24.07.2014 Views

Governance, Growth, and Development Decision-making - School of ...

Governance, Growth, and Development Decision-making - School of ...

Governance, Growth, and Development Decision-making - School of ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

tutional prerequisites <strong>and</strong> one where they have been remarkably effective.<br />

A similar kind <strong>of</strong> institutionally-rich thinking has developed<br />

in a few other areas as well—as in education policy <strong>and</strong> in telecom<br />

regulation. But in many other areas, such thinking is either quite<br />

naïve or non-existent. I would cite trade policy <strong>and</strong> industrial policy<br />

as examples <strong>of</strong> the first <strong>and</strong> second categories, respectively. In trade<br />

policy, the long-st<strong>and</strong>ing advocacy by external advisors <strong>of</strong> uniform<br />

tariff rules (or <strong>of</strong> external commitments) is typically motivated by<br />

very poorly articulated political <strong>and</strong> institutional priors—basically<br />

lots <strong>of</strong> arm-waving. And in industrial policy, the dominant view—<br />

held essentially on a priori grounds—seems to be that the requisite<br />

institutional arrangement are impossible to design <strong>and</strong> implement,<br />

even when such a policy is desirable in principle.<br />

As the example <strong>of</strong> central banking shows, economists have a lot<br />

to contribute to thinking about such issues in specific policy areas.<br />

Their underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>of</strong> the substantive issues, their pr<strong>of</strong>essional<br />

obsession with incentives, <strong>and</strong> their eye for the unanticipated consequences<br />

give them a natural advantage in designing institutional<br />

arrangements to further the objectives in question while minimizing<br />

behavioral distortions. A certain amount <strong>of</strong> local knowledge<br />

is clearly indispensable here. Economists need to underst<strong>and</strong> the<br />

local context well enough to recognize the limits on the range <strong>of</strong><br />

possibilities <strong>and</strong> to anticipate the likely obstacles. But doing this in<br />

the context <strong>of</strong> relaxing a constraint in a particular policy area—be<br />

it monetary policy, trade policy, industrial policy, or education<br />

policy—seems to be me to be an order <strong>of</strong> magnitude simpler than<br />

designing wholesale legal reform or mounting an effective anti-corruption<br />

drive across the board. And as I have argued above, it is also<br />

more effective where growth is concerned.<br />

4. Avoiding the Best-practices Trap<br />

Designing appropriate institutional arrangements requires local<br />

knowledge <strong>and</strong> creativity. What works in one setting is unlikely to<br />

work in another. In a second-best, (i.e., real) world, the nature <strong>of</strong><br />

Dani Rodrik 21

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!