20<br />

undertakings (PSUs) have persistently<br />

overshadowed the private sector bond issuance<br />

over the years. Corporate debt<br />

can be raised either by private placement<br />

or public issue. Private placement is preferred<br />

owing to the regulatory processes,<br />

higher cost associated with public issuance,<br />

and enormous hurdles in public issues<br />

process in the form of various types<br />

of disclosure, registration requisites etc<br />

(NSE, 2005).<strong>The</strong>se reasons have also incentivized<br />

the corporate to raise debt<br />

from abroad because of lesser listing and<br />

disclosure requirements, lower cost, and<br />

better liquidity in secondary market.<br />

Debt raised abroad increased around two<br />

and a half times from 2001 to 2005 equivalent<br />

to 60 percent of corporate issuance<br />

in domestic debt market (NSE, 2005).<br />

<strong>The</strong> latest report by the Goldman Sachs<br />

titled, “ Bonding the BRICs: Big chance<br />

0<br />

market is going to grow fourfold and<br />

reach to the level of $1.5 trillion by 2016.<br />

It also reports that the corporate bond<br />

market will annually grow by around 28<br />

percent from $100 billion to $575 billion<br />

in 2016.Such a high benchmark (required<br />

growth of 28 percent) when contrasted<br />

with almost non-existent growth rate of<br />

the corporate bond market (historically)<br />

raises a big concern for policy makers and<br />

According to Goldman Sachs, Indian bond market is going<br />

to grow fourfold and reach to the level of $1.5 trillion by<br />

2016. <strong>The</strong> corporate bond market will annually grow by<br />

around 28 % from $100 billion to $575 billion in 2016<br />

India<br />

China<br />

Korea<br />

Malaysia<br />

Singapore<br />

USA<br />

market participants equally. A robust<br />

policy framework together with a performance<br />

based regulatory approach is<br />

urgently required to push the market to a<br />

higher growth and market friendly frontier.<br />

<strong>The</strong> booming economy, growing<br />

populations, and rising household income<br />

are exerting huge demand for infrastructure<br />

services. <strong>The</strong> inability to meet such<br />

a fast growing demand has become more<br />

visible in recent past and evident by congestion<br />

on the roads, airports, ports, frequent<br />

electricity cut etc. <strong>The</strong>re is no way<br />

India can take its infrastructure requirement<br />

for granted if it aims to<br />

traverse the sustainable growth trajectory.<br />

<strong>The</strong> government officials estimate<br />

the infrastructure requirement<br />

of about $500 billion in next five<br />

years. It is also expected that about 40<br />

percent of the fund will be infused by<br />

the private sector. Considering the<br />

long term irreversible nature of infrastructure<br />

investment and short to<br />

medium term liabilities of banks, long<br />

term financing in the form of debt is<br />

widely accepted as the most appropri-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

133


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

External Commercial Borrowings<br />

Year<br />

ate financing approach. However current<br />

shallow status of Indian bond market<br />

does not seem to be geared to meet the<br />

target capital requirement. <strong>The</strong> inability<br />

to meet the financing requirement of infrastructure<br />

leads to a lower output and<br />

hence a shortfall in the welfare and GDP<br />

and other various dominos effects.<br />

<strong>The</strong> demand for corporate debt can be<br />

gauged by the fact that Indian corporate<br />

papers are in huge demand in overseas<br />

market in the form of external commercial<br />

borrowings (ECBs). In <strong>2007</strong> itself,<br />

the net ECB inflow in the country was<br />

about $16 billion and RBI had to tighten<br />

the norms on ECB borrowing in order to<br />

keep inflation and rupee-dollar exchange<br />

rate in check.<br />

ECB Gross<br />

inflow<br />

<strong>The</strong> experience of US and other developed<br />

countries clearly indicates that the<br />

corporate bond market played an important<br />

role in the development of the economy<br />

as a whole. During the last few years,<br />

DFI’s access to long-term funds has dwindled<br />

and they cannot meet the demand<br />

for term funds of industry and infrastructure<br />

sectors when investment activity is<br />

all set to pick up from the present low<br />

levels. Moreover, as the demand term<br />

debt increases significantly to finance<br />

ECB outflow<br />

(imputed)<br />

Net ECB<br />

inflow<br />

high level of investments, excessive dependence<br />

on banks will hit the creditworthy<br />

borrowers, as they would end up<br />

paying up more than what they would<br />

have to pay if they decide to raise funds<br />

from the market directly.<br />

DEMAND SIDE<br />

<strong>The</strong> corporate bond market in India is<br />

underdeveloped owing to the limitations/<br />

reluctance of the various market<br />

participants:-<br />

Corporate – <strong>The</strong> cash credit system of<br />

banks operates in effect like a loan in<br />

perpetuity, many corporates prefer it to<br />

bond financing where the amount has to<br />

be returned on a specific date. Moreover,<br />

they are either riding on the current equity<br />

boom in the economy or relying<br />

more on retained earnings.<br />

Foreign Institutional Investors are<br />

major players in the equities market.<br />

However, there exists a ceiling on their<br />

investment in the debt market (currently<br />

there is a ceiling of $1.5 billion on investment<br />

in corporate debt), they are present<br />

only in a limited way in the bond<br />

market.<br />

Pension Funds And <strong>The</strong> Insurance<br />

Sector could spurt the market activities<br />

but the absence of pension funds and low<br />

insurance penetration has meant limited<br />

demand for long-term bonds.<br />

Gross inflow<br />

on ECB<br />

2002 2687 4272 -1585<br />

2003 3514 5206 -1692 827<br />

2004 5228 8153 -2925 1714<br />

2005 9084 3890 5194 3856<br />

2006 14547 11824 2723 5463<br />

<strong>2007</strong> 21291 5207 16084 6744<br />

SOURCE - RBI<br />

Households too are almost completely<br />

absent from the market, due to the lack<br />

of an efficient legal system, and unhappy<br />

experience with debenture trustees.<br />

SUPPLY SIDE<br />

• Public Placement – <strong>The</strong>re are a lot<br />

many regulations related to disclosure<br />

and filing of the norms which adds to<br />

the overall costs of issuing the bonds.<br />

Corporate prefer private placements<br />

owing to less hassles and almost non<br />

existent disclosure norms. Though the<br />

government has limited the private<br />

placement partners to 50 in case of<br />

private placement, corporate has<br />

sought a way out because the partners<br />

can issue the debt issued to them to<br />

new partners.<br />

• Illiquidity – A large part of the market<br />

does not mark-to-market the corporate<br />

bond portfolio. As a result, once any<br />

bond goes into the books, it does not<br />

come out. This takes away liquidity<br />

from the market.<br />

• Trading is concentrated in AAA – rated<br />

bonds, as they are the safest and<br />

most liquid. A large part of the market,<br />

including insurance companies, provident<br />

funds and banks, has restrictions<br />

on private sector paper. Thus the<br />

bonds of public sector units are much<br />

more liquid than private sector<br />

bonds.<br />

Benefits Of Efficient Market For<br />

Market Participants<br />

Corporate<br />

• Availability of long term funds – An<br />

efficient bond market gives the freedom<br />

to issue long term debt. This is<br />

particularly important for India where<br />

there is a large requirement of infra-<br />

134 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

structure financing which involves long<br />

term loans. A well-functioning corporate<br />

bond market allows firms to tailor<br />

their asset and liability profiles and<br />

hence allows them to raise long-term<br />

funds to invest in ventures that have a<br />

long-term payoff.<br />

• Reduced fund costs – <strong>The</strong> corporate<br />

may borrow directly from the investors<br />

eliminating the intermediaries like<br />

banks which will reduce their overall<br />

cost of funds.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Financial System<br />

• <strong>The</strong> net interest margin of Indian banks<br />

has increased from about 225 basis points<br />

to 400 basis points during the last 10 years<br />

leading to a high cost of commercial borrowing.<br />

<strong>The</strong> high cost of commercial borrowing<br />

has prompted the big corporate<br />

to borrow from overseas markets however<br />

smaller companies are bound to borrow<br />

at high rates from the banks. <strong>The</strong><br />

high cost of borrowing is also evident<br />

from low credit-deposit ratio of Indian<br />

banks which is a almost 50 percent to that<br />

Credit-Deposit Ratio Of Indian Banks<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

130<br />

114<br />

101<br />

92 90<br />

83 81 80 79<br />

61 61<br />

53<br />

China<br />

UK<br />

Source -RBI & McKinsey<br />

Malaysia<br />

US<br />

Korea<br />

Thailand<br />

Japan<br />

Brazil<br />

Singapore<br />

India<br />

Czech Rep<br />

Turkey<br />

of China. <strong>The</strong> corporate bond market can rating agencies, a wide range of corporate<br />

exert a competitive pressure on commercial<br />

banks in the matter of lending to priing<br />

sophisticated credit analysis, an op-<br />

debt securities and derivatives demandvate<br />

business and thus help improve the portunity to make private placements,<br />

efficiency of the capital market as a whole. and efficient procedures for corporate.<br />

A well developed corporate bond market<br />

would lead to a reduction in the systemic Investors<br />

risk and probability of crisis. This is because<br />

the presence of such an environ-<br />

is also essential for the investors because<br />

A well developed corporate bond market<br />

ment is associated with greater accounting<br />

transparency, a large community of safe way of investment but also helps<br />

it not only provides them an alternate and<br />

professional financial analysts, respected them diversify their risks.<br />

Leading Rates In India<br />

SOURCE - RBI<br />

Average5 Year<br />

Deposit Rates Average<br />

Lending<br />

Rates<br />

Spread(%)<br />

1997-98 11.75 14.00 2.25<br />

1998-99 11.00 12.50 1.50<br />

1999-00 10.25 12.25 2.00<br />

2000-01 9.75 11.50 1.75<br />

2001-02 8.25 11.50 3.25<br />

2002-03 5.88 11.13 5.25<br />

2003-04 5.38 10.63 5.25<br />

2004-05 6.00 10.50 4.50<br />

2005-06 6.63 10.50 3.88<br />

2006-07 7.25 11.25 4.00<br />

Developing <strong>The</strong> Corporate Bond<br />

Market<br />

Increasing Market Participation<br />

By Widening <strong>The</strong> Investor Base<br />

Banks – At present, banks’ loan portfolios<br />

are not treated at par with their investment<br />

portfolio. <strong>The</strong> investment<br />

portfolio (banks’ investments in corporate<br />

bonds) has to be marked to market<br />

where as the same constraint is not there<br />

in the case of a loan extended to the same<br />

corporate. Hence there is incentive for<br />

the bank to extend loans to the corporate<br />

instead of investing in corporate bonds.<br />

Banks’ investments in corporate bonds<br />

need to be encouraged especially by<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

135


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

bringing in changes in the prudential<br />

regulatory mechanism which treats loans<br />

portfolio on par with investment portfolio.<br />

Moreover, Co-operative banks are<br />

permitted to invest only a small part of<br />

their deposits in bonds issued by PSUs<br />

and only scheduled co-operative banks<br />

are allowed to invest in private sector<br />

bonds. Allowing all co-operatives banks<br />

to invest in high quality corporate bonds<br />

would be helpful as cooperative banks<br />

have large deposits.<br />

FIIs – <strong>The</strong> investment limits of FII in<br />

corporate bonds should be increased<br />

because FIIs are a major investor class<br />

and can bring volumes to the corporate<br />

bond markets. Though the limit was<br />

hiked recently to USD 1.5 billion, still<br />

this is too small for big players taking any<br />

active interest in this market<br />

meaningfully.<br />

Provident Funds And Pension<br />

Funds – <strong>The</strong>se should be allowed to<br />

invest on the basis of rating rather than<br />

in terms of category of issuers. This may<br />

encourage these funds to invest in high<br />

quality corporate bonds. Currently, these<br />

funds are allowed to invest only up to 10<br />

percent of the accruals in a year in private<br />

corporate bonds and 40 percent of the<br />

corpus can be invested in bonds issued by<br />

public sector undertakings. As the Risk<br />

profile of a large number of the PSUs<br />

established by the state governments is<br />

not materially different from that of several<br />

private corporate sector companies.<br />

ECB in India has increased during the last fi ve years.<br />

This is an indication that Indian corporate want to raise<br />

debt... which is not easily available in the market owing to<br />

regulatory issues and high cost of borrowing<br />

Hence, investment that rating quality as<br />

indicated by the recognized rating companies<br />

should become the main criteria<br />

for investment in corporate bonds and<br />

not category of bonds in terms of issuers.<br />

Thus the guidelines issued to PFs and<br />

EPFs need not discriminate between<br />

State Govt. PSUs and private corporate<br />

sector entities. To encourage small investors,<br />

the bond market structure should<br />

emulate the equity market structure and<br />

retail investors should be able to buy and<br />

sell bonds without any restriction on the<br />

minimum market lot. Currently an investor<br />

can buy even one share in the equity<br />

market.<br />

Increasing Market Participation<br />

By Widening <strong>The</strong> <strong>Issue</strong>r Base<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Issue</strong>r base can be increased primarily<br />

by reviewing the current guidelines<br />

for issuance, disclosure and listing of corporate<br />

bonds. <strong>The</strong> current regulations<br />

and guidelines should be made less stringent<br />

so that it would become easier for<br />

the companies to issue bonds. On the flip<br />

side, regulations are needed to promote<br />

the volume and liquidity in the primary<br />

market apart from increased issuance.<br />

Currently banks are allowed to issue<br />

bonds of maturities over five years only<br />

for financing infrastructure sector. Since<br />

banks are one of the leading issuers of<br />

bonds, they should be allowed to issue<br />

bonds of maturities over five years subject<br />

to their asset liability matching norms.<br />

<strong>The</strong> development of an interest rate derivatives<br />

markets is a major prerequisite<br />

to facilitate this.<br />

Banks are one of the major issuers of<br />

bonds to augment their tier-II capital and<br />

these bonds are in turn subscribed to by<br />

other banks (cross holdings). This reduces<br />

the overall volume and liquidity in the<br />

market. Regulatory caps should be fixed<br />

for such cross investments so that other<br />

participants are given an opportunity to<br />

subscribe to these bonds.<br />

Market Makers<br />

Market makers provide exit options to<br />

investors to buy or sell bonds whenever<br />

desired by the investors. <strong>The</strong> market<br />

making in corporate bonds is necessary<br />

as the market is in a nascent stage and it<br />

would require the psychological comfort<br />

in the beginning. Investment banks that<br />

help corporate to raise money from the<br />

market can possibly be roped in to market<br />

making in the bonds which they have<br />

helped in issuance.<br />

Listing Norms To Be Eased And<br />

Enhancing Liquidity<br />

As mentioned earlier, External Commercial<br />

Borrowing in India has increased<br />

during the last five years which is an indication<br />

that Indian corporate want to<br />

raise debt which is not easily available in<br />

the market owing to regulatory issues<br />

and high cost of borrowing. <strong>The</strong>re is less<br />

issuance of corporate debt in the first<br />

place and secondly disclosure and documentation<br />

norms deter the corporate to<br />

issue debt publicly. Thus, the corporate<br />

debt market is dominated by private<br />

placements. For listed entities, norms<br />

can be made simpler; they should be allowed<br />

an abridged version of disclosure;<br />

whereas unlisted companies issuing<br />

136 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

bonds to institutional investors and<br />

QIBs, rating should form the basis for<br />

placement. However, companies which<br />

are not listed and which are opting for<br />

the private placement mode should be<br />

subjected to stringent disclosure norms.<br />

Privately placed bonds should be mandatorily<br />

listed within seven days from the<br />

date of allotment, as is the case with public<br />

issues. <strong>The</strong> practice of suspension of<br />

trading/delisting of securities in case of<br />

non compliance with listing norms by an<br />

issuer needs to be replaced by heavy penalties<br />

on the promoters and directors of<br />

the erring company. Debenture trusties<br />

should be made more responsible and<br />

accountable. <strong>The</strong>y also should ensure<br />

that important information such as rating<br />

downgrades should be disseminated<br />

to the investors.<br />

Trade Reporting System<br />

<strong>The</strong>re should be a mechanism to capture<br />

all the information relating to trades in<br />

corporate bonds, disseminate the same<br />

and maintaining a database of trade history.<br />

Regulators should direct the market<br />

participants to report all the transactions<br />

done by them to the trade<br />

reporting system.<br />

Trading, Clearing And Settling<br />

Mechanism<br />

Anonymous screen based order matching<br />

trading systems should be adopted in<br />

order to improve the transparency and<br />

efficiency in the corporate bond transactions.<br />

However, multiple trading platforms<br />

may also impact the liquidity adversely.<br />

Moreover, novation and<br />

multilateral netting should form the<br />

backbone for risk mitigation and enhancement<br />

of liquidity.<br />

Development Of Derivative<br />

Market<br />

Derivative market is essential for hedging<br />

interest rate risk. Though interest<br />

rate swaps and forward rate agreements<br />

exist in India, there is a need for advanced<br />

derivative instruments for better<br />

price discovery and hedging. RBI has<br />

already initiated certain steps and<br />

formed committees to formulate<br />

a framework for some advanced<br />

derivative instruments.<br />

Price Distorting <strong>Issue</strong>s<br />

Stamp duty is a levied by the State<br />

Governments and RBI should reduce the<br />

stamp duty and rationalize it<br />

between different states. Tax Deducted<br />

at Source (TDS) also distorts the pricing<br />

of bonds. TDS on interest income from<br />

corporate bonds is not uniformly<br />

applicable to all the investors. While insurance<br />

companies and mutual funds are<br />

exempt from the provisions of TDS, all<br />

other market players are subject to it in<br />

respect of interest paid on corporate<br />

bonds. An automated computerized<br />

trading system and a meaningful price<br />

discovery process cannot be introduced<br />

because of the differing TDS treatment<br />

for different market player. <strong>The</strong>refore it<br />

is desirable to have a uniformTDS rule<br />

for all the market players.<br />

<strong>The</strong> shut period (for reckoning the registered<br />

owner of the bond for payment of<br />

coupons) is very long and may be brought<br />

on par with that for the government securities,<br />

which is one day. It is also necessary<br />

to standardize the day count conventions.<br />

Currently the day count<br />

conventions in the market differ depending<br />

upon the nature of the<br />

instruments and the nature of<br />

the transaction.<br />

References<br />

• Sharma, V. K. and Sinha, Chandan.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Corporate Debt Market in India<br />

(2006). Bank for International Settlements,<br />

Paper No. 26<br />

• Stone, M. Corporate Debt Restructuring<br />

in East Asia: Some Lessons from<br />

International Experience (1998). International<br />

Monetary Fund<br />

PPAA/98/13<br />

• Mohan, R. 'Recent Trends in the Indian<br />

Debt Market and Current Initiatives'<br />

(2006)<br />

• Bose, S and Coondoo, D. A Study of the<br />

Indian Corporate Bond Market (2003).<br />

Social Science Research Network.<br />

• Kar , S and Khasnobis, B.G. <strong>The</strong> Corporate<br />

Debt Market-A Firm-Level<br />

Panel Study for India. Research Paper<br />

No. 2006/50, UNU-WIDER World<br />

Institute for Development Economics<br />

Research<br />

• Reddy, Y.V. '<strong>Issue</strong>s and challenges in<br />

the development of the debt market in<br />

India' (2003). BIS Paper No.11, Bank<br />

for International Settlements<br />

• '<strong>The</strong> Indian Bond Market, Current<br />

Situations and Developments' (2006),<br />

Keio University.<br />

• India’s Capital Market (<strong>2007</strong>), Deutsche<br />

Bank<br />

• "Bonding the BRICs: A big chance for<br />

India’s Debt Capital Market"(<strong>2007</strong>),<br />

Goldman Sachs<br />

• IMF Global Financial Stability Report,<br />

September <strong>2007</strong><br />

• IMF Global Financial Stability Report,<br />

April <strong>2007</strong><br />

• NSE Debt RoundUp, October <strong>2007</strong><br />

• "India on fire", <strong>The</strong> Economist; February<br />

1st <strong>2007</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

137


Paul Conway Richard Herd<br />

Sean Dougherty<br />

Organisation For Economic Co-operation And Development (OECD), Paris<br />

Just How Free Are India's Labour<br />

And Product Markets?<br />

"Freedom in economic arrangements<br />

is itself a component<br />

of freedom broadly understood,<br />

so economic<br />

freedom is an end in itself ...<br />

Economic freedom is also an<br />

indispensable means toward<br />

the achievement of political<br />

freedom."<br />

-Milton Friedman<br />

1. Since the mid 1980s India has undergone<br />

a profound shift in economic management<br />

as successive reforms have<br />

progressively moved the economy towards<br />

a market-based system. State intervention<br />

and control over economic<br />

activity has been reduced significantly<br />

and the role of private-sector entrepreneurship<br />

increased. Overall, reform has<br />

had a major beneficial impact on the<br />

economy. Annual growth in GDP per<br />

capita has accelerated from just 1¼ per<br />

cent in the three decades after Independence<br />

to 7½ per cent currently, a<br />

rate of growth that will double average<br />

income in a decade. <strong>The</strong> sustainable<br />

growth rate of the economy is currently<br />

estimated to be 8½ per cent and India<br />

is now the fourth largest economy in the<br />

world when measured using the most<br />

up-to-date purchasing power parities.<br />

Increased economic growth has helped<br />

reduce poverty, which has begun to fall<br />

in absolute terms.<br />

2. In general, areas of the Indian business<br />

sector that have been opened to<br />

private sector involvement have responded<br />

well. In service sectors where<br />

government regulation has either been<br />

eased significantly or was less burdensome<br />

to start with, such as insurance,<br />

asset management and information<br />

technology, output has grown rapidly<br />

with exports of information technology<br />

enabled services being particularly<br />

strong and a key component of India’s<br />

economic transformation. In some of<br />

the former fully government-owned infrastructure<br />

sectors, such as telecommunications<br />

and domestic civil aviation,<br />

opening to the private sector has produced<br />

exemplary results and growth has<br />

been phenomenal. <strong>The</strong> market shares<br />

of new entrants in both these sectors are<br />

now over 75% while consumer choice<br />

has expanded and prices have fallen.<br />

3. Notwithstanding these and other success<br />

stories, government regulation is<br />

still excessively restrictive and acts as a<br />

barrier to private sector involvement in<br />

a number of areas. In this article we<br />

draw on the OECD’s first Economic<br />

138 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Survey of India, which was released in<br />

October <strong>2007</strong>, to briefly assess two areas<br />

in which regulation could be made<br />

more supportive of competition and private<br />

sector involvement: the business<br />

environment in markets for goods and<br />

services (henceforth referred to as the<br />

product market) and labour markets.<br />

This work is based on field work in<br />

twenty one states that has enabled us to<br />

construct cross-state indicators of regulation<br />

in product and labour markets.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are other areas where government<br />

interference is also high, such as<br />

the financial and energy sectors, and<br />

areas where large subsidies are paid.<br />

Our views on these areas can be found<br />

in the Survey.<br />

Despite Liberalisation, Product<br />

Market Regulation Could<br />

Still Do More To Support<br />

Competition<br />

Figure 1. Product Market Regulations: An International Comparison<br />

Australia<br />

UK<br />

Iceland<br />

US<br />

Ireland<br />

Denmark<br />

New Zealand<br />

Canada<br />

Sweden<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Japan<br />

Finland<br />

Belgium<br />

Netherlands<br />

Austria<br />

Slovak R.<br />

Germany<br />

Norway<br />

Korea<br />

Portugal<br />

Spain<br />

Switzerland<br />

Grance<br />

Czech R.<br />

Greece<br />

Italy<br />

Brazil<br />

Hungary<br />

Mexico<br />

Chile<br />

Turkey<br />

Poland<br />

INDIA<br />

number of barriers that do limit private<br />

sector involvement and competition in<br />

markets.<br />

PSEs for 14 % of GDP, rising to 22 % of the non-agricultural<br />

business sector and an even higher share of activity<br />

in the formal sector of the economy. Many of the sectors<br />

in which they operate are inherently competitive<br />

OECD<br />

Average<br />

0 1 2 3<br />

<strong>The</strong> indicator score runs from 0-6 from least to most restrictive of competition<br />

4. Overall, product market regulation in<br />

India restricts completion to a greater<br />

extent than in all OECD countries and<br />

both Brazil and Chile (Figure 1). This<br />

is despite some aspects of India’s regulatory<br />

framework in product markets<br />

being comparable with best practice in<br />

OECD countries. For example, formal<br />

legal barriers to market entry have been<br />

removed in almost all sectors and there<br />

is minimal government interference in<br />

the conduct of private sector firms<br />

through, for example, price controls and<br />

special voting rights (notwithstanding<br />

restrictions on the voting rights of private<br />

shareholders in government-owned<br />

banks). <strong>The</strong>re are, however, still a<br />

<strong>The</strong> Public Enterprise Sector Is<br />

Large And Distorts Competition<br />

5. A high level of government involvement<br />

in commercial activity is one important<br />

reason why India’s business<br />

environment is less supportive of competition<br />

in comparison to other countries.<br />

Overall, public enterprises account<br />

for 14% of GDP, rising to 22% of<br />

the non-agricultural business sector and<br />

an even higher share of activity in the<br />

formal sector of the economy. Many of<br />

the sectors in which public sector enterprises<br />

(PSEs) operate are inherently<br />

competitive.<br />

6. PSEs have a negative effect on the<br />

business environment for a number of<br />

reasons. First and foremost, because<br />

government plays the dual role of major<br />

market player and policy maker (and<br />

sometimes regulator in infrastructure<br />

sectors), there is often no clear separation<br />

between the ownership function<br />

and other functions that influence market<br />

conditions. For example, PSEs are<br />

often required to fulfil social and public<br />

policy obligations with their governance<br />

adversely affected by political interference<br />

and the use of civil servants as directors.<br />

Moreover, in many states the<br />

strategic commercial choices of PSEs<br />

often have to be cleared by the state assembly.<br />

Finally, the procurement poli-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

139


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 2. Distribution Of Rates Of Return Of Public Sector Enterprises<br />

Rate of Return (%)<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

-10<br />

-20<br />

-30<br />

-40<br />

PrivateSector Listed Firms<br />

PSEs (Centre)<br />

PSEs (State)<br />

-50<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90<br />

Percentile<br />

cies of the central and state governments<br />

often favour PSEs. Because they<br />

dominate some markets, political interference<br />

in the operation of PSEs also<br />

adversely influences overall market conditions.<br />

7. <strong>The</strong>re have been some attempts to<br />

commercialise the activities of central<br />

PSEs through, for example, the Navratna<br />

and Mini-Ratna concepts and<br />

the introduction of higher limits for investments<br />

that do not need to be cleared<br />

by parliament. <strong>The</strong> proportion of loss<br />

significant variation across states (Table<br />

1). With a large tail of unprofitable<br />

firms, the total losses of loss-making<br />

central and state PSEs amounted to almost<br />

1% of GDP in 2005.<br />

8. <strong>The</strong>re are a number of ways in which<br />

the corporate governance of the PSEs<br />

could be improved to ensure a level<br />

playing field and government neutrality<br />

in its dealings with the private sector<br />

and thereby increase competition. <strong>The</strong><br />

centre and state governments need to<br />

transparently unbundle the commercial<br />

<strong>The</strong> financial health of the state-owned PSEs is, on average,<br />

poor and worse than that of the central enterprises.<br />

<strong>The</strong> total losses of loss-making central and state PSEs<br />

amounted to almost 1% of GDP in 2005<br />

making central enterprises has been reduced<br />

but, even so, the return earned by<br />

the median PSE was only 3% in 2005<br />

(after subsidies) against 10% in the private<br />

sector (Figure 2). <strong>The</strong> financial<br />

health of the state-owned PSEs is, on<br />

average, poor and worse than that of the<br />

central enterprises, although there is<br />

and promotional/policy roles of the<br />

PSEs. Moving towards a more centralised<br />

model of PSE management would<br />

be a large step in this direction. Currently,<br />

at the centre, responsibility for<br />

the PSEs rests primarily with the line<br />

ministry while the Department of Public<br />

Enterprises plays a coordinating role<br />

and elaborates the overall<br />

ownership policy. This decentralised<br />

model was predominant<br />

in OECD countries before<br />

the first wave of public<br />

sector reforms during the<br />

1970s. With the shift from<br />

industry-specific policies to<br />

more framework-oriented<br />

and market liberalisation<br />

policies, the main advantage<br />

of this approach of allowing a<br />

more activist industrial policy<br />

has now vanished.<br />

9. A more centralised approach,<br />

where PSEs are put<br />

under the responsibility of an investment<br />

agency, would achieve a clearer<br />

separation between policy and commercial<br />

functions and distance PSEs from<br />

political control. It would also facilitate<br />

a more unified and consistent ownership<br />

policy, simplify the often elaborate<br />

committee structures that currently supervise<br />

and control PSEs, and ensure<br />

equitable treatment of non-state shareholders.<br />

Care would be needed to ensure<br />

that centralising the ownership<br />

function of the PSEs did not entail the<br />

creation of additional layers of control<br />

or bureaucracy within government. Ultimately,<br />

the structure of the public administration<br />

needs to be reorganised to<br />

be more consistent with a modern-day<br />

focus on general framework conditions<br />

instead of the current “command and<br />

control” approach. This will entail a<br />

significant consolidation and reduction<br />

in the number of ministries and departments<br />

in both the central and state<br />

governments.<br />

10. In addition to a more centralised approach,<br />

the way in which any remaining<br />

140 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1. Performance Of State-Level PSEs<br />

Number<br />

of<br />

PSEs<br />

Proportion<br />

of loss making<br />

PSEs<br />

Losses of<br />

loss making<br />

PSEs<br />

Proportion of capital<br />

in 'non-working'<br />

PSEs<br />

Proportion of<br />

PSEs with negative<br />

net worth<br />

Rate of Return on<br />

Capital<br />

% % SGDP % % medium average<br />

Andhra Pradesh 54 15 -0.06 2.3 14.8 5.6 10.0<br />

Assam 43 77 -3.47 1.6 20.9 -3.3 -16.4<br />

Bihar 54 70 -1.38 13.0 11.1 -2.5 -7.7<br />

Chhattisgarh 11 36 -0.02 0.0 9.1 5.1 4.6<br />

Delhi 11 45 -4.21 0.0 9.1 3.6 -27.8<br />

Goa 16 63 -0.57 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -11.0<br />

Gujarat 51 39 -0.38 50.5 17.6 2.2 -8.9<br />

Haryana 29 59 -0.05 1.4 13.8 5.5 5.0<br />

Himachal<br />

21 62 -0.50 27.8 23.8 3.3 5.7<br />

Pradesh<br />

Jharkhand 6 17 -0.15 0.0 0.0 33.6 43.1<br />

Karnataka 82 41 -0.28 1.5 7.3 3.6 31.2<br />

Kerala 114 61 -0.39 1.1 14.0 1.7 -15.3<br />

Madhya Pradesh 42 33 -0.13 3.8 14.3 1.3 2.2<br />

Maharashtra 82 68 -0.38 3.2 20.7 -0.3 -4.6<br />

Orissa 69 70 -0.28 1.1 21.7 -1.3 -35.0<br />

Punjab 57 44 -0.23 0.3 15.8 -1.2 -12.0<br />

Rajasthan 24 38 -0.06 0.1 20.8 7.4 20.6<br />

Tamil Nadu 68 53 -0.14 0.6 29.4 2.4 -1.6<br />

Uttar Pradesh 94 62 -0.94 51.1 17.0 -1.0 -29.9<br />

Uttaranchal 25 60 -0.32 47.7 12.0 -2.3 -16.4<br />

West Bengal 86 72 -0.50 0.8 44.2 1.4 -45.2<br />

Source: OECD Analysis Of Data From <strong>The</strong> Comptroller and Auditor General<br />

obligations and responsibilities that<br />

PSEs are required to undertake in terms<br />

of public services should be clearly mandated<br />

by laws or regulations. <strong>The</strong>se obligations<br />

and responsibilities should<br />

also be disclosed to the general public<br />

and the related costs should be covered<br />

by government in a transparent manner.<br />

PSEs should be exposed to competitive<br />

conditions in access to finance. Finally,<br />

preferential procurement policies<br />

should be ended at the state level, following<br />

plans by central government to<br />

do so in 2008.<br />

11. Once these steps have been taken,<br />

the privatisation programme needs to<br />

be revitalised, especially in the competitive<br />

sectors of the economy. To date,<br />

privatisation has been slow and involved<br />

only partial sales which, according to<br />

international evidence, are less effective<br />

in raising productivity and profitability<br />

than full sales to the private sector,<br />

as control stays with the<br />

government. 1 Going forward, mixed<br />

sales that transfer control to the private<br />

sector and combine strategic investors<br />

with public share offerings, have the<br />

potential advantages of developing<br />

strong corporate governance structures<br />

and introducing new management and<br />

technology into the company. For PSEs<br />

operating in network sectors in which<br />

there are monopoly elements, the regulatory<br />

environment needs to be made<br />

consistent with private ownership and<br />

competition with independent regulators<br />

in place as part of the privatisation<br />

process. <strong>The</strong> worst performing and<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

141


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 3. Product Market Regulation And Average Labour Productivity<br />

120<br />

Average labour productivity, 1994 -2004<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

0.5<br />

Goa<br />

Uttaranchal<br />

Delhi<br />

Correlation coefficient= -0.51<br />

t-statistic= -2.56<br />

Haryana<br />

Punjab<br />

Maharashtra<br />

Gujarat<br />

Tamil Nadu<br />

Jharkhand<br />

Kerala<br />

Assam Himachal Pradesh<br />

Madhya Pradesh<br />

Karnataka<br />

Andhra Pradesh<br />

Rajasthan<br />

Chhattisgarh<br />

Uttar Pradesh<br />

Orissa<br />

Bihar<br />

West Bengal<br />

1 1.5 2 2.5 3<br />

Product Market Regulation Indicator Score<br />

1. Reflecting data constraints, labour productivity in Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand & Uttaranchal is measured as the average over 2002-03 period.<br />

Figure 4. An International Comparison Of Employment Protection<br />

Legislation<br />

Australia<br />

United Kingdom<br />

Switzerland<br />

Canada<br />

Brazil<br />

Denmark<br />

Austria<br />

Ireland<br />

New Zealand<br />

Belgium<br />

Italy<br />

Hungary<br />

Finland<br />

Poland<br />

China<br />

Norway<br />

Mexico<br />

Chile<br />

EU 15<br />

Korea<br />

Australia<br />

Greece<br />

Japan<br />

France<br />

Slovak Republic<br />

Turkey<br />

Luxemburg<br />

Netherlands<br />

Germany<br />

Sweden<br />

Spain<br />

India<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Portugal<br />

OECD<br />

average<br />

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0<br />

4.5<br />

142 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 5. Net Employment Across Different Types Of Workers And Firms<br />

Net Employment (annual % change)<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

-5<br />

-10<br />

-15<br />

“non-working” PSEs need to be restructured<br />

to the point where they can be<br />

wound up.<br />

Inefficient Government Procedures,<br />

Particularly In Some Of<br />

<strong>The</strong> States, Act As A Barrier To<br />

Competition<br />

12. Administrative barriers to entrepreneurship<br />

are also high in India and another<br />

reason why the regulatory environment<br />

is less supportive of<br />

competition than in other countries. In<br />

many state governments, departments<br />

operate in “silos” with minimal information<br />

flows between them. Given a<br />

lack of coordination, administrative<br />

procedures often duplicate the same<br />

function across a number of departments,<br />

leaving firms and citizens in a<br />

complex maze of regulations and administrative<br />

requirements that can be<br />

repetitive, non-transparent, and sometimes<br />

contradictory. This increases<br />

compliance costs, especially for small<br />

firms, and discourages firm expansion,<br />

reducing competition and productivity.<br />

Large Small Overall<br />

All employees Workers Contract Supervisors Others<br />

Overly complex administrative procedures<br />

also increase the discretion of<br />

government staff, thereby facilitating<br />

corruption. In Transparency International’s<br />

Corruption Perceptions Index,<br />

India ranks 70 out of 163 countries in<br />

2006.<br />

13. A number of initiatives for simplifying<br />

red tape have been introduced by<br />

the central and state governments, with<br />

varying degrees of success. For example,<br />

some states have introduced “onestop<br />

shops” for providing information<br />

and, in some cases, applying for licenses<br />

and notifications. In some cases, a<br />

system of “deemed clearance” under<br />

which licenses are issued automatically<br />

if the licensing office does not act by the<br />

end of the statutory response period,<br />

have also been introduced. Some of the<br />

state governments have tried improving<br />

the interface with the private sector by<br />

simplifying and consolidating various<br />

application forms and registers and introducing<br />

self-inspection regimes. Information<br />

and communications technology<br />

(ICT) has also been<br />

successfully integrated into some administrative<br />

procedures.<br />

14. A key element in all efforts to simplify<br />

and improve government bureaucracy<br />

is that administrative processes are<br />

reengineered from the ground up. For<br />

example, one-stop shops need to be implemented<br />

along with other reforms<br />

geared towards cutting red tape. Otherwise<br />

they run the risk of simply adding<br />

another layer of bureaucracy to the<br />

approval process. Alternatively, using<br />

ICT to simply automate existing inefficient<br />

processes or disseminate information<br />

will only produce a limited payoff.<br />

At present, India has no centralised oversight body<br />

charged with reviewing regulatory proposals, using Regulatory<br />

Impact Analysis, to ensure that the costs of administrative<br />

burdens do not outweigh the benefi ts<br />

15. A crucial aspect of reengineering<br />

administrative processes, especially<br />

within some of the state governments,<br />

is improving the coordination of regulatory<br />

functions across government departments.<br />

This is complex and time<br />

consuming and requires a “whole of<br />

government” approach to institutional<br />

change. Indeed, the OECD experience<br />

has been that regulatory reform will often<br />

fail if left entirely to ministries. At<br />

present, India has no centralised oversight<br />

body charged with reviewing regulatory<br />

proposals, using Regulatory Impact<br />

Analysis, to ensure that the costs<br />

of administrative burdens do not outweigh<br />

the benefits. One advantage of<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

143


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

centralised oversight bodies is that they<br />

promote a consistent and systematic<br />

method of reform across the entire administration.<br />

Ideally, its objectives<br />

should be outlined as part of an explicit<br />

regulatory policy which generally<br />

helps countries make greater reform<br />

progress. 2<br />

States That Have Liberalised<br />

More Than Others Are Reaping<br />

<strong>The</strong> Benefits<br />

16. With state governments having control<br />

over certain aspects of regulatory<br />

policy and responsibility for enforcement,<br />

there are significant differences<br />

in the business environment across<br />

states as shown by our indicators. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

differences have an important bearing<br />

on economic performance. Labour productivity<br />

is higher in states with a regulatory<br />

environment that is more supportive<br />

of competition (Figure 3). <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are a number of reasons for this. First,<br />

virtually all of India’s foreign direct investment<br />

flows to the relatively more<br />

liberal states and domestic investment<br />

also appears to be higher, boosting state<br />

productivity. Second, in states with excessively<br />

restrictive administrative burdens<br />

firms are more likely to remain<br />

informal so as to avoid government administrative<br />

requirements. However,<br />

informal sector firms are usually much<br />

smaller with lower capital intensity and<br />

much less productive than formal sector<br />

enterprises.<br />

A Further Rationalisation And<br />

Reduction Of Restrictions On<br />

Foreign Is Trade Needed<br />

17. As recently as the beginning of this<br />

decade, India’s tariffs were the highest<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is a considerable gap between the standard tariff<br />

rates and the actual revenue raised from tariffs. Such gaps<br />

are indicative of special concessions to certain products or<br />

industries and distort the allocation of resources<br />

in the world and among the most discriminatory.<br />

Significant reforms to liberalise<br />

foreign trade have been undertaking<br />

since then and average tariffs<br />

are scheduled to reach the average<br />

level in ASEAN countries in the near<br />

future. Despite the fears of domestic<br />

producers, the manufacturing sector<br />

has profited from this policy shift and<br />

has been growing as fast as the service<br />

sector since 2003. Manufacturing exports<br />

have also started to grow rapidly,<br />

outpacing most other Asian countries<br />

in the first half of this decade. However,<br />

more could be done to liberalise<br />

foreign trade. Tariffs in ASEAN countries<br />

are still high in relation to those<br />

in developed countries. Moreover,<br />

there is a considerable gap in India between<br />

the standard tariff rates and the<br />

actual revenue raised from tariffs. Such<br />

gaps are indicative of special concessions<br />

granted to favour certain products<br />

or industries and distort the allocation<br />

of resources and lower<br />

productivity. Cross-country evidence<br />

has found that openness to global markets<br />

acts as an important stimulus to<br />

growth and ongoing reductions and rationalisation<br />

of the tariff structure in<br />

India would pay dividends.<br />

Labour Market Regulation Is<br />

Also Excessively Restrictive<br />

18. <strong>The</strong> dichotomy between formal and<br />

informal businesses is in part caused by<br />

labour market regulation, which is another<br />

key area in which restrictive government<br />

intervention imposes high<br />

economic costs. <strong>The</strong> strictness of employment<br />

regulation varies across different<br />

segments of the Indian labour<br />

market according to the <strong>size</strong> of firms<br />

and the type of employment contract.<br />

According to the OECD’s indicators of<br />

employment protection legislation<br />

(EPL), larger firms employing workers<br />

on regular contracts are subject to EPL<br />

that is more restrictive than in all but<br />

two OECD countries. For smaller<br />

firms, the extent of employment protection<br />

is similar to that in the OECD<br />

144 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

area. Very small businesses in the unorganised<br />

sector are subject to few labour<br />

regulations. Across different<br />

types of employment contact, EPL for<br />

temporary or contract employees is just<br />

above the OECD average. Allowing<br />

employees to carry out “non core” work<br />

on temporary agency contracts has<br />

been a main area of recent labour reform.<br />

19. <strong>The</strong>se differences in employment<br />

regulations are mirrored in recent development<br />

in labour markets. While<br />

employment growth has been strong<br />

over recent years, net gains in employment<br />

have been occurring almost exclusively<br />

in the unorganised part of the<br />

economy, which is not subject to restrictive<br />

labour market regulation. In<br />

the organised sector, employment has<br />

actually fallen. <strong>The</strong> detrimental impact<br />

of excessively restrictive EPL can also<br />

be clearly seen across types of employment<br />

contract; while contract employment<br />

has grown, regular employment<br />

has shrunk (Figure 5). This bias towards<br />

contract employment is only<br />

evident in larger firms, which bear the<br />

brunt of India’s restrictive EPL. Employment<br />

in smaller firms has been increasing<br />

for both contract and regular<br />

workers.<br />

20. It is often argued in India that strict<br />

EPL is not particularly harmful because<br />

firms find ways to circumvent the<br />

legislation. One way of avoiding difficulties<br />

with the labour laws is to stay<br />

small. Indeed, almost 90% of manufacturing<br />

firms employ less than ten people,<br />

a much larger share than in all<br />

OECD countries and China. However,<br />

most of these firms produce far below<br />

minimum efficient scale and are in the<br />

informal sector, the least productive<br />

segment of India’s business sector.<br />

Large firms, faced with high implicit<br />

employment costs, substitute capital<br />

for labour. Thus, restrictive EPL also<br />

effectively negates one of India’s key<br />

comparative advantages of relatively<br />

low-cost labour.<br />

21. Overall, labour market policy in India<br />

is ineffective at protecting employment;<br />

job destruction is lower in areas<br />

of the labour market not subject to the<br />

most restrictive of India’s labour market<br />

regulations. It has also resulted in<br />

a number of unintended consequences<br />

that have been accentuated as product<br />

markets have became more competitive.<br />

With newcomers to the labour<br />

market being pushed into lower-paid<br />

informal employment, economic<br />

growth has not been as inclusive as it<br />

could have been. Our indicators suggest<br />

that some states have introduced a<br />

degree of reform into labour markets.<br />

As yet, these reforms have been at the<br />

margin but, nonetheless, they do appear<br />

to be having some impact on labour<br />

markets. <strong>The</strong> share of labour income<br />

has stabilised in reforming states<br />

whereas it continues to fall in more restrictive<br />

states. Liberalisation also appears<br />

to be positively related to the<br />

extent of job turnover. Even if there is<br />

currently little evidence of employment<br />

gains in the most liberal states, higher<br />

job turnover improves a person’s chances<br />

of finding a job that matches their<br />

skills. To improve the functioning of<br />

the labour market as the labour force<br />

grows over the next decade comprehensive<br />

labour reform is needed to better<br />

protect all workers, lower the costs of<br />

employment adjustment, and help address<br />

the distortions that have<br />

emerged.<br />

Reforms Need To Be Ongoing If<br />

Government Is To Achieve Its<br />

Growth Target<br />

22. An important key to improving India’s<br />

economic performance further is to<br />

change policies at both the central and<br />

state government level that result in high<br />

levels of government interference in markets<br />

and restrict competition. Relative to<br />

recent history, the government has already<br />

moved significantly in this direction.<br />

However, this article has touched on<br />

areas in which less government intervention<br />

would increase the extent to which<br />

market forces are able to operate and<br />

result in more efficient outcomes. Reform<br />

in these key areas would yield enormous<br />

benefit for the Indian economy.<br />

Indeed, it is difficult to envisage government<br />

achieving its GDP growth target of<br />

10% in 2011 without further reform in<br />

these and other areas outlined in detail<br />

in the recent OECD Economic Survey of<br />

India. <strong>The</strong> impressive response of the<br />

Indian economy in areas that have been<br />

reformed in the past should give policymakers<br />

confidence that further liberalisation<br />

will deliver additional growth<br />

dividends and foster the process of pulling<br />

millions of people out of poverty.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

OECD (2003b), Privatising stateowned<br />

enterprises: an overview of<br />

policies and practices in OECD countries,<br />

OECD, Paris.<br />

2<br />

OECD (2002), Regulatory policies in<br />

OECD countries: From interventionism<br />

to regulatory governance,<br />

OECD, Paris.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

145


Rok SPRUK<br />

International Economist,<br />

Slovenia<br />

Going For Growth Through<br />

Economic Reforms: <strong>The</strong> Case Of India<br />

"A more innovative economy tends to devote<br />

more resources to investing of all kinds--in new<br />

employees and customers as well as new offi ce<br />

and factory space. And although this may come<br />

about through a shift of resources from the<br />

consumer-goods sector, it also comes through<br />

the recruitment of new participants to the labor<br />

force. Also, the resulting increase of employeeengagement<br />

serves to lower quit rates and,<br />

hence, to make possible a reduction of the<br />

“natural” unemployment rate. Thus, high dynamism<br />

tends to bring a pervasive prosperity to<br />

the economy on top of the productivity advances<br />

and all the self-realization going on. True,<br />

that may not be pronounced every month or<br />

year. Just as the creative artist does not create<br />

all the time, but rather in episodes and breaks,<br />

so the dynamic economy has heightened highfrequency<br />

volatility and may go through wide<br />

swings. Perhaps this volatility is not only normal<br />

but also productive from the point of view of<br />

creativity and, ultimately, achievement."<br />

-Edmund S. Phelps,<br />

Nobel Laureate in Economics, 2006<br />

<strong>The</strong> purpose of this article is to<br />

highlight some of the increasingly<br />

important issues regarding<br />

India’s economic prospects. In recent<br />

years, the operating capacity of India’s<br />

high-growing economy has been reflected<br />

by a surge in real GDP growth and a slight<br />

downturn in inflation pressures. By the<br />

end of <strong>2007</strong>, India’s GDP is estimated to<br />

rise by 8.9 percent and 8.4 percent in 2008<br />

while consumer price index increased by<br />

6.2 percent in <strong>2007</strong> and is expected to decrease<br />

to a mere 4.4 percent rate of overall<br />

price increase. 2 Growth estimates differ<br />

respectively subject to different<br />

methodological evolution of the real GDP<br />

growth measurement. It also depends on<br />

how the engines of growth are estimated,<br />

especially the importance of those factors<br />

in driving growth. <strong>The</strong>re are, in an academic<br />

economic literature, two main economic<br />

paradigms regarding the philosophy,<br />

theory and policy perspective of<br />

economic growth. Keynesian economic<br />

analysis supports the view that the aggregate<br />

demand 3 is a primary source of economic<br />

growth, claiming that an increase<br />

in the government spending per unit of<br />

output, increases investment activity and<br />

drives growth onto a stable trajectory.<br />

Keynesian emulation of the evolution of<br />

economic growth is based on false assertions.<br />

For example, Keynesian interpretation<br />

of economic growth neglects the<br />

impact of aggregate demand on inflation.<br />

As public spending and fiscal outlays increase,<br />

there is a growing probability of<br />

higher inflation. In the short-run, such<br />

policy features boost the economic activity<br />

through an expansionary monetary<br />

incentive, but in the long-run, the negative<br />

impact of government spending surpasses<br />

the short-run effect of government<br />

spending subject to a persistent inflationary<br />

pressures, falling growth rates and<br />

tight grip on capital markets. Notably,<br />

when government spending increases<br />

whereas fiscal expenditure is anchored in<br />

budget deficit, government borrowing reduces<br />

the supply of available monetary<br />

means and thus, increases the interest<br />

rate balance which investors have to bear.<br />

146 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

<strong>The</strong> answer to the question what impedes<br />

the investment is government spending<br />

and consequently budget deficit, but not<br />

only the budget deficit. Claiming that<br />

‘catch-up’ effects, when a country with<br />

low GDP per capita is catching-up countries<br />

with higher GDP per capita, allow an<br />

expansionary fiscal policy cannot be justified<br />

on empirical grounds and experience<br />

nevertheless. Empirically, high government<br />

spending reduces the operating capacity<br />

of the economic growth due to high<br />

tax burden and expanded public sector<br />

activities. It is crucial for a high-growing<br />

‘catch-up’ economy to reduce government<br />

spending and thus lay a solid foundation<br />

of growth. On the other side, contemporary<br />

growth theory empha<strong>size</strong>s the quality<br />

of growth engines such as the quality<br />

of institutions and means of productivity<br />

as determinants of economic growth.<br />

Neoclassical growth theory supports low<br />

government spending, low taxation of<br />

productive behavior, emphasis on price<br />

stability and solid free market institutions,<br />

the enforcement of private property rights<br />

and the rule of law. <strong>The</strong> latter is essential<br />

to macroeconomic stability. For decades,<br />

economists have questioned the impact of<br />

government spending on economic<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> Keynesian controversy began<br />

in 1930s when John Maynard Keynes<br />

wrote a voluminous book on the theory of<br />

employment, interest and money. Keynes<br />

argued that economy’s growth capacity<br />

can be boosted by injecting more purchasing<br />

power into the economy. Keynesians<br />

argued that government could reverse the<br />

economic downturn by borrowing more<br />

money from the private sector to help end<br />

the recession or depression and then return<br />

the money in all sorts of public incentive<br />

programs such as tax rebates. Keynesians<br />

supported high government<br />

spending because they believed that inflation<br />

was resulted from too much economic<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> Keynesian economic analysis<br />

and doctrine became a corner-stone<br />

between 1930 and 1970. <strong>The</strong> overall impact<br />

of Keynesian economics bluntly diminished<br />

when the reality has shown that<br />

there is no long-run trade-off between<br />

inflation and unemployment; an assertion<br />

which was postulated into the famous<br />

Phillips curve. <strong>The</strong> economies which were<br />

operating under staunch Keynesian economic<br />

policy have faced significant economic<br />

downturns such as multi-year recessions<br />

and even economic depression.<br />

In 1991, Sweden slid into economic recession,<br />

facing high unemployment and rampant<br />

inflation. In Finland, where Keynesian<br />

economic policy dominated the<br />

public policy course from 1945 onwards,<br />

at the beginning of 1990s, economic<br />

growth turned into a decline in GDP,<br />

while inflation and unemployment grew<br />

severely. Numerous other countries faced<br />

the same experience of mistaken Keynesian<br />

economic policy.<br />

One of the fundamental questions<br />

which transition economies, such as India,<br />

face is what the optimal goals of economic<br />

policy are. In addition, what are<br />

important and empirically relevant areas<br />

demanding competitive economic reforms<br />

as a guarantee of sustainable long-term<br />

growth of real GDP and standards of living.<br />

In this article, I entail empirical studies<br />

into economic policy and attempt to<br />

suggest the reform agenda that would<br />

boost India’s competitiveness in terms of<br />

sound market economy with sustainable<br />

economic growth, price stability and freemarket<br />

institutions.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Empirics Of Growth<br />

Government spending and consumption<br />

is inversely related to the economic<br />

growth. 4 Higher government spending<br />

correlates with higher tax burden while<br />

higher taxes on productive behavior such<br />

as entrepreneurship, saving and investment,<br />

labor supply and innovation impede<br />

growth performance. On the other hand,<br />

the share of government spending positively<br />

relates to the share of public investment<br />

in the GDP. <strong>The</strong> quality and productivity<br />

of investment highly differs whether<br />

Public investment is directed via political decisions and its<br />

time preference rates of politicians on the electoral basis is<br />

subject to the realization of promises which is oftenly<br />

negatively related to growth prospects<br />

it is conducted in the private sector or on<br />

behalf of public sector. <strong>The</strong> reason why<br />

resources invested by private investors are<br />

normally more efficient than investment<br />

in the public sector is the fact that risktaking<br />

plays more powerful role in the<br />

private sector. Private investors bear the<br />

information and investment resources efficiently<br />

because of the motives such as<br />

higher productivity perspective and competitive<br />

pressures in the market economy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> investment conducted by the managers<br />

in public sector is subject to political<br />

pressures while politicians do not pursue<br />

the same goals as private investors. Public<br />

investment is directed via political decisions<br />

and its time preference rates of<br />

politicians on the electoral basis is subject<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

147


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Taxes, Corruption And Structural<br />

Defect<br />

Tax system is a powerful weapon in the<br />

hands of economic policymakers. Tax system<br />

is a major source of funding where<br />

political parties and government planners<br />

collect money and slice a fraction of the<br />

GDP for government spending and consumption.<br />

Currently India levies moderate<br />

tax rates on corporate and individual<br />

income. By <strong>2007</strong>, top personal and corporate<br />

income tax rates were 33 percent plus<br />

10 percent surcharge. Other taxes includto<br />

the realization of promises which is oftenly<br />

negatively related to growth prospects<br />

and economic performance. Political<br />

preference for expansionary welfare<br />

state demand greater involvement of government<br />

into the economic structure and<br />

thus political pressures reduce the scope<br />

of growth potentials. Every economic<br />

theory agrees that the long-term engine<br />

of growth is capital creation which means<br />

savings and investment. <strong>The</strong> share of government<br />

in the economy is equally important.<br />

<strong>The</strong> following picture known as the<br />

Rahn Curve shows the empirical relationship<br />

between economic growth and government<br />

spending.<br />

Output<br />

performance<br />

RAHN CURVE<br />

Goverment apending<br />

as a share of the GDP<br />

Source: Brimelow (1993), Mitchell (2005)<br />

Picture-1: Rahn Curve<br />

An Empirical Perspective On <strong>The</strong><br />

Trade-Off Between Government<br />

Size And Economic Growth<br />

Extensive public sector involves several<br />

macroeconomically important costs. Every<br />

single per unit increase in government<br />

<strong>size</strong> reduces potential unit of output added<br />

to the gross domestic product. <strong>The</strong><br />

costs associated with government spending<br />

are huge. First, government spending<br />

requires the collection of funds of spending.<br />

Costly choices mean an inevitable<br />

adverse consequence such as reducing the<br />

<strong>size</strong> of investment which is an important<br />

component of the GDP. Second, the effi-<br />

ciency of investment is determined by the<br />

efficiency of allocation of resources. In<br />

this respect, expanded public sector hinders<br />

private sector activities subject to the<br />

fact that resources are scarce; the foremost<br />

basic corner-stone of economics.<br />

Third, government spending supports<br />

backward regulation and intervention,<br />

displacing the competitiveness of product<br />

markets and interfering growth performance.<br />

Phillips and Shen (2003) showed<br />

that the overall impact of a 10 percent decrease<br />

of state-owned enterprises in China<br />

boosted the regional growth of GDP<br />

by 1.14 percent. 5 <strong>The</strong> case of China shows<br />

that costs involved in government spending<br />

include economically undesirable<br />

choices and decisions. In addition, high<br />

level of government intervention through<br />

regulatory agencies protecting existing<br />

monopoly or oligopoly structures stimulates<br />

market distortions by discouraging<br />

productive behavior. <strong>The</strong> reason why government<br />

spending is wasteful and burdensome<br />

at some point, as demonstrated by<br />

the Rahn Curve, is that additional spending<br />

empowers the <strong>size</strong> of government and<br />

also because spending outlays boost the<br />

misallocation of resources due to asymmetric<br />

information.<br />

A valuable lesson for Indian policymakers<br />

is to learn the lessons associated with<br />

government spending from other countries<br />

where decades of output growth and<br />

rising productivity returned a comparatively<br />

high GDP per capita and sound<br />

economic performance and also an experience<br />

with economic setbacks and downturns<br />

caused by the mistakes in economic<br />

policy. Bassanini and Scarpetta (2001)<br />

showed that an increase in one percentage<br />

point in tax pressure – two thirds of what<br />

was observed over the past decade in the<br />

OECD sample – could be associated with<br />

a direct reduction of about 0.3 percent in<br />

output per capita. If the investment effect<br />

is taken into account, the overall reduction<br />

would be 0,6-0.7 percent. 6 Tanzi and<br />

Schuknecht (1996) compared the <strong>size</strong> of<br />

government and growth performance in<br />

selected industrial countries, concluding<br />

that average 5-year growth was higher in<br />

countries with small governments. <strong>The</strong><br />

investigation showed that countries with<br />

small governments observed lower actual<br />

unemployment rate, lower rate of shadow<br />

economy and also exhibited more regulatory<br />

efficiency, higher innovation levels<br />

and a well functioning non-distortionary<br />

labor markets. 7 Another argument in favor<br />

of lower government <strong>size</strong> and spending<br />

as a core economic reform is the wellobserved<br />

fact that the reduction in public<br />

spending as a share of the GDP is positively<br />

related to the growth of total factor<br />

productivity. <strong>Dec</strong>ades of mismanaged<br />

economic policy led to an obscure increase<br />

in the <strong>size</strong> of state-owned enterprises<br />

carrying out some major deficiencies<br />

and the failure in the allocation of<br />

resources which caused a decline in the<br />

overall competitiveness of the economy.<br />

148 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ed dividend tax, property tax and tax on<br />

insurance contracts. 8 India’s tax system<br />

demands a radical change towards a reduction<br />

in taxation of productive behavior<br />

such as labor supply and investment nevertheless.<br />

<strong>The</strong> demand and supply of labor<br />

is elastic which supports the thesis<br />

that labor supply is highly sensitive and<br />

responsive to tax rates. 9 Recent highlights<br />

in empirical investigation of the behavior<br />

of labor supply has shown that labor supply<br />

responds dramatically to lower tax<br />

rates on work whereas productivity has<br />

been soaring due to cutting taxes on productive<br />

activity. India’s particular competitive<br />

advantage in terms of tax system<br />

could be innovative; public products such<br />

as internationally competitive territorial<br />

tax system, a model in which Indian provinces<br />

could compete to attract inflows of<br />

direct investment on the international basis.<br />

A strong argument in favor of open<br />

territorial tax competition is that it is rational<br />

to expect lower tax rates on productive<br />

behavior and thus adversely positive<br />

effects on output and productivity growth.<br />

Recent research evidence by Djankov,<br />

Ganser, McLiesh, Ramalho and Schleifer<br />

(<strong>2007</strong>) has shown consistent and large<br />

adverse effect of corporate taxation on<br />

investment and entrepreneurship. According<br />

to authors’ calculations, a 10 percentage<br />

point increase in the effective<br />

corporate tax rate reduces the investment<br />

to GDP ratio by about 2 percentage<br />

points. 10 Alternatively, India could consider<br />

a possible move in a direction of<br />

abolishing the corporate tax due to its effect<br />

on capital creation and entrepreneurial<br />

activity. Also, India should consider a<br />

fundamental tax refom in a pro-growth<br />

direction. Practically, India may switch its<br />

taxation regime from income tax to consumption-based<br />

tax. In case of cutting-off<br />

income taxes and alternatively adopting<br />

taxes on consumption, higher savings<br />

would dramatically boost the productivity<br />

and living standards. <strong>The</strong> encouragement<br />

of competitiveness deserves a concrete<br />

treatment of pro-growth tax and economic<br />

policy proposals that could boost output<br />

performance. A significant amount of<br />

empirical evidence suggests that the reduction<br />

in corporate and individual taxation<br />

boosts the operating capacity of the<br />

economy in going for growth as well as<br />

private initiative in fighting India’s structural<br />

weaknesses and human capital creation<br />

which is, by any means, an essential<br />

ingredient of growth in an economy with<br />

astonishing growth potentials. 11<br />

Despite a moderately free fiscal and<br />

public consumption , 12 India’s structural<br />

defects are mostly subject to an inefficient<br />

administrative environment, weak property<br />

rights, government involvement in<br />

the financial sector and widespread perception<br />

of corruption. For instance, India<br />

ranks 72nd out of 188 countries included<br />

in Transparency International’s Corruption<br />

Perception Index. 13 A spiral of structural<br />

deficiencies contributes to the hindering<br />

of India’s growth sustainability and<br />

international macroeconomic and microeconomic<br />

competitiveness. Corruption is<br />

a huge cost reflecting the governance of<br />

institutions enforcing private property<br />

rights, the rule of law and competitive<br />

framework of the economy and individual<br />

interaction. Noteworthy, tax complexity<br />

and high costs of tax compliance contribute<br />

a significant fraction to the legal<br />

and illegal level of corruption. In European<br />

Union, pressures for harmful tax<br />

harmonization 14 aim to expand the scope<br />

Research evidence shows a consistent and large adverse<br />

effect of corporate tax on investment and entrepreneurship.<br />

A 10% point increase in the effective corporate tax<br />

rate reduces the investment to GDP ratio by about 2%<br />

of government bureaucracy in tax collection.<br />

Tax rebates, exemptions, loopholes<br />

and numerous deductions contribute to<br />

the rise of hidden corruption within legal<br />

limits. Fighting against corruption requires<br />

an active approach codified by the<br />

enforcement of competitive law, deregulated<br />

product markets and the elimination<br />

of government involvement in financial<br />

sector and any other sector in the economy.<br />

Of course, in economic theory and<br />

practice there are externalities and market<br />

failures which excuse the role of government<br />

in certain areas. But such approach<br />

would be needed under<br />

cost-benefit analysis, clearly defined competitive<br />

rules and under the absence of<br />

government coercion and political intervention.<br />

Anti-corruption legislation and<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

149


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

policy enforcement can significantly reduce<br />

persistence of corruption as a major<br />

structural backlash of an economy in<br />

transition such as India. However, tax<br />

competition, competitive and secure contractual<br />

law, deregulation, private ownership,<br />

strong protection of property rights<br />

and other components of political stability<br />

and economic prosperity are the guiding<br />

swords in fighting against corruption 15<br />

as an obstacle to long-term growth and<br />

stability.<br />

brightest reform concepts and case studies<br />

of the macroeconomic and structural<br />

reforms. I suggest learning from two small<br />

countries, Ireland and Iceland.<br />

Ireland dramatically changed its fiscal<br />

policy over the past 20 years. Once a bastion<br />

of poverty, now became the second<br />

wealthiest economy in the European Union<br />

according to real GDP per capita,<br />

after Luxemburg. Ireland’s reform agenda<br />

included a supply-side package of policy<br />

inputs. For example, top individual income<br />

tax rates was slashed from 65 percent<br />

to 42 percent and the corporate tax<br />

rate was reduced<br />

to 12.5 percent<br />

and was made flat. Low Taxes,<br />

Tax competition<br />

In 1980s, unemployment<br />

was se-<br />

Sound regulation<br />

vere at a doubledigit<br />

rate and government spending<br />

consumed more than 52 percent of total<br />

output. Consequently, growth rates were<br />

rachitic and high tax rates discouraged<br />

the creation of productive behavior. Ireland<br />

quickly became the “sick-man-of-<br />

An increase in one percentage point in tax pressure – two<br />

thirds of what was observed over the past decade in the<br />

OECD sample – could be associated with a direct reduction<br />

of about 0.3 percent in output per capita<br />

Europe”. In early 1990s, Irish policymakers<br />

decided to embrace supply-side<br />

economic policy, deregulate product markets,<br />

cut the <strong>size</strong> of government and slash<br />

the expenditures. After decades of low<br />

output, overall government spending was<br />

reduced from 52.3 percent in 1986 to 37.7<br />

percent in 1996. Free trade, rigorous tax<br />

cuts and productive education policies<br />

turned the incredible emulation of the<br />

Irish hare into the Celtic Tiger .16 <strong>The</strong>re is<br />

an interesting comparison between Ireland<br />

and Slovenia as a case study between<br />

the supply-side success and Keynesian<br />

failure. Using the data from Penn World<br />

Tables 17 , by the end of 1990, Slovenia and<br />

Ireland had the same real GDP per capita<br />

after inflation, using current prices as<br />

a comparison measure. Throughout the<br />

1990s, Slovenia’s output grew at low rates,<br />

recovering from economic depression in<br />

transition while having high taxes, high<br />

fraction of government ownership and<br />

weak institutions, while Irish economy<br />

International Lessons For India<br />

<strong>The</strong> growth experience of countries from<br />

around the world offers a useful guideline<br />

in learning from the world’s best and<br />

Picture No.2: Dynamic Engines Of Growth<br />

Sophisticated<br />

Infrastructure<br />

Cost and prices,<br />

Environment of<br />

the firm<br />

Quality of the<br />

Labor Supply<br />

SUSTAINABLE<br />

GROWTH<br />

Human Capital<br />

Source: Forfas, author’s own projections<br />

Business<br />

Performance<br />

Productivity<br />

Performance<br />

Innovation,<br />

Competitiveness,<br />

Entrepreneurship<br />

TARGET<br />

ESSENTIALS<br />

Property Rights,<br />

Rule-of-Law<br />

Free Markets<br />

I<br />

N<br />

P<br />

U<br />

T<br />

S<br />

150 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

grew at robust annual rates, with free<br />

markets, established rule-of-law and protected<br />

private property rights. Using time<br />

difference calculation as a measure, today’s<br />

time gap between Slovenia and Ireland<br />

is approximately 40 years 18 Iceland’s<br />

recovery from decades of interrupted<br />

Keynesian economic policy lasted from<br />

than Icelandic policymakers estimated.<br />

Until late 1980s, Icelandic economy was<br />

marred by government ownership, periods<br />

of high inflation when oil shocks, tight<br />

labor markets and devaluation bias caused<br />

a spiral of inflationary pressures. 19 In<br />

1990, Icelandic policymakers reduced the<br />

corporate tax rate from 50 percent to 33<br />

percent by the mid 1990s. In 2003, the<br />

rate was further slashed to 18 percent.<br />

<strong>The</strong> effect of supply-side tax reform was<br />

a pure theoretical assertion of the Laffer<br />

curve whereby lower tax rates increased<br />

revenue from taxes as a share of the GDP<br />

respectively. According to Iceland’s Ministry<br />

of Finance, in 1985 when corporate<br />

tax rate was 50 percent, the share of corporate<br />

tax revenue in the GDP was 0.9<br />

percent. In 2003, when the corporate tax<br />

rate was 18 percent, corporate tax revenue<br />

in the share of the GDP jumped to 1.5<br />

percent. 20 Thus, during the period of a<br />

continued reduction of corporate tax rate,<br />

overall revenue from corporate tax increased<br />

by 67 percent. Noteworthy, the<br />

restructuring of Iceland’s economy was<br />

primarily based on privatization of nationalized<br />

enterprises and assets, strong<br />

fiscal management and responsible leadership<br />

on the part of labor unions and<br />

employers. Now, Iceland is one of the<br />

wealthiest countries in the world. In 2006,<br />

according to World Bank, 21 Iceland’s<br />

gross national income per capita was<br />

$50,580 per capita as measured by Atlas<br />

method and $36,560 per capita in terms<br />

of purchasing power parity.<br />

India: High-Growing Tiger Or An<br />

Economic Laggard?<br />

In this article I highlighted the prospects<br />

of the economic reforms in India. After a<br />

detailed study of the data and empirical<br />

work, I concluded the research and put it<br />

in a written and hopefully understandable<br />

form. India is an economy in transition<br />

currently facing high output growth rates<br />

and enviable economic perspective in the<br />

future. Growth is expected to remain<br />

steady over years in the future. However,<br />

substantial change in global environment<br />

demand a significant infusion of economic<br />

reforms to boost the productive behavior,<br />

economic growth while ‘rules-ratherthan-discretion’<br />

monetary policy is<br />

essential to the pursuit of price stability<br />

instead of discretionary price controls and<br />

market regulation that harm competitive<br />

forces in the market. In the international<br />

arena, India is frequently associated with<br />

high-growing East Asian phenomena besides<br />

China. 22 By 2040, China will reach<br />

$123 trillion USD which is equal to three<br />

times of global output by the end of<br />

2000. 23 Growth estimates for India suggest<br />

a relatively lower but steady-state<br />

growth rate mainly because of political<br />

constraints and structural costs such as<br />

widespread perception of corruption, government<br />

intervention and ownership of<br />

enterprises and harmful regulation of the<br />

economy through obscure administrative<br />

code, fiercely uncompetitive investment<br />

environment marred by red-tape, complexity<br />

hostile to foreign direct investors,<br />

trade protectionism and weak enforcement<br />

of private property rights. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

particular politically-installed disadvantages<br />

may hamper India’s long-term economic<br />

performance and impede growth<br />

prospects respectively. Relying on neoclassical<br />

growth theory and strong growth<br />

foundations such as free and deregulated<br />

product markets, liberalized labor market,<br />

the protection of private property,<br />

trade liberalization to the fullest possible<br />

extent, an independent judicial system,<br />

the rule of law and market institutions<br />

would, by experience and empirical<br />

premise, significantly boost India’s economic<br />

potentials and growth perspectives.<br />

Deregulated product and labor markets, protection of<br />

private property, trade liberalization to the fullest possible<br />

extent, an independent judicial system and the rule of law<br />

would signifi cantly boost India’s economic potential<br />

A growing burden of taxes, corruption<br />

and government <strong>size</strong> and spending would,<br />

contrary to popular assertions, impede<br />

India’s economic performance and its<br />

prospects as a global economic powerhouse<br />

in the 21st century.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

See: Edmund S. Phelps, Dynamic<br />

Capitalism, Opinion Journal, Tuesday,<br />

October 10, 2006<br />

http://www.opinionjournal.com/editorial/feature.html?id=110009068<br />

2<br />

See: World Economic Outlook, International<br />

Monetary Fund, October<br />

<strong>2007</strong>, Washington D.C.<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/<br />

weo/<strong>2007</strong>/02/index.htm<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

151


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

3<br />

Aggregate demand is an investment<br />

driven by government spending<br />

4<br />

Robert Barro: Economic Growth in a<br />

Cross Section of Countries, <strong>Quarterly</strong><br />

Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, p.<br />

407-43, May, 1991<br />

http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/<br />

v106y1991i2p407-43.html<br />

5<br />

Kerk Phillips, Kunrong Shen: What<br />

Effect does the Size of the State-<br />

Owned Sector Have on Regional<br />

Growth in China, Birgham Young<br />

University, Economics Working Papers,<br />

April 2003<br />

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.<br />

cfm?abstract_id=395890<br />

6<br />

Andrea Bassanini, Stefano Scarpetta:<br />

<strong>The</strong> Driving Forces of Economic<br />

Growth: Panel Data Evidence for the<br />

OECD Countries, Organization for<br />

Economic Cooperation and Development,<br />

Economic Studies No.33, February<br />

2001<br />

http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/26/2/18450995.pdf<br />

7<br />

Vito Tanzi,. Ludger Schuknecht: Reforming<br />

Government in Industrial<br />

Countries, International Monetary<br />

Fund Finance & Development, September<br />

1996<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/<br />

fandd/1996/09/pdf/tanzi.pdf<br />

8<br />

Index of Economic Freedom <strong>2007</strong> –<br />

India, Heritage Foundation http://<br />

www.heritage.org/research/features/<br />

index/country.cfm?id=India<br />

9<br />

Edward Prescott: <strong>The</strong> Elasticity of the<br />

Labor Supply and the Consequences<br />

for Tax Policy, Federal Reserve Bank<br />

of Minneapolis, February 2005<br />

http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/prescott/papers/Labor<br />

Supply.pdf<br />

10<br />

Simoen Djankov, Tim Ganser, Caralee<br />

McLiesh, Rita Ramalho, Andrei<br />

Schleifer: <strong>The</strong> Effect of Corporate<br />

Taxes on Investment and Entrepreneurship,<br />

Public Economics Program<br />

Meeting <strong>2007</strong>, National Bureau of<br />

Economic Research<br />

http://www.nber.org/confer/<strong>2007</strong>/<br />

pef07/shleifer.pdf<br />

11<br />

Hiroko Oura, Wild or Tamed? India’s<br />

Potential Growth Rate, International<br />

Monetary Fund, Working Paper No.<br />

07/224, September <strong>2007</strong><br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/<br />

longres.cfm?sk=21326.0<br />

12<br />

According to Heritage Foundation’s<br />

annual Index of Economic Freedom<br />

(<strong>2007</strong>), India is 84,8 percent free in fiscal<br />

terms and 89 percent free in terms<br />

of freedom from government<br />

http://www.heritage.org/research/features/index/country<strong>File</strong>s/pdfs/India.<br />

pdf<br />

13<br />

Transparency International: Corruption<br />

Perception Index, <strong>2007</strong><br />

http://www.transparency.org/policy_<br />

research/surveys_indices/cpi<br />

14<br />

Peter van de Hoek: Tax Harmonization<br />

and Competition in the European<br />

Union, eJournal of Tax Research,<br />

2003<br />

http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/<br />

eJTR/2003/2.html#Heading50<br />

15<br />

A detailed investigation of corruption<br />

and its effect on growth and economic<br />

performance was conducted by:<br />

Paolo Mauro: Corruption and Growth,<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Quarterly</strong> Journal of Economics,<br />

vol. 110, <strong>Issue</strong> 3, p. 681-712, 1995<br />

http://econpapers.repec.org/article/<br />

tprqjecon/v_3A110_3Ay_3A1995_<br />

3Ai_3A3_3Ap_3A681-712.htm<br />

16<br />

Brendan Walsh: <strong>The</strong> Source of Wealth<br />

in Small States. Small States as Financial<br />

Centers: <strong>The</strong> Case of Ireland, A<br />

presentation at the conference Small<br />

States as Financial Centers, University<br />

of Iceland, Reykjavik, Friday 14<br />

<strong>Dec</strong>ember, <strong>2007</strong><br />

http://www.skattamal.is/smallstates/<br />

Walsh.SmallStates.14.09.07.ppt<br />

17<br />

Penn World Table<br />

http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/php_site/<br />

pwt_index.php<br />

18<br />

Author’s own calculations<br />

19<br />

Már Guðmundsson, Palle S. Andersen:<br />

Inflation and disinflation in Iceland,<br />

BIS Working Paper No.52, Bank for<br />

International Settlements, June 1998<br />

http://ideas.repec.org/p/bis/biswps/52.<br />

html<br />

20<br />

Ministry of Finance, Iceland, »Principal<br />

Tax Rates«, July 2006<br />

http://eng.fjarmalaraduneyti.is/media/<br />

Taxes/Principal_tax_rates_2006.pdf.<br />

21<br />

World Bank, GNI per capita 2006, Atlas<br />

method and PPP, World Development<br />

Indicators database, July 1<br />

2006<br />

http://siteresources.worldbank.org/<br />

DATASTATISTICS/Resources/<br />

GNIPC.pdf<br />

22<br />

Srinivasan (2004)<br />

23<br />

Robert W. Fogel: Capitalism and Democracy<br />

in 2040: Forecasts and Speculations,<br />

NBER Working Paper No.<br />

13184, National Bureau of Economic<br />

Research, June <strong>2007</strong>; http://www.nber.<br />

org/papers/w13184<br />

References<br />

• Barro, Robert J. (1991), Economic<br />

Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,<br />

<strong>Quarterly</strong> Journal of Economics,<br />

Vol. 106, p. 407-43<br />

http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/<br />

152 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

v106y1991i2p407-43.html<br />

• Bassanini, Andrea, Scarpetta Stefano<br />

(2001), <strong>The</strong> Driving Forces of Economic<br />

Growth: Panel Data Evidence<br />

for the OECD Countries, Organization<br />

for Economic Cooperation and<br />

Development, Economic Studies<br />

No.33. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/26/2/18450995.pdf<br />

• Bergström, Friderik, Gidehag, Robert<br />

(2004), EU vs. USA, Timbro<br />

http://www.timbro.se/bokhandel/<br />

pdf/9175665646.pdf<br />

• Brimelow, Peter (1993), Why the Deficit<br />

is the Wrong Number, Forbes<br />

• Corruption Perception Index <strong>2007</strong>,<br />

Transparency International<br />

http://www.transparency.org/policy_<br />

research/surveys_indices/cpi<br />

• Djankov, Simeon, Ganser, Tim, McLiesh,<br />

Caralee, Ramalho, Rita, Schleifer,<br />

Andrei (<strong>2007</strong>): <strong>The</strong> Effect of Corporate<br />

Taxes on Investment and<br />

Entrepreneurship, Public Economics<br />

Program Meeting <strong>2007</strong>, National Bureau<br />

of Economic Research<br />

http://www.nber.org/confer/<strong>2007</strong>/<br />

pef07/shleifer.pdf<br />

• Fogel, Robert W (<strong>2007</strong>): Capitalism<br />

and Democracy in 2040: Forecasts<br />

and Speculations, NBER Working<br />

Paper No. 13184, National Bureau of<br />

Economic Research<br />

http://www.nber.org/papers/w13184<br />

• Guðmundsson, Már, Andersen, Palle<br />

S. (1998): Inflation and disinflation in<br />

Iceland, BIS Working Paper No.52,<br />

Bank for International Settlements<br />

http://ideas.repec.org/p/bis/biswps/52.<br />

html<br />

• Index of Economic Freedom <strong>2007</strong><br />

http://www.heritage.org/index<br />

• Mauro, Paulo (1995): Corruption and<br />

Growth, <strong>The</strong> <strong>Quarterly</strong> Journal of<br />

Economics, vol. 110, <strong>Issue</strong> 3, p. 681-<br />

712<br />

http://econpapers.repec.org/article/<br />

tprqjecon/v_3A110_3Ay_3A1995_<br />

3Ai_3A3_3Ap_3A681-712.htm<br />

• Ministry of Finance, Iceland, »Principal<br />

Tax Rates«, July 2006<br />

http://eng.fjarmalaraduneyti.is/media/<br />

Taxes/Principal_tax_rates_2006.pdf.<br />

• Mitchell, Daniel J. (2005), <strong>The</strong> Impact<br />

of Government Spending, Heritage<br />

Backgrounder #1831, Heritage Foundation<br />

http://www.heritage.org/Research/<br />

Budget/bg1831.cfm<br />

• Oura, Hiroko (<strong>2007</strong>), Wild or Tamed?<br />

India’s Potential Growth Rate, International<br />

Monetary Fund, Working<br />

Paper No. 07/224<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/<br />

longres.cfm?sk=21326.0<br />

• Penn World Table<br />

http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/php_site/<br />

pwt_index.php<br />

• Phelps, Edmund S. (2006), Dynamic<br />

Capitalism, Opinion Journal, Tuesday,<br />

October 10, 2006<br />

http://www.opinionjournal.com/editorial/feature.html?id=110009068<br />

• Phillips, Kerk, Shen, Kunrong (2003):<br />

What Effect does the Size of the State-<br />

Owned Sector Have on Regional<br />

Growth in China, Birgham Young<br />

University, Economics Working Papers<br />

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.<br />

cfm?abstract_id=395890<br />

• Prescott, Edward (2005): <strong>The</strong> Elasticity<br />

of the Labor Supply and the Consequences<br />

for Tax Policy, Federal Reserve<br />

Bank of Minneapolis<br />

http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/prescott/papers/LaborSupply.<br />

pdf<br />

• Srinivasan, T.N. (2004), China and India:<br />

Economic Performance, Competition<br />

and Cooperation. An Update,<br />

WTO Accession, Policy Reform and<br />

Poverty, World Trade Organization<br />

http://www.econ.yale.edu/~srinivas/<br />

C&I%20Economic%20Performance<br />

%20Update.pdf<br />

• Tanzi, Vito, Schuknecht, Ludger<br />

(1996): Reforming Government in Industrial<br />

Countries, International<br />

Monetary Fund Finance & Development<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/<br />

fandd/1996/09/pdf/tanzi.pdf<br />

• van de Hoek, Peter (2003): Tax Harmonization<br />

and Competition in the<br />

European Union, eJournal of Tax Research<br />

http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/<br />

eJTR/2003/2.html#Heading50<br />

• Walsh, Brendan (<strong>2007</strong>): <strong>The</strong> Source of<br />

Wealth in Small States. Small States<br />

as Financial Centers: <strong>The</strong> Case of Ireland,<br />

A presentation at the conference<br />

Small States as Financial Centers,<br />

University of Iceland, Reykjavik<br />

http://www.skattamal.is/smallstates/<br />

Walsh.SmallStates.14.09.07.ppt<br />

• World Bank, GNI per capita 2006, Atlas<br />

method and PPP, World Development<br />

Indicators database, July 1<br />

2006<br />

http://siteresources.worldbank.org/<br />

DATASTATISTICS/Resources/<br />

GNIPC.pdf<br />

• World Economic Outlook, International<br />

Monetary Fund, October <strong>2007</strong>,<br />

Washington D.C.<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/<br />

weo/<strong>2007</strong>/02/index.htm<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

153


Kalpana Kochhar,<br />

Senior Advisor, Asia and<br />

Pacific Department,<br />

International Monetary Fund,<br />

Washington D.C.<br />

India’s Unique Pattern Of<br />

Development: Quo vadis? 1<br />

"If I were asked under what<br />

sky the human mind has<br />

most fully developed some of<br />

its choicest gifts, has most<br />

deeply pondered on the greatest<br />

problems of life, and has<br />

found solutions, I should point<br />

to India."<br />

-Max Muller<br />

Introduction<br />

Much has been written about India’s ongoing<br />

demographic transition and the<br />

dividend from the rise in working age<br />

population that is expected to continue<br />

well into this century. But, of course, this<br />

dividend will only be realized if the 13 million<br />

or so people that will enter the labor<br />

force each year for the next four decades<br />

can be gainfully employed. Has India specialized<br />

in labor intensive as one would<br />

expect in a labor abundant country? And,<br />

if not, how will India be able to foster<br />

growth in labor-intensive manufacturing<br />

going forward so that jobs can be provided<br />

for India’s vast and growing pool of lowskilled<br />

labor?<br />

We start with an examination of how<br />

India’s policies since independence have<br />

influenced its pattern of development.<br />

<strong>The</strong>n we ask whether the wide-ranging<br />

reforms beginning in the 1980s and accelerating<br />

in the 1990s changed this pattern<br />

of specialization. Finally, we look at the<br />

way India’s states have developed to consider<br />

what the future might look like?<br />

What were the main elements of India’s<br />

development strategy in the first three and<br />

a half decades since Independence? A<br />

simplified view of the main aspects include:<br />

(i) the emphasis on self-sufficiency,<br />

which led to the creation of industries producing<br />

capital goods and extensive trade<br />

restrictions; (ii) the combination of heavy<br />

public sector involvement in production<br />

being reserved only for the public sector<br />

and controlled private sector involvement<br />

to take account of the fact that India was<br />

capital poor. Licenses were required for<br />

investment, capacity expansion, production,<br />

and imports, while foreign exchange,<br />

credit allocation, and even prices were<br />

controlled; (iii) avoidance of undue concentration<br />

of economic power through the<br />

Monopoly and Restrictive Trade Practices<br />

act (MRTP)—which imposed severe<br />

constraints on expansion by large firms<br />

and groups, and the Foreign Exchange<br />

Regulation Act (FERA); (iv) geographically<br />

balanced development with investment<br />

directed towards underdeveloped<br />

areas, even if these areas were not near<br />

154 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1. Sectoral Shares In Value-Added And Employment<br />

Value Added As Percent Of GDP<br />

Employment In Sector As Percent Of<br />

Total Employment<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)<br />

Agriculture Manufacturing Industry Services Agriculture Industry Services<br />

1980<br />

India 38.9 16.3 24.5 36.6 68.1 13.9 18.6<br />

Brazil 11.0 33.5 43.8 45.2 29.3 24.7 46.1<br />

China 30.1 40.5 48.5 21.4 68.7 18.2 11.7<br />

Indonesia 24.0 13.0 41.7 34.3 55.9 13.2 30.2<br />

Korea 15.1 28.6 40.5 44.4 34.0 29.0 37.0<br />

Malaysia 22.6 21.6 41.0 36.3 37.2 24.1 38.7<br />

Mexico 9.0 22.3 33.6 57.4 23.5 26.5 49.0<br />

Thailand 23.2 21.5 28.7 48.1 70.8 10.3 18.9<br />

Turkey 26.4 14.3 22.2 51.4 43.0 34.9 22.1<br />

Low income 36.4 14.8 24.4 39.2 74.6 8.7 16.5<br />

Lower middle income 21.5 29.1 41.7 36.8 64.0 18.5 16.4<br />

2000<br />

India 24.6 15.9 26.6 48.8 59.3 18.2 22.4<br />

Brazil 7.3 17.1 28.0 64.7 24.2 19.3 56.5<br />

China 16.4 34.7 50.2 33.4 46.9 23.0 29.9<br />

Indonesia 17.2 24.9 46.1 36.7 45.3 17.3 37.3<br />

Korea 4.3 26.1 36.2 59.5 10.9 28.0 61.0<br />

Malaysia 8.8 32.6 50.7 40.5 18.4 32.2 49.5<br />

Mexico 4.2 20.3 28.0 67.8 17.5 26.9 55.2<br />

Thailand 9.0 33.6 42.0 49.0 48.8 19.0 32.2<br />

Turkey 15.4 15.7 25.3 59.4 34.5 24.5 40.9<br />

Low Income 27.3 14.1 26.6 46.1 64.5 12.3 23.2<br />

Lower Middle Income 12.5 24.2 38.3 49.1 43.2 18.5 38.3<br />

Sources: World Bank, World Development Indicators 2005, except Korea, OECD-Structural Analysis Database, and India, National Accounts Statistics, Indiastat.com.<br />

Notes: For the low income, and lower middle income groups as classified by the World Bank, we report the respective averages. Employment shares are reported for the years indicated,<br />

except India (1983), Brazil (1981 and 1999), and Turkey (1982). Employment shares for the low-income group for 2000 are estimates.<br />

markets or even if scale was inefficiently<br />

small; (v) encouraging labor-intensive<br />

manufacture in the private sector, by giving<br />

significant benefits to small-scale firms<br />

(tax concessions, preferential access to<br />

subsidized credit, preferential treatment<br />

in procurement by the government, and<br />

reserving some goods for exclusive production<br />

by the small-scale sector); (vi)<br />

significant protections for labor, especially<br />

in large firms, through the Industrial<br />

Disputes Act (1947), which in 1982 was<br />

tightened to make it compulsory for firms<br />

with 100 or more workers to seek the permission<br />

of the relevant government to dismiss<br />

workers; (vii) relatively more resources<br />

spent on higher education than on<br />

primary education.<br />

Economic Development<br />

Circa 1980<br />

Next, we examine the legacy of this web<br />

of policies on the pattern of development.<br />

In Table 1, we present the share of output<br />

in the different sectors in India in 1981<br />

and compare it with that in a number of<br />

developing and developed countries. At<br />

a little over 16 percent of GDP, India’s<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

155


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 2. India In <strong>The</strong> Cross Section: Share Of Manufacturing And Services, Early 1980s<br />

Share Of Output (1981) Share Of Employment (1983)<br />

Manufacturing Services Industry Services<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

Log GDP Per-capita 15.37 21.58 36.27** 27.81 26.76 22.09 66.5** 67.20**<br />

(14.58) (13.75) (17.01) (17.79) (20.8) (20.8) (29.07) (30.07)<br />

Log GDP Per-capita -0.73 -1.09 -1.95* -1.46 -1.17 -0.92 -3.15* -3.19*<br />

(0.88) (0.83) (1.03) (1.08) (1.2) (1.2) (1.71) (1.76)<br />

India Indicator 4.58*** 2.33 -6.50*** -3.55** -0.260 0.560 -7.41** -7.53**<br />

(1.25) (1.76) (1.3) (1.61) (2.52) (2.82) (3.27) (3.63)<br />

Control for country <strong>size</strong> No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes<br />

Observations 101 101 122 122 44 44 43 43<br />

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.<br />

***represents significance at 1 percent, **represents significance at 5 percent, *represents significance at 10 percent levels.<br />

Country <strong>size</strong> is measured by area in square kilometers.<br />

share in manufacturing seems low, especially<br />

when compared with a number of<br />

East Asian countries and China.<br />

But from the work of Kuznets and<br />

Chenery, we know that the manufacturing<br />

share varies with the level of development,<br />

rising and then falling off once a<br />

country approaches a high level of income.<br />

So we examine whether India’s<br />

share of manufacturing is too low after<br />

correcting for its level of income and its<br />

square (to account for non-linearities) 2 .<br />

Correcting only for income, India is a<br />

positive outlier among countries in its<br />

share of value added in manufacturing in<br />

1981 (Table 2). Its share significantly exceeds<br />

the norm by 4.6 percentage points<br />

(see Table 2, column 1). After correcting<br />

for country <strong>size</strong>, the coefficient on the<br />

India indicator declines to 2.3 percentage<br />

points in 1981 which is not statistically<br />

significant (column 2). When we compare<br />

the shares of industrial sector employment<br />

in total employment across countries,<br />

India is again not an outlier (Table<br />

2, columns 5 and 6) 3 .<br />

What were the characteristics of industry<br />

in 1980? <strong>The</strong> first industry characteristic<br />

we examine is labor intensity, for<br />

which we use as a proxy the share of wages<br />

in value added for the industry in a<br />

country from the UNIDO database, averaged<br />

across a broad group of developing<br />

countries. For each country, we calculate<br />

Compared with countries at a similar level of development<br />

and <strong>size</strong>, in 1981 India had approximately the normal<br />

share of output and employment in manufacturing. Output<br />

in services was below the norm, as was employment.<br />

the ratio of value added in industries with<br />

above-median labor-intensity to the value<br />

added in industries with below-median<br />

labor-intensity. If Indian manufacturing<br />

generated relatively more value added in<br />

labor intensive industries in 1981, then in<br />

a cross-country regression of this ratio<br />

against log per capita GDP, its square,<br />

and an indicator for India, the India indicator<br />

should be positive and significant.<br />

However, the coefficient is insignificant<br />

suggesting that India does not have more<br />

value added coming out of labor intensive<br />

industries.<br />

<strong>The</strong> second characteristic we examined<br />

is skill intensity. We used data from South<br />

Africa contains on 45 sectors and five<br />

primary factors of production—capital<br />

plus four categories of labor: highly<br />

skilled, skilled, unskilled, and informal<br />

sector. We use the share of remuneration<br />

of the highly skilled and skilled categories<br />

of workers in total value as a proxy<br />

for the skill intensity of an industry. 4 If<br />

Indian manufacturing generated relatively<br />

less value added in skill intensive<br />

industries in 1981, then in a cross-country<br />

regression of this ratio against log per<br />

capita GDP, its square, and an indicator<br />

for India, the India indicator should be<br />

negative and significant. What we find is<br />

striking—even by 1981, India specialized<br />

more than the average country in skillintensive<br />

industries.<br />

A third characteristic we examine is<br />

156 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

diversification. Imbs and Wacziarg (2003)<br />

show that in the course of development,<br />

countries first diversify within manufacturing,<br />

producing many things, and then<br />

after a certain level of income, start specializing,<br />

producing fewer things. Technically,<br />

the relationship between the concentration<br />

of value added across<br />

industries (the Gini coefficient or the<br />

Herfindahl index), and income is U-<br />

shaped, with the turning point occurring<br />

at about US$10,000 per capita. Given that<br />

India has more of a presence in skill-intensive<br />

industries, the presumption would<br />

be that it has specialized in more areas<br />

than the typical developing country, and<br />

hence it should exhibit a more diverse<br />

pattern of production. When we examine<br />

the concentration of Indian industry compared<br />

to the average country pattern, we<br />

indeed find that India is significantly<br />

more diversified (less concentrated) in<br />

terms of the distribution of value-added<br />

across industries.<br />

To summarize, compared with countries<br />

at a similar level of development and<br />

<strong>size</strong>, in 1981 India had approximately the<br />

normal share of output and employment<br />

in manufacturing. Output in services was<br />

below the norm, as was employment in<br />

services. Output and employment were<br />

about average in labor intensive manufacturing<br />

industries and above the norm in<br />

skill intensive industries. And finally, Indian<br />

manufacturing was significantly<br />

more diversified both in terms of output<br />

and employment than countries of comparable<br />

income and <strong>size</strong>. <strong>The</strong> paradox of<br />

Indian manufacturing in the early 1980s<br />

is thus that of a labor-rich, capital-poor<br />

economy using too little of the former. 5<br />

<strong>The</strong> reason, most likely, was policy. <strong>The</strong><br />

large investment in tertiary education for<br />

a country of its per capita income resulted<br />

in the plentiful availability of highly<br />

skilled, cheap labor. In addition, labor<br />

laws afforded much less protection to<br />

skilled labor. <strong>The</strong>se factors are likely to<br />

have contributed to India generating<br />

relatively greater value added and employment<br />

in skill-intensive industries as<br />

compared to the typical poor country.<br />

Reforms Of <strong>The</strong> 1980s And 1990s<br />

<strong>The</strong> key features of reforms in the<br />

1980s—characterized as “pro business”<br />

in orientation were (i) the liberalization<br />

of capital goods and intermediate input<br />

imports; (ii) the extension of export incentives<br />

through the tax system, and more<br />

liberal access to credit and foreign exchange;<br />

(iii) the significant relaxation of<br />

industrial licensing requirements through<br />

direct “delicensing” of some industries<br />

and through “broad banding”, which permitted<br />

firms in some industries to switch<br />

production between similar product lines;<br />

(iv) the decontrol of administered prices<br />

of key intermediate inputs.<br />

<strong>The</strong> reforms of the 1990s—characterized<br />

as “pro-market” in orientation—included<br />

(i) the abolition of industrial licensing<br />

and the narrowing of the scope<br />

of public sector monopolies to a much<br />

smaller number of industries; (ii) the liberalization<br />

of inward foreign direct and<br />

portfolio investment; (iii) the sweeping<br />

liberalization of trade which included the<br />

elimination of import licensing and the<br />

progressive reduction of non-tariff barriers;<br />

(iv) financial sector liberalization,<br />

including the removal of controls on capital<br />

issues, freer entry for domestic, and<br />

foreign, private banks and the opening up<br />

Between 1980 and 2002, India’s share of services in<br />

value added exploded from 37 percent to 49 percent. Its<br />

share of manufacturing in value-added remained<br />

broadly unchanged at 16 percent<br />

of the insurance sector; (v) and the liberalization<br />

of investment in important services,<br />

such as telecommunications. Areas<br />

that remained largely untouched by reforms<br />

in the 1990s were the labor market;<br />

small-scale reservations (where there has<br />

been some movement only in the last 4-5<br />

years); privatization both of non-financial<br />

enterprises and of banks; and further agricultural<br />

sector reforms.<br />

Economic Development After<br />

Reforms<br />

How have these twenty years of slow but<br />

steady reforms affected the pattern of<br />

development, if at all? Let us look again<br />

at the variables discussed above—sectoral<br />

shares, factor intensities, and diversification,<br />

between the early 1980s and<br />

early 2000s. <strong>The</strong> traditional perspective<br />

of Kuznets or Chenery would predict a<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

157


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 3: India In <strong>The</strong> Cross Section: Shares Of Mfg. & Services, 2000<br />

Panel A<br />

Share Of Output<br />

Share Of Employment<br />

Manufacturing Services Industry Services<br />

(i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii)<br />

Log GDP Per-capita 13.18** 15.41** 10.88 8.01 51.79*** 52.4*** 38.99 39.69**<br />

(6.41) (6.38) (10.34) (10.3) (11.28) (11.23) (23.91) (23.83)<br />

Log GDP Per-capita 2 -0.61 -0.72* -0.19 -0.04 -2.67*** -2.71*** -1.49 -1.54<br />

(0.12) (0.38) (0.6) (0.6) (0.62) (0.63) (1.31) (1.3)<br />

India Indicator 2.4** 0.26 -0.05 3.77** 0.56 1.13 -17.22*** -16.57***<br />

(0.73) (1.11) (1.17) (1.46) (1.17) (1.36) (3.03) (3.78)<br />

Control For Size No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes<br />

Observations 149 149 156 156 76 76 74 74<br />

Panel B<br />

Change In Share Of output (1981-2000)<br />

Change In Share Of Employment<br />

Manufacturing Services Industry Services<br />

(i) (ii) (iii) (iv)<br />

Log Initial GDP Per-Capita -1.19*** 3.96*** -3.37*** 2.91**<br />

(0.66) (0.77) (0.92) (1.39)<br />

Average Annual growth rate 0.7** 0.41 0.47 -0.18<br />

(0.33) (0.53) (0.6) (0.64)<br />

India Indicator -2.56* 9.86*** 1.7 0.94<br />

(1.37) (1.63) (2.05) (3.59)<br />

Observations 93 116 39 38<br />

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses<br />

***represents significance at 1%, **represents significance at 5%, *represents significance at 5%, *represents significance at 10%<br />

Country <strong>size</strong> is measured by area in square killometers.<br />

rapid increase in the share of manufacturing,<br />

a decline in agriculture and an<br />

uncertain or modest effect on services.<br />

However, between 1980 and 2002, India’s<br />

share of services in value added exploded<br />

from 37 percent to 49 percent. Its share<br />

of manufacturing in value added remained<br />

broadly unchanged at 16 percent,<br />

while the decline in agriculture mirrored<br />

the performance of services. 6 <strong>The</strong> corresponding<br />

numbers for employment were<br />

19 percent to 22 percent and 14 percent<br />

to 18 percent (Table 1).<br />

Is this evolution in sectoral shares unusual<br />

when compared with that of other<br />

countries? In Table 3, columns 1 and 2,<br />

panel A, we see that the coefficient of the<br />

India indicator is still positive but smaller<br />

than in the corresponding specification<br />

for 1981. 7 Furthermore, in the regressions<br />

using the change in the share of<br />

manufacturing value-added to overall<br />

growth (column 1, Panel B), the India indicator<br />

is negative. Thus, the data suggest<br />

a relative slowing in manufacturing<br />

growth.<br />

In contrast, the performance of services<br />

over this period has been unusual.<br />

India’s share in services is a significant 3.8<br />

percent higher than in other countries in<br />

2000 (Table 3, panel A, column 4). This<br />

is broadly confirmed in the change regressions<br />

(panel B), where India records<br />

an increase in the <strong>size</strong> of the services sector<br />

that is 10 percentage points of GDP<br />

greater than that of the average country.<br />

What happened to labor, skill intensity<br />

and diversification in manufacturing after<br />

the reforms? In Figure 1, we plot the evolution<br />

in the share of output generated in<br />

labor-intensive relative to non labor-intensive<br />

industries for India and a selected<br />

158 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 1. Value-Added Share of Labor Intensive Industries<br />

Ratio of value added<br />

1<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

Ratio of value added in above median labor intensive intensive sectors to below median sectors<br />

7.5 8 7.5 9 9.5<br />

CHN IND IDN KOR MYS<br />

Sources: Authors’ calculations; UNIDO 3-digit industrial statistics database (2003).<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> sample for all countries includes observations from 1981 to 1996. <strong>The</strong> classification of above and below<br />

median labor-intensive sectors is given in Table 3. CHN stands for China, IND for India, IDN for Indonesia, KOR for<br />

Korea, and MYS for Malaysia.<br />

Figure 2. Value-Added Share Of Skill Intensive Industries<br />

Ratio of value added<br />

2.5<br />

2<br />

1.5<br />

1<br />

0.5<br />

Ratio of value added in above median skill intensive sectors to below median sectors<br />

7.5 8 7.5 9 9.5<br />

CHN IND IDN KOR MYS<br />

Sources: Authors’ calculations; UNIDO 3-digit industrial statistics database (2003).<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> sample for all countries includes observations from 1981 to 1996. <strong>The</strong> classification of above and below<br />

median skill intensive sectors is given in Table 3. CHN stands for China, IND for India, IDN for Indonesia, KOR for<br />

Korea, and MYS for Malaysia.<br />

group of comparator countries. India’s<br />

share is decreasing, when that of many of<br />

the other countries is either increasing, or<br />

decreasing at much higher levels of income.<br />

In Figure 2, we plot the evolution<br />

in the relative share of output generated<br />

in skill-intensive industries for India and<br />

a selected group of comparator countries.<br />

Again, it is striking that India’s share in<br />

skill-intensive manufacturing, which was<br />

already high in 1980 despite its lower<br />

level of per capita income, has been increasing;<br />

it is at levels reached by Malaysia<br />

or Korea at much higher levels of per<br />

capita income. <strong>The</strong>se developments are<br />

not affected by the fact that our data so<br />

far have been limited to the registered<br />

manufacturing sector in India. Indeed,<br />

when we trace the evolution of labor- and<br />

skill-intensive products in the informal<br />

sector, we see the same pattern (Figure<br />

3). Finally, we find that India continues to<br />

be an outlier in 2000 on both measures of<br />

diversification. Indeed, when we compare<br />

the change in diversification between<br />

1980 and 2000, we find that India is again<br />

an outlier, implying that the pace of diversification<br />

in India after 1980 has been<br />

greater than that for the average country<br />

(see Figure 4).<br />

In sum, the evidence suggests that<br />

many of the unique features of India’s<br />

development that were apparent in 1981<br />

have not changed, despite the reforms.<br />

This continuity of trends may be explained<br />

partly by the fact that the reforms<br />

have not been completed. For example,<br />

labor markets remain untouched and<br />

education expenditure is still skewed. But<br />

part of the explanation may well rest with<br />

the fact that in India, the policy distortions<br />

created organizational capabilities<br />

and human capital that led to hysteresis<br />

in growth paths. <strong>The</strong> growth experience<br />

of the Indian states offers some support<br />

to this view.<br />

Development At <strong>The</strong> State Level<br />

Are these patterns repeated in India’s<br />

states and are there differences between<br />

the fast growing and the laggard states?<br />

We find that in the fast-growing Indian<br />

states, the share of manufacturing has<br />

remained constant or declined. Where<br />

there has been an increase—in Andhra<br />

Pradesh, Gujarat, and Haryana—it has<br />

occurred in capital- and skill-intensive<br />

industries (In Gujarat, the share of the<br />

textile industry declined a lot, while that<br />

of the petrochemical industry rose substantially;<br />

similarly, in Andhra Pradesh<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

159


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 3. Value-Added Shares In Unregistered Manufacturing<br />

3.0<br />

2.5<br />

2.0<br />

1.5<br />

1.0<br />

0.5<br />

Share of High Labor Intensity Industries<br />

Share of High Skill Intensity Industries<br />

0.0<br />

1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000<br />

Source: Authors’ calculations; data on unregistered manufacturing are from the Central Statistical Organization,<br />

Government of India.<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> share of high labor (skill) intensity industries is the ratio of value added in sectors with above-median labor<br />

(skill) intensity to that in sectors with below-median labor (skill) intensity. <strong>The</strong> relevant sector classification is given in<br />

Table 3.<br />

Figure 4. Diversification In Indian Manufacturing<br />

Herfindahl Index<br />

.12<br />

.1<br />

.08<br />

.06<br />

Herfindahl Index based on value added<br />

7.5 8 7.5 9 9.5<br />

CHN IND IDN KOR MYS<br />

Sources: Authors’ calculations; UNIDO 3-digit industrial statistics database (2003).<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> sample for all countries includes observations from 1981 to 1996. CHN stands for China, IND<br />

for India, IDN for Indonesia, KOR for Korea, and MYS for Malaysia. For each country, the Herfindahl<br />

Index measures concentration in the value added across sectors; the lower the index, the lower the concentration,<br />

or the higher the diversification.<br />

the decline in the share of food, beverages,<br />

tobacco, textiles, and paper related<br />

industries was matched by a significant<br />

increase in the share of basic metals and<br />

alloys). Interestingly, neither the fast nor<br />

the slow growing states increased their<br />

share of value added in labor intensive<br />

industries.<br />

By contrast, nearly all states in India<br />

have seen a uniform shift toward services<br />

but there is a noteworthy difference between<br />

services that are predominantly in<br />

the public sector and those that are in the<br />

private sector. In Figure 5, we find a neg-<br />

ative correlation between the change in<br />

share of services that are performed<br />

mostly by the public sector (such as electricity,<br />

public administration, railways,<br />

and other community services) and the<br />

average annual state growth. In other<br />

words, the share of public sector services<br />

including administration is growing in the<br />

laggard states, while the share of private<br />

sector services is growing in the fast-moving<br />

states.<br />

Armed with all this, let us turn to the<br />

question of where India may be headed?<br />

It would appear that the fast growing peninsular<br />

states are starting to resemble<br />

more developed countries in their specialization,<br />

while the slow growing hinterland<br />

states, with their still rapidly growing,<br />

less well-educated, populations are<br />

falling behind. Visaria and Visaria (2003)<br />

suggest that 60 percent of the expected<br />

620 million addition to the Indian population<br />

between now and 2051 will be in Bihar,<br />

Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan and Uttar<br />

Pradesh; only 22 percent will be in the<br />

fast growing states of Kerala, Tamil Nadu,<br />

Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, and Maharashtra.<br />

Such trends could create immense<br />

economic and political strains between<br />

Indian states.<br />

It may well be that the slow growing<br />

states will have to follow a more traditional<br />

path of growth, focusing on laborintensive<br />

manufacturing. But for that<br />

further reform is needed—in particular,<br />

more flexible labor laws and an improvement<br />

of infrastructure, especially vis-à-vis<br />

the states in the hinterland so that these<br />

industries can be internationally costcompetitive—to<br />

revitalize labor-intensive<br />

manufacturing. But the archaic labor laws<br />

have strong organized constituencies, in<br />

particular, labor unions tied to political<br />

160 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 5. Public Services And States’ Growth<br />

Change in share of Public Services in<br />

NSDP 1980-2000 (%)<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

Change in share of Public Services in NSDP 1980-2000<br />

JK<br />

BH OR<br />

MP<br />

MN<br />

RJ<br />

HP<br />

pervisory skilled workers are affordable<br />

only if they are used very economically<br />

relative to the use of unskilled labor – if,<br />

for example, firms have scale. 9 Here<br />

again, the fast moving states where the<br />

business and political climate is more<br />

conducive to scale have an advantage. In<br />

5<br />

sum, the fast-growing states could absorb<br />

AS UP<br />

KL GJ MH AP KK TN<br />

the more mobile skilled labor from the<br />

0<br />

PJ<br />

HY<br />

WB slow moving states leading to a further<br />

hollowing out of prospects there. <strong>The</strong><br />

-5<br />

DL<br />

obvious solution is not to impede the<br />

1 2 3 4<br />

Average Annual Growth of NSDP per capita 1980-2000 (%)<br />

5 growth of the fast-movers but to enhance<br />

the availability of the resource in scarce<br />

Source: Authors’ calculations; data on unregistered manufacturing are from the Central Statistical Organization, Government<br />

of India.<br />

supply. Although the earlier emphasis on<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> share of high labor (skill) intensity industries is the ratio of value added in sectors with above-median labor<br />

(skill) intensity to that in sectors with below-median labor (skill) intensity. <strong>The</strong> relevant sector classification is given in funding tertiary education at the expense<br />

Table 3.<br />

of primary education may<br />

Code State Code State Code State<br />

have been an aberration,<br />

AP Andhra Pradesh JK Jammu & Kashmir OR Orissa<br />

India may now have too<br />

little tertiary education of<br />

AS Assam KK Karnataka PJ Punjab<br />

the right kind at this juncture.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are serious<br />

BH Bihar KL Kerala RJ Rajasthan<br />

DL Delhi MH Maharashtra TN Tamil Nadu<br />

doubts about the quality<br />

GJ Gujarat MN Manipur TP Tripura<br />

of education received by<br />

HP Himachal Pradesh MP Madhya Pradesh UP Uttar Pradesh<br />

the large number of graduates<br />

HY Haryana NG Nagaland WB West Bengal<br />

emerging from uni-<br />

versity every year. <strong>The</strong><br />

parties, backing them. Given the way Indian<br />

industry has specialized, the costs of<br />

these laws are not experienced by incumbents,<br />

and the political leadership, or will,<br />

to amend them has not emerged. 8<br />

Even if serious reforms were undertaken<br />

in the laggard states, competition<br />

from the more advanced states will not<br />

make it easy for them to grow. First, laggard<br />

states are typically distant from<br />

ports and airports. Transportation costs<br />

will come down as infrastructure is built<br />

up, but it is unclear whether the improvements<br />

will help them out-compete the<br />

fast-growing peninsular states where<br />

many of the initial large-scale infrastructure<br />

projects are being undertaken, and<br />

where ancillary infrastructure exists.<br />

Second, even labor-intensive unskilled<br />

manufacturing—should it pick up—requires<br />

a skilled supervisory and managerial<br />

force. Despite the large numbers of<br />

graduates emerging from universities in<br />

India, the number of graduates with the<br />

skills to work in industry or the service<br />

sector is relatively limited. With the immense<br />

demand for skilled workers in the<br />

export-oriented services industry, wages<br />

of skilled workers have been going up<br />

very fast. Given the extremely competitive<br />

situation in (typically tradable) labor-intensive<br />

industries, highly paid su-<br />

number of high-quality institutions is<br />

still very small, and thus, India needs to<br />

remove the barriers to starting new institutions,<br />

as well as encourage foreign direct<br />

investment here. In short, from a<br />

policy perspective, the irony is that in<br />

order to promote unskilled labor-intensive<br />

activities in the future, a great deal<br />

of attention may need to be paid in fostering<br />

the supply of skilled labor.<br />

<strong>The</strong> changes since the early 1980s have<br />

unleashed tremendous economic opportunities,<br />

but also divergence between<br />

states. From uniformly mediocre economic<br />

performance, India has evolved<br />

into a conglomeration of states with per-<br />

TP<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

161


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

formance more related to the capabilities<br />

of individual states and the opportunities<br />

they create. It is possible that the laggard<br />

states would do what it takes to utilize<br />

their vast pools of underemployed lowcost<br />

labor to attract investment in laborintensive<br />

manufacturing and agri-business.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y would thereby catch up with<br />

the leading states in India. <strong>The</strong> revival of<br />

manufacturing growth since 2004, albeit<br />

still concentrated in skill-intensive<br />

and capital-intensive industries, offers<br />

hope for this scenario.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

This paper is based upon Kochhar et<br />

al. (2006)<br />

2<br />

Of course, other factors also affect<br />

sectoral shares (see, for example,<br />

Chenery and Taylor (1968)), but our<br />

intent here is primarily to see whether<br />

India is an outlier after controlling for<br />

obvious factors, rather than to do an<br />

exhaustive study of the sectoral composition<br />

of growth per se. Also, we<br />

report results for the largest sample of<br />

countries, though the results are qualitatively<br />

similar, when not specifically<br />

noted, for a smaller cross-section restricted<br />

to non-OECD countries.<br />

3<br />

Comparable cross-country data on<br />

employment shares are not available<br />

separately for the manufacturing sector,<br />

only for industry (manufacturing,<br />

mining, and core infrastructure sectors),<br />

and services. Thus the analysis<br />

of employment shares is conducted for<br />

industry and services .<br />

4<br />

<strong>The</strong> choice of South Africa was dictated<br />

primarily by data availability.<br />

Our results are robust to alternative<br />

definitions of skill intensity, including<br />

restricting the definition to the highly<br />

skilled category and defining skill intensity<br />

in terms of share of remuneration<br />

in output rather than value added.<br />

We also checked the correlation of our<br />

measures of skill intensity with that<br />

compiled for the U.S. by Rajan and<br />

Wulf (2004). It is 0.66, for the highly<br />

skilled category, and 0.5 when skill<br />

intensity includes highly skilled and<br />

skilled workers.<br />

5<br />

It may well be, of course, that India’s<br />

labor-intensive production was concentrated<br />

in the unregistered sector,<br />

for which we do not have comparable<br />

data from other countries. To the extent<br />

that firms in the unregistered sector<br />

have inefficiently small scale, total<br />

production would still be smaller and<br />

less competitive than it could be without<br />

the spectrum of regulations. Also,<br />

unregistered labor-intensive production<br />

has been falling considerably over<br />

time, suggesting that this explanation<br />

for India’s lack of concentration in labor-intensive<br />

manufacturing is less<br />

applicable today.<br />

6<br />

This development contradicts the<br />

Kuznets-Chenery hypothesis. Kongsamut,<br />

Rebelo, and Xie (2001), however,<br />

argued based on an analysis of<br />

123 countries over the period 1970-89<br />

that the share of services rises with<br />

development more than anticipated by<br />

the Kuznets-Chenery view.<br />

7<br />

However, we find that industry (that<br />

is, manufacturing, mining and core<br />

infrastructure industries) was a significant<br />

negative outlier in 2000, possibly<br />

related to the much worse than<br />

average performance of India’s infrastructure<br />

sector.<br />

8<br />

In other words, most commentators<br />

look to existing firms to see if labor<br />

laws are a problem. But existing firms<br />

have adapted to these laws, as suggested<br />

both by their pattern of specialization<br />

and their scale. <strong>The</strong> more<br />

pertinent question is whether new<br />

firms are kept from entering because<br />

of the laws. <strong>The</strong> pattern of specialization<br />

in India suggest they are.<br />

9<br />

Alternatively, the wages on unskilled<br />

labor may fall, but wages in agriculture<br />

may place a floor here.<br />

References<br />

• Chenery, H.B., 1960, Patterns of industrial<br />

growth, American Economic<br />

Review Vol. 57, 415-26, and L.J. Taylor,<br />

1968, Development patterns:<br />

among countries and over time, Review<br />

of Economics and Statistics, Vol.<br />

50, 391-416.<br />

• Imbs, J., and R. Wacziarg, 2003, Stages<br />

of development, <strong>The</strong> American<br />

Economic Review, March, Vol. 93,<br />

No. 1.<br />

• Kochhar, Kalpana, Utsav Kumar, Raghuram<br />

Rajan, Arvind Subramanian,<br />

Ioannis Tokatlidis, “India’s Pattern of<br />

Development: What Happened, What<br />

Follows?” Journal of Monetary Economics,<br />

Vol 53(5), July 2006<br />

• Kongsamut, P., S. Rebelo, and D. Xie,<br />

2001, Beyond balanced growth, IMF<br />

Working Paper 01/85 (Washington:<br />

International Monetary Fund).<br />

• Visaria, L., and P. Visaria, 2003, Long<br />

term population projections for major<br />

states, 1991-2101, Economic and Political<br />

Weekly, November.<br />

• Rajan, R. and J.Wulf, 2004, Are perks<br />

purely managerial excess? NBER<br />

Working Paper No. 10494 (Cambridge,<br />

Massachusetts : National Bureau of<br />

Economic Research).<br />

162 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


TECH WATCH<br />

What’s in store<br />

for technology freaks in 2008<br />

INDIA’S FIRST AND NO. 1<br />

BUSINESS AND MARKETING MAGAZINE<br />

✮ PRODUCT ✮ PRICE ✮ PLACE ✮ PROMOTION ✮<br />

4Ps<br />

BUSINESS AND<br />

MARKETING<br />

<strong>Volume</strong>-II <strong>Issue</strong>-24 4 January - 17 January 2008<br />

Why Toyota, GM,<br />

Ford & Renault<br />

love India...<br />

Power, passion, leadership skills,<br />

strategic expertise and many<br />

such qualities... they have it all;<br />

the maestros who will turn things<br />

around for India in 2008. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

are the very forces who will make<br />

2008 worthwhile for India Inc. An<br />

exclusive 4Ps B&M compilation...<br />

20<br />

Meet the 2nd<br />

Son of the East<br />

Rendezvous with<br />

Kenji Anai,<br />

Global Head,<br />

Multifuncl. Devices,<br />

National Panasonic<br />

88 Supermodels<br />

NOW ONLY<br />

Rs.10<br />

alone can’t<br />

cast the<br />

marketing<br />

spell.<br />

You<br />

need<br />

Pill(ow) fight<br />

more! Why Dabur needs a<br />

‘new u’ look soon<br />

by Rajita<br />

Chaudhuri<br />

38<br />

Top 5:<br />

Why Airtel &<br />

Kingfisher Airlines<br />

reign supreme<br />

this fortnight<br />

...and why India loves Jaguar, Land<br />

Rover & Suzuki. <strong>The</strong> reason: India<br />

may emerge as a global player in the<br />

passenger car segment<br />

4Ps<br />

BUSINESS AND<br />

MARKETING


T.R.Manoharan,<br />

Senior Coordinator, Forest Programme,<br />

WWF-India,New Delhi<br />

India’s Growing Ecological Footprint: Exploring<br />

Past And Future Changes<br />

"<strong>The</strong>re is enough for everybody’s<br />

need, but not enough<br />

for anybody’s greed."<br />

-Mahatma Gandhi<br />

Introduction<br />

A high economic growth is essential for<br />

India to ensure improved living conditions<br />

of its citizens, which majorly consists of<br />

poor and marginalized sections. <strong>The</strong> nation<br />

possesses only 2.2 per cent of the land<br />

mass but home to 16 per cent of world<br />

population and 27 percent of world’s poor.<br />

Despite its low per capita income, India is<br />

presently the world’s tenth largest economy<br />

in terms of GDP. <strong>The</strong> economy is<br />

growing at 7 to 8 per cent per annum since<br />

2003 and is targeted to grow at 9 per cent<br />

or above during <strong>2007</strong>-12 (Planning Commission,<br />

2006; World Bank, <strong>2007</strong>). To<br />

achieve this target, increased use of bioresources-<br />

both within the country and<br />

elsewhere is inevitable.<br />

Available estimates show that humanity’s<br />

ecological footprint (demand on ecosystems)<br />

has exceeded the bio-capacity of<br />

the planet by late 1980s and the over shoot<br />

is accumulating ever since. It is pointed<br />

out that world is following unsustainable<br />

path of development and the growing ecological<br />

debt is a major factor. Presently,<br />

we are using 30 percent more resources<br />

than the planet can regenerate (In other<br />

words, 1.3 planets). <strong>The</strong> global footprint<br />

network estimates ecological debt day for<br />

every year to create awareness on how humanity’s<br />

consumption patterns are depleting<br />

the planets bio-resources . In <strong>2007</strong>,<br />

the ecological debt day was October 6. By<br />

that day the humanity has consumed total<br />

amount of new resources that the planet<br />

can produce this year. Ecological debt day<br />

marks the day when we begin to live beyond<br />

our ecological means. If we continue<br />

the current path of development, the<br />

ecological debt day will come earlier in<br />

every year. Several options are available<br />

now to minimize the risk of accumulated<br />

ecological debt (WWF, 2006; UNEP,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>). India, being one of the fastest<br />

growing economies in the world with more<br />

than one billion people, can play a crucial<br />

role to address this global challenge. It is<br />

possible to minimize the ecological footprint<br />

of the nation while continuing higher<br />

economic growth and efforts to attain<br />

high human development.<br />

164 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS<br />

Table-1: India’s Economic Growth<br />

Plan<br />

Period<br />

Real Income<br />

Plan<br />

Target<br />

Use Of Natural Resources<br />

India is rich in terms of natural resource<br />

endowments and biodiversity. <strong>The</strong> nation<br />

is one of the 12 mega biodiversity countries<br />

in the world. More than 45000 flora<br />

and 77000 species of fauna are recorded.<br />

<strong>The</strong> natural ecosystem include 16 types of<br />

forests 5 types of grass lands, 27,403 wetland<br />

units (both inland and coastal) including<br />

lakes, swamps, tanks and reservoirs,<br />

tidal mudflats, mangroves, estuaries,<br />

lagoons, coral reefs, sand beach (Verma<br />

et. al, <strong>2007</strong>). <strong>The</strong>se resources provide a<br />

flow of environmental (ecosystem) services<br />

required for production/economic<br />

development. However, the depletion and<br />

degradation of natural resources pose a<br />

serious threat to the sustained flow of<br />

these ecosystem services. <strong>The</strong> uncertainty<br />

of quality and quantity of such services<br />

has not been suitably factored into the development<br />

models. Forest is the second<br />

largest land use in India next to agriculture.<br />

<strong>The</strong> latest assessment of forest survey<br />

of India in 2003 estimated about 67.8 million<br />

hectares of forest cover in the country<br />

Actual<br />

Growth<br />

Sectoral Growth Rate<br />

Agriculture Industry Services<br />

First Plan 1951-56 2.1 3.6 2.9 5.9 3.7<br />

Second Plan 1956-61 4.5 3.9 3.2 6.4 4.6<br />

Third Plan 1961-66 5.6 2.3 -0.5 6.8 5.0<br />

Fourth Plan 1969-74 5.7 3.2 2.6 3.7 4.0<br />

Fifth Plan 1974-79 4.4 4.8 3.4 6.3 5.5<br />

Sixth Plan 1980-85 5.2 5.7 5.5 6.2 5.4<br />

Seventh Plan 1985-90 5.0 6.0 3.4 7.5 7.4<br />

Eighth Plan 1992-97 5.6 6.8 3.9 8.0 7.9<br />

Ninth Plan 1997-02 6.5 5.5 2.1 4.6 8.1<br />

Tenth Plan 2002-07 8.0 7.2* 1.7 8.3 9.0<br />

Eleventh Plan <strong>2007</strong>-12 9.0 - 4.1* 10.5* 9.9*<br />

* projected.<br />

Sources: Planning Commission, Govt. of India & http://www.indiastat.com<br />

which is 20.64 percent of the total geographical<br />

area (FSI, 2005). It shows a marginal<br />

increase in the total forest cover, but<br />

the loss of 2.6 million ha of dense forests<br />

when compared to previous assessment in<br />

2001. <strong>The</strong> nation is targeted to achieve 33<br />

per cent of its area under forest and tree<br />

cover by 2012. <strong>The</strong> per capita availability<br />

of land in India has declined from 0.91 ha<br />

to 0.33 ha between 1950 and 2001.<strong>The</strong> per<br />

capita availability of farm land declined<br />

from 0.64 ha to 0.25 ha during the same<br />

period. India occupies 4 per cent of world’s<br />

water resources which are depleting fast.<br />

In 1947, the per capita availability of fresh<br />

water in India was 5150 cu.m but it reduced<br />

to 2200 cu.m in 2000. It is projected<br />

that in 2017, the same will become 1600<br />

cu.m. resulting water stress in many places.<br />

<strong>The</strong> melting of glaziers in Himalayas and<br />

other climate change related issues can<br />

lead to irreversible changes in ecosystems.<br />

India is said to be particularly vulnerable<br />

due to these effects.<br />

While there is overall decline in India’s<br />

bio-capacity, its use has increased faster<br />

to meet the growing needs of development.<br />

Electricity generation in India has<br />

increased from 6 billion KWH to 556 billion<br />

KWH between 1951 and 2001. <strong>The</strong><br />

coal production has increased from 32<br />

million tonnes to 332 million tones between<br />

1951 and 2001. In 2006, the production<br />

was 670 million tones. In order to<br />

meet the growing demand for energy, the<br />

production is targeted to increase to 670<br />

million tones by 2012. In addition to domestic<br />

production, 40-50 million tones of<br />

superior coal is required to be imported<br />

during the 11 th plan period. Crude oil imports<br />

increased from six million tones to<br />

78 million tones between 1961 and 2001<br />

(Table-2).<br />

Ecological Footprint<br />

An ecological footprint measures people’s<br />

demand on nature and compares human<br />

consumption of natural resources with the<br />

Earth’s ecological capacity (bio-capacity)<br />

to regenerate them. A country’s ecological<br />

Available estimates show that humanity’s ecological footprint<br />

has exceeded the bio-capacity of the planet by late<br />

1980s. Presently, we are using 30 percent more<br />

resources than the planet can regenerate<br />

footprint is the total area required to produce<br />

the food and fibre that it consumes,<br />

absorb its waste, and provide space for its<br />

infrastructure. People consume resources<br />

and ecological services all over the world,<br />

so their footprint is the sum of these areas,<br />

wherever they are on the planet. Ecologi-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

165


PROGRESS WITHIN LIMITS<br />

Table-2: Changes In Select Indicators Of India’s Bio Capacity And Its Use<br />

Per capita Availability Of:<br />

Year Population<br />

(million)<br />

Land<br />

(ha)<br />

Farm<br />

Land<br />

(ha)<br />

Forest<br />

Area<br />

(ha)<br />

Population<br />

Density<br />

(per<br />

q.km)<br />

Energy<br />

generated<br />

(Billion<br />

KWH)<br />

Crude<br />

Oil<br />

Imports<br />

(Millon<br />

Tonnes)<br />

Imports Of<br />

Petroleum<br />

(Million<br />

tonnes)<br />

Production<br />

Of Coal<br />

(Million<br />

tonnes)<br />

Export (US$<br />

Million)<br />

(including<br />

re-exports)<br />

Import<br />

(US$<br />

Million)<br />

1951 361.1 110 0.91 0.64 0.113 6.6 3.1 32.3 1490 1852<br />

1961 439.2 134 0.75 0.50 0.124 20.1 6 2.5 55.2 1381 2281<br />

1971 548.2 167 0.60 0.41 0.115 61.2 11.7 1.1 76.3 2153 2443<br />

1981 683.3 208 0.48 0.36 0.099 129.2 16.2 7.3 119 8704 15174<br />

1991 846.3 257 0.39 0.30 0.081 289.4 20.7 8.7 225.5 17865 19411<br />

2001 1028.7 313 0.30 0.25 0.074 554.5 78.7 7.0 332.6 43827 51413<br />

Source: Ministry of Environment and Forests,Government of India (Various Reports).<br />

cal footprints enable people to take personal<br />

or collective actions in support of a<br />

world where humanity lives within the<br />

means of one planet (WWF, 2006; Global<br />

footprint network). <strong>The</strong> available estimates<br />

show that India’s ecological footprint<br />

per person (0.8 global hectares) is<br />

lower than the world average (2.2 global<br />

hectares) but it is much higher than the<br />

nations' biocapacity and this has placed<br />

India in the list of “ecological deficit”<br />

countries. <strong>The</strong> Living Planet Report -<br />

2006 ranked India as the third largest<br />

footprint country followed by United<br />

States and China. “India’s total ecological<br />

footprint is likely to increase due to the<br />

twin pressures from population and consumption<br />

patterns unless suitable actions<br />

are taken. In 2002, the humanity’s per person<br />

footprint was 2.2 global hectares (gha)<br />

whereas the bio capacity per person was<br />

1.8 gha. India’s footprint was 0.8 gha<br />

which is lower than world average but<br />

lower than the nation’s biocapacity (04<br />

gha). Between 1975 and 2003, India’s foot<br />

print per person has increased faster (16<br />

percent) than that of the world (14 percent)<br />

but much lower than many other economies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> ecological footprint estimates<br />

indicate that India’s bio-capacity is not<br />

sufficient to meet the needs of the nations'<br />

growing population. In other words, future<br />

development in India is also dependant<br />

on the use of natural resources of<br />

other countries. Globalization makes it<br />

possible to use these resources legally and<br />

openly. <strong>The</strong> nation has committed to conservation<br />

of natural resources and biodiversity<br />

and implemented several policy<br />

and legal measures. It is also party to<br />

many Multilateral Environmental Agreements<br />

(MEAs) such as Convention on<br />

Biological Diversity (CBD), CITES, Montreal<br />

Table-2: Changes In Select Indicators Of India’s Bio Capacity And Its Use<br />

Protocol. In practice,<br />

Country Ecological<br />

Footprint<br />

(Demand)<br />

Biocapacity<br />

(Supply)<br />

(gha. Per<br />

Ecol. Footprint –<br />

Biocapacity =Ecological<br />

Reserve Or<br />

Footprint<br />

Change Per<br />

Person (%)<br />

Biocapacity<br />

Change Per<br />

Person (%)<br />

these measures have regulated<br />

or prohibited consumptive<br />

use (extraction) of natural resources<br />

in India. However,<br />

(gha. Per Person) Ecological Deficit (-) 1975-2003 1975-2003<br />

Person) 2003 2003 gha. Per Person)2003<br />

this gives economic opportunities<br />

for many biodiversity<br />

India 0.8 0.4 -0.4 16 -23<br />

China 1.6 0.8 -0.9 82 -3<br />

rich countries where such resources<br />

Brazil<br />

South Africa<br />

USA<br />

Indonesia<br />

World<br />

Source: WWF (2006)<br />

2.1<br />

2.3<br />

9.6<br />

1.1<br />

2.2<br />

9.9<br />

2.0<br />

4.7<br />

1.0<br />

1.8<br />

7.8<br />

-0.3<br />

-4.8<br />

-0.1<br />

-0.45<br />

30<br />

-13<br />

38<br />

36<br />

14<br />

-27<br />

-23<br />

-20<br />

-20<br />

-25<br />

are abundant. For<br />

example, felling of timber is<br />

prohibited, wood in log forms<br />

cannot be exported from India<br />

with a view to safeguard<br />

our remaining forests. But,<br />

166 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS<br />

we permit imports from all over the world<br />

including those originated from rainforests/<br />

worlds critical eco-regions. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are several restrictions for land in India for<br />

establishing plantations, but enough land<br />

is offered for Indian companies in many<br />

countries in order to attract investment<br />

and creating employment opportunities in<br />

those countries. <strong>The</strong> proponents of trade<br />

liberalization may argue that this is the<br />

principle of trade and here the comparative<br />

advantage is the natural resources<br />

(mineral/ timber). <strong>The</strong>oretically, there is<br />

no inherent conflict between trade and<br />

environment (Ripetto,1994). <strong>The</strong>y admit<br />

that environmental issues are negative externalities<br />

and the same can be internalized<br />

through appropriate policies such as<br />

“Polluter Pays Principle” (PPP). But, the<br />

environmentalists are concerned about<br />

the depletion of these resources due to<br />

unsustainable extraction. If they are unable<br />

to influence the countries that permit<br />

extraction of such resources, they can request/lobbey<br />

for impose regulation of the<br />

products and services in the leading markets<br />

it reaches/ importing countries. Such<br />

regulations can be in the form of certification,<br />

labeling or other environmental<br />

standards. This in turn can be challenged<br />

by the affected countries as environmental<br />

non-tariff barriers are targeted to distort<br />

their international trade. <strong>The</strong>refore, these<br />

measures are applied voluntarily in most<br />

cases. <strong>The</strong> success of these measures is<br />

dependant on the ability to develop techniques<br />

or approaches for sustainable use<br />

of these resources with the active participation<br />

of all stake holders. Forest Stewardship<br />

Council (FSC) certification is an<br />

example for sustainable and resourceful<br />

usage of timber and other forest products.<br />

Presently, in India, these novel approaches<br />

are yet to gain popularity.<br />

What Options Are Available?<br />

Several options are available to minimize<br />

the ecological footprint and enhance the<br />

bio-capacity. This include appropriate<br />

population policy enabling slowing down<br />

the population growth and providing incentives<br />

for those opting for fewer children.<br />

Promotion of policies and programmes<br />

that can influence changes in<br />

consumption patterns at all levels. It is<br />

recgonised that people living below subsistence<br />

need to increase their consumption<br />

to reach out of poverty, others can<br />

reduce consumption and lavish life style.<br />

<strong>The</strong> quantity of resources used in the production<br />

of goods and services can be reduced.<br />

This can be achieved through energy<br />

efficiency; minimizing waste;<br />

increasing recycling and reuse, use of fuel<br />

efficient transportation systems; reduction<br />

in transportation of goods and services;<br />

technical innovation; Technologies<br />

need to be promoted to increase productivity.<br />

Biocapacity can be enhanced<br />

through implementation of environmentally<br />

sound land management, effective<br />

use of marginal lands, promotion of agricultural<br />

technologies; protecting soil from<br />

erosion. Several options, including carbon<br />

markets are available for prevention<br />

and mitigation of climate change issues.<br />

Inappropriate use of chemicals can degrade<br />

ecosystems and loss of biodiversity.<br />

To address this, organic farming need to<br />

be promoted. Business and Industry<br />

should adopt environmentally credible<br />

procurement policies to minimize their<br />

footprint. For this, several voluntary certification<br />

schemes, such as forest certification<br />

are available. <strong>The</strong> approach to the<br />

11 th plan has rightly suggested that environmental<br />

issues cannot be addressed by<br />

slowing economic growth in India. Rather,<br />

high economic growth can provide the<br />

resources to prevent and deal with environmental<br />

issues.<br />

References<br />

• FSI (2005) State of forest report-2003,<br />

Forest survey of India, Dehra Dun<br />

• Haripriya Gundimeda, Sanjeev Sanyal,<br />

Rajiv Sinha and Pavan Sukhdev<br />

(2005) Estimating the value of<br />

agricultural cropland and pastureland<br />

in India, Green Accounting for<br />

Indian States Project-(GIST),<br />

(monograph-)Chennai<br />

• Ripetto, R (1994) Trade and Sustainable<br />

Development, United Nations Environment<br />

Programme, Nairobi<br />

• Planning Commission (2006) Towards<br />

more faster and more inclusive growth-<br />

An approach to the 11 th Five Year Plan,<br />

Planning Commission, Govt. of India<br />

• (1998) Looking Back to <strong>Think</strong> Ahead-<br />

Green India-2047, Tata Energy Research<br />

Institute, New Delhi.<br />

• UNEP (<strong>2007</strong>) Global Environment<br />

Outlook-4, Environment and Development,<br />

United Nations Environment<br />

Programme, Nairobi.<br />

• Verma, D D, S Arora and R K Rai<br />

(Eds) (<strong>2007</strong>); 'Perspectives on biodiversity-<br />

A vision for mega diverse countries',<br />

Ministry of Environment and<br />

Forests (MoEF), Government of India,<br />

New Delhi.<br />

• WWF (2006) Living Planet Report-<br />

2006, WWF-International, Gland<br />

• World Bank (<strong>2007</strong>) Strengthening Institutions<br />

for Sustainable Growth,<br />

Country environment analysis for India,<br />

<strong>The</strong> World Bank (India Country<br />

Office), New Delhi.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

167


Shubha Ghosh<br />

Professor of Law<br />

SMU Dedman School of Law<br />

Dallas, Texas USA<br />

<strong>The</strong> First Sale Doctrine Before <strong>The</strong> U.S. Supreme Court:<br />

Intellectual Property Implications For India<br />

"Bad laws are the worst sort<br />

of tyranny."<br />

-Edmund Burke<br />

<strong>The</strong> United States Supreme<br />

Court will be hearing oral arguments<br />

in a case called Quanta<br />

Computers v. LG Electronics in<br />

January, 2008. At issue in the case is<br />

the status of the first sale doctrine in<br />

light of recent decisions by the United<br />

States Court of Appeals for the Federal<br />

Circuit, the intermediate appeals court<br />

for the review of claims under patent<br />

law. <strong>The</strong> Federal Circuit has created a<br />

doctrine called the conditional sale<br />

doctrine which allows patent owners to<br />

impose conditions on the sale of license<br />

of a patented invention which limits the<br />

application of the first sale doctrine.<br />

<strong>The</strong> following is a summary of an argument<br />

from a brief that I submitted on<br />

behalf of the American Antitrust Institute<br />

that supports Quanta’s position in<br />

the case. Although resolving issues of<br />

U.S. law, the outcome of this case has<br />

important implications for the development<br />

of intellectual property law globally<br />

and in India.<br />

For over a century and a half, the first<br />

sale doctrine (also known as the exhaustion<br />

doctrine) has provided certainty<br />

for users, manufacturers and<br />

other business entities in the distribution<br />

of goods and services protected by<br />

intellectual property law. Patent and<br />

copyright law grants to inventors and<br />

authors limited rights to control the distribution<br />

of the products of their creativity.<br />

However, the first sale doctrine<br />

creates a bright-line rule that ensures<br />

that purchasers of these works can further<br />

transfer these items to third parties<br />

without the interference of the original<br />

intellectual property owners. In this<br />

way, the first sale promotes an active<br />

and vibrant marketplace for works created<br />

through the benefit of patent and<br />

copyright and therefore is integral to<br />

the goals of innovation and competition<br />

that are at the foundation of the system<br />

of intellectual property rights. <strong>The</strong><br />

doctrine of conditional sale, as articulated<br />

and applied by the United States<br />

168 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


LAW AND PUBLIC POLICY<br />

Court of Appeals for the Federal circuit,<br />

allows patent owners to circumvent<br />

the first sale doctrine and undermine<br />

its beneficial policies, and is inconsistent<br />

with this Court’s precedent.<br />

Given the intangibility and nonrivalrous<br />

characteristic of intellectual property<br />

rights, formal legal titling systems<br />

cannot readily be created to ensure that<br />

such works can be transferred without<br />

being at the sufferance of the original<br />

patent or copyright owner. <strong>The</strong> first<br />

sale doctrine serves the function of a<br />

formal legal titling system for intellectual<br />

property. Under the first sale doctrine,<br />

a patent or copyright owner exhausts<br />

her distribution right upon the<br />

first sale of the protected work thereby<br />

allowing subsequent purchasers to further<br />

transfer the work. <strong>The</strong> doctrine<br />

requires that the intellectual property<br />

owner obtain its consideration in the<br />

first sale (or license to sell), before allowing<br />

the distribution of a product<br />

embodying its intellectual property into<br />

the stream of commerce. In this way, it<br />

allows for active and vibrant markets<br />

for works of art, for novels, for movies,<br />

for innovative gadgets containing patented<br />

inventions, and for technology<br />

itself. <strong>The</strong> doctrine provides the legal<br />

foundation for primary markets, for<br />

secondary markets for rentals of these<br />

types of works, and for credit markets<br />

in which copyright and patents can<br />

serve as security interests. Absent the<br />

first sale doctrine, business people engaged<br />

in the buying and selling of works<br />

that are either directly protected by intellectual<br />

property or contain components<br />

protected by intellectual property<br />

may be required to compensate the<br />

original intellectual property owner<br />

whenever a transfer of interest in the<br />

work occurs. And purchasers of such<br />

works would always take title subject to<br />

the claims of the original intellectual<br />

property owner, perhaps unaware of<br />

such claims. Such actual or potential<br />

interference from the original creator<br />

would only serve to raise transaction<br />

costs and to create impediments to free<br />

and open markets.<br />

Starting with its decision in Mallinckrodt,<br />

Inc. v. Medipart, Inc., 976 F.2d<br />

700 (Fed. Cir. 1992), the Federal Circuit<br />

has misconstrued this Court’s precedent<br />

to permit a patent owner that<br />

“conditions” the sale of a patented invention<br />

to sue subsequent purchasers<br />

who violate the condition for patent infringement.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Federal Circuit’s justification<br />

for the conditional sale doctrine<br />

rests on a misunderstanding of the<br />

relationship between the transfer of<br />

works protected by intellectual property<br />

rights and conditions attendant in<br />

contracts that accompany such a transfer.<br />

While purporting to rely on contract<br />

principles, the Federal Circuit has<br />

converted restrictions ancillary to the<br />

transfer of a patented invention from<br />

contractual rights, subject to the scrutiny<br />

under relevant contract, antitrust,<br />

and patent law, to intellectual property<br />

rights enforceable through a claim for<br />

patent infringement, with its attendant<br />

panoply of remedies and potential immunity<br />

from antitrust scrutiny. Because<br />

the Federal Circuit’s conditional sale<br />

doctrine allows a patent owner to expand<br />

the reach of its patent grant and<br />

disrupt free and open markets, it should<br />

be reversed.<br />

In the case at bar, respondent’s licensee<br />

has sold an article that “embodies<br />

essential features” of the patented<br />

invention and “has destined the article<br />

to be finished by the purchaser in conformity<br />

to the patent.” Respondent<br />

acquired a large patent portfolio of<br />

technologies used in the manufacture<br />

of computer chips. After a dispute with<br />

Intel, the chip manufacturer, respondent<br />

entered into a complex licensing<br />

agreement with Intel that allowed Intel<br />

to use the technology in the construction<br />

and sale of chips. <strong>The</strong>se chips in<br />

turn were sold to petitioners and incorporated<br />

as components in computer<br />

hardware systems. <strong>The</strong> LG-Intel license<br />

agreement contained a proviso<br />

that no license was granted to any third<br />

party to combine the chips with non-<br />

Intel products, and that Intel was re-<br />

<strong>The</strong> first sale doctrine creates a bright-line rule that ensures<br />

that purchasers of the creative works can further<br />

transfer these items to third parties without the interference<br />

of the original intellectual property owners<br />

quired to and did provide notice of this<br />

limitation to petitioners. See LG Electronics,<br />

Inc. v. Bizcom Electronics, Inc.,<br />

453 F.3d 1364, 1368 (Fed. Cir. 2006).<br />

But the license agreement also stipulated<br />

that it would not “limit or alter the<br />

effect of patent exhaustion that otherwise<br />

would apply when” the chips were<br />

sold, the notice received by petitioners<br />

was apparently sent after many of the<br />

sales had already occurred, and the<br />

chips had no other reasonable use. See<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

169


A NEW BEGINNING<br />

Brief for Petitioners 2, 8-9. Now, respondent<br />

seeks to enforce its patent<br />

rights against the petitioners based on<br />

their alleged violation of “conditions”<br />

placed on the original agreement with<br />

Intel. <strong>The</strong> first sale doctrine was designed<br />

to prohibit precisely this type of<br />

reach-through by the patent owner to<br />

enforce its patent rights. Under this<br />

Court’s precedents, once the petitioners<br />

purchased products embodying essential<br />

features of the patented invention<br />

in an authorized sale, respondent’s<br />

patent rights were exhausted. If the<br />

conditions placed in the license with<br />

Intel are consistent with contract law,<br />

antitrust law, and the patent misuse<br />

doctrine, then any violations can be enforced<br />

against Intel as contract claims<br />

(or possibly against the petitioners as<br />

third party contract claims), rather than<br />

patent infringement claims with the attendant<br />

remedies of injunctive relief,<br />

treble damages, and attorneys’ fees.<br />

Such a result is consistent with the need<br />

for certainty and competitiveness of not<br />

only this market transaction, but also<br />

the wide ranges of market transactions<br />

that rest on intellectual property. In<br />

eBay Inc. v. Mercexchange, L.L.C., 126<br />

S.Ct. 1837 (2006), a plurality of the<br />

Court was concerned about the development<br />

of an industry “in which firms<br />

use patents not as a basis for producing<br />

and selling goods but, instead, primarily<br />

for obtaining licensing fees”, and the<br />

potentially harmful effects of injunctive<br />

relief “[w]hen the patented invention is<br />

but a small component of the product<br />

the companies seek to produce….” Id.<br />

at 1842 (Kennedy, J., concurring). <strong>The</strong><br />

In future cases, Indian High Courts could look to procompetition<br />

decisions in the United States, such as eBay<br />

and perhaps Quanta, to recognize that the need for competition<br />

balances the need for intellectual property rights<br />

first sale doctrine plays a role in preventing<br />

similar market disruption, as<br />

here, when a non-manufacturing patentee<br />

seeks to control the manufacture of<br />

end products in which the patented item<br />

is but a small component.<br />

<strong>The</strong> United States Supreme Court’s<br />

resolution of the Quanta case has implications<br />

globally. By abrogating the<br />

conditional sale doctrine, the Court will<br />

be affirming the bedrock principle of<br />

the first sale doctrine. More importantly,<br />

it will be recognizing competitive<br />

values in intellectual property law.<br />

Such a result is imperative for countries<br />

like India that are reforming intellectual<br />

property law and institutions. As<br />

the recent dispute brought by Novartis<br />

over the patentability of Gleevak shows,<br />

intellectual property norms are still being<br />

debated locally. <strong>The</strong> Quanta case<br />

shows that these norms are global. If<br />

the first sale doctrine is affirmed, then<br />

competition becomes an important normative<br />

goal for the design of intellectual<br />

property systems. India will have<br />

a strong position in asserting the values<br />

of competition as a limit on patent and<br />

other intellectual property rights.<br />

More subtly, if the Supreme Court<br />

strikes down the conditional sale doctrine,<br />

the Court will be placing some<br />

limits on the power of the Federal Circuit,<br />

the specialized patent appellate<br />

court in the United States. <strong>The</strong> Court<br />

will be implicitly saying that despite its<br />

expertise in patent law, the Federal Circuit<br />

cannot alter through the creation<br />

of new rules, like the conditional sale<br />

doctrine, that counter established principles<br />

of competition law and policy,<br />

like the first sale doctrine. In the Novartis<br />

dispute, the High Court of Chennai<br />

deferred to the Indian patent office<br />

and left open the standard for innovation<br />

in the pharmaceutical industry. In<br />

future cases, Indian High Courts could<br />

look to pro-competition decisions in the<br />

United States, such as eBay and perhaps<br />

Quanta, to recognize that the need for<br />

competition balances the need for intellectual<br />

property rights. As discussion<br />

in this essay suggests, intellectual property<br />

rights and competition together are<br />

both important for innovation.<br />

In conclusion, a business dispute over<br />

a patent license is the basis for the dispute<br />

in Quanta. But at stake is a bedrock<br />

principle of law, the first sale doctrine,<br />

and the relationship between<br />

competition norms and intellectual<br />

property law. <strong>The</strong> Supreme Court’s<br />

decision in the case should be closely<br />

watched for what it implies for international<br />

intellectual property law.<br />

170 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


Ali Mehdi,<br />

Research Associate,<br />

Indian Council for Research on International<br />

Economic Relations (ICRIER), New Delhi<br />

Liberty And Prohibition:<br />

A Governance Dilemma<br />

"I don't make jokes. I just<br />

watch the government and<br />

report the facts."<br />

-Will Rogers<br />

<strong>The</strong> Excise department of the<br />

Delhi government is, self-professedly,<br />

the second largest<br />

revenue earning department of the<br />

state. It generated Rs. 6190 crores as<br />

liquor revenue between 1994-95 and<br />

2004-05, while targeting an all-time<br />

high of Rs.900 crores for 2005-06. <strong>The</strong><br />

department’s website boasts that the<br />

success of the government is reflected<br />

in its ever-increasing revenue collection<br />

through liquor sales, which<br />

reached 15.3 crore bottles in 2002-03<br />

from 6.4 crore bottles in 1994-95. Most<br />

of the retail liquor trade in Delhi is<br />

done by four government agencies---<br />

Delhi Tourism and Transportation<br />

Development Corporation (DTTDC),<br />

<strong>The</strong> Delhi State Civil Supplies Corporation<br />

(DSCSC), Delhi State Industrial<br />

Development Corporation<br />

(DSIDC) and Delhi Consumer Co-operative<br />

Wholesale Store Limited (DC-<br />

CWS) through 309 shops. Private entrepreneurs<br />

hold 95 shops, and two<br />

L-53 licenses for retail sale through<br />

departmental stores for “off-site” consumption<br />

have been granted.<br />

Within the same Delhi government,<br />

there is the Directorate of Prohibition<br />

which vows by Article 47 of the Constitution<br />

and Mahatma gandhi, the Father<br />

of the Nation, claiming that<br />

“drinking in the society has ominous<br />

implications and weakens the entire<br />

social structure by disrupting the institution<br />

of the family and the country<br />

and also distorts the priorities of the<br />

development process.” While the Excise<br />

department is committed to “making<br />

safe liquor available to the consumers,”<br />

the Directorate of Prohibition<br />

tries “to promote healthy living among<br />

the citizens of Delhi by educating them<br />

regarding the ill effects of liquor and<br />

drug abuse and on the damage caused<br />

by the substances of abuse to the society<br />

and to the physical, psychological,<br />

social, economic and occupational life<br />

of an individual.”<br />

Starting as a cell in the Directorate<br />

of Information & Publicity in 1978-79,<br />

172 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


SOTTO VOCE<br />

the Directorate of Prohibition has<br />

been organizing fairs/melas, nukkar<br />

nataks, magic programmes, short films,<br />

and propaganda through kiosks,<br />

hoardings, backlit pillars, banners, bus<br />

back panels/queue shelters, computer<br />

animation display systems, seminars<br />

and conferences, personality development<br />

programmes, adventure activities,<br />

youth camps in collaboration with<br />

voluntary organizations. It has a staff<br />

of 21 employees (2005), a budget allocation<br />

of Rs. 1.7 crores for 2006-07,<br />

and has spent almost Rs. 8 crores in 7<br />

years (between 1997-98 and 2004-05).<br />

73.4 percent of the expenditure went as<br />

‘other charges', 10.2 percent into salaries,<br />

6.9 percent into strengthening of<br />

the department, and 9.1 percent in actual<br />

advertisement & publicity. All this<br />

to convey the message, which is mentioned<br />

as the last point in the Do’s &<br />

Don’ts list of the Excise department:<br />

“Consumption of liquor is injurious to<br />

health.” According to a survey conducted<br />

in 2002 by the Evaluation Unit<br />

of Planning department, 92 percent of<br />

those who consumed liquor were aware<br />

of its ill-effects, while 30 percent had<br />

reduced consumption due to Directorate’s<br />

publicity, doctor’s advise, social<br />

compulsion and financial difficulties.<br />

Starting with the name of the Directorate<br />

itself, there is no more “Prohibition”<br />

(as it refers officially to a restriction<br />

or ban on manufacture, import,<br />

export and sale of liquor) in Delhi. Appraisal<br />

of the Annual Plan 2004-05 by<br />

Planning department says that the<br />

functional utility and role of departments/undertakings<br />

like the Directorate<br />

of Prohibition needs to be assessed<br />

in view of “the changed scenario.” At<br />

a time when liquor sector has been liberalized<br />

by the state government,<br />

where is the moral/technical justification<br />

for Directorate of Prohibition?<br />

Alcohol consumption has increased<br />

over the years, but who is reaping the<br />

benefits of it? <strong>The</strong> government itself,<br />

through its Excise department and infact,<br />

more than the so-called “liquor<br />

mafia.” <strong>The</strong> government should think<br />

clear and decide what it needs: revenues<br />

or Gandhigiri?<br />

More importantly, by the Directorate’s<br />

own admission, in course of addressing<br />

the reasons for alcohol intake,<br />

the will power of the consumer, love<br />

and affection by people close to him/<br />

her, motivate a consumer to reduce/<br />

give up alcohol consumption (Annual<br />

Report 2001-2002). Is the Directorate<br />

capable of any of these? By all measures,<br />

not in the least. Institutionally,<br />

de-addiction centers would be more<br />

helpful. But the Directorate has none.<br />

If information dissemination is the<br />

aim, civil society does take care of that,<br />

and newspapers do publish newer research<br />

on health issues as well as on<br />

While the Excise department is committed to “making safe<br />

liquor available to the consumers,” the Directorate of Prohibition<br />

tries “to promote healthy living among the citizens<br />

of Delhi by educating the ill effects of liquor!<br />

alcohol consumption (<strong>The</strong> Times of<br />

India, New Delhi, <strong>Dec</strong>ember 29, 2006).<br />

And they are probably much more effective<br />

owing to their wide reach. If the<br />

government still insists, it could either<br />

remould the Directorate to the status<br />

of a cell within Directorate of Information<br />

& Publicity. This in my opinion,<br />

makes good economic sense. Alternatively,<br />

it can outsource publicity to an<br />

ad vertising agency, as it has undertaken<br />

in the case of ‘India Shining’<br />

campaign. People will vote in its favour.<br />

Widening the debate, and with<br />

far-reaching consequences, let us ask<br />

if the government, especially in a pluralistic<br />

country like India, should be<br />

involved with moral issues of either individual<br />

or social import? Claiming<br />

that alcohol consumption “weakens<br />

the entire social structure” and “distorts<br />

the priorities of the development<br />

process” is too far-fetched to be discussed<br />

seriously. <strong>The</strong> moral argument<br />

touches upon individual and community<br />

rights, and the freedom that is or<br />

should be available to them. As a<br />

staunch advocate of individual choice,<br />

I am in favour of letting the individuals<br />

decide for themselves, without making<br />

value-judgments or taking subjective<br />

decisions, to the extent that their actions<br />

do not hurt others or the system.<br />

Making drunk driving illegal is fine,<br />

but the invasion of moral spaces in a<br />

secular state like India is extremely<br />

‘disenchanting.’<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

173


Baharul Islam<br />

Chairman & CEO, South Asia Development<br />

Gateway, & Member, High Power Committee on<br />

International Cooperation,<br />

Government of Mizoram<br />

An Alternative Integrated Development Perspective For <strong>The</strong><br />

Peripheral Regions: <strong>The</strong> Case Of Barak Valley In Northeast India<br />

"Make no little plans; they<br />

have no magic to stir men's<br />

blood...Make big plans, aim<br />

high in hope and work."<br />

-Daniel H. Burnham<br />

Background<br />

It is a legitimate desire for any region like<br />

Barak Valley in Assam (specifically Cachar,<br />

Karimganj & Hailakandi districts) to<br />

mobilize its intellectual resources and<br />

technical expertise including those in the<br />

diasporas, to plan for growth, equity and<br />

economic development. At the dawn of the<br />

third millennium various regions and communities<br />

around the world have weathered<br />

the storm of economic and social crises<br />

that have been the order of the day ever<br />

since the mid seventies. However, due<br />

many reasons, social, political and economic,<br />

Barak Valley region doesn’t have<br />

any such perspective plan. Sons and daughters<br />

of the valley who hold various high<br />

professional positions in India and abroad<br />

often feel a deep urge to work for the development<br />

of the area but in the absence<br />

of any institutional civil society platform,<br />

such desires remain isolated. Looking<br />

ahead into the coming century, it is with<br />

great optimism that some groups of people<br />

from the valley have started to think of<br />

breaking down the developmental processes<br />

into discrete but technically feasible<br />

objectives, the pronouncements-cum-mission<br />

objectives of an integrated socio-economic<br />

development plan for the valley.<br />

<strong>The</strong> South Asia Development Gateway<br />

early <strong>2007</strong>, undertook a mission to incorporate<br />

an Integrated Development Plan<br />

(IDP) for this region. It is to elaborate,<br />

propose and initiate such an exercise within<br />

the civil society and research platforms<br />

such as India Economy Review (IER), I<br />

take this opportunity to put forward some<br />

of the potential plans that we can put together<br />

to develop the region. A sweeping<br />

look at the objectives of various national<br />

plans like Vision 2020 around the world<br />

may give a critical insight into how such<br />

plans are formulated nationally in the strategic<br />

sense: they were measured against<br />

the background of the present situation,<br />

and strategies were designed to attain the<br />

national goals. Despite its constraints,<br />

Barak Valley has a lot more opportunities<br />

than we usually bother to decipher and<br />

indeed, rapid economic growth can only<br />

be achieved if our aspiration gap incites a<br />

174 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE OTHER PATH<br />

proper management of our technical, financial<br />

and human resources. True, these<br />

resources alone would not suffice, and as<br />

such we have to be very vigilant on those<br />

necessary institutional reforms without<br />

which the transformation of these resources<br />

into socio-economic development<br />

achievements will not be attained.<br />

Development Paradigm<br />

Development is all about people, how they<br />

live their daily lives, how they attain selfrealization<br />

and how they improve on their<br />

living standards. <strong>The</strong> preliminary work<br />

from which an Integrated Regional Development<br />

Plan emanates is through discussions<br />

at all levels of society, the plan can<br />

therefore validly be said to represent the<br />

aspirations of the local people. This article<br />

covers some of those critical developmental<br />

sectors for Barak Valley that are capable<br />

of showing the most leverage on our<br />

endeavor to improve our position on the<br />

collective income ladder. It is diagnosed<br />

that agriculture, which is presently the<br />

dominant activity in our economy, will<br />

need continuous appraisal of the existing<br />

farming systems and technologies. Effective<br />

research and development within the<br />

framework of local agricultural activities<br />

will enhance productivity and improve on<br />

the quality of farm output. As a corollary<br />

to improvements in farming, a proper marketing<br />

strategy for farm output is needed<br />

to translate these into income. In view of<br />

the subsumed financial resources for this<br />

strategy, it is prescribed that new institutional<br />

arrangements be forged to improve<br />

on financing agribusiness activity through<br />

the establishment of specialized financial<br />

institutions. Although industrial activity<br />

is, as yet, at an early stage of development<br />

in our area, or almost absent in general, it<br />

is common knowledge that this type of<br />

activity has a great leverage on income and<br />

social status in the development process.<br />

Rapid industrialization is perceived to signify<br />

an increase in the population of industrial<br />

units, a quality improvement in output<br />

as well as a geographical expansion of the<br />

market for industrial output.<br />

Looking at the constraints of these specific<br />

objectives, we recommend the adoption<br />

of improved monetary and fiscal<br />

policies that will enhance the mobilization<br />

of savings and facilitate their transfer to<br />

this sector, the targeting of industries<br />

whose technologies are easily assimilated<br />

by the present workforce, the designing of<br />

policies and building of institutions at local<br />

level that will reduce the mortality rate<br />

of the start-ups and spin-offs for all direct<br />

investments and a spatial distribution of<br />

industry in order to curb the rural-urban<br />

drift. Strategies for the main productive<br />

sectors, namely Agriculture and Industry,<br />

have been well articulated with strategies<br />

for the service industries in various states<br />

and regions of the country. Smaller areas,<br />

for instance Guna district in Madhya<br />

Pradesh, have also put in place such perspective<br />

plan but with so much intellectual<br />

and technical expertise belonging to<br />

Barak Valley, no such plan has been<br />

formed till date. <strong>The</strong> financial sector,<br />

transport sectors as well as the energy and<br />

industry sectors, have been examined in<br />

light of the ultimate objective of such a<br />

plan, namely the transformation of the<br />

Barak Valley into a prosperous region by<br />

the end of the first quarter of the this century.<br />

In an integrated development plan<br />

for the area, the social sectors should be<br />

given the prominence they deserve.<br />

Health, Education and other Social services<br />

form essential pillars of Human Capital<br />

development. Without a coherent and<br />

consistent Human Resource Development<br />

(HRD) strategy, “a decent standard of living<br />

for one and all” as aspired by the people<br />

of the valley today would not be attained.<br />

Finally, perhaps a word of caution<br />

will help dissipate some concerns that people<br />

here and there, may evoke on important<br />

matters not featuring in the document.<br />

<strong>The</strong> idea of presenting a possible<br />

integrated development plan for Barak<br />

Valley is a specific developmental perspective<br />

and as such constitutional and other<br />

legal matters are best dealt with outside<br />

such a document that proposes to be blue<br />

print for guiding economic and social<br />

policy formulation, implementation and<br />

Resources alone would not suffi ce, and we have to be<br />

vigilant on the necessary institutional reforms, without<br />

which the transformation of these resources into socioeconomic<br />

development achievements will not be attained<br />

monitoring. Implementation strategies do<br />

not also feature in this document but are<br />

already under discussion as to the optimal<br />

strategies and monitoring arrangements.<br />

In order to pilot such an district level integrated<br />

plan, Karimganj district administration<br />

in collaboration with the South<br />

Asia Development Gateway has formed a<br />

District Level Integrated Development<br />

Committee under the Chairmanship of<br />

the local Deputy Commissioner (Collector)<br />

and an expert from the UN Economic<br />

Commission for Asia (Bangkok) will<br />

visit the district in late <strong>Dec</strong>ember, <strong>2007</strong> to<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

175


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

have a detailed consultation with the stakeholders.<br />

Barak Valley Contexts<br />

An Integrated Development Plan for any<br />

area comprises three inter-related documents,<br />

namely:<br />

(1) A Policy Framework Paper (PFP)<br />

that spells out the strategic thrust, the<br />

strategy content and the budgetary and<br />

institutional framework within which various<br />

projects and programmes will configure,<br />

explicitly linking the region to the<br />

national Vision 2020;<br />

(2) <strong>The</strong> Operational Framework of the<br />

area Development Strategy which takes<br />

the form of a Medium Term Expenditure<br />

Framework (MTEF). <strong>The</strong> MTEF is linked<br />

to the Macroeconomic Growth Strategy<br />

through the PFP, the latter reflecting the<br />

objectives of national Vision 2020; and,<br />

(3) <strong>The</strong> Action Plan for the target area,<br />

which highlights the Implementation Strategy,<br />

the Participatory Plan and the organizational<br />

setting within which strategic<br />

action is implemented, monitored and<br />

evaluated.<br />

<strong>The</strong> integrated development plan, as opposed<br />

to the state or country level plans, is<br />

intended to be a comprehensive “local development<br />

framework” that links macroeconomic<br />

growth with poverty reduction<br />

strategies. <strong>The</strong> objective of the plan is to<br />

ensure greater focus on poverty reduction<br />

through generating employment avenues<br />

and renewed emphasis on faster job-sector<br />

growth within the valley outside the traditional<br />

‘government job syndrome’ that ails<br />

the mindset of the potential workforce in<br />

the valley. It is essentially a prerequisite<br />

for sustainable development efforts in the<br />

valley to change that mindset and build an<br />

‘employable workforce’ out of the thousands<br />

of ‘degree-holding but unemployable’<br />

manpower that exist today in the<br />

region.<br />

<strong>The</strong> integrated development plan is to<br />

serve as the first building block for opera-<br />

<strong>The</strong> integrated development plan serve as the first building<br />

block for operationalizing an overall development mission<br />

that is locale-specifi c, based on the aspirations of the local<br />

people and don't follow the ‘trickle-down approach<br />

tionalizing an overall development mission<br />

that is locale-specific, based on the aspirations<br />

of the local people and do not necessarily<br />

follow the ‘trickle-down residual<br />

flow approach’ of development. All the<br />

proposed development projects and programmes<br />

financed by government, international<br />

development partners, NGOs,<br />

civil society will be implemented within<br />

this framework of the plan. <strong>The</strong> rationale<br />

is to move away from the prevailing peacemeal<br />

project approach in the development<br />

process and to give a road-map for the region<br />

that will be a reference point in formulating<br />

programmes/projects to ensure<br />

maximum impact and focus on priorities.<br />

It essentially calls for a more efficient use<br />

of local (in country) and external resources<br />

in support of the ultimate goal of economic<br />

development. <strong>The</strong> essential feature<br />

of the Barak Valley Integrated Development<br />

Plan is that it is locally owned implying<br />

that it reflects the needs of the people<br />

whose interests are being attended.<br />

An important element of the process is<br />

monitoring and evaluation. This entails<br />

the establishment of benchmarks of performance<br />

indicators by all the sectors in<br />

the implementation of the plan which will<br />

facilitate the measurement of progress towards<br />

the achievement of targets.<br />

Targets And Programme Areas<br />

In line with the international development<br />

goals, a Barak Valley Integrated Development<br />

Plan (BVIDP) will be in tandem with<br />

national and international efforts towards<br />

the achievement of poverty reduction targets,<br />

such as:<br />

• A reduction by one-half of the unemployed<br />

population in the valley.<br />

• Enforced Universal “employable lifeskill”<br />

Education in<br />

• Equality and empowerment of women<br />

by eliminating gender disparities<br />

• Access through the primary health care<br />

system, to reproductive health services<br />

for all people of appropriate ages as<br />

soon as possible<br />

• <strong>The</strong> implementation of a regional strategy<br />

for sustainable development so as to<br />

ensure that current trends in the loss of<br />

environmental resources are effectively<br />

reversed<br />

• Creation of economic opportunities for<br />

the poor in order to substantially reduce<br />

income and food poverty and the general<br />

feeling of insecurity related to food<br />

176 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE OTHER PATH<br />

and income poverty; and,<br />

• Development of a full fledged participatory<br />

government based on the consent<br />

of the citizenry and a strong social-audit<br />

system.<br />

<strong>The</strong> programme areas in the BVIDP<br />

will include macroeconomic growth strategy,<br />

income generating activities, re-distributive<br />

activities, social service delivery,<br />

food security, improving public resource<br />

management, creation of an accounting<br />

framework for poverty reduction interventions,<br />

improving participation in local decision<br />

making, coordination and monitoring<br />

and information, education and<br />

communication.<br />

Integrated Development Plan<br />

Process(es)<br />

Orissa and Madhya Pradesh were among<br />

the few Indian states that reiterated its<br />

commitment to a region-specific Integrated<br />

Development Plan process thus acknowledging<br />

the truism that growth and<br />

pro-poor policies have to focus on the<br />

needs and circumstances of the particular<br />

area. South Asia Development Gateway,<br />

as indicated earlier, initiated the formulation<br />

of such plans in the Northeastern region<br />

starting with Mizoram (state level)<br />

and Karimganj (District level) in Assam.<br />

It was agreed that in view of the multi sectoral<br />

nature of development, a task force<br />

or core committee be formed consisting of<br />

all key decision makers at the highest level<br />

in government sectors and donor representatives.<br />

A technical working group<br />

comprising the concerned departments<br />

was also constituted where necessary. This<br />

group held several consultations and subsequently<br />

United Nations Economic &<br />

Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific<br />

(UNESCAP), Bangkok agreed that<br />

it will assist the pilot programme in the<br />

target levels to develop the Integrated Development<br />

Plans. Accordingly, a senior<br />

UN Regional Advisor will visit the areas.<br />

An expert review of all relevant development<br />

data and surveys will be conducted<br />

first and a draft outline of the plan will be<br />

prepared which will be used as a basis for<br />

starting the process.<br />

Though the Government of Assam was<br />

approached at the very beginning of the<br />

exercise in <strong>Dec</strong>ember 2006, there was no<br />

positive response from the government<br />

departments and even the special requests<br />

from a central minister were found missing<br />

in the secretariat. In the mean time, states<br />

like Mizoram and autonomous regions<br />

like Bodoland shown tremendous interest<br />

in cooperating with international agencies<br />

to develop such plans. <strong>The</strong> Chief Minister<br />

of Mizoram, himself chairs the High Power<br />

Committee formed for this purpose.<br />

However, in the District of Karimganj, the<br />

Deputy Commissioner and specially the<br />

Additional Deputy Commissioner (Development)<br />

took special interest in formulating<br />

such a plan. In a recently conducted<br />

meeting, Prof.S. P. Parashar, the Director<br />

of IIM, Indore, has agreed to help the district<br />

in formalizing such a development<br />

plan and implement it, after following the<br />

Guna (Madhya Pradesh) model.<br />

Ongoing Activities<br />

Ongoing activities include a review of the<br />

objectives and strategies of the integrated<br />

development programme with a view to<br />

identifying tangible activities for achieving<br />

the said objectives. <strong>The</strong>se objectives have<br />

been identified during the participatory<br />

process. <strong>The</strong> programme is being designed<br />

to address cross cutting issues such as gender<br />

and environment. In addition, performance<br />

indicators and benchmarks are<br />

being developed for each of the objectives.<br />

Some of the major areas of activities are<br />

outlined below.<br />

Agriculture And Natural<br />

Resources<br />

Agricultural and Natural Resources<br />

(ANR) is the dominant sector in Barak<br />

Valley’s economy, employing the majority<br />

of the total work force. Notwithstanding,<br />

ANR continues to lag behind in productivity<br />

and modernization and is still characterized<br />

by an undiversified primary agricultural<br />

system. It is also conditioned by a<br />

seemingly unbreakable cycle of erratic inadequate<br />

input supplies, inappropriate<br />

technology, low output and productivity<br />

Agricultural and Natural Resources continues to lag behind<br />

in productivity and modernization and is still characterized<br />

by an undiversifi ed primary agricultural system<br />

growth, low incomes and an acute inability<br />

to generate savings for investment.<br />

While some of the constraints are exogenous,<br />

many are occasioned by human deficiencies<br />

and failures. ANR continues to<br />

lack a local policy focus and the political<br />

will necessary to transform the sector.<br />

Progress into next two decades will call for<br />

substantial improvements in the sector’s<br />

output and linkage to the sectors. In particular,<br />

overall productivity will have to<br />

improve significantly.<br />

Improvements in the ANR sector therefore<br />

call for serious examination and setting<br />

of projects that are both realistic and<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

177


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

attainable in the medium to long term.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se improvements also require an unfailing<br />

commitment and dedication to the<br />

pursuit of the objectives to ensure balanced<br />

growth and an equitable distribution<br />

of incomes. <strong>The</strong> more important objectives<br />

for the sector are, among others,<br />

to:<br />

1. Increase ANR output of both domestic<br />

and exports produce in order to ensure<br />

food security and generate earnings of<br />

foreign exchange to finance other aspects<br />

of the development process.<br />

2. Create employment and generate income<br />

for the majority of the rural population<br />

who are largely dependent on<br />

ANR.<br />

3. Diversify the ANR base to facilitate the<br />

production of a wider range of food and<br />

export produce in order to reduce the<br />

fluctuations and uncertainties associated<br />

with rural household incomes and<br />

export earnings.<br />

4. Formulate a post-flood recovery plan<br />

when devastating floods coming late in<br />

the year (like in <strong>2007</strong>) destroy the crop<br />

in that particular year.<br />

5. Provide effective linkages between ANR<br />

and other sectors of the economy such<br />

that developments in the non-agricultural<br />

sectors, particularly manufacturing<br />

and tourism are founded on a firm<br />

and diversified ANR base capable of<br />

progressively releasing both labour and<br />

financial resources to other sectors of<br />

the economy.<br />

6. Create a sustainable and balanced mix<br />

between rain-fed and irrigated agriculture,<br />

thus ensuring an optimal use of<br />

natural resources of surface and ground<br />

water, animal, aqua-culture and crop<br />

production as well as between chemical<br />

and organic inputs and the use of agricultural<br />

by-products. Improvements in<br />

ANR productivity require a conscious<br />

evaluation of strategies to pursue the<br />

desired objectives. <strong>The</strong> strategies to be<br />

employed will necessarily have focus on<br />

the constraints and opportunities in the<br />

ANR sector.<br />

Industry And Infrastructure<br />

<strong>The</strong> long term aspiration of the people of<br />

the Barak Valley is perceived to achieve a<br />

solid infrastructural base for industrial<br />

Effective linkages between ANR and other sectors<br />

ensure that developments in the non-agricultural sectors,<br />

particularly manufacturing and tourism are founded on<br />

a firm and diversifi ed ANR base<br />

development that would permit the<br />

processing of major primary products by<br />

the year 2020. At present, the industrial<br />

sector is very much limited. <strong>The</strong> following<br />

manufacturing sub-sector will be relied<br />

upon to achieve that objective:<br />

1. Energy<br />

<strong>The</strong> importance of this sector in the realisation<br />

of the objectives of any Integrated<br />

Development Plan cannot be overemphasised.<br />

<strong>The</strong> prime objective for this sector<br />

is to overcome the existing bottlenecks and<br />

to ensure a reliable and adequate supply of<br />

energy, both conventional and renewable,<br />

at affordable prices.<br />

2. Manufacturing<br />

Consistent with the objectives of improving<br />

the income status of the people,<br />

the manufacturing sector will undergo<br />

substantial re-orientation aimed at increasing<br />

and diversifying industrial output.<br />

Specifically, this means realizing a net increase<br />

in the number of industrial units,<br />

greater diversification of industry, greater<br />

employment opportunities and capturing<br />

an established and growing export market.<br />

In this regard, priority will be given to a<br />

smoother technology transfer mechanism,<br />

the encouragement of adaptive research in<br />

production and process technologies and<br />

accelerated training and development of<br />

our human resources. By the next decade,<br />

the share of industry should rise through<br />

the provision of institutional support services<br />

and targeted incentives. A manufacturing<br />

base supplying both the domestic<br />

and export markets will be established in<br />

order to reduce the overt dependence on<br />

Agriculture and Trade. Again, on an unfortunate<br />

note, repeated efforts to establish<br />

a specialized rural technology transfer<br />

institute have been impeded by the Govt.<br />

of Assam. Even after ensuring external<br />

funding and a positive response from the<br />

Govt of India, the state government discouraged<br />

and responded negatively to our<br />

proposal. Though the Cachar district administration<br />

identified suitable land for the<br />

institute and the union minister for heavy<br />

industries personally spoke and written to<br />

the Chief Minister of Assam, the concerned<br />

department refused to give ‘no<br />

objection’ to the project on the pretext that<br />

‘there is no financial liability’ upon the<br />

state government! To overcome this felt<br />

undercurrent of apathy towards the development<br />

of Barak Valley, there is a proposal<br />

to establish a national institute of<br />

manufacturing excellence in Barak Valley,<br />

which inturn will help catalyze the growth<br />

178 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE OTHER PATH<br />

of manufacturing industries in the valley<br />

and train many young people for employment<br />

in this sector.<br />

3. Transport<br />

<strong>The</strong> railway, airport and road and waterway<br />

network will play a crucial role as providers<br />

of efficient infrastructural services.<br />

<strong>The</strong> river port in the valley will be upgraded<br />

and rendered more efficient and competitive<br />

in order to cater adequately for<br />

transhipment needs to countries in the<br />

sub-region. With supporting road and rail<br />

links, the transformation of the border<br />

posts with Bangladesh into a regional trade<br />

‘Freeport’ should herald major investment<br />

opportunities in our local businesses. It is<br />

envisaged that such investments will be effected<br />

through joint-ventures with private<br />

sector partners in a bid to involve operators<br />

in the transformation process. Consequently,<br />

there will be created a local international<br />

trade promotion agency which<br />

will offer an unrivalled fiscal and regulatory<br />

regime as well as infrastructural facilities<br />

in order to accelerate the growth of<br />

our industrial development arena. <strong>The</strong> upgrading<br />

and expansion of the airport is a<br />

major component of the “Barak Valley<br />

Gateway” strategy. <strong>The</strong> multi-modal transport<br />

initiative subsumed in this initiative<br />

is the valley’s spearhead strategy to play a<br />

crucial role in international trade with<br />

neighbouring countries. In this regard,<br />

facilities at the airport will be upgraded<br />

and modernized, security improved to international<br />

standards to handle an increased<br />

passenger and cargo traffic with<br />

an eye to serving as a transit point for East<br />

Asia. <strong>The</strong> development of inland road and<br />

water-way transport networks will focus on<br />

improving connections to regional trading<br />

centres, while offering logistic services<br />

(storage and communications) .<br />

Human Resource Development<br />

<strong>The</strong> developments envisaged under an Integrated<br />

Development Plan can hardly be<br />

realized unless supported by a deliberate<br />

policy of investing in those human capital<br />

resources required to produce, organise,<br />

mobilize and manage the development<br />

processes that will be indispensable in the<br />

21st Century. <strong>The</strong> Education and Health<br />

sectors therefore have a central place in<br />

the plan. Since independence, Barak valley’s<br />

educational institutional growth have<br />

been default focused on the development<br />

of human resources in the white collar and<br />

peripheral services sector to the detriment<br />

of the advanced and ‘employable’ areas of<br />

Science, Technology, Agriculture and Industry,<br />

particularly the Manufacturing<br />

sector. This focus has created a market<br />

failure, resulting in the creation of a huge<br />

backlog of unemployed human capital, a<br />

dependence on government jobs by the<br />

products of the education systems in the<br />

valley. Unlike some states in south India<br />

like Kerala, we failed to create an export<br />

market for local manpower with the result<br />

that no firm foundation has been laid over<br />

the past decades to provide for sustainable<br />

training and placement of our youths in<br />

the foreign job market. Consequently, in<br />

formulating the Integrated Development<br />

Plan, a proper diagnosis of the available<br />

programmes and skills is needed to redesign<br />

and incorporate new curriculum in<br />

our local institutions that will ensure a capable<br />

human resource base for local and<br />

international market. Objectives for education<br />

include increasing the accessibility<br />

of technical and skill based education to<br />

all the school-age population, a diversification<br />

of institutions to favor vocational and<br />

skilled based training, encouragement of<br />

entrepreneurship skills as a corner-stone<br />

of education and an overall enrichment of<br />

curricula and other extracurricular activities.<br />

Health and Social Welfare<br />

Considering the present inadequacies and<br />

mindful of the constraints faced by the<br />

economy, the provision of adequate, effective<br />

and affordable health care for all is<br />

Notwithstanding the the private sector's role in region’s<br />

future socio-economic development, public sector institutions<br />

have a critical role to play in the delivery of support<br />

infrastructural and social services<br />

one of the long term objective for the<br />

health sector. Intermediate objectives for<br />

the health sector are to provide better infrastructure<br />

for Referral Hospitals and<br />

health facilities. Plans are proposed to establish<br />

a South Asian Research Institute<br />

for Medical Sciences (SARIMS) in Karimganj<br />

– the first medical college for the<br />

border district. Simultaneously, the facility<br />

to produce trained staff for health sector<br />

across East Asia and the establishment<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

179


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

of efficient procurement arrangements for<br />

the trained staff in health sector should<br />

complete the array of institutional reforms<br />

to ensure effective and efficient health<br />

services. Improvements in ancillary services<br />

will focus on the management of<br />

health data and enhancing research into<br />

paramedical services such as traditional<br />

healing methods.<br />

Housing Amenities<br />

As a consequence of the more recent and<br />

prevailing demographic trends, rapid urbanization<br />

and concentration of the urban<br />

population, the demand for decent housing<br />

is increasingly elusive to satisfy. <strong>The</strong><br />

long term objectives of housing sector will<br />

aim at increasing production of decent<br />

housing stock on a more regular basis. A<br />

review of the existing housing schemes like<br />

Indira Awas Yojana (Indira Housing Plan)<br />

is a study in decentralization and institutionalization<br />

of corruption upto the grassroots<br />

level. Contrary to this and to effectively<br />

address the problems posed by<br />

pressing demography and rapid urbanization,<br />

particular attention will be focused<br />

on the need for specialized housing finance<br />

institutions such as housing banks<br />

and housing co-operatives. Improving<br />

housing development capabilities is a prerequisite<br />

for providing a decent standing<br />

of living.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Way Forward<br />

<strong>The</strong> foregoing discussion highlights the<br />

potential implications of a proposed Integrated<br />

Development Plan for the Barak<br />

Valley that will be piloted in Karimganj<br />

district. <strong>The</strong> South Asia Development<br />

Gateway has discussed this plan on various<br />

platforms and consultations to determine<br />

the readiness of the stakeholders<br />

with a view to project a road map leading<br />

to the structure of a development strategy<br />

for the area. <strong>The</strong> outcome of these consultations<br />

were largely encouraging and<br />

attracted valuable inputs which were as<br />

well enlisted. <strong>The</strong> approach taken in the<br />

formulation of the strategy is participatory<br />

since all stakeholders will be provided<br />

the opportunity to contribute to the<br />

fundamental design of the strategy based<br />

on the guidelines provided.<br />

On a concluding note, it will not be out<br />

of place to mention that among many<br />

promises of the digital revolution is the<br />

potential to strengthen democracy and<br />

make governments more responsive to<br />

Institutional performance is a critical factor, not only<br />

in the design and implementation of development<br />

programs, but also in the effective realization of any<br />

development policy goals and targets<br />

the needs of the citizens. This Integrated<br />

Development Plan includes the use of<br />

information and communication technologies<br />

to transform the way Government<br />

conducts its business, which includes:<br />

Providing greater access to<br />

government information; Promoting<br />

civic engagement by enabling public to<br />

interact with government officials; Making<br />

government more accountable by<br />

making its operations more transparent<br />

and thus reducing the opportunities for<br />

corruption; Providing development opportunities,<br />

especially benefiting rural<br />

and traditional underserved communi-<br />

ties. Let us now dream to establish “<strong>The</strong><br />

Barak Valley Incorporated” as the Integrated<br />

Development Plan aims at a fullfledged<br />

private sector that is responsible<br />

to the development needs of this area and<br />

that can play an active role in the domestic<br />

economy. Government will ensure<br />

that market mechanism function smoothly<br />

within a free market and a stable macro-economic<br />

environment. On the external<br />

front, the maintenance of a steady<br />

exchange rate between the valley and major<br />

foreign trade agencies as well as the<br />

implementation of agreements signed<br />

with international financial institutions<br />

will ensure a more positive insertion of<br />

the economy into the international<br />

scene.<br />

Over the last decade, it has become<br />

clear that an internally consistent set of<br />

economic and financial policies is a necessary<br />

but not sufficient condition for<br />

growth and development. Institution performance<br />

is a critical factor, not only in<br />

the design and implementation to development<br />

programs, but also in the effective<br />

realization of any development policy<br />

goals and targets. Integrated<br />

Development Plan integrates institutional<br />

capacities as a key factor of production<br />

and sets as an objective the correction of<br />

institutional failures in order to accelerate<br />

the implementation of development<br />

programs. Notwithstanding the lead role<br />

of the private sector in region’s future<br />

socio-economic development, public sector<br />

institutions have a critical role to play<br />

in the delivery of support infrastructural<br />

and social services to buttress the development<br />

efforts of the private sector. It is<br />

therefore envisaged that the plan shall<br />

refer to parastatals on one hand and the<br />

bureaucracy on the other hand.<br />

180 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE OTHER PATH<br />

Sr. Director HR on why GAP is a great place to work! Invitation price<br />

RS.50 Only<br />

H<br />

THE<br />

UMAN<br />

FACTO<br />

R<br />

Contemporary | Actionable | Cutting-Edge<br />

<strong>The</strong> man’s got<br />

Pizzazz!<br />

Find out why the CEO, Domino’s<br />

India is sometimes called the Chief<br />

Enthusiasm Officer by his colleagues<br />

Director HR for Affinity<br />

Infotech tells us<br />

how he uses technology<br />

to aid HR<br />

How do you recruit top<br />

- level talent? Director<br />

GCH, Ranbaxy ponders<br />

the issue<br />

GM HR, Indraprastha Gas<br />

charts out the Development<br />

Plan for the HR<br />

manager


Mrutyunjay Dash<br />

Professor of Economics and<br />

Business Environment,<br />

Asian School of Business<br />

Management,Bhubaneswar<br />

Tenancy Reforms in Orissa:<br />

A Critical Perspective<br />

"He who owns the soil, owns<br />

up to the sky."<br />

- Douglas Gerrold<br />

I. Introduction<br />

Orissa is primarily an agrarian economy.<br />

Agriculture is the state’s dominant sector<br />

with a contribution of nearly 28.13 percent<br />

to net state domestic product during 2001-<br />

2002. Agriculture alone provides direct<br />

and indirect employment to around 65<br />

percent of the total workforce of the state<br />

as per 2001 provisional Census. Nearly 87<br />

percent of total population lives in rural<br />

areas. It has remained as an agriculturally<br />

backward state of India with high incidence<br />

of concealed tenancy. Though tenancy<br />

is legally prohibited in the state, it is<br />

observed in large scale across the length<br />

and breadth of Orissa. <strong>The</strong> Orissa Land<br />

Reforms Committee, 1980, has brought to<br />

the limelight the existence of a vast number<br />

of tenants, mostly unrecorded sharecroppers,<br />

in the rural areas of Orissa. Neither<br />

these tenants have opted for the legal provision<br />

of applying to the revenue officers<br />

for obtaining ryoti right nor the latter, empowered<br />

to initiate action to confer ownership<br />

rights on tenants, have shown any<br />

interest in this regard. Adam Smith (1969)<br />

has rightly remarked that a person, who<br />

has no property rights over land, can have<br />

no other interest except eating as much<br />

and labouring as little as possible, since<br />

the fruit of his hard labour is expropriated<br />

by the proprietor. Psychological feelings of<br />

non-ownership coupled with insecurity<br />

kill their efficiency, enthusiasm and physical<br />

ability. Besides, social distinctions between<br />

landowner and agricultural labourer<br />

deaden the interest and the zeal of the<br />

latter. This is why land reforms in general<br />

and tenurial reforms in particular have to<br />

be assigned the top-most priority in bringing<br />

about the transformation of agricultural<br />

sector so as to make it vibrant, dynamic<br />

and more productive. However, lack<br />

of proper implementation of tenancy reform<br />

measures, prevalence of large scale<br />

concealed tenancy with oral leases, absence<br />

of rent receipts, ignorance of the<br />

legal provisions of tenancy legislations,<br />

built-in legal loopholes and above all, lack<br />

of political will can be attributed for the<br />

results being not so encouraging. In this<br />

paper an attempt has been made to give a<br />

182 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


TENANCY REFORMS<br />

brief outline of the extent, types and incidence<br />

of tenancy in the second section. In<br />

the third section reference to important<br />

tenancy legislation is undertaken. Finally,<br />

evaluation of tenancy reforms in Orissa is<br />

made followed by concluding remarks.<br />

II. Extent, Types And<br />

Incidence Of Tenancy<br />

India achieved independence from British<br />

Rule in 1947. Having been created with six<br />

districts: Balasore, Cuttack, Puri, Ganjam,<br />

Koraput and Sambalpur initially, in 1936<br />

Orissa acquired a new geographical shape<br />

after merger of 26 feudatory states on<br />

January 1,1948. In the first stage an attempt<br />

has been made to give a brief account<br />

on the extent of tenancy, types of<br />

Table-1: State-Wise Tenancy Statistics For Rural India,<br />

1981-82 And 1991-92<br />

State<br />

% of Tenant Holdings<br />

to Operational<br />

Holdings<br />

% of Leased-in<br />

Area to Operational<br />

Area<br />

% of Leased-in<br />

Area under<br />

ShareTenancy<br />

1981-82 1991-92 1981-82 1991-92 1991-92<br />

Andhra Pradesh 13.8 14.1 6.2 9.6 20.9<br />

Assam 12.9 10.1 6.4 8.9 27.8<br />

Bihar 19.7 5.6 10.3 3.9 43.5<br />

Gujarat 4.8 3.7 2 3.3 23.7<br />

Haryana 25.9 17.1 18.2 33.7 19.9<br />

Karnataka 10.7 8 6 7.4 28.6<br />

Kerala 6.7 5.2 2.6 2.9 2.1<br />

Madhya Pradesh 8.0 9 3.6 6.3 24.9<br />

Maharashtra 10.6 6.9 5.2 5.5 20.9<br />

Orissa 18.2 16.9 9.9 9.5 50.9<br />

Punjab 21.3 15.9 16.1 18.8 11.3<br />

Rajsthan 7.1 6.5 4.3 5.2 23.4<br />

Tamilnadu 24.7 15.3 10.9 10.9 16.5<br />

Uttar Pradesh 20.5 15.5 10.2 10.5 46.5<br />

West Bengal 23.1 14.4 12.3 10.4 46.5<br />

India 15.2 11 7.2 8.3 34.4<br />

Source: Sarvekshana, Vol,20, No.3, 70th issue, Jan-March, 1997, NSS 48th Round.<br />

tenancy NSS (National Sample Survey).<br />

In India data on extent of tenancy are<br />

available from two sources: National Sample<br />

Survey estimates and Agricultural<br />

Census data, out of which the former is<br />

more reliable being based on independent<br />

household surveys.<br />

However, it will not be out of place<br />

to mention that there is commonality<br />

of opinion on reliability of official data<br />

on incidence of tenancy due to several<br />

reasons. Principally because lease contracts<br />

are mainly oral without any written<br />

record of lease details and tenants’<br />

hesitation to reveal their tenurial identity<br />

in fear of eviction by the landowner.<br />

With this reservation in mind NSS<br />

estimates on incident of tenancy have<br />

been furnished. This is the reason for<br />

which NSS is referred to in this section.<br />

And secondly different tenancy reform<br />

measures undertaken by the Government<br />

of Orissa and their evaluation are<br />

considered also. Orissa belongs to the<br />

category of high Tenancy State in India.<br />

This is supported by NSS findings. As<br />

per NSS data in the year 1981-82 tenants<br />

household constituted 18.2 per cent<br />

of total operational household and it<br />

has been reduced to 16.9 percent (only<br />

by a meagre 1.3 percent), in 1991-92, as<br />

reflected in Table-1. In 1991-92 there<br />

were numerically 6.9 lakh tenant holdings<br />

and leased-in land constituted<br />

4.5 lakh hectares of land. This was 9.5<br />

percent of total operated area and infact<br />

surpasses the All India average of 8.3<br />

percent in the same period. Tenancy in<br />

Orissa is manifested mostly in the form<br />

of sharecropping. Share tenancy is more<br />

pervasive than fixed rent tenancy based<br />

on either fixed produce or fixed money.<br />

Nearly 42.0 percent of leased-in area is<br />

under shared tenancy compared to that<br />

of 13.6 percent and 7.6 percent are on<br />

fixed produce and fixed money respectively<br />

NSS (1971-72) and this figure has<br />

further been increased to 50.9 percent in<br />

1991-92 (Please refer Table-2).<br />

Further, in a labour abundant coupled<br />

with land scarce agrarian economy like<br />

ours, i.e., of Orissa, the tenant is subject<br />

to weak bargaining power and thus<br />

is placed in a disadvantageous position.<br />

<strong>The</strong> obvious alternative left with, therefore<br />

relates to leasing-in-land irrespective<br />

of the degree of benefits accruing<br />

to the tenants from a certain mode of<br />

lease contract. This is more prominent in<br />

case of marginal and small farmers as is<br />

evident from Table-3. <strong>The</strong> distribution of<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

183


THE 'OTHER' INDIA<br />

Table-2: Changes In Percentage Distribution Of Leased- in Area By<br />

Terms Of Lease<br />

Terms of 1971-72 1981-82 1991-92<br />

Lease (26th) (37th) (48th)<br />

Fixed Money 7.6 5.1 19.7<br />

Fixed Produce 13.6 8.1 4.7<br />

Share of Produce 41.6 42.0 50.9<br />

Others 37.2 44.8 24.7<br />

All Terms 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Sources: (a) N.S.S. Report 26th Round (1971-72)<br />

(b) N.S.S. Report 37 th Round (1981-82)<br />

(c) N.S.S. Report 48 th Round (1991-92)<br />

lease-in area according to <strong>size</strong> classes of<br />

operational holdings shows that in 1991-<br />

92 about 89.76 percent of leased-in area<br />

was in the <strong>size</strong> classes of less than one<br />

hectare and only 0.47 percent of leasedin<br />

area was in <strong>size</strong> classes above 4 hectares.<br />

Likewise a significant proportion<br />

of tenant holdings (89.21%) belonged to<br />

the category of marginal farmer. This is<br />

also confirmed from another study that<br />

subsistence tenancy is more widespread<br />

than commercial or capitalist tenancy in<br />

Orissa (Swain; 1999b, 1999c).<br />

III. Tenancy Reforms And Tenancy<br />

Legislation In Orissa<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is no denying the fact that exploitative<br />

land tenant system is one of the<br />

important economic causes leading to<br />

agrarian unrest in land scarce and labour<br />

abundant economies. Various factors<br />

like socio-economic factor, relative<br />

bargaining strength, relative differences<br />

in <strong>size</strong> class, to mention a few, determine<br />

the degree and extent of exploitation to<br />

which the tenants are subjected. This<br />

is especially because tenants do not<br />

belong to homogeneous groups rather<br />

a lot of heterogeneities witnessed with<br />

regard to their socio-economic status,<br />

<strong>size</strong> class, etc., are held responsible for<br />

exploitation. As such, differences arise<br />

in their economic resource position and<br />

therefore, in their bargaining strength.<br />

Tenancy reforms include all those measures aiming at<br />

protecting and safeguarding the interest of tenant with<br />

regard to the realization of their due share accruing from<br />

leased-in land and conferring ownership rights<br />

Thus they are all not equally prone to exploitation<br />

by their landlords (Bhardwaj,<br />

1974; Bhardwaj and Das, 1975a; 1975b).<br />

Besides, the extreme concentration of<br />

land ownership (Myrdal, 1982, 1306)<br />

and exploitative production relations,<br />

being established between the landlord<br />

and the tenant during the process of production,<br />

are sufficient enough to make<br />

agricultural growth sluggish (Joshi, 1974,<br />

167;Appu, 1996,40-5). This necessitates<br />

to bring about a thorough and complete<br />

transformation in production relations<br />

between the landlord and tenant on<br />

one hand and in forces of production<br />

on the other. Indian peasant history is<br />

replete with examples which show that<br />

radical tenancy reform legislation, far<br />

from being a liberal gift from the state<br />

is an outcome of a long and protracted<br />

struggle by the tenants. Orissa is not an<br />

exception to this.<br />

As the term suggests tenancy reforms<br />

includes all those measures aiming at<br />

protecting and safeguarding the interest<br />

of tenant with regard to the realization<br />

of their due share or benefits of produce<br />

accruing from leased-in land and conferring<br />

ownership right on land which<br />

they cultivate. In Orissa tenancy contracts<br />

were oral, unrecorded, insecured<br />

and the rent prevailed mostly at around<br />

(on an average basis) 50 percent of the<br />

gross produce in pre-independent era.<br />

Thus to remove the inherent loopholes<br />

in the tenancy system radical tenancy<br />

reform measures were called for after<br />

a long struggle and oppression by the<br />

so-called land owning class. With the<br />

passage of time some legislative measures<br />

undertaken in the years of 1881,<br />

1885, and 1913 to remove the intolerable<br />

suffering of the tenants. For example<br />

in Orissa Tenancy Act, 1913 and<br />

subsequent amendments effected to it<br />

granted some new concessions to the<br />

tenants and raiyats through fixing limitations<br />

on landlords to extract anything<br />

beyond their legitimate dues from the<br />

tenants. Consider this: Section 54 of<br />

Regulation VIII of 1793 declares that<br />

all impositions and exactions (whatever<br />

their designation might be), over and<br />

above the actual rent are illegal. Section<br />

3 of Regulation V of 1812 1 altered<br />

some of the provisions Regulation VIII<br />

of 1793 but attention being given not to<br />

incorporate anything, which sanctions<br />

or legalizes the impositions of arbitrary<br />

184 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


TENANCY REFORMS<br />

or indefinite cesses. By the Amendment<br />

Act of 1938, all kinds of illegal cesses as<br />

codified in the original Orissa Tenancy<br />

Act 1913, were deleted so as to make<br />

it more purposive. Further with respect<br />

to recovering from a landlord (by means<br />

of a legal suit), the amount exacted by<br />

the landlord in excess of the rent, the<br />

Amendment Act of 1938 empowered<br />

the Collector of the District or any<br />

Deputy Collector on his behalf to take<br />

action and impose on the landlord such<br />

penalty not exceeding Rs.500/- or simple<br />

imprisonment not exceeding six months.<br />

Thus the amended provision incorporated<br />

certain features for preventing collection<br />

of illegal cesses from tenants. But<br />

for all matters whatsoever, such as illegal<br />

exaction, collections of exorbitant rent, a<br />

ryot was required to move to court of law<br />

and the financial vulnerability and powerful<br />

influence of potential landowning<br />

class taken together could not allow a<br />

majority of poor tenants to realize the<br />

fruits of legislation.<br />

However as a result of the passing of<br />

various Tenancy Acts, i.e. of 1881, 1885,<br />

and in 1913, some well-to-do tenants<br />

could also acquire hereditary rights to<br />

occupancy ryots, and with their legally<br />

protected right, followed the path of their<br />

masters, and found it more profitable to<br />

rent out the land to the under-tenants<br />

and share-croppers who became more<br />

tenants-at-will. <strong>The</strong>y could be evicted<br />

on short notice and virtually enjoyed no<br />

security of tenure. Taking cognizance of<br />

this actuality, immediately after independence,<br />

various tenancy legislation<br />

and subsequent amendments to them<br />

were passed with a view to minimise<br />

the sufferings of the tenants. A brief account<br />

of these legal developments are<br />

given below:<br />

a. <strong>The</strong> Orissa Tenants’ Protection<br />

Act of 1948<br />

Under the Orissa Tenants Protection<br />

Table-3: Percentage Distribution Of Lessor And Lessee Households<br />

And Leased-in And leased-out Area By Size Class Of Land Ownership<br />

Holdings In Rural Orissa,1991-92<br />

Size Class Of<br />

Ownership<br />

Holdings(ha.)<br />

Percentage Of<br />

Total Lessor<br />

Households<br />

Percentage f<br />

Total Tenant<br />

Households<br />

Percentage f<br />

Total Leased-<br />

In Area<br />

Percentage of<br />

Total Leasedout<br />

Area<br />

Less than1.01 63.96 89.21 89.76 29.40<br />

1.01-2.00 25.96 6.42 5.61 51.18<br />

2.01-4.00 7.01 3.56 4.16 11.51<br />

4.01-10.00 2.38 0.81 0.47 3.53<br />

Above10.00 0.69 0.00 0.00 4.38<br />

All Sizes 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00<br />

Sources: N.S.S. Report 48 th Round (1991-92)<br />

Act, 1948, it was declared that notwithstanding<br />

anything contained in the<br />

law, contract or usage or any decree of<br />

any court, a person who was cultivating<br />

any land as a tenant on the first day<br />

of September, 1947, should continue<br />

to have the right to cultivate such land<br />

and no landlord was legally entitled<br />

For all matters whatsoever, such as illegal exaction, collections<br />

of exorbitant rent, a ryot was required to move to<br />

court of law and the financial vulnerability and powerful<br />

influence of potential landowning class could not allow a<br />

majority of poor tenants to realize the fruits of legislation<br />

to evict such tenant, O.T.P Act, 1948,<br />

Section 3 (1) (b).<br />

Further as per the Act, tenants enjoying<br />

occupancy rights were not bound<br />

to pay more than one third of the gross<br />

produce as rent to the superior ryot (c)<br />

tenants without security of tenure were<br />

not bound to pay more than two fifths<br />

of the gross produce as rent to the landowners.<br />

However this Act lost its real<br />

purpose of protecting tenants as it allows<br />

landowners (owning 33 acres of land) to<br />

evict his/her tenants from land holding.<br />

b. Orissa Tenants’ Relief Act, 1955<br />

This Act intends to confer security of<br />

tenure, resumption of land for personal<br />

cultivation and regulation of rent so<br />

as to bring relief to the oppressed and<br />

exploited tenants. <strong>The</strong> Act defined a<br />

tenant a person who under the system<br />

commonly known as Bhag, Sanjha, Kata<br />

or such similar terms under any other<br />

system, law, contract, custom, or usage<br />

cultivated the land of another person on<br />

payment of rent in cash or in kind or<br />

in both or on condition of delivering to<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

185


THE 'OTHER' INDIA<br />

that person.<br />

i) a share of the produce of such<br />

land or<br />

ii) the estimated value of a portion of<br />

the crop raised on the land or<br />

iii) a fixed quantity of produce irrespective<br />

of the yield from the land, or<br />

iv) produce or its estimated value partly<br />

in any one of the ways described above<br />

and partly in another, Das (1989).<br />

<strong>The</strong> law provided that notwithstanding<br />

anything in Law, contract or usage or<br />

in any decree or order of any Court but<br />

subject to the provisions of this Acta)<br />

No tenant with permanent and heritable<br />

rights over holdings in terms of<br />

produce rent was liable to pay more<br />

than 2/3 rd of the rate of rent payable<br />

or to express it in a different way rent<br />

payable was not to exceed 1/6 th of the<br />

produce or value thereof.<br />

b) No landlord was entitled to recover<br />

any cess, rates or other dues payable<br />

or deliverable in relation to the land<br />

by a tenant holding on produce rent.<br />

c) When rent was deliverable in kind it<br />

was to be delivered at the landlords’<br />

granary in the village in which the<br />

land was situated or at such other<br />

granary, within 3 miles of the village,<br />

as may be provided on that behalf by<br />

the landlord.<br />

Further as per the Act, a temporary<br />

tenant was not bound to pay more than<br />

25 percent in kind or cash of the gross<br />

produce of the land. Further it was added<br />

that no tenant having permanent or<br />

hereditary right in land was bound to<br />

pay more than 16 percent of the gross<br />

produce of the land. However to nullify<br />

the very purpose of the Act, the landowners<br />

were obtaining written undertakings<br />

from the tenants to pay 50 percent<br />

of the gross produce after harvest and<br />

that too without any rent receipt.<br />

c. Orissa Land Reforms Act, 1960<br />

<strong>The</strong> Orissa Land Reforms Act, 1960 and<br />

its subsequent amendments exhibited a<br />

certain degree of qualitative shift from<br />

the earlier tenancy legislation as discussed<br />

above. <strong>The</strong> basic thrust was given<br />

on land to the tiller. One of the notable<br />

features of O.L.R. Act 1960 relates to<br />

conferment of permanent, heritable and<br />

transferable rights on all raiyats over<br />

their land.<br />

Besides, the agricultural labourers<br />

To nullify the very purpose of the <strong>The</strong> Orissa Tenants’ Relief<br />

Act, 1955, the landowners were obtaining written undertakings<br />

from the tenants to pay 50 percent of the gross produce<br />

after harvest and that too without any rent receipt<br />

and the village artisans were granted<br />

property rights in respect of their dwelling<br />

houses constructed on the lands of<br />

the superior landlords. Amendment in<br />

O.L.R. Act (Act 17 of 1972) also enabled<br />

the tenants to become ryots in<br />

whole of the land under their occupation<br />

under section 36-A, subject to receipt<br />

of application by the tenant within two<br />

years from October 2 nd , 1973. But the<br />

response from the tenants to claim occupancy<br />

rights was not satisfactory. Hence<br />

under section 36-B the Revenue Officer<br />

was empowered to take appropriate action<br />

where no application was received<br />

from a tenant. Besides, the amount of<br />

rent was retained at 25 percent of the<br />

gross produce of the land or the value<br />

thereof or the value of 25 percent of the<br />

estimated produce of the land.<br />

IV. Evaluation Of Tenancy Reforms<br />

Act In Orissa<br />

After having gone through a brief account<br />

of some of the important tenancy<br />

legislation it would be wise to ascertain<br />

as to what extent these legislation have<br />

yielded results as were supposed to be<br />

during the time of their inception. With<br />

regard to the operation of the Orissa<br />

Tenants’ Protection Act of 1948 it experienced<br />

varied results in different areas<br />

and in most of the cases the tenants did<br />

not claim their dues. For instance Puri<br />

District alone accounted for more than<br />

2/3rd of the cases filed (in the years between<br />

1955-56 and 1956-57) and about<br />

70 percent of the cases filed settled<br />

without any claim on behalf of tenants,<br />

Dash (1989). Moreover, allowing landlord<br />

owning less than 33 acres of land<br />

to evict tenant also questions the very<br />

purpose of the Act. <strong>The</strong> limit of 33 acres<br />

of land was too high in the land holding<br />

context of Orissa where the majority of<br />

farmers do belong to the categories of<br />

landless labourers or marginal or small<br />

farmer categories (Jena, 1968).<br />

Similarly a Report on the working of<br />

tenancy laws prepared by B. Mishra and<br />

B. Jena (1958) 2 also confirmed that in<br />

three villages of Balasore District, namely<br />

Kalei, Mahadevpur and Balarampur,<br />

out of 105 cultivating families 45 families<br />

reported to have cultivated land on payment<br />

of the share of 50 percent of the<br />

gross produce which strictly violates the<br />

O.T.R. Act, 1955 recommending strongly<br />

a tenant not to pay more than 25 per-<br />

186 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


TENANCY REFORMS<br />

cent in kind or cash of the gross produce<br />

of the land. A Report on An Enquiry<br />

into the Working of Orissa Tenants’<br />

Protection Act, 1948, and Orissa Tenants’<br />

Relief Act, 1955 in Five Districts of<br />

Orissa, 1970 by B. Mishra revealed that<br />

payment of rent receipt was not received<br />

by 80 percent of the tenants.<br />

It is interesting to note that even as<br />

the Report states that although the tenants<br />

were fully aware of O.T.R. Act,<br />

1955 only one tenant filed a case and the<br />

case ultimately cost the tenant Rs.130/-<br />

and the decision finally went against<br />

him. Further the Orissa Land Reforms<br />

Committee, 1980, brings to the limelight<br />

the existence of a vast number of tenants<br />

mostly unrecorded sharecroppers<br />

who have neither taken any legal steps<br />

through applying revenue officers to get<br />

ryoti right nor the revenue officers empowered<br />

to initiate actions at their own<br />

level endeavoured to confer ownership<br />

rights on tenants. <strong>The</strong> tenants also do<br />

not dare to agitate in order to promote<br />

their case because of the fear of retaliation<br />

by the ryoti type of landlords. Thus<br />

various legislation enacted and subsequently<br />

modified from time to time in<br />

the better interest of tenants could not<br />

yield desired result so far. However generalisation<br />

of findings of the Report on<br />

the basis of observation in only three villages<br />

would be improper and it is needless<br />

to say that further detailed empirical<br />

studies need to be undertaken for seeking<br />

definitive and conclusive judgment<br />

on this aspect.<br />

With regard to working of O.L.R.<br />

Act, 1960, also the experiences are not<br />

so encouraging. To substantiate such a<br />

stand in this regard two principal aspects<br />

need to be empha<strong>size</strong>d. Firstly,<br />

the response from the tenants to claim<br />

occupancy rights, as stressed in O.L.R.<br />

1960, was not satisfactory. Even though<br />

under Section 36-B, the Revenue Officer<br />

was empowered to take appropriate<br />

action in case of any application not<br />

received from tenants the result lagged<br />

far behind expectation. Secondly, as<br />

is evident from O.L.R. Act 1960, the<br />

landlords have been doubly compensated<br />

for their property right over land<br />

once by the Government in the case of<br />

abolition of estates and by fixing Rs 800<br />

per standard acre for tenants to acquire<br />

land vide amendment effected to 1965<br />

Act, for the second time. As the tenants<br />

were subjected to grinding poverty they<br />

failed to acquire the land they cultivated<br />

for want of funds required to pay the<br />

compensation fee. Further, the apparent<br />

inequity evident in the O.L.R. Act 1960,<br />

relates to the payment of heavy premium<br />

to the Government on one hand and receipt<br />

of application from tenants by the<br />

Revenue Officer with respect to getting<br />

proprietary rights within a short period<br />

of 90 days on the other.<br />

Thus heavy compensation fee and premium<br />

coupled with short period of time<br />

to get proprietary rights reveal deliberate<br />

and unjust attempts of legislators to<br />

safeguard the interest of the landowning<br />

class. As a result uptil now oral tenancy,<br />

without any records whatsoever, along<br />

with high rent and insecurity of tenure<br />

do outline the prevailing tenancy system<br />

in Orissa. Such an unfortunate trend has<br />

crept in the agrarian structure of Orissa<br />

not because the tenants lack awareness<br />

of various tenancy legislation but<br />

because the prevailing socio-economic<br />

conditions do not possibly allow exercising<br />

their rights in this regard.<br />

With the provision of resumption of tenanted lands on the<br />

grounds of so-called “personal cultivation” being not defined<br />

clearly by many states, a lot of tenants were subjected<br />

to eviction on a large-scale basis. Many tenants after<br />

conferment of ownership rights either sold or mortgaged it<br />

V. Conclusion<br />

Thus to sum up, different tenancy legislation<br />

and consequent regulations incorporated<br />

in them failed to serve the<br />

very purpose of bringing socio-economic<br />

justice to the poor tenants and thereby<br />

establishing an egalitarian society. With<br />

an exception to few financially better-off<br />

tenants who were in a position to vindicate<br />

their cause, the hardships and sufferings<br />

of tenants in general continued.<br />

Several reasons may be cited in this regard<br />

as to why these tenancy legislation<br />

did not yield desired results.<br />

To mention a few, firstly, there is a<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

187


THE 'OTHER' INDIA<br />

wide gulf between policy formulation<br />

and its effective implementation from<br />

the grassroots level. Secondly, universal<br />

application of a single and uniform<br />

standard to the entire State without any<br />

proper understanding of rural agrarian<br />

set-up and prevalence of varied socioeconomic<br />

constraints, might have been<br />

responsible for results being not so<br />

encouraging and last but not the least,<br />

prolonged time taken in the settlement<br />

of legal issues and more often than not,<br />

results going in favor of the land owning<br />

class discouraged tenants to take<br />

recourse to various tenancy legislation.<br />

Thus, the foregoing analysis reveals that<br />

the prevalent inequitable property relationship,<br />

inherent legal loopholes with<br />

an attitude of protection to the so-called<br />

land owning class and unorganized behavior<br />

of tenants have reduced the reforms<br />

package to a near fallacious one.<br />

Despite all legislative measures undertaken<br />

by different State Governments<br />

to take care of the interest of the<br />

actual tiller of the soil from time to time,<br />

a lot remains yet to be achieved in this<br />

regard. With the provision of resumption<br />

of tenanted lands on the grounds<br />

of so-called “personal cultivation” being<br />

not defined clearly by many states, a lot<br />

of tenants were subjected to eviction on<br />

a large-scale basis. Further due to noneconomic<br />

holdings, many tenants after<br />

conferment of ownership rights either<br />

sold or mortgaged it. Protected tenant<br />

also leased out their lands to rich farmers<br />

for want of funds. A large number<br />

of tenants still remain out of the purview<br />

of the law for not being recorded<br />

for one reason or other. Thus, tenancy<br />

reform has not succeeded in achieving<br />

any great impact either in terms of reorienting<br />

the property relationship in<br />

favor of the tenants or elevating their<br />

socio-economic condition.<br />

Additional Notes<br />

1. All sums received by the proprietors<br />

in excess of the amount of rent specified<br />

in the contract would be considered<br />

as extortion and be repaid by<br />

the proprietors with a penalty of 200<br />

percent of the amount exhorted.<br />

Owing to the prevalent inequitable property relationships<br />

and inherent legal loopholes, tenancy reform has not<br />

succeeded in achieving any great impact, either in terms<br />

of reorienting the property relationship in favor of the tenants<br />

or elevating their socio-economic condition<br />

2. A Report on An Enquiry into the<br />

Working of Orissa Tenants’ Protection<br />

Act, 1948, and Orissa Tenants’<br />

Relief Act, 1955 in Five Districts<br />

of Orissa, 1970 by B. Mishra revealed<br />

that payment of rent receipt<br />

was not received by 80 percent of<br />

the tenants.<br />

References<br />

• AICC (All India Congress Committee)<br />

(1949), “Report of the Congress<br />

Agrarian Reforms Committee”, New<br />

Delhi.<br />

• Appu, P.S. (1996). “Land Reforms in<br />

India: A Survey of Policy, Legislation<br />

ad Implementation,” Vikas Publishing<br />

House, New Delhi.<br />

• Bhardwaj, K and P.K. Das (1975a).<br />

Tenurial Conditions and Modes of<br />

Exploitation:”A Study of Some Villages<br />

in Orissa,” EPW Annual Number,<br />

10:221-40, February; and P.K.Das<br />

(1975b). “Tenurial Conditions and<br />

Modes of Exploitation: A Study of<br />

Some Villages in Orissa; Further<br />

Notes,” EPW, Review of Agriculture<br />

10:A49-55, June.<br />

• Dash, Giridhari. (1989). <strong>The</strong><br />

Land Systems and Land Reforms<br />

in Orissa,Published by G.<br />

Dash, Cuttack<br />

• Jena, K.C. (1968). Land Revenue<br />

Administration in Orissa During<br />

19 th Century, S. Chand & Co,<br />

New Delhi.<br />

• Joshi, P.C. (1974). Land Reform and<br />

Agrarian Change in India and Pakistan<br />

Since 1947 : I, Journal of Peasant<br />

Studies 1 (2):164-85, January, II.1<br />

(3), April.<br />

• Mitra, A. (1981). Tenancy Reforms<br />

in Orissa, in M. Bose (ed). Land Reforms<br />

in Eastern India, Planning Forum,<br />

Jadavpur University.<br />

• Orissa Tenancy Act, 1913 & Rules<br />

with Notes and Latest Case Laws,<br />

ed. By A. Mohapatra, 1991-92.<br />

• Orissa Govt. (1987). Agricultural Statistics<br />

of Orissa, Directorate of Agriculture<br />

and Food Production.<br />

• Smith,Adam. (1969). <strong>The</strong> Wealth of<br />

Nations. Pelican Classics, (ed.) Andrew<br />

Skinner, reprint:1974<br />

• Swain,Mamata.(1999b). Agricultural<br />

Share Tenancy and Efficiency: Testing<br />

Alternative <strong>The</strong>ories with Micro<br />

Evidence from Orissa, IASSI, <strong>Quarterly</strong>,<br />

Vol.17.No.4. June 1999.<br />

188 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE HUMAN FACTOR<br />

THE<br />

INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

<strong>2007</strong><br />

<strong>Volume</strong> 5 | <strong>Quarterly</strong> <strong>Issue</strong>: 31st <strong>Dec</strong>ember <strong>2007</strong><br />

www.iipmthinktank.com<br />

www.gidf.org<br />

REIMAGINING INDIA:<br />

MORE MARKET,<br />

LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

RETHINK<br />

EDIFY<br />

DELINEATE<br />

INSIDE THIS ISSUE<br />

Development Agenda<br />

<strong>The</strong> Visible Hand<br />

Free Exchange<br />

India Reexamined<br />

Progress Within Limits<br />

<strong>The</strong> Other Path<br />

A New Beginning<br />

A N I I P M T H I N K T A N K<br />

&<br />

G R E A T I N D I A N D R E A M F O U N D A T I O N P R E S E N T A T I O N<br />

August-October 2005<br />

189 | An <strong>IIPM</strong> Intelligence Unit Publication


D A R E T O D R E A M : S T R A T E G I C A L L Y ! I N N O V A T I V E L Y !<br />

STRATEGIC CHOICES: ANEEL KARNANI<br />

PROFESSOR OF STRATEGY, UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN<br />

ILLUSION & REALITY: ANDREW LIKIERMAN<br />

DEAN, LONDON BUSINESS SCHOOL<br />

PR AND COMMUNICATION SYSTEM: DAVID NORDFORS<br />

SEMIOR RESEARCH SCHOLAR, STANFORD UNIVERSITY<br />

ENTREPRENEURSHIP: ELIZABETH R. THORNTON<br />

PROFESSOR OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP, BABSON COLLEGE<br />

INDIA’S PATH TO INNOVATION: DR. DAN STEINBOCK<br />

DIRECTOR, ICT RESEARCH INSTITUTE<br />

www.iipm.edu<br />

THE HUMAN FACTOR<br />

Subscription Form<br />

OTHER <strong>IIPM</strong> JOURNALS<br />

M A K E W E A L T H W H I L E O T H E R S T H I N K O F I T<br />

NEED THE DOUGH?<br />

July-October <strong>2007</strong> <strong>Volume</strong> 2 <strong>Issue</strong> I1 www.iipmthinktank.com<br />

SPECIAL ISSUE<br />

MERGERS & ACQUISITIONS<br />

Rs. 100<br />

Please enter my subscription for <strong>The</strong> India Economy Review<br />

<strong>The</strong> India Economy Review For India and SAARC Region Non SAARC<br />

Subscription<br />

Countries<br />

Per <strong>Issue</strong> INR 100 USD 3<br />

1 year (4 issues) INR 380 USD 13<br />

2 years (8 issues) INR 720 USD 21<br />

3 years (12 issues) INR 1020 USD 27<br />

INDIA INC. GOING<br />

GLOBAL<br />

AN <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK PUBLICATION<br />

I am enclosing my cheque/DD no. __________ dated __________ for INR/USD ________<br />

on bank ________________________ branch ____________________ drawn in favour of<br />

“<strong>The</strong> Indian Institute of Planning and Management”.<br />

Strategic Innovators<br />

w<br />

July-September <strong>2007</strong>, <strong>Volume</strong> 1 <strong>Issue</strong> 3<br />

Unveiling the rich<br />

secrets behind those<br />

unanticipated strategic<br />

master-strokes<br />

w w . i i p m p u b l i c a t i o n s . c o m<br />

INSIDE THIS ISSUE<br />

20<br />

32<br />

40<br />

48<br />

56<br />

How Indian firms can make better strategic choices &<br />

execute them to achieve true competitive advantages<br />

How the success of an organisation is not reflected by<br />

its sheer <strong>size</strong>; rather it’s linked to shareholders’ returns<br />

How communicators & journalists are “attention workers”<br />

driving the “innovation communication system”<br />

Explaining the risks and returns behind many<br />

entrepreneurial motives to start their own businesses<br />

On how India’s future depends on the private sector<br />

players becoming the highly-active innovation drivers<br />

Rs.100<br />

Radical knowledge<br />

Re-structuring<br />

My Personal Details (IN BLOCK LETTERS)<br />

Name ______________________________________________________________________<br />

Designation _________________________________________________________________<br />

Organization ________________________________________________________________<br />

Address ____________________________________________________________________<br />

City ________________________________ State __________________________________<br />

Country _______________________________ Pin (mandatory) _____________________<br />

Tel ______________________Mobile __________________ e-mail ___________________<br />

AN AN <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> INTELLIGENCE UNIT UNIT PUBLICATION<br />

Age Below 25 25-35 35-50 Above 50<br />

Education Graduate MBA CA/CFA Other<br />

THE<br />

H UMAN<br />

FACTO<br />

R<br />

Contemporary | Actionable | Cutting-Edge<br />

Sr. Director HR on why GAP is a great place to work!<br />

<strong>The</strong> man’s got<br />

Pizzazz!<br />

Find out why the CEO, Domino’s<br />

India is sometimes called the Chief<br />

Enthusiasm Officer by his colleagues<br />

Director HR for Affinity<br />

Infotech tells us<br />

how he uses technology<br />

to aid HR<br />

How do you recruit top<br />

- level talent? Director<br />

GCH, Ranbaxy ponders<br />

the issue<br />

GM HR, Indraprastha Gas<br />

charts out the Development<br />

Plan for the HR<br />

manager<br />

Invitation price<br />

RS.50 Only<br />

Signature (Mandatory) _______________________<br />

Please Mail it to:<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW, <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank,<br />

Neha Malhotra (Asst. Manager-Subscription)<br />

Satbari, Chandan Haula, Chattarpur, Bhatimines Road, New Delhi-110074<br />

Contact Details : 9818825794/9810459839 or E-mail : neha.malhotra@iipm.edu<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> reserves the right to accept subscriptions. For any another queries please write to<br />

m.chaitanya@iipm.edu<br />

An <strong>IIPM</strong> Intelligence Unit Publication | 190 August-October 2005


P LANMAN TECHNOLOGIES<br />

KNOWLEDGE . IT . OUTSOURCING<br />

P LANMAN FINANCIAL<br />

INVESTMENT BANKING . CORPORATE ADVISORY<br />

P LANMAN CONSULTING<br />

GLOBAL STRATEGY . HUMAN RESOURCE . MARKET INTELLIGENCE<br />

P LANMAN MARCOM<br />

ADVERTISING . BRANDING . PR & CRM . ACTIVATION<br />

o<br />

360 Business Growth Consulting<br />

WWW. PLANMANCONSULTING. COM<br />

PLANMAN IS PERHAPS THE ONLY GLOBAL CONSULTING FIRM THAT CAN GIVE YOUR ORGANISATION A<br />

360 O BUSINESS GROWTH CONSULTING THROUGH IT’ S 360 O CAPABILITIES. FOR US CONSULTING DOES NOT ONLY MEAN<br />

MECHANICAL COST REDUCTION THROUGH BETTER I.T. APPLICATIONS. WE FIND OUT WHAT YOUR<br />

ORGANISATION REALLY NEEDS AND GIVE YOU AN INTELLECTUAL SOLUTION THAT HELPS YOU REDUCE COSTS AS WELL AS<br />

HELPS YOUR BUSINESS GROW AND BEAT THE COMPETITION.<br />

TO BEAT THE COMPETITION E-MAIL TO growth@planmanconsulting.com<br />

NOW!! OUR CONSULTANTS WILL GET BACK TO YOU IN 24 HOURS AND PUT YOU INTO THE HIGH GROWTH PATH!<br />

Planman. Beat <strong>The</strong> Competition.<br />

PLANMAN MARCOM/336<br />

ASIA | EUROPE | AMERICA


PRAISE FOR IER<br />

“Most credible and valuable resource book...”<br />

Prof. M.S.Swaminathan, M. S. Swaminathan Research Foundation, Chennai<br />

“I am happy that the <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank has been doing excellent<br />

work on various strategic sectors and issues of importance to Indian<br />

Economy... IER 2003-2004 is extremely fascinating and value adding...”<br />

Dr. P.L. Sanjeev Reddy, Former Secretary to Govt. of India, Director, Indian Institute<br />

of Public Administration, New Delhi<br />

“…I have gone through it and it is really a professional exercise to<br />

help everyone. What impressed me the most is its analytical approach<br />

used for articulating the figures, which otherwise are lifeless entities… ”<br />

Dr. Mruthyunjaya, Director, NCAEPR, New Delhi<br />

“...the contents are extremely relevant and thought provoking...”<br />

Dr. Charan Wadhwa, Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi<br />

“...It highlights the wealth of intellectual synthesis of agrarian economy<br />

available to us for re-energising the thought process endeavoured at<br />

your end…..I hope that the platform of further synthesis of many such issues<br />

provided by IER will be serving great interest of agriculture sector.”<br />

Dr. Rajiv Mehta, Member Secretary, Commission for Agricultural Costs & Prices,<br />

Ministry of Agriculture, New Delhi<br />

“.In my opinion, it has fulfilled its objective in presenting a comprehensive,<br />

upto-date and clear exposition of the issues and concerns<br />

that are essential for understanding, evaluating and suggesting<br />

solutions to the important national economic problems.”<br />

Mr. U.K.S. Chauhan, Director, Department of Agriculture and Cooperation,<br />

Ministry of Agriculture, New Delhi<br />

“...I laud your info base and analytical prowess; particularly your solutions<br />

vis-a-vis international experience….you may like to examine further<br />

from your side the aspects of futures trading in the perspective of the Indian<br />

farming community given your extant knowledge base in agriculture.”<br />

Mr. Suvendu Ganguly, Deputy Director, Forward Markets Commission,<br />

Kolkotta<br />

“<strong>The</strong> IER, a thematic compilation of economic thoughts, ideas, questions,<br />

answers and solutions…..promises to usher in a potentially better, if<br />

not necessarily newer, dawn of economic policies that radiates the power<br />

to dispel the current darkness of socio-economic and socio political confusion...<br />

the review exudes qualified optimism about country’s prospects.”<br />

Mr. S.R.Kasbekar Senior Editor, <strong>The</strong> Financial Express, Mumbai<br />

“I have to say that the Indian Economic Review, 2005 Vol. III, is<br />

very impressive and the material is very good. I send all of you involved<br />

with it, my heartiest congratulations and wish you all the best.”<br />

<strong>The</strong> Lord Paul, <strong>The</strong> Rt. Hon. Lord Paul of Marylebone<br />

“I liked the review... it is stimulating reading which forces the reader to think<br />

about the issue...”<br />

Dr. A. K. Singh, Giri Institute of Development Studies, Lucknow<br />

“Undoubtedly, it is of exceptional quality and amongst the best that I have<br />

seen in my interaction with similar organisations in different countries. I merely<br />

wanted to write to you and congratulate you and your institution on an extremely<br />

well researched and presented endeavour... I have taken the liberty of putting<br />

the copies that I had got along in the WTO library.”<br />

Mr. Shishir Priyadarshi, Development Division, WTO, Geneva<br />

“…...It is a very informative document.”<br />

Dr. V.L. Chopra, Member, Planning Commission, New Delhi<br />

“...I found it very useful material, which has dealt with the vital issues that<br />

we are facing in the field of education, health, poverty and employment. I would<br />

like to compliment all the authors as well as the editorial team for bringing out<br />

such a valuable publication.”<br />

Dr. Arun Nigavekar, Chairman, UGC, New Delhi<br />

“If the purpose of a think tank is not merely to think issues through but also<br />

to ignite thinking among the readers, I think you have succeeded very well<br />

indeed.”<br />

Mr. R. Badrinath, Director, Division of Trade Support Services, International Trade<br />

Centre, Geneva<br />

“…I thoroughly enjoyed going through your recent<br />

IER…it is undoubtedly a mammoth task of pulling together<br />

divergent perspectives on the critical issues of the nation…..”<br />

Dr. Parth J Shah, Centre for Civil Society, New Delhi<br />

“Modern India certainly needs more think tanks like yours... unlike most<br />

academic journals, yours is well-designed, readable and also conveys a sense<br />

of aesthetics and humour through the illustrations... it well reflects the high<br />

standards of the <strong>IIPM</strong>.”<br />

Mr. Brij Khindaria, President, Diplomatic forum for Business, Geneva.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!