12.11.2014 Views

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

[Dec 2007, Volume 4 Quarterly Issue] Pdf File size - The IIPM Think ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

THE<br />

INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

<strong>2007</strong><br />

<strong>Volume</strong> 4 | <strong>Quarterly</strong> <strong>Issue</strong>: 31st <strong>Dec</strong>ember <strong>2007</strong><br />

www.iipmthinktank.com<br />

www.gidf.org<br />

REIMAGINING INDIA:<br />

MORE MARKET,<br />

RETHINK<br />

EDIFY<br />

DELINEATE<br />

LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

INSIDE THIS ISSUE<br />

Development Agenda<br />

<strong>The</strong> Visible Hand<br />

Free Exchange<br />

India Re-examined<br />

Progress Within Limits<br />

<strong>The</strong> Other Path<br />

A New Beginning<br />

A N I I P M T H I N K T A N K<br />

&<br />

G R E A T I N D I A N D R E A M F O U N D A T I O N P R E S E N T A T I O N


THE GREAT INDIAN DREAM<br />

“Let us together dream of a country where poor are<br />

not just merely reduced to statistics but where there are<br />

no poor. Let there be a day when small children are<br />

taken to a poverty museum like science museum where<br />

they shiver at the plight of the way people used to live in<br />

the last millennium. Let this dream take the form of a<br />

revolution and as long as our dreams keep outweighing<br />

our memories, India would remain a young and dynamic<br />

nation on this path to global equality. And for this let the<br />

wait not be for eternity. Let us together achieve this in<br />

the next 25 years.”<br />

Prof. Arindam Chaudhuri<br />

<strong>The</strong> Great Indian Dream, 2003, Macmillan India,New Delhi<br />

“A Society where man is at the centre of all activities,<br />

a society where exploitation of man by man has been<br />

abolished, where he is cared for as an in a family, where<br />

“to each according to his need’ is practised, a society where<br />

non bureaucratic National Economic Planning is given<br />

due importance for sustainable optimum growth, where<br />

adequate social safety net is a reality and yet market’s<br />

advantages are fully taken care of for creativity and<br />

entrepreneurship, such a society can be truly described as<br />

humane society and the vision as “Humanism”.<br />

Dr. M K Chaudhuri<br />

<strong>The</strong> Great Indian Dream, 2003, Macmillan India,New Delhi<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate


ethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

4 edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate<br />

CREDITS<br />

Founder<br />

Dr. M. K. Chaudhuri<br />

Editor-in-Chief<br />

Arindam Chaudhuri<br />

Managing Editor<br />

Prasoon.S. Majumdar<br />

Deputy Editor<br />

M.N.V.V.K. Chaitanya<br />

Consulting Editor<br />

Prashanto Banerji<br />

Research Fellows<br />

Pathikrit Payne<br />

Sray Agarwal<br />

Akram Hoque<br />

Tanaya Bose<br />

Group Design Director<br />

Satyajit Datta<br />

Senior Designer<br />

Amit Sharma<br />

Designer<br />

Dinesh Chandelkar<br />

Saurabh Mishra<br />

Production Manager<br />

Gurudas Mallik Thakur<br />

Production Supervisors<br />

Digember Singh Chauhan<br />

Soumyajeet Gupta<br />

Chief Marketing Advisor<br />

Amit Saxena<br />

Marketing & Sales<br />

Neha Malhotra<br />

Principal Offices<br />

Satbari, Chandan Haula, Chattarpur, Bhatimines Road, New Delhi - 110074<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, Junction of , 32nd Road & S.V. Road, Bandra (W), Mumbai - 400 050<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, 419 100ft. Road, Koramngala, Bangalore - 560 034<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, 893/4, Bhandarkar Road, <strong>Dec</strong>can Gymkhana, Pune - 411 004<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, 145, Marshall’s Road, Egmore, Chennai - 600 008<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower , 19, Inqulab Society, gulbai Tekra, Off C.G. Road, Ahmedabad - 380 015<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Tower, 6-3-252/2, Erramanzil, Banjara Hills, Hyderabad - 500 082<br />

We are keen to hear from anyone, who would like to share their experiences concerning Indian<br />

economic issues, or would like to know more about<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> Publications. You can e-mail us on m.chaitanya@iipm.edu & neha.malhotra@iipm.edu<br />

Or alternatively please call Neha Malhotra at 9818825794<br />

Additional <strong>Think</strong>ing<br />

www.iipmthinktank.com<br />

www.iipm.edu<br />

www.iipmpublications.com<br />

www.arindamchaudhuri.com<br />

www.thesundayindian.com<br />

www.thedailyindian.com<br />

www.businessandeconomy.org<br />

www.gidf.org<br />

www.planmanconsulting.com<br />

Printed by:<br />

Rolleract Press Servies, C-163, Ground Floor,<br />

Naraina industrial Area, Phase-I, New Delhi - 16<br />

Disclaimer :<br />

All efforts have been taken to ensure the veracity of the information contained in the research, however <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong><br />

<strong>Think</strong> Tank expressly disclaims any and all warranties, express or implied, including without limitation warranties of<br />

merchantability and fitness for a particular purpose, with respect to any service or material. In no event shall <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong><br />

<strong>Think</strong> Tank be liable for any direct, indirect, incidental, punitive, or consequential damages of any kind whatsoever<br />

with respect to the and materials, although the reader may freely use the research and material provided, <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong><br />

<strong>Think</strong> Tank retains all trademark right and copyright on all the text and graphics.


PARADIGM PRISM<br />

“<strong>The</strong>re is no knowledge, no light, no<br />

wisdom that you are in possession of, but<br />

what you have received it from some source.”<br />

Who we are?<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank, an independent, India-centric research body, is inspired by<br />

Dr. M.K. Chaudhuri’s vision of India as an economic powerhouse in the 21st century; a modern<br />

nation state where poverty becomes history and the underprivileged are not consigned to<br />

the dustbin of amnesia. <strong>The</strong> national presence (across 7 nodes, New Delhi, Mumbai, Chennai,<br />

Pune, Bangalore, Hyderabad, & Ahmedabad) makes our understanding of the economy superior,<br />

where in many research fellows and scholars, embark on research assignments and network<br />

with global intelligentsia.<br />

What we believe?<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank is wholly free of ideology and looks at the Indian developmental paradigms,<br />

purely modelled upon the basis of ‘objective reality’ by opting for prescriptive economics. We<br />

start with real-life problems, lay down solutions and examine them in real-life context (through<br />

G.I.D Foundation) and observe what we learn about people and other variables in the systems<br />

in India as we opine that there is much more to boundary between the humanity and the world<br />

of ideas. We passionately believe in the credo that we constantly seek to follow: rethink, edify<br />

and delineate. This enduring commitment has helped us foster and broaden the parameters of<br />

public policy debate and alternatives. Toward that goal, it strives to achieve greater involvement<br />

of the intelligent, concerned change agents (reform minded politicians, public servants, socially<br />

responsible firms and citizens) in questions of policy and the ideation. Furthermore, we ardently<br />

believe that the managers of tomorrow that are being groomed at <strong>IIPM</strong> today will play a decisive<br />

role in India’s renewed tryst with destiny.<br />

What we do?<br />

-Brigham Young<br />

As a premier ‘ideas organisation’, <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank is committed to enhance public<br />

awareness of policy issues in economics and management and to engineer solutions that will<br />

fulfill the Great Indian Dream. By publishing the findings of its research, and through the active<br />

participation of its senior researchers in the media and policy, it aims to bring new knowledge<br />

to the attention of policy makers. Every year, <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank commissions and publishes<br />

socio-economic three quarterly reviews and an annual review, on a wide range of policy<br />

issues including education, health, poverty, unemployment, agriculture, industry, services, FDI,<br />

external trade, infrastructure and environment. All these outputs meet the highest standards of<br />

scholarship, are accessible to a broad readership, and explore policy alternatives consistent<br />

with the philosophy of ours. <strong>The</strong> central theme of our issues are devoted to assess where the<br />

critical predicaments are, analysing what needs to be done to annul the element of development<br />

deterrents in the economy and offer concrete proposals on how to accelerate welfare<br />

everywhere towards achieving inclusive development. <strong>The</strong> India Economy Review is a small<br />

manifestation of that vision. More than 3,000 students (7 nodes of <strong>IIPM</strong>) have—and continue<br />

to—spent endless hours conducting primary and secondary research on strategic issues that<br />

confront India. This research is then analysed by many scholars across the 7 campuses. Brand<br />

new insights and policy recommendations that are provided by this core team are then crafted,<br />

honed and polished by member Economics Research Group (ERG). This massive effort is<br />

spearheaded and led by the renowned economist and management guru, Prof. Arindam<br />

Chaudhuri. We trust that the untiring efforts of <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank are a modest, yet<br />

significant contribution to the policy reinvention that is poised to transform India.<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate


ethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate<br />

THE FUTURE IS HERE<br />

“<strong>The</strong> great aim of education is not<br />

knowledge but action.”<br />

-Herbert Spencer<br />

Since its incorporation (1973), <strong>IIPM</strong> has been an institution with privileged traditions, in the<br />

diversity of its fraternity, its global outlook, its world class research and its commitment to alternative<br />

national economic planning process.<br />

It can be said, without much oversimplification that there are no ‘underdeveloped economies’.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are only ‘under managed’ countries. Japan 140 years was ago was an underdeveloped<br />

country by every material measurement. But it very quickly produced management of great<br />

competence, indeed of excellence. <strong>The</strong> policy inference is that ‘management’ is the prime mover<br />

and ‘development’ is the consequence. At <strong>IIPM</strong>, every one considers that development is a matter<br />

of human energies rather than economic wealth. And the generation and direction of these human<br />

energies is the task of ‘management’. Accordingly, we formed <strong>The</strong> Great Indian Dream. Unlike<br />

any other dream, this is one dream which each one of us are determined to realise and that too in<br />

our own lifetimes. Each bit of cynicism and condemnation from pessimists makes us evolve even<br />

stronger and determined.<br />

All our endeavours and initiative is towards realisation of this dream, where in we produce<br />

committed ‘bare foot’ managers and entrepreneurs who are needed by nation, on an insistent<br />

basis. As an educational institute, we aim at initializing a three dimensional personality in <strong>IIPM</strong>ites,<br />

viz.<br />

Pursuit of knowledge in economics and management<br />

Commitment to economic, social, political and technological upliftment of masses and<br />

Cultivation of taste for literature, fine arts and etc.<br />

Economists often have limited access to the practical problems facing senior managers, while<br />

senior managers often lack the time and motivation to look beyond their own industry to the<br />

larger issues of the global economy. It has set before it the twin tasks: to reorient education and<br />

research towards the needs of both the private and public sectors and to establish the link between<br />

the National Economic Planning and the development of private enterprises in Indian economy.<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> dares to look beyond, and understands that what we teach today, other adopt tomorrow.<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong>’s service output (education, research and consulting,) is a unique combination of two distinct<br />

disciplines: economics and management. Through this integration, <strong>IIPM</strong> helps guide business and<br />

policy leaders in shaping the Indian and global economy, bringing together the practical insights<br />

of industry with broader national and global perspectives.<br />

A hall mark of <strong>IIPM</strong> is that it is armed with the comparative advantage of engaging the<br />

committed, passionate and brightest management post graduates and undergraduates, who<br />

pursued the education at <strong>IIPM</strong> and subsequently joined it, to realise the dream. <strong>IIPM</strong> alumni, spread<br />

across the globe, holding crucial decision-making positions in the corporate sector, are bonded by<br />

the one ideology of making a positive difference, turning that ideology into a movement itself.<br />

<strong>The</strong> India Economy Review is another humble initiative towards the realisation of the same and<br />

more distinctly, engaging the broader publics and pertinent stakeholders.


FROM THE EDITOR’S DESK<br />

planning for competition, not by planning against competition<br />

Dear reader,<br />

After being shackled for nearly five<br />

decades, a <strong>size</strong>able class of ingenious private<br />

entrepreneurs have been fully liberated,<br />

at least in some economic spheres.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y are now exhibiting their true potential<br />

and international competitiveness as<br />

is reflected in the popular media. In this<br />

context, after perusing all those informative,<br />

yet disparate nuggets and given the<br />

fact that India boasts of a deep financial<br />

services sector, long standing and diversified<br />

private participation (relative to<br />

China, Brazil and other emerging economies),<br />

vibrant entrepreneurial class and<br />

Anglo-Saxon legal institutions, it may<br />

seem surprising that India still painfully<br />

needs a much more market-orientation<br />

across all levels. <strong>The</strong>re is still exists a robust<br />

economic reasoning which asserts<br />

that the state should disentangle all obstacles<br />

and disengage the past planning<br />

follies to release the creative, social and<br />

economic energies of the fast growing<br />

‘bottom millions’. Consider this: According<br />

to the Heritage Foundation’s Index of<br />

Economic Freedom (<strong>2007</strong>), India is only<br />

55.6 percent free. This score makes it the<br />

world’s 104th freest economy!<br />

In this issue of IER, many empirical<br />

research studies profess that, among<br />

other positive outcomes, economic freedom<br />

promotes national growth and poverty<br />

reduction. Furthermore, different<br />

research papers outline the processes and<br />

policy implications of business freedom,<br />

financial freedom and investment freedom<br />

in several areas, which specifically<br />

and importantly includes<br />

basic education,<br />

labour markets<br />

and financial markets.<br />

Unlike most other issues,<br />

IER this time<br />

covers not only business<br />

and economics,<br />

but also deals with<br />

important research<br />

submissions that falls<br />

outside the realm of traditional economics-<br />

such as intellectual property, ecology<br />

and environment, economic history and<br />

politics This issue, we have some original<br />

research and novel analysis about<br />

• Public governance, market, deprivation<br />

and the political system.<br />

• India’s growing ecological footprint<br />

• <strong>The</strong> international trade in higher education<br />

and implications for India.<br />

Prasoon.S.Majumdar<br />

Managing Editor<br />

M.N.V.V.K.Chaitanya<br />

Deputy Editor<br />

• Why poor parents are choosing ‘More<br />

Market, Less Government’ in education,<br />

and what we should do about it?<br />

• Accountable governance and pro-poor<br />

markets for poverty reduction<br />

• Reforms in the Indian banking sector<br />

and policy reversal<br />

• Economic freedom in India’s product<br />

and labour markets<br />

Above all, after reading all the opinions<br />

featured here in this issue, we at the<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank are of the firm opinion<br />

that, if we get a state that reflects more of<br />

what this country is actually about, India<br />

can indeed turn the century and its market--<br />

around, in the very near future. <strong>The</strong><br />

impressive response in areas that have<br />

been reformed in the recent past must<br />

give policymakers confidence that further<br />

liberalisation will eventually deliver additional<br />

growth dividends and foster the<br />

process of pulling millions of people out<br />

of poverty.<br />

Best,<br />

Prasoon.S.Majumdar<br />

M.N.V.V.K. Chaitanya


SEARCH, SIEVE, SCHEME...<br />

“Research is formalised curiosity. It is poking<br />

and prying with a purpose.”<br />

Zora Neale Hurston<br />

In economics, like in everyday existence, it is<br />

imperative to hear, perceive and consider what<br />

others have to say. Each issue of <strong>The</strong> IER brings<br />

together a selection of important contributions on a<br />

particular theme, authored by some of the brightest<br />

minds in different areas of Indian economics. <strong>The</strong><br />

provocation for publishing these issues arises from<br />

the fact that over the years economic journals have<br />

become copious, exclusive and expensive. Most of<br />

the journals and a good many of the books have gone<br />

beyond the cerebral and financial reach of general<br />

students and other scholars. It is for them that these<br />

issues are primarily being raised and debated here.<br />

Much about India is transparent enough. One does<br />

not require detailed criteria, cunning calibration or<br />

probing analysis to pinpoint India’s problems and<br />

recognise its antecedents. <strong>The</strong>re is in fact much that<br />

is perceptible about India. But not everything about<br />

India is even if simplistic is so simple. <strong>The</strong> learned<br />

reader would appreciate the fact that India is like an<br />

elephant that looms too large to be grasped within a<br />

distinct structure and paradigm the constituent parts<br />

of which would fail to reveal the entirety. Obviously and<br />

observably, no suggested solution to any protracted<br />

and complex socio-economic problem will satisfy<br />

all sides and stake-holders evenly. Consequently,<br />

there exists an enormous diversity in economic<br />

thinking and perspectives, as is also reflected in the<br />

viewpoints of different expert contributors in this<br />

issue. <strong>The</strong> intended outcome of this exercise is to<br />

facilitate the invention, improvement, deliberation<br />

and dissemination of innovation in economic thinking<br />

and national economic planning, insisting merely on<br />

well-grounded, open and unbiased debates, without<br />

predetermined outcomes. It is impossible to do justice<br />

to the entire field of Indian economics in a single<br />

issue. <strong>The</strong> topics selected for this issue are those<br />

which are of critical and immediate importance to<br />

India. Majority of them were freshly and exclusively<br />

written. Encapsulated, it is a constructive attempt<br />

aimed at helping India actualise its promises and<br />

potential. <strong>The</strong> editors hope that this issue of IER<br />

will proffer the reader a flavour of dynamism and<br />

excitement and persuade her/him to participate<br />

in the journey towards realising ‘<strong>The</strong> Great Indian<br />

Dream’. At the same time, it illuminates the terrible,<br />

practical problems of India and Bharat.<br />

HAPPY READING...<br />

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank likes to thank all the internal faculty who have been instrumental in coordinating<br />

with many authors all across India and according their unstinted support. <strong>The</strong> assistance of Prof.<br />

R.Krishnan and Syed Ahmed (<strong>IIPM</strong> Chennai), Mr. Tareque Laskar (<strong>IIPM</strong> Bangalore), Mr. Sudipto<br />

Chatterjee (<strong>IIPM</strong> Ahmedabad), Prof.Jayanta Chakraborti and Ms. Bindiya Naik (<strong>IIPM</strong> Pune), has been<br />

more valuable than, perhaps, they realise. Ms. Vareen Gadhoke Ray at Planman Media, particularly, did<br />

all that it was possible to do for this issue of IER.


(F)ACT SHEET<br />

INDIA’S FUTURE: Redesigning Development Agenda<br />

Liberalism As <strong>The</strong> Basis Of Human Rights And Dignity<br />

Christopher LINGLE 12<br />

India’s Future – Knowledge And Learning<br />

Societies Or Mere Markets And State<br />

Lawrence Surendra 16<br />

State And Market Conundrum In <strong>The</strong> Indian<br />

Context –A Need For Debates<br />

Pradeep Banerjee 24<br />

Larger Market Role, Reduced Government Interventions–<br />

Is It A Misnomer?<br />

Anandajit Goswami 32<br />

THE VISIBLE HAND: Government’s Role<br />

Governance, Market, Deprivation And <strong>The</strong> Political System<br />

Amal Sanyal 36<br />

<strong>The</strong> Economics Of Social Unrest – Its Causes And Cure<br />

Nilanjan Banik 42<br />

More Market, Less Government: A Recipe For Disaster For <strong>The</strong><br />

Water Sector<br />

Shripad Dharmadikary 46<br />

Inclusive Growth In India: A Case Of Structural And Agrarian<br />

Challenges<br />

D.M. Diwakar 52<br />

Market Economy And <strong>The</strong> State Of Regional<br />

Disparities In India<br />

Anu Singh 62<br />

Accountable Governance And Pro-poor Markets For Effective<br />

Poverty Reduction<br />

Anindo Banerjee 68<br />

Food Security In India: <strong>Issue</strong>s And Implications<br />

Anajani Sinha 74<br />

FREE EXCHANGE: More Markets<br />

Why Poor Parents Are Choosing ‘More Market, Less Government’<br />

In Education, And What We Should Do About It?<br />

James Tooley 80<br />

International Trade In Higher Education: What Should India Do?<br />

Stephen P. Heyneman 86<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate


ethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink<br />

edify edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

rethink edify<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

delineate<br />

rethink<br />

edify<br />

10 edify<br />

delineate<br />

delineate<br />

Water Resources In Gujarat And Role Of Water Markets In<br />

Breaking Gridlock In Water Scarcity – A Replicable Policy<br />

Prescription At National Level<br />

Jharna Pathak 94<br />

Commodity Futures: A Catalyst For Agricultural Development<br />

V. Shunmugam & D.G. Prasad 102<br />

Overseas Investment By Indian Firms: Recent Trends<br />

And Patterns<br />

Deepika Wadhwa 108<br />

Indian Banking Reforms And Policy Reversal: A Vicious Cycle<br />

Anurag Sharma 116<br />

Indian Corporate Bond Market: <strong>The</strong> Road Ahead<br />

Pramod K. Yadav & Ritesh Agarwal 132<br />

QUO VADIS: India Reexamined<br />

Just How Free Are India’s Labour And Product Markets?<br />

Paul Conway, Richard Herd & Sean Dougherty 138<br />

Going For Growth Through Economic Reforms: <strong>The</strong> Case Of India<br />

Rok Spruk 146<br />

India’s Unique Pattern Of Development: Quo vadis?<br />

Kalpana Kochhar 154<br />

PROGRESS WITHIN LIMITS: Environmental Economics<br />

India’s Growing Ecological Footprint: Exploring Past And<br />

Future Changes<br />

T R Manoharan 164<br />

A NEW BEGINNING: Law And Public Policy<br />

<strong>The</strong> First Sale Doctrine Before <strong>The</strong> U.S. Supreme Court:<br />

Intellectual Property Implications For India<br />

Shubha Ghosh 168<br />

SOTTO VOCE: Economic Exposition<br />

Liberty And Prohibition: A Governance Dilemma<br />

Ali Mehdi 172<br />

THE OTHER PATH: Reimagining India<br />

An Alternative Integrated Development Perspective For <strong>The</strong><br />

Peripheral Regions: <strong>The</strong> Case Of Barak Valley In Northeast India<br />

Baharul Islam 174<br />

THE ‘OTHER’ INDIA: Tenancy Reforms<br />

Tenancy Reforms in Orissa: A Critical Perspective<br />

Mrutyunjay Dash 182


CALL FOR PAPERS<br />

IER is a quarterly journal featuring contents of academic and professional interest that are of utility to managers,<br />

policy makers, politicians, consultants, teachers and students in the areas of Economics and Management. It<br />

is a multidisciplinary platform for sharing and disseminating knowledge in the issues of education, health,<br />

poverty, unemployment, agriculture, industry, service, FDI, international trade, infrastructure and environment,<br />

pertaining to Indian economy. We passionately believe in the credo that we constantly seek to follow: rethink,<br />

edify and delineate. This enduring commitment has helped us foster and broaden the parameters of public<br />

policy debate and alternatives. Toward that goal, we strive to achieve greater involvement of the intelligent,<br />

concerned change agents (reform minded politicians, public servants, academicians, socially responsible firms,<br />

civil society organizations and citizens) in questions of policy and the ideation. In order to further augment value<br />

and provision a broad perspective to Indian economic problems, your knowledge and expertise in the above<br />

mentioned fields would be highly valuable to IER. We would like the possibility of receiving a write-up from you,<br />

on a topic of your expertise and interest as per the under-mentioned guidelines.<br />

Guidelines For Contributors<br />

Content: Articles should be in the areas of education, health, poverty, unemployment, agriculture, industry,<br />

service, FDI, international trade, infrastructure and environment, pertaining to Indian economy, which are<br />

of contemporary interest and value to the esteemed and intellectual readers. <strong>The</strong> journal seeks to present<br />

an eclectic approach supported by empirical research or practical applications as necessary. Contents that<br />

demonstrate clear and bold thinking, fresh and useful ideas and solutions, accessible and jargon-free expression,<br />

and unmistakable authority and proficiency are those most likely to meet our reader’s needs.<br />

Reviewing Process: Each article is reviewed by the Economics Research Group (ERG). If found suitable, the<br />

same may be sent for another round of review before final acceptance. With prior information and consent,<br />

the editors reserve the right to modify and improve the manuscripts to meet IER’s standards of presentation<br />

and style. <strong>The</strong> editors also have full right to accept or reject an article for publication. Editorial decisions will be<br />

communicated within a period of 2 weeks of the receipt of the submission.<br />

Word Length: Articles should be of 2,500 to 3,000 words including abstract and references.<br />

Headings And Sub-Headings: Headings should be typed in capital and underlined; sub-headings should be<br />

typed in upper and lower case and underlined.<br />

References: References to other publications should follow the Harvard style.<br />

Figures, Charts And Diagrams: Use of figures, charts and diagrams should be kept to the minimum and text<br />

should indicate where the same will appear. All tables, charts, graphs should be typed on separate sheets. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

should be numbered as Table-1, Table 2, etc. <strong>The</strong> graphs must have the minimum amount of descriptive text and<br />

the axes should be labeled with variable written out in full, along the length of axes.<br />

Abstract And Key Words: An abstract within 100 words and three key words should be submitted.<br />

Author’s Bio-data And Photograph: A brief bio-data with full postal and e-mail addresses and a coloured<br />

photograph should be sent along with the articles.<br />

Copyright: Authors should warrant that their work is not an infringement of any existing copyright and will<br />

indemnify the publisher against any breach of warranty. <strong>The</strong> articles published in IER will become the legal<br />

copyright of the publisher. <strong>The</strong> articles appearing in IER are the personal responsibility of the authors themselves<br />

and do not reflect the views of the editor, principal or the Economics Research Group (ERG) or the sponsoring<br />

organization. <strong>The</strong> author(s) will receive a complementary copy of IER in which their articles are published; they<br />

will also receive ten reprints of their articles for their personal use.<br />

Submission: <strong>The</strong> submission should be sent to M.N.V.V.K. Chaitanya at m.chaitanya@iipm.edu


Christopher LINGLE,<br />

Professor of Economic at<br />

Universidad Francisco<br />

Marroquin in Guatemala<br />

Liberalism As <strong>The</strong> Basis Of<br />

Human Rights And Dignity<br />

"Of all the varieties of virtues,<br />

liberalism is the most beloved."<br />

-Aristotle<br />

I<br />

dealism and an abiding concern<br />

for mankind tend to preoccupy<br />

young intellectuals throughout<br />

the world. Ironically, despite the successes<br />

in promoting human development,<br />

Liberalism remains relatively<br />

underappreciated by the youth in<br />

most countries.<br />

This problem is compounded in India<br />

by legal arrangements that make it<br />

impossible to form political organizations<br />

that identify with Liberal ideals.<br />

As it is, modifications to the preamble<br />

of the Constitution made during the<br />

Emergency specify that: “India is a<br />

sovereign, secular, socialist republic.”<br />

At the same time, an amendment<br />

was made to the relevant section in the<br />

Representation of the People Act, 1950<br />

to require all recognized and registered<br />

parties to swear to uphold the<br />

Constitution. <strong>The</strong> courts have ruled<br />

variously on whether or not the Preamble<br />

is to be deemed a part of the Constitution.<br />

<strong>The</strong> current view on this is<br />

that since all parties must stand for<br />

Socialism, no party can legally register<br />

to espouse Classical Liberalism as a<br />

political platform. Attempts to challenge<br />

this ban on political speech of<br />

Liberals languish in the court system.<br />

One might consider the level of outrage<br />

that would lead to a rapid hearing<br />

if socialist or communist parties were<br />

banned. And the strongest voice to remove<br />

such limits would almost certainly<br />

be led by Liberals! Another<br />

problem is that opponents of the Liberal<br />

view effectively create a veil of<br />

good intentions to obscure the obvious<br />

flaws and failings of Socialism. Meanwhile,<br />

critiques of Liberalism make the<br />

unfounded assertion that it offers few<br />

answers for solving social problems<br />

within the larger community.<br />

To counter this latter tactic, Liberals<br />

must make clear representations of the<br />

social benefits of Liberalism. One area<br />

that might be fruitful is to articulate<br />

the Liberal basis of the concept of socalled<br />

human rights. It turns out that<br />

Human rights did not formally appear<br />

12 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

in international law until 1948 when<br />

the Universal <strong>Dec</strong>laration of Human<br />

Rights (UDHR) was signed. This document<br />

enshrines principles of equality<br />

and justice, and the sanctity of a person’s<br />

rights regardless of their ethnicity,<br />

religion or gender. <strong>The</strong> first sentence<br />

of the 1948 <strong>Dec</strong>laration states<br />

that “inherent human dignity” should<br />

be recognized. As such, a balanced application<br />

of human rights principles<br />

would not impose social responsibilities<br />

that come into conflict with<br />

personal rights.<br />

But some attempts to curb assaults<br />

on the dignity of human beings have<br />

contributed to the continuing problems<br />

that offend a collective sense of justice.<br />

Indeed, many of the most vocal supporters<br />

of so-called human rights actually<br />

promote legal concepts that inadvertently<br />

support the sort of misconduct<br />

they wish to see ended. In particular,<br />

demands for human rights in terms of<br />

social or collective rights undermine<br />

the universality intended by the drafters<br />

of the UDHR. For example, government<br />

officials frequently engage in<br />

populist promises that define rights<br />

based on economic or social characteristics.<br />

In modern times, there has been<br />

an emergence of identity politics<br />

whereby leaders of group-based movements<br />

claim they represent the interests<br />

of groups defined by ethnicity,<br />

class, religion, gender, sexual orientation<br />

or other criteria.<br />

A focus on group “rights” divides<br />

communities into distinctive and separate<br />

political classes that are in conflict<br />

with the interests and rights of other<br />

groups. Demands for an assignment of<br />

rights as a matter of law tend to be<br />

based on a perception of some historical<br />

oppression or victimhood. In the<br />

first instance, assignment of particular<br />

rights contradicts a notion of universal<br />

rights wherein all humans possess<br />

equal rights regardless of differences<br />

race or ethnicity. And basing human<br />

rights upon collective concepts of<br />

“fundamental” social rights leads to<br />

zero or negative-sum policy outcomes<br />

with some groups benefiting and others<br />

losing. One common intrusion to<br />

individual liberties relating is the imposition<br />

of limits on the exercise of<br />

private property rights and the freedom<br />

of exchange. In this regard, the<br />

excesses of protectionism and unlawful<br />

expropriation are legendary. <strong>The</strong>re is<br />

an unfortunate tendency for few objections<br />

being raised when the assets of<br />

private corporations are nationalized.<br />

But this indifference overlooks the fact<br />

that acts that diminish economic<br />

freedoms provide the logic and mechanisms<br />

for reducing civic and political<br />

freedoms. Those wishing to support<br />

human rights should consider that<br />

rights and dignity of humans are best<br />

preserved through rigorous support for<br />

individual rights and the Rule of Law.<br />

As it is, proponents of collective or<br />

group rights that ignore the key role of<br />

individuals as bearers of rights guaranteed<br />

to autonomous humans undermine<br />

the Rule of Law.<br />

Indeed, the assertion of group rights<br />

over individual rights provided the basis<br />

for the injustices of apartheid in<br />

South Africa and genocide in other<br />

parts of the world. <strong>The</strong> assignment of<br />

group rights in the case of apartheid is<br />

a worst-case scenario of abuses arising<br />

from the violation of these generality<br />

conditions. But other extreme acts<br />

arising out of the exclusivity of ethnic<br />

nationalism had destructive consequences<br />

in the Balkans and plague<br />

other parts of the world.<br />

References to social or collective or<br />

group rights mask the fact that assignment<br />

of such rights may involve empowerment<br />

or possessions that require<br />

the action or aid of others. In the process<br />

of activating such group rights, the<br />

rights of other individuals will be violated<br />

by imposing obligation upon<br />

them. Rights that impose obligations<br />

necessarily attenuate the freedom of<br />

choice and action of others. In such an<br />

order, human beings are treated as objects<br />

or servants of the community<br />

Rights that impose obligations necessarily attenuate the<br />

freedom of choice and action of others. In such an order,<br />

human beings are treated as objects or servants of the<br />

community rather than valued as unique individuals<br />

rather than valued as unique individuals.<br />

Whereas the assignment and enforcement<br />

of individual rights encourages<br />

coordination and cooperation,<br />

collectivized rights involve conflict<br />

and require coercion. As it turns out,<br />

many of the countries that suffer most<br />

from communal violence and sectarianism<br />

are those that have imple<br />

mented policies that define rights of<br />

minorities. Clearly, this approach has<br />

not worked.<br />

A collectivistic approach to human<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

13


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

rights as group rights also violates the<br />

generality requirement of jurisprudence<br />

associated with Kant’s categorical<br />

imperative. Under a Kantian system,<br />

justice is served when rights are<br />

applied generally without particular,<br />

arbitrary preferences for either individuals<br />

or groups.<br />

What is at stake is the choice of a<br />

system that serves as the means for attaining<br />

and measuring social justice.<br />

On the one hand, private property<br />

rights might be seen as essential for<br />

safeguarding most other civil rights.<br />

On the other hand, these rights might<br />

be the most effective incentive to inspire<br />

individual effort that may lead to<br />

general prosperity of the community.<br />

A focus on “social” or communitarian<br />

rights tends to lead to reliance<br />

upon a politicization of the economic<br />

position (income and wealth) of individuals<br />

in the community. Politicizing<br />

such outcomes in pursuit of a special<br />

sense of social justice is open to exploitation<br />

by special interest groups or<br />

power elites of other groups or specific<br />

individuals within the community.<br />

It also allows envy and politics to brew<br />

up a ghastly stew. Anchoring human<br />

rights to a (more or less inviolable)<br />

concept of private property reduces<br />

the number of politicized decisions affecting<br />

peoples’ lives. This would be<br />

less exploitative and also less arbitrary<br />

and probably more stable since community<br />

actions are justified by mutual<br />

consent and voluntary exchange among<br />

individuals. Despite well-intentioned<br />

attempts to create or promote a broad<br />

sense of community, democracy allows<br />

the interests of special groups to dominate<br />

the interests of the wider community.<br />

Mechanisms that rely upon<br />

For greater harmony in the future, political initiatives<br />

and the relentless expansion of restrictions and bureaucracy<br />

that contribute to dehumanization should be<br />

replaced by individual initiatives<br />

majority rule to determine the distribution<br />

of wealth or goods tends to reinforce<br />

an increased sense of collective<br />

identity as a means to avoid, to deflect<br />

or to harness as well as to direct<br />

the policies.<br />

In the end, politicization arising out<br />

of attempts to enforce collective rights<br />

can be seen as the principal cause of<br />

the powerlessness of individuals. Expansion<br />

in the nature and direction of<br />

state intervention replaces the rights<br />

of the individual, except as a member<br />

of a group.<br />

In the United States of America, increased<br />

political divisiveness has<br />

emerged as more collective action has<br />

been mandated. Despite emphasizing<br />

multi-cultural studies in American<br />

universities, one result has been demands<br />

for a restoration of “separate<br />

but equal” facilities for different<br />

groups. More troubling is what seems<br />

to be a growing intolerance of diversity<br />

due to resentment of members of<br />

groups who are perceived as recipients<br />

of preferential treatment. Members of<br />

groups identified as historical victimizers<br />

begin to imagine that they are<br />

being victimized and captive to an insubstantial<br />

logic of retribution. Certain<br />

members of the Hindu community in<br />

India are making such claims against<br />

the Muslim population.<br />

Defining human rights in collective<br />

or group terms invites an increased<br />

politicization of life outcomes, something<br />

to be avoided given India’s ethic<br />

and religious diversity. Unfortunately,<br />

populist politicians seldom search for<br />

private solutions to solve problems or<br />

conflicting interests in a private manner.<br />

For greater harmony in the future,<br />

political initiatives and the relentless<br />

expansion of restrictions and bureaucracy<br />

that contribute to dehumanization<br />

should be replaced by individual initiatives.<br />

As such, the best way serve<br />

humane ends is to ground the concept<br />

of human rights in a Liberal order<br />

where individual rights are protected<br />

within a Rule of Law.<br />

14 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


10 WEBSITES TO IMPROVE YOUR LIFE<br />

INVITATION<br />

PRICE RS.50<br />

ONLY!<br />

GET MORE FROM TECHNOLOGY<br />

JANUARY, 2008<br />

Intel vs AMD<br />

<strong>The</strong> battle intensifies<br />

in 2008<br />

•WordPerfect Office X3 •Zoho<br />

•OpenOffice.org •Google Docs Beta<br />

Best Office<br />

Alternatives<br />

•Lotus Symphony Beta<br />

•iWork<br />

•<strong>Think</strong>Free Online<br />

Best products of<br />

the year <strong>2007</strong>


Lawrence Surendra,<br />

Planning Commission of India Chair in<br />

Economics, Department of Studies in<br />

Economics and Cooperation,<br />

University of Mysore<br />

India’s Future – Knowledge And Learning<br />

Societies Or Mere Markets And State<br />

"Economics is not a body of concrete<br />

wealth but an engine for<br />

the discovery of concrete truth."<br />

-Alfred Marshall<br />

<strong>The</strong> Central Statistical Organization<br />

in its estimate released on<br />

May 21, <strong>2007</strong>, estimated GDP at<br />

factor cost at 1999 – 2000 prices as<br />

Rs.28,482 billion. India’s GDP at factor<br />

cost increased from US$20 billion in<br />

1950-51 to US$828 billion in 2006-07.<br />

GDP at current market prices was estimated<br />

at US$912 billion in 2006-07. With<br />

increasing integration, share of merchandise<br />

trade (imports + exports) increased<br />

from 12.2 percent of GDP in 1950-51 to<br />

33.6 percent in 2006-07. Inclusion of<br />

services will increase this share further.<br />

As per the World Economic Outlook<br />

(April <strong>2007</strong>), India accounted for 6.3<br />

percent of global GDP measured in terms<br />

of Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) and<br />

1.3 percent export of goods and services.<br />

In terms of PPP, India’s GDP in 2006 was<br />

valued at around US$ four trillion, nearly<br />

five times the GDP valued at current<br />

nominal exchange rate.<br />

<strong>The</strong> figures in terms economic growth<br />

are impressive with the Finance Minister<br />

aiming for a growth rate of above 10 percent<br />

(around 12 percent) next year. Ambitious<br />

but very much in the realm of<br />

possibility, if the Finance Minister plays<br />

his hands well. For those who directly or<br />

indirectly benefit by this growth, especially<br />

the middle and upper middle classes,<br />

this is news to cheer and feel gratified,<br />

in the sense of feeling a sense of pleasure<br />

and comfort. <strong>The</strong> latter sense of gratification<br />

leads not only to the desire for<br />

greater and greater gratification but also<br />

leads to over-confidence and arrogance;<br />

signs of the latter are plenty and all it requires<br />

is to read the papers in the metros.<br />

This arrogance around a growing economy<br />

also leads to all kinds of fanciful assumptions<br />

about the role of state and<br />

markets and a kind of evangelical zeal<br />

about markets. For those who will benefit<br />

little or nothing by this growth and<br />

for the many who may even become or<br />

already are, victims of the rapid economic<br />

growth, they may still hope that there<br />

would be some protections for them and<br />

that they still remain constitutionally<br />

citizens of India with equal opportunities<br />

16 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

and rights. <strong>The</strong> fact that the economy<br />

and its growth happens within the framework<br />

of a solemnly constituted nation<br />

bound by constitutional obligations,<br />

could give the poor and disadvantaged<br />

reasons to hope and aspire for an inclusive<br />

growth, something that the Finance<br />

Minister has also recently been referring<br />

to and on more than one occasion. If inclusive<br />

growth is not to become a mantra<br />

but serious policy, then it has important<br />

implications for the future of India as we<br />

know it. <strong>The</strong> future of India as a nation,<br />

as an idea that has so important a place<br />

in the comity of nations globally, will<br />

critically depend on how economic policy<br />

in our country deals with India’s large<br />

scale mass poverty. That remains and<br />

will remain the Indian economy’s most<br />

central problem; how economic policy<br />

deals with it, will be what makes or breaks<br />

economic growth and political stability;<br />

in the ultimate analysis our ability to<br />

break the poverty trap is what will determine<br />

whether we pull through as a society<br />

or descend gradually into chaos and<br />

anarchy. This reality needs to be stated<br />

upfront before entering into any discussion<br />

about state and markets.<br />

<strong>The</strong> State And Economists<br />

Faster growth rates in the economy has<br />

led to calls for an entirely market based<br />

economic growth model and to even assume<br />

that, the state is and can no longer<br />

be the primum mobilum of development.<br />

If that is so, then how does one deal with<br />

the question of the state when it comes to<br />

thorny problems such as poverty alleviation,<br />

social exclusion and gross societal<br />

inequalities that are a drag on the overall<br />

development of a nation. Often there is a<br />

scare tactic that is mounted about the<br />

dangers of a dirigistic state and which the<br />

Indian state hardly is, especially after the<br />

reforms of the 1990s and from the VIII<br />

Plan onwards. Once, the distinction between<br />

accepting a role for the state in<br />

development and that of a dirigistic state<br />

is deliberately blurred, it is easier to<br />

equate the two and call all state involvement<br />

as dirigistic and then try to figure<br />

out in the push for market friendly economic<br />

reforms how to reduce the role of<br />

the state. This then becomes a false debate.<br />

More critical than raising false<br />

clashes between state and market in the<br />

new millennium, is whether the state in<br />

developing societies such as India has a<br />

developmental role, if so how does then<br />

one define it and shape it? <strong>The</strong>re is no<br />

point in putting questions arising out of<br />

the 19th century and early 20th century<br />

problems that developed states have gone<br />

through and more so when most states,<br />

including the Indian state in an age of<br />

globalization are bending over backwards<br />

to be market and corporate friendly.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is nothing in our ‘karma’ that says,<br />

we have to go through the routes other<br />

societies have gone through. Pluralistic<br />

and sensible approaches to economic<br />

policy making and economic reform in<br />

particular requires a profound understanding<br />

that economic policy making<br />

especially in open and still vibrant democracies<br />

as ours, is related to good governance<br />

as a public good and multiplier<br />

of economic efficiency. Good governance<br />

in a society of diverse groups, interests<br />

and pulls and pressures is an art. In a developmental<br />

strategy sense, governance<br />

is central to economic policy. For this the<br />

state has a critical role in the management<br />

of the political economy of the large<br />

economies as ours and with such large<br />

and varied socio-economic problems,<br />

agro-eco systems and federal political<br />

structure. Good governance is an important<br />

and critical public good and for<br />

which the state cannot be seen as an adversary<br />

by the market. Undermining the<br />

state has serious consequences for markets<br />

as well. <strong>The</strong> State can very well be<br />

undermined from within the State by<br />

market forces. Instead of tired debates<br />

about state versus markets, what we need<br />

is serious debate on better policy and<br />

polity, involving state and markets.<br />

Once, the distinction between accepting a role for the<br />

state in development and that of a dirigistic state is deliberately<br />

blurred, it is easier to equate the two and call all<br />

state involvement as dirigistic<br />

Better policy and polity that works to the<br />

welfare of the nation as a whole than satisfy<br />

the greed of a few be it business<br />

or politicians.<br />

Economics and economic growth is<br />

part of the complexity of social systems<br />

and their inbuilt injustices, contradictions<br />

and handicaps. To think that the<br />

problems of economic growth can be unraveled<br />

without reference to the social<br />

system, would mean that when the social<br />

system starts unraveling itself, it will<br />

sweep in its wake, all traces of economics<br />

development. This is an issue that many<br />

economists have tried to skirt. It may be<br />

fashionable amidst the greed and individualism<br />

in the wake of the benefits<br />

brought to the leisure classes as a result<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

17


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

of globalization, for media gurus to triumphantly<br />

embrace the market as the<br />

panacea for all our ills. But it requires<br />

some humility to recognize that economic<br />

policy making, doing economics and<br />

shaping public policy in the context of<br />

poor and developing societies as ours,<br />

requires also a deep sense of humanity.<br />

A central issue in discussing the role of<br />

the state and economic growth is the issue<br />

about balanced growth, to avoid<br />

growing disparities between states, between<br />

regions and between different sectors<br />

of the population. For example, one<br />

of the major points of criticism by market<br />

friendly economic reformers’ is that<br />

policy and theoretical approaches, based<br />

on ‘balanced growth’, has been the bane<br />

of earlier economic policy making. Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty one of our foremost<br />

economists and who engaged in policy<br />

with that deep sense of humanity, in dismissing<br />

the debate about ‘balanced and<br />

unbalanced growth’ as semantic, refers<br />

ence to discussions of trade as a major<br />

engine for growth and like Amartya Sen,<br />

he recognizes “cycles of optimism and<br />

pessimism in trade led growth”. As Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty says, “the point I<br />

am driving at is that it was not much due<br />

to the alleged doctrine of ‘market failures’<br />

in the sense indicated by fundamental<br />

theorems of welfare economics that<br />

policy-makers in both developed and developing<br />

countries agreed to a theory of<br />

state-directed industrialization, but from<br />

a growth perspective based on data on<br />

massive agrarian overpopulation in<br />

South and Eastern Europe. Obviously<br />

the extension of this argument to deal<br />

<strong>The</strong> need to forge the new consensus that Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravorty made a plea for in the 1980s is ironically<br />

even more relevant now in the end of the first decade of<br />

the new millennium<br />

to the problem of surplus labour as a<br />

more serious conceptual and policy issue<br />

to deal with, especially in rural areas.<br />

Economist of the intellectual caliber of<br />

Sukhamoy Chakravarty, in addressing<br />

such critical issues as that of surplus labour<br />

also dealt with the problem of the<br />

state. With regard to debate about the<br />

state he points to the compatibility or<br />

otherwise between the planning principle<br />

and the principle of comparative advantage.<br />

A dichotomy which he says has<br />

been misleadingly drawn. This has refer-<br />

with countries like India was done later,<br />

although it was present in a general way<br />

from the beginning”. So much for the arguments<br />

about socialist inspired penchant<br />

for state involvement in economic<br />

planning and growth. In connection with<br />

the extension of the argument on surplus<br />

labour to underdeveloped areas, he refers<br />

to the UN Expert Group Report of<br />

1951 on 'Measures for the Economic Development<br />

of Underdeveloped Areas.<br />

'Chakravarty says, “this report reflected<br />

the emergence of a ‘development consensus’<br />

which lasted for nearly twenty five<br />

years”. He then refers to the breakdown<br />

of the consensus – “more prominently in<br />

the 1980s, based on criticisms which were<br />

first voiced by a resurgent neo-classicism<br />

on the one hand, and a ‘radical critique’<br />

of the left on the other”. This he says<br />

does not imply a demise of the sub-discipline<br />

of ‘development economics’, but,<br />

“the need to forge a new consensus” (emphasis<br />

added). <strong>The</strong> need to forge the new<br />

consensus that Sukhamoy Chakravorty<br />

made a plea for in the 1980s is ironically<br />

even more relevant now in the end of the<br />

first decade of the new millennium.<br />

We must consider ourselves very fortunate,<br />

that our nation has been blessed<br />

with a whole number of good, intellectually<br />

honest economists. In the context of<br />

looking at the perspectives of economic<br />

theory and policy, there is much that we<br />

can glean from the insightful writings of<br />

economists like the late Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty, (who along with Amartya<br />

Sen) belongs to that unique class of intellectually<br />

honest economists who have not<br />

done their economics only to pander to<br />

the tunes of the times. Economists who<br />

always did their theoretical and practical<br />

policy work, not only standing above<br />

vested interest pulls and pushes but also<br />

with a deep sense of humanity unconcerned<br />

whether that got them applause<br />

from the galleries or not. Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty’s contributions in the context<br />

of the discussion on state and markets<br />

are several and relate to the role of<br />

knowledge, the significance of coordination<br />

failure and surplus labour, the need<br />

to go beyond ‘the market failure’ or stages<br />

of growth argument, the impact of<br />

economic organizations from the viewpoint<br />

of “ensuring creativity, growth and<br />

18 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

equity”, the interdependence between<br />

agriculture and industry and the dilemma<br />

between the need for widening the<br />

market and the prevention of the abuse<br />

of monopoly power.<br />

Especially with regard to the abuse of<br />

monopoly power, let us also for example<br />

and for a moment keep in view economists<br />

and others who act like petty salesmen<br />

for the Commerce Ministry concept<br />

of SEZs. <strong>The</strong>se economists, both within<br />

state institutions and belonging to dubious<br />

NGOs, who on the one hand are the<br />

loudest ones to run the State down while<br />

singing the paens of the market, are the<br />

same ones on the other hand who are encouraging<br />

the worst abuses of monopoly<br />

power and the dismantling of the constitutional<br />

state in the name of SEZs. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

can be no greater irony than this. SEZs<br />

are best described as state encouraged<br />

rapacity by market players who cannot<br />

function in a market more even handedly<br />

regulated by the state and by a state<br />

that stands by the Indian Constitution<br />

and its protections for the rights of all<br />

citizens, be they poor peasants or workers.<br />

Those professing an almost evangelistic<br />

deal to have “growth at any cost”<br />

are oblivious to the principle that any<br />

abuse of monopoly power by the state in<br />

the name of the market, is a sure recipe<br />

that can take any nation however great it<br />

may be, including India, down a vortex of<br />

social instability and violence. This is the<br />

reality that is stares before us not only in<br />

the aftermath of Nandigram but in places<br />

like Mangalore, where fraud and deception<br />

is sought to used to divest people<br />

of productive agricultural land and create<br />

social tension and conflict. Finance<br />

Minister Chidambaram’s note of caution<br />

at the recent Indian Economic Forum<br />

that growth cannot be only for the top<br />

ten percent is not only a welcome note of<br />

caution but also an indication that<br />

policy making at the highest level is<br />

recognizing the larger objectives of<br />

economic growth.<br />

Such caution seems absent at the Commerce<br />

Ministry and most statements that<br />

emanate from the Commerce Ministry,<br />

including that of the Commerce Secretary<br />

seems not only totally oblivious to<br />

ground realities but a very unbalanced<br />

approach to economic growth priorities.<br />

While it is a matter of very deep concern<br />

as regards the long term implications for<br />

India of the SEZ route to rapid economic<br />

growth, the fact is that the disastrous<br />

nature of its implementation could actually<br />

bring down the government and the<br />

Congress Party to which belongs Mr.<br />

Kamal Nath the Commerce Minister<br />

whose Ministry seems to be recklessly<br />

spearheading the SEZ concept. Though<br />

all this may not happen before huge economic<br />

and social costs have accrued to<br />

the nation in terms of not only the accentuated<br />

conflicts it is going to engender<br />

but also in terms of the loss of revenues<br />

in terms of the state and loss of income<br />

and livelihood for thousands of people.<br />

In a globalised world where sovereignty<br />

is also at stake, the Commerce Ministry<br />

can try to run rough shod over all other<br />

Ministries including the Finance Ministry.<br />

However, what such deepening fissures<br />

in economic governance shows is<br />

the possibilities that exist for sections of<br />

the market to use one instrumentality of<br />

state, in this case the Commerce Ministry,<br />

to undermine the state as a whole<br />

and thereby society, showing the hollowness<br />

of arguments pitting market versus<br />

the state. In the end the greed and rapacity<br />

of the market can take both state and<br />

market together down.<br />

<strong>The</strong> challenge for the academic as well<br />

as working economist, for any person<br />

concerned about and engaged with public<br />

policy, is how even in these circumstances<br />

to focus on long term issues for<br />

the country as a whole. In the Indian<br />

context, what seems in my mind and<br />

echoing Sukhamoy Chakravarty, a key<br />

issue that is of great relevance for the immediate<br />

and the long term, is “a proper<br />

formulation of the role of knowledge as<br />

A key issue that is of great relevance for the immediate<br />

and the long term is “a proper formulation of the role of<br />

knowledge as a productive factor” and “institutional arrangements<br />

necessary for transition to a ‘learning society’<br />

a productive factor” and “institutional<br />

arrangements necessary for transition to<br />

a ‘learning society’ ".<br />

Knowledge And <strong>The</strong> Learning<br />

Society<br />

Chakravarty refers to Simon Kuznets<br />

who was of the conclusion that in the final<br />

analysis, it was the growth of knowledge<br />

which was the most decisive characteristic<br />

of modern economic growth.<br />

Here Kuznets was not referring to technology<br />

alone but as Chakravarty puts it,<br />

“also of basic sciences which are increasingly<br />

having profound impacts on transformations<br />

in the sphere of production<br />

that are leading to changes in the international<br />

economy”. He warns us that a<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

19


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

systematic underinvestment in science “is<br />

likely to be the result if the growth of science<br />

is left to competitive market forces”.<br />

He then refers to the “dilemma of ‘knowledge”,<br />

which he describes as that which,<br />

“pertains to the lack of compatibility between<br />

institutions which lead to the widest<br />

possible diffusion and utilization of<br />

knowledge and those which are particularly<br />

relevant for its creation in the very<br />

first instance”.<br />

If you need active, democratic, broader<br />

socially based, natural resource sustaining<br />

and future oriented policy, you<br />

need to create the intellectual environment<br />

for it. This then means better and<br />

more funding for research, in both the<br />

social sciences and natural sciences, especially<br />

in our universities. It is commendable<br />

that the 11th plan visualizes a<br />

massive investment in a whole new generation<br />

of advanced higher education<br />

institutions but existing universities do<br />

not adequately figure in the plan. <strong>The</strong><br />

Finance Minister allocating sums in his<br />

annual budget to Universities is also a<br />

good and welcome sign.<br />

<strong>The</strong> second theme that I would like to<br />

pick up and highlight from Sukhamoy<br />

Chakravarty’s prodigious output of his<br />

intellectual labour for economics and the<br />

country, is that relating to social learning,<br />

social innovation and questions regarding<br />

when do societies really become<br />

‘learning societies’. To a certain extent,<br />

in my view, it relates to the larger noninstitutional<br />

aspects of knowledge, unlike<br />

above where I partly referred to the<br />

institutional conditions for ‘knowledge’<br />

and ‘learning’. <strong>The</strong>re is also the other<br />

aspect of our ability to learn from other<br />

societies. In referring to the question of<br />

‘learning society’, we are dealing with<br />

broader questions of Human Resources<br />

Development and which are critical and<br />

particularly relevant where we stand today<br />

in our nation’s history. Knowledge in<br />

the perspective of Chakravarty needs to<br />

be seen as a public good. One could say,<br />

that in spite of all the middle class parlour<br />

talk and fashion for criticizing Nehruvian<br />

– Mahalanobis (N-M) strategy,<br />

it did give us a higher initial level of<br />

knowledge to start with. Chakravarty<br />

while objective and critical of the N-M<br />

strategy shows its validity and contribution<br />

also. On the second aspect, that of<br />

knowledge being widely shared, this is<br />

where we as a highly caste-ridden and<br />

hierarchical society, have had our problems<br />

and also by and large inherited so-<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is an extra-ordinarily rich harvest of ideas from<br />

Sukhamoy Chakravarty’s writings and how we can go<br />

beyond the dichotomies of market and state, to address<br />

urgent and needed tasks of creating ‘a learning society’<br />

cially serious failures also.<br />

Other than these broad based requirements<br />

and aspects related to creating a<br />

dynamic learning society, that can be<br />

self-sustaining and sustainable, in an<br />

economic, ecological and social sense,<br />

there are other related aspects. Some of<br />

this is related to problems such as technology,<br />

its adaptation, innovation, use<br />

and dissemination. Chakravarty is of the<br />

view that while TNCs do bring technology,<br />

we have to seriously consider whether<br />

it will in fact “lead to a significant<br />

accretion of technical knowledge appropriate<br />

to Indian conditions”. So the creation<br />

and promotion of the conditions for<br />

a learning society, is not just to import<br />

and imitate but also to adapt and contextualize.<br />

Chakravarty with reference to<br />

technology adaptation says how it is,<br />

“more appropriate to the factor endowments<br />

of developing countries deserve<br />

very close considerations”; then adds a<br />

very important qualifier, “it would be<br />

most inappropriate to leave questions of<br />

adaptation to technologists alone” and<br />

the overall macro-economic framework<br />

must be also made conducive to the process<br />

of adaptation. Finally, his other related<br />

and important point, that “given<br />

the contemporary trends in technology,<br />

it is important to allow for a theory of<br />

‘knowledge’ production and dissemination”.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is an extra-ordinarily rich<br />

harvest of ideas and practical policy options<br />

from Sukhamoy Chakravarty’s writings<br />

and how we can go beyond the dichotomies<br />

of market and state, to address<br />

urgent and needed tasks of creating ‘a<br />

learning society’. Time and space does<br />

not allow us to go, into further discussion<br />

and elaboration in this area. In sum, one<br />

can only say that we need to see how to<br />

bring ‘knowledge’ and ‘learning’, as two<br />

very critical aspects of not just economic<br />

growth, but for economic, social and cultural<br />

progress in large and complex developing<br />

societies as ours. It would be a<br />

mockery and travesty to reduce such<br />

unique, rich and diverse societies as ours,<br />

to narrow and limited frameworks of<br />

‘state versus market’.<br />

Comparative Development And<br />

Governance<br />

<strong>The</strong> renowned, ecological and environ-<br />

20 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

mental economist, Herman Daly in his<br />

writings points to the current dilemmas<br />

of economic planning under globalization<br />

wherein comparative advantage has<br />

become absolute advantage, in a situation<br />

of greater integration of economies<br />

and the attempts by powerful countries<br />

to have absolute advantage as regards<br />

trade and investment. Sukhamoy Chakravarty,<br />

with great perspicacity already in<br />

the 1980s pointed to two necessary directions<br />

of theoretical efforts for development<br />

economics in developing countries.<br />

Firstly he had called for “a deeper study<br />

of economic organization from the point<br />

of view of ensuring creativity, growth and<br />

equity” and went on to add that “earlier<br />

discussion of the market versus the Plan<br />

was much too crude”. Secondly and<br />

which is very relevant to our discussion<br />

here, is that “we should possibly reorient<br />

the study of international economics<br />

from its preoccupation with problems of<br />

comparative advantage based on internationally-immobile<br />

primary factors,<br />

towards a study of processes based on<br />

internationalization of capital, changes<br />

in income distribution and the resulting<br />

variations in sectoral productivity levels<br />

which give rise to the emergence of a<br />

process of uneven world economic<br />

growth”. Sukhamoy Chakravarty’s reference<br />

to uneven growth on a world scale<br />

has much relevance even within our<br />

country, in the context of current economic<br />

growth patterns and growth models<br />

dependent and unleashed by globalization,<br />

which in turn are producing very<br />

uneven growth across the country. Thus,<br />

producing income inequalities not only<br />

between groups and individuals but also<br />

between states and regions as a whole<br />

and which has serious implications for<br />

national growth as a whole.<br />

Amartya Sen, similarly has argued (including<br />

in his joint book with Dreze),<br />

“that the success of liberalization and<br />

closer integration with the world economy<br />

may be severely impaired by India’s<br />

backwardness in basic education, elementary<br />

health care, gender inequality<br />

and limitations of land reforms”. He goes<br />

on to say, “While Manmohan Singh (previously<br />

as Finance Minister) did initiate<br />

the correction of governmental over-activity<br />

in some fields, the need to correct<br />

governmental under-activity in other areas<br />

has not really been addressed”. Amartya<br />

Sen’s states that Manmohan Singh,<br />

considered to be the architect of India’s<br />

economic reforms, “stood solidly for<br />

critical scrutiny of the empirical picture,<br />

rather than a large reliance on theory”<br />

and adds that “it would be in the tradition<br />

of his (Manmohan Singh’s) research<br />

to point out that the relevant picture includes<br />

– in the context of the east and<br />

south-east Asian success stories – not<br />

just an orientation towards exports but<br />

also widespread public efforts in basic<br />

education, public health care, female independence,<br />

land reforms, and other<br />

components of social infrastructure”.<br />

Amartya Sen points out that the South-<br />

East Asian and East Asian countries<br />

share conditions “that are particularly<br />

favourable to widespread participation<br />

of the population in economic change.<br />

<strong>The</strong> relevant features include high rates<br />

of literacy, a fair degree of female empowerment,<br />

and quite radical land reforms”.<br />

He then goes to ask the basic<br />

questions that many market-oriented<br />

economists have not had the courage or<br />

honesty to ask, or have even been deeply<br />

uncomfortable when faced with these<br />

questions. Amartya Sen asks, “Can we<br />

expect in India results similar to those<br />

that the more socially egalitarian countries<br />

have achieved, given that half of the<br />

Indian population (and two-thirds of the<br />

women) are still illiterate, that the female<br />

empowerment is very little achieved in<br />

most parts of India, that credit is very<br />

hard to secure by the rural poor, and that<br />

land reforms remain only partially and<br />

We need to seriously study ‘comparative development’<br />

between us and other economies especially in East and<br />

South East Asia to make the correct conclusions<br />

about the role of state and markets<br />

unevenly executed?”<br />

In the foregoing arguments that I have<br />

put forward buttressed by the views of<br />

eminent economists like Amartya Sen,<br />

the point I am emphasizing is that<br />

progress in economic development and<br />

growth cannot be achieved just by putting<br />

up the state against the market, both have<br />

a role and in many instances have even a<br />

synergetic role to play. I go further and<br />

advocate that we need to seriously study<br />

‘comparative development’ between us<br />

and other economies especially in East<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

21


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

and South-East Asia to make the correct<br />

conclusions about the role of state and<br />

markets and to have the pragmatic approach<br />

to use both. Instead what we have<br />

today is simplistic journalistic comparisons<br />

to other economies and often to<br />

only advance the point that in other cases<br />

cited, they have been more market<br />

friendly than the Indian state has been.<br />

What one witnesses, especially in the<br />

popular press and in TV business programmes,<br />

are almost illiterate comparisons<br />

by journalists to other countries and<br />

societies in East and South-East Asia<br />

without any reference to their history or<br />

a deeper understanding of these societies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> comparisons are like frozen in<br />

time and are snapshots of the present<br />

without any reference to how they have<br />

come there. Unfortunately academics<br />

also, instead of making up for their lack<br />

of knowledge of Asian societies, in an<br />

incestuous manner quote these journalistic<br />

comparisons when for example there<br />

is opposition to the entry of TNCs to the<br />

retail trade or to the coercive attempts to<br />

deprive people of their land and force<br />

SEZs down the throat of unsuspecting<br />

citizens. In contrast what we seriously<br />

and urgently need is the building of institutional<br />

capacity to study comparative<br />

development between India and other<br />

developing countries especially in the<br />

Asia and Pacific region and focused on<br />

different aspects of economy, society,<br />

social policy and in general the shaping<br />

of public policy. In a sense the old institutional<br />

arrangements that exist in most<br />

of our universities in the form of area<br />

studies and associated centres and departments<br />

may have to be revisited and<br />

both existing capacity strengthened as<br />

well as new capacity created.<br />

An important dimension of generating<br />

knowledge on comparative development<br />

is to link with governance and understanding<br />

governance related issues. Keeping<br />

in line with what has been said earlier<br />

in this paper about the centrality of governance<br />

to ensure growth that can be socially,<br />

culturally and ecologically sustained,<br />

research and studies need to be<br />

done not only comparing India and Asian<br />

countries but also comparisons within<br />

India between regions and states. Keynes<br />

had held that, “the theory of economics<br />

does not furnish a body of settled conclusions<br />

immediately applicable to policy<br />

Unfortunately academics, instead of making up for their<br />

lack of knowledge of Asian societies, in an incestuous<br />

manner quote journalistic simplistic comparisons down the<br />

throat of unsuspecting citizens<br />

and it is a method rather than a doctrine,<br />

an apparatus of the mind, a technique of<br />

thinking”. Comparative development, in<br />

contemporary times, almost two decades<br />

after the emergence of globalization, is “a<br />

technique of thinking’. Keynes was only<br />

echoing Marshall who in his Principle of<br />

Economics had long ago held the view,<br />

“economics is not a body of concrete<br />

wealth but an engine for the discovery of<br />

concrete truth”. Economists and social<br />

scientists in our country have much work<br />

to do to study and learn from other societies<br />

and in order to ensure that economic<br />

progress and development in our country,<br />

means a full human life for all our citizens<br />

not a situation of vulgar wealth mocking<br />

the inhuman conditions of existence that<br />

is the day to day reality for a very large<br />

number of our citizens. Only then India<br />

will be truly and respected for its greatness<br />

and the extraordinary cultural and<br />

philosophical wealth that it possesses.<br />

Otherwise, we will continued to be seen<br />

as a nation of hypocrites (even if no one<br />

for politeness does not say this to our face)<br />

and no amount of nationalistic jingoism<br />

and fanatical cultural nationalism will<br />

change our image or the situation we are<br />

in as a nation. It is therefore time that<br />

middle class intelligentsia, academics and<br />

intellectuals in India came to grips with<br />

this reality than delude themselves with<br />

false images of greatness.<br />

References<br />

• Sukhamoy Chakravarty, ‘Writings on<br />

Development, with an Introduction by<br />

Mihir Rakshit’, Oxford University<br />

Press, Delhi, 1997<br />

• Dreze, Jean and Amartya Sen, ‘India:<br />

Economic Development and Social<br />

Opportunity’, Oxford University Press,<br />

Delhi, 1995<br />

• Dreze, Jean and Amartya Sen (eds),<br />

‘Indian Development: Regional Perspectives’,<br />

Oxford University Press,<br />

Delhi, 1996<br />

• Amartya Sen, ‘<strong>The</strong>ory and Practice of<br />

Development’, in ‘Indias economic Reforms<br />

and Development-Essays for<br />

Manmohan Singh’, Isher Judge Ahluwalia<br />

and I.M.D.Little (eds), Oxford<br />

University Press, 1998<br />

• Amaresh Bagchi, ‘Role of Planning and<br />

the Planning Commission in the New<br />

Indian Economy: case for a Review’,<br />

Economic and Political Weekly, Bombay,<br />

November 3, <strong>2007</strong>.<br />

22 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


D A R E T O D R E A M : S T R A T E G I C A L L Y ! I N N O V A T I V E L Y !<br />

Strategicw w<br />

July-September <strong>2007</strong>, <strong>Volume</strong> 1 <strong>Issue</strong> 3<br />

Innovators<br />

www.iipm.edu<br />

w . i i p m p u b l i c a t i o n s . c o m<br />

Rs.100<br />

Radical knowledge<br />

Re-structuring<br />

INSIDE THIS ISSUE<br />

20 STRATEGIC CHOICES: ANEEL KARNANI<br />

PROFESSOR OF STRATEGY, UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN<br />

How Indian firms can make better strategic choices &<br />

execute them to achieve true competitive advantages<br />

32<br />

ILLUSION & REALITY: ANDREW LIKIERMAN<br />

DEAN, LONDON BUSINESS SCHOOL<br />

How the success of an organisation is not reflected by<br />

its sheer <strong>size</strong>; rather it’s linked to shareholders’ returns<br />

40<br />

PR AND COMMUNICATION SYSTEM: DAVID NORDFORS<br />

SEMIOR RESEARCH SCHOLAR, STANFORD UNIVERSITY<br />

How communicators & journalists are “attention workers”<br />

driving the “innovation communication system”<br />

48<br />

ENTREPRENEURSHIP: ELIZABETH R. THORNTON<br />

PROFESSOR OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP, BABSON COLLEGE<br />

Unveiling the rich<br />

secrets behind those<br />

unanticipated strategic<br />

master-strokes<br />

Explaining the risks and returns behind many<br />

entrepreneurial motives to start their own businesses<br />

56 INDIA’S PATH TO INNOVATION: DR. DAN STEINBOCK<br />

DIRECTOR, ICT RESEARCH INSTITUTE<br />

On how India’s future depends on the private sector<br />

players becoming the highly-active innovation drivers<br />

AN AN <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> INTELLIGENCE UNIT UNIT PUBLICATION


Pradeep Banerjee,<br />

Independent Consultant,<br />

Bangalore<br />

State And Market Conundrum In <strong>The</strong> Indian<br />

Context – A Need For Debates<br />

"Freedom is hammered out on<br />

the anvil of discussion, dissent<br />

and debate."<br />

-Hubert H. Humphrey<br />

A<br />

concern about the economy is<br />

one that has many a participant.<br />

<strong>The</strong> concern is expressed<br />

in the many debates that refer<br />

to this concern and it does so in a myriad<br />

of ways. It ranges from the animated<br />

to the scholarly, from the simple to the<br />

complex, and from the informed to the<br />

expected. <strong>The</strong>se discussions, then, have<br />

moved out of the confines of the political<br />

class and the academicians. It has<br />

moved in to include members of the<br />

larger civil society. In a manner of<br />

speaking, the debates have become a<br />

part of the discourse of the many participants.<br />

A favoured point in discussions<br />

and debates about the economy is<br />

that about the market. <strong>The</strong>se debates<br />

and discussions are more about the manner<br />

that markets envelope the society,<br />

and also about the manner in which<br />

markets relate to the individual. In some<br />

ways markets have come to be associated<br />

with helping men in their ‘desire of bettering<br />

(their) condition’. 1 That is a probable<br />

reason based on which markets<br />

have almost assumed a proxy for the<br />

economy. Markets, then, are structures<br />

that hold the interest of many. <strong>The</strong> grip<br />

on the interest accrues from a recognition<br />

that markets and human societies<br />

have moved in tandem over long periods<br />

of time now. It is the ubiquitous presence<br />

of the market that makes it an immediate<br />

point of reference. Markets<br />

existed before economists adopted analytical<br />

tools to work on this ubiquitous<br />

item of every day occurrence. Markets<br />

have been analyzed to understand their<br />

dynamics. Markets have been identified<br />

at a spatial level that on immediate reckoning<br />

looms large as structural constructs.<br />

So there are global markets<br />

where the sheer <strong>size</strong> is at once baffling.<br />

And then there are country level markets<br />

that operate using methods and<br />

processes to draw lines of conventions<br />

and lines of practice to retain an identity<br />

that is independent of the global<br />

mind sweep. <strong>The</strong> hierarchy of markets<br />

includes local markets and these local<br />

markets themselves may be larger than<br />

24 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

what can be provided for in a cognitive<br />

mind set of an individual. <strong>The</strong> calibration<br />

of markets using hierarchy, however,<br />

as the defining attribute, does not quiet<br />

capture all that what make up for markets.<br />

Markets as constructs have evolved<br />

and have changed with time moving<br />

from points at which barter was entered<br />

into to places where the magnitude is at<br />

once large and complex. <strong>The</strong> pattern of<br />

thinking and arriving at explanations<br />

that have accompanied these transformations<br />

have similarly changed course.<br />

What causes them and why these are<br />

useful to transactions in society, therefore,<br />

remain important issues. And these<br />

have been so for some time now if we<br />

exclude the antiquity from the purview.<br />

Arriving At A Framework Handy<br />

Enough For A Debate<br />

<strong>The</strong> market is not an island floating in a<br />

sea of societal events. <strong>The</strong> market is<br />

probably more like an iceberg that has<br />

a ninth of it unseen. <strong>The</strong>se are not institutions<br />

that occur in relative isolation.<br />

Instead these occur when commerce<br />

clearly engages the society as an activity<br />

that a society needs to engage itself<br />

with. Accordingly, and for instance, ‘the<br />

“Spirit” of Capitalism’, in a manner that<br />

Weber approached the issue and elaborated<br />

upon it, probably has a lot to do<br />

with the issue of markets. Weber was of<br />

course concerned with commerce, and<br />

the manner in which this activity<br />

emerged from after being confined to<br />

ethical pits for a long time and particularly<br />

during the Middle Ages and up to<br />

the beginnings of the modern period. As<br />

regards markets, these were accepted as<br />

a part of commerce for these went alongside<br />

commerce. Weber was writing in<br />

the 1890s and he referred to the term<br />

‘economic order’ to which both the individual<br />

and the enterprise had to comply<br />

with. If the modern period is identified<br />

with a pervasiveness of the economic<br />

order and in which compliance comes in<br />

as given, it was not so earlier. ‘<strong>The</strong> capitalist<br />

spirit’ Weber wrote, ‘has had to<br />

prove itself in a hard struggle against a<br />

world of hostile forces.’ 2 On matters related<br />

to the establishment of commerce,<br />

then, we would need to go an earlier author.<br />

Adam Smith in his <strong>The</strong> Wealth of<br />

Nations wrote of the manner in which<br />

feudalism underwent erosion. <strong>The</strong> erosion<br />

had to do with the establishment<br />

and the consequent spread of commerce<br />

and manufacture. <strong>The</strong> observations of<br />

Smith are relevant in yet another manner.<br />

<strong>The</strong> spread of commerce and manufacture<br />

brought in certain fundamental<br />

changes in the society. And finally it<br />

brought in the first hints of the involvement<br />

of the ruling elite in this spread.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Chapter was entitled tellingly “How<br />

the Commerce of Towns Contributed to<br />

the Improvement of the Country”. In it<br />

Smith wrote, ‘commerce and manufactures<br />

gradually introduced order and<br />

good government, and with them, the<br />

liberty and security of individuals.’ 3 <strong>The</strong><br />

rationale for the coming in of peace over<br />

that of warfare that were carried on by<br />

manor lords between themselves was<br />

traced to the declining influence of these<br />

manor lords over the sovereign. <strong>The</strong> surplus<br />

could now be expended on manufactories<br />

that commerce helped deliver<br />

for consumption. And Smith, who was a<br />

votary for individual efforts, once again<br />

empha<strong>size</strong>d on the ‘desire of bettering<br />

(their) condition’. Smith wrote that, ‘<strong>The</strong><br />

natural efforts of every individual to better<br />

his own condition, when suffered to<br />

exert itself with freedom and security, is<br />

so powerful a principle, that it is alone,<br />

and without any assistance, not only capable<br />

of carrying on the society to wealth<br />

and prosperity, but of surmounting a<br />

hundred impertinent obstructions with<br />

which the folly of human laws too often<br />

encumber its operations.’ 4 Smith had his<br />

reservations about commerce and those<br />

who practiced it, and yet he was emphatic<br />

on the impact that commerce and<br />

manufacturing had on society. On the<br />

whole the impact was good. <strong>The</strong>re is a<br />

primacy of economics in his statement<br />

Markets have almost assumed a proxy for the economy.<br />

Markets, then are structures that hold the interest of many.<br />

<strong>The</strong> grip on the interest accrues from a recognition<br />

that markets and human societies have moved in<br />

tandem over long periods of time now<br />

for he points out that the momentum<br />

generated could surmount the hindrances<br />

to progress. It is of these and similar<br />

hindrances that the referencing by Weber<br />

highlighted.<br />

<strong>The</strong> intermixing of politics and economics<br />

was clearly seen by others too<br />

and the emerging viewpoint clarified<br />

that the expansion of economics went<br />

along with an expansion of the political<br />

landscape. Of the many who wrote on<br />

this issue, Adam Fergusson (1723-1816),<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

25


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

yet another Scot and identified with the<br />

Scottish Enlightenment, was articulate<br />

on the issue. In his An Essay on the History<br />

of Civil Society (1767), Fergusson<br />

wrote that, ‘It has been found, that, except<br />

in a few singular cases, the commercial<br />

and political arts have advanced<br />

together.’ 5 Fergusson maintained that<br />

the incidence of commerce was quiet<br />

engaged with the ways of nations and<br />

pointed out that, ‘In some nations the<br />

spirit of commerce, intent on securing<br />

its profits, has led the way to political<br />

wisdom’. 6 <strong>The</strong> point that was being made<br />

by Fergusson was received well and the<br />

text of the Essay on the History of Civil<br />

Society ‘found many enthusiastic readers<br />

in London, where it went through<br />

seven editions in Fergusson’s lifetime.’ 7<br />

It was an endorsement of the general acceptance<br />

of these thoughts and explanations<br />

about the working of the economy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> schools of German Philosophy<br />

tors who debated on a host of areas that<br />

were at once connected with the enquiries<br />

that Smith and Fergusson were working<br />

on. <strong>The</strong> transition was clearly visible<br />

and so much so that until the seventeenth<br />

century, the term economy did<br />

not quiet signify much and that university<br />

chairs were set up for studies in ethics<br />

and not that for economics. Smith<br />

himself was appointed as a professor of<br />

moral philosophy in 1752 and published<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>The</strong>ory of the Moral Sentiments in<br />

1759, years earlier to <strong>The</strong> Wealth of Nations<br />

which was published in 1776. <strong>The</strong><br />

transition was notable enough and<br />

It was reasoned that if the interests of these contending<br />

actors (Commercial class and State) were so intense, the<br />

resultant interactions could well be inimical to either of<br />

them and could therefore be a source of stress in the<br />

society. Hence, came the idea of civil society<br />

would also remain indebted to Fergusson<br />

for the term civil society, a term that<br />

would also be used here in connection<br />

with the market and the State.<br />

<strong>The</strong> contributions of Smith and Fergusson<br />

were important. <strong>The</strong>y helped<br />

recognize the reasons for commerce and<br />

further enabled recognition of an additional<br />

two domains that were relevant to<br />

matters of manufactories and commerce.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se were those of markets and that of<br />

States. <strong>The</strong>re were many more contribu-<br />

Watson points out that when Smith died<br />

‘after a life of intellectual adventure and<br />

social prudence’, a local newspaper complained<br />

in its obituary (4 August 1790)<br />

that he had ‘converted his chair of moral<br />

philosophy at Glasgow University into<br />

one of trade and finance’.’ 8 And while<br />

earlier in Britain ‘men argued that human<br />

nature rather than the state should<br />

govern economics’, matters changed<br />

course and the role of the state became<br />

clearer so much so that, ‘We should not<br />

forget that state intervention in the<br />

eighteenth century was very important<br />

to economic development and Smith<br />

never disagreed with this.’ 9 <strong>The</strong> debates<br />

initiated by thinkers such as Smith and<br />

Fergusson, among the many others, had<br />

initiated major long term changes. And<br />

if the stage was set for expansion of commercial<br />

trade and manufactories, their<br />

momentum was quiet clearly induced by<br />

debates that took place during these periods.<br />

Changes during the next period of<br />

the nineteenth century and those thereafter<br />

are testimony to the expansion that<br />

had been achieved by these nations.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Third Actor – Inclusion Of<br />

<strong>The</strong> Civil Society As Part Of<br />

<strong>The</strong> Triad<br />

<strong>The</strong> growth of these economies brought<br />

into sharp focus a number of developments<br />

that claimed for attention. <strong>The</strong><br />

rise of the commercial class with its<br />

members quiet clearly interested in their<br />

private interests and that of the State<br />

could expectedly raise the requirements<br />

of boundaries determining their spheres<br />

of operation. It was reasoned that if the<br />

interests of these contending actors were<br />

so intense, as it appeared to be, the resultant<br />

interactions could well be inimical<br />

to either of them and could therefore<br />

be a source of stress in the society. It is<br />

as an outcome of this concern that the<br />

idea of civil society came to be articulated.<br />

If the term civil society has been<br />

an old one, it is with John Locke (1632-<br />

1704), the Scottish Enlightenment<br />

group, and Georg Hegel (1770-1831) that<br />

the term came to be positioned more<br />

firmly and done so in the contextual format<br />

that includes the State and the market.<br />

Seligman observes that ‘what stood<br />

26 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

at the core of all attempts to articulate<br />

a notion of civil society in that period,<br />

and since, has been the problematic relation<br />

between the private and the public;<br />

the individual and the social; public ethics<br />

and individual interests; and individual<br />

passions, and public concerns.’ 10<br />

<strong>The</strong> organization of society being an endeavor<br />

of immediate concern, the inclusion<br />

of civil society as a building block is<br />

as relevant and in this context plays a<br />

normative role. Civil society as a normative<br />

ideal emerged, as Seligman points<br />

out to ‘as the result of a crisis in social<br />

order and a breakdown of existing paradigms<br />

of the idea of order.’ 11 <strong>The</strong> stress<br />

points and crisis refers to that between<br />

the State and individual interests. <strong>The</strong><br />

role of civil society has been assessed in<br />

these contexts, and to discharge which<br />

role civil society ‘is most usefully thought<br />

as identifying a set of human capacities,<br />

moral and political.’ 12 This is an effective<br />

expression to hold on to for assessing<br />

the impact of civil society when<br />

functioning as a part of the triad formed<br />

by the State, the market and the<br />

civil society.<br />

Spread Of Markets, Influence<br />

Of States And <strong>The</strong> Colonial<br />

Period In India<br />

It is a point that is made that the state of<br />

the economy in the earlier part of the<br />

eighteenth century in India was not so<br />

different as compared to that in Britain<br />

and other European countries. It is observed<br />

that the ‘economies of India,<br />

China, and other Asian regions in the<br />

early eighteenth century were not so different<br />

– hardly less sophisticated than in<br />

Europe’ and that ‘the economies of Britain<br />

and Europe accelerated after 1750,<br />

quickly outstripping those of India, China,<br />

Japan and the rest of Asia.’ 13 <strong>The</strong><br />

stirrings of the early differences began<br />

at some time during the seventeenth and<br />

the eighteenth centuries. <strong>The</strong> case study<br />

of India is an illustration of what occurred<br />

as a response to the emergent<br />

State and interactions between the State,<br />

the market and the civil society.<br />

<strong>The</strong> pre-colonial history of India has<br />

a continuity that is easily segregated<br />

from that of the beginnings of the arrival<br />

of commercial class from Britain<br />

and other European nation states to India<br />

in search of markets. This early history<br />

of travelers, merchants and those of<br />

the East India Company officials are<br />

that of commercial interests in search of<br />

markets. In various ways the State in<br />

Britain and those in other nations too<br />

emerged as supporters that enabled a<br />

deepening of interests. It is, however,<br />

the cessation of the Company rule and<br />

the initiation of the colonial rule by the<br />

State in Britain that the changes came<br />

into much sharper focus. This is expected<br />

inasmuch as the rule by the colonial<br />

State was qualitatively different from<br />

that by commercial interests in the form<br />

of the Company supported though the<br />

Company was by the State. Accordingly,<br />

while the early stages, and that prior to<br />

the proclamation transferring power to<br />

the State of Britain of the territory of<br />

India, offers a fascinating story of the<br />

manner in which the commercial class<br />

established its presence in the country,<br />

it is the firming up of the relationships<br />

under the State that is of relevance here.<br />

<strong>The</strong> response of the civil society to the<br />

colonial State was at once sharp and often<br />

provocative. Dadabhai Naoroji, the<br />

forefront spokesperson of the economic<br />

drain theory and who estimated the<br />

drain to be to the extent of ‘30,000,000<br />

to 40,000,000 a year’ did not find any<br />

issues with the ‘operations of economic<br />

laws’ as a cause behind this sorry state<br />

of India. Instead, he identified the British<br />

State and its policies that were the<br />

cause. Writing in 1880, Dadabhai pointed<br />

out that, ‘It is not the pitiless operations<br />

of economic laws, but it is the<br />

thoughtless and pitiless action of the<br />

British policy; … in short, it is the pitiless<br />

perversion of economic laws by the<br />

sad bleeding to which India is subjected,<br />

that is destroying India.’ 14 <strong>The</strong> point<br />

Dadabhai Naoroji, the forefront spokesperson of the economic<br />

drain theory and who estimated the drain to be to<br />

the extent of ‘30,000,000 to 40,000,000 a year’ did not<br />

find any issues with the ‘operations of economic laws’ as a<br />

cause behind this sorry state of India<br />

about the overreach by the State was not<br />

restricted to identifying that it was the<br />

role of the State, and the manner in<br />

which the State denuded the economy<br />

causing, that were the reason for the severe<br />

handicap faced by the populace of<br />

the country over which the State presided.<br />

A further issue was raised, and it<br />

was about the operation and influence<br />

of the colonial State as against that of<br />

the pre-colonial State. Dadabhai pointed<br />

out that under the suzerainty of the<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

27


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

‘native despot the people keep and enjoy<br />

what they produce, though at times they<br />

suffer some violence in the back. Under<br />

the British Indian despot the man is at<br />

peace, there is no violence; his substance<br />

is drained away, unseen, peaceably and<br />

subtly – he starves in peace, and peaceably<br />

perishes in peace, with law and order!”<br />

15 This was a clear recognition of<br />

the differences among the type of States,<br />

and it was a rendition of practices that<br />

each of these States had on the economy.<br />

Dadabhai, a civil society member, was<br />

elaborating on the overreach by the<br />

State and the manner in which its hegemony<br />

overshadowed the development<br />

of indigenous commercial class. <strong>The</strong> focus<br />

of the drain theory was not on the<br />

underdevelopment of the commercial<br />

class per se. <strong>The</strong> State and Commercial<br />

interest were locked into a symbiotic relationship<br />

such as to benefit the British<br />

economy. <strong>The</strong> loss to the peripheral<br />

economy was a consequence. <strong>The</strong> indigenous<br />

commercial class moved forward<br />

instead on a stunted road.<br />

If the State arose as a means to reduce<br />

the violence among interacting individuals<br />

and groups, the colonial State quiet<br />

well performed on this attribute of Statehood.<br />

Dadabhai clearly recognized this<br />

at the empirical level and wrote about<br />

this while elaborating on the arrival of a<br />

more peaceful time over that which prevailed<br />

earlier. <strong>The</strong> peaceful time that<br />

the Colonial State brought in augmented<br />

an increase in economic produce in the<br />

form of raw material that the colonizing<br />

economy required as inputs to its produce.<br />

<strong>The</strong> peripheral economy also provided<br />

the market that the Commercial<br />

interests of the class in that economy<br />

required. <strong>The</strong> peace that came in was<br />

required for the market and yet there<br />

was no getting away from the fact that<br />

the Colonial State while engaged in doing<br />

so was engendering growth of the<br />

markets for the colonizing State. Dadabhai<br />

wrote that, ‘<strong>The</strong>re is security of life<br />

and property in one sense or way, i.e.,<br />

the people are secure from any violence<br />

from each other or from Native despots.’<br />

And yet this did not secure the economy<br />

from the drain that the colonial State<br />

had established. Accordingly, ‘What is<br />

secure, and well secure, is that England<br />

is perfectly safe and secure …to carry<br />

away from India, and to eat up in India,<br />

<strong>The</strong> State and Commercial interest were locked into a<br />

symbiotic relationship such as to benefi t the British<br />

economy. <strong>The</strong> loss to the peripheral economy was a<br />

consequence. <strong>The</strong> indigenous commercial class moved<br />

forward instead on a stunted road<br />

her property at the present rate of<br />

30,000,000 to 40,000,000 a year.’ 16<br />

So clear were the State and Market<br />

relationship recognized that other members<br />

of the civil society too expressed<br />

their dissension with the practices that<br />

emerged out of this relationship. Writing<br />

in the Indian People on 27 th of February<br />

1903, Sachidanand Sinha, pointed out<br />

that the effective administration practiced<br />

during the governance of Lord<br />

Curzon was more an outcome necessitated<br />

by the requirements of commerce.<br />

‘Trade cannot thrive without efficient<br />

administration’, wrote Sinha and adding<br />

that the ‘latter is not worth attending to<br />

in the absence of profits of the former.’<br />

Consequently, it is ‘always with the assent<br />

and often to the dictates of the<br />

Chambers of Commerce (that) the Government<br />

of India is carried on’. 17<br />

This is not a place for arriving at exhaustive<br />

details of the manner in which<br />

the colonial State worked around to address<br />

the requirements of the markets.<br />

Suffice it note that the thesis of Sate and<br />

market reinforcing each other is quiet<br />

clearly observable during this period<br />

and that the members of the Indian civil<br />

society had been able to identify this<br />

relationship. It was recognition of this<br />

relationship that brought the civil society<br />

to debate about the relationship and<br />

so as to arrive at what was required to<br />

change the coordinates of the relationship.<br />

It was the cohesion of the civil society,<br />

which over the years gathered<br />

members of the commercial class that<br />

prompted the building of alternative<br />

viewpoints of the manner that the economy<br />

should function. <strong>The</strong> subsequent<br />

participation by political parties as a<br />

joint effort brought in the transition<br />

from the colonial State to a State that<br />

was part of the Indian scenario. This<br />

constitutes the second issue that merits<br />

recognition and it is that of the civil society<br />

playing an important role in influencing<br />

the changeover from the earlier<br />

State mode to that of yet another one.<br />

Post-Colonialism And <strong>The</strong><br />

Search For New Paradigms<br />

<strong>The</strong> triad of State, market and civil society<br />

as it were during the colonial pe-<br />

28 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

riod came in for significant changes after<br />

the colonial period came to their end. In<br />

the Indian instance, their build up were<br />

influenced by the colonial forces. <strong>The</strong><br />

market that was more local in the precolonial<br />

period was not quiet so at the<br />

start of the post-colonial period. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

was the availability of a market economy<br />

enabled to a significant degree by a network<br />

of railway connection. <strong>The</strong> availability<br />

of a market economy is an important<br />

distinction, for it helps to make a<br />

transition from where an economy is to<br />

where it wants to reach in a manner that<br />

is akin to a transformation of the economy.<br />

In the Indian instance, Jha points<br />

out that the country at the start of its<br />

post-colonial journey was, among other<br />

countries, the one that was ‘best placed<br />

to make a transition quickly because it<br />

was the only country with a fully developed<br />

national market economy.’ 18 And<br />

yet at the end of about six decades of<br />

economic management, the changes in<br />

the economy is seemingly short of that<br />

which can be viewed as one of transformation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> economic transformation<br />

of India, it is contended, ‘has run into<br />

difficulties because it has gone too slow’,<br />

leading to an outcome that Jha refers to<br />

as ‘the paradox of India’s slow transition’.<br />

19 <strong>The</strong> presence of markets at this<br />

point in time came along with the presence<br />

of the indigenous commercial class<br />

too. As regards the State and the civil<br />

society, the changes recorded by these<br />

two actors require further exploration.<br />

<strong>The</strong> explanation lies in the specific historical<br />

experiences that the State and<br />

civil society underwent in the country.<br />

<strong>The</strong> dimensions of the market are<br />

easier to discern; it is not so with that of<br />

the State and the civil society. <strong>The</strong> involvement<br />

of the civil society in the colonial<br />

period with the colonial State gave<br />

rise to an important development unique<br />

in its own way and quiet different from<br />

that which the European instances<br />

record. In this case, there was a formation<br />

of a ‘we’ that was distinctly different<br />

from the State. It was the norm that nationalist<br />

movements would recruit their<br />

support of interested parties from<br />

among the intending participants in<br />

their cause. <strong>The</strong> goal was the removal of<br />

the colonial State. Towards this, the participation<br />

that was sought was from an<br />

increasing number of participants and<br />

even from those who were not quiet covered<br />

by the colonial State. <strong>The</strong> practitioners<br />

of nationalism, in other words,<br />

were making a case of representing the<br />

indigenous populace in all their domains<br />

of practice, be it economic or be it otherwise.<br />

<strong>The</strong> change from a colonial State<br />

to a nation State was carried out under<br />

the controlling interest of nationalism.<br />

This led to the formation of a State that<br />

was different from the colonial State.<br />

Characterizing this State, Kaviraj points<br />

out that the ‘secret of the immense power<br />

of the nation-states was not the inheritance<br />

from colonialism but from their<br />

nationalist mobilization.’ 20 <strong>The</strong> range of<br />

activities that the State could now command<br />

over was large and it now had the<br />

advantage of being a representative<br />

State that could speak for all. Note that<br />

this was distinct from the European instances<br />

where attempts were consistently<br />

made to sustain different domains<br />

for the State, the market and the civil<br />

society. <strong>The</strong> contributions of theorists<br />

who tried to find solutions to the problem<br />

of one of the actors in an overreach<br />

situation over the other the other two,<br />

and covered in the earlier part of this<br />

essay, were directed to this end. In the<br />

evolving model that had emerged in a<br />

post-colonial State, the overreach by the<br />

State was at the cost of the civil society.<br />

An outcome of the influence of the nation State during<br />

the post colonial period, upon most matters that<br />

the nationalists had embedded their positions on in the<br />

colonial period, was that the State took on contingent<br />

responsibilities in a number of activities<br />

An outcome of the influence of the nation<br />

State during the post colonial period<br />

on most matters that the nationalists<br />

had embedded their positions on in<br />

the colonial period was that the State<br />

took on contingent responsibilities in a<br />

number of activities. This meant a<br />

squeezing of the markets that the commercial<br />

classes in the society would have<br />

endorsed targeting for their growth. A<br />

large spread of influence and an inclusive<br />

control over economic activities can<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

29


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

mean a slow down in pushing the economic<br />

agenda. A lesser reliance on market<br />

forces of the type that emerges as<br />

with a market economy and coupled with<br />

an intensifying bureaucratization of<br />

processes can bring in a slow down making<br />

the transition that much more difficult<br />

to execute. Bhagwati points out to<br />

the overhang of the State leading to ‘the<br />

inability to trust the market when scarcities<br />

are acute and the tasks are challenging’.<br />

21 <strong>The</strong> impact of this overhang on<br />

the market had certain long term effects<br />

for the practices of the State in the economic<br />

sphere. A ‘combination of industrial<br />

licensing and controls at home with<br />

import and exchange controls externally,<br />

effectively cut off rigours of competition<br />

from all sources and made the creation<br />

of a rentier, as against an entrepreneurial,<br />

economy more likely.’ 22 An overhang<br />

of this type has an adverse impact on the<br />

creation of the market and on agents, or<br />

entrepreneurs, who constitute an important<br />

part of the market. <strong>The</strong> movement<br />

from early post-colonial period and into<br />

latter day envisages the highs and the<br />

lows of the State and its influence on the<br />

economy and the polity. This has not<br />

been a period of the routine; it has instead<br />

been a period that can be characterized<br />

by the term ‘change’.<strong>The</strong> economy<br />

progressed from early reaching of<br />

high notches as at the end of the early<br />

plans, to a leveling of the growth and<br />

whereby the economy was described as<br />

one that was inflicted by a Hindu rate of<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> economy periodically recorded<br />

weaknesses in its ability to deliver<br />

as much as was demanded of it. In<br />

a manner of speaking the overstretched<br />

State which depended on large scale<br />

controls to be able to deliver the promises<br />

that were made now faced road<br />

blocks in its way forward. <strong>The</strong> liberaliza-<br />

<strong>The</strong> process of debate is augmentative. <strong>The</strong> need is to<br />

engage the State by the civil society. Debates are expected<br />

to enhance an understanding of the way that the intricate<br />

relationships between the triad of actors and also to help<br />

determine the way forward from the current relationship<br />

tion of the 1990s and thereafter, accordingly,<br />

focused on dismantling the economic<br />

controls that had been instituted<br />

during the course of the journey after<br />

independence. <strong>The</strong> growth rates that<br />

have been realized, and the prospects<br />

that have come to be expected, has<br />

prompted a re-look yet again at what<br />

could be the best solution for moving<br />

forward. <strong>The</strong> market has expectedly become<br />

an arena to be looked into with<br />

more than usual interest.<br />

Debates Are Contributive<br />

We started with the observation that the<br />

debate on the market has progressed<br />

beyond the confines of the few. It now<br />

includes the many instead, and this for<br />

the simple reason that the market concerns<br />

all. Markets, then, turn out to be<br />

constructs that are influenced by the<br />

manner in which economic activities are<br />

handled in society. Markets have that<br />

quality which encourages the many to<br />

arrive at answers about its construct.<br />

This happens because of the relationship<br />

that individuals have with the market.<br />

This is important because it also<br />

brings in the role of democracy and following<br />

the adoption of which there is an<br />

influence by members of society who opt<br />

for a political governance of the type<br />

that is shaped by this political mode of<br />

participation. It is about the influence<br />

that civil society has on the political terrain<br />

and also about the influence that<br />

civil society can have on that terrain.<br />

<strong>The</strong> influence that matters in the context<br />

that has been drawn out here is that on<br />

the State and Market relationship and it<br />

is here that the influence could be one<br />

of moving forward such that the outcome<br />

is that of consensual gain. <strong>The</strong><br />

political influence that leads to the<br />

putting up of a confrontationist barrier<br />

is of negative consequence. It is here<br />

that the process of debate is augmentative.<br />

<strong>The</strong> need is to engage the State by<br />

the civil society. <strong>The</strong> debates are expected<br />

to enhance an understanding of the<br />

way that the intricate relationships between<br />

the triad of actors, namely, the<br />

State, the market and the civil society<br />

works and also to help determine the<br />

way forward from the current status of<br />

existing relationship. A preponderant<br />

30 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

reliance on the market can be debilitative<br />

as much as one on the role of the<br />

State to work as the redeemer in view of<br />

its spread and involvement in a majority<br />

of human spheres of activities. A civil<br />

society that is built on representing sectional<br />

interests is yet again a handicap.<br />

<strong>The</strong> rationale for debates into and about<br />

the interacting relationships is expected<br />

to yield a better perspective about actions<br />

to be taken. In a maturing political<br />

economy, these debates are important<br />

given that ‘these debates form parts of<br />

a collective reflection on the nature of<br />

the conditions which political democracy<br />

requires to take root and flourish.’<br />

23<br />

<strong>The</strong> market, as it stands, is but a construct.<br />

Taken by itself the market could<br />

be amoral. It is constructed best, and<br />

functions so, when it is mediated by the<br />

State in terms of the coordinates set up<br />

by the civil society. To say so is not to<br />

reduce the entirety of the State, market<br />

and civil society complex as an outcome<br />

of an instrumentalist intervention.<br />

For doing so is not even a good<br />

theoretical exercise, leave alone a matter<br />

of practice.<br />

<strong>The</strong> State and market conundrum is<br />

an intricate issue and particularly so in<br />

an economy that has had a past of the<br />

type that India has. It is that debates<br />

would address complex body made up<br />

by the State, the market and the civil<br />

society the necessary enabling momentum<br />

to take those steps that would address<br />

needs of the society. That is why<br />

there is a need for debates. And as we<br />

have seen, there have been instances of<br />

such debates influencing the society.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Indian instance is not exempt<br />

from this.<br />

References<br />

1.<br />

Adam Smith in his ‘An Inquiry into<br />

the Nature and Causes of the Wealth<br />

of Nations’ pointed out that ‘an augmentation<br />

of fortune is the means by<br />

which the greater part of men propose<br />

and wish to better their conditions.’<br />

2.<br />

Weber, Max., ‘<strong>The</strong> Protestant Ethic<br />

and the “Spirit” of Capitalism and<br />

Other Writings’, Penguin Books, New<br />

York, 2002, p.15.<br />

3.<br />

Hirschman, A., ‘<strong>The</strong> Passions and the<br />

Interests – Political Arguments for<br />

Capitalism before Its Triumph’, Princeton<br />

University Press, Princeton,<br />

New Jersey, 1997, p.100.<br />

4.<br />

Ibid., p.103<br />

5.<br />

Ibid, p. 120.<br />

6<br />

. Ibid, p. 120.<br />

7.<br />

Watson, P., ‘Ideas – A History from<br />

Fire to Freud’, Widenfield & Nicolson,<br />

London, 2005, p.539.<br />

8.<br />

Ibid., p. 541. Watson herein refers to<br />

the work of Ian Simpson Ross, ‘<strong>The</strong><br />

Life of Adam Smith’, Oxford: <strong>The</strong> Oxford<br />

University Press, 1995.<br />

9.<br />

Ibid., p.541. In this elaboration,<br />

Watson refers to the work of Paul<br />

Langford, ‘A Polite and Commercial<br />

People’, Oxford University Press, Oxford,<br />

1989.<br />

10.<br />

Seligman, A., “Civil Society as Idea<br />

and Ideal”, in Chambers, S and Kymlicka,<br />

W’, (edited)., ‘Alternative Conceptions<br />

of Civil Society’, Princeton<br />

University Press, Princeton, 2002, pp.<br />

13-14.<br />

11.<br />

Ibid., p.14.<br />

12.<br />

Khilnani, S., “<strong>The</strong> development of<br />

civil society”, in Kaviraj, S and Khilnani,<br />

S, (edited)., ‘Civil Society – History<br />

and Possibilities’, Cambridge<br />

University Press, Foundation Books,<br />

2002, p. 25.<br />

13.<br />

Pomeranz, C., ‘<strong>The</strong> Great Divergence:<br />

China, Europe and the making of the<br />

Modern World Economy’, Princeton<br />

University Press, Princeton, 2000,<br />

quoted in Watson, P., Ibid.’ p.570.<br />

Also see Frank, Andre Gunder., Review<br />

of ‘<strong>The</strong> Great Divergence’, Journal<br />

of Asian Studies, at www.rrojasdatabank.org/agfrank/pomeranz.html,<br />

accessed on 19th November <strong>2007</strong>.<br />

14.<br />

Naoroji, Dadabhai., ‘Poverty and Un-<br />

British Rule in India’, p.216 and quoted<br />

in Chandra, B, Mukherjee, M,<br />

Mukherjee, A, Panikkar, K. N, and<br />

Mahajan, S., ‘India’s Struggle for Independence<br />

– 1857 – 1947, Penguin<br />

Books, 1991, New Delhi, p.97.<br />

15.<br />

Naoroji, Dadabhai., ‘Speeches’, p.389<br />

and quoted in Chandra, B et al., Op.<br />

cit., p.100.<br />

16.<br />

Naoroji, Dadabhai., ‘Poverty and Un-<br />

British Rule in India’, pp.224-25, Op.<br />

cit., p.99.<br />

17.<br />

Chandra, B et al., Op. cit., p.99.<br />

18.<br />

Jha, Prem Shankar., ‘<strong>The</strong> Perilous<br />

Road to the Market – <strong>The</strong> Political<br />

Economy of Reform in Russia, India<br />

and China’, Rupa and Company, New<br />

Delhi, 2002, p. 165.<br />

19<br />

. Ibid., p.165<br />

20.<br />

Kaviraj, S., “In Search of Civil Society”,<br />

in Kaviraj, S and Khilnani, S, (edited).,<br />

Op. cit., p. 314.<br />

21<br />

. Bhagwati, Jagdish., ‘India in Transition<br />

– Freeing the Economy’, Oxford<br />

University Press, New Delhi, 1994,<br />

page. 51.<br />

22<br />

. Ibid., p. 61.<br />

23<br />

.Kaviraj, S., “In Search of Civil<br />

Society”, in Kaviraj, Sudipta and<br />

Khilnani, Sunil, (edited)., Op. cit.,<br />

page. 323.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

31


Anandajit Goswami,<br />

Associate Fellow, <strong>The</strong> Energy<br />

and Resources Institute (TERI),<br />

New Delhi<br />

Larger Market Role, Reduced<br />

Government Interventions – Is It A Misnomer?<br />

"Liberty is the only thing you<br />

cannot have unless you are<br />

willing to give it to others."<br />

-William Allen White<br />

<strong>The</strong> above title highlights some basic<br />

facets of the reformist changes that<br />

have taken place in India during<br />

the liberalization period. <strong>The</strong> “India Shining”<br />

campaign marked by stupendous<br />

growth rates of the economy owing to diversified<br />

market led reforms has created a notion<br />

of reimagination of India fraught by<br />

greater role of the market with less government<br />

intervention. But it is absolutely imperative<br />

to look onto other dimensions of<br />

the growth story before such a reimagination<br />

of India is well established. <strong>The</strong> following<br />

sections of this article would dwell upon<br />

some of those dimensions.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Growth Story<br />

We all know that the growth of the Indian<br />

economy has not followed the classical<br />

growth pattern as stated by many growth<br />

theorists like Solow where the growth of the<br />

economy starts from agriculture sector followed<br />

by its transmission to the manufacturing<br />

and services sector. In India’s case the<br />

larger part of the growth has been a result<br />

of service led growth. <strong>The</strong> growth in agriculture<br />

sector started with green revolution<br />

in Indian economy. <strong>The</strong>re after there has<br />

been a leap frogging jump in the growth pattern<br />

towards service sector during the period<br />

from 1990s till now without a subsequent<br />

growth in manufacturing sector. <strong>The</strong><br />

manufacturing growth has stagnated at the<br />

same time. According to recent estimates<br />

the share of service sector has increased to<br />

more than 50 percent of the GDP of the Indian<br />

economy whereas the sectoral share for<br />

agriculture in the GDP has dropped down<br />

to 16 percent. 1 Another factor that has contributed<br />

to the growth of Indian economy is<br />

the opening up of the economy through<br />

larger exports and imports. This has been<br />

evident in the double digit (close to 20 percent)<br />

growth rate in the export of principal<br />

commodities from India in the recent years.<br />

<strong>The</strong> trade policy (2004–2009) 2 of India also<br />

highlights the point of the growth of Indian<br />

economy by meeting export targets. Statistics<br />

show that our current account is in a<br />

deficit due to huge imports, which is balanced<br />

by capital account surplus. This has<br />

been triggered mainly by large amount of<br />

32 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

foreign institutional investments in the Indian<br />

economy. However at the back of all<br />

these shining stories, the cause for worry lies<br />

in another fact. Statistics show that although<br />

Indian GDP has grown at a rate of 7 percent<br />

– 8 percent and is hinting to touch a doubledigit<br />

figure of 10 percent 3 in recent times,<br />

the employment elasticity of the Indian<br />

economy has not grown proportionately<br />

with respect to the growth in GDP. Thus<br />

although income of the country has grown<br />

by one unit it has not increased the employment<br />

potential by one unit. Thus the growth<br />

has created inequality in the Indian economy<br />

which is a serious question at the backdrop<br />

of the service led growth. Studies also<br />

show that the sectoral inequality (Goswami<br />

A, Chakraborty P <strong>2007</strong>) across the Indian<br />

economy has also increased during the period<br />

of 1990–2003. So the question is in spite<br />

of market led reforms leading to growth in<br />

the economy why the growth has not been<br />

chanellised to tackle important developmental<br />

factors like growing inequality? <strong>The</strong><br />

next section highlights some of the factors<br />

which have contributed to this gloomy side<br />

of the India Shining Story.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Developmental Side<br />

<strong>The</strong> startling facts regarding development<br />

come with certain important numbers. Data<br />

shows that in spite of moving in a growth<br />

trajectory India’s ranking in Human Development<br />

Index is 126. 4 This is much lower<br />

than the rank, which many other developing<br />

countries with which India’s growth is being<br />

compared. Development has many dimensions<br />

like poverty, nutrition, fertility rates,<br />

mortality rates, access to safe water and<br />

sanitation. Statistics shows that although<br />

poverty rate (Head Count Ratio) in India is<br />

going down, the malnutrition index is going<br />

up. 5 <strong>The</strong> moot question is whether it is due<br />

to lack of access to public services and goods<br />

like safe water and sanitation or is it because<br />

of lifestyle changes. <strong>The</strong> infant mortality<br />

rates are still quite low in certain states like<br />

Orissa in India. <strong>The</strong> primary school drop<br />

out rates have not decreased to a large extent<br />

in some states and it has failed in some<br />

instances in Rajasthan largely due to institutional<br />

failures. <strong>The</strong> teacher attendances<br />

in primary schools have not improved in<br />

many rural parts of India. <strong>The</strong> mid–day<br />

meal programme has failed in some states<br />

like Rajasthan owing to corruption and governance<br />

failures. <strong>The</strong>se governance failures<br />

are reflected in the fact that according to the<br />

recent IFPRI report India stands out at 94<br />

in the Hunger Index and is below African<br />

countries like Burkina Faso, Zimbabwe<br />

whose ranks are 92 and 93 respectively. 6<br />

Some of the neighbouring countries of India<br />

like Srilanka (with a rank 69) are above India<br />

in the Hunger Index. Other than this, the<br />

Transparency International Report quotes<br />

India’s rank in corruption index as 74 7 that<br />

is quite dismal in comparison to many other<br />

growing developing countries like Taiwan.<br />

India has been very poor in implementation<br />

of contract also which is reflected in its position<br />

beyond 150 in the “Implementation of<br />

Contract Index”. 8 This shows that as a country<br />

we have been not been capable of implementing<br />

designed contracts. <strong>The</strong> next question<br />

is as a country, whether we have the<br />

economic freedom to implement contracts<br />

even in today’s context of booming GDP<br />

growth. As Prof. Amartya Sen brought out<br />

the concept of “Freedom for Development”,<br />

if on those lines one considers India’s development<br />

then the facts are not too striking.<br />

This is because India’s ranking in the “Economic<br />

Freedom Index” stands out at 104 9<br />

which is not an optimistic picture considering<br />

the growth and development of many<br />

other developing countries. Other than this,<br />

a World Bank report also shows that it takes<br />

much more time in opening and closing<br />

business in India in comparison to other<br />

countries of South Asia like Pakistan. This<br />

reduces the ranking of the country in the<br />

economic freedom index. According to a<br />

report 10 India ranked 69 in 2005 amongst<br />

141 countries by the rankings of “Economic<br />

Freedom of the World Report <strong>2007</strong>”. This<br />

index gives a relative picture of the countries<br />

in terms of how policies and institutions of<br />

countries stand out in economic freedom.<br />

Economic freedom according to this index<br />

includes indicators like “personal choice,<br />

voluntary exchange, freedom to compete<br />

and security of privately owned property”.<br />

Although India’s position has improved<br />

Statistics show that although GDP has grown at a rate of<br />

7-8% and is hinting to touch a double-digit fi gure of 10%<br />

in recent times, the employment elasticity of the Economy<br />

has not grown proportionately w.r.t. GDP growth<br />

from 89 (in 1990) to 69 (in 2005) in the ranking,<br />

it still leaves scope for lot of improvement.<br />

Domestic institutional structures will<br />

have a critical role to play in such upliftment<br />

of India’s ranking. <strong>The</strong> reason for highlighting<br />

these facts is that all the above-mentioned<br />

factors play a role towards the development<br />

of the country. A consideration of<br />

these factors is also important while moving<br />

in the service driven growth path of Indian<br />

economy. A large outcome of the index<br />

rankings of India is a result of the governance<br />

failures within the country. As the<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

33


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

country grows it would be more important<br />

to build up institutions within India which<br />

are functional and proactive. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

has a very critical role to play in building<br />

up action oriented efficient institution<br />

structures and in implementing them. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

institutions have to facilitate the functioning<br />

of the market in an efficient way in certain<br />

segments of the economy to promote the<br />

growth of the Indian economy. This has to<br />

be facilitated by sound governance framework<br />

in Indian economy to address the developmental<br />

dimensions of India along its<br />

growth path. <strong>The</strong> next section briefly highlights<br />

the governance aspect.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Governance Aspect<br />

With regard to governance structure the<br />

important issue to ponder about is the role<br />

of the government market driven economy.<br />

In context of India, the role of government<br />

has to be efficient provisioning of public<br />

ment. This needs efficient functioning of<br />

the departments and the bodies associated<br />

with the basic infrastructure services. However<br />

the expenses for such provision of infrastructure<br />

and health care services should<br />

also be met through collection of taxes. <strong>The</strong><br />

tax collection policy has to be well targeted<br />

and progressive. This would mean that people<br />

with higher income would pay higher<br />

Market oriented growth is not a solution to the mitigation<br />

of this problem of conflicts. <strong>The</strong> role of a debating, progressive<br />

society holds the key towards this conflict resolution<br />

and for which government has to take a proactive role<br />

goods, services like safe, wider road networks,<br />

hospital services, water and sanitation<br />

services. In certain cases of such provisioning<br />

public private partnerships could be<br />

tried out in the form of concession, management<br />

contracts. <strong>The</strong> efficient functioning of<br />

these partnerships would again depend to a<br />

large extent on the nature and extent of implementation<br />

of such contracts, reduction of<br />

corruption in the process of awarding contracts.<br />

Efficient delivery of basic infrastructure<br />

services like safer roads, water and<br />

quality health care could tackle many of the<br />

developmental dimensions of the economy,<br />

which is lying at a dismal state at the mo-<br />

taxes for the provisioning of the infrastructure<br />

services for development. <strong>The</strong> key towards<br />

the success of this is the implementation<br />

mechanism which has to be monitored<br />

and reviewed from time to time. An accountability<br />

framework has to be brought in<br />

the governance structure for trickling down<br />

of growth of Indian economy towards development.<br />

This trickling down in simpler<br />

terms would mean provision of basic services<br />

like road, health care, water, information<br />

network to the rural areas of India.<br />

Along with that this would also mean provision<br />

of finance to the rural people for generation<br />

of economic activities and income<br />

for them.<br />

<strong>The</strong> growth of self-help groups and microfinance<br />

with favorable interest rate structure<br />

along with a reduction of intermediaries<br />

and informal lending could be one possible<br />

step in this direction. Larger penetration of<br />

banks, ATMs by allowing large number of<br />

players in banking segment could also be<br />

another step in this direction. However, this<br />

would need the support system of a governance<br />

framework, which would facilitate the<br />

efficient players to operate in the system.<br />

Market led growth thereby doesn’t necessarily<br />

mean a lesser government intervention as<br />

market led growth could often create a larger<br />

need for regulating the costs of growth so<br />

that growth could percolate and transit towards<br />

development of the society. Thus the<br />

importance of the government increases in<br />

that case with a change in its governance<br />

framework and operational structure. If this<br />

doesn’t happen then it could be termed as a<br />

failure of the governance framework, which<br />

could create disparities in the society<br />

through larger conflicts across sections of<br />

the society. <strong>The</strong> type and extent of these<br />

conflicts would vary from place to place and<br />

from region to region. <strong>The</strong>se could range<br />

from conflicts having their origin in caste<br />

discrimination (like the ones prevalent in<br />

Bihar) to conflicts, hatred originating from<br />

one section of the society, which has been<br />

deprived of the fruits of growth and development<br />

(like the ones in the North-Western<br />

parts of Andhra Pradesh, North-Eastern<br />

states of India). <strong>The</strong>re could be many other<br />

forms, but the two has been cited to bring<br />

out the role of the failure of governance<br />

framework in the development of a country<br />

even with the presence of a market driven<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> caste driven conflict (ones in<br />

Bihar) could be because of corruption and<br />

the political system as well as an ineffective<br />

education system. <strong>The</strong> resource scarcity and<br />

developmental needs driven conflict (ones<br />

in Andhra Pradesh, North-Eastern states of<br />

India) could be because of a lack of governance<br />

framework to enable efficient distribution<br />

of resources between regions across<br />

India. Conflict resolution is an integral part<br />

of development of a country. It arises because<br />

of domestic failures and exists because<br />

of ineffective implementation of stated policies,<br />

contracts. Market oriented growth is<br />

not a solution to the mitigation of this problem<br />

of conflicts. <strong>The</strong> role of a debating, pro-<br />

34 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

gressive society holds the key towards this<br />

conflict resolution and for which government<br />

has to take a proactive role through an<br />

efficient functioning of the governance<br />

framework. However in this regard one<br />

should mention the role of an important arm<br />

of the governance framework of India viz.<br />

the Administrative Services. It is absolutely<br />

essential in India to create an accountability<br />

system for the civil servants of the country.<br />

Such accountability could be created by efficient<br />

reviewing and monitoring of the performance<br />

of the civil servants. <strong>The</strong> civil society<br />

has to take a proactive role in<br />

questioning the role of the civil servants of<br />

the country on a regular basis by monitoring<br />

of the performance of the civil servants,<br />

which has to be target oriented. One could<br />

also think of incorporation of efficient managers<br />

in different arms of governance of the<br />

country. <strong>The</strong> governance framework could<br />

be led by these managers and the research<br />

inputs for further direction for managers<br />

could come from civil society. <strong>The</strong>se are<br />

some of the roads, which have to be traversed<br />

in modification of the existing governance<br />

regime in India to translate the<br />

growth story of India into a larger developmental<br />

story also.<br />

Conclusion<br />

Thus it is clear from the above stated analysis<br />

that if India has to be reimagined it has<br />

to be done in a holistic way. Such a reimagination<br />

would include an efficient functioning<br />

of market along with an effective functioning<br />

of the government through reduction<br />

of corruption and rent seeking activities. It<br />

would also mean an effective governance<br />

framework which would mean government<br />

with a target oriented role towards reduction<br />

of corruption, hunger, death rates, school<br />

drop outs etc. It would also mean a proactive<br />

government, which contributes towards<br />

creation of a well debated progressive society<br />

through a reduction in conflicts across<br />

states of India. Thus given the paradigm of<br />

development in which India is moving, the<br />

time is apt to imagine future India with an<br />

efficient role of market in certain segments<br />

of the economy along with proactive, efficient,<br />

accountable government functioning<br />

to create a trickle down effect of the growth<br />

towards its development.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

www.oecd.org/dataoecd/17/52/39452196.pdf<br />

2<br />

www.foreigntradepolicy.com/main_<br />

policy.htm<br />

3<br />

Emerging Structure of Indian Economy:<br />

Implications of Growing Inter -<br />

Sectoral Imbalances, T. S. Papola<br />

Director, Institute for Studies in Industrial<br />

Development, New Delhi, Presidential<br />

Address, 88 th Conference of <strong>The</strong> Indian<br />

Economic Association, Andhra<br />

University, Vishakhapatnam, <strong>Dec</strong>ember<br />

27-29, 2005; isidev.nic.in/pdf/presAdd_<br />

IEA05.pdf<br />

4<br />

http://hdr.undp.org/en/statistics/<br />

5<br />

Jha P & Negre M Indian Economy in the<br />

Era of Contemporary Globalisation:<br />

Some Core Elements of the Balance<br />

Sheet, www.macroscan.com/anl/may07/<br />

pdf/Indian_Economy.pdf<br />

6<br />

<strong>The</strong> Challenge of Hunger <strong>2007</strong> Global<br />

Hunger Index: Facts, determinants, and<br />

trends; Measures being taken to reduce<br />

acute undernourishment and chronic<br />

hunger, Bonn, October <strong>2007</strong>, published<br />

by Welt Hunger Hilfe, International Food<br />

Policy Research Institute, Concern<br />

7<br />

www.transparency.org/publications/gcr<br />

8<br />

www.adb.org/Documents/Fact_Sheets/<br />

IND.asp<br />

9<br />

www.heritage.org/research/ features/index/country.cfm?id=India<br />

- 15k -<br />

10<br />

“India ranks 69th in global economies<br />

freedom index”, 4 sep, <strong>2007</strong>, Economic<br />

Times. economictimes.indiatimes.com/<br />

articleshow/2337548.cms<br />

References<br />

• <strong>The</strong> Economic Times. economictimes.<br />

indiatimes.com/articleshow/2337548.cms;<br />

“India ranks 69 th in global economies<br />

freedom index”, 4 Sep, <strong>2007</strong>, accessed on<br />

1 st October <strong>2007</strong><br />

• Goswami, A. Chakraborty, P, Inequality<br />

in Indian Economy, Studies in Indian<br />

Economy, Vol. II/ edited by K. R. Gupta;<br />

New Delhi, Atlantic Pub., <strong>2007</strong><br />

• Jha P & Negre M Indian Economy in the<br />

Era of Contemporary Globalisation:<br />

Some Core Elements of the Balance<br />

Sheet , www.macroscan.com/anl/may07/<br />

pdf/Indian_Economy.pdf, accessed on 1 st<br />

Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• http://hdr.undp.org/en/statistics/ accessed<br />

on 30th October <strong>2007</strong><br />

• Welt Hunger Hilfe, International Food<br />

Policy Research Institute, Concern , <strong>The</strong><br />

Challenge of Hunger <strong>2007</strong> Global Hunger<br />

Index: Facts, determinants, and<br />

trends; Measures being taken to reduce<br />

acute undernourishment and chronic<br />

hunger, Bonn, October <strong>2007</strong>,<br />

• www.oecd.org/dataoecd/17/52/39452196.<br />

pdf accessed on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• www.foreigntradepolicy.com/main_policy.htm<br />

accessed on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• www.transparency.org/publications/gcr<br />

accessed on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• www.adb.org/Documents/Fact_Sheets/<br />

IND.asp accessed on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

• www.heritage.org/research/ features/index/country.cfm?id=India<br />

- 15k – accessed<br />

on 2 nd Nov <strong>2007</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

35


Amal Sanyal,<br />

Associate Professor,<br />

Lincoln University,<br />

Canterbury, New Zealand<br />

Governance, Market, Deprivation<br />

And <strong>The</strong> Political System<br />

"<strong>The</strong> care of human life and<br />

happiness, and not their destruction,<br />

is the first and only<br />

object of good government."<br />

-Thomas Jefferson<br />

A<br />

lot has changed in our economic<br />

institutions in the last<br />

two decades. <strong>The</strong>se changes<br />

have not made much impression on water,<br />

housing, healthcare and power for<br />

low income people, or on poverty. I<br />

strongly believe that these issues are<br />

similarly handled in pre- and post-reform<br />

and that this is a matter of the political<br />

system, which has not changed across the<br />

periods. To these issues it is extraneous<br />

if we have a globally integrated fullfledged<br />

market economy or an importsubstituting<br />

economy run by administered<br />

production and pricing. To address<br />

them properly we need governments to<br />

act pro-actively against deprivation. A<br />

necessary condition is to have governments<br />

formed with competent and<br />

public-minded persons. <strong>The</strong> present political<br />

system is not capable of producing<br />

such governments. We need a thorough<br />

political reform, not economic, to get<br />

such governments.<br />

I am not competent to discuss the political<br />

system or its reform possibilities.<br />

Given that this issue of the journal focuses<br />

on market reform, I explore if certain<br />

market reforms can play a catalytic<br />

role in reducing deprivation by either<br />

inducing change in the political system<br />

or in spite it. We can get such effects to<br />

a degree by ridding the government of a<br />

variety of governance tasks, i.e. by letting<br />

markets produce these services. My suggestions<br />

do not arise from an economist’s<br />

habit of preaching ‘market’ for the sake<br />

of the economy. Rather, it is a sort of<br />

preaching ‘market’ for the sake of the<br />

political system. I will focus entirely on<br />

market reforms in the provision of governance.<br />

Though I will mainly examine<br />

possible effects on the political system<br />

and deprivation, I will also elaborate on<br />

more general economic effects.<br />

<strong>The</strong> abstract notion of governance in<br />

practical terms involves production of<br />

services for individuals or communities.<br />

Depending on jurisdiction, central, state<br />

and local governments provide them.<br />

Principles are laid down by the legislature<br />

and production and delivery are<br />

36 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

managed by the executive. At the point<br />

of delivery it is handled by government<br />

offices and workers. Leaving aside defence,<br />

judicial service and policing, we<br />

are left with a bewildering variety of<br />

services that touch our everyday life.<br />

Need for them has appeared gradually<br />

with the evolution of governance and it<br />

was expedient for the government of the<br />

day to start producing them. But taking<br />

stock today, there is no strategic, technical<br />

or logistical reason why they can not<br />

be produced outside the government. On<br />

the other hand there is an important<br />

connection between these services and<br />

the political system. As I reason below<br />

their marketisation can improve our political<br />

system significantly. Further, for<br />

one class of services marketisation can<br />

directly alleviate deprivation, i.e. in spite<br />

of the political system.<br />

We expect three types of gain from<br />

these changes. More important are social<br />

and political. <strong>The</strong>re are of course<br />

economic benefits, though they come<br />

with adverse side effects which need to<br />

be addressed. In the social area, delegation<br />

can produce a significant dent on<br />

corruption. As long as government is the<br />

sole producer and provider, the delivery<br />

person can seek private money for service<br />

or speed. Replacing government by<br />

markets in governance can disable a<br />

large field of rent-seeking. Leaving that<br />

paid to police, bribes the public pays are<br />

to local, state and central government<br />

workers for governance services of this<br />

kind. <strong>The</strong>y can be mostly eliminated by<br />

moving them to the market and keeping<br />

the markets competitive. Improvement<br />

in the political system can come as a direct<br />

result of mitigation of corruption.<br />

Note that service at a government office<br />

can be as easily sped up by bribe as<br />

by show of political power. Those with<br />

right political affiliation easily jump<br />

service queues. Also, politicians reward<br />

people by getting their work done or<br />

sped up in return for vote or allegiance.<br />

This kind of favour is extremely valuable<br />

because certain services are indispensable<br />

for business, property, jobs, pension,<br />

healthcare, litigation, reputation or even<br />

freedom. Government workers who<br />

oblige politicians in this game expect reciprocation.<br />

Generally the return is<br />

through rewards related to their career—promotions,<br />

suitable placements<br />

and protection. This creates a second<br />

round effect on work culture as promotion<br />

gets detached from merit. It reinforces<br />

poor governance and allegiance<br />

to the political system.<br />

Through repeated feedback the nexus<br />

intensifies the corruption of politics. <strong>The</strong><br />

nexus itself becomes a stable feature<br />

rather than occasional. Given this stable<br />

relation, politics and political affiliation<br />

have emerged as the surest way of ‘getting<br />

things done’. Politics is now widely<br />

perceived as a tool for benefiting oneself<br />

rather than the community, country or<br />

nation. This image of politics leads to<br />

adverse selection in politics. Relatively<br />

competent people--- sure about their<br />

ability--- tend to stay away to avoid the<br />

stigma. At the same time those who have<br />

the taste and the ability to manipulate,<br />

subvert and criminalise tend to join politics.<br />

Obviously, we do not choose from<br />

among the best of Indians when we vote<br />

in elections. This leads to governments<br />

formed of the less competent and the<br />

corrupt. Reform that snaps the tie between<br />

politics and provision can have<br />

noticeable effect on the nature of our<br />

politics. We can also expect some direct<br />

effects on deprivation in spite of the<br />

apathy of the political system. Services<br />

like forestation, land recovery, bunding,<br />

dredging and de-silting of rivers, arid<br />

area programs etc. have direct impact on<br />

income and quality of life below and<br />

around the poverty line. <strong>The</strong>se services<br />

are under-produced in the present system<br />

and their production can be significantly<br />

increased by marketisation.<br />

On the economic side, we expect improvement<br />

in efficiency. Inefficiency of<br />

the present system shows as poor quality,<br />

Improvement of effi ciency would reduce cost and<br />

generate either taxpayers’ saving or release budgetary<br />

resource for worthwhile projects. <strong>The</strong>se overall gains<br />

will be attended with dislocation for some<br />

failure to deliver in time or to deliver at<br />

all. Cost far exceeds what is technically<br />

required. Part of the resources are<br />

drained through bureaucratic and political<br />

delay, inappropriate technology<br />

and overstaffing. Improvement of efficiency<br />

would reduce cost and generate<br />

either taxpayers’ saving or release budgetary<br />

resource for worthwhile projects.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se overall gains will be attended with<br />

dislocation for some. <strong>The</strong> most pronounced<br />

short run effect is that the government<br />

has to persuade some employees<br />

to retire. Some retirees would find<br />

employment in new outfits and others’<br />

retirement has to be financed from cost<br />

saving. If we go for this variant of reform,<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

37


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

then the resource saving should be properly<br />

accounted and used strictly for alleviating<br />

adverse side effects.<br />

Model For delegation<br />

For ease of discussion I will arrange governance<br />

services into three groups. First<br />

are the services for individuals that are<br />

provided on demand. As far as the consumer<br />

is concerned, these are like any<br />

other private good that she or he uses<br />

exclusively. Getting a passport, a driving<br />

licence, a variety of registration, certification<br />

and so on are of this category. <strong>The</strong><br />

second group consists of services that are<br />

public goods by nature. Once produced<br />

and in place, any one can dip into their<br />

benefit and it is not possible to deny anyone<br />

access. Hence governance involves<br />

producing these services for whoever is<br />

interested and not for any one in particular.<br />

Examples are roads, bridges, street<br />

lighting and road maintenance and so<br />

on. People are quite aware of the usefulness<br />

of these services, but are prone to<br />

understate how much they would be willing<br />

to pay. <strong>The</strong> reason is so called ‘free<br />

riding’ – why pay if they can’t stop me<br />

from using it? <strong>The</strong> third group is a special<br />

class of public goods type services<br />

whose benefit most may not be aware of.<br />

Or, even if they are aware, most people<br />

put a low priority on them because the<br />

benefit appears distant and dispersed. I<br />

will call them pro-active governance<br />

services because the public may not generally<br />

press for them as they do for other<br />

public goods like roads or bridges. Some<br />

of these services may be directed at individuals<br />

but most are not directed to anyone<br />

in particular. When serving individuals,<br />

they produce large scale<br />

externality benefits. An example is a program<br />

of immunisation against a contagious<br />

disease. It saves an immunised<br />

person from the disease even as it reduces<br />

the chance of others getting it.<br />

More generally these services are not<br />

directed and are produced for the benefit<br />

of everyone at present and in the future.<br />

Examples are services like foresta-<br />

Services that are public goods by nature are thought to be an<br />

area where markets would fail to produce the right amount at<br />

the right cost even if markets are competitive to the hilt<br />

tion, dredging and cleaning of rivers,<br />

reforestation of hill sides, creating buffers<br />

at arid zones and so on.<br />

<strong>The</strong> three groups of services lend<br />

themselves to marketisation in different<br />

degrees and are amenable to different<br />

business models. <strong>The</strong>ir impact on corruption<br />

and the political system vary.<br />

Some have more impact on the political<br />

system while others have more<br />

positive and attending adverse side effects<br />

upon the economy.<br />

Individually Demanded Services<br />

Provision of an individually demanded<br />

service can be most easily transferred to<br />

markets. Unlike for public goods, its demand<br />

is easy to recognise. Because demand<br />

arises from the need of an individual<br />

who benefits from it alone, it can<br />

be priced. Also generally these services<br />

are not free under our present system.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y are either sold at a price or a fee is<br />

charged. <strong>The</strong>refore they can be sold like<br />

any item of consumption by private sellers.<br />

However, unlike a consumption item,<br />

some services are conditional on not only<br />

the price but also characteristics of the<br />

applicant or buyer. Suppose a registration<br />

service can not be sold to persons<br />

below 18 years. <strong>The</strong> selling organisation<br />

has to carry out the necessary verification.<br />

In fact part of the price accounts<br />

for the cost of verification of the applicant.<br />

Like clerks in government offices<br />

who currently provide these services,<br />

sellers are to be provided with relevant<br />

rules. <strong>The</strong>se rules should be made public,<br />

displayed prominently at service<br />

shops and should be mandated to be<br />

available on demand.<br />

What are the potential objections to<br />

this possibility? First, will the price remain<br />

reasonable? Yes, if firms are allowed<br />

to enter this business freely, their<br />

competition should keep price close to<br />

the cost of production and provision. In<br />

the present system government offices<br />

producing these services are over-staffed.<br />

It is easy to see that the cost of providing<br />

them would be significantly lower for private<br />

firms. <strong>The</strong> government often subsidises<br />

the price, which means that part of<br />

the true cost and whole of the cost of inefficiency<br />

of government offices is passed<br />

to the government budget for the tax<br />

payer to bear. Tax payers would be spared<br />

this in the suggested scenario. What if<br />

38 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

the market price turns out to be higher<br />

than what poorer applicants can bear? If<br />

the government means to help, sellers<br />

can be required to sell at lower price to<br />

some applicants and get the difference<br />

reimbursed by the government. Sellers<br />

will be required to verify an applicant’s<br />

claim to the subsidy as per guideline.<br />

What is the incentive of a seller to do the<br />

extra work rather than pass on to the next<br />

applicant? If a seller is not keen to service<br />

these applicants it will simply lose<br />

some business. Poorer buyers will move<br />

to other sellers.<br />

What do we gain by upsetting the<br />

present system? First, as I suggested<br />

above, is to reduce the space for rentseeking.<br />

It not only reduces the burden<br />

of bribes in an ordinary household’s<br />

budget, but cleans the environment of<br />

governance. As rent-seeking abates, the<br />

grip of politics on service provision too<br />

falls to that extent. <strong>The</strong> effect on political<br />

life can be easily appreciated. Second,<br />

resource spent on providing this<br />

item will come down close to what is necessary<br />

with present technology of provision<br />

and verification. This gain actually<br />

means saving of resources, which should<br />

be earmarked for supporting loss of government<br />

job and hardship. Private firms<br />

are also expected to innovate processes<br />

in order to increase profit margin. This<br />

would bring in improvement in speed<br />

and quality for service users.<br />

Universal Services Or Public<br />

Goods<br />

Services that are public goods by nature<br />

are thought to be an area where markets<br />

would fail to produce the right amount<br />

at the right cost even if markets are competitive<br />

to the hilt. Because people can<br />

not be excluded from such a service once<br />

it is produced, it is difficult to get them<br />

pay the right price -- that is price commensurate<br />

with the benefit. Knowing<br />

that the service is going to be available<br />

any way, no one would be too keen to pay<br />

the deserving price, however much someone<br />

needs it. If such a service were to be<br />

produced by private sellers, they would<br />

find much less than the true demand in<br />

the market. Production will be less than<br />

requirement. Because there is no way of<br />

getting the right price paid, these services<br />

are usually funded from taxes.<br />

However many services that are traditionally<br />

known as public goods have<br />

ceased to be really so. We now have technology<br />

to prevent using many of these<br />

services even when they are available to<br />

others. Toll gates at the ends of a bridge<br />

are now common. We also have toll gates<br />

at the end of newly-built highways. In<br />

many countries gates are operated electronically<br />

to prevent users from skipping<br />

the toll and employees from stealing toll<br />

money. We have the technology to separate<br />

payers and non-payers in much more<br />

complicated situation than the bridge or<br />

the highway example. In London any vehicle<br />

entering the central business district<br />

with many entry and exit points is<br />

automatically billed for entry in working<br />

hours. This is done without obstructing<br />

traffic flow. As soon as we have a lowcost<br />

way to exclude non-payers, the service<br />

becomes like a private good and we<br />

could be better off by delegating them to<br />

market operation. Several state governments<br />

have invited private firms to build<br />

roads and bridges and collect tolls for a<br />

stipulated number of years. A common<br />

uneasiness about marketisation of these<br />

services comes from the belief that tolls<br />

or similar fees are an encroachment on<br />

our private budgets. “Why should we pay<br />

for using roads and bridges at all?”—it is<br />

asked. <strong>The</strong> fact of the matter is that we<br />

pay and have always paid for similar services<br />

through taxes. Paying a road charge<br />

at the toll gate is definitely fairer than<br />

that because those who do not use a road<br />

do not have to pay.<br />

Much of this is happening in India as I<br />

remarked earlier. <strong>The</strong> point here is that<br />

this model can be extended over a larger<br />

variety of government services. Maintenance<br />

of public places, government offices<br />

and buildings, railway stations and<br />

property, tourist routes and spots, places<br />

Majority of the services that are traditionally known as<br />

public goods have ceased to be really so. We now have<br />

technology to prevent using many of these services<br />

even when they are available to others<br />

of historical interest and so on can be<br />

brought under this mode of operation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> basic toll-gate model of business of<br />

course requires adaptation depending on<br />

the service. Several imaginative improvisations<br />

are already in use in various<br />

countries. For example, in some instances<br />

the government may not want to<br />

charge individuals though it is possible.<br />

<strong>The</strong> government may decide to waive<br />

tolls along the road to a pilgrimage or<br />

not to charge visitors of historical and<br />

educational sites. In this case the government<br />

itself pays the bill to the business<br />

that produces the service. Users do ‘buy’<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

39


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

entry tickets or toll stamps to keep account<br />

of the number of uses. But they buy<br />

it for free, and the bill is paid by the government.<br />

A useful improvement is to allow<br />

a market for these businesses, which<br />

lets an investor sell off, say a toll service,<br />

to a buyer with obligations and rights of<br />

the original contract. This facilitates entry<br />

and exit, allow firms to specialise in<br />

specific services by acquiring similar<br />

business in different places. Can we gain<br />

anything for the political system from<br />

marketisation of these services? Since<br />

these services are not individually demanded,<br />

there is no scope for bribes<br />

from individual buyers and hence no effect<br />

on the political system along the<br />

route discussed earlier. <strong>The</strong>se services<br />

however are a source of significant political<br />

corruption. Public goods are often<br />

gifted to a community before elections.<br />

Secondly when a sanctioned service gets<br />

delayed or stopped on the way it can be<br />

started or re-started only with lobbying.<br />

For urgent service local business or communities<br />

often collectively pay into party<br />

funds as part of lobbying. To stop these<br />

occurrences, of course marketisation<br />

alone is not enough. Whether a project<br />

or a service is taken up will continue to<br />

depend on the political system and hence<br />

on lobbying. But stoppage of work and<br />

allied corruption can be avoided to a<br />

large extent. Economic advantage of<br />

marketisation of these services merits<br />

separate mention. First, to match our<br />

current economic growth investment<br />

needed for infrastructure is beyond the<br />

government’s means. If the government<br />

insists on doing by itself the task will be<br />

either delayed or have to be done by borrowing.<br />

<strong>The</strong> cost of borrowing is raised<br />

from tax payers while in the suggested<br />

alternative it is substituted by toll paying<br />

users. Toll rates can be reduced as much<br />

as possible through competitive bids<br />

Pro-active services are particularly recommended for<br />

delegation to markets. While their impact on the political<br />

system could be marginal, they could help alleviate<br />

deprivation in spite of the political system<br />

from interested firms. Secondly, it is<br />

easier to assure quality of construction<br />

and subsequent maintenance under the<br />

market system. <strong>The</strong>y are to form part of<br />

the deal with the government who should<br />

enforce them strictly with penalty provisions.<br />

Because of the contractual nature<br />

of the obligation, there is no haziness<br />

about accountability when construction<br />

or maintenance is poor. This contrasts<br />

starkly with government provision, where<br />

it is nearly impossible to fi x responsibility<br />

for failure because of multiple agencies,<br />

hierarchical decisions and change<br />

of governments.<br />

Pro-active Services<br />

<strong>The</strong>se tasks are important and urgent<br />

but government organisations do a poor<br />

job. <strong>The</strong> primary reason is that assigned<br />

organisations do not have to face customers<br />

because there are no identifiable<br />

customers. Neither they nor the government<br />

or political parties are subject to<br />

any pressure for quantum, quality or<br />

speed. <strong>The</strong>se services are particularly<br />

recommended for delegation to markets.<br />

While their impact on the political<br />

system could be marginal, they could<br />

help alleviate deprivation in spite of the<br />

political system. At present markets for<br />

these services exist only in an odd, theoretical<br />

way. <strong>The</strong>re are no private buyers<br />

willing to pay. <strong>The</strong> government assumes<br />

a dual personality as both buyer and<br />

producer. It does not help because the<br />

government is only a buying agent, not<br />

a true buyer. It is expected to buy on behalf<br />

of a billion people who do not press<br />

for the services and billions more who<br />

are not even born. <strong>The</strong>re is no economic<br />

or political mechanism to keep the<br />

government interested. <strong>The</strong> result is too<br />

little production and poor quality.<br />

Whatever little is produced is produced<br />

indifferently. Inefficiency of government<br />

services is compounded here because of<br />

buyer apathy.<br />

Inviting private firms creates a group<br />

seriously interested in them--- as hotly<br />

interested as commercial firms are in<br />

their line of business. Firms specialising<br />

in these services take on the job of demand<br />

creation as part of their business<br />

agenda. <strong>The</strong>y produce media campaigns<br />

to generate public awareness of the urgency<br />

of the services and organise special<br />

interest groups that press on the<br />

political system. Some of these services<br />

40 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

like immunisation, social forestry, reforestation<br />

of hill sides or de-silting of waterways<br />

etc. have a direct impact on the<br />

livelihood and quality of life of the poor.<br />

By generating pressure from the demand<br />

side on the political system, marketisation<br />

can help to produce more of<br />

them and make a difference. We also<br />

gain from the supply side. Since producers<br />

are to make a profit at the end of the<br />

day, every rupee of taxpayer drawn into<br />

the work has to work efficiently. It may<br />

appear puzzling that there should be<br />

any scope for profit in these services. If<br />

the government were to do the job it is<br />

not expected to make a profit out of it.<br />

Taxpayers would then just pay for the<br />

cost. However that cost contains, as experience<br />

tells, not only the technically<br />

required cost but that of inappropriate<br />

technical and political choices, of bureaucratic<br />

delays, of coalition politics<br />

and above all of general inefficiency. For<br />

the same amount of money budgeted for<br />

a project, the suggested system promises<br />

to meet the stipulated quality and<br />

complete it in time with a profit to spare<br />

for the producers. In a sense the profit<br />

is hidden in the present system. It is enjoyed<br />

by bureaucrats and government<br />

workers not in cash but in kind. It takes<br />

the form of the luxury of slack work environment<br />

and unaccountability. It is<br />

this hidden profit that motivates private<br />

firms as much as it motivates some government<br />

workers to prefer jobs in these<br />

areas. <strong>The</strong> latter take it in kind while<br />

private business would convert it to cash<br />

profit. But the winner would be the public<br />

who would get more services, done in<br />

time at lower cost. To get this going we<br />

need to initiate a market-like environment<br />

by announcing that these services<br />

will be bought on the market. This will<br />

spawn an industry producing these services<br />

that will not only efficiently produce<br />

better quality service but also generate<br />

a demand side awareness to sustain the<br />

industry. United States, North Europe<br />

and Pacific countries like Japan, Australia<br />

and New Zealand have made big<br />

strides in the technology of environment<br />

protection and nurturing in the last decade.<br />

<strong>The</strong> business model generates ample<br />

incentive for cost-cutting, improvement<br />

of technology and research. A<br />

switch to this model could help us to<br />

make significant difference to the lives<br />

of lower income people and also reduce<br />

resource costs in the long run.


Nilanjan Banik,<br />

Associate Professor, Institute for<br />

Financial Management and<br />

Research (IFMR),Chennai<br />

<strong>The</strong> Economics Of Social Unrest –<br />

Its Causes And Cure<br />

"Injustice anywhere is a threat<br />

to justice everywhere."<br />

-Martin Luther King Jr.<br />

"Naxalite faction vows to avenge Nandigram<br />

killings"<br />

26 May <strong>2007</strong>, Times of India.<br />

Newspaper headlines, such as these,<br />

are not hard to find these days.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Naxalite movement takes its<br />

name from a peasant uprising which took<br />

place in May 1967 at Naxalbari – a place on<br />

the north-eastern tip of India situated in the<br />

state of West Bengal. Many believe that<br />

these fearsome Naxals are now in Nandigram.<br />

Although to a layman what is happening<br />

in Nandigram carries more political<br />

connotation there are some economics behind<br />

it. <strong>The</strong> purpose of this article is to examine<br />

the economics of social unrest.<br />

Nandigram is a case in point but the following<br />

arguments in general will have a broader<br />

implication for India as a whole. As is<br />

known, recently the Naxals have also expanded<br />

their area of operations (from their<br />

old pockets in West Bengal, Bihar and Andhra<br />

Pradesh in the 1970s) to new guerilla<br />

zones in other states like Orissa, Maharashtra,<br />

Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand, Madhya<br />

Pradesh and Uttar Pradesh. So what goes<br />

into making a militant? Actually, it is the<br />

socially deprived group of people who takes<br />

arm against the administration. Does the<br />

people are more socially deprived now than<br />

what they were before? We are considering<br />

the period before and after reforms. This<br />

benchmark is because of less militant activities<br />

during the period before reforms.<br />

Although there were few reforms during<br />

early 1980s, the all encompassing process<br />

of reforms started during 1991. We are defining<br />

reforms in terms of globalization and<br />

liberalization. Surprisingly, incidence of<br />

anti-government activities was less during<br />

the period before reforms. Surprising because<br />

then the average Indian in terms of<br />

economic well-being was worse off compared<br />

to what the people are now. For example,<br />

India’s GDP grew at an average rate<br />

of 3.5 percent until mid-1970s; it increased<br />

to 5.5 percent during the 1980s; and further<br />

to around six percent during the 1990s.<br />

During the last three years, Indian economy<br />

has recorded a growth rate of around nine<br />

percent per annum.<br />

42 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1: Poverty In India<br />

Population below Poverty Line (As per Expert Group Methodology) in India<br />

Sector 1973-74 1977-78 1983 1978-88 1993-94 1999-2000<br />

Population (Millions)<br />

Rural 261.3 264.3 252 231.9 244 193.2<br />

Urban 60 64.6 70.9 75.2 76.3 67<br />

Total 321.3 328.9 322.9 307.1 320.3 260.2<br />

Poverty Ratio (%)<br />

Rural 56.4 53.1 45.7 39.1 37.3 27.1<br />

Urban 49 45.2 40.8 38.2 32.4 23.6<br />

Total 54.9 51.3 44.5 38.9 36 26.1<br />

Source: Rural Development Statistics 2002-03, National Institute of Rural Development<br />

A reflection of this higher growth rate other hand, share of services sector in GDP<br />

also got reflected in terms of higher percapita<br />

income and lower poverty numbers. 1950-51 to 55 percent during 2006-<strong>2007</strong>.<br />

has increased from 29.80 percent during<br />

Measured in constant US 2005 dollars India’s<br />

per-capita GDP has increased from mained more or less constant at around 27<br />

<strong>The</strong> share of manufacturing sector has re-<br />

215 during 1975 to 293 during 1988 and further<br />

to 546 during 2005. Like wise, the pov-<br />

Now let us concentrate on the number of<br />

percent during post reforms era.<br />

erty number (measured in terms of head people who are earning their livelihood<br />

count ratio) has fallen from 42 percent during<br />

1987 to the present level of 26.1 percent. cent of the Indian population earns their<br />

from these three sectors. Around, 58.6 per-<br />

Measured by these numbers reforms have livelihood from agricultural and agricultural<br />

related allied activities compared to<br />

increased overall economic well-being.<br />

So where lie the problem? How can we less than 10 percent of the population earning<br />

their livelihood from organized services<br />

explain this anomaly of a rise in social unrest?<br />

<strong>The</strong> answer to this apparent puzzle lies sector (Table 4). What does it means? In<br />

in examining impact of reforms on income simple words, if the national income is Rs<br />

distribution. Reforms entail unequal payoff 100 then agricultural and allied activities<br />

to economic agents. People with more skill are contributing 18.5 percent of the national<br />

income, that is, Rs 18.5 compared to Rs<br />

stand to gain more compared to people with<br />

less skill sets (read, less productive people). 55 generated by the services sector. Income<br />

And this has resulted in more skewed income<br />

distribution (read, right skewed dentributing<br />

Rs 18.5 to 58.6 people (employed<br />

inequality becomes evident as it is like dissity<br />

function) leading to social unrest. <strong>The</strong> in agricultural sector) compared to distributing<br />

Rs 55 to less than 10 people (employed<br />

following two boxes will help us to analyze<br />

this scenario better.<br />

in organized service sector) or 23 people<br />

Looking at sectoral GDP share, we find (employed in both organized and unorganized<br />

service sector). What is more worrying<br />

that the share of agriculture has fallen from<br />

56.90 percent during 1950-51 to 18.5 percent<br />

during 2006-<strong>2007</strong> (Table 2). On the more as going by the latest data<br />

is that this inequality is going to increase<br />

agricultural<br />

sector is growing at an annual rate of 2.6<br />

percent compared to services growing at<br />

a rate of 11 percent. If the present trend<br />

continues, then share of agriculture in national<br />

income is to become a single digit<br />

number within the next 15 years<br />

– contributing more to inequality in<br />

income distribution.<br />

Table-2 complements Table-1 by throwing<br />

some more additional information. <strong>The</strong><br />

share of income generated by the agricultural<br />

sector is more volatile (measured by<br />

the variance of the growth rates) compared<br />

to manufacturing, services and overall GDP.<br />

Uncertainties associated with income have<br />

two specific outcomes: postponement of<br />

investment decision and migration. As is<br />

evident from Table-4 because of fluctuating<br />

agricultural income level of investment<br />

is also least in the agricultural sector. Postponement<br />

of investment decisions have<br />

bearing on future income and reduce future<br />

expected earning from the sector. This is<br />

one way to contribute to the burgeoning<br />

disparity in earnings across sectors. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

is another way and that has to do with migration.<br />

Uncertainty associated with volatile<br />

income leads to migration. As ‘expected’<br />

return in the urban sector (dominated by<br />

the services sector) is higher than ‘actual’<br />

return in the agricultural sector, migration<br />

happens. However, many migrating labors<br />

lack adequate skills for finding<br />

meaningful employment in the services<br />

sector. Consequently, these unemployed<br />

people find add to a higher skewed<br />

income distribution.<br />

Now let us examine why are the workers<br />

in the services sector, especially in the organized<br />

services sector, like, banking, telecommunication,<br />

teaching, medical, legal,<br />

etc., are making so much money relative to<br />

the agriculture workers. For that one has to<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

43


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 2: Reforms And Income Generation<br />

Components 1950-51 1960-61 1970-71 1980-81 1990-91 1995-96 2004-05 2006-07<br />

Agriculture and<br />

allied activities<br />

56.90 46.74 46.07 38.86 31.27 28.24 21.13 18.5<br />

(2.6%)!<br />

Industry 14.28 19.46 20.65 24.50 27.64 28.12 27.15 26.4<br />

(10.4%)<br />

Services 29.80 34.30 33.66 36.64 41.10 43.64 51.72 55<br />

(11%)<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (2006) and Central Statistical Organization (2006)<br />

examine the productivity data. <strong>The</strong> growth<br />

theory literature tells us that more productive<br />

countries tend to prosper more compared<br />

to the less productive ones. If market<br />

is determining the pay-off, same kind of<br />

argument holds true within a country but<br />

across its laborers. So it makes sense to look<br />

at labor productivity data in India. Figure 1<br />

gives a glimpse of sector wise labor productivity<br />

growth in India. Output per worker in<br />

the services sector grew at a rate of seven<br />

percent during 1993-99, compared to only<br />

2.7 percent during the previous decade. <strong>The</strong><br />

performance of the labor productivity in the<br />

manufacturing sector was more modest<br />

growing from 3.1 percent to 4.5 percent during<br />

the same period. Agriculture sector was<br />

the lagging sector, with output per worker<br />

rising only to 2.4 percent during 1993-99,<br />

compared to 1.5 percent during the previous<br />

decade. As wages are linked to productivity<br />

it is little surprising to figure out why<br />

people in the services sector making more<br />

money compared to the other sector.<br />

<strong>The</strong> fact that services is the fastest growing<br />

sector (that is, demand for skilled labors<br />

are always there) and requires only skilled<br />

labors (less in numbers in India); wage rate<br />

in the services sector is much higher than<br />

in the agricultural sector. <strong>The</strong> average per<br />

day return of agricultural worker varies between<br />

Rs 25 (read Indian Rupees; Rs 39.5<br />

is one US dollar) in States, like, Bihar, Mi-<br />

zoram, Manipur, Arunachal Pradesh, etc.<br />

to an average of around Rs 125 per day in<br />

States, like, Haryana, Punjab, Kerala,<br />

Tamil Nadu, Gujarat, etc. Although spatial<br />

inequalities exist for agricultural sector;<br />

income inequality becomes large considering<br />

inter-sector inequality, i.e. inequality<br />

between services and agricultural sectors.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se days the average salaries for a standard<br />

Business School graduates ranges between<br />

five lacs to seven lacs, per annum.<br />

Quite evidently these are much higher figures<br />

compared to an average agricultural<br />

earning. So what needs to be done? From<br />

the demand side perspective government is<br />

Table 3: Uncertainty In Agricultural Income<br />

spending money on schemes like, minimum<br />

rural employment guarantee<br />

scheme in 200 most<br />

backward districts in India<br />

with the objective of providing<br />

100 days of guaranteed<br />

unskilled wage employment<br />

to each rural<br />

household opting for it. <strong>The</strong>se schemes are<br />

to be spread to other districts as well. However,<br />

such demand management policies<br />

sometime can be self defeating. For instance,<br />

if these people are hired for building<br />

a road and the project never gets completed<br />

then the money allocated for the<br />

purpose will add on to inflation. A better<br />

1971-72 to<br />

1980-81<br />

way to address this problem associated with<br />

income inequality will be to address long<br />

term supply management policies. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are two major problems. First has to do<br />

with skill formation. Workers can be trained<br />

giving vocational education. <strong>The</strong> experiences<br />

of some South-East Asian economies<br />

show that one reason these economies fared<br />

well on the distributional aspect of income<br />

1981-82 to<br />

1990-91<br />

1991-92 to<br />

2004-05<br />

GDP<br />

Growth (Mean) 3.16 5.64 5.83<br />

Coff. of Variation 137.75 39.05 31.84<br />

Agriculture and Allied Service<br />

Growth (Mean) 1.83 3.55 2.58<br />

Coff. of Variation 475.21 150.74 188.74<br />

Industry<br />

Growth (Mean) 4.05 7.11 5.81<br />

Coff. of Variation 88.91 28.22 51.85<br />

Services<br />

Growth (Mean) 4.42 6.72 7.78<br />

Coff. of Variation 34.03 17.16 23.04<br />

Source: National Account Statistics<br />

44 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 1: Sector Wise Factor Productivity<br />

Average Annual Percent Change<br />

7<br />

6<br />

5<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

1<br />

0<br />

Labor And Total Factor Productivity Growth In India<br />

Output Per Worker<br />

Total Factor Productivity<br />

1960-73 1973-83 1983-93 1993-99 1999-2004<br />

Source: Bosworth, Collins and Virmani (2006)<br />

Table 4: Capital Formation And Employment sion. A better provision<br />

of services<br />

Investment (as a % of 1993-94 1999-2000 2004-2005<br />

total investment)<br />

especially in the<br />

Agricultural and Allied 8.42 8.48 6.63<br />

education sector<br />

will usher in an<br />

Industry 50.09 51.44 54.06<br />

even income distribution.<br />

<strong>The</strong> sec-<br />

Services 41.19 40.08 39.31<br />

Employment Ratios (as a % of total employment)<br />

ond major problem<br />

Agricultural and Allied 60.39 56.70 58.60<br />

is associated with<br />

Industry 15.83 17.57 18.50<br />

volatile agricultural<br />

Services 23.78 25.73 22.90<br />

income. As we have<br />

Source: Reserve Bank of India (2006) and Central Statistical Organization (2006)<br />

seen volatile agricultural<br />

is because the governments put emphasis<br />

on vocational education. Growth in these<br />

economies is primarily driven by increase<br />

labor force participation. It would make<br />

sense to impart adequate training so that<br />

labors from countryside have necessary<br />

skills to find employment in the services<br />

and manufacturing sectors. Government<br />

expenditure should be directed towards<br />

sectors, like primary education, where social<br />

return is higher than the private return.<br />

For the sector, like higher education and<br />

also vocational education, government can<br />

encourage private participation. Private<br />

participation brings in accountability and<br />

hence efficiency in the way of service provi-<br />

output contributes to rural poverty<br />

affecting the distribution of income. It also<br />

leads to increase migration which in turn is<br />

contributing to inequality. A reason for<br />

volatility in agricultural production is because<br />

of lack of adequate infrastructure.<br />

Because of lack of cold storage facilities,<br />

irrigation system, dams and roads network<br />

connecting to market considerable portion<br />

of agricultural produce depends on weather.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is a loss of agricultural output either<br />

because of flood or because of drought.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are not enough man made tanks and<br />

canals which can store water during flood<br />

and supply water during drought.<br />

To reduce this volatility there is a need<br />

to build rural infrastructure. A proper<br />

infrastructural investment in rural sector,<br />

such as irrigation and drainage, storage,<br />

soil conservation, water management systems<br />

and road networks connecting the<br />

rural markets with their urban counterpart,<br />

is necessary to reduce this fluctuation<br />

in agricultural output. Demand management<br />

policies like introduction of crop<br />

insurance, futures trading in agricultural<br />

commodities and greater accessibility to<br />

credit will complement these supply side<br />

measures. None of these exists at this<br />

point of time. It’s a little wonder why the<br />

people in the country side feel deprived<br />

and with further reforms the level of desperation<br />

is growing. Finally, referring<br />

back to our issue about Nandigram what<br />

started the flare in Nandigram was lack of<br />

well defined property rights. Initially, it<br />

was the marginal farmers or share croppers<br />

(working on other’s lands) who were<br />

up in arms against the government. <strong>The</strong><br />

land owners were happy with the price<br />

offered by the government for acquiring<br />

their land. However, there exist no property<br />

rights which spell out how the money<br />

is going to get distributed from the land<br />

owners to these share croppers or the<br />

land less laborers. <strong>The</strong> seed of unrest<br />

could have been solved by addressing<br />

this issue.<br />

End Notes<br />

1 Bosworth, B., Collins, S. and Virmani,<br />

A. (2006), ‘Sources of growth in the Indian<br />

economy’, paper presented to the<br />

Indian Policy Forum, New Delhi, July.<br />

2 Bhanumurthy N. R. and A. Mitra<br />

(2004), ‘Economic growth, poverty, and<br />

inequality in Indian States in the prereform<br />

and reform periods’, Asian Development<br />

Review, Vol. 21, pp. 79-99.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

45


Shripad Dharmadikary<br />

Manthan Adhyayan Kendra,<br />

Badwani, Madhya Pradesh<br />

More Market, Less Government<br />

A Recipe For Disaster For <strong>The</strong> Water Sector<br />

"We never know the worth of<br />

water till the well is dry."<br />

-Thomas Fuller<br />

An article published some time<br />

back argued that in Rajasthan,<br />

petrol was freely available<br />

to anyone who wanted it, while millions<br />

of people faced great difficulty in<br />

obtaining water, even though water is far<br />

more abundant in the state than petrol.<br />

This phenomenon was attributed by the<br />

author to the fact that while the management<br />

of water was entirely controlled by<br />

the government, the supply and management<br />

of petrol was by private players and<br />

operated on market principles. Since<br />

last 16 years, the call to harness the power<br />

of the market (and of private enterprise)<br />

for the better performance of<br />

various sectors of the economy has been<br />

growing stronger. In 1991, the introduction<br />

of the policies of Liberalisation,<br />

Privatisation and Globalisation (LPG)<br />

in the country initiated the process of<br />

the opening up of the financial sector on<br />

one hand, and on the other, the transformation<br />

of sectors hitherto owned and<br />

managed by the government or by other<br />

public agencies into market based operations<br />

and private ownership and<br />

management. While some of the important<br />

sectors where wide-ranging reforms<br />

were introduced included power, telcom<br />

and insurance, the process began later,<br />

and in a fragmented way for other sectors.<br />

<strong>The</strong> water sector can be put in the<br />

latter category.<br />

Water Markets In India<br />

It is not as if water markets or trade have<br />

not existed in India. In the British times,<br />

several large irrigation schemes were<br />

owned and operated privately, with the<br />

company selling water on a commercial<br />

basis. For example, the Orissa Canal<br />

Scheme, first proposed by Sir Arthur<br />

Cotton in 1858, was started in 1865, with<br />

the East India (Orissa) Irrigation and<br />

Canal Company (EIICC) financing the<br />

project and selling all the water to the<br />

Government, who in turn was to collect<br />

the water charges from farmers, and<br />

pass on the profits to the EIICC after<br />

deducting administrative expenses 1 . In<br />

many parts of the country, for example<br />

46 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

in North Gujarat, thriving groundwater<br />

markets exist, as farmers extract groundwater<br />

using tubewells and sell it primarily<br />

to other farmers for irrigation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> ‘tanker economy’ is very well established,<br />

with highly developed networks<br />

of tanker owners supplying water<br />

to industries, colonies, commercial establishments<br />

and even households on a<br />

regular or need-based basis. In cities<br />

like Ahemdabad, regular home delivery<br />

of bottled drinking water is a common<br />

feature. Last but not the least, the bottled<br />

water industry has become a thriving<br />

multi-crore rupees business. For all<br />

this, water remains largely in the public<br />

domain. <strong>The</strong> British experiments with<br />

private irrigation were not very successful<br />

and canal irrigation has been essentially<br />

a public sector endeavour in independent<br />

India. While groundwater is<br />

largely in the private domain, with the<br />

landowners having unrestricted right to<br />

pump out as much water as they want<br />

from their lands – it is largely operated<br />

on an individual and unorganised basis.<br />

Tankers and other supplies to households,<br />

colonies etc. operate more like<br />

informal markets. Even otherwise, these<br />

water markets have formed a small part<br />

of the huge water economy and even a<br />

smaller part of the vast water system.<br />

This is so for a good reason.<br />

Water As A Social Responsibility<br />

Water is a biological necessity for survival.<br />

Water is also the foundation of the<br />

livelihoods of millions of people – agriculture,<br />

fishing, dairying, cattle rearing<br />

being some of the occupations that depend<br />

critically on water. Water is a critical<br />

input into the development process,<br />

apart from the being an essential requirement<br />

for industry and manufacturing.<br />

Thus, water has a vital social significance<br />

apart from its commercial<br />

value. Indeed, water is a basic, fundamental<br />

human right. Due to all this, the<br />

production and provision of water has<br />

long been considered a social and moral<br />

responsibility of the community and the<br />

Government. This is all the more so in<br />

India - since the income and resource<br />

distribution in India is heavily skewed<br />

and iniquitous, and we have large sections<br />

of populations who cannot afford<br />

to bear the cost of even the minimum<br />

necessary supplies of water. This makes<br />

low-priced provision of water services<br />

essential. This is also the reason that<br />

the sector has been heavily subsidised,<br />

and has remained in the public domain<br />

till now.<br />

A New Regime<br />

In the last decade or so, it is being argued<br />

that the water sector must be operated<br />

on market based principles and the<br />

Government must change its role to only<br />

that of a regulator, with the private sector<br />

being allowed into the sector.<br />

Several reasons are being advanced<br />

for this. <strong>The</strong> many serious problems of<br />

the water sector and its abysmal performance<br />

in delivering services is being attributed<br />

primarily to the inefficiency and<br />

corruption of the government system –<br />

qualities that are believed to be largely<br />

inherent to public sector. <strong>The</strong> public sector<br />

is also generally considered as deficient<br />

in modern technology, lacking<br />

management skills and badly administered.<br />

Further, the lack of internal resource<br />

generation due to below-cost supply<br />

is leading to deficiency of resources<br />

with the Government to invest in the<br />

needs of the sector.<strong>The</strong> achievements of<br />

Tankers and other supplies to households, etc. operate<br />

more like informal markets. Even otherwise, these water<br />

markets have formed a small part of the huge water economy<br />

and even a smaller part of the vast water system<br />

the telcom sector, now operating on<br />

market based principles with a large<br />

number of private players is also being<br />

cited as evidence that these polices can<br />

improve access and service levels. Thus,<br />

“More Market, Less Government” is the<br />

mantra being advocated for the water<br />

sector also. As this approach gets translated<br />

into new policies, laws and programs,<br />

some important questions need<br />

to be answered – will this work? What<br />

will be the consequences of such an approach<br />

in the water sector? Is this the<br />

correct policy choice? In some ways, the<br />

cart has already been put before the<br />

horse. While these serious questions<br />

have not been fully debated, far-reaching<br />

transformations in the sector have<br />

already been set in motion.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se transformations can be seen as<br />

an extension of the LPG regime into the<br />

water sector. As with the initial set of<br />

reforms in 1991, the changes in the water<br />

sector are also being driven by the World<br />

Bank and other international financial<br />

a g e n c i e s l i k e t h e A s i a n D e ve l o p m e nt B<br />

ank. Water has been among the last of<br />

the sectors to be opened up to the reforms<br />

process; however, we just note this<br />

without going into the reasons for<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

47


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

the same.<br />

<strong>The</strong> process to aggressively bring LPG<br />

policies into the water sector was initiated<br />

around the mid-1990s with a key<br />

knowledge activity. Around this time,<br />

the World Bank began a comprehensive<br />

and wide-ranging review of India’s water<br />

sector – called the India Water Resources<br />

Management Sector Review.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Water Sector Review 1998 was a<br />

“sector-wide program undertaken in<br />

partnership between the Government of<br />

India and the World Bank, also with<br />

contributions from the Governments of<br />

U.K., Denmark and the Netherlands.” 2<br />

<strong>The</strong> purpose was “collectively assessing<br />

and establishing a Reform Agenda and<br />

Action plan for India’s Water Sector.” 3<br />

In 1996, a series of missions visited<br />

India, and then the World Bank team,<br />

with inputs from the Government of India,<br />

and many consultants, finalised five<br />

specialists reports 4 , dealing with<br />

(1) Intersectoral Water Allocation,<br />

Planning and Management<br />

(2) Groundwater Regulation and<br />

Management<br />

(3) Irrigation<br />

(4) Rural Water Supply and Sanitation<br />

(5) Urban Water Supply & Sanitation<br />

A sixth report, synthesising all the<br />

above was also prepared 5 . <strong>The</strong>se were<br />

first published as World Bank reports in<br />

the year 1998.<br />

This Review identified two broad issues<br />

that needed to be addressed –<br />

“Mechanisms ....for integrated treatment<br />

of surface and groundwater... and<br />

for efficiently and equitably allocating<br />

scare water resources between competing<br />

uses...[that is, inter-sector allocations].<br />

Second, reforms to improve service<br />

delivery in the water sub-sectors<br />

(i.e. irrigation, urban water supply, rural<br />

water supply...)”.<br />

For both these broad objectives, the<br />

measures suggested consisted essentially<br />

of transforming the sector to operate<br />

on commercial and market basis, and<br />

the privatisation of various activities.<br />

This agenda is being rolled out through<br />

a number of different measures. <strong>The</strong> key<br />

One of the far reaching recommendations made by the<br />

World Bank was the introduction of tradable water rights<br />

or water entitlements. <strong>The</strong> idea is this – that all (or at least<br />

some) people have a defined water entitlement<br />

mechanism to further this approach has<br />

been a series of Water Sector Restructuring<br />

loans given by the World Bank to<br />

a number of states, for example in Madhya<br />

Pradesh, Maharashtra, Rajasthan<br />

etc. 6 <strong>The</strong> reforms package implemented<br />

through the conditionalities in these<br />

loans is often supported by other loans,<br />

grants and technical assistance from<br />

Asian Development Bank, or agencies<br />

like British Government’s development<br />

assistance agency DFID.<br />

<strong>The</strong> reforms processes have the following<br />

common elements:<br />

• Unbundling (separation of source,<br />

‘transmission’ and ‘distribution’)<br />

• Independent regulator to set tariffs<br />

and decide other issues<br />

• Steeply increasing tariffs, de-politicisation<br />

of tariffs<br />

• Full cost recovery<br />

• Elimination of subsidies<br />

Cutting off supplies for non-payment<br />

• Dismantling public / community supplies<br />

like public taps, stand posts<br />

• Retrenchment<br />

• Privatisation and PPPs<br />

• Allocation of water to highest value<br />

use through market mechanism<br />

<strong>The</strong> net result of these policies is the<br />

conversion of the sector into a market.<br />

Not only is the service provision within<br />

a sub-sector (for example irrigation) to<br />

be carried out on a commercial basis, on<br />

market principles, but the inter-sectoral<br />

allocation also is to be done through<br />

market mechanisms. What are the implications?<br />

Let us examine the inter-sectoral<br />

allocation in more detail.<br />

Tradable Water Rights For Inter-<br />

Sectoral Allocation<br />

One of the far reaching recommendations<br />

made by the World Bank in the<br />

Water Sector Review 1998 was the introduction<br />

of tradable water rights or water<br />

entitlements. <strong>The</strong> idea is this – that all<br />

(or at least some) people have a defined<br />

water entitlement. <strong>The</strong>re is also a<br />

developed market of such entitlements,<br />

in which these can be sold or bartered.<br />

<strong>The</strong> economic logic is that this trading<br />

will ensure that water is allocated to the<br />

highest value user – thus ensuring<br />

efficiency of use. This is being justified<br />

as an easy way (where political resistance<br />

will be least) of inter-sectoral<br />

allocations.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Water Sector Resources Stra<br />

tegy of the World Bank, adopted in<br />

2003, states 7 :<br />

“....those requiring additional resources<br />

(such as cities) will be ...able to meet<br />

48 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

their needs by acquiring the rights of<br />

those who are using water for low-value<br />

purposes.<br />

“....there are strong incentives for<br />

those using water for low-value purposes<br />

to voluntarily give up their rights,<br />

making reallocation politically attractive<br />

and practical.”<br />

<strong>The</strong> Water Sector Review 1998’s Report<br />

on Intersectoral Allocation gives<br />

the example of Chennai. It says 8 :<br />

“As in all parts of the world, the value<br />

of water for irrigated foodcrops is a fraction<br />

of the value for urban and domestic<br />

purposes. Rough calculations suggest<br />

that the value of water in irrigation in<br />

Tamil Nadu is less than Rs. 0.5/cubic<br />

meter. Even if Metrowater could pay several<br />

times this amount, it could obtain<br />

additional water….<br />

“<strong>The</strong> potential for voluntary inter-sectoral<br />

transfer of water to urban users<br />

from irrigation provide a promising low<br />

cost alternative...”<br />

Thus, the Bank argues that in a water<br />

market, the farmer would find it more<br />

profitable to sell his share of water to the<br />

city (or an industry, or a golf course)<br />

than to grow crops.<br />

One of the first ‘trials’ of this approach<br />

is taking place in Maharashtra. <strong>The</strong> Maharashtra<br />

Water Resources Regulatory<br />

Authority Act (MWRRA) 2005 came<br />

into force on 8th June 2005. Maharashtra<br />

soon became the first, and so far the<br />

only, state to set up the Water Resources<br />

Regulatory Authority - more or less<br />

on the lines of the regulatory commissions<br />

set up for electricity in various<br />

states - with objectives that include fi x-<br />

ing the rates for use of water for agriculture,<br />

industrial, drinking and other purposes<br />

and several related matters.<br />

Among the functions of the Authority is<br />

the mandate to develop a framework for<br />

trading in water entitlements. <strong>The</strong> Authority<br />

is to determine the distribution<br />

of entitlements between various users,<br />

and then these entitlements can be<br />

“transferred, bartered, bought or sold<br />

on annual or seasonal basis within a<br />

market system” 9 to be created by the Authority.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Authority has already begun<br />

the exercise of setting up entitlements in<br />

six irrigation projects in Maharashtra on<br />

a pilot basis, inlcuding tow major projects.<br />

Will such an exercise lead to a rational<br />

and efficient allocation of water?<br />

While the economic argument that water<br />

will be allocated to the highest valueadding<br />

user looks attractive, there are<br />

likely to be serious implications. For example,<br />

if a farmer finds it more profitable<br />

to sell his share of water to industry<br />

or a near by city – and this happens on a<br />

large scale, what are the implications for<br />

food security? What would happen to<br />

associated rural economic activity? For<br />

example, agricultural residues provide<br />

fodder for cattle, but if a farmer does not<br />

cultivate his land, what happens to the<br />

cattle? Another important question is<br />

related to the conversion of livelihood to<br />

cash. <strong>The</strong> farmer, by cultivating his land,<br />

gets the output in the form of grain,<br />

food, milk and some cash. By selling his<br />

water right, this is likely to be largely<br />

Market driven inter-sector allocation poses more serious<br />

broader concerns. Water is not just an economic commodity<br />

– it is essentially an ecological, natural entity, and<br />

water as an ecological system is vast and complex<br />

converted to cash. This has the danger<br />

of being spent on careless consumptive<br />

expenditure, or worse, on liquor and<br />

other addictions. More cash can also<br />

mean that women will have lesser<br />

control on the household income as cash<br />

is more likely to be controlled by<br />

the men.<br />

Apart from these individual-related<br />

issues, market driven inter-sector allocation<br />

poses even more serious broader<br />

concerns. First of all, water is not just an<br />

economic commodity – it is essentially<br />

an ecological, natural entity, and water<br />

as an ecological system is vast and complex.<br />

Water – and water bodies like rivers,<br />

lakes etc. – have many cultural, social<br />

and religious associations. Thus,<br />

there are many externalities associated<br />

with water, and it is simply not possible<br />

for market mechanisms to address these.<br />

Consider (as is happening in several<br />

places like Chennai) if a farmer wants to<br />

sell his groundwater to the city instead<br />

of farming. But unrestricted withdrawals<br />

by the farmer could affect the wells<br />

of the neighbouring farmers. Or, consider<br />

whether the waters of a river that<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

49


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

has a religious ghat and temple could be<br />

sold for industrial or other purposes? In<br />

fact, this raises another serious issue –<br />

who would be entitled to sell such a<br />

right? For a market to operate there<br />

have to be tradable commodities and<br />

some understanding of ‘ownership’. But<br />

can what is essentially a community resource<br />

– like a river, lake or rainwater<br />

– can such an entity be subjected to a<br />

market regime?<br />

It is because of these very important<br />

externalities and social and human aspects<br />

that water, and in particular the<br />

sectoral allocation of water needs to be<br />

outside the market system. This is the<br />

reason why the priorities for allocation<br />

of water between sectors are prescribed<br />

by policy rather than left to the market.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Water Policy of the Government of<br />

India, approved in 2002, specifies in its<br />

Clause 5 that<br />

“In the planning and operation of systems,<br />

water allocation priorities should<br />

be broadly as follows:<br />

• Drinking water<br />

• Irrigation<br />

• Hydro-power<br />

• Ecology<br />

• Agro-industries and non-agricultural<br />

industries<br />

• Navigation and other uses.”<br />

Several states too have developed their<br />

own policies which also lay down these<br />

priorities. A market based inter-sectoral<br />

allocation of water is inherently in contradiction<br />

to the allocation based on<br />

criteria of social and environmental<br />

need and equity. This is all the more so<br />

in a country like India where there is<br />

vast inequity in the distribution of income<br />

and where conservation of ecology<br />

is not a luxury but rather a necessity as<br />

it supports the livelihoods of millions.<br />

Last, but not the least, is that by definition,<br />

a market based system allocates<br />

resources to those who have purchasing<br />

power. This not only means that the poor<br />

will be disadvantaged, but that there is<br />

a real danger of concentration of (water)<br />

recourses in the hands of the economically<br />

powerful. <strong>The</strong>re are very few places<br />

where such a market based allocation<br />

of water has been tried out. Chile is one<br />

such country where this system was put<br />

in place in the early 1980s. Indeed, the<br />

World Bank is using Chile as a model to<br />

justify the implementation of this in India.<br />

But the Bank’s own study (which it<br />

seems to have ignored) says 10 :<br />

“According to some reports, the establishment<br />

of tradable water rights in Chile<br />

has encouraged efficient agricultural use<br />

and increased agricultural productivity<br />

per unit of water… Recent reports indicate,<br />

however, that the model encountered<br />

problems as well as successes….<br />

Although benefits have accrued, significant<br />

negative impacts have been felt by<br />

farmers unfamiliar with legal processes<br />

or lacking the money to participate in<br />

markets for water (the poor). Significant<br />

conflicts have also emerged between different<br />

groups of users, and many social<br />

and environmental externalities have yet<br />

to be addressed….”<br />

And 11 :<br />

“<strong>The</strong> main disadvantage, or risk, of<br />

the new system is monopolisation of water<br />

rights. A couple of power companies<br />

and a single individual have been accused<br />

of accumulating some 70 percent<br />

of all water rights in Chile”<br />

This clearly shows how real the danger<br />

of the monopolisation of the resource<br />

are when it is left to market forces, as<br />

well as the inability of market forces to<br />

handle social, ecological and equity related<br />

externalities.<br />

Intra-Sector Marketisation<br />

<strong>The</strong> same issues come up in context of<br />

market based operations within a sector<br />

like bringing in private players for service<br />

delivery of irrigation or urban waters, or<br />

transforming these sectors into purely<br />

commercial operations. <strong>The</strong>re is massive<br />

evidence from all over the world that this<br />

has led to very serious impacts on the<br />

economically poor sections of the society.<br />

This is well documented and a subject<br />

in its own right, so we may only mention<br />

a few things here 12 .<br />

<strong>The</strong> reforms package of full cost recovery,<br />

elimination of subsidies, disconnections<br />

on non-payment (often due to unaffordability),<br />

privatisation and so on may<br />

remove ‘economic ‘distortions’ and lead<br />

to better financial sustainability – the two<br />

major arguments for the justification of<br />

reforms– but this is at the cost of social<br />

responsibility. Where this package has<br />

been implemented, tariffs have often shot<br />

up, and the poor have been disconnected<br />

as they have been unable to pay the high<br />

price for water. For example, in Guinea,<br />

on privatisation of the water supply, water<br />

rates shot up 6-7 times, and more than<br />

10,000 connections, one-third of the total,<br />

were disconnected due to non-payment.<br />

Access of the poor to water has<br />

been the first casualty in many cases of<br />

water sector privatisation and reforms.<br />

Farmers in India are already caught in<br />

a vicious economic pincer grip of rising<br />

prices of inputs and lack of commensurate<br />

prices for their products. Rising water<br />

tariffs in the irrigation sector – a sure<br />

consequence of marketisation - are like-<br />

50 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ly to skew further the economics of agriculture<br />

that is already leading to large<br />

scale suicides of farmers. Moreover, it is<br />

likely to have a casacading effect on prices<br />

of essentials like foodgrains.<br />

In Indore, an Asian Development<br />

Bank (ADB) loan for Urban Water Supply<br />

has put a condition that all public<br />

standposts must be phased out and the<br />

city Municipal Corporation has taken an<br />

in-principle decision that this should be<br />

done unless the person (who happens to<br />

have a standpost in front of the house)<br />

agrees to pay the bills. <strong>The</strong> logic is that<br />

public stand posts are a source of leakage<br />

and do not yield revenue. Removing<br />

standposts certainly fits into the process<br />

of making the system more market oriented<br />

– no supply without payment – but<br />

impacts the poor very hard.<br />

Less Market, More Accountable<br />

Government<br />

It is difficult to escape the conclusion<br />

that the marketisation of the system can<br />

only be at the cost of social responsibility.<br />

‘More Market’ in the water sector is<br />

likely to hit hard the most vulnerable sections<br />

of the society, and those living on<br />

the margins are likely to be pushed out<br />

even from there. It is also likely to have a<br />

deleterious impact on livelihoods of<br />

farmers and a cascading effect on millions<br />

of other poor as food prices too<br />

could be affected. Further, the market<br />

cannot handle the many critically important<br />

externalities – social, ecological,<br />

cultural and religious- associated with<br />

water. Commodification and marketisation<br />

of water will also create the dangers<br />

of monopolistic control on this vital resource.<br />

Thus, the advocacy of ‘More<br />

Market’ in the water sector is a sure recipe<br />

for disaster. However, this does in any<br />

way mean, automatically, that business as<br />

usual is fine or that more ‘governmentas-usual’<br />

is the answer. For there is no<br />

denying that the myriad problems of the<br />

water sector – lack of access, inequity,<br />

deteriorating quality, destruction of environment,<br />

displacement due to dams<br />

etc. – are in many ways due to the gross<br />

inefficiency, corruption and mismanagement<br />

by the public agencies handling<br />

water resources. However, water, with its<br />

vital necessity for our very daily survival<br />

as well as its central role in livelihood,<br />

economy, society and culture has to be<br />

under public control. But this public control<br />

has to be really ‘public’ –that is, by<br />

the community at large and not just by<br />

the Government or bureaucratic agencies.<br />

What we need is an accountable,<br />

responsible, transparent and participatory<br />

system of managing water –<br />

Less Markets, More Accountable<br />

Public Systems.<br />

Endnotes<br />

1<br />

D’souza 2006 Page 128-129<br />

2<br />

World Bank 1999a Page ix<br />

3<br />

ibid<br />

4<br />

World Bank 1999b to 1999f<br />

5<br />

World Bank 1999a<br />

6<br />

Since water is primarily a state subject,<br />

the reforms have to take place at the<br />

state level.<br />

7<br />

World Bank 2004<br />

8<br />

World Bank 1999b Page 133-134<br />

9<br />

Maharashtra Water Resources Regulatory<br />

Authority Act (MWRRA)<br />

2005, Clause 11 (i)<br />

10<br />

World Bank 1999c Page 29<br />

11<br />

World Bank 1999d Page 108<br />

l2<br />

For more information, see for example<br />

Water: Private, Limited <strong>Issue</strong>s in Privatisation,<br />

Corporatisation and Commercialisation<br />

of Water Sector in India,<br />

Manthan Adhyayan Kendra 2006,<br />

available at www.manthan-india.org<br />

References<br />

• D’souza Rohan (2006): ‘Drowned and<br />

Dammed – Colonial Capitalism and<br />

flood control in Eastern India’, Oxford<br />

University Press, New Delhi.<br />

• Dwivedi Gaurav, Rehmat and Shripad<br />

Dharmadhikary (<strong>2007</strong>): ‘Water: Private,<br />

Limited’, Manthan Adhyayan<br />

Kendra, Badwani, Madhya Pradesh.<br />

• World Bank (1999a): ‘Initiating and<br />

Sustaining Water Sector Reforms: A<br />

Synthesis’, World Bank, Washington<br />

D.C. and Allied Publishers Limited,<br />

Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999b): ‘Inter-Sectoral<br />

Water Allocation, Planning and Management’,<br />

World Bank, Washington<br />

D.C. and Allied Publishers Limited,<br />

Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999c): ‘Groundwater<br />

Regulation and Management’, World<br />

Bank, Washington D.C. and Allied<br />

Publishers Limited, Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999d): ‘<strong>The</strong> Irrigation<br />

Sector’, World Bank, Washington D.<br />

C. and Allied Publishers Limited,<br />

Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999e): ‘Rural Water<br />

Supply and Sanitation’, World Bank,<br />

Washington D.C. and Allied Publishers<br />

Limited, Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (1999f): ‘Urban Water<br />

Supply and Sanitation’, World Bank,<br />

Washington D.C. and Allied Publishers<br />

Limited, Mumbai.<br />

• World Bank (2004): ‘Water Resources<br />

Sector Strategy’, World Bank, Washington<br />

D.C.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

51


D.M.Diwakar,<br />

Professor of Economics<br />

Giri Institute of Development Studies<br />

(GIDS), Lucknow<br />

Inclusive Growth In India: A Case Of<br />

Structural And Agrarian Challenges<br />

"To forget how to dig the<br />

earth and tend the soil is to<br />

forget ourselves."<br />

-Mahatma Gandhi<br />

Measures of economic reforms<br />

in India were expected to<br />

deliver goods and services to<br />

attain higher growth rate of the economy<br />

and provide better employability to accommodate<br />

underemployed, unemployed<br />

and marginalized sections of the<br />

society into mainstream of development.<br />

But realisations over the years have not<br />

been in conformity with the expectations.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is common agreement<br />

among the experts across the board that<br />

economy has attained higher growth<br />

rates but reforms measures are yet to<br />

prove effective towards distributive justice<br />

with higher growth. Latest Human<br />

Development Report indicates further<br />

sliding down to the rank of 128. Indian<br />

agriculture irrespective of the <strong>size</strong> of<br />

holdings, which is mainstay for majority<br />

of the masses, has been experiencing<br />

worst forms of crises culminated and<br />

manifested in starvation and tragic suicides<br />

of its producers, who have been<br />

feeding the nation. Besides unregistered<br />

starvation in backward regions in absence<br />

of employment at least at subsistence<br />

level, even diversified and prosperous<br />

agriculture of Punjab, petty cotton<br />

growers of Maharashtra, Andhra and<br />

Karnataka are also not spared from this<br />

trap. Expert Group on agrarian crisis<br />

underlines suicides as a disturbing symptom<br />

of deep-rooted crises that Indian<br />

agriculture has been confronting. Broadly<br />

two dimensions of agrarian crises –<br />

low growth with declining productivity<br />

and high dependence of population on<br />

lower farm income have been the root<br />

causes. Reflecting a little further stagnation,<br />

increasing risk in production and<br />

marketing, collapse of the extension<br />

system, growing institutional vacuum,<br />

and the lack of alternative livelihood<br />

opportunities, etc., are inter alia main<br />

factors behind agrarian crisis (Radhakrishna,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>).<br />

Challenges of the syndrome of fatigue<br />

at the front of technology, institution,<br />

policy and governance (Narayanamoorthy,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>; Behera and Mishra, <strong>2007</strong>)<br />

have been debated at length. Mounting<br />

52 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

criticisms loaded with adverse results of<br />

reforms undermining human face compelled<br />

planners and policy makers to<br />

incorporate such policies that may appear<br />

addressing the crises and concerns<br />

of marginalisation. Hence the Eleventh<br />

Five Year Plan has been claimed to focus<br />

on faster inclusive growth (GOI, 2006)<br />

to address the issues of exclusions. This<br />

exercise is an attempt to underline challenges<br />

on the way to achieve the targets<br />

of inclusive growth. It is not possible to<br />

do justice with all the factors in one exercise<br />

and therefore, this exercise is intended<br />

to analyse a few important dimensions<br />

of agrarian challenges towards<br />

achieving the objectives of inclusive<br />

growth. This paper is divided in four<br />

parts. Part one examines growth performance<br />

of agricultural economy. Part two<br />

deals with indebtedness and credit markets<br />

and institutions. Part three concentrates<br />

on farmers despair and part four<br />

consolidates discussion and reflects on<br />

possible imperatives and options in<br />

this regard.<br />

1. <strong>Dec</strong>elerating Growth<br />

Share of the agricultural sector declined<br />

from 59.2 percent of Gross Domestic<br />

Product (GDP) in 1950-51 to 27.36 percent<br />

in 1999-2000, This figure has further<br />

fallen to 18.5 percent in 2006-07<br />

(Economic Survey, GOI, <strong>2007</strong>:1). Contribution<br />

of agriculture to GDP has been<br />

declining not only because the other sectors<br />

are growing fast but also because of<br />

continued neglect of this sector leading<br />

to decline in rural income. However,<br />

over 56.5 percent of the workforce and<br />

63.9 percent of the rural workforce – 39.8<br />

percent self employed and 24.1 percent<br />

agricultural labour are still directly dependent<br />

on this sector for their livelihood<br />

(National Sample Survey Organisation<br />

(NSSO), 61 st Round, 2006:27).<br />

Out of self-employed workforce majority<br />

of holdings are of marginal and small<br />

farmers. On an average, this sector grew<br />

at the rate of 2.54 percent during 1950-<br />

51 to 2003-04. During pre-Green Revolution<br />

(1950-51 to 1964-65) agriculture<br />

grew by 2.54 percent. Interestingly average<br />

growth rate in post -Green Revolution<br />

period until 1980 was only 2.05 percent,<br />

which was slightly lower than<br />

earlier period. Growth rate of agriculture<br />

in 1980s was the highest at 3.08 percent<br />

and later in last one decade (1993-<br />

94 to 2003-04) this sector suffered<br />

deceleration and grew only by 2.38 percent<br />

(Bhalla, 2005: p.2). During Ninth<br />

and Tenth Five Year Plan, agriculture<br />

grew only by 2 and 1.7 percent respectively<br />

(GOI, 2006:4).<br />

In pre–Green Revolution period<br />

growth rates of all principal crops, in<br />

terms of their area production and yield<br />

were 1.58, 3.15, 1.21 percent, food grains<br />

1.35, 2.82, 1.36 percent and non food<br />

grains 2.44, 3.74, 0.89 percent respectively.<br />

Post-Green Revolution data of<br />

growth rates suggest that area and production<br />

of all principal crops had lower<br />

rate of growth but yield registered higher<br />

rate of growth than that of pre-Green<br />

Revolution period. So far non-food<br />

grains are concerned, growth rates of<br />

area and production witnessed deceleration.<br />

However productivity registered<br />

increasing trend from 0.89 percent to<br />

1.59 percent. In case of food grains area<br />

declined, production registered lower<br />

rate of growth and yield rate increased.<br />

Statisticall, the comparison of 1980s<br />

with 1990s suggests that, in case of all<br />

principal crops, cultivable area increased<br />

in 1990s and production and productivity<br />

parameters registered deceleration.<br />

In the case of food grains, area declined,<br />

production and productivity encountered<br />

lower rate of growth than 1980s.<br />

So far non-food grains are concerned<br />

area, production and productivity indicated<br />

an increasing trend with deceleration,<br />

i.e., lower rate of growth than<br />

1980s. However there was an evidence<br />

of recovery in terms of area and productivity<br />

of food grains, and area production<br />

and productivity in non-food grains<br />

during 2000-01 to 2006-07. As a result,<br />

there was a sign of recovery in area production<br />

and productivity of all principal<br />

crops. However, in terms of the growth<br />

According to NSSO data, over 56.5% of the workforce<br />

and 63.9% of the rural workforce – 39.8% self employed<br />

and 24.1% agricultural labour are still directly dependent<br />

on agriculture sector for their livelihood<br />

rates of production it was still lower than<br />

the growth rates of the production of<br />

1980s (GOI, 2006a).<br />

Expansion of irrigation network, use<br />

of modern technology - HYV seeds,<br />

chemical fertilizer, pesticides combined<br />

- cropping pattern changed remarkably.<br />

Cropping intensity also improved to the<br />

level of 134 percent. But percentage coverage<br />

of food grains did not change significantly<br />

until 1980-81. Coverage of<br />

total cereals hardly changed and remained<br />

at the level of about 75 percent.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

53


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

During 1990-91 to 2000-01 it remained<br />

around 65 percent. Coverage of oil seeds,<br />

fruits and vegetables almost doubled and<br />

area under HYV increased from 1.2 percent<br />

of GCA to 41.17 percent. Paddy<br />

coverage of HYV has increased from<br />

0.56 percent in 1966-67 to 17.34 percent<br />

in 1998-99, wheat from 0.34 to 12.61 percent,<br />

jowar from 0.12 to 4.89 percent,<br />

bajra from 0.04 to 3.76 and maize 0.13 to<br />

1.89 percent of GCA. Important factors<br />

inter alia for such poor performance was<br />

continued neglect of agriculture towards<br />

structural inequity, prevailing non-development<br />

syndrome in infrastructure,<br />

lack of adequate budgetary allocation of<br />

resources for investment. Agricultural<br />

investment to GDP witnessed declining<br />

trend over the years. During 1985-86 it<br />

was 2.3 percent at 1993-94 prices, which<br />

declined to 1.6 percent in 1989-90 and<br />

continued to decline further to 1.4 percent<br />

in 1999-2000 and 1.3 percent in<br />

2003-04. Even at prices of 1999-2000 the<br />

level of investment in 2003-04 was 1.9<br />

percent and remained stagnated at 1.9<br />

percent only for three consecutive years,<br />

i.e., up to 2005-06 (GOI, 2006-07). This<br />

clearly indicated a decline in investment<br />

in real terms. Realisation at the level of<br />

the Planning Commission of the Government<br />

of India suggests that private<br />

investment cannot be sustained without<br />

sustained public investment. Thus, syndrome<br />

of non-development left this sector<br />

under performed. Much hope is<br />

pinned on Bharat Nirman Yojana to expand<br />

irrigation network. But the provision<br />

made under this scheme in the budget<br />

of current financial year does not<br />

appear consistent with targets. With this<br />

speed the target of covering additional<br />

10 million hectare under irrigation will<br />

take at least 17 years.<br />

Cost of cultivation increased significantly<br />

with the increasing use of modern<br />

technology across the states (Diwakar,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>). Variation in terms of percentage<br />

rate of change in cost of cultivation since<br />

1991 at least for a few major commodities<br />

suggests that lower range of the cost<br />

of cultivation for paddy increased from<br />

over 73 percent in 97-98 to<br />

117 percent in 2002-03 and<br />

about 173 percent in 2004-<br />

05. Upper range of cost increased<br />

by over 92 percent<br />

in 97-98 to about 149 percent<br />

in 2002-03 and 124 percent<br />

40% of the farmers did not like to continue with agriculture.<br />

About 27% were reluctant to continue in this occpation<br />

precisely because of non-viability. Interstate variations<br />

were even higher than that of all India fi gures<br />

in 2004-05. Lower range of cost of cultivation<br />

of wheat increased by 105 percent<br />

in 1997-98 compared to 1990-91, 132<br />

percent in 2002-03 and 170 percent by<br />

2004-05. Upper range of variation increased<br />

from 85 percent to 106 percent.<br />

Lower range of cost of cultivation for<br />

cotton increased by 149 percent in 97-98<br />

to 184 percent in 2002-03 and upper<br />

range by 235 and 167 percent respectively.<br />

Cost of cultivation for other crops<br />

can similarly worked out to assess the<br />

trend and variation of specific crop<br />

across the states. Difference in cost and<br />

price structure is another dimension for<br />

examination of the viability of the crops.<br />

For example, farm harvest price/cost of<br />

cultivating cotton ratio in 1997-98 in<br />

Haryana, was 0.8633 with respect to<br />

Desi and 0.9656 for American cotton<br />

and in Punjab 0.5515 and 0.6914 respectively.<br />

In Maharashtra price–cost ratio<br />

was 0.9452. Thus, farmers of these states<br />

were not in a position to recover even<br />

cost from the returns. In case of paddy<br />

Andhra Pradesh however, was getting<br />

Rs.445 price per quintal against cost of<br />

cultivation Rs.436.77. Escalating cost of<br />

production with poor returns from agriculture<br />

amidst uncertainty of monsoon,<br />

risk of crop failures, absence<br />

of effective insurance<br />

cover, and almost<br />

non-existence of extension<br />

services pushed farmers<br />

into unprecedented hardships.<br />

Terms of trade remained<br />

against agriculture<br />

even after termination of industrial protection<br />

and devaluation of rupee in 1991<br />

(Bhalla, 2005). Data also suggest that<br />

about 40 percent of the farmers did not<br />

like to continue with agriculture (NSSO,<br />

2005:59 th Round). About 27 percent were<br />

reluctant to continue in this occupation<br />

precisely because of non-viability. Interstate<br />

variations were even higher than<br />

that of all India figures. About 36 percent<br />

of the farmers of Bihar, West Bengal,<br />

34 percent of Orissa, 30 percent of<br />

Haryana and Jharkhand, 29 percent of<br />

Maharashtra, and even 28 percent of the<br />

farmers of Punjab – agriculturally one of<br />

the most developed regions and Kerala,<br />

one of the most developed states in terms<br />

of social development indicators of the<br />

country and Karnataka, and 30 percent<br />

farmers of Haryana did not like agricul-<br />

54 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ture occupation. Encountering deceleration<br />

resulted into lower farm income<br />

and widening gap between agricultural<br />

and non-agricultural income. <strong>The</strong>refore<br />

major challenge is not simply to attain<br />

higher growth target in agriculture,<br />

which has been projected at 4 percent,<br />

but to include agricultural labourers and<br />

marginal and small farmers participating<br />

in the growth process effectively. In<br />

order to make them to participate in the<br />

growth process institutional, infrastructure<br />

and technological constraints need<br />

to be addressed on priority basis. This<br />

sector by and large is dependant on vagaries<br />

of monsoon and unprotected from<br />

the risks of crop failures despite expansion<br />

of significant network of irrigation.<br />

Rising cost of cultivation, embedded<br />

with insufficient infrastructure support<br />

and slowing down of employment and<br />

income, left farmers trapped in the syndrome<br />

of indebtedness and despair. Performance<br />

of agriculture remained dismal<br />

with some minor exceptions, thanks<br />

to the unpredictable monsoon and governmental<br />

indifference towards this sector.<br />

As a result, employment in rural<br />

sector grew at declining rate (Bhalla,<br />

2005). Data from NSS rounds suggest<br />

that there was significant decline in employment<br />

in primary sector for both<br />

males and females (NSSO, 60:506).<br />

Findings are supporting the apprehensions<br />

that National Rural Employment<br />

Guarantee Scheme with this speed cannot<br />

deliver the jobs to rural workforce,<br />

.as implementation reports from different<br />

states is adding frustrations only.<br />

Another disturbing factor is decelerating<br />

real wage rates in agriculture and nonagriculture<br />

(Sharma, 2005). But the<br />

question is whether these were substantial<br />

to offset the decelerating impacts of<br />

primary sector on the income of rural<br />

economy. <strong>Dec</strong>elerating growth rate suggests<br />

that this sector could not generate<br />

sufficient capital and investment even<br />

through private sector. Limited benefits<br />

of expansion of the post -Green Revolution<br />

technology could increase production<br />

and productivity but that also could<br />

not be sustained. Moreover, the gains<br />

could not be transferred significantly to<br />

the rural poor in particular and farm<br />

sector at large in general. Rather due to<br />

lack of effective infrastructure and extension<br />

services, modern technology<br />

added confusions in absence of effective<br />

extension services, increased cost of production,<br />

and created environmental<br />

complications and imbalances added<br />

with greater intensity of exploitation of<br />

poor farmers through usury network of<br />

non-institutional credit market in absence<br />

of effective institutional credit<br />

support.<br />

2. Indebtedness, Credit Markets<br />

And Institutions<br />

Rural indebtedness is an indicative of<br />

deficiency of rural income to carry out<br />

necessary activities for livelihood support.<br />

<strong>Dec</strong>elerating growth in agriculture<br />

and increasing income gap between agriculture<br />

and non-agriculture forced a<br />

great majority of farmers and agricultural<br />

labourers to borrow. Findings of<br />

the Royal Commission (which stated<br />

that 'farmers are born in debt, they live,<br />

die in debt and transfer debt liability to<br />

next generation') still hold good. <strong>The</strong><br />

worsening state of farmer's despair is a<br />

matter of serious social concern. In order<br />

to address the deficient need of the<br />

farmers many players – formal as well as<br />

informal - have been operating in the<br />

credit market. NSSO survey report suggests<br />

that about 48.6 percent of the farmers’<br />

households were indebted with an<br />

average outstanding loan amount of<br />

Rs.12,585. Out of indebted farmers<br />

households, 31.3 percent were from the<br />

category of landless and below marginal<br />

farmers, 29.8 percent were from marginal<br />

farmers and 18.8 percent from<br />

small farmers category. Thus, altogether<br />

80 percent of the indebted households<br />

were from the poorest lot in terms of<br />

land in possession. Prevalent rate of indebtedness<br />

of landless labour households<br />

of rural area were 45.3 percent,<br />

About 48.6% of the farmers’ households were indebted<br />

with an average outstanding loan amount of Rs. 12585.<br />

Altogether 80% of the indebted households were from the<br />

poorest lot in terms of land in possession<br />

who owed on an average Rs.6,121. With<br />

the increasing <strong>size</strong> of land in possession<br />

prevalent rate of indebtedness increased<br />

and so was the amount of loan. Considering<br />

per farmer loan amount by Monthly<br />

Per-capita Expenditure (MPCE), extent<br />

of indebtedness was higher in lower<br />

consumption bracket. With the increase<br />

in monthly per capita expenditure percentage<br />

of indebtedness decreased.<br />

However, amount of loan per farmer remained<br />

positive with the increasing<br />

monthly per capita expenditure. Indebtedness<br />

by social groups suggest that<br />

spread of indebtedness and loan amount<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

55


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

was lowest in STs and second lowest in<br />

SCs. OBCs reported higher spread of<br />

indebtedness and amount of loan than<br />

SCs but lower spread and higher amount<br />

of loan than general category of<br />

social group.<br />

State wise distribution of farmers’ indebtedness<br />

suggests that Andhra<br />

Pradesh registered highest incidence of<br />

debts with 82 percent followed by Tamil<br />

Nadu (74.5 percent), Punjab (65.4 percent),<br />

Kerala (64.4 percent) and Karnataka<br />

(61.6 percent). Uttaranchal reported<br />

lowest percentage of farmers with<br />

loan. In terms of per farmer amount of<br />

loan, Punjab carried the highest burden<br />

of loan amount at Rs.41,576 followed by<br />

Kerala (33,907). Haryana stood at third<br />

with Rs.26,007 followed by Andhra<br />

Pradesh (Rs.23,965), Tamil Nadu<br />

(Rs.23,963), Rajasthan (Rs.18,372),<br />

Karnataka (Rs.18,135) and Maharashrtra<br />

(Rs.16,973). Among social groups of<br />

STs, per farmer loan amount was highest<br />

in Punjab (Rs.1,18,495), followed by<br />

Haryana (Rs.23,555), Tamil Nadu<br />

(Rs.21,023) and Andhra Pradesh<br />

(Rs.12,760). In case of SCs, per farmer<br />

loan amount was highest in Rajasthan<br />

(Rs.16,708) followed by Haryana<br />

(Rs.13,341), Kerala (Rs.13308), Tamil<br />

Nadu 12,786 and Andhra Pradesh<br />

(Rs.12,720). For OBCs per farmer loan<br />

amount was highest in Kerala<br />

(Rs.33,116), followed by Tamil Nadu<br />

(Rs.27,355), Haryana (Rs.26,226),<br />

Andhra Pradesh (Rs.23,697), and Rajasthan<br />

(Rs.22,009). In general category<br />

also per farmer loan amount was highest<br />

in Kerala (Rs.38,013) followed by<br />

Andhra Pradesh (Rs.37,802), Haryana<br />

(Rs.31,548), Gujarat, Karnataka and<br />

Tamil Nadu.<br />

Amount of loan taken was generally<br />

utilized for production and consumption<br />

purposes. Data suggest that 30.6 percent<br />

of loan amount was spent for capital expenditure<br />

in farm business followed by<br />

current capital expenditure (27.8 percent).<br />

Non-farm business consumed 6.7<br />

percent. Thus, altogether 65 percent<br />

loan amount was directly used for production<br />

purposes. Another 15 percent<br />

was spent for social development and<br />

remaining 20 percent was on marriage<br />

and other ceremonial occasions and on<br />

consumption expenditure. Medical<br />

treatment and other expenditure could<br />

eat significant proportion in some of<br />

Near landless and marginal households took 56.7 % and<br />

47.2 % of loan amount respectively from informal usury<br />

networks. State wise variations suggest that non-institutional<br />

share of loan fi nance was higher in many states<br />

the states.<br />

Rural credit market has both formal<br />

and informal players. Formal players are<br />

government, cooperatives, commercial<br />

banks, whereas informal credit market<br />

is run by and large by moneylenders - often<br />

farmer, traders including dealers of<br />

inputs, other professionals, friends and<br />

relatives, and others operate as moneylenders.<br />

NSS data suggest that commercial<br />

banks remained major player in providing<br />

credit to farmers (35.6 percent)<br />

followed by cooperatives (19.6 percent)<br />

and government (2.5 percent). Altogether<br />

57.7 percent of credit taken by farmers<br />

was provided through institutional arrangements.<br />

Remaining 42.3 percent<br />

credit market was controlled by informal<br />

players. <strong>The</strong>se players may be categorized<br />

in one bracket of moneylenders<br />

with a few individual exceptions. It is<br />

evident from data in reference that credit<br />

extended by cooperatives and commercial<br />

banks emerged positively directed<br />

towards increasing <strong>size</strong> of holdings<br />

whereas credit extended by moneylenders<br />

had inverse direction. Landless<br />

households took 47.3 percent loan from<br />

moneylenders alone. Adding extended<br />

informal usury network it came to 77<br />

percent. Near landless and marginal<br />

households took 56.7 percent and 47.2<br />

percent of loan amount respectively from<br />

informal usury networks. State wise<br />

variations suggest that non-institutional<br />

share of loan finance was higher in many<br />

states. Non-institutional finance controlled<br />

greater credit market to the tune<br />

of 68 percent in Andhra Pradesh followed<br />

by Rajasthan, Assam Bihar and<br />

Punjab. Although Maharashtra provided<br />

83 .8 percent credit through institutional<br />

sources farmers were not free from<br />

distress and suicides. This suggests that<br />

provision of institutional credit is although<br />

important it alone cannot be sufficient<br />

to rescue the farmers from the<br />

syndrome of despair.<br />

Flow of institutional credit amount to<br />

agriculture over the years increased<br />

many folds by cooperatives, commercial<br />

and regional rural banks in terms of<br />

short, medium and long terms loan. But<br />

the question of distributional aspects of<br />

credit remained to be addressed effectively.<br />

Total credit extended by cooperatives<br />

was to the tune of Rs.24.23 crore in<br />

1950-51 to Rs.15,957 crore in 1998-99<br />

56 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

and 33,174 crore by <strong>Dec</strong>ember 2006<br />

(GOI, <strong>2007</strong>:171). Credit volume extended<br />

by commercial banks and regional<br />

rural banks were even higher than cooperatives<br />

although initials were the same.<br />

<strong>The</strong>ir initial credit amount was to the<br />

tune of Rs.24.23 crore in 1950-51, which<br />

further got increased to Rs.36,860 crore<br />

in 1998-99 and in <strong>Dec</strong>ember 2006, it<br />

stands at 1, 16, 169 crores. Provisional<br />

estimates, projection and targets indicated<br />

increasing volume of credit. <strong>The</strong><br />

share of agriculture in total bank credit<br />

had steadily increased under the impulse<br />

of bank nationalization and reached 18<br />

percent towards the end of<br />

the 1980s. But thereafter,<br />

agriculture suffered severe<br />

neglect of institutional<br />

credit delivery mechanism<br />

in the post reform period.<br />

<strong>The</strong> achievement has been<br />

almost completely reversed<br />

and the agricultural credit share dipped<br />

to less than 10 percent in the late 90s – a<br />

ratio that had prevailed in the early<br />

1970s. Even the number of farm loan accounts<br />

with scheduled commercial banks<br />

has declined in absolute terms from<br />

27.74 million in March 1992 to 20.84 million<br />

in March 2003 (Shetty, Economic<br />

and Political Weekly, July 17, 2004).<br />

Similarly per hectare credit in rupees to<br />

agriculture in recent years increased<br />

from 1,940 in 1998-99 to 4,578 in 2003-<br />

04, but annual growth rate of per hectare<br />

credit to agriculture, which was 25.5<br />

percent in 1999-00 over previous year,<br />

slipped down to 14.2 percent in the year<br />

2000-01. After witnessing partially recovery<br />

(17.4 percent) in 2001-02, growth<br />

of per hectare credit registered lower<br />

rate ( at 14.1 percent) in 2002-03 (Lok<br />

Sabha.2005). This also partially explains<br />

as to why moneylenders were dominating<br />

the credit market, wherein appropriating<br />

surpluses through exorbitant interest<br />

rates (Bhalla, 2005:6).<br />

3. Farmers In Despair<br />

Vagaries of monsoon added with rising<br />

costs and uncertainty of access to reliable<br />

technology, market and public credit<br />

institutions amidst unprotected risks<br />

with non-profitable agriculture aggravated<br />

the syndrome of frustration among<br />

farmers across the states of India irrespective<br />

of level of development of agriculture.<br />

Initially anticipating<br />

better returns farmers invested<br />

capital mobilising<br />

through public and private<br />

institutions and stayed in<br />

production for couple of<br />

years to make their fortunes.<br />

Richer lots of farmers could stay<br />

for couple of years because of their staying<br />

power and relatively better access to<br />

credit and inputs even if they suffered<br />

losses. Unfortunately many of them specially<br />

farmers from smaller farm <strong>size</strong><br />

could not sustain growing burden of<br />

loans from moneylenders, traders, dealers<br />

of inputs for many years. Because of<br />

loss of face before the community consequent<br />

upon mounting burden of debts,<br />

failures of credit, insurance and procurement<br />

delivery mechanisms and agencies,<br />

they were forced to commit suicides.<br />

Various studies and reports have been<br />

conducted on this serious problem. Indira<br />

Gandhi Institute Of Development<br />

Research (IGIDR) has brought a comprehensive<br />

study on suicides of farmers<br />

(Mishra 2006:41) for the government of<br />

Maharashtra. Study found various reasons<br />

for suicides. About 86.5 percent<br />

suicides were because of indebtedness,<br />

73.9 percent for deteriorating economic<br />

status, and 40.5 percent because of crop<br />

failures. Loss of face in community (because<br />

of non-payment of loan, inability<br />

to marry their marriageable sisters and<br />

daughters, etc.), were the other reasons.<br />

About 91 percent of suicides were committed<br />

by males. As per police records,<br />

number of suicides in Maharashtra in<br />

2004 alone was 4147. Study reported that<br />

number of suicides increased from 11866<br />

to 14729 between 1995 to 2004.Study<br />

suggests that suicides in females registered<br />

decline after 1999. Another study<br />

<strong>The</strong> central issue of farmers’ suicides is the debt trap.<br />

Small and marginal farmers are not eligible for availing<br />

institutional credit and crop insurance. Thus, they land at<br />

the doorsteps of the usurious moneylenders<br />

(Mohanty, 2005) revealed that cash crop<br />

growers, small and marginal farmers of<br />

Amaravati and Yavatmal districts were<br />

trapped in debt anticipating better returns<br />

from cultivation and committed<br />

suicides.<br />

Kisan Sabha estimates that more than<br />

5,000 farmers committed suicide in<br />

Andhra Pradesh since 1998, more than<br />

3000 committed suicide in Maharashtra,<br />

about 1,000 farmers committed suicide<br />

in Punjab from 1998 to the present, and<br />

about 5,000 committed suicide in Karnataka<br />

over the same period. It is estimated<br />

that 488 farmers committed sui-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

57


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

cide in Wayanad District in Kerala<br />

between 2001 and 2005.” (People’s Democracy,<br />

Vol.30, No. 09, Feb 26, 2006).<br />

Another study (Ridyasagar, and Sunianchandra,<br />

2003) argued that “<strong>The</strong> central<br />

issue of farmers’ suicides is the debt trap.<br />

Small and marginal farmers, especially<br />

those, who lease in land from others, are<br />

not eligible for availing institutional<br />

credit and crop insurance. Thus, they<br />

land at the doorsteps of the usurious<br />

moneylenders. This debt trap is tightening<br />

because of the drastic shifts in the<br />

cropping pattern that is market driven.”<br />

Seeds, fertilizer and pesticide dealers<br />

are at the centre of a growing controversy<br />

in Andhra Pradesh. <strong>The</strong>y are the<br />

new moneylenders to a peasantry<br />

strapped for credit. “<strong>The</strong> banks have<br />

given no loans in the past seven years,”<br />

says Malla Reddy, General Secretary of<br />

the Andhra Pradesh Ryuthu Sangham<br />

(APRS). “So many farmers are forced to<br />

depend on sources like these for credit.<br />

<strong>The</strong> same man advises them on what to<br />

buy and then sets the rates for the purchase.”<br />

With the seed dealers charging<br />

hefty interest rates on their credit sales,<br />

the problem gets more acute. <strong>The</strong> series<br />

of reports filed by P. Sainath which appeared<br />

in the Hindu and India Together<br />

is indeed an eye opener. <strong>The</strong> <strong>Dec</strong>can<br />

Herald dated August 11, 2005 reported<br />

that Movement Against State Repression<br />

(MASR) claims that about 40000<br />

farmers committed suicides in Punjab<br />

alone since 1988 whereas state government<br />

admitted only 2116 cases. Rising<br />

cost of cultivation, lack of market security,<br />

exorbitant rate of interests charged<br />

by moneylenders, dishonouring contracts<br />

etc. were inter alia a few important<br />

reasons. After 1996 loan amounts increased<br />

four times but public institutions’<br />

share was merely 20 percent. Despande<br />

and Prabhu (2005) found that<br />

most of the suicides were driven by debt.<br />

Delivery mechanism of institutional<br />

credit and its defined connivance with<br />

local middle men and functionaries often<br />

hatches conspiracy to confiscate the<br />

land of the poor marginal and small<br />

farmers and forcing them to<br />

commit suicide. Suicide<br />

committed by Manasa Ram<br />

of Maraucha Ishwari Singh<br />

Village (Suratganj Block in<br />

Barabanki district of Uttar<br />

Pradesh) is an example of<br />

Near landless and marginal households took 56.7 % and<br />

47.2 % of loan amount respectively from informal usury<br />

networks. State wise variations suggest that non-institutional<br />

share of loan fi nance was higher in many states<br />

many such cases. However, efforts of social<br />

activists foiled this conspiracy and<br />

the confiscation got cancelled later. Tenant<br />

farmers have seldom access to institutional<br />

credit in absence of ownership<br />

of land as collateral security and therefore<br />

they are forced to be trapped in<br />

usurious exploitative network. <strong>The</strong>y often<br />

sell their crops at pre-decided tied<br />

price to the input dealers or at best at<br />

farm harvest price to petty traders.<br />

Kisan Sabha deliberated upon this serious<br />

crisis and noted: “While every such<br />

death is a tragic individual reality for<br />

grieving families and loved ones, there<br />

are important common features to the<br />

farmers’ suicides. <strong>The</strong>se farmers invested<br />

heavily in inputs – biological inputs,<br />

electricity, machinery, and other components<br />

of fixed and variable costs. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

costs have risen sharply in the period of<br />

liberalisation, and are especially onerous<br />

when the farmer invests in seeds<br />

produced by private companies, particularly<br />

multinational corporations. <strong>The</strong><br />

farmers were often the victims of plain<br />

cheating – they were sold spurious seed<br />

and other inputs by unscrupulous traders.<br />

Since 1991, farmers have had to witness<br />

the massive withdrawal of the formal<br />

sector credit from the<br />

countryside, and have had<br />

to borrow from the informal<br />

sector at usurious rates<br />

of interest for their production<br />

and consumption<br />

needs. Finally, when they<br />

reaped a harvest, neo liberalism<br />

and the new trade regime robbed<br />

them of prices that could even cover<br />

their costs, let alone earn them a livelihood.<br />

Where the output itself is destroyed<br />

by pest, disease or natural disaster,<br />

the farmer was un-indemnified by<br />

any system of insurance, and inadequately<br />

compensated, if at all, by the<br />

state. It is the stark reality that, for many<br />

in our society and in such a situation,<br />

suicide appears as the alternative of last<br />

resort” (People’s Democracy, vol.30, no.<br />

09, Feb 26, 2006). Market driven farm<br />

diversification, not necessarily designed<br />

differently but for the interests of corporate<br />

sectors, exploited farm land, thereby<br />

undermining ecological and fertility<br />

balance. Globalisation and new trade<br />

regime has made farmers condition vulnerable<br />

and exposed to uncertainty<br />

58 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

(Vidyasagar and Chandra, 2003, CSD,<br />

NIRD). <strong>The</strong>re is every possibility of<br />

worsening condition of poor farmers<br />

further with the emphasis on investment<br />

through corporate contract farming.<br />

Unless means of production is reoriented<br />

in favour of producers and meaningful<br />

employment and employability of<br />

poor cultivators are ensured through<br />

public sector initiatives for infrastructure<br />

development and input and output<br />

markets are regulated in the interest of<br />

producers it will be difficult to rescue<br />

farmers from the syndrome of distress<br />

and despair leading towards suicides.<br />

4. Policy Imperatives And Options<br />

We have discussed a few dimensions of<br />

agrarian crises rooted in the syndrome<br />

of decelerating growth of agriculture<br />

amidst rising costs and inadequate infrastructure<br />

leading to deficient employment<br />

and income for the livelihood of<br />

rural workers specially small and marginal<br />

cultivators and agricultural labourers.<br />

It emerged from the analysis that<br />

decelerating growth with inadequate infrastructure,<br />

technological support and<br />

institutional arrangements forced majority<br />

of the peasants in the debt trap. Majority<br />

of indebted households were from<br />

the poorest lot in terms of <strong>size</strong> of land<br />

possession and monthly per capita consumption<br />

expenditure. However, rate of<br />

indebtedness and amount of loan was<br />

directly related with increasing <strong>size</strong> of<br />

land possession and households with<br />

higher MPCE. Contrary to belief major<br />

amount of loan utilized were for capital<br />

expenditure and current expenditure of<br />

farm and non-farm business instead of<br />

consumption purposes. However, significant<br />

amount of loan was spent on essential<br />

consumption expenditure, marriage<br />

and other ceremonial occasions<br />

also. Expenditure on education and<br />

health was the least. So far sources of<br />

loan were concerned with formal sector<br />

- commercial bank remained the major<br />

player followed by cooperative societies.<br />

Moneylender was yet significantly present<br />

in the rural borrowing market and<br />

other informal sources, i.e., traders,<br />

friends and relatives, professionals and<br />

others were not different than moneylenders<br />

with a few individual exceptions.<br />

Institutional credit remained favourable<br />

for increasing <strong>size</strong> of land possessions<br />

but mostly in poor states. Banks remained<br />

effective after nationalisation<br />

until 1980s but its performance declined<br />

significantly in late 90s. Per hectare<br />

credit to agriculture was also declined.<br />

Analysis suggests that the geneses of indebtedness<br />

were rooted in continued<br />

neglect of agriculture resulted in decelerated<br />

growth syndrome. <strong>Dec</strong>lining investment<br />

and inadequate infrastructure<br />

acted as a drag on institutional and technological<br />

transformation and modernisation<br />

with ecological balance. Poor support<br />

system for technological transfer<br />

and updating, credit, input, insurance<br />

and marketing with dependence on vagaries<br />

of monsoon resulted in crop failures<br />

and lower returns leading to misery,<br />

distress and despair.<br />

In this sort of syndrome, cultivators<br />

were often not in a position to repay the<br />

loan(s). <strong>The</strong>y hardly sustained the loss<br />

<strong>The</strong> central issue of farmers’ suicides is the debt trap.<br />

Small and marginal farmers are not eligible for availing<br />

institutional credit and crop insurance. Thus, they land at<br />

the doorsteps of the usurious moneylenders<br />

of face before the community and committed<br />

suicides. Thus, most of the unfortunate<br />

suicides were debt driven. Credit<br />

needs have been grown considerably<br />

over the time following commercialisation<br />

and modernization. However, average<br />

household borrowing in rural India<br />

has not been excessive. Inadequacy of<br />

institutional credit delivery network,<br />

poor performance of credit cooperatives,<br />

regional rural banks, and commercial<br />

banks, to meet their farm lending<br />

targets, and high cost of rural banking,<br />

etc., have aggravated further (Radhakrishna,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>). Consecutive failures<br />

of governance (in terms of effective policies<br />

and their effectual implementation)<br />

were witnessed. Instead of correcting<br />

aforesaid those lapses the economy has<br />

been moving in a different direction in<br />

the interest of the rich and corporate<br />

sectors with a faster pace of reforms. Interestingly<br />

despite symptoms of all the<br />

negative indications against the poor,<br />

contradictory policies for reforms have<br />

been put in place with a lip service to the<br />

poor. Unless poor producers are brought<br />

in the mainstream of production, control<br />

over the means of production and distribution<br />

on sustainable basis this process<br />

of marginalization, distress and despair,<br />

which has emerged out sharply in the era<br />

of reforms and globalisation of markets,<br />

may not be checked. Lowering the rate<br />

of interest on institutional loans and<br />

Right to Work may have positive effects<br />

subject to effective implementation<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

59


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

which is always doubtful. However, Right<br />

to Work on ad hoc basis cannot be continued<br />

for long. Sustainable employment<br />

generation led growth process for poor<br />

producers need to be put in place. This<br />

needs stronger and active role of State,<br />

which has been narrowing down during<br />

reform process. State has compromised<br />

with anti-poor development players. Unskilled<br />

labour force has hardly any space<br />

in the reform led labour market. Meaningful<br />

employment for skilled and unskilled<br />

workforce and initiatives to create<br />

institutions and opportunities to<br />

speed up skill transformation to enter<br />

into the job market is the prime tasks<br />

which market can seldom perform for<br />

poor having no purchasing power. And<br />

civil society cannot rest in peace if the<br />

idle hands do not get employment.<br />

<strong>The</strong>refore, pro-poor activism of civil<br />

society and effective mobilisation and<br />

resistance of peasants and social activists<br />

have become an imperative for all<br />

peace loving people to create pressure<br />

upon the state to perform pro-poor role<br />

inorder to achieve growth, with<br />

meaningful employment and actionable<br />

social justice.<br />

Reference<br />

• Behera, B. and Mishra, P., (<strong>2007</strong>): Acceleration<br />

of Agricultural Growth in<br />

India: Suggestive Policy Framework,<br />

Economic and Political Weekly, vol.<br />

42, No. 42. October 20-26.<br />

•. Bhalla, G.S., (2005): <strong>The</strong> State of the<br />

Indian Farmers, G. Parthasarathi Memorial<br />

Lecture in 88th Annual Conference<br />

of the Indian Economic Association,<br />

<strong>Dec</strong>ember 28, 2005.<br />

• Despande, R.S., and Prabhu, Nagesh,<br />

(2005): Farmers Distress – Proof beyond<br />

Questions, Economic and Political<br />

Weekly, Vol.40, No. 44 and 45, November<br />

4.<br />

• Diwakar, D.M., (<strong>2007</strong>): Contours of<br />

Agrarian Crises in India, Uttar<br />

Pradesh-Uttaranchal Economic Association<br />

(UPUEA) Economic Journal,<br />

Annual Conference Number.<br />

• Government of India (2006): Towards<br />

Faster and More Inclusive Growth: An<br />

Approach to the 11th Five Year Plan,<br />

Planning Commission, New Delhi, November<br />

2006.<br />

• Government of India (2006a): Agriculture<br />

at a Glance 2006, Ministry of Agriculture,<br />

New Delhi.<br />

• Government of India (<strong>2007</strong>): Economic<br />

Survey, Ministry of Finance, New<br />

Delhi.<br />

• Lok Sabha Starred Question No. 611,<br />

dated on 09.05.2005.<br />

• Mishra, Srijit, (2006): Farmers’ Suicide<br />

in Maharashtra, Economic and Political<br />

Weekly,Vol.41,No. 16, April 22-28,<br />

pp. 1538-45,see also, Suicide Mortality<br />

Rates across States of India, in the<br />

same issue p. 1567.<br />

• Mohanty, B.B., (2005): We are Like the<br />

Living Dead: Farmer Suicides in Maharashtra,<br />

Western India, Journal of<br />

Peasant Studies, Vol.32, No.2, April,<br />

pp. 243-276.<br />

• Narayanamoorthy, A., (<strong>2007</strong>): <strong>Dec</strong>eleration<br />

in Agricultural Growth: Technology<br />

Fatigue or Policy Fatigue? Economic<br />

and Political Weekly, Vol.42,<br />

No.25, June 23.<br />

• National Sample Survey Organisation<br />

(2005): Indebtedness of Farmer Households<br />

in India, NSS Report No. 498,<br />

59 th Round, January-<strong>Dec</strong>ember 2003.<br />

• National Sample Survey Organisation<br />

(NSSO) (2006): Employment and Unemployment<br />

Situation in India, 2004-<br />

05, Report No. 515 -I<br />

• People’s Democracy, Vol.30, No. 09,<br />

February 26 th , 2006.<br />

• Rao, Nageswara, <strong>The</strong> Hindu, September<br />

11, 2005.<br />

• Radhakrishna, R. (<strong>2007</strong>): Expert Group<br />

Report on Agrarian Crisis<br />

in India, Government of India,<br />

New Delhi.<br />

• RBI’s Basic Statistical Returns of<br />

Scheduled Commercial Banks in India,<br />

various <strong>Issue</strong>s.<br />

• Sharma, H.R., (2005): Recent Trends<br />

in Wage Earnings of Agricultural Labourers<br />

State Level Analysis for Different<br />

Social Groups, Arth Vijnana,<br />

Vol. XLVII, Nos. 3-4, September-<strong>Dec</strong>ember,<br />

pp. 329-344.<br />

• Shetty, S.L. (2004): Distributional <strong>Issue</strong>s<br />

in Bank Credit, Multi-pronged<br />

Strategy for Correcting Past Neglect,<br />

Economic and Political Weekly, Vol.<br />

Xxxix, no. 29, July 17.<br />

•Sainath,P.,IndiaTogether, accessible at<br />

http://indiatogether.com/agriculture/<br />

suicides.htm; Sainath, P. (<strong>2007</strong>): Farming-<br />

it ‘s what they do, <strong>The</strong> Hindu, May<br />

24, <strong>2007</strong>, p.11; Suicides are about the<br />

living, not dead, <strong>The</strong> Hindu, May 21,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>, p.p.13.; Vidarbha: Packaging an<br />

anniversary, <strong>The</strong> Hindu, August 31,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>; it’s official: distress up, suicides<br />

appalling, India Together, 22 November<br />

2006, courtesy <strong>The</strong> Hindu, p.11;<br />

When farmers die, India Together,<br />

http://www.indiatogether.org/2004/<br />

june/psa-farmdie.htm<br />

• Vidyasagar, R. and Sunianchandra, K.,<br />

(2003): Study on Farmers’ Suicides<br />

in Andhra Pradesh and Karnataka,<br />

CSD, National Institute of Rural<br />

Development.<br />

60 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


I.T. = Business Growth<br />

At Planman Technologies we don’t believe in mindless application of I.T.<br />

because, I.T. is not about having systems to enable employees to e-mail<br />

and chat more effectively nor is it just about being connected. We help you<br />

apply I.T. to grow your Business.<br />

Planman is a 360° Business Growth Consulting firm. We enable you to<br />

take intellect driven growth decisions and apply I.T. only to increase your<br />

ROI and Beat <strong>The</strong> Competition In A Wrinkle Free Manner!<br />

To us, I.T. = Business Growth.<br />

To understand how we can help your business grow E-MAIL TO<br />

growth@planmantechnologies.com<br />

www.planmanconsulting.com<br />

www.planmantechnologies.com<br />

O UTREACH • OUTPERFORM • OUTSHINE


Anu Singh,<br />

Professor of Economics, Alliance<br />

Business Academy, Bangalore<br />

Market Economy And <strong>The</strong> State Of Regional<br />

Disparities In India<br />

"By definition, a government<br />

has no conscience. Sometimes<br />

it has a policy, but<br />

nothing more."<br />

-Albert Camus<br />

Economic and social regional<br />

disparities in India among different<br />

segments of the society<br />

have been the major force behind adopting<br />

planning process in India. With the<br />

establishment of planning commission<br />

in March 1950, India launched the process<br />

of state led ‘growth with social justice’<br />

its prime concern of over all development<br />

of India and of all its states. <strong>The</strong><br />

first three decades of planned development<br />

involves massive investments in<br />

backward regions, moreover various<br />

public policies encouraged private investments<br />

in regions which are not very<br />

economically sound. Capital and other<br />

subsidies were seen as the best way of<br />

addressing regional imbalance through<br />

capital formation as well as income and<br />

employment generation. It’s considered<br />

to be the responsibility of the government,<br />

in promoting balanced development<br />

in which all states should get opportunity<br />

to develop evenly through<br />

direct investment in public sector units.<br />

In spite of these commendable efforts<br />

and policy interventions, considerable<br />

level of regional disparities remained at<br />

the end of the Seventies. <strong>The</strong> accelerated<br />

economic growth since the early<br />

Eighties appears to have aggravated regional<br />

disparities. In 1991 after the balance<br />

of payment crises Indian government<br />

followed the policy regime of<br />

Liberalization, Privatization and Globalization<br />

(LPG), which resulted in a<br />

tremendous increase in GDP and per<br />

capita Income. India today is the fourth<br />

largest economy, in the world in Purchasing<br />

Power Parity (PPP) dollars, after<br />

the US, China and Japan, and has<br />

the third largest GDP in the entire continent<br />

of Asia. It is also the second largest<br />

among emerging nations. India is<br />

also one of the select three markets in<br />

the world which proffers high prospects<br />

for growth and earning potential in<br />

practically all areas of business. <strong>The</strong> reforms<br />

generated results are quite commendable<br />

at all India level and demonstrated<br />

very great picture of our nation.<br />

But the question is whether these<br />

62 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

achievements like increase in GDP, per<br />

capita income, foreign direct investment<br />

and foreign exchange reserves are sufficient<br />

conditions for the over all development<br />

of the nation and its nationals.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se on-going economic reforms with<br />

stabilization and deregulation policies<br />

as their central pieces seem to have further<br />

widened the regional disparities.<br />

<strong>The</strong> impact of globalization and privatization<br />

is not uniform across economies<br />

and also across different sections of the<br />

population within an economy. Market<br />

economy is not meant for the equal distribution<br />

of wealth, it is an uneven process<br />

with unequal distribution of benefits<br />

and losses, both across the countries and<br />

within a country across different income<br />

groups: the rich get richer and everyone<br />

else gets poorer, many absolutely and<br />

the rest in relation to the rapidly growing<br />

wealth of the rich. It has distorted<br />

investment priorities, for wealth gets directed<br />

into areas wherein it will earn the<br />

largest profit and not into spaces that<br />

most people really need (accordingly,<br />

public health, education and other basic<br />

social services receive little attention).<br />

II. Analyzing Growth Across<br />

Select Indian States<br />

Economic reforms among other things,<br />

implied that private sector would be the<br />

principal engine of economic growth.<br />

Most of the restrictions on private investment<br />

have been removed. Mounting<br />

debt burden of the government has imposed<br />

a cap on public investment. As a<br />

result, while there was significant increase<br />

in the quantum of private investment,<br />

there was a sharp fall in the public<br />

investment over the last decade. This<br />

has created even more imbalance among<br />

different states throughout India.<br />

For studying the effects of LPG on<br />

regional growth and regional imbalances<br />

among different states we have<br />

taken indicators which have direct<br />

bearing on social and economic development<br />

of the nation or region. <strong>The</strong><br />

scope of our analysis in this article is<br />

restricted to a comparative analysis of<br />

the eight major States in respect to few<br />

key parameters which have an intrinsic<br />

bearing on social, human and economic<br />

development. For the purpose of this<br />

article, we have divided these states<br />

into two groups; forward and backward.<br />

Forward states category consists<br />

of Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka Maharashtra,<br />

and Tamil Nadu, the backward<br />

states group comprises of Bihar, Madhya<br />

Pradesh, Orissa, Rajasthan and<br />

Uttar Pradesh. <strong>The</strong> parameters taken<br />

to analyze the situation are per capita<br />

income, percentage share of poor and<br />

per capita consumption expenditure.<br />

In order to analyze the nature of the<br />

private players or the market mechanism<br />

we have collected cumulative figures of<br />

total cases of foreign direct investments<br />

done in these states. <strong>The</strong> most important<br />

indicator of the economic development<br />

of a society is the Per-capita Annual Income<br />

(PCI) generated by it. PCI is an<br />

indicator of the level of economic development<br />

and it measures the inequality<br />

in the income distribution among different<br />

regions. Per capita Gross State Domestic<br />

Product (GSDP) as a percentage<br />

of per capita GDP of the country for forward<br />

and backward group of States are<br />

presented in the Table-1. It shows the<br />

growth in per capita incomes of the two<br />

groups of States over the last two and<br />

half decades, especially from 1991. All<br />

the States in the forward group, have<br />

improved their relative position over the<br />

last two and half decades. One important<br />

point is worth mentioning is that the<br />

Per capita incomes of the three states in<br />

the forward group category except Maharashtra<br />

were below the national aver-<br />

Table 1: Per-capita GSDP As A Percentage Of GDP<br />

States 1981-82 1990-91 1999-2000 2005-2006<br />

Forward Group<br />

Andhra Pradesh 87.4 92.5 97.9 101.9<br />

Karnataka 92.8 95.4 105.8 106.1<br />

Maharashtra 143 144.7 147.4 144.2<br />

Tamil Nadu 92.8 100 122.3 116.5<br />

Backward Group<br />

Bihar 58.8 53.5 36.4 30.6<br />

Madhya Pradesh 80.8 78.1 78.2 60.8<br />

Orissa 75 66.9 66.7 NA<br />

Rajasthan 76.6 79.3 85.1 69.5<br />

Uttar Pradesh 75.8 70.6 59.4 51.6<br />

All India 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: http://mospi.nic.in/<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

63


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

age in the eighties, but by the year 2005,<br />

all have gone above the national average.<br />

This is basically due to the increasing<br />

share of private investment in these<br />

states and in stark contrast, states in the<br />

backward group experienced relative<br />

deterioration in terms of per capita income<br />

and this specific deterioration was<br />

more marked after the reforms. Table-1<br />

also shows the degree of disparity in per<br />

capita income among these states,<br />

wherein Bihar and Uttar Pradesh have<br />

the greatest degree of disparity, in comparison<br />

to the forward states. <strong>The</strong> differences<br />

in per capita income between<br />

forward and backward states were minimum<br />

in 1980-81 and maximum in<br />

2005-2006.<br />

Percentage Of Poor<br />

<strong>The</strong> percentage of poverty is worth to<br />

discuss while analyzing regional disparities<br />

in India. <strong>The</strong> overall percentage of<br />

poverty has decreased from 51.3 percent<br />

in 1977-78 to 38.9 in 1987-88 and reached<br />

to the level of 36.0% in 1993-94. Now in<br />

2004-05 fewer Indians were living in<br />

poverty than in 1999-2000, with official<br />

data showing poverty declined by 4.3 per<br />

cent during this period. Poverty in India<br />

has declined to 21.8 per cent in 2004-05<br />

from 26.1 per cent in 1999-2000.While<br />

there has been great progress in reducing<br />

poverty, it has been far from even,<br />

and these data masks large regional differences.<br />

Based on NSS data, Orissa was<br />

the poorest state with 39.9 per cent of<br />

people living below poverty line followed<br />

by Jharkhand (34.8 per cent) and Bihar<br />

(32.5 per cent). Poverty levels were low<br />

in Chandigarh (3.8 per cent people living<br />

below poverty line), Jammu and<br />

Kashmir (4.2 per cent) and Punjab<br />

(5.2 percent).<br />

Among the other major states, percentage<br />

of people living below poverty<br />

line was 15 per cent in Assam, 12.5 per<br />

cent in Gujarat, 9.9 per cent in Haryana,<br />

17.4 per cent in Karnataka, 11.4 per cent<br />

in Kerala, 32.4 per cent in Madhya<br />

Pradesh, 17.5 per cent in Rajasthan, 17.8<br />

per cent in Tamil Nadu and 20.6 per cent<br />

in West Bengal. National trends in poverty<br />

reduction have been dominated by<br />

rapid growth in Forward states only<br />

other regions have seen little or no<br />

change. This is clearly presented in Table-2<br />

which is showing the<br />

percentage of poverty share<br />

among different states of<br />

India. <strong>The</strong> main beneficiaries<br />

of the overall decline in<br />

poverty in the country have<br />

been the fast growing States<br />

in the forward group. In<br />

contrast, the share of the poor in the<br />

States in the backward group has gone<br />

up significantly. As the table indicates,<br />

Table-2 Percentage Share Of Poor<br />

each one of the States in this group has<br />

now increasing share of poor from 1980s<br />

to 2000. <strong>The</strong>se show that economic<br />

growth of forward states is more than<br />

the backward states due to market<br />

mechanism.<br />

Average Monthly Per-capita<br />

Consumption Expenditure<br />

After 15 years of reforms Average<br />

Monthly Per Capita consumption Expenditure<br />

among different states is still<br />

showing wide disparities. For the forward<br />

states, it seems the formula of more<br />

market and less government<br />

is working well, but<br />

for poor states it is working<br />

in opposite direction,<br />

where government gives<br />

incentives to establish industries<br />

in these backward<br />

states, industrialist are<br />

only interested in profit maximization.<br />

All the states in the forward categories<br />

have PCCE more than Rs.1000, whereas<br />

States 1983-84 1987-88 1993-94 1999-2000<br />

Forward Group<br />

Andhra Pradesh 5.1 5.22 4.81 4.57<br />

Karnataka 4.64 5.17 4.88 4.01<br />

Maharashtra 9.01 9.65 9.53 8.76<br />

Tamil Nadu 8.05 7.53 6.31 5.01<br />

Backward Group<br />

Bihar 14.31 13.71 15.4 16.36<br />

Madhya Pradesh 8.61 8.61 9.32 11.47<br />

Orissa 5.62 5.4 5.01 6.5<br />

Rajasthan 3.93 4.65 4.01 3.14<br />

Uttar Pradesh 17.24 17.47 18.87 20.36<br />

All India 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: Planning Commission, Government of India.<br />

64 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

all the states in backward categories are<br />

having PCCE which is less than Rs.1000.<br />

<strong>The</strong> lowest among them is Bihar with<br />

only Rs.696.27 and highest PCCE is<br />

earned in Uttar Pradesh (Rs.964.02). In<br />

comparison to backward states, the lowest<br />

PCCE stands at Rs.1018.55 and highest<br />

at Rs.1148.27 (Maharashtra).<br />

Total Cases Of Foreign Direct<br />

Investment<br />

FDI influences growth by increasing total<br />

factor productivity and, more generally,<br />

the efficiency of resource use in the<br />

recipient economy. Technology transfers<br />

through FDI generate positive externalities<br />

in the host country. FDI contributes<br />

to export growth, productivity<br />

growth and finance for balance of payments;<br />

it supports increase in national<br />

income. FDI increases employment and<br />

contributes to economic growth. FDI<br />

has increased manifold over the past two<br />

decades. FDI brings private overseas<br />

funds into the country for investments.<br />

Under the new Industrial Policy Resolution<br />

the industrial policy reforms have<br />

substantially reduced the industrial licensing<br />

requirements, removed restrictions<br />

on expansion and facilitated easy<br />

access to foreign technology and foreign<br />

direct investment. Foreign Direct Investment<br />

in India is allowed on automatic<br />

route in almost all sectors. Table-<br />

3 will help us in explaining the much<br />

widening of regional imbalance<br />

throughout India. As it is evident from<br />

the table, the cumulative numbers of<br />

FDI cases are lowest in the state of Bihar(27),<br />

followed by Orissa (91) and<br />

highest in the state of Maharashtra with<br />

3743 and seconded only by Karnataka,<br />

with 2147 cases. That means the total<br />

Table-3 Total Cases Of FDI In Select States Of India<br />

Total Cases of FDI<br />

States Aug 1991-<strong>Dec</strong> 2004<br />

Forward Group Number Investment in Rs Cr<br />

Andhra Pradesh 1026 11634.44<br />

Karnataka 2147 19096.39<br />

Maharashtra 3743 37107.79<br />

Tamil Nadu 2066 22651.29<br />

Total FG 90489.91<br />

Backward Group<br />

Bihar 27 739.71<br />

Madhya Pradesh 170 9271<br />

Orissa 91 8229.31<br />

Rajasthan 241 2911.21<br />

Uttar Pradesh 536 4836.56<br />

Total BG 25987.79<br />

Source: http://eaindustry.nic.in/handbk0305/chap143.pdf<br />

gap between the highest and the lowest regions of the country. This has enabled<br />

is almost 3716 cases and this depicts the the developed regions to achieve accelerated<br />

economic growth during the<br />

clear case of wide regional inequalities.<br />

Again, the total investment in aforementioned<br />

backward states is only 28.7% of which were unable to attract any signifi-<br />

1990s. Backward regions of the country,<br />

the forward states. Ever since reforms cant private, experienced decelerated<br />

started, a great majority of FDI is directed<br />

only into select states which al-<br />

<strong>The</strong> issue of regional balance has been<br />

economic growth during this period.<br />

ready had good standard of living. <strong>The</strong> an integral component of almost every<br />

flow of private investment, both domestic<br />

and foreign, has been extremely bining<br />

and a strategy of State-led industri-<br />

Five Year Plan. <strong>The</strong> adoption of planased<br />

in favour of the more developed alization, with Plans and policies designed<br />

to facilitate more investments in<br />

the relatively backward areas were intended<br />

to lead to a more balanced<br />

growth in the country. It was expected<br />

that, over time, inter-state disparities<br />

would be minimized. An analysis of<br />

these trends, especially the more recent<br />

trends (after 1991), leads to the inevitable<br />

inference that, regional disparities<br />

still persist and in some indicators it has<br />

widened more especially after reform<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

65


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

period. Also, there are others parameters<br />

like number of bank branches<br />

and credit deposit ratio which are showing<br />

the same trend of accentuating<br />

inequality.<br />

Policy Payoffs!<br />

Thus, it is clear from the above discussion<br />

that mere free market forces and<br />

mechanisms will not help in improving<br />

the overall condition of Indian economy.<br />

Government has to work side by side and<br />

even equally with the private sector, in<br />

addition to the policy incentives aimed<br />

at private bodies for attracting the requisite<br />

investments in backward regions.<br />

But as reflected in the data, they did not<br />

work properly because of other reasons<br />

like poor social capital and weak economic<br />

conditions in backward states.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is, arguably, a greater need for<br />

higher levels of investment in social<br />

services and infrastructure, specifically<br />

in relatively backward states as compared<br />

to the more developed counterparts.<br />

<strong>The</strong> state governments of the<br />

backward regions tend to be fiscally<br />

weaker and are therefore unable to find<br />

enough resources to meet the huge investment<br />

requirements needed to catch<br />

up. <strong>The</strong>refore, if possible government<br />

should concentrate in developing backward<br />

regions and let private bodies concentrate<br />

on forward states and areas. In<br />

addition to this macro policy approach,<br />

there are several other direct and indirect<br />

measures which the state can think<br />

over. It will require Herculean tasks on<br />

the part of the Centre and the leadership<br />

in the concerned regions to ensure that<br />

the gap does not widen further.<br />

In order to reap the maximum benefits<br />

from FDI, there is a need to establish a<br />

transparent, broad and effective enabling<br />

policy environment for investment<br />

and to direct these capital flows into the<br />

areas where it is required most.<br />

References<br />

• http://planningcommission.nic.in/<br />

midterm/english-pdf/chapter-18.<br />

pdf<br />

• http://rbidocs.rbi.org.in/rdocs/Publications/PDFs/81450.pdf<br />

• http://www.iht.com/articles/<strong>2007</strong>/04/19/news/fdi.php<br />

• http://www.mospi.nic.in/mospi_<br />

nsso_rept_pubn.htm<br />

• http://www.nyu.edu/projects/ollman/docs/china_speech2_content.<br />

php<br />

• http://www.rba.gov.au/PublicationsAndResearch/Conferences/2002/<br />

kishore.pdf<br />

• http://www.rediff.com/money/<strong>2007</strong>/mar/21poor.htm<br />

Our Weapons of Mass Instruction<br />

66 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE GREAT INDIAN DREAM<br />

“Many ideas grow better when transplanted into another<br />

mind than in the one where they sprang up.”<br />

-Oliver Wendell Holmes<br />

When Great Indian Dream got released in August 2003, it created<br />

scores of academic debates and ideological dissent among<br />

many leaders. After inquiring into fallacies in national economic<br />

planning, specifically resource mobilisation strategies, it proffers<br />

an alternate plan, reconciling key social developmental imperatives,<br />

economic challenges and political constraints. <strong>The</strong> futuristic<br />

and unconventional economic wisdom inherent in it has been<br />

gaining a lot of acceptance and appreciation from many thought<br />

leaders in all walks of life. Accrediting their three decade old research<br />

at <strong>IIPM</strong>, the authors’ talk of potential growth rates over<br />

14%, since then. <strong>The</strong>ir observations were disregarded. But nowadays,<br />

every national and international think-tank, including the PM<br />

talks about a 10%. <strong>The</strong> Election Commission took a leaf out of<br />

this book and ordered enquiry into the rigging process in West<br />

Bengal. Many politicians were defamed and intelligentsia was<br />

provoked. Veteran lawyer, Ram Jethmalani used it for his campaigns<br />

in opposition to Atal Bihari Vajpayee. As on <strong>Dec</strong>ember<br />

2005, the tax component is almost 55 per cent in petrol and for<br />

diesel, the tax component in the price is almost 34 per cent, in line<br />

with the resource mobilisation strategies of the authors. It is indeed<br />

very assuring to find that in the last two years as it hit book stands,<br />

tolerant of a few minor deviations, the compelling socioecononomic<br />

recommendations mentioned in it remain convincingly<br />

well-founded. <strong>The</strong> ideology integral to this book has turned<br />

into a movement called ‘GID Foundation’ (GIDF), stirring a social<br />

revolution, as it supports developmental initiatives in more than<br />

2000 villages across 12 states and supporting an estimated 25,<br />

00,000 people residing primarily in the remote/backward areas.<br />

Effectual ideas relating to all social sectors are featured in the<br />

book are being executed to restore pride to the ‘betrayed India’.<br />

Reminds one about Sigmund Freud’s associable observation:<br />

‘Thought is action in rehearsal’.


Anindo Banerjee,<br />

Head, Programme Initiatives, Praxis -<br />

Institute for Participatory Practices,<br />

Patna<br />

Accountable Governance And Pro-poor Markets<br />

For Effective Poverty Reduction<br />

"Adam Smith, the father of modern economics,<br />

is often cited as arguing for the “invisible hand”<br />

and free markets: fi rms, in the pursuit of profi ts,<br />

are led, as if by an invisible hand, to do what is<br />

best for the world. But unlike his followers, Adam<br />

Smith was aware of some of the limitations of<br />

free markets, and research since then has further<br />

clarifi ed why free markets, by themselves, often<br />

do not lead to what is best. As I put it in my<br />

new book, Making Globalization Work, the<br />

reason that the invisible hand often seems invisible<br />

is that it is often not there."<br />

ALTMAN Daniel, Managing Globalization.<br />

In: Q & A with Joseph E. Stiglitz,<br />

Columbia University and <strong>The</strong> International<br />

Herald Tribune (IHT),<br />

October 11, 2006<br />

In the month of October, when<br />

over twenty five thousand landless<br />

agricultural labourers hailing<br />

from various dalit 1 and tribal communities<br />

of India marched to New Delhi<br />

to press for their land rights and succeeded<br />

in securing a vital policy decision<br />

towards constitution of a highpowered<br />

‘National Land Reforms<br />

Council’ headed by the Prime Minister,<br />

they heralded a historic assertion<br />

against increasing market-led appropriation<br />

of vital resources like land,<br />

water, mines and forests. Given that<br />

the last two decades have witnessed<br />

countless instances of dispossession of<br />

the poor in developing economies<br />

from critical life-support systems,<br />

mostly at the behest of market-forces<br />

actively aided by agencies of the State,<br />

the issues concerning the role and obligations<br />

of market forces and agencies<br />

of the State towards poverty reduction<br />

need to be examined cautiously, with<br />

an eye on the impacts of contemporary<br />

trends and policies on the well-being<br />

of poor communities.<br />

Markets And <strong>The</strong> Poor<br />

<strong>The</strong> experiences of several African<br />

governments during the eighties and<br />

the nineties relating to policies aimed<br />

at overcoming acute fiscal imbalances<br />

are a good pointer to the potential impact<br />

of ungoverned market forces on<br />

critical sectors such as agriculture.<br />

Measures administered to this effect<br />

on the advice of international financial<br />

institutions like the World Bank included<br />

withdrawal of the public sector<br />

from sectors like agriculture, de-control<br />

of prices, reduction of farm subsidies<br />

and increased privatization. <strong>The</strong><br />

outcomes were equally radical: the<br />

drastic steps immediately affected<br />

over seventy percent of the poor in the<br />

region by drastically suppressing food<br />

production. A recently concluded evaluation<br />

2 of World Bank’s role in African<br />

agriculture attributed the crisis to the<br />

68 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

inability of market forces to step in<br />

and jump-start agricultural growth.<br />

According to Professor Jeffery Sachs<br />

of Columbia University, “<strong>The</strong> whole<br />

thing was based on the idea that if you<br />

take away the government for the poorest<br />

of the poor, markets will somehow<br />

solve the problems, but markets can’t<br />

step in and won’t step in when people<br />

have nothing. And if you take away<br />

help, you leave them to die.” 3<br />

<strong>The</strong> example of sub-Saharan Africa<br />

clearly illustrates the criticality of the<br />

role of a pro-poor ‘welfare state’ in<br />

safeguarding the survival needs of the<br />

poorest of the poor, who do not offer<br />

any investment incentives to profitseeking<br />

market forces.<br />

According to the United Nations-<br />

Millennium Development Goals<br />

(MDGs) report of <strong>2007</strong>, the share of<br />

the poorest fifth of populations in developing<br />

regions in national consumption<br />

decreased from 4.6 to 3.9 percent<br />

between 1990 and 2004. Widening income<br />

inequality is of particular concern<br />

in Eastern Asia, where the share<br />

of consumption among the poorest<br />

people declined dramatically during<br />

this period. Inequality is the highest in<br />

Latin America, the Caribbean and in<br />

sub-Saharan Africa, where the poorest<br />

fifth of the people account for only<br />

about three percent of national income,<br />

despite increased involvement<br />

of market forces in local economies.<br />

Internationally, 46 countries of the<br />

world have become poorer today than<br />

they were in 1990, according to Human<br />

Development Report 2004.<br />

Nearly 1300 million people live in<br />

absolute poverty, earning less than one<br />

dollar a day, while about 3000 million<br />

people, more than a half of the world’s million people are officially registered<br />

population live on less than two dollars as unemployed, besides an additional<br />

a day. According to the International 700 million underemployed people.<br />

Labour Organization (ILO), over 120 Instances of poverty, which often are<br />

Growing Inequality In <strong>The</strong> World<br />

Share Of Poorest Quintile In National Consumption,<br />

1990 And 2004 (Percentage)<br />

Latin America & the Caribbean<br />

2.8<br />

2.7<br />

3.4<br />

1990<br />

3.4<br />

2004<br />

Eastern Asia<br />

7.1<br />

4.5<br />

Western Asia<br />

5.9<br />

5.4<br />

South-Eastern Asia<br />

6.2<br />

6.1<br />

CIS<br />

7.9<br />

6.2<br />

Northern Africa<br />

6.2<br />

6.3<br />

Southern Africa<br />

7.2<br />

6.7<br />

Transition Countries Of South-Eastern Europe<br />

8.3<br />

7.8<br />

Developing Regions<br />

4.6<br />

3.9<br />

0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0 4.0 5.0 6.0 7.0 8.0 9.0<br />

Source: UN MDG Report <strong>2007</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

69


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

a complex interplay of social, political<br />

and economic factors, can be addressed<br />

only by interventions that hit<br />

hard at the root causes of inequalities,<br />

rather than by the quirks of unregulated<br />

markets that by design are tailored<br />

to suit the conditions of the rich<br />

and the powerful. Given the enormous<br />

amounts of power, influence and resources<br />

that the latter tend to have at<br />

their disposal, often catalyzed by increasing<br />

overlap of political and business<br />

interests in most modern economies,<br />

the only chance for the poorest<br />

people rests on systems of governance<br />

that can be held to account and at least<br />

be subjected to a floor test of popularity<br />

based on electoral performance of<br />

alternative political ideologies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> message of the poorest people<br />

is loud and clear: governments must<br />

protect them from the vagaries of market!<br />

<strong>The</strong>ir verdict has been communicated<br />

clearly on many an occasion,<br />

evident in the electoral defeat of the<br />

‘India Shining’ campaign in India. <strong>The</strong><br />

resurrection of the ‘Aam Aadmi’ (i.e.<br />

the ‘common man’) as a reference<br />

point of current development policies,<br />

at least rhetorically, has been compelled<br />

by lessons learnt from many of<br />

these recent trends. Yet, the poorest of<br />

the poor in countries like India continue<br />

to face unprecedented challenges<br />

to their existence. <strong>The</strong> markets are<br />

pushing them hard to extinction, by<br />

encroaching upon some of their commonest<br />

avenues of survival, notably<br />

retail trade, artisan-crafts, common<br />

property resources and most alarmingly,<br />

agriculture.<br />

One needs to delve into the basic<br />

Food grain off-take through the PDS declined from 17<br />

million tonnes per year in the early nineties to 12 million<br />

tonnes per year around the end of the decade, endangering<br />

the food security of millions of the poor<br />

character and orientation of markets<br />

to assess their potential role in poverty<br />

reduction. Markets operate on the<br />

laws of supply and demand, and thereby<br />

play a role in fixation of prices and<br />

wages. <strong>The</strong>oretically speaking, the<br />

price of a product or service is directly<br />

proportional to the rarity of its supply,<br />

its quality, the cost of production, and<br />

inversely proportional to the bargaining<br />

power of the buyer and degree of<br />

regulation of unfair practices. For<br />

markets to be favourable entities for<br />

the poor (when participating in markets<br />

as sellers), the latter ought to be<br />

able to vie with competing forces towards<br />

suppressing the cost of production,<br />

acquiring greater market share to<br />

limit the range of suppliers and towards<br />

investing adequately in optimizing<br />

the quality of the product. Such<br />

possibilities are likely to be highly infeasible,<br />

given their limited economic<br />

abilities. Similarly, as buyers of products<br />

or users of services, their bargaining<br />

power is often limited on account<br />

of their limited ability to promise continuity<br />

as buyers or users, limited creditworthiness<br />

and lack of effective<br />

mechanisms to hold sellers/service<br />

providers accountable. Profit-seeking<br />

markets are more likely to serve clients<br />

that can offer greater economic returns<br />

to producers and therefore are<br />

likely to exclude the poor. <strong>The</strong> only<br />

ways to offset this fundamental likelihood<br />

of exclusion is to either regulate<br />

the markets in order that the poor are<br />

compulsorily served on pro bono terms<br />

as a principle of policy, or to create<br />

alternative providers that by mandate<br />

serve the poor. This necessitates a<br />

role for a pro-poor welfare state<br />

or non-profit organizations in<br />

serving the needs and interests of<br />

the poor.<br />

India was one of the fastest growing<br />

economies in the world during the<br />

nineties. <strong>The</strong> decade also witnessed an<br />

unprecedented scale of entry of market<br />

forces in various sectors of the<br />

economy. Yet, despite a significant<br />

spurt in macroeconomic growth, the<br />

rate of reduction of rural poverty in<br />

India was halted during the 1990s. Estimates<br />

show that the incidence of poverty,<br />

which between 1972-1973 and<br />

1989-1990 fell from 55.4 percent to<br />

34.3 percent in rural India, never went<br />

below the 1989-90 level in subsequent<br />

70 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

NSSO rounds undertaken up to 1997<br />

(Please refer to the diagram) iv . Though<br />

the rate of decline of rural poverty<br />

picked up again during the subsequent<br />

years (from 1999-2004), the rate of<br />

GDP growth was in fact less during<br />

this phase than during 1993–1999. <strong>The</strong><br />

average per-capita expenditure in rural<br />

areas was not even ten percent<br />

higher in 1999-2000 than in 1993-1994,<br />

and rural poverty actually went up in<br />

some of the poorer states, such as Assam<br />

and Orissa. Also, food grain offtake<br />

through the public distribution<br />

system declined from 17 million tonnes<br />

per year in the early nineties to 12 million<br />

tonnes per year around the end of<br />

the decade 5 , endangering the food security<br />

of millions of the poor in the<br />

country at the time when the GDP<br />

growth was unprecedented.<br />

<strong>The</strong> State vis-à-vis <strong>The</strong> Poor<br />

<strong>The</strong> Eleventh Five-Year Plan of India<br />

underscores the challenge of providing<br />

employment to 70 million additional<br />

people by 2011-12. It is also a well-established<br />

fact that the incidence of<br />

It is a well-established fact that the incidence of unemployment<br />

is substantially higher in the ‘below poverty line’<br />

category, and particularly high amongst the Scheduled<br />

Castes (SCs) and Scheduled Tribes(STs)<br />

unemployment is substantially higher<br />

in the ‘Below Poverty Line’ category,<br />

and particularly high amongst the<br />

scheduled castes and tribes therein (as<br />

indicated by successive National Sample<br />

Surveys). A critical question therefore<br />

is: what strategies and preparedness<br />

does the State have to meet this<br />

challenge, which is important to be addressed<br />

to prevent the nation’s slide<br />

into anarchy? Do markets provide a<br />

Trends In <strong>The</strong> Poverty Ratio (1972 - 1997)<br />

60<br />

55<br />

55.36<br />

Rural<br />

Urban<br />

50<br />

50.6<br />

45<br />

40<br />

35<br />

30<br />

45.67<br />

45.31<br />

40.5<br />

38.81<br />

35.65<br />

34.29<br />

39.23 39.06<br />

36.6<br />

34.3<br />

36.2<br />

33.4<br />

43.47<br />

36.43<br />

33.73<br />

32.76<br />

41.02<br />

36.66<br />

33.5<br />

30.51<br />

37.15<br />

35.78<br />

29.99<br />

25<br />

28.04<br />

Oct 72-Sep 73<br />

Jul 77- Jun 78<br />

Jan 83- <strong>Dec</strong> 83<br />

Jul 86-Jun 87<br />

Jul 87-Jun 88<br />

Jul 88-Jun 89<br />

Jul 89-Jun 90<br />

Jul 90-Jun 91<br />

Jan 92-<strong>Dec</strong> 92<br />

Jun 93-Jun 94<br />

Jul 94-Jun 95<br />

Jul 95-Jun 96<br />

Jan 97-<strong>Dec</strong> 97<br />

Percent Population<br />

(Source: "<strong>The</strong> Poverty Puzzle" by C.P. Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh, Macroscon, Feb. 22, 2000)<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

71


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

solution, or do they further endanger<br />

the chances of survival of the poor?<br />

Can democratic governments be allowed<br />

to forego their duties towards a<br />

majority of their trustees who vote<br />

them into power?<br />

Of late, various governments in India<br />

have been offering unprecedented<br />

incentives to the private sector with an<br />

eye on macro-economic growth. For<br />

instance, policies relating to establishment<br />

of Special Economic Zones<br />

(SEZs) include significant supports to<br />

private entrepreneurs in the form of<br />

facilitation of land acquisition, tax rebates<br />

and friendlier administrative<br />

mechanisms, amongst others. However,<br />

many of the provisions jeopardize<br />

the long-term interests of the poor in<br />

many ways and the much-touted objective<br />

of inclusive growth hasn’t come<br />

into effect. For instance, one of the<br />

largest Special Economic Zones in India<br />

proposed to be set up by Reliance<br />

Industries Limited in Maharashtra<br />

across three tehsils of Raigad district<br />

threatens to displace nearly 35,000<br />

farmers based over 25,000 hectares of<br />

agricultural land. <strong>The</strong> threat to the<br />

livelihoods of the farmers likely to lose<br />

ownership of land are sought to be offset<br />

merely by providing monetary compensation<br />

without any thoughts about<br />

the limited livelihood-choices available<br />

to them, consequent pressure on<br />

limited urban infrastructure, or the<br />

implications for a large number of nonowner<br />

dependents of farmland, e.g.<br />

sharecroppers or wage labourers.<br />

In similar developments across the<br />

country, as many as 396 SEZs have<br />

been accorded formal clearance by the<br />

government (by October <strong>2007</strong>), of<br />

which 149 have already been notified.<br />

When households displaced by SEZs<br />

or big projects migrate to cities, their<br />

survival becomes even more arduous,<br />

thanks to modern urban policies that<br />

increasingly shut out spaces from the<br />

reach of the poor. <strong>The</strong> commonest<br />

Markets, unless regulated with a pro-poor orientation, can<br />

eliminate the poor rather than contributing to poverty<br />

reduction, given the inherent tendencies of supply-side<br />

domination and profi t maximization<br />

coping avenues for the poor, e.g. participation<br />

in retail trade, accessing<br />

state-run basic services, or opting for<br />

low-investment livelihoods (e.g. rag<br />

picking or plying rickshaws) are made<br />

increasingly inaccessible by policies<br />

that allow entry of big business houses<br />

in retail trade, enhance the cost<br />

of basic services by allowing their<br />

privatization, or block public spaces<br />

for the poor.<br />

Another area of concern relates to<br />

increasing privatization of common<br />

property resources in the country,<br />

bearing life-threatening implications<br />

for a large number of poor communities.<br />

<strong>The</strong> operations of mining companies<br />

in various forest-rich areas of<br />

states like Chhattisgarh and Jharkhand<br />

have destroyed the age-old forestbased<br />

livelihoods of many tribal families.<br />

In Orissa, the state government<br />

has already committed several rivers<br />

and reservoirs for use by industry for<br />

water-intensive activities. In Chhattisgarh<br />

too, industries have been permitted<br />

to draw water from rivers like Kelo<br />

and Sheonath. Kelo, a tributary of Mahanadi<br />

river, happens to be an important<br />

source of livelihood for over sixty<br />

village communities settled alongside<br />

its 98 kilometer long stretch across<br />

Raigarh district of Chhattisgarh,<br />

whose lives have been badly affected<br />

due to severe decline in the stock of<br />

river water. During a People’s Tribunal<br />

held in Kolkata in January <strong>2007</strong>, Santwana<br />

Dey – an elderly woman hailing<br />

from a farmer household based in Bejiberia<br />

village of Singur where the<br />

Government of West Bengal acquired<br />

land for handing over to Tata Motors<br />

in lieu of promises of jobs in a car factory<br />

and offers of monetary compensation,<br />

raised a fundamental issue: ‘no<br />

one can dictate what should my family<br />

do for a living; we have a right to pursue<br />

occupations that we are capable of and<br />

cannot be forced to work in a car factory,<br />

which we have no inkling about!’<br />

Santwana’s straightforward assertion<br />

in the Tribunal underscored a legiti-<br />

72 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

mate contention of millions of marginalized<br />

citizens of the country – regarding<br />

their right to work, and<br />

particularly the right to avail of work<br />

of a suitable and gainful nature, in<br />

keeping with the directive of the constitution<br />

of India (Article 41; Directive<br />

Principles of State Policy) calling upon<br />

the State to make effective provisions,<br />

within the limits of its economic capacity<br />

and development, for securing<br />

the right to work. In a country where<br />

the rate of growth of the <strong>size</strong> of labour<br />

force exceeds the rate of growth of employment,<br />

and where over ninety percent<br />

of the workforce is employed in<br />

the unorganized sector, the challenge<br />

of creating gainful employment opportunities<br />

for a large segment of socially<br />

and economically disadvantaged citizens<br />

remains the greatest trial of relevance<br />

of our welfare state. <strong>The</strong> performance<br />

of the State with respect to<br />

its duties towards the poorest of the<br />

poor people might have been inadequate<br />

and often inefficient, but it has<br />

undoubtedly been critical. No other<br />

agency has the scale and depth of presence<br />

amongst the poor like agencies of<br />

the State. <strong>The</strong>re are important policies<br />

favouring affirmative action for the<br />

socially marginalized, employment<br />

guarantees, relief from disasters, decentralized<br />

governance, right to information,<br />

provisions against atrocities<br />

and social security benefits for especially-challenged<br />

people and affordable<br />

basic services. However, bureaucracies<br />

managing a State’s performance<br />

have often failed to administer the<br />

pro-poor provisions effectively and<br />

have eluded any kind of accountability<br />

to the people. In many states, they<br />

have also undermined the status and<br />

potential of Panchayati Raj institutions<br />

by assuming sweeping powers over decisions<br />

relating to local development.<br />

Holding functionaries of the State accountable<br />

is the greatest need of the<br />

hour, not reducing the role of<br />

the State.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Way Forward<br />

For poverty reduction to be effective<br />

and viable in the long run, the State<br />

needs to play a far more efficient and<br />

accountable role than it is today, without<br />

withdrawing itself from the obligation<br />

of poverty reduction. Markets can<br />

be made a supportive channel towards<br />

creation of more development opportunities<br />

for the people, through regulations<br />

that bring about a level playing<br />

field. A two-pronged strategy, where<br />

the State assumes full responsibility<br />

for efficient and accountable delivery<br />

of crucial basic services and entitlements,<br />

and also enables poor communities<br />

to effectively engage with markets<br />

can significantly contribute to the<br />

wellbeing of the poor. Facilitating<br />

meaningful participation of the poor<br />

in contemporary markets would call<br />

for support towards value addition and<br />

sale of economic products of the poor;<br />

storage of goods; establishment of efficient<br />

institutions for managing procurements,<br />

forward movements and<br />

linkages; price control and equitable<br />

incentives, amongst other things. Local<br />

institutions of governance need to<br />

be freed from the control of bureaucracy<br />

and capacitated to play an effective<br />

regulatory role towards safeguarding<br />

the strategic needs of the poor,<br />

based on principles of equity and<br />

social justice.<br />

Markets, unless regulated with a<br />

pro-poor orientation, can eliminate<br />

the poor rather than contributing to<br />

poverty reduction, given the inherent<br />

tendencies of supply-side domination<br />

and profit maximization. <strong>The</strong> poor<br />

have little say in the functioning of<br />

market forces, but have some stake and<br />

control in the governments they elect.<br />

<strong>The</strong> only way in which the poor can<br />

safeguard their interests in a market is<br />

by electing pro-poor governments that<br />

eliminate anti-poor market forces and<br />

regulate supplies of essential goods<br />

and services in order that they remain<br />

accessible and affordable to the poor.<br />

Good governance is the right of every<br />

citizen, and ensuring the same through<br />

effective mechanisms of accountability<br />

of government functionaries is the<br />

greatest need of the hour.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

‘Dalit’ literally means ‘oppressed’<br />

and refers to socially marginalized<br />

communities living in India.<br />

2<br />

Evaluation undertaken by <strong>The</strong> Independent<br />

Evaluation Group of the<br />

World Bank, titled “Assessment<br />

of the Bank’s assistance to agricultural<br />

development in Sub-Saharan<br />

Africa during FY 1991-06”<br />

3<br />

Ref. report titled ‘World Bank Neglects<br />

African Farming, Study Says’,<br />

published in the New York<br />

Times, October 15 <strong>2007</strong><br />

4<br />

Ref. ‘<strong>The</strong> Poverty Puzzle’ by C.P.<br />

Chandrasekhar and Jayati Ghosh,<br />

Macroscan, February 22, 2000<br />

5<br />

Ref. ‘Hunger amidst Plenty’ by Jean<br />

Drèze, India Together, <strong>Dec</strong>ember 3,<br />

<strong>2007</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

73


Anjani Sinha<br />

Managing Director & CEO,<br />

National Spot Exchange Limited,<br />

Mumbai<br />

Food Security In India:<br />

<strong>Issue</strong>s And Implications<br />

"annam na nindyat. tadvratam."<br />

(Do not look down upon anna. That is<br />

the inviolable discipline of life for the one<br />

who knows.)<br />

"annam na paricaksita. tadvratam."<br />

(Do not neglect anna. That is the<br />

inviolable discipline of life for the one<br />

who knows.)<br />

"annam bahu kurvita. tadvratam."<br />

(Multiply anna many-fold. Ensure an<br />

abundance of food all around. That is the<br />

inviolable discipline of life for the one<br />

who knows.)<br />

-<strong>The</strong> Taittiriyopanisad<br />

1. Concept<br />

Food Security refers to the scenario in<br />

which every citizen of the country has access<br />

to sufficient and affordable good<br />

quality food. <strong>The</strong> concept has evolved<br />

during the last three decades to include<br />

not only food availability, but also economic<br />

access to food and biological absorption<br />

of food in the body. It is considered<br />

in terms of availability of foods, its<br />

quality, its accessibility and affordability<br />

for general mass. Thus we can say that<br />

there are four pillars of food secu<br />

rity - Availability, Affordability, Accessi<br />

bility and Quality of food in terms of<br />

balanced diet.<br />

2. Objectives And Focus<br />

2.1 India’s food security policy has a<br />

laudable objective to ensure availability<br />

of food grains to common mass at an affordable<br />

price. It has enabled the poor to<br />

have access to food where none existed.<br />

When India got Independence, the then<br />

Prime Minister Late Sri Jawaharlal Nehru<br />

said, “Everything else can wait but<br />

not agriculture.”<br />

2.2 Historically, India’s food security<br />

policy has focused essentially on growth<br />

in agriculture production, fixing minimum<br />

support price for procurement and maintaining<br />

buffer stocks of rice and wheat to<br />

ensure food security.<br />

3. Concerns<br />

3.1 As a matter of fact, concern on<br />

food security has always haunted the<br />

scholars and policy makers right from<br />

Malthusian <strong>The</strong>ory way back in eighteenth<br />

century. This is mainly because of limited<br />

and declining natural resources and ever<br />

increasing population.<br />

3.2 Recently, Government of India<br />

has taken a policy decision to allocate Rs.<br />

48.82 billion for National Food Security<br />

Mission (NFSM). <strong>The</strong> primary objective<br />

is to raise the production of rice, wheat<br />

and pulses during the 11 th Five-Year Plan<br />

period (<strong>2007</strong>-12) and ensure food security<br />

in the country. Assuming requirement of<br />

175 kg cereals and 11 kg of pulses per<br />

capita per annum, India needs 265 million<br />

74 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Per-capita Per Day Availability Of Foodgrains<br />

In India Since 1971<br />

Period Cereals Pulses Food Grains<br />

1971-1975 393 44 437<br />

1981-1985 417 39 456<br />

1991-1995 445 37 482<br />

2001-2005 414 32 446<br />

Projected Growth Rate And Demand For<br />

Various Food Commodities Towards 2011-12<br />

Food Item<br />

Projected<br />

Growth<br />

Rate (%)<br />

tons of cereals production and 17 million<br />

tons of pulses production by the end of<br />

2050. Achieving this level of production is<br />

not a big task as India currently produces<br />

around 210 million tons of food grains.<br />

But, it needs a serious planning and<br />

effective implementation.<br />

3.3 Adequate per capita availability of<br />

food is a function of food production on<br />

one hand, and growth in population and<br />

purchasing power, on the other. Nature of<br />

food security varies across population categories<br />

and geography. Food production<br />

is the result of interaction of human being’s<br />

crop production technique and management<br />

of the natural resources such as<br />

Demand:<br />

Million<br />

Tonnes<br />

Food grains 2.21 251.7<br />

Milk and milk products 3.18 100.39<br />

Meat 4.65 5.36<br />

Eggs: Billion 4.62 35.77<br />

Fish 4.58 5.91<br />

Oilseeds 2.94 49.2#<br />

Vegetables 2.51 92.93<br />

Fresh Fruits 3.46 29.43<br />

Sugar and gur 1.88 22.49<br />

# Assume 40% dependence on import for edible oil<br />

Source: NACP–ICAR In House Estimates<br />

Note: Projected demand includes export in the same ratio as n the base scenario<br />

2003-04 for foodgrains and in 2004-05 for others.<br />

land, water, weather and climatic<br />

condition. <strong>The</strong> guiding<br />

principle should be optimal<br />

utilization of scarce<br />

resources. Thus it is important<br />

to know the natural<br />

Resources, understand the<br />

level of technology utilization,<br />

and understand effect<br />

of modern production technology<br />

on the natural resources,<br />

limitation of total<br />

efforts towards production<br />

increase and understanding<br />

of the scope of overall utilization<br />

of scientific knowledge<br />

in our present agriculture.<br />

It is also important<br />

that natural resources<br />

should continue to be available<br />

without deterioration<br />

over a long period of time.<br />

3.4 <strong>The</strong> natural resources,<br />

which we have, are limited<br />

especially land and<br />

water. Fertility of land is<br />

declining. Soil health has<br />

been declining because of excessive usage<br />

of fertilizer and pesticide. Organic contents<br />

and microenvironment of the soil has<br />

undergone noticeable changes impacting<br />

productivity. <strong>The</strong>re is change in weather<br />

pattern and climatic condition. Frequency<br />

of erratic rain, floods and droughts has<br />

increased considerably.<br />

3.5 Level of technology utilization in<br />

Indian agriculture is highly uneven and<br />

biased to certain pockets of the county.<br />

Green revolution helped India to transform<br />

itself from food deficit to food surplus<br />

country. But unfortunately, green<br />

Revolution has not percolated across all<br />

the states. Application of modern production<br />

techniques is still limited to some<br />

pockets, like the states of Punjab and<br />

Haryana. High variation in production<br />

and productivity in different states is the<br />

result of varying level of technology integration<br />

in our agriculture production.<br />

3.6 <strong>The</strong> long term sustainability of<br />

agriculture and consistent growth in production<br />

and productivity matching with<br />

population growth is a big question mark.<br />

It has been noticed that in various parts of<br />

Punjab and Haryana, water level has gone<br />

down to such levels that water extraction<br />

has become economically unviable. Nitrogen<br />

contents of water has increased, there<br />

is presence of pesticides residue in drinking<br />

water. Heavy and unscientific method<br />

of fertilizer application has taken a toll on<br />

the soil quality. <strong>The</strong>re is adverse impact on<br />

the local microclimate because of intensive<br />

agriculture and similar crop cycle over<br />

a long period of time. Higher contents of<br />

fertilizer and pesticides in ground water<br />

not only affect productivity, but it also severely<br />

affects the food quality. Situation<br />

Food production is the result of interaction of human being’s<br />

crop production technique and management of the<br />

natural resources. <strong>The</strong> guiding principle must be<br />

optimal utilization of scarce resources<br />

demands to take corrective as well as preventive<br />

actions to maintain agriculture<br />

growth sustainable in the long run.<br />

3.7 In India average per capita land<br />

holding is less than 0.16 hectare. Average<br />

farm holding with farmers is 1.6 acre. Now<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

75


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

let us take the case of a typical farmer. His<br />

crop production decision is guided by his<br />

immediate needs. <strong>The</strong> decisions of seeds<br />

selection, fertilizer, pesticides etc are<br />

based on his own feeling or fellow farmers’<br />

advice that may be scientific or unscientific.<br />

Crop cycle is decided not on the basis<br />

of scientific procedure but the personal<br />

requirements of the farmer. Hence, the<br />

concern is how to transform sustenance<br />

agriculture into agri-business.<br />

4. Strategy To Combat<br />

<strong>The</strong> Concerns<br />

4.1 Though the Government and<br />

different agencies have done commendable<br />

job to transform India from food<br />

starved to food surplus nation, still due<br />

to lack of effective extension services,<br />

the impact in a number of States has<br />

been less than desirable levels. <strong>The</strong><br />

States of UP, Bihar and West Bengal<br />

cities, service industry has penetrated in<br />

our day to day life in such a manner, that<br />

we are dependent upon one or the other<br />

service provider for our daily needs. Examples<br />

are newspaper vendor, milk supplier,<br />

etc. without whom the daily routine<br />

does not start in cities. But, in agriculture,<br />

it is not so. A farmer does sowing, irrigation,<br />

pesticide treatment, harvesting and<br />

marketing of produce – all activities himself.<br />

He knows agriculture very well, but<br />

his knowledge is confined to old techniques.<br />

He does not get any professional<br />

training to use modern techniques. In<br />

most cases, he is dependent upon the vendor<br />

only for advisory services also. For<br />

example, he asks the pesticide vendor how<br />

much quantity of pesticide he should use<br />

to treat his farms. <strong>The</strong>re are cases where<br />

only one liter of pesticide is sufficient, if<br />

properly applied, but, the pesticide vendor<br />

sells a 5 liters container advising him to<br />

Crop cycle is decided not on the basis of scientifi c procedure<br />

but the personal requirements of the farmer.<br />

Hence, the concern is how to transform sustenance<br />

agriculture into agri-business<br />

have very fertile land, but productivity is<br />

lower than the national average. Here<br />

lies the potential to be tapped. Major<br />

constraints in these areas are limited use<br />

of modern agriculture production technique<br />

by farmers in absence of effective<br />

extension activities. <strong>The</strong> productivity of<br />

rice and wheat grown in these areas is<br />

quite low. Hence, by focusing on these<br />

states, we can achieve remarkable success<br />

in ensuring food security.<br />

4.2 Another strategy to ensure food<br />

security is launching of professional commercial<br />

services at village levels to provide<br />

various agri solutions to the farmers. In<br />

apply the same frequently, because the<br />

main interest of the vendor could be to sell<br />

pesticide. If there is a service agency locally<br />

available, which is run by a qualified<br />

agriculture graduate, and he provides an<br />

end to end solution for pesticide treatment<br />

at a fee, the farmer may save money because<br />

of reduction in input cost, yield may<br />

improve because of non application of excessive<br />

pesticide and still the agriculture<br />

graduate can run the service unit in a profitable<br />

manner. We can apply this theory<br />

for all activities associated with agriculture-sowing,<br />

harvesting, processing and<br />

so on. A well qualified professional having<br />

expertise in mangoes can provide excellent<br />

services in mango growing area about<br />

plucking of mangoes scientifically, identifying<br />

such mangoes which are totally matured.<br />

This will give confidence to the<br />

marginal farmer that he himself is the<br />

owner of his land, he himself is in possession<br />

of his land, though he is a marginal<br />

farmer who otherwise cannot buy new machines<br />

and agricultural equipments as it is<br />

not viable for marginal holding, still he can<br />

avail all the modern facilities at his doorstep.<br />

Hence, the second mantra for ensuring<br />

food security in Indian context, considering<br />

the fragmented holding and<br />

marginal farmers, is organizing extensive<br />

application of professional but commercial<br />

services at farm level in the form of either<br />

independent small ventures run by agriculture<br />

graduates or by big corporate<br />

launching such service on a large scale.<br />

4.3 Nature has bestowed us with<br />

enough resources. <strong>The</strong> Ganges belt is so<br />

fertile that it can feed wheat to the entire<br />

world, if it is utilized properly. Similarly,<br />

soil in other area is most ideal for cotton<br />

production. In order to ensure comprehensive<br />

and sustained growth, what is important<br />

is to have a national level unbiased<br />

scientific crop planning, based on agro<br />

climatic conditions, soil type, soil condition,<br />

method of available irrigation, potential<br />

of irrigation, infrastructure requirement,<br />

existence of infrastructure,<br />

suitability of various crops to be grown in<br />

that area, seed variety selection, fertilizer<br />

dosage determination, application of pesticides<br />

and plant nutrient, crop monitoring,<br />

scientific method of problem identification<br />

and suitable solution, food habits in<br />

the area. India is divided in 15-agro climatic<br />

zones. Each zone has got its own<br />

potential and limitation. Crop production<br />

76 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

planning based on the resources availability<br />

in these zones is required to be done to<br />

use the resources judiciously. Planning<br />

should be based on scientific study coupled<br />

with commercial planning, with farmers’<br />

interest in mind. If his land is suitable<br />

for a specific cash crop, which will give<br />

him better return on investment, he should<br />

be induced to do so, even if it means he has<br />

to buy food grains from the market. Under<br />

this planning, the country as a whole has<br />

to evaluate, which crop we should produce<br />

here and which crop we should import, so<br />

that overall return on agriculture improves.<br />

Similarly, if water is deficient in an<br />

area, farmers should not cultivate sugarcane<br />

there. Instead of thinking in terms<br />

of quintals per hectare, we have to start<br />

thinking in terms of Rupees per hectare.<br />

This will be the real transformation of sustenance<br />

agriculture into agri business.<br />

Hence, the third mantra is national level<br />

integrated crop planning, with focus on<br />

farmers’ return on investment.<br />

4.4 Information is key to success. Authentic<br />

and timely information reduces<br />

uncertainty in business. India is one of the<br />

leading countries in respect of Information<br />

technology. But, if we look at Indian<br />

agriculture or even information relating<br />

to Indian agriculture, we do not find IT<br />

application working anywhere. We know<br />

from USDA data what is happening in US,<br />

but we do not know what is happening in<br />

our own villages. Authentic information<br />

can be generated only if we have robust<br />

information system coupled with robust<br />

connectivity backbone upto village level.<br />

For this purpose, if the entire agricultural<br />

land in the country is mapped on computer<br />

software and latest technology for database<br />

designing and data mining is used,<br />

it will prove to be the most powerful tool<br />

to help agriculture. If the village level representative<br />

is required to feed data on<br />

daily basis regarding sowing, crop pattern,<br />

harvesting on daily basis relating to all<br />

land holding in his area and all such data<br />

travels to a central server, where it is processed<br />

to generate consolidated reports, we<br />

will get the most valuable information<br />

about Indian agriculture on daily basis.<br />

This information will be most useful for<br />

the farmers also, because they will know<br />

in how much area, onion is already sown<br />

and so, whether he should do onion cultivation<br />

or shift to some other crop. Today,<br />

if price of a commodity is higher in a year,<br />

lot of farmers will cultivate the same commodity<br />

next year, which leads to glut; fall<br />

in price and resultant loss. A number of<br />

companies will be interested to buy data,<br />

because their business is connected with<br />

agriculture and hence, the entire venture<br />

can be run in a profitable manner. Looking<br />

at the outstanding success of telecom<br />

revolution in our country, it is not a difficult<br />

target. Hence, the forth important<br />

strategy should be to develop real time<br />

database system to track agriculture after<br />

mapping each and every land holding cultivated<br />

in our country.<br />

4.5 <strong>The</strong> area under cultivation in our<br />

country is consistently under pressure. Urbanization,<br />

industrialization, housing for<br />

increasing population are taking a toll on<br />

the land under cultivation. But, still India<br />

has a lot of barren and wasteful land, which<br />

is not under cultivation. Such land is wasteful<br />

due to variety of reasons. Somewhere<br />

land is not fit for agriculture because it is<br />

full of stones and hilly layers. Somewhere<br />

it is not cultivable because of poor rainfall<br />

and lack of irrigation facilities. If through<br />

comprehensive planning we can convert at<br />

least a part of such wasteful land into agriculture<br />

land, it will ease the food security<br />

threat. In Rajasthan, agriculture has<br />

progressed very well after creating irrigation<br />

facilities through canalization. In<br />

Kutch area, similar wonders have been<br />

achieved by using Narmada water through<br />

canalization. Similarly, area covered with<br />

stony layers not fit for agriculture can be<br />

developed for poultry. Hence, the next<br />

In Rajasthan, agriculture has progressed very well after<br />

creating irrigation facilities through canalization. In Kutch<br />

area, similar wonders have been achieved by using<br />

Narmada water through canalization<br />

strategy for solving food security problem<br />

should be to convert wasteful land into agriculture<br />

wherever possible.<br />

4.6 If land resources are limited and<br />

population is continuously increasing, fundamentally<br />

there will always be a mismatch<br />

in the long run. <strong>The</strong> production of food<br />

grains has a degree of inelasticity in the<br />

long run because of long crop period and<br />

seasonality factors. Compared to that, in<br />

the same area production of fruits and vegetables<br />

can be increased manifold by using<br />

better techniques, multi-layer cropping,<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

77


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

etc. <strong>The</strong> idea is to increase production of<br />

fruits and vegetables manifold if production<br />

of food grains cannot be increased<br />

significantly. Human food habits also keep<br />

on changing, with change in socio economic<br />

factors. If fruits and vegetables are<br />

commercially within reach of lower middle<br />

class people, it will ease the pressure<br />

on cereals. However, this will also need<br />

good investment in rural infrastructure,<br />

cold chain, transportation and<br />

marketing support.<br />

4.7 In order to ensure food security,<br />

another important strategy should be to<br />

strengthen marketing infrastructure and<br />

make the farming more remunerative. If<br />

production increases, but marketing infrastructure<br />

is not strong to tackle load of<br />

increased production, it will be a big disaster.<br />

In case of absence of strong marketing<br />

infrastructure, increase in production<br />

will lead to glut at arrival centers, which<br />

means unremunerative prices to the farmers<br />

and in such case, increase in production<br />

cannot be sustained. <strong>The</strong> solution lies<br />

in improving marketing efficiency by reducing<br />

cost of intermediation and bringing<br />

in price transparency. This can be achieved<br />

through developing electronic spot markets<br />

with facilities for deliveries at various<br />

arrival centers and developing a robust<br />

structured market, which can be relied<br />

upon by buyers located anywhere in the<br />

country for sourcing deliveries. <strong>The</strong> Exchange<br />

will, guarantee payment to the sellers<br />

against deliveries and delivery of quality<br />

certified material to the buyers. Hence,<br />

electronic national level spot exchange is<br />

the next strategy to ensure food security.<br />

4.8 Now, we have Warehousing Development<br />

and Regulation Act in place.<br />

This will certainly promote investment in<br />

rural infrastructure in terms of warehousing,<br />

cold storage, etc. We know that around<br />

Futures market has helped in discovering correct price<br />

levels and improving farmers’ realization. In Uttar Pradesh,<br />

Mentha farmers are now getting Rs.500 per kg; while<br />

earlier they were getting only Rs.300-350 per kg<br />

15% of total production goes as post harvest<br />

losses. Even bringing the storage loss<br />

to 5% will have large effects on our food<br />

security. However, marketability of warehouses<br />

is also crucial, because it is a capital<br />

intensive project and unless people use it,<br />

private investment in rural warehouses will<br />

not be viable in a big way. Marketability of<br />

warehouses means a platform, where warehouse<br />

receipts can be negotiated. If a<br />

farmer or trader knows that by keeping<br />

goods in a designated warehouse, he can<br />

sell his produce on a national level electronic<br />

platform, he will certainly choose to<br />

keep his produce in such designated scientific<br />

rural warehouses. But, for this purpose<br />

national level electronic spot exchange<br />

has to come up, where warehouse<br />

receipts representing quality certified farm<br />

produce can be traded. This will create a<br />

business model for institutional investors<br />

for creating rural infrastructure. In absence<br />

of this, we may find big shopping<br />

malls coming up in cities, but creating<br />

warehouses and cold storage in rural area<br />

may not be achieved, unless we also have<br />

a viable business model enhancing marketability<br />

of warehouses at national level.<br />

Hence, strengthening rural infrastructure<br />

and linking them to modern market is next<br />

strategy to ensure food security.<br />

4.9 Futures market has helped in discovering<br />

correct price levels for various<br />

commodities and hence improving farmers’<br />

realization. In U.P., Mentha farmers<br />

are now getting Rs.500 per kg; while earlier<br />

they were getting only Rs. 300- 350 per<br />

kg. As a result, area under cultivation has<br />

doubled. Production has also increased<br />

from 18000 MT to 32000 MT per annum.<br />

But, futures market will be more helpful<br />

to the farmers, if there is also an electronic<br />

spot market, so that farmers can use<br />

futures market for price discovery and spot<br />

market for price realization. For developing<br />

electronic spot market, the most important<br />

requirement is amendment in<br />

APMC law and recognition of the concept<br />

of E Trading, E Markets or Electronic<br />

Spot Exchanges under the APMC Act.<br />

Presently, the scenario is that sale and purchase<br />

of farm produce outside the principal<br />

yard and sub yard is illegal. A farmer<br />

is not allowed to sell more than head load<br />

to a person not holding APMC license,<br />

otherwise the buyer can be prosecuted.<br />

Futures markets and spot markets will<br />

help ensure food security by making farming<br />

remunerative and improving farmers’<br />

realization thereby strengthening rural<br />

economy. Hence, amendment in APMC<br />

Act, promoting alternative marketing<br />

channels, recognizing E Trading and E<br />

Market as national level platforms, giving<br />

the farmers a choice to sell wherever he<br />

desires, are important steps towards ensuring<br />

food security. In order to ensure<br />

food security, we have to make farming<br />

remunerative and attractive. Developing<br />

alternative channels for marketing of agriculture<br />

produce and giving freedom to<br />

farmers to sell wherever they get the highest<br />

price is key to achieve this goal.<br />

78 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

1 0 j a n 2 0 0 8<br />

YEAR-END SPECIAL<br />

only Rs. 10<br />

i nd i a ’ s mo s t i nf l uen t i a l bus i ne s s and ec onomy m a g a z i n e<br />

India’s No. 1<br />

Business & Economy<br />

Magazine<br />

India’s most<br />

Disruptive<br />

Dynasties<br />

<strong>The</strong>y were kings in<br />

several sectors. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

spotted opportunities in<br />

new sectors, controlled by<br />

strong players. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

gatecrashed, and caused<br />

massive disruptions.<br />

Finally, they changed the<br />

rules of the game<br />

Vijay Mallya, UB Group


James Tooley,<br />

President,<br />

<strong>The</strong> Education Fund,<br />

Orient Global,Singapore<br />

Why Poor Parents Are Choosing ‘More Market, Less<br />

Government’ In Education And What We Should Do About It?<br />

"Freedom necessarily means<br />

that many things will be done<br />

which we do not like. Our<br />

faith in freedom does not rest<br />

on the foreseeable results in<br />

particular circumstances but<br />

in the belief that it will, on<br />

balance, release more forces<br />

for the good than the bad."<br />

-Friedrich Hayek<br />

I’ve moved to India because something<br />

extraordinary is happening<br />

in education, and I want to be a<br />

part of it. Most excitingly, it concerns<br />

the education of the less well-off in society,<br />

rather than the rich. <strong>The</strong> accepted<br />

wisdom says that the poor need<br />

governments to provide their education<br />

– in most developing countries,<br />

governments supplemented by hefty<br />

international aid. But government<br />

education for the poor in India isn’t<br />

working well. Visiting a government<br />

school for the poor here is not an edifying<br />

experience. Where there should<br />

be ten teachers, you’ll often only find<br />

two or three present. <strong>The</strong>y won’t all be<br />

teaching either. Children– bright-eyed,<br />

eager young children – will often be<br />

seating on the floor, doing nothing.<br />

Nor will there be sanitation facilities<br />

in many schools. I know one government<br />

school in the slums behind the<br />

Charminar in Hyderabad where the<br />

children have an arrangement to use a<br />

neighbour’s toilet, and avail themselves<br />

of drinking water from him too. In another,<br />

they have to wait until they get<br />

home (which sometimes stops them<br />

coming to school altogether). In a<br />

third, a well-known foundation has<br />

provided computers and a television to<br />

transform teaching. <strong>The</strong> television is<br />

in the headteacher’s office, still in its<br />

box; the computers are in a locked<br />

room. Reason: the school has no electricity.<br />

This too is commonplace. I’m<br />

not the only one to feel that the poor<br />

deserve much more than what government<br />

education apparently has to offer.<br />

It would all be deeply depressing if it<br />

wasn’t for the fact that the poor, in<br />

huge numbers, are already embracing<br />

an alternative. Private schools are blossoming<br />

in the slums and low-income<br />

areas of urban India, and in rural India<br />

too. <strong>The</strong>se low-cost private schools are<br />

run by entrepreneurs from the communities.<br />

Perhaps a woman has started a<br />

nursery, then been persuaded to extend<br />

it further when parents report<br />

that their children are happy with her.<br />

80 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Or a husband and wife team starts a<br />

school as a joint business, seeing the<br />

success of other schools in the neighbourhood.<br />

Visit these schools, and<br />

you’ll find the vast majority of teachers<br />

present and teaching, and a vibrant atmosphere<br />

of learning taking place.<br />

And the market for these schools seems<br />

huge: I first discovered for myself these<br />

low cost private schools in poor areas<br />

of the Old City of Hyderabad a few<br />

years back. From the roof of one, I<br />

could see five or six other private<br />

schools, all vying for the same customers.<br />

‘More Market, Less Government’<br />

in education already seemed to be the<br />

impulse of poor parents across India.<br />

How many schools are there? What<br />

proportion of children are they serving?<br />

How good are these low cost private<br />

schools? What is their business<br />

model – and does it have implications<br />

for the way the sector can be enhanced?<br />

<strong>The</strong>se were the questions that leapt out<br />

at me when I first found these schools<br />

for myself. I procured funding from<br />

the John Templeton Foundation to<br />

conduct detailed research – in India,<br />

and also in Nigeria, Ghana, Kenya and<br />

China, for the phenomenon of low cost<br />

private schools turns out to be something<br />

that is widespread across the developing<br />

world. My research teams<br />

explored selected, officially designated<br />

‘poor’ areas, such as slums and shanty<br />

towns in metropolitan cities in these<br />

countries, and poor areas in the rural<br />

hinterlands surrounding these cities.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y researched remote villages in impoverished<br />

North-West China, and<br />

rural communities in south India. <strong>The</strong><br />

teams combed these poor areas, going<br />

down every alleyway in the slums, visiting<br />

every settlement in the rural areas,<br />

asking of people on market stalls and<br />

in the streets, to find where the poor<br />

were being educated. <strong>The</strong>y found large<br />

numbers of schools – 918 in the ‘notified’<br />

slums of three zones of Hyderabad,<br />

India, for instance.<br />

What the research teams found<br />

points to an extraordinary grassroots<br />

educational revolution that is taking<br />

place – in India and across the developing<br />

world. In poor urban areas surveyed,<br />

a large majority of school children<br />

were found to be in ‘budget’<br />

private schools. For instance, in the<br />

slums of Hyderabad, India, 65 percent<br />

of schoolchildren were in private unaided<br />

schools. <strong>The</strong>se schools charge<br />

very low fees, affordable to parents on<br />

poverty-line and minimum-wages. In<br />

Hyderabad, mean monthly fees at 4th<br />

grade were Rs.78.17 ($1.74) in unrecognized<br />

and Rs.102.55 ($2.28) in recognized<br />

private schools in the slums –<br />

about 4.2 percent and 5.5 percent<br />

respectively of the monthly wage for a<br />

breadwinner on a typical minimum<br />

wage of about Rs.78/-per day (Government<br />

of India, 2005, assuming 24 working<br />

days per month).<br />

Private schools for the poor are not<br />

just an urban phenomenon either. In<br />

the deprived district of Mahbubnagar,<br />

in Andhra Pradesh, I found around<br />

three-fifths of schools were government,<br />

only a tiny number private aided,<br />

and well over a third were private unaided.<br />

But breaking these figures into<br />

schools in the small towns and rural<br />

areas proper, I could see that small<br />

town Andhra Pradesh is rather similar<br />

to the metropolitan areas: Just as in<br />

urban Hyderabad, the vast majority of<br />

schools – nearly two-thirds – were private<br />

unaided in the small towns of<br />

Mahbubnagar. In the rural areas proper,<br />

however, government schools were<br />

in a majority – around fourth-fifths,<br />

with private unaided schools making<br />

up the remaining fifth. Development<br />

experts who are aware of the existence<br />

of this low cost private sector appear<br />

uniformly to worry about their low<br />

quality: <strong>The</strong> Oxfam Education Report,<br />

for instance, notes that private schools<br />

for the poor are of ‘inferior quality’,<br />

offering ‘a low-quality service’ that will<br />

In Hyderabad, mean monthly fees at 4th grade were<br />

Rs. 78.17 ($1.74) in unrecognized and Rs.102.55 ($2.28)<br />

in recognized private schools in the slums – about 4.2<br />

percent and 5.5 percent respectively of the monthly wage<br />

for a breadwinner on a typical minimum wage<br />

‘restrict children’s future opportunities.’<br />

(Watkins, 2000, p. 230). Nambissan<br />

(2003) notes that in Calcutta, ‘the<br />

mushrooming of privately managed<br />

unregulated pre-primary and primary<br />

schools… can have only deleterious<br />

consequences for the spread of education<br />

in general and among the poor in<br />

particular’ (p. 52), for the quality of the<br />

private schools is ‘often suspect’ (p. 15,<br />

footnote 25). Significantly, such concerns<br />

about low quality of private provision<br />

must be read in the context of<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

81


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

the reported low standard of government<br />

provision. <strong>The</strong> Oxfam Education<br />

Report prefaces the remarks quoted<br />

above with the observation that ‘there<br />

is no doubting the appalling standard<br />

of provision in public education systems’<br />

(Watkins, 2000, p. 230). Indeed,<br />

the low quality of government schools<br />

for the poor is one reason given for the<br />

‘mushrooming’ of the private schools:<br />

Venkatanarayana (2004) notes that the<br />

‘failure of public school in terms of<br />

meeting parents’ expectations/aspirations’<br />

has led to a ‘growing demand’ for<br />

private schools in rural Andhra<br />

Pradesh, India (p. 40).<br />

Are the low cost private schools as<br />

bad as the development experts think?<br />

I looked at the issue of quality in detail.<br />

My researchers tested around<br />

24,000 children in the global sample,<br />

taken from stratified random samples<br />

of schools within these poor communities.<br />

Children were tested in key curriculum<br />

subjects, and questionnaires<br />

given to children, their parents, teachers<br />

and school managers, and IQ tests<br />

to children and their teachers, to elicit<br />

data to control for a wide range of<br />

background variables, including peergroup<br />

variables. <strong>The</strong> results from Delhi<br />

were typical. In mathematics, mean<br />

scores of children in government<br />

schools were 24.5 percent, while those<br />

in private unrecognised schools were<br />

42.1 percent and private recognised<br />

were 43.9 percent. That is, children in<br />

unrecognised private schools achieved<br />

nearly 18 percentage points higher in<br />

Low cost private schools are accountable to the parents –<br />

who can withdraw their children if they’re not satisfi ed; the<br />

entrepreneurs knows this, and knows he or she will feel<br />

the pinch for each parents who doesn’t pay fees, so<br />

makes sure things go well within the school<br />

maths than children in government<br />

schools (a 72 percent advantage!),<br />

while children in recognised private<br />

schools were over 19 percentage points<br />

higher than children in government<br />

schools (a 79 percent advantage). In<br />

English, the performance difference<br />

was much greater (children in unrecognised<br />

schools gaining 35 percentage<br />

points higher, while children in recognised<br />

schools were 41 percentage<br />

points higher). However, these differences<br />

might be expected, given that<br />

government schools are not providing<br />

what parents want, English medium.<br />

(On the other hand, they might not be<br />

expected, given an oft-repeated criticism<br />

that private schools are Englishmedium<br />

in name only, that this is just<br />

another way they pull the wool over ignorant<br />

poor parents’ eyes. What we<br />

found showed that the private schools<br />

were in fact getting their children to a<br />

much higher English standard than<br />

what children might pick up in the environment,<br />

through radio, television<br />

and advertisements, for instance –<br />

which is perhaps what the tests were<br />

measuring for children in government<br />

schools). But in any case, if more private<br />

schools are English medium, this<br />

might lead us to expect that government<br />

schools would be superior in<br />

achievement in Hindi: the opposite was<br />

true. Children in private unrecognised<br />

schools achieved on average 22 percentage<br />

points higher than children in<br />

government schools (an 83 percent advantage).<br />

In recognised private schools,<br />

children scored on average 24 percentage<br />

points higher (an 89 percent advantage.)<br />

Controlling for relevant background<br />

variables, the differences<br />

between government and private<br />

schools were reduced but still hugely<br />

significant: In Hyderabad, for instance,<br />

a child attending a private unrecognised<br />

school would be predicted to<br />

gain 16.1 percentage points higher in<br />

mathematics than the same child attending<br />

a government school. In a private<br />

recognised school, the difference<br />

in scores would be 17.3 percentage<br />

points. In English, the advantages<br />

would be even greater –16.9 percentage<br />

points higher in an unrecognised<br />

school, and 18.9 percentage points in a<br />

recognised school. In Urdu, after controlling<br />

for the background variables,<br />

there turned out to be no statistically<br />

significant difference between government<br />

and either type of private school.<br />

More market, less government in education<br />

– this appears to be how poor<br />

parents see the way forward. And they<br />

are doing it for a good reason – the low<br />

cost private schools are better than the<br />

government alternative. Presumably<br />

they’re better because they’re accountable<br />

to the parents – who can withdraw<br />

their children if they’re not satisfied;<br />

the entrepreneurs knows this, and<br />

knows he or she will feel the pinch for<br />

each parents who doesn’t pay fees, so<br />

keeps a close eye on his teachers and<br />

makes sure things go well within the<br />

82 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

school. Better, however, but perhaps<br />

not good enough. For whatever the advantages<br />

of the low cost private schools<br />

that I’ve outlined above, clearly their<br />

quality could be improved – and noone<br />

acknowledges this more, in my experience,<br />

than the private school entrepreneurs<br />

themselves. <strong>The</strong>y are hungry<br />

for new ideas in curriculum and pedagogy.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y are hungry for investment<br />

in infrastructure and technology. But<br />

this is where something rather exciting<br />

opens up for us. We can see the low<br />

cost private education sector as a new<br />

frontier for investment. <strong>The</strong> key relevant<br />

finding of my research is that the<br />

vast majority of the private schools in<br />

the poor areas are run as businesses,<br />

not charities, dependent more or less<br />

entirely on fee income and, very importantly,<br />

making a reasonable profit.<br />

In Hyderabad for instance, 91 percent<br />

unrecognized and 82 percent recognized<br />

private schools were entirely dependent<br />

on student fee income, receiving<br />

no outside funding at all. Profit<br />

margins, my research showed, could be<br />

in the region of 20-40 percent of fee<br />

income. Because the private schools<br />

for the poor are run as businesses, this<br />

provides at least three ways forward for<br />

investors to help in improving quality<br />

– each of which is prompted by the observation<br />

that school proprietors are<br />

hungry for improvement and innovation.<br />

Why? Because whatever the critics<br />

of private schools for the poor may<br />

claim, many care about children’s education.<br />

On its own, this might be<br />

enough for some to invest. But, the<br />

power of the market means that it’s<br />

coupled with another major incentive:<br />

proprietors know that they are in an<br />

increasingly competitive market. <strong>The</strong>y<br />

need parents to know that their school<br />

is special, to maintain or increase market<br />

share. If school improvements seem<br />

to have demonstrably better outcomes,<br />

they’ll want them for their schools.<br />

So we can, first, help school proprietors<br />

improve their infrastructure<br />

through providing loans, through existing<br />

or purpose-created non-banking<br />

finance organizations. Typical projects<br />

would include refurbishing or building<br />

new classrooms and buying land. Second,<br />

investors can conduct research<br />

and development to find out what works<br />

to improve desired curriculum and<br />

pedagogical outcomes in low cost education.<br />

Investors can then partner with<br />

local entrepreneurs to ensure that the<br />

improved methods are made available,<br />

suitably packaged, at a price acceptable<br />

to school entrepreneurs.<br />

And this leads to a third exciting<br />

possibility. In '<strong>The</strong> Fortune at the Bottom<br />

of the Pyramid', Prof. C.K. Prahalad<br />

challenges the ‘dominant assumption’<br />

that the poor are not bothered<br />

about brand-names: ‘On the contrary’,<br />

his findings suggest, ‘the poor are very<br />

brand-conscious’ (2005, p. 13). In private<br />

education, brand names could be<br />

important to help solve the genuine<br />

information problem that exists – and<br />

this provides a third major opportunity<br />

for investors to enter the education<br />

market. How can poor parents<br />

judge if one private school in their<br />

community is better than another, and<br />

that it is adequately serving the educational<br />

needs of their children? Typically,<br />

my research showed parents using<br />

a variety of informal methods, such<br />

as visiting several schools to see how<br />

committed teachers and the proprietor<br />

appear. Or they talk to friends, comparing<br />

notes about how frequently exercise<br />

books are marked and homework<br />

checked. Importantly, I found<br />

that if parents choose one private<br />

school, but subsequently discover that<br />

another seems better, they have little<br />

In private education, brand names could be important to<br />

help solve the genuine information problem that exists –<br />

and this provides a third major opportunity for investors to<br />

enter the education market<br />

hesitation in moving their child to<br />

where they think they will get a better<br />

education. And school proprietors<br />

know all of this, so make sure teachers<br />

turn up and teach, and invest any surpluses<br />

in school improvement, to ensure<br />

parental satisfaction. So there is<br />

an information problem, but there are<br />

ways around it.<br />

However, in other markets, brand<br />

names provide a safer way of overcoming<br />

parallel information asymmetries.<br />

Buying into trusted brands would be<br />

one way of overcoming the information<br />

problem too, for poor parents wanting<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

83


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

the best education for their children.<br />

One possibility would be for investors<br />

to assist expansion-minded proprietors<br />

accessing loan capital. Or it could involve<br />

creating a specialised education<br />

investment fund, to provide equity to<br />

education companies that run chains<br />

of budget private schools. Suitable exit<br />

strategies could be worked out for the<br />

investment fund, perhaps by giving advice<br />

on how to list on local stock markets,<br />

or to get other investors on board.<br />

A further possibility could involve investors<br />

engaging in a joint venture with<br />

local educational entrepreneurs to set<br />

up a chain themselves. Investment in<br />

initial R&D would be required, to create<br />

the standards for a demonstrable<br />

and truly replicable model of private<br />

education for the poor. But here’s the<br />

rub: although it is possible to envisage<br />

creating chains of private schools here<br />

in India as things stand now, the regulatory<br />

environment certainly doesn’t<br />

make life easy for investors and innovators.<br />

<strong>The</strong> problem is profit. It all<br />

seems to go back to the Unnikrishnan<br />

Supreme Court Judgement of 1993<br />

(Unnikrishnan vs. State of Andhra<br />

Pradesh., 1993, in Padala Rama Reddi<br />

(1993) <strong>The</strong> Andhra Pradesh Education<br />

Code, Hyderabad, pp. 399-400). <strong>The</strong><br />

judgement reads: ‘Education has never<br />

been commerce in this country. Making<br />

it one is opposed to the ethos, tradition<br />

and sensibilities of this nation.’<br />

Moreover, ‘Commercialisation of education<br />

cannot and should not be permitted<br />

… Both in the light of our tradition<br />

and from the standpoint of interest<br />

of general public, commercialisation is<br />

positively harmful, it is opposed to<br />

public policy.’<br />

It’s hard to read these statements<br />

now in the light of the activities of successful<br />

businesses such as NIIT and<br />

Aptech and think that they make much<br />

Although it is possible to envisage creating chains of private<br />

schools here in India as things stand now, the regulatory<br />

environment certainly doesn’t make life easy for investors<br />

and innovators.<strong>The</strong> problem is profi t<br />

sense. <strong>The</strong>se certainly are commercial<br />

companies, and their business is clearly<br />

education. So they seem to show<br />

that, in point of fact, there is a very fine<br />

Indian ethos and tradition of the ‘business<br />

of education’. Usefully, the Unnikrishnan<br />

judgement was partially<br />

revoked in 2002. In the Supreme Court<br />

on October 31 st 2002 (TMA Pai Foundation<br />

versus State of Karnataka), it<br />

was pointed out that it is ‘no secret that<br />

the examination results at all levels of<br />

unaided private schools, notwithstanding<br />

the stringent regulations of the governmental<br />

authorities, are far superior<br />

to the results of the government-maintained<br />

schools’ (Para 61, p. 40). So<br />

clearly, the judgement said, Unni<br />

Krishnan needs reconsideration if it is<br />

having a dampening effect on private<br />

education entrepreneurs. However,<br />

did this reconsideration mean that Unnikrishnan’s<br />

rejection of profit is also<br />

superseded? It is not clear to me. <strong>The</strong><br />

new judgement reads: in ‘setting up a<br />

reasonable fee structure, the element<br />

of profiteering is not as yet accepted in<br />

Indian conditions’ (Para. 53, p. 34).<br />

However, ‘Reasonable surplus to meet<br />

cost of expansion and augmentation of<br />

facilities does not, however amount to<br />

profiteering’ (p. 128). Does this allow<br />

for-profit education? Or not? It seems<br />

that it may still be a grey area – and<br />

grey areas like this can breed corruption<br />

and inefficiency. To make matters<br />

worse, the sentiments behind Unnikrishnan<br />

are there in the regulations<br />

of the examination boards. <strong>The</strong> CBSE<br />

for instance says that only schools that<br />

are run ‘as a community service and<br />

not as a business’ are able to be affiliated<br />

to the board. And they are there<br />

in many state regulations too, that only<br />

allow schools to be registered if they<br />

are run by non-profit educational societies<br />

or trusts, but not by companies.<br />

All this means that if investors want<br />

to invest in education, it’s not straightforward.<br />

Of course it’s possible. Forprofit<br />

companies can contract with<br />

educational societies and trusts to provide<br />

management and educational inputs.<br />

But these means are cumbersome,<br />

open to regulatory risk, and in<br />

any case obtuse: for the regulations<br />

want to protect us from something that<br />

in other areas of our lives seems whol-<br />

84 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ly desirable. <strong>The</strong> profit motive is accepted<br />

as beneficial in most areas of<br />

our lives, in spurring innovation, improving<br />

quality and extending access.<br />

For instance, would anyone deny that<br />

the mobile phone revolution has accomplished<br />

each of these, and that<br />

profit was a key factor underlying each?<br />

<strong>The</strong> same could be true of the delivery<br />

of education – the profit motive could<br />

spur new methods of learning, which<br />

improve learner outcomes, and help<br />

reach those who currently don’t have<br />

access to quality education. Allowing<br />

the profit motive into education – and<br />

hence allowing masses of investment<br />

into this area – would be wholly beneficial<br />

to education in India. If only India<br />

could break away from this regulatory<br />

morass, then the future could be golden.<br />

If the entrepreneurial spirit that<br />

Indians daily show in the field of education<br />

could be harnessed, rather than<br />

damped down (as it is by current regulations),<br />

then the emerging chains of<br />

private schools, including low cost<br />

schools, funded by investment from<br />

within India and overseas, could have<br />

an extraordinary impact. And this impact<br />

could be felt not only in India but<br />

on the rest of the world too. American<br />

brand names like McDonald’s and<br />

Starbucks are predominant in the current<br />

wave of globalisation. In the next<br />

wave, there could be the educational<br />

equivalents of these chains – offering<br />

standardised delivery of high quality<br />

educational experiences – emanating<br />

from India to take on the rest of the<br />

world. I find that prospect pretty exciting.<br />

Which is why, as I say, I’ve come to<br />

India to see if I can be a part of this<br />

educational revolution.<br />

References<br />

• Nambissan, Geetha, B. (2003) Educational<br />

deprivation and primary school<br />

provision: a study of providers in the<br />

city of Calcutta, IDS Working Paper<br />

187, (Brighton, Institute of Development<br />

Studies).<br />

• Prahalad, C.K. (2005) <strong>The</strong> Fortune at<br />

the Bottom of the Pyramid, Wharton<br />

School Publishing, Upper Saddle<br />

River, NJ.<br />

• Tooley, James, Dixon, Pauline and<br />

Gomathi, S.V., (<strong>2007</strong>) Private Schools<br />

and the Millennium Development<br />

Goal of Universal Primary Education:<br />

A census and comparative survey in<br />

Hyderabad, India, Oxford Review of<br />

Education 33(5).<br />

• Tooley, James and Dixon, Pauline,<br />

(2006) ‘De Facto’ Privatisation of<br />

Education and the Poor: Implications<br />

of a Study from sub-Saharan Africa<br />

and India, Compare 36(4), 443-462<br />

• Tooley, James (2006), Backing the<br />

Wrong Horse: How Private Schools<br />

Are Good for the Poor, <strong>The</strong> Freeman,<br />

May, 8-13.<br />

• Tooley, James (2005) Private schools<br />

for the poor, Education Next: A Journal<br />

of Opinion and Research, Fall,<br />

Vol. 5 (4), 22-32.<br />

• Venkatanarayana, M. (2004) Educational<br />

Deprivation of Children in A.<br />

P: Levels and Trends, Disparities and<br />

Associate Factors, Working Paper<br />

362, Centre for Development Studies<br />

(www.cds.edu), August.<br />

• Watkins, K. (2000), <strong>The</strong> Oxfam Education<br />

Report. (Oxford, Oxfam in<br />

Great Britain).<br />

TECH WATCH<br />

What’s in store<br />

for technology freaks in 2008<br />

INDIA’S FIRST AND NO. 1 BUSINESS AND MARKETING MAGAZINE<br />

4Ps<br />

✮ PRODUCT ✮ PRICE ✮ PLACE ✮ PROMOTION ✮<br />

BUSINESS AND<br />

MARKETING<br />

<strong>Volume</strong>-II <strong>Issue</strong>-24 4 January - 17 January 2008<br />

Why Toyota, GM,<br />

Ford & Renault<br />

love India...<br />

Power, passion, leadership skills,<br />

strategic expertise and many<br />

such qualities... they have it all;<br />

the maestros who will turn things<br />

around for India in 2008. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

are the very forces who will make<br />

2008 worthwhile for India Inc. An<br />

exclusive 4Ps B&M compilation...<br />

20<br />

...and why India loves Jaguar, Land<br />

Rover & Suzuki. <strong>The</strong> reason: India<br />

may emerge as a global player in the<br />

passenger car segment<br />

Meet the 2nd<br />

Son of the East<br />

Rendezvous with<br />

Kenji Anai,<br />

Global Head,<br />

Multifuncl. Devices,<br />

National Panasonic<br />

88 Supermodels<br />

NOW ONLY<br />

Rs.10<br />

alone can’t<br />

cast the<br />

marketing<br />

spell.<br />

You<br />

need<br />

Pill(ow) fight<br />

more! Why Dabur needs a<br />

‘new u’ look soon<br />

by Rajita<br />

Chaudhuri<br />

38<br />

Top 5:<br />

Why Airtel &<br />

Kingfisher Airlines<br />

reign supreme<br />

this fortnight<br />

4Ps<br />

BUSINESS AND<br />

MARKETING<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

85


Stephen P. Heyneman,<br />

Professor, International Education Policy,<br />

Vanderbilt University, Nashville, Tennessee<br />

International Trade in Higher Education:<br />

What Should India Do?<br />

"Higher education should be left to private enterprise<br />

and for meeting national requirements<br />

whether in the various industries, technical arts,<br />

belles-letters or fi ne arts. <strong>The</strong> State Universities<br />

should be purely examining bodies, self-supporting<br />

through the fees charged for examinations.<br />

Universities will look after the whole of the fi eld<br />

of education and will prepare and approve<br />

courses of studies in the various departments<br />

of education. No private school should be run<br />

without the previous sanction of the respective<br />

Universities. University charters should be<br />

given liberally to any body of persons of proved<br />

worth and integrity, it being always understood<br />

that the Universities will not cost the State anything<br />

except that it will bear the cost of running<br />

a Central Education Department.<strong>The</strong> foregoing<br />

scheme does not absolve the State from running<br />

such seminaries as may be required for supplying<br />

State needs."<br />

-Mahatma Gandhi, Harijan,<br />

2 October 1937<br />

At independence, India had<br />

twenty universities; today<br />

there are 348. From a rate of<br />

attendance of less than one percent,<br />

today it is 12 percent. Between 1990<br />

and 2000 the number of students in<br />

higher education grew by 113 percent.<br />

Providers are diverse. Approximately<br />

one third of the students attend nongovernment<br />

institutions and 63 percent<br />

attend institutions financed by state<br />

governments. Of the world’s most famous<br />

scientists and economists, many<br />

received their training in India. Indian<br />

higher education appears healthy. But<br />

according to some estimates India<br />

needs at least 150 new universities. Although<br />

enrollment (12 percent) is<br />

higher than at any time in India’s history,<br />

it is less than any OECD country<br />

and has even fallen behind that of China<br />

(with 16 percent). Less then 2 percent<br />

of the students in India have an<br />

opportunity to attend any of the top<br />

universities sponsored by the national<br />

government. Only $US 406 is spent/<br />

year on the typical university student<br />

in India. This includes expenditures<br />

for electronic libraries, books, research<br />

laboratories, physical infrastructure,<br />

and salaries. <strong>The</strong> typical student in<br />

China has seven times more resources<br />

at his disposal. <strong>The</strong> typical student in<br />

Malaysia has 30 times more resources<br />

available, and a student in Canada has<br />

37 times more resources available.<br />

Though overall growth in the last ten<br />

years has been rapid, universities with<br />

advanced research programs grew by<br />

only 51 percent; in the Russian Federation<br />

they grew by 113 percent, in<br />

China by 167 percent and in Malaysia<br />

by 200 percent. Though foreign universities<br />

are higher in cost, 160,000 students<br />

leave India each year seeking<br />

higher education elsewhere. Over<br />

5,000 Indian students arrive annually<br />

to study in the U.S., where the price of<br />

attending universities is higher than<br />

anywhere in the world. <strong>The</strong>y do this<br />

because they cannot find a university<br />

in India comparable in quality.<br />

86 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure I: Ranking Of Asian Universities By Size Of Bandwidth<br />

Rank Multi-Disciplinary Schools Internet Bandwidth per student (kbps) Overall Rank 2000<br />

1 Sun Yat-sen University (Taiwan) 33.53 20<br />

2 Kyungpock National University 27.76 35<br />

3 Chungnam National Unviersity 20.84 50<br />

4 Australian National University 19.58 8<br />

5 Taiwan Normal University 19.02 37<br />

6 Seoul national University 17.14 4<br />

7 Tsing Hua University(Taiwan)* 14.77 18<br />

8 Chonnam National University 14.77 1<br />

9 Tohcku University (Japan) 13.52 34<br />

10 Tianjin University (China) 11.84 2<br />

11 National University of Singapore 11.54 46<br />

12 University of Wollongong 10.81 54<br />

13 University of Adelaide 7.1 5<br />

14 Nagoya University 6.92 45<br />

15 Central University (Taiwan)* 6.88 26<br />

16 Nagoya University 6.58 11<br />

17 Central University (Taiwan)* 6.12 24<br />

18 University of Melbourne 6.06 9<br />

19 Kasetsart University 5.56 63<br />

20 Chao Toung University (Taiwan)* 5.5 28<br />

21 Monash University 5.14 30<br />

22 Chonbuk National University 5 43<br />

23 Taiwan University* 4.1 12<br />

24 Pusan National Unviersity 3.99 39<br />

25 City University of Hong Kong 3.9 27<br />

26 Hckkaido University 3.81 19<br />

27 Southeast University (China) 3.56 60<br />

28 Chung Hsing University (Taiwan)* 3.35 65<br />

29 Keio University* 3.24 22<br />

30 Hanyang University 3.16 38<br />

31 University of Western Australia 2.89 23<br />

32 Sungkyunkwan U niversity 2.83 33<br />

33 Ewha Womans University 2.46 32<br />

34 Macquarie University 2.32 56<br />

35 Ritsumeikan University 2.18 67<br />

36 Waseda University 2.13 29<br />

37 Chinese University of Hong Kong 2.1 6<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

87


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure I: Ranking Of Asian Universities By Size Of Bandwidth (Contd.)<br />

Rank Multi-Disciplinary Schools Internet bandwidth per student (kbps) Over all Rank 2000<br />

38 University of Hong Kong 2.05 3<br />

39 Korew University 2.04 414<br />

40 Cheng Kung University (Taiwan)* 1.6 16<br />

Although there are many famous Indian<br />

scientists and economists, they<br />

often teach in foreign universities.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y do this because universities in<br />

India cannot offer comparable research<br />

facilities, programs with comparable<br />

innovation, or comparable<br />

levels of remuneration. When one<br />

ranks a nation by the number of citations<br />

to its published scientific literature,<br />

citations from India in 2005<br />

ranked number 21, accounting for only<br />

1.1 percent share of the total. <strong>The</strong> scarcity<br />

of world class faculty in Indian<br />

Figure II. Asia Week: Multi-Disiplinary Ranking: Top<br />

77 Universities in Asia<br />

Country Number (Percentage) Highes Rank<br />

Korea 13(16.9) 4<br />

Japan 11(14.9) 1<br />

Australia 10(13.0) 8<br />

Taiwan 10(13.0) 12<br />

Thailand 5(6.5) 51<br />

Philippines 4(5.2) 48<br />

New Zealand 4(5.2) 21<br />

Indonesia 4(5.2) 61<br />

Hong Kong 4(5.2) 3<br />

China 4(5.2) 42<br />

Malaysia 3(3.9) 47<br />

India 2(2.6) 40<br />

Bangladesh 1(1.3) 64<br />

Singapore 1(1.3) 5<br />

Sri Lanka 1(1.3) 77<br />

Source: www.asiaweek.com/features/universities2000/school/<br />

multi.overall.html<br />

universities is one explanation for the<br />

fact that of the applications for patents<br />

India accounted for only 0.5 percent.,<br />

and of the ‘capacity to innovate’ in<br />

2005 India ranked 50. No Indian university<br />

appears in the ranking of world<br />

universities; and no university appears<br />

in the top ranked universities in Asia<br />

in terms of what is now considered a<br />

sine qua non of university quality:<br />

bandwidth (Please refer Figure -I). Of<br />

the top ranked 77 universities within<br />

Asia, the highest university in India<br />

only ranked number 40. Only two universities<br />

were even considered (See<br />

Figure-II). It is unfortunate but nevertheless<br />

it is fair to characterize universities<br />

in India as being ‘asleep’, while<br />

universities in other countries quickly<br />

pass by.<br />

In Medieval Europe it is said that<br />

plagues were accompanied by numerous<br />

theories of ‘what went wrong’.<br />

Some attributed impending catastrophe<br />

to insufficient piety. If citizens repent<br />

they said, their futures would<br />

brighten. <strong>The</strong> problems of Indian higher<br />

education are similarly accompanied<br />

by theories of ‘what went wrong’.<br />

Some theories hold that international<br />

evidence to the contrary is irrelevant<br />

and that there is nothing wrong. Others<br />

suggest that the problems can only<br />

be solved if India does more of what it<br />

has done in the past --- finance higher<br />

education largely from public tax resources,<br />

control prices, limit providers<br />

and forbid foreign competition. And<br />

then there are some theories which<br />

point to the unmitigated success of India’s<br />

entry into telecommunications.<br />

When allowed in, foreign providers<br />

quickly rejuvenated India’s ancient telecommunications<br />

sector thus making<br />

it possible for entrepreneurial spinoffs,<br />

which spurred India into high<br />

economic growth and a decline in poverty.<br />

Why couldn’t international competition<br />

not jump start the Indian<br />

higher education sector as it has other<br />

88 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure III: Pros And Cons For Opening India To International Trade In Education<br />

Cons<br />

Loss of public good character<br />

Only serves individual needs<br />

Rewards universitites independent<br />

of the broad public good<br />

Weakens public funding<br />

Eclipses the public sector by the<br />

private sector quality<br />

Pros<br />

Increased efficiency, quality and choice<br />

Consistent with human rights<br />

Breaks the monopoly of having low quality universities define what whould be learned<br />

Strengthens public funding because it would strengthen public confidence through increased<br />

accountability<br />

Strengthens the public sector due to competition<br />

sectors? <strong>The</strong>re are two paths in Indian<br />

higher education policy: to continue to<br />

protect it or to open it up to international<br />

competition with all of the impending<br />

implications. <strong>The</strong> answer will<br />

determine India’s future. So what<br />

should India do? One problem is that<br />

the arguments for and against opening<br />

India to higher education trade is generally<br />

made by two divergent groups of<br />

stakeholders. Macro-economists generally<br />

favor international competition;<br />

education policy officials generally do<br />

not. It might be useful to place each of<br />

their arguments on the table and analyze<br />

them one by one (Please do refer<br />

Figures- III and IV).<br />

Higher Education As A Public<br />

Good<br />

Those who oppose international trade<br />

in higher education will argue that<br />

higher education is a public good and<br />

that opening up India to international<br />

providers would threaten the maintenance<br />

of the public interest. Those who<br />

favor international trade will point out<br />

that overtly sectarian or philosophically<br />

dangerous providers can be controlled<br />

through the accreditation process.<br />

Further, they will argue that<br />

competition stimulates efficiency, wider<br />

choice, and higher quality (as it does<br />

in many sectors). In their view these<br />

characteristics are part of public interest.<br />

Is it in the public interest, they<br />

ask, to allow access only to low quality,<br />

inefficient and a narrow choice of professional<br />

programs?<br />

Figure IV: Pros And Cons (Contd.)<br />

Cons<br />

Leads to “Knowledge Capitalism”<br />

Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual<br />

Property Rights (TRIPS) would exclude<br />

low income scholars by maintaining<br />

high prices for curriculum<br />

materials<br />

Since knowledge is public good, reforms<br />

in education finance with decrease<br />

access to public good<br />

Threatens the “Social contract” in<br />

which the present generation finances<br />

future generations<br />

Trade jeopardizes human rights because<br />

it contradicts national commitments<br />

supporting free education<br />

Individual Vs. Social Needs<br />

Those who oppose say that international<br />

trade would serve only the needs<br />

of the individual and that service to the<br />

community, a natural part of higher<br />

education, would be lost if trade barriers<br />

were liberalized. Those who favor<br />

point out that at present human rights<br />

are being abrogated. All individuals<br />

have the right to education they might<br />

say, and if one individual wishes to<br />

study in a field provided by a foreign<br />

university, what right do we have as a<br />

Pros<br />

Leads of the strengthening of non-resourced<br />

subjects through cross-faculty<br />

resource transfer<br />

Adhering to TRIPS would increse access<br />

to high quality products by insuring incomes<br />

from their sale. Hence it would<br />

increase supply, the choice of products,<br />

and lower the real price<br />

Public goods are never free. Reforms in<br />

education finance will increase the income<br />

to public and private producers.<br />

Hence, it will increase the supply and access<br />

to a public good.<br />

Strengthens the social contract by increasing<br />

access, quality and equity<br />

(through cross-subsidization)<br />

Trade would increase human rights by<br />

allowing access to education where it is<br />

currently denied of unavailable<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

89


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

democracy to limit that access to education?<br />

<strong>The</strong> same might be true to<br />

textbooks, foreign faculty, internet<br />

facilities and the like. Limitation of<br />

education trade itself is an abrogation<br />

of human rights.<br />

Universities Would Be Rewarded<br />

Independent Of <strong>The</strong> Public<br />

Good.<br />

Those who oppose would say that universities<br />

should be rewarded for their<br />

research and teaching independent of<br />

their abilities to generate revenue; if<br />

foreign competition were allowed then<br />

Indian universities would have to follow<br />

commercial rather than intellectual<br />

incentives. Those who favor say<br />

that competition is necessary to break<br />

what is now a monopoly. If only low<br />

quality institutions are available, there<br />

is little incentive to imp<br />

rove. Instead of being a threat to intellectual<br />

incentives, foreign comp<br />

etition may be an essential ingredient<br />

to stimulate it.<br />

International Education Trade<br />

Would Weaken <strong>The</strong> Case For<br />

Public Funding<br />

Those who oppose would point out<br />

that public funding is essential for university<br />

development and if foreign<br />

competition were allowed the case for<br />

more public resources would weaken.<br />

‘Let the private sector provide the facilities’,<br />

the politicians might say, ‘Now<br />

we can allocate resources to problems<br />

other than higher education’. Those<br />

who favor argue the opposite. <strong>The</strong>y say<br />

that foreign competition would<br />

strengthen the case for public funding,<br />

not weaken it. It would strengthen the<br />

Up for consideration should be changes in the entire legal<br />

structure, which would allow the creation of endowments<br />

often from the overseas diaspora (something China has<br />

mastered) and a new tax regime which encourages donations<br />

and gifts to education from both citizens and firms<br />

case because it would increase public<br />

confidence in the higher education<br />

sector because of increased accountability.<br />

Why should the public allocate<br />

additional resources to a sector crippled<br />

by low quality and inefficiency?<br />

Wouldn’t the public be more likely to<br />

allocate resources to a sector in which<br />

it had more confidence? And wouldn’t<br />

open competition help stimulate the<br />

supply response in which they could be<br />

more confident?<br />

Public Wector Quality Would<br />

Be Eclipsed By Private Sector<br />

Quality<br />

If foreign competition were allowed,<br />

what India now thinks of higher quality<br />

would be eclipsed by foreign private<br />

providers. Imagine Oxford in Madras,<br />

or Harvard in Bangalore? For economic<br />

reasons, there is little likelihood that<br />

a high quality provider will open a<br />

multi-faculty university. Most would<br />

open programs highly specific to vocations<br />

such as engineering or business.<br />

However narrow the presence of international<br />

providers would strengthen<br />

the quality of current universities because<br />

of the competition. <strong>The</strong>y would<br />

be more likely to study the syllabi,<br />

student services, faculty productivity<br />

and other indicators of quality if there<br />

is competition than if there is not.<br />

Those who argue for international<br />

trade would say that it is essential for<br />

maintaining the quality of the current<br />

public universities.<br />

International Trade Leads To<br />

‘Knowledge Capitalism’<br />

Critics argue that trade in education<br />

would result in having knowledge pursued<br />

if it results in remuneration and<br />

ignored if it does not. <strong>The</strong>y ask if it is<br />

right for professors to be better rewarded<br />

by virtue of the fact that their<br />

subject is in higher market demand.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y ask what will happen to the pursuit<br />

of truth if it is subject to a price.<br />

Others respond by pointing to the fact<br />

that knowledge can not be immune<br />

from its market value. <strong>The</strong>re is no hiding<br />

the fact that the demand to study<br />

history is less than the demand for<br />

commerce. However, competition need<br />

not lead to a diminishment of history<br />

or other non-revenue producing subject.<br />

<strong>The</strong> major managerial challenge<br />

in any university is how to cross-subsidize<br />

faculties, or transfer resources<br />

90 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

within the institution to support under<br />

resourced but important subjects.<br />

Without cross-subsidization, a university<br />

cannot successfully compete.<br />

Hence they would argue that international<br />

trade and the success of mastering<br />

the modern art of university administration<br />

is the key ingredient<br />

preventing ‘academic capitalism’.<br />

Trade Related Aspects Of<br />

Intellectual Property Rights<br />

(TRIPS) Excludes Low-Income<br />

scholars from successfully<br />

marketing their own curricula<br />

Critics worry that international trade<br />

in education would lower access to local<br />

curricula; international property<br />

rights agreements would protect the<br />

privileged and freeze-out those who<br />

have not yet broken into the market.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y imagine that there will be an avalanche<br />

of foreign books, guidelines,<br />

and syllabi entering India, making it<br />

difficult for local students to be educated<br />

with local materials. Those who<br />

favor open trade say that adhering to<br />

agreements on intellectual property<br />

would increase access to high quality<br />

pedagogical materials because it would<br />

insure income from their sale. In turn<br />

this would increase the incentive to<br />

write new curricula, and would lead to<br />

greater supply, wider choice, and lower<br />

real prices. In their vision, Indian producers<br />

of curricula would compete successfully,<br />

placing the Indian student<br />

consumer at a distinct advantage over<br />

a circumstance in which there would<br />

be no competition.<br />

Privatization Of Education<br />

Finance Will <strong>Dec</strong>rease Access<br />

To A Public Good<br />

Critics argue that international trade<br />

in education will lead to privatization,<br />

meaning that it will lead to an increase<br />

in the proportion of higher education<br />

finance from sources other than government.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y say that the higher the<br />

privatization the lower the access to a<br />

public good. <strong>The</strong>y say that privatization<br />

helps exclude the poor since they<br />

are the ones who least can afford it.<br />

Those who argue in favor of trade<br />

point out that no public good is ‘free’.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y believe that reforms in education<br />

finance will increase the revenue<br />

for both public and private educational<br />

providers; hence, it will increase<br />

the supply and will increase access to<br />

a public good. Recent international<br />

research on stratification and higher<br />

education suggests that higher education<br />

expansion reduces inequality;<br />

greater privatization is associated<br />

with higher levels of expansion and<br />

higher levels of social equity. <strong>The</strong> opposite<br />

is also true: control of expansion<br />

is associated with<br />

a monopoly of state financing,<br />

and hence with greater inequality<br />

of access.<br />

Trade Threatens <strong>The</strong> ‘social<br />

Contract’ Between Generations<br />

If trade leads to greater privatization<br />

(higher portions of the university<br />

budget from sources other than government),<br />

students will have to pay<br />

tuition. To do that they will have to rely<br />

on the generosity of their families,<br />

<strong>The</strong> problem is that the arguments for and against<br />

opening India to higher education trade are generally made<br />

by two divergent groups of stakeholders. Macro-economists<br />

generally favor international competition;<br />

education policy offi cials generally do not<br />

hence the present generation is expected<br />

to finance the education of future<br />

generations; and the social contract is<br />

broken. Proponents of more open trade<br />

counter with a question and a statement.<br />

<strong>The</strong> question is: when did it become<br />

true that the present generation<br />

should not sacrifice to help pay for a<br />

future generation? Isn’t that how generations<br />

have been organized since the<br />

beginning? Also, for those who cannot<br />

afford the tuition there would be scholarship<br />

aid. <strong>The</strong>refore with tuition there<br />

would be more equity, and more equity<br />

would help to strengthen the social<br />

contract between generations.<br />

Trade Jeopardizes Human<br />

Rights Because It Contradicts<br />

National Commitments For<br />

Free Education<br />

Critics point to the <strong>Dec</strong>laration of Human<br />

Rights and other legal contracts<br />

associated with the United Nations to<br />

suggest that if higher education is not<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

91


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

free of private cost it constitutes an<br />

abrogation of human rights. Those who<br />

favor open trade point out that the UN<br />

statements on education apply to mandatory<br />

education but not necessarily<br />

all education. But they also say that<br />

trade would increase human rights because<br />

it would allow access to education<br />

when currently denied, unavailable,<br />

or too costly.<br />

Trade Will Lead To Education<br />

Corruption<br />

Trade leads to greater privatization,<br />

and greater privatization leads to a decline<br />

in professionalism. <strong>The</strong> profit<br />

motive is behind corruption; hence<br />

trade will lead to greater corruption<br />

of education. Proponents of open<br />

trade acknowledge the fact that education<br />

corruption is becoming more<br />

common and is a serious problem.<br />

But they point out that it occurs in<br />

local systems without any education<br />

trade. <strong>The</strong>y also point to recent evidence<br />

suggesting that having international<br />

providers in local education<br />

markets puts a break on corruption.<br />

Students tend to demand an institution<br />

free of corruption and may frequent<br />

international higher education providers<br />

in part because they adhere to<br />

standards of professional conduct in<br />

the foreign nation where they are accredited.<br />

When international providers<br />

of higher education services offer programs<br />

free of corruption local universities<br />

will have to respond with an environment<br />

similarly corruption-free.<br />

Three Universal Ambitions For<br />

Higher Education And A Universal<br />

Dilemma<br />

Today virtually every country has three<br />

ambitions for higher education. First<br />

is the demand for greater access. And<br />

in every country the portion of the age<br />

cohort with access to post secondary<br />

education of some kind is on the<br />

increase.<br />

Second is the ambition to improve<br />

quality. Over the last decade there has<br />

been a revolution in the criteria that<br />

help define quality. Higher education<br />

If foreign competition were allowed, what India now thinks<br />

of higher quality would be eclipsed by foreign private providers.<br />

Imagine Oxford in Madras, or Harvard in Bangalore?<br />

quality now requires electronic modernity<br />

in classrooms, dormitories, libraries,<br />

science laboratories, study halls.<br />

Students are often older, work part<br />

time, and live far away from campus.<br />

High quality syllabi are no longer<br />

based on textbooks but on the most upto-date<br />

information from print and<br />

electronic sources. Students in a modern<br />

university need to have access to<br />

curricular information wherever they<br />

live or travel. Classroom instruction<br />

has changed. Class time is no longer<br />

devoted to providing information for<br />

students; instead it is devoted to the<br />

analysis of information absorbed prior<br />

to class. <strong>The</strong> internet and other forms<br />

of electronic information have changed<br />

the academic library and enhanced its<br />

quality. <strong>The</strong>re is less need for faculty<br />

or students to visit the physical place.<br />

A high quality academic library used<br />

to be defined by the quantity of its<br />

‘holdings’; now it is defined by the<br />

quantity of its access to information.<br />

<strong>The</strong> difference is enormous. Every<br />

high quality academic library has<br />

enough money to join exclusive ‘information<br />

networks’ where holdings are<br />

shared with one another, for a fee.<br />

Networks of academic libraries are<br />

trans-national, and cover university<br />

libraries in Europe, Asia and North<br />

America. Access to information<br />

is what separates the excellent libraries<br />

from the mediocre. All acad<br />

emic services, both teaching and<br />

bibliographic, are delivered through<br />

broadband facilities. Universities with<br />

low bandwidth cannot compete in<br />

quality with universities with<br />

large bandwidth. A third common ambition<br />

is to improve equity, that is, to<br />

offer scholarships and fellowships to<br />

the able students from impoverished<br />

families or from disadvantaged regions.<br />

First class universities will have<br />

enough resources to offer about one<br />

third of the students’ scholarships or<br />

fellowships from their own resources.<br />

Taken together, all three ambitions are<br />

expensive and there are few countries<br />

where all three can be financed out of<br />

public resources alone. With the increase<br />

in student numbers and with<br />

92 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

rising expectations for improvements<br />

in quality and in equity, public resources<br />

are insufficient. <strong>The</strong> scarcity of public<br />

resources is likely to be permanent<br />

and this poses a dilemma: how can<br />

higher education successfully finance<br />

its own objectives, including the<br />

traditional objectives for serving the<br />

public good?<br />

Summary<br />

Many university managers welcome<br />

the freedom to compete and lobby governments<br />

into changing legislation to<br />

make it possible. No rector or university<br />

president who has visited universities<br />

in other countries is unaware of<br />

the responsibilities and privileges of<br />

university managers in less restrictive<br />

environments. Public authorities in India<br />

should not just allow foreign universities<br />

into the country and neglect<br />

to significantly reform the legal environment<br />

in which Indian universities<br />

are asked to operate. That would neither<br />

be fair nor intelligent. Up for consideration<br />

should be changes in the<br />

entire legal structure which would allow<br />

the creation of endowments often<br />

from the overseas Diaspora (something<br />

China has mastered) and a new tax regime<br />

which encourages donations and<br />

gifts to education from both citizens<br />

and firms. Great universities, even<br />

public universities, need not depend on<br />

government financial allocation, but<br />

rather generate their own revenues<br />

though careful management. It is important<br />

to remember that new university<br />

management is the key to success.<br />

Old management styles will likely fail.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are thirty programs offering<br />

PhD degrees in university management<br />

in the United States of America, with<br />

one (Vanderbilt University) which offers<br />

a doctorate in university advancement<br />

(how to raise money). Shouldn’t<br />

similar programs be available in India?<br />

But in essence India has no choice but<br />

to invite competition into higher education.<br />

No university can be competitive<br />

today unless it has access to its<br />

own resources. <strong>The</strong> best universities<br />

have to be wise in the re-allocation of<br />

the resources they raise to help preserve<br />

their public good function. To be<br />

sure, institutions will differ in how successful<br />

they are in financing their own<br />

objectives. Some are slow because they<br />

may not recognize that to be of high<br />

quality, all universities have to take<br />

finance and management into their<br />

own hands.<br />

Some could see this ‘privatization’<br />

trend as being reprehensible, and will<br />

want to call for more piety and a return<br />

to traditional sources of finance, i.e.,<br />

from greater allocations of public expenditures<br />

at the expense of other public<br />

priorities. But others see this trend<br />

as no more than a long overdue professionalization<br />

of higher education in<br />

the legitimate pursuit of excellence.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y do not see this as a threat or as<br />

‘copying of the West’, but rather as a<br />

successful model without geographic<br />

origin in which all higher education<br />

systems must participate in order to<br />

address what is now a universal dilemma<br />

of public resource inadequacy and<br />

high public demand for quality.<br />

References<br />

• Agarwal, Pawan 2006 (May). “Higher<br />

Education in India: <strong>The</strong> Need for<br />

Change,” Working Paper Number<br />

179, ICRIER, New Delhi.<br />

• 2006 (November 11th ) “Higher<br />

Education Policy: Many Contradictions,”<br />

Economic and Political<br />

Weekly. pp. 4645 – 8.<br />

• Heyneman, SP. 1980 “Investment in<br />

Education in India: Unecon<br />

omic?” World Development No. 4 p.<br />

145 – 63<br />

• 1997 “Economics of Education: Disappointments<br />

and Potential,” pp. 25<br />

– 51 in Economics of Human Behaviour<br />

edited by T. Lakshmanasamy<br />

Mumbai: Allied Publishers Ltd.<br />

• 2001 “<strong>The</strong> Growing International<br />

Market for Education Goods and<br />

Services,” International Journal of<br />

Education Development Vol. 21 No.<br />

4 (July), pp. 345 – 61.<br />

• 2006 “Global <strong>Issue</strong>s in Higher Education”<br />

2006 eJournal USA Washington<br />

D.C.: U.S. Department of<br />

State. http://usinfo.state.gov/journals/journals.htm.<br />

• Heyneman, S.P., Anderson, K. H.<br />

and Nuraliyeva, Nazym. 2008 “<strong>The</strong><br />

Cost of Corruption in Higher Education,”<br />

2008 Comparative Education<br />

Review (forthcoming)<br />

• Yossi, Shavit, Arum, Richard and<br />

Gamoran, Adam (eds.) <strong>2007</strong> Stratification<br />

in Higher Education: A<br />

Comparative Study. Stanford, California:<br />

Stanford University Press<br />

• Tilak, Jandhyala B.G. 2005 (<strong>Dec</strong>ember<br />

2 nd .) “Higher Education: A<br />

Public Good or a Commodity for<br />

Trade: Commitment to Higher Education<br />

or Commitment of Higher<br />

Education to Trade?” Barcelona<br />

(Spain): Second Nobel Laureates<br />

Meeting. Global University Network<br />

for Innovation.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

93


Jharna Pathak<br />

Assistant Professor,<br />

Gujarat Institute of Development<br />

Research, Ahmedabad<br />

Water Resources In Gujarat And Role Of Water Markets In Breaking Gridlock In<br />

Water Scarcity – A Replicable Policy Prescription At National Level<br />

"Whiskey is for drinkin'; water<br />

is for fi ghtin'."<br />

-Mark Twain<br />

Conferences like Paris <strong>Dec</strong>laration<br />

(1998), Millennium Development<br />

Goals (2000), Vision 21:<br />

Water for People (2003); and water policies<br />

like National Water Policy (1987 and<br />

2002) and Gujarat 2010 emphasises on access<br />

to hygienic conditions, safe water and<br />

sanitation as fundamental rights to be<br />

achieved for all citizens of Gujarat.<br />

As far as availability of water resources<br />

are concerned, Gujarat can be divided into<br />

three dependent hydro-geological units,<br />

namely South, North Gujarat, Saurashtra<br />

and Kachchh. South Gujarat is better<br />

placed in terms of water resource potential<br />

than other three regions. According to the<br />

available statistics, Gujarat state has experienced<br />

rising population on one hand<br />

(from 19 million in 1951 to 60 million in<br />

2001) and the declining water resources on<br />

the other hand. As a result, the state has<br />

experienced a consistent decline in per<br />

capita availability of water, from more than<br />

2000 cubic meters in 1951 to about 1200<br />

cubic meter at present (Government of<br />

Gujarat, 1999). It has been estimated that<br />

the per capita availability will decline to<br />

910 cubic meters in 2010 and to 800 cubic<br />

meters in 2025 (Patel, 1998). <strong>The</strong> corresponding<br />

figures for India are much higher,<br />

150 cubic meters in 2010 and 1500 cubic<br />

meters in 2025. Let us examine different<br />

components of the total water resource<br />

carefully like groundwater and surface<br />

water resource.<br />

a. Surface Water<br />

As regard to surface water resources, regional<br />

inequalities are high across the regions<br />

(Table-1). <strong>The</strong> table shows that south<br />

Gujarat has 54 percent of the total surface<br />

water potential and 78 percent of the total<br />

utilisable surface water potential of the<br />

state. <strong>The</strong>se percentages are much lower<br />

in the other regions. This is mainly because<br />

of the high rainfall (upto 2000 mm)<br />

and the large number of perennial rivers<br />

in South Gujarat. Saurashtra and Kachchh<br />

have 71 and 97 rivers respectively, but except<br />

for two major rivers, Bhadar and<br />

Shetrunji, all the rivers are small and more<br />

or less seasonal. In the case of South Gu-<br />

94 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1: Region-wise Potential And Development Of Surface Water<br />

In Gujarat<br />

Details<br />

South<br />

Gujarat<br />

North<br />

Gujarat<br />

Saurashtra Kachchh Total<br />

the state during 1984, 1991, and 1997 is<br />

evident in figure 1. Figure 1 shows that the<br />

potential has declined from 20 thousand<br />

mcm per year in 1984 to 16 thousand mcm<br />

Regional Details<br />

per year in 1997, implying about 21 percent<br />

No. Of Districts 7 5 6 1 19<br />

decline. Though there has been a small<br />

increase during 1991-97 (11.16 percent increase)<br />

due to the consecutive good sea-<br />

Area sq. kms 47557 38478 64337 45612 195984<br />

% Area Of State (24%) (20%) (33%) (23%) (100%)<br />

sons, the potential is still much less than<br />

No. Of Rivers 11 6 71 97 185<br />

the same in 1984. <strong>The</strong> same trend is observed<br />

among the districts also; also the<br />

Surface Water Potential<br />

Available Mm3 17510 7940 4550 2430 32430<br />

districts show a decline in the time period<br />

(%) (54%) (25%) (14%) (7%) (100%)<br />

1984-97 (except Amreli, which shows marginal<br />

Utilisable Mm3 13900 2000 1500 400 17800<br />

increase) (Please do refer Figure-2).<br />

(%) (78%) (12%) (8%) (2%) (100%) All except four districts show some increase<br />

Source: NWRD, 1991<br />

in the potential during 1991-97,<br />

jarat, there are 17 rivers and most of them<br />

are perennial. Irrigation increases productivity,<br />

stability and sustainability (Vaidyanathan<br />

(1999); Dhawan (1995). <strong>The</strong> foremost<br />

issue is the availability of irrigation<br />

potential, its creation and utilization. Ultimate<br />

Irrigation Potential (UIP) corresponds<br />

to the gross area that could theoretically<br />

be irrigated in a year on the basis<br />

of the assumed cropping pattern and the<br />

given probability of rainfall. Pushing the<br />

irrigation potential to the ultimate level<br />

resources in the state. This along with second<br />

committee on Estimation of Groundwater<br />

Resources and Irrigation Potential<br />

in 1991 and the third Committee in 1997<br />

throws light on the changing status of<br />

groundwater in the state.<br />

About 90 percent of the groundwater is<br />

used for irrigation in agriculture. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are two types of groundwater schemes:<br />

government tubewells and private tubewells.<br />

<strong>The</strong> total groundwater potential in<br />

thanks to good rainfall (GoG 1999).<br />

Government of Gujarat (1999) in their<br />

study showed the ranges of increase and<br />

decline in groundwater potential across<br />

the different talukas of districts in the<br />

state. <strong>The</strong>y stated that talukas that experienced<br />

the highest declines in groundwater<br />

potential are from North Gujarat<br />

as well as Saurashtra and Kachchh<br />

regions.<br />

Utilisable groundwater resource is equal<br />

to the total groundwater resources<br />

available may be unsustainable in some<br />

cases. Gujarat has utilized its created potential<br />

with almost full utilization (Table-<br />

Table 2: Ultimate Irrigation Potential and<br />

Utilisation (‘000 ha)<br />

minus the provision<br />

for domestic, industrial and<br />

other uses (15 percent of the<br />

2). In as much as most of the available<br />

water resources have been almost fully<br />

exploited, special attention needs to be<br />

paid to management and maximization of<br />

utilization of the available resources.<br />

Details<br />

Utilised Irrigation Potential<br />

Potential created (97-98)<br />

Potential utilised (97-98)<br />

% of potential created to<br />

utilised irrigation potential<br />

Gujarat<br />

6103<br />

3379<br />

3097<br />

55.37<br />

India<br />

139893<br />

92742<br />

82740<br />

66.29<br />

total resources). As seen from<br />

Figure-3, that the total utilisable<br />

groundwater resources<br />

for the state is also declining.<br />

<strong>The</strong> total utilisable water resources<br />

in fact follow a similar<br />

b. Groundwater Resources<br />

Government of Gujarat has started estimating<br />

groundwater resources systematically<br />

since 1984 when the first technical<br />

group was set up to estimate the resources<br />

% of potential utilised to<br />

potential created<br />

Potential used to Utilised<br />

irrigation potential<br />

Gross irrigated area (98-99)<br />

91.65<br />

50.75<br />

3379<br />

89.19<br />

59.13<br />

73007<br />

trend as that of total water resources.<br />

Government of Gujarat<br />

(1999) shows that 76 percent<br />

of the total talukas in the<br />

state register a decrease in utilisable<br />

as well as the irrigation potential of the Source: Department of Agriculture, Government of Gujarat<br />

groundwater resources<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

95


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure-1: Total Groundwater Reserves<br />

Total Groundwater Reserves (mcm/yr)<br />

21000<br />

16000<br />

11000<br />

6000<br />

1000<br />

-4000<br />

Ahmedabad<br />

Amreli<br />

Banaskantha<br />

Baroda<br />

Bhavnagar<br />

Bharuch<br />

Valsad<br />

Dangs<br />

Districts<br />

Source: Narmada and Water Resource Department, 1984, 1991 and 1997<br />

Gandhinagar<br />

Jamnagar<br />

Junagadh<br />

Kheda<br />

Kutch<br />

1984 1991 1997<br />

Panchmahals<br />

Rajkot<br />

Sabarkantha<br />

Surat<br />

Surendranagar<br />

Mehsana<br />

Gujarat<br />

Figure-2: Bar Graph Showing Absolute Percent Change In Groundwater Reserves In Gujarat<br />

Percentage Change in Groundwater<br />

Reserves (%)<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

-20<br />

-40<br />

-60<br />

Ahmedabad<br />

Amreli<br />

Banaskantha<br />

Baroda<br />

Bhavnagar<br />

Bharuch<br />

Valsad<br />

Districts<br />

Dangs<br />

Gandhinagar<br />

Jamnagar<br />

Junagadh<br />

Kheda<br />

Kutch<br />

Panchmahals<br />

1984-1991 1991-1997 1984-1997<br />

Rajkot<br />

Sabarkantha<br />

Surat<br />

Surendranagar<br />

Mehsana<br />

Gujarat<br />

Source: Narmada and Water Resource Department, 1984, 1991 and 1997<br />

in the period 1984-97. For most of the talukas<br />

the decrease has been 25-50 percent<br />

(Government of Gujarat 1999).<br />

Figure 4 showed data relating to the levels<br />

of development of groundwater in districts<br />

of Gujarat during 1984, 1991 and<br />

1997. <strong>The</strong> average level of development<br />

shows a jump from 31 percent in 1984 to<br />

76 percent in 1997, implying an increase of<br />

more than 145 percent during the period.<br />

<strong>The</strong> state as a whole thus falls into “grey”<br />

category which is a serious situation indeed.<br />

This is evident from Map 1.<br />

In short, the long term trends do not indicate<br />

any improvement in the quality<br />

of groundwater in the state. In fact,<br />

they showed negative trends indicating<br />

worsening of the quality of groundwater<br />

96 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure-3: Bar Graph Showing Percentage Change In Utilisable Groundwater Reserves In Gujarat<br />

Percentage Change in total utilisable<br />

groundwater (%)<br />

90<br />

70<br />

50<br />

30<br />

10<br />

-10<br />

-30<br />

-50<br />

Ahmedabad<br />

Amreli<br />

Banaskantha<br />

Baroda<br />

Bhavnagar<br />

Bharuch<br />

Valsad<br />

Dangs<br />

1984-1991<br />

Districts<br />

Gandhinagar<br />

Jamnagar<br />

Junagadh<br />

Kheda<br />

Kutch<br />

Panchmahals<br />

Rajkot<br />

Sabarkantha<br />

Surat<br />

1991-1997 1984-1997<br />

Surendranagar<br />

Mehsana<br />

Gujarat<br />

Source: Narmada and Water Resource Department, 1984, 1991 and 1997<br />

over time.<br />

Government of Gujarat (1999) has projected<br />

the demand and supply of water<br />

resources in the state for 2010 and 2025.<br />

Table 3 is evident of the fact that in the<br />

year 2010 as well as in 2025, South Gujarat<br />

will be the surplus region for water while<br />

North Gujarat, Saurashtra and Kachchh<br />

will be water deficient region. <strong>The</strong> shortage<br />

is expected to increase in both the regions<br />

from 35 percent in 2010 to 83 percent<br />

in 2025 in the case of North Gujarat. This<br />

growth in demand has not been matched<br />

by an increase in supply. <strong>The</strong> problem is<br />

compounded by pollution of water, which<br />

has reduced its suitability for various uses.<br />

At the same time, in traditionally water<br />

intensive sectors of the economy such as<br />

agriculture, costs of irrigation have increased<br />

significantly. Under these circumstances,<br />

it is more important than ever<br />

before to use water efficiently. It is also<br />

necessary to anticipate and address intersectoral<br />

conflicts over allocation and use<br />

of water. <strong>The</strong> standard approach so far has<br />

been to advocate reform of water pricing<br />

across sectors to reflect the scarcity value<br />

of water. This advocacy is based on theoretical<br />

and empirical evidence on the need<br />

and desirability of such reforms including<br />

willing-to-pay studies. Nevertheless, major<br />

users of water (particularly of irrigation<br />

water) have resisted these reforms so far.<br />

Water Markets<br />

In this context, economic theory tells us<br />

that markets increase economic efficiency<br />

by allocating resources to their most valuable<br />

uses. In other words, if certain conditions<br />

are met, markets provide the correct<br />

incentives and lead to efficient resource<br />

use. <strong>The</strong>refore, one way to change the incentives<br />

so that water users support the<br />

reallocation of water and to achieving a<br />

more efficient allocation of water is<br />

through water markets. <strong>The</strong>se allow water<br />

users to buy and sell water, thus changing<br />

the whole incentive structure and breaking<br />

the logjam of water pricing reforms – when<br />

water users can gain from reallocation,<br />

they would be willing to sell water or pay a<br />

higher price for new supplies. This paper<br />

explores the role of water markets, particularly<br />

in the context of India’s water supply<br />

and sanitation sector.<br />

Apart from water markets there already<br />

In Gujarat, the per capita availability will decline to 910<br />

cubic meters in 2010 and to 800 cubic meters in 2025.<br />

<strong>The</strong> corresponding fi gures for India are much higher, 150<br />

cubic meters in 2010 and 1500 cubic meters in 2025<br />

exist numerous non-market mechanisms<br />

for allocating water in most countries.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se usufructuary rights to water have<br />

evolved either explicitly through laws and<br />

regulations or implicitly through conventions.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se water rights are generally<br />

based on one of three systems: first-come,<br />

first-served allocation (also known as<br />

prior appropriation rights), allocation<br />

based on proximity to flows (or riparian<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

97


Ahmedabad<br />

Amreli<br />

Banaskantha<br />

Baroda<br />

Bhavnagar<br />

Bharuch<br />

Vaksad<br />

Dangs<br />

Gandhinagar<br />

Jamnagar<br />

Junagadh<br />

Kheda<br />

Kutch<br />

Panchmahals<br />

Rajkot<br />

Sabarkantha<br />

Surat<br />

Surendranagar<br />

Mehsana<br />

Gujarat<br />

REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

rights) and public allocation (Sampath<br />

1992, Holden and Thobani 1996, Haddad<br />

2000). Whereas queuing for water is the<br />

basic approach of the prior appropriation<br />

doctrine, the location of one’s land determines<br />

water rights under the riparian doctrine.<br />

Under this approach whoever owns<br />

land along (above) the water has the right<br />

to ownership/reasonable use of the water.<br />

Finally, public allocation involves publicly<br />

administered distribution of water. “Under<br />

this system, public authorities decide<br />

how to allocate water using guidelines or<br />

laws establishing priorities and often specify<br />

the uses to which the water can be put.”<br />

(Holden and Thobani op. cit. p. 2) Most<br />

developing countries follow variants of the<br />

last approach where essentially the rights<br />

are allocated free – though there may be<br />

a charge for water use (typically based on<br />

the amount of irrigated area), the water<br />

rights themselves are obtained without<br />

charge. <strong>The</strong> track record, however, of administered<br />

systems of water allocation has<br />

not been impressive - across different systems<br />

and states in India, governments,<br />

however experience shortage of funds to<br />

carry out necessary R&R works of the<br />

system. At many places, canals were laid<br />

at uneven level and structures were in bad<br />

shape, which results in frequent breaching<br />

of canals. Consequently, reliability of water<br />

at scheduled time was not taken care<br />

off. Given these problems, Rosegrant and<br />

Binswanger (1994) have suggested that<br />

there may be a better way to achieve efficient<br />

allocation of water by changing incentives<br />

so that users support the efforts<br />

to reallocate water. <strong>The</strong>y argue that if water<br />

markets are established where water is<br />

scarce, then users can buy and sell water<br />

or pay a higher price for new supplies.<br />

While this is well known, the important<br />

point to note here is that none of these<br />

systems fulfil the conditions for well-defined<br />

property rights to water, which in<br />

turn are essential for water markets to exist.<br />

In this context, the question could well<br />

be asked, “Why not use administered efficiency-based<br />

pricing of water as an intermediate<br />

policy between managed quantity<br />

allocation and water markets?” <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are three reasons why water markets could<br />

be preferred to administer efficiency pricing<br />

(i.e., pricing marginal units of water at<br />

their marginal cost). First is the reduction<br />

in information costs – whereas it is theoretically<br />

possible to devise and implement<br />

a system of administered prices which<br />

would lead to efficient allocation of water,<br />

the information requirements are demanding<br />

and may require experimentation<br />

by trial and error. Second and perhaps<br />

more important, if the value of prevailing<br />

usufructuary water rights (formal or informal)<br />

has already been capitalised into<br />

the value of irrigated land, then imposition<br />

of administered pricing is perceived<br />

by right holders as expropriation of those<br />

rights. In effect, this would result in a<br />

capital loss for irrigated farms. This could<br />

explain the strong resistance by these<br />

groups to establishing administered efficiency<br />

prices. Finally, the administrative<br />

solution presumes “far-seeing,incorrupti<br />

Figure-4: Bar And Line Graph Showing In Level Of Groundwater Development<br />

200<br />

150<br />

Level of development (%)<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

Source: Narmada and Water Resource Department, 1984, 1991 and 1997<br />

Districts<br />

1984 1991 1997<br />

98 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Map-1: Ground Water Categorisation<br />

Source: NWR and WSD, Government of Gujarat<br />

ble,influence-free” administrative bodies<br />

that are able to design and implement the<br />

‘correct’ prices. In practice, this may often<br />

not be the case: these bodies could be captured<br />

by interest groups or they may be<br />

short-sighted and unable to estimate future<br />

demand, or they may be unable to set<br />

and collect appropriate water charges.<br />

Advocates of administrative approaches,<br />

however, often ignore these problems focusing<br />

at the same time on imperfections<br />

of markets that supposedly reduce the efficacy<br />

of market-based solutions! In effect,<br />

if two second best states are being compared<br />

it may be difficult to order them.<br />

<strong>The</strong> numerous informal water markets<br />

existing in North Gujarat (tubewell companies)<br />

and South Gujarat (illegal water<br />

lifting from canal) suggest that water users<br />

will buy and sell water even if it is illegal or<br />

discouraged by the government.<br />

Even though water markets are believed<br />

to change incentives for water user and<br />

improve water allocation, there are number<br />

of constraints that may prevent introduction<br />

of water markets. For formal water<br />

markets to work, one key component is for<br />

users to have some type of water right or<br />

use right they can buy or sell. This may<br />

create a serious problem not only because<br />

water rights may be difficult to establish,<br />

but also because public water agencies feel<br />

they will lose a great deal of power if they<br />

allocate water rights to users. If water users<br />

have rights, this means that system operators<br />

have the responsibility to deliver<br />

water to the users more or less when the<br />

users want it. In contrast, if a government<br />

agency holds the water rights, they can dictate<br />

farmers the conditions under which<br />

they will receive water including in some<br />

cases, necessary side payments from farmers.<br />

If water rights are made tradable, this<br />

creates an even greater dilemma for government<br />

agencies. To prevent losing control<br />

over tradable water rights, Comision<br />

Nacional del Agua in Mexico and some of<br />

the water districts of western United States<br />

limit trading among water districts. A water<br />

user must obtain special government<br />

approval to sell water outside the jurisdiction<br />

and any profits from the sale must accrue<br />

to district and not the seller. This, of<br />

course, discourages interdistrict trading,<br />

but reduces the chance that trades will<br />

have third party effect. Such instances of<br />

formal water markets in India are non-existent.<br />

Experience of Mexico, Chile, United<br />

States, France, where water markets<br />

exist in one form or the other, assists in<br />

understanding organisational problems of<br />

water trading through market. First is the<br />

resistance to water trading between or<br />

among district or jurisdiction. Second is<br />

the problem of establishing water rights<br />

and giving the users more control over water.<br />

Other problems which raise the transaction<br />

cost of water trading include legal<br />

challenges by third parties who feel they<br />

In the formal water markets water rights may be very diffi<br />

cult to establish. What's more, public water agencies feel<br />

that they will lose a great deal of power if they allocate<br />

water rights/user rights to users<br />

might be damaged by a transfer, the lack<br />

of sufficient infrastructure to transfer water<br />

among potential buyers, and lack of an<br />

effective means for verifying and enforcing<br />

water rights.<br />

Establishing Water Markets<br />

Before we determine whether there is a<br />

need of reducing transaction cost and<br />

methods to do so, there is a need to understand<br />

the past experience of markets for<br />

allocating water resource. This is done<br />

with the assumption that if a country has<br />

experience with water markets, then it is<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

99


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table-3: Details Of Availability And Requirement Of Water Resources In Gujarat<br />

Details<br />

Availability Of<br />

Water (mcm)<br />

Requirement Of<br />

Water (mcm)<br />

Surplus (mcm)<br />

Deficit Of Water Resources<br />

(mcm)<br />

As Per <strong>The</strong> Year 2010<br />

South Gujarat 24750 14390 10360 -<br />

Saurashtra & Kachchh 9740 13100 - 3360 (34.49)<br />

North Gujarat 10400 17400 - 7000 (67.31)<br />

Total 44890 44890 10360 10360<br />

As Per <strong>The</strong> Year 2025<br />

South Gujarat 28187 15500 12687 -<br />

Saurashtra & Kachchh 10170 14440 - 4269 (41.97)<br />

North Gujarat 10212 18630 - 8418 (82.43)<br />

Total 48570 48570 12687 12687<br />

Source: NWR and WSD, Government of Gujarat<br />

Note: figures in parentheses indicate the percentage shortage<br />

likely that water will be one of the goods<br />

that can be allocated using market forces.<br />

At least in the case of markets for irrigation<br />

water it appears that both formal and<br />

informal systems of water system are at<br />

work. In India, other than recent intervention<br />

in Maharashtra, there is a dearth of<br />

the experience of the formal market systems.<br />

But numerous countries experience<br />

with water markets are wide ranging, with<br />

most of the formal water markets in North<br />

and South America. For example in several<br />

areas of Chile, the legalisation of water<br />

trading and recording of water use<br />

rights were sufficient to foster an active<br />

formal water markets with relatively low<br />

transaction costs. <strong>The</strong> combination of effective<br />

water user association and well developed<br />

irrigation infrastructure allowed<br />

these farmers to easily trade water<br />

throughout the system including trades<br />

with the urban section (Hearne 1995).<br />

Garrido (1997) shows the economic gains,<br />

when trading is restricted to an individual<br />

water district. In contrast, if trades are allowed<br />

among communities that are subject<br />

to different supply constraints and drought<br />

conditions, the gains from trade can be<br />

substantial. As per his estimates, inter<br />

community trading results in 50 percent<br />

gain. In their analysis of selected water<br />

markets in Chile, Hearne and Easter<br />

(1997) found trading both within and between<br />

sectors. For permanent transactions,<br />

they felt the importance of well defined<br />

water use rights.<br />

In the case of informal markets in Asia,<br />

Shah (1993) finds that in areas with dependable<br />

groundwater recharge, the selling<br />

of tubewell water has benefited a wide<br />

range of farmers by allowing them to increase<br />

crop production and income.<br />

Groundwater markets play a major role in<br />

boosting agricultural production and returns<br />

to farmers from crop production.<br />

Saleth (1997) estimates that 20 percent of<br />

14 million pump sets are likely to be involved<br />

in water trading. This means that<br />

water markets are providing water for<br />

about 6 million hectares or 15 percent of<br />

the total area irrigated by groundwater. In<br />

Pakistan, 21 percent of the total area irrigated<br />

is from groundwater. Meinzen-Dick<br />

(1997) found that water markets increased<br />

the availability of water and the reliability<br />

of supplies. Study by Pathak (<strong>2007</strong>) showed<br />

that with greater water supplies and reliability,<br />

yield and returns increased for those<br />

who purchased water particularly for those<br />

who also had access to canal water. However,<br />

the highest yields and income was<br />

still found among farmers who owned<br />

tubewells and had access to canal water.<br />

Even though groundwater markets appear<br />

to be growing rapidly and providing a more<br />

assured source of water to many farmers,<br />

a number of concerns have been raised<br />

about the performance of informal water<br />

markets. Some of the problems are the<br />

following:<br />

• high water demand and declining<br />

groundwater level.<br />

• water rights are not well defined.<br />

• lead to over drafting of aquifers whichcauses<br />

decline in groundwater supplies.<br />

• potential for monopoly pricing and discrimination.<br />

Conclusion<br />

This paper shows that water markets have<br />

100 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

been in operation in many parts of the<br />

world including India. Although informal<br />

water markets have been in existence for<br />

decades, formal markets with clearly assigned,<br />

private and transferable water<br />

rights are of relatively recent origin. In<br />

Chile, Western USA and Australia, where<br />

there are developed formal water markets,<br />

there have been significant gains from water<br />

trading, particularly from trades between<br />

agricultural and urban users as water<br />

gets reallocated to more productive<br />

uses. In many instances, water trading has<br />

alleviated water shortages. International<br />

experience also shows that formal and developed<br />

water markets strengthen the incentives<br />

for conservation and more efficient<br />

use of water. For example, farmers<br />

have responded by switching to water-saving<br />

technologies and high-value, less water<br />

intensive crops. <strong>The</strong> Indian experience<br />

with water markets has been positive, although<br />

there have been only limited gains<br />

as markets have remained informal, localised<br />

and primitive. Thus, while these markets<br />

have led to some efficiency gains and<br />

have expanded the scope for many resource-poor<br />

farmers to access irrigation,<br />

inter-sectoral water transfers have not<br />

taken place so far. <strong>The</strong> current challenge<br />

in India is therefore to establish formal<br />

water markets, which will expand the scope<br />

of trading and make inter-sectoral water<br />

transfers possible. Further, since formal<br />

water markets have a legal basis, effective<br />

regulation can be designed to address the<br />

issue of ecological sustainability. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

markets will be of significant relevance to<br />

the urban sector, which has been suffering<br />

from acute shortages of water, but has not<br />

been able to access informal markets. A<br />

formal water market has the potential to<br />

provide low cost solutions to augmentation<br />

of water supply relatively quickly. With respect<br />

to further steps, it is desirable to<br />

make an indepth analysis on various important<br />

questions like<br />

• What are the legitimate users that need<br />

to be protected in water transaction?<br />

• Should third parties have to take into<br />

account the economic losses caused by<br />

not allowing the transfer?<br />

References<br />

• Dhawan, B.D. (1995), “Groundwater<br />

depletion, Land Degradation and Irrigated<br />

Agriculture in India. New Delhi:<br />

Commonwealth Publishers<br />

• Easter, K. William, Ariel Dinar and<br />

Mark W. Rosegrant. 1998. “Water Markets:<br />

Transaction Costs and Institutional<br />

Options,” in K.W. Easter et al. (eds.),<br />

Markets for Water: Potential and<br />

• Performance, Kluwer, Dordrecht, <strong>The</strong><br />

Netherlands.<br />

• Shah, Tushaar. 1993. Groundwater Market<br />

and Irrigation Development, Mumbai,<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

• Hearne R., 1995. <strong>The</strong> Market Allocation<br />

of Natural Resources: Transaction<br />

of Water Use in Chile. Ph.D Dissertation,<br />

Department of Applied Economics,<br />

University of Minnesota.<br />

• Garrido, (1997). An Economic Analysis<br />

of Water Markets within the Spanish<br />

Agricultural Sector: Can they Provide<br />

Substantial Benefits? In K.W. Easter et<br />

al. (eds.), Markets for Water: Potential<br />

and Performance, Kluwer, Dordrecht,<br />

<strong>The</strong> Netherlands.<br />

• Government of India. (2002): “National<br />

Water Policy”, Ministry of Water Resources,<br />

New Delhi, India<br />

• Government of India. (1987): “National<br />

Water Policy”, Ministry of Water Resources,<br />

New Delhi, India<br />

• Government of Gujarat. (1999): “White<br />

Paper on Water Policy”, Ministry of<br />

Water Resources, Government of Gujarat,<br />

Gujarat.<br />

• Haddad, Brent M. 2000. Rivers of<br />

Gold: Designing Markets to Allocate<br />

Water in California, Island Press,<br />

Washington, DC.<br />

• Hearne and Easter (1997). <strong>The</strong> Economic<br />

and Financial Gains from Water<br />

Markets in Chile. In K.W. Easter et al.<br />

(eds.), Markets for Water: Potential and<br />

Performance, Kluwer, Dordrecht, <strong>The</strong><br />

Netherlands.<br />

• Holden, Paul and Mateen Thobani.<br />

1996. “Tradable Water Rights: A Property<br />

Rights Approach to Resolving Water<br />

Shortages and Promoting Investment”,<br />

Policy Research Working Paper<br />

-1627, World Bank, Washington, DC.<br />

• Meinzen-Dick (1997) Groundwater<br />

Markets in Pakistan: Institutional Development<br />

and Productivity Impacts. In<br />

K.W. Easter et al. (eds.), Markets for<br />

Water: Potential and Performance, Kluwer,<br />

Dordrecht, <strong>The</strong> Netherlands.<br />

• Pathak Jharna (<strong>2007</strong>). Irrigation Management<br />

Transfer: Problems and Policies.<br />

A Ph.D thesis submitted to Gujarat<br />

University.<br />

• Rosegrant, Mark W. and Hans P. Binswanger.<br />

1994. “Markets in Tradable<br />

Water Rights: Potential for Efficiency<br />

Gains in Developing Country Water<br />

Resource Allocation,” World Development,<br />

22(11): 1613-1625.<br />

• Sampath, R.K. 1992. “<strong>Issue</strong>s in Irrigation<br />

Pricing in Developing Countries”,<br />

World Development, 20(7): 967-977.<br />

• Vaidyanathan, A. (1999). Water Resource<br />

Management: Institutions and<br />

Irrigation Development in India. New<br />

Delhi: Oxford University Press.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

101


V. Shunmugam D.G. Prasad<br />

Chief Economist<br />

Economist<br />

Multi Commodity Exchange Of India Ltd., Mumbai<br />

Commodity Futures: A Catalyst For<br />

Agricultural Development<br />

“Everything else can wait but<br />

not agriculture.”<br />

-Pandit Jawaharlal Nehru<br />

Historically, India has been considered<br />

an agrarian society;<br />

the fact that the basics of our<br />

culture and lifestyle have been derived<br />

from it stands testimony to our historical<br />

dependence on agriculture. Of late, the<br />

relative share of agriculture during early<br />

1990s declined significantly due to its<br />

sagging growth and leaping progress in<br />

the other sectors. Currently, services<br />

sector had become the largest contributor<br />

to the GDP and the agriculture sector<br />

had become the least contributor<br />

with its share of below 20 percent. <strong>The</strong><br />

reality is India cannot afford to neglect<br />

the agriculture sector and back pedal on<br />

reforms related to this sector with about<br />

two thirds of its population still directly<br />

or indirectly dependent on it, especially<br />

with apparent imbalances in the commodities<br />

economy making the policy<br />

choices narrow for the decision makers.<br />

At this point in time the high agricultural<br />

commodities prices combined with<br />

poor supply chain efficiency in the country<br />

affecting all sections of the society<br />

especially with the common man bearing<br />

the brunt of it. Despite the reports<br />

of high commodity prices at the retail<br />

end, farmers today are still complaining<br />

about stagnant prices at the market they<br />

sell. This could lead to the risk of many<br />

shifting their profession, often abandoning<br />

farming activities.<br />

Agrarian Challenges<br />

At the current situation of limited availability<br />

of resources, the country, indeed,<br />

requires a paradigm change from increase<br />

in production to improvement in<br />

the input-use efficiency, to enhance our<br />

competency in the agriculture sector.<br />

Given the current constraints of poor<br />

realization from agriculture and hence<br />

their poor investment in technology and<br />

lack of investment in infrastructure<br />

leading to the operation of a vicious cycle<br />

in the farming sector. This is not to<br />

say that those who command resources<br />

for example the large landholders were<br />

able to overcome the operation of this<br />

vicious cycle with their sheer bargaining<br />

102<br />

THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

power and reinvestment of profits back<br />

into farming. However, a large chunk of<br />

medium, small, and marginal farmers<br />

are still to come out of the clutches of<br />

the operation of this vicious cycle. Hence<br />

the need of the hour is to provide market<br />

based solutions to these farmers that<br />

could address the problems associated<br />

with inefficient and opaque markets;<br />

poor infrastructure including input supply<br />

systems, low credibility among the<br />

lending institutions, poor infrastructure<br />

especially in terms of transportation,<br />

warehouses, standardization and quality<br />

testing facilities, low value addition and<br />

a rather weak agricultural extension system,<br />

among others. Though there are<br />

production related issues that would<br />

need to be addressed, we believe it could<br />

be effectively tackled by equipping the<br />

farmers through market based empowerment.<br />

Remedies for these challenges<br />

can be approached by classifying them<br />

into two broad categories — marketing<br />

system ills and infrastructure challenges.<br />

As for addressing the infrastructure<br />

challenges, increased private investment<br />

could well be the answer, at least for<br />

overcoming them partially in commercially<br />

profitable areas. However, in the<br />

current marketing system wherein a<br />

large number of middlemen are involved<br />

in the supply chain, prices are largely<br />

determined by traders with immediate<br />

consideration to their profits. This eventually<br />

leads to lesser returns on agriculture<br />

making private investments in agriculture<br />

least remunerative.<br />

<strong>The</strong> current marketing system in the<br />

country leads to large price spreads suppressing<br />

the prices of commodities actually<br />

offered to the producers while inflating<br />

the prices that the end consumers<br />

are made to pay which often has no relation<br />

to the value addition that the products<br />

had undergone. This could be attributable<br />

to lack of transparency in the<br />

market and an inefficient price discovery<br />

mechanism. Farmers in most of the rural<br />

areas arrive at the market uninformed<br />

of the market situation due to lack of effective/reliable<br />

market information dissemination<br />

systems. Adding to their<br />

woes, farmers more often take sowing<br />

decisions based on the prevailing prices<br />

(unaware of the future price directions),<br />

which would most often prove them<br />

wrong. Thus, remunerative prices for<br />

their produce remain ever elusive to<br />

farmers and remain a major cause of the<br />

current stagnation in agricultural<br />

growth. In other words, the lack of motivational<br />

factor i.e. dwindling returns<br />

to labor and investment is the key reason<br />

for this stagnancy. Increased profits<br />

would be possible only if farmers were<br />

provided fair prices that are reflective of<br />

their supply and demand.<br />

Reforms On Anvil: Move towards<br />

Market Based Mechanism<br />

In a perfect market, price is determined<br />

by the forces of demand and supply (fundamentals).<br />

Frequent changes in the<br />

fundamentals lead to increased price<br />

volatility. In order to make the agriculture<br />

sector more vibrant the Indian Government<br />

allowed national online futures<br />

trading in commodities during 2003.<br />

<strong>The</strong> objective was to ensure stabilization<br />

of prices of agricultural products and<br />

provide farmers with alternative markets<br />

that could equip them in taking the right<br />

decisions in sowing, harvesting, and selling<br />

of the right crop at the right market<br />

value at the right time. Emergence of<br />

futures trading in this context, following<br />

the Government’s initiative, which serves<br />

the above needs is of great significance<br />

as a remedy to the ills in the existing<br />

marketing system.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Advent Of Futures Trading<br />

Introduction of national online commodity<br />

derivatives trading would remain<br />

the most significant development in the<br />

history of Indian commodity markets as<br />

the earlier exchanges remained regional<br />

Existence of the three national exchanges had brought in<br />

revolutionary changes in the Indian commodity markets<br />

by bringing in spatial integration and temporal price discovery<br />

for commodities at the national level.<br />

both in terms of their participation and<br />

products. Currently, there are three national<br />

exchanges, and twenty two regional<br />

exchanges that are operating in the<br />

country. Existence of the three national<br />

exchanges had brought in revolutionary<br />

changes in the Indian commodity markets<br />

by bringing in spatial integration<br />

and temporal price discovery for commodities<br />

at the national level.<br />

Undoubtedly, the revival of commodity<br />

futures trading in India has led to a<br />

reduction in daily price volatility of various<br />

commodities in the domestic spot<br />

markets. Table - I provides a comparative<br />

account of price volatility of three<br />

select agri-commodities in the spot markets<br />

before and after the introduction of<br />

futures trading at the Multi Commodity<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

103


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table I: Volatility Of Spot Prices<br />

Commodity<br />

Pre MCX futures<br />

(Percentage)<br />

Exchange of India Ltd. (MCX), the<br />

country’s No. 1 commodity derivatives<br />

exchange (in <strong>2007</strong>) located in Mumbai.<br />

It was found that there has been a<br />

marked reduction in daily price volatility<br />

in all these three commodities. <strong>The</strong><br />

finding corroborates that the resurrection<br />

of futures trading has indeed contributed<br />

to increased stability in agricultural<br />

markets, which in turn has helped<br />

Indian farmers receive a stable income<br />

besides making efficient sell/store decisions.<br />

Availability of future price signals<br />

also reduced the pre and post harvest<br />

differences in prices avoiding the rush of<br />

arrivals immediately post-harvest.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Drive Behind And <strong>The</strong><br />

Benefits Of Futures Markets<br />

Virtually all agricultural commodities<br />

in India have a long supply chain with a<br />

number of middlemen performing the<br />

roles and functions of the brokers, commission<br />

agents, processors, wholesalers,<br />

retailers, etc., and thus making their<br />

marketing costlier that their production<br />

at times. In almost all the cases, the middlemen-levied<br />

charges do not really mirror<br />

the true value of the economic function<br />

they perform in taking a given<br />

commodity from farm gate to the consumer’s<br />

plate. Thus the existing markets<br />

Post MCX futures<br />

(Percentage)<br />

Wheat 4.80 3.49<br />

Tur 1.47 2.4<br />

Urad 2.58 1.8<br />

Source: Delhi Wholesale Market, CMIE, www.cmie.com/database/services<br />

Note: Daily prices were considered.<br />

Post futures period include inception of specific contracts on MCX platform<br />

till June 2006 and corresponding period before inception of futures contracts<br />

was considered for pre-futures.<br />

had a biased marketing<br />

system offering the producer<br />

the lowest while<br />

charging the consumer<br />

the highest. Obviously,<br />

such an undesirable system<br />

cannot continue for<br />

ever and the stakeholders<br />

would look for a way out<br />

— an efficient market<br />

that enables everybody to<br />

participate in a price discovery mechanism<br />

that is fully transparent and yet is<br />

capable of bringing the cost of the value<br />

chain down to the minimum. Here is<br />

where the birth of futures exchanges<br />

proved out to be the panacea for many<br />

of the above ills faced by the physical<br />

markets. <strong>The</strong>se exchanges performed<br />

the function of advance price discovery,<br />

increasing the efficiency of the markets<br />

by helping them streamline prices to reflect<br />

on the commodity fundamentals<br />

rather than reflecting the profit making<br />

initiatives of the private players in the<br />

value chain. That apart, commodity exchanges<br />

also facilitate private participation<br />

in the market related infrastructure<br />

investments. <strong>The</strong> exchanges’ efforts in<br />

providing effective collateral management,<br />

improved warehousing for<br />

agri-products, widening the network of<br />

quality certification and product standardization<br />

agencies, and providing better<br />

logistics solutions have already<br />

brought in the much needed efficiencies<br />

in the ecosystem.<br />

Commodity Exchanges As Catalysts<br />

Of Agricultural Marketing<br />

Infrastructure Development<br />

MCX took various initiatives to launch<br />

two major infrastructure projects — Na-<br />

tional Spot Exchange Ltd. (NSEL) and<br />

National Bulk Handling Corporation<br />

Ltd. (NBHC). NSEL would provide a<br />

national-level electronic platform for<br />

spot trading in agricultural commodities<br />

by integrating all the physical markets<br />

into a common national market. This<br />

initiative is meant to empower rural India<br />

to usher in the next Green Revolution<br />

by harnessing technology. <strong>The</strong> effective<br />

co-existence of the spot and<br />

futures markets in the ecosystem will<br />

surely help in coming up with fair price<br />

discovery empowering Indian farmers in<br />

several ways, including leading them to<br />

the use of improved technology, thus,<br />

catalyzing rapid growth in agricultural<br />

production. Services that NBHC – the<br />

delivery arm of MCX extend include<br />

warehousing and bulk handling of agricultural<br />

commodities by managing a<br />

chain of accredited warehouses across<br />

the country, grading and assaying, quality<br />

systems for storage and protection,<br />

offloading and disposal services, demating<br />

of warehouse receipts, etc. In a nutshell,<br />

NBHC’s existence is slowly leading<br />

to awareness in the ecosystem regarding<br />

futures trading, collateral management<br />

systems, warehouse receipt financing,<br />

quality and standards, etc., leading to an<br />

overall improvement in the ecosystem.<br />

Thus, commodity exchanges are the seed<br />

sown to provide a new direction to agricultural<br />

productivity and returns to agriproducts<br />

by improving the marketing<br />

systems of the country with participatory<br />

efforts from all the stakeholders in the<br />

system. Exchanges ensured sustained<br />

and increased returns to agricultural<br />

products through transparent and participatory<br />

price discovery process. Besides,<br />

they also create an environment<br />

104<br />

THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

where farmers have a choice — many options<br />

of selling their commodities such<br />

as spot markets and futures markets.<br />

Also, as futures trading is done at the<br />

national level in an electronic format,<br />

integration of banks and institutional<br />

traders on the commodities marketplace<br />

creates several institutional options for<br />

farmers. Thus, with the introduction of<br />

national online commodity exchanges,<br />

the seed for democratic reforms in market<br />

in its process and its infrastructure<br />

has been sown and only time and appropriate<br />

nurturing by supporting policies<br />

can tell us how far these could go.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Global Impact Of Domestic<br />

Commexes<br />

<strong>The</strong> establishment of national commodity<br />

exchanges in India is creating a nearperfect<br />

market situation, with a much<br />

wider participation from the market<br />

ecosystem during local and global market<br />

timings. Feeling the necessity for<br />

aligning themselves with the international<br />

markets in globally traded commodities<br />

where there are international<br />

linkages, the domestic commodity exchanges<br />

make use of maximum possible<br />

hours of operation unlike their equity<br />

counterparts in the country by bridging<br />

the time zones of Tokyo and New York<br />

while passing on the price signals to the<br />

European markets. In fact, given the<br />

country’s potential share in global supply<br />

and demand, India has the potential<br />

to become the price-setter in about seventeen<br />

commodities and thus, emerge as<br />

a dominant player in the global markets.<br />

Of late, with the constant strengthening<br />

of the futures market, India has started<br />

emitting price signals to linked global<br />

markets in those commodities having<br />

international linkages. In commodities<br />

such as gold, of which India is the world’s<br />

largest importer and consumer, and<br />

chana, of which the country is the largest<br />

producer/consumer,India, with the<br />

emergence of futures markets, is slowly<br />

gaining the rightful place in the world<br />

markets by setting the prices. <strong>The</strong> prices<br />

disseminated by Indian exchanges have<br />

become increasingly acceptable to the<br />

business and farmer communities as<br />

they are discovered after assimilating<br />

the information available to<br />

the participants.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Global Commodity Arena<br />

And MCX’s Role<br />

MCX has made its mark in the global<br />

commodities exchange industry by becoming<br />

the largest silver exchange (in<br />

terms of the number of contracts traded),<br />

the second largest in natural gas,<br />

the third largest bullion exchange after<br />

NYMEX & TOCOM, and also the third<br />

largest exchange in crude oil among the<br />

top 10 commodity derivatives exchanges<br />

in the world in <strong>2007</strong> with only retail, and<br />

corporate participation and without<br />

products other than futures on its platform.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Exchange believes that as India<br />

becomes a truly global economy, it<br />

would offer greater potential in commodities,<br />

as regulatory and market impediments<br />

that prevent building up of<br />

volumes in the exchanges would get dissolved<br />

and the exchanges would be left<br />

to their own to prove their mettle. <strong>The</strong><br />

price correlation in the globally traded<br />

commodities indicates that the prices<br />

discovered in the MCX had more than<br />

90 percent correlation with their international<br />

benchmarks suggesting that the<br />

prices moved in tandem with the international<br />

markets, following a right combination<br />

of domestic and international<br />

Given India's potential share in global supply and demand,<br />

India has the potential to become the price-setter in about<br />

seventeen commodities and thus, emerge as a dominant<br />

player in the global markets<br />

fundamentals. This makes the domestic<br />

online exchanges a cost-effective better<br />

alternative to the domestic participants<br />

particularly for the SME companies,<br />

with enough liquidity as found in the International<br />

benchmark exchanges. However,<br />

the potential in other commodities<br />

and for reaching out to the end-users is<br />

yet to be harnessed, pending various<br />

regulatory reforms.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Road Ahead<br />

<strong>The</strong> proposed amendments to the Forward<br />

Contracts Regulation Act is likely<br />

to originate a slew of changes in the<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

105


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

commodity derivatives ecosystem. Firstly,<br />

the functional autonomy of the Forward<br />

Markets Commission (FMC) – the<br />

regulator for the commodity markets, as<br />

proposed in the FCRA would make it<br />

more vibrant in the eyes of the market<br />

participants and policy makers and other<br />

regulators such as RBI and SEBI.<br />

This could help facilitate entry of other<br />

participants such as banks and mutual<br />

funds as their regulators namely RBI<br />

and SEBI respectively develop confidence<br />

in the functioning and regulation<br />

of the markets. Further, new products<br />

such as options will offer the stakeholders<br />

(least risk appetite) with one more<br />

instrument for risk management. This<br />

could be more suited to farmers participation<br />

as they are less risk-hungry and<br />

could help them overcome the liquidity<br />

problems that they would otherwise face<br />

in the futures instrument in meeting the<br />

daily MTM margin requirements. <strong>The</strong><br />

entry of banks, MFs and foreign institutional<br />

investors (FIIs) would enhance<br />

the liquidity and professionalism in the<br />

markets and thereby bolstering the efficiency<br />

of the Indian commodity markets,<br />

which is essentially needed at a time<br />

when the country’s market is being<br />

opened to traders and investors from<br />

across the borders. Perhaps, with banks<br />

allowed it could even facilitate farmer’s<br />

participation helping them overcome the<br />

present hurdles in their participation.<br />

<strong>The</strong> permission to launch index-based<br />

instruments following the amendment to<br />

FCRA would open the doors for exchanges<br />

to come out with derivatives<br />

such as index linked futures and options,<br />

sector based derivatives, and weather<br />

derivatives. While rocketing in the current<br />

high-growth trajectory, the domestic<br />

exchanges have also effectively adopted<br />

global best practices from the<br />

<strong>The</strong> permission to launch index-based instruments would<br />

open the doors for exchanges to come out with derivatives<br />

such as index linked futures and options, sector based<br />

derivatives, and weather derivatives<br />

benchmark exchanges to leap forward<br />

and attain higher levels of efficiency and<br />

trading volumes. In turn, these efficient<br />

marketplaces with right products and<br />

participation are likely to transform the<br />

economy’s competitiveness and help<br />

raise the global competitiveness of Indian<br />

products and services This would<br />

help India to become an efficient global<br />

manufacturing hub and shore up its performance<br />

on the external trade front.<br />

Given all the positive effects of the futures<br />

exchanges to the economy and the<br />

markets, the growth in the commodities<br />

sector has been unsupported unlike its<br />

financial derivatives counterpart.<br />

All in all, one must acknowledge that<br />

given the current trend in globalization<br />

of economies, competitiveness would<br />

remain a major factor affecting the performance<br />

of many of these economies<br />

and may even determine their survival<br />

in a more liberalized trade environment.<br />

As production determines part of the<br />

costs of the product or a service so is<br />

its marketing cost. <strong>The</strong> more efficiently<br />

commodities are marketed in an<br />

economy could solve a part of the<br />

problem that India is facing in moving<br />

up the ladder in its trading competitiveness.<br />

As goods and services becomes<br />

cheaper due to reduced cost of<br />

marketing it, such as through reduced<br />

wastages through quality production,<br />

standardization and grading, and scientific<br />

storage, paying the intermediary<br />

the right value for the services that<br />

he renders to the marketing of the<br />

commodity. Increased marketing efficiency<br />

coupled with increased production<br />

efficiency is likely to help India remain<br />

competitive. For increased market<br />

efficiency, it is necessary that there are<br />

efficient futures markets that help the<br />

producers and value chain players take<br />

effective production and marketing decisions<br />

to reduce the cost of marketing.<br />

Hence no one can deny that efficient<br />

markets are as much important as like<br />

the efficient industries or the agricultural<br />

production systems that would efficiently<br />

produce primary or the processed<br />

products to help our economy<br />

remain competitive and there is no other<br />

alternative to the commodity derivatives<br />

trading that can bring about necessary<br />

efficiency in the existing<br />

market ecosystem.<br />

106<br />

THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


AN ARINDAM CHAUDHURI & PLANMAN MEDIA PRESENTATION<br />

TSI on Tragedies Stalking South Asia’s<br />

Leading Political Families<br />

only<br />

7 J A N - 1 3 JAN2008 Rs 10<br />

SPECIAL REPORT 24<br />

THE CROSS AROUND<br />

THEIR NECK IN ORISSA<br />

t h e n a t i o n ’ s g r e a t e s t n e w s w e e k l y<br />

DESTINY’S<br />

CHILDREN<br />

TRYST 54<br />

Exclusive<br />

interview: Air<br />

Chief Fali Major<br />

A TSI EXCLUSIVE XPOSÉ 74<br />

<strong>The</strong> sexiest woman alive<br />

Charlize (angel?) <strong>The</strong>ron, in a candid<br />

conversation about her profession<br />

NO . 1 I N R EG I ONAL REACH<br />

NOW<br />

LANGUAGES!<br />

THE NEW ADDICTION OF THE<br />

SMART INDIAN<br />

For <strong>The</strong> First Time In Global Media History... A Newsweekly In 13 Languages!


Deepika Wadhwa,<br />

Research Scholar,<br />

Centre for Economic Studies<br />

and Planning, Jawaharlal<br />

Nehru University, New Delhi<br />

Overseas Investment By Indian Firms:<br />

Recent Trends and Patterns<br />

"Today, one of the engines powering the remarkable<br />

growth in India is entrepreneurship. After<br />

being shackled for a number of decades, the<br />

wings of India's large class of talented private<br />

entrepreneurs have been fully freed. After a few<br />

tentative fl utters in the early 1990s, they are<br />

now showing their true worth. Many indigenous<br />

start-ups are becoming global success stories<br />

and Indian business has done unexpectedly<br />

well in the last decade and a half – largely as a<br />

result of more effi cient use of resources, men<br />

and machines."<br />

-Kamal Nath<br />

Minister of Commerce & Industry at<br />

United States-India Business Council<br />

(USIBC) Annual Summit, June 27, <strong>2007</strong><br />

1. Introduction<br />

Last two decades have witnessed liberalisation<br />

and globalisation of many developing<br />

economies across the world.<br />

One of the key outcomes of this process<br />

has been enhanced mobility of capital<br />

across different countries. This has resulted<br />

in a significant increase in the<br />

outward Foreign Direct Investment<br />

(FDI) flows not only from the developed<br />

countries but also from several developing<br />

and transition economies, especially<br />

since the early 1990s. <strong>The</strong> value of<br />

outward FDI flows from the developing<br />

and transition economies increased<br />

from $ 12 billion in 1990 to $193 billion<br />

in 2006 (which accounted for about 16<br />

percent of the world total outward FDI<br />

flows). Likewise, the value of the outward<br />

FDI stock of developing and transition<br />

economies went up from only $146<br />

billion in 1990 to $881 billion in 2000,<br />

reaching $1.7 trillion in 2006 (14 percent<br />

of the world total outward FDI stock).<br />

In case of India too, the FDI outflows<br />

have assumed significant proportions<br />

(in absolute terms) only since the early<br />

1990s. India’s total outward FDI stock<br />

rose from $124 million in 1990 to (almost)<br />

$13 billion in 2006; still it was<br />

ranked only 16th among the developing<br />

countries in terms of the total outward<br />

FDI stock. Likewise, India’s outward<br />

FDI flows increased from a meagre $6<br />

million in 1990 to $9.7 billion in 2006. 1<br />

India’s ranking in the Outward FDI<br />

Performance Index (of UNCTAD) has<br />

improved over these years, from 82 in<br />

1990 to 56 in 2006. <strong>The</strong> ‘internationalization’<br />

of Indian firms is also reflected<br />

in the growing number of Indian companies<br />

investing abroad, which has increased<br />

from 187 in the early 1990s to<br />

1700 by the early years of the present<br />

decade. 2<br />

In this backdrop, the present paper<br />

deals with some of the important aspects<br />

of overseas investment by Indian<br />

firms over the last decade. <strong>The</strong> second<br />

section of the paper presents a brief account<br />

of the changing policy framework<br />

in India with regard to outward FDI.<br />

108 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

<strong>The</strong> third section discusses the geographical<br />

and sectoral patterns of outward<br />

FDI flows from India. <strong>The</strong> fourth<br />

section highlights some of the overseas<br />

Mergers & Acquisitions (M&As) made<br />

by Indian firms. <strong>The</strong> fifth section discusses<br />

their likely motives and the factors<br />

driving overseas investments. <strong>The</strong><br />

paper ends with concluding remarks on<br />

some policy implications of the recent<br />

surge in outward FDI from India.<br />

2. <strong>The</strong> Policy Framework<br />

<strong>The</strong> policy guidelines for outward FDI<br />

from the country have evolved over the<br />

last few decades. <strong>The</strong> evolution of India’s<br />

overseas investment policy can be<br />

traced back to 1969, when the guidelines<br />

for overseas direct investment were issued<br />

by the Government of India for the<br />

first time. <strong>The</strong>se guidelines had defined<br />

the extent of participation of Indian<br />

companies in projects abroad. Indian<br />

companies were permitted minority<br />

participation in ‘turnkey projects’ involving<br />

no cash remittances. Subsequently,<br />

these guidelines were revised<br />

in 1978 and 1986, in the pre-reform era.<br />

<strong>The</strong> main objective of outward investment<br />

policy during this era was to encourage<br />

outward investments by Indian<br />

companies as means of promoting exports<br />

of Indian capital goods, technology<br />

and consultancy services. 3<br />

However, since the onset of economic<br />

reforms in India, overseas investment<br />

policy has undergone a structural<br />

change; with the last five years witnessing<br />

a clear thrust in policy towards promotion<br />

of greater investment opportunities<br />

for Indian firms. <strong>The</strong> stated<br />

objectives of this structural change in<br />

the overseas investment policy regime<br />

were: to help promote exports from the<br />

country, strengthen its economic linkages<br />

with other countries, provide Indian<br />

firms the access to new markets<br />

and technologies, and increase the global<br />

competitiveness of Indian firms. India’s<br />

overseas investment policy was first<br />

liberalised in 1992, which marked the<br />

introduction of an Automatic Route for<br />

overseas investments and allowed cash<br />

remittances for the first time with restrictions<br />

on the total value of investments.<br />

<strong>The</strong> total value of overseas investment<br />

by an Indian firm was<br />

restricted to $2 million in a block of<br />

three years, with a cash component of<br />

only $0.5 million. In 1995, the upper<br />

limit for automatic approval was raised<br />

to $4 million; and, the Reserve Bank of<br />

India (RBI) was given the authority for<br />

approval of overseas investment proposals<br />

worth up to $15 million, 4 while overseas<br />

investments worth more than $15<br />

million were still considered and approved<br />

by the Ministry of Finance. <strong>The</strong><br />

introduction of Foreign Exchange Management<br />

Act (FEMA), in 2000, brought<br />

in further changes in the policy relating<br />

to investments abroad. <strong>The</strong> limit for<br />

overseas investment was raised to $50<br />

million annually, without any condition<br />

relating to repatriation of a part of the<br />

declared profits. In March 2002, the upper<br />

limit for automatic approval was<br />

further increased to $100 million annually,<br />

of which 50 percent could be funded<br />

in foreign exchange from any authorized<br />

dealer (i.e. a bank authorized by<br />

RBI to deal in foreign exchange or<br />

foreign securities). 5<br />

Since 2003, however, the policy regime<br />

for overseas investment has been<br />

liberalized significantly. In 2003, Indian<br />

firms were allowed to make overseas<br />

investment (annually) of up to 100 percent<br />

of their net worth under the automatic<br />

approval route. This limit was<br />

enhanced later to 200 percent in 2005<br />

and 300 percent in <strong>2007</strong>. 6 In March<br />

2006, RBI also paved the way for proprietary/<br />

unregistered partnership firms<br />

to set up joint ventures or wholly owned<br />

subsidiaries abroad. Recently, the upper<br />

limit for total overseas investment of an<br />

Indian party in all its joint ventures and/<br />

or Wholly Owned Subsidiaries abroad<br />

has been enhanced to, not exceeding<br />

400 percent of its net worth. 7<br />

As regards the implications of these<br />

policy changes in India, Nayyar (<strong>2007</strong>) 8<br />

observes that the liberalization of the<br />

overseas investment policy regime,<br />

India’s total outward FDI stock rose from $ 124<br />

million in 1990 to (almost) $ 13 billion in 2006.<br />

Still, it was ranked only 16 th among the developing<br />

countries in terms of the total outward FDI stock<br />

along with reforms in the financial sector<br />

particularly those since early 2000s,<br />

have enhanced Indian firms’ access to<br />

capital from both domestic and international<br />

financial markets. For instance,<br />

in April 2003, banks in India were permitted<br />

to provide credit and non-credit<br />

facilities to Indian Joint Ventures or<br />

Wholly Owned Subsidiaries abroad<br />

worth up to 10 percent of their unimpaired<br />

capital funds. This limit was further<br />

raised to 20 percent in November<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

109


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

2006. Besides, India has also entered<br />

into Bilateral Investment Promotion<br />

and Protection Agreements (BIPAs)<br />

with a number of countries to promote<br />

and protect foreign investment on a reciprocal<br />

basis. All these policy changes<br />

have resulted in an environment conducive<br />

to a rapid expansion of outward<br />

FDI flows from the country.<br />

3. Overseas Investment: Geographical<br />

And Sectoral Patterns<br />

India’s outward FDI has steadily increased<br />

since 1996, both in terms of<br />

number of approvals and value. Indian<br />

investment abroad has gone up from $<br />

557 million (290 approvals) in the financial<br />

year 1996-97 to $2855 million (1395<br />

approvals) in the financial year 2005-06,<br />

representing an increase of 513 percent<br />

in terms of value of investments and 380<br />

percent in terms of the number of approvals<br />

given. In the financial year<br />

2006-07 (for the period April-October<br />

2006), actual FDI outflows stood at $<br />

3320 million as compared to $ 2109 million<br />

in the corresponding period of<br />

2005-06. 9 Before we move on to a discussion<br />

of geographical and sectoral<br />

patterns of FDI outflows from India, we<br />

must pay attention to some of the limitations<br />

of the statistics on FDI outflows:<br />

these statistics relate only to approvals<br />

rather than actual FDI outflows; the<br />

FDI outflow statistics do not include investment<br />

financed by borrowing in international<br />

financial markets through<br />

special purpose vehicles (SPVs); moreover,<br />

the data on sectoral distribution of<br />

outward FDI are not disaggregated<br />

enough 10 . Nonetheless, even the currently<br />

available statistics on outward<br />

FDI from India provide valuable<br />

insights.<br />

3.1 Geographical Patterns<br />

Until mid-1980s, much of the outward<br />

Indian investment abroad has gone up from $557 million<br />

(290 approvals) in the financial year 1996-97 to $2855<br />

million (1395 approvals) in 2005-06, representing an<br />

increase of 513% in terms of value of investments and<br />

380% in terms of the no. of approvals given<br />

FDI from India was concentrated primarily<br />

in a few developing regions of<br />

Africa (Kenya and Nigeria), Southeast<br />

Asia (Malaysia, Indonesia, and Singapore)<br />

and South Asia (Sri Lanka and<br />

Nepal) 11 . In fact, in the 1980s, India had<br />

emerged as the third largest foreign direct<br />

investor among the developing<br />

countries after Hong Kong and Singapore.<br />

12 <strong>The</strong> geographical pattern of Indian<br />

outward FDI underwent noticeable<br />

changes since early 1990s, when the<br />

outward FDI flows from India (in some<br />

of the sectors, such as software and<br />

pharmaceuticals) started shifting towards<br />

the developed regions, mainly<br />

North America and European Union.<br />

Over the period from April 1996 to<br />

October 2006, the largest recipient of<br />

India’s FDI was Russia with total Indian<br />

outward FDI of $ 2831 million, which<br />

was followed by USA at $ 2768 million,<br />

Mauritius at $ 2151 million, and UK at<br />

$ 2150 million (see Table 1). More recently,<br />

in 2006-07 (during the period<br />

April-October 2006), the top three destinations<br />

of India’s outward FDI were<br />

UK, Netherlands and Mauritius. In<br />

2006-07, India became the second-biggest<br />

source of outward FDI flows to UK.<br />

While most of the investments in USA<br />

and UK have been in IT services and<br />

pharmaceuticals, those in the Russian<br />

Federation and Sudan have been mainly<br />

in oil exploration. 13 A sizable chunk<br />

of Indian outward FDI has been going<br />

to the tax havens or offshore financial<br />

centres, like Mauritius (10 percent),<br />

British Virgin Islands (4.5 percent), and<br />

Bermuda (3 percent). In fact, it has been<br />

observed that the double taxation avoidance<br />

treaty between India and Mauritius<br />

(and other such tax haven countries)<br />

has encouraged Indian firms to ‘round<br />

trip’ investment through Mauritius (and<br />

other tax haven countries) to take advantage<br />

of the tax benefits enjoyed by<br />

overseas investors. 14 Thus, the geographical<br />

spread of Indian outward FDI<br />

has expanded over the last decade,<br />

with a shift towards the developed<br />

countries.<br />

3.2 Sectoral Patterns<br />

It has been highlighted by several ob-<br />

110 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

servers [see, for instance, Kumar (1995)<br />

& Pradhan (<strong>2007</strong>) 15 ] that the bulk of<br />

India’s outward FDI during 1970s and<br />

1980s was in the manufacturing sector,<br />

primarily in light engineering, pharmaceuticals,<br />

chemicals and textiles. Along<br />

with the increasing geographical diversification<br />

of outward FDI from the<br />

country, a sectoral diversification (towards<br />

services) also started taking place<br />

in the early 1990s. Although in case of<br />

certain services like, communication<br />

and software, broadcasting and publishing,<br />

engineering and construction, and<br />

hotels and restaurants, outward FDI<br />

from India has been rising; manufacturing<br />

sector still accounts for a major<br />

chunk of total outward FDI from India.<br />

Table-2 presents the sectoral composition<br />

of outward FDI flows from India<br />

during the period from April 1999 to<br />

October 2006. In this period, the largest<br />

amount approved for overseas investment<br />

was in the manufacturing sector<br />

(at $11093 million) followed by non-financial<br />

services sector (including software<br />

development), trading sector and<br />

other activities (see Table-2). Over this<br />

A sizable chunk of Indian outward FDI has been<br />

going to the tax havens or offshore financial<br />

centres like Mauritius (10 percent), British Virgin<br />

Islands (4.5 percent), and Bermuda (3 percent)<br />

period, the share of manufacturing sector<br />

was 53 percent while that of non-financial<br />

services was 33 percent and that<br />

of trading was 5 percent. An almost<br />

similar pattern emerges for the period<br />

Table 1: Geographical Distribution Of Approved Outward FDI Flows From India<br />

(Top 15 Destinations)(Million $ )<br />

Rank Country April 1996 to<br />

March 2002<br />

2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 * Total Share<br />

(in%)<br />

1 Russia 1748.7 0.2 1.4 1076.2 1.2 3.0 2830.6 12.78<br />

2 USA 1540.8 185.3 207.1 251.4 270.3 313.4 2768.3 12.50<br />

3 Mauritius 618.3 133.4 175.6 149.4 332.7 741.4 2150.7 9.71<br />

4 U.K 410.6 34.5 138.5 71.9 158.3 1335.9 2149.6 9.71<br />

5 Netherlands 157.9 15.9 30.2 30.7 284.6 1005.5 1524.8 6.89<br />

6 Singapore 153.0 46.8 15.9 239.3 200.5 499.5 1154.9 5.22<br />

7 Sudan - 750.0 162.0 51.5 63.0 118.1 1144.7 5.17<br />

8 British Virgin Island 776.5 3.3 4.9 131.4 29.5 39.0 984.7 4.45<br />

9 Cyprus 1.9 - 0.0 1.9 13.4 701.6 718.8 3.25<br />

10 Hong Kong 445.1 14.8 16.2 73.6 88.8 41.5 679.9 3.07<br />

11 Bermuda 232.6 29.0 142.5 221.3 2.6 627.9 2.84<br />

12 UAE 110.2 12.6 32.1 41.9 141.0 205.3 543.0 2.45<br />

13 Australia 7.0 95.0 92.9 158.8 75.3 95.2 524.1 2.37<br />

14 Brazil 13.0 5.2 5.0 17.2 420.1 6.7 467.2 2.11<br />

15 Canada 5.6 2.3 0.7 0.8 3.5 397.8 410.7 1.85<br />

Total Outward Investment<br />

7543.1 1472.1 1450.9 2804.0 2859.1 6003.9 22142.9<br />

All Developed Countries<br />

(Share in%)<br />

All Developing<br />

Countries (Share in%)<br />

2608.8<br />

(35)<br />

4934.2<br />

(65)<br />

396.6<br />

(27)<br />

1075.5<br />

(73)<br />

774.0<br />

(53)<br />

676.9<br />

(47)<br />

799.6<br />

(29)<br />

2004.3<br />

(71)<br />

1015.4<br />

(36)<br />

1843.6<br />

(64)<br />

Source: Compiled from data given in the website of Department of Economic Affairs, Ministry of Finance, Government of India.<br />

Note: * April-October 2006.<br />

4073.9<br />

(68)<br />

1929.8<br />

(32)<br />

9668.4<br />

(44)<br />

12474.4<br />

(56)<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

111


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

2006-07 (April-October 2006), with the<br />

largest amount of India’s outward FDI<br />

going to the manufacturing sector at<br />

$2403 million (40 percent)<br />

followed by financial and nonfinancial<br />

services sector (37 percent),<br />

other activities (16 percent) and trading<br />

sector (7 percent), respectively. Although<br />

there has been a decline in the<br />

share of manufacturing sector in India’s<br />

total outward FDI, it still accounts for<br />

While most of the investments from developing<br />

|countries are into other developing countries and in<br />

the service sector, outward FDI from India in the<br />

recent years has been primarily in the developed<br />

countries and in the manufacturing sector<br />

more than half of the outflows of FDI<br />

from the country. In terms of its geographical<br />

and sectoral diversification of<br />

outward FDI, India presents two sharp<br />

contrasts with other developing countries.<br />

While most of the investments<br />

vice sector, outward FDI from India in<br />

the recent years has been primarily in<br />

the developed countries and in the manufacturing<br />

sector. 16<br />

4. Modes Of Outward FDI<br />

From India<br />

In the period preceding 1990s, most of<br />

the outward FDI from India was in the<br />

form of greenfield investments for establishing<br />

new joint ventures or subsidiaries<br />

overseas. Since late 1990s, however,<br />

most of the outward FDI from the<br />

country has been through Mergers and<br />

Acquisitions (M&As) abroad, which was<br />

possibly due to the fact that greater risks<br />

and time could be associated with<br />

greenfield investments abroad. We may<br />

also note here that India’s overseas in-<br />

from developing countries are into other<br />

developing countries and in the servestment<br />

was traditionally led by a small<br />

group of family-owned large business<br />

conglomerates, like Tatas, Birlas,<br />

Thapars etc., which focused mainly on<br />

the neighbouring developing countries.<br />

Since 1990s, there has been an emergence<br />

of a large number of non familyowned<br />

as well as small and medium<br />

<strong>size</strong>d Indian firms, which have chosen<br />

outward investment as an important<br />

strategy for ‘internationalization’. 17<br />

As mentioned above, the expansion of<br />

outward FDI from India over the last<br />

decade has been led mainly by M&As<br />

abroad. Indian companies have marked<br />

their presence in several industries –<br />

software and IT services, pharmaceuticals,<br />

biotechnology, automotives, hotels<br />

and hospitality, and other consumer<br />

products. Although a significant part of<br />

the Indian outward FDI stock is still in<br />

manufacturing, overseas investment in<br />

software and IT services (for instance,<br />

those by Infosys, TCS and Wipro) has<br />

grown rapidly. Pharmaceuticals companies<br />

such as Dr. Reddy’s and Ranbaxy<br />

Table 2: Sectoral Distribution Of Approved Outward FDI Flows From India (Million $)<br />

Year<br />

Manufacturing<br />

Financial services<br />

Non- financial<br />

services<br />

Trading<br />

Others<br />

Total<br />

OFDI<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

Value<br />

Share<br />

(in%)<br />

1999-00 548.8 31.2 4.3 0.2 1143.5 65.1 58.3 3.3 2.3 0.1 1757.2<br />

2000-01 370.7 26.8 16.6 1.2 876.5 63.4 89.2 6.5 29.1 2.1 1382.1<br />

2001-02 2210.9 73.1 48.6 1.6 565.5 18.7 139.2 4.6 61.3 2.0 3025.5<br />

2002-03 1056.7 71.9 1.8 0.1 280.2 19.1 69.9 4.8 61.7 4.2 1470.3<br />

2003-04 765.6 52.8 35.1 2.4 438.8 30.3 76.9 5.3 134.1 9.2 1450.5<br />

2004-05 2026.4 72.3 9.2 0.3 548.2 19.5 69.1 2.5 151.3 5.4 2804.2<br />

2005-06 1711.1 59.9 167.7 5.9 707.4 24.8 134.3 4.7 134.3 4.7 2854.8<br />

2006-07* 2402.8 39.8 5.8 0.1 2250.0 37.3 390.8 6.5 985.6 16.3 6035.0<br />

Total 11093.1 53.4 289.1 1.4 6810.1 32.8 1027.7 4.9 1559.7 7.5 20779.7<br />

Source: Same as Table 1 above. Note: * April-October 2006.<br />

112 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 3: Cross-Border Mergers And Acquisitions By Indian Firms<br />

Year Purchases Sales<br />

No. of deals Value No. of deals<br />

Value<br />

(Million $)<br />

2000 55 910 111 1219<br />

2001 35 2195 84 1037<br />

2002 35 270 66 1698<br />

2003 57 1362 83 949<br />

2004 64 863 80 1760<br />

2005 91 2649 126 4210<br />

2006 133 4740 163 6716<br />

Source: FDI Database, UNCTAD<br />

have also made <strong>size</strong>able overseas investments.<br />

Large Indian companies in industries<br />

such as steel and chemicals<br />

have also begun to ‘internationalize’ by<br />

acquiring upstream companies, for instance,<br />

in countries like, Australia and<br />

Canada. 18 In the energy sector, India’s<br />

State-owned groups, such as ONGC<br />

Videsh, Indian Oil Corporation and Oil<br />

India, have acquired stakes abroad in<br />

exploration, refining and retailing.<br />

Table 3 presents a snapshot of Indian<br />

firms’ purchases and sales in the form of<br />

cross-border Mergers and Acquisitions.<br />

It shows that the number of Indian companies<br />

investing abroad has been steadily<br />

rising and in some of the years, the<br />

value of outbound deals was more than<br />

the value of in-bound deals.<br />

Presently, systematic information on<br />

cross-border M&As by Indian companies<br />

is not available from any government<br />

agency. <strong>The</strong>refore, in this paper,<br />

we rely mainly upon a study on Indian<br />

Acquisitions Abroad by MAPE Advisory<br />

Group 19 and refer to some other<br />

sources as well. According to the said<br />

study, Indian companies acquired 244<br />

foreign companies over the period 1st<br />

January 2000 to 31st March 2006.<br />

Table 4 shows the sectoral distribution<br />

of the 244 acquisitions by Indian<br />

companies covered by the MAPE study.<br />

<strong>The</strong> software and business process outsourcing<br />

industry saw the largest deal<br />

count, followed by pharmaceuticals and<br />

automotive. In terms of the value of the<br />

acquisitions, however, Manufacturing<br />

sector dominated with more than 40<br />

percent of the acquisitions in industries<br />

such as pharmaceuticals, automotive,<br />

consumer goods, chemicals, fertilizers<br />

and metals; whereas software and business<br />

process outsourcing accounted for<br />

almost 30 percent of the total value of<br />

acquisitions during this period. <strong>The</strong><br />

largest number of Indian acquisitions<br />

was in North America and Europe accounting<br />

for (approximately) 34 percent<br />

and 40 percent of the total, respectively.<br />

This reiterates the fact that Indian companies<br />

are investing more in the developed<br />

economies. <strong>The</strong> MAPE Study<br />

also reports that a certain degree of<br />

concentration can be found among the<br />

Indian firms that made these acquisitions<br />

abroad. Out of the 244 deals, 163<br />

deals involved Indian companies which<br />

have made more than one acquisition<br />

abroad. For instance, ONGC made a<br />

total of 9 acquisitions and Ranbaxy has<br />

made 8. <strong>The</strong> other main players include<br />

United Phosphorous, Bharat Forge, Dr<br />

Reddy’s, Tatas, HCL Tech, Mahindra &<br />

Mahindra and Nicholas Piramal,<br />

among others.<br />

This outbound M&As activity by Indian<br />

firms has continued to increase.<br />

<strong>The</strong> year <strong>2007</strong> has already witnessed<br />

two major acquisitions of Tata-Corus<br />

and Hindalco-Novelis. <strong>The</strong> former acquisition<br />

by Tata Steel was worth over<br />

$12 billion, which has been the largest<br />

acquisition ever by an Indian company;<br />

whereas the latter by Aditya Birla<br />

Group’s Hindalco Industries was worth<br />

$6 billion.<br />

5. Driving Factors And Motives<br />

For Overseas Investment<br />

<strong>The</strong> recent wave of outward FDI from<br />

India has been boosted by both domestic<br />

and international factors. In some<br />

In some industries such as pharmaceuticals, import substituting<br />

industrialization regime (of the pre-1990s era) had<br />

encouraged local technology and skill development and<br />

also created capacities and abilities in Indian firms which<br />

enabled them to become cost competitive globally<br />

cases, industry specific factors have also<br />

favoured the outward FDI. As regards<br />

the domestic factors, the policy regime<br />

on outward FDI from India has been<br />

liberalized significantly since 2003; a<br />

liberalised investment regime has provided<br />

Indian firms with easy access to<br />

cheap credit from both domestic and<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

113


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 4: Acquisitions Abroad By Indian Firms<br />

(From January 2000 To March 2006)<br />

Sector Value (Million $) Number Of Deals<br />

Automotives 427.3 24<br />

Chemicals & Fertilizers 655.2 17<br />

Consumer 668.5 10<br />

Pharmaceuticals/ Healthcare 1,604.2 50<br />

Software / BPO 1,115.4 82<br />

Metals & Mining 970.5 11<br />

Oil & Gas 1,587.0 13<br />

Other 1,525.8 37<br />

Total 8,553.8 244<br />

Source: MAPE Advisory Group, 2006<br />

international market; and a booming<br />

stock market too has had a favourable<br />

impact on their capacity to invest. On<br />

the international front, a changing economic<br />

environment has left many small<br />

to medium-<strong>size</strong>d manufacturing companies<br />

in the developed economies (such<br />

as, USA and Europe) vulnerable for acquisitions,<br />

as their prevailing business<br />

model could no longer be cost<br />

competitive. At the industry level, the<br />

lowering of trade barriers and entry of<br />

multinational firms has increased competition<br />

in the Indian market; which has<br />

compelled many Indian companies to<br />

look overseas for their growth. In this<br />

new competitive environment, the strategy<br />

of ‘internationalization’ has become<br />

vital for many firms. Secondly, as Nagaraj<br />

(2006) argues, in some industries<br />

such as, pharmaceuticals, import substituting<br />

industrialization regime (of the<br />

pre-1990s era) had encouraged local<br />

technology and skill development and<br />

also created capacities and abilities in<br />

Indian firms, which enabled them to become<br />

cost competitive globally. He<br />

In their overseas investments, Indian firms must try to<br />

focus more on resource-seeking activities like exploration<br />

and development of mineral and energy resources. China,<br />

in order to sustain its rapid growth, has invested the most<br />

in exploration of oil fi elds and industrial raw materials<br />

opines that the international competitiveness<br />

of Indian firms in the pharmaceuticals<br />

sector is attributable, to some<br />

extent, to the Patents Act of 1970 that<br />

did not allow ‘product patents’ but allowed<br />

only ‘process patents’ and thus<br />

facilitated the possibilities of ‘reverse<br />

engineering’. Indian firms at present see<br />

an opportunity to produce a large number<br />

of drugs that are going off patent in<br />

the developed countries. Moreover, getting<br />

access to specialised R&D of firms<br />

in developed nations is also one of the<br />

important reasons for Indian firms’ investments<br />

abroad in sectors like<br />

pharmaceuticals. <strong>The</strong> World Investment<br />

Report 2006 identifies four specific motives,<br />

for which firms look abroad, viz.<br />

market-seeking (i.e. looking for new<br />

customers), efficiency-seeking (i.e. reducing<br />

the costs), resources-seeking (i.e.<br />

accessing key factor inputs), or created/<br />

strategic-asset-seeking (i.e. such as<br />

technology, brands, distribution networks,<br />

R&D facilities and managerial<br />

competences).<br />

As regards the Indian firms, the key<br />

motives for their cross-border M&As<br />

have been gaining market access and<br />

acquiring new technologies and competencies.<br />

For instance, the acquisition of<br />

the Anglo-Dutch company, Corus, by<br />

Tata Steel (for more than $12 billion)<br />

seems driven by this kind of a strategy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> key motive of Tata Steel could have<br />

been to gain access to European markets;<br />

since Corus, which controls about<br />

50 percent of the UK steel market (in<br />

volume terms), is likely to offer Tata<br />

Steel a direct gateway into the European<br />

markets (where Tata Steel did not<br />

have a presence until now). It would also<br />

provide Tata Steel the access to advanced<br />

technology of Corus. This acquisition<br />

has made Tata Steel the 5th<br />

largest steel producer in the world.<br />

Thus, the main motive of Indian firms<br />

has been getting access to large markets<br />

and acquiring new technologies, and in<br />

several industries, acquisition of firms<br />

in the developed countries seems to offer<br />

the Indian firms not only better technology<br />

but also a <strong>size</strong>able market.<br />

6. Conclusion<br />

Thus, the strategy of ‘internationalization’<br />

being adopted by Indian firms<br />

seems to have been driven by a host of<br />

114 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

factors, such as, a liberalized policy regime<br />

and growing competitive pressures<br />

in the domestic market, among others.<br />

As the Indian firms look out for other<br />

markets and better technologies, the<br />

firms in the developed countries seem<br />

to have offered both in case of several<br />

industries. However, there is a clear<br />

need for precaution in this regard, since<br />

Indian firms borrowing from the global<br />

financial markets for the overseas acquisitions<br />

get exposed to the volatilities of<br />

the global financial markets. In fact,<br />

some of the major acquisitions by Indian<br />

firms in the recent years have been predominantly<br />

financed by debt from the<br />

global financial markets. <strong>The</strong>re is also a<br />

strong need to reorient the motives of<br />

the overseas acquisitions by Indian firms<br />

towards the long-term development of<br />

the country. In their overseas investments,<br />

Indian firms should try to focus<br />

more on resource-seeking activities,<br />

such as exploration and development of<br />

mineral and energy resources (the acquisition<br />

of Sakhalin Oil fields in Russia<br />

by ONGC is an example of this). We<br />

may note here that China, in order to<br />

sustain its rapid growth, has invested<br />

the most in exploration of oil fields and<br />

industrial raw materials. However, it<br />

would be interesting to see how the recent<br />

weakening of Dollar influences<br />

policies governing overseas investment<br />

as well as the capacities of Indian firms<br />

in this regard.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

<strong>The</strong>se results have been computed<br />

from the UNCTAD FDI database accessed<br />

from .<br />

2<br />

UNCTAD (2006) ‘World Investment<br />

Report 2006–FDI from Developing<br />

and Transition Economies: Implications<br />

for Development’.<br />

3<br />

As has been argued by Kumar, Nagesh<br />

(1995) ‘Industrialization, Liberalization<br />

and Two Way Flows of Foreign<br />

Direct Investments: <strong>The</strong> Case of India’,<br />

Discussion Paper Series, No.<br />

9504, INTECH- <strong>The</strong> United Nations<br />

University, Netherlands.<br />

4<br />

In 1995, the task of supervision of<br />

overseas investments was transferred<br />

from Ministry of Commerce, Govt.<br />

of India to the Reserve Bank of India<br />

(RBI). This was intended to provide<br />

a single window system for overseas<br />

investment approvals.<br />

5<br />

Gopinath, Shyamala (<strong>2007</strong>) ‘Overseas<br />

Investments by Indian companies<br />

- Evolution of Policy and Trends,’<br />

Key note address at the International<br />

Conference on Indian cross-border<br />

presence/acquisitions, Mumbai, January<br />

19.<br />

6<br />

As per the Annual Policy Statement<br />

for the Year <strong>2007</strong>-08 by Dr. Y. Venugopal<br />

Reddy, Governor, Reserve<br />

Bank of India, May 14, <strong>2007</strong>.<br />

7<br />

“RBI further liberalises Forex Rules’,<br />

RBI Press Release, September<br />

<strong>2007</strong>.<br />

8<br />

Nayyar, Deepak (<strong>2007</strong>) ‘<strong>The</strong> Internationalization<br />

of Firms from India:<br />

Investment, Mergers and Acquisitions’<br />

, SLPTMD Working Paper Series,<br />

No. 004, Department of International<br />

Development, University<br />

of Oxford.<br />

9<br />

As has been reported by the Department<br />

of Economic Affairs, Ministry<br />

of Finance, Government of India.<br />

10<br />

<strong>The</strong>se limitations have been pointed<br />

out by several analysts, for instance,<br />

Nayyar (<strong>2007</strong>).<br />

11<br />

As has been observed by Nagesh Kumar<br />

(1995).<br />

12<br />

Lall, S. (1983) <strong>The</strong> New Multinationals:<br />

<strong>The</strong> Spread of Third World Enterprises,<br />

New York: John Wiley<br />

13<br />

As reported by UNCTAD in World<br />

Investment Report 2006.<br />

14<br />

UNCTAD (2004) ‘India’s Outward<br />

FDI: A Giant Awakening?’,<br />

UNCTAD/DITE/IIAB/2004/1,<br />

20th October.<br />

15<br />

Pradhan, J. P. (<strong>2007</strong>) ‘Growth of Indian<br />

Multinationals in the World<br />

Economy: Implications for Development’,<br />

Working Paper, No. <strong>2007</strong>/04,<br />

ISID, New Delhi.<br />

16<br />

Nagaraj, R. (2006) ‘Indian Investments<br />

Abroad: What Explains the<br />

Boom?, Economic and Political<br />

Weekly, Vol. XLI, No. 46, pp.<br />

4716-4718.<br />

17<br />

Pradhan, J. P. (2005) ‘Outward Foreign<br />

Direct Investment from India:<br />

Recent Trends and Patterns’, Working<br />

Paper, No. 153, Gujarat<br />

Institute of Development Research,<br />

Ahmedabad.<br />

18<br />

As reported by UNCTAD in World<br />

Investment Report 2006.<br />

19<br />

MAPE Advisory Group ( 2006)<br />

“India Inc Going Abroad: Indian<br />

Companies’ Foreign Acquisitions’,<br />

background paper for the Seminar<br />

hosted by the IIM Calcutta on<br />

India Inc Going Abroad - Investing<br />

and Managing Internationally,<br />

Bangalore, April 19. <strong>The</strong>re are two<br />

other studies on acquisitions abroad<br />

by Indian firms. First is by FICCI<br />

in 2006 and, the second is by CMIE<br />

in <strong>2007</strong>.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

115


Anurag Sharma<br />

Research Fellow,<br />

Faculty of Business and Economics,<br />

Monash University, Melbourne<br />

Indian Banking Reforms and Policy<br />

Reversal: A Vicious Cycle<br />

"In sovereignty there are no gradations. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

may be limited royalty, there may be limited<br />

consulship; but there can be no limited government.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re must, in every society, be some<br />

power or other, from which there is no appeal,<br />

which admits no restrictions, which pervades the<br />

whole mass of the community, regulates and<br />

adjusts all subordination, enacts laws or repeals<br />

them, erects or annuls judicatures, extends or<br />

contracts privileges, exempt itself from question<br />

or control, and bounded only by physical<br />

necessity.<br />

By this power, wherever it subsists, all legislation<br />

and jurisdiction is animated and maintained.<br />

From this all legal rights are emanations, which,<br />

whether equitably or not, may be legally recalled.<br />

It is not infallible, for it may do wrong; but it is<br />

irresistible, for it can be resisted only by rebellion,<br />

by an act which makes it questionable, what shall<br />

be thenceforward the supreme power."<br />

-Samuel Johnson<br />

1. Introduction<br />

In the first decade following India’s independence<br />

in 1947, the banking sector<br />

was characterized by low reserve requirements<br />

and no control on interest<br />

rates (Demetriades and Luintel, 1996).<br />

Acting pursuant to its policy of directed<br />

and concessional lending to priority<br />

sectors (agriculture, exports, small<br />

scale industry) the government assumed<br />

control of the financial sector in the<br />

1960’s by nationalizing the major banks.<br />

Liquidity requirements were raised and<br />

interest rates on lending and deposits<br />

controlled and these became a major<br />

source of inefficiencies in the banking<br />

sector, through out the 1970’s and<br />

1980’s. Concessional lending to priority<br />

sectors with weak regulatory and supervision<br />

framework led to a high incidence<br />

of Non Performing Assets (NPA)<br />

in the banking sector. In 1992-93 NPA<br />

amounted to 24 percent of the total assets<br />

of public sector banks. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

began a gradual process of financial<br />

sector reforms in the mid 1980’s.<br />

Even though the pace of reform increased<br />

following the 1991 financial<br />

crisis, they remain incomplete. Demetriades<br />

and Luintel (1996) examine the<br />

effect of various types of banking controls<br />

on financial deepening in India<br />

and conclude these controls (with the<br />

exception of the lending rate ceiling)<br />

are having a negative impact on financial<br />

deepening and thus adversely affecting<br />

economic growth.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Indian economy has experienced<br />

more than a decade of economic reform<br />

following the 1991 financial crisis. <strong>The</strong><br />

present paper focuses on a critical analysis<br />

of the reforms process with emphasis<br />

on the banking sector, to highlight<br />

those inefficiencies which can contribute<br />

to “policy reversal” by the government.<br />

Policy reversal can be described<br />

as a situation in which government policies<br />

of sound fiscal management or<br />

financial restructuring adversely affect<br />

the banking sector (due to underlying<br />

inefficiencies) so that the government<br />

is forced to revive the banking sector by<br />

116 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

using policies such as recapitalization<br />

of public sector banks, honouring contingent<br />

and reserve of not less than Rs.500000<br />

and b) Satisfy the Reserve Bank of In-<br />

the SBI and its seven independently<br />

capitalized subsidiaries. <strong>The</strong> govern-<br />

liabilities or explicit bail-out dia (RBI) that its affairs are not ment of India is the major share holder<br />

packages that serve to undermine its<br />

initial efforts and adversely affect the<br />

government exchequer. This paper provides<br />

a brief overview of the evolution<br />

of the banking sector in India. Particular<br />

conducted in a manner detrimental to<br />

the interests of depositors.<br />

Scheduled commercial banks are further<br />

split into Public Sector Banks<br />

(PSB), private sector banks, foreign<br />

in these banks. Prior to 1991, PSBs accounted<br />

for about 90% of all deposits<br />

assets and credit in the economy. Private<br />

sector banks are classified as old<br />

and new private sector banks. <strong>The</strong>re are<br />

emphasis is placed on the possibility<br />

of policy reversal. <strong>The</strong> outline of the<br />

paper is as follows: Section-1 describes<br />

Concessional lending to priority sectors with weak regulatory<br />

and supervision framework led to a high incidence of<br />

the structure of the banking sector in<br />

India and its main characteristics in the Non Performing Assets (NPA) in the banking sector. In<br />

pre-1991 period. Section-2 outlines the 1992-93 NPA amounted to 24 percent of the total assets<br />

causes and impact of the 1991 financial<br />

of public sector banks<br />

crisis focussing on the changes in exchange<br />

rate regime. Section-3 critically banks and Regional Rural Banks 23 old private sector banks. Eight private<br />

analyses the banking sector reforms after<br />

1991 and summarizes current inefficiencies<br />

in the banking sector emphasizing<br />

high transaction costs and<br />

presence of the contingent liabilities.<br />

Section-4 discusses the relevance of<br />

policy reversals in India and cites some<br />

examples. Section-5 contains the policy<br />

conclusions and other impertaives.<br />

2. Banking Sector In India<br />

Banks in India are classified under the<br />

broad categories of scheduled and nonscheduled.<br />

Scheduled banks consist of<br />

(RRB).<br />

Public sector banks consist of nationalized<br />

banks and State Bank of India<br />

(SBI) group of banks. In 1969 the Indian<br />

government nationalized existing<br />

large private sector banks under its<br />

policy of assisting India’s planned development<br />

strategy by mobilizing financial<br />

resources to strategically important<br />

sectors. Fourteen banks were nationalized<br />

in 1969 and six in 1980. <strong>The</strong> Punjab<br />

National Bank was merged with the<br />

New Bank of India in 1993 thereby reducing<br />

the total count of national<br />

sector banks opened for business<br />

after 1991 and are classified as new private<br />

sector banks. Currently there are<br />

42 foreign banks in India, although<br />

their share in the holdings of banking<br />

sector assets remains negligible due to<br />

strict regulatory and entry requirements.<br />

RRB’s operate exclusively in<br />

Figure 1: Banking Structure In<br />

India<br />

Reserve Bank of India<br />

Scheduled Commercial bank (SCB) and<br />

banks to nineteen. <strong>The</strong><br />

Banks in India<br />

Financial Institutions<br />

scheduled cooperative banks. Non SBI group comprises<br />

Scheduled Banks comprise banks that<br />

are not included in the Second Schedule<br />

of the Banking Regulation Act of<br />

Scheduled Banks<br />

Non-Scheduled Banks<br />

1965 and thus do not satisfy the following<br />

conditions: a)<br />

have paidup<br />

Scheduled Commercial Banks<br />

Scheduled Co-operative Banks<br />

capital Public Sector Banks Private Sector Banks Foreign Banks Regional Rural<br />

Banks<br />

Nationalized Banks<br />

SBI Group<br />

Old Private Sector Banks<br />

New Private Sector Banks<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

117


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

rural areas to provide credit to small<br />

farmers and entrepreneurs. <strong>The</strong>re are<br />

currently 196 RRB’s accounting for<br />

four percent of the total assets of scheduled<br />

commercial banks. India also has<br />

specialized financial institutions under<br />

the following categories: big industry,<br />

investment and credit guarantee, exim<br />

trade, capital market, agriculture and<br />

housing development. <strong>The</strong>ir geographic<br />

reach is classified as all India, statelevel<br />

and other institutions. All-India<br />

financial institutions include (a) development<br />

banks (i.e., Industrial Development<br />

Bank of India, Industrial Credit<br />

and Investment Corporation of India,<br />

Small Industrial Development Bank,<br />

Industrial Investment Bank of India,<br />

and Industrial Finance Corporation of<br />

India); (b) specialized financial institutions<br />

(such as, Export Import Bank of<br />

India, Technology Development and<br />

Information Company of India); (c) investment<br />

institutions (i.e., Unit Trust of<br />

India (UTI), Life Insurance Corporation<br />

of India, General Insurance Corporation<br />

and subsidiaries); and (d) refinance<br />

institutions (i.e., National Bank<br />

for Agriculture and Rural Development<br />

(NABARD) and National Housing<br />

Bank). <strong>The</strong> role of these financial institutions<br />

is to promote economic development<br />

in various sectors of the economy.<br />

State level institutions include<br />

state financial corporations and state<br />

industrial development corporations.<br />

Other institutions consist of the Export<br />

Credit and Guarantee Corporation of<br />

India and Deposit Insurance<br />

and Credit Guarantee Corporation.(S<br />

hirai,2002).<br />

2.1 Pre-reform Period<br />

<strong>The</strong> banking system in India prior to<br />

1991 was highly regulated and inefficient.<br />

<strong>The</strong> most significant of these distortions<br />

were:<br />

• <strong>The</strong> existence of high levels of Cash<br />

Reserve Ratio (CRR) and Statuary<br />

Liquidity Ratio (SLR): CRR is a requirement<br />

on banks to hold a certain<br />

amount of deposits in the form of deposits<br />

to RBI. It is calculated as a<br />

percentage of reserve liabilities<br />

which are defined as a difference between<br />

all liabilities exempted from<br />

the SLR requirement and net time<br />

and demand deposits. <strong>The</strong> CRR rose<br />

from around 15 percent in 1960-70 to<br />

its upper legal limit of 15 percent in<br />

Banking reforms started in the second half of the 1980’s<br />

but was only seriously implemented after the 1991 financial<br />

crisis. <strong>The</strong> role of foreign and private sector banks<br />

remained negligible due to restricted entry regulations and<br />

strict branch licensing policies<br />

1991. <strong>The</strong> high value of CRR led to<br />

low profitability for banks and higher<br />

spreads. <strong>The</strong> RBI uses CRR as a<br />

tool for monetary intervention in the<br />

economy; e.g. the RBI increased<br />

CRR in August 1993 in order to sterilize<br />

capital inflows (Shirai, 2002).<br />

SLR is a liquidity requirement 1 for<br />

banks to hold a certain amount of<br />

deposits in the form of government<br />

and eligible securities. <strong>The</strong> upper legal<br />

limit of SLR is 40 percent. SLR<br />

increased from 25 percent in 1970 to<br />

38.5 percent in 1991. Hence for some<br />

time periods overall reserve requirements<br />

exceeded 50 percent.<br />

• Prior to 1991, Indian interest rates<br />

were administered by government.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se included lending and deposits<br />

rates including rates on saving deposits.<br />

<strong>The</strong> administration of rates<br />

was politically motivated and adversely<br />

affected bank balance sheets.<br />

Joshi and Little (1996) report the average<br />

return on assets in the second<br />

half of the 1980’s was just<br />

0.15 percent.<br />

• Directed and Concessional Lending:<br />

<strong>The</strong> state pursued a policy of allocation<br />

of financial resources to the socalled<br />

“priority sectors”. <strong>The</strong>se included<br />

agriculture, small scale<br />

industries, small business and selfemployed<br />

persons. Thus policy set<br />

quantitative loan targets 2 on banks<br />

and was a major reason behind the<br />

NPA of public sector banks. At the<br />

beginning of 1992-93 NPA amounted<br />

to 24 percent of total credit. 3<br />

• Lack of competition in the banking<br />

sector: <strong>The</strong> role of foreign and private<br />

sector banks remained negligible<br />

due to restricted entry<br />

regulations and strict branch<br />

licensing policies.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se government policies were the<br />

main cause of deteriorating bank performances<br />

and diminished banks’ incentive<br />

to operate efficiently. <strong>The</strong>re was<br />

lack of a proper regulation and supervision<br />

mechanism, which allowed banks<br />

to take high risks. This situation was<br />

worsened by the presence of implicit<br />

118<br />

THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1: Progress Of Commercial Banking In India<br />

Jun-69 <strong>Dec</strong>-80 Mar-91 Mar-95 Mar-99<br />

No. of SCB 73.0 154.0 272.0 281.0 297.0<br />

Per capita Deposit (Rs.) 88.0 738.0 2368.0 4242.0 8247.0<br />

Per capita Credit (Rs.) 68.0 457.0 1434.0 2320.0 4705.0<br />

Share of Priority Sector advances<br />

in Total Non-food credit of 15.0 40.3 39.2 35.8 35.9<br />

SCB(%)<br />

Deposits (% of National Income)<br />

15.5 36.0 48.1 46.4 48.7<br />

Total Assets (Rs. Billion) 68.4 710.8 3275.2 5215.4 11516.2<br />

Source: RBI (2003a)<br />

government guarantees i.e. the<br />

existence of contingent liabilities in<br />

the system.<br />

<strong>The</strong> reform process in the banking<br />

sector started in the second half of the<br />

1980’s but was only seriously implemented<br />

after the 1991 financial crisis.<br />

Table-1 summarizes salient aspects of<br />

the progress of the commercial banking<br />

sector in India. <strong>The</strong> evolution of the financial<br />

crisis of 1991 and its impact<br />

on the Indian economy is now<br />

briefly outlined 4 .<br />

3. Financial Crisis In India<br />

Prior to 1991 some important financial<br />

characteristics of the Indian economy<br />

can be summarized as follows:<br />

• Restrictive Capital Controls: Direct<br />

Investment was restricted. Capital<br />

inflows mainly consisted of foreign<br />

aid, commercial borrowings and Non<br />

Resident Indian (NRI) deposits. Indian<br />

companies were not allowed to<br />

hold foreign equities. <strong>The</strong> foreign<br />

portfolio investment was mainly directed<br />

toward a small number of public<br />

sector bond issues.<br />

• High fiscal deficits: Fiscal deficits<br />

were consistently high (combined<br />

gross fiscal deficit of state and central<br />

government rose by 20 and 24<br />

percent respectively in 1990 and<br />

1991) and mainly financed by borrowings<br />

and financial repression<br />

rather than monetization (Jha and<br />

Sharma (2004)). As a result the inflation<br />

rate did not reach extremely high<br />

levels and was at a par with India’s<br />

trading partners.<br />

• Pegged Exchange Rate: <strong>The</strong> exchange<br />

rate was officially pegged to<br />

a basket of currencies. However the<br />

trade-weighted nominal exchange<br />

rate depreciated steadily relative to<br />

the US$ in the latter half of the<br />

1980’s leading to small frequent devaluations.<br />

<strong>The</strong> rate of nominal depreciation<br />

was faster than the relative<br />

inflation differential leading to falls<br />

in the real exchange rate.<br />

• Trade: <strong>The</strong> government strategy was<br />

highly interventionist since independence<br />

and consisted of import<br />

substitution, complex industrial licensing<br />

requirements and public<br />

ownership of heavy industry. In the<br />

second half of the 1980’s, the emphasis<br />

shifted from import substitution<br />

to export-led growth. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

began a process of gradual liberalization<br />

of trade, investment, and<br />

financial markets. Export growth<br />

was rapid due to real depreciation of<br />

the rupee. However the value of<br />

imports increased at a faster rate<br />

(mainly in the petroleum sector)<br />

because of the easing of<br />

quantitative restrictions.<br />

India’s credit rating was downgraded and outfl ows were<br />

quick. As the forex reserves declined, economy was on<br />

the brink of default by January 1991. One of the major<br />

policy shifts in response to the financial crisis was the<br />

change in exchange rate management<br />

3.1 1991 Financial Crisis<br />

• Due to a widening gap between exports<br />

and imports and downturn of<br />

capital flows the current account<br />

deficit grew steadily and was financed<br />

by external borrowings and<br />

remittances of NRI making the<br />

economy extremely vulnerable to external<br />

shocks. External debt was $69<br />

billion in 1990-91 compared with $35<br />

billion in 1984-85.<br />

• Shocks: <strong>The</strong> first external shock was<br />

the sharp increase in world oil prices<br />

due to the Gulf War increasing the<br />

value of petroleum imports from $2<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

119


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 2: Cost Of Banks’ Rescue (Rs.Billion)<br />

in terms of a foreign currency<br />

and commits to<br />

1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 2001-2002<br />

trade in unlimited<br />

Capital Infusion 57.0 52.9 8.5 15.1 27.0 4.0 18.0<br />

amounts at that rate.<br />

Cumulative Infusion 97.0* 149.9 158.4 173.5 200.5 204.5 222.5 Normally the exchange<br />

*: Includes Rs.40 billion injected prior to 1993<br />

rate is allowed to vary<br />

billion to $5.7 billion which was quite<br />

high compared to 5 percent increase<br />

in non-oil imports. Exports were also<br />

adversely affected due to the impact<br />

of the Gulf war on India’s trading<br />

partners. For example, growth of India’s<br />

single largest trading partner,<br />

the US, fell from 3.9 percent in 1989<br />

to -1 percent in 1991. This led to a<br />

sharp deterioration in the trade account.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Gulf crisis also resulted<br />

in a decline in non resident workers’<br />

remittances to India.<br />

Apart from these external factors,<br />

political uncertainty in India in 1990<br />

and 1991 led to a fall in investor confidence<br />

further widening current account<br />

imbalances and causing a loss in reserves.<br />

India’s credit rating was downgraded<br />

by credit rating agencies leading<br />

to difficulties in commercial bank financing.<br />

<strong>The</strong> outflows from the economy<br />

were quick and as the forex reserves<br />

declined, the economy was on the brink<br />

of default by January 1991. One of the<br />

major policy shifts in response to the<br />

financial crisis was a change in exchange<br />

rate management. <strong>The</strong> next section<br />

briefly outlines exchange rate policy<br />

changes from 1970 to the present.<br />

3.2. Exchange Rate Regime<br />

In India<br />

With the collapse of the Bretton Woods<br />

arrangement in 1973 most developed<br />

economies switched from a fixed exchange<br />

rate to a flexible exchange rate<br />

regime. Under a fixed exchange rate<br />

regime the central bank announces the<br />

buying and selling rates of its currency<br />

within a narrow band.<br />

One major drawback of a fixed exchange<br />

rate regime in economies with<br />

perfect capital mobility is that monetary<br />

stabilization policy becomes ineffective<br />

(Obstfeld, 1995). For example if a government<br />

attempts to increase money<br />

supply by open market purchase of domestic<br />

bonds, households will find<br />

themselves holding more money than<br />

they desire. Since interest rate parity<br />

condition holds, household will sell<br />

their excess money holdings to the central<br />

bank for foreign currency at the<br />

fixed exchange rate and invest abroad<br />

to buy the desired amount of bonds.<br />

Such a mechanism will keep interest<br />

rates unchanged and leave the government<br />

with more bonds on the cost of<br />

forex reserves. One option for government<br />

will then be to refuse to buy the<br />

excess money supply and allow the currency<br />

Table 3: Comparison Of Central Government Holdings By Major<br />

Indian Banks After Public <strong>Issue</strong><br />

to depreciate.<br />

In spite of its drawbacks a fixed exchange<br />

rate regime is preferred in some<br />

Bank Name Date of Public <strong>Issue</strong> Government Percentage<br />

holding after public<br />

developing economies especially those<br />

with limited capital mobility. This is<br />

issue (%) as of 2001<br />

due to the following perceptions: a) A<br />

State Bank of India <strong>Dec</strong>ember 1993 66.34<br />

fixed exchange rate regime removes exchange<br />

rate uncertainty thereby retain-<br />

Sate Bank of Bikaner November 1997 75.00<br />

State Bank of Baroda <strong>Dec</strong>ember 1996 66.88<br />

ing investor confidence and macroeconomic<br />

stability; b) <strong>The</strong> export import<br />

State Bank of Travancore<br />

January 1998 76.00<br />

industry can be protected from huge<br />

Bank of India February 1997 77.00<br />

swings in exchange rates by keeping it<br />

Corporation Bank October 1997 66.33<br />

stable and c) If the currency is pegged<br />

Oriental Bank October 1994 66.48<br />

to a low inflation currency it helps keep<br />

Dena Bank <strong>Dec</strong>ember 1996 71.00<br />

domestic inflation low. For example, a<br />

120 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 2: Pre- reform Exchange Rate Variability<br />

government running a very high deficit<br />

will be reluctant to adopt an expansionary<br />

monetary policy because of its ineffectiveness<br />

in a fixed rate regime.<br />

Macroeconomic stability is a priority<br />

for any economy and all governments<br />

(irrespective of exchange rate regime)<br />

tend to intervene in the forex markets<br />

in order to influence the exchange rate.<br />

<strong>The</strong> government can take direct or indirect<br />

measures to counter exchange<br />

rate movements. Direct measures involve<br />

trading in the forex market. <strong>The</strong><br />

government uses its foreign exchange<br />

reserves to affect demand and supply in<br />

the forex market. For example, if domestic<br />

currency is depreciating the government<br />

will buy excess money supply<br />

by selling forex reserves to stabilize<br />

supply demand imbalances. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

can further offset this contractionary<br />

effect in domestic money supply<br />

by a simultaneous and equal purchase<br />

of domestic currency bonds. Such intervention<br />

is called “sterilized intervention”<br />

and is preferred by most governments.<br />

Such direct measures of<br />

intervention are complemented by some<br />

indirect measures like trade and interest<br />

rate restrictions to affect the demand<br />

and supply of foreign currency.<br />

For example, variable interest rates will<br />

affect the capacity of importers. One<br />

example is an interest rate surcharge on<br />

import finance: In order to curb imports<br />

and retain forex reserves, the RBI<br />

increased the interest rate surcharge on<br />

import finance from 15 percent to 25<br />

percent in January 1996.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

121


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

in 2004. <strong>The</strong> general perception is that<br />

if the government reduces SLR the reduced<br />

demand for government bonds<br />

will lead to a rise in interest rates the<br />

government has to pay bond holders.<br />

This may adversely affect the fiscal<br />

deficit. However, banks have continued<br />

to invest around 40 percent of their deposits<br />

in government securities in spite<br />

of the reduction in SLR. This is essentially<br />

because government bonds are<br />

considered to be a risk-free investment<br />

for banks.<br />

Interest rates were deregulated in<br />

1992 leading to complete liberalization<br />

of all term deposit and lending rates,<br />

except for savings deposit rates which<br />

remain controlled. <strong>The</strong> RBI has also<br />

begun using the bank rate (the rate at<br />

which RBI lends to commercial banks<br />

Table 4: Regulatory Framework Of Indian Banking Sector<br />

Variable 1992-93 2000-01 2001-02 2002-03<br />

Capital to Risk-weighted Assets<br />

Ratio (%)<br />

Domestic banks with international<br />

4 9 9 9<br />

business<br />

Foreign banks 8 9 9 9<br />

Non-performing assets<br />

(period overdue)<br />

Sub-standard assets 4 Q 2 Q 180 days 180<br />

days*<br />

Doubtful Assets<br />

period for which remained substandard<br />

24 M 18 M 18 M 18 M@<br />

Provisioning requirements (%)<br />

Standard Assets - 0.25 0.25 0.25<br />

Sub-standard assets 10 10 10 10<br />

Doubtful Assets (unsecured portion)<br />

100 100 100 100<br />

Loss assets 100 100 100 100<br />

Source: RBI (2003d)<br />

M: Month ; Q: Quarter<br />

by rediscounting bills or eligible paper)<br />

as a reference rate for influencing the<br />

direction of interest rates in the economy<br />

(Bhide et al., 2001). <strong>The</strong> flexibility<br />

to set lending rates led the banks to use<br />

this measure to offset the cost involved<br />

in concessional lending to priority<br />

sectors. During the reform period the<br />

ceiling of 40 percent on domestic banks<br />

and 33 percent on foreign banks for priority<br />

sector lending remained but banks<br />

were allowed to set the lending rates<br />

and more profitable sectors like the<br />

software industry and venture capital<br />

were included in the definition of priority<br />

sectors. <strong>The</strong> government relaxed the<br />

norms for entry in the banking sector in<br />

<strong>The</strong> deregulation of interest rates is also incomplete. Interest<br />

rates on saving deposits and other saving schemes<br />

such as National Savings Certifi cates, public provident<br />

funds etc. remain regulated. Such rigidities reduce the<br />

effectiveness of the transmission of monetary policy<br />

order to increase competitiveness. For<br />

example the ceiling of voting rights of<br />

an individual shareholder was increased<br />

from 1 to 10 percent in 1994. <strong>The</strong> relaxed<br />

guidelines led to the entry of 8<br />

private sector banks and 26 new foreign<br />

banks in the Indian banking sector.<br />

In response to the Narsimhan Committee<br />

recommendations, the government<br />

gradually started to privatize PSB.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se banks were accumulating large<br />

amounts of NPA due to the pre-reform<br />

regulated regime. <strong>The</strong>y made an aggregate<br />

loss of Rs.35 billion and almost<br />

half of the public sector banks had negative<br />

net worth. Realizing the importance<br />

of recapitalization, the government<br />

spent in the range of 0.02 to 0.7<br />

percent of GDP each year to wipe off<br />

accumulated NPA (Table 2). This<br />

helped the banks clean up their balance<br />

sheets and make public issues of equity.<br />

As Table 3 shows, the central government<br />

still continues to hold a large<br />

share of holdings in major state-owned<br />

banks. 6 Adoption of regulatory and supervision<br />

norms: Strengthening of the<br />

regulatory and supervisory framework<br />

of the banking sector remains a key element<br />

of financial sector reform. <strong>The</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

125


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

policy focus is on streamlining banking<br />

operations, upgrading risk management<br />

systems and enhancing the level of bank<br />

compliance with accounting standards<br />

and operationalizing consolidated accounting<br />

practices (RBI, 2003b). However,<br />

progress in this direction has been<br />

gradual. <strong>The</strong> RBI notes: “Within the<br />

process of convergence with best practices,<br />

finetuning is undertaken keeping<br />

in view the country specific circumstances.”<br />

(RBI, 2003c). For example,<br />

NPA have been defined as loans in<br />

which interest has remained unpaid for<br />

four quarters in 1992-93. This period<br />

was shortened to three quarters in<br />

1993-94 and two quarters in 1994-95.<br />

<strong>The</strong> central bank now plans to further<br />

shorten the period (in March 2004) to<br />

match the international norm of one<br />

quarter. Thus NPA were underestimated<br />

by Indian accounting standards. <strong>The</strong><br />

main reason behind such a policy was<br />

the political lobbying of borrowers. A<br />

summary of some aspects of the regulatory<br />

framework used by the RBI is given<br />

in Table 4.<br />

<strong>The</strong> financial sector reform process<br />

in India can be described as a graduated<br />

approach in the direction of liberalization.<br />

Figure 5 plots major banking<br />

indicators for the pre-reform and postreform<br />

period. <strong>The</strong>re are still some<br />

weaknesses in the financial sector<br />

which contribute to its inefficiencies.<br />

Though reduced from 40 percent to 25<br />

percent, the SLR has remained at high<br />

levels. Moreover, bank investment in<br />

government bonds and securities is still<br />

around 40 percent of their assets (Bhattacharya<br />

and Patel, 2003). This is because<br />

interest rates paid by the government<br />

are more market based due to the<br />

auction mechanism of its securities such<br />

as Treasury Bills; and also because<br />

banks prefer to invest in government<br />

securities as they are relatively risk free<br />

and more liquid. Banks are reluctant to<br />

take risks in alternative markets because<br />

of stricter prudential norms and<br />

accounting standards. <strong>The</strong> high investment<br />

in government securities is convenient<br />

for government which is running<br />

high fiscal deficits. However, when<br />

economic growth accelerates, high SLR<br />

can adversely affect the credit formation<br />

role of banks. Banks will be reluctant<br />

to lay off their securities in order<br />

to satisfy increased dem-and for credit.<br />

<strong>The</strong> CRR also remains higher than its<br />

Table 5: Non Performing Assets 0f Commercial Banking Sector: 1997-2003<br />

Year Public Sector Old Private New Private Foreign Banks<br />

Banks Sector Banks Sector Banks in India<br />

1997 17.80 10.70 2.60 4.30<br />

1998 16.00 10.90 3.50 6.40<br />

1999 15.90 13.10 6.20 7.60<br />

2000 14.00 10.80 4.10 7.00<br />

2001 12.40 11.10 5.10 6.80<br />

2002 11.09 11.01 8.86 5.38<br />

2003 9.36 8.90 7.64 5.22<br />

Definition: Gross NPA/Gross Advances (%)<br />

statuary minimum of three percent.<br />

<strong>The</strong> deregulation in interest rates is<br />

also incomplete. Interest rates on saving<br />

deposits and other saving schemes<br />

such as National Savings Certificates,<br />

public provident funds etc. remain regulated.<br />

7 Such rigidities reduce the effectiveness<br />

of the transmission of monetary<br />

policy (Sharma, 2004). <strong>The</strong><br />

lending rate for advances of over<br />

Rs.200000 was subjected to a ceiling of<br />

16.5 percent in 1987-88. This was eventually<br />

removed in 1994. <strong>The</strong> Prime<br />

Lending Rate (PLR) was set as a floor<br />

rate and banks are now free to set lending<br />

rates without any upper restriction.<br />

<strong>The</strong> lending rates though, officially<br />

flexible, are affected by public sector<br />

banks which are the dominant players<br />

in the banking sector. <strong>The</strong>se banks offer<br />

rates below the PLR because of their<br />

advantage in market share and quality<br />

of borrowers. <strong>The</strong>refore other banks’<br />

lending rates do not diverge much from<br />

the rates set by PSB thereby making<br />

PLR ineffective. <strong>The</strong> banks still have to<br />

make some loans based totally on the<br />

political agenda of the government. For<br />

example banks are forced to provide<br />

concessional loans to individuals or<br />

firms belonging to scheduled caste or<br />

scheduled tribes.<br />

4.1 High Transaction Costs<br />

One of the major concerns of the banking<br />

sector is the high transaction costs<br />

involved in the lending operations of<br />

banks. Transaction costs are particularly<br />

high in rural sector areas which<br />

are one of the priority sectors defined<br />

by government. Puhazhendhi (1995)<br />

estimated the transaction costs of lending<br />

to the rural poor in India. He con-<br />

126 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

sidered two major commercial banks,<br />

one regional rural bank and one private<br />

commercial bank from the southern<br />

states of Tamil Nadu and Kerala. <strong>The</strong><br />

estimated transaction cost was 3.68 percent<br />

of the loan amount if the loan was<br />

delivered through a direct lending<br />

channel. <strong>The</strong> literature on micro-credit<br />

(see (Ghatak, 2000) and (de Aghion<br />

and Gollier, 2000)) argues that group<br />

lending to the poor through Non-Governmental<br />

Organization (NGO) and<br />

Self Help Group (SHG) may be an efficient<br />

method of credit delivery system.<br />

In 1991, the RBI initiated the policy of<br />

encouraging direct linkages between<br />

the banks and NGO and SHG due to<br />

the presence of high transaction costs.<br />

Puhazhendhi (1995) estimated the financial<br />

intermediation of NGO and<br />

SHG reduced transaction costs by between<br />

21 and 41 percent relative to the<br />

direct lending channel. In spite of these<br />

efforts transaction costs remain high<br />

even after a decade of reform. <strong>The</strong> estimated<br />

opportunity cost of existing<br />

high transaction costs in India is<br />

still high. 8<br />

Though heading in the right direction,<br />

prudential norms are yet to reach<br />

global standards. <strong>The</strong> pace of restructuring<br />

nationalized banks through privatization<br />

is slow. This is mainly because<br />

nationalized banks’ balance<br />

sheets are weak due to accumulated<br />

NPA over the past three decades. <strong>The</strong><br />

government needs to clean up balance<br />

sheets by recapitalization and other<br />

measures in order to make these banks<br />

more attractive to investors. Given recent<br />

trends on the magnitude of NPA<br />

(Table 5) the cost of restructuring appears<br />

to be very high, particularly since<br />

it is already running very high deficits.<br />

Such liabilities on the government to<br />

revive the banking sector (contingent<br />

liabilitie000s), are significant in the<br />

case of India. <strong>The</strong> impact of contingent<br />

liabilities is now examined.<br />

4.2. Contingent Liabilities<br />

<strong>The</strong> financial sector in transition and<br />

developing economies is characterized<br />

by poor regulatory and enforcement<br />

systems, and inadequate disclosure of<br />

information which may lead to a high<br />

incidence of NPA. When the banking<br />

sector is in stress, out of legal obligation<br />

or political compulsion the central government<br />

has to rescue the banks. Such<br />

public financing by government represents<br />

its contingent liabilities and can<br />

potentially lead to a large increase in<br />

public debt. Because of their uncertain<br />

nature these contingent liabilities are<br />

unbudgeted and, hence, are hidden fiscal<br />

risks. Contingent liabilities are also<br />

important because the government cannot<br />

achieve its long-run objective of a<br />

sound fiscal system without addressing<br />

the problem. Explicit contingent liabilities<br />

are specific obligations which the<br />

government has to settle under a contract<br />

or a law. <strong>The</strong>se include obligations<br />

issued to state governments and public<br />

sector banks, etc. <strong>The</strong> government can<br />

foresee such guarantees and includes<br />

them in its budget constraint. 9<br />

However, contingent liabilities or implicit<br />

liabilities are uncertain and their<br />

realization is dependent on the probability<br />

of particular events. Sometimes,<br />

these events could be totally exogenous<br />

to government policy, e.g., an earthquake<br />

or any other natural disaster.<br />

Most of the time, these liabilities are a<br />

result of government policy. One interesting<br />

example is a guarantee extended<br />

by government to foreign creditors of<br />

domestic banks. <strong>The</strong>se guarantees may<br />

lead to moral hazard problems in the<br />

banking sector as banks may take high<br />

risks, eventually leading to default on<br />

foreign loanswww, and pressure on the<br />

government to bail them out because of<br />

It is argued that under current ineffi ciencies in the banking<br />

sector, any efforts by government to ensure macroeconomic<br />

stabilization or restructuring will involve an offsetting<br />

effect, adversely affecting the initial policy objectives,<br />

which will transmit mainly through the financial sector<br />

public expectations or political compulsion<br />

(For a detailed model see (Sharma,<br />

2004)). One relevant case study in this<br />

regard is the crisis in the UTI mutual<br />

fund discussed in section 5.<br />

Contingent implicit liabilities are<br />

normally calculated after the event occurs,<br />

as they are dependent on the probability<br />

of the triggering event, the actual<br />

loss and the amount government<br />

pays to bail out the system. (Polackova,<br />

1999) notes the financial systems represent<br />

the most serious contingent implicit<br />

liability. For example the cost of<br />

resolving past banking crises varies<br />

from around 1 percent of GDP (Thailand<br />

1983-87) to around 55 percent of<br />

GDP (Argentina 1980-82) depending<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

127


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

can subsequently cause what can be<br />

termed a “policy reversal” by government.<br />

Such policy reversals can arise<br />

under several conditions some of which<br />

are:<br />

• Suppose government is running high<br />

deficits and implements a tight monetary<br />

policy by increasing interest<br />

rates. Due to the inflexibility of the<br />

banking sector in passing on interest<br />

higher incidence of NPA in balance<br />

sheets. This may force the government<br />

to revive the banking sector<br />

through measures like recapitalization<br />

which will be a direct burden on<br />

government budget. As discussed<br />

earlier, the cost of reviving banks is<br />

very high in the case of India. <strong>The</strong><br />

government indeed began a partial<br />

privatization of banks as part of its<br />

economic reform process initially<br />

providing Rs.40 billion from 1991-92<br />

to 1992-93 to 19 nationalized banks.<br />

Subsequently, the government has<br />

spent around Rs.164.5 billion at a<br />

rate of between 0.02 and 0.7 percent<br />

of GDP each year from 1993-99.<br />

Though there was a decline in NPA<br />

from 17.8 percent in 1997 to 11.4 percent<br />

in 2002 they are still very high.<br />

• A second reason for policy reversal is<br />

the existence of weak regulatory and<br />

supervisory framework in the Indian<br />

Banking sector. <strong>The</strong> UTI mutual<br />

funds crisis is an example of this (See<br />

Appendix A.1).<br />

<strong>The</strong> government began a partial privatization of banks,<br />

initially providing Rs.40 billion from 1991-92 to 1992-93<br />

to 19 nationalized banks. Subsequently, ithas spent<br />

around Rs.164.5 billion at a rate of between 0.02 and 0.7<br />

percent of GDP each year from 1993-99<br />

on the state of the financial system.<br />

Standard and Poor’s (Polackova, 1999)<br />

estimate the fiscal cost of a future<br />

banking crisis in India will be around<br />

15 percent of GDP. This is so high because<br />

of the persistent inefficiencies in<br />

the banking system even after a decade<br />

of financial reform (Bhattacharya and<br />

Patel, 2003). Bhattacharya and Patel<br />

(2003) put the estimate of government<br />

guarantees in India as around 12 percent<br />

of GDP. Hence government guarantees<br />

are a crucial part of analysis of<br />

a financial sector especially in developing<br />

economies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> overview of the reform process<br />

brings up the question of policy reversal<br />

which is covered in the next section.<br />

5. Policy Reversal<br />

Most of the financial reforms in the Indian<br />

economy were guided by “.... objectives<br />

of increasing operational efficacy<br />

of monetary policy....” (RBI, 1997,<br />

page I-9). It is argued that under current<br />

inefficiencies (especially high NPA<br />

and the large share of government ownership)<br />

in the banking sector, any efforts<br />

by government to ensure macroeconomic<br />

stabilization (say reduction<br />

in fiscal deficit) or restructuring will<br />

involve an offsetting effect, adversely<br />

affecting the initial policy objectives,<br />

which will transmit mainly through the<br />

financial sector. This offsetting effect<br />

rates rise this will lead to banking<br />

stress. This inflexibility arises mainly<br />

because of the government’s policy<br />

of directed and concessional lending<br />

to priority sectors. Because of a regulated<br />

interest rate regime, the banks<br />

cannot adjust their deposit rates<br />

much, say in the, area of savings deposits.<br />

Thus stress in the banking<br />

sector will be directly reflected in a<br />

6. Conclusion<br />

<strong>The</strong> present paper has reviewed the financial<br />

sector reform process in India<br />

focussing on the banking sector. It can<br />

be safely concluded that financial sector<br />

reform in India is incomplete. <strong>The</strong><br />

banking sector remains inefficient because<br />

of several factors viz. high reserves<br />

and liquidity requirements, a<br />

poor regulatory and supervisory framework,<br />

the presence of implicit government<br />

guarantees, high transaction costs<br />

etc. <strong>The</strong>se inefficiencies can adversely<br />

affect the long-term policy objectives<br />

of a sound fiscal system and can even<br />

lead to policy reversals.<br />

128 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

APPENDIX<br />

A.1 UTI Crisis<br />

<strong>The</strong> section is compiled from the www.<br />

rediff.com archives. UTI mutual fund<br />

commenced operation on July 1964. It<br />

was established by the central government<br />

to channel community savings into<br />

productive uses in order to speed up industrial<br />

growth. To quote then Finance<br />

Minister T.T. Krishnamachari “the trust<br />

would be open to any person or institutions<br />

to purchase the units offered by the<br />

trust. However, this institution as we see<br />

it, is intended to cater to the needs of individual<br />

investors, and even among them<br />

as far as possible, to those whose means<br />

are small.” <strong>The</strong> main objective of the<br />

UTI was to invest retail savings in the<br />

capital market and pass the benefits back<br />

to small investors. UTI had a monopoly<br />

in the funds industry until 1986. Subsequently,<br />

PSBs sponsored funds entered<br />

the market and in 1993 there were 8 mutual<br />

funds. After 1993 private sector mutual<br />

funds were allowed. <strong>The</strong> funds industry<br />

has grown at a compounded<br />

average rate of 27 percent from an asset<br />

base of Rs.250 million in 1964 to its current<br />

<strong>size</strong> of Rs.900 billion. <strong>The</strong> share of<br />

UTI is around Rs.600 billion. UTI invests<br />

about a quarter of this through the<br />

US-64 fund, India’s largest, and accounts<br />

for about 15 percent of the domestic mutual<br />

fund industry’s assets in a year. <strong>The</strong><br />

mutual funds (particularly UTI) are very<br />

popular among small investors and became<br />

even more attractive in 1996 when<br />

the mutual fund dividend returned by<br />

equity-oriented schemes was exempted<br />

from tax. In mid 2002, the UTI bank decided<br />

to skip a dividend for its flagship<br />

US-64 scheme for the year 2001-02. This<br />

was because the NAV of the scheme had<br />

eroded sharply and was much lower than<br />

its face value of Rs.10. On 1st August,<br />

2002 the NAV of US-64 was Rs.5.80.<br />

This was the first time the UTI had<br />

skipped paying a dividend for the US-64<br />

scheme, since its inception in 1964. <strong>The</strong><br />

UTI Board decided to skip a dividend as<br />

the government had been providing budgetary<br />

support to unit holders, to bridge<br />

the gap between the NAV and repurchase<br />

price of 2001. In the period January-June<br />

2002 the SEBI reported that the UTI had<br />

redemption/repurchase to the tune of<br />

over Rs.63 billion against a mobilization<br />

of just Rs.6.3 billion. All the Minimum<br />

Income Plan (MIP) schemes of the UTI<br />

showed negative reserves on 30 June<br />

2002. According to a report by SEBI, 35<br />

out of 63 schemes (whose unaudited results<br />

were available) had negative reserves.<br />

For the MIP schemes, negative<br />

reserves totalled up to Rs.30 billion.<br />

MIP97(III) had egative reserves of<br />

Rs.2.6 billion and MIP97(IV) had negative<br />

reserves of Rs.2.5 billion. For the<br />

three years between 1999 and 2002, UTI<br />

consistently lost market share in terms of<br />

net assets. On 31 March 1999, UTI had<br />

a 77 percent market share with assets at<br />

Rs.531.45 billion out of total Rs.681.93<br />

billion. <strong>The</strong>se figures dropped dramatically<br />

over the following years and on 30<br />

June 2002 the market share of UTI was<br />

46 percent with assets amounting to<br />

Rs.463.96 billion out of total Rs.1007.03<br />

billion. UTI’s investments make up 11<br />

percent of the value of all stocks traded<br />

on the Bombay Stock Exchange.<br />

<strong>The</strong> collapse of UTI began in 1999.<br />

<strong>The</strong> UTI mutual fund scheme was ailing,<br />

the government had issued a Special Securities<br />

Scheme for Rs.33 billion by taking<br />

over a large percentage of public sector<br />

scrips which had a considerably lower<br />

book value. <strong>The</strong> government continued<br />

to pay interest of 11.2 percent to the trust<br />

until 2002. UTI had not paid any dividend<br />

to the government until then. However,<br />

things did not turn out as planned<br />

and due to harsh market conditions, especially<br />

with the tech meltdown, US- 64<br />

holdings fell by Rs.10 billion during January<br />

to November 2001. <strong>The</strong> problem<br />

was aggravated because unlike most open<br />

ended schemes US-64 did not declare its<br />

NAV on a daily basis. In 2001-02, the<br />

government provided a cash support of<br />

Rs.3 billion to US-64 following the sudden<br />

freezing of sale and repurchase of<br />

units on 2nd July 2001. In 2002, the central<br />

government doled out Rs.5 billion<br />

and promised another Rs.5 billion for the<br />

US-64 scheme to meet the difference between<br />

its net assets value and the administered<br />

repurchase price. <strong>The</strong> government<br />

planned to work out a tax concession<br />

package to enthuse investors to remain<br />

with the scheme after May 2003. A committee<br />

was set up to investigate the matter<br />

and make recommendations. <strong>The</strong><br />

committee revealed certain weaknesses<br />

in investments made by UTI.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se were:<br />

• Bad investments, including in firms it<br />

had been warned against investing in<br />

by its own internal advisory team. For<br />

example, UTI lost Rs 328 million investing<br />

in an Internet company against<br />

the advice of their own<br />

research department.<br />

• All 19 individual investment decisions<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

129


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

of the trust were imprudent and turned<br />

out to be in error.<br />

Apart from these investment inconsistencies,<br />

the stock scam in 2001 revealed<br />

the unhealthy nexus among the UTI (and<br />

possibly other mutual funds as well), local<br />

operators and promoters/corporates.<br />

It was believed the UTI mutual fund was<br />

the backbone of purchases in the infotech<br />

sector supported by the infamous operator<br />

Ketan Parikh. <strong>The</strong> tech meltdown of<br />

2001 resulted in sharp redemption for the<br />

scheme in early 2002. In mid 2002, the<br />

UTI decided to skip a dividend for its<br />

flagship US-64 scheme for the 2001-2002<br />

year. This was because the Net Asset<br />

Value (NAV) of the scheme has eroded<br />

sharply and was much lower than the face<br />

value of Rs.10. On 1st August 2002, the<br />

NAV of US-64 was only Rs.5.80. <strong>The</strong><br />

RBI was reported as contemplating a repurchase<br />

arrangement with UTI. This<br />

behavior of the RBI was an attempt to<br />

insulate the guilds market from the UTI<br />

crisis which was already having an impact<br />

on the equity market. Even some commercial<br />

banks such as the Bank of India,<br />

and State Bank of India started extending<br />

loans against UTI’s US-64 scheme<br />

at a steep discount. However, many<br />

other banks adopted a wait and<br />

watch policy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Finance inister, Yashwant Sinha<br />

was initially reluctant to provide any sort<br />

of government support to UTI. In a press<br />

conference he was quoted as saying, “We<br />

cannot go on spending government money<br />

for bailouts. A budgetary support is<br />

not a desirable option at the moment.”<br />

However this policy could not be sustained.<br />

A majority of public sector banks<br />

rejected the proposal of buying stocks<br />

held under its flagship US-64 scheme.<br />

However, these banks were willing to extend<br />

clean loans to UTI for a short period,<br />

provided the central government gave<br />

a “comfort letter” ensuring timely payment<br />

of the interest and principal amount.<br />

However, the finance minister was not<br />

keen on providing a “sovereign guarantee”<br />

to public sector banks in lieu of loans<br />

extended to UTI. <strong>The</strong> chairman of UTI,<br />

Mr. M. Damodaran was quoted as saying<br />

that “<strong>The</strong>re were problems on two fronts<br />

- liquidity and solvency. <strong>The</strong> liquidity can<br />

be taken care of by the banks line of<br />

credit. But, to address the solvency issue,<br />

the government will have to step in at the<br />

second stage, if the market does not pick<br />

up by that time- That is, the government<br />

will have to bail out UTI.” M. Damodaran<br />

said that, in the wake of a problem<br />

regarding the solvency issue, if the government<br />

was not forthcoming with funding,<br />

UTI would dump its illiquid stocks<br />

in the market.<br />

A report by global consultancy firm<br />

Mckinsey declared that UTI may need<br />

$500 million to stay solvent. Mckinsey<br />

argued that, given the high fiscal deficit,<br />

recapitalization from government funds<br />

would not be easy. Also, funds raised<br />

from the capital market would not be sufficient.<br />

After a series of meetings between<br />

UTI chairman, M. Damodaran and Secretary<br />

of the Department of Economic<br />

Affairs and later with Finance Minister<br />

Y. Sinha, the government decided to provide<br />

cash assistance to UTI of Rs.5 billion.<br />

Officials said the liabilities to the<br />

center would be provided for either in the<br />

budget or the final supplementary demand<br />

for grants and will be in the nature<br />

of a contingent liability on the government.<br />

Financial analysts began suggesting<br />

the government would have to bail<br />

out the country’s largest mutual fund operator<br />

for another year. In the light of a<br />

negative reserve of about Rs.37 billion<br />

and payment obligation for about Rs.9<br />

billion for two of its MIP schemes maturing<br />

2002 UTI had demanded around<br />

Rs.50 billion. <strong>The</strong> Cabinet Committee<br />

on Economic Affairs chaired by the<br />

Prime minister, Mr. A. B. Vajpayee, approved<br />

a bailout package of over Rs.145<br />

billion for UTI to meet the liabilities on<br />

its flagship US-64 and assured return<br />

schemes. <strong>The</strong> government also considered<br />

some tax concessions for US-64 unit<br />

holders so as to create a market, reduce<br />

redemption and keep up investment in<br />

the scheme. <strong>The</strong> Finance Minister also<br />

asserted there would be no budgetary<br />

impact as a result of the package, although<br />

it would add to the fiscal burden<br />

and contribute to public debt. <strong>The</strong> UTI<br />

case provides an interesting and important<br />

example of policy reversal in the face<br />

of financial crisis.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

“Under section 24 (b) of the Banking<br />

Regulation Act, 1949, every bank is<br />

required to maintain at the close of<br />

business every day, a minimum proportion<br />

of their Net Demand and Time<br />

Liabilities as liquid assets in the form<br />

of cash, gold and un-encumbered approved<br />

securities. <strong>The</strong> ratio of liquid<br />

assets to demand and time liabilities is<br />

known as Statutory Liquidity Ratio<br />

(SLR). Present SLR is 25 percent. <strong>The</strong><br />

RBI is empowered to increase the SLR<br />

up to 40 percent” (RBI Glossary).<br />

2<br />

In 1974, banks were required to direct<br />

33 percent of their net bank credit at<br />

concessional fixed interest rates to priority<br />

sectors. This was raised gradu-<br />

130 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ally to 40 percent in 1980.<br />

3<br />

NPA have been defined as those loans<br />

for which interest has remained unpaid<br />

for four quarters in 1992-93.<br />

4<br />

For a detailed analysis on financial crisis<br />

see Joshi and Little (1996), Cerra<br />

and Saxena (2002), Kapila and Kapila<br />

(1996) and Rangrajan (1991) among<br />

others.<br />

5<br />

For example (Kohli, 2001) reports the<br />

dates of indirect intervention done by<br />

RBI as October 1995, January and July<br />

1996, November 1997 and January,<br />

June and August 1998.<br />

6<br />

<strong>The</strong> 1998 committee on banking sector<br />

reforms recommended the minimum<br />

shareholding by the government<br />

or RBI equity in nationalized bank<br />

should be brought down to 33 percent.<br />

7<br />

In fact, few allies in the newly formed<br />

United Progressive Alliance (UPA)<br />

government are demanding a rise in<br />

the interest rates on various provident<br />

fund schemes.<br />

8<br />

To quote RBI Governor Y.V.<br />

Reddy:“<strong>The</strong> transaction costs are a<br />

drag on the economy and it is time to<br />

put emphasis on their reduction which<br />

can facilitate the growth of GDP by 2<br />

to 3 percent. (November 3, 2003, http://<br />

www.rediff.com/money/2003/nov/<br />

03cred10.htm)<br />

9<br />

Australian and New Zealand governments<br />

currently report such liabilities<br />

in their balance sheets.<br />

References<br />

• Bhattacharya, S. and U. R. Patel<br />

(2003). Reform Strategies in the<br />

Indian Financial Sector. In Conference<br />

on India’s and China’s Experience<br />

with Reform and Growth, New<br />

Delhi. International Monetary Fund<br />

and National Council of Applied<br />

Economic Research.<br />

• Bhide, M. G., A. Prasad, and S. Ghosh<br />

(2001). Emerging Challenges in Indian<br />

Banking. CREDPR Working Paper<br />

103.<br />

• Cerra, V. and S. C. Saxena (2002).<br />

What Caused the 1991 Currency Crisis<br />

in India? IMF Staff Papers 49.<br />

• de Aghion, B. A. and C. Gollier (2000).<br />

Peer Group Formation in an Adverse<br />

Selection Model. Economic Journal<br />

110, 632–43.<br />

• Demetriades, P. O. and K. B. Luintel<br />

(1996). Financial Development, Economic<br />

Growth and Banking Sector<br />

Controls: Evidence from India. <strong>The</strong><br />

Economic Journal 106, 359–374.<br />

• Ghatak, M. (2000). Screening by the<br />

Company you Keep: Joint Liability<br />

Lending and the Peer Selection Effect.<br />

Economic Journal 110, 601–31.<br />

• ha, R. and A. Sharma (2004). Structural<br />

Breaks, Unit Roots and Cointegration:<br />

A Further<br />

• Test of the Sustainability of the Indian<br />

Fiscal Deficit. Public Finance Review<br />

32.<br />

• Joshi, V. and I. M. D. Little (1996). India’s<br />

Economic Reforms: 1991-2001.<br />

Oxford: Claredon Press.<br />

• Kapila, R. and U. Kapila (1996). Understanding<br />

India’s Economic Reforms.<br />

New Delhi: Acedamic Foundation.<br />

• Kohli, R. (2001). Aspects of Exchange<br />

Rate Behavior and Management in<br />

India 1993-98. Economic and Political<br />

Weekly January 29.<br />

• Obstfeld, M. (1995). <strong>The</strong> Mirage of<br />

Fixed Exchange Rates. NBER Working<br />

Paper No. 5191.<br />

• Polackova, H. (1999). Contingent Government<br />

Liabilities: A Hidden Fiscal<br />

Risk. Finance and Development 36.<br />

• Puhazhendhi, V. (1995). Transaction<br />

Costs of Lending to the Rural Poor:<br />

Non-Governmental Organizations<br />

and Self-Help Groups of the Poor as<br />

Intermediaries for Banks in India.<br />

Banking with the Poor (BWTP) network.<br />

• Rangrajan, C. (1991). Recent Monetary<br />

Policy Measures and the Balance<br />

of Payments. Reserve Bank of India<br />

Bulletin July.<br />

• RBI (1990-2003b). Report on Currency<br />

and Finance.<br />

• RBI (1993-2003a). Trend and Progress<br />

in Banking in India.<br />

• RBI (1993-2003c). Reserve Bank of<br />

India Bulletin.<br />

• RBI (1997). Report on Currency and<br />

Finance.<br />

• RBI (2003d). Reserve Bank of India<br />

Annual Report.<br />

• Saez, L. (2001). Banking Reform in<br />

India and China. International Journal<br />

of Finance and Economics 6, 235–44.<br />

• Saggar, M. (1999). Some <strong>Issue</strong>s Relating<br />

to Exchange Rate Policy in India in<br />

the Post Liberalization Period. Ph. D.<br />

Dissertation, Indira Gandhi Institute<br />

of Development Research (IGIDR),<br />

Mumbai, India.<br />

• Sharma, A. (2004) Fiscal Deficits,<br />

Banking Crises And Adjustment Policy<br />

In A Semi-Open Economy Ph. D<br />

Dissertation, Australian National University,<br />

Canberra, Australia<br />

• Shirai, S. (2002). Banking Sector Reforms<br />

in India and China: Does India’s<br />

Experience Offer Lessons for China’s<br />

Future Reform Agenda. JBIC Discussion<br />

Paper No.2.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

131


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 3: Post-reform Exchange Rate Variability<br />

Prior to 1991, the exchange rate regime<br />

in India, was pegged to a currency <strong>The</strong> plots show the nominal exchange<br />

the currency.<br />

basket. Hence India had a fixed rate rate remained almost stable during the<br />

regime. Figure 1 plots the exchange rate two decades of the 1970’s and 1980’s.<br />

and its annual change, for rupee from <strong>The</strong> rate of change moved in a band of<br />

1970 to 1990. A positive change +/- 6 percent in the 1970’s except for<br />

indicates depreciation and a negative<br />

change indicates appreciation of percent due to the oil price<br />

1979 when the rupee depreciated by 10<br />

shock.<br />

During the 1991 financial crisis, faced<br />

with very low forex reserves the government<br />

floated the rupee, though the<br />

transition was gradual. Between 1991-<br />

93 there was a dual exchange rate regime<br />

and the rupee was subsequently<br />

floated in early 1993. International experience<br />

has shown exchange rate variability<br />

increases with a change to a<br />

more flexible rate regime. This has not<br />

been the case for India even after a decade<br />

of a floating rate regime as evident<br />

from the Figure 2 which plots the real<br />

effective exchange rate for the rupee<br />

from 1993-2002. This is essentially because<br />

a stable exchange rate remains an<br />

important objective of government exchange<br />

rate policy. Saggar (1999) notes<br />

the RBI’s intervention (measured by<br />

changes in foreign reserves) has in fact<br />

increased in the post 1993 period.<br />

<strong>The</strong> central bank has used both direct<br />

and indirect methods of market<br />

intervention. 5 <strong>The</strong> main objective of<br />

government policy is to keep the exchange<br />

rate aligned with the fundamentals<br />

of the economy like inflation. Thus<br />

the exchange rate depreciated by 1.5<br />

percent in September 1997 and the<br />

speed of depreciation was moderated<br />

by intervention sales by the RBI. In the<br />

central banks’ own words “...the conduct<br />

of exchange rate policy was guided<br />

by the need to maintain a delicate balance<br />

between the considerations of external<br />

competitiveness and price stability”<br />

(RBI, 1997, page I-9). This is also<br />

confirmed by analyzing the standard<br />

deviation of the rate of change in exchange<br />

rates, a measure of variability<br />

of the exchange rate. <strong>The</strong> standard deviation<br />

was 4.7 from 1970-80, 4.6 from<br />

1980-90 and 4.7 from 1993-2003. This<br />

122 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 4: Trends In Major Macroeconomic Indicators (1970-99)<br />

evidence clearly indicates that although<br />

the rupee has been floated, the government<br />

plays an important role in influencing<br />

demand and supply of forex reserves<br />

and thereby the exchange rate.<br />

4. Post-1991 Banking Reforms<br />

Financial sector reform was launched<br />

in 1991, based on the recommendation<br />

of the Narsimhan Committee (1991)<br />

that was set up by the government. <strong>The</strong><br />

1991 financial reforms were based on<br />

five fundamentals: Strengthening prudential<br />

norms and market discipline,<br />

appropriate adoption of international<br />

benchmarks, management of organiza-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

123


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 5: Trends In Major Banking Variables (1970-99)<br />

tional change and consolidation, technological<br />

upgrading and human resource<br />

development. Figure-3 compares<br />

major macroeconomic variables in the<br />

pre-reform and post-reform period.<br />

<strong>The</strong> banking sector reforms specifically<br />

included the following measures:<br />

<strong>The</strong> RBI reduced the CRR from 15<br />

percent in 1991 to 5.75 percent in November<br />

2001. <strong>The</strong> cash reserve ratio<br />

was further reduced to 4.5 percent in<br />

May 2004, although it remains higher<br />

than its statuary minimum level of 3<br />

percent. <strong>The</strong> SLR has been reduced<br />

from 38.5 percent in 1991 to 25 percent<br />

124 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


Pramod K.Yadav Ritesh Agarwal<br />

Doctoral Students, Indian Institute of Management (IIM)-Ahmedabad<br />

Indian Corporate Bond Market:<br />

<strong>The</strong> Road Ahead<br />

"In the age of globalization, where vast amounts<br />

of capital can be moved across the world with<br />

a mere computer keystroke, functioning bond<br />

markets are more important than ever. So is<br />

having a group of infl uential, globally known<br />

bond buyers who can alert the government if its<br />

policies are roiling markets, either by dumping<br />

its debt or speaking out. It's incredibly important<br />

that India's government and central bank continue<br />

to nurture the market's growth. India needs<br />

to take advantage of the favorable economic<br />

climate to strengthen regulation, improve transparency<br />

and bolster liquidity. It also needs to act<br />

faster to increase foreign investors' ability to move<br />

funds here. were put to productive use here.<br />

investor and business confi dence...India is<br />

stepping up efforts to do just that. For all China's<br />

advantages, bonds are one important area where<br />

India is ahead. It means markets here in Mumbai<br />

are likely to have their own Bill Gross before<br />

Shanghai does."<br />

William Pesek Jr.,<br />

International Herald Tribune,(IHT),<br />

October 11, 2004<br />

<strong>The</strong> Corporate Debt Market in<br />

India is underdeveloped, both in<br />

terms of the market participation<br />

and efficient price discovery; and the<br />

volume of fixed income securities is very<br />

small as compared to equity market.<br />

Most of the big Indian Corporate still<br />

seek bank finance and retained earnings<br />

to fulfill their funding requirements. Primary<br />

corporate debt market is dominated<br />

by non-banking finance companies and<br />

the total corporate debt market is a minuscule<br />

2 percent of the total debt market.<br />

Over the years, Indian firms have<br />

relied more on the equity market, retained<br />

earnings and bank loans to fulfill<br />

the funding requirements. To make the<br />

matter worse, the secondary market in<br />

corporate bonds has also not picked up<br />

as desired. Securities Exchange Board of<br />

India (SEBI) and the stock exchanges did<br />

realize the need of corporate bond and<br />

introduced various regulations to provide<br />

an impetus to the bond market; however<br />

none of the regulations or norm could<br />

yield the desired results. <strong>The</strong> debt market<br />

in India is broadly classified as government<br />

securities market and corporate<br />

securities market. <strong>The</strong> Indian debt market<br />

is highly skewed towards government<br />

securities market. Total outstanding debt<br />

of India has increased over the years and<br />

was around 36 percent of the GDP in<br />

2004-way below the mature financial<br />

markets (IMF,2004). <strong>The</strong> current government<br />

bond segment resulting from<br />

persistently high fiscal deficits and regulatory<br />

requirement in India is about 40<br />

percent of the GDP –at par with the well<br />

functioning financial markets. Nearly 90<br />

percent of the bonds issued in India are<br />

government bonds. <strong>The</strong> enormous <strong>size</strong> of<br />

the government bond market is not surprising<br />

considering the persistent high<br />

fiscal deficit and consequentially high<br />

public sector borrowings. Mandatory requirement<br />

on the part of banks to invest<br />

through statutory liquidity reserve<br />

(SLR,currently at 25 percent) compounds<br />

the problem. Perceived risk free nature<br />

132 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

of the government bonds leads banks to<br />

include even greater percentage of government<br />

bonds in their portfolio than the<br />

prescribed SRL of 25 percent. Government<br />

and Reserve Bank of India introduced<br />

many structural changes to improve<br />

transparency in the market<br />

dealings, method of primary auctions, allowing<br />

Primary Dealers, borrowings at<br />

market determined rates, and creating<br />

technology platforms like NDS to recognize<br />

the institutional characteristics of<br />

the market. <strong>The</strong> same kind of impetus<br />

has been lacking in the Indian corporate<br />

bond markets and as a result of this, major<br />

source of corporate funding is all but<br />

non-existent.<br />

<strong>The</strong> corporate bond market, in the<br />

sense of raising debt through public issuance<br />

in capital market, is shadowed by<br />

growing equity market and government<br />

bond market and was less than 2 percent<br />

of Indian GDP in 2004 compared to 50<br />

percent in Singapore,68 percent in South<br />

Korea, and 143 percent in USA (IMF,<br />

2004). A well developed corporate bond<br />

market facilitates the firms operating in<br />

the economy to devise their optimum for Indian debt capital markets”,<br />

capital structure and investors to have (Nov,<strong>2007</strong>), predicts that Indian bond<br />

better spectrum of asset classes to 160<br />

hedge and diversify their fixed income<br />

risks. <strong>The</strong> share of corporate<br />

140<br />

Government Debt<br />

bonds in the total bond issued has 120<br />

also decreased from 34 percent in<br />

Corporate Debt<br />

100<br />

1999-00 to a 29 percent in 2003-<br />

80<br />

04. <strong>The</strong> weak status of corporate<br />

bond market was mainly due to 60<br />

dominance of government securities<br />

and structure of the market<br />

itself where government was borrowing<br />

at pre-decided coupon<br />

rates from a group of investors<br />

such as banks. <strong>The</strong> public sector<br />

Debt As Percentage Of GDP<br />

40<br />

20<br />

undertakings (PSUs) have persistently<br />

overshadowed the private sector bond issuance<br />

over the years. Corporate debt<br />

can be raised either by private placement<br />

or public issue. Private placement is preferred<br />

owing to the regulatory processes,<br />

higher cost associated with public issuance,<br />

and enormous hurdles in public issues<br />

process in the form of various types<br />

of disclosure, registration requisites etc<br />

(NSE, 2005).<strong>The</strong>se reasons have also incentivized<br />

the corporate to raise debt<br />

from abroad because of lesser listing and<br />

disclosure requirements, lower cost, and<br />

better liquidity in secondary market.<br />

Debt raised abroad increased around two<br />

and a half times from 2001 to 2005 equivalent<br />

to 60 percent of corporate issuance<br />

in domestic debt market (NSE, 2005).<br />

<strong>The</strong> latest report by the Goldman Sachs<br />

titled, “ Bonding the BRICs: Big chance<br />

0<br />

market is going to grow fourfold and<br />

reach to the level of $1.5 trillion by 2016.<br />

It also reports that the corporate bond<br />

market will annually grow by around 28<br />

percent from $100 billion to $575 billion<br />

in 2016.Such a high benchmark (required<br />

growth of 28 percent) when contrasted<br />

with almost non-existent growth rate of<br />

the corporate bond market (historically)<br />

raises a big concern for policy makers and<br />

According to Goldman Sachs, Indian bond market is going<br />

to grow fourfold and reach to the level of $1.5 trillion by<br />

2016. <strong>The</strong> corporate bond market will annually grow by<br />

around 28 % from $100 billion to $575 billion in 2016<br />

India<br />

China<br />

Korea<br />

Malaysia<br />

Singapore<br />

USA<br />

market participants equally. A robust<br />

policy framework together with a performance<br />

based regulatory approach is<br />

urgently required to push the market to a<br />

higher growth and market friendly frontier.<br />

<strong>The</strong> booming economy, growing<br />

populations, and rising household income<br />

are exerting huge demand for infrastructure<br />

services. <strong>The</strong> inability to meet such<br />

a fast growing demand has become more<br />

visible in recent past and evident by congestion<br />

on the roads, airports, ports, frequent<br />

electricity cut etc. <strong>The</strong>re is no way<br />

India can take its infrastructure requirement<br />

for granted if it aims to<br />

traverse the sustainable growth trajectory.<br />

<strong>The</strong> government officials estimate<br />

the infrastructure requirement<br />

of about $500 billion in next five<br />

years. It is also expected that about 40<br />

percent of the fund will be infused by<br />

the private sector. Considering the<br />

long term irreversible nature of infrastructure<br />

investment and short to<br />

medium term liabilities of banks, long<br />

term financing in the form of debt is<br />

widely accepted as the most appropri-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

133


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

External Commercial Borrowings<br />

Year<br />

ate financing approach. However current<br />

shallow status of Indian bond market<br />

does not seem to be geared to meet the<br />

target capital requirement. <strong>The</strong> inability<br />

to meet the financing requirement of infrastructure<br />

leads to a lower output and<br />

hence a shortfall in the welfare and GDP<br />

and other various dominos effects.<br />

<strong>The</strong> demand for corporate debt can be<br />

gauged by the fact that Indian corporate<br />

papers are in huge demand in overseas<br />

market in the form of external commercial<br />

borrowings (ECBs). In <strong>2007</strong> itself,<br />

the net ECB inflow in the country was<br />

about $16 billion and RBI had to tighten<br />

the norms on ECB borrowing in order to<br />

keep inflation and rupee-dollar exchange<br />

rate in check.<br />

ECB Gross<br />

inflow<br />

<strong>The</strong> experience of US and other developed<br />

countries clearly indicates that the<br />

corporate bond market played an important<br />

role in the development of the economy<br />

as a whole. During the last few years,<br />

DFI’s access to long-term funds has dwindled<br />

and they cannot meet the demand<br />

for term funds of industry and infrastructure<br />

sectors when investment activity is<br />

all set to pick up from the present low<br />

levels. Moreover, as the demand term<br />

debt increases significantly to finance<br />

ECB outflow<br />

(imputed)<br />

Net ECB<br />

inflow<br />

high level of investments, excessive dependence<br />

on banks will hit the creditworthy<br />

borrowers, as they would end up<br />

paying up more than what they would<br />

have to pay if they decide to raise funds<br />

from the market directly.<br />

DEMAND SIDE<br />

<strong>The</strong> corporate bond market in India is<br />

underdeveloped owing to the limitations/<br />

reluctance of the various market<br />

participants:-<br />

Corporate – <strong>The</strong> cash credit system of<br />

banks operates in effect like a loan in<br />

perpetuity, many corporates prefer it to<br />

bond financing where the amount has to<br />

be returned on a specific date. Moreover,<br />

they are either riding on the current equity<br />

boom in the economy or relying<br />

more on retained earnings.<br />

Foreign Institutional Investors are<br />

major players in the equities market.<br />

However, there exists a ceiling on their<br />

investment in the debt market (currently<br />

there is a ceiling of $1.5 billion on investment<br />

in corporate debt), they are present<br />

only in a limited way in the bond<br />

market.<br />

Pension Funds And <strong>The</strong> Insurance<br />

Sector could spurt the market activities<br />

but the absence of pension funds and low<br />

insurance penetration has meant limited<br />

demand for long-term bonds.<br />

Gross inflow<br />

on ECB<br />

2002 2687 4272 -1585<br />

2003 3514 5206 -1692 827<br />

2004 5228 8153 -2925 1714<br />

2005 9084 3890 5194 3856<br />

2006 14547 11824 2723 5463<br />

<strong>2007</strong> 21291 5207 16084 6744<br />

SOURCE - RBI<br />

Households too are almost completely<br />

absent from the market, due to the lack<br />

of an efficient legal system, and unhappy<br />

experience with debenture trustees.<br />

SUPPLY SIDE<br />

• Public Placement – <strong>The</strong>re are a lot<br />

many regulations related to disclosure<br />

and filing of the norms which adds to<br />

the overall costs of issuing the bonds.<br />

Corporate prefer private placements<br />

owing to less hassles and almost non<br />

existent disclosure norms. Though the<br />

government has limited the private<br />

placement partners to 50 in case of<br />

private placement, corporate has<br />

sought a way out because the partners<br />

can issue the debt issued to them to<br />

new partners.<br />

• Illiquidity – A large part of the market<br />

does not mark-to-market the corporate<br />

bond portfolio. As a result, once any<br />

bond goes into the books, it does not<br />

come out. This takes away liquidity<br />

from the market.<br />

• Trading is concentrated in AAA – rated<br />

bonds, as they are the safest and<br />

most liquid. A large part of the market,<br />

including insurance companies, provident<br />

funds and banks, has restrictions<br />

on private sector paper. Thus the<br />

bonds of public sector units are much<br />

more liquid than private sector<br />

bonds.<br />

Benefits Of Efficient Market For<br />

Market Participants<br />

Corporate<br />

• Availability of long term funds – An<br />

efficient bond market gives the freedom<br />

to issue long term debt. This is<br />

particularly important for India where<br />

there is a large requirement of infra-<br />

134 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

structure financing which involves long<br />

term loans. A well-functioning corporate<br />

bond market allows firms to tailor<br />

their asset and liability profiles and<br />

hence allows them to raise long-term<br />

funds to invest in ventures that have a<br />

long-term payoff.<br />

• Reduced fund costs – <strong>The</strong> corporate<br />

may borrow directly from the investors<br />

eliminating the intermediaries like<br />

banks which will reduce their overall<br />

cost of funds.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Financial System<br />

• <strong>The</strong> net interest margin of Indian banks<br />

has increased from about 225 basis points<br />

to 400 basis points during the last 10 years<br />

leading to a high cost of commercial borrowing.<br />

<strong>The</strong> high cost of commercial borrowing<br />

has prompted the big corporate<br />

to borrow from overseas markets however<br />

smaller companies are bound to borrow<br />

at high rates from the banks. <strong>The</strong><br />

high cost of borrowing is also evident<br />

from low credit-deposit ratio of Indian<br />

banks which is a almost 50 percent to that<br />

Credit-Deposit Ratio Of Indian Banks<br />

140<br />

120<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

130<br />

114<br />

101<br />

92 90<br />

83 81 80 79<br />

61 61<br />

53<br />

China<br />

UK<br />

Source -RBI & McKinsey<br />

Malaysia<br />

US<br />

Korea<br />

Thailand<br />

Japan<br />

Brazil<br />

Singapore<br />

India<br />

Czech Rep<br />

Turkey<br />

of China. <strong>The</strong> corporate bond market can rating agencies, a wide range of corporate<br />

exert a competitive pressure on commercial<br />

banks in the matter of lending to priing<br />

sophisticated credit analysis, an op-<br />

debt securities and derivatives demandvate<br />

business and thus help improve the portunity to make private placements,<br />

efficiency of the capital market as a whole. and efficient procedures for corporate.<br />

A well developed corporate bond market<br />

would lead to a reduction in the systemic Investors<br />

risk and probability of crisis. This is because<br />

the presence of such an environ-<br />

is also essential for the investors because<br />

A well developed corporate bond market<br />

ment is associated with greater accounting<br />

transparency, a large community of safe way of investment but also helps<br />

it not only provides them an alternate and<br />

professional financial analysts, respected them diversify their risks.<br />

Leading Rates In India<br />

SOURCE - RBI<br />

Average5 Year<br />

Deposit Rates Average<br />

Lending<br />

Rates<br />

Spread(%)<br />

1997-98 11.75 14.00 2.25<br />

1998-99 11.00 12.50 1.50<br />

1999-00 10.25 12.25 2.00<br />

2000-01 9.75 11.50 1.75<br />

2001-02 8.25 11.50 3.25<br />

2002-03 5.88 11.13 5.25<br />

2003-04 5.38 10.63 5.25<br />

2004-05 6.00 10.50 4.50<br />

2005-06 6.63 10.50 3.88<br />

2006-07 7.25 11.25 4.00<br />

Developing <strong>The</strong> Corporate Bond<br />

Market<br />

Increasing Market Participation<br />

By Widening <strong>The</strong> Investor Base<br />

Banks – At present, banks’ loan portfolios<br />

are not treated at par with their investment<br />

portfolio. <strong>The</strong> investment<br />

portfolio (banks’ investments in corporate<br />

bonds) has to be marked to market<br />

where as the same constraint is not there<br />

in the case of a loan extended to the same<br />

corporate. Hence there is incentive for<br />

the bank to extend loans to the corporate<br />

instead of investing in corporate bonds.<br />

Banks’ investments in corporate bonds<br />

need to be encouraged especially by<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

135


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

bringing in changes in the prudential<br />

regulatory mechanism which treats loans<br />

portfolio on par with investment portfolio.<br />

Moreover, Co-operative banks are<br />

permitted to invest only a small part of<br />

their deposits in bonds issued by PSUs<br />

and only scheduled co-operative banks<br />

are allowed to invest in private sector<br />

bonds. Allowing all co-operatives banks<br />

to invest in high quality corporate bonds<br />

would be helpful as cooperative banks<br />

have large deposits.<br />

FIIs – <strong>The</strong> investment limits of FII in<br />

corporate bonds should be increased<br />

because FIIs are a major investor class<br />

and can bring volumes to the corporate<br />

bond markets. Though the limit was<br />

hiked recently to USD 1.5 billion, still<br />

this is too small for big players taking any<br />

active interest in this market<br />

meaningfully.<br />

Provident Funds And Pension<br />

Funds – <strong>The</strong>se should be allowed to<br />

invest on the basis of rating rather than<br />

in terms of category of issuers. This may<br />

encourage these funds to invest in high<br />

quality corporate bonds. Currently, these<br />

funds are allowed to invest only up to 10<br />

percent of the accruals in a year in private<br />

corporate bonds and 40 percent of the<br />

corpus can be invested in bonds issued by<br />

public sector undertakings. As the Risk<br />

profile of a large number of the PSUs<br />

established by the state governments is<br />

not materially different from that of several<br />

private corporate sector companies.<br />

ECB in India has increased during the last fi ve years.<br />

This is an indication that Indian corporate want to raise<br />

debt... which is not easily available in the market owing to<br />

regulatory issues and high cost of borrowing<br />

Hence, investment that rating quality as<br />

indicated by the recognized rating companies<br />

should become the main criteria<br />

for investment in corporate bonds and<br />

not category of bonds in terms of issuers.<br />

Thus the guidelines issued to PFs and<br />

EPFs need not discriminate between<br />

State Govt. PSUs and private corporate<br />

sector entities. To encourage small investors,<br />

the bond market structure should<br />

emulate the equity market structure and<br />

retail investors should be able to buy and<br />

sell bonds without any restriction on the<br />

minimum market lot. Currently an investor<br />

can buy even one share in the equity<br />

market.<br />

Increasing Market Participation<br />

By Widening <strong>The</strong> <strong>Issue</strong>r Base<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Issue</strong>r base can be increased primarily<br />

by reviewing the current guidelines<br />

for issuance, disclosure and listing of corporate<br />

bonds. <strong>The</strong> current regulations<br />

and guidelines should be made less stringent<br />

so that it would become easier for<br />

the companies to issue bonds. On the flip<br />

side, regulations are needed to promote<br />

the volume and liquidity in the primary<br />

market apart from increased issuance.<br />

Currently banks are allowed to issue<br />

bonds of maturities over five years only<br />

for financing infrastructure sector. Since<br />

banks are one of the leading issuers of<br />

bonds, they should be allowed to issue<br />

bonds of maturities over five years subject<br />

to their asset liability matching norms.<br />

<strong>The</strong> development of an interest rate derivatives<br />

markets is a major prerequisite<br />

to facilitate this.<br />

Banks are one of the major issuers of<br />

bonds to augment their tier-II capital and<br />

these bonds are in turn subscribed to by<br />

other banks (cross holdings). This reduces<br />

the overall volume and liquidity in the<br />

market. Regulatory caps should be fixed<br />

for such cross investments so that other<br />

participants are given an opportunity to<br />

subscribe to these bonds.<br />

Market Makers<br />

Market makers provide exit options to<br />

investors to buy or sell bonds whenever<br />

desired by the investors. <strong>The</strong> market<br />

making in corporate bonds is necessary<br />

as the market is in a nascent stage and it<br />

would require the psychological comfort<br />

in the beginning. Investment banks that<br />

help corporate to raise money from the<br />

market can possibly be roped in to market<br />

making in the bonds which they have<br />

helped in issuance.<br />

Listing Norms To Be Eased And<br />

Enhancing Liquidity<br />

As mentioned earlier, External Commercial<br />

Borrowing in India has increased<br />

during the last five years which is an indication<br />

that Indian corporate want to<br />

raise debt which is not easily available in<br />

the market owing to regulatory issues<br />

and high cost of borrowing. <strong>The</strong>re is less<br />

issuance of corporate debt in the first<br />

place and secondly disclosure and documentation<br />

norms deter the corporate to<br />

issue debt publicly. Thus, the corporate<br />

debt market is dominated by private<br />

placements. For listed entities, norms<br />

can be made simpler; they should be allowed<br />

an abridged version of disclosure;<br />

whereas unlisted companies issuing<br />

136 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

bonds to institutional investors and<br />

QIBs, rating should form the basis for<br />

placement. However, companies which<br />

are not listed and which are opting for<br />

the private placement mode should be<br />

subjected to stringent disclosure norms.<br />

Privately placed bonds should be mandatorily<br />

listed within seven days from the<br />

date of allotment, as is the case with public<br />

issues. <strong>The</strong> practice of suspension of<br />

trading/delisting of securities in case of<br />

non compliance with listing norms by an<br />

issuer needs to be replaced by heavy penalties<br />

on the promoters and directors of<br />

the erring company. Debenture trusties<br />

should be made more responsible and<br />

accountable. <strong>The</strong>y also should ensure<br />

that important information such as rating<br />

downgrades should be disseminated<br />

to the investors.<br />

Trade Reporting System<br />

<strong>The</strong>re should be a mechanism to capture<br />

all the information relating to trades in<br />

corporate bonds, disseminate the same<br />

and maintaining a database of trade history.<br />

Regulators should direct the market<br />

participants to report all the transactions<br />

done by them to the trade<br />

reporting system.<br />

Trading, Clearing And Settling<br />

Mechanism<br />

Anonymous screen based order matching<br />

trading systems should be adopted in<br />

order to improve the transparency and<br />

efficiency in the corporate bond transactions.<br />

However, multiple trading platforms<br />

may also impact the liquidity adversely.<br />

Moreover, novation and<br />

multilateral netting should form the<br />

backbone for risk mitigation and enhancement<br />

of liquidity.<br />

Development Of Derivative<br />

Market<br />

Derivative market is essential for hedging<br />

interest rate risk. Though interest<br />

rate swaps and forward rate agreements<br />

exist in India, there is a need for advanced<br />

derivative instruments for better<br />

price discovery and hedging. RBI has<br />

already initiated certain steps and<br />

formed committees to formulate<br />

a framework for some advanced<br />

derivative instruments.<br />

Price Distorting <strong>Issue</strong>s<br />

Stamp duty is a levied by the State<br />

Governments and RBI should reduce the<br />

stamp duty and rationalize it<br />

between different states. Tax Deducted<br />

at Source (TDS) also distorts the pricing<br />

of bonds. TDS on interest income from<br />

corporate bonds is not uniformly<br />

applicable to all the investors. While insurance<br />

companies and mutual funds are<br />

exempt from the provisions of TDS, all<br />

other market players are subject to it in<br />

respect of interest paid on corporate<br />

bonds. An automated computerized<br />

trading system and a meaningful price<br />

discovery process cannot be introduced<br />

because of the differing TDS treatment<br />

for different market player. <strong>The</strong>refore it<br />

is desirable to have a uniformTDS rule<br />

for all the market players.<br />

<strong>The</strong> shut period (for reckoning the registered<br />

owner of the bond for payment of<br />

coupons) is very long and may be brought<br />

on par with that for the government securities,<br />

which is one day. It is also necessary<br />

to standardize the day count conventions.<br />

Currently the day count<br />

conventions in the market differ depending<br />

upon the nature of the<br />

instruments and the nature of<br />

the transaction.<br />

References<br />

• Sharma, V. K. and Sinha, Chandan.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Corporate Debt Market in India<br />

(2006). Bank for International Settlements,<br />

Paper No. 26<br />

• Stone, M. Corporate Debt Restructuring<br />

in East Asia: Some Lessons from<br />

International Experience (1998). International<br />

Monetary Fund<br />

PPAA/98/13<br />

• Mohan, R. 'Recent Trends in the Indian<br />

Debt Market and Current Initiatives'<br />

(2006)<br />

• Bose, S and Coondoo, D. A Study of the<br />

Indian Corporate Bond Market (2003).<br />

Social Science Research Network.<br />

• Kar , S and Khasnobis, B.G. <strong>The</strong> Corporate<br />

Debt Market-A Firm-Level<br />

Panel Study for India. Research Paper<br />

No. 2006/50, UNU-WIDER World<br />

Institute for Development Economics<br />

Research<br />

• Reddy, Y.V. '<strong>Issue</strong>s and challenges in<br />

the development of the debt market in<br />

India' (2003). BIS Paper No.11, Bank<br />

for International Settlements<br />

• '<strong>The</strong> Indian Bond Market, Current<br />

Situations and Developments' (2006),<br />

Keio University.<br />

• India’s Capital Market (<strong>2007</strong>), Deutsche<br />

Bank<br />

• "Bonding the BRICs: A big chance for<br />

India’s Debt Capital Market"(<strong>2007</strong>),<br />

Goldman Sachs<br />

• IMF Global Financial Stability Report,<br />

September <strong>2007</strong><br />

• IMF Global Financial Stability Report,<br />

April <strong>2007</strong><br />

• NSE Debt RoundUp, October <strong>2007</strong><br />

• "India on fire", <strong>The</strong> Economist; February<br />

1st <strong>2007</strong><br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

137


Paul Conway Richard Herd<br />

Sean Dougherty<br />

Organisation For Economic Co-operation And Development (OECD), Paris<br />

Just How Free Are India's Labour<br />

And Product Markets?<br />

"Freedom in economic arrangements<br />

is itself a component<br />

of freedom broadly understood,<br />

so economic<br />

freedom is an end in itself ...<br />

Economic freedom is also an<br />

indispensable means toward<br />

the achievement of political<br />

freedom."<br />

-Milton Friedman<br />

1. Since the mid 1980s India has undergone<br />

a profound shift in economic management<br />

as successive reforms have<br />

progressively moved the economy towards<br />

a market-based system. State intervention<br />

and control over economic<br />

activity has been reduced significantly<br />

and the role of private-sector entrepreneurship<br />

increased. Overall, reform has<br />

had a major beneficial impact on the<br />

economy. Annual growth in GDP per<br />

capita has accelerated from just 1¼ per<br />

cent in the three decades after Independence<br />

to 7½ per cent currently, a<br />

rate of growth that will double average<br />

income in a decade. <strong>The</strong> sustainable<br />

growth rate of the economy is currently<br />

estimated to be 8½ per cent and India<br />

is now the fourth largest economy in the<br />

world when measured using the most<br />

up-to-date purchasing power parities.<br />

Increased economic growth has helped<br />

reduce poverty, which has begun to fall<br />

in absolute terms.<br />

2. In general, areas of the Indian business<br />

sector that have been opened to<br />

private sector involvement have responded<br />

well. In service sectors where<br />

government regulation has either been<br />

eased significantly or was less burdensome<br />

to start with, such as insurance,<br />

asset management and information<br />

technology, output has grown rapidly<br />

with exports of information technology<br />

enabled services being particularly<br />

strong and a key component of India’s<br />

economic transformation. In some of<br />

the former fully government-owned infrastructure<br />

sectors, such as telecommunications<br />

and domestic civil aviation,<br />

opening to the private sector has produced<br />

exemplary results and growth has<br />

been phenomenal. <strong>The</strong> market shares<br />

of new entrants in both these sectors are<br />

now over 75% while consumer choice<br />

has expanded and prices have fallen.<br />

3. Notwithstanding these and other success<br />

stories, government regulation is<br />

still excessively restrictive and acts as a<br />

barrier to private sector involvement in<br />

a number of areas. In this article we<br />

draw on the OECD’s first Economic<br />

138 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Survey of India, which was released in<br />

October <strong>2007</strong>, to briefly assess two areas<br />

in which regulation could be made<br />

more supportive of competition and private<br />

sector involvement: the business<br />

environment in markets for goods and<br />

services (henceforth referred to as the<br />

product market) and labour markets.<br />

This work is based on field work in<br />

twenty one states that has enabled us to<br />

construct cross-state indicators of regulation<br />

in product and labour markets.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are other areas where government<br />

interference is also high, such as<br />

the financial and energy sectors, and<br />

areas where large subsidies are paid.<br />

Our views on these areas can be found<br />

in the Survey.<br />

Despite Liberalisation, Product<br />

Market Regulation Could<br />

Still Do More To Support<br />

Competition<br />

Figure 1. Product Market Regulations: An International Comparison<br />

Australia<br />

UK<br />

Iceland<br />

US<br />

Ireland<br />

Denmark<br />

New Zealand<br />

Canada<br />

Sweden<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Japan<br />

Finland<br />

Belgium<br />

Netherlands<br />

Austria<br />

Slovak R.<br />

Germany<br />

Norway<br />

Korea<br />

Portugal<br />

Spain<br />

Switzerland<br />

Grance<br />

Czech R.<br />

Greece<br />

Italy<br />

Brazil<br />

Hungary<br />

Mexico<br />

Chile<br />

Turkey<br />

Poland<br />

INDIA<br />

number of barriers that do limit private<br />

sector involvement and competition in<br />

markets.<br />

PSEs for 14 % of GDP, rising to 22 % of the non-agricultural<br />

business sector and an even higher share of activity<br />

in the formal sector of the economy. Many of the sectors<br />

in which they operate are inherently competitive<br />

OECD<br />

Average<br />

0 1 2 3<br />

<strong>The</strong> indicator score runs from 0-6 from least to most restrictive of competition<br />

4. Overall, product market regulation in<br />

India restricts completion to a greater<br />

extent than in all OECD countries and<br />

both Brazil and Chile (Figure 1). This<br />

is despite some aspects of India’s regulatory<br />

framework in product markets<br />

being comparable with best practice in<br />

OECD countries. For example, formal<br />

legal barriers to market entry have been<br />

removed in almost all sectors and there<br />

is minimal government interference in<br />

the conduct of private sector firms<br />

through, for example, price controls and<br />

special voting rights (notwithstanding<br />

restrictions on the voting rights of private<br />

shareholders in government-owned<br />

banks). <strong>The</strong>re are, however, still a<br />

<strong>The</strong> Public Enterprise Sector Is<br />

Large And Distorts Competition<br />

5. A high level of government involvement<br />

in commercial activity is one important<br />

reason why India’s business<br />

environment is less supportive of competition<br />

in comparison to other countries.<br />

Overall, public enterprises account<br />

for 14% of GDP, rising to 22% of<br />

the non-agricultural business sector and<br />

an even higher share of activity in the<br />

formal sector of the economy. Many of<br />

the sectors in which public sector enterprises<br />

(PSEs) operate are inherently<br />

competitive.<br />

6. PSEs have a negative effect on the<br />

business environment for a number of<br />

reasons. First and foremost, because<br />

government plays the dual role of major<br />

market player and policy maker (and<br />

sometimes regulator in infrastructure<br />

sectors), there is often no clear separation<br />

between the ownership function<br />

and other functions that influence market<br />

conditions. For example, PSEs are<br />

often required to fulfil social and public<br />

policy obligations with their governance<br />

adversely affected by political interference<br />

and the use of civil servants as directors.<br />

Moreover, in many states the<br />

strategic commercial choices of PSEs<br />

often have to be cleared by the state assembly.<br />

Finally, the procurement poli-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

139


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 2. Distribution Of Rates Of Return Of Public Sector Enterprises<br />

Rate of Return (%)<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

-10<br />

-20<br />

-30<br />

-40<br />

PrivateSector Listed Firms<br />

PSEs (Centre)<br />

PSEs (State)<br />

-50<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90<br />

Percentile<br />

cies of the central and state governments<br />

often favour PSEs. Because they<br />

dominate some markets, political interference<br />

in the operation of PSEs also<br />

adversely influences overall market conditions.<br />

7. <strong>The</strong>re have been some attempts to<br />

commercialise the activities of central<br />

PSEs through, for example, the Navratna<br />

and Mini-Ratna concepts and<br />

the introduction of higher limits for investments<br />

that do not need to be cleared<br />

by parliament. <strong>The</strong> proportion of loss<br />

significant variation across states (Table<br />

1). With a large tail of unprofitable<br />

firms, the total losses of loss-making<br />

central and state PSEs amounted to almost<br />

1% of GDP in 2005.<br />

8. <strong>The</strong>re are a number of ways in which<br />

the corporate governance of the PSEs<br />

could be improved to ensure a level<br />

playing field and government neutrality<br />

in its dealings with the private sector<br />

and thereby increase competition. <strong>The</strong><br />

centre and state governments need to<br />

transparently unbundle the commercial<br />

<strong>The</strong> financial health of the state-owned PSEs is, on average,<br />

poor and worse than that of the central enterprises.<br />

<strong>The</strong> total losses of loss-making central and state PSEs<br />

amounted to almost 1% of GDP in 2005<br />

making central enterprises has been reduced<br />

but, even so, the return earned by<br />

the median PSE was only 3% in 2005<br />

(after subsidies) against 10% in the private<br />

sector (Figure 2). <strong>The</strong> financial<br />

health of the state-owned PSEs is, on<br />

average, poor and worse than that of the<br />

central enterprises, although there is<br />

and promotional/policy roles of the<br />

PSEs. Moving towards a more centralised<br />

model of PSE management would<br />

be a large step in this direction. Currently,<br />

at the centre, responsibility for<br />

the PSEs rests primarily with the line<br />

ministry while the Department of Public<br />

Enterprises plays a coordinating role<br />

and elaborates the overall<br />

ownership policy. This decentralised<br />

model was predominant<br />

in OECD countries before<br />

the first wave of public<br />

sector reforms during the<br />

1970s. With the shift from<br />

industry-specific policies to<br />

more framework-oriented<br />

and market liberalisation<br />

policies, the main advantage<br />

of this approach of allowing a<br />

more activist industrial policy<br />

has now vanished.<br />

9. A more centralised approach,<br />

where PSEs are put<br />

under the responsibility of an investment<br />

agency, would achieve a clearer<br />

separation between policy and commercial<br />

functions and distance PSEs from<br />

political control. It would also facilitate<br />

a more unified and consistent ownership<br />

policy, simplify the often elaborate<br />

committee structures that currently supervise<br />

and control PSEs, and ensure<br />

equitable treatment of non-state shareholders.<br />

Care would be needed to ensure<br />

that centralising the ownership<br />

function of the PSEs did not entail the<br />

creation of additional layers of control<br />

or bureaucracy within government. Ultimately,<br />

the structure of the public administration<br />

needs to be reorganised to<br />

be more consistent with a modern-day<br />

focus on general framework conditions<br />

instead of the current “command and<br />

control” approach. This will entail a<br />

significant consolidation and reduction<br />

in the number of ministries and departments<br />

in both the central and state<br />

governments.<br />

10. In addition to a more centralised approach,<br />

the way in which any remaining<br />

140 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1. Performance Of State-Level PSEs<br />

Number<br />

of<br />

PSEs<br />

Proportion<br />

of loss making<br />

PSEs<br />

Losses of<br />

loss making<br />

PSEs<br />

Proportion of capital<br />

in 'non-working'<br />

PSEs<br />

Proportion of<br />

PSEs with negative<br />

net worth<br />

Rate of Return on<br />

Capital<br />

% % SGDP % % medium average<br />

Andhra Pradesh 54 15 -0.06 2.3 14.8 5.6 10.0<br />

Assam 43 77 -3.47 1.6 20.9 -3.3 -16.4<br />

Bihar 54 70 -1.38 13.0 11.1 -2.5 -7.7<br />

Chhattisgarh 11 36 -0.02 0.0 9.1 5.1 4.6<br />

Delhi 11 45 -4.21 0.0 9.1 3.6 -27.8<br />

Goa 16 63 -0.57 0.0 0.0 -0.1 -11.0<br />

Gujarat 51 39 -0.38 50.5 17.6 2.2 -8.9<br />

Haryana 29 59 -0.05 1.4 13.8 5.5 5.0<br />

Himachal<br />

21 62 -0.50 27.8 23.8 3.3 5.7<br />

Pradesh<br />

Jharkhand 6 17 -0.15 0.0 0.0 33.6 43.1<br />

Karnataka 82 41 -0.28 1.5 7.3 3.6 31.2<br />

Kerala 114 61 -0.39 1.1 14.0 1.7 -15.3<br />

Madhya Pradesh 42 33 -0.13 3.8 14.3 1.3 2.2<br />

Maharashtra 82 68 -0.38 3.2 20.7 -0.3 -4.6<br />

Orissa 69 70 -0.28 1.1 21.7 -1.3 -35.0<br />

Punjab 57 44 -0.23 0.3 15.8 -1.2 -12.0<br />

Rajasthan 24 38 -0.06 0.1 20.8 7.4 20.6<br />

Tamil Nadu 68 53 -0.14 0.6 29.4 2.4 -1.6<br />

Uttar Pradesh 94 62 -0.94 51.1 17.0 -1.0 -29.9<br />

Uttaranchal 25 60 -0.32 47.7 12.0 -2.3 -16.4<br />

West Bengal 86 72 -0.50 0.8 44.2 1.4 -45.2<br />

Source: OECD Analysis Of Data From <strong>The</strong> Comptroller and Auditor General<br />

obligations and responsibilities that<br />

PSEs are required to undertake in terms<br />

of public services should be clearly mandated<br />

by laws or regulations. <strong>The</strong>se obligations<br />

and responsibilities should<br />

also be disclosed to the general public<br />

and the related costs should be covered<br />

by government in a transparent manner.<br />

PSEs should be exposed to competitive<br />

conditions in access to finance. Finally,<br />

preferential procurement policies<br />

should be ended at the state level, following<br />

plans by central government to<br />

do so in 2008.<br />

11. Once these steps have been taken,<br />

the privatisation programme needs to<br />

be revitalised, especially in the competitive<br />

sectors of the economy. To date,<br />

privatisation has been slow and involved<br />

only partial sales which, according to<br />

international evidence, are less effective<br />

in raising productivity and profitability<br />

than full sales to the private sector,<br />

as control stays with the<br />

government. 1 Going forward, mixed<br />

sales that transfer control to the private<br />

sector and combine strategic investors<br />

with public share offerings, have the<br />

potential advantages of developing<br />

strong corporate governance structures<br />

and introducing new management and<br />

technology into the company. For PSEs<br />

operating in network sectors in which<br />

there are monopoly elements, the regulatory<br />

environment needs to be made<br />

consistent with private ownership and<br />

competition with independent regulators<br />

in place as part of the privatisation<br />

process. <strong>The</strong> worst performing and<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

141


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 3. Product Market Regulation And Average Labour Productivity<br />

120<br />

Average labour productivity, 1994 -2004<br />

100<br />

80<br />

60<br />

40<br />

20<br />

0<br />

0.5<br />

Goa<br />

Uttaranchal<br />

Delhi<br />

Correlation coefficient= -0.51<br />

t-statistic= -2.56<br />

Haryana<br />

Punjab<br />

Maharashtra<br />

Gujarat<br />

Tamil Nadu<br />

Jharkhand<br />

Kerala<br />

Assam Himachal Pradesh<br />

Madhya Pradesh<br />

Karnataka<br />

Andhra Pradesh<br />

Rajasthan<br />

Chhattisgarh<br />

Uttar Pradesh<br />

Orissa<br />

Bihar<br />

West Bengal<br />

1 1.5 2 2.5 3<br />

Product Market Regulation Indicator Score<br />

1. Reflecting data constraints, labour productivity in Chhattisgarh, Jharkhand & Uttaranchal is measured as the average over 2002-03 period.<br />

Figure 4. An International Comparison Of Employment Protection<br />

Legislation<br />

Australia<br />

United Kingdom<br />

Switzerland<br />

Canada<br />

Brazil<br />

Denmark<br />

Austria<br />

Ireland<br />

New Zealand<br />

Belgium<br />

Italy<br />

Hungary<br />

Finland<br />

Poland<br />

China<br />

Norway<br />

Mexico<br />

Chile<br />

EU 15<br />

Korea<br />

Australia<br />

Greece<br />

Japan<br />

France<br />

Slovak Republic<br />

Turkey<br />

Luxemburg<br />

Netherlands<br />

Germany<br />

Sweden<br />

Spain<br />

India<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Portugal<br />

OECD<br />

average<br />

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0<br />

4.5<br />

142 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 5. Net Employment Across Different Types Of Workers And Firms<br />

Net Employment (annual % change)<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

-5<br />

-10<br />

-15<br />

“non-working” PSEs need to be restructured<br />

to the point where they can be<br />

wound up.<br />

Inefficient Government Procedures,<br />

Particularly In Some Of<br />

<strong>The</strong> States, Act As A Barrier To<br />

Competition<br />

12. Administrative barriers to entrepreneurship<br />

are also high in India and another<br />

reason why the regulatory environment<br />

is less supportive of<br />

competition than in other countries. In<br />

many state governments, departments<br />

operate in “silos” with minimal information<br />

flows between them. Given a<br />

lack of coordination, administrative<br />

procedures often duplicate the same<br />

function across a number of departments,<br />

leaving firms and citizens in a<br />

complex maze of regulations and administrative<br />

requirements that can be<br />

repetitive, non-transparent, and sometimes<br />

contradictory. This increases<br />

compliance costs, especially for small<br />

firms, and discourages firm expansion,<br />

reducing competition and productivity.<br />

Large Small Overall<br />

All employees Workers Contract Supervisors Others<br />

Overly complex administrative procedures<br />

also increase the discretion of<br />

government staff, thereby facilitating<br />

corruption. In Transparency International’s<br />

Corruption Perceptions Index,<br />

India ranks 70 out of 163 countries in<br />

2006.<br />

13. A number of initiatives for simplifying<br />

red tape have been introduced by<br />

the central and state governments, with<br />

varying degrees of success. For example,<br />

some states have introduced “onestop<br />

shops” for providing information<br />

and, in some cases, applying for licenses<br />

and notifications. In some cases, a<br />

system of “deemed clearance” under<br />

which licenses are issued automatically<br />

if the licensing office does not act by the<br />

end of the statutory response period,<br />

have also been introduced. Some of the<br />

state governments have tried improving<br />

the interface with the private sector by<br />

simplifying and consolidating various<br />

application forms and registers and introducing<br />

self-inspection regimes. Information<br />

and communications technology<br />

(ICT) has also been<br />

successfully integrated into some administrative<br />

procedures.<br />

14. A key element in all efforts to simplify<br />

and improve government bureaucracy<br />

is that administrative processes are<br />

reengineered from the ground up. For<br />

example, one-stop shops need to be implemented<br />

along with other reforms<br />

geared towards cutting red tape. Otherwise<br />

they run the risk of simply adding<br />

another layer of bureaucracy to the<br />

approval process. Alternatively, using<br />

ICT to simply automate existing inefficient<br />

processes or disseminate information<br />

will only produce a limited payoff.<br />

At present, India has no centralised oversight body<br />

charged with reviewing regulatory proposals, using Regulatory<br />

Impact Analysis, to ensure that the costs of administrative<br />

burdens do not outweigh the benefi ts<br />

15. A crucial aspect of reengineering<br />

administrative processes, especially<br />

within some of the state governments,<br />

is improving the coordination of regulatory<br />

functions across government departments.<br />

This is complex and time<br />

consuming and requires a “whole of<br />

government” approach to institutional<br />

change. Indeed, the OECD experience<br />

has been that regulatory reform will often<br />

fail if left entirely to ministries. At<br />

present, India has no centralised oversight<br />

body charged with reviewing regulatory<br />

proposals, using Regulatory Impact<br />

Analysis, to ensure that the costs<br />

of administrative burdens do not outweigh<br />

the benefits. One advantage of<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

143


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

centralised oversight bodies is that they<br />

promote a consistent and systematic<br />

method of reform across the entire administration.<br />

Ideally, its objectives<br />

should be outlined as part of an explicit<br />

regulatory policy which generally<br />

helps countries make greater reform<br />

progress. 2<br />

States That Have Liberalised<br />

More Than Others Are Reaping<br />

<strong>The</strong> Benefits<br />

16. With state governments having control<br />

over certain aspects of regulatory<br />

policy and responsibility for enforcement,<br />

there are significant differences<br />

in the business environment across<br />

states as shown by our indicators. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

differences have an important bearing<br />

on economic performance. Labour productivity<br />

is higher in states with a regulatory<br />

environment that is more supportive<br />

of competition (Figure 3). <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are a number of reasons for this. First,<br />

virtually all of India’s foreign direct investment<br />

flows to the relatively more<br />

liberal states and domestic investment<br />

also appears to be higher, boosting state<br />

productivity. Second, in states with excessively<br />

restrictive administrative burdens<br />

firms are more likely to remain<br />

informal so as to avoid government administrative<br />

requirements. However,<br />

informal sector firms are usually much<br />

smaller with lower capital intensity and<br />

much less productive than formal sector<br />

enterprises.<br />

A Further Rationalisation And<br />

Reduction Of Restrictions On<br />

Foreign Is Trade Needed<br />

17. As recently as the beginning of this<br />

decade, India’s tariffs were the highest<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is a considerable gap between the standard tariff<br />

rates and the actual revenue raised from tariffs. Such gaps<br />

are indicative of special concessions to certain products or<br />

industries and distort the allocation of resources<br />

in the world and among the most discriminatory.<br />

Significant reforms to liberalise<br />

foreign trade have been undertaking<br />

since then and average tariffs<br />

are scheduled to reach the average<br />

level in ASEAN countries in the near<br />

future. Despite the fears of domestic<br />

producers, the manufacturing sector<br />

has profited from this policy shift and<br />

has been growing as fast as the service<br />

sector since 2003. Manufacturing exports<br />

have also started to grow rapidly,<br />

outpacing most other Asian countries<br />

in the first half of this decade. However,<br />

more could be done to liberalise<br />

foreign trade. Tariffs in ASEAN countries<br />

are still high in relation to those<br />

in developed countries. Moreover,<br />

there is a considerable gap in India between<br />

the standard tariff rates and the<br />

actual revenue raised from tariffs. Such<br />

gaps are indicative of special concessions<br />

granted to favour certain products<br />

or industries and distort the allocation<br />

of resources and lower<br />

productivity. Cross-country evidence<br />

has found that openness to global markets<br />

acts as an important stimulus to<br />

growth and ongoing reductions and rationalisation<br />

of the tariff structure in<br />

India would pay dividends.<br />

Labour Market Regulation Is<br />

Also Excessively Restrictive<br />

18. <strong>The</strong> dichotomy between formal and<br />

informal businesses is in part caused by<br />

labour market regulation, which is another<br />

key area in which restrictive government<br />

intervention imposes high<br />

economic costs. <strong>The</strong> strictness of employment<br />

regulation varies across different<br />

segments of the Indian labour<br />

market according to the <strong>size</strong> of firms<br />

and the type of employment contract.<br />

According to the OECD’s indicators of<br />

employment protection legislation<br />

(EPL), larger firms employing workers<br />

on regular contracts are subject to EPL<br />

that is more restrictive than in all but<br />

two OECD countries. For smaller<br />

firms, the extent of employment protection<br />

is similar to that in the OECD<br />

144 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

area. Very small businesses in the unorganised<br />

sector are subject to few labour<br />

regulations. Across different<br />

types of employment contact, EPL for<br />

temporary or contract employees is just<br />

above the OECD average. Allowing<br />

employees to carry out “non core” work<br />

on temporary agency contracts has<br />

been a main area of recent labour reform.<br />

19. <strong>The</strong>se differences in employment<br />

regulations are mirrored in recent development<br />

in labour markets. While<br />

employment growth has been strong<br />

over recent years, net gains in employment<br />

have been occurring almost exclusively<br />

in the unorganised part of the<br />

economy, which is not subject to restrictive<br />

labour market regulation. In<br />

the organised sector, employment has<br />

actually fallen. <strong>The</strong> detrimental impact<br />

of excessively restrictive EPL can also<br />

be clearly seen across types of employment<br />

contract; while contract employment<br />

has grown, regular employment<br />

has shrunk (Figure 5). This bias towards<br />

contract employment is only<br />

evident in larger firms, which bear the<br />

brunt of India’s restrictive EPL. Employment<br />

in smaller firms has been increasing<br />

for both contract and regular<br />

workers.<br />

20. It is often argued in India that strict<br />

EPL is not particularly harmful because<br />

firms find ways to circumvent the<br />

legislation. One way of avoiding difficulties<br />

with the labour laws is to stay<br />

small. Indeed, almost 90% of manufacturing<br />

firms employ less than ten people,<br />

a much larger share than in all<br />

OECD countries and China. However,<br />

most of these firms produce far below<br />

minimum efficient scale and are in the<br />

informal sector, the least productive<br />

segment of India’s business sector.<br />

Large firms, faced with high implicit<br />

employment costs, substitute capital<br />

for labour. Thus, restrictive EPL also<br />

effectively negates one of India’s key<br />

comparative advantages of relatively<br />

low-cost labour.<br />

21. Overall, labour market policy in India<br />

is ineffective at protecting employment;<br />

job destruction is lower in areas<br />

of the labour market not subject to the<br />

most restrictive of India’s labour market<br />

regulations. It has also resulted in<br />

a number of unintended consequences<br />

that have been accentuated as product<br />

markets have became more competitive.<br />

With newcomers to the labour<br />

market being pushed into lower-paid<br />

informal employment, economic<br />

growth has not been as inclusive as it<br />

could have been. Our indicators suggest<br />

that some states have introduced a<br />

degree of reform into labour markets.<br />

As yet, these reforms have been at the<br />

margin but, nonetheless, they do appear<br />

to be having some impact on labour<br />

markets. <strong>The</strong> share of labour income<br />

has stabilised in reforming states<br />

whereas it continues to fall in more restrictive<br />

states. Liberalisation also appears<br />

to be positively related to the<br />

extent of job turnover. Even if there is<br />

currently little evidence of employment<br />

gains in the most liberal states, higher<br />

job turnover improves a person’s chances<br />

of finding a job that matches their<br />

skills. To improve the functioning of<br />

the labour market as the labour force<br />

grows over the next decade comprehensive<br />

labour reform is needed to better<br />

protect all workers, lower the costs of<br />

employment adjustment, and help address<br />

the distortions that have<br />

emerged.<br />

Reforms Need To Be Ongoing If<br />

Government Is To Achieve Its<br />

Growth Target<br />

22. An important key to improving India’s<br />

economic performance further is to<br />

change policies at both the central and<br />

state government level that result in high<br />

levels of government interference in markets<br />

and restrict competition. Relative to<br />

recent history, the government has already<br />

moved significantly in this direction.<br />

However, this article has touched on<br />

areas in which less government intervention<br />

would increase the extent to which<br />

market forces are able to operate and<br />

result in more efficient outcomes. Reform<br />

in these key areas would yield enormous<br />

benefit for the Indian economy.<br />

Indeed, it is difficult to envisage government<br />

achieving its GDP growth target of<br />

10% in 2011 without further reform in<br />

these and other areas outlined in detail<br />

in the recent OECD Economic Survey of<br />

India. <strong>The</strong> impressive response of the<br />

Indian economy in areas that have been<br />

reformed in the past should give policymakers<br />

confidence that further liberalisation<br />

will deliver additional growth<br />

dividends and foster the process of pulling<br />

millions of people out of poverty.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

OECD (2003b), Privatising stateowned<br />

enterprises: an overview of<br />

policies and practices in OECD countries,<br />

OECD, Paris.<br />

2<br />

OECD (2002), Regulatory policies in<br />

OECD countries: From interventionism<br />

to regulatory governance,<br />

OECD, Paris.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

145


Rok SPRUK<br />

International Economist,<br />

Slovenia<br />

Going For Growth Through<br />

Economic Reforms: <strong>The</strong> Case Of India<br />

"A more innovative economy tends to devote<br />

more resources to investing of all kinds--in new<br />

employees and customers as well as new offi ce<br />

and factory space. And although this may come<br />

about through a shift of resources from the<br />

consumer-goods sector, it also comes through<br />

the recruitment of new participants to the labor<br />

force. Also, the resulting increase of employeeengagement<br />

serves to lower quit rates and,<br />

hence, to make possible a reduction of the<br />

“natural” unemployment rate. Thus, high dynamism<br />

tends to bring a pervasive prosperity to<br />

the economy on top of the productivity advances<br />

and all the self-realization going on. True,<br />

that may not be pronounced every month or<br />

year. Just as the creative artist does not create<br />

all the time, but rather in episodes and breaks,<br />

so the dynamic economy has heightened highfrequency<br />

volatility and may go through wide<br />

swings. Perhaps this volatility is not only normal<br />

but also productive from the point of view of<br />

creativity and, ultimately, achievement."<br />

-Edmund S. Phelps,<br />

Nobel Laureate in Economics, 2006<br />

<strong>The</strong> purpose of this article is to<br />

highlight some of the increasingly<br />

important issues regarding<br />

India’s economic prospects. In recent<br />

years, the operating capacity of India’s<br />

high-growing economy has been reflected<br />

by a surge in real GDP growth and a slight<br />

downturn in inflation pressures. By the<br />

end of <strong>2007</strong>, India’s GDP is estimated to<br />

rise by 8.9 percent and 8.4 percent in 2008<br />

while consumer price index increased by<br />

6.2 percent in <strong>2007</strong> and is expected to decrease<br />

to a mere 4.4 percent rate of overall<br />

price increase. 2 Growth estimates differ<br />

respectively subject to different<br />

methodological evolution of the real GDP<br />

growth measurement. It also depends on<br />

how the engines of growth are estimated,<br />

especially the importance of those factors<br />

in driving growth. <strong>The</strong>re are, in an academic<br />

economic literature, two main economic<br />

paradigms regarding the philosophy,<br />

theory and policy perspective of<br />

economic growth. Keynesian economic<br />

analysis supports the view that the aggregate<br />

demand 3 is a primary source of economic<br />

growth, claiming that an increase<br />

in the government spending per unit of<br />

output, increases investment activity and<br />

drives growth onto a stable trajectory.<br />

Keynesian emulation of the evolution of<br />

economic growth is based on false assertions.<br />

For example, Keynesian interpretation<br />

of economic growth neglects the<br />

impact of aggregate demand on inflation.<br />

As public spending and fiscal outlays increase,<br />

there is a growing probability of<br />

higher inflation. In the short-run, such<br />

policy features boost the economic activity<br />

through an expansionary monetary<br />

incentive, but in the long-run, the negative<br />

impact of government spending surpasses<br />

the short-run effect of government<br />

spending subject to a persistent inflationary<br />

pressures, falling growth rates and<br />

tight grip on capital markets. Notably,<br />

when government spending increases<br />

whereas fiscal expenditure is anchored in<br />

budget deficit, government borrowing reduces<br />

the supply of available monetary<br />

means and thus, increases the interest<br />

rate balance which investors have to bear.<br />

146 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

<strong>The</strong> answer to the question what impedes<br />

the investment is government spending<br />

and consequently budget deficit, but not<br />

only the budget deficit. Claiming that<br />

‘catch-up’ effects, when a country with<br />

low GDP per capita is catching-up countries<br />

with higher GDP per capita, allow an<br />

expansionary fiscal policy cannot be justified<br />

on empirical grounds and experience<br />

nevertheless. Empirically, high government<br />

spending reduces the operating capacity<br />

of the economic growth due to high<br />

tax burden and expanded public sector<br />

activities. It is crucial for a high-growing<br />

‘catch-up’ economy to reduce government<br />

spending and thus lay a solid foundation<br />

of growth. On the other side, contemporary<br />

growth theory empha<strong>size</strong>s the quality<br />

of growth engines such as the quality<br />

of institutions and means of productivity<br />

as determinants of economic growth.<br />

Neoclassical growth theory supports low<br />

government spending, low taxation of<br />

productive behavior, emphasis on price<br />

stability and solid free market institutions,<br />

the enforcement of private property rights<br />

and the rule of law. <strong>The</strong> latter is essential<br />

to macroeconomic stability. For decades,<br />

economists have questioned the impact of<br />

government spending on economic<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> Keynesian controversy began<br />

in 1930s when John Maynard Keynes<br />

wrote a voluminous book on the theory of<br />

employment, interest and money. Keynes<br />

argued that economy’s growth capacity<br />

can be boosted by injecting more purchasing<br />

power into the economy. Keynesians<br />

argued that government could reverse the<br />

economic downturn by borrowing more<br />

money from the private sector to help end<br />

the recession or depression and then return<br />

the money in all sorts of public incentive<br />

programs such as tax rebates. Keynesians<br />

supported high government<br />

spending because they believed that inflation<br />

was resulted from too much economic<br />

growth. <strong>The</strong> Keynesian economic analysis<br />

and doctrine became a corner-stone<br />

between 1930 and 1970. <strong>The</strong> overall impact<br />

of Keynesian economics bluntly diminished<br />

when the reality has shown that<br />

there is no long-run trade-off between<br />

inflation and unemployment; an assertion<br />

which was postulated into the famous<br />

Phillips curve. <strong>The</strong> economies which were<br />

operating under staunch Keynesian economic<br />

policy have faced significant economic<br />

downturns such as multi-year recessions<br />

and even economic depression.<br />

In 1991, Sweden slid into economic recession,<br />

facing high unemployment and rampant<br />

inflation. In Finland, where Keynesian<br />

economic policy dominated the<br />

public policy course from 1945 onwards,<br />

at the beginning of 1990s, economic<br />

growth turned into a decline in GDP,<br />

while inflation and unemployment grew<br />

severely. Numerous other countries faced<br />

the same experience of mistaken Keynesian<br />

economic policy.<br />

One of the fundamental questions<br />

which transition economies, such as India,<br />

face is what the optimal goals of economic<br />

policy are. In addition, what are<br />

important and empirically relevant areas<br />

demanding competitive economic reforms<br />

as a guarantee of sustainable long-term<br />

growth of real GDP and standards of living.<br />

In this article, I entail empirical studies<br />

into economic policy and attempt to<br />

suggest the reform agenda that would<br />

boost India’s competitiveness in terms of<br />

sound market economy with sustainable<br />

economic growth, price stability and freemarket<br />

institutions.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Empirics Of Growth<br />

Government spending and consumption<br />

is inversely related to the economic<br />

growth. 4 Higher government spending<br />

correlates with higher tax burden while<br />

higher taxes on productive behavior such<br />

as entrepreneurship, saving and investment,<br />

labor supply and innovation impede<br />

growth performance. On the other hand,<br />

the share of government spending positively<br />

relates to the share of public investment<br />

in the GDP. <strong>The</strong> quality and productivity<br />

of investment highly differs whether<br />

Public investment is directed via political decisions and its<br />

time preference rates of politicians on the electoral basis is<br />

subject to the realization of promises which is oftenly<br />

negatively related to growth prospects<br />

it is conducted in the private sector or on<br />

behalf of public sector. <strong>The</strong> reason why<br />

resources invested by private investors are<br />

normally more efficient than investment<br />

in the public sector is the fact that risktaking<br />

plays more powerful role in the<br />

private sector. Private investors bear the<br />

information and investment resources efficiently<br />

because of the motives such as<br />

higher productivity perspective and competitive<br />

pressures in the market economy.<br />

<strong>The</strong> investment conducted by the managers<br />

in public sector is subject to political<br />

pressures while politicians do not pursue<br />

the same goals as private investors. Public<br />

investment is directed via political decisions<br />

and its time preference rates of<br />

politicians on the electoral basis is subject<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

147


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Taxes, Corruption And Structural<br />

Defect<br />

Tax system is a powerful weapon in the<br />

hands of economic policymakers. Tax system<br />

is a major source of funding where<br />

political parties and government planners<br />

collect money and slice a fraction of the<br />

GDP for government spending and consumption.<br />

Currently India levies moderate<br />

tax rates on corporate and individual<br />

income. By <strong>2007</strong>, top personal and corporate<br />

income tax rates were 33 percent plus<br />

10 percent surcharge. Other taxes includto<br />

the realization of promises which is oftenly<br />

negatively related to growth prospects<br />

and economic performance. Political<br />

preference for expansionary welfare<br />

state demand greater involvement of government<br />

into the economic structure and<br />

thus political pressures reduce the scope<br />

of growth potentials. Every economic<br />

theory agrees that the long-term engine<br />

of growth is capital creation which means<br />

savings and investment. <strong>The</strong> share of government<br />

in the economy is equally important.<br />

<strong>The</strong> following picture known as the<br />

Rahn Curve shows the empirical relationship<br />

between economic growth and government<br />

spending.<br />

Output<br />

performance<br />

RAHN CURVE<br />

Goverment apending<br />

as a share of the GDP<br />

Source: Brimelow (1993), Mitchell (2005)<br />

Picture-1: Rahn Curve<br />

An Empirical Perspective On <strong>The</strong><br />

Trade-Off Between Government<br />

Size And Economic Growth<br />

Extensive public sector involves several<br />

macroeconomically important costs. Every<br />

single per unit increase in government<br />

<strong>size</strong> reduces potential unit of output added<br />

to the gross domestic product. <strong>The</strong><br />

costs associated with government spending<br />

are huge. First, government spending<br />

requires the collection of funds of spending.<br />

Costly choices mean an inevitable<br />

adverse consequence such as reducing the<br />

<strong>size</strong> of investment which is an important<br />

component of the GDP. Second, the effi-<br />

ciency of investment is determined by the<br />

efficiency of allocation of resources. In<br />

this respect, expanded public sector hinders<br />

private sector activities subject to the<br />

fact that resources are scarce; the foremost<br />

basic corner-stone of economics.<br />

Third, government spending supports<br />

backward regulation and intervention,<br />

displacing the competitiveness of product<br />

markets and interfering growth performance.<br />

Phillips and Shen (2003) showed<br />

that the overall impact of a 10 percent decrease<br />

of state-owned enterprises in China<br />

boosted the regional growth of GDP<br />

by 1.14 percent. 5 <strong>The</strong> case of China shows<br />

that costs involved in government spending<br />

include economically undesirable<br />

choices and decisions. In addition, high<br />

level of government intervention through<br />

regulatory agencies protecting existing<br />

monopoly or oligopoly structures stimulates<br />

market distortions by discouraging<br />

productive behavior. <strong>The</strong> reason why government<br />

spending is wasteful and burdensome<br />

at some point, as demonstrated by<br />

the Rahn Curve, is that additional spending<br />

empowers the <strong>size</strong> of government and<br />

also because spending outlays boost the<br />

misallocation of resources due to asymmetric<br />

information.<br />

A valuable lesson for Indian policymakers<br />

is to learn the lessons associated with<br />

government spending from other countries<br />

where decades of output growth and<br />

rising productivity returned a comparatively<br />

high GDP per capita and sound<br />

economic performance and also an experience<br />

with economic setbacks and downturns<br />

caused by the mistakes in economic<br />

policy. Bassanini and Scarpetta (2001)<br />

showed that an increase in one percentage<br />

point in tax pressure – two thirds of what<br />

was observed over the past decade in the<br />

OECD sample – could be associated with<br />

a direct reduction of about 0.3 percent in<br />

output per capita. If the investment effect<br />

is taken into account, the overall reduction<br />

would be 0,6-0.7 percent. 6 Tanzi and<br />

Schuknecht (1996) compared the <strong>size</strong> of<br />

government and growth performance in<br />

selected industrial countries, concluding<br />

that average 5-year growth was higher in<br />

countries with small governments. <strong>The</strong><br />

investigation showed that countries with<br />

small governments observed lower actual<br />

unemployment rate, lower rate of shadow<br />

economy and also exhibited more regulatory<br />

efficiency, higher innovation levels<br />

and a well functioning non-distortionary<br />

labor markets. 7 Another argument in favor<br />

of lower government <strong>size</strong> and spending<br />

as a core economic reform is the wellobserved<br />

fact that the reduction in public<br />

spending as a share of the GDP is positively<br />

related to the growth of total factor<br />

productivity. <strong>Dec</strong>ades of mismanaged<br />

economic policy led to an obscure increase<br />

in the <strong>size</strong> of state-owned enterprises<br />

carrying out some major deficiencies<br />

and the failure in the allocation of<br />

resources which caused a decline in the<br />

overall competitiveness of the economy.<br />

148 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

ed dividend tax, property tax and tax on<br />

insurance contracts. 8 India’s tax system<br />

demands a radical change towards a reduction<br />

in taxation of productive behavior<br />

such as labor supply and investment nevertheless.<br />

<strong>The</strong> demand and supply of labor<br />

is elastic which supports the thesis<br />

that labor supply is highly sensitive and<br />

responsive to tax rates. 9 Recent highlights<br />

in empirical investigation of the behavior<br />

of labor supply has shown that labor supply<br />

responds dramatically to lower tax<br />

rates on work whereas productivity has<br />

been soaring due to cutting taxes on productive<br />

activity. India’s particular competitive<br />

advantage in terms of tax system<br />

could be innovative; public products such<br />

as internationally competitive territorial<br />

tax system, a model in which Indian provinces<br />

could compete to attract inflows of<br />

direct investment on the international basis.<br />

A strong argument in favor of open<br />

territorial tax competition is that it is rational<br />

to expect lower tax rates on productive<br />

behavior and thus adversely positive<br />

effects on output and productivity growth.<br />

Recent research evidence by Djankov,<br />

Ganser, McLiesh, Ramalho and Schleifer<br />

(<strong>2007</strong>) has shown consistent and large<br />

adverse effect of corporate taxation on<br />

investment and entrepreneurship. According<br />

to authors’ calculations, a 10 percentage<br />

point increase in the effective<br />

corporate tax rate reduces the investment<br />

to GDP ratio by about 2 percentage<br />

points. 10 Alternatively, India could consider<br />

a possible move in a direction of<br />

abolishing the corporate tax due to its effect<br />

on capital creation and entrepreneurial<br />

activity. Also, India should consider a<br />

fundamental tax refom in a pro-growth<br />

direction. Practically, India may switch its<br />

taxation regime from income tax to consumption-based<br />

tax. In case of cutting-off<br />

income taxes and alternatively adopting<br />

taxes on consumption, higher savings<br />

would dramatically boost the productivity<br />

and living standards. <strong>The</strong> encouragement<br />

of competitiveness deserves a concrete<br />

treatment of pro-growth tax and economic<br />

policy proposals that could boost output<br />

performance. A significant amount of<br />

empirical evidence suggests that the reduction<br />

in corporate and individual taxation<br />

boosts the operating capacity of the<br />

economy in going for growth as well as<br />

private initiative in fighting India’s structural<br />

weaknesses and human capital creation<br />

which is, by any means, an essential<br />

ingredient of growth in an economy with<br />

astonishing growth potentials. 11<br />

Despite a moderately free fiscal and<br />

public consumption , 12 India’s structural<br />

defects are mostly subject to an inefficient<br />

administrative environment, weak property<br />

rights, government involvement in<br />

the financial sector and widespread perception<br />

of corruption. For instance, India<br />

ranks 72nd out of 188 countries included<br />

in Transparency International’s Corruption<br />

Perception Index. 13 A spiral of structural<br />

deficiencies contributes to the hindering<br />

of India’s growth sustainability and<br />

international macroeconomic and microeconomic<br />

competitiveness. Corruption is<br />

a huge cost reflecting the governance of<br />

institutions enforcing private property<br />

rights, the rule of law and competitive<br />

framework of the economy and individual<br />

interaction. Noteworthy, tax complexity<br />

and high costs of tax compliance contribute<br />

a significant fraction to the legal<br />

and illegal level of corruption. In European<br />

Union, pressures for harmful tax<br />

harmonization 14 aim to expand the scope<br />

Research evidence shows a consistent and large adverse<br />

effect of corporate tax on investment and entrepreneurship.<br />

A 10% point increase in the effective corporate tax<br />

rate reduces the investment to GDP ratio by about 2%<br />

of government bureaucracy in tax collection.<br />

Tax rebates, exemptions, loopholes<br />

and numerous deductions contribute to<br />

the rise of hidden corruption within legal<br />

limits. Fighting against corruption requires<br />

an active approach codified by the<br />

enforcement of competitive law, deregulated<br />

product markets and the elimination<br />

of government involvement in financial<br />

sector and any other sector in the economy.<br />

Of course, in economic theory and<br />

practice there are externalities and market<br />

failures which excuse the role of government<br />

in certain areas. But such approach<br />

would be needed under<br />

cost-benefit analysis, clearly defined competitive<br />

rules and under the absence of<br />

government coercion and political intervention.<br />

Anti-corruption legislation and<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

149


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

policy enforcement can significantly reduce<br />

persistence of corruption as a major<br />

structural backlash of an economy in<br />

transition such as India. However, tax<br />

competition, competitive and secure contractual<br />

law, deregulation, private ownership,<br />

strong protection of property rights<br />

and other components of political stability<br />

and economic prosperity are the guiding<br />

swords in fighting against corruption 15<br />

as an obstacle to long-term growth and<br />

stability.<br />

brightest reform concepts and case studies<br />

of the macroeconomic and structural<br />

reforms. I suggest learning from two small<br />

countries, Ireland and Iceland.<br />

Ireland dramatically changed its fiscal<br />

policy over the past 20 years. Once a bastion<br />

of poverty, now became the second<br />

wealthiest economy in the European Union<br />

according to real GDP per capita,<br />

after Luxemburg. Ireland’s reform agenda<br />

included a supply-side package of policy<br />

inputs. For example, top individual income<br />

tax rates was slashed from 65 percent<br />

to 42 percent and the corporate tax<br />

rate was reduced<br />

to 12.5 percent<br />

and was made flat. Low Taxes,<br />

Tax competition<br />

In 1980s, unemployment<br />

was se-<br />

Sound regulation<br />

vere at a doubledigit<br />

rate and government spending<br />

consumed more than 52 percent of total<br />

output. Consequently, growth rates were<br />

rachitic and high tax rates discouraged<br />

the creation of productive behavior. Ireland<br />

quickly became the “sick-man-of-<br />

An increase in one percentage point in tax pressure – two<br />

thirds of what was observed over the past decade in the<br />

OECD sample – could be associated with a direct reduction<br />

of about 0.3 percent in output per capita<br />

Europe”. In early 1990s, Irish policymakers<br />

decided to embrace supply-side<br />

economic policy, deregulate product markets,<br />

cut the <strong>size</strong> of government and slash<br />

the expenditures. After decades of low<br />

output, overall government spending was<br />

reduced from 52.3 percent in 1986 to 37.7<br />

percent in 1996. Free trade, rigorous tax<br />

cuts and productive education policies<br />

turned the incredible emulation of the<br />

Irish hare into the Celtic Tiger .16 <strong>The</strong>re is<br />

an interesting comparison between Ireland<br />

and Slovenia as a case study between<br />

the supply-side success and Keynesian<br />

failure. Using the data from Penn World<br />

Tables 17 , by the end of 1990, Slovenia and<br />

Ireland had the same real GDP per capita<br />

after inflation, using current prices as<br />

a comparison measure. Throughout the<br />

1990s, Slovenia’s output grew at low rates,<br />

recovering from economic depression in<br />

transition while having high taxes, high<br />

fraction of government ownership and<br />

weak institutions, while Irish economy<br />

International Lessons For India<br />

<strong>The</strong> growth experience of countries from<br />

around the world offers a useful guideline<br />

in learning from the world’s best and<br />

Picture No.2: Dynamic Engines Of Growth<br />

Sophisticated<br />

Infrastructure<br />

Cost and prices,<br />

Environment of<br />

the firm<br />

Quality of the<br />

Labor Supply<br />

SUSTAINABLE<br />

GROWTH<br />

Human Capital<br />

Source: Forfas, author’s own projections<br />

Business<br />

Performance<br />

Productivity<br />

Performance<br />

Innovation,<br />

Competitiveness,<br />

Entrepreneurship<br />

TARGET<br />

ESSENTIALS<br />

Property Rights,<br />

Rule-of-Law<br />

Free Markets<br />

I<br />

N<br />

P<br />

U<br />

T<br />

S<br />

150 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

grew at robust annual rates, with free<br />

markets, established rule-of-law and protected<br />

private property rights. Using time<br />

difference calculation as a measure, today’s<br />

time gap between Slovenia and Ireland<br />

is approximately 40 years 18 Iceland’s<br />

recovery from decades of interrupted<br />

Keynesian economic policy lasted from<br />

than Icelandic policymakers estimated.<br />

Until late 1980s, Icelandic economy was<br />

marred by government ownership, periods<br />

of high inflation when oil shocks, tight<br />

labor markets and devaluation bias caused<br />

a spiral of inflationary pressures. 19 In<br />

1990, Icelandic policymakers reduced the<br />

corporate tax rate from 50 percent to 33<br />

percent by the mid 1990s. In 2003, the<br />

rate was further slashed to 18 percent.<br />

<strong>The</strong> effect of supply-side tax reform was<br />

a pure theoretical assertion of the Laffer<br />

curve whereby lower tax rates increased<br />

revenue from taxes as a share of the GDP<br />

respectively. According to Iceland’s Ministry<br />

of Finance, in 1985 when corporate<br />

tax rate was 50 percent, the share of corporate<br />

tax revenue in the GDP was 0.9<br />

percent. In 2003, when the corporate tax<br />

rate was 18 percent, corporate tax revenue<br />

in the share of the GDP jumped to 1.5<br />

percent. 20 Thus, during the period of a<br />

continued reduction of corporate tax rate,<br />

overall revenue from corporate tax increased<br />

by 67 percent. Noteworthy, the<br />

restructuring of Iceland’s economy was<br />

primarily based on privatization of nationalized<br />

enterprises and assets, strong<br />

fiscal management and responsible leadership<br />

on the part of labor unions and<br />

employers. Now, Iceland is one of the<br />

wealthiest countries in the world. In 2006,<br />

according to World Bank, 21 Iceland’s<br />

gross national income per capita was<br />

$50,580 per capita as measured by Atlas<br />

method and $36,560 per capita in terms<br />

of purchasing power parity.<br />

India: High-Growing Tiger Or An<br />

Economic Laggard?<br />

In this article I highlighted the prospects<br />

of the economic reforms in India. After a<br />

detailed study of the data and empirical<br />

work, I concluded the research and put it<br />

in a written and hopefully understandable<br />

form. India is an economy in transition<br />

currently facing high output growth rates<br />

and enviable economic perspective in the<br />

future. Growth is expected to remain<br />

steady over years in the future. However,<br />

substantial change in global environment<br />

demand a significant infusion of economic<br />

reforms to boost the productive behavior,<br />

economic growth while ‘rules-ratherthan-discretion’<br />

monetary policy is<br />

essential to the pursuit of price stability<br />

instead of discretionary price controls and<br />

market regulation that harm competitive<br />

forces in the market. In the international<br />

arena, India is frequently associated with<br />

high-growing East Asian phenomena besides<br />

China. 22 By 2040, China will reach<br />

$123 trillion USD which is equal to three<br />

times of global output by the end of<br />

2000. 23 Growth estimates for India suggest<br />

a relatively lower but steady-state<br />

growth rate mainly because of political<br />

constraints and structural costs such as<br />

widespread perception of corruption, government<br />

intervention and ownership of<br />

enterprises and harmful regulation of the<br />

economy through obscure administrative<br />

code, fiercely uncompetitive investment<br />

environment marred by red-tape, complexity<br />

hostile to foreign direct investors,<br />

trade protectionism and weak enforcement<br />

of private property rights. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

particular politically-installed disadvantages<br />

may hamper India’s long-term economic<br />

performance and impede growth<br />

prospects respectively. Relying on neoclassical<br />

growth theory and strong growth<br />

foundations such as free and deregulated<br />

product markets, liberalized labor market,<br />

the protection of private property,<br />

trade liberalization to the fullest possible<br />

extent, an independent judicial system,<br />

the rule of law and market institutions<br />

would, by experience and empirical<br />

premise, significantly boost India’s economic<br />

potentials and growth perspectives.<br />

Deregulated product and labor markets, protection of<br />

private property, trade liberalization to the fullest possible<br />

extent, an independent judicial system and the rule of law<br />

would signifi cantly boost India’s economic potential<br />

A growing burden of taxes, corruption<br />

and government <strong>size</strong> and spending would,<br />

contrary to popular assertions, impede<br />

India’s economic performance and its<br />

prospects as a global economic powerhouse<br />

in the 21st century.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

See: Edmund S. Phelps, Dynamic<br />

Capitalism, Opinion Journal, Tuesday,<br />

October 10, 2006<br />

http://www.opinionjournal.com/editorial/feature.html?id=110009068<br />

2<br />

See: World Economic Outlook, International<br />

Monetary Fund, October<br />

<strong>2007</strong>, Washington D.C.<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/<br />

weo/<strong>2007</strong>/02/index.htm<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

151


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

3<br />

Aggregate demand is an investment<br />

driven by government spending<br />

4<br />

Robert Barro: Economic Growth in a<br />

Cross Section of Countries, <strong>Quarterly</strong><br />

Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, p.<br />

407-43, May, 1991<br />

http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/<br />

v106y1991i2p407-43.html<br />

5<br />

Kerk Phillips, Kunrong Shen: What<br />

Effect does the Size of the State-<br />

Owned Sector Have on Regional<br />

Growth in China, Birgham Young<br />

University, Economics Working Papers,<br />

April 2003<br />

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.<br />

cfm?abstract_id=395890<br />

6<br />

Andrea Bassanini, Stefano Scarpetta:<br />

<strong>The</strong> Driving Forces of Economic<br />

Growth: Panel Data Evidence for the<br />

OECD Countries, Organization for<br />

Economic Cooperation and Development,<br />

Economic Studies No.33, February<br />

2001<br />

http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/26/2/18450995.pdf<br />

7<br />

Vito Tanzi,. Ludger Schuknecht: Reforming<br />

Government in Industrial<br />

Countries, International Monetary<br />

Fund Finance & Development, September<br />

1996<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/<br />

fandd/1996/09/pdf/tanzi.pdf<br />

8<br />

Index of Economic Freedom <strong>2007</strong> –<br />

India, Heritage Foundation http://<br />

www.heritage.org/research/features/<br />

index/country.cfm?id=India<br />

9<br />

Edward Prescott: <strong>The</strong> Elasticity of the<br />

Labor Supply and the Consequences<br />

for Tax Policy, Federal Reserve Bank<br />

of Minneapolis, February 2005<br />

http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/prescott/papers/Labor<br />

Supply.pdf<br />

10<br />

Simoen Djankov, Tim Ganser, Caralee<br />

McLiesh, Rita Ramalho, Andrei<br />

Schleifer: <strong>The</strong> Effect of Corporate<br />

Taxes on Investment and Entrepreneurship,<br />

Public Economics Program<br />

Meeting <strong>2007</strong>, National Bureau of<br />

Economic Research<br />

http://www.nber.org/confer/<strong>2007</strong>/<br />

pef07/shleifer.pdf<br />

11<br />

Hiroko Oura, Wild or Tamed? India’s<br />

Potential Growth Rate, International<br />

Monetary Fund, Working Paper No.<br />

07/224, September <strong>2007</strong><br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/<br />

longres.cfm?sk=21326.0<br />

12<br />

According to Heritage Foundation’s<br />

annual Index of Economic Freedom<br />

(<strong>2007</strong>), India is 84,8 percent free in fiscal<br />

terms and 89 percent free in terms<br />

of freedom from government<br />

http://www.heritage.org/research/features/index/country<strong>File</strong>s/pdfs/India.<br />

pdf<br />

13<br />

Transparency International: Corruption<br />

Perception Index, <strong>2007</strong><br />

http://www.transparency.org/policy_<br />

research/surveys_indices/cpi<br />

14<br />

Peter van de Hoek: Tax Harmonization<br />

and Competition in the European<br />

Union, eJournal of Tax Research,<br />

2003<br />

http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/<br />

eJTR/2003/2.html#Heading50<br />

15<br />

A detailed investigation of corruption<br />

and its effect on growth and economic<br />

performance was conducted by:<br />

Paolo Mauro: Corruption and Growth,<br />

<strong>The</strong> <strong>Quarterly</strong> Journal of Economics,<br />

vol. 110, <strong>Issue</strong> 3, p. 681-712, 1995<br />

http://econpapers.repec.org/article/<br />

tprqjecon/v_3A110_3Ay_3A1995_<br />

3Ai_3A3_3Ap_3A681-712.htm<br />

16<br />

Brendan Walsh: <strong>The</strong> Source of Wealth<br />

in Small States. Small States as Financial<br />

Centers: <strong>The</strong> Case of Ireland, A<br />

presentation at the conference Small<br />

States as Financial Centers, University<br />

of Iceland, Reykjavik, Friday 14<br />

<strong>Dec</strong>ember, <strong>2007</strong><br />

http://www.skattamal.is/smallstates/<br />

Walsh.SmallStates.14.09.07.ppt<br />

17<br />

Penn World Table<br />

http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/php_site/<br />

pwt_index.php<br />

18<br />

Author’s own calculations<br />

19<br />

Már Guðmundsson, Palle S. Andersen:<br />

Inflation and disinflation in Iceland,<br />

BIS Working Paper No.52, Bank for<br />

International Settlements, June 1998<br />

http://ideas.repec.org/p/bis/biswps/52.<br />

html<br />

20<br />

Ministry of Finance, Iceland, »Principal<br />

Tax Rates«, July 2006<br />

http://eng.fjarmalaraduneyti.is/media/<br />

Taxes/Principal_tax_rates_2006.pdf.<br />

21<br />

World Bank, GNI per capita 2006, Atlas<br />

method and PPP, World Development<br />

Indicators database, July 1<br />

2006<br />

http://siteresources.worldbank.org/<br />

DATASTATISTICS/Resources/<br />

GNIPC.pdf<br />

22<br />

Srinivasan (2004)<br />

23<br />

Robert W. Fogel: Capitalism and Democracy<br />

in 2040: Forecasts and Speculations,<br />

NBER Working Paper No.<br />

13184, National Bureau of Economic<br />

Research, June <strong>2007</strong>; http://www.nber.<br />

org/papers/w13184<br />

References<br />

• Barro, Robert J. (1991), Economic<br />

Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,<br />

<strong>Quarterly</strong> Journal of Economics,<br />

Vol. 106, p. 407-43<br />

http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/<br />

152 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

v106y1991i2p407-43.html<br />

• Bassanini, Andrea, Scarpetta Stefano<br />

(2001), <strong>The</strong> Driving Forces of Economic<br />

Growth: Panel Data Evidence<br />

for the OECD Countries, Organization<br />

for Economic Cooperation and<br />

Development, Economic Studies<br />

No.33. http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/26/2/18450995.pdf<br />

• Bergström, Friderik, Gidehag, Robert<br />

(2004), EU vs. USA, Timbro<br />

http://www.timbro.se/bokhandel/<br />

pdf/9175665646.pdf<br />

• Brimelow, Peter (1993), Why the Deficit<br />

is the Wrong Number, Forbes<br />

• Corruption Perception Index <strong>2007</strong>,<br />

Transparency International<br />

http://www.transparency.org/policy_<br />

research/surveys_indices/cpi<br />

• Djankov, Simeon, Ganser, Tim, McLiesh,<br />

Caralee, Ramalho, Rita, Schleifer,<br />

Andrei (<strong>2007</strong>): <strong>The</strong> Effect of Corporate<br />

Taxes on Investment and<br />

Entrepreneurship, Public Economics<br />

Program Meeting <strong>2007</strong>, National Bureau<br />

of Economic Research<br />

http://www.nber.org/confer/<strong>2007</strong>/<br />

pef07/shleifer.pdf<br />

• Fogel, Robert W (<strong>2007</strong>): Capitalism<br />

and Democracy in 2040: Forecasts<br />

and Speculations, NBER Working<br />

Paper No. 13184, National Bureau of<br />

Economic Research<br />

http://www.nber.org/papers/w13184<br />

• Guðmundsson, Már, Andersen, Palle<br />

S. (1998): Inflation and disinflation in<br />

Iceland, BIS Working Paper No.52,<br />

Bank for International Settlements<br />

http://ideas.repec.org/p/bis/biswps/52.<br />

html<br />

• Index of Economic Freedom <strong>2007</strong><br />

http://www.heritage.org/index<br />

• Mauro, Paulo (1995): Corruption and<br />

Growth, <strong>The</strong> <strong>Quarterly</strong> Journal of<br />

Economics, vol. 110, <strong>Issue</strong> 3, p. 681-<br />

712<br />

http://econpapers.repec.org/article/<br />

tprqjecon/v_3A110_3Ay_3A1995_<br />

3Ai_3A3_3Ap_3A681-712.htm<br />

• Ministry of Finance, Iceland, »Principal<br />

Tax Rates«, July 2006<br />

http://eng.fjarmalaraduneyti.is/media/<br />

Taxes/Principal_tax_rates_2006.pdf.<br />

• Mitchell, Daniel J. (2005), <strong>The</strong> Impact<br />

of Government Spending, Heritage<br />

Backgrounder #1831, Heritage Foundation<br />

http://www.heritage.org/Research/<br />

Budget/bg1831.cfm<br />

• Oura, Hiroko (<strong>2007</strong>), Wild or Tamed?<br />

India’s Potential Growth Rate, International<br />

Monetary Fund, Working<br />

Paper No. 07/224<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/cat/<br />

longres.cfm?sk=21326.0<br />

• Penn World Table<br />

http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/php_site/<br />

pwt_index.php<br />

• Phelps, Edmund S. (2006), Dynamic<br />

Capitalism, Opinion Journal, Tuesday,<br />

October 10, 2006<br />

http://www.opinionjournal.com/editorial/feature.html?id=110009068<br />

• Phillips, Kerk, Shen, Kunrong (2003):<br />

What Effect does the Size of the State-<br />

Owned Sector Have on Regional<br />

Growth in China, Birgham Young<br />

University, Economics Working Papers<br />

http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.<br />

cfm?abstract_id=395890<br />

• Prescott, Edward (2005): <strong>The</strong> Elasticity<br />

of the Labor Supply and the Consequences<br />

for Tax Policy, Federal Reserve<br />

Bank of Minneapolis<br />

http://www.minneapolisfed.org/research/prescott/papers/LaborSupply.<br />

pdf<br />

• Srinivasan, T.N. (2004), China and India:<br />

Economic Performance, Competition<br />

and Cooperation. An Update,<br />

WTO Accession, Policy Reform and<br />

Poverty, World Trade Organization<br />

http://www.econ.yale.edu/~srinivas/<br />

C&I%20Economic%20Performance<br />

%20Update.pdf<br />

• Tanzi, Vito, Schuknecht, Ludger<br />

(1996): Reforming Government in Industrial<br />

Countries, International<br />

Monetary Fund Finance & Development<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/<br />

fandd/1996/09/pdf/tanzi.pdf<br />

• van de Hoek, Peter (2003): Tax Harmonization<br />

and Competition in the<br />

European Union, eJournal of Tax Research<br />

http://www.austlii.edu.au/au/journals/<br />

eJTR/2003/2.html#Heading50<br />

• Walsh, Brendan (<strong>2007</strong>): <strong>The</strong> Source of<br />

Wealth in Small States. Small States<br />

as Financial Centers: <strong>The</strong> Case of Ireland,<br />

A presentation at the conference<br />

Small States as Financial Centers,<br />

University of Iceland, Reykjavik<br />

http://www.skattamal.is/smallstates/<br />

Walsh.SmallStates.14.09.07.ppt<br />

• World Bank, GNI per capita 2006, Atlas<br />

method and PPP, World Development<br />

Indicators database, July 1<br />

2006<br />

http://siteresources.worldbank.org/<br />

DATASTATISTICS/Resources/<br />

GNIPC.pdf<br />

• World Economic Outlook, International<br />

Monetary Fund, October <strong>2007</strong>,<br />

Washington D.C.<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/<br />

weo/<strong>2007</strong>/02/index.htm<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

153


Kalpana Kochhar,<br />

Senior Advisor, Asia and<br />

Pacific Department,<br />

International Monetary Fund,<br />

Washington D.C.<br />

India’s Unique Pattern Of<br />

Development: Quo vadis? 1<br />

"If I were asked under what<br />

sky the human mind has<br />

most fully developed some of<br />

its choicest gifts, has most<br />

deeply pondered on the greatest<br />

problems of life, and has<br />

found solutions, I should point<br />

to India."<br />

-Max Muller<br />

Introduction<br />

Much has been written about India’s ongoing<br />

demographic transition and the<br />

dividend from the rise in working age<br />

population that is expected to continue<br />

well into this century. But, of course, this<br />

dividend will only be realized if the 13 million<br />

or so people that will enter the labor<br />

force each year for the next four decades<br />

can be gainfully employed. Has India specialized<br />

in labor intensive as one would<br />

expect in a labor abundant country? And,<br />

if not, how will India be able to foster<br />

growth in labor-intensive manufacturing<br />

going forward so that jobs can be provided<br />

for India’s vast and growing pool of lowskilled<br />

labor?<br />

We start with an examination of how<br />

India’s policies since independence have<br />

influenced its pattern of development.<br />

<strong>The</strong>n we ask whether the wide-ranging<br />

reforms beginning in the 1980s and accelerating<br />

in the 1990s changed this pattern<br />

of specialization. Finally, we look at the<br />

way India’s states have developed to consider<br />

what the future might look like?<br />

What were the main elements of India’s<br />

development strategy in the first three and<br />

a half decades since Independence? A<br />

simplified view of the main aspects include:<br />

(i) the emphasis on self-sufficiency,<br />

which led to the creation of industries producing<br />

capital goods and extensive trade<br />

restrictions; (ii) the combination of heavy<br />

public sector involvement in production<br />

being reserved only for the public sector<br />

and controlled private sector involvement<br />

to take account of the fact that India was<br />

capital poor. Licenses were required for<br />

investment, capacity expansion, production,<br />

and imports, while foreign exchange,<br />

credit allocation, and even prices were<br />

controlled; (iii) avoidance of undue concentration<br />

of economic power through the<br />

Monopoly and Restrictive Trade Practices<br />

act (MRTP)—which imposed severe<br />

constraints on expansion by large firms<br />

and groups, and the Foreign Exchange<br />

Regulation Act (FERA); (iv) geographically<br />

balanced development with investment<br />

directed towards underdeveloped<br />

areas, even if these areas were not near<br />

154 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Table 1. Sectoral Shares In Value-Added And Employment<br />

Value Added As Percent Of GDP<br />

Employment In Sector As Percent Of<br />

Total Employment<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)<br />

Agriculture Manufacturing Industry Services Agriculture Industry Services<br />

1980<br />

India 38.9 16.3 24.5 36.6 68.1 13.9 18.6<br />

Brazil 11.0 33.5 43.8 45.2 29.3 24.7 46.1<br />

China 30.1 40.5 48.5 21.4 68.7 18.2 11.7<br />

Indonesia 24.0 13.0 41.7 34.3 55.9 13.2 30.2<br />

Korea 15.1 28.6 40.5 44.4 34.0 29.0 37.0<br />

Malaysia 22.6 21.6 41.0 36.3 37.2 24.1 38.7<br />

Mexico 9.0 22.3 33.6 57.4 23.5 26.5 49.0<br />

Thailand 23.2 21.5 28.7 48.1 70.8 10.3 18.9<br />

Turkey 26.4 14.3 22.2 51.4 43.0 34.9 22.1<br />

Low income 36.4 14.8 24.4 39.2 74.6 8.7 16.5<br />

Lower middle income 21.5 29.1 41.7 36.8 64.0 18.5 16.4<br />

2000<br />

India 24.6 15.9 26.6 48.8 59.3 18.2 22.4<br />

Brazil 7.3 17.1 28.0 64.7 24.2 19.3 56.5<br />

China 16.4 34.7 50.2 33.4 46.9 23.0 29.9<br />

Indonesia 17.2 24.9 46.1 36.7 45.3 17.3 37.3<br />

Korea 4.3 26.1 36.2 59.5 10.9 28.0 61.0<br />

Malaysia 8.8 32.6 50.7 40.5 18.4 32.2 49.5<br />

Mexico 4.2 20.3 28.0 67.8 17.5 26.9 55.2<br />

Thailand 9.0 33.6 42.0 49.0 48.8 19.0 32.2<br />

Turkey 15.4 15.7 25.3 59.4 34.5 24.5 40.9<br />

Low Income 27.3 14.1 26.6 46.1 64.5 12.3 23.2<br />

Lower Middle Income 12.5 24.2 38.3 49.1 43.2 18.5 38.3<br />

Sources: World Bank, World Development Indicators 2005, except Korea, OECD-Structural Analysis Database, and India, National Accounts Statistics, Indiastat.com.<br />

Notes: For the low income, and lower middle income groups as classified by the World Bank, we report the respective averages. Employment shares are reported for the years indicated,<br />

except India (1983), Brazil (1981 and 1999), and Turkey (1982). Employment shares for the low-income group for 2000 are estimates.<br />

markets or even if scale was inefficiently<br />

small; (v) encouraging labor-intensive<br />

manufacture in the private sector, by giving<br />

significant benefits to small-scale firms<br />

(tax concessions, preferential access to<br />

subsidized credit, preferential treatment<br />

in procurement by the government, and<br />

reserving some goods for exclusive production<br />

by the small-scale sector); (vi)<br />

significant protections for labor, especially<br />

in large firms, through the Industrial<br />

Disputes Act (1947), which in 1982 was<br />

tightened to make it compulsory for firms<br />

with 100 or more workers to seek the permission<br />

of the relevant government to dismiss<br />

workers; (vii) relatively more resources<br />

spent on higher education than on<br />

primary education.<br />

Economic Development<br />

Circa 1980<br />

Next, we examine the legacy of this web<br />

of policies on the pattern of development.<br />

In Table 1, we present the share of output<br />

in the different sectors in India in 1981<br />

and compare it with that in a number of<br />

developing and developed countries. At<br />

a little over 16 percent of GDP, India’s<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

155


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 2. India In <strong>The</strong> Cross Section: Share Of Manufacturing And Services, Early 1980s<br />

Share Of Output (1981) Share Of Employment (1983)<br />

Manufacturing Services Industry Services<br />

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)<br />

Log GDP Per-capita 15.37 21.58 36.27** 27.81 26.76 22.09 66.5** 67.20**<br />

(14.58) (13.75) (17.01) (17.79) (20.8) (20.8) (29.07) (30.07)<br />

Log GDP Per-capita -0.73 -1.09 -1.95* -1.46 -1.17 -0.92 -3.15* -3.19*<br />

(0.88) (0.83) (1.03) (1.08) (1.2) (1.2) (1.71) (1.76)<br />

India Indicator 4.58*** 2.33 -6.50*** -3.55** -0.260 0.560 -7.41** -7.53**<br />

(1.25) (1.76) (1.3) (1.61) (2.52) (2.82) (3.27) (3.63)<br />

Control for country <strong>size</strong> No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes<br />

Observations 101 101 122 122 44 44 43 43<br />

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses.<br />

***represents significance at 1 percent, **represents significance at 5 percent, *represents significance at 10 percent levels.<br />

Country <strong>size</strong> is measured by area in square kilometers.<br />

share in manufacturing seems low, especially<br />

when compared with a number of<br />

East Asian countries and China.<br />

But from the work of Kuznets and<br />

Chenery, we know that the manufacturing<br />

share varies with the level of development,<br />

rising and then falling off once a<br />

country approaches a high level of income.<br />

So we examine whether India’s<br />

share of manufacturing is too low after<br />

correcting for its level of income and its<br />

square (to account for non-linearities) 2 .<br />

Correcting only for income, India is a<br />

positive outlier among countries in its<br />

share of value added in manufacturing in<br />

1981 (Table 2). Its share significantly exceeds<br />

the norm by 4.6 percentage points<br />

(see Table 2, column 1). After correcting<br />

for country <strong>size</strong>, the coefficient on the<br />

India indicator declines to 2.3 percentage<br />

points in 1981 which is not statistically<br />

significant (column 2). When we compare<br />

the shares of industrial sector employment<br />

in total employment across countries,<br />

India is again not an outlier (Table<br />

2, columns 5 and 6) 3 .<br />

What were the characteristics of industry<br />

in 1980? <strong>The</strong> first industry characteristic<br />

we examine is labor intensity, for<br />

which we use as a proxy the share of wages<br />

in value added for the industry in a<br />

country from the UNIDO database, averaged<br />

across a broad group of developing<br />

countries. For each country, we calculate<br />

Compared with countries at a similar level of development<br />

and <strong>size</strong>, in 1981 India had approximately the normal<br />

share of output and employment in manufacturing. Output<br />

in services was below the norm, as was employment.<br />

the ratio of value added in industries with<br />

above-median labor-intensity to the value<br />

added in industries with below-median<br />

labor-intensity. If Indian manufacturing<br />

generated relatively more value added in<br />

labor intensive industries in 1981, then in<br />

a cross-country regression of this ratio<br />

against log per capita GDP, its square,<br />

and an indicator for India, the India indicator<br />

should be positive and significant.<br />

However, the coefficient is insignificant<br />

suggesting that India does not have more<br />

value added coming out of labor intensive<br />

industries.<br />

<strong>The</strong> second characteristic we examined<br />

is skill intensity. We used data from South<br />

Africa contains on 45 sectors and five<br />

primary factors of production—capital<br />

plus four categories of labor: highly<br />

skilled, skilled, unskilled, and informal<br />

sector. We use the share of remuneration<br />

of the highly skilled and skilled categories<br />

of workers in total value as a proxy<br />

for the skill intensity of an industry. 4 If<br />

Indian manufacturing generated relatively<br />

less value added in skill intensive<br />

industries in 1981, then in a cross-country<br />

regression of this ratio against log per<br />

capita GDP, its square, and an indicator<br />

for India, the India indicator should be<br />

negative and significant. What we find is<br />

striking—even by 1981, India specialized<br />

more than the average country in skillintensive<br />

industries.<br />

A third characteristic we examine is<br />

156 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

diversification. Imbs and Wacziarg (2003)<br />

show that in the course of development,<br />

countries first diversify within manufacturing,<br />

producing many things, and then<br />

after a certain level of income, start specializing,<br />

producing fewer things. Technically,<br />

the relationship between the concentration<br />

of value added across<br />

industries (the Gini coefficient or the<br />

Herfindahl index), and income is U-<br />

shaped, with the turning point occurring<br />

at about US$10,000 per capita. Given that<br />

India has more of a presence in skill-intensive<br />

industries, the presumption would<br />

be that it has specialized in more areas<br />

than the typical developing country, and<br />

hence it should exhibit a more diverse<br />

pattern of production. When we examine<br />

the concentration of Indian industry compared<br />

to the average country pattern, we<br />

indeed find that India is significantly<br />

more diversified (less concentrated) in<br />

terms of the distribution of value-added<br />

across industries.<br />

To summarize, compared with countries<br />

at a similar level of development and<br />

<strong>size</strong>, in 1981 India had approximately the<br />

normal share of output and employment<br />

in manufacturing. Output in services was<br />

below the norm, as was employment in<br />

services. Output and employment were<br />

about average in labor intensive manufacturing<br />

industries and above the norm in<br />

skill intensive industries. And finally, Indian<br />

manufacturing was significantly<br />

more diversified both in terms of output<br />

and employment than countries of comparable<br />

income and <strong>size</strong>. <strong>The</strong> paradox of<br />

Indian manufacturing in the early 1980s<br />

is thus that of a labor-rich, capital-poor<br />

economy using too little of the former. 5<br />

<strong>The</strong> reason, most likely, was policy. <strong>The</strong><br />

large investment in tertiary education for<br />

a country of its per capita income resulted<br />

in the plentiful availability of highly<br />

skilled, cheap labor. In addition, labor<br />

laws afforded much less protection to<br />

skilled labor. <strong>The</strong>se factors are likely to<br />

have contributed to India generating<br />

relatively greater value added and employment<br />

in skill-intensive industries as<br />

compared to the typical poor country.<br />

Reforms Of <strong>The</strong> 1980s And 1990s<br />

<strong>The</strong> key features of reforms in the<br />

1980s—characterized as “pro business”<br />

in orientation were (i) the liberalization<br />

of capital goods and intermediate input<br />

imports; (ii) the extension of export incentives<br />

through the tax system, and more<br />

liberal access to credit and foreign exchange;<br />

(iii) the significant relaxation of<br />

industrial licensing requirements through<br />

direct “delicensing” of some industries<br />

and through “broad banding”, which permitted<br />

firms in some industries to switch<br />

production between similar product lines;<br />

(iv) the decontrol of administered prices<br />

of key intermediate inputs.<br />

<strong>The</strong> reforms of the 1990s—characterized<br />

as “pro-market” in orientation—included<br />

(i) the abolition of industrial licensing<br />

and the narrowing of the scope<br />

of public sector monopolies to a much<br />

smaller number of industries; (ii) the liberalization<br />

of inward foreign direct and<br />

portfolio investment; (iii) the sweeping<br />

liberalization of trade which included the<br />

elimination of import licensing and the<br />

progressive reduction of non-tariff barriers;<br />

(iv) financial sector liberalization,<br />

including the removal of controls on capital<br />

issues, freer entry for domestic, and<br />

foreign, private banks and the opening up<br />

Between 1980 and 2002, India’s share of services in<br />

value added exploded from 37 percent to 49 percent. Its<br />

share of manufacturing in value-added remained<br />

broadly unchanged at 16 percent<br />

of the insurance sector; (v) and the liberalization<br />

of investment in important services,<br />

such as telecommunications. Areas<br />

that remained largely untouched by reforms<br />

in the 1990s were the labor market;<br />

small-scale reservations (where there has<br />

been some movement only in the last 4-5<br />

years); privatization both of non-financial<br />

enterprises and of banks; and further agricultural<br />

sector reforms.<br />

Economic Development After<br />

Reforms<br />

How have these twenty years of slow but<br />

steady reforms affected the pattern of<br />

development, if at all? Let us look again<br />

at the variables discussed above—sectoral<br />

shares, factor intensities, and diversification,<br />

between the early 1980s and<br />

early 2000s. <strong>The</strong> traditional perspective<br />

of Kuznets or Chenery would predict a<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

157


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Table 3: India In <strong>The</strong> Cross Section: Shares Of Mfg. & Services, 2000<br />

Panel A<br />

Share Of Output<br />

Share Of Employment<br />

Manufacturing Services Industry Services<br />

(i) (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) (vii) (viii)<br />

Log GDP Per-capita 13.18** 15.41** 10.88 8.01 51.79*** 52.4*** 38.99 39.69**<br />

(6.41) (6.38) (10.34) (10.3) (11.28) (11.23) (23.91) (23.83)<br />

Log GDP Per-capita 2 -0.61 -0.72* -0.19 -0.04 -2.67*** -2.71*** -1.49 -1.54<br />

(0.12) (0.38) (0.6) (0.6) (0.62) (0.63) (1.31) (1.3)<br />

India Indicator 2.4** 0.26 -0.05 3.77** 0.56 1.13 -17.22*** -16.57***<br />

(0.73) (1.11) (1.17) (1.46) (1.17) (1.36) (3.03) (3.78)<br />

Control For Size No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes<br />

Observations 149 149 156 156 76 76 74 74<br />

Panel B<br />

Change In Share Of output (1981-2000)<br />

Change In Share Of Employment<br />

Manufacturing Services Industry Services<br />

(i) (ii) (iii) (iv)<br />

Log Initial GDP Per-Capita -1.19*** 3.96*** -3.37*** 2.91**<br />

(0.66) (0.77) (0.92) (1.39)<br />

Average Annual growth rate 0.7** 0.41 0.47 -0.18<br />

(0.33) (0.53) (0.6) (0.64)<br />

India Indicator -2.56* 9.86*** 1.7 0.94<br />

(1.37) (1.63) (2.05) (3.59)<br />

Observations 93 116 39 38<br />

Notes: Robust standard errors are reported in parentheses<br />

***represents significance at 1%, **represents significance at 5%, *represents significance at 5%, *represents significance at 10%<br />

Country <strong>size</strong> is measured by area in square killometers.<br />

rapid increase in the share of manufacturing,<br />

a decline in agriculture and an<br />

uncertain or modest effect on services.<br />

However, between 1980 and 2002, India’s<br />

share of services in value added exploded<br />

from 37 percent to 49 percent. Its share<br />

of manufacturing in value added remained<br />

broadly unchanged at 16 percent,<br />

while the decline in agriculture mirrored<br />

the performance of services. 6 <strong>The</strong> corresponding<br />

numbers for employment were<br />

19 percent to 22 percent and 14 percent<br />

to 18 percent (Table 1).<br />

Is this evolution in sectoral shares unusual<br />

when compared with that of other<br />

countries? In Table 3, columns 1 and 2,<br />

panel A, we see that the coefficient of the<br />

India indicator is still positive but smaller<br />

than in the corresponding specification<br />

for 1981. 7 Furthermore, in the regressions<br />

using the change in the share of<br />

manufacturing value-added to overall<br />

growth (column 1, Panel B), the India indicator<br />

is negative. Thus, the data suggest<br />

a relative slowing in manufacturing<br />

growth.<br />

In contrast, the performance of services<br />

over this period has been unusual.<br />

India’s share in services is a significant 3.8<br />

percent higher than in other countries in<br />

2000 (Table 3, panel A, column 4). This<br />

is broadly confirmed in the change regressions<br />

(panel B), where India records<br />

an increase in the <strong>size</strong> of the services sector<br />

that is 10 percentage points of GDP<br />

greater than that of the average country.<br />

What happened to labor, skill intensity<br />

and diversification in manufacturing after<br />

the reforms? In Figure 1, we plot the evolution<br />

in the share of output generated in<br />

labor-intensive relative to non labor-intensive<br />

industries for India and a selected<br />

158 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 1. Value-Added Share of Labor Intensive Industries<br />

Ratio of value added<br />

1<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

Ratio of value added in above median labor intensive intensive sectors to below median sectors<br />

7.5 8 7.5 9 9.5<br />

CHN IND IDN KOR MYS<br />

Sources: Authors’ calculations; UNIDO 3-digit industrial statistics database (2003).<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> sample for all countries includes observations from 1981 to 1996. <strong>The</strong> classification of above and below<br />

median labor-intensive sectors is given in Table 3. CHN stands for China, IND for India, IDN for Indonesia, KOR for<br />

Korea, and MYS for Malaysia.<br />

Figure 2. Value-Added Share Of Skill Intensive Industries<br />

Ratio of value added<br />

2.5<br />

2<br />

1.5<br />

1<br />

0.5<br />

Ratio of value added in above median skill intensive sectors to below median sectors<br />

7.5 8 7.5 9 9.5<br />

CHN IND IDN KOR MYS<br />

Sources: Authors’ calculations; UNIDO 3-digit industrial statistics database (2003).<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> sample for all countries includes observations from 1981 to 1996. <strong>The</strong> classification of above and below<br />

median skill intensive sectors is given in Table 3. CHN stands for China, IND for India, IDN for Indonesia, KOR for<br />

Korea, and MYS for Malaysia.<br />

group of comparator countries. India’s<br />

share is decreasing, when that of many of<br />

the other countries is either increasing, or<br />

decreasing at much higher levels of income.<br />

In Figure 2, we plot the evolution<br />

in the relative share of output generated<br />

in skill-intensive industries for India and<br />

a selected group of comparator countries.<br />

Again, it is striking that India’s share in<br />

skill-intensive manufacturing, which was<br />

already high in 1980 despite its lower<br />

level of per capita income, has been increasing;<br />

it is at levels reached by Malaysia<br />

or Korea at much higher levels of per<br />

capita income. <strong>The</strong>se developments are<br />

not affected by the fact that our data so<br />

far have been limited to the registered<br />

manufacturing sector in India. Indeed,<br />

when we trace the evolution of labor- and<br />

skill-intensive products in the informal<br />

sector, we see the same pattern (Figure<br />

3). Finally, we find that India continues to<br />

be an outlier in 2000 on both measures of<br />

diversification. Indeed, when we compare<br />

the change in diversification between<br />

1980 and 2000, we find that India is again<br />

an outlier, implying that the pace of diversification<br />

in India after 1980 has been<br />

greater than that for the average country<br />

(see Figure 4).<br />

In sum, the evidence suggests that<br />

many of the unique features of India’s<br />

development that were apparent in 1981<br />

have not changed, despite the reforms.<br />

This continuity of trends may be explained<br />

partly by the fact that the reforms<br />

have not been completed. For example,<br />

labor markets remain untouched and<br />

education expenditure is still skewed. But<br />

part of the explanation may well rest with<br />

the fact that in India, the policy distortions<br />

created organizational capabilities<br />

and human capital that led to hysteresis<br />

in growth paths. <strong>The</strong> growth experience<br />

of the Indian states offers some support<br />

to this view.<br />

Development At <strong>The</strong> State Level<br />

Are these patterns repeated in India’s<br />

states and are there differences between<br />

the fast growing and the laggard states?<br />

We find that in the fast-growing Indian<br />

states, the share of manufacturing has<br />

remained constant or declined. Where<br />

there has been an increase—in Andhra<br />

Pradesh, Gujarat, and Haryana—it has<br />

occurred in capital- and skill-intensive<br />

industries (In Gujarat, the share of the<br />

textile industry declined a lot, while that<br />

of the petrochemical industry rose substantially;<br />

similarly, in Andhra Pradesh<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

159


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

Figure 3. Value-Added Shares In Unregistered Manufacturing<br />

3.0<br />

2.5<br />

2.0<br />

1.5<br />

1.0<br />

0.5<br />

Share of High Labor Intensity Industries<br />

Share of High Skill Intensity Industries<br />

0.0<br />

1970 1973 1976 1979 1982 1985 1988 1991 1994 1997 2000<br />

Source: Authors’ calculations; data on unregistered manufacturing are from the Central Statistical Organization,<br />

Government of India.<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> share of high labor (skill) intensity industries is the ratio of value added in sectors with above-median labor<br />

(skill) intensity to that in sectors with below-median labor (skill) intensity. <strong>The</strong> relevant sector classification is given in<br />

Table 3.<br />

Figure 4. Diversification In Indian Manufacturing<br />

Herfindahl Index<br />

.12<br />

.1<br />

.08<br />

.06<br />

Herfindahl Index based on value added<br />

7.5 8 7.5 9 9.5<br />

CHN IND IDN KOR MYS<br />

Sources: Authors’ calculations; UNIDO 3-digit industrial statistics database (2003).<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> sample for all countries includes observations from 1981 to 1996. CHN stands for China, IND<br />

for India, IDN for Indonesia, KOR for Korea, and MYS for Malaysia. For each country, the Herfindahl<br />

Index measures concentration in the value added across sectors; the lower the index, the lower the concentration,<br />

or the higher the diversification.<br />

the decline in the share of food, beverages,<br />

tobacco, textiles, and paper related<br />

industries was matched by a significant<br />

increase in the share of basic metals and<br />

alloys). Interestingly, neither the fast nor<br />

the slow growing states increased their<br />

share of value added in labor intensive<br />

industries.<br />

By contrast, nearly all states in India<br />

have seen a uniform shift toward services<br />

but there is a noteworthy difference between<br />

services that are predominantly in<br />

the public sector and those that are in the<br />

private sector. In Figure 5, we find a neg-<br />

ative correlation between the change in<br />

share of services that are performed<br />

mostly by the public sector (such as electricity,<br />

public administration, railways,<br />

and other community services) and the<br />

average annual state growth. In other<br />

words, the share of public sector services<br />

including administration is growing in the<br />

laggard states, while the share of private<br />

sector services is growing in the fast-moving<br />

states.<br />

Armed with all this, let us turn to the<br />

question of where India may be headed?<br />

It would appear that the fast growing peninsular<br />

states are starting to resemble<br />

more developed countries in their specialization,<br />

while the slow growing hinterland<br />

states, with their still rapidly growing,<br />

less well-educated, populations are<br />

falling behind. Visaria and Visaria (2003)<br />

suggest that 60 percent of the expected<br />

620 million addition to the Indian population<br />

between now and 2051 will be in Bihar,<br />

Madhya Pradesh, Rajasthan and Uttar<br />

Pradesh; only 22 percent will be in the<br />

fast growing states of Kerala, Tamil Nadu,<br />

Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, and Maharashtra.<br />

Such trends could create immense<br />

economic and political strains between<br />

Indian states.<br />

It may well be that the slow growing<br />

states will have to follow a more traditional<br />

path of growth, focusing on laborintensive<br />

manufacturing. But for that<br />

further reform is needed—in particular,<br />

more flexible labor laws and an improvement<br />

of infrastructure, especially vis-à-vis<br />

the states in the hinterland so that these<br />

industries can be internationally costcompetitive—to<br />

revitalize labor-intensive<br />

manufacturing. But the archaic labor laws<br />

have strong organized constituencies, in<br />

particular, labor unions tied to political<br />

160 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


MORE MARKETS, LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

Figure 5. Public Services And States’ Growth<br />

Change in share of Public Services in<br />

NSDP 1980-2000 (%)<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

Change in share of Public Services in NSDP 1980-2000<br />

JK<br />

BH OR<br />

MP<br />

MN<br />

RJ<br />

HP<br />

pervisory skilled workers are affordable<br />

only if they are used very economically<br />

relative to the use of unskilled labor – if,<br />

for example, firms have scale. 9 Here<br />

again, the fast moving states where the<br />

business and political climate is more<br />

conducive to scale have an advantage. In<br />

5<br />

sum, the fast-growing states could absorb<br />

AS UP<br />

KL GJ MH AP KK TN<br />

the more mobile skilled labor from the<br />

0<br />

PJ<br />

HY<br />

WB slow moving states leading to a further<br />

hollowing out of prospects there. <strong>The</strong><br />

-5<br />

DL<br />

obvious solution is not to impede the<br />

1 2 3 4<br />

Average Annual Growth of NSDP per capita 1980-2000 (%)<br />

5 growth of the fast-movers but to enhance<br />

the availability of the resource in scarce<br />

Source: Authors’ calculations; data on unregistered manufacturing are from the Central Statistical Organization, Government<br />

of India.<br />

supply. Although the earlier emphasis on<br />

Notes: <strong>The</strong> share of high labor (skill) intensity industries is the ratio of value added in sectors with above-median labor<br />

(skill) intensity to that in sectors with below-median labor (skill) intensity. <strong>The</strong> relevant sector classification is given in funding tertiary education at the expense<br />

Table 3.<br />

of primary education may<br />

Code State Code State Code State<br />

have been an aberration,<br />

AP Andhra Pradesh JK Jammu & Kashmir OR Orissa<br />

India may now have too<br />

little tertiary education of<br />

AS Assam KK Karnataka PJ Punjab<br />

the right kind at this juncture.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re are serious<br />

BH Bihar KL Kerala RJ Rajasthan<br />

DL Delhi MH Maharashtra TN Tamil Nadu<br />

doubts about the quality<br />

GJ Gujarat MN Manipur TP Tripura<br />

of education received by<br />

HP Himachal Pradesh MP Madhya Pradesh UP Uttar Pradesh<br />

the large number of graduates<br />

HY Haryana NG Nagaland WB West Bengal<br />

emerging from uni-<br />

versity every year. <strong>The</strong><br />

parties, backing them. Given the way Indian<br />

industry has specialized, the costs of<br />

these laws are not experienced by incumbents,<br />

and the political leadership, or will,<br />

to amend them has not emerged. 8<br />

Even if serious reforms were undertaken<br />

in the laggard states, competition<br />

from the more advanced states will not<br />

make it easy for them to grow. First, laggard<br />

states are typically distant from<br />

ports and airports. Transportation costs<br />

will come down as infrastructure is built<br />

up, but it is unclear whether the improvements<br />

will help them out-compete the<br />

fast-growing peninsular states where<br />

many of the initial large-scale infrastructure<br />

projects are being undertaken, and<br />

where ancillary infrastructure exists.<br />

Second, even labor-intensive unskilled<br />

manufacturing—should it pick up—requires<br />

a skilled supervisory and managerial<br />

force. Despite the large numbers of<br />

graduates emerging from universities in<br />

India, the number of graduates with the<br />

skills to work in industry or the service<br />

sector is relatively limited. With the immense<br />

demand for skilled workers in the<br />

export-oriented services industry, wages<br />

of skilled workers have been going up<br />

very fast. Given the extremely competitive<br />

situation in (typically tradable) labor-intensive<br />

industries, highly paid su-<br />

number of high-quality institutions is<br />

still very small, and thus, India needs to<br />

remove the barriers to starting new institutions,<br />

as well as encourage foreign direct<br />

investment here. In short, from a<br />

policy perspective, the irony is that in<br />

order to promote unskilled labor-intensive<br />

activities in the future, a great deal<br />

of attention may need to be paid in fostering<br />

the supply of skilled labor.<br />

<strong>The</strong> changes since the early 1980s have<br />

unleashed tremendous economic opportunities,<br />

but also divergence between<br />

states. From uniformly mediocre economic<br />

performance, India has evolved<br />

into a conglomeration of states with per-<br />

TP<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

161


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

formance more related to the capabilities<br />

of individual states and the opportunities<br />

they create. It is possible that the laggard<br />

states would do what it takes to utilize<br />

their vast pools of underemployed lowcost<br />

labor to attract investment in laborintensive<br />

manufacturing and agri-business.<br />

<strong>The</strong>y would thereby catch up with<br />

the leading states in India. <strong>The</strong> revival of<br />

manufacturing growth since 2004, albeit<br />

still concentrated in skill-intensive<br />

and capital-intensive industries, offers<br />

hope for this scenario.<br />

End Notes<br />

1<br />

This paper is based upon Kochhar et<br />

al. (2006)<br />

2<br />

Of course, other factors also affect<br />

sectoral shares (see, for example,<br />

Chenery and Taylor (1968)), but our<br />

intent here is primarily to see whether<br />

India is an outlier after controlling for<br />

obvious factors, rather than to do an<br />

exhaustive study of the sectoral composition<br />

of growth per se. Also, we<br />

report results for the largest sample of<br />

countries, though the results are qualitatively<br />

similar, when not specifically<br />

noted, for a smaller cross-section restricted<br />

to non-OECD countries.<br />

3<br />

Comparable cross-country data on<br />

employment shares are not available<br />

separately for the manufacturing sector,<br />

only for industry (manufacturing,<br />

mining, and core infrastructure sectors),<br />

and services. Thus the analysis<br />

of employment shares is conducted for<br />

industry and services .<br />

4<br />

<strong>The</strong> choice of South Africa was dictated<br />

primarily by data availability.<br />

Our results are robust to alternative<br />

definitions of skill intensity, including<br />

restricting the definition to the highly<br />

skilled category and defining skill intensity<br />

in terms of share of remuneration<br />

in output rather than value added.<br />

We also checked the correlation of our<br />

measures of skill intensity with that<br />

compiled for the U.S. by Rajan and<br />

Wulf (2004). It is 0.66, for the highly<br />

skilled category, and 0.5 when skill<br />

intensity includes highly skilled and<br />

skilled workers.<br />

5<br />

It may well be, of course, that India’s<br />

labor-intensive production was concentrated<br />

in the unregistered sector,<br />

for which we do not have comparable<br />

data from other countries. To the extent<br />

that firms in the unregistered sector<br />

have inefficiently small scale, total<br />

production would still be smaller and<br />

less competitive than it could be without<br />

the spectrum of regulations. Also,<br />

unregistered labor-intensive production<br />

has been falling considerably over<br />

time, suggesting that this explanation<br />

for India’s lack of concentration in labor-intensive<br />

manufacturing is less<br />

applicable today.<br />

6<br />

This development contradicts the<br />

Kuznets-Chenery hypothesis. Kongsamut,<br />

Rebelo, and Xie (2001), however,<br />

argued based on an analysis of<br />

123 countries over the period 1970-89<br />

that the share of services rises with<br />

development more than anticipated by<br />

the Kuznets-Chenery view.<br />

7<br />

However, we find that industry (that<br />

is, manufacturing, mining and core<br />

infrastructure industries) was a significant<br />

negative outlier in 2000, possibly<br />

related to the much worse than<br />

average performance of India’s infrastructure<br />

sector.<br />

8<br />

In other words, most commentators<br />

look to existing firms to see if labor<br />

laws are a problem. But existing firms<br />

have adapted to these laws, as suggested<br />

both by their pattern of specialization<br />

and their scale. <strong>The</strong> more<br />

pertinent question is whether new<br />

firms are kept from entering because<br />

of the laws. <strong>The</strong> pattern of specialization<br />

in India suggest they are.<br />

9<br />

Alternatively, the wages on unskilled<br />

labor may fall, but wages in agriculture<br />

may place a floor here.<br />

References<br />

• Chenery, H.B., 1960, Patterns of industrial<br />

growth, American Economic<br />

Review Vol. 57, 415-26, and L.J. Taylor,<br />

1968, Development patterns:<br />

among countries and over time, Review<br />

of Economics and Statistics, Vol.<br />

50, 391-416.<br />

• Imbs, J., and R. Wacziarg, 2003, Stages<br />

of development, <strong>The</strong> American<br />

Economic Review, March, Vol. 93,<br />

No. 1.<br />

• Kochhar, Kalpana, Utsav Kumar, Raghuram<br />

Rajan, Arvind Subramanian,<br />

Ioannis Tokatlidis, “India’s Pattern of<br />

Development: What Happened, What<br />

Follows?” Journal of Monetary Economics,<br />

Vol 53(5), July 2006<br />

• Kongsamut, P., S. Rebelo, and D. Xie,<br />

2001, Beyond balanced growth, IMF<br />

Working Paper 01/85 (Washington:<br />

International Monetary Fund).<br />

• Visaria, L., and P. Visaria, 2003, Long<br />

term population projections for major<br />

states, 1991-2101, Economic and Political<br />

Weekly, November.<br />

• Rajan, R. and J.Wulf, 2004, Are perks<br />

purely managerial excess? NBER<br />

Working Paper No. 10494 (Cambridge,<br />

Massachusetts : National Bureau of<br />

Economic Research).<br />

162 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


TECH WATCH<br />

What’s in store<br />

for technology freaks in 2008<br />

INDIA’S FIRST AND NO. 1<br />

BUSINESS AND MARKETING MAGAZINE<br />

✮ PRODUCT ✮ PRICE ✮ PLACE ✮ PROMOTION ✮<br />

4Ps<br />

BUSINESS AND<br />

MARKETING<br />

<strong>Volume</strong>-II <strong>Issue</strong>-24 4 January - 17 January 2008<br />

Why Toyota, GM,<br />

Ford & Renault<br />

love India...<br />

Power, passion, leadership skills,<br />

strategic expertise and many<br />

such qualities... they have it all;<br />

the maestros who will turn things<br />

around for India in 2008. <strong>The</strong>se<br />

are the very forces who will make<br />

2008 worthwhile for India Inc. An<br />

exclusive 4Ps B&M compilation...<br />

20<br />

Meet the 2nd<br />

Son of the East<br />

Rendezvous with<br />

Kenji Anai,<br />

Global Head,<br />

Multifuncl. Devices,<br />

National Panasonic<br />

88 Supermodels<br />

NOW ONLY<br />

Rs.10<br />

alone can’t<br />

cast the<br />

marketing<br />

spell.<br />

You<br />

need<br />

Pill(ow) fight<br />

more! Why Dabur needs a<br />

‘new u’ look soon<br />

by Rajita<br />

Chaudhuri<br />

38<br />

Top 5:<br />

Why Airtel &<br />

Kingfisher Airlines<br />

reign supreme<br />

this fortnight<br />

...and why India loves Jaguar, Land<br />

Rover & Suzuki. <strong>The</strong> reason: India<br />

may emerge as a global player in the<br />

passenger car segment<br />

4Ps<br />

BUSINESS AND<br />

MARKETING


T.R.Manoharan,<br />

Senior Coordinator, Forest Programme,<br />

WWF-India,New Delhi<br />

India’s Growing Ecological Footprint: Exploring<br />

Past And Future Changes<br />

"<strong>The</strong>re is enough for everybody’s<br />

need, but not enough<br />

for anybody’s greed."<br />

-Mahatma Gandhi<br />

Introduction<br />

A high economic growth is essential for<br />

India to ensure improved living conditions<br />

of its citizens, which majorly consists of<br />

poor and marginalized sections. <strong>The</strong> nation<br />

possesses only 2.2 per cent of the land<br />

mass but home to 16 per cent of world<br />

population and 27 percent of world’s poor.<br />

Despite its low per capita income, India is<br />

presently the world’s tenth largest economy<br />

in terms of GDP. <strong>The</strong> economy is<br />

growing at 7 to 8 per cent per annum since<br />

2003 and is targeted to grow at 9 per cent<br />

or above during <strong>2007</strong>-12 (Planning Commission,<br />

2006; World Bank, <strong>2007</strong>). To<br />

achieve this target, increased use of bioresources-<br />

both within the country and<br />

elsewhere is inevitable.<br />

Available estimates show that humanity’s<br />

ecological footprint (demand on ecosystems)<br />

has exceeded the bio-capacity of<br />

the planet by late 1980s and the over shoot<br />

is accumulating ever since. It is pointed<br />

out that world is following unsustainable<br />

path of development and the growing ecological<br />

debt is a major factor. Presently,<br />

we are using 30 percent more resources<br />

than the planet can regenerate (In other<br />

words, 1.3 planets). <strong>The</strong> global footprint<br />

network estimates ecological debt day for<br />

every year to create awareness on how humanity’s<br />

consumption patterns are depleting<br />

the planets bio-resources . In <strong>2007</strong>,<br />

the ecological debt day was October 6. By<br />

that day the humanity has consumed total<br />

amount of new resources that the planet<br />

can produce this year. Ecological debt day<br />

marks the day when we begin to live beyond<br />

our ecological means. If we continue<br />

the current path of development, the<br />

ecological debt day will come earlier in<br />

every year. Several options are available<br />

now to minimize the risk of accumulated<br />

ecological debt (WWF, 2006; UNEP,<br />

<strong>2007</strong>). India, being one of the fastest<br />

growing economies in the world with more<br />

than one billion people, can play a crucial<br />

role to address this global challenge. It is<br />

possible to minimize the ecological footprint<br />

of the nation while continuing higher<br />

economic growth and efforts to attain<br />

high human development.<br />

164 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS<br />

Table-1: India’s Economic Growth<br />

Plan<br />

Period<br />

Real Income<br />

Plan<br />

Target<br />

Use Of Natural Resources<br />

India is rich in terms of natural resource<br />

endowments and biodiversity. <strong>The</strong> nation<br />

is one of the 12 mega biodiversity countries<br />

in the world. More than 45000 flora<br />

and 77000 species of fauna are recorded.<br />

<strong>The</strong> natural ecosystem include 16 types of<br />

forests 5 types of grass lands, 27,403 wetland<br />

units (both inland and coastal) including<br />

lakes, swamps, tanks and reservoirs,<br />

tidal mudflats, mangroves, estuaries,<br />

lagoons, coral reefs, sand beach (Verma<br />

et. al, <strong>2007</strong>). <strong>The</strong>se resources provide a<br />

flow of environmental (ecosystem) services<br />

required for production/economic<br />

development. However, the depletion and<br />

degradation of natural resources pose a<br />

serious threat to the sustained flow of<br />

these ecosystem services. <strong>The</strong> uncertainty<br />

of quality and quantity of such services<br />

has not been suitably factored into the development<br />

models. Forest is the second<br />

largest land use in India next to agriculture.<br />

<strong>The</strong> latest assessment of forest survey<br />

of India in 2003 estimated about 67.8 million<br />

hectares of forest cover in the country<br />

Actual<br />

Growth<br />

Sectoral Growth Rate<br />

Agriculture Industry Services<br />

First Plan 1951-56 2.1 3.6 2.9 5.9 3.7<br />

Second Plan 1956-61 4.5 3.9 3.2 6.4 4.6<br />

Third Plan 1961-66 5.6 2.3 -0.5 6.8 5.0<br />

Fourth Plan 1969-74 5.7 3.2 2.6 3.7 4.0<br />

Fifth Plan 1974-79 4.4 4.8 3.4 6.3 5.5<br />

Sixth Plan 1980-85 5.2 5.7 5.5 6.2 5.4<br />

Seventh Plan 1985-90 5.0 6.0 3.4 7.5 7.4<br />

Eighth Plan 1992-97 5.6 6.8 3.9 8.0 7.9<br />

Ninth Plan 1997-02 6.5 5.5 2.1 4.6 8.1<br />

Tenth Plan 2002-07 8.0 7.2* 1.7 8.3 9.0<br />

Eleventh Plan <strong>2007</strong>-12 9.0 - 4.1* 10.5* 9.9*<br />

* projected.<br />

Sources: Planning Commission, Govt. of India & http://www.indiastat.com<br />

which is 20.64 percent of the total geographical<br />

area (FSI, 2005). It shows a marginal<br />

increase in the total forest cover, but<br />

the loss of 2.6 million ha of dense forests<br />

when compared to previous assessment in<br />

2001. <strong>The</strong> nation is targeted to achieve 33<br />

per cent of its area under forest and tree<br />

cover by 2012. <strong>The</strong> per capita availability<br />

of land in India has declined from 0.91 ha<br />

to 0.33 ha between 1950 and 2001.<strong>The</strong> per<br />

capita availability of farm land declined<br />

from 0.64 ha to 0.25 ha during the same<br />

period. India occupies 4 per cent of world’s<br />

water resources which are depleting fast.<br />

In 1947, the per capita availability of fresh<br />

water in India was 5150 cu.m but it reduced<br />

to 2200 cu.m in 2000. It is projected<br />

that in 2017, the same will become 1600<br />

cu.m. resulting water stress in many places.<br />

<strong>The</strong> melting of glaziers in Himalayas and<br />

other climate change related issues can<br />

lead to irreversible changes in ecosystems.<br />

India is said to be particularly vulnerable<br />

due to these effects.<br />

While there is overall decline in India’s<br />

bio-capacity, its use has increased faster<br />

to meet the growing needs of development.<br />

Electricity generation in India has<br />

increased from 6 billion KWH to 556 billion<br />

KWH between 1951 and 2001. <strong>The</strong><br />

coal production has increased from 32<br />

million tonnes to 332 million tones between<br />

1951 and 2001. In 2006, the production<br />

was 670 million tones. In order to<br />

meet the growing demand for energy, the<br />

production is targeted to increase to 670<br />

million tones by 2012. In addition to domestic<br />

production, 40-50 million tones of<br />

superior coal is required to be imported<br />

during the 11 th plan period. Crude oil imports<br />

increased from six million tones to<br />

78 million tones between 1961 and 2001<br />

(Table-2).<br />

Ecological Footprint<br />

An ecological footprint measures people’s<br />

demand on nature and compares human<br />

consumption of natural resources with the<br />

Earth’s ecological capacity (bio-capacity)<br />

to regenerate them. A country’s ecological<br />

Available estimates show that humanity’s ecological footprint<br />

has exceeded the bio-capacity of the planet by late<br />

1980s. Presently, we are using 30 percent more<br />

resources than the planet can regenerate<br />

footprint is the total area required to produce<br />

the food and fibre that it consumes,<br />

absorb its waste, and provide space for its<br />

infrastructure. People consume resources<br />

and ecological services all over the world,<br />

so their footprint is the sum of these areas,<br />

wherever they are on the planet. Ecologi-<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

165


PROGRESS WITHIN LIMITS<br />

Table-2: Changes In Select Indicators Of India’s Bio Capacity And Its Use<br />

Per capita Availability Of:<br />

Year Population<br />

(million)<br />

Land<br />

(ha)<br />

Farm<br />

Land<br />

(ha)<br />

Forest<br />

Area<br />

(ha)<br />

Population<br />

Density<br />

(per<br />

q.km)<br />

Energy<br />

generated<br />

(Billion<br />

KWH)<br />

Crude<br />

Oil<br />

Imports<br />

(Millon<br />

Tonnes)<br />

Imports Of<br />

Petroleum<br />

(Million<br />

tonnes)<br />

Production<br />

Of Coal<br />

(Million<br />

tonnes)<br />

Export (US$<br />

Million)<br />

(including<br />

re-exports)<br />

Import<br />

(US$<br />

Million)<br />

1951 361.1 110 0.91 0.64 0.113 6.6 3.1 32.3 1490 1852<br />

1961 439.2 134 0.75 0.50 0.124 20.1 6 2.5 55.2 1381 2281<br />

1971 548.2 167 0.60 0.41 0.115 61.2 11.7 1.1 76.3 2153 2443<br />

1981 683.3 208 0.48 0.36 0.099 129.2 16.2 7.3 119 8704 15174<br />

1991 846.3 257 0.39 0.30 0.081 289.4 20.7 8.7 225.5 17865 19411<br />

2001 1028.7 313 0.30 0.25 0.074 554.5 78.7 7.0 332.6 43827 51413<br />

Source: Ministry of Environment and Forests,Government of India (Various Reports).<br />

cal footprints enable people to take personal<br />

or collective actions in support of a<br />

world where humanity lives within the<br />

means of one planet (WWF, 2006; Global<br />

footprint network). <strong>The</strong> available estimates<br />

show that India’s ecological footprint<br />

per person (0.8 global hectares) is<br />

lower than the world average (2.2 global<br />

hectares) but it is much higher than the<br />

nations' biocapacity and this has placed<br />

India in the list of “ecological deficit”<br />

countries. <strong>The</strong> Living Planet Report -<br />

2006 ranked India as the third largest<br />

footprint country followed by United<br />

States and China. “India’s total ecological<br />

footprint is likely to increase due to the<br />

twin pressures from population and consumption<br />

patterns unless suitable actions<br />

are taken. In 2002, the humanity’s per person<br />

footprint was 2.2 global hectares (gha)<br />

whereas the bio capacity per person was<br />

1.8 gha. India’s footprint was 0.8 gha<br />

which is lower than world average but<br />

lower than the nation’s biocapacity (04<br />

gha). Between 1975 and 2003, India’s foot<br />

print per person has increased faster (16<br />

percent) than that of the world (14 percent)<br />

but much lower than many other economies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> ecological footprint estimates<br />

indicate that India’s bio-capacity is not<br />

sufficient to meet the needs of the nations'<br />

growing population. In other words, future<br />

development in India is also dependant<br />

on the use of natural resources of<br />

other countries. Globalization makes it<br />

possible to use these resources legally and<br />

openly. <strong>The</strong> nation has committed to conservation<br />

of natural resources and biodiversity<br />

and implemented several policy<br />

and legal measures. It is also party to<br />

many Multilateral Environmental Agreements<br />

(MEAs) such as Convention on<br />

Biological Diversity (CBD), CITES, Montreal<br />

Table-2: Changes In Select Indicators Of India’s Bio Capacity And Its Use<br />

Protocol. In practice,<br />

Country Ecological<br />

Footprint<br />

(Demand)<br />

Biocapacity<br />

(Supply)<br />

(gha. Per<br />

Ecol. Footprint –<br />

Biocapacity =Ecological<br />

Reserve Or<br />

Footprint<br />

Change Per<br />

Person (%)<br />

Biocapacity<br />

Change Per<br />

Person (%)<br />

these measures have regulated<br />

or prohibited consumptive<br />

use (extraction) of natural resources<br />

in India. However,<br />

(gha. Per Person) Ecological Deficit (-) 1975-2003 1975-2003<br />

Person) 2003 2003 gha. Per Person)2003<br />

this gives economic opportunities<br />

for many biodiversity<br />

India 0.8 0.4 -0.4 16 -23<br />

China 1.6 0.8 -0.9 82 -3<br />

rich countries where such resources<br />

Brazil<br />

South Africa<br />

USA<br />

Indonesia<br />

World<br />

Source: WWF (2006)<br />

2.1<br />

2.3<br />

9.6<br />

1.1<br />

2.2<br />

9.9<br />

2.0<br />

4.7<br />

1.0<br />

1.8<br />

7.8<br />

-0.3<br />

-4.8<br />

-0.1<br />

-0.45<br />

30<br />

-13<br />

38<br />

36<br />

14<br />

-27<br />

-23<br />

-20<br />

-20<br />

-25<br />

are abundant. For<br />

example, felling of timber is<br />

prohibited, wood in log forms<br />

cannot be exported from India<br />

with a view to safeguard<br />

our remaining forests. But,<br />

166 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


ENVIRONMENTAL ECONOMICS<br />

we permit imports from all over the world<br />

including those originated from rainforests/<br />

worlds critical eco-regions. <strong>The</strong>re<br />

are several restrictions for land in India for<br />

establishing plantations, but enough land<br />

is offered for Indian companies in many<br />

countries in order to attract investment<br />

and creating employment opportunities in<br />

those countries. <strong>The</strong> proponents of trade<br />

liberalization may argue that this is the<br />

principle of trade and here the comparative<br />

advantage is the natural resources<br />

(mineral/ timber). <strong>The</strong>oretically, there is<br />

no inherent conflict between trade and<br />

environment (Ripetto,1994). <strong>The</strong>y admit<br />

that environmental issues are negative externalities<br />

and the same can be internalized<br />

through appropriate policies such as<br />

“Polluter Pays Principle” (PPP). But, the<br />

environmentalists are concerned about<br />

the depletion of these resources due to<br />

unsustainable extraction. If they are unable<br />

to influence the countries that permit<br />

extraction of such resources, they can request/lobbey<br />

for impose regulation of the<br />

products and services in the leading markets<br />

it reaches/ importing countries. Such<br />

regulations can be in the form of certification,<br />

labeling or other environmental<br />

standards. This in turn can be challenged<br />

by the affected countries as environmental<br />

non-tariff barriers are targeted to distort<br />

their international trade. <strong>The</strong>refore, these<br />

measures are applied voluntarily in most<br />

cases. <strong>The</strong> success of these measures is<br />

dependant on the ability to develop techniques<br />

or approaches for sustainable use<br />

of these resources with the active participation<br />

of all stake holders. Forest Stewardship<br />

Council (FSC) certification is an<br />

example for sustainable and resourceful<br />

usage of timber and other forest products.<br />

Presently, in India, these novel approaches<br />

are yet to gain popularity.<br />

What Options Are Available?<br />

Several options are available to minimize<br />

the ecological footprint and enhance the<br />

bio-capacity. This include appropriate<br />

population policy enabling slowing down<br />

the population growth and providing incentives<br />

for those opting for fewer children.<br />

Promotion of policies and programmes<br />

that can influence changes in<br />

consumption patterns at all levels. It is<br />

recgonised that people living below subsistence<br />

need to increase their consumption<br />

to reach out of poverty, others can<br />

reduce consumption and lavish life style.<br />

<strong>The</strong> quantity of resources used in the production<br />

of goods and services can be reduced.<br />

This can be achieved through energy<br />

efficiency; minimizing waste;<br />

increasing recycling and reuse, use of fuel<br />

efficient transportation systems; reduction<br />

in transportation of goods and services;<br />

technical innovation; Technologies<br />

need to be promoted to increase productivity.<br />

Biocapacity can be enhanced<br />

through implementation of environmentally<br />

sound land management, effective<br />

use of marginal lands, promotion of agricultural<br />

technologies; protecting soil from<br />

erosion. Several options, including carbon<br />

markets are available for prevention<br />

and mitigation of climate change issues.<br />

Inappropriate use of chemicals can degrade<br />

ecosystems and loss of biodiversity.<br />

To address this, organic farming need to<br />

be promoted. Business and Industry<br />

should adopt environmentally credible<br />

procurement policies to minimize their<br />

footprint. For this, several voluntary certification<br />

schemes, such as forest certification<br />

are available. <strong>The</strong> approach to the<br />

11 th plan has rightly suggested that environmental<br />

issues cannot be addressed by<br />

slowing economic growth in India. Rather,<br />

high economic growth can provide the<br />

resources to prevent and deal with environmental<br />

issues.<br />

References<br />

• FSI (2005) State of forest report-2003,<br />

Forest survey of India, Dehra Dun<br />

• Haripriya Gundimeda, Sanjeev Sanyal,<br />

Rajiv Sinha and Pavan Sukhdev<br />

(2005) Estimating the value of<br />

agricultural cropland and pastureland<br />

in India, Green Accounting for<br />

Indian States Project-(GIST),<br />

(monograph-)Chennai<br />

• Ripetto, R (1994) Trade and Sustainable<br />

Development, United Nations Environment<br />

Programme, Nairobi<br />

• Planning Commission (2006) Towards<br />

more faster and more inclusive growth-<br />

An approach to the 11 th Five Year Plan,<br />

Planning Commission, Govt. of India<br />

• (1998) Looking Back to <strong>Think</strong> Ahead-<br />

Green India-2047, Tata Energy Research<br />

Institute, New Delhi.<br />

• UNEP (<strong>2007</strong>) Global Environment<br />

Outlook-4, Environment and Development,<br />

United Nations Environment<br />

Programme, Nairobi.<br />

• Verma, D D, S Arora and R K Rai<br />

(Eds) (<strong>2007</strong>); 'Perspectives on biodiversity-<br />

A vision for mega diverse countries',<br />

Ministry of Environment and<br />

Forests (MoEF), Government of India,<br />

New Delhi.<br />

• WWF (2006) Living Planet Report-<br />

2006, WWF-International, Gland<br />

• World Bank (<strong>2007</strong>) Strengthening Institutions<br />

for Sustainable Growth,<br />

Country environment analysis for India,<br />

<strong>The</strong> World Bank (India Country<br />

Office), New Delhi.<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

167


Shubha Ghosh<br />

Professor of Law<br />

SMU Dedman School of Law<br />

Dallas, Texas USA<br />

<strong>The</strong> First Sale Doctrine Before <strong>The</strong> U.S. Supreme Court:<br />

Intellectual Property Implications For India<br />

"Bad laws are the worst sort<br />

of tyranny."<br />

-Edmund Burke<br />

<strong>The</strong> United States Supreme<br />

Court will be hearing oral arguments<br />

in a case called Quanta<br />

Computers v. LG Electronics in<br />

January, 2008. At issue in the case is<br />

the status of the first sale doctrine in<br />

light of recent decisions by the United<br />

States Court of Appeals for the Federal<br />

Circuit, the intermediate appeals court<br />

for the review of claims under patent<br />

law. <strong>The</strong> Federal Circuit has created a<br />

doctrine called the conditional sale<br />

doctrine which allows patent owners to<br />

impose conditions on the sale of license<br />

of a patented invention which limits the<br />

application of the first sale doctrine.<br />

<strong>The</strong> following is a summary of an argument<br />

from a brief that I submitted on<br />

behalf of the American Antitrust Institute<br />

that supports Quanta’s position in<br />

the case. Although resolving issues of<br />

U.S. law, the outcome of this case has<br />

important implications for the development<br />

of intellectual property law globally<br />

and in India.<br />

For over a century and a half, the first<br />

sale doctrine (also known as the exhaustion<br />

doctrine) has provided certainty<br />

for users, manufacturers and<br />

other business entities in the distribution<br />

of goods and services protected by<br />

intellectual property law. Patent and<br />

copyright law grants to inventors and<br />

authors limited rights to control the distribution<br />

of the products of their creativity.<br />

However, the first sale doctrine<br />

creates a bright-line rule that ensures<br />

that purchasers of these works can further<br />

transfer these items to third parties<br />

without the interference of the original<br />

intellectual property owners. In this<br />

way, the first sale promotes an active<br />

and vibrant marketplace for works created<br />

through the benefit of patent and<br />

copyright and therefore is integral to<br />

the goals of innovation and competition<br />

that are at the foundation of the system<br />

of intellectual property rights. <strong>The</strong><br />

doctrine of conditional sale, as articulated<br />

and applied by the United States<br />

168 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


LAW AND PUBLIC POLICY<br />

Court of Appeals for the Federal circuit,<br />

allows patent owners to circumvent<br />

the first sale doctrine and undermine<br />

its beneficial policies, and is inconsistent<br />

with this Court’s precedent.<br />

Given the intangibility and nonrivalrous<br />

characteristic of intellectual property<br />

rights, formal legal titling systems<br />

cannot readily be created to ensure that<br />

such works can be transferred without<br />

being at the sufferance of the original<br />

patent or copyright owner. <strong>The</strong> first<br />

sale doctrine serves the function of a<br />

formal legal titling system for intellectual<br />

property. Under the first sale doctrine,<br />

a patent or copyright owner exhausts<br />

her distribution right upon the<br />

first sale of the protected work thereby<br />

allowing subsequent purchasers to further<br />

transfer the work. <strong>The</strong> doctrine<br />

requires that the intellectual property<br />

owner obtain its consideration in the<br />

first sale (or license to sell), before allowing<br />

the distribution of a product<br />

embodying its intellectual property into<br />

the stream of commerce. In this way, it<br />

allows for active and vibrant markets<br />

for works of art, for novels, for movies,<br />

for innovative gadgets containing patented<br />

inventions, and for technology<br />

itself. <strong>The</strong> doctrine provides the legal<br />

foundation for primary markets, for<br />

secondary markets for rentals of these<br />

types of works, and for credit markets<br />

in which copyright and patents can<br />

serve as security interests. Absent the<br />

first sale doctrine, business people engaged<br />

in the buying and selling of works<br />

that are either directly protected by intellectual<br />

property or contain components<br />

protected by intellectual property<br />

may be required to compensate the<br />

original intellectual property owner<br />

whenever a transfer of interest in the<br />

work occurs. And purchasers of such<br />

works would always take title subject to<br />

the claims of the original intellectual<br />

property owner, perhaps unaware of<br />

such claims. Such actual or potential<br />

interference from the original creator<br />

would only serve to raise transaction<br />

costs and to create impediments to free<br />

and open markets.<br />

Starting with its decision in Mallinckrodt,<br />

Inc. v. Medipart, Inc., 976 F.2d<br />

700 (Fed. Cir. 1992), the Federal Circuit<br />

has misconstrued this Court’s precedent<br />

to permit a patent owner that<br />

“conditions” the sale of a patented invention<br />

to sue subsequent purchasers<br />

who violate the condition for patent infringement.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Federal Circuit’s justification<br />

for the conditional sale doctrine<br />

rests on a misunderstanding of the<br />

relationship between the transfer of<br />

works protected by intellectual property<br />

rights and conditions attendant in<br />

contracts that accompany such a transfer.<br />

While purporting to rely on contract<br />

principles, the Federal Circuit has<br />

converted restrictions ancillary to the<br />

transfer of a patented invention from<br />

contractual rights, subject to the scrutiny<br />

under relevant contract, antitrust,<br />

and patent law, to intellectual property<br />

rights enforceable through a claim for<br />

patent infringement, with its attendant<br />

panoply of remedies and potential immunity<br />

from antitrust scrutiny. Because<br />

the Federal Circuit’s conditional sale<br />

doctrine allows a patent owner to expand<br />

the reach of its patent grant and<br />

disrupt free and open markets, it should<br />

be reversed.<br />

In the case at bar, respondent’s licensee<br />

has sold an article that “embodies<br />

essential features” of the patented<br />

invention and “has destined the article<br />

to be finished by the purchaser in conformity<br />

to the patent.” Respondent<br />

acquired a large patent portfolio of<br />

technologies used in the manufacture<br />

of computer chips. After a dispute with<br />

Intel, the chip manufacturer, respondent<br />

entered into a complex licensing<br />

agreement with Intel that allowed Intel<br />

to use the technology in the construction<br />

and sale of chips. <strong>The</strong>se chips in<br />

turn were sold to petitioners and incorporated<br />

as components in computer<br />

hardware systems. <strong>The</strong> LG-Intel license<br />

agreement contained a proviso<br />

that no license was granted to any third<br />

party to combine the chips with non-<br />

Intel products, and that Intel was re-<br />

<strong>The</strong> first sale doctrine creates a bright-line rule that ensures<br />

that purchasers of the creative works can further<br />

transfer these items to third parties without the interference<br />

of the original intellectual property owners<br />

quired to and did provide notice of this<br />

limitation to petitioners. See LG Electronics,<br />

Inc. v. Bizcom Electronics, Inc.,<br />

453 F.3d 1364, 1368 (Fed. Cir. 2006).<br />

But the license agreement also stipulated<br />

that it would not “limit or alter the<br />

effect of patent exhaustion that otherwise<br />

would apply when” the chips were<br />

sold, the notice received by petitioners<br />

was apparently sent after many of the<br />

sales had already occurred, and the<br />

chips had no other reasonable use. See<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

169


A NEW BEGINNING<br />

Brief for Petitioners 2, 8-9. Now, respondent<br />

seeks to enforce its patent<br />

rights against the petitioners based on<br />

their alleged violation of “conditions”<br />

placed on the original agreement with<br />

Intel. <strong>The</strong> first sale doctrine was designed<br />

to prohibit precisely this type of<br />

reach-through by the patent owner to<br />

enforce its patent rights. Under this<br />

Court’s precedents, once the petitioners<br />

purchased products embodying essential<br />

features of the patented invention<br />

in an authorized sale, respondent’s<br />

patent rights were exhausted. If the<br />

conditions placed in the license with<br />

Intel are consistent with contract law,<br />

antitrust law, and the patent misuse<br />

doctrine, then any violations can be enforced<br />

against Intel as contract claims<br />

(or possibly against the petitioners as<br />

third party contract claims), rather than<br />

patent infringement claims with the attendant<br />

remedies of injunctive relief,<br />

treble damages, and attorneys’ fees.<br />

Such a result is consistent with the need<br />

for certainty and competitiveness of not<br />

only this market transaction, but also<br />

the wide ranges of market transactions<br />

that rest on intellectual property. In<br />

eBay Inc. v. Mercexchange, L.L.C., 126<br />

S.Ct. 1837 (2006), a plurality of the<br />

Court was concerned about the development<br />

of an industry “in which firms<br />

use patents not as a basis for producing<br />

and selling goods but, instead, primarily<br />

for obtaining licensing fees”, and the<br />

potentially harmful effects of injunctive<br />

relief “[w]hen the patented invention is<br />

but a small component of the product<br />

the companies seek to produce….” Id.<br />

at 1842 (Kennedy, J., concurring). <strong>The</strong><br />

In future cases, Indian High Courts could look to procompetition<br />

decisions in the United States, such as eBay<br />

and perhaps Quanta, to recognize that the need for competition<br />

balances the need for intellectual property rights<br />

first sale doctrine plays a role in preventing<br />

similar market disruption, as<br />

here, when a non-manufacturing patentee<br />

seeks to control the manufacture of<br />

end products in which the patented item<br />

is but a small component.<br />

<strong>The</strong> United States Supreme Court’s<br />

resolution of the Quanta case has implications<br />

globally. By abrogating the<br />

conditional sale doctrine, the Court will<br />

be affirming the bedrock principle of<br />

the first sale doctrine. More importantly,<br />

it will be recognizing competitive<br />

values in intellectual property law.<br />

Such a result is imperative for countries<br />

like India that are reforming intellectual<br />

property law and institutions. As<br />

the recent dispute brought by Novartis<br />

over the patentability of Gleevak shows,<br />

intellectual property norms are still being<br />

debated locally. <strong>The</strong> Quanta case<br />

shows that these norms are global. If<br />

the first sale doctrine is affirmed, then<br />

competition becomes an important normative<br />

goal for the design of intellectual<br />

property systems. India will have<br />

a strong position in asserting the values<br />

of competition as a limit on patent and<br />

other intellectual property rights.<br />

More subtly, if the Supreme Court<br />

strikes down the conditional sale doctrine,<br />

the Court will be placing some<br />

limits on the power of the Federal Circuit,<br />

the specialized patent appellate<br />

court in the United States. <strong>The</strong> Court<br />

will be implicitly saying that despite its<br />

expertise in patent law, the Federal Circuit<br />

cannot alter through the creation<br />

of new rules, like the conditional sale<br />

doctrine, that counter established principles<br />

of competition law and policy,<br />

like the first sale doctrine. In the Novartis<br />

dispute, the High Court of Chennai<br />

deferred to the Indian patent office<br />

and left open the standard for innovation<br />

in the pharmaceutical industry. In<br />

future cases, Indian High Courts could<br />

look to pro-competition decisions in the<br />

United States, such as eBay and perhaps<br />

Quanta, to recognize that the need for<br />

competition balances the need for intellectual<br />

property rights. As discussion<br />

in this essay suggests, intellectual property<br />

rights and competition together are<br />

both important for innovation.<br />

In conclusion, a business dispute over<br />

a patent license is the basis for the dispute<br />

in Quanta. But at stake is a bedrock<br />

principle of law, the first sale doctrine,<br />

and the relationship between<br />

competition norms and intellectual<br />

property law. <strong>The</strong> Supreme Court’s<br />

decision in the case should be closely<br />

watched for what it implies for international<br />

intellectual property law.<br />

170 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


Ali Mehdi,<br />

Research Associate,<br />

Indian Council for Research on International<br />

Economic Relations (ICRIER), New Delhi<br />

Liberty And Prohibition:<br />

A Governance Dilemma<br />

"I don't make jokes. I just<br />

watch the government and<br />

report the facts."<br />

-Will Rogers<br />

<strong>The</strong> Excise department of the<br />

Delhi government is, self-professedly,<br />

the second largest<br />

revenue earning department of the<br />

state. It generated Rs. 6190 crores as<br />

liquor revenue between 1994-95 and<br />

2004-05, while targeting an all-time<br />

high of Rs.900 crores for 2005-06. <strong>The</strong><br />

department’s website boasts that the<br />

success of the government is reflected<br />

in its ever-increasing revenue collection<br />

through liquor sales, which<br />

reached 15.3 crore bottles in 2002-03<br />

from 6.4 crore bottles in 1994-95. Most<br />

of the retail liquor trade in Delhi is<br />

done by four government agencies---<br />

Delhi Tourism and Transportation<br />

Development Corporation (DTTDC),<br />

<strong>The</strong> Delhi State Civil Supplies Corporation<br />

(DSCSC), Delhi State Industrial<br />

Development Corporation<br />

(DSIDC) and Delhi Consumer Co-operative<br />

Wholesale Store Limited (DC-<br />

CWS) through 309 shops. Private entrepreneurs<br />

hold 95 shops, and two<br />

L-53 licenses for retail sale through<br />

departmental stores for “off-site” consumption<br />

have been granted.<br />

Within the same Delhi government,<br />

there is the Directorate of Prohibition<br />

which vows by Article 47 of the Constitution<br />

and Mahatma gandhi, the Father<br />

of the Nation, claiming that<br />

“drinking in the society has ominous<br />

implications and weakens the entire<br />

social structure by disrupting the institution<br />

of the family and the country<br />

and also distorts the priorities of the<br />

development process.” While the Excise<br />

department is committed to “making<br />

safe liquor available to the consumers,”<br />

the Directorate of Prohibition<br />

tries “to promote healthy living among<br />

the citizens of Delhi by educating them<br />

regarding the ill effects of liquor and<br />

drug abuse and on the damage caused<br />

by the substances of abuse to the society<br />

and to the physical, psychological,<br />

social, economic and occupational life<br />

of an individual.”<br />

Starting as a cell in the Directorate<br />

of Information & Publicity in 1978-79,<br />

172 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


SOTTO VOCE<br />

the Directorate of Prohibition has<br />

been organizing fairs/melas, nukkar<br />

nataks, magic programmes, short films,<br />

and propaganda through kiosks,<br />

hoardings, backlit pillars, banners, bus<br />

back panels/queue shelters, computer<br />

animation display systems, seminars<br />

and conferences, personality development<br />

programmes, adventure activities,<br />

youth camps in collaboration with<br />

voluntary organizations. It has a staff<br />

of 21 employees (2005), a budget allocation<br />

of Rs. 1.7 crores for 2006-07,<br />

and has spent almost Rs. 8 crores in 7<br />

years (between 1997-98 and 2004-05).<br />

73.4 percent of the expenditure went as<br />

‘other charges', 10.2 percent into salaries,<br />

6.9 percent into strengthening of<br />

the department, and 9.1 percent in actual<br />

advertisement & publicity. All this<br />

to convey the message, which is mentioned<br />

as the last point in the Do’s &<br />

Don’ts list of the Excise department:<br />

“Consumption of liquor is injurious to<br />

health.” According to a survey conducted<br />

in 2002 by the Evaluation Unit<br />

of Planning department, 92 percent of<br />

those who consumed liquor were aware<br />

of its ill-effects, while 30 percent had<br />

reduced consumption due to Directorate’s<br />

publicity, doctor’s advise, social<br />

compulsion and financial difficulties.<br />

Starting with the name of the Directorate<br />

itself, there is no more “Prohibition”<br />

(as it refers officially to a restriction<br />

or ban on manufacture, import,<br />

export and sale of liquor) in Delhi. Appraisal<br />

of the Annual Plan 2004-05 by<br />

Planning department says that the<br />

functional utility and role of departments/undertakings<br />

like the Directorate<br />

of Prohibition needs to be assessed<br />

in view of “the changed scenario.” At<br />

a time when liquor sector has been liberalized<br />

by the state government,<br />

where is the moral/technical justification<br />

for Directorate of Prohibition?<br />

Alcohol consumption has increased<br />

over the years, but who is reaping the<br />

benefits of it? <strong>The</strong> government itself,<br />

through its Excise department and infact,<br />

more than the so-called “liquor<br />

mafia.” <strong>The</strong> government should think<br />

clear and decide what it needs: revenues<br />

or Gandhigiri?<br />

More importantly, by the Directorate’s<br />

own admission, in course of addressing<br />

the reasons for alcohol intake,<br />

the will power of the consumer, love<br />

and affection by people close to him/<br />

her, motivate a consumer to reduce/<br />

give up alcohol consumption (Annual<br />

Report 2001-2002). Is the Directorate<br />

capable of any of these? By all measures,<br />

not in the least. Institutionally,<br />

de-addiction centers would be more<br />

helpful. But the Directorate has none.<br />

If information dissemination is the<br />

aim, civil society does take care of that,<br />

and newspapers do publish newer research<br />

on health issues as well as on<br />

While the Excise department is committed to “making safe<br />

liquor available to the consumers,” the Directorate of Prohibition<br />

tries “to promote healthy living among the citizens<br />

of Delhi by educating the ill effects of liquor!<br />

alcohol consumption (<strong>The</strong> Times of<br />

India, New Delhi, <strong>Dec</strong>ember 29, 2006).<br />

And they are probably much more effective<br />

owing to their wide reach. If the<br />

government still insists, it could either<br />

remould the Directorate to the status<br />

of a cell within Directorate of Information<br />

& Publicity. This in my opinion,<br />

makes good economic sense. Alternatively,<br />

it can outsource publicity to an<br />

ad vertising agency, as it has undertaken<br />

in the case of ‘India Shining’<br />

campaign. People will vote in its favour.<br />

Widening the debate, and with<br />

far-reaching consequences, let us ask<br />

if the government, especially in a pluralistic<br />

country like India, should be<br />

involved with moral issues of either individual<br />

or social import? Claiming<br />

that alcohol consumption “weakens<br />

the entire social structure” and “distorts<br />

the priorities of the development<br />

process” is too far-fetched to be discussed<br />

seriously. <strong>The</strong> moral argument<br />

touches upon individual and community<br />

rights, and the freedom that is or<br />

should be available to them. As a<br />

staunch advocate of individual choice,<br />

I am in favour of letting the individuals<br />

decide for themselves, without making<br />

value-judgments or taking subjective<br />

decisions, to the extent that their actions<br />

do not hurt others or the system.<br />

Making drunk driving illegal is fine,<br />

but the invasion of moral spaces in a<br />

secular state like India is extremely<br />

‘disenchanting.’<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

173


Baharul Islam<br />

Chairman & CEO, South Asia Development<br />

Gateway, & Member, High Power Committee on<br />

International Cooperation,<br />

Government of Mizoram<br />

An Alternative Integrated Development Perspective For <strong>The</strong><br />

Peripheral Regions: <strong>The</strong> Case Of Barak Valley In Northeast India<br />

"Make no little plans; they<br />

have no magic to stir men's<br />

blood...Make big plans, aim<br />

high in hope and work."<br />

-Daniel H. Burnham<br />

Background<br />

It is a legitimate desire for any region like<br />

Barak Valley in Assam (specifically Cachar,<br />

Karimganj & Hailakandi districts) to<br />

mobilize its intellectual resources and<br />

technical expertise including those in the<br />

diasporas, to plan for growth, equity and<br />

economic development. At the dawn of the<br />

third millennium various regions and communities<br />

around the world have weathered<br />

the storm of economic and social crises<br />

that have been the order of the day ever<br />

since the mid seventies. However, due<br />

many reasons, social, political and economic,<br />

Barak Valley region doesn’t have<br />

any such perspective plan. Sons and daughters<br />

of the valley who hold various high<br />

professional positions in India and abroad<br />

often feel a deep urge to work for the development<br />

of the area but in the absence<br />

of any institutional civil society platform,<br />

such desires remain isolated. Looking<br />

ahead into the coming century, it is with<br />

great optimism that some groups of people<br />

from the valley have started to think of<br />

breaking down the developmental processes<br />

into discrete but technically feasible<br />

objectives, the pronouncements-cum-mission<br />

objectives of an integrated socio-economic<br />

development plan for the valley.<br />

<strong>The</strong> South Asia Development Gateway<br />

early <strong>2007</strong>, undertook a mission to incorporate<br />

an Integrated Development Plan<br />

(IDP) for this region. It is to elaborate,<br />

propose and initiate such an exercise within<br />

the civil society and research platforms<br />

such as India Economy Review (IER), I<br />

take this opportunity to put forward some<br />

of the potential plans that we can put together<br />

to develop the region. A sweeping<br />

look at the objectives of various national<br />

plans like Vision 2020 around the world<br />

may give a critical insight into how such<br />

plans are formulated nationally in the strategic<br />

sense: they were measured against<br />

the background of the present situation,<br />

and strategies were designed to attain the<br />

national goals. Despite its constraints,<br />

Barak Valley has a lot more opportunities<br />

than we usually bother to decipher and<br />

indeed, rapid economic growth can only<br />

be achieved if our aspiration gap incites a<br />

174 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE OTHER PATH<br />

proper management of our technical, financial<br />

and human resources. True, these<br />

resources alone would not suffice, and as<br />

such we have to be very vigilant on those<br />

necessary institutional reforms without<br />

which the transformation of these resources<br />

into socio-economic development<br />

achievements will not be attained.<br />

Development Paradigm<br />

Development is all about people, how they<br />

live their daily lives, how they attain selfrealization<br />

and how they improve on their<br />

living standards. <strong>The</strong> preliminary work<br />

from which an Integrated Regional Development<br />

Plan emanates is through discussions<br />

at all levels of society, the plan can<br />

therefore validly be said to represent the<br />

aspirations of the local people. This article<br />

covers some of those critical developmental<br />

sectors for Barak Valley that are capable<br />

of showing the most leverage on our<br />

endeavor to improve our position on the<br />

collective income ladder. It is diagnosed<br />

that agriculture, which is presently the<br />

dominant activity in our economy, will<br />

need continuous appraisal of the existing<br />

farming systems and technologies. Effective<br />

research and development within the<br />

framework of local agricultural activities<br />

will enhance productivity and improve on<br />

the quality of farm output. As a corollary<br />

to improvements in farming, a proper marketing<br />

strategy for farm output is needed<br />

to translate these into income. In view of<br />

the subsumed financial resources for this<br />

strategy, it is prescribed that new institutional<br />

arrangements be forged to improve<br />

on financing agribusiness activity through<br />

the establishment of specialized financial<br />

institutions. Although industrial activity<br />

is, as yet, at an early stage of development<br />

in our area, or almost absent in general, it<br />

is common knowledge that this type of<br />

activity has a great leverage on income and<br />

social status in the development process.<br />

Rapid industrialization is perceived to signify<br />

an increase in the population of industrial<br />

units, a quality improvement in output<br />

as well as a geographical expansion of the<br />

market for industrial output.<br />

Looking at the constraints of these specific<br />

objectives, we recommend the adoption<br />

of improved monetary and fiscal<br />

policies that will enhance the mobilization<br />

of savings and facilitate their transfer to<br />

this sector, the targeting of industries<br />

whose technologies are easily assimilated<br />

by the present workforce, the designing of<br />

policies and building of institutions at local<br />

level that will reduce the mortality rate<br />

of the start-ups and spin-offs for all direct<br />

investments and a spatial distribution of<br />

industry in order to curb the rural-urban<br />

drift. Strategies for the main productive<br />

sectors, namely Agriculture and Industry,<br />

have been well articulated with strategies<br />

for the service industries in various states<br />

and regions of the country. Smaller areas,<br />

for instance Guna district in Madhya<br />

Pradesh, have also put in place such perspective<br />

plan but with so much intellectual<br />

and technical expertise belonging to<br />

Barak Valley, no such plan has been<br />

formed till date. <strong>The</strong> financial sector,<br />

transport sectors as well as the energy and<br />

industry sectors, have been examined in<br />

light of the ultimate objective of such a<br />

plan, namely the transformation of the<br />

Barak Valley into a prosperous region by<br />

the end of the first quarter of the this century.<br />

In an integrated development plan<br />

for the area, the social sectors should be<br />

given the prominence they deserve.<br />

Health, Education and other Social services<br />

form essential pillars of Human Capital<br />

development. Without a coherent and<br />

consistent Human Resource Development<br />

(HRD) strategy, “a decent standard of living<br />

for one and all” as aspired by the people<br />

of the valley today would not be attained.<br />

Finally, perhaps a word of caution<br />

will help dissipate some concerns that people<br />

here and there, may evoke on important<br />

matters not featuring in the document.<br />

<strong>The</strong> idea of presenting a possible<br />

integrated development plan for Barak<br />

Valley is a specific developmental perspective<br />

and as such constitutional and other<br />

legal matters are best dealt with outside<br />

such a document that proposes to be blue<br />

print for guiding economic and social<br />

policy formulation, implementation and<br />

Resources alone would not suffi ce, and we have to be<br />

vigilant on the necessary institutional reforms, without<br />

which the transformation of these resources into socioeconomic<br />

development achievements will not be attained<br />

monitoring. Implementation strategies do<br />

not also feature in this document but are<br />

already under discussion as to the optimal<br />

strategies and monitoring arrangements.<br />

In order to pilot such an district level integrated<br />

plan, Karimganj district administration<br />

in collaboration with the South<br />

Asia Development Gateway has formed a<br />

District Level Integrated Development<br />

Committee under the Chairmanship of<br />

the local Deputy Commissioner (Collector)<br />

and an expert from the UN Economic<br />

Commission for Asia (Bangkok) will<br />

visit the district in late <strong>Dec</strong>ember, <strong>2007</strong> to<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

175


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

have a detailed consultation with the stakeholders.<br />

Barak Valley Contexts<br />

An Integrated Development Plan for any<br />

area comprises three inter-related documents,<br />

namely:<br />

(1) A Policy Framework Paper (PFP)<br />

that spells out the strategic thrust, the<br />

strategy content and the budgetary and<br />

institutional framework within which various<br />

projects and programmes will configure,<br />

explicitly linking the region to the<br />

national Vision 2020;<br />

(2) <strong>The</strong> Operational Framework of the<br />

area Development Strategy which takes<br />

the form of a Medium Term Expenditure<br />

Framework (MTEF). <strong>The</strong> MTEF is linked<br />

to the Macroeconomic Growth Strategy<br />

through the PFP, the latter reflecting the<br />

objectives of national Vision 2020; and,<br />

(3) <strong>The</strong> Action Plan for the target area,<br />

which highlights the Implementation Strategy,<br />

the Participatory Plan and the organizational<br />

setting within which strategic<br />

action is implemented, monitored and<br />

evaluated.<br />

<strong>The</strong> integrated development plan, as opposed<br />

to the state or country level plans, is<br />

intended to be a comprehensive “local development<br />

framework” that links macroeconomic<br />

growth with poverty reduction<br />

strategies. <strong>The</strong> objective of the plan is to<br />

ensure greater focus on poverty reduction<br />

through generating employment avenues<br />

and renewed emphasis on faster job-sector<br />

growth within the valley outside the traditional<br />

‘government job syndrome’ that ails<br />

the mindset of the potential workforce in<br />

the valley. It is essentially a prerequisite<br />

for sustainable development efforts in the<br />

valley to change that mindset and build an<br />

‘employable workforce’ out of the thousands<br />

of ‘degree-holding but unemployable’<br />

manpower that exist today in the<br />

region.<br />

<strong>The</strong> integrated development plan is to<br />

serve as the first building block for opera-<br />

<strong>The</strong> integrated development plan serve as the first building<br />

block for operationalizing an overall development mission<br />

that is locale-specifi c, based on the aspirations of the local<br />

people and don't follow the ‘trickle-down approach<br />

tionalizing an overall development mission<br />

that is locale-specific, based on the aspirations<br />

of the local people and do not necessarily<br />

follow the ‘trickle-down residual<br />

flow approach’ of development. All the<br />

proposed development projects and programmes<br />

financed by government, international<br />

development partners, NGOs,<br />

civil society will be implemented within<br />

this framework of the plan. <strong>The</strong> rationale<br />

is to move away from the prevailing peacemeal<br />

project approach in the development<br />

process and to give a road-map for the region<br />

that will be a reference point in formulating<br />

programmes/projects to ensure<br />

maximum impact and focus on priorities.<br />

It essentially calls for a more efficient use<br />

of local (in country) and external resources<br />

in support of the ultimate goal of economic<br />

development. <strong>The</strong> essential feature<br />

of the Barak Valley Integrated Development<br />

Plan is that it is locally owned implying<br />

that it reflects the needs of the people<br />

whose interests are being attended.<br />

An important element of the process is<br />

monitoring and evaluation. This entails<br />

the establishment of benchmarks of performance<br />

indicators by all the sectors in<br />

the implementation of the plan which will<br />

facilitate the measurement of progress towards<br />

the achievement of targets.<br />

Targets And Programme Areas<br />

In line with the international development<br />

goals, a Barak Valley Integrated Development<br />

Plan (BVIDP) will be in tandem with<br />

national and international efforts towards<br />

the achievement of poverty reduction targets,<br />

such as:<br />

• A reduction by one-half of the unemployed<br />

population in the valley.<br />

• Enforced Universal “employable lifeskill”<br />

Education in<br />

• Equality and empowerment of women<br />

by eliminating gender disparities<br />

• Access through the primary health care<br />

system, to reproductive health services<br />

for all people of appropriate ages as<br />

soon as possible<br />

• <strong>The</strong> implementation of a regional strategy<br />

for sustainable development so as to<br />

ensure that current trends in the loss of<br />

environmental resources are effectively<br />

reversed<br />

• Creation of economic opportunities for<br />

the poor in order to substantially reduce<br />

income and food poverty and the general<br />

feeling of insecurity related to food<br />

176 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE OTHER PATH<br />

and income poverty; and,<br />

• Development of a full fledged participatory<br />

government based on the consent<br />

of the citizenry and a strong social-audit<br />

system.<br />

<strong>The</strong> programme areas in the BVIDP<br />

will include macroeconomic growth strategy,<br />

income generating activities, re-distributive<br />

activities, social service delivery,<br />

food security, improving public resource<br />

management, creation of an accounting<br />

framework for poverty reduction interventions,<br />

improving participation in local decision<br />

making, coordination and monitoring<br />

and information, education and<br />

communication.<br />

Integrated Development Plan<br />

Process(es)<br />

Orissa and Madhya Pradesh were among<br />

the few Indian states that reiterated its<br />

commitment to a region-specific Integrated<br />

Development Plan process thus acknowledging<br />

the truism that growth and<br />

pro-poor policies have to focus on the<br />

needs and circumstances of the particular<br />

area. South Asia Development Gateway,<br />

as indicated earlier, initiated the formulation<br />

of such plans in the Northeastern region<br />

starting with Mizoram (state level)<br />

and Karimganj (District level) in Assam.<br />

It was agreed that in view of the multi sectoral<br />

nature of development, a task force<br />

or core committee be formed consisting of<br />

all key decision makers at the highest level<br />

in government sectors and donor representatives.<br />

A technical working group<br />

comprising the concerned departments<br />

was also constituted where necessary. This<br />

group held several consultations and subsequently<br />

United Nations Economic &<br />

Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific<br />

(UNESCAP), Bangkok agreed that<br />

it will assist the pilot programme in the<br />

target levels to develop the Integrated Development<br />

Plans. Accordingly, a senior<br />

UN Regional Advisor will visit the areas.<br />

An expert review of all relevant development<br />

data and surveys will be conducted<br />

first and a draft outline of the plan will be<br />

prepared which will be used as a basis for<br />

starting the process.<br />

Though the Government of Assam was<br />

approached at the very beginning of the<br />

exercise in <strong>Dec</strong>ember 2006, there was no<br />

positive response from the government<br />

departments and even the special requests<br />

from a central minister were found missing<br />

in the secretariat. In the mean time, states<br />

like Mizoram and autonomous regions<br />

like Bodoland shown tremendous interest<br />

in cooperating with international agencies<br />

to develop such plans. <strong>The</strong> Chief Minister<br />

of Mizoram, himself chairs the High Power<br />

Committee formed for this purpose.<br />

However, in the District of Karimganj, the<br />

Deputy Commissioner and specially the<br />

Additional Deputy Commissioner (Development)<br />

took special interest in formulating<br />

such a plan. In a recently conducted<br />

meeting, Prof.S. P. Parashar, the Director<br />

of IIM, Indore, has agreed to help the district<br />

in formalizing such a development<br />

plan and implement it, after following the<br />

Guna (Madhya Pradesh) model.<br />

Ongoing Activities<br />

Ongoing activities include a review of the<br />

objectives and strategies of the integrated<br />

development programme with a view to<br />

identifying tangible activities for achieving<br />

the said objectives. <strong>The</strong>se objectives have<br />

been identified during the participatory<br />

process. <strong>The</strong> programme is being designed<br />

to address cross cutting issues such as gender<br />

and environment. In addition, performance<br />

indicators and benchmarks are<br />

being developed for each of the objectives.<br />

Some of the major areas of activities are<br />

outlined below.<br />

Agriculture And Natural<br />

Resources<br />

Agricultural and Natural Resources<br />

(ANR) is the dominant sector in Barak<br />

Valley’s economy, employing the majority<br />

of the total work force. Notwithstanding,<br />

ANR continues to lag behind in productivity<br />

and modernization and is still characterized<br />

by an undiversified primary agricultural<br />

system. It is also conditioned by a<br />

seemingly unbreakable cycle of erratic inadequate<br />

input supplies, inappropriate<br />

technology, low output and productivity<br />

Agricultural and Natural Resources continues to lag behind<br />

in productivity and modernization and is still characterized<br />

by an undiversifi ed primary agricultural system<br />

growth, low incomes and an acute inability<br />

to generate savings for investment.<br />

While some of the constraints are exogenous,<br />

many are occasioned by human deficiencies<br />

and failures. ANR continues to<br />

lack a local policy focus and the political<br />

will necessary to transform the sector.<br />

Progress into next two decades will call for<br />

substantial improvements in the sector’s<br />

output and linkage to the sectors. In particular,<br />

overall productivity will have to<br />

improve significantly.<br />

Improvements in the ANR sector therefore<br />

call for serious examination and setting<br />

of projects that are both realistic and<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

177


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

attainable in the medium to long term.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se improvements also require an unfailing<br />

commitment and dedication to the<br />

pursuit of the objectives to ensure balanced<br />

growth and an equitable distribution<br />

of incomes. <strong>The</strong> more important objectives<br />

for the sector are, among others,<br />

to:<br />

1. Increase ANR output of both domestic<br />

and exports produce in order to ensure<br />

food security and generate earnings of<br />

foreign exchange to finance other aspects<br />

of the development process.<br />

2. Create employment and generate income<br />

for the majority of the rural population<br />

who are largely dependent on<br />

ANR.<br />

3. Diversify the ANR base to facilitate the<br />

production of a wider range of food and<br />

export produce in order to reduce the<br />

fluctuations and uncertainties associated<br />

with rural household incomes and<br />

export earnings.<br />

4. Formulate a post-flood recovery plan<br />

when devastating floods coming late in<br />

the year (like in <strong>2007</strong>) destroy the crop<br />

in that particular year.<br />

5. Provide effective linkages between ANR<br />

and other sectors of the economy such<br />

that developments in the non-agricultural<br />

sectors, particularly manufacturing<br />

and tourism are founded on a firm<br />

and diversified ANR base capable of<br />

progressively releasing both labour and<br />

financial resources to other sectors of<br />

the economy.<br />

6. Create a sustainable and balanced mix<br />

between rain-fed and irrigated agriculture,<br />

thus ensuring an optimal use of<br />

natural resources of surface and ground<br />

water, animal, aqua-culture and crop<br />

production as well as between chemical<br />

and organic inputs and the use of agricultural<br />

by-products. Improvements in<br />

ANR productivity require a conscious<br />

evaluation of strategies to pursue the<br />

desired objectives. <strong>The</strong> strategies to be<br />

employed will necessarily have focus on<br />

the constraints and opportunities in the<br />

ANR sector.<br />

Industry And Infrastructure<br />

<strong>The</strong> long term aspiration of the people of<br />

the Barak Valley is perceived to achieve a<br />

solid infrastructural base for industrial<br />

Effective linkages between ANR and other sectors<br />

ensure that developments in the non-agricultural sectors,<br />

particularly manufacturing and tourism are founded on<br />

a firm and diversifi ed ANR base<br />

development that would permit the<br />

processing of major primary products by<br />

the year 2020. At present, the industrial<br />

sector is very much limited. <strong>The</strong> following<br />

manufacturing sub-sector will be relied<br />

upon to achieve that objective:<br />

1. Energy<br />

<strong>The</strong> importance of this sector in the realisation<br />

of the objectives of any Integrated<br />

Development Plan cannot be overemphasised.<br />

<strong>The</strong> prime objective for this sector<br />

is to overcome the existing bottlenecks and<br />

to ensure a reliable and adequate supply of<br />

energy, both conventional and renewable,<br />

at affordable prices.<br />

2. Manufacturing<br />

Consistent with the objectives of improving<br />

the income status of the people,<br />

the manufacturing sector will undergo<br />

substantial re-orientation aimed at increasing<br />

and diversifying industrial output.<br />

Specifically, this means realizing a net increase<br />

in the number of industrial units,<br />

greater diversification of industry, greater<br />

employment opportunities and capturing<br />

an established and growing export market.<br />

In this regard, priority will be given to a<br />

smoother technology transfer mechanism,<br />

the encouragement of adaptive research in<br />

production and process technologies and<br />

accelerated training and development of<br />

our human resources. By the next decade,<br />

the share of industry should rise through<br />

the provision of institutional support services<br />

and targeted incentives. A manufacturing<br />

base supplying both the domestic<br />

and export markets will be established in<br />

order to reduce the overt dependence on<br />

Agriculture and Trade. Again, on an unfortunate<br />

note, repeated efforts to establish<br />

a specialized rural technology transfer<br />

institute have been impeded by the Govt.<br />

of Assam. Even after ensuring external<br />

funding and a positive response from the<br />

Govt of India, the state government discouraged<br />

and responded negatively to our<br />

proposal. Though the Cachar district administration<br />

identified suitable land for the<br />

institute and the union minister for heavy<br />

industries personally spoke and written to<br />

the Chief Minister of Assam, the concerned<br />

department refused to give ‘no<br />

objection’ to the project on the pretext that<br />

‘there is no financial liability’ upon the<br />

state government! To overcome this felt<br />

undercurrent of apathy towards the development<br />

of Barak Valley, there is a proposal<br />

to establish a national institute of<br />

manufacturing excellence in Barak Valley,<br />

which inturn will help catalyze the growth<br />

178 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE OTHER PATH<br />

of manufacturing industries in the valley<br />

and train many young people for employment<br />

in this sector.<br />

3. Transport<br />

<strong>The</strong> railway, airport and road and waterway<br />

network will play a crucial role as providers<br />

of efficient infrastructural services.<br />

<strong>The</strong> river port in the valley will be upgraded<br />

and rendered more efficient and competitive<br />

in order to cater adequately for<br />

transhipment needs to countries in the<br />

sub-region. With supporting road and rail<br />

links, the transformation of the border<br />

posts with Bangladesh into a regional trade<br />

‘Freeport’ should herald major investment<br />

opportunities in our local businesses. It is<br />

envisaged that such investments will be effected<br />

through joint-ventures with private<br />

sector partners in a bid to involve operators<br />

in the transformation process. Consequently,<br />

there will be created a local international<br />

trade promotion agency which<br />

will offer an unrivalled fiscal and regulatory<br />

regime as well as infrastructural facilities<br />

in order to accelerate the growth of<br />

our industrial development arena. <strong>The</strong> upgrading<br />

and expansion of the airport is a<br />

major component of the “Barak Valley<br />

Gateway” strategy. <strong>The</strong> multi-modal transport<br />

initiative subsumed in this initiative<br />

is the valley’s spearhead strategy to play a<br />

crucial role in international trade with<br />

neighbouring countries. In this regard,<br />

facilities at the airport will be upgraded<br />

and modernized, security improved to international<br />

standards to handle an increased<br />

passenger and cargo traffic with<br />

an eye to serving as a transit point for East<br />

Asia. <strong>The</strong> development of inland road and<br />

water-way transport networks will focus on<br />

improving connections to regional trading<br />

centres, while offering logistic services<br />

(storage and communications) .<br />

Human Resource Development<br />

<strong>The</strong> developments envisaged under an Integrated<br />

Development Plan can hardly be<br />

realized unless supported by a deliberate<br />

policy of investing in those human capital<br />

resources required to produce, organise,<br />

mobilize and manage the development<br />

processes that will be indispensable in the<br />

21st Century. <strong>The</strong> Education and Health<br />

sectors therefore have a central place in<br />

the plan. Since independence, Barak valley’s<br />

educational institutional growth have<br />

been default focused on the development<br />

of human resources in the white collar and<br />

peripheral services sector to the detriment<br />

of the advanced and ‘employable’ areas of<br />

Science, Technology, Agriculture and Industry,<br />

particularly the Manufacturing<br />

sector. This focus has created a market<br />

failure, resulting in the creation of a huge<br />

backlog of unemployed human capital, a<br />

dependence on government jobs by the<br />

products of the education systems in the<br />

valley. Unlike some states in south India<br />

like Kerala, we failed to create an export<br />

market for local manpower with the result<br />

that no firm foundation has been laid over<br />

the past decades to provide for sustainable<br />

training and placement of our youths in<br />

the foreign job market. Consequently, in<br />

formulating the Integrated Development<br />

Plan, a proper diagnosis of the available<br />

programmes and skills is needed to redesign<br />

and incorporate new curriculum in<br />

our local institutions that will ensure a capable<br />

human resource base for local and<br />

international market. Objectives for education<br />

include increasing the accessibility<br />

of technical and skill based education to<br />

all the school-age population, a diversification<br />

of institutions to favor vocational and<br />

skilled based training, encouragement of<br />

entrepreneurship skills as a corner-stone<br />

of education and an overall enrichment of<br />

curricula and other extracurricular activities.<br />

Health and Social Welfare<br />

Considering the present inadequacies and<br />

mindful of the constraints faced by the<br />

economy, the provision of adequate, effective<br />

and affordable health care for all is<br />

Notwithstanding the the private sector's role in region’s<br />

future socio-economic development, public sector institutions<br />

have a critical role to play in the delivery of support<br />

infrastructural and social services<br />

one of the long term objective for the<br />

health sector. Intermediate objectives for<br />

the health sector are to provide better infrastructure<br />

for Referral Hospitals and<br />

health facilities. Plans are proposed to establish<br />

a South Asian Research Institute<br />

for Medical Sciences (SARIMS) in Karimganj<br />

– the first medical college for the<br />

border district. Simultaneously, the facility<br />

to produce trained staff for health sector<br />

across East Asia and the establishment<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

179


REIMAGINING INDIA<br />

of efficient procurement arrangements for<br />

the trained staff in health sector should<br />

complete the array of institutional reforms<br />

to ensure effective and efficient health<br />

services. Improvements in ancillary services<br />

will focus on the management of<br />

health data and enhancing research into<br />

paramedical services such as traditional<br />

healing methods.<br />

Housing Amenities<br />

As a consequence of the more recent and<br />

prevailing demographic trends, rapid urbanization<br />

and concentration of the urban<br />

population, the demand for decent housing<br />

is increasingly elusive to satisfy. <strong>The</strong><br />

long term objectives of housing sector will<br />

aim at increasing production of decent<br />

housing stock on a more regular basis. A<br />

review of the existing housing schemes like<br />

Indira Awas Yojana (Indira Housing Plan)<br />

is a study in decentralization and institutionalization<br />

of corruption upto the grassroots<br />

level. Contrary to this and to effectively<br />

address the problems posed by<br />

pressing demography and rapid urbanization,<br />

particular attention will be focused<br />

on the need for specialized housing finance<br />

institutions such as housing banks<br />

and housing co-operatives. Improving<br />

housing development capabilities is a prerequisite<br />

for providing a decent standing<br />

of living.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Way Forward<br />

<strong>The</strong> foregoing discussion highlights the<br />

potential implications of a proposed Integrated<br />

Development Plan for the Barak<br />

Valley that will be piloted in Karimganj<br />

district. <strong>The</strong> South Asia Development<br />

Gateway has discussed this plan on various<br />

platforms and consultations to determine<br />

the readiness of the stakeholders<br />

with a view to project a road map leading<br />

to the structure of a development strategy<br />

for the area. <strong>The</strong> outcome of these consultations<br />

were largely encouraging and<br />

attracted valuable inputs which were as<br />

well enlisted. <strong>The</strong> approach taken in the<br />

formulation of the strategy is participatory<br />

since all stakeholders will be provided<br />

the opportunity to contribute to the<br />

fundamental design of the strategy based<br />

on the guidelines provided.<br />

On a concluding note, it will not be out<br />

of place to mention that among many<br />

promises of the digital revolution is the<br />

potential to strengthen democracy and<br />

make governments more responsive to<br />

Institutional performance is a critical factor, not only<br />

in the design and implementation of development<br />

programs, but also in the effective realization of any<br />

development policy goals and targets<br />

the needs of the citizens. This Integrated<br />

Development Plan includes the use of<br />

information and communication technologies<br />

to transform the way Government<br />

conducts its business, which includes:<br />

Providing greater access to<br />

government information; Promoting<br />

civic engagement by enabling public to<br />

interact with government officials; Making<br />

government more accountable by<br />

making its operations more transparent<br />

and thus reducing the opportunities for<br />

corruption; Providing development opportunities,<br />

especially benefiting rural<br />

and traditional underserved communi-<br />

ties. Let us now dream to establish “<strong>The</strong><br />

Barak Valley Incorporated” as the Integrated<br />

Development Plan aims at a fullfledged<br />

private sector that is responsible<br />

to the development needs of this area and<br />

that can play an active role in the domestic<br />

economy. Government will ensure<br />

that market mechanism function smoothly<br />

within a free market and a stable macro-economic<br />

environment. On the external<br />

front, the maintenance of a steady<br />

exchange rate between the valley and major<br />

foreign trade agencies as well as the<br />

implementation of agreements signed<br />

with international financial institutions<br />

will ensure a more positive insertion of<br />

the economy into the international<br />

scene.<br />

Over the last decade, it has become<br />

clear that an internally consistent set of<br />

economic and financial policies is a necessary<br />

but not sufficient condition for<br />

growth and development. Institution performance<br />

is a critical factor, not only in<br />

the design and implementation to development<br />

programs, but also in the effective<br />

realization of any development policy<br />

goals and targets. Integrated<br />

Development Plan integrates institutional<br />

capacities as a key factor of production<br />

and sets as an objective the correction of<br />

institutional failures in order to accelerate<br />

the implementation of development<br />

programs. Notwithstanding the lead role<br />

of the private sector in region’s future<br />

socio-economic development, public sector<br />

institutions have a critical role to play<br />

in the delivery of support infrastructural<br />

and social services to buttress the development<br />

efforts of the private sector. It is<br />

therefore envisaged that the plan shall<br />

refer to parastatals on one hand and the<br />

bureaucracy on the other hand.<br />

180 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE OTHER PATH<br />

Sr. Director HR on why GAP is a great place to work! Invitation price<br />

RS.50 Only<br />

H<br />

THE<br />

UMAN<br />

FACTO<br />

R<br />

Contemporary | Actionable | Cutting-Edge<br />

<strong>The</strong> man’s got<br />

Pizzazz!<br />

Find out why the CEO, Domino’s<br />

India is sometimes called the Chief<br />

Enthusiasm Officer by his colleagues<br />

Director HR for Affinity<br />

Infotech tells us<br />

how he uses technology<br />

to aid HR<br />

How do you recruit top<br />

- level talent? Director<br />

GCH, Ranbaxy ponders<br />

the issue<br />

GM HR, Indraprastha Gas<br />

charts out the Development<br />

Plan for the HR<br />

manager


Mrutyunjay Dash<br />

Professor of Economics and<br />

Business Environment,<br />

Asian School of Business<br />

Management,Bhubaneswar<br />

Tenancy Reforms in Orissa:<br />

A Critical Perspective<br />

"He who owns the soil, owns<br />

up to the sky."<br />

- Douglas Gerrold<br />

I. Introduction<br />

Orissa is primarily an agrarian economy.<br />

Agriculture is the state’s dominant sector<br />

with a contribution of nearly 28.13 percent<br />

to net state domestic product during 2001-<br />

2002. Agriculture alone provides direct<br />

and indirect employment to around 65<br />

percent of the total workforce of the state<br />

as per 2001 provisional Census. Nearly 87<br />

percent of total population lives in rural<br />

areas. It has remained as an agriculturally<br />

backward state of India with high incidence<br />

of concealed tenancy. Though tenancy<br />

is legally prohibited in the state, it is<br />

observed in large scale across the length<br />

and breadth of Orissa. <strong>The</strong> Orissa Land<br />

Reforms Committee, 1980, has brought to<br />

the limelight the existence of a vast number<br />

of tenants, mostly unrecorded sharecroppers,<br />

in the rural areas of Orissa. Neither<br />

these tenants have opted for the legal provision<br />

of applying to the revenue officers<br />

for obtaining ryoti right nor the latter, empowered<br />

to initiate action to confer ownership<br />

rights on tenants, have shown any<br />

interest in this regard. Adam Smith (1969)<br />

has rightly remarked that a person, who<br />

has no property rights over land, can have<br />

no other interest except eating as much<br />

and labouring as little as possible, since<br />

the fruit of his hard labour is expropriated<br />

by the proprietor. Psychological feelings of<br />

non-ownership coupled with insecurity<br />

kill their efficiency, enthusiasm and physical<br />

ability. Besides, social distinctions between<br />

landowner and agricultural labourer<br />

deaden the interest and the zeal of the<br />

latter. This is why land reforms in general<br />

and tenurial reforms in particular have to<br />

be assigned the top-most priority in bringing<br />

about the transformation of agricultural<br />

sector so as to make it vibrant, dynamic<br />

and more productive. However, lack<br />

of proper implementation of tenancy reform<br />

measures, prevalence of large scale<br />

concealed tenancy with oral leases, absence<br />

of rent receipts, ignorance of the<br />

legal provisions of tenancy legislations,<br />

built-in legal loopholes and above all, lack<br />

of political will can be attributed for the<br />

results being not so encouraging. In this<br />

paper an attempt has been made to give a<br />

182 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


TENANCY REFORMS<br />

brief outline of the extent, types and incidence<br />

of tenancy in the second section. In<br />

the third section reference to important<br />

tenancy legislation is undertaken. Finally,<br />

evaluation of tenancy reforms in Orissa is<br />

made followed by concluding remarks.<br />

II. Extent, Types And<br />

Incidence Of Tenancy<br />

India achieved independence from British<br />

Rule in 1947. Having been created with six<br />

districts: Balasore, Cuttack, Puri, Ganjam,<br />

Koraput and Sambalpur initially, in 1936<br />

Orissa acquired a new geographical shape<br />

after merger of 26 feudatory states on<br />

January 1,1948. In the first stage an attempt<br />

has been made to give a brief account<br />

on the extent of tenancy, types of<br />

Table-1: State-Wise Tenancy Statistics For Rural India,<br />

1981-82 And 1991-92<br />

State<br />

% of Tenant Holdings<br />

to Operational<br />

Holdings<br />

% of Leased-in<br />

Area to Operational<br />

Area<br />

% of Leased-in<br />

Area under<br />

ShareTenancy<br />

1981-82 1991-92 1981-82 1991-92 1991-92<br />

Andhra Pradesh 13.8 14.1 6.2 9.6 20.9<br />

Assam 12.9 10.1 6.4 8.9 27.8<br />

Bihar 19.7 5.6 10.3 3.9 43.5<br />

Gujarat 4.8 3.7 2 3.3 23.7<br />

Haryana 25.9 17.1 18.2 33.7 19.9<br />

Karnataka 10.7 8 6 7.4 28.6<br />

Kerala 6.7 5.2 2.6 2.9 2.1<br />

Madhya Pradesh 8.0 9 3.6 6.3 24.9<br />

Maharashtra 10.6 6.9 5.2 5.5 20.9<br />

Orissa 18.2 16.9 9.9 9.5 50.9<br />

Punjab 21.3 15.9 16.1 18.8 11.3<br />

Rajsthan 7.1 6.5 4.3 5.2 23.4<br />

Tamilnadu 24.7 15.3 10.9 10.9 16.5<br />

Uttar Pradesh 20.5 15.5 10.2 10.5 46.5<br />

West Bengal 23.1 14.4 12.3 10.4 46.5<br />

India 15.2 11 7.2 8.3 34.4<br />

Source: Sarvekshana, Vol,20, No.3, 70th issue, Jan-March, 1997, NSS 48th Round.<br />

tenancy NSS (National Sample Survey).<br />

In India data on extent of tenancy are<br />

available from two sources: National Sample<br />

Survey estimates and Agricultural<br />

Census data, out of which the former is<br />

more reliable being based on independent<br />

household surveys.<br />

However, it will not be out of place<br />

to mention that there is commonality<br />

of opinion on reliability of official data<br />

on incidence of tenancy due to several<br />

reasons. Principally because lease contracts<br />

are mainly oral without any written<br />

record of lease details and tenants’<br />

hesitation to reveal their tenurial identity<br />

in fear of eviction by the landowner.<br />

With this reservation in mind NSS<br />

estimates on incident of tenancy have<br />

been furnished. This is the reason for<br />

which NSS is referred to in this section.<br />

And secondly different tenancy reform<br />

measures undertaken by the Government<br />

of Orissa and their evaluation are<br />

considered also. Orissa belongs to the<br />

category of high Tenancy State in India.<br />

This is supported by NSS findings. As<br />

per NSS data in the year 1981-82 tenants<br />

household constituted 18.2 per cent<br />

of total operational household and it<br />

has been reduced to 16.9 percent (only<br />

by a meagre 1.3 percent), in 1991-92, as<br />

reflected in Table-1. In 1991-92 there<br />

were numerically 6.9 lakh tenant holdings<br />

and leased-in land constituted<br />

4.5 lakh hectares of land. This was 9.5<br />

percent of total operated area and infact<br />

surpasses the All India average of 8.3<br />

percent in the same period. Tenancy in<br />

Orissa is manifested mostly in the form<br />

of sharecropping. Share tenancy is more<br />

pervasive than fixed rent tenancy based<br />

on either fixed produce or fixed money.<br />

Nearly 42.0 percent of leased-in area is<br />

under shared tenancy compared to that<br />

of 13.6 percent and 7.6 percent are on<br />

fixed produce and fixed money respectively<br />

NSS (1971-72) and this figure has<br />

further been increased to 50.9 percent in<br />

1991-92 (Please refer Table-2).<br />

Further, in a labour abundant coupled<br />

with land scarce agrarian economy like<br />

ours, i.e., of Orissa, the tenant is subject<br />

to weak bargaining power and thus<br />

is placed in a disadvantageous position.<br />

<strong>The</strong> obvious alternative left with, therefore<br />

relates to leasing-in-land irrespective<br />

of the degree of benefits accruing<br />

to the tenants from a certain mode of<br />

lease contract. This is more prominent in<br />

case of marginal and small farmers as is<br />

evident from Table-3. <strong>The</strong> distribution of<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

183


THE 'OTHER' INDIA<br />

Table-2: Changes In Percentage Distribution Of Leased- in Area By<br />

Terms Of Lease<br />

Terms of 1971-72 1981-82 1991-92<br />

Lease (26th) (37th) (48th)<br />

Fixed Money 7.6 5.1 19.7<br />

Fixed Produce 13.6 8.1 4.7<br />

Share of Produce 41.6 42.0 50.9<br />

Others 37.2 44.8 24.7<br />

All Terms 100.0 100.0 100.0<br />

Sources: (a) N.S.S. Report 26th Round (1971-72)<br />

(b) N.S.S. Report 37 th Round (1981-82)<br />

(c) N.S.S. Report 48 th Round (1991-92)<br />

lease-in area according to <strong>size</strong> classes of<br />

operational holdings shows that in 1991-<br />

92 about 89.76 percent of leased-in area<br />

was in the <strong>size</strong> classes of less than one<br />

hectare and only 0.47 percent of leasedin<br />

area was in <strong>size</strong> classes above 4 hectares.<br />

Likewise a significant proportion<br />

of tenant holdings (89.21%) belonged to<br />

the category of marginal farmer. This is<br />

also confirmed from another study that<br />

subsistence tenancy is more widespread<br />

than commercial or capitalist tenancy in<br />

Orissa (Swain; 1999b, 1999c).<br />

III. Tenancy Reforms And Tenancy<br />

Legislation In Orissa<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is no denying the fact that exploitative<br />

land tenant system is one of the<br />

important economic causes leading to<br />

agrarian unrest in land scarce and labour<br />

abundant economies. Various factors<br />

like socio-economic factor, relative<br />

bargaining strength, relative differences<br />

in <strong>size</strong> class, to mention a few, determine<br />

the degree and extent of exploitation to<br />

which the tenants are subjected. This<br />

is especially because tenants do not<br />

belong to homogeneous groups rather<br />

a lot of heterogeneities witnessed with<br />

regard to their socio-economic status,<br />

<strong>size</strong> class, etc., are held responsible for<br />

exploitation. As such, differences arise<br />

in their economic resource position and<br />

therefore, in their bargaining strength.<br />

Tenancy reforms include all those measures aiming at<br />

protecting and safeguarding the interest of tenant with<br />

regard to the realization of their due share accruing from<br />

leased-in land and conferring ownership rights<br />

Thus they are all not equally prone to exploitation<br />

by their landlords (Bhardwaj,<br />

1974; Bhardwaj and Das, 1975a; 1975b).<br />

Besides, the extreme concentration of<br />

land ownership (Myrdal, 1982, 1306)<br />

and exploitative production relations,<br />

being established between the landlord<br />

and the tenant during the process of production,<br />

are sufficient enough to make<br />

agricultural growth sluggish (Joshi, 1974,<br />

167;Appu, 1996,40-5). This necessitates<br />

to bring about a thorough and complete<br />

transformation in production relations<br />

between the landlord and tenant on<br />

one hand and in forces of production<br />

on the other. Indian peasant history is<br />

replete with examples which show that<br />

radical tenancy reform legislation, far<br />

from being a liberal gift from the state<br />

is an outcome of a long and protracted<br />

struggle by the tenants. Orissa is not an<br />

exception to this.<br />

As the term suggests tenancy reforms<br />

includes all those measures aiming at<br />

protecting and safeguarding the interest<br />

of tenant with regard to the realization<br />

of their due share or benefits of produce<br />

accruing from leased-in land and conferring<br />

ownership right on land which<br />

they cultivate. In Orissa tenancy contracts<br />

were oral, unrecorded, insecured<br />

and the rent prevailed mostly at around<br />

(on an average basis) 50 percent of the<br />

gross produce in pre-independent era.<br />

Thus to remove the inherent loopholes<br />

in the tenancy system radical tenancy<br />

reform measures were called for after<br />

a long struggle and oppression by the<br />

so-called land owning class. With the<br />

passage of time some legislative measures<br />

undertaken in the years of 1881,<br />

1885, and 1913 to remove the intolerable<br />

suffering of the tenants. For example<br />

in Orissa Tenancy Act, 1913 and<br />

subsequent amendments effected to it<br />

granted some new concessions to the<br />

tenants and raiyats through fixing limitations<br />

on landlords to extract anything<br />

beyond their legitimate dues from the<br />

tenants. Consider this: Section 54 of<br />

Regulation VIII of 1793 declares that<br />

all impositions and exactions (whatever<br />

their designation might be), over and<br />

above the actual rent are illegal. Section<br />

3 of Regulation V of 1812 1 altered<br />

some of the provisions Regulation VIII<br />

of 1793 but attention being given not to<br />

incorporate anything, which sanctions<br />

or legalizes the impositions of arbitrary<br />

184 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


TENANCY REFORMS<br />

or indefinite cesses. By the Amendment<br />

Act of 1938, all kinds of illegal cesses as<br />

codified in the original Orissa Tenancy<br />

Act 1913, were deleted so as to make<br />

it more purposive. Further with respect<br />

to recovering from a landlord (by means<br />

of a legal suit), the amount exacted by<br />

the landlord in excess of the rent, the<br />

Amendment Act of 1938 empowered<br />

the Collector of the District or any<br />

Deputy Collector on his behalf to take<br />

action and impose on the landlord such<br />

penalty not exceeding Rs.500/- or simple<br />

imprisonment not exceeding six months.<br />

Thus the amended provision incorporated<br />

certain features for preventing collection<br />

of illegal cesses from tenants. But<br />

for all matters whatsoever, such as illegal<br />

exaction, collections of exorbitant rent, a<br />

ryot was required to move to court of law<br />

and the financial vulnerability and powerful<br />

influence of potential landowning<br />

class taken together could not allow a<br />

majority of poor tenants to realize the<br />

fruits of legislation.<br />

However as a result of the passing of<br />

various Tenancy Acts, i.e. of 1881, 1885,<br />

and in 1913, some well-to-do tenants<br />

could also acquire hereditary rights to<br />

occupancy ryots, and with their legally<br />

protected right, followed the path of their<br />

masters, and found it more profitable to<br />

rent out the land to the under-tenants<br />

and share-croppers who became more<br />

tenants-at-will. <strong>The</strong>y could be evicted<br />

on short notice and virtually enjoyed no<br />

security of tenure. Taking cognizance of<br />

this actuality, immediately after independence,<br />

various tenancy legislation<br />

and subsequent amendments to them<br />

were passed with a view to minimise<br />

the sufferings of the tenants. A brief account<br />

of these legal developments are<br />

given below:<br />

a. <strong>The</strong> Orissa Tenants’ Protection<br />

Act of 1948<br />

Under the Orissa Tenants Protection<br />

Table-3: Percentage Distribution Of Lessor And Lessee Households<br />

And Leased-in And leased-out Area By Size Class Of Land Ownership<br />

Holdings In Rural Orissa,1991-92<br />

Size Class Of<br />

Ownership<br />

Holdings(ha.)<br />

Percentage Of<br />

Total Lessor<br />

Households<br />

Percentage f<br />

Total Tenant<br />

Households<br />

Percentage f<br />

Total Leased-<br />

In Area<br />

Percentage of<br />

Total Leasedout<br />

Area<br />

Less than1.01 63.96 89.21 89.76 29.40<br />

1.01-2.00 25.96 6.42 5.61 51.18<br />

2.01-4.00 7.01 3.56 4.16 11.51<br />

4.01-10.00 2.38 0.81 0.47 3.53<br />

Above10.00 0.69 0.00 0.00 4.38<br />

All Sizes 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00<br />

Sources: N.S.S. Report 48 th Round (1991-92)<br />

Act, 1948, it was declared that notwithstanding<br />

anything contained in the<br />

law, contract or usage or any decree of<br />

any court, a person who was cultivating<br />

any land as a tenant on the first day<br />

of September, 1947, should continue<br />

to have the right to cultivate such land<br />

and no landlord was legally entitled<br />

For all matters whatsoever, such as illegal exaction, collections<br />

of exorbitant rent, a ryot was required to move to<br />

court of law and the financial vulnerability and powerful<br />

influence of potential landowning class could not allow a<br />

majority of poor tenants to realize the fruits of legislation<br />

to evict such tenant, O.T.P Act, 1948,<br />

Section 3 (1) (b).<br />

Further as per the Act, tenants enjoying<br />

occupancy rights were not bound<br />

to pay more than one third of the gross<br />

produce as rent to the superior ryot (c)<br />

tenants without security of tenure were<br />

not bound to pay more than two fifths<br />

of the gross produce as rent to the landowners.<br />

However this Act lost its real<br />

purpose of protecting tenants as it allows<br />

landowners (owning 33 acres of land) to<br />

evict his/her tenants from land holding.<br />

b. Orissa Tenants’ Relief Act, 1955<br />

This Act intends to confer security of<br />

tenure, resumption of land for personal<br />

cultivation and regulation of rent so<br />

as to bring relief to the oppressed and<br />

exploited tenants. <strong>The</strong> Act defined a<br />

tenant a person who under the system<br />

commonly known as Bhag, Sanjha, Kata<br />

or such similar terms under any other<br />

system, law, contract, custom, or usage<br />

cultivated the land of another person on<br />

payment of rent in cash or in kind or<br />

in both or on condition of delivering to<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

185


THE 'OTHER' INDIA<br />

that person.<br />

i) a share of the produce of such<br />

land or<br />

ii) the estimated value of a portion of<br />

the crop raised on the land or<br />

iii) a fixed quantity of produce irrespective<br />

of the yield from the land, or<br />

iv) produce or its estimated value partly<br />

in any one of the ways described above<br />

and partly in another, Das (1989).<br />

<strong>The</strong> law provided that notwithstanding<br />

anything in Law, contract or usage or<br />

in any decree or order of any Court but<br />

subject to the provisions of this Acta)<br />

No tenant with permanent and heritable<br />

rights over holdings in terms of<br />

produce rent was liable to pay more<br />

than 2/3 rd of the rate of rent payable<br />

or to express it in a different way rent<br />

payable was not to exceed 1/6 th of the<br />

produce or value thereof.<br />

b) No landlord was entitled to recover<br />

any cess, rates or other dues payable<br />

or deliverable in relation to the land<br />

by a tenant holding on produce rent.<br />

c) When rent was deliverable in kind it<br />

was to be delivered at the landlords’<br />

granary in the village in which the<br />

land was situated or at such other<br />

granary, within 3 miles of the village,<br />

as may be provided on that behalf by<br />

the landlord.<br />

Further as per the Act, a temporary<br />

tenant was not bound to pay more than<br />

25 percent in kind or cash of the gross<br />

produce of the land. Further it was added<br />

that no tenant having permanent or<br />

hereditary right in land was bound to<br />

pay more than 16 percent of the gross<br />

produce of the land. However to nullify<br />

the very purpose of the Act, the landowners<br />

were obtaining written undertakings<br />

from the tenants to pay 50 percent<br />

of the gross produce after harvest and<br />

that too without any rent receipt.<br />

c. Orissa Land Reforms Act, 1960<br />

<strong>The</strong> Orissa Land Reforms Act, 1960 and<br />

its subsequent amendments exhibited a<br />

certain degree of qualitative shift from<br />

the earlier tenancy legislation as discussed<br />

above. <strong>The</strong> basic thrust was given<br />

on land to the tiller. One of the notable<br />

features of O.L.R. Act 1960 relates to<br />

conferment of permanent, heritable and<br />

transferable rights on all raiyats over<br />

their land.<br />

Besides, the agricultural labourers<br />

To nullify the very purpose of the <strong>The</strong> Orissa Tenants’ Relief<br />

Act, 1955, the landowners were obtaining written undertakings<br />

from the tenants to pay 50 percent of the gross produce<br />

after harvest and that too without any rent receipt<br />

and the village artisans were granted<br />

property rights in respect of their dwelling<br />

houses constructed on the lands of<br />

the superior landlords. Amendment in<br />

O.L.R. Act (Act 17 of 1972) also enabled<br />

the tenants to become ryots in<br />

whole of the land under their occupation<br />

under section 36-A, subject to receipt<br />

of application by the tenant within two<br />

years from October 2 nd , 1973. But the<br />

response from the tenants to claim occupancy<br />

rights was not satisfactory. Hence<br />

under section 36-B the Revenue Officer<br />

was empowered to take appropriate action<br />

where no application was received<br />

from a tenant. Besides, the amount of<br />

rent was retained at 25 percent of the<br />

gross produce of the land or the value<br />

thereof or the value of 25 percent of the<br />

estimated produce of the land.<br />

IV. Evaluation Of Tenancy Reforms<br />

Act In Orissa<br />

After having gone through a brief account<br />

of some of the important tenancy<br />

legislation it would be wise to ascertain<br />

as to what extent these legislation have<br />

yielded results as were supposed to be<br />

during the time of their inception. With<br />

regard to the operation of the Orissa<br />

Tenants’ Protection Act of 1948 it experienced<br />

varied results in different areas<br />

and in most of the cases the tenants did<br />

not claim their dues. For instance Puri<br />

District alone accounted for more than<br />

2/3rd of the cases filed (in the years between<br />

1955-56 and 1956-57) and about<br />

70 percent of the cases filed settled<br />

without any claim on behalf of tenants,<br />

Dash (1989). Moreover, allowing landlord<br />

owning less than 33 acres of land<br />

to evict tenant also questions the very<br />

purpose of the Act. <strong>The</strong> limit of 33 acres<br />

of land was too high in the land holding<br />

context of Orissa where the majority of<br />

farmers do belong to the categories of<br />

landless labourers or marginal or small<br />

farmer categories (Jena, 1968).<br />

Similarly a Report on the working of<br />

tenancy laws prepared by B. Mishra and<br />

B. Jena (1958) 2 also confirmed that in<br />

three villages of Balasore District, namely<br />

Kalei, Mahadevpur and Balarampur,<br />

out of 105 cultivating families 45 families<br />

reported to have cultivated land on payment<br />

of the share of 50 percent of the<br />

gross produce which strictly violates the<br />

O.T.R. Act, 1955 recommending strongly<br />

a tenant not to pay more than 25 per-<br />

186 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


TENANCY REFORMS<br />

cent in kind or cash of the gross produce<br />

of the land. A Report on An Enquiry<br />

into the Working of Orissa Tenants’<br />

Protection Act, 1948, and Orissa Tenants’<br />

Relief Act, 1955 in Five Districts of<br />

Orissa, 1970 by B. Mishra revealed that<br />

payment of rent receipt was not received<br />

by 80 percent of the tenants.<br />

It is interesting to note that even as<br />

the Report states that although the tenants<br />

were fully aware of O.T.R. Act,<br />

1955 only one tenant filed a case and the<br />

case ultimately cost the tenant Rs.130/-<br />

and the decision finally went against<br />

him. Further the Orissa Land Reforms<br />

Committee, 1980, brings to the limelight<br />

the existence of a vast number of tenants<br />

mostly unrecorded sharecroppers<br />

who have neither taken any legal steps<br />

through applying revenue officers to get<br />

ryoti right nor the revenue officers empowered<br />

to initiate actions at their own<br />

level endeavoured to confer ownership<br />

rights on tenants. <strong>The</strong> tenants also do<br />

not dare to agitate in order to promote<br />

their case because of the fear of retaliation<br />

by the ryoti type of landlords. Thus<br />

various legislation enacted and subsequently<br />

modified from time to time in<br />

the better interest of tenants could not<br />

yield desired result so far. However generalisation<br />

of findings of the Report on<br />

the basis of observation in only three villages<br />

would be improper and it is needless<br />

to say that further detailed empirical<br />

studies need to be undertaken for seeking<br />

definitive and conclusive judgment<br />

on this aspect.<br />

With regard to working of O.L.R.<br />

Act, 1960, also the experiences are not<br />

so encouraging. To substantiate such a<br />

stand in this regard two principal aspects<br />

need to be empha<strong>size</strong>d. Firstly,<br />

the response from the tenants to claim<br />

occupancy rights, as stressed in O.L.R.<br />

1960, was not satisfactory. Even though<br />

under Section 36-B, the Revenue Officer<br />

was empowered to take appropriate<br />

action in case of any application not<br />

received from tenants the result lagged<br />

far behind expectation. Secondly, as<br />

is evident from O.L.R. Act 1960, the<br />

landlords have been doubly compensated<br />

for their property right over land<br />

once by the Government in the case of<br />

abolition of estates and by fixing Rs 800<br />

per standard acre for tenants to acquire<br />

land vide amendment effected to 1965<br />

Act, for the second time. As the tenants<br />

were subjected to grinding poverty they<br />

failed to acquire the land they cultivated<br />

for want of funds required to pay the<br />

compensation fee. Further, the apparent<br />

inequity evident in the O.L.R. Act 1960,<br />

relates to the payment of heavy premium<br />

to the Government on one hand and receipt<br />

of application from tenants by the<br />

Revenue Officer with respect to getting<br />

proprietary rights within a short period<br />

of 90 days on the other.<br />

Thus heavy compensation fee and premium<br />

coupled with short period of time<br />

to get proprietary rights reveal deliberate<br />

and unjust attempts of legislators to<br />

safeguard the interest of the landowning<br />

class. As a result uptil now oral tenancy,<br />

without any records whatsoever, along<br />

with high rent and insecurity of tenure<br />

do outline the prevailing tenancy system<br />

in Orissa. Such an unfortunate trend has<br />

crept in the agrarian structure of Orissa<br />

not because the tenants lack awareness<br />

of various tenancy legislation but<br />

because the prevailing socio-economic<br />

conditions do not possibly allow exercising<br />

their rights in this regard.<br />

With the provision of resumption of tenanted lands on the<br />

grounds of so-called “personal cultivation” being not defined<br />

clearly by many states, a lot of tenants were subjected<br />

to eviction on a large-scale basis. Many tenants after<br />

conferment of ownership rights either sold or mortgaged it<br />

V. Conclusion<br />

Thus to sum up, different tenancy legislation<br />

and consequent regulations incorporated<br />

in them failed to serve the<br />

very purpose of bringing socio-economic<br />

justice to the poor tenants and thereby<br />

establishing an egalitarian society. With<br />

an exception to few financially better-off<br />

tenants who were in a position to vindicate<br />

their cause, the hardships and sufferings<br />

of tenants in general continued.<br />

Several reasons may be cited in this regard<br />

as to why these tenancy legislation<br />

did not yield desired results.<br />

To mention a few, firstly, there is a<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

187


THE 'OTHER' INDIA<br />

wide gulf between policy formulation<br />

and its effective implementation from<br />

the grassroots level. Secondly, universal<br />

application of a single and uniform<br />

standard to the entire State without any<br />

proper understanding of rural agrarian<br />

set-up and prevalence of varied socioeconomic<br />

constraints, might have been<br />

responsible for results being not so<br />

encouraging and last but not the least,<br />

prolonged time taken in the settlement<br />

of legal issues and more often than not,<br />

results going in favor of the land owning<br />

class discouraged tenants to take<br />

recourse to various tenancy legislation.<br />

Thus, the foregoing analysis reveals that<br />

the prevalent inequitable property relationship,<br />

inherent legal loopholes with<br />

an attitude of protection to the so-called<br />

land owning class and unorganized behavior<br />

of tenants have reduced the reforms<br />

package to a near fallacious one.<br />

Despite all legislative measures undertaken<br />

by different State Governments<br />

to take care of the interest of the<br />

actual tiller of the soil from time to time,<br />

a lot remains yet to be achieved in this<br />

regard. With the provision of resumption<br />

of tenanted lands on the grounds<br />

of so-called “personal cultivation” being<br />

not defined clearly by many states, a lot<br />

of tenants were subjected to eviction on<br />

a large-scale basis. Further due to noneconomic<br />

holdings, many tenants after<br />

conferment of ownership rights either<br />

sold or mortgaged it. Protected tenant<br />

also leased out their lands to rich farmers<br />

for want of funds. A large number<br />

of tenants still remain out of the purview<br />

of the law for not being recorded<br />

for one reason or other. Thus, tenancy<br />

reform has not succeeded in achieving<br />

any great impact either in terms of reorienting<br />

the property relationship in<br />

favor of the tenants or elevating their<br />

socio-economic condition.<br />

Additional Notes<br />

1. All sums received by the proprietors<br />

in excess of the amount of rent specified<br />

in the contract would be considered<br />

as extortion and be repaid by<br />

the proprietors with a penalty of 200<br />

percent of the amount exhorted.<br />

Owing to the prevalent inequitable property relationships<br />

and inherent legal loopholes, tenancy reform has not<br />

succeeded in achieving any great impact, either in terms<br />

of reorienting the property relationship in favor of the tenants<br />

or elevating their socio-economic condition<br />

2. A Report on An Enquiry into the<br />

Working of Orissa Tenants’ Protection<br />

Act, 1948, and Orissa Tenants’<br />

Relief Act, 1955 in Five Districts<br />

of Orissa, 1970 by B. Mishra revealed<br />

that payment of rent receipt<br />

was not received by 80 percent of<br />

the tenants.<br />

References<br />

• AICC (All India Congress Committee)<br />

(1949), “Report of the Congress<br />

Agrarian Reforms Committee”, New<br />

Delhi.<br />

• Appu, P.S. (1996). “Land Reforms in<br />

India: A Survey of Policy, Legislation<br />

ad Implementation,” Vikas Publishing<br />

House, New Delhi.<br />

• Bhardwaj, K and P.K. Das (1975a).<br />

Tenurial Conditions and Modes of<br />

Exploitation:”A Study of Some Villages<br />

in Orissa,” EPW Annual Number,<br />

10:221-40, February; and P.K.Das<br />

(1975b). “Tenurial Conditions and<br />

Modes of Exploitation: A Study of<br />

Some Villages in Orissa; Further<br />

Notes,” EPW, Review of Agriculture<br />

10:A49-55, June.<br />

• Dash, Giridhari. (1989). <strong>The</strong><br />

Land Systems and Land Reforms<br />

in Orissa,Published by G.<br />

Dash, Cuttack<br />

• Jena, K.C. (1968). Land Revenue<br />

Administration in Orissa During<br />

19 th Century, S. Chand & Co,<br />

New Delhi.<br />

• Joshi, P.C. (1974). Land Reform and<br />

Agrarian Change in India and Pakistan<br />

Since 1947 : I, Journal of Peasant<br />

Studies 1 (2):164-85, January, II.1<br />

(3), April.<br />

• Mitra, A. (1981). Tenancy Reforms<br />

in Orissa, in M. Bose (ed). Land Reforms<br />

in Eastern India, Planning Forum,<br />

Jadavpur University.<br />

• Orissa Tenancy Act, 1913 & Rules<br />

with Notes and Latest Case Laws,<br />

ed. By A. Mohapatra, 1991-92.<br />

• Orissa Govt. (1987). Agricultural Statistics<br />

of Orissa, Directorate of Agriculture<br />

and Food Production.<br />

• Smith,Adam. (1969). <strong>The</strong> Wealth of<br />

Nations. Pelican Classics, (ed.) Andrew<br />

Skinner, reprint:1974<br />

• Swain,Mamata.(1999b). Agricultural<br />

Share Tenancy and Efficiency: Testing<br />

Alternative <strong>The</strong>ories with Micro<br />

Evidence from Orissa, IASSI, <strong>Quarterly</strong>,<br />

Vol.17.No.4. June 1999.<br />

188 THE <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK


THE HUMAN FACTOR<br />

THE<br />

INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW<br />

<strong>2007</strong><br />

<strong>Volume</strong> 5 | <strong>Quarterly</strong> <strong>Issue</strong>: 31st <strong>Dec</strong>ember <strong>2007</strong><br />

www.iipmthinktank.com<br />

www.gidf.org<br />

REIMAGINING INDIA:<br />

MORE MARKET,<br />

LESS GOVERNMENT<br />

RETHINK<br />

EDIFY<br />

DELINEATE<br />

INSIDE THIS ISSUE<br />

Development Agenda<br />

<strong>The</strong> Visible Hand<br />

Free Exchange<br />

India Reexamined<br />

Progress Within Limits<br />

<strong>The</strong> Other Path<br />

A New Beginning<br />

A N I I P M T H I N K T A N K<br />

&<br />

G R E A T I N D I A N D R E A M F O U N D A T I O N P R E S E N T A T I O N<br />

August-October 2005<br />

189 | An <strong>IIPM</strong> Intelligence Unit Publication


D A R E T O D R E A M : S T R A T E G I C A L L Y ! I N N O V A T I V E L Y !<br />

STRATEGIC CHOICES: ANEEL KARNANI<br />

PROFESSOR OF STRATEGY, UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN<br />

ILLUSION & REALITY: ANDREW LIKIERMAN<br />

DEAN, LONDON BUSINESS SCHOOL<br />

PR AND COMMUNICATION SYSTEM: DAVID NORDFORS<br />

SEMIOR RESEARCH SCHOLAR, STANFORD UNIVERSITY<br />

ENTREPRENEURSHIP: ELIZABETH R. THORNTON<br />

PROFESSOR OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP, BABSON COLLEGE<br />

INDIA’S PATH TO INNOVATION: DR. DAN STEINBOCK<br />

DIRECTOR, ICT RESEARCH INSTITUTE<br />

www.iipm.edu<br />

THE HUMAN FACTOR<br />

Subscription Form<br />

OTHER <strong>IIPM</strong> JOURNALS<br />

M A K E W E A L T H W H I L E O T H E R S T H I N K O F I T<br />

NEED THE DOUGH?<br />

July-October <strong>2007</strong> <strong>Volume</strong> 2 <strong>Issue</strong> I1 www.iipmthinktank.com<br />

SPECIAL ISSUE<br />

MERGERS & ACQUISITIONS<br />

Rs. 100<br />

Please enter my subscription for <strong>The</strong> India Economy Review<br />

<strong>The</strong> India Economy Review For India and SAARC Region Non SAARC<br />

Subscription<br />

Countries<br />

Per <strong>Issue</strong> INR 100 USD 3<br />

1 year (4 issues) INR 380 USD 13<br />

2 years (8 issues) INR 720 USD 21<br />

3 years (12 issues) INR 1020 USD 27<br />

INDIA INC. GOING<br />

GLOBAL<br />

AN <strong>IIPM</strong> THINK TANK PUBLICATION<br />

I am enclosing my cheque/DD no. __________ dated __________ for INR/USD ________<br />

on bank ________________________ branch ____________________ drawn in favour of<br />

“<strong>The</strong> Indian Institute of Planning and Management”.<br />

Strategic Innovators<br />

w<br />

July-September <strong>2007</strong>, <strong>Volume</strong> 1 <strong>Issue</strong> 3<br />

Unveiling the rich<br />

secrets behind those<br />

unanticipated strategic<br />

master-strokes<br />

w w . i i p m p u b l i c a t i o n s . c o m<br />

INSIDE THIS ISSUE<br />

20<br />

32<br />

40<br />

48<br />

56<br />

How Indian firms can make better strategic choices &<br />

execute them to achieve true competitive advantages<br />

How the success of an organisation is not reflected by<br />

its sheer <strong>size</strong>; rather it’s linked to shareholders’ returns<br />

How communicators & journalists are “attention workers”<br />

driving the “innovation communication system”<br />

Explaining the risks and returns behind many<br />

entrepreneurial motives to start their own businesses<br />

On how India’s future depends on the private sector<br />

players becoming the highly-active innovation drivers<br />

Rs.100<br />

Radical knowledge<br />

Re-structuring<br />

My Personal Details (IN BLOCK LETTERS)<br />

Name ______________________________________________________________________<br />

Designation _________________________________________________________________<br />

Organization ________________________________________________________________<br />

Address ____________________________________________________________________<br />

City ________________________________ State __________________________________<br />

Country _______________________________ Pin (mandatory) _____________________<br />

Tel ______________________Mobile __________________ e-mail ___________________<br />

AN AN <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> INTELLIGENCE UNIT UNIT PUBLICATION<br />

Age Below 25 25-35 35-50 Above 50<br />

Education Graduate MBA CA/CFA Other<br />

THE<br />

H UMAN<br />

FACTO<br />

R<br />

Contemporary | Actionable | Cutting-Edge<br />

Sr. Director HR on why GAP is a great place to work!<br />

<strong>The</strong> man’s got<br />

Pizzazz!<br />

Find out why the CEO, Domino’s<br />

India is sometimes called the Chief<br />

Enthusiasm Officer by his colleagues<br />

Director HR for Affinity<br />

Infotech tells us<br />

how he uses technology<br />

to aid HR<br />

How do you recruit top<br />

- level talent? Director<br />

GCH, Ranbaxy ponders<br />

the issue<br />

GM HR, Indraprastha Gas<br />

charts out the Development<br />

Plan for the HR<br />

manager<br />

Invitation price<br />

RS.50 Only<br />

Signature (Mandatory) _______________________<br />

Please Mail it to:<br />

THE INDIA ECONOMY REVIEW, <strong>The</strong> <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank,<br />

Neha Malhotra (Asst. Manager-Subscription)<br />

Satbari, Chandan Haula, Chattarpur, Bhatimines Road, New Delhi-110074<br />

Contact Details : 9818825794/9810459839 or E-mail : neha.malhotra@iipm.edu<br />

<strong>IIPM</strong> reserves the right to accept subscriptions. For any another queries please write to<br />

m.chaitanya@iipm.edu<br />

An <strong>IIPM</strong> Intelligence Unit Publication | 190 August-October 2005


P LANMAN TECHNOLOGIES<br />

KNOWLEDGE . IT . OUTSOURCING<br />

P LANMAN FINANCIAL<br />

INVESTMENT BANKING . CORPORATE ADVISORY<br />

P LANMAN CONSULTING<br />

GLOBAL STRATEGY . HUMAN RESOURCE . MARKET INTELLIGENCE<br />

P LANMAN MARCOM<br />

ADVERTISING . BRANDING . PR & CRM . ACTIVATION<br />

o<br />

360 Business Growth Consulting<br />

WWW. PLANMANCONSULTING. COM<br />

PLANMAN IS PERHAPS THE ONLY GLOBAL CONSULTING FIRM THAT CAN GIVE YOUR ORGANISATION A<br />

360 O BUSINESS GROWTH CONSULTING THROUGH IT’ S 360 O CAPABILITIES. FOR US CONSULTING DOES NOT ONLY MEAN<br />

MECHANICAL COST REDUCTION THROUGH BETTER I.T. APPLICATIONS. WE FIND OUT WHAT YOUR<br />

ORGANISATION REALLY NEEDS AND GIVE YOU AN INTELLECTUAL SOLUTION THAT HELPS YOU REDUCE COSTS AS WELL AS<br />

HELPS YOUR BUSINESS GROW AND BEAT THE COMPETITION.<br />

TO BEAT THE COMPETITION E-MAIL TO growth@planmanconsulting.com<br />

NOW!! OUR CONSULTANTS WILL GET BACK TO YOU IN 24 HOURS AND PUT YOU INTO THE HIGH GROWTH PATH!<br />

Planman. Beat <strong>The</strong> Competition.<br />

PLANMAN MARCOM/336<br />

ASIA | EUROPE | AMERICA


PRAISE FOR IER<br />

“Most credible and valuable resource book...”<br />

Prof. M.S.Swaminathan, M. S. Swaminathan Research Foundation, Chennai<br />

“I am happy that the <strong>IIPM</strong> <strong>Think</strong> Tank has been doing excellent<br />

work on various strategic sectors and issues of importance to Indian<br />

Economy... IER 2003-2004 is extremely fascinating and value adding...”<br />

Dr. P.L. Sanjeev Reddy, Former Secretary to Govt. of India, Director, Indian Institute<br />

of Public Administration, New Delhi<br />

“…I have gone through it and it is really a professional exercise to<br />

help everyone. What impressed me the most is its analytical approach<br />

used for articulating the figures, which otherwise are lifeless entities… ”<br />

Dr. Mruthyunjaya, Director, NCAEPR, New Delhi<br />

“...the contents are extremely relevant and thought provoking...”<br />

Dr. Charan Wadhwa, Centre for Policy Research, New Delhi<br />

“...It highlights the wealth of intellectual synthesis of agrarian economy<br />

available to us for re-energising the thought process endeavoured at<br />

your end…..I hope that the platform of further synthesis of many such issues<br />

provided by IER will be serving great interest of agriculture sector.”<br />

Dr. Rajiv Mehta, Member Secretary, Commission for Agricultural Costs & Prices,<br />

Ministry of Agriculture, New Delhi<br />

“.In my opinion, it has fulfilled its objective in presenting a comprehensive,<br />

upto-date and clear exposition of the issues and concerns<br />

that are essential for understanding, evaluating and suggesting<br />

solutions to the important national economic problems.”<br />

Mr. U.K.S. Chauhan, Director, Department of Agriculture and Cooperation,<br />

Ministry of Agriculture, New Delhi<br />

“...I laud your info base and analytical prowess; particularly your solutions<br />

vis-a-vis international experience….you may like to examine further<br />

from your side the aspects of futures trading in the perspective of the Indian<br />

farming community given your extant knowledge base in agriculture.”<br />

Mr. Suvendu Ganguly, Deputy Director, Forward Markets Commission,<br />

Kolkotta<br />

“<strong>The</strong> IER, a thematic compilation of economic thoughts, ideas, questions,<br />

answers and solutions…..promises to usher in a potentially better, if<br />

not necessarily newer, dawn of economic policies that radiates the power<br />

to dispel the current darkness of socio-economic and socio political confusion...<br />

the review exudes qualified optimism about country’s prospects.”<br />

Mr. S.R.Kasbekar Senior Editor, <strong>The</strong> Financial Express, Mumbai<br />

“I have to say that the Indian Economic Review, 2005 Vol. III, is<br />

very impressive and the material is very good. I send all of you involved<br />

with it, my heartiest congratulations and wish you all the best.”<br />

<strong>The</strong> Lord Paul, <strong>The</strong> Rt. Hon. Lord Paul of Marylebone<br />

“I liked the review... it is stimulating reading which forces the reader to think<br />

about the issue...”<br />

Dr. A. K. Singh, Giri Institute of Development Studies, Lucknow<br />

“Undoubtedly, it is of exceptional quality and amongst the best that I have<br />

seen in my interaction with similar organisations in different countries. I merely<br />

wanted to write to you and congratulate you and your institution on an extremely<br />

well researched and presented endeavour... I have taken the liberty of putting<br />

the copies that I had got along in the WTO library.”<br />

Mr. Shishir Priyadarshi, Development Division, WTO, Geneva<br />

“…...It is a very informative document.”<br />

Dr. V.L. Chopra, Member, Planning Commission, New Delhi<br />

“...I found it very useful material, which has dealt with the vital issues that<br />

we are facing in the field of education, health, poverty and employment. I would<br />

like to compliment all the authors as well as the editorial team for bringing out<br />

such a valuable publication.”<br />

Dr. Arun Nigavekar, Chairman, UGC, New Delhi<br />

“If the purpose of a think tank is not merely to think issues through but also<br />

to ignite thinking among the readers, I think you have succeeded very well<br />

indeed.”<br />

Mr. R. Badrinath, Director, Division of Trade Support Services, International Trade<br />

Centre, Geneva<br />

“…I thoroughly enjoyed going through your recent<br />

IER…it is undoubtedly a mammoth task of pulling together<br />

divergent perspectives on the critical issues of the nation…..”<br />

Dr. Parth J Shah, Centre for Civil Society, New Delhi<br />

“Modern India certainly needs more think tanks like yours... unlike most<br />

academic journals, yours is well-designed, readable and also conveys a sense<br />

of aesthetics and humour through the illustrations... it well reflects the high<br />

standards of the <strong>IIPM</strong>.”<br />

Mr. Brij Khindaria, President, Diplomatic forum for Business, Geneva.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!