04.09.2014 Views

Trade Policy Note Final-rev08 - Development

Trade Policy Note Final-rev08 - Development

Trade Policy Note Final-rev08 - Development

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

percent of domestic consumption) was provided by a system of tariff rate quotas<br />

(TRQs), 37 at lower, but usually positive rates, often allocated to individual suppliers.<br />

As the out of quota tariffs are usually prohibitively high, imports of a large number of<br />

agricultural products into developed countries are in fact subject to de facto<br />

quantitative limits. This protective regime is supplemented by a Special Safeguard<br />

Mechanism (SSM), which permits additional import charges to be applied when<br />

imports of “tariffied” products exceed trigger prices or trigger volumes.<br />

Thus, the new regime retained, in a somewhat different form, the quantitative<br />

restrictions (de facto) and variable levies that were central to the EU protective<br />

regime. It also established a framework for “micro-negotiation” for the granting of<br />

bilateral quotas reminiscent of the MFA. Within such a structure, analysis based on<br />

average tariff rates provides little useful guidance for policy makers. 38<br />

The WTO Agriculture Agreement also imposed some discipline on agricultural<br />

subsides. Export subsidies are subject to sectoral commitments, (volume and<br />

payments). Domestic production subsidies designed to have a distorting effect, (e.g..<br />

price supports), are also subject to overall negotiated ceilings (based on AMSaggregate<br />

measure of support) with a de minimis exception (5 per cent for developed,<br />

10 per cent for developing countries). Two other categories of subsidies are not<br />

subject to limitations: (i) direct payments to producers when linked to supply<br />

reduction (“blue” box), and (ii) those determined to have minimal trade impact<br />

(“green” box). This structure has not served to limit agricultural subsidization, which<br />

has increased to almost $300 billion annually. Subsidy programmes have simply been<br />

directed to those ‘boxes” where no limits are applied. 39<br />

Bound limits of domestic production subsidies (AMS) total $64 billion. However<br />

actual subsidization does not reach these limits. The utilization rate was 88 per cent in<br />

USA, 62 per cent in EU and 17 per cent in Japan. 40 Twenty nine WTO members have<br />

made AMS commitments. They are phrased in terms of overall payments, e.g. the<br />

European Community’s commitment is EUR 67 billion, that of the United States $19<br />

billion.<br />

“a primary agricultural product that is the predominant staple in the traditional diet of a developing<br />

country”. O nly Korea, the Philippines and Israel make use of this provision<br />

37 In practice not all countries have met the 5 per cent access commitment and the TRQs have been<br />

significantly under utilized.<br />

38 Stiglitz and Charlton, op. cit., pp. 217-234.<br />

39<br />

There is a concise description of the subsidy boxes on the WTO website at<br />

http://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/agric_e/agboxes_e.htm.<br />

40 See presentation by Ralf Peters UNCTAD at UNECA Ad Hoc Meeting on Agriculture, Tunis,<br />

November 2004, http://www.uneca.og/eca_programes/trade.<br />

33

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!