11.11.2014 Views

Media Policy and Globalization - Blogs Unpad

Media Policy and Globalization - Blogs Unpad

Media Policy and Globalization - Blogs Unpad

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

TELECOMMUNICATIONS POLICY 69<br />

rhetoric of development in the economic realm to justify corrupt practices,<br />

in many instances reproducing colonial technologies of governance.<br />

In the area of telecommunications this meant everything from influential<br />

politicians or bureaucrats taking bribes from foreign equipment manufacturers<br />

to politicians reserving telephone lines for friends <strong>and</strong> family, <strong>and</strong><br />

much in between. For the news <strong>and</strong> emerging business media in urban<br />

centres across the developing world, it was issues like these that catalyzed<br />

important sections of public opinion against the state <strong>and</strong> towards market<br />

solutions to exp<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> modernize services (Chakravartty 2001b).<br />

Domestic policy-makers, often ‘experts’ trained in US business <strong>and</strong><br />

law schools with stints at the World Bank <strong>and</strong> the ITU, consequently explained<br />

that the urgency of reforms was a direct result of the failing performance<br />

of state enterprises. The solution spelled out by numerous World<br />

Bank <strong>and</strong> ITU policy reports was to implement a comprehensive reform<br />

process that would enable competition <strong>and</strong> technological modernization,<br />

promising to balance the concerns of equity with those of efficiency. In<br />

theory this included the deregulation of the state-operated network with<br />

the ultimate goal of privatization, liberalization of the supply of services,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the separation of the government’s policy <strong>and</strong> regulatory arm from<br />

its responsibilities as a network operator. In effect, most governments in<br />

this first period of liberalization implemented some form of privatization<br />

whereby state-operated telecommunications monopolies were either sold<br />

to private investors or re-organized as private corporations (corporatization).<br />

Early reformers such as Chile (1988) <strong>and</strong> Argentina <strong>and</strong> Mexico<br />

(1990) led the way in allowing a certain amount of foreign ownership in<br />

basic networks, followed up in a few years by allowing foreign competitors<br />

to enter long-distance <strong>and</strong> other value-added markets, with other<br />

countries quickly adopting similar strategies (Singh 1999; Tigre 1999).<br />

In this way, privatization almost always came before regulatory reform,<br />

which might have allowed the possibility of balancing efficiency <strong>and</strong> equity<br />

<strong>and</strong> demonstrates that the impetus for reform was driven by the<br />

need to ‘generate revenue’ for national governments ‘strapped for funds’.<br />

Economist Roger Noll writes plainly:<br />

Thus part of the impetus for neoliberal reform in telecommunications<br />

<strong>and</strong> other infrastructure sectors had nothing to do with performance,<br />

but instead the possibility to use their reform as a means to ease the<br />

pain of the larger neoliberal reform agenda. (Noll 2002: 13)<br />

Although influential urban middle classes supported neoliberal reforms<br />

on the grounds of state inefficiency, opposition to privatization schemes<br />

was a common feature of broader public sentiment against globalization.<br />

In Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, Puerto Rico, India <strong>and</strong> South Africa, to

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!