12.09.2014 Views

A brief history of tax - The Chartered Institute of Taxation

A brief history of tax - The Chartered Institute of Taxation

A brief history of tax - The Chartered Institute of Taxation

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

INAUGURAL LECTURE<br />

A <strong>brief</strong> <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>tax</strong><br />

In this article based on her inaugural lecture, Jane Frecknall-Hughes looks at<br />

historical issues which have a bearing on <strong>tax</strong> today<br />

<strong>Taxation</strong> is not only fascinating in<br />

its own right academically, but has<br />

an everyday relevance that many<br />

other subjects may, indeed, lack. Tax is<br />

something that affects all our lives on a<br />

daily basis, yet knowledge <strong>of</strong> how <strong>tax</strong>es<br />

work or appreciation <strong>of</strong> their impact is not<br />

as common as one might wish.<br />

<strong>The</strong>re is in academia a general lack <strong>of</strong><br />

appreciation <strong>of</strong> the ways in which <strong>tax</strong>ation<br />

interacts with other academic subjects,<br />

as it is relevant in accounting and finance,<br />

public and local finance, law, economics,<br />

psychology, sociology, management,<br />

philosophy (especially ethics), political<br />

science and <strong>history</strong>. <strong>The</strong> last, together with<br />

law, form the focus <strong>of</strong> this article.<br />

For the the man on the Clapham omnibus,<br />

there is frequently a disconnect between the<br />

daily impact <strong>of</strong> <strong>tax</strong>ation and the Government<br />

policies underlying it, which we <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

become actively aware <strong>of</strong> only when they<br />

hit the media headlines. We certainly do<br />

not have a general consciousness <strong>of</strong> how<br />

we came to be where we are today or <strong>of</strong> the<br />

vast underlying back <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>tax</strong>ation. By<br />

this term I refer not only to the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> the<br />

subject itself, but its inseparable effects on<br />

historical events and human behaviour.<br />

If we look back in time, we will see that<br />

as now, in the past, means and devices were<br />

employed that were driven by the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

the times and the art <strong>of</strong> what was possible,<br />

but nonetheless have a clear relevance and<br />

resonance for our current times.<br />

<strong>tax</strong> theory – a historical perspective<br />

When discussing <strong>tax</strong>es and <strong>tax</strong> theory, it<br />

is customary to refer to the four famous<br />

canons <strong>of</strong> <strong>tax</strong>ation outlined by Adam Smith<br />

in his work An Inquiry into the Nature and<br />

Causes <strong>of</strong> the Wealth <strong>of</strong> Nations (1776) as the<br />

defining characteristics <strong>of</strong> an effective <strong>tax</strong>.<br />

<strong>The</strong>se are equity/proportionality, certainty,<br />

convenience and efficiency, as follows:<br />

1. <strong>The</strong> subjects <strong>of</strong> every state ought to<br />

contribute towards the support <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Government, as nearly as possible, in<br />

proportion to the revenue which they<br />

respectively enjoy under the protection<br />

<strong>of</strong> the state. (Equity/proportionality,<br />

ie, contribution in accordance with a<br />

person’s ability to pay.)<br />

KeY pointS<br />

• Tax and <strong>tax</strong> avoidance go back into<br />

the dawn <strong>of</strong> democracy in the UK<br />

• Some <strong>of</strong> the issues we regard as<br />

modern problems in fact were also<br />

relevant 800 years ago<br />

• Looking back over the <strong>history</strong> <strong>of</strong> <strong>tax</strong><br />

can <strong>of</strong>fer some interesting parallels<br />

for the modern observer – and maybe<br />

some lessons<br />

2. <strong>The</strong> <strong>tax</strong> which each individual is bound to<br />

pay, ought to be certain, and not arbitrary.<br />

<strong>The</strong> time <strong>of</strong> payment, the manner <strong>of</strong><br />

payment, the amount to be paid ought to<br />

be plain and clear to the contributor and<br />

to every other person. (Certainty.)<br />

3. Every <strong>tax</strong> ought to be levied at the time,<br />

or in the manner, in which it is most likely<br />

to be convenient for the contributor to<br />

pay it. (Convenience – although ‘least<br />

degree <strong>of</strong> inconvenience’ might be a<br />

better way <strong>of</strong> putting this.)<br />

4. Every <strong>tax</strong> ought to be so contrived, as<br />

both to take out and to keep out <strong>of</strong> the<br />

pockets <strong>of</strong> the people as little as possible,<br />

over and above what it brings into the<br />

public treasury <strong>of</strong> the state. (Efficiency,<br />

that is, it does not cost more to collect the<br />

<strong>tax</strong> than the levy itself would produce.)<br />

To these four canons, which are still<br />

relevant today, has been added a fifth in<br />

more recent years, that <strong>of</strong> neutrality. This<br />

means that the <strong>tax</strong> system itself should<br />

influence as little as possible the way in<br />

which economic activities are carried out.<br />

In addition one would also hope to<br />

find that any <strong>tax</strong> system is flexible (ie,<br />

capable <strong>of</strong> being altered without too much<br />

difficulty to cope with changes in economic<br />

circumstances); is relatively simple to deal<br />

with and understand; and is perceived as<br />

being equitable by those upon whom it is<br />

imposed.<br />

However, we have to remember that<br />

these are ideals and in real life <strong>tax</strong>ation<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten has fallen far short <strong>of</strong> meeting them.<br />

Common themes emerging are problems<br />

<strong>of</strong> defining what is (or should be) <strong>tax</strong>ed,<br />

whether <strong>tax</strong> collection can be increased by<br />

decreasing the <strong>tax</strong> rate (the Laffer curve<br />

effect), the use <strong>of</strong> <strong>tax</strong>ation for non-fiscal<br />

purposes and to attempt to alter behaviour,<br />

<strong>tax</strong> protests, unintended consequences,<br />

Revenue discretion, evasion and avoidance –<br />

all <strong>of</strong> which, arguably, remain with us today.<br />

King John<br />

King John was nothing if not an innovative,<br />

extortionary and opportunistic <strong>tax</strong> collector.<br />

He was perennially short <strong>of</strong> funds, as the<br />

Treasury was depleted by the demands <strong>of</strong> his<br />

predecessor, Richard, in terms <strong>of</strong> overseas<br />

wars, building castles in contested French<br />

demesnes and the ransom demanded for his<br />

release.<br />

However, John’s <strong>tax</strong> measures succeeded<br />

in the early years <strong>of</strong> his reign because he<br />

had one <strong>of</strong> the ablest financial advisers that<br />

England has ever produced, a largely unsung<br />

hero by the name <strong>of</strong> Hubert Walter, who<br />

combined the role <strong>of</strong> Chancellor (<strong>of</strong> the<br />

Exchequer) and Archbishop <strong>of</strong> Canterbury,<br />

and had been head <strong>of</strong> the legal system as<br />

it then was. He not only controlled John,<br />

but also national finances until his death in<br />

1205, and had done so under Richard, and<br />

Richard’s and John’s father, Henry II. He was<br />

particularly good at amending <strong>tax</strong>es to which<br />

people were accustomed, to obtain more<br />

money but without causing undue unrest,<br />

and apparently with a reasonable degree<br />

<strong>of</strong> equity. Some <strong>of</strong> the <strong>tax</strong>es that existed at<br />

that time we would not today consider as<br />

22 January 2012 | www.<strong>tax</strong>advisermagazine.com


INAUGURAL LECTURE<br />

their power to bear it and to revolt, when<br />

the restraining influence <strong>of</strong> Hubert Walter<br />

was no longer there. John inherited a<br />

nearly bankrupt kingdom, depleted by his<br />

predecessor and made worse by wars in his<br />

own reign which the right financial advice<br />

from the right man in the right place at the<br />

right time was on the way to rectifying by<br />

extending the use <strong>of</strong> customary measures,<br />

not introducing new ones which would<br />

create disharmony. <strong>The</strong>se events resonate<br />

clearly for our own times.<br />

pr<strong>of</strong>iLe<br />

name Jane Frecknall-Hughes<br />

position Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Law and Head <strong>of</strong> the Law School<br />

company <strong>The</strong> Open University<br />

tel 01908 332565<br />

email j.frecknall-hughes@open.ac.uk<br />

p r o fi l e Jane Frecknall-Hughes is currently Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Law and Head<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Law School at <strong>The</strong> Open University, to which post she was appointed from 1<br />

December 2011, to lead forward the School’s research, scholarship and teaching. This<br />

article summarises Jane’s recent inaugural pr<strong>of</strong>essorial lecture in her previous post as<br />

Pr<strong>of</strong>essor <strong>of</strong> Accounting at <strong>The</strong> Open University. This is based on her research, which<br />

centres on <strong>tax</strong>ation with <strong>tax</strong>ation <strong>history</strong> being a particular interest.<br />

<strong>tax</strong>es, but it is common to consider any input<br />

into the royal Treasury at this time as a <strong>tax</strong>,<br />

however derived.<br />

Walter’s death produced a crisis in<br />

<strong>tax</strong>ation, in that Walter’s restraining<br />

influence on John’s rapaciousness was lost,<br />

leading to extreme <strong>tax</strong>ation measures.<br />

Desperate for money, John lost no time,<br />

following a disagreement with Rome, in<br />

seizing church property. Crown envy <strong>of</strong> the<br />

church’s wealth was nothing new, although<br />

monarchs generally exercised a degree <strong>of</strong><br />

restraint. John then sold their property back<br />

to the clergy, while retaining some part <strong>of</strong><br />

the church revenues as an income stream.<br />

<strong>The</strong> revenue John obtained from church<br />

sources undoubtedly meant that he did not<br />

ask for so much from the barons, and so<br />

deferred the <strong>tax</strong> revolt which led to Magna<br />

Carta. Over half the clauses in the 1215<br />

version <strong>of</strong> Magna Carta, incidentally, refer to<br />

John’s financial exactions.<br />

Another scheme was also devised for<br />

relieving the clergy <strong>of</strong> substantial sums <strong>of</strong><br />

money. Although priests were supposed to<br />

be celibate, the Church had great difficulty<br />

in enforcing this, and many parish priests,<br />

it is believed, had undergone some form<br />

<strong>of</strong> marriage, or kept housekeepers, who<br />

were rather more than this. Henry I had<br />

fined the clergy for disobeying the Church<br />

in this matter – at the same time as selling<br />

them licences to do so. John ordered all<br />

the clergy’s womenfolk <strong>of</strong> this nature to be<br />

seized and held for ransom.<br />

From the <strong>tax</strong> events <strong>of</strong> John’s reign in<br />

general, it is easy to see how economic<br />

hardship led to people being <strong>tax</strong>ed beyond<br />

moving forward in time<br />

Often the habits <strong>of</strong> society at large provide<br />

the means by which <strong>tax</strong>es can be raised,<br />

for example, because people drink, smoke,<br />

drive cars, travel by air, etc. A Government<br />

may be faced with <strong>tax</strong>ing something that is<br />

widespread (leading to a broad <strong>tax</strong> base, so a<br />

lot <strong>of</strong> people/things are <strong>tax</strong>ed) or expensive<br />

(leading to not so broad a <strong>tax</strong> base, but<br />

compensated for because <strong>tax</strong> is applied<br />

to higher cost base). An ideal ‘thing’ for a<br />

Government to <strong>tax</strong> is something which is<br />

both widespread and expensive, as this can<br />

raise a lot <strong>of</strong> <strong>tax</strong> revenue – but, as some <strong>of</strong><br />

my examples show, it has to be something<br />

that will last for a reasonable length <strong>of</strong> time.<br />

Typically ‘things’ are <strong>tax</strong>ed by the use<br />

<strong>of</strong> excise duties (or <strong>tax</strong>es). <strong>The</strong>se were<br />

particularly prevalent in England during the<br />

17th, 18th and 19th centuries.<br />

Excises are very flexible <strong>tax</strong>es, and have<br />

been popular for centuries in a wide variety<br />

<strong>of</strong> different countries. <strong>The</strong>ir advent in<br />

England and the English colonies in the 17th<br />

century is likely to be associated with the<br />

arrival <strong>of</strong> William <strong>of</strong> Orange, when he came<br />

to England from the Netherlands in 1689, as<br />

excises had gained great popularity at this<br />

time in Holland. <strong>The</strong> word ‘excise’ itself is<br />

derived from a Middle Dutch word (‘excijs’),<br />

one <strong>of</strong> the meanings <strong>of</strong> which is ‘assessment’.<br />

the 17th-century <strong>tax</strong> base<br />

Taxes were introduced on a variety <strong>of</strong> things<br />

(though some had existed before this in<br />

different forms):<br />

• salt (1694);<br />

• births, deaths and marriages; bachelors;<br />

sea-borne coal; spices, beer, wine, spirits,<br />

tea, c<strong>of</strong>fee, cocoa; and tobacco (1695);<br />

• windows (1696, lasting until 1851), also<br />

later, bricks and wallpaper;<br />

• trades via hackney carriages (1694) and<br />

hawkers (1697);<br />

• malt and leather (1697)<br />

• variously later – male servants, hair<br />

powder, soap, candles, hats and gloves.<br />

Bachelor <strong>tax</strong><br />

In times <strong>of</strong> economic crisis, Governments<br />

sometimes try to implement rather unusual<br />

measures.<br />

<strong>The</strong> so-called ‘bachelor <strong>tax</strong>’ was one<br />

<strong>of</strong> these <strong>tax</strong>es. More formally, it was part<br />

www.<strong>tax</strong>advisermagazine.com | January 2012 23


INAUGURAL LECTURE<br />

<strong>of</strong> the Marriage Duty Tax, authorised in<br />

England by an Act <strong>of</strong> Parliament in 1694 and<br />

implemented in 1695, which levied <strong>tax</strong> on<br />

marriages, births and burials, but also upon<br />

bachelors and widowers. It was imposed<br />

initially for five years, and then prolonged to<br />

1706, after which it was not renewed.<br />

<strong>The</strong> background to the <strong>tax</strong> was again a<br />

severe shortage <strong>of</strong> Government revenue,<br />

on this occasion required to fight an almost<br />

constant war against the French during the<br />

reign <strong>of</strong> William III and his wife, Mary II.<br />

As the name <strong>of</strong> the Act implies, a <strong>tax</strong> was<br />

levied on all births, marriages and deaths. In<br />

addition, an annual fee was charged on all<br />

bachelors over 25 years <strong>of</strong> age and childless<br />

widowers. Rates varied according to the<br />

social status <strong>of</strong> the individual: the gentry<br />

and nobility, and anyone with a personal<br />

estate over £600, or an annual income <strong>of</strong><br />

£50, paid extra. Persons receiving alms<br />

were exempt. In England, it seems that an<br />

unmarried duke would pay a minimum <strong>of</strong><br />

£12 11s (in old money).<br />

To assess this <strong>tax</strong> and prevent evasion, it<br />

was necessary to have a complete listing <strong>of</strong><br />

the whole population. This was, in effect a<br />

census, as it listed names, family and marital<br />

status, and titles. <strong>The</strong> listings generated,<br />

first in the summer <strong>of</strong> 1695, are the most<br />

comprehensive <strong>of</strong> the English population that<br />

existed before the 1801 census.<br />

While one might think that a <strong>tax</strong><br />

on bachelors is unusual, it has <strong>of</strong>ten<br />

been implemented or suggested,<br />

as a strategy <strong>of</strong> Governments to<br />

encourage population growth and<br />

raise money at the same time.<br />

Augustus Caesar attempted to<br />

impose penalties (if not actual<br />

<strong>tax</strong>es) on the unmarried in 18 BC,<br />

as did the Spartans <strong>of</strong> ancient<br />

Greece. <strong>The</strong> latter preferred<br />

public humiliation, however,<br />

to money-raising: bachelors in<br />

Sparta were required to march<br />

around the public market in<br />

wintertime stark naked, while<br />

singing a song mocking<br />

their unmarried status.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Missouri<br />

legislature in the USA<br />

attempted to levy such a <strong>tax</strong> in 1820, as did<br />

the Russians under Peter the Great in 1702.<br />

Indeed, there has been a recent suggestion<br />

that it should be applied to wealthy Russian<br />

bachelors, as many <strong>of</strong> these are, apparently,<br />

unmarried. <strong>The</strong>re has been a similar<br />

suggestion, made in 2008, in Ireland in<br />

regard to unmarried men over 18 (in this case<br />

to re-establish the institution <strong>of</strong> marriage), so<br />

it has not gone away.<br />

Window <strong>tax</strong><br />

Moving on to consider the window <strong>tax</strong>,<br />

this was introduced in England and Wales<br />

in 1696. It was intended to <strong>tax</strong> people<br />

relative to their wealth, as demonstrated<br />

by the number <strong>of</strong> windows they had in their<br />

houses, and was always accepted as a proxy<br />

for income <strong>tax</strong>: the larger one’s house, the<br />

more windows it was likely to possess and<br />

so the wealthier one might be deemed to<br />

be. Income <strong>tax</strong> was then an unwelcome and<br />

controversial idea, as it would involve the<br />

disclosure <strong>of</strong> personal details about income<br />

to a Government authority, which was felt to<br />

be a gross intrusion – an idea which dogged<br />

income <strong>tax</strong> well into the early years <strong>of</strong> the<br />

20th century.<br />

On introduction, the window <strong>tax</strong><br />

consisted <strong>of</strong> a flat-rate house <strong>tax</strong> <strong>of</strong> two<br />

shillings per house and a variable <strong>tax</strong> relating<br />

Bachelors in Sparta were required to march around<br />

the public market in wintertime stark naked, while<br />

singing a song mocking their unmarried status<br />

to the number <strong>of</strong> windows (if there were<br />

more than ten windows). If a property<br />

had between ten and 20 windows, four<br />

shillings were due and if it had more than<br />

20, eight shillings were due. <strong>The</strong> number<br />

<strong>of</strong> ‘chargeable’ windows was variously<br />

amended later on. In 1778, a variable rate <strong>tax</strong><br />

replaced the flat-rate one, which depended<br />

on property value.<br />

As windows could be easily counted, the<br />

<strong>tax</strong> was regarded as non-intrusive and easy<br />

to assess. However, the <strong>tax</strong> was regarded as<br />

an impost on air and light, and when it was<br />

finally repealed, it was on health grounds.<br />

It was also relatively easy to avoid as when<br />

inspectors came into a district to count<br />

windows, house owners would brick them up<br />

before they arrived and then unbrick them<br />

when the inspectors left. Eventually many<br />

tired <strong>of</strong> this continual cycle and left some<br />

windows bricked up permanently – hence<br />

they can still be seen in this condition today<br />

in many English stately homes.<br />

Brick <strong>tax</strong><br />

Brick <strong>tax</strong> was introduced in 1784 during<br />

the reign <strong>of</strong> George III to help fund wars in<br />

America. Bricks were originally assessed to<br />

<strong>tax</strong> a rate <strong>of</strong> four shillings per thousand. To<br />

try to get round this, manufacturers simply<br />

made larger bricks, which resulted in the<br />

introducing a maximum volume for a brick <strong>of</strong><br />

150 cubic inches (2,500cm 3 ).<br />

Two effects <strong>of</strong> this <strong>tax</strong> were that many<br />

smaller manufacturers went out <strong>of</strong> business<br />

(they had to sell their inventory to pay their<br />

<strong>tax</strong>es), and that architectural styles changed,<br />

with a return to the use <strong>of</strong> wood in house<br />

construction. <strong>The</strong> Government abolished<br />

the <strong>tax</strong> in 1850 as it was considered an<br />

impediment to industrial growth.<br />

Soap <strong>tax</strong><br />

In England, there is evidence <strong>of</strong> soap<br />

production in Bristol and Cheapside in<br />

London from the 12th, 13th and 14th<br />

centuries respectively. Soap was <strong>tax</strong>ed<br />

because it was expensive, and so provided<br />

a good source <strong>of</strong> revenue – although few<br />

people apparently washed (believing that<br />

dirt actually kept out harmful diseases and<br />

germs). During the wars against Napoleonic<br />

France, soap <strong>tax</strong> increased so much that <strong>tax</strong><br />

inspectors would lock up the soap boiling<br />

pans to stop illegal production at night. This<br />

<strong>tax</strong> was repealed in 1835.<br />

Candle <strong>tax</strong><br />

In 1709 a <strong>tax</strong> was introduced on all English<br />

and imported candles, the rate on tallow<br />

candles being one halfpenny a pound, and on<br />

wax fourpence apound. <strong>The</strong>se amounts were<br />

doubled in 1711. <strong>The</strong> <strong>tax</strong> was unpopular and<br />

was repealed in 1831.<br />

Hats and gloves<br />

<strong>The</strong>re had long been rules as to who could<br />

wear a hat and what it might be made <strong>of</strong>,<br />

dating from medieval and feudal rules.<br />

Hats, helmets, etc, were indicative <strong>of</strong> social<br />

status and political connections (eg, in the<br />

form <strong>of</strong> livery).<br />

A hat <strong>tax</strong> as such existed from 1784–1811.<br />

Apparently England was renowned for the<br />

excellence <strong>of</strong> its hats – a trade helped to<br />

develop by the French imposing a <strong>tax</strong> on hats<br />

in 1690. By 1784 it was felt that the English<br />

hat trade likewise could support a <strong>tax</strong>.<br />

Hat retailers had to take out an annual<br />

licence and have ‘Dealer in hats by retail’<br />

written above their shop doors. Every hat<br />

sold bore a duty according to its sale price.<br />

This was collected by means <strong>of</strong> a stamped<br />

ticket which was fixed to lining in the<br />

crown <strong>of</strong> the hat. <strong>The</strong> hatter had to charge<br />

separately for the stamp on the customer’s<br />

bill. Inevitably, this led to questions <strong>of</strong> what<br />

a hat was, as this had never been defined.<br />

In 1767 a separate <strong>tax</strong> was imposed on a<br />

certain kind <strong>of</strong> straw hat, called a ‘chip’<br />

hat, but the fashion changed and the <strong>tax</strong><br />

collected was minimal. In 1804, however,<br />

duties were imposed on substances from<br />

which hats could be made, and on every<br />

sort <strong>of</strong> hat (pretty much any head covering).<br />

Perhaps rather surprisingly, this led to a<br />

‘black market’ trade in hats.<br />

24 January 2012 | www.<strong>tax</strong>advisermagazine.com


INAUGURAL LECTURE<br />

A similar duty was imposed on gloves<br />

and mittens between 1785 and 1794.<br />

Tax on toiletries 1786–1800, especially<br />

hair/wig powder<br />

Between 1786 and 1800, <strong>tax</strong>es were also<br />

imposed on a variety <strong>of</strong> perfumes, pastes,<br />

balsams, ointments, waters, tinctures, tooth<br />

powder, pomatum, etc. Perhaps one <strong>of</strong> the<br />

more unusual items eventually to be <strong>tax</strong>ed<br />

was hair powder. This could be made from<br />

various different substances, for example,<br />

ground starch – and it was common to add<br />

perfume and colouring (commonly powder<br />

was coloured blue, pink, violet or yellow,<br />

although <strong>of</strong>f-white was most popular).<br />

However, in 1795 the Government<br />

introduced a <strong>tax</strong> <strong>of</strong> one guinea a year<br />

payable by those who wished to wear a<br />

powdered wig or directly powder their<br />

hair, which was the death knell for an<br />

already moribund fashion.<br />

relevance for today<br />

Let us just pause for a moment in<br />

consideration <strong>of</strong> some <strong>of</strong> these more<br />

outlandish <strong>tax</strong> provisions to point to the<br />

relevance for the current day.<br />

<strong>The</strong> bachelor <strong>tax</strong> was an attempt to<br />

raise <strong>tax</strong> and influence behaviour. It did not<br />

work very well or for very long. Using <strong>tax</strong><br />

to influence behaviour is as controversial<br />

today as it was then. We are now, for<br />

example, encouraged by higher duties on<br />

alcohol to give up or reduce intake, the<br />

latter more actively, perhaps, in Scotland<br />

than England and Wales.<br />

<strong>The</strong> need for a census was an unintended<br />

consequence <strong>of</strong> the bachelor <strong>tax</strong>, as was the<br />

imposition <strong>of</strong> a maximum brick size resulting<br />

from the brick <strong>tax</strong>. Not all unintended <strong>tax</strong><br />

consequences are unwelcome, but some<br />

can be – for example, in recent times the<br />

10p <strong>tax</strong> rate problems and, perhaps, the<br />

increase in company registrations when the<br />

first £10,000 <strong>of</strong> company pr<strong>of</strong>its were freed<br />

from corporation <strong>tax</strong>.<br />

In terms <strong>of</strong> candles and soap, it seems<br />

that the Government gave up a <strong>tax</strong> which had<br />

a broad base and could raise considerable<br />

revenue, especially after the development <strong>of</strong><br />

soap mass production. Why? One suggestion<br />

might be an increasing concern for public<br />

health and a better appreciation <strong>of</strong> what<br />

contributed to it. Would it not have raised<br />

more revenue to have lowered the duty on<br />

soap, and thus collected more as it became<br />

more widely available? It is, in fact, rather<br />

difficult to find out very much about these<br />

<strong>tax</strong>es. <strong>The</strong>re is more about soap <strong>tax</strong>es on<br />

soap manufacturers’ websites than in any<br />

textbook that I have encountered.<br />

However, excise duties on the necessities<br />

<strong>of</strong> life had always been unpopular, which is<br />

why the excise on beer was so unwelcome.<br />

Beer was not drunk primarily because it was<br />

alcoholic (though that might have been an<br />

Box 1 – the <strong>tax</strong> advice Spectrum<br />

Tax Tax Tax Tax Tax Tax<br />

morale compliance planning avoidance ‘avoision’ evasion<br />

added bonus), but because it was safe to<br />

drink. <strong>The</strong> manufacturing process involved<br />

boiling so it was safer than water, which was<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten severely polluted. It was thus the drink<br />

<strong>of</strong> the poorer classes, not a luxury item.<br />

To provide a sound <strong>tax</strong> base, something<br />

that is <strong>tax</strong>ed has to endure and the <strong>tax</strong><br />

imposed has to be perceived as fair. <strong>The</strong><br />

<strong>tax</strong> on ‘chip’ hats, for example, ‘missed the<br />

<strong>tax</strong> boat’ and that on hair powder was too<br />

late by far to collect any really substantial<br />

amount <strong>of</strong> revenue. It was a desperate<br />

measure, again during the Napoleanic wars,<br />

to raise funds. Income <strong>tax</strong>, introduced only<br />

a few years afterwards in 1799, was a move<br />

towards a wider <strong>tax</strong> base – income – which<br />

while subject to fluctuation, would not be<br />

subject to fashion.<br />

avoidance<br />

Some <strong>tax</strong>es are, <strong>of</strong> course, easier to avoid<br />

or evade. We have seen this in terms<br />

<strong>of</strong> the window <strong>tax</strong> and the hat <strong>tax</strong>. <strong>The</strong><br />

Government’s campaign against <strong>tax</strong><br />

avoidance is well known. However, opinions<br />

<strong>of</strong> what is avoidance have varied over the<br />

years, although there seem to have been<br />

two basic ways in which the authorities<br />

have looked at avoidance – either by<br />

reference to where something has fallen<br />

on a spectrum, (See Box 1) or by the way<br />

something has ‘smelt’, that is, ‘fishy’. <strong>The</strong><br />

spectrum idea does actually appear to be<br />

the more modern idea. By spectrum, I mean<br />

what is shown above. One can decide where<br />

an acceptable point lies.<br />

<strong>The</strong> ‘smell’ or ‘sniff’ test appears to be<br />

older. In an article in the British Tax Review in<br />

1981, Ian Ferrier reports on a scheme in 1783<br />

devised to ‘get round’ the payment <strong>of</strong> a two<br />

pence Scot duty (a type <strong>of</strong> excise) payable in<br />

Glasgow on each pint <strong>of</strong> ale or beer brewed,<br />

brought in or sold in the city and suburbs,<br />

in the case <strong>of</strong> Magistrates and Town Council<br />

<strong>of</strong> the City <strong>of</strong> Glasgow v Messrs. Murdoch,<br />

Warren & Co 2 Paton 615 52. <strong>The</strong> brewers,<br />

based at Anderston, then far enough away to<br />

be considered as not in the city or suburbs,<br />

announced that they would cease to supply<br />

the city, and made a contract with a certain<br />

Mr Munro, who bought the beer and<br />

supplied it to customers from the Anderston<br />

premises. One is compelled to wonder<br />

why the brewers could not have done this<br />

themselves.<br />

<strong>The</strong> case was taken to the House <strong>of</strong> Lords,<br />

though it was then a somewhat different<br />

Acceptable point?<br />

body legally from that which it subsequently<br />

became. Lord Mansfield was the foremost<br />

judge, and had no qualms about judging<br />

this a scheme which should not be allowed,<br />

and ignored the ‘device <strong>of</strong> the intermediate<br />

contract with Munro’. It was a perfectly legal<br />

contract, but it smacked <strong>of</strong> what we would<br />

now call unacceptable avoidance.<br />

conclusion<br />

Many <strong>tax</strong> ideas and problems have been<br />

around for a very long time. I will conclude<br />

by looking <strong>brief</strong>ly at current environmental<br />

<strong>tax</strong>es on certain kinds <strong>of</strong> waste.<br />

<strong>The</strong> idea <strong>of</strong> such a <strong>tax</strong> is <strong>of</strong>ten to <strong>tax</strong><br />

the producer <strong>of</strong> waste to try to minimise<br />

the impact on the environment, and/or<br />

the costs <strong>of</strong> cleaning up. <strong>The</strong> RSPCA has<br />

suggested re-introducing a dog licence<br />

very much along these lines, although it is<br />

interesting to note that the last dog licence<br />

that existed was scrapped some time ago<br />

as being inefficient: it cost more to collect<br />

the <strong>tax</strong> than was raised.<br />

<strong>The</strong> Romans, however, got there a<br />

long time before we did, and, perhaps<br />

unsurprisingly, did it rather more effectively.<br />

In Rome, urine was collected from public<br />

toilets and used in tanneries and laundries.<br />

<strong>The</strong> ammonia it contained was needed to<br />

cure leather and bleach togas. Urine was<br />

similarly used, incidentally, many years<br />

later in the production <strong>of</strong> Scottish tweed.<br />

Thus we have waste products being put<br />

to use in a way that we now are only just<br />

beginning to emulate. In Sheffield, the city<br />

council, for example, is running a trial <strong>of</strong><br />

council vehicles powered by methane gas<br />

derived from sewage. <strong>The</strong> Romans, however,<br />

went a step further. <strong>The</strong>y not only actually<br />

used the waste material, but <strong>tax</strong>ed it. <strong>The</strong><br />

Roman emperor, Nero, levied a <strong>tax</strong> on urine<br />

collectors (not, incidentally, on its producers),<br />

which generated a substantial amount <strong>of</strong><br />

revenue. Vespasian, who was emperor<br />

after Nero, continued to collect the <strong>tax</strong>.<br />

Vespasian’s son, Titus, complained about the<br />

unpleasant nature <strong>of</strong> the <strong>tax</strong>, but Vespasian<br />

is alleged to have held al<strong>of</strong>t gold coins from<br />

the <strong>tax</strong> collected with the words, ‘tell me, my<br />

son, whether they smell’.<br />

further information<br />

References within this article can be<br />

viewed at: www.<strong>tax</strong>advisermagazine.<br />

com/ta/article/references-1018341<br />

www.<strong>tax</strong>advisermagazine.com | January 2012 25

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!