10.11.2014 Views

Bondarenko Dmitri M. Homoarchy

Bondarenko Dmitri M. Homoarchy

Bondarenko Dmitri M. Homoarchy

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

25<br />

confederations (Korotayev 1995a; 1996; 1998b; <strong>Bondarenko</strong> and Korotayev<br />

2000a: 157–227; Kradin et al. 2000: 213–224, 242–257; Grinin 2004b).<br />

However, such structures could fulfill the typically state functions at a<br />

respectively high level only partially or occasionally (Grinin 1997; 2000a;<br />

2004b; Claessen 2002). Only supercomplex societies could become stable and<br />

effective in long-run alternatives to the state, only they can be (and I am sure<br />

should be) considered as realizations of “historical projects”, alternative to the<br />

statehood ones in the true sense of the word. In my belief, Benin Kingdom of<br />

the 13 th – 19 th centuries discussed at some length in the subsequent chapters<br />

was just “a proper candidate” for this role, as well as the other presumably nonstate<br />

supercomplex societies mentioned in the last chapter.<br />

3. Centralization and bureaucratization: the criteria’s relevance for the<br />

state theory<br />

Notwithstanding the historiographic tradition described sketchily in this<br />

chapter’s opening sections, and particularly contrary to the postulate of political<br />

anthropology’s Founding Fathers, Fortes and Evans-Pritchard (1987/1940b: 5),<br />

political centralization cannot be regarded as a specifically state’s feature as it<br />

is applicable more or less to all the forms of complex homoarchic (organized<br />

basically “vertically”) societies including chiefdoms first and foremost<br />

(<strong>Bondarenko</strong> 1997c: 10–15; 2000c; <strong>Bondarenko</strong> et al. 2002; Korotayev et al.<br />

2000; Korotayev 2003a: 45–91; Testart 2004: 10). For example, see the<br />

following definitions (my emphases): “Chiefdoms are redistributional societies<br />

with a permanent central agency of coordination” (Service 1971/1962: 134);<br />

chiefdom is “a polity that organizes centrally a regional population in the<br />

thousands” (Earle 1991: 1); “… a chiefdom is an aggregate of villages under<br />

the centralized rule of a paramount political leader. This is the basic structural<br />

nature of a chiefdom” (Carneiro 1998: 19); chiefdoms are “societies with<br />

centralized but not internally specialized authority” (Spencer 1998: 5;<br />

following [Wright 1977: 381]). This is even more so in the case of complex<br />

chiefdom (e.g., Earle 1978: 173–185; Pauketat 1994; Johnson, A. W. and Earle<br />

2000: 301–303). As Timothy Earle resumes in his prominent review article<br />

(1987: 289), “… centrality is the clearest indicator of chiefdoms” (see also in<br />

other review articles: Kradin 1995: 11, 16–17; Beliaev et al. 2001, the latter<br />

being a general discussion of chiefdoms as centralized polities). Furthermore,<br />

even in simple societies power may be centralized by a “big man”, “great man”<br />

(Sahlins 1963; Godelier 1982; Godelier and Strathern 1991), or “chieftain” who<br />

thus establishes “… centralized political leadership that operates from time to<br />

time among autonomous village societies but that is generally short-lived”, so<br />

the term “chieftain” “… designates explicitly the form of centralized<br />

leadership…” (Redmond 1998: 3). The variety of non-state centralized forms<br />

of societies and leadership types is by no means at all limited to those<br />

mentioned above.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!