05.07.2014 Views

Heft36 1 - SFB 580 - Friedrich-Schiller-Universität Jena

Heft36 1 - SFB 580 - Friedrich-Schiller-Universität Jena

Heft36 1 - SFB 580 - Friedrich-Schiller-Universität Jena

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

(socialist legacy) and current factors (EU<br />

membership, policy choices, wars). Because<br />

many different variables are chosen to explain<br />

variety, sometimes one and the same country is<br />

put in different clusters of countries. Therefore,<br />

classification of countries depends strongly on<br />

the level of analysis (micro/macro level), the<br />

research design, the length of the study period<br />

and the sectors chosen (Deeg 2007; Deeg/<br />

Jackson 2007).<br />

b. No consistent relationship between economic<br />

performance and complementary institutions. The<br />

institutional trajectories of post-communist<br />

countries do not confirm a correlation of<br />

economic success and institutional system<br />

purity. On the one hand, countries with<br />

complementary institutions are economic<br />

frontrunners (Slovenia and Estonia) while<br />

countries with non-complementary institutions<br />

(most countries from SEE and the former<br />

Soviet Union) are economically less successful.<br />

On the other hand, there are mixed political<br />

economies with non-coherent institutions that<br />

are also economically successful (e.g. Poland,<br />

Czech Republic, Hungary).<br />

c. Unfinished transition process to capitalism. In<br />

most post-socialist countries, the transition<br />

towards a certain type of market economy is still<br />

unfinished and unsettled. Especially in South-<br />

Eastern Europe and former Soviet Republics,<br />

capitalist structures are underdeveloped and<br />

institutional enforcement is low. Therefore, it is<br />

difficult to classify these economies and predict<br />

which type of capitalism will emerge.<br />

does not capture the development of postcommunist<br />

transition countries because of the<br />

peculiarities of the former socialist societies<br />

(path dependent informal institutions, diverse<br />

communist legacies). As a result, scholars<br />

propose an extention of the CME and<br />

LME typologies and, with that, introduce<br />

additionally some “mixed type” or “hybrids<br />

of capitalism” (e.g. Bartlett 2007; Charman<br />

2007; Cernat 2006; Lane 2007a; King 2007).<br />

Moreover, Hall/Soskice’s VoC approach<br />

is extended by bringing in other actors<br />

(state, international organizations, political<br />

entrepreneurs, networks between economic<br />

actors) that bargain over institutional reforms<br />

under different political systems (authoritarian<br />

or repressive state) and are constrained by<br />

informal institutions and history. In summary,<br />

VoC literature on post-communist Europe<br />

claims that capitalist diversity cannot be<br />

explained solely by internal complementarities<br />

between institutional sub-systems and firms as<br />

the main actors. Instead, explaining capitalist<br />

diversity and institutional change must<br />

include diverse historical and future variables,<br />

which can be internal (national state, national<br />

interest groups, structural legacy) or external<br />

(EU, international organizations).<br />

Seite Page page 15<br />

d. Extension of VoC proposed. Most authors,<br />

especially those in the volume edited by Lane/<br />

Myant 2007, conclude that the VoC approach

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!