05.07.2014 Views

Heft36 1 - SFB 580 - Friedrich-Schiller-Universität Jena

Heft36 1 - SFB 580 - Friedrich-Schiller-Universität Jena

Heft36 1 - SFB 580 - Friedrich-Schiller-Universität Jena

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

WHAT CAPITALISM?<br />

SOCIO-ECONOMIC CHANGE IN<br />

CENTRAL EASTERN EUROPE.<br />

PROCEEDINGS OF THE WORKSHOP THE 29/30 OCTOBER 2009<br />

COLLABORATIVE RESEARCH CENTRE <strong>580</strong> IN COOPERATION WITH<br />

THE UNIVERSITY OF OSNABRÜCK, LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND<br />

THE OTTO-BRENNER FOUNDATION<br />

Agnieszka Cianciara, Péter Csizmadia, Alexandra Janovskaia,<br />

Alexandra Krause (Ed.), Kathrin Loer, Martin Mendelski, Abel Polese,<br />

Catherine Spieser, Ivett Szalma, Bernadett Szél, Vera Trappmann (Ed.),<br />

Lyudmyla Volynets<br />

<strong>SFB</strong> <strong>580</strong> MITTEILUNGEN 2010 36


36 <strong>SFB</strong> <strong>580</strong> MITTEILUNG<br />

Heft 36, August 2010<br />

Sonderforschungsbereich <strong>580</strong><br />

What Capitalism? Socio-Economic Change in Central Eastern Europe.<br />

Proceedings of the Workshop the 29/30 October 2009<br />

Collaborative Research Centre <strong>580</strong> in Cooperation with the University of Osnabrück,<br />

London School of Economics and the Otto-Brenner Foundation<br />

Sprecher:<br />

Prof. Dr. Everhard Holtmann<br />

Martin-Luther-<strong>Universität</strong> Halle-Wittenberg<br />

Institut für Politikwissenschaft und Japanologie<br />

06099 Halle (Saale)<br />

Verantwortlich für dieses Heft:<br />

Dr. Alexandra Krause<br />

<strong>Friedrich</strong>-<strong>Schiller</strong>-<strong>Universität</strong> <strong>Jena</strong><br />

Institut für Soziologie<br />

Carl-Zeiß-Straße 2<br />

07743 <strong>Jena</strong><br />

Tel.: +49 (0) 3641/ 945564<br />

Email: alexandra.krause@uni-jena.de<br />

Logo:<br />

Elisabeth Blum; Peter Neitzke (Zürich)<br />

Cover & Satz: Romana Lutzack<br />

Druck:<br />

<strong>Universität</strong> <strong>Jena</strong><br />

ISSN: 1619-6171<br />

Diese Arbeit ist im Sonderforschungsbereich <strong>580</strong> „Gesellschaftliche<br />

Entwicklungen nach dem Systemumbruch. Diskontinuität, Tradition und Strukturbildung“<br />

entstanden und wurde auf seine Veranlassung unter Verwendung<br />

der ihm von der Deutschen Forschungsgemeinschaft zur Verfügung gestellten<br />

Mittel gedruckt.<br />

Alle Rechte vorbehalten.


WHAT CAPITALISM?<br />

SOCIO-ECONOMIC CHANGE IN<br />

CENTRAL EASTERN EUROPE.<br />

PROCEEDINGS OF THE WORKSHOP<br />

THE 29/30 OCTOBER 2009<br />

COLLABORATIVE RESEARCH CENTRE <strong>580</strong> IN COOPERATION<br />

WITH THE UNIVERSITY OF OSNABRÜCK,<br />

LONDON SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND THE<br />

OTTO-BRENNER FOUNDATION


REFERENCES LITERATUR CONTENTS<br />

Chapters<br />

1<br />

Editorial<br />

Alexandra Krause, Vera Trappmann ...........6<br />

Varieties of Capitalism<br />

2<br />

3<br />

The Varieties of Capitalism Approach Goes East:<br />

Institutional Complementarities and Law Enforcement during<br />

Post-Communist Transition<br />

Martin Mendelski ...........8<br />

Polish business – politics relations and their impact on national<br />

lobbying at the EU level<br />

Agnieszka K. Cianciara ..........45<br />

Companies in transition<br />

4<br />

5<br />

Germans on their way East – Austrians staying at home<br />

Kathrin Loer ..........62<br />

Automotive MNCs in Central Europe: The enterprise as a<br />

source of competitive industrial capabilities<br />

Aleksandra Janovskaia ..........80<br />

Seite page 4


REFERENCES LITERATUR CONTENTS<br />

Chapters<br />

6<br />

Organisational Innovations in the Hungarian Knowledge-intensive<br />

Business Service Sector: Lessons from a Company Survey<br />

Péter Csizmadia .........103<br />

Welfare state and labour markets<br />

7<br />

8<br />

The politics of labour market adjustment in post-1989 Poland.<br />

Trajectory of policy reform, politics of social change and emerging<br />

welfare regime<br />

Catherine Spieser .........121<br />

Analysis of the Hungarian labour market by deliberative methods<br />

Szalma Ivett/Szel Bernadett .........155<br />

Welfare Insights from the Ukraine<br />

9<br />

At the origins of informal economies: some evidence from Ukraine<br />

(1991-2009)<br />

Abel Polese .........200<br />

10<br />

Industrial Relations and post-socialist transformation: the case<br />

of the Ukraine.<br />

Lyudmyla Volynets .........217<br />

Seite page 5<br />

Authors .........242


REFERENCES LITERATUR EDITORIAL<br />

EDITORIAL<br />

1<br />

Alexandra Krause and Vera Trappmann<br />

Seite page 6<br />

Twenty years after the fall of the<br />

Berlin wall, it is due time for a balance<br />

sheet of whether the transition from<br />

a planned economy to a market economy<br />

in Central and Eastern Europe has been<br />

accomplished or is still under way - in both<br />

cases, we would like to know what economic<br />

system has emerged. The workshop held at the<br />

<strong>Friedrich</strong>-<strong>Schiller</strong> University in <strong>Jena</strong> in October<br />

2009 brought together researchers offering<br />

answers to this question. The approach was<br />

two-fold. First, we had empirical contributions<br />

of young scholars, two of which focused on<br />

Poland, Hungary and the Ukraine, respectively,<br />

whereas two additional contributions analysed<br />

offshoring and management strategies in<br />

the automobile industry from a comparative<br />

perspective. Altogether, these papers provide<br />

evidence of the variety of capitalism in the<br />

region. Diversity, in terms of the level of<br />

modernization and market regulation achieved,<br />

is still large. Moreover, the Ukraine is not at<br />

the same level as the Visegrad four, even<br />

considering the level of corruption or informal<br />

economy alone. This finding, however, provokes<br />

the question of how to deal with this variety? Is<br />

it mirrored at other world regions? Do some<br />

countries resemble those in Western Europe?<br />

How do we explain variety among the extransition<br />

countries, in terms of different elite<br />

constellations, as Eyal, Szeleny and King have<br />

suggested, or path dependencies or the varying<br />

influence of foreign direct investments?<br />

Therefore, in a second step, we had conceptual<br />

contributions that attempted to assess whether<br />

the emergent capitalisms and the ongoing<br />

social changes in the region can still be best<br />

analyzed by transformation theory or whether<br />

the region has become affluent of a particular


ALEXANDRA KRAUSE, REFERENCES LITERATUR VERA TRAPPMANN<br />

theory. Assuming the latter, we invited experts<br />

in the field to elaborate on existing analytical<br />

paradigms for socio-economic change and<br />

examine their adaptability to Central Eastern<br />

Europe.<br />

Professor Elena Iankova fom Cornell University<br />

dealt with the VoC paradigm and industrial<br />

relations; Professor Lawrence King from<br />

Cambridge University presented neoclassical<br />

sociology arguing for a re-evaluation of the<br />

role of the state in economic change in CEE;<br />

and Professor Christoph Köhler from <strong>Jena</strong><br />

discussed the challenge-and-response approach<br />

developed by the Collaborative Research<br />

Centre <strong>580</strong>.<br />

The event was part of a series of workshops<br />

for post-graduates and early career researchers<br />

studying Central and Eastern Europe.<br />

The network of these young scholars is<br />

supported by the Otto Brenner Foundation<br />

and benefits from the generosity of the<br />

various host institutions. While in the past<br />

the London School of Econmics, under the<br />

head of Aleksandra Janovskaia, organized the<br />

meetings, we are very grateful of the support<br />

of the <strong>SFB</strong> <strong>580</strong> for the meeting in 2009, which<br />

was organized by two <strong>SFB</strong> projects dealing, in<br />

particular, with Central and Eastern Europe.<br />

The A2 project compares economic elites in<br />

Poland and Hungary with those in Germany,<br />

while B2 compares employment relationships<br />

in Russia with Germany. The workshop in 2010<br />

will take place at Osnabrück University. The<br />

following workshop is planned in Bratislava. If<br />

any of the readers feels inspired by this project,<br />

please do not hesitate to host one of the future<br />

workshops!<br />

Finally, we must say that it has been extremely<br />

fruitful to engage the young researchers in a<br />

dialogue with the senior researchers of the<br />

field, who participated in the workshop. We,<br />

therefore, would particularly like to thank<br />

Katharina Bluhm, Elena Iankova, Lawrence<br />

King and Christoph Köhler for their helpful<br />

comments and a lively debate.<br />

We are even more fortunate to be able to<br />

present the empirical workshop contributions<br />

here to a broader audience and would like to<br />

thank all authors for revising their papers for<br />

this publication.<br />

Seite page 7


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

THE VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM APPROACH<br />

GOES EAST:<br />

INSTITUTIONAL COMPLEMENTARITIES AND<br />

LAW ENFORCEMENT DURING POST-COMMU-<br />

NIST TRANSITION<br />

Martin Mendelski<br />

2<br />

The Varieties of Capitalism (VoC) approach<br />

is a popular paradigm used to<br />

explain the institutional diversity and<br />

economic performance in developed market<br />

economies. Does the VoC approach also have<br />

explanatory power for post-communist economies<br />

from Central and Eastern Europe and the<br />

former Soviet Union? This guiding question<br />

will be answered by analyzing the role of institutional<br />

complementarities and coordination<br />

for institutional diversity and development. It<br />

is argued that, while the VoC approach can<br />

serve as an analytical framework of analysis<br />

and in parts as a tool for classifying transition<br />

economies regarding their modes of coordination,<br />

it is less suited to explain the process of<br />

path-dependent and volatile institutional development<br />

in most transition countries because<br />

of its static perspective and the negligence of<br />

enforcement. Therefore, the VoC approach can<br />

be applied only restrictively to post-communist<br />

economies.<br />

1. INTRODUCTION<br />

Seite Page page 8<br />

With the accession into the EU, transition<br />

seems to be over for most post-communist<br />

countries. Remaining work is to be done in<br />

Central Asia and South-Eastern Europe (SEE),<br />

where transition has not yet come to an end. A<br />

comparison of countries from SEE, Central<br />

Eastern Europe (CEE) and Central Asia on<br />

the basis of selected institutional indicators (e.g.<br />

EBRD transition indicators 1989-2007; World<br />

Bank governance indicators, 1996-2007) reveals<br />

dissimilar institutional trajectories during the<br />

last two decades. According to the average


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

transition score in the EBRD 2006 report,<br />

countries from SEE (except Bulgaria, Croatia<br />

and Romania) and the former Soviet Union<br />

still lag behind the development of the CEECs<br />

and the Baltic States (see EBRD 2006). So why<br />

do institutional quality and reform progress<br />

differ between post-communist countries?<br />

What accounts for persisting differences of<br />

institutional systems?<br />

Research on institutional diversity is addressed<br />

by scholars of the VoC literature (Albert 1993;<br />

Whitley 1999; Hall/Soskice 2001; Amable 2003;<br />

Crouch 2005). The VoC approach, elaborated<br />

most prominently by Hall and Soskice 2001,<br />

sees institutional complementarities behind<br />

the persisting institutional and organizational<br />

diversity of developed Western countries.<br />

Hall and Soskice emphasize limited diversity<br />

of capitalism (institutional diversity) and<br />

limited ways to economic success (comparative<br />

advantage/economic growth). The reason for<br />

limited diversity can be found in complementary<br />

institutions, i.e. mutual enhancing institutions,<br />

which leave basically two possibilities for the<br />

coordination of economic activities, via market<br />

and non-market relationships (Hall and<br />

Soskice 2001, p.8).<br />

The VoC approach has mainly been applied<br />

to developed Western countries and has<br />

only recently been extended to countries<br />

from CEE, SEE and Central Asia (Hancke/<br />

Rhodes/Thatcher 2007; Lane/Myant 2007).<br />

Scholars who apply the VoC approach to<br />

post-communist countries attempt to explain<br />

institutional diversity (type of emerging<br />

capitalism) and institutional development<br />

during transition. They do so by grouping<br />

post-communist countries into successful<br />

and less successful clusters, by comparing<br />

selected countries in qualitative case studies<br />

or by analyzing single countries. Dynamic<br />

comparative studies including all transition<br />

countries are rare (Knell/Srholec 2007) and<br />

the recent application of the VoC approach to<br />

post-communist countries seems to have only<br />

explanatory power for the most successful<br />

transition countries such as Slovenia and<br />

Estonia (Feldmann 2007; Buchen 2007).<br />

What makes it so difficult to extend the<br />

approach to other post-communist countries<br />

from the region? Unfinished transition in<br />

several states and methodological difficulties<br />

(missing data, comparability of data) could<br />

be part of the answer, but there are additional<br />

reasons, as well.<br />

This paper’s aim is to explore these reasons why<br />

the VoC approach has only limited explanatory<br />

power in post-communist countries.<br />

Particularly, the question should be answered<br />

whether certain VoC concepts (institutional<br />

complementarity, coordination concept) can<br />

be helpful in explaining institutional diversity<br />

and institutional development during postcommunist<br />

transition. The basic argument of<br />

the paper is that the creation of institutional<br />

complementarities is more difficult to achieve<br />

under conditions of transition (i.e. uncertain<br />

environmental conditions, changing power<br />

relations of diverse actors, capacity restrictions)<br />

than under conditions of stability,<br />

prevailing in developed countries.<br />

Such difficult transition conditions Seite Page page 9<br />

as well as persisting institutions from<br />

the past make the enforcement of<br />

new formal institutions difficult and require a<br />

cautious application of the VoC to transition<br />

economies.


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

The outline of this paper is as follows. The<br />

next section gives an overview of the literature<br />

attempting to apply the VoC to post-communist<br />

economies. The third section elaborates the<br />

limits and possibilities of the VoC approach<br />

to explain divergent transition outcomes. In<br />

this section, I will attempt to reveal whether<br />

the concept of institutional complementarity<br />

and that of pure types of coordination are<br />

helpful in the transition context. I argue<br />

that, in general, the VoC approach can be<br />

useful as a framework of analysis, but that its<br />

application in the transition context also has<br />

certain limits. In particular, I identify three<br />

limitations (uncertainty resulting from a<br />

changing environment, diversity of actors, lack<br />

of capacity) that restrict the ex ante design of a<br />

complementary institutional system. In the last<br />

section, I will conclude that the VoC approach<br />

is less suitable to explain institutional quality<br />

and diversity during transition and, therefore,<br />

is restrictively applicable to the still evolving<br />

capitalist systems in most post-communist<br />

countries.<br />

2. VARIETIES OF CAPITALISM AND POST-COM-<br />

MUNIST TRANSITION (LITERATURE OVERVIEW)<br />

Before giving an overview of the VoC literature<br />

focusing on post-communist countries,<br />

some basic differences must be kept in mind<br />

when comparing capitalist systems.<br />

By considering four types of capitalist<br />

classification (coordination, re-<br />

Seite Page page 10<br />

gionalism/nationalism, development<br />

stage, origin), the deeper underlying<br />

assumptions and sources of capitalist diversity<br />

should become clearer.<br />

A first possibility to distinguish among<br />

capitalist systems is to classify them according<br />

to regional and national characteristics. This<br />

popular typology is based on similar national<br />

or regional logics of organization, which are<br />

related to socio-cultural and geographic factors.<br />

Forms of regional developed capitalist systems<br />

were labeled Scandinavian, East Asian, Latin<br />

American or Mediterranean capitalism. National<br />

typologies of capitalism are, for instance, British,<br />

Dutch, Prussian, American and Japanese. Most<br />

of these national and regional categories refer<br />

to developed economies; and only recently have<br />

scholars begun to label the evolving forms of<br />

capitalism among post-communist countries<br />

as East European Capitalism (Stark 1996;<br />

Iankova 2002), Central European Capitalism<br />

(Lawrence/King 2007), Russian capitalism<br />

(Woodruff 1999) or post-soviet capitalism<br />

(Tholen 2005, p. 228). 1<br />

A second method to classify capitalism is<br />

according to the dominant logic of coordination<br />

(e.g. Hall/Soskice 2001). Scholars focusing on<br />

different modes of coordination between subsystems<br />

of the political economy identified<br />

liberal market economies (LMEs), where<br />

firms coordinate via competitive market<br />

arrangements, coordinated market economies<br />

(CMEs), where firms interact strategically<br />

with other actors via non-market relationships,<br />

and mixed market economies (MMEs), which<br />

face high state intervention on the supply side<br />

(Hall/Gingerich 2004, p. 17).<br />

A third criterion of classification is the degree<br />

of “capitalism ripeness”, i.e. the stage in capitalist<br />

development. This criterion makes more sense<br />

to distinguish between evolving capitalism in<br />

post-communist and developed capitalism


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

in the West. Developed economies, which<br />

have already reached a certain level of stable<br />

and settled market economy, possess a more<br />

developed and settled form of capitalism<br />

than post-communist economies, which are<br />

still building their economic and institutional<br />

systems. Given the different stages of<br />

development between the developed West<br />

and the lagging East, it is not surprising that<br />

there is a different organizational logic in postcommunist<br />

countries. This special logic in postcommunist<br />

countries is driven by institutional<br />

and economic catch-up strategies in still young<br />

and evolving capitalist systems. Nevertheless,<br />

the degree of capitalism ripeness differs even<br />

among post-communist countries. On the one<br />

hand, very advanced frontrunners (Estonia,<br />

Slovenia) have already established clear and<br />

settled institutional structures and are classified<br />

in the Hall/Soskice framework as either LME’s<br />

or CME’s. On the other hand, laggards from<br />

South-Eastern Europe, Central Asia and the<br />

Caucasus are still constructing and improving<br />

their institutional system. Under such transitory<br />

conditions, their still unsettled institutional<br />

system does not allow for a classification in<br />

Hall/Soskice’s framework. However, even the<br />

situation of stable but mixed type of capitalism<br />

in the Visegrad States makes categorization<br />

difficult and would imply a need for additional<br />

criteria describing capitalist variety.<br />

A fourth method to classify capitalist systems<br />

is according to their origin. Basically, two<br />

forms are possible, internally or externally<br />

driven capitalism. Internally driven capitalism<br />

indicates a domestic and gradual development<br />

of capitalist institutions over time. Successful<br />

Western capitalist systems were developed<br />

internally (e.g. in USA, Great Britain, Prussia)<br />

and formal institutions could be adjusted to<br />

local conditions. In contrast, externally induced<br />

capitalism stands for imported capitalist<br />

institutions from abroad. Such institutional<br />

transfers based on Western models occurred in<br />

CEE after the end of Habsburg domination at<br />

the turn of the 19 th century and again after the<br />

end of communism in the 1990s. Institutional<br />

development in the CEECs has been based on<br />

the imitation of technological or organizational<br />

leaders from the West, characterized by<br />

institutional or economic catch-up strategies<br />

and institutional recombination (Stark 1996)<br />

leading to an institutional patch-work system.<br />

According to the VoC literature, such mixed<br />

systems should not be very successful (Hall/<br />

Soskice 2001; Cernat 2006).<br />

Which criterion matters most to explain postcommunist<br />

capitalist diversity? Is it possible to<br />

apply Hall/Soskice’s VoC framework to postcommunist<br />

economies? Before trying to answer<br />

these questions myself, I would like to give an<br />

overview of what other scholars have written<br />

so far. Literature related to the application<br />

of VoC in post-communist countries can be<br />

divided into four kinds of analyses: single<br />

country case studies, comparative case studies,<br />

static comparative analysis and dynamic<br />

comparative analysis.<br />

Single country case studies focus on institutional<br />

development in a single country<br />

(see Charman 2007; Christophe<br />

2007; Myant 2007; Hanson/Teague; Seite Page page 11<br />

Korosteleva 2007). While this<br />

frequent approach, conducted as a<br />

qualitative case study, is able to reveal complex<br />

agency-structure relationships over time, it<br />

does not allow one to identify the sources


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

of capitalist divergence at a general level of<br />

analysis.<br />

Another popular method to study VoC is the<br />

comparative case study of few selected countries<br />

(Mykhnenko 2007; Feldmann 2007; Buchen<br />

2007; King 2007). Although this approach<br />

allows for institutional change over time,<br />

generalized findings are not possible, as only few<br />

CEECs are compared. However, this approach<br />

requires detailed information and sufficient<br />

data for a thorough qualitative analysis. For<br />

lagging post-communist countries data is<br />

still not available. Another problem is that<br />

most data is not standardized and, therefore,<br />

difficult to compare. Thus, researchers prefer<br />

to focus on countries where distinct structures<br />

of capitalism are clearly discernible such as<br />

Estonia and Slovenia. Other country studies<br />

(on SEE and Central Asia) are rare, mainly<br />

because their institutional systems are still<br />

evolving and data is difficult to obtain.<br />

In static comparative analysis of a larger group of<br />

countries, different indicators (e.g. state control,<br />

proportion of FDI, stock market capitalization)<br />

are compared at a certain point in time (Lane<br />

2007). The authors of such studies are able<br />

to identify diversity among post-communist<br />

countries in terms of institutional and socioeconomic<br />

indicators. Although these broad<br />

studies provide an overview of the current<br />

situation and enable the grouping<br />

of countries into clusters, their<br />

Seite Page page 12<br />

snapshot approach does not capture<br />

the dynamics of institutional change.<br />

Therefore, important dynamics, such<br />

as the transfer from one type of capitalism<br />

to another, are overlooked. Such changes in<br />

institutional and organizational structures are<br />

especially likely in transition countries where<br />

structures are still developing, enforcement is<br />

weak and complementarities seem to be not yet<br />

developed. A static comparison brings about<br />

the danger of overlooking important changes<br />

and, therefore, incorrectly classifying postcommunist<br />

transition countries.<br />

A sophisticated approach to consider<br />

institutional change and capitalist transfer is<br />

dynamic comparative analysis (Knell/Srholec<br />

2007; Paunescu/Schneider 2004). These studies<br />

compare several countries over time and are able<br />

to capture dynamics and change to a certain<br />

extent, but unfortunately are quite rare. Because<br />

of data and comparability constraints, dynamic<br />

comparative studies of CEE often consider<br />

few countries (e.g. Paunescu/Schneider 2004<br />

consider just three CEECs) and only a short<br />

period of time (Knell/Srholec 2007 analyze the<br />

period 2001-2004). If the problem of obtaining<br />

and comparing data could be overcome, dynamic<br />

comparative studies are most promising for the<br />

analysis of capitalist diversity.


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

Table 1. Summary of VoC literature on post-communist countries<br />

Publication<br />

Lane/<br />

Myant 2007<br />

(edited<br />

volume)<br />

Conclusion<br />

Lane: Most post-communist economies have a high state control, a high proportion of<br />

foreign direct investment and a low market capitalization. Three types of capitalism are<br />

identified: Continental type, hybrid state/market uncoordinated type, non-capitalist type.<br />

Knell/Srholec: The diversity of production regimes is measured. Most post-socialist economies<br />

have liberal welfare systems (except SLO, BLR, BIH, CZ), coordinate business<br />

regulation (except RUS, LIT, HU, EST) and mixed forms of labor market regulation<br />

(period: 2001-2004). The difference of post-communist capitalist models is attributed to<br />

historical legacy.<br />

Buchen: The VoC approach is used to identify what kind of capitalism has been emerging<br />

in Estonia (LME) and Slovenia (CME), two post-communist countries with high degrees<br />

of complementary institutions.<br />

Myant: The Czech capitalist system shows institutional features of LMEs (wage bargaining)<br />

and CMEs (social policy). The hybrid Czech system is not a consequence of<br />

institutional complementarities, but the result of diverse interests and political compromises<br />

(government, management and foreign firms’ interests), the need to comply with EU<br />

membership conditions, the legal heritage and state budget constraints. The VoC approach<br />

needs modification in order to be applied in the case of the Czech Republic.<br />

Hanson/Teague: The VoC approach is not useful to explain Russia’s capitalist development<br />

as still many features of developed capitalism (financial system, independent judiciary,<br />

government efficiency) are lacking and other explaining factors must be considered<br />

(important role of the state, natural resources, international market integration, informal<br />

institutions). The VoC criteria which are applied to assess Russia produce a misleading<br />

picture and mask the economic role of the state.<br />

Charman: Kazakhstan has a still an unsettled dual-type economic structure (“state led<br />

liberal economy”) resulting from two parallel developments (LME focus and hegemonic<br />

role of the state).<br />

Christophe: The VoC paradigm is difficult to apply in Georgia because the transfer of contradicting<br />

institutions from abroad (Germany, USA) has resulted in a non-complementary<br />

institutional system, because institutional subsystems (e.g. capital market, welfare system)<br />

are still underdeveloped and formal institutions are rarely enforced.<br />

Bartlett: The application of the VoC approach is difficult. War-torn Western Balkans<br />

relied on policy and institutional transfer from different international organizations, which<br />

created non-complementary institutions. Additionally, the strong reliance on informal<br />

institutions makes capitalism classification difficult. An attempt of classification is made:<br />

Continental European model (Croatia, Macedonia), LME with strong influence of informal<br />

institutions/organized crime (Albania, Kosovo), Mediterranean model with informal<br />

economy/black market activities (Serbia, Montenegro, Bosnia and Herzegovina).<br />

Seite Page page 13<br />

Korosteleva: Belarus does not fit in conventional VoC type classifications and is considered<br />

to be a “state capitalist economy” (state ownership, state control over the economy, price<br />

controls and elements of market economy).


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

Hancke/<br />

Rhodes/<br />

Thatcher<br />

2007<br />

(edited<br />

volume)<br />

King: The VoC can be applied to CEE as a framework of analysis, but it has to consider<br />

post-communist similarities (importance of backwardness, lack of working-class pressure)<br />

which are more important than the respective differences in terms of VoC typology. Two<br />

expanded typologies, “liberal dependent capitalism” in Hungary and Poland and “patrimonial<br />

capitalism” in Russia, are identified as a consequence of dependency conditions<br />

in the former (dependency on FDI and technology transfer, lack of domestic banks and<br />

stock markets, denationalized vocational training) and patrimonial network structures in<br />

the latter, resulting from financial crisis.<br />

Feldmann: The VoC approach is applied successfully to explain institutional diversity in<br />

Slovenia and Estonia. Diversity is explained by a different degree of old networks between<br />

economic actors, which were built under socialism and influenced by policy choices during<br />

transition (e.g. mode of privatization).<br />

Mykhnenko: Poland and Ukraine are institutional hybrids (mixed market economies)<br />

which can function successfully and escape predetermined trajectories. No complementarity<br />

effects between science/technology education system and revealed comparative trade<br />

advantage are detected. As institutional and organizational factors explain only a part of<br />

macroeconomic performance of post-communist countries, there is a need to integrate<br />

exogenous factors (internationalization, globalization, Europeanization) into the national<br />

state-oriented VoC approach.<br />

Cernat<br />

2006<br />

In the Romanian case, the inconsistent mixture of domestic and external institutions<br />

(“cocktail capitalism”) explains poor economic performance during post-communist transition.<br />

Bohle/<br />

Greskovits<br />

2007<br />

The VoC approach is difficult to apply to Eastern Europe as institutions are still not<br />

consolidated. Four types of capitalist systems, based on institutional configurations and<br />

performances are identified: state crafted neoliberalism of the Baltic States, world-market<br />

driven neoliberalism of the CIS countries, embedded neoliberalism of the Visegrád countries,<br />

and neo-corporatism in Slovenia. Capitalist diversity is explained by differences in<br />

external factors and state capacity.<br />

Paunescu/<br />

Schneider<br />

2004<br />

Crowley<br />

2008<br />

Several OECD countries moved towards the liberal market model in a relatively short period<br />

of time (1990-1999). Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic have mixed systems.<br />

The VoC framework is successfully applied to assess the type of capitalism which has<br />

developed in CEE, particularly in the sphere of industrial relations (labor). However, the<br />

VoC logic fails to explain the outcome in this sphere because it neglects the role of labor (its<br />

absence and presence), the state and international actors as the main drivers of change.<br />

Source: Own elaboration.<br />

Seite Page page 14<br />

Table 1 gives an overview of conclusions<br />

on the VoC studies in postcommunist<br />

countries. On the basis<br />

of these conclusions, four summarizing statements<br />

are made:<br />

a. Variety defined in most studies based on postsocialist<br />

economies. However, this variety often<br />

refers to the stage of institutional and economic<br />

development (e.g. FDI proportion, stock<br />

market capitalization, privatization proportion),<br />

which is explained as an outcome of historical


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

(socialist legacy) and current factors (EU<br />

membership, policy choices, wars). Because<br />

many different variables are chosen to explain<br />

variety, sometimes one and the same country is<br />

put in different clusters of countries. Therefore,<br />

classification of countries depends strongly on<br />

the level of analysis (micro/macro level), the<br />

research design, the length of the study period<br />

and the sectors chosen (Deeg 2007; Deeg/<br />

Jackson 2007).<br />

b. No consistent relationship between economic<br />

performance and complementary institutions. The<br />

institutional trajectories of post-communist<br />

countries do not confirm a correlation of<br />

economic success and institutional system<br />

purity. On the one hand, countries with<br />

complementary institutions are economic<br />

frontrunners (Slovenia and Estonia) while<br />

countries with non-complementary institutions<br />

(most countries from SEE and the former<br />

Soviet Union) are economically less successful.<br />

On the other hand, there are mixed political<br />

economies with non-coherent institutions that<br />

are also economically successful (e.g. Poland,<br />

Czech Republic, Hungary).<br />

c. Unfinished transition process to capitalism. In<br />

most post-socialist countries, the transition<br />

towards a certain type of market economy is still<br />

unfinished and unsettled. Especially in South-<br />

Eastern Europe and former Soviet Republics,<br />

capitalist structures are underdeveloped and<br />

institutional enforcement is low. Therefore, it is<br />

difficult to classify these economies and predict<br />

which type of capitalism will emerge.<br />

does not capture the development of postcommunist<br />

transition countries because of the<br />

peculiarities of the former socialist societies<br />

(path dependent informal institutions, diverse<br />

communist legacies). As a result, scholars<br />

propose an extention of the CME and<br />

LME typologies and, with that, introduce<br />

additionally some “mixed type” or “hybrids<br />

of capitalism” (e.g. Bartlett 2007; Charman<br />

2007; Cernat 2006; Lane 2007a; King 2007).<br />

Moreover, Hall/Soskice’s VoC approach<br />

is extended by bringing in other actors<br />

(state, international organizations, political<br />

entrepreneurs, networks between economic<br />

actors) that bargain over institutional reforms<br />

under different political systems (authoritarian<br />

or repressive state) and are constrained by<br />

informal institutions and history. In summary,<br />

VoC literature on post-communist Europe<br />

claims that capitalist diversity cannot be<br />

explained solely by internal complementarities<br />

between institutional sub-systems and firms as<br />

the main actors. Instead, explaining capitalist<br />

diversity and institutional change must<br />

include diverse historical and future variables,<br />

which can be internal (national state, national<br />

interest groups, structural legacy) or external<br />

(EU, international organizations).<br />

Seite Page page 15<br />

d. Extension of VoC proposed. Most authors,<br />

especially those in the volume edited by Lane/<br />

Myant 2007, conclude that the VoC approach


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

3. THE POSSIBILITIES AND LIMITS OF THE VOC<br />

APPROACH TO EXPLAIN INSTITUTIONAL DIVER-<br />

SITY AND INSTITUTIONAL DEVELOPMENT DURI-<br />

NG TRANSITION<br />

3.1 The possibilities of the VoC approach in<br />

the analysis of transition economies<br />

Despite the critiques and the need of the<br />

extension mentioned in the previous section,<br />

the analyzed literature gives several ideas of<br />

how the VoC approach can be applied to postcommunist<br />

economies.<br />

First, the VoC approach can serve as an<br />

analytical framework to classify economic<br />

institutions in post-communist countries. It<br />

can serve as a point of departure for ex post<br />

analysis. Therefore, it can help to conduct<br />

descriptive and explanatory research. Indeed,<br />

several researchers have employed the VoC<br />

approach as an analytical framework in their<br />

comparative case studies of post-communist<br />

countries (e.g. Crowley 2008; Buchen 2007;<br />

Mykhnenko 2007; Feldmann 2007; Knell/<br />

Srholec 2007).<br />

Second, by shifting the focus of attention to<br />

coordination and complementarity between<br />

institutional sub-systems, the VoC approach<br />

opens up a fruitful perspective from which the<br />

transition process can be analyzed. The study<br />

of institutional complementarities<br />

and their relationship with economic<br />

Seite Page page 16<br />

performance has been widely<br />

neglected in the transition literature.<br />

Given its relational perspective on the<br />

outcomes of complementary institutions, the<br />

VoC approach could help to refocus transition<br />

research on complementarity aspects. Studies<br />

which analyze complementarity in transition<br />

economies (e.g. Knell/Srholec 2007; Buchen<br />

2007) are rare and there is still much potential<br />

for future research.<br />

Third, to put the firm’s behavior into the focus<br />

of attention can be a refreshing counterbalance<br />

to the strong emphasis of the state (and its role<br />

in reform strategies) by transition researchers.<br />

Considering the firm as an important<br />

actor during transition shifts attention to<br />

important long-term drivers of economic<br />

growth such as innovation, technology,<br />

research & development, cooperation and<br />

skills. Although Hall/Soskice’s approach sees<br />

firm behavior as an outcome of institutional<br />

structure, an extended version of the VoC to<br />

post-communist economies should consider<br />

–besides the supply side of institutional change<br />

(state, international actors)– the demand side as<br />

well, i.e. firms’ pressure for institutional reforms<br />

and particularly, the influence of foreign firms<br />

on institutional and organizational change (see<br />

King 2007; UNECE 2001, p. 186).<br />

To sum up, the VoC approach can function as a<br />

reference model of an ideal type of coordination<br />

between different institutional sub-systems and<br />

the firm. Such a model shows the researcher<br />

how a capitalist system should look, i.e. which<br />

institutions it should contain and how the<br />

relationships between those institutions should<br />

be. Applying the VoC approach to understand<br />

the relationships between institutional subsystems<br />

can be useful in explaining what<br />

kind of market economy has evolved in postcommunist<br />

countries. Given its theoretical<br />

and conceptual strength, Drahokoupil argues<br />

that the VoC approach “seems to fill the<br />

theoretical vacuum left by the death of the


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

‘transition’ debate in the political economic<br />

research on Central and Eastern Europe” and<br />

provides a “major post-transition research<br />

agenda” (Drahokoupil 2008, forthcoming). At<br />

the same time, the uncritical and mechanical<br />

application of the concepts and preconditions<br />

of the VoC to post-communist countries can<br />

also be misleading (Bohle/Greskovits 2007;<br />

Drahokoupil 2008, forthcoming). In the next<br />

two sections I will share this critical view and<br />

describe some limitations of the VoC approach<br />

when applied to post-communist transition<br />

countries.<br />

3.2 The limits of institutional<br />

complementarities in the transition context<br />

How useful is the VoC approach to explain<br />

divergent institutional development trajectories<br />

during transition? I will try to answer this<br />

question by focusing first on institutional<br />

complementarity, the central concept of Hall/<br />

Soskice’s approach. According to Hall and<br />

Soskice, institutions are complementary “if<br />

the presence (or efficiency) of one increases<br />

the returns from (or efficiency) of the other”<br />

(Hall/Soskice 2001, p. 17). 2 Institutional<br />

complementarities are basically positive synergy<br />

effects, i.e. they create additional efficiency 3 for<br />

institutional performance. In a short formula<br />

we can portray institutional complementarity<br />

as follows:<br />

efficiency (institution A + institution B) ><br />

efficiency (institution A) + efficiency (institution<br />

B)<br />

As this formula shows, institutions are<br />

complementary if the combined efficiency of<br />

two institutions is larger than the efficiency<br />

of the single efficiencies, i.e. if the left side<br />

of the equation has a higher value than the<br />

right side. The main message of institutional<br />

complementary is that institutions are<br />

not only important alone, but also in their<br />

composition.<br />

Hall/Soskice are mainly interested in<br />

complementarities between institutional subsystems<br />

of the political economy (education<br />

and vocational training, corporate governance,<br />

inter-company-relations, industrial relations). 4<br />

Complementarity between these spheres will<br />

lead to limited clusters of capitalist systems.<br />

Political economies can be classified according<br />

the modes in which firms resolve coordination<br />

problems, namely via corporate hierarchies<br />

and market relationships (LMEs) or via<br />

non-market modes of coordination (CMEs),<br />

such as relational contracting, networks,<br />

associations and collaborative relationships<br />

and strategic interaction with other actors<br />

(Hall/ Soskice 2001, p. 8-10). Typically, LMEs<br />

are exemplified by the organizational system<br />

of the United States and CMEs by that of<br />

Germany. Developed economies, which lie<br />

between these two ideal poles of coordination,<br />

are identified as non-complementary, mixed<br />

systems (France and other Mediterranean<br />

economies). Hall/Soskice assume that in the<br />

long-run complementary institutions are more<br />

efficient than non-complementary ones and,<br />

therefore, advise that “nations with<br />

a particular type of coordination in<br />

one sphere of the economy should Seite Page page 17<br />

tend to develop complementary<br />

practices in other spheres as well”<br />

(Hall/Sockice 2001, p. 18). In an empirical<br />

study, Hall/Gingerich confirm the theoretical<br />

assumptions of limited diversity as well as the


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

correlation of complementarity with economic<br />

performance in developed economies (Hall/<br />

Gingerich 2004). Kenworthy, however, does<br />

not find such a correlation and questions the<br />

importance of institutional complementarity<br />

for economic success (Kenworthy 2006).<br />

Despite such diverse empirical results, why<br />

should institutional complementarities be so<br />

important for the functioning of institutional<br />

systems? According to Roland, institutional<br />

systems are not interchangable “modular<br />

constructions”. Rather, they complement each<br />

other, meaning that “replacing one institution by<br />

another can in some cases dangerously disrupt<br />

this systemic consistency” (Roland 2004, p.<br />

113). Such disruptions of the institutional<br />

coherence are not desirable if the system is<br />

performing well economically. However, if<br />

a country loses its institutional comparative<br />

advantage -for instance, due to changing<br />

environmental circumstances- institutional<br />

reforms are greatly required. In this case,<br />

complementary institutions become a burden<br />

because they are more resistant to change than<br />

non-complementary ones (Greif 1998, p. 82;<br />

Jackson/Deeg 2006, p. 37). Disrupting coherent<br />

but socially inefficient institutions is especially<br />

required when system complementarity is<br />

sustained by “brute force” (Mayntz 2007, p. 20)<br />

and provides sole benefits to a small predatory<br />

group (e.g. for the nomenklatura during the<br />

communism).<br />

Seite Page page 18<br />

The 1990s fundamental institutional<br />

reforms, known as post-communist<br />

transition, were a rapid disruption of<br />

an inefficient but coherent communist system. 5<br />

But did institutional complementarities<br />

play a role during this period of system<br />

transformation? I will try to answer this<br />

question by analyzing the extent of conscious<br />

ex ante design versus spontaneous, ex-post<br />

emergence of complementary institutions<br />

during transition. These two possibilities of<br />

conducting institutional reforms are grounded<br />

in two views about institutional change:<br />

institutions by design vs. institutions by<br />

bricolage.<br />

Institutions by design: This view of conscious<br />

design of institutions is reflected in rationalist<br />

theories, such as property rights theory or<br />

rational choice theory (see Williamson 1985;<br />

Demsetz 1967; Shepsle 1989; Calvert 1995).<br />

According to this actor-centered approach,<br />

rational individuals construct and change<br />

institutions on the basis of cost-benefit<br />

calculations. This approach presupposes the<br />

existence of non-selfish designers 6 who are<br />

powerful enough to create efficient institutions.<br />

Transition scholars who follow the design<br />

approach believe that institutions and legacies<br />

from the past can be overcome by adequate<br />

institutional and policy choices ( Johnson 2003,<br />

p. 290). They assume that after getting rid of<br />

formal communist institutions (tabula rasa<br />

approach) and designing the new system on<br />

Western models a successful transition could be<br />

achieved. Therefore, they favor radical reforms,<br />

in the form of “big bang” institutional change<br />

(Sachs 1993; Aslund 1991; Boycko 1992;<br />

Przeworski 1991; Lipton and Sachs 1990).<br />

These authors believe that “big bang reforms”<br />

(i. e. simultaneous liberalization, privatization<br />

and restructuring) are more effective than<br />

piecemeal gradual reforms, as they benefit<br />

from complementarities between different<br />

policies and institutions. Partial reforms,<br />

instead, would eliminate the positive effects


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

of complementarities (Murphy et al. 1992;<br />

Gates et al. 1993) and lead to rent-seeking<br />

and corruption (Havrylyshyn 2007, p. 3). The<br />

prevailing credo of the design view in the<br />

transition context is the introduction of market<br />

economy in one stroke.<br />

Institutions by bricolage (trial-error): This<br />

evolutionary and structure-based view<br />

reflects the ideas of Austrian scholars such as<br />

Menger or Hayek, who see social order not<br />

as the outcome of conscious design but of<br />

spontaneous and unintended human action<br />

(see Ahrens 2002, p.60; Poznanski 1996).<br />

According to this view, historical legacies can<br />

constrain rational institutional design and<br />

produce unintended outcomes (Goodin 1996,<br />

p. 28). Institutional change and institutional<br />

complementarity are endogenous, i.e. driven<br />

by internal dynamics. They are the results of<br />

experimentation, bricolage and learning under<br />

a constantly changing environment (Stark/<br />

Bruszt 1998; Mukand/Rodrik 2005, p. 375).<br />

Referring to the design of complementary<br />

institutions, Amable summarizes as follows:<br />

“There is no social engineer in charge of<br />

the efficiency of institutional design, and<br />

there is no pre-established fit of institutions<br />

either. Economic models, i.e. specific sets<br />

of institutional forms and the associated<br />

complementarities, are not designed from<br />

scratch with all the different pieces intended to<br />

nicely complement each other. The coherence<br />

of a model is usually defined ex post and the<br />

complementarities may sometimes come as a<br />

surprise...“ (Amable 2003, p. 12). Transition<br />

scholars, who adhere to the “bricolage view”,<br />

stress the evolutionary and path-dependent<br />

nature of institutional change and support<br />

gradualist reforms (Portes 1990; McKinnon<br />

1990; Murrell 1995; Poznanski 1996; Roland<br />

2000). Gradualist reformers argue that, in the<br />

presence of aggregate uncertainty, gradual<br />

reforms are politically more acceptable, because<br />

they have lower reversal costs, i.e. lower costs<br />

of trial and error (Dewatripoint/Roland 1995,<br />

p. 1209; Roland 2000). Therefore, this view<br />

stresses a sequenced design of reforms, i.e. to<br />

start with reforms that are socially less costly<br />

and provide constituencies for more difficult<br />

reforms. An example for sequenced reforms is<br />

to do privatization before painful restructuring<br />

(Zecchini 1997, p. 174-175).<br />

Which view has more explanatory power for<br />

post-communist transition? Initially, without<br />

a doubt, transition period was one of conscious<br />

institutional design. In all former communist<br />

states, basic institutions of a capitalist system<br />

were missing and had to be constructed in a<br />

short period of time. Post-communist states<br />

designed their formal institutional framework<br />

on the basis of Western models. Because<br />

capitalist knowledge was limited, reformers<br />

had to rely on advisors from the West, who<br />

were mostly advocates of the big bang<br />

approach (e.g. Jeffrey Sachs, David Lipton,<br />

Anders Aslund). Market-oriented institutions<br />

(e.g. fiscal and financial institutions, property<br />

rights) and government agencies (e.g. Central<br />

Bank, Finance Ministry, anti-monopoly<br />

agency) had to be created from scratch.<br />

However, supporters of radical reforms<br />

forgot that the degree of communist Seite Page page 19<br />

implementation differed among<br />

communist countries. Some states<br />

(Hungary, Poland, Yugoslavia) had already<br />

undertaken market-oriented reforms during<br />

the last decades of communism and, therefore,


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

had superior economic and institutional<br />

starting conditions (EBRD Transition Report<br />

1999, p. 29) than states with more rigorously<br />

implemented communism (e.g. the Soviet<br />

Union, Romania, Bulgaria, Albania). The<br />

more beneficial communist legacy of Hungary,<br />

Poland and Yugoslavia was reflected in a less<br />

centralized economy, enterprise autonomy,<br />

small private sector, entrepreneurial skills, or<br />

even tax and banking regulations that were<br />

similar to Western ones (Szalai 2005, p. 9;<br />

Rona-Tas 1997, p. 130; Fischer/Gelb 1991,<br />

p. 92f ). Because of this advanced starting<br />

position, in some economic or political areas<br />

institutional design from scratch was more<br />

pronounced in former Soviet republics than in<br />

CEECs. While the Baltic and Central Asian<br />

states had to design commercial laws anew,<br />

Poland, for instance, could rely on its precommunist<br />

commercial code (Havrylyshyn<br />

2006, p. 35). Rather than designing institutions<br />

from scratch, CEECs had to redesign them,<br />

i.e. to recombine old institutions with new<br />

ones (Stark/Bruszt 1998). In some cases, new<br />

institutions substituted for old ones, in other<br />

cases, new institutions only supplemented old<br />

ones (Grzymala-Busse/Jones Luong 2002,<br />

p. 542). What is important to see is that<br />

institutional reforms were not done on a tabula<br />

rasa, and no matter which transition strategy<br />

was used (big-bang or gradualism), historical<br />

formal and informal legacies influenced the<br />

functioning of new institutions. 7<br />

Seite Page page 20<br />

One has to bear in mind that the good<br />

intention to design a complementary<br />

institutional system is always subject<br />

to hindering factors. Unintended events (wars,<br />

external financial crisis) and historical structural<br />

restrictions can hinder the implementation of<br />

formal reforms and policies. Although in all<br />

post-communist countries institutional subsystems<br />

were (re)designed, the relevant question<br />

is how strongly radical or gradual designers<br />

insisted on institutional complementarities<br />

(efficiency aspects) during post-communist<br />

transition and whether complementarities can<br />

explain post-communist institutional variety<br />

and performance. I will argue that the design of<br />

ex ante complementary institutions is difficult<br />

due to three limitations: changing environment,<br />

lack of resources/capacity for law enforcement<br />

and changing power relations of diverse actors.<br />

Changing environment (uncertainty): All<br />

institutional designers face a changing external<br />

environment and an uncertain future (Streeck<br />

2004, p. 102 and p. 112). These changing<br />

conditions guarantee neither that the goal<br />

to build complementary institutions can be<br />

maintained, nor that initially complementary<br />

institutions will remain complementary in the<br />

future. Future environmental changes are not<br />

always easy to predict by institutional designers.<br />

Thus it is not straightforward to evaluate<br />

which institutions will be complementary<br />

in the next years. According to Streeck “…<br />

institutional complementarity is hard to predict<br />

and provide for ex ante. Where it exists, it is<br />

mostly generated ex post, through corrective<br />

intervention and piecemeal mutual adjustment.<br />

Rather than being planned and designed in<br />

one step, complementarity seems the product<br />

of continuous, more or less improvised debugging<br />

of perceived frictions...“ (Streeck<br />

2004, p. 107). A good example for changing<br />

effects of the same institutional configuration<br />

comes from Japan and Germany. The Japanese<br />

and German institutional systems, which were<br />

praised as highly complementary and efficient


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

in the second half of the 20 th century, are<br />

regarded some decades later as hard to reform<br />

and inefficient. The explanation according<br />

to Streeck is that, with the technological<br />

change in form of micro-electronic revolution,<br />

the formerly complementary institutional<br />

systems, although still coherent, became less<br />

complementary (Streeck 2004, p. 112).<br />

As post-communist countries experienced<br />

a great deal of geopolitical and economic<br />

uncertainty, institutional adjustments and<br />

experimentation were strongly required during<br />

the transition period (McFaul 1999, p. 28).<br />

Initial variation in uncertainty among transition<br />

countries can be explained by different exit<br />

modes from communism. Whereas CEECs<br />

(e.g. in Hungary, Czech Republic, Poland)<br />

created competitive democracies in roundtable<br />

negotiations “in Bulgaria and Romania, for<br />

example, the collapse of incumbent regimes<br />

caused greater uncertainty than in the<br />

negotiated transitions of Central Europe…”<br />

(World Bank 2002, p. 108). Similarly, the<br />

initial degree of uncertainty was relatively high<br />

in concentrated political regimes emerging<br />

from former regional blocks (Soviet Union,<br />

Yugoslavia).<br />

Even if institutions were designed ex ante<br />

as coherent, they could not be sustained in a<br />

rapidly changing environment. For instance,<br />

in SEE (Croatia, Serbia, Bosnia-Herzogovina,<br />

Macedonia, Albania, Moldova), the Caucasus<br />

(Armenia, Azerbaijan, Georgia) and Central<br />

Asia (Tajikistan), economic and geopolitical<br />

uncertainty increased because of wars, ethnic<br />

conflicts or spillovers from the Russian financial<br />

crisis. It is not surprising that under such<br />

quickly changing and uncertain conditions the<br />

design and implementation of complementary<br />

institutions was difficult. Wars and conflicts<br />

sharply reduced living standards and the<br />

capacity of the state (World Bank 2002, p.<br />

110). In the presence of negative feedbacks<br />

and aggregate uncertainty about reform<br />

outcomes, the leaders of unstable economies<br />

relied on former practices. According to<br />

Grzymala-Busse and Jones Luong, elites<br />

in Central Asia and the Caucasus relied on<br />

old formal and informal institutions (e.g.<br />

patronage) because of the rapidity of statebuilding<br />

and a weak central state apparatus<br />

(see Grzymala-Busse/Jones Luong 2002,<br />

p. 535 and p. 541). In contrast, geopolitical<br />

and economic uncertainty disappeared in the<br />

Baltic States, CEECs, Bulgaria and Romania<br />

with NATO and EU membership. The EU<br />

has served as an “outside anchor” (Berglöf/<br />

Roland 1997) and, through its membership<br />

criteria, conditioned the applicants to reform<br />

their political and economic institutions. An<br />

unstable environment (high uncertainty in<br />

the short-run) explains why complementary<br />

institutional design was not possible for a<br />

certain time during transition. It also explains<br />

why economic cooperation based on trust<br />

and repeated interaction was difficult in wartorn<br />

countries. But why was complementary<br />

institutional design also complicated in<br />

peaceful transition countries? The answer is<br />

closely related to lack of resources (low state<br />

capacity) and a weak enforcement of<br />

rules.<br />

Seite Page page 21<br />

Lack of resources (time, capital, state<br />

capacity) can prevent the implementation<br />

of coherent institution building, despite the<br />

focus of institutional designers on institutional<br />

complementarity. During rapid institutional


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

building, reformers do not have the time<br />

to collect and evaluate “facts” about the<br />

environment (Grzymala-Busse/Jones Luong<br />

2002, p. 541). Furthermore, institutional<br />

reformers can be constrained by financial<br />

resources and weak state capacity. Lacking the<br />

financial means, third parties (state agencies,<br />

courts) are not able to enforce new institutions,<br />

especially when other informal mechanisms<br />

of enforcement (shaming, gossip, ostracism,<br />

shunning) are absent (Ostrom 2005). The<br />

available state capacity to enforce institutions<br />

can result from historical structural deficits or<br />

from current environmental context (external<br />

shocks).<br />

Post-communist transition involved both<br />

socio-economic and political reforms, which<br />

left relatively little time to conduct an<br />

analysis of the most efficient combination of<br />

institutions. As transition countries had to<br />

simultaneously conduct reforms in different<br />

areas (Elster/ Offe/Preuss 1998), they often<br />

did not have the time for long-term master<br />

plans of complementary institutional systems. 8<br />

The simultaneity of reforms compelled actors<br />

to prioritize and neglect some areas of reforms<br />

(McFaul 1999, p. 31). Whereas developed<br />

countries had built up democracy and market<br />

economy over a period of several decades,<br />

post-communist countries had to do so in only<br />

a few years (Grzymala-Busse/Jones Luong<br />

2002, p. 535). Similarly, EU candidate<br />

countries were under time pressure and<br />

Seite Page page 22<br />

the adoption of EU legislation (acquis<br />

communautaire) was often carried out<br />

as a rapid legislation passing in the<br />

parliament without a correct implementation. 9<br />

According to Sadurski “…the sheer volume of<br />

the acquis meant that parliaments had to adopt<br />

fast-track procedures for passing the related<br />

laws…“ (Sadurski 2006, p. 34). Such hastened<br />

institutional reforms could not have produced<br />

complementary institutions.<br />

Similarly, resource constraints (resulting from<br />

the past, from financial crises or wars) hindered<br />

the enforcement of institutions and did not give<br />

way for a complementary design of institutions.<br />

The leaders of economically instable countries<br />

had to postpone reforms, relied either on<br />

transitional institutions or even alternative<br />

solutions by half-legal private actors. Initially,<br />

informal and unofficial practices (black market)<br />

were a popular means to resolve coordination<br />

problems in almost all transition states.<br />

However, there were strong regional differences<br />

in terms of informal practices. According to<br />

the estimations of Johnson et al., the average<br />

share of unofficial economy in CEE was at its<br />

peak with 21,3% in the year 1992 much lower<br />

than in former Soviet countries, which had its<br />

highest value with 36,2% in the year 1996 (See<br />

Johnson et al. p. 182-183). 10<br />

With progressive institutional reforms, some<br />

transition countries (e.g. Poland, Hungary,<br />

Slovenia, the Baltic States) overcame these<br />

initial problems of the shadow economy<br />

and were able to provide a stable business<br />

environment and attract FDI. Why? Higher<br />

state capacity seems to be an important key to<br />

success. Better state capacity in CEE can be<br />

attributed to structural differences of the past 11<br />

as well as the absence of wars and financial<br />

crisis (World Bank 2002, p. 13 and p. 110). In<br />

contrast, reform laggard countries from SEE<br />

or CIS neither had the “beneficial legacies”<br />

nor the resources to train lawyers, bureaucrats<br />

and teachers to change quickly to capitalist


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

mentality and guarantee the enforcement of<br />

capitalist institutions. While transplanted<br />

formal institutions were often the same,<br />

enforcement and implementation were not.<br />

Otherwise, best practices (first-best institutions)<br />

would have had the same effect everywhere.<br />

The Worldwide Governance indicators from<br />

the World Bank provide some evidence that<br />

enforcement and legal quality differed. Rule<br />

of law 12 has on average been lower in CIS<br />

(Commonwealth of Independent States) and<br />

SEE than in CEB (Central Eastern Europe<br />

and the Baltic States) between 1996 and 2006.<br />

Whereas average scores on legal quality have<br />

been constantly high in CEC (around 70%),<br />

SEE had a considerably lower and fluctuating<br />

development (score between 33% and 43%)<br />

and the CIS even a deterioration from about<br />

24% to 19% (see table 2).<br />

Table 2. Regional average scores on the rule of law in transition countries<br />

CIS SEE CEB<br />

1996 24.3 33.3 69.4<br />

1998 20.8 44.2 68.8<br />

2000 18.6 33.9 68.2<br />

2002 18.3 36.7 69.2<br />

2004 19.8 40.8 70.2<br />

2006 19.1 42.7 68.0<br />

Source: Worldwide governance indicators 1996-2006, World Bank.<br />

Note: The Scores are calculated on a scale of 0 to 100, with 100 being the highest possible score.<br />

This general evidence on different quality<br />

of the institutional environment is reflected<br />

in more specific economic institutions. The<br />

EBRD’s legal indicator survey 13 from the year<br />

2005 provides some evidence that enforcement<br />

(legal effectiveness) of corporate governance<br />

laws differed among transition countries and<br />

that “even excellent laws can suffer from poor<br />

implementation” (see EBRD Report 2005,<br />

Annex 1.2.: Corporate governance, p. 30).<br />

EBRD survey data reveals on average a weaker<br />

legal effectiveness of corporate governance 14<br />

in CIS and SEE than in Central Europe<br />

and the Baltic States (see table 3). Although<br />

some countries in SEE (e.g. Macedonia)<br />

and in the CIS (e.g. Armenia, Kazakhstan,<br />

Moldova) have high compliance with<br />

international standards and score high on legal<br />

extensiveness (quality of “laws on the<br />

books”), they score only poorly on<br />

legal effectiveness, i.e. the laws do not Seite Page page 23<br />

work well in practice. In contrast, the<br />

corporate governance legislation in<br />

most Central European and Baltic States is in<br />

most cases reasonably well implemented.


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

Table 3. Regional average of corporate governance effectiveness in 2005<br />

CIS SEE CEB<br />

Effectiveness of disclosure 4.74 5.32 5.73<br />

Effectiveness of redress 4.74 4.98 5.35<br />

Source: Source: EBRD Legal Indicator Survey 2005 and author’s own<br />

calculation.<br />

Note: The scores are calculated on 0 to 10, with 10 being the highest possible<br />

score. Data on SEE does not include Kosovo.<br />

This implementation gap in SEE and former<br />

Soviet countries in contrast to CEECs<br />

recurs in other areas of legislation. The<br />

difference for these three groups of countries<br />

among extensiveness and effectiveness<br />

(implementation gap) is especially obvious<br />

in the area of commercial laws (see figures<br />

2 and 3 in appendix), insolvency regulation<br />

(see figure 4 in appendix), concession laws 15 ,<br />

securities markets legislation (see EBRD’s<br />

legal indicator survey 2007) and labor market<br />

institutions. 16 Using survey data from three<br />

different sources, 17 Pistor et al. 2000 confirm<br />

a weak institutional environment and weak<br />

implementation of economic institutions in<br />

most countries from SEE and the CIS (see<br />

Pistor et al. 2000).<br />

Legal and economic research on<br />

institutional enforcement has shown<br />

Seite Page page 24<br />

that there are important constraints<br />

to implementation of economic<br />

institutions (most notably in the CIS<br />

and also in SEE) and, consequently, limits to<br />

a coherent or complementary system in this<br />

region. Thus, lower institutional quality and<br />

absent institutional complementarity in these<br />

regions can be explained. But what accounts for<br />

different institutional configurations among the<br />

most advanced transition countries? Why did<br />

only Slovenia and Estonia develop coherent<br />

institutional systems and the other CEECs<br />

(Poland, Hungary or the Czech Republic,<br />

Lithuania, Latvia) did not? The rule of law<br />

indicator for the CEE group may indeed explain<br />

coherence in Slovenia and Estonia, as these<br />

countries have the highest scores on effective<br />

legal environment (see figure 5 in appendix).<br />

However, as Hungary and the Czech Republic<br />

have similarly high levels, but less coherent<br />

institutions (see Knell/Srholec 2007, p. 60),<br />

even an overall good institutional environment<br />

(high enforcement) does not guarantee a<br />

coherent system. Another explanation why<br />

coherent and complementary institutions<br />

were difficult to create during transition could<br />

have been the degree of diverse interests and<br />

ideologies of domestic and external actors<br />

during transition.<br />

Power relations (diversity of actors): Scholars<br />

stress the increasing importance of actors over


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

institutions during transition and emphasize<br />

the role of the state for institutional reforms<br />

(Hanson/Teague 2007; Charman 2007;<br />

Schmidt 2008; Higley/Pakulski/Wesołowski<br />

1998). 18 However, it must be considered that<br />

institutions and institutional complementarities<br />

are not only created at the regime level alone,<br />

but are the outcome of many actors with<br />

diverse interests and power positions (Streeck<br />

2004, p. 111). Institutions are often the result<br />

of a political compromise and not an optimal<br />

solution to a given problem or, as Amable<br />

puts it: “…institutions do not emerge as the<br />

result of a welfare-maximizing process. They<br />

are the outcomes of a political process. The<br />

whole set of institutions is not chosen all at<br />

once, by agents possessing a clear view of all<br />

the interdependencies between institutions<br />

concerning all areas of the economy” (Amable<br />

2003, p. 63). Both Streeck and Amable remind us<br />

that the pursuit of political and economic power<br />

can limit rational design of complementary<br />

institutions. This is particularly true if there is no<br />

benevolent “dominant social block” (Callaghan<br />

2008, p. 9) and when institutional reformers<br />

have opposing ideological backgrounds. But<br />

even when ideologically diverse reformers<br />

find a compromise, this compromise will<br />

not necessarily lead to the first best solution<br />

(complementary institutions).<br />

The emerging post-communist state was not<br />

a unitary actor with uniform authority, but<br />

underwent a formation process characterized<br />

by “multiple actors, domestic as well as<br />

international” (Grzymala-Busse/Jones Luong<br />

2002, p. 533). Let me first focus on domestic<br />

actors 19 and explain why so few complementary<br />

systems emerged during transition. A main<br />

reason can be found in opposing ideologies and<br />

changing power relations of these actors. After<br />

the demise of communism, old power structures<br />

changed and a battle for political and economic<br />

power began among different domestic actors.<br />

Communist rulers lost their legitimacy and<br />

previously constructed institutions were<br />

contested. The early transition years became a<br />

period of bargaining about political power and<br />

the future institutions to stabilize this power.<br />

Institutional change was not an outcome of<br />

designed complementarities, but of conflicts<br />

and compromises between different domestic<br />

actors. It is difficult to imagine that the<br />

competing interests between internal actors<br />

were reconciled in all post-communist countries<br />

and led to ex ante creation of complementary<br />

institutions. Although in some countries a<br />

political compromise by consensually united<br />

elites was reached, such as Poland, Hungary<br />

and Slovenia (Higley/Burton 2006, p. 83), in<br />

other countries (e.g. Bulgaria, Russia, Croatia,<br />

Serbia, Belarus and Romania) disunited<br />

political elites hindered the implementation<br />

of coherent transition strategies (see Higley/<br />

Burton 2006, p. 90 and p. 171). In these<br />

countries, quite often reform strategies<br />

changed with a change in the government<br />

(see Havrylyshyn 2007). Although electoral<br />

backlash and some modification of initial<br />

policies occurred even in advanced transition<br />

countries such as Poland, Hungary and the<br />

Czech Republic (King 2002, p. 8), the general<br />

reform paths were not altered.<br />

Changing power relations and the Seite Page page 25<br />

redesign of institutional reforms were<br />

often the result of changing economic<br />

conditions, which differed among transition<br />

countries. In former Soviet Republics<br />

and SEE, prolonged economic decline


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

and deteriorating living conditions made<br />

cooperation between domestic actors more<br />

difficult. Intense struggle among different<br />

domestic actors or ethnic groups, which also<br />

produced violence (e.g. in Yugoslavia), did not<br />

leave room for stability and a complementary<br />

institutional system. In war-torn countries<br />

(e.g. Azerbaijan, Georgia) and countries with<br />

high concentrations of political power (e.g.<br />

Moldova, Russia, Ukraine, Kyrgyz Republic),<br />

powerful domestic groups actively influenced<br />

institutional reforms (see World Bank 2002, p.<br />

106). Influence of such actors is nothing bad,<br />

as long as the state remains powerful enough<br />

and will not be captured by powerful internal<br />

business groups or oligarchs, who seek to extract<br />

rents from the state. The composite index<br />

of state capture 20 provides snapshot evidence<br />

that in the year 1999 the influence of firms on<br />

institutional and policy reforms was on average<br />

more pronounced in SEE and the CIS as<br />

compared to CEB (see table 4).<br />

Table 4. Regional average of state capture among transition economies in 1999<br />

CIS AM AZ BY GG KZ KG MD RU UA UZ<br />

regional<br />

average<br />

state capture index 7 41 8 24 12 29 37 32 32 6 22.8<br />

SEE ALB BG HR RO<br />

state capture index 16 28 27 21 23<br />

CEB CZ EE HU LV LT SK SI PL<br />

state capture index 11 10 7 30 11 24 7 12 14<br />

Source: Calculations based on Hellman./Jones/Kaufmann, 2000, p. 9.<br />

Note: The index is constructed as the average proportion of firms responding that their businesses are directly affected by private payments<br />

made to public officials to influence decision making in one or more of the following six institutions: parliament, the executive<br />

apparatus, the criminal courts, the civil courts, the central bank, and political parties (Hellman/Kaumann 2001).<br />

While dealing with institutional<br />

change and institutional complementarity<br />

during transition, ex-<br />

Seite Page page 26<br />

ternal actors should be taken into<br />

account. Post-communist institution<br />

building has been subject to pressure<br />

from Western consultants, international organizations<br />

(IMF, World Bank, USAID),<br />

multinational corporations and foreign banks.<br />

The EU was particularly important for<br />

institutional reforms. 21 Although international<br />

actors initially produced institutional and<br />

policy similarities (best practices), at the same<br />

time multiple conditionalities and interests<br />

hindered coherent institutional strategies, as<br />

well. Bartlett shows, for instance, that former


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

Yugoslavian states became dependent on<br />

financial aid from external actors (IMF, EU,<br />

World Bank) who were able to impose their<br />

own diverse interests and thus hindered the<br />

creation of a complementary institutional<br />

system (Bartlett 2007). However, because of<br />

different geopolitical locations and economic<br />

resource bases, external pressure to adopt the<br />

same institutions was far from universal among<br />

post-communist states (Grzymala-Busse/Jones<br />

Luong 2002, p. 547).<br />

Even in states with a similar geopolitical<br />

location and resource endowments (EU<br />

candidate states from CEE) diversity persisted.<br />

Similar EU impact on economic institutions<br />

of candidate countries (see for instance Myant<br />

2007; Cernat 2006) does not automatically<br />

mean a convergence towards a complementary<br />

“EU logic of coordination”. According to<br />

Philip Hanson, who analyzed the impact of<br />

EU membership on economic institutions<br />

(labor market regulation and business<br />

regulation), considerable institutional diversity<br />

among the new EU members has persisted.<br />

His explanation of diversity is that economic<br />

accession requirements left a “wide scope for<br />

institutional variation” and that institutional<br />

convergence towards either state or market<br />

coordination was not enforced by the EU<br />

(Hanson 2007, p. 97 and p. 100). By setting the<br />

goal (minimum standards) of the institutional<br />

reform, yet leaving enough room for the method<br />

to implement the economic regulations, the EU<br />

did not necessarily induce a full convergence,<br />

but rather a divergent convergence. However,<br />

despite persisting differences, the EU’s indirect<br />

influence on post-communist diversity as a<br />

whole must be acknowledged. By accelerating<br />

institutional reforms in reform laggard<br />

countries (Romanian, Bulgaria), the EU<br />

accession process widened the gap with<br />

post-communist countries without an EU<br />

membership perspective.<br />

Let me briefly assess the EU’s role regarding<br />

complementary institutions. I would not<br />

consider external conditionality as the optimal<br />

solution to create complementary institutions,<br />

as it brings in additional external interests and<br />

is not based on a strategy of coherent design.<br />

However, I would consider EU conditionality<br />

as a second-best solution to accelerate<br />

institutional reforms in the short-run. This<br />

would imply that institutional reformers have<br />

to make a trade-off between institutional<br />

effectiveness (enforcement), which can be<br />

improved in the short-term and institutional<br />

efficiency (complementarity), which is a rather<br />

long-term goal. The best example for the EU<br />

impact on improved institutional quality in<br />

a short period of time comes from Romania,<br />

Bulgaria and Slovakia (see Schimmelfennig/<br />

Sedelmeier 2005; Vachudova 2005). However,<br />

whether the improvement in institutional<br />

effectiveness will translate into long term<br />

complementarity is an open question that can<br />

only be answered in the future.<br />

The last puzzle which remains to be solved<br />

is why Slovenia and Estonia have created a<br />

coherent institutional system, while Hungary,<br />

Poland and the Czech Republic,<br />

which had similar state capacities,<br />

beneficial historical legacies and the Seite Page page 27<br />

EU membership perspective, did<br />

not. According to Feldmann, the mechanism<br />

behind coherent institutions in Slovenia and<br />

Estonia are economic networks between key<br />

economic actors (Feldmann 2007, p. 337).


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

He argues that the combined effect of<br />

communist legacy (degree of centralization<br />

under communism) and policy choices during<br />

transition (privatization strategy, monetary<br />

policy, centralization of wage bargaining)<br />

encouraged network-promotion in Slovenia<br />

and network-disruption in Estonia and<br />

created two diverse but coherent systems.<br />

Although this may be an explanation for<br />

these two countries, Feldmann cautions: “The<br />

conditions necessary to promote or disrupt<br />

networks may in fact be quite stringent, and<br />

Estonia and Slovenia may be quite exceptional<br />

in terms of their combination of legacies and<br />

political preconditions for their reform paths”<br />

(Feldmann 2007, p. 348). Broader comparative<br />

analysis is required to clarify this remaining<br />

puzzle.<br />

If we recapitulate the arguments on the design<br />

vs. spontaneous emergence of institutions<br />

(agency-structure importance), it is most<br />

reasonable to seek a reconciliation of both<br />

approaches. Particularly, if we conceive<br />

institutional change occurring simultaneously<br />

as a short-term change (e.g. agency design,<br />

external shocks) and long-term change (e.g.<br />

structural change, enforcement, informal<br />

institutions) it makes sense to see both views<br />

as complementary rather than contradictory.<br />

Institutional change is an interplay between<br />

agency and structure. It is an interaction between<br />

the old structure (historical legacy),<br />

the current agency actions (policy<br />

Seite Page page 28<br />

and institutional choices) and future<br />

possibilities (e.g. EU membership or<br />

new opportunities due to scarcity of<br />

resources). In such an interdependent process,<br />

where in the short-run the causal direction<br />

can run from economic performance to<br />

institutions, institutional complementarities<br />

can be no more than one consideration among<br />

others to explain institutional divergence.<br />

I have mentioned some limitations of the<br />

complementarity concept to explain shortterm<br />

institutional diversity in post-communist<br />

countries: a changing external environment<br />

and uncertainty, diversity of actors and power<br />

relations, weak enforcement of institutions<br />

due to lacking capacity. If such limitations<br />

are absent thanks to beneficial legacies, or<br />

become absent, for instance after economic<br />

and geopolitical stabilization, the design of<br />

complementary institutions could be easier.<br />

Generally, the argument of complementarity<br />

is more convincing in the evolutionary, long<br />

run emergence of institutions. Nevertheless,<br />

particular institutional or policy reform areas<br />

(e.g. policy complementarities 22 between<br />

macroeconomic stabilization and price<br />

liberalization), where fewer actors or resources<br />

(lower state capacity) for enforcement are<br />

required, may make complementarity relevant<br />

in the short-run. The transformation of an<br />

entire economic system, however, requires time<br />

and experimentation.<br />

3.3 The limits of pure types of coordination in<br />

the transition context<br />

The VoC approach insinuates that, because of<br />

efficiency considerations, developed economies<br />

tend to converge towards two ideal types<br />

of coordination (LMEs and CMEs) and<br />

institutional complementarities constrain<br />

switching between CMEs and LMEs. After<br />

being criticized for not considering change in<br />

coordination logics (Goodin 2003; Blyth 2003;<br />

Watson 2003; Jackson/Deeg 2006), Peter Hall,<br />

together with his co author(s), responded to


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

the criticism and underlined the importance<br />

of politics for institutional change (Hall/<br />

Soskice 2003, p. 245; Hall/Thelen 2005; Hall<br />

2006). A recent empirical study by Paunescu/<br />

Schneider has confirmed switching from state<br />

to market coordination for several developed<br />

economies (Paunescu/Schneider 2004). The<br />

relevant question for transition countries is<br />

whether mixed logics of coordination can<br />

become complementary and converge towards<br />

pure LMEs and CMEs or rather remain noncomplementary<br />

hybrids. Put differently, will<br />

there be dual convergence towards pure forms<br />

of organization or rather a lock-in of mixed<br />

organizational logics?<br />

In my opinion, sustained mixed logics of<br />

coordination (second-best solution) are<br />

possible due to positive feedbacks resulting<br />

from increased enforcement, i.e. more<br />

effectiveness. Let me illustrate a more dynamic<br />

model of capitalist diversity (see figure 1) to<br />

explain the fundamental differences between<br />

developed economies (CMEs, LMEs) and<br />

transitional market economies (TMEs). In<br />

contrast to transition economies, developed<br />

economies have strongly enforced and<br />

effective institutions. While in developed<br />

economies the possibility to increase economic<br />

performance by increasing the quality of<br />

institutions (effectiveness) is nearly exhausted,<br />

performance can still be improved by making<br />

institutions complementary (efficiency).<br />

Given that complementarity depends on<br />

external environment changes, developed<br />

countries can improve efficiency by adapting<br />

to external pressures by switching their logic of<br />

coordination (horizontal shifts between CMEs<br />

and LMEs). 23 These horizontal shifts tend to<br />

be slow due to institutional complementarities,<br />

path dependence and certain reforms (e.g.<br />

better protection of minority shareholders,<br />

adopting international accounting standards)<br />

and often do not have a major impact on other<br />

sub-systems or corporate strategies. Therefore,<br />

despite “liberalizing” reforms, switching of<br />

coordination modes should remain difficult in<br />

developed economies (Hall/Thelen 2005, p. 26<br />

and p. 31).<br />

While gradual institutional and economic<br />

development may be true for developed market<br />

economies, transition economies experience<br />

rapid formal institutional change. Due to the<br />

unfinished stage of capitalism (lower economic<br />

development) and high uncertainty (transition<br />

as an open-ended process), institutions in<br />

post-communist economies have initially a<br />

transitory character, i.e. they are only weakly<br />

enforced. Because of weak enforcement,<br />

institutional change is easier and, at least<br />

in the short or middle-run, there are more<br />

alternatives for capitalist trajectories than in<br />

developed economies. 24<br />

Seite Page page 29


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

Figure 1. Modes of coordination under consideration of different levels of development<br />

high<br />

LMEs<br />

CMEs<br />

level of development<br />

TMEs<br />

low<br />

low<br />

high<br />

Source: Own elaboration<br />

At a lower level of (capitalism) development,<br />

TMEs can move vertically and diagonally.<br />

The paths of institutional and economic<br />

development are not yet fixed and can develop<br />

towards LME, CME or a mixed form of<br />

both. In the absence of positive feedback,<br />

development towards a stronger role of the<br />

state and even less capitalism is possible (e.g.<br />

downward diagonal shift in Venezuela and<br />

Belarus). Such upward and downward diagonal<br />

and vertical shifts are reflected in capitalist<br />

reforms or reform reversals and are possible<br />

because political and economic institutions are<br />

enforced only weakly. 25<br />

Seite Page page 30<br />

How does the model reflect the<br />

transition period? At the beginning of<br />

transition, the initial strong decline of<br />

GDP and a lengthy and burdensome recovery<br />

hindered positive feedbacks to stabilize<br />

the institutional system. Weakly enforced<br />

institutions (“frames without content”) could<br />

be changed more easily and reform reversals<br />

were the case in states with a low capacity<br />

(e.g. in Russia, Romania and Bulgaria).<br />

Transition countries, which succeeded in<br />

increasing state capacity and enforcing formal<br />

institutions, created a stable institutional<br />

environment for economic cooperation and<br />

entrepreneurship. The Visegrad states, for<br />

instance, although having missed the chance to<br />

build complementary institutions, nevertheless<br />

established a stable and relatively effective<br />

institutional system. Institutional quality in<br />

Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic<br />

was increased through better enforcement,<br />

not through better complementarity. If we<br />

consider positive feedback and lock-in effects,<br />

these non-coherent systems should be difficult<br />

to reverse for a while. As long as efficiency<br />

or effectiveness gains are possible through<br />

improved enforcement or other means (for


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

instance, by increasing the compatibility<br />

between formal and informal institutions),<br />

mixed market economies should persist.<br />

The success story of transition frontrunners<br />

with non-complementary institutions shows<br />

that the primary step to an efficient institutional<br />

system and system stability is enforcement of<br />

rules. While enforcement does not exclude<br />

a focus on institutional complementarity,<br />

it should be a secondary step to increase<br />

efficiency. The main reason for precedence<br />

of enforcement over complementarity are<br />

capacity restrictions (time constraints, financial<br />

and human resource constraints), which make<br />

it difficult to create complementary (efficient)<br />

and well-enforced (effective) institutions at<br />

the same time. A look at the ranking of three<br />

post-communist countries in the coordination<br />

index constructed by Knell/Srholec 2007 will<br />

make my argument more clear. According<br />

to this index, Estonia, Armenia and Russia<br />

have all a strongly liberalized system with<br />

coherent formal institutions. However, because<br />

of weak enforcement capacity in Russia and<br />

Armenia (low effectiveness), coherence did not<br />

translate into complementarity and good de<br />

jure institutions are being undermined by the<br />

interests of powerful companies. In contrast,<br />

Estonia’s coherent and well enforced institutions<br />

have facilitated competition and cooperation<br />

and translated in complementary institutions.<br />

Enforcement does not mean enforcing<br />

every detail of the political economy and<br />

restricting critical institutional entrepreneurs<br />

and arbitrageurs who are discovering the<br />

weaknesses of the system and create a demand<br />

for improvement. What it does mean is that<br />

the state has to establish and enforce a set<br />

of core institutions, which guarantee the<br />

rule of law and stability for a stable business<br />

environment, while experimentation and<br />

change are still possible at the periphery. Such<br />

an approach, which distinguishes between<br />

core and peripheral institutions, allows for the<br />

exploitation of possibilities of both enforcement<br />

and complementarity. When enforcement<br />

is guaranteed for a set of central institutions<br />

across different sub-systems, complementarities<br />

between these core institutions can be<br />

established with less effort and resources than<br />

in the case of complementarities between all<br />

institutions (including peripheral, less enforced<br />

institutions). In other words, the basic skeleton<br />

of the political economy could be initially<br />

designed, but the flesh should be developed in<br />

a trial and error process.<br />

Although I am suggesting that institutional<br />

complementarity should not be that important<br />

for transition and developing countries lacking<br />

enforcement capacities, it could become more<br />

important with increasing enforcement.<br />

Consolidated transition countries (e.g. Slovenia<br />

and Estonia), where efficiency gains resulting<br />

from good enforcement of institutions were<br />

already exploited, can increase their institutional<br />

and economic performance by focusing on<br />

complementarity aspects. In contrast, nonconsolidated<br />

transition economies (e.g. most<br />

economies in the CIS and SEE) should<br />

focus on the enforcement of core<br />

institutions or, if possible, pair-wise<br />

complementarities (e.g. between Seite Page page 31<br />

financial institutions and institutions<br />

regarding inter-firm relations).<br />

Only when a certain level of enforcement is<br />

achieved, should institutional complementarities<br />

bring about additional efficiency.


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

What we have to keep in mind is that the<br />

ability of enforcement and complementarity<br />

depend on the context (external environment,<br />

historical legacy, state capacity). As this context<br />

varies among transition countries, every country<br />

should conduct reforms that take into account<br />

different environmental pre-conditions in<br />

terms of economic development, geographic<br />

situation, resource endowment, human<br />

resources, networks and informal institutions.<br />

In my opinion, institutional complementarity<br />

in the transition context should be understood<br />

more broadly, namely as compatibility in time,<br />

space and existing structures. A good model<br />

of institutional change in post-communist<br />

economies should, therefore, incorporate<br />

resources, geography, history and the dynamic<br />

interplay between the economic and political<br />

arenas during transition.<br />

The complementarity of institutions depends<br />

on changing environmental circumstances.<br />

This means that coherent institutions will<br />

be beneficial in the “good times” (i.e. when<br />

fundamental reforms are not required), but<br />

detrimental in the “bad times”, when change<br />

is most needed. Because of a changing<br />

environment, institutional complementarity<br />

and enforcement should be understood as<br />

dynamic concepts, i.e., there should always<br />

be room for experimentation and adaptation<br />

of the institutional structure (see North<br />

1990). To enable change and<br />

flexibility, adaptive institutional<br />

Seite Page page 32<br />

complementarity is required. If<br />

too much emphasis is put on static<br />

institutional complementarity, the<br />

political economy can become inflexible and<br />

lose its comparative advantage. The emphasis<br />

on enforcement, which I made before, does not<br />

necessarily produce inflexibility and institutional<br />

inertia as long as enough room is left for<br />

institutional experimentation and competition.<br />

The dynamic approach of adaptive institutional<br />

efficiency would enable institutional change<br />

within particular types of institutions without<br />

necessarily changing the entire institutional<br />

sub-system. Allowing Siemens, Infineon or<br />

IBM to increase engineers’ wages to cope with<br />

low supply of engineers, without changing the<br />

overall wage policy, is such an adaptive way of<br />

specific peripheral change. A second example for<br />

experimentation, under continuing dominant<br />

logics of coordination, is the introduction<br />

of temporary work agencies to reduce labor<br />

market rigidities in Germany (Höpner 2005,<br />

p. 333). Within such an adaptive process of<br />

change, learning and the adoption of new skills<br />

are important. However, learning does not<br />

mean transferring best practices from abroad,<br />

but rather searching for functional equivalents<br />

and local solutions.<br />

4. CONCLUSION<br />

The research question I started with was<br />

whether the VoC approach and, particularly,<br />

its concepts of institutional complementarity<br />

and limited coordination modes can be<br />

helpful in explaining institutional diversity<br />

and institutional development during postcommunist<br />

transition. The answer is: “yes, but<br />

only in parts”. Let me summarize my results by<br />

evaluating the usefulness of the VoC approach<br />

for every research step in a comparative analysis<br />

(table 5).


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

Table 5. Concluding evaluation of VoC’s application to post-communist economies<br />

Research steps in a comparative analysis of post-communist economies<br />

VoC’s<br />

usefulness<br />

1. Classification of institutions Yes<br />

2. Explaining origin institutions No<br />

3. Explaining institutional development (enforcement of institutions) No<br />

4. Classifying type of market economy based on coordination Yes/No<br />

5. Explaining link between complementary institutions and economic success Yes<br />

Source: Own elaboration<br />

As I argued before, the VoC approach can<br />

be used as analytical framework and point<br />

of departure to classify formal economic<br />

institutions (step 1). The VoC approach is also<br />

partly useful to identify which market economy<br />

has emerged in post-communist countries<br />

(step 4). Thus, it can help shed some light on<br />

the formal institutional diversity of capitalist<br />

systems. Furthermore, its theoretical insights<br />

can be used to test the relationship between<br />

institutional complementarity and economic<br />

performance (step 5). However, the VoC<br />

approach in its current form has difficulties<br />

explaining institutional origin and institutional<br />

development of institutions (step 2, 3) and<br />

needs to be extended by theories of institutional<br />

change (e.g. New Institutional Economics,<br />

Historical institutionalism) in order to account<br />

for institutional enforcement and other actors<br />

(e.g. the state) than firms.<br />

On the whole, Hall/Soskice’s VoC approach<br />

can only be restrictively applied to postcommunist<br />

economies. Post-communist<br />

transition demonstrates that institutional<br />

complementarity is not a short-term project.<br />

Complementarity is more difficult to create<br />

in times of turmoil, rapid socio-economic<br />

change, low state capacity and diverse interests<br />

of actors. Although there are also diverse<br />

actors in stable and developed economies,<br />

well-enforced institutions control both state<br />

actors and other groups from predation<br />

(rent seeking, state capture). The dynamism<br />

of transition implies that mechanisms other<br />

than complementarities explain institutional<br />

diversity and performance. It has been argued<br />

that enforcement rather than complementarity<br />

is such a mechanism. If enforcement of rules<br />

is guaranteed, institutional stability will<br />

produce a good business climate for economic<br />

cooperation, innovation and FDI.<br />

What are the implications of institutional<br />

complementarity for future Seite Page page 33<br />

reforms? As certain institutions (e.g.<br />

financial institutions and institutions<br />

regarding inter-firm relations) are established<br />

with less financial resources and<br />

time than others (e.g. educational or labor


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

market institutions), there is room for the<br />

design of pair-wise institutional complementarities.<br />

However, an entire complementary<br />

institutional system (including core and peripheral<br />

institutions) is a long-term project<br />

that cannot be designed and implemented in<br />

several years. Therefore, the concept of institutional<br />

complementarity can be applied mainly<br />

in countries where the capacity for enforcement<br />

of institutions works (the developed<br />

West, advanced transition countries). Where<br />

the capacity for enforcement is low (the CIS,<br />

SEE), a first step should be the strengthening<br />

of enforcement and only then the fine<br />

tuning of efficiency through complementarity.<br />

In other words: Prefer second-best institutions<br />

that are implemented over first-best<br />

institutions that are not enforced (need for<br />

“small and pragmatic solutions that work” in<br />

the short-run).<br />

NOTES<br />

1<br />

The notion of „Central Asian capitalism“ still does not appear in<br />

the literature. However, a recently initiated research project aims<br />

to discover whether a distinct form of capitalism is emerging in<br />

Central Asia. For details see www.centralasiaproject.de.<br />

2<br />

The concept of institutional complementarity was debated in<br />

detail elsewhere (Boyer 2005; Deeg 2005; Amable 2003; Crouch<br />

et al. 2005; Streeck 2004; Höpner 2005).<br />

3<br />

Hall/Soskice define efficiency as the “net returns to the use of an<br />

institution given its costs” (Hall/Soskice 2001, p. 17).<br />

4<br />

Note that Hall/Soskice’s notion of institutions also includes<br />

organizations (Hall/Soskice, p. 9-10). Therefore, institutional<br />

complementarity should not be understood as a complementarity<br />

among rules only, but also among policies, relationships, strategies<br />

and skills.<br />

5<br />

On the coherence of the classical communist system (Stalinist<br />

system), see Kornai 1992.<br />

6<br />

In reality, this is seldom the case, especially in countries that lack<br />

the political institutions to control the grand designer (state).<br />

7<br />

For the impact of communist legacies (initial conditions) on<br />

institutional and economic outcomes during transition, see Jowitt<br />

1992; Elster/Offe/Preuss 1998; Ekiert/Hanson 2003; Fischer/<br />

Gelb 1991; De Melo et al. 1998; Falcetti et al. 2000.<br />

Seite Page page 34<br />

8<br />

According to Michel Camdessus, the former managing director of<br />

the International Monetary Fund, “…there was no master plan<br />

and scarce relevant experience to guide action. In the economic<br />

sphere, a host of proposals quickly filled the vacuum, jostling with<br />

the force of events and circumstance to determine what happened”<br />

(Camdessus 1999, p. 9).<br />

9<br />

In Hungary’s June parliamentary session in 1999, the majority<br />

of EU-required laws were passed in parliament without any<br />

debate (see Schimmelfennig/Sedelmeier 2005, p. 2).


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

10<br />

Despite these different average results, there are some exceptions<br />

in these two groups of countries. In the period 1990-1995, Hungary<br />

had a constantly high share of shadow economy (approx.<br />

30%). Uzbekistan (around 10%) and Belarus (around 15%) had<br />

instead relatively low ones.<br />

11<br />

The better structural and economic conditions in CEE in<br />

contrast to the CIS are reflected in better starting conditions.<br />

For evidence, see the initial conditions indicator in the EBRD<br />

Transition Report 1999, p. 29.<br />

12<br />

The rule of law indicator „measures the extent to which agents<br />

have confidence in and abide by the rules of society, in particular<br />

the quality of contract enforcement, police, and courts, as well as<br />

the likelihood of crime and violence (http://info.worldbank.org/<br />

governance/wgi/pdf/rl.pdf ).<br />

13<br />

The quality of legislation (“laws on the books”) is based on<br />

the EBRD’s annually conducted survey of legal experts from 27<br />

transition countries. See legal annex of various EBRD Transition<br />

reports.<br />

14<br />

By analyzing the effectiveness of corporate governance laws,<br />

the 2005 EBRD survey tries to reveal how well minority shareholders<br />

are protected in each transition country. Legal effectiveness<br />

is assessed in terms of information disclosure for minority<br />

shareholders and effective mechanisms to obtain redress (legal<br />

actions).<br />

15<br />

See EBRD Concession assessment project report on the quality<br />

of concession legislation in early transition countries. http://<br />

www.ebrd.org/country/sector/law/etc/etccon.pdf.<br />

16<br />

On the different degrees of enforcement regarding employment<br />

protection legislation in the CIS, SEE, and CEE, see Rutkowski/<br />

Scarpetta 2005, p. 37.<br />

17<br />

Sources: Experts’ assessment from the Central European Economic<br />

Review; EBRD legal indicator surveys; World Business<br />

Environment and Enterprise Performance (BEEPS) survey (see<br />

Pistor et al. 2000, p.341-342).<br />

18<br />

This is particularly true in a rapidly changing environment,<br />

when newly introduced rules are only forms without meaning.<br />

Then it is more plausible that the direction of influence goes<br />

mainly from actors to institutions.<br />

19<br />

Internal actors are political parties with opposing ideologies<br />

(e.g. former communists, non-communists), oligarchs, business<br />

groups, trade unions and cultural or military elites.<br />

20<br />

Hellman and Kaufmann define state capture as „ the efforts<br />

of firms to shape the laws, policies, and regulations of the state to<br />

their own advantage by providing illicit private gains to public<br />

officials“ (Hellmann/ Kaufmann 2001).<br />

21<br />

The EU’s influence on institutional development has been<br />

acknowledged by the Europeanization literature (Grabbe 2001;<br />

Schimmelfennig/Sedelmeier 2005; Vachudova 2005) and the<br />

most recent VoC literature (Menz 2005; Schmidt 2002; Callaghan<br />

2008).<br />

22<br />

On policy complementarities during transition, see Braga De<br />

Macedo/Martins 2008; Staehr 2005.<br />

23<br />

Although most economies tend to shift towards the liberal model<br />

of coordination, Paunescu/Schneider’s study shows that France<br />

and Belgium moved between 1990 and 1999 in the opposite<br />

direction, i.e. towards more state coordination. On the switching<br />

of coordination regimes, see Paunescu/Schneider 2004.<br />

24<br />

There are more options to achieve institutional efficiency than<br />

in developed states. This was, for instance, the case when Taiwan,<br />

South Korea and Singapore were transition/developing<br />

countries and achieved economic success by developing a different<br />

type of capitalism than in the West.<br />

25<br />

The assumption of a beneficial effect of enforcement<br />

is only true when there is no predatory authoritarian<br />

regime, who has designed institutions<br />

to their benefit and who maintains the status quo<br />

by force.<br />

Seite Page page 35


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Ahrens, Joachim, 2002: Governance and Economic Development.<br />

A Comparative Institutional Approach. Cheltenham:<br />

Edward Elgar.<br />

Albert, Michel, 1993: Capitalism against Capitalism, London:<br />

Whurr Publishers.<br />

Amable, Bruno, 2003: The Diversity of Modern Capitalism.<br />

Oxford: Oxford University Press.<br />

Aslund, Anders, 1991: Principles of Privatization. In: Laszlo<br />

Csaba (eds.), Systemic change and stabilization in Eastern<br />

Europe. Dartmouth, U.K.: Aldershot, 17-31.<br />

Boyer, Robert, 2005: Coherence, Diversity and Evolution of<br />

Capitalisms: The Institutional Complementarity Hypothesis.<br />

Minda de Gunzburg Center for European Studies Working<br />

Paper. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University.<br />

Braga De Macedo, Jorge/ Joaquim Oliveira Martins 2008:<br />

Growth, Reform Indicators and Policy Complementarities. In:<br />

Economics of Transition 16 (2), 141-164.<br />

Buchen, Clemens, 2007: Estonia and Slovenia as Antipodes. In:<br />

David Lane/Martin Myant (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism in<br />

Post-Communist Countries, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillian,<br />

65-89.<br />

Callaghan, Helen, 2008: How Multilevel Governance Affects<br />

the Clash of Capitalisms MPIfG Discussion Paper 08 / 5<br />

Seite Page page 36<br />

Bartlett, Will, 2007: The Western Balkans. In: David Lane,<br />

Martin Myant (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism in the Post-<br />

Communist Countries, London: Palgrave, 201-220.<br />

Berg, Andrew, 1994: Does Macroeconomic Reform Cause<br />

Structural Adjustments? Lesson from Poland. In: Journal of<br />

Comparative Economics 18 (3), 376-409.<br />

Berglöf, Erik/Gérard Roland 1997: The EU as an “Outside<br />

Anchor” for Transition Reforms, Working Paper No. 132. Stockholm:<br />

Stockholm Institute of Transition Economies.<br />

Blyth, Mark, 2003: Same as It Never Was: Temporality and<br />

Typology in the Varieties of Capitalism, Comparative European<br />

Politics, 1 (2): 215-25.<br />

Bohle, Dorothee/Béla Greskovits 2007: The State, Internationalization,<br />

and Capitalist Diversity in Eastern Europe.<br />

Competition & Change 11(2): 89-115.<br />

Boycko, Maxim, 1992: When Higher Incomes<br />

Reduce Welfare: Queues, Labor Supply, and Macro<br />

Equilibrium in Socialist Economies. In: Quarterly<br />

Journal of Economics, 107(3), 907-20.<br />

Calvert, Randall, 1995: Rational Actors, Equilibrium, and<br />

Social Institutions. In: Jack Knight and Itai Sened (eds.), Explaining<br />

Social Institutions, Ann Arbor: University of Michigan<br />

Press, 57-95.<br />

Camdessus, Michel, 2001: Opening Address. In: Oleh Havrylyshyn/Saleh<br />

M., Nsouli (eds.): A Decade of Transition: Achievements<br />

and Challenges, Washington: International Monetary<br />

Fund, p. 9-11.<br />

Cernat, Lucian 2006: Europeanization, Varieties of Capitalism<br />

and Economic Performance in Central and Eastern Europe<br />

(New York: Palgrave).<br />

Charman, Ken, 2007: Kazakhstan, A State-Led Liberalized<br />

Market Economy? In: David Lane/Martin Myant (eds.), Varieties<br />

of Capitalism in Post-Communist Countries, Basingstoke:<br />

Palgrave Macmillian,165-182.<br />

Christophe, Barbara, 2007: Georgia: Capitalism as Organized<br />

Chaos. In: David Lane/Martin Myant (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism<br />

in Post-Communist Countries, Basingstoke: Palgrave<br />

Macmillian, 183-200


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

Crouch, Colin, 2005: Capitalist Diversity and Change: Recombinant<br />

Governance and Institutional Entrepreneurs. Oxford:<br />

Oxford University Press.<br />

Crouch, Colin, Robert Boyer, Wolfgang Streeck, Bruno Amable,<br />

Peter A. Hall and Gregory Jackson, 2005: Dialogue on Institutional<br />

Complementarity and Political Economy. In: Socio-<br />

Economic Review 3, 2, 359-382.<br />

Jackson, Gregory and Richard Deeg, 2006: How Many Varieties<br />

of Capitalism? Comparing the Comparative Institutional<br />

Analyses of Capitalist Diversity. MPIfG Discussion Paper<br />

06/2. Cologne: Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies. <<br />

http://www.mpi-fg-koeln.mpg.de/pu/mpifg_dp/dp06-2.pdf ><br />

EBRD, 1999: Transition Report 1999. Ten Years of Transition,<br />

London 1999<br />

Crowley, Stephen 2008: Does Labor Still Matter? Eastern Europe,<br />

the Varieties of Capitalism, and the European Social Model.<br />

NCEER Working Paper (April 2, 2008).<br />

Deeg, Richard 2005: Complementarity and institutional Change:<br />

How Useful a Concept?, Discussion Paper SP II 2005-21,<br />

Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin, 2005<br />

Deeg, Richard, 2007: Complementarity and institutional change<br />

in capitalist systems, In: Journal of European Public Policy, 14<br />

(4), 611-630<br />

Deeg, Richard/Gregory Jackson, 2007: Towards A More Dynamic<br />

Theory of Capitalist Variety. In: Socio-Economic Review 5,<br />

149-180.<br />

De Melo, Martha/Cevdet Denizer/Alan Gelb/Stoyan Tenev,<br />

1998: Circumstances and Choice: The Role of Initial Conditions<br />

and Policies in Transition Economies, World Bank Policy Research<br />

Working Paper no. 1866<br />

Demsetz, Harold, 1967: Towards a Theory of Property Rights.<br />

In: The American Economic Review, 57 (2), 347-359.<br />

Dewatripont, Mathias, and Gérard Roland, 1995: The Design<br />

of Reform Packages Under Uncertainty. In: American Economic<br />

Review 85, 1207–23.<br />

EBRD, 2006: Transition Report 2006. Finance in Transition,<br />

London 2006<br />

Ekiert, Grzegorz/Stephen E. Hanson, 2003: Time, Space<br />

and Institutional Change in Central and Eastern Europe in:<br />

Ekiert, Grzegorz / Stephen. E. Hanson, (eds.): Capitalism<br />

and Democracy in Central and Eastern Europe: Assessing the<br />

Legacy of Communist Rule, Cambridge 2003, 15-48<br />

Falcetti, Elisabetta/Martin Raiser/ Peter Sanfey, 2000:<br />

Defying the Odds: Initial Conditions, Reforms and Growth in<br />

the First Decade of Transition, EBRD Working Paper no. 55<br />

Feldmann, Magnus, 2007: The Origins of the Varieties of<br />

Capitalism: Lessons from Post-Socialist Transition in Estonia<br />

and Slovenia. In: Bob Hancke/Martin Rhodes/Mark Thatcher<br />

(eds.), Beyond Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict, Contradictions,<br />

and Complementarities in the European Economy, Oxford:<br />

Oxford University Press, 328-350<br />

Fischer, Stanley/Gelb, Alan, 1991: The Process of Socialist<br />

Economic Transformation. In: Journal of Economic Perspectives<br />

5 (4), 91-105.<br />

Gates, Susan/ Paul Milgrom/ John Roberts 1993: Complementarities<br />

in the Transition from Socialism: A Firm-Level<br />

Analysis. Mimeo, Stanford University, 1993.<br />

Drahokoupil, Jan, 2008: After Transition: Varieties of Political-<br />

Economic Development in Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet<br />

Union. In: Comparative European Politics, 6(3), forthcoming.<br />

Goodin, Robert E. 1996: The Theory of Institutional<br />

Design. Cambridge: Cambridge University<br />

Press.<br />

Seite Page page 37<br />

Goodin, Robert. 2003. “Choose Your Capitalism?” Comparative<br />

European Politics 1 (2): 203-13.


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

Seite Page page 38<br />

Grabbe, Heather, 2001: How does Europeanization Affect<br />

CEE Governance? Conditionality, Diffusion and Diversity.<br />

In: Journal of European Public Policy, 8 (6), 1013-1031.<br />

Greif, Avner 1998: Historical and Comparative Institutional<br />

AnalysisAuthor(s):The American Economic Review, Vol. 88,<br />

No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of theHundred and Tenth Annual<br />

Meeting of the American Economic Association, (May, 1998),<br />

pp.80-84Published by: American Economic Association.<br />

Hall, Peter 2006: Stabilität und Wandel in den Spielarten<br />

des Kapitalismus in Jens Beckert, Bernard Ebbinghaus, Anke<br />

Hassel, Philip Manow (eds). Festschrift for Wolfgang Streeck<br />

Frankfurt: Campus Verlag, 2006.<br />

Hall, Peter A./Daniel W. Gingerich, 2004: Varieties of Capitalism<br />

and Institutional Complementarities in the Political<br />

Economy: An Empirical Analysis. MPIfG Discussion Paper<br />

04/5. Cologne: MaxPlanck Institute for the Study of Societies.<br />

<br />

Hall, Peter A./David Soskice, 2001: An Introduction to Varieties<br />

of Capitalism. In: Peter A. Hall/David Soskice (eds.), Varieties<br />

of Capitalism: Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage.<br />

Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1–68.<br />

Hall, Peter A./David Soskice, 2003: Varieties of Capitalism and<br />

Institutional Change: A Response to Three Critics. In: Comparative<br />

European Politics 1, 241-250.<br />

Hall, Peter A./Kathleen Thelen, 2005: Institutional Change in<br />

Varieties of Capitalism. Conference Paper. American Political<br />

Science Association Annual Meeting, Washington, 1 September<br />

2005.<br />

Hancké, Bob/Martin Rhodes/Mark Thatcher (eds.),<br />

2007: Beyond Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict<br />

Contradictions, and Complementarities in the European<br />

Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.<br />

Hanson Philip, Elizabeth, Teague 2007: Russian Political Capitalism<br />

and its Environment In: David Lane/Martin Myant<br />

(eds.), Varieties of Capitalism in Post-Communist Countries,<br />

Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillian, 149-65.<br />

Havrylyshyn, Oleh 2006: Divergent Paths in Post-Communist<br />

Transformation. Capitalism for All or Capitalism for the Few?<br />

Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.<br />

Havrylyshyn, Oleh 2007: Fifteen Years of Transformation in the<br />

Post-Communist World Rapid Reformers Outperformed Gradualists,<br />

CATO Development Policy Analysis paper no. 4<br />

Hellman, Joel S./Geraint Jones/Daniel Kaufmann, 2000:<br />

Seize the State, Seize the Day. State Capture, Corruption and<br />

Influence. In: Transition. Policy Research Working Paper 2444,<br />

September 2000. Washington: World Bank/World Bank Institute<br />

& European Bank of Reconstruction and Development.<br />

Hellman, Joel S./Daniel Kaufmann, 2001: Confronting the<br />

Challenge of State Capture in Transition Economies. In: Finance<br />

& Development – A quarterly magazine of the IMF, 38 (3).<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/2001/09/hellman.<br />

htm<br />

Higley, John/ Michael G. Burton 2006: Elite Foundations of<br />

Liberal Democracy, Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield<br />

Higley, John/ Jan Pakulski/ Włodzimierz Wesołowski: Postcommunist<br />

Elites and Democracy in Eastern Europe. Basingstoke:<br />

Macmillan, 1998<br />

Höpner, Martin, 2005: What Connects Industrial Relations and<br />

Corporate Governance? Explaining Institutional Complementarity.<br />

In: Socio-Economic Review 3, 331–358.<br />

Iankova Elena A. 2002: Eastern European Capitalism in the<br />

Making. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Hanson, Philip, 2007: The European Union’s influence on<br />

the development of Capitalism in Central Europe. In: David<br />

Lane (ed.), The Transformation of State Socialism, Basingstoke:<br />

Palgrave Macmillian, 95-112.<br />

Johnson, Simon/Daniel Kaufmann/Andrei Shleifer/Marshall I.<br />

Goldman/Martin L.Weitzman 1997: The Unofficial Economy<br />

in Transition, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2(1997),<br />

159-239


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

Johnson, Juliet, 2003: Past Dependency or Path Contingency?<br />

Institutional Design in Post-Communist Financial Systems. In:<br />

Grzegorz Ekiert and Stephen Hanson (eds.), Capitalism and<br />

Democracy in Central and Eastern Europe: Assessing the Legacy<br />

of Communist Rule, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,<br />

289-316.<br />

Jowitt, Ken, 1992: The Leninist Legacy. In: Jowitt, Kenn (ed.):<br />

New World Disorder: The Leninist Extinction, Berkeley: University<br />

of California Press, 284-305.<br />

Kaufmann, Daniel/Aart Kraay/Massimo Mastruzzi 2008:<br />

Governance Matters VII: Aggregate and Individual Governance<br />

Indicators, 1996-2007. World Bank Policy Research Working<br />

Paper No. 4654.<br />

Kenworthy, Lane, 2006: Institutional Coherence and Macroeconomic<br />

Performance. In: Socio-Economic Review 4, 69–91.<br />

King, Lawrence, 2007. Central European Capitalism in Comparative<br />

Perspective. In: Bob Hancke/Martin Rhodes/Mark<br />

Thatcher (eds.), Beyond Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict, Contradictions,<br />

and Complementarities in the European Economy,<br />

Oxford: Oxford University Press, 307-327.<br />

Knell, Mark/Martin Srholec, 2007: Diverging Pathways in<br />

Central and Eastern Europe. In: David Lane/Martin Myant<br />

(eds.), Varieties of Capitalism in Post-Communist Countries,<br />

Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillian, 40–62.<br />

Korosteleva, Julia, 2007: Belarus: Heading towards State Capitalism?<br />

In: David Lane/Martin Myant (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism<br />

in Post-Communist Countries, Basingstoke: Palgrave<br />

Macmillian, 221-238.<br />

Kornai János, 1992, The Socialist System. The Political Economy<br />

of Communism, Oxford: Oxford University Press<br />

Lane, David, 2007: Post-State Socialism: A Diversity of Capitalisms?<br />

In: David Lane/Martin Myant (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism<br />

in Post-Communist Countries, Basingstoke: Palgrave<br />

Macmillian, 13–39.<br />

Lipton, David/Jeffrey Sachs, 1990: Creating a Market Economy<br />

in Eastern Europe: The Case of Poland. Brookings Papers on<br />

Economic Activity, 1990, (1), 75-133<br />

Mayntz, Renate, 2007: The Architecture of Multi-level Governance<br />

of Economic Sectors, MPIfG Discussion Paper 07/13.<br />

McFaul, Michael, 1998: Institutional Design, Uncertainty,<br />

and Path Dependency during Transitions: Cases from Russia.<br />

In: Constitutional Political Economy, 10, 27–52.<br />

McKinnon, Ronald, 1991: The order of economic liberalization.<br />

Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.<br />

Menz, Georg, 2005: Varieties of Capitalism and Europeanization.<br />

Oxford: Oxford University Press.<br />

Mukand, Sharun W./ Dani Rodrik 2005: In Search of the Holy<br />

Grail: Policy Convergence, Experimentation, and Economic<br />

Performance, The American Economic Review, 95 (1), 374-<br />

383.<br />

Murphy, Kevin/ Andrei Shleifer/ Robert Vishny 1992: The<br />

Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform,<br />

In: Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(3), 889-906.<br />

Myant, Martin, 2007: The Czech Republic: From “Czech”<br />

Capitalism to “European” Capitalism, In: David Lane/Martin<br />

Myant (eds.), Varieties of Capitalism in Post-Communist<br />

Countries, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillian, 105–123.<br />

Mykhnenko, Vlad, 2007: Strengths and weaknesses of ‘weak<br />

co-ordination’: Economic institutions, revealed comparative<br />

advantages, and socio-economic performance of mixed market<br />

economies in Poland and Ukraine. In: Bob Hancke/<br />

Martin Rhodes/Mark Thatcher (eds.), Beyond<br />

Varieties of Capitalism: Conflict, Contradictions,<br />

and Complementarities in the European Economy,<br />

Oxford: Oxford University Press, 351-378.<br />

Ostrom, Elinor, 2005: Understanding Institutional Diversity.<br />

Princeton: Princeton University Press.<br />

Seite Page page 39


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

Paunescu, Mihai / Martin Schneider, 2004: Wettbewerbsfähigkeit<br />

und Dynamik institutioneller Standortbedingungen:<br />

Ein empirischer Test des “Varieties of Capitalism”-Ansatzes.<br />

In: Schmollers Jahrbuch 124(1), 31-59.<br />

Pistor, Katharina/Martin Raiser/ Stanislaw Gelfer: Law and<br />

Finance in Transition Economies. In: Economics of Transition<br />

8(2), 325-368.<br />

Poznanski, Kazimierz, 1996: Poland’s Protracted Transition:<br />

Institutional Change and Economic Growth. 1970-1994.<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Portes, Richard, 1990: Introduction to Economic Transformation<br />

of Hungary and Poland, In: European Economy 43, 11-<br />

18.<br />

Sachs, Jeffrey, 1993: Poland’s jump to the market economy.<br />

Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.<br />

Sadurski, Wojciech 2006: EU Enlargement and Democracy in<br />

New Member States. In Wojciech Sadurski/Adam Czarnota/<br />

Martin Krygier (eds.), Spreading Democracy and the Rule of<br />

Law? The Impact of Enlargement on the Rule of Law, Democracy<br />

and Constitutionalism in Post-Communist Legal Orders,<br />

Springer: Dordrecht, 27-49.<br />

Schimmelfennig, Frank/Ulrich Sedelmeier, 2005: The Europeanization<br />

of Central and Eastern Europe, Ithaca: Cornell<br />

University Press.<br />

Schmidt, Vivien A., 2002: The Futures of European Capitalism.<br />

New York: Oxford University Press.<br />

Przeworski, Adam, 1991: Democracy and the market: Political<br />

and economic reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America.<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991.<br />

Schmidt, Vivien A., 2008: European Political Economy: Labour<br />

Out, State Back In, Firm to the Fore. In: West European Politics,<br />

31 (1), 302-320.<br />

Ramasastry, Anita, 2002: What Local Lawyers Think: A<br />

retrospective on the EBRD’s Legal Indicator Surveys Law in<br />

Transition (European Bank for Reconstruction and Development.<br />

In: Law in Transition (Autumn 2002), 14-30.<br />

Shepsle, Kenneth A., 1989: Studying Institutions. Some Lessons<br />

from the Rational Choice Approach. In: Journal of Theoretical<br />

Politics 1, 131-147.<br />

Seite Page page 40<br />

Roland, Gerard 2002: The Political Economy of Transition. In:<br />

The Journal of Economic Perspectives 16 (1), 29-50.<br />

Roland, Gerard 2004. Understanding Institutional Change:<br />

Fast-Moving and Slow-Moving Institutions. In: Studies in<br />

Comparative International Development 38 (4), 109-131.<br />

Rona-Tas, Akos, 1997: Social Engineering and Historical<br />

Legacies: Privatization and the Business Elite in Hungary<br />

and the Czech Republic, in: Beverly Crawford /<br />

Arend Lijphart, (eds.): Liberalization and Leninist<br />

Legacies: Comparative Perspectives on Democratic<br />

Transitions, Berkeley: University of California<br />

Press 126-141.<br />

Rutkowski, Jan J./Stefano Scarpetta 2005: Enhancing Job<br />

Opportunities. Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union.<br />

Washington: The World Bank.<br />

Staehr, Karsten, 2005: Economic reforms in transition economies:<br />

Complementarity, sequencing. and speed’, European Journal of<br />

Comparative Economics, 2(2), 177-202.<br />

Stark, David 1996: Recombinant Property in East European<br />

Capitalism. The American Journal of Sociology, 101 (4), 993-<br />

1027.<br />

Stark, David/László, Bruszt, 1998: Postsocialist Pathways:<br />

Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe.<br />

New York: Cambridge University Press.<br />

Streeck, Wolfgang, 2004: Taking Uncertainty Seriously: Complementarity<br />

as a Moving Target. In: Österreichische Nationalbank<br />

Wien (Hrsg.), Proceedings of OeNB Workshops 1(1). Wien:<br />

Österreichische Nationalbank, 101–115.


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

Szalai, Julia, 2005: “Poverty and the Traps of Postcommunist<br />

Welfare Reforms in Hungary: A Fourth World of Welfare Capitalism<br />

on the Rise?” , Paper prepared for the Annual Conference<br />

of RC19, ISA on “Retheorizing Welfare States: Restructuring<br />

States, Restructuring Analysis”, Chicago 2005 http://www.<br />

northwester.edu/rc19/Szalai.pdf<br />

Tholen, Jochen 2005; Young Entrepreneurs in the New market<br />

Economies: Cultural and social Capital as a Basis for Economic<br />

Capital. In: Sokratis M. Koniordos (ed): Networks, trust and<br />

social capital: theoretical and empirical, Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing,<br />

225-243.<br />

UNECE 2001: Economic Survey of Europe, 2001 No. 1. Economic<br />

Commission for Europe, Geneva<br />

Vachudova, Milada Anna, 2005: Europe Undivided. Democracy,<br />

Leverage, and Integration After Communism, Oxford: Oxford<br />

University Press.<br />

Watson, Michael, 2003: Ricardian Political Economy and the<br />

Varieties of Capitalism Approach: Specialisation, Trade and<br />

Comparative Institutional Advantage, Comparative European<br />

Politics 1 (2): 227-40.<br />

Whitley, Richard, 1999: Divergent Capitalisms: The Social<br />

Structuring of Business Systems. Oxford: Oxford University<br />

Press.<br />

Williamson, Oliver E., 1985: The Economic Institutions of<br />

Capitalism. New York: The Free Press.<br />

World Bank 2002: Transition. The First Ten Years. Analysis<br />

and Lessons for Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union.<br />

Washington: The World Bank.<br />

Woodruff, David M., 1999: Money Unmade: Barter and the<br />

Fate of Russian Capitalism. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University<br />

Press, 146-202.<br />

Seite Page page 41<br />

Zecchini, Salvatore, 1997: Lessons from the Economic Transition:<br />

Central and Eastern Europe in the 1990s. Dordrecht:<br />

Kluwer Academic Publishers.


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

APPENDIX<br />

Figure 2. Perception of commercial law extensiveness over time<br />

Source: Ramastry 2002 and EBRD Legal Indicator Survey 1997-2001.<br />

Figure 3. Perception of commercial law effectiveness over time<br />

Seite Page page 42<br />

Source: Ramastry 2002 and EBRD Legal Indicator Survey 1997-2001.


MARTIN SEMENOVA MENDELSKI<br />

Figure 4. Extensiveness and effectiveness of insolvency legal regimes<br />

Source: EBRD Legal Indicator Survey, 2004.<br />

Seite Page page 43


THE VOC EINLEITUNG APPROACH GOES EAST<br />

Figure 5. Rule of law in Central and Eastern Europe<br />

Seite Page page 44<br />

Source: Kaufmann/Kraay/Mastruzzi 2008: Governance Matters VII: Governance Indicators for 1996-2007.


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

SUMMARY<br />

3<br />

POLISH BUSINESS – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

AND THEIR IMPACT ON NATIONAL LOBBYING<br />

AT THE EU LEVEL<br />

Agnieszka K. Cianciara<br />

There are differences in businesspolitics<br />

relations between CEEC and<br />

Western Europe that stem from the<br />

specificities of the post-communist capitalist<br />

model. The communist heritage, as well<br />

the three simultaneous processes of change<br />

(transformation to capitalism and democracy,<br />

Europeanization, globalization) have created<br />

hybrid institutions at the CEE national level.<br />

Polish capitalism is characterized by significant<br />

public sector, weak corporate governance<br />

mechanisms, relatively poor business climate,<br />

inefficient governance structures and weak<br />

institutionalization of civil and social dialogue,<br />

as well as extremely weak legitimization of<br />

lobbying. This is translated into specific types<br />

of relations between business and political<br />

elites: clientelistic relations of state-owned<br />

companies, oligarchic relations of biggest<br />

national private companies and weak organization<br />

of SMEs, while professional lobbying<br />

strategies are used mostly by multinational<br />

companies. How do these domestic patterns<br />

of relations between business and politics<br />

affect mobilization, resources and strategies<br />

of Polish business interest representation at<br />

the EU level? It appears that post-communist<br />

formal and informal heritage still plays an<br />

important role in politics-business relations.<br />

In the Polish case, this is manifested in the<br />

degree of embeddedness in domestic<br />

clientelistic and oligarchic networks,<br />

the level of internationalization and Seite Page page 45<br />

resulting autonomy vis-a-vis national<br />

political elites, as well as a lack of tradition,<br />

institutionalization and legitimization<br />

of pluralist interest representation.


POLISH BUSINESS REFERENCES LITERATUR – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

Twenty years after the fall of communism,<br />

Central-European member states of the<br />

EU are still struggling with the transition to<br />

democratic market capitalism (Hancke, et al.,<br />

2007). It is argued that the Polish economy<br />

has not yet reached the level of institutional<br />

development comparable to developed economies<br />

of Western Europe. According to the<br />

World Bank, in 2009 Poland was still classified<br />

as an ‘emerging market’, although it shifted,<br />

together with Hungary, to the sub-group of<br />

‘advanced emerging markets’ 1 . Economically,<br />

Poland should be perceived, in the light<br />

of the theory of world system, in terms of<br />

‘semi-periphery’ or ‘internal periphery’ of<br />

the European Union ( Jasiecki, 2004). Other<br />

authors differentiate between Visegrad and<br />

Baltic countries, while treating the latter as<br />

‘semi-periphery’ and characterizing the former<br />

by ‘semi-core’ features (Greskovits, 2008).<br />

In this article, I argue that differences in the<br />

development of capitalism and market economy<br />

between the Western and Eastern members of<br />

the European Union (EU) are translated into<br />

divergent patterns of relations between politics<br />

and business at the national level. In turn, these<br />

patterns affect mobilization, resources and<br />

strategies of business representatives at the EU<br />

level. The EU business lobbying environment<br />

is determined by Western models<br />

of consolidated democracy and<br />

Seite Page page 46<br />

developed market economy. Thus,<br />

the observed institutional differences<br />

between national CEE and European<br />

levels explain, to a significant extent, the<br />

perceived ineffectiveness of Polish national<br />

lobbying in EU institutions. Both scholars<br />

and public affairs practitioners would argue<br />

that the effectiveness of lobbyists in the EU<br />

depends on the position and function lobbying<br />

occupies in their country of origin (Van<br />

Schendelen, 1994, p. 15; Greenwood, 2007,<br />

p. 14; Chorus, 05.03.2007). Consequently,<br />

in order to analyze strengths and weaknesses<br />

of national interest representation, one must<br />

look at the institutional environment at the<br />

national level, which provides opportunities<br />

but also constraints and barriers to active<br />

and effective lobbying strategies. Among the<br />

intervening variables, one does not only find<br />

the critical resource dependencies (Beyres<br />

& Kerremans, 2007), but also institutional,<br />

structural and normative specificities of the<br />

Central-European context of post-communist<br />

(advanced) emerging economy.<br />

The particularities of Central-European, or<br />

in this case Polish, capitalism stem from the<br />

incomplete consolidation of the formal market<br />

institutions, as well as from the informal socialist<br />

heritage, which is present in the spheres of both<br />

economic and political governance. Within the<br />

transformation process, the emerging marketoriented<br />

network of institutions is constrained<br />

by path dependency. Thus transformation is of<br />

incremental and continuous nature, as various<br />

actors attempt to improve their situation by<br />

forcing subsequent institutional changes (North,<br />

1999). Consequently, the socialist burden and<br />

the three simultaneous processes of change<br />

(transformation to capitalism and democracy,<br />

Europeanization 2 and globalization) have<br />

created a hybrid environment of formal and<br />

informal institutions. This hybrid institutional<br />

context plays a crucial role regarding relations<br />

between the state and economic, political and<br />

business elites.


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

The institutionalist-evolutionary approach<br />

provides the most adequate perspective for<br />

socio-economic analysis of business-politics<br />

relations in the CEE hybrid environment.<br />

This is in line with the so-called 4 th wave of<br />

transition studies, which are rather suspicious<br />

of modernist logics of linear transformation<br />

and the centrality of markets, liberalization<br />

and liberal politics for the social re-engineering<br />

of post-socialist economy (Pickles, 2008).<br />

Instead, emphasis is put on cultural studies,<br />

social theory, historical legacies and new forms<br />

of regional economic analysis that account for<br />

specificities of state rule and economic practice.<br />

Varieties of post-communist capitalist models<br />

derive from cultural and historical contexts and<br />

greatly depend on the state of institutions in<br />

the initial phase of transformation (Lissowska,<br />

2008).<br />

The purpose of this article is thus to analyse<br />

how business-politics relations at the<br />

national level, structured by the processes of<br />

transformation and consolidation, affect the<br />

effectiveness of Polish lobbying 3 at the EU<br />

level. To this end, I draw on recent literature<br />

on post-socialist politics and economic change,<br />

varieties of capitalism, Europeanization and<br />

business interests at the national and EU levels.<br />

The empirical analysis is carried out on the<br />

basis of interviews (March 2007-March 2009)<br />

with Polish representatives of state-owned<br />

companies, national federations and european<br />

federations based in Brussels.<br />

POLISH CAPITALISM: MAIN FEATURES SHAPING<br />

BUSINESS-POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

The crucial factor shaping capitalism in Poland,<br />

including relations between political and<br />

business elites, is the socialist or post-socialist<br />

heritage transferred directly or indirectly in<br />

the transformation process. Namely, Poland<br />

inherited a system of ‘destroyed capitalism’<br />

(Balcerowicz, 1997). The socialist economy was<br />

based on fundamentally different incentives<br />

and organizational forms than the ones proper<br />

to the market economy. Therefore, remnants<br />

of this system constitute barriers to effective<br />

functioning of mechanisms of the developed<br />

capitalist economy. Under socialism, private<br />

economic activity was subject to strict state<br />

control, notably through the granting of<br />

licenses, or permissions and enforcement of<br />

changeable maximum levels of production,<br />

as well as employment limits. Officially,<br />

social ownership was supported by the state,<br />

regardless of its economic efficiency, while<br />

private initiative was regarded as the necessary<br />

evil. Due to unstable conditions of economic<br />

activities and fully discretionary character of<br />

administrative decisions, the entrepreneurs<br />

were restraining their activities, cutting on<br />

investments, employing temporary, instead<br />

of long distance, business perspectives and<br />

counting for immediate gains without paying<br />

attention to economic or social consequences<br />

of their activities ( Jasiecki, 2002).<br />

Such thinking survived the transition<br />

in the form of lack of strategic<br />

planning, lack of social responsibility<br />

and limited trust towards law or<br />

decision-makers.<br />

Seite Page page 47


POLISH BUSINESS REFERENCES LITERATUR – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

In terms of social status, a paradoxical<br />

situation emerged, where private owners<br />

constituted a privileged group in terms of<br />

income, but operated at the margins of the<br />

official socio-economic life and enjoyed little<br />

social prestige. Growing consent of authorities<br />

to private economic activities resulted only<br />

from the basic needs of the society that<br />

could not be satisfied in the framework of<br />

the normative socialist order. In terms of<br />

assumptions underlying the communist<br />

system, private ownership was perceived as a<br />

systemic deviation. But it led to the emergence<br />

of new pathological phenomena, taking the<br />

form of informal adaptation mechanisms.<br />

The latter involved practices of ‘arranging<br />

things’, abuse of public resources for private<br />

gain, creation of interdependent networks of<br />

the management of state-owned companies,<br />

administration and party officials based on<br />

bribery, as well as trading of permissions and<br />

licenses (Balcerowicz, 1997). These networks<br />

have survived the transformation process,<br />

particularly in the heavy industry sector,<br />

blocking restructuring efforts and privatization<br />

as well as petrifying clientelistic ties between<br />

political and economic elites.<br />

The socialist system led to an emergence of<br />

specific forms of interest representation, fully<br />

dysfunctional from the point of view of market<br />

economy and democratic governance. As the<br />

expression of particularistic interests<br />

was excluded for ideological reasons<br />

Seite Page page 48<br />

and administration enjoyed utterly<br />

arbitrary power over the economy,<br />

influence could only be exerted<br />

through secret and corruptive means. In the<br />

absence of channels of dialogue between the<br />

state and society, corruption became the sole<br />

facilitator of communication with authorities<br />

(Lissowska, 2008).<br />

Economically speaking, transformation from<br />

socialist to market economy consisted of<br />

macroeconomic stabilization, microeconomic<br />

liberalization and institutional change. Due to<br />

serious economic crisis in Poland, emphasis was<br />

placed on the former two while institutional<br />

change was neglected. As a consequence,<br />

market mechanisms were introduced, while<br />

no efficient governance institutions (economic,<br />

judicial, and political) were in place to support,<br />

control and correct those mechanisms in the<br />

first period. This is one of the main elements of<br />

the specificity of hybrid Polish economy, which<br />

is well reflected in the field of privatization and<br />

corporate governance in the privatized and<br />

state-owned companies (Kozarzewski, 2006,<br />

pp. 73-74).<br />

As a consequence, the ‘semi-periphery’ or ‘semicore’<br />

capitalist systems of CEEC have a number<br />

of features that distinguish them from the<br />

developed market economies of Western EU<br />

member states. These features are embedded<br />

in the initial transition paths from socialism<br />

to capitalism 4 . The relative domination of one<br />

of the paths in each particular state determines<br />

the degree of success in transformation to<br />

market economy. Capitalism from above leads<br />

to patron-client relationships, notably typical<br />

for Ukraine and Russia. On the other hand,<br />

capitalism from without, with its substantial<br />

reliance on foreign investors, leads to a more<br />

liberal, but also more externally dependent<br />

market economy (King, Szelenyi, 2005; King,<br />

2007). Foreign direct investments also play an<br />

important role in technology transfer, gradually<br />

modernizing outdated technological structures,


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

resulting from the late and largely obsolete<br />

industrialization under state socialism.<br />

In the Polish case, a crucial role was played<br />

in the privatization process by multinational<br />

corporations, which ensured capital, technology,<br />

know-how and access to foreign markets for<br />

the restructured companies. However, the first<br />

transformation phase was to a large extent<br />

dominated by capitalism from above created<br />

by the economic and technocratic elites of<br />

the ancien regime. Finally, success of private<br />

companies that did not have access to resources<br />

of the socialist economy, only became visible<br />

after the year 2000. The economic crisis in the<br />

late ‘90s eliminated actors that relied mostly on<br />

political resources and were not able to cope<br />

with requirements of the competitive market<br />

economy. The expansion of Polish private<br />

capital was also accelerated by EU membership<br />

and prospects for greater internationalization<br />

of Polish firms. However, it appears that<br />

Europeanization of economic activities has<br />

been progressing faster than Europeanization<br />

of interest representation.<br />

Polish capitalism is thus characterized by a<br />

relatively large public sector (slow pace of<br />

privatization), weak corporate governance<br />

mechanisms (especially in public sector), a<br />

relatively poor business climate, inefficient<br />

governance structures of the state, weak<br />

economic and political culturea, as well as weak<br />

institutionalization of interest representation.<br />

The public sector accounts for approximately 3%<br />

of firms operating in Poland. However, 7 out<br />

of the 10 largest companies in the year 2008<br />

were at least partially state-owned (‘500 biggest<br />

firms in Poland’ by daily Rzeczpospolita, 2009).<br />

In 2005, 162 (12.5%) of 1300 biggest firms<br />

in Poland were at least partially state-owned,<br />

but they generated 22.5% of net income and<br />

employed more than 40% of the workforce<br />

(CASE, 2007). Though in the years 2002-<br />

2007 the number of public firms among the<br />

500 biggest companies decreased from 128<br />

to 81, this was linked to the rapid expansion<br />

of Polish private capital after joining the<br />

EU in 2004, rather than to the process of<br />

privatization. The level of internationalization<br />

of Polish firms is still low and 96.3% of them<br />

are micro-firms, employing up to 9 people<br />

(Ministry of Economy, 2009).<br />

Weaknesses of the corporate governance system<br />

are particularly visible in the biggest stateowned<br />

companies 5 . In post-communist state,<br />

due to private capital shortages, the German<br />

(internal control through supervisory board),<br />

rather than Anglo-Saxon system (external<br />

control mechanisms by dispersed shareholders)<br />

was introduced. However, Central-European<br />

experience shows that control is much<br />

more effective when a company is being<br />

restructured by a foreign strategic investor.<br />

In case of continuous state ownership,<br />

the commercialization of the enterprise<br />

constitutes only a minor adjustment to formal<br />

market requirements, while petrifying existing<br />

economic, political and social networks of<br />

informal nature. Consequently, supervisory<br />

and executive boards of state-owned<br />

companies often demonstrate classic<br />

traits of political corruption ( Jarosz, Seite Page page 49<br />

2006). These executives are strongly<br />

embedded in political elites, thus the<br />

rotation in these posts depends on the current<br />

constellation of the unstable political scene.<br />

Posts are perceived as rewards for party loyalty,


POLISH BUSINESS REFERENCES LITERATUR – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

or a comfortable ‘waiting room’ before entering<br />

into high politics ( Jasiecki, 2004). Research<br />

clearly demonstrated clientelistic dependence<br />

of Polish economic elites on political elites<br />

and the role of the state as both the greatest<br />

investor and client in the economy throughout<br />

the 1990s ( Jasiecki, 2002).<br />

According to World Bank 2009 Doing Business<br />

ranking, Poland occupies position 72 (out of<br />

183 countries examined) when it comes to the<br />

ease of engaging in and conducting economic<br />

activities. There were only 3 EU member<br />

states with even poorer business climate: Czech<br />

Republic (74), Italy (78) and Greece (109).<br />

Moreover, Poland’s position has not changed<br />

over the last 3 years, which suggests a limited<br />

reform effort 6 . The Polish score is also quite<br />

ambivalent: the country enjoys a relatively<br />

high level of investor protection (41), while<br />

rules for granting permits in the construction<br />

sector are among the least business friendly in<br />

the world (164). The generalized problem with<br />

granting permits and licenses in many business<br />

sectors (lengthy and difficult administrative<br />

procedures, high levels of officials’ discretion,<br />

and politicization of decision-making) is highly<br />

conducive to corruptive practices, which is also<br />

confirmed by Poland’s unsatisfactory score in<br />

Transparency International rankings. Finally,<br />

in the 2009 Index of Economic Freedom (Wall<br />

Street Journal and Heritage Foundation),<br />

Poland was classified as the last of all<br />

the EU member states (position 82 out<br />

Seite Page page 50<br />

of 179 countries). Main factors constraining<br />

economic freedom involved:<br />

high level of corruption (as measured<br />

by CPI - corruption perception index),<br />

excessive state intervention in the economy,<br />

as well as inefficiency of the judicial system.<br />

In terms of efficiency of governance structures of<br />

the state, research indicates a prevalent practice<br />

of subordinating long-term goals to short-term<br />

political gains, an underestimation of continuity<br />

and the role of experts, as well as consultative<br />

bodies and procedures in the policy-making<br />

(Raciborski, 2006). Decision-makers perceive<br />

experts’ opinions more in terms of support for<br />

decisions that were already taken, rather than<br />

a factor determining the content of decisions.<br />

Similarly, little understanding for social and<br />

civil dialogue, as well as for socio-economic<br />

programming is observed (Hausner, 2007).<br />

Consequently, decisions in the sphere of socioeconomic<br />

policy produce ineffective, façade<br />

and poorly legitimized solutions. At the same<br />

time, Europeanization of the administration<br />

was visible mostly among young officials of<br />

departments dealing with European affairs<br />

in each ministry. Research conducted in<br />

2005 among Polish officials pointed out their<br />

perceptions of Western administrations as<br />

more professional, less hierarchical, more open<br />

and transparent (Kochanowicz, et al., 2007).<br />

Meanwhile, Polish administration continues<br />

to function within a culture of secrecy, where<br />

power is understood more in terms of privileges<br />

than responsibility, and where technological<br />

and organizational distance from Western<br />

counterparts still poses serious governance<br />

problems.<br />

Empirical material gathered by R. Inglehart<br />

indicates that beliefs and values typical for<br />

the socialist economic system have, to a large<br />

extent, survived the transformation process and<br />

co-exist with the new capitalist institutions.<br />

Polish economic culture is characterized by<br />

egalitarian attitudes, a lack of trust towards<br />

private business and more importance


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

attached to state control, than freedom of<br />

economic activity. Polish society represents<br />

more materialist attitudes (preponderance of<br />

survival values), which results from permanent<br />

deprivation typical for socialist economy. Thus,<br />

despite the remarkable economic development<br />

and growth in welfare over the last 20 years,<br />

Central-European societies are still classified<br />

as materialist. Relative scarcity of postmaterialist<br />

values is also visible among Polish<br />

entrepreneurs, in particular in their attitudes<br />

towards CSR - corporate social responsibility<br />

(Lewicka-Strzałecka, 2006).<br />

Contrary to what is often upheld by Western<br />

scholars, basing their arguments on the<br />

experience of Solidarity movement, Poland is<br />

characterized by weak civil society organization,<br />

together with weak institutionalization of interest<br />

representation. In fact, Polish society has hardly<br />

any traditions of constructive civil involvement,<br />

as it was historically focused on protest and<br />

opposition. Social dialogue in the form of<br />

tripartite councils is formally well established,<br />

but produces questionable results and lacks<br />

autonomy, as it is dominated by the government<br />

(Gardawski et al., 2008). Other forms of<br />

involvement of business interest representation<br />

practiced in the modern governance systems, be<br />

it in the form of consultations in the framework<br />

of impact assessment procedures, or in the form<br />

of public hearings, are frequently of facade<br />

nature. They do not contribute to mobilization<br />

and consolidation of interest groups. Finally,<br />

and contrary to developments at the EU<br />

level, lobbying activities are not legitimized<br />

in Poland and are not considered part and<br />

parcel of the democratic decision-making by<br />

both the public opinion and political elite<br />

(Burson-Marsteller, 2009).<br />

BUSINESS-POLITICS RELATIONS IN POLAND:<br />

FROM TRANSFORMATION TO CONSOLIDATION<br />

PHASE?<br />

The above mentioned characteristics of the<br />

institutional environment of Polish capitalism<br />

structure business-politics relations to a<br />

significant extent. Inefficient governance<br />

structures in the largest (usually state-owned)<br />

companies, a low level of political culture of<br />

decision-makers conducive to high levels of<br />

corruption, a relatively unfavourable business<br />

environment due to substantial administrative<br />

burden and very weak legitimization of<br />

lobbying as an element of democratic<br />

decision-making – all these factors hamper<br />

the development of interest representation<br />

procedures compatible with those developed<br />

at the EU level.<br />

At the same time, patterns of Polish capitalism<br />

are obviously subejct to processes of change<br />

over time. Notably, the pattern of change<br />

from transformation phase to consolidation of<br />

market economy and democratic governance is<br />

assumed, in particular due to Europeanization<br />

process ( Jasiecki, 2008). It is worth underlining<br />

the fact that different companies and sectors<br />

belong to different phases of development<br />

(for instance, compare energy and ICT<br />

sectors). The passage from transformation<br />

to consolidation phase is also linked to the<br />

growing level of autonomy of business<br />

elites from political elites, which<br />

heavily affects their mutual relations. Seite Page page 51<br />

It is expected that with the progress<br />

of consolidation phase, professional<br />

lobbying would gradually weaken and replace<br />

clientelistic and oligarchic ties. Nevertheless,<br />

as experience of Western democracies and


POLISH BUSINESS REFERENCES LITERATUR – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

developed market economies shows, the latter<br />

are never completely eliminated, no matter<br />

how advanced transparency and consultation<br />

procedures are.<br />

It is stressed that the low level of autonomy of<br />

economic elites, typical for the transformation<br />

phase, is reflected in clientelistic relations<br />

of state-owned companies and oligarchic<br />

relations of biggest national private companies<br />

with decision makers ( Jasiecki, 2004,<br />

2008). Another important element is poor<br />

organization and interest representation of<br />

SMEs - small and medium-sized enterprises<br />

(they account for 99.8% of all companies in<br />

Poland). Under such conditions professional<br />

lobbying strategies are used almost exclusively<br />

by foreign and multinational companies, as<br />

they dispose of much higher levels of autonomy<br />

vis-a-vis national political elites.<br />

Thus, if ownership structure and size of firms<br />

are taken as key variables, four strategies of<br />

business-politics relations can be enumerated.<br />

These strategies are typical for economic elites<br />

of the transformation phase, undergoing<br />

a process of professionalization. Whereas<br />

clientelism is the characteristic of relations<br />

maintained by state-owned companies<br />

(especially heavy industry and energy sectors),<br />

the largest Polish private firms tend to exploit<br />

oligarchic links 7 . In terms of professional<br />

interest representation, such strategies<br />

constitute pathological behaviour,<br />

Seite Page page 52<br />

generating corruption and suboptimal<br />

distribution of resources. In Poland,<br />

the most emblematic example of<br />

political-economic clientelism is delivered by<br />

sectoral networks forming a closed system<br />

of interdependence between politicians,<br />

management of state-owned companies (usually<br />

party-affiliated) and economic environment of<br />

these companies (Gadowska, 2002; Jasiecki,<br />

2004). In fact, decisions-making processes in<br />

these companies depend on current, shortterm<br />

party interest and particularistic personal<br />

gains, and not on economic calculation. In<br />

case of highly symbiotic, oligarchic relations,<br />

a company monopolizes delivery of certain<br />

services to the state and relies on a single<br />

client – the state, while avoiding competition<br />

on the market. Cost on the state budget is very<br />

high, while size and certainty of state contracts<br />

guaranteed by public funding enable the<br />

emergence of huge fortunes at low risk, thus<br />

creating conditions for the so-called ‘political<br />

capitalism’ (Staniszkis, 2001).<br />

However, a question emerges, whether patterns<br />

described above persist, petrifying businesspolitics<br />

relations typical for the period of<br />

economic and political transformation to<br />

capitalism? Or, whether they are becoming<br />

marginalized with the progression of the<br />

consolidation phase of market economy and new<br />

economic elites? On the one hand, the post-<br />

2004 expansion of Polish private capital (slightly<br />

mitigated by the 2008 crisis) both domestically<br />

and abroad, together with the incremental<br />

Europeanization of public administration,<br />

seems to confirm the consolidation hypothesis.<br />

On the other hand, despite recent political<br />

declarations, the privatization process is not<br />

accelerating and governance standards in public<br />

sector are not improving.<br />

Equally, the public affairs market in Poland is<br />

not yet developed. Few domestic companies<br />

are operating, with their services focused<br />

mostly on foreign players. Subsidiaries of


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

international consultancies are concentrated<br />

on public relations, media relations, or crisis<br />

management communication, only occasionally<br />

dealing with actual lobbying (Matraszek,<br />

24.08.2009). The relatively new phenomenon<br />

concerns the quasi-lobbying activities of law<br />

firms that provide clients with legal arguments<br />

and expertise necessary to influence the<br />

decision-making process. We thus observe a<br />

certain degree of professionalization in terms<br />

of argumentation, but not of the core formal<br />

and informal institutions that define businesspolitics<br />

relations and access to decisionmakers.<br />

Large parts of the business elite are<br />

still interdependent and closely linked with<br />

personal ties to the world of politics, thus<br />

lacking autonomous status.<br />

At the same time, new members of the<br />

business elite emerged in the aftermath of the<br />

post-accession economic boom. The 1998-<br />

2002 economic crisis, together with new<br />

opportunities offered by the single market,<br />

have enabled growth of private companies that<br />

disposed of real competitive advantage. In the<br />

rankings of fastest growing firms, a substantial<br />

change is also evident, as the new generation<br />

of successful businessmen is too young to have<br />

been socialized in the former system, as well as<br />

benefit from the early transformation period,<br />

its unclear rules and ambiguous opportunities.<br />

This part of the elite demonstrates a high<br />

degree of autonomy from the political elite, but<br />

also avoids active participation in any forms of<br />

collective action and interest representation.<br />

To sum up, various forms of business-politics<br />

relations co-exist in Poland, depending on sector,<br />

ownership structure, size and resources of the<br />

company, as well as socialization background<br />

of management. Consequently, heterogeneity<br />

reigns among the business elite, where some<br />

groups demonstrate characteristics typical for<br />

the (early) transformation period, whereas<br />

others belong to the modern, internationalized<br />

elite of consolidated capitalist system.<br />

However, this partial consolidation seems not<br />

yet to be translated into mobilization and<br />

effective lobbying of Polish business interests<br />

at the EU level. Consequently, I argue<br />

that the short period of participation and<br />

learning process within the EU governance<br />

structures (after accession in 2004) cannot be<br />

seen as the main explanatory factor. Nor do<br />

the critical resources (Beyers & Kerremans,<br />

2007) such as membership density, funding<br />

and sector consolidation provide sufficient<br />

explanation in the case of mobilization and<br />

impact exerted at the EU level by economic<br />

interest groups coming from post-communist<br />

CEE member states. It appears that postcommunist<br />

formal and informal heritage<br />

still plays an important role in businesspolitics<br />

relations. In the Polish case, this is<br />

manifested in the degree of embeddedness in<br />

domestic clientelistic and oligarchic networks,<br />

level of internationalization and resulting<br />

autonomy vis-a-vis national political elites, as<br />

well as lack of tradition, institutionalization<br />

and legitimization of pluralist interest<br />

representation.<br />

EXPLAINING THE EFFECTIVENESS OF<br />

POLISH BUSINESS LOBBYING AT THE<br />

EU LEVEL<br />

Studies on Europeanization of interest groups<br />

suggest that membership density, funding and<br />

sector consolidation constitute critical factors<br />

Seite Page page 53


POLISH BUSINESS REFERENCES LITERATUR – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

of mobilization and exerting influence at the<br />

EU level. Reflection on Polish interest groups<br />

in a comparative perspective leads us to the<br />

conclusion that their resources are rather<br />

scarce, which results in weaker mobilization<br />

and influence compared to groups from<br />

Western Europe.<br />

In terms of membership and funding, a<br />

comparison of Spanish and Polish member<br />

organizations of Business Europe (largest EUlevel<br />

business umbrella organization) shows<br />

that while Polish PKPP has 3000 members,<br />

Spanish CEOE accounts for 1 million of<br />

them (in both cases these are mostly SMEs).<br />

This is translated into 1.5 million euro in<br />

membership fees for Polish organization and<br />

more than 20 million euro for the Spanish one;<br />

however, their membership fees in Buiness<br />

Europe are roughly the same (Karaszewska,<br />

04.08.2009). The Brussels office of PKPP<br />

employs 2 lobbyists, whereas CEOE employs<br />

6. Not only does this juxtaposition indicate<br />

important disparities in terms of capacities<br />

of exerting potential influence, it also points<br />

to the fact that activities at the European<br />

level constitute a huge financial effort for the<br />

Polish organization, incomparable with the<br />

one the Spanish association is experiencing.<br />

The importance of sector consolidation is<br />

best depicted by the example of the chemical<br />

industry. A relatively small number of large<br />

companies allows for more efficient<br />

mobilization, both at the domestic<br />

Seite Page page 54<br />

and European level. In fact, the<br />

sectoral EU umbrella association,<br />

CEFIC, with its huge funding and<br />

relatively smooth and timely decision-making<br />

process, is typically mentioned as one of the<br />

most efficient corporate groups in Brussels.<br />

However, the critical resources approach does<br />

not offer plausible explanations to a number<br />

of questions, which are particularly evident in<br />

the CEE context. Why do large and wealthy<br />

Polish companies not engage in EU level<br />

lobbying or only at a very late stage? Why<br />

do groups and companies with substantial<br />

resources tend to choose the national route of<br />

influencing EU affairs, even if they are aware<br />

of the fact that the number of national officials<br />

occupying key Brussels posts is extremely<br />

limited? Why do Polish representatives of the<br />

chemical sector not see themselves influential<br />

despite relatively high sectoral consolidation<br />

and active participation in CEFIC works? In<br />

order to solve these dilemmas, I offer three<br />

additional explanations based on the argument<br />

of direct impact of domestic business-politics<br />

relations on mobilization patterns and lobbying<br />

strategies at the EU level.<br />

It is widely acknowledged that EU impact is<br />

largely mediated through, and conditioned<br />

by, existing domestic institutions, policies,<br />

cultures and identities. There is no automatic<br />

shift of loyalties and activities to the European<br />

level (Ladrech, 1994). Much of the literature<br />

emphasizes that the Europeanization process of<br />

interest groups is constrained at both European<br />

and national levels (Woll, 2007). Notably, a<br />

negative correlation is found between the extent<br />

to which a group is embedded in domestic<br />

policy networks and the extent of its integration<br />

in European networks (Beyers & Kerremans,<br />

2007). Thus, mobilization and lobbying<br />

strategies of interest groups are conditioned by<br />

the immediate institutional and organizational<br />

environment of the domestic groups and the<br />

level of dependence or autonomy of groups visà-vis<br />

this environment.


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

Accordingly, privileged access to domestic<br />

decision-makers, especially in the form of<br />

clientelistic or oligarchic relations, is to decrease<br />

motivation for interests’ mobilization at the<br />

EU level. Actors that are heavily embedded<br />

in domestic networks have a tendency to<br />

rely on routine contacts with national-level<br />

decision-makers and are unwilling to develop<br />

new networks in Brussels. In fact, existing<br />

literature suggests that the national route<br />

is typical for Southern (Italy, Greece) and<br />

Eastern member states (Greenwood, 2007).<br />

Such a path-dependent strategy allows<br />

for avoiding additional costs, but prevents<br />

influencing actors other than the national<br />

government representatives in the Council of<br />

the EU. In particular, with the growing impact<br />

of bargaining in the European Parliament on<br />

the entire decision-making process, illustrated<br />

notably by the cases of services directive (2006)<br />

or regulation on spirit drinks (2008), such an<br />

approach is ineffective 8 .<br />

The largest Polish companies, which are<br />

usually state-owned, are constantly entangled<br />

in politics. Frequently changing and partyaffiliated<br />

executives, who often dispose of<br />

doubtful management competences, do not<br />

usually promote long-term strategic planning.<br />

Interest representation instruments, such as<br />

public hearings, which are common at the EU<br />

level, are often underestimated. Regular data<br />

gathering, reporting and impact assessments,<br />

aiming at supporting arguments, are neglected<br />

(Lubiewa-Wieleżyński, 24.08.2009). Consequently,<br />

benefits of the high consolidation<br />

of the sector cannot be realized, as companies<br />

are subjecting their decisions to demands of<br />

current party politics and are often unfamiliar<br />

with procedures of professional and expertisebased<br />

lobbying. Awareness of the necessity<br />

to defend the industry’s interests in Brussels<br />

is still not well developed among the largest<br />

Polish companies; and EU-oriented attempts<br />

of influence are often limited to isolated<br />

consultations with a national vice-minister<br />

responsible for the dossier. Such a method<br />

fits very well into a tradition of ‘arranging<br />

things’ with an acquainted politician, often<br />

in exchange for concrete benefits. This shows<br />

a huge difference in the rules of the game<br />

operational in EU and Polish politics.<br />

It is thus argued that the preference for the<br />

national route is reinforced by uncertainties<br />

stemming from the distinctively different<br />

institutional context of the European level,<br />

in comparison to the hybrid, post-communist<br />

environment. In fact, formal and informal<br />

institutions that exist at the European level<br />

are more conducive to open and participatory<br />

interest representation than those present in<br />

post-communist countries, including Poland.<br />

Clientelistic and oligarchic strategies, practiced<br />

by the largest Polish companies at the national<br />

level, cannot be applied in the EU due to<br />

multiple points of access and a high level of<br />

bureaucratization of the decision-making<br />

process. This is further reinforced by the<br />

scarcity of Polish politicians and high officials<br />

occupying key posts in Brussels. Sticking<br />

exclusively to the national route is particularly<br />

inefficient for a new member state, as<br />

the number of its officials is limited<br />

due to a short period of presence in Seite Page page 55<br />

Brussels institutions. At the stage<br />

of agenda-setting and preparing<br />

proposals in the European Commission, it is<br />

necessary to go beyond national ties and gain<br />

access to decision-makers working directly on


POLISH BUSINESS REFERENCES LITERATUR – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

the dossier in question notwithstanding their<br />

nationality.<br />

Moreover, the repartition of Polish deputies<br />

among the European Parliament committees<br />

is not at all functional from the point of view<br />

of business interest representation. Poland is<br />

overrepresented in the foreign affairs committee,<br />

whereas membership in committees<br />

dealing with single market or environmental<br />

issues is more than scarce (the tendency has<br />

been similar after the 2009 EP elections). Thus<br />

the potential for opinion shaping in economic<br />

matters is considerably limited.<br />

At the same time, the specificities of Polish<br />

capitalism discussed above result in a relatively<br />

weak level of internationalization of Polish<br />

business and an absence of large national corporations<br />

capable of attracting and mobilizing<br />

smaller players into national and European<br />

business associations. Just as in the third sector,<br />

business organizations are seriously underdeveloped<br />

in terms of membership and financing<br />

in comparison with the situation in Western<br />

member states. Meanwhile, company size, together<br />

with the level of internationalization,<br />

constitutes a crucial resource for mobilization<br />

and influence in the EU arena.<br />

In fact, the more transnational ties and activities<br />

the company has, the more it is interested<br />

in influencing the regulation of the<br />

single market. Such a company is<br />

Seite Page page 56<br />

naturally much more affected by<br />

acquis communautaire than a company<br />

operating locally within one member<br />

state. The expansion of economic activities can<br />

also be accompanied by socialization to the<br />

international management standards. Finally,<br />

an important position on the European market<br />

should make the firm more autonomous<br />

towards domestic political elites. Meanwhile,<br />

a low level of internationalization impedes<br />

mobilization and implementation of effective<br />

lobbying strategies, while the company is<br />

focused on domestic market and traditional<br />

linkages between the world of business and the<br />

world of politics. In particular, this occurs with<br />

a high level of dependence on politicians and<br />

administration due to the overwhelming and<br />

burdensome intervention of the latter in the<br />

economic activities of private entrepreneurs.<br />

Finally, policy-making in the EU is technical in<br />

nature; and the EU governance system relies to<br />

a significant extent on knowledge and expertise,<br />

which is reflected in the great number of advisory<br />

and expert committees in the Commission and<br />

public hearings in the Parliament. At the same<br />

time, the nature of Polish business-politics<br />

relations has been traditionally based not so<br />

much on information exchange but more on<br />

‘making deals’, nepotism, and corruption. Both<br />

the government and interest organizations are<br />

not yet prepared to play the game by European<br />

rules, too often relying on populist arguments<br />

of national interest or veto (Rey, 09.03.2009;<br />

Karaszewska, 04.08.2009).<br />

Lobbying is far from being the dominant<br />

form of relations between business and politics<br />

in Poland. Socialist tradition of interest<br />

representation as systemic deviation contributed<br />

to the delegitimization of the pluralist game<br />

of interests. Lobbying is not recognized as a<br />

legitimate element of the democratic decisionmaking<br />

process. As interest representation<br />

strategies of argumentation, persuasion and<br />

opinion formation are not well developed


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

nationally, actors are poorly socialized to<br />

develop the necessary strategies at the EU<br />

level. For instance, consultations and public<br />

hearings are poorly institutionalized in Poland,<br />

which is impeding active engagement in similar<br />

practices in the Brussels arena.<br />

Polish lobbying at the European level is also<br />

characterized by an ad hoc approach. On one<br />

hand, this is due to high costs of permanent<br />

presence in Brussels. On the other hand,<br />

companies still do not possess the awareness<br />

as to the importance of the continuous opinion-shaping<br />

at the EU level. They often limit<br />

themselves to the participation in works of an<br />

EU-level trade association but use it more for<br />

an informative purpose than active interest<br />

representation. The lack of long-term planning<br />

and continuity in business strategies might be<br />

considered a result of a specific economic culture<br />

derived from the post-communist heritage,<br />

in particular business-politics relations<br />

in state-owned companies. Meanwhile, the ad<br />

hoc practice of ‘arranging things’ is fully dysfunctional<br />

in the formalized and highly institutionalized<br />

lobbying environment of the EU.<br />

CONCLUSIONS<br />

Specificities of Polish capitalism are particularly<br />

well reflected in existing patterns of businesspolitics<br />

relations and lobbying. In this<br />

article, I looked at how the post-communist<br />

heritage, transferred into the institutions of<br />

Polish ‘advanced emerging market’, affects<br />

representation of economic interests at both<br />

national and European levels. I made an attempt<br />

to explain the relative ineffectiveness of Polish<br />

lobbying in Brussels, while going beyond the<br />

critical resources approach and pointing to<br />

the characteristics of the CEE institutional<br />

and organizational environment. It seems that<br />

the perceived ineffectiveness results from the<br />

incompatibility of the hybrid, post-communist<br />

socialization context with the institutions of<br />

consolidated democracy and developed market<br />

economy at the EU level.<br />

As stated above, various forms of businesspolitics<br />

relations co-exist in Poland, depending<br />

on the sector, ownership structure, size<br />

and resources of the company, as well as socialization<br />

background of the management.<br />

The partial consolidation of economic elites,<br />

also resulting from the opportunities offered<br />

by EU membership and internationalization<br />

of economic activities, is not yet translated<br />

into effective mobilization of Polish business<br />

interests at the European level. The critical<br />

resources approach neither fully explains the<br />

low level of mobilization in the EU arena, nor<br />

the use of strategies that are not adequate to<br />

the European rules of the game. Among other<br />

explanatory factors proposed, one can find the<br />

argument about the embeddedness in domestic<br />

networks where specific, post-communist<br />

types of business-politics relations dominate.<br />

Clientelistic and oligarchic strategies practiced<br />

in Poland cannot be successfully used in<br />

the European environment, in particular due<br />

to the high level of autonomy of economic<br />

and political elites, as well as scarcity<br />

of Polish politicians and officials occupying<br />

key posts. A lack of tradition Seite Page page 57<br />

and institutionalization of pluralistic<br />

interest representation and civil society,<br />

together with weak financial and human<br />

resources of business organizations, further<br />

obstruct the capacity to exert influence.


POLISH BUSINESS REFERENCES LITERATUR – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

NOTES<br />

1<br />

According to the FTSE group ranking (Sept. 2008), all EU15<br />

countries were classified within the group of 25 developed market<br />

economies in the world. Apart from Poland and Hungary,<br />

all the other new member states from Central Europe that joined<br />

the EU in 2004-2007 were still labelled as emerging markets;<br />

www.ftse.com.<br />

2<br />

In his classic essay, Radaelli (2000) defines Europeanization<br />

as ‘processes of construction, diffusion and institutionalization of<br />

formal and informal rules, procedures, policy paradigms, styles,<br />

‘ways of doing things’ and shared beliefs and norms which are<br />

first defined and consolidated in the making of EU decisions<br />

and then incorporated in the logic of domestic discourse, identities,<br />

political structures and public policies’. Understood as process<br />

of adaptation, Europeanization does not lead to homogenization.<br />

As abundant literature demonstrates, due to interaction,<br />

institutional systems undergo adaptation processes according to<br />

their own specific paths (Heritier 2005, Radaelli 2000, Ladrech<br />

1994).<br />

5<br />

Corporate governance is understood here as ‘legal and economic<br />

institutions constituting a system of formal and informal rules,<br />

determining the behaviour of entrepreneurs’ (Kozarzewski,<br />

2007).<br />

6<br />

For instance, Hungary has moved up 19 positions and Romania<br />

16 positions during the same period.<br />

7<br />

The phenomenon of clientelism constitutes a continuation of the<br />

nomenclature system of state socialism in many respects. It defines<br />

the asymmetric governance system, where decisions are taken in a<br />

fully discretionary way, and personal loyalty together with commitment<br />

to exchange goods of unequal value form the backbone of<br />

the relationship. In such a system, the patron uses public resources<br />

in pursuit of private benefits, as the division between public and<br />

private is blurred ( Jarosz, 2004). As for oligarchic patterns, they<br />

are based on social networks, direct contacts with politicians and<br />

administration, abuse of personal ties and reciprocity of favours<br />

( Jasiecki 2002). The classic example is the financing of political<br />

party activities by businessmen in exchange for privileged positions<br />

in public tenders.<br />

3<br />

The scope of this article does not allow for detailed explanation<br />

of the different understanding of lobbying, in particular, in<br />

contrast to notions of interest representation, or social and civil<br />

dialogue. For instance, the understanding of who a lobbyist is<br />

under Polish law is quite different from the definition used by<br />

the European Commission. I assume that lobbying constitutes<br />

one of the forms of interest representation, next to territorial<br />

parliamentary representation and corporatist representation<br />

(Łabno 2009). For different aspects with regard to the conceptualization<br />

of lobbying phenomenon in Polish literature, see:<br />

Wołpiuk 2004, Jasiecki 2006, Wiszowaty 2006, 2008.<br />

8<br />

In these cases, the focus on building a blocking minority in the<br />

Council of the EU was not sufficient, as the main political battle<br />

took place in the European Parliament. With the expanding competences<br />

of the European Parliament (also with the intialization<br />

of the Lisbon Treaty on 1 December 2009), the Council appears to<br />

be losing its crucial bargaining position within the EU decisionmaking<br />

process. This puts the efficiency of the national route of<br />

lobbying into question even further. For details on the lobbying<br />

campaigns with regard to the above mentioned legislative acts,<br />

see: Petsch (2006), Gazeta Wyborcza (2007a, 2007b).<br />

Seite Page page 58<br />

4<br />

There are three transformation models identified, namely capitalism<br />

from below, capitalism from above and capitalism from<br />

without. The first model stipulated that a new private market<br />

sector emerged in the shadow of old socialist redistributive<br />

economy. The second one pointed to the attempts of the socialist<br />

nomenclature to transform the system, while converting<br />

themselves into the grand bourgeoisie and using<br />

the resources (political and social capital) acquired<br />

under the previous institutional setting. Finally, the<br />

third model accounts for dominant impact of foreign<br />

capital and ownership in the transformation process<br />

(King, Szelenyi in Smelser, Swedberg, 2005).


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Balcerowicz, L., 1997, Socjalizm, kapitalizm, transformacja:<br />

szkice z przełomu epok, Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN, Warszawa.<br />

Gardawski, J. et al., 2008, Socjologia gospodarki, wydanie 2,<br />

Difin, Warszawa.<br />

Greenwood, J., 2007, Interest Representation in the European<br />

Union, 2 nd edition, Palgrave Macmillan.<br />

Beyers, J., Kerremans, B., 2007, ‘Critical resource dependencies<br />

and the Europeanization of domestic interest groups’. In: Journal<br />

of European Public Policy, 14:3, no 4.<br />

Burson-Marsteller, 2009, ‘A guide to effective lobbying in Europe’,<br />

October, availabe at: http://www.oursocialmedia.com/brussels/bursonmarsteller-brussels/effective-lobbying-europe-2009<br />

[accessed: 26.02.2010]<br />

CASE (Centre for Socio-Economic Analyses), 2007,<br />

‘Przedsiębiorstwa sektora prywatnego i publiczneho w Polsce<br />

w latach 1999-2005’, no 89, available at: http://www.case.<br />

com.pl/upload/publikacja_plik/14583751_bre89.pdf [accessed:<br />

26.02.2010]<br />

Jarosz, M., 2006, ‘Okazja czyni złodzieja, czyli proces transformacji<br />

i prywatyzacji w Polsce’. In: A. Dylus et al. ed., 2006,<br />

Korupcja: oblicza, uwarunkowania, przeciwdziałanie, UKSW,<br />

Zakład Narodowy im. Ossolińskich, Wrocław.<br />

Eising, R., 2007a, ‘Institutional context, organizational resources<br />

and strategic choices:explaining interest group access in the<br />

European Union’. In: European Union Politics, Vol. 8 (3).<br />

Eising, R., 2007b, ‘The access of business interests to EU institutions:<br />

towards elite pluralism?’In: Journal of European Public<br />

Policy, 14:3, April.<br />

King, L. P., 2007, ‘Central European Capitalism in Comparative<br />

Perspective’. In: B. Hancke et al. ed., 2007, Beyond the<br />

varieties of capitalism: conflict, contradictions and complementarities<br />

in European economy, Oxford University Press.<br />

Héritier, A., 2005, ‘Europeanization Research East and West: a<br />

comparative assessment’. In: F. Schimmelfennig, U. Sedelmeier.<br />

ed., 2005, The Europeanization of Central and Eastern Europe,<br />

Cornell University Press.<br />

Hausner, J., 2007, Pętle rozwoju: o polityce gospodarczej lat<br />

2001-2005, Warszawa.<br />

Jarosz, M., 2004, Władza, przywileje, korupcja, ISP PAN,<br />

PWN, Warszawa.<br />

Jasiecki, K., 2008, ‘The changing role of post-transitional<br />

Economic Elite in Poland’. In: Journal for East European<br />

Management Studies, Vol. 13, no 4.<br />

Jasiecki, K., 2004, ‘Związki biznesu z polityką: pomiędzy lobbingiem<br />

a korupcją’. In: H. Domański et al. ed., 2004, Niepokoje<br />

polskie, IFiS PAN, Warszawa.<br />

Jasiecki, K., 2002, Elity biznesu w Polsce: drugie narodziny<br />

kapitalizmu, IFiS PAN, Warszawa.<br />

Forum Odpowiedzialnego Biznesu, Bank Światowy, Akademia<br />

Rozwoju Filantropii, 2003, Menedżerowie 500 i odpowiedzialny<br />

biznes: wiedza, postawy, praktyka, Warszawa, available at:<br />

www.etykabiznesu.pl [accessed: 14.08.2009]<br />

Jasiecki, K. et al., 2006, Lobbing – sztuka skutecznego<br />

wywierania wpływu, 2 edition, Oficyna<br />

Ekonomiczna, Kraków.<br />

Seite Page page 59<br />

Gadowska, K., 2002, Zjawisko klientelizmu politycznoekonomicznego:<br />

systemowa analiza powiązań sieciowych na<br />

przykładzie przekształceń sektora górniczego w Polsce, Uniwersytet<br />

Jagielloński, Kraków.<br />

Kochanowicz, J. et al., 2007, Kulturowe aspekty<br />

transformacji ekonomicznej, Instytut Spraw Publicznych,<br />

Warszawa.


POLISH BUSINESS REFERENCES LITERATUR – POLITICS RELATIONS<br />

Kozarzewski, P., 2006, Prywatyzacja w krajach postkomunistycznych,<br />

ISP PAN, Warszawa.<br />

Ladrech, R., 1994, ‘Europeanization of domestic politics and<br />

institutions: the case of France’. In: Journal of Common Market<br />

Studies, 32(1), March.<br />

Radaelli, C.M., 2000, ‘Whither Europeanization? Concept<br />

stretching and substantive change’. In: European Integration<br />

online Papers, 4/ 8, http://eiop.or.at/eiop/texte/2000-008a.htm<br />

Raciborski, J., 2006, Elity rządowe III RP 1997-2004. Portret<br />

socjologiczny, Warszawa.<br />

Lewicka-Strzałecka, A., 2006, Odpowiedzialność moralna w<br />

życiu gospodarczym, IfiS PAN, Warszawa.<br />

Lissowska, M., 2008, Instytucje gospodarki rynkowej w Polsce,<br />

C.H. Beck, Warszawa.<br />

Ministry of Economy, 2009, ‘Przedsiębiorczość w Polsce’,<br />

Warszawa.<br />

Morawski, I., 28.04.2008, ‘Orlen po raz dziewiąty’. In: Rzeczpospolita.<br />

North, D. C.,1999, Understanding the Process of Economic<br />

Change, Institute of Economic Affairs for the Wincott Foundation,<br />

London.<br />

Sapała, M., 2005, Rola władz terytorialnych w Unii Europejskiej:<br />

formy reprezentacji interesów na forum europejskim,<br />

Akademia Ekonomiczna w Poznaniu.<br />

King, L. P., Szelenyi, I., 2005, ‘Post-communist economic systems’.<br />

In: N. J. Smelser, R. Swedberg, ed., 2005, The Handbook<br />

of Economic Sociology, 2nd edition, Princeton University Press.<br />

Staniszkis, J., 2001, Postkomunizm: próba opisu, Gdańsk.<br />

Wiszowaty, M. M., 2008, Regulacja prawna lobbingu na<br />

świecie, Wydawnictwo Sejmowe, Warszawa.<br />

Wiszowaty, M. M, 2006, ‘Ustawa o działalności lobbingowej w<br />

procesie stanowienia prawa’. In: Przegląd Sejmowy, 5 (76).<br />

Petsch, J., 2006, ‘Dyrektywa usługowa’. In: Analizy Natolińskie,<br />

no 9(13).<br />

Woll, C., 2007, ‘Leading the dance? Power and political resources<br />

of business lobbyists’. In: Journal of Public Policy, 27/1.<br />

Seite Page page 60<br />

Greskovits, B., 2008, ‘Leading sectors and the variety of capitalism<br />

in Eastern Europe’. In: J. Pickles, ed., 2008, State and<br />

Society in Post-Socialist Economies, Palgrave Macmillan.<br />

Pickles, J., 2008, ‘The spirit of post-socialism’. In: J. Pickles, ed.,<br />

2008, State and Society in Post-Socialist Economies, Palgrave<br />

Macmillan.<br />

‘Polska jeszcze walczy o definicję wódki’,<br />

13.06.2007. In: Gazeta Wyborcza.<br />

‘Przegrana Polski, bananowa wódka unijnym<br />

standardem’, 19.06.2007. In: Gazeta Wyborcza.<br />

Wołpiuk, W. J., 2004, ‘Lobbing – próba ustalenia treści pojęcia i<br />

funkcji prawnopublicznych’. In: Przegląd Sejmowy, 4(63).<br />

Interviews<br />

Chorus, R., Cérame-Unie Secretary General, former President<br />

of SEAP (Society of European Affairs Practitioners) in 1998-<br />

2006, Brussels, 05.03.2007.<br />

Karaszewska, A. , Deputy General Director of the Polish Confederation<br />

of Private Employers and Member of the BusinessEurope<br />

Executive Committee, Warsaw, 04.08.2009.


AGNIESZKA REFERENCES LITERATUR K. CIANCIARA<br />

Lubiewa-Wieleżyński, W., President, Polish Chamber of Chemical<br />

Industry, Warsaw, 24.08.2009.<br />

Matraszek, M., Executive Director, CEC Government Relations,<br />

Warsaw, 24.08.2009.<br />

Mulewicz, J., Avon, Business Centre Club, Member of EESC,<br />

Warsaw, 28.08.2009.<br />

Rey, B., Director of the PGNiG Brussels Office, Brussels,<br />

9.03.2009.<br />

Sochacka, K., acting Director of the Brussels Office of the Polish<br />

Confederation of Private Employers, Brussels, 05.03.2007.<br />

Websites<br />

http://www.mg.gov.pl/Wiadomosci/Przedsiebiorcy/I+posiedze<br />

nie+Zespolu+ds+Spolecznej+Odpowiedzialnosci+Przedsiebiors<br />

tw.htm<br />

www.doingbusiness.org<br />

www.odpowiedzialnybiznes.pl<br />

http://margaux.grandvinum.se/SebTest/wvs/articles/folder_published/article_base_54<br />

http://www.ftse.com/Indices/Country_Classification/Downloads/FTSE_Country_Classification_Sept_08_update.pdf<br />

http://www.europarl.europa.eu/activities/committees/committeesList.do?language=EN<br />

Seite Page page 61


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

1. INTRODUCTION<br />

4<br />

Ultimately, all automotive companies are<br />

international companies with a global<br />

focus, acting at several locations and<br />

on different markets. While some are actively<br />

engaged in establishing new sites, finding new<br />

cooperation partners and exploring foreign<br />

markets, others seems to act conservatively,<br />

appearing reluctant while focussing on and<br />

strengthening their position in their traditional<br />

markets.<br />

GERMANS ON THEIR WAY EAST – AUSTRIANS<br />

STAYING AT HOME<br />

Kathrin Loer<br />

In this regard the title of this paper must be<br />

explained, as it does not seem to say anything<br />

about the topic. Who is meant by “Germans”<br />

and “Austrians” and what is meant by “way<br />

east” in contrast to “staying at home”?<br />

The following text addresses problems of<br />

the European automobile industry, more<br />

precisely problems and challenges of a certain<br />

segment of the automotive sector: the contract<br />

manufacturers. On the basis of two case<br />

studies, I will explain under what conditions a<br />

German company begins to build production<br />

units in Poland, while its major Austrian<br />

competitor does not follow the trend to use<br />

attractive Central and Eastern European<br />

production sites and still remains competitive.<br />

Seite page 62<br />

From an institutional point of view,<br />

interdependencies between the institutional<br />

surrounding 1 and a company’s economic<br />

performance and (international) competitiveness<br />

can be assumed, whereas the cases show<br />

dissolution of these interrelations and some<br />

weakness of the argumentation. Hence, the<br />

aim of this paper, from a theoretical point of<br />

view, is to show the limits of institutionalist<br />

approaches and the need to broaden or


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

modify these approaches in the face of serious<br />

transformations of economic surroundings<br />

and market transformations. Perhaps this<br />

diagnosis could be transferred to other sectors<br />

or market structures. The empirical contents<br />

of this paper will support the assumption of<br />

serious market transformations and their<br />

complexity. To a certain degree, behaviour<br />

and decisions of economic actors are expected<br />

to be rational or the result of figure-based<br />

analyses summing up the situation. The paper<br />

will show that – at the latest – the complexity<br />

of the business environment does not make<br />

it possible to act and decide (completely)<br />

rationally; economic rationality could instead<br />

be used as an auxiliary tool to legitimate the<br />

decisions of an economic actor.<br />

Given a framework of transformation<br />

processes, changes and characteristics of the<br />

automotive sector, this paper will explain how<br />

and why automotive companies invest abroad,<br />

more precisely in Central and Eastern Europe. As<br />

mentioned above, not the whole automotive<br />

industry will be covered but rather a small<br />

sample that might be a representative example<br />

of the complex framework of mechanisms that<br />

restricts, promotes or undermines the actor’s<br />

behaviour. On the basis of the two case studies<br />

of European “contract manufacturers”, this<br />

paper shows under what prerequisites foreign<br />

direct investments in Central Eastern Europe<br />

can overstrain (medium-sized) companies as<br />

well as when disregarding the trend to move<br />

east leads to greater competitiveness. With<br />

a focus on different types of foreign direct<br />

investments of these automotive companies<br />

in CEE transformation processes of the<br />

market, manufacturer-supplier-relations as<br />

well as consequences for industrial relations<br />

will be explored. Before the two case studies<br />

are presented, the theoretical and empirical<br />

framework will be explained in more detail.<br />

2. THE EUROPEAN AUTOMOBILE INDUSTRY –<br />

A STARTING POINT.<br />

In order to first reduce complexity, a simple<br />

picture is drawn: The automobile industry<br />

evolved during the last century from small<br />

factories producing the first, mainly handcrafted,<br />

cars into huge corporate groups with<br />

a very high employment volume (compared to<br />

other parts of the industrial sector) (Altshuler<br />

et al. 1986). Although each region of the<br />

triad has its own specialities regarding the<br />

production models, generally speaking similar<br />

developments can be identified in Europe,<br />

North America (mainly the United States)<br />

and Japan (later: Southeast Asia) after the<br />

Second World War. Common is especially<br />

one characteristic feature: The automobile<br />

is a very complex as well as labour and<br />

knowledge intensive good. The Original<br />

Equipment Manufacturers 2 (OEM) represent<br />

the key players in the sector but do not build<br />

automobiles on their own, which is why a<br />

more or less differentiated supplier industry is<br />

needed for automobile production (Hoetker,<br />

Swaminathan & Mitchell 2007, Helper, Kiehl<br />

2004, Kaufman, Wood & Theyel 2000). In the<br />

Japanese automobile industry, supplier<br />

companies are mostly affiliates of the<br />

OEM (e.g. Toyota), which is a small Seite page 63<br />

deviance to the organization of the<br />

automotive value chain in Europe or<br />

North America. Traditionally, the European<br />

automotive suppliers are independent<br />

companies varying from small and medium


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

to large companies. The automotive supply<br />

chain and its hierarchy can be illustrated with<br />

a pyramid.<br />

Figure 1. Automotive Supplier Hierarchy<br />

(by author)<br />

If it was a simple and successful story, it could<br />

be followed by reports of continuous growth,<br />

expansions, and developments of new markets.<br />

Automobiles would be the main transportation<br />

means, the OEM portfolio would become<br />

increasingly diversified, and automobiles in<br />

nearly all price classes would be offered. There<br />

would be mainly growth prospects for<br />

companies in the automotive sector<br />

Seite page 64<br />

for OEM and the supply industry. As<br />

one can imagine, considering the many<br />

countries and regions in the world<br />

that are still not saturated as far as individual<br />

transport (by car) is concerned, OEMs and<br />

supplier companies would be “lucky devils” in<br />

the era of globalization. Indeed, all that is partly<br />

true, yet accompanied by other developments<br />

and mechanisms:<br />

International production- and distribution<br />

strategies of the large multinational OEMs<br />

are constitutive for all other entrepreneurial<br />

decisions in this sector. Internationalization<br />

and an extensive process of consolidation have<br />

taken place simultaneously since the 1990s –<br />

for the Original Equipment Manufacturers<br />

(OEM) as well as for supplier companies. This<br />

process produces “mega suppliers” as a result<br />

of fusions and takeovers and the reduction<br />

of the in-house production depth on the


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

OEM-side. Different reports and consultancy<br />

studies forecast a promising economic future<br />

for the mega suppliers because of vertical<br />

disintegration of tasks, growing specialization<br />

and the need for flexibility (Mercer<br />

Management Consulting 2004, Verband der<br />

deutschen Automobilindustrie (VDA) 2003,<br />

Kinkel, Zanker 2007, Kinkel, Lay 2005). In<br />

an extreme scenario, one could think about<br />

task sharing to such an extent that the OEM<br />

is “merely” responsible for marketing and<br />

distribution as well as for the management of<br />

the automotive brand(s), whereas the supplier<br />

industry performs all steps of the production.<br />

Research and development in the development<br />

of a new automobile model is also vertically<br />

disintegrated. Considering such a high impact<br />

for supplier companies regarding production<br />

activities, one could raise the question<br />

whether relocation of production sites may<br />

be economically advisable to escape high-cost<br />

countries (e.g. Germany or Austria). From the<br />

perspective of (Western) European automobile<br />

producers, this question is asked again given<br />

very attractive conditions for production<br />

activities in Central and Eastern Europe as<br />

well as their proximity to the automobile<br />

producer’s headquarters in France, Germany,<br />

Italy etc. Indeed, the automotive industry<br />

can be identified as a pioneer regarding the<br />

constitution of new sites in Central and Eastern<br />

Europe, not only since the “iron curtain” fell in<br />

1989 (Bandelj 2008) but also with investments<br />

of GM and Suzuki, for example, in Hungary<br />

already in the early 1980s (Sadler, Swain 1994).<br />

As this was the case for the OEM, the supplier<br />

industry also realized the new opportunities or<br />

was forced to follow the OEMs to gain new<br />

contracts.<br />

The automobile industry retains a large volume<br />

of employment as (despite a high degree of<br />

automation) the assembly of automobiles still<br />

requires manpower on a large scale, especially<br />

for the production of certain supply parts as<br />

well as during the last steps of the assembly line.<br />

Workers in the automotive sector unionized<br />

and founded workers’ councils in the early years,<br />

which continuously grew and developed in the<br />

second half of the last century. Particularly in<br />

Europe the development of the automobile<br />

industry was accompanied by the growth of<br />

trade unions (metal unions). Hence, in this<br />

paper the perspective on enterprise’s strategies<br />

and interdependencies between the OEM and<br />

the supplier industry is complemented by the<br />

perspective on power and powerlessness of the<br />

workers’ councils. Negotiation and bargaining<br />

processes between the workers’ councils of the<br />

traditional and established production sites<br />

“at home” influence business and investment<br />

strategies – not only of the respective company<br />

but also of the dependent companies in<br />

the supply-chain (Cooke 2006, Marginson,<br />

Meardi 2006, Doellgast, Greer 2007). The<br />

same is true by looking the other way around:<br />

business and investment strategies as well as<br />

high cost pressure can force the organized<br />

labour of one company to concede or give<br />

up standards or previous conditions or – to<br />

mention an extreme case – to capitulate.<br />

This very brief sketch of major developments<br />

may lead to the assumption<br />

that the supplier companies that survived<br />

the consolidation process and<br />

Seite page 65<br />

grew in the course of joint ventures<br />

and takeovers turn out to be the part of the automotive<br />

sector that continues to achieve high<br />

employment rates and are important, or even


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

Seite page 66<br />

the most important players in the automotive<br />

sector as counterpart of the OEM. Of course,<br />

one can also identify a strong dependency of<br />

supplier companies on the OEMs, insofar a<br />

picture of great interdependence between international<br />

companies arises. The same is true<br />

for the European “contract manufacturers” (or<br />

“0.5-tier suppliers”, see Figure 1) as a special<br />

segment of the automotive industry yet still<br />

very much subject to the OEM. Contract<br />

manufacturers are developing and producing<br />

automobiles on behalf of large automotive<br />

producers, the OEMs. They are capable of fulfilling<br />

all tasks required to produce a vehicle.<br />

In this regard, these companies can be viewed<br />

as “miniature” automobile manufacturers or<br />

“small” OEMs. In addition, most of these<br />

companies are market-leaders for the production<br />

of specific supply modules. The segment<br />

of “contract manufacturers” is chosen to present<br />

two cases from Germany and Austria 3 .<br />

Similar to a magnifying glass, this approach<br />

should help to point out and analyse important<br />

structural changes and actor’s behaviour<br />

within this changing environment. Summing<br />

up, the following aspects are important for this<br />

paper:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

High degree of internationalization.<br />

High relevance of Central and Eastern<br />

Europe regarding production sites in<br />

this region for all automobile<br />

companies (European, North<br />

American and Asian) and the<br />

supplier industry.<br />

Interdependence between OEM and<br />

suppliers as well as OEM and contract<br />

manufacturers.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Importance of workers’ councils and<br />

(metal) trade unions.<br />

Importance of sector with regard to the<br />

whole producing sector of a national<br />

economy.<br />

Large assembly lines and a multiplicity of<br />

automated production steps, but the need<br />

for (highly) skilled workers, manpower<br />

and engineering capabilities to compete<br />

in the sector.<br />

Necessary development of new technologies,<br />

innovations and inventions forces the<br />

companies (OEM and suppliers) to invest<br />

in research and development divisions.<br />

The recent crisis of the automobile industry<br />

just shows the tip of the iceberg. Even if the<br />

bankruptcy of famous automobile companies<br />

is on everyone’s lips in the light of the current<br />

economic crisis, the crisis in the automotive<br />

sector is not a new phenomenon. Automobile<br />

companies have faced several severe problems<br />

during the last two decades. Their economic<br />

drawbacks are mainly caused by changing<br />

circumstances on buyers’ and sellers’ markets<br />

and resulting large overcapacities. Even if<br />

this paper does not discuss these long-term,<br />

structural problems, it is necessary to keep<br />

their influence in the back of our minds when<br />

regarding the following investigations.<br />

2.1 General changes in the automotive sector<br />

If one were to describe the market strategies of<br />

automobile producers not in an analytical and<br />

academic, but rather a heretical and exaggerated<br />

way, a general diagnose could be: The European


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

automotive companies, particularly the OEMs,<br />

have dug their own (economic) grave step by<br />

step because of immense overcapacities over<br />

the last decade. Of course, this picture is onedimensional,<br />

as the problem of overcapacities is<br />

not only caused by (independent) management<br />

or executive decisions but is the result of<br />

parallels in the development of the market<br />

that complicate these decisions. To describe it<br />

concisely: The opening of Central and Eastern<br />

European countries opens new markets with<br />

a huge demand and backlog in people having<br />

their own automobiles. This is an example<br />

of a (quite) unexpected potential to expand<br />

for market changes during a short period of<br />

time (van Tulder, Ruigrok 1998, Keune, Tóth<br />

2005). As demand for expensive investment<br />

goods such as automobiles cannot be exactly<br />

predicted, the forecast of trends is sophisticated<br />

and partly coincidently. As new competitors<br />

enter the market and the automotive<br />

industry is profoundly dependent on general<br />

developments of national and international<br />

economies and their rapid shocks and changes,<br />

unilateral criticism against the OEM does<br />

not cope with the complexity of the situation.<br />

However, the impact of market instabilities,<br />

the need for flexibility and fast adaptation<br />

to new circumstances pressures workers and<br />

employees in the sector as their employment<br />

conditions are often seen as an “adjustable<br />

screw” in the eyes of company management<br />

( Jürgens 2005a, Jürgens 2005b, Jürgens 2004,<br />

Kahancová, van der Meer 2006, Charron,<br />

Stewart 2004). Another remarkable change is<br />

related to cooperation between competitors in<br />

the market that reach from buying syndicates<br />

to joint production sites. On the other hand,<br />

new competitors enter the international market<br />

and discover Europe as an interesting economic<br />

region (mostly cheap automotive producers<br />

from emerging markets, India or China…).<br />

In summary the transformation of the automotive<br />

sector proceeds in different respects:<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Growing cost pressure.<br />

Changes regarding the terms and<br />

conditions for workers in the sector.<br />

Growth of new flexible employment<br />

strategies, namely temporary employment,<br />

which produces a segmentation of<br />

employees with permanent staff, on<br />

the one hand, and workers that accept<br />

precarious employment conditions<br />

(continuity, wage levels), on the other.<br />

Organized labour is hardly achievable<br />

and the counterpart of the management<br />

weakened.<br />

After years of implementation, the<br />

concept of “lean production” and the<br />

idea of a “breathing plant” are enforced<br />

to cope with changing circumstances<br />

(Schumann et al. 2006) 4 . The concept<br />

aims at introducing terms of employment<br />

that allow hiring and firing at short<br />

notice, without difficult legal bindings.<br />

Of course, this concept is judged very<br />

differently depending on the perspective.<br />

Employers recognize the need<br />

to be flexible if they want to<br />

stay competitive and search Seite page 67<br />

for solutions in the range of<br />

employment conditions as they<br />

turn out to be the most extensive cost<br />

factor. The employees’ perspective claims<br />

the trend to capitalize the current market


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

<br />

situation (particularly on the labour<br />

market) to force the workers to accept<br />

bad conditions. However, the employees’<br />

behaviour in reaction to these changes<br />

also shows their powerlessness, as they<br />

actually widely accept and adapt to these<br />

new situations.<br />

The relation between OEM and<br />

supplier companies alters exceptionally<br />

regarding bargaining position and power:<br />

Cooperation structures of OEMs (from<br />

buying syndicates up to productioncooperation)<br />

form a powerful counterpart<br />

to the supplier companies.<br />

What are the consequences for contract<br />

manufacturers referring to this? These general<br />

changes hit the contract manufacturers hard<br />

due to the fact that they occupy a “niche” of car<br />

production, being experts for special features,<br />

design, and exceptional functionalities and<br />

notably low volume production. Their special<br />

niche productions could be classified in the<br />

“premium segment”, which is difficult to<br />

combine with growing cost pressure. If we think<br />

of economies of scale, this target is also hardly<br />

to be achieved with low volume production. As<br />

far as the flexibility of employment strategies<br />

is concerned, it might be a competitive<br />

disadvantage to rely on skilled workers, highly<br />

skilled engineers and other technical staff to<br />

realize high quality production and<br />

complex products. The dependency<br />

Seite page 68<br />

of OEM was and is extensive with<br />

regard to niche production, which<br />

also changes and creates a very<br />

unstable economic situation. The contract<br />

manufacturers appear to be powerlessness and<br />

– in a way – “abandoned to their fate” as far<br />

as the production of full vehicles is concerned.<br />

Remembering the OEM-supplier hierarchy,<br />

the changes let the 0.5-tier suppliers descent<br />

to 1 st -tier suppliers specialized on modules and<br />

systems. In such times it is doubtful whether<br />

outsourcing to foreign countries like those in<br />

Central and Eastern Europe helps to master<br />

the crisis. If an OEM starts to invest in CEE,<br />

contract manufacturers may get an opportunity<br />

by following them, or are forced to follow?<br />

3. ANALYTICAL FRAMEWORK<br />

In order to compare and analyse the two case<br />

studies, a starting point is defined that regards<br />

similarities and differences, whereas the<br />

similarities are seen as formative for the specific<br />

character and function of these companies.<br />

Therefore, firstly attention is turned to<br />

institutionalist theory that might be helpful to<br />

understand the environmental conditions of the<br />

two companies. In a second step, characteristic<br />

features of the company’s constitution will be<br />

divided into similarities and distinctions.<br />

Considering the classification of the “Varieties<br />

of Capitalism” (VOC), the home countries<br />

of both enterprises fall into the category of<br />

“coordinated market economies” (CME) (Hall,<br />

Soskice 2001) p.19f ). Although the VOC<br />

approach is broadly assailed and enhanced<br />

(Crouch 2005, Jackson, Deeg 2006, Deeg,<br />

Jackson 2007, Hirt 2004, Campbell, Pedersen<br />

2007, Allen 2006), this substantial debate<br />

will not be addressed in this paper. Rather,<br />

the approach is used to emphasize some<br />

characteristics of the coordinated market<br />

economies in Germany and Austria, which are<br />

not challenged by the criticisms of the VOC


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

approach. Asked how wages and working<br />

conditions are established in these coordinated<br />

economies, the bargaining structures between<br />

the employers and the organized labour and a<br />

long tradition of unionism are the answer. This<br />

characteristic is important for the case studies,<br />

because wage structure and working conditions<br />

are presumably the most important aspects<br />

when it comes to decisions on new production<br />

sites abroad, vertical disintegration and foreign<br />

direct investments. From this theoretical<br />

classification, one could expect similar<br />

confrontations inside the enterprises in times<br />

of growing cost pressure, increasing difficulties<br />

to gain new contracts and orders. A second<br />

characteristic regards vocational training and<br />

education. The coordinated market economies,<br />

especially Germany and Austria, are famous for<br />

their publicly organized and subsidized training<br />

system (Culpepper 2001). Companies in the<br />

automotive sector take part in the vocational<br />

training system and can, therefore, secure a<br />

skilled labour force. Looking at inter-company<br />

relations, coordinated market economies dispose<br />

of appropriate and manifold institutions. By<br />

using institutionalist approaches, one attempts<br />

to respect the political embeddedness of actors.<br />

Path dependency provides an explanation<br />

for this as well as for why institutions do not<br />

change in a way that completely shifts the<br />

national economy. However, with regard to this<br />

theory, two important remarks must be taken<br />

into account. The VOC-paradigm is an ideal<br />

typology – even though Hall and Soskice bring<br />

forward their argument by using OECD-data,<br />

national figures and statistics and link their<br />

two capitalist models (coordinated and liberal)<br />

to “real” countries. At the latest in the course<br />

of the European Integration process, growing<br />

reform pressure with regard to welfare state<br />

institutions, and considering the Globalization<br />

processes, these countries “move” away from<br />

their ideal type. With the two case studies<br />

in mind, the significance of industrial<br />

relations, vocational training and inter-firm<br />

relation might be doubtful on two counts:<br />

the automotive industry was (and partly still<br />

is) very much affected by a strong influence<br />

of workers’ councils and trade unions. They<br />

might have changed their role and function<br />

but are still an important counterpart of the<br />

company’s management – in Germany as<br />

well as in Austria. Referring to this, but also<br />

with regard to the other two categories (VC and<br />

interfirm-relations), particularly traditional and<br />

regional (rooted) companies adhere to well known<br />

and long established routines and institutions.<br />

Also the cooperation-partners of those companies<br />

(employees, prospective apprentices, chambers<br />

and other organizations dealing with inter-firm<br />

relations) stick to familiar routines. The case<br />

studies can show whether these statements can<br />

be confirmed and, if so, provide an explanation<br />

– particularly as far as the decision about foreign<br />

investments (in CEE) is concerned.<br />

In addition to thoughts about national<br />

economies, some theoretical remarks about<br />

the constitution of the market should be<br />

introduced and linked with the case studies. It<br />

seems helpful to use Beckert’s categories for the<br />

constitution of markets: the “value problem”,<br />

the “problem of competition”, and the<br />

“cooperation problem” (Beckert 2009).<br />

The following paragraph includes all<br />

important aspects that can be used for<br />

the case studies:<br />

„I argue that three coordination problems<br />

in the sense of “mutual coordination” can be<br />

Seite page 69


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

analytically distinguished: I call them the value<br />

problem, the problem of competition, and the<br />

cooperation problem. These coordination<br />

problems can only be resolved if market actors<br />

are able to form stable expectations with regard to<br />

the actions of other market actors and future<br />

events relevant for their decisions as well<br />

as whether they consider the expected outcomes<br />

to be sufficient in their material interest and<br />

normatively acceptable. In this sense, markets<br />

are understood as “fully social institutions,<br />

reflecting a complex alchemy of politics,<br />

culture, and ideology” (Krippner 2001: 782).<br />

While the notion of the “order of markets”<br />

refers to the macrolevel result of the solution<br />

of the three identified coordination problems,<br />

the expectations formed by actors constitute<br />

the building blocks of this order on the actor<br />

level.”<br />

(emphasis added)<br />

With this understanding of the constitution<br />

of markets, the severe problems and also<br />

contradictions in actor’s (here: company’s)<br />

behaviour and decisions can be explained.<br />

The following case studies will show where<br />

and under which conditions it is remarkably<br />

difficult or almost impossible to achieve the<br />

necessary level of coordination.<br />

4. CASE STUDIES: WHAT IS SO SPECIAL ABOUT<br />

THE CONTRACT MANUFACTURERS – ARE THEY<br />

SPECIAL?<br />

4.1 …some remarks on the empirical studies:<br />

The case studies are based on media reports,<br />

business reports and interviews with decision<br />

makers 5 of these companies and actors in the<br />

company’s environment as the major source.<br />

The aim is to explain corporate decisions<br />

and strategies as well as the dramatic changes<br />

affecting the market segment. The case studies<br />

focus on the following figures: changes of<br />

business sections, company size, company<br />

locations, foreign investments, co-operations<br />

among suppliers and contractors. The two<br />

companies from Austria and Germany were<br />

chosen as the main focus, because they are<br />

(were) by far the leading and largest companies<br />

for contract manufacturing worldwide.<br />

Summarizing the main characteristics for<br />

the segment of niche producers and contract<br />

manufacturers, they mainly produce for the<br />

premium sector, while the production is labour<br />

intensive, requires specialized and expert<br />

knowledge to create unique selling points. All<br />

contract manufacturers have a long tradition in<br />

their home countries and no or few production<br />

sites abroad.<br />

4.2 Transformation of manufacturer –<br />

supplier – relations<br />

Seite page 70<br />

Referring to the main aspects mentioned<br />

above, which show what happens in the sector,<br />

these characteristics can be applied to the<br />

relation between contract manufacturer and<br />

suppliers as well. Due to the interdependencies<br />

between OEM and contract manufacturers,


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

these countries are also to a certain degree<br />

internationalized. As the case studies will<br />

explain, there are very different concepts<br />

followed by the contract manufacturers<br />

grounded in different ratings of opportunities<br />

and economic risks but also dependent on their<br />

relation to the OEM. Central and Eastern<br />

Europe attracts investments from all kinds of<br />

automobile industries, contract manufacturers<br />

are not excluded. As far as the interdependencies<br />

between OEM and contract manufacturers are<br />

concerned, there is strong evidence suggesting<br />

less balance and more power of the OEM with<br />

the result that the dependency gains weight in<br />

one direction. It shall not be forgotten that the<br />

automobile industry started with a high degree<br />

of manufacturing in its early years (at the end of<br />

the 19 th century / beginning of the 20 th century);<br />

in the market for “premium cars”, individualized<br />

products, skilled workers, manpower and<br />

engineering capabilities are still important. If<br />

OEMs decide to outsource production, it is<br />

presumably this part of the product portfolio.<br />

The role of Central and Eastern European<br />

countries for this production will be explained<br />

with regard to the case studies.<br />

4.3 Case Study 1.<br />

This case study takes a closer look at the<br />

Wilhelm Karmann GmbH, which was<br />

founded in 1901 (Knust 1996). Until recently,<br />

Karmann employed around 8.000 persons<br />

spread at six locations worldwide (Karmann<br />

2006, Handelsblatt.com 2009a). The company<br />

specialized historically in manufacturing<br />

cabriolets as well as modules necessary to build<br />

cabriolets such as retractable tops. During the<br />

last years, several rounds of layoffs needed<br />

to be executed (still some layoffs could be<br />

prevented). Overall, the situation for the<br />

company staff has worsened since 2006. At<br />

the moment, the insolvency proceedings<br />

are short of being concluded (Handelsblatt.<br />

com 2009b, neue-oz.de 2009). Excluding the<br />

current and ongoing events, the Karmann case<br />

shows interesting aspects for the purpose of<br />

this paper. With regard to different categories,<br />

serious changes can be observed. As a family<br />

business, the company grew steadily and<br />

employed around almost 10.000 people at<br />

the company’s climax. Over time, Karmann<br />

emerged to an established regional company that<br />

was well known nationally and internationally<br />

for its niche production of cabriolets. Long time<br />

tradition and strong regional roots are main<br />

characteristics that can also be identified by the<br />

embeddedness of the principal of the company in<br />

social and political networks. This might be seen<br />

as typical for German family owned business,<br />

but also for the industrial sector and specificly<br />

the metal sector. Especially the grandson of the<br />

founder and also the first successor beyond the<br />

family were very much involved in “old-boysnetworks”,<br />

the traditional, informal German<br />

management-networks used to negotiate and<br />

complete deals, for example at the automotive<br />

fair. As such, Karmann mostly cooperated<br />

with German OEMs for the manufacturing of<br />

automobiles in the 1970s and 1980s. Rooted<br />

in trust, long-time relationships and business à<br />

la “you scratch my back and I’ll scratch yours”<br />

characterized most of the deals.<br />

Trusting in the apparent assurance<br />

to be and stay market leader in the Seite page 71<br />

special niche segment of cabriolet<br />

production, the company was not<br />

bothered with fear for its existence during a<br />

long period, although the production of cabriolets<br />

always had to deal with fluctuations. In former


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

times it was not easy to embed the niche<br />

production, especially of cabriolets in larger<br />

production sites or assembly lines of OEMs<br />

with higher volumes. One interview partner<br />

expressed: “Cabrio production will provoke<br />

serious headaches, if it has to be implemented<br />

in OEM’s production sites. That’s why the<br />

OEM give it to contract manufacturers.”<br />

As far as foreign investments are concerned,<br />

Karmann used to be connected to investments of<br />

OEMs (for example: Volkswagen in Mexico<br />

and Brasil, Nissan-cooperation in England)<br />

but did not invest abroad on their own. They<br />

always produced abroad to realize a specific<br />

car production – as a kind of piggyback<br />

international production.<br />

Compared to the recent situation, several<br />

serious changes took place during the last<br />

five to ten years. The company’s heir left the<br />

company in 1990. A manager followed him,<br />

who again remained a comparatively long<br />

time and continued the business practices.<br />

But then more frequent personal changes in<br />

the management could be recorded. As the<br />

“business landscape” internationalized, the<br />

new executives have been less embedded<br />

in social and political networks or these<br />

networks have been very much expanded and<br />

internationalized. If there are new contracts,<br />

they are concluded in the context of complex<br />

treaties that require legal expertise. Technological<br />

change enables OEMs to produce<br />

niche cars and small production series<br />

Seite page 72<br />

within their own assembly lines.<br />

Simultaneously, the importance of<br />

system and module suppliers with<br />

high technological competitiveness grows.<br />

For contract manufacturing, Karmann could<br />

no longer rely on stability and certainty of<br />

following orders – new mechanisms of shorttime<br />

business relations, high flexibility, and high<br />

internationalization replace the old system<br />

of trust and long-term partnerships. The<br />

company tried to explore new ground after the<br />

year 2004/2005 and was “on its way east” with<br />

foreign investments on its own authority: two<br />

investments in Poland that are not piggyback<br />

with an OEM. One of the new Polish sites is<br />

connected with a contract for BMW in Leipzig<br />

but is not a contract manufacturier of a full<br />

vehicles but rather systems and modules. This<br />

might be interpreted as a prognosticator for the<br />

company’s following development. The Polish<br />

site is economicly and legaly independent from<br />

the other parts of the company and was erected<br />

to support an OEM under high cost pressure.<br />

The second site in Poland was founded as a<br />

tooling shop where Karmann wanted to realize<br />

low cost structures. However, problems already<br />

appeared in the early years of those sites:<br />

(Skilled) labour is rare, wages are higher than<br />

expected (and especially the growth rate of wage<br />

levels), institutional conditions in that country<br />

prove to be more difficult than assumed, the<br />

company laments organizational problems. The<br />

increase of transaction costs is enormous. During<br />

the last years, the company was unable to obtain<br />

new orders for the manufacturing of complete<br />

vehicles – regardless of the production site. The<br />

combination of OEMs being able to integrate<br />

small volume and niche production in their sites,<br />

“Standortsicherungsvereinbarungen” binding<br />

employment in the OEMs factories, and the<br />

opportunities for the OEM to build sites in<br />

Central and Eastern Europe to produce special<br />

products (for example Porsche together with<br />

Volkswagen: Cayenne in Bratislava, Slovenia)<br />

seems to be the “knock out” for the German<br />

contract manufacturer Karmann. Negotiations


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

with OEMs during the last years showed that<br />

the sites in Osnabrück and Rheine tried to<br />

compete with factories in Central and Eastern<br />

Europe (e.g. with Györ in Hungary / Audi).<br />

From an external perspective it is not possible<br />

to judge whether the wage conditions and<br />

production costs have been the most important<br />

and decisive criteria.<br />

The changes and problems described have<br />

serious impacts on the industrial relations:<br />

Workers’ councils are increasingly forced to<br />

accept conditions that they would not have<br />

accepted in former times. The threat to start new<br />

production sites at cheaper locations, especially<br />

in CEE, with cheaper labour determines the<br />

strategy of the workers’ council. Staggered,<br />

but similar to the changes in the company’s<br />

management, the leaders in the workers’<br />

council have been replaced and bargaining<br />

routines have differed. Now, technical, skilled<br />

staff represents the workforce and has been<br />

transformed to a “co-management” without<br />

strong negotiation power. The downward<br />

tendency of the company has intensified the<br />

feeling of being powerless in terms of ensuring<br />

employment.<br />

4.4 Case Study 2.<br />

Magna Steyr in Graz is an affiliate of the<br />

Austro-Canadian mega-supplier “Magna<br />

International”. The company has a long history<br />

but changed its name: it was well known as<br />

“Steyr Puch” in former times. Originally<br />

founded as an arms manufacturer in 1864,<br />

it transitioned to a bicycle producer. Later,<br />

Puch was specialised in the production of<br />

motorcycles in 1901 shortly before it entered<br />

the automobile-manufacturing sector in 1904.<br />

After a merger with the German automobile<br />

company “Daimler” in 1928, the company<br />

was named “Steyr-Daimler-Puch AG” (since<br />

1935) and started to assemble vehicles ordered<br />

by different European automobile companies<br />

after the Second World War. In 1999, the<br />

Canadian Corporation “Magna International”<br />

took the majority of shares – meanwhile,<br />

Magna Steyr reached comparatively high<br />

volumes and was very successful with new<br />

contracts from a wide spectrum of OEMs.<br />

The Austrian contract manufacturer looks<br />

back on a long time tradition. Similar to its<br />

German competitor, it has strong regional<br />

roots but, likewise, records quite a few<br />

changes regarding the ownership structure. The<br />

interviews showed that, particularly during<br />

the last decades, the continuity of the Austrian<br />

management (as well the Canadian corporate<br />

management in persona Frank Stronach)<br />

and a quite flexible way of bargaining and<br />

finding specific solutions with the workers’<br />

council and trade union form the framework<br />

for (new) strategies. This might be part of a<br />

“secret recipe”. Stemming from a “coordinated<br />

market economy”, strong industrial relations<br />

can be expected – but the way of negotiation,<br />

the bargaining method and interrelationship of<br />

politics, associations, corporate organizations and<br />

management executives might be characterized<br />

with “high flexibility”, pragmatism, and the<br />

ability to agree upon package deals.<br />

Magna Steyr thoroughly continued<br />

to maintain long time partnerships<br />

and cooperation with international<br />

OEMs but was never very much<br />

interwoven with one or more OEMs 6 .<br />

Seite page 73


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

Regarding its niche competence, the Austrian<br />

company has never had the assurance to be<br />

and stay market leader, although the company<br />

offers a special segment: the 4-wheel-drive.<br />

However, different from cabriolet production,<br />

this special engine technology could be<br />

integrated in the production lines of the OEM.<br />

They have nearly always been competitors<br />

for this production, so that Magna Steyr was<br />

in danger that OEM would undertake this<br />

production on their own. Taking a look at<br />

foreign investments, the Austrians “stayed at<br />

home” as far as production is concerned. The<br />

case study shows a surprising strategy: High<br />

quality services are transferred or established<br />

abroad while all production tasks remain in<br />

Austria. At first glance, this strategy may seem<br />

unrealistic and implausible. But reality shows<br />

that thoughts about relocating high quality<br />

services accompany foreign investments<br />

considerations – regardless of whether<br />

production will remain at the home-site<br />

(Rudas, Witzani & Fritzer-Posch 2003).<br />

Asked if they invest in Central and Eastern<br />

Europe, the interview partners express two<br />

statements. First, they affirm that the niche<br />

and low volume production of premium cars<br />

can only be done adequately with a skilled<br />

labour force and trusted workmen by using<br />

engineer support and experiences located<br />

close to the production sites. In the eyes of<br />

the interview partners, this is only the case<br />

in Austria. Second, an investment<br />

in Central and Eastern Europe for<br />

Seite page 74<br />

financial reasons is not needed, as<br />

supplier parts can easily be purchased<br />

from neighbouring countries (just<br />

a few kilometres from the headquarter in<br />

Graz). Beyond that, the company’s executives<br />

refer to the next migration trend far more east<br />

(because of rising labour cost, difficulties to<br />

recruit skilled employees…).<br />

Although it might be judged as “accompanying<br />

measures” that could be neglected, the institution<br />

of the “Automotive Cluster Steiermark” should be<br />

named. The Bundesland Steiermark initiated<br />

a relatively large-scale and financially wellsupported<br />

institution that provides collective<br />

goods specifically to the automotive industry.<br />

Leading companies are AVL List (an engine<br />

company) and Magna Steyr. Besides offers to<br />

meet staff from other companies in order to<br />

build business-networks, the effort to develop<br />

cluster-specific infrastructure, the cluster acts<br />

as a lobby for the Austrian automobile industry.<br />

The initiative finds acceptance, which is not<br />

self-evident, because the companies have to<br />

pay to be members of the cluster. Therefore,<br />

they staff the decision-making body and are<br />

involved in decisions about new initiatives such<br />

as the constitution of the automotive-specific<br />

cooperation of all Steyrian universities and<br />

research institutes to support the companies.<br />

Regarding all these aspects, one must<br />

emphasize that – compared to other European<br />

contract manufacturers - Magna Steyr proceeds<br />

and decides in a different role. As an affiliate<br />

there are opportunities to compensate. As an<br />

affiliate of a mega-supplier being part of a<br />

large corporation, the company can benefit<br />

from supplier-relations, utilize the corporate<br />

structure and take advantage of corporate<br />

decisions. Furthermore, interviews, reports and<br />

other sources basically rely on information from<br />

the “Magna era”. On closer examination of the<br />

company’s history, it becomes apparent that this<br />

contract manufacturer rather seriously starts to<br />

play in the concert of the European contract<br />

manufacturer since it became part of the Magna


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

Group. Decades ago, when the company traded<br />

under the name “Steyr-Daimler-Puch”, the<br />

interconnection with Daimler-Benz was highly<br />

visible and formative.<br />

5. CONCLUSION<br />

Not only are the national boundaries literally<br />

crossed in the course of companies’ investments<br />

in Central and Eastern Europe, the case studies<br />

show that Central and Eastern European<br />

countries are highly competitive regarding<br />

the quality and highly skilled production<br />

and have crossed the boarder that divides<br />

production regions in “low cost” in terms of a<br />

cheap subcontractor (“verlängerte Werkbank”<br />

in German) and “high cost” countries. This<br />

region is no longer (if it even ever was) solely a<br />

low cost production region for the automobile<br />

industry. Of course, parts of the 2 nd -tier or 3 rd -<br />

tier supplier industries can be found in CEE<br />

and might still realize cost advantages, but<br />

with regard to more complex manufacturing<br />

processes, a different picture must be drawn.<br />

The case studies show that, as the companies are<br />

part of the premium segment of the automobile<br />

industry, low-cost production might not be an<br />

adequate option. As OEMs invest in Central<br />

and Eastern Europe – also in the premium<br />

segment, as the examples of Porsche, BMW and<br />

Daimler show – these countries have become<br />

serious alternatives to Western European<br />

production sites. Karmann exported production<br />

to be able to leave high skilled engineering<br />

services at their home site. However, for this<br />

German contract manufacturer it is obvious<br />

that last year’s investments abroad caused<br />

(transaction) costs that must be compensated<br />

by appropriate savings on labour costs, both<br />

in the past and present. This target seems<br />

to be hardly achievable when a company<br />

has started to invest in Central and Eastern<br />

Europe during the last five years with the<br />

objective to start low cost production. On the<br />

contrary, especially the acceding countries to<br />

the European Union became attractive sites as<br />

far as quality production and the involvement<br />

of skilled labour is concerned. As an affiliate of<br />

Magna International (Canada), Magna Steyr<br />

relocated high skilled engineering services<br />

to different countries to keep production<br />

in Austria. The company did not decide to<br />

outsource production to Central and Eastern<br />

Europe. Of course, the proximity to this region<br />

from the Austrian site in the “Steiermark”<br />

might be an argument, as supply parts are quite<br />

easy to purchase from supplier companies in<br />

the Eastern European neighbourhood. I argue<br />

that relocation of production is controversial<br />

and has to be judged critically. As far as<br />

automobile manufacturing is concerned, CEE<br />

is no “cheap region” or low cost region in a<br />

broader sense. It is not the institutional setting<br />

that determines the competitive strength of<br />

the contract manufacturers or hinders their<br />

success (for example regulations in coordinated<br />

market economies). Rather the company’s<br />

configurations, its financial background, the<br />

continuity of cooperation with OEM and –<br />

although from an academic perspective this<br />

might not be satisfying – serendipity<br />

are decisive.<br />

Seite page 75<br />

Returning to the conceptualizing<br />

approach of Beckert regarding the<br />

constitution of the market, the case studies<br />

exemplify how and why the balance of actors<br />

and their competence to solve the “value


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

problem”, “problem of competition”, and<br />

“cooperation problem” is disrupted. Insofar<br />

the developments in the automotive sector can<br />

be operated as counterevidence, the market<br />

for independent contract manufacturing – as<br />

it existed during the last century - nearly<br />

collapses. A specific segment of the automotive<br />

industry may survive by changing its role and<br />

becoming a 1 st tier supplier, giving up the<br />

contract manufacturing by being taken over by<br />

or purchasing an OEM. With regard to the<br />

new capitalist states in Central and Eastern<br />

Europe, it can be identified that they have<br />

the capability to meet all requirements of<br />

the automotive industry. Yet concurrently<br />

they might loose their status as “verlängerte<br />

Werkbank” or as a cheap manufacturing base<br />

and may subsequently have to develop an<br />

equal production and development place of<br />

location.<br />

A second concluding remark refers to the<br />

VOC-debate. Even if the two cases are small<br />

aspects, a narrow picture and just a small<br />

part of the automotive industry, they may<br />

be appropriate to question the similarities of<br />

coordinated market economies. The German<br />

case illustrates how a traditional and regional<br />

(rooted) company can tend and adhere to<br />

well known and long established routines<br />

and institutions. As assumed before, the<br />

cooperation-partners of that company stick<br />

to these familiar routines as well.<br />

In the light of these diagnoses, the<br />

Seite page 76<br />

company’s investment in Poland<br />

produces the impression of a flight<br />

forward. The traditional routines and<br />

reliabilities of the management seem to be<br />

broken, even if the institutional surrounding<br />

did not change markedly. At first sight, the<br />

second case might not be a typical Austrian case<br />

– primarily because it should be titled Austro-<br />

Canadian correctly – but the specificities that<br />

can be identified with regard to industrial<br />

relations and inter-firm relations are nearly in<br />

line with the idea of the “coordinated market<br />

economy”. Heretically, their “interpretation”<br />

and performance of industrial relations might<br />

be seen as betrayal of labour. From a pragmatic<br />

perspective, the case shows an example of how<br />

to save employment and continue to keep<br />

industrial production in a so called high-cost<br />

country.<br />

The link between the case studies and the<br />

chosen theoretical background shows a<br />

balancing act with some weakness, but may<br />

frame the question and presentation of the case<br />

studies in an appropriate way.<br />

The differences regarding investments in<br />

Central and Eastern Europe are hard to judge.<br />

In addition to a certain degree of coincidence,<br />

the proximity of the Austrian company to<br />

Central and Eastern Europe might be an<br />

easy explanation. To benefit from attractive<br />

cost structures as far as supplier-goods are<br />

concerned, the company does not have to<br />

invest abroad but rather can purchase in<br />

the neighbourhood. Moreover, it might be<br />

in a closer relation to get information what<br />

earnings and benefits are realisable effectively.<br />

The mixture of competitive labour force, skilled<br />

workers and engineers, public collective goods<br />

and less unionized labour force is still very<br />

attractive for industrial production.


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

NOTES<br />

1<br />

E.g. industrial relations, institutions of vocational training,<br />

corporate governance structures, institutions to support intercompany<br />

relations.<br />

2<br />

I.e. leading companies such as Volkswagen, Renault, Fiat,<br />

Toyota, General Motors and Ford.<br />

3<br />

If the current developments (of the last weeks) are excluded,<br />

the segment of European Contract Manufacturers consists of<br />

six companies: two from Italy, and one from Finland, France,<br />

Germany, and Austria, respectively. They are all automobile<br />

producers “without an own brand” – they produce automobiles in<br />

order of the European or US-American (rarely and under special<br />

conditions Asian) OEMs.<br />

4<br />

The author is aware of the background of this book. It is published<br />

as “Begleitforschung” (translation: accompanying research)<br />

and is taken into account with care because of its proximity to the<br />

sponsor (Volkswagen).<br />

5<br />

These sources are not specifically noted in this paper.<br />

6<br />

This is the case when we are strictly referring to Magna Steyr.<br />

The merger with Daimler (Steyr-Daimler-Puch) must be evaluated<br />

differently.<br />

Seite page 77


AUTOMOTIVE REFERENCES LITERATUR COMPANIES GO EAST -<br />

GERMANY AND AUSTRIA<br />

Seite page 78<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Allen, M.M.C. 2006, The varieties of capitalism paradigm:<br />

explaining Germany’s comparative advantage? Palgrave.<br />

Altshuler, A., Anderson, M., Jones, D., Roos, D. & Womack, J.P.<br />

1986, The Future of the Automobile. The Report of MIT’s International<br />

Automobile Program, The MIT Press, Cambridge,<br />

MA.<br />

Bandelj, N. 2008, From communists to foreign capitalists : the<br />

social foundations of foreign direct investment in postsocialist<br />

Europe, Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton, NJ u.a.<br />

Beckert, J. 2009, The social order of markets, Max-Planck-Inst.<br />

für Gesellschaftsforschung, Köln.<br />

Campbell, J.L. & Pedersen, O.K. 2007, “The Varieties of Capitalism<br />

and Hybrid Success. Denmark in the Global Economy”,<br />

vol. 40, pp. 307-332.<br />

Charron, E. & Stewart, P. 2004, Work and employment relations<br />

in the automobile industry, Palgrave Macmillan.<br />

Cooke, W.N. 2006, “Multinationals, globalisation and industrial<br />

relations” in , ed. Global industrial relations, Routledge,<br />

, pp. 326-348.<br />

Crouch, C. 2005, Capitalist diversity and change: recombinant<br />

governance and institutional entrepreneurs, Oxford Univ.<br />

Press.<br />

Culpepper, P.D. 2001, “Employers, Public Policy, and the Politics<br />

of Decentralized Cooperation in Germany and France” in<br />

Varieties of Capitalism. The Institutional Foundations of Comparative<br />

Advantage, eds. P.A. Hall & D.(.). Soskice,<br />

Oxford University Press, , pp. 243-304.<br />

Deeg, R. & Jackson, G. 2007, “Towards a more dynamic<br />

theory of capitalist variety”, , pp. 149-179.<br />

Doellgast, V. & Greer, I. 2007, “Vertical disintegration and the<br />

disorganization of German industrial relations”, British journal<br />

of industrial relations.- Oxford [u.a.] : Blackwell, vol. 45, no.<br />

1, pp. 55-76.<br />

Hall, P.A. & Soskice, D.(.). 2001, Varieties of Capitalism, Oxford<br />

University Press.<br />

Handelsblatt.com 2009a, 19.2.2009-last update, Bei Karmann<br />

drohen weitere Stellenstreichungen. Available: http://www.<br />

handelsblatt.com/unternehmen/industrie/bei-karmann-drohenweitere-stellenstreichungen;2163414<br />

[2009, 21.6.2009] .<br />

Handelsblatt.com 2009b, 29.6.2009-last update, Insolvenzverfahren<br />

bei Karmann eröffnet. Available: http://www.<br />

handelsblatt.com/unternehmen/industrie/insolvenzverfahrenbei-karmann-eroeffnet;2405104<br />

[2009, 7.7.2009] .<br />

Helper, S. & Kiehl, J. 2004, „Developing Supplier Capabilities:<br />

Market and Non-Market Approaches“, vol. 11, no. 1, pp. 89-<br />

107.<br />

Hirt, O. 2004, Varieties of Capitalism and the Diversity of Productive<br />

Models or the exploration of macro-micro relationships.<br />

Hoetker, G., Swaminathan, A. & Mitchell, W. 2007, “Modularity<br />

and the impact of buyer-supplier relationships on the survival<br />

of suppliers”, Management Science, vol. 53, no. 2, pp. 178-191.<br />

Jackson, G. & Deeg, R. 2006, How many varieties of capitalism?<br />

Comparing the comparative institutional analyses of capitalist<br />

diversity, MPIfG.<br />

Jürgens, U. 2005a, „Charakteristika der europäischen Automobilindustrie.<br />

Gibt es einen europaspezifischen Entwicklungsweg?“<br />

in Und es fährt und fährt... Automobilindustrie und Automobilkultur<br />

am Beginn des 21. Jahrhunderts, ed. G. Schmidt, edition<br />

sigma, Berlin, pp. 11-45.<br />

Jürgens, U. 2005b, “Restructuring the automobile industry and<br />

its workforce: a worldwide perspective” in , ed. F. Garibaldo,<br />

Lang, , pp. 31-56.


KATHRIN REFERENCES LITERATUR LOER<br />

Jürgens, U. 2004, “An elusive model: diversified quality production<br />

and the transformation of the German automobile industry”,<br />

vol. 8 411-423, no. 4, pp. 411-423.<br />

Kahancová, M. & van der Meer, M. 2006, “Coordination,<br />

employment flexibility, and industrial rleations in Western<br />

European multinationals: evidence from Poland”, vol. 17, no. 8,<br />

pp. 1379-1395.<br />

Karmann,(Wilhelm Karmann GmbH und Co KG) 2006, Jahresbericht,<br />

Osnabrück.<br />

Kaufman, A., Wood, C.H. & Theyel, G. 2000, “Collaboration<br />

and technology linkages: A strategic supplier typology”, Strategic<br />

Management Journal, vol. 21, no. 6, pp. 649-663.<br />

Keune, M. & Tóth, A. 2005, , FDI and the Governance of the<br />

Car Industry in Central and Eastern Europe: the Case of Audi<br />

Hungary.<br />

Kinkel, S. & Lay, G. 2005, „Automobilzulieferer in der Klemme.<br />

Vom Spagat zwischen strategischer Ausrichtung und Auslandsorientierung“<br />

in Deutsche Autoproduktion im globalen Wandel : Altindustrie<br />

im Rückwärtsgang oder Hightech-Branche mit Zukunft?,<br />

eds. L. Pries & M. Hertwig, Ed. Sigma, Berlin, pp. 59-74.<br />

Kinkel, S. & Zanker, C. 2007, Globale Produktionsstrategien<br />

in der Automobilzulieferindustrie :, Springer-Verlag Berlin<br />

Heidelberg, Berlin, Heidelberg.<br />

neue-oz.de 2009, 22.6.2009-last update, Letztes Auto fährt bei<br />

Karmann vom Band. Available: http://www.neue-oz.de/_archiv/noz_print/stadt_osnabrueck/2009/06/20090622_karmann1.html<br />

[2009, 7.7.2009] .<br />

Rudas, A., Witzani, D. & Fritzer-Posch, S. 2003, „Magna<br />

International Inc. - mitarbeiterorientierte Unternehmenskultur<br />

als gemeinsamer Erfolgsfaktor“ in Internationale Fusionen und<br />

Kooperationen - erfolgreich umgesetzt : Best-Practice-Beispiele<br />

zur Integration der Unternehmenskulturen, ed. P. Maier, 1 Aufl<br />

edn, Wiley-VCH, Weinheim.<br />

Sadler, D. & Swain, A. 1994, „State and market in Eastern<br />

Europe: Regional Development and Workplace Implication<br />

of Direct Foreign Investment in the Automobile Industry in<br />

Hungary“, Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers,<br />

vol. 19, no. 4, pp. 387-403.<br />

Schumann, M., Kuhlmann, M., Sanders, F. & Sperling, H.J.<br />

(eds) 2006, VW-Auto 5000: Ein neues Produktionskonzept: die<br />

deutsche Antwort auf den Toyota weg?, VSA, Hamburg.<br />

van Tulder, R. & Ruigrok, W. 1998, European cross-national<br />

production networks in the auto-industry: Eastern Europe as<br />

the low end of European car complex, Berkeley, Calif.<br />

Verband der deutschen Automobilindustrie (VDA) 2003,<br />

HAWK 2015 - Herausforderung Automobile Wertschöpfungskette,<br />

Frankfurt am Main.<br />

Knust, D. 1996, Vom Kutschenbauer zum Auto-Karossier: Karmann<br />

- die Geschichte eines Familien-Unternehmens, Meinders<br />

Elstermann.<br />

Marginson, P. & Meardi, G. 2006, “European Union enlargement<br />

and the foreign direct investment channel of industrial<br />

relations transfer”, vol. 37, no. 2, pp. 92-110.<br />

Seite page 79<br />

Mercer Management Consulting, Fraunhofer-Institut für<br />

Produktionstechnik und Automatisierung & Fraunhofer-<br />

Institut für Materialfluss und Logistik 2004, Future automotive<br />

industry structure (FAST) 2015-die neue Arbeitsteilung in der<br />

Automobilindustrie, Verb. der Automobilindustrie, Frankfurt am<br />

Main.


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

5<br />

AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE:<br />

THE ENTERPRISE AS A SOURCE OF COMPETI-<br />

TIVE INDUSTRIAL CAPABILITIES<br />

Employment stability based on the administratively<br />

set output targets was a<br />

key feature of state socialist production<br />

regime. A shift from state socialism to market<br />

economy in this context meant an adaptation<br />

of employment and production numbers to<br />

‘market demands’ and market prices. In market<br />

economies, the volatility in product demand<br />

can imply an increased ‘flexibility’ of production<br />

and, thus, employment levels that could<br />

endanger employment stability. Thus, with the<br />

introduction of a market economic rationale,<br />

state socialist non-economic enterprise institutions<br />

have been challenged by the new logic of<br />

market-driven efficiency and competitiveness.<br />

The combination of private ownership, pressures<br />

of international competition and the increased<br />

role of cost efficiency were expected to<br />

contribute to making enterprises focus more on<br />

their economic competitiveness as the first and<br />

dominant measure of enterprise performance.<br />

page 80<br />

Alexandra Janovskaia<br />

State withdrawal from the production<br />

process and the arrival of foreign owners were<br />

associated with a larger focus on profitability,<br />

the new desired field of managerial action. In<br />

other words, these reforms characterised by a<br />

strong purposeful rationality considered social<br />

relations in the enterprise as means, not ends<br />

of social action. However, this paper argues<br />

that despite important institutional changes in<br />

the structure of markets and firm ownership,<br />

preserving industrial capabilities has remained<br />

an enterprise norm for local actors, an end in<br />

itself. Thus, an understanding of the enterprise<br />

as a social organism and a source of industrial<br />

capabilities remains alive. Despite the new<br />

institutions of increased competition, the<br />

expectation of an enterprise commitment to its<br />

employees survived from state socialist era to


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

the present day. This commitment is associated<br />

with what I call a ‘productionist stance’ of<br />

local actors. It is embedded in their desire to<br />

preserve employment numbers and develop<br />

local industrial capabilities, even if it sometimes<br />

goes contrary to the pure logic of cost efficiency<br />

and financial competitiveness.<br />

In the four VW subsidiaries that served as a<br />

case study for this paper – the Czech Skoda,<br />

Slovak VW Bratislava or VW Slovakia, Polish<br />

VW Poznan and Hungarian Audi Györ - an<br />

important industrial upgrading took place<br />

during the late 1990s and early 2000s in<br />

production volumes but, most importantly, in<br />

production depth, product range and strategic<br />

positioning within the VW Group. It also<br />

related this industrial upgrading to a dramatic<br />

increase in employment volumes in all four<br />

subsidiaries. To a certain extent, this industrial<br />

upgrading and employment increase have been<br />

part of the overall group’s strategy, which largely<br />

depended on decisions about transnational<br />

distribution of production volumes and<br />

technology investments mainly made in the<br />

VW Group headquarters. Yet I was able to<br />

identify an important role of local stakeholders<br />

in this process. The valuation of the industrial<br />

capabilities has been an important factor for<br />

industrial upgrading and employment growth.<br />

Despite the new ‘market’ organising logic<br />

of greater efficiency and increased market<br />

competition, local management has preserved<br />

a clear ‘productionist’ attitude in its desire to<br />

attract more investment to the production<br />

location, ensure production over time and<br />

upgrade. This ‘productionist’ norm is rooted in<br />

the experience of state socialism. Its overarching<br />

goal has been to develop local capabilities and<br />

make companies a full-fledged partner within<br />

the VW group. Both local unions and local<br />

management have shared this productionist<br />

attitude. Local managers were looking for<br />

German know-how to modernise their plant,<br />

but they still perceived it as their main task<br />

to ‘develop’ the company. Thus, whenever the<br />

opportunity emerged, local managers, together<br />

with unions, showed through their actions that<br />

high employment and industrial upgrading<br />

remained their highest priority, while market<br />

efficiency rationale remained a secondary<br />

factor.<br />

The rest of this paper develops this<br />

argument further. Several dimensions of<br />

this productionist attitude are brought out.<br />

First, stakeholder attitudes and strategies of<br />

preserving the industrial capabilities at the<br />

time of privatisation are discussed. The role<br />

of local coalitions between government and<br />

unions as guarantors for brand survival for the<br />

case of Škoda is discussed. Second, Section<br />

II disentangles the productionist logic that<br />

underpinned the actions of the stakeholders,<br />

while Section III elaborates the formal<br />

agreements between management and union<br />

representatives that followed this implicit<br />

coalition. The last section underlines the role<br />

of the external dimension – the role of public<br />

opinion – in strengthening and reinforcing<br />

the local ‘productionist’ commitment to firm<br />

industrial capabilities.<br />

This paper argues that the organis-<br />

page 81<br />

ing logic of economic liberalism of<br />

increased cost-efficiency and financial<br />

performance standards affected the firms<br />

when the institutions of ownership and control<br />

changed. Yet the local norms that set up the


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

firm as a source of valuable industrial capabilities<br />

remained alive. These norms imply a local<br />

commitment to the preservation of industrial<br />

capabilities independent from pure market efficiency<br />

and competitiveness logic. Thus, the<br />

norms related to economic liberalism have<br />

been challenged by the other, non-economic<br />

enterprise norm that partially goes back to a<br />

state socialist enterprise function. The result<br />

of this constant tension between the organising<br />

logic of efficiency and competition, on the<br />

one hand, and the value of industrial capabilities,<br />

on the other, is that the firm continues to<br />

function as a source of competitive industrial<br />

capabilities.<br />

I. STAKEHOLDER COALITION FOR BRAND<br />

SURVIVAL<br />

The system of state socialist central planning<br />

was characterised by the fact that resource<br />

allocation took place through political decisions<br />

rather than being driven by the economic<br />

rationale of the price mechanism, resource<br />

scarcity and cost efficiency. With the regime<br />

change, direct political allocation of productive<br />

resources disappeared and the ‘market rationale’<br />

officially entered the scene either anew or less<br />

disturbed by ‘social intervention’ in countries<br />

such as Hungary where certain market<br />

reforms were already implemented earlier. In<br />

the company context, the new market<br />

rationale meant three things. First,<br />

page 82 the links to the Communist Party<br />

were dismantled. Second, politicallyoriented<br />

setting of production<br />

volumes and prices stopped as production<br />

orders were left to ‘markets’, which meant that<br />

only orders from customers who were ready<br />

to pay in the hard currency at ‘market’ rather<br />

than at the subsidised rates would be taken.<br />

Finally, the state withdrew from the ownership<br />

structures by privatising the previously stateowned<br />

enterprises.<br />

However, despite the new dominant logic<br />

of market efficiency that was established<br />

in the early years of post-communism, the<br />

company level reality was more complex. The<br />

new organising logic of economic liberalism<br />

formulated and defended by the new political<br />

elites did not penetrate the companies overnight<br />

and did not make the previously existing norms<br />

and commitments towards the enterprise<br />

disappear completely. In an environment of<br />

high uncertainty, a medium- and long-term<br />

‘market value’ of enterprises and their viability<br />

in the future was unclear, yet decisions still<br />

had to be made. The governments and other<br />

stakeholders such as managers and trade<br />

union leaders needed to decide which existing<br />

industrial projects were viable for the market<br />

economy environment. It is in these decisions<br />

that the desire of stakeholders to preserve the<br />

existing industrial capabilities despite financial<br />

difficulties can be identified.<br />

At first glance, market-oriented rationale<br />

entered the scene in a very prominent way:<br />

financial viability of entrepreneurship became<br />

a crucial factor considered by stakeholders.<br />

In 1990, it was acknowledged by many that,<br />

economically, Škoda was not a viable company<br />

as it had large debts, declining sales and<br />

falling orders. Due to high debts, the company<br />

was unable to take out new loans that were<br />

urgently needed to pay day-to-day operations<br />

and the suppliers of components. There were<br />

voices among the Czechoslovak public that


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

suggested abandoning car production in<br />

favour of automotive components for foreign<br />

car producers (Pavlínek 2008: 80). Also, the<br />

government, as company owner, did not want<br />

to take a high financial risk and the option of<br />

government-led restructuring of the company<br />

and its subsequent privatisation were ruled out<br />

due to the fact that neither the government nor<br />

the banks were ready to guarantee the capital<br />

needed, despite the fact that the domestic and<br />

foreign demand were estimated to be far above<br />

production capacity (Pavlínek 2008: 80). Thus,<br />

Škoda was a troubled company with its East<br />

European markets collapsing; its financial<br />

position was close to bankruptcy.<br />

Yet market-oriented rationale has been<br />

restrained by non-economic organising logic.<br />

Thus, already during the privatisation process,<br />

next to the market-oriented logic of cost<br />

efficiency and market pricing, a ‘productionist’<br />

attitude of local stakeholders has become visible.<br />

Industrial traditions and industrial capabilities,<br />

rather than pure financial returns-oriented<br />

thinking, were important to local stakeholders.<br />

Due to its over 100-year-old history, Škoda’s<br />

reputation as a ‘family jewel’ was strong. It<br />

gave stakeholders the legitimacy to demand<br />

a continuation of firm activities. A foreign<br />

partner that would enter the joint venture was<br />

expected to invest in the company in order<br />

to improve quality and expand production<br />

volume (Pavlínek 2008). Thus, the solution<br />

of joint venture can, in this light, be seen as<br />

a compromise of the two logics – letting the<br />

‘market forces’ in the form of a foreign investor<br />

enter the scene, while at the same time ensuring<br />

the survival and preservation of already existing<br />

local industrial capabilities. Thus, Škoda’s<br />

example demonstrates that local stakeholders<br />

valued the company as a source of industrial<br />

capabilities and wanted to preserve these.<br />

The dramatic financial situation of Škoda might<br />

even explain the eagerness of the Czechoslovak<br />

government to privatise such an important<br />

industrial project at such a fast pace. In other<br />

Visegrad countries, if important industrial<br />

projects existed, they were either privatised<br />

but remained in domestic ownership, as in<br />

the case of Hungarian industrial giant Raba,<br />

or they were privatised much later following<br />

prolonged negotiations and a search for the<br />

‘right’ partner, as in the case of Polish FSO.<br />

Thus, a comparison across national borders<br />

allows us to conclude that Škoda’s foreign<br />

privatisation in itself can be interpreted in<br />

this context as evidence of the ‘productionist’<br />

logic, as marketisation through privatisation<br />

had as its final goal the strengthening of the<br />

company’s industrial capabilities.<br />

Large-scale government-led restructuring<br />

plans and with them more advantageous<br />

valuations of companies were ruled out<br />

quite early in the three cases of brownfield<br />

investments analysed in more depth in this<br />

study: Czech Škoda, Polish Tarpan and Slovak<br />

BAZ. In the case of Škoda, the government<br />

demands went furthest. This is what makes us<br />

focus on Škoda’s privatisation in the rest of this<br />

section. These demands went beyond general<br />

investment demands and covered,<br />

among other things, preservation of<br />

the Škoda brand. Yet why were these<br />

page 83<br />

advanced ‘productionist’ demands<br />

for preserving industrial capabilities<br />

formulated and followed in Škoda, but not in<br />

its former supplier Slovak BAZ or in Polish<br />

Tarpan? The explanation has to do with the


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

power balance and a perceived more prominent<br />

role of the government in the negotiations for<br />

Škoda: the local stakeholders were perceived<br />

to be in a stronger bargaining position<br />

when selling their ‘family jewel’. Focussing<br />

on the company’s medium-term industrial<br />

capabilities, the stakeholders were confident<br />

that Škoda’s reputation and its position in<br />

international markets were good: a large share<br />

of Škoda cars were sold abroad and thus Škoda<br />

was considered by stakeholders to be able to<br />

pass ‘the test of markets’.<br />

Yet, also non-economic rationales have been<br />

important for Škoda’s stronger negotiating<br />

position. Its reputation was strengthened by<br />

the fact that Škoda was among the few East<br />

European car brands that had home-grown<br />

technological developments – many other state<br />

socialist car brands had to buy the technology<br />

in the West. The introduction of its last<br />

model in the late 1980s strongly contributed<br />

to a significant improvement of its previous<br />

international image of a low cost, low quality<br />

car: introduction of Favorit ‘narrowed the gap<br />

between Škoda and its Western competitors in<br />

the class of small passenger cars so that Škoda<br />

could offer a (potentially highly) competitive<br />

product’ (Pavlínek 2008: 75). Thus, privatising<br />

the ‘family jewel’ with long industrial traditions<br />

guaranteed a strategically strong position for<br />

the government to formulate high demands<br />

on the foreign investor. In other<br />

plants, the local stakeholders in and<br />

page 84 outside of the plant were perceived<br />

to be in a weak bargaining position<br />

in relation to the foreign investor: in<br />

Slovakian BAZ and Polish Tarpan the strategic<br />

importance of the plants was considered<br />

low. VW group is argued to have found out<br />

about the BAZ supplier plant only during<br />

government negotiations concerning Škoda. As<br />

a manager in VW Slovakia explained: ‘we did<br />

not have Škoda’s hundred years of industrial<br />

history, this plant was relatively new’ (Interview<br />

March 2007). Thus, it is only in Czech Škoda<br />

where local stakeholders such as management,<br />

but even more importantly trade unions and<br />

government, could have a strong influence<br />

on the privatisation process; in the two other<br />

brownfield locations and, of course, in the new<br />

greenfield Audi Györ plant the new foreign<br />

owner was dominant.<br />

Two rationales dominated Škoda’s early partial<br />

privatisation. First, it was driven by the desire<br />

of local stakeholders - within the company as<br />

well as in the government – to preserve local<br />

industrial capabilities with the help of foreign<br />

investors in the short-term. Apart from having<br />

high debt, practically no long-term investment<br />

capital and thus no chances of being able<br />

to compete in international markets, Škoda<br />

even lacked financing to keep up day-today<br />

production (Pavlinek and Smith 1998).<br />

Sperling believes that:<br />

[T]he government of Czechoslovakia […] was<br />

of course interested in continuing the production<br />

activities of Škoda as a foundation for future<br />

economic development under the conditions,<br />

although the Czechs involved knew too well that<br />

Škoda would not survive in the changing and<br />

more competitive markets without some form of cooperation<br />

with Western manufacturers (Sperling<br />

2004: 184).<br />

The situation of Škoda’s suppliers was also<br />

critical given the following considerations: if<br />

Škoda went bankrupt, the suppliers would have


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

to share its fate. At that time, Škoda had 237<br />

domestic suppliers. Its bankruptcy, therefore,<br />

would have had a high impact on the regional<br />

economy (Pavlínek 2008: 80).<br />

However, the time dimension is very important<br />

for the understanding of this privatisation<br />

strategy. Foreign investors were perceived by<br />

the public and the government as a solution<br />

for the company’s short-term survival, but also<br />

as a guarantor of the long-term prosperity of<br />

the company as well as the regional economy<br />

as a whole. Thus, these so-called ‘strategic<br />

privatisations’ were not only motivated by the<br />

short-term financial returns. Preserving the<br />

existing industrial capabilities – even if they were<br />

weak and not up to international competition at<br />

that moment – was considered crucial because<br />

preserving industrial traditions was a symbol of<br />

continuous economic development. It is in this<br />

context that foreign investors were considered<br />

as ‘saviours’ of local companies and guarantors<br />

of long-term enterprise success.<br />

The role of government was important, as it<br />

could dictate the conditions of the joint venture.<br />

The preservation of the Škoda brand was a<br />

precondition for privatisation. It was explicitly<br />

expressed in the privatisation negotiations,<br />

together with other demands such as<br />

maintenance of the labour force, continuation<br />

of relations with local suppliers, continuation<br />

of R&D activities and Czech participation<br />

in company’s management ( Jung, Klemm et<br />

al. 2004). The choice of the foreign partner -<br />

the VW group - was thus made dependent<br />

on the condition of preserving the industrial<br />

capabilities of the enterprise. The other foreign<br />

bidder for Škoda was Renault, yet this major<br />

French car manufacturer was not interested in<br />

preserving and developing Škoda’s industrial<br />

capabilities: ‘to opt for a co-operation with<br />

Volkswagen was the credible commitment<br />

of Volkswagen to keep Škoda as a brand<br />

manufacturer coupled with the promises of<br />

major modernisation’(Sperling 2004: 184).<br />

The joint venture agreement signed between<br />

the VW group and the Czech government<br />

in April 1991 explicitly stated the level<br />

of expected investment on the part of the<br />

German investor and the future production<br />

capacities. It also included clauses concerning<br />

Czech components producers and Škoda’s<br />

employees (Pavlínek 2008). These numerous<br />

special clauses were developed by government<br />

officials and were one of the first expressions<br />

of government stakeholders before a more<br />

formalised process of privatisation was<br />

established. As Pavlinek (2008: 86) points out,<br />

it was only several months after drafting the<br />

Škoda joint venture agreement that the Czech<br />

Ministry for National Property Management<br />

formulated a directive that set out how<br />

privatisation projects should look.<br />

Yet the joint venture plants were made by<br />

government officials in cooperation with<br />

the management and trade unions, and not<br />

against their will. The role of Škoda’s direct<br />

stakeholders - i.e. management and trade<br />

unions - in the privatisation decision was<br />

crucial. Local management supported<br />

the idea of a joint venture with<br />

a foreign company: ‘as a leading<br />

page 85<br />

industry in Czechoslovakia and based<br />

on past trade experience with Western<br />

partners, the Škoda management quickly<br />

realized that drastic measures needed to be<br />

taken if the company was to survive under the


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

pressure of competition with Western auto<br />

producers’ ( Jung, Klemm et al. 2004: 206).<br />

The role of local unions was also crucial for<br />

the choice of the foreign partner. Despite the<br />

original preference of government officials and<br />

the broad public for Renault, Škoda unions<br />

persuaded the government to select VW<br />

as the preferred candidate (Pavlínek 2008).<br />

They voted against cooperation with Renault<br />

fearing downgrading and loosing the status of<br />

an independent brand. Volkswagen’s previous<br />

fair treatment of the SEAT – keeping it as<br />

independent brand – gave Czech stakeholders<br />

more confidence that VW promises would be<br />

kept. Union representatives also supported<br />

the German bidder due to strong industrial<br />

relations in Germany (Sperling 2004: 185).<br />

Renault, on the other hand, ‘was seen as a<br />

state company and, hence, not the appropriate<br />

partner for the privatisation process, in which<br />

the main challenge Škoda faced was overcoming<br />

the deficits created by the period as a state<br />

company’ ( Jung, Klemm et al. 2004: 207).<br />

Thus, unions were an important stakeholder in<br />

this choice of the foreign investor. It was with<br />

the agreement of Škoda’s management and<br />

unions that the foreign investor was chosen.<br />

Preserving the labour force was part of the joint<br />

venture agreement between the government<br />

and the VW group. Despite a very large<br />

headcount, the majority of employees were<br />

taken over. The fact that high levels<br />

of employment - around 15,000<br />

page 86 employees in the early 1990s – were<br />

preserved was a direct consequence of<br />

stakeholder demands. In the Slovak<br />

BAZ that then became VW Bratislava, on the<br />

other hand, the influence of local management<br />

and government backing were much weaker.<br />

As a consequence, a very different employment<br />

strategy was chosen: all ‘old’ employees were<br />

laid off and had to go through re-hiring process.<br />

The company restarted with 400 employees in<br />

1992 (Interview March 2007). Also, far fewer<br />

privatisation conditions from the government<br />

side were formulated.<br />

As the VW group experienced a crisis in 1993-<br />

1994 and announced a reduction in production<br />

numbers, lower level of investments and overall<br />

much more modest investment approach – so,<br />

for example, no new engine factory was going<br />

to be built in Škoda despite the original promise<br />

– the Czech government took an active stance<br />

to protect regional industrial capabilities. It<br />

requested an addendum to the existing joint<br />

venture agreement that would clearly stipulate<br />

the group’s continuous commitments towards<br />

Škoda. Although the investment levels stated in<br />

the document signed in November 1994 were<br />

more modest than in the original agreement<br />

of 1991, it was the government’s goal to<br />

have a formal commitment of the German<br />

investor to its Czech investment project. The<br />

state also gained the right to participate in<br />

‘all fundamental decisions regarding the joint<br />

venture and a veto power over any decision<br />

that would dramatically affect Škoda’s activities<br />

until December 1999, when the VW group was<br />

planning to buy the remaining shares of the<br />

company’ (Pavlínek 2008: 90). The government<br />

also added an additional protection for the<br />

Czech suppliers in the agreement: once able to<br />

compete with other suppliers, local component<br />

suppliers had the right to supply the whole<br />

group.<br />

What could be demonstrated by the example<br />

of Škoda is a general pattern of several


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

organising enterprise logics being at work;<br />

sometimes in conflict with each other but<br />

sometimes supporting each other. The main<br />

demands to the foreign investor were related<br />

to the non-economic enterprise logics of<br />

brand preservation, employment guarantees<br />

and modernisation of the company, yet market<br />

organising logic has also been visible. It has<br />

been the means to reach the non-economic<br />

ends. Applying this economic logic and<br />

‘second guessing the markets’ allowed Škoda<br />

stakeholders to take a much stronger stance<br />

vis-à-vis the foreign buyers during the joint<br />

venture negotiations.<br />

The valuation of the enterprise as a social and<br />

industrial organism went against other sets<br />

of non-economic norms. For Czechs, such<br />

other non-economic logic was the strong anti-<br />

German sentiment related to World War II.<br />

Thus, the transfer of Škoda’s ownership to the<br />

VW group caused some controversies in the<br />

Czech public during the time of privatisation<br />

talks (Sperling 2004). But also on the German<br />

side, different organising logics co-existed.<br />

Even if the warnings about a potential<br />

cannibalisation of the main Volkswagen brand<br />

that focuses on good quality but more expensive<br />

family sedans by the re-emerging Škoda brand<br />

were expressed, non-economic organising<br />

logics have prevailed. The respect for industrial<br />

capabilities of Skoda engineering tradition has<br />

been stronger than the fear of cannibalisation<br />

of the main VW brand. Even today, when<br />

the evidence of certain cannibalisation of the<br />

German production is large, this issue is hardly<br />

discussed and, as Sperling argues, ‘denied by<br />

the group itself or made to appear harmless’<br />

(Sperling 2004: 187).<br />

This section attempted to demonstrate how<br />

during the privatisation process, despite several<br />

economic and non-economic logics playing<br />

a role, the non-economic organising logic<br />

that conceptuliased enterprise as a source of<br />

industrial capabilities has been crucial. Škoda’s<br />

privatisation has been an example of local<br />

stakeholders - managers, trade unions and<br />

government officials - becoming a coalition<br />

for protection of local industrial capabilities.<br />

II. THE NEW COST EFFICIENCY GOALS RECON-<br />

SIDERED<br />

During state socialism, company goals were<br />

expressed in units of production output. With<br />

the joint venture, these non-economic goals<br />

were supposed to be replaced by other, more<br />

market efficiency-oriented targets. But how<br />

has this change towards new company goals<br />

taken place and what exactly are the new<br />

company performance goals?<br />

Formal administratively set production output<br />

goals were replaced by cost efficiency and<br />

productivity goals. Financial targets and cost<br />

monitoring became a higher priority for local<br />

management that received responsibilities<br />

of ‘profit centres’ within the VW group.<br />

The cost goals are set in cooperation with<br />

the headquarters and play a decisive role in<br />

companies’ affairs. A finance director<br />

at VW Slovakia explained that<br />

the company is ‘managed through<br />

page 87<br />

these cost goals’: the company<br />

has performance and profit goals<br />

(Interview March 2007). Also, the internal<br />

cost benchmarking has become a norm.<br />

There exists comparative data on production


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

costs per hour across the group and this data<br />

is communicated to all subsidiaries. Thus,<br />

even among ‘low cost’ production sites of<br />

Central Europe, the headquarters try to build<br />

up competition. As a consequence, greater<br />

attention is devoted to monitoring production<br />

costs. At Audi Györ, the works council leader<br />

stated that ‘We cannot go above 10 euro<br />

[per hour] if we want to remain competitive’<br />

(Interview August 2007). In addition to<br />

the continuous benchmarking, the tender<br />

system of the VW Group that is comparable<br />

with that in most other large automotive<br />

MNCs requires subsidiaries to apply for new<br />

models and, thus, represents an additional<br />

pressure of cost-efficiency for companies. ‘The<br />

competition for new models within the group<br />

is very, very strong. For each new model we<br />

need to apply, there are three criteria: quality,<br />

costs and flexibility’, stated the HR director in<br />

VW Slovakia (Interview March 2007).<br />

Credit institutions impose further ‘hard budget<br />

constraints’. They lend money to the VW<br />

subsidiaries for investment projects. These loans<br />

can be taken without headquarters’ permission.<br />

Thus, normally, no inter-company credits take<br />

place, but loans are taken from private or semipublic<br />

banks. Thus, in case of VW Slovakia,<br />

these banks have been the European Bank of<br />

Reconstruction and Development (EBRD)<br />

and a number of private banks (Interview<br />

March 2007). The manager was<br />

happy to announce that all debts of an<br />

page 88 enormous investment – 1.53 billion<br />

euro over 15 years - have been paid<br />

back by 2006 (Interview March 2007).<br />

Furthermore, the modern auditing concepts<br />

common in market economies such as balance<br />

sheets and own capital ratios have become<br />

widely used (Interview March 2007). Thus,<br />

the level of financial accountability, but also<br />

of financial pressures, increased substantially<br />

to make the previously existing soft budget<br />

constraints disappear.<br />

Productivity pressures that also come from<br />

headquarters’ benchmarking are a further<br />

dimension of the new organising logic of<br />

cost efficiency. Productivity increases are fixed<br />

every year, often they are set quite high. Fixing<br />

expected productivity increases at the level of<br />

inflation is justified by arguing that the wage<br />

increases are covered by inflation increases<br />

without jeopardising the financial stability of<br />

the company (Interview March 2007). The<br />

consequences of these pressures are a greater<br />

emphasis on optimisation and efficiency at<br />

work. A line manager from production unit<br />

explained:<br />

Of course, productivity does not only depend on<br />

production process, but also on design and the<br />

nature of parts and construction. However, the<br />

part of production process and the assembly line is<br />

important. Less mistakes are made, less cars need<br />

to go into repair. […] The group’s goal is a ‘first<br />

in’ quote of 95%, at VW Slovakia this quote has<br />

been 90-95%, sometimes 80% (Interview March<br />

2007).<br />

Also in Škoda, there has been a clear change in<br />

the narratives of management; it underlines a<br />

new orientation ‘towards achievement, quality<br />

and efficiency’ ( Jung, Klemm et al. 2004: 208).<br />

The narratives of constant improvement of<br />

work organisation have become widely spread.<br />

Thus, in Škoda, management introduced the<br />

‘Škoda production model’. The predecessor of it<br />

was ‘fractal production organisation’, a German


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

inspired version of the lean production system<br />

introduced in Škoda in 1994 with a new model<br />

Felicia. Apart from following the philosophy of<br />

continuous improvement, the idea behind the<br />

fractal – modular – organisation of production<br />

was to make the production process more<br />

transparent by improving information flows<br />

and more flexible by dividing production in<br />

modular groups (Pavlínek 2008: 95). In other<br />

VW subsidiaries, no ‘extra’ names were given,<br />

but new practices of work organisation have<br />

been introduced in all plants since the mid-<br />

1990s. The idea of continuous improvement<br />

is known and referred to. KVP Kaskaden<br />

– ‘continued improvement workshops’ in<br />

product and process exist where team leaders<br />

from assembly lines come together with<br />

engineers and specialists from industrial<br />

engineering to propose things ‘to make their<br />

work better’. Similarly, a production manager<br />

in VW Slovakia argued that ‘there are always<br />

still reserves that can be optimised: material,<br />

reduction of work errors, maintenance, non<br />

ergonomic movements’ (Interview March<br />

2007). Just-in-time working practices are<br />

omnipresent: in many cases ‘system suppliers’<br />

deliver their products directly to the assembly<br />

line. The manager at VW Slovakia referred to<br />

them as ’Just-in-sequence’, an expression that<br />

implies an even faster turn-around, as delivery<br />

times are very low, usually two hours (Interview<br />

March 2007). Similarly, in Škoda, delivery times<br />

are two to three hours. The visible consequences<br />

of this clear shift to a lean production-oriented<br />

work organisation have been an increased level<br />

of work effort required and an increased work<br />

pace. The director of the sport utility vehicle<br />

(SUV) production at VW Slovakia confirmed<br />

that ‘turnover is high, qualified people are going<br />

away: work at the assembly line is hard, people<br />

prefer to work in the repair shop rather than<br />

on the assembly line’ (Interview March 2007).<br />

Yet the development of tougher productivity<br />

and cost efficiency benchmarks is subject to<br />

certain limits set by the productionist focus<br />

and by the commitment to local industrial<br />

capabilities that has been preserved in the<br />

Central European VW subsidiaries. Next to<br />

embracing the logic of ever higher productivity<br />

and cost efficiency, from the beginning of this<br />

joint venture, the non-economic organising<br />

logic has also been an important rationale for<br />

local management. At the core of managerial<br />

thinking are ‘productionist’ variables related to<br />

employment, industrial upgrading, and product<br />

quality as well as engineering and technical<br />

proficiency. They matter to stakeholders<br />

regardless of their cost-efficiency. Two phases<br />

can be distinguished in the evolution of the<br />

VW subsidiaries: the early 1990s to mid-1990s<br />

and the late 1990s to mid-2000s. During the<br />

second phase - from the late 1990s to early<br />

2000s - the technological and organisational<br />

upgrading took place. The following paragraphs<br />

elaborate how during both phases the role of<br />

‘productionist’ variables remained important<br />

for local stakeholders.<br />

During the first phase in the early 1990s, the<br />

process of adaptation was most intense. It is<br />

especially during the early period of special<br />

‘hardship’ and restructuring where<br />

the objectives related to employment<br />

levels can be identified easily. During<br />

page 89<br />

this early phase, the policies of<br />

employment pursued directly during<br />

and after the privatisation are telling. During<br />

the early 1990s when production numbers<br />

were low, employees were to a large extent


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

kept on board at Škoda, at least the ‘core<br />

workers’. In 1994, restructuring of production<br />

organisation meant that 800 Czech workers<br />

and a much larger number of foreign workers<br />

lost their jobs. Among these foreign workers<br />

were 800 Cubans, 700 Poles and more then<br />

1,500 Vietnamese (Pavlínek 2008: 97). Yet<br />

these large lay-offs have still been relatively<br />

small in relation to the overall headcount of<br />

15,000 and 17,000 in the early 1990s. Thus,<br />

labour hoarding, even if at a much smaller<br />

scale in comparison to state socialist times,<br />

was still partially preserved. Also, during the<br />

second phase, examples of temporary ‘labour<br />

hoarding’ still exist. Thus, at Audi Györ, during<br />

the periods of model change when production<br />

volumes are low due to technical restructuring<br />

of the assembly line, the company could afford<br />

to keep employees on board.<br />

The second phase of company developments is<br />

associated with industrial upgrading and, thus,<br />

with another type of ‘productionist’ enterprise<br />

norm. VW group’s internationalisation<br />

strategies in all four production locations<br />

intensified in terms of investment volumes,<br />

production and employment numbers that<br />

went together with industrial upgrading. For<br />

Central European managers, the importance<br />

of engineering and technical proficiency has<br />

been at the heart of this modernisation process.<br />

In Škoda, introduction of the Octavia model<br />

in 1996 was described as a crucial<br />

moment despite the fact that the<br />

page 90 joint venture has been in place since<br />

1991 and two early models - Felicia<br />

and Favorit - were already produced<br />

in cooperation with German headquarters.<br />

These two commonly developed models still<br />

had some elements of the original Škoda<br />

design and technology, but local managers<br />

did not express any regret about them being<br />

replaced by Volkswagen technology (Interview<br />

December 2006). The technical and engineering<br />

supremacy of German know-how definitely<br />

seems to have priority for local managers.<br />

International comparative benchmarking<br />

techniques such as Harbour Report, which<br />

compares data of productivity and efficiency,<br />

are familiar to the production management; but<br />

when confronted with relatively ‘bad’ results for<br />

VW group on financial and productivity figures<br />

from the Harbour Report, Škoda management<br />

did not see a big problem (Interview December<br />

2006). The director for industrial engineering<br />

explained that the low productivity figures of<br />

Central European VW subsidiaries can be<br />

explained by low levels of automation. Thus,<br />

the role of comparative benchmarks in labour<br />

costs does not seem to be high. When costs are<br />

evoked, they are used to justify ‘productionist’<br />

decisions such as keeping a high headcount: it<br />

is acknowledged that the share of labour costs<br />

in Central European automotive production is<br />

relatively low. In Škoda’s case it is 20-30% of<br />

total production costs, which is significantly<br />

lower than the share for the VW group as a<br />

whole (around 50%). It is argued that employing<br />

people is cheaper and more flexible than using<br />

machines. These would need to be replaced,<br />

while people can adapt. This fact allowed for<br />

the retention of a high headcount (Interview<br />

December 2006). A similar argument has been<br />

developed by the HR director of VW Slovakia,<br />

who argued that ‘The sophisticated cars that<br />

we produce here demand a lot of manual work<br />

and manual work is cheap in Slovakia’. He also<br />

explained that: ‘One reason for low automation<br />

is that we wanted employment. [..] Ten years


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

ago employment of people was priority number<br />

one. At that time, unemployment was very high<br />

in Slovakia - 20-30%’ (Interview March 2007).<br />

A clear indicator of managerial ‘productionist’<br />

attitude has been its desire of medium-term<br />

modernisation of the plants: the goal has been<br />

to attract more investment to the production<br />

location, ensure production over time and<br />

upgrade the facilities from low value added<br />

to high value added. The overarching goal has<br />

been to develop local capabilities and move the<br />

company’s position within the group from the<br />

periphery to the centre. In Škoda, improvement<br />

in the quality of production has been described<br />

by insiders as one of the crucial reasons for<br />

success. The second reason stated has been the<br />

recognition of the plant as a mature partner<br />

within the VW group (Interview December<br />

2006). Thus, despite the growing importance of<br />

short-term cost efficiency pressures, the focus<br />

on technology and production quality remains.<br />

Responding to the question whether the<br />

financial side has become more important than<br />

the production side, the top finance manager at<br />

VW Slovakia, responded: ‘No, I cannot say that<br />

this is the case. The production and quality still<br />

matter. The allocation of production resources<br />

could have been different’ (Interview March<br />

2007). Thus, despite a shift towards the logic<br />

of cost efficiency, the financial parameters<br />

still have not completely replaced mediumterm<br />

goals of production and employment<br />

parameters in managerial thinking.<br />

A clear desire to build up local research<br />

capabilities has also been emphasised. Even if a<br />

large part of innovation know-how is imported<br />

from the headquarters, especially in the field of<br />

process innovation, the role of local managers<br />

is not negligible. Even if local decision makers<br />

are not fully autonomous, process innovation<br />

still takes place (Interview December 2006).<br />

Thus, the director for industrial engineering<br />

at VW Slovakia was proud to report examples<br />

of process innovation that were introduced in<br />

his company. Thus, for example, the concept of<br />

‘supplier basket’ was introduced in his plant to<br />

deal with variety and complexity of the vehicles<br />

constructed at the same assembly line.<br />

Union representatives – together with<br />

management – also continue to share a strong<br />

‘productionist’ identity. Like management,<br />

company unions see their goal in company<br />

advancement and prosperity. An example of<br />

union adherence to the ‘productionist mode’<br />

is their emphasis on the union function of<br />

assuring production quality and discipline.<br />

Especially since the early 2000s, a high turnover<br />

has been an increasingly important issue in all<br />

plants. For example, in Audi Hungaria, labour<br />

force fluctuation has been 1% per month in<br />

2000, while the goal has been 0.4%. In VW<br />

Slovakia, where turnover rates increased in<br />

mid-2000s from 7-9% to higher levels of<br />

9-10% annually, they are still reported to be<br />

only half of turnover rates of other Slovak firms<br />

(Interview March 2007). Unions have started<br />

to capitalise on their function of assuring<br />

discipline during the production process.<br />

The HR director of VW Slovakia stated that<br />

‘unions are our eyes and ears: what we<br />

don’t see, they see’ (Interview March<br />

2007). Furthermore, a productionist<br />

page 91<br />

part of union identity is also visible<br />

in the fact that unions also started<br />

to develop a discourse based on the valuation<br />

of skills and knowledge. Finally, unions are<br />

directly involved in the issue of industrial


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

upgrading. A Hungarian union leader at Audi<br />

Györ stated referring to German management<br />

that: ‘if they do not take our problems seriously<br />

then maybe the best solution for them is to<br />

go home, because we cannot be efficient’<br />

(Interview August 2007). Furthermore, unions<br />

sometimes intervene directly and express their<br />

opinions concerning upgrading. Thus, in 2002<br />

in Škoda, as employees perceived the danger<br />

of degradation of the product profile, a short<br />

protest action organised by trade unions was<br />

staged (Sperling 2004: 191).<br />

The underlying reasons for the productionist<br />

approach among company stakeholders are<br />

complex. First, the highly ‘productionist’<br />

approach of VW group in Germany has<br />

further reinforced the productionist attitude<br />

of Central European stakeholders. A<br />

productionist approach on the German side<br />

meant that core-periphery division between<br />

the headquarters and subsidiaries was not<br />

permanent. The original investment decisions<br />

were driven by the desire to build up low-cost<br />

production locations and access new markets;<br />

the upgrading of the new subsidiaries to the<br />

state-of-the-art production locations was<br />

not the original intention of the VW Group<br />

headquarters. ‘At the beginning, three halls<br />

were constructed here. Now, the whole area is<br />

full of buildings. At that time, no one could<br />

imagine that VW Slovakia would become such<br />

a huge factory’, emphasised the HR<br />

manager (Interview March 2007).<br />

page 92 It was subsidiaries’ initiatives to use<br />

the window of opportunity whenever<br />

it emerged to upgrade their plants.<br />

A productionist norm of technical and craft<br />

proficiency that was also a feature of the VW<br />

group headquarters was the underlying factor<br />

in industrial upgrading of subsidiaries: when<br />

Central European subsidiaries proved that they<br />

were capable to produce highly sophisticated<br />

products, their upgrading was launched. The<br />

HR director of VW Slovakia makes this<br />

argument clear with the example of his plant:<br />

Originally, the plan for this plant was to produce<br />

Passat. Yet in 1994, we were offered an opportunity<br />

to produce a four-wheel ‘Golf for motion’. And it is<br />

in this project that we showed that we were capable<br />

of producing these most sophisticated cars. And this<br />

was the starting point. But this was a coincidence,<br />

not a strategic decision. The headquarters were<br />

looking for a cheap production location, they realised<br />

that in Bratislava there was an empty capacity, so<br />

they decided to give it a try.[..] It was in 2000 that<br />

the strategic decision to produce the SUVs in VW<br />

Slovakia was made. [..] And one of the reasons for<br />

this was that earlier we showed ourselves capable<br />

of producing these sophisticated cars [...], in the<br />

excellent quality (Interview March 2007).<br />

Thus, a high level of openness about the future<br />

upgrading in the VW Group headquarters<br />

has been an important factor supporting the<br />

productionist attitude and the preservation<br />

of the local non-economic enterprise norm.<br />

The local stakeholders were the driving forces<br />

behind the upgrading, yet this crucial role of<br />

local management has been possible due to the<br />

specific control mode and commitment mode<br />

of the German MNC. More generally, Bluhm<br />

(2007) argues that the arm’s length control<br />

mode of the German MNC headquarters<br />

allows certain opportunity structures to<br />

emerge. When these opportunities emerge,<br />

they are capitalised upon by local management<br />

to strategically enlarge the mandate of its<br />

subsidiary within the group.


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

Furthermore, VW group has not used any ‘back<br />

door’ strategy to achieve compliance with new<br />

managerial goals but followed a route that took<br />

into consideration the previous experience<br />

of old managerial staff. Replacement of<br />

managerial staff by new people with experience<br />

of working in market economies could have<br />

been a strategy of the headquarters. However,<br />

this happened only to a limited extent. Only<br />

top management was replaced by the German<br />

expatriates, while the large share of local middle<br />

and line management was kept. Even in 2006,<br />

30% of old local managers were still employed<br />

by Škoda. The role of expatriates has been<br />

relatively limited in the medium term. Apart<br />

from Škoda’s experimental three year tandem<br />

program that has attracted a large number of<br />

German managers to the subsidiary, the usual<br />

trend in all subsidiaries is that only the top<br />

management team is dominated by expatriates,<br />

while the human resource manager is usually<br />

a local person. VW Bratislava and Škoda have<br />

several top local managers; Audi Györ has<br />

had the smallest number so far with only one<br />

local top manager - responsible for human<br />

resources.<br />

Another reason for the ‘productionist attitude’<br />

is the technical-engineering background<br />

dominant among local managers, rather<br />

than an orientation towards pure financial<br />

accountability and profit maximization. The<br />

training background of managers in engineering<br />

facilitates their technical-engineering orientation.<br />

This is how Škoda senior manager for<br />

industrial engineering describes his reasons to<br />

come to Škoda:<br />

I’ve studied mechanical engineering. [...] During<br />

my studies, in 1994, I was a trainee in the Audi<br />

plant. This is where I saw the first models of the<br />

new Octavia. And this is the point when I became<br />

fascinated by it. I told myself: ‘If we had this car in<br />

production at Škoda, this would be unbelievable’.<br />

Then, some time later, I saw this car on the street<br />

for the first time and this is when my decision was<br />

made – I wanted to go work for Škoda, because<br />

the cars that they produce there are amazing<br />

(Interview December 2006).<br />

The manager further reports that what was<br />

crucial in the new model was the new level<br />

of quality compared to previous models. Thus,<br />

engineering and technical excellence rather<br />

than pure financial parameters are the defining<br />

features of managerial thinking.<br />

Internal career progression is another factor<br />

that facilitates the preservation of productionist<br />

focus. Internal labour advancement has<br />

remained important and many of senior<br />

managers started as simple blue-collar<br />

workers. The director of motor production at<br />

Škoda was one of them. He has been working<br />

in the factory for 20 years. Originally, he was<br />

a welder, and then moved to the planning and<br />

preparing new models as a technical specialist<br />

before becoming the director of the engine<br />

plant (Interview December 2006). Similarly,<br />

the director of the SUV production at VW<br />

Slovakia was previously a blue-collar worker<br />

(Interview March 2007). Interestingly, the<br />

internal career ladder has also worked<br />

for trade union leader: the head of<br />

VW Slovakia’s human resources was<br />

a trade union leader during state<br />

socialist times (Interview March 2007).<br />

To sum up, the introduction of certain<br />

benchmarking and financial accountability<br />

page 93


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

tools in the Central European VW subsidiaries<br />

allowed a new, more market-oriented efficiency<br />

logic of firm valuation to emerge. At the same<br />

time, the headquarters’ lenient approach to<br />

managerial staff as well as training background<br />

and internal career ladder allowed a part of<br />

the old productionist attitudes to persist. The<br />

next section shows the role of local production<br />

coalitions between management and unions in<br />

translating this productionist enterprise norm<br />

into industrial upgrading.<br />

III. COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS AS PRODUC-<br />

TION COALITIONS<br />

As the previous section demonstrated, local<br />

management in VW subsidiaries has had a clear<br />

‘productionist’ attitude in its desire to attract<br />

investment, ensure production over time and<br />

upgrade. The industrial upgrading has been a<br />

unique phenomenon due to its speed and scale.<br />

To convince the headquarters, management<br />

had to rely on the support of key stakeholders<br />

such as local trade unions. As a consequence,<br />

to achieve the goal of plant modernisation<br />

and upgrading, local management in VW<br />

subsidiaries chose to treat trade unions as<br />

partners1 in issues where unions have legal<br />

co-decision rights. Unions have thus become<br />

important in the industrial upgrading process<br />

of VW subsidiaries. This section brings out<br />

the dominant part of union identity:<br />

between union functions – production<br />

page 94 and protection – union identity<br />

remains strongly ‘productionist’. In<br />

this argument, the last section tried<br />

to disentangle the rationale behind union<br />

productionist attitudes. I argued that also on<br />

the union side, preserving and developing<br />

industrial capabilities was a core goal. This<br />

section, in turn, discusses formal collective<br />

agreements as examples of management-union<br />

coalitions for upgrading.<br />

In the German VW plants, as in most other<br />

German automotive producers, company level<br />

management-labour production coalitions<br />

have become quite wide-spread in the 1990s.<br />

In Germany, the goal of these coalitions was to<br />

‘minimise the costs’ of the economic downturn<br />

or of the increased international competition.<br />

Also in Central European VW production sites,<br />

collective agreements have been used in some<br />

cases for similar purposes. Thus, in 2005 in VW<br />

Slovakia, due to reduced demand, management<br />

sought an arrangement with unions which<br />

was found by reducing the number of hours<br />

worked. The trade-off agreement was reached<br />

between management and unions mainly by<br />

increasing the pay. Thus, management used<br />

cooperation with unions in cases of strong<br />

demand decreases although these cases were<br />

rather exceptional. Yet the main purpose of local<br />

production coalitions in Central Europe has<br />

been different in comparison to Germany. In<br />

Central European VW subsidiaries, company<br />

collective agreements have been the major<br />

examples of enterprise ‘production coalitions’<br />

for upgrading and industrial modernisation. In<br />

this way, the common goal of building up of<br />

industrial capabilities was achieved: collectively<br />

agreed additional, although limited, bonuses<br />

and pay benefits for the core labour force are<br />

traded-off against more working time flexibility<br />

at continuously overall relatively low wages.<br />

Working time flexibility includes the variety<br />

of shift systems and overtime arrangements.<br />

A more flexible use of these arrangements<br />

allowed a more intensive use of machines and


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

other productive investment, making Central<br />

European subsidiaries highly competitive<br />

production locations within the VW group.<br />

Local management was the main driver in<br />

the industrial modernisation process, while<br />

unions were the facilitators. Collective<br />

agreements cover the issues of overtime, shift<br />

organisation and time accounts. Working<br />

time and work organisation are two crucial<br />

fields, in addition to wages, where unions<br />

have had legal rights to be consulted and be<br />

taken into account. The case of Audi Györ is<br />

the clearest example of union-management<br />

cooperation for upgrading. The cooperation<br />

only materialised once management saw an<br />

advantage in concluding the agreement. It has<br />

been looking for a ‘win-win situation’ before<br />

engaging in serious collective bargaining. Thus,<br />

collective negotiations took place for six years<br />

without an agreement and only in 2001, when<br />

the Hungarian employment law was amended<br />

introducing more possibilities for negotiating<br />

working time flexibility, did management<br />

became serious about collective bargaining and<br />

the first deal was struck. The manager explained<br />

how introduction of this time flexibility was<br />

fostered by changes in labour law that made<br />

such an agreement with unions possible and<br />

how this allowed the company to save costs:<br />

‘Before we had to pay overtime, once we had<br />

the collective agreement longer working time<br />

periods could be used. […] This was the most<br />

important reason for us [management] to have<br />

this collective agreement’ (Interview August<br />

2007). What these collective agreements<br />

allow is a very high level of working time<br />

flexibility and thus better use of machines<br />

and productive investment. The Audi HR<br />

manager stated that ‘there are 70 working time<br />

models here. It has been very important for<br />

our company to be able to be flexible, ‘to play’<br />

with working time’ (Interview August 2007).<br />

Yet also in other subsidiaries, the collective<br />

agreements have been used by management<br />

more intensively since the late 1990s-early<br />

2000s to achieve the necessary flexibility in<br />

working time, shift structure, etc. Thus, also<br />

in Škoda and in VW Slovakia, management<br />

used collective agreements as a flexibility tool.<br />

HR director at VW Slovakia put ‘enormous<br />

flexibility’ as one of the key reasons for the<br />

success of VW Slovakia: ‘I don’t know if there<br />

is another firm in the group that has such a<br />

high level of flexibility. […] The workers work<br />

normal number of hours, but they also work<br />

Saturdays, Sundays’ (Interview March 2007).<br />

The shift system has been changed from a<br />

three-shift to a four-shift to a continuous shift<br />

system. The latter allows a more intensive use<br />

of machines and people. This ‘flexibility’ that<br />

is praised by management has been possible<br />

due to company level collective agreements<br />

between management and trade unions.<br />

According to labour law and collective<br />

agreements in Škoda, most working time<br />

flexibility measures need to be agreed with<br />

unions. Thus, to introduce new working time<br />

systems for the period of one year, agreement<br />

with trade unions is required. Also working<br />

time systems that extend the work week to the<br />

weekend are agreed with trade unions<br />

two months in advance (Škoda 2005:<br />

18-20). Similarly, in VW Slovakia, all<br />

page 95<br />

important changes in shift systems<br />

are agreed with unions. The collective<br />

agreements create a limit of weekly and annual<br />

over-time thus effectively allowing for working<br />

time accounts. In terms of work organisation,


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

a three-shift system operates (with time<br />

accounts2).<br />

Also in VW Slovakia, the ‘extreme flexibility’<br />

of the labour force is presented as a crucial<br />

ingredient for the upgrading success. The<br />

management used agreements with unions to<br />

achieve a level of very high shift flexibility. A<br />

three-shift system was first tested since 1996<br />

and was fully introduced in 1998. In this<br />

system, the weekends were free but employees<br />

could be asked to come to work if necessary.<br />

In March 2007, the system was ‘flexibilised’<br />

further when the three-shift system was<br />

replaced by a ‘continuous shift3’ system with<br />

four shifts a day. In this system, people work<br />

for seven days and then have two to three days<br />

free. It allows the plant to utilise the equipment<br />

and the labour to its extreme: ‘flexibility is one<br />

of the main factors that explain the success<br />

of our plant. […] we are able to do with our<br />

employees everything we need’, explained the<br />

director for human resources in VW Slovakia<br />

(Interview March 2007). The cooperation<br />

with unions was assured after an early stage<br />

of conflict: ‘When we first introduced this<br />

working time flexibility, we met with resistance<br />

from the labour force i.e. the unions’, the<br />

manager reported (Interview March 2007).<br />

In addition to flexible shift systems, most<br />

collective agreements also cover additional<br />

agreements between management<br />

and unions concerning maximum<br />

page 96 allowed overtime. Thus, for example,<br />

while the labour code allows 200<br />

hours overtime per year, the company<br />

collective agreement in Audi Györ made it<br />

possible to increase this level up to 300 hours<br />

overtime per year (Interview August 2007).<br />

Also, in VW Slovakia, the collective agreement<br />

allows overtime to go above the national<br />

legislation maximum of annual overtime.<br />

Similarly in Škoda, the overtime work is<br />

regulated by collective agreements: it sets an<br />

average maximum number of overtime per<br />

week and establishes a yearly account for the<br />

calculation of overtime (Škoda 2005).<br />

The second pillar of these production<br />

coalitions in form of collective agreements<br />

has been important wage moderation. Unions<br />

share management’s new rationale of strong<br />

pressures of international competition. During<br />

most of the 1990s and early 2000s, limited<br />

wage increases have been a substantial part<br />

of these enterprise production pacts. Wage<br />

restraint and inflation indexation remain the<br />

norm, as it is seen by both local management<br />

and local unions as the safest option to secure<br />

additional foreign investment inflows – unions<br />

and management both admit that they do not<br />

want to lose out in international competition<br />

and would like to preserve their low-cost<br />

location advantage. Thus, the HR director at<br />

VW Slovakia states: ‘The main reference point<br />

for us in wage increases have been the inflation<br />

rates. This year, because of tight labour markets,<br />

we decided to implement the planned wage<br />

increase earlier then planned because for such<br />

sophisticated products we need the best people.<br />

But we do need to fit within the VW brand, we<br />

should not go far beyond, otherwise we won’t<br />

be competitive within the brand’ (Interview<br />

March 2007).<br />

The tension between wage increases and<br />

competitiveness is especially strong for<br />

the metalworking industry, as it is hugely<br />

internationalised. Trade unions have been


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

very sensitive as far as the competitive<br />

positions of their countries were concerned.<br />

Rather than following the advice of the<br />

European Metalworker Federation, which<br />

since 1998 has been formulating guidelines<br />

insisting that wage bargaining should cover<br />

at least a part of labour productivity increases,<br />

metalworker unions in Central Europe have<br />

not seriously made participation in labour<br />

productivity a part of their bargaining agenda.<br />

Their bargaining demands as well as achieved<br />

outcomes have been much closer focussing on<br />

covering inflation. Union officials confirmed<br />

that it was important to preserve the wage gap<br />

to Germany, as this has been their comparative<br />

advantage: thus, Czech and Slovak wages are<br />

still at about one third of German wages, while<br />

productivity differences are substantial but<br />

smaller (Interview August 2007). This explicit<br />

union goal of preserving wage gap to the<br />

German wages despite very high productivity<br />

increases is a clear sign of competitiveness logic<br />

that unions now share with local management.<br />

To sum up, during the late 1990s and early<br />

2000s, the local management-labour coalitions<br />

have become stronger in VW subsidiaries.<br />

High functional flexibility and low wage<br />

increases have been the two central pillars of<br />

these enterprise production coalitions. These<br />

were traded by unions for company expansion<br />

and product and production upgrading. These<br />

collective agreements represent ‘local pacts<br />

for production’: their intensification went<br />

together with industrial upgrading that took<br />

place since the late 1990s and early 2000s.<br />

Management-union cooperation has thus<br />

been crucial for upgrading: it is the intensified<br />

exchange between labour and management<br />

since the late 1990s that contributed to the<br />

success of industrial upgrading in Eastern VW<br />

subsidiaries. Collective agreements have been<br />

examples of ‘productionist’ attitudes shared<br />

by local management and trade unions. The<br />

productionist legacy of state socialist era has<br />

thus been preserved even if in a very different<br />

institutional form.<br />

IV. INDUSTRIAL CAPABILITIES AS AN ISSUE OF<br />

PUBLIC CONCERN<br />

During state socialism, public ownership of<br />

enterprises was not a monetary ownership<br />

– profits could not be re-invested. Rather, it<br />

was ownership that represented a control<br />

of allocation of productive resources. As<br />

abundance of productive resources was mostly<br />

linked to high employment figures and all<br />

related social provisions, large industrial<br />

projects were also high prestige projects. Thus,<br />

although in state socialism there was no free<br />

public media or free civil society and, thus,<br />

no means for the public to express its opinion<br />

about industrial policies or similar, large<br />

industrial projects still enjoyed high status and<br />

prestige. Furthermore, even if the decisions<br />

concerning industrial priorities might have<br />

served more the particularistic interests of the<br />

Communist Party officials than the broad goals<br />

of economic development, the official version<br />

of events presented company affairs as an issue<br />

of public concern. This section shows<br />

how, to a certain extent, this rationale<br />

of industrial capabilities being an<br />

page 97<br />

issue of public concern has been<br />

preserved from state socialist period<br />

to the current day. What has survived is the<br />

idea that enterprise is not just an issue between<br />

employees and management of a particular


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

enterprise, but an issue of public interest. In<br />

other words, public concern has been a further<br />

stakeholder in the industrial upgrading process<br />

that pushed the decision makers to preserve<br />

local industrial capabilities. Central European<br />

VW subsidiaries are a useful case for assessing<br />

the role of public opinion, as these companies<br />

have enjoyed high coverage in the national<br />

media and high public interest due to the size<br />

of these industrial projects, early arrival of the<br />

foreign investor to the region and the strategic<br />

role of the automotive industry in the region<br />

in general.<br />

The role of public opinion in the restructuring<br />

and privatisation of former state-owned<br />

automotive companies cannot be underestimated.<br />

Already during the privatisation<br />

process, public opinion de-radicalised the<br />

intentions of the Czech government to sell<br />

Škoda off completely.<br />

The fear of the public that the German investor<br />

would completely restructure the factory and<br />

implement purely German means of production<br />

and employment led the Czech government to<br />

agree with VW on a form of a Joint Venture,<br />

where government’s share gradually decreased<br />

[…] (Mikulikova 2002: 46).<br />

The role of public opinion also mattered for<br />

management training. Public opinion meant<br />

that the old management structures<br />

that were partially considered as<br />

page 98 obsolete could not be completely<br />

ignored. Thus, Mikulikova (2002)<br />

interprets introduction of management<br />

tandems at Škoda as a consequence of public<br />

pressures. Blazejewski, Claasen et al. (2003)<br />

report a case of a privatised - less known -<br />

large Polish company where the managerial<br />

structures were completely circumvented by<br />

the new German managers, as they felt it was<br />

too cumbersome for the new owner to retrain<br />

the Polish old-school managers. A high media<br />

exposure and media attention to the VW<br />

subsidiaries prevented this from happening in<br />

the VW subsidiaries.<br />

The idea of enterprise and industrial capabilities<br />

being an issue of public concern was explicitly<br />

expressed by company insiders as well as<br />

stakeholders in the automotive sector. Thus, in<br />

Audi Györ, the union leader underlined the role<br />

of ‘public ownership’: ‘On paper this company<br />

is the property of Audi but in our heads it is<br />

our property because this company is based in<br />

Hungary’ (Interview August 2007). The linkage<br />

between company affairs and regional/ national<br />

economic development has also been clearly<br />

identified. The HR director at VW Slovakia<br />

elaborated on his company’s involvement in<br />

improving the deteriorating national industrial<br />

capabilities of vocational training:<br />

Before we had a complete dual system of vocational<br />

training. [With the regime change] the first<br />

thing that enterprises did when they were about<br />

to privatise was to give these schools back to the<br />

state. [..] Today, these schools do not train properly<br />

for vocational training. [..] No one thought that<br />

vocational training would take such a turn, and<br />

you know, now it will take a long time – I would<br />

say 10 years – to make the system work again. You<br />

know, it is much easier to destroy something than<br />

to build it up. [..] The government needs to take<br />

the lead here to improve the system of vocational<br />

training. [..] We cooperate with Kia and PSA<br />

in these issues, even if we are competitors. On<br />

issues of labour markets we are partners [...]


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

and we agree on a common position about what<br />

government activities we need. We need to<br />

convince the government to cooperate on that. We<br />

are developing a pilot project that should advance<br />

Slovakia (Interview March 2007).<br />

Thus, company stakeholders see company<br />

affairs and general interest of national industrial<br />

capabilities as closely interlinked.<br />

Across the board, representatives of employer<br />

federations, trade unions and national<br />

chambers of commerce and industry referred to<br />

the importance of strong local manufacturing<br />

traditions as relevant for society as a whole<br />

rather than only as an enterprise relevant<br />

issue. The embeddedness of engineering<br />

and manufacturing capabilities in the local<br />

history and economy is explicitly stated by<br />

practitioners. Thus, in Hungary, the legacies<br />

of state socialist industrial development are<br />

evoked as crucial despite the fact that it did<br />

not have automotive final producers after the<br />

World War II. Yet it is argued that it had strong<br />

manufacturing capabilities in bus production,<br />

engines and other components (Interview July<br />

2008). Similarly in Slovakia, the representative<br />

of the chamber of commerce said:<br />

You cannot create industrial history on this<br />

table. You cannot do that. Either it exists or not.<br />

Czechoslovakia in the past had a tradition of<br />

machinery industry […]. It is not possible just<br />

to say: ‘it is good to make electronics, let’s start<br />

producing electronics now’ (Interview March<br />

2007).<br />

The importance of historical heritage of<br />

machine tools production in the emergence of<br />

a strong automotive industry today has been<br />

evoked by the stakeholders. It has been pointed<br />

out that Audi Györ is located in the area of the<br />

traditional Hungarian engine producer Raba.<br />

In Slovakia, the region of Martin has been<br />

a stronghold of arms production (Interview<br />

March 2008).<br />

The destiny of enterprises and industry is<br />

closely linked to broader societal changes.<br />

Industrial modernisation of enterprises and<br />

country modernisation are often seen as<br />

interdependent. Thus, the representative of the<br />

Slovak chamber of commerce stated:<br />

[After Slovakia’s independence], we did not have<br />

a big choice –we were happy if anyone came to us.<br />

There was not much choice – it was a new country,<br />

new Slovakia, new currency, new government,<br />

and new problems. You know how it is: political<br />

ups and downs. This is like when you go to eat:<br />

when you are hungry, you eat anything, but once<br />

you are half full, you will choose the better things<br />

– it is normal. And it is also like this in business<br />

(Interview March 2007).<br />

Making business is also associated with a longterm<br />

sustainability rather than with short-term<br />

windfall gains. Stakeholders differentiated<br />

between good and bad investment. ‘Bad’<br />

investments are associated with speculation,<br />

while ‘good’ investments are associated with<br />

‘productive investment’ that would develop the<br />

company’s capabilities:<br />

The entrepreneurs of the first wave, they<br />

page 99<br />

are the so called ‘gold diggers’. Everybody<br />

wanted to own a company, but they were not<br />

ready to spend their own lives in it. Neither to<br />

wake up at 6 am, nor to take care of hundreds of<br />

employees, not to take care of the sub-suppliers,


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

nor pay attention if exports are working fine, if<br />

the [Slovak] crown is up or down. Buy cheap, sell<br />

expensive. Buy a Lamborghini; go on holidays in<br />

the Caribbean. This was the first privatisation.<br />

They did not know much about the industry. Their<br />

way of thinking was: ‘certainly one day someone<br />

will come who will want to buy it from me and<br />

it is my aim to sell it then. So, it was all around<br />

the speculation motive. […] After a few years,<br />

now it is clearer - the best way was when the<br />

management made a buy-out. It could be a factory<br />

producing colours, painting. They would say: we<br />

work here for 20 years, we know the company well<br />

- we shall decide about its future, we continue to<br />

develop it. This was a positive privatisation<br />

(Interview March 2007).<br />

Investors are thus clearly differentiated between<br />

those with productionst attitudes and the rest.<br />

There are those who are interested in investing<br />

in and developing the company and others<br />

who acquire companies for other reasons:<br />

speculation or reducing the competition.<br />

Thus, ‘real’ businesses are seen as long-term<br />

preservers of industrial capabilities. While<br />

VW subsidiaries are considered as successful<br />

cases of preserving and developing local<br />

industrial capabilities, the stakeholders quoted<br />

a large number of unsuccessful privatisations<br />

where industrial capabilities were destroyed.<br />

One such case is the foreign privatisation<br />

of a previously internationally renowned<br />

Hungarian bus producer Ikarus.<br />

Ikarus, one of the largest Hungarian<br />

page 100 bus producers in the state socialist<br />

era, was bought by an Italian bus<br />

producer Iveco in 1999. Its two plants<br />

were closed down in 2003 and 2007. A trade<br />

union leader wondered: ‘What was the point<br />

for Iveco to buy Ikarus, what was the interest<br />

[of the foreign investor]: to buy a competitor<br />

or to buy a plant with capacity?’ (Interview<br />

September 2008). The implicit argument<br />

behind this question is that the Italian bus<br />

producer bought its Hungarian competitor<br />

to reduce competition in the market and not<br />

to develop regional industrial capabilities –<br />

something the trade union leaders would have<br />

expected, as it would have been conform to the<br />

‘productionist logic’.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

This paper demonstrated that some enterprises<br />

in post-communist Central Europe still<br />

function as sources of competitive industrial<br />

capabilities. Despite dramatic changes in the<br />

institutions of firm performance associated<br />

with cost efficiency and a stronger focus on the<br />

firm as an actor in product market competition,<br />

the local commitment to industrial capabilities<br />

that existed in state socialist times has at<br />

least partially been preserved. The increased<br />

financialisation of firm performance and the<br />

new cost-efficiency logic did not completely<br />

replace the non-economic old productionist<br />

enterprise norms of firm stakeholders.<br />

Company collective agreements have been good<br />

examples of coalitions of stakeholders with a<br />

productionist norm of upgrading company’s<br />

industrial capabilities and advancement within<br />

the group. In addition, this commitment to<br />

industrial capabilities has also been propagated<br />

outside the firm: enterprise development and<br />

industrial upgrading are considered an issue<br />

of public concern. Preserving and developing<br />

local and national industrial capabilities has<br />

been important for stakeholders inside and<br />

outside the company. Despite the emergence


ALEKSANDRA JANOVSKAIA<br />

of organising logics within the enterprise that<br />

are associated with economic liberalism, the<br />

productionist logic contributes to enterprises<br />

functioning as sources of competitive industrial<br />

capabilities.<br />

NOTES<br />

1<br />

Some other auomtoive MNCs in the region such as Suzuki<br />

Hungaria or Kia in Slovak Republic still do not recognise unions<br />

on their premises or build adversarial relationships with them.<br />

2<br />

The overtime is first put in the time accounts and paid three<br />

months later.<br />

3<br />

Not for workers on the assembly line.<br />

page 101


AUTOMOTIVE MNCS IN CENTRAL EUROPE<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Blazejewski, S., F. Claassen, et al. (2003). Case study: Beiersdorf-Lechia<br />

SA., Poznan. Change Management in Transition<br />

Economies. Integrating Corporate Strategy, Structure and Culture.<br />

H.-J. Stüting, W. Dorow, F. Claassen and S. Blazejewski.<br />

Houndmills, Basingstoke, Palgrave Macmillan.<br />

Bluhm, K. (2007). Experimentierfeld Mittelosteuropa? Deutsche<br />

Unternehmen in Polen und der Tschechischen Republik.<br />

Wiesbaden, VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.<br />

Jung, A., M. Klemm, et al. (2004). Culture Matters - The<br />

Success-Story of the Volkswagen-Škoda Venture. European<br />

Industrial Restructuring in a Global Economy: Fragmentation<br />

and Relocaction of Value Chains. M. Faust, Voskamp, U.,<br />

Wittke, V. (eds.). Göttingen, SOFI Berichte: 201-220.<br />

Mikulikova, M. (2002). Preserving of escaping the German<br />

model of industrial relations? The case of Volkswagen and its<br />

subsidiaries in Central Europe. M.A. Thesis. Budapest, Central<br />

European University.<br />

Pavlínek, P. (2008). A Successful Transformation? Restructuring<br />

of the Czech Automobile Industry. Heidelberg, Physica-<br />

Verlag, A Springer Company.<br />

Pavlinek, P. and A. Smith (1998). “Internationalization and<br />

Embeddedness in East-Central European Transition: The<br />

Contrasting Geographies of Inward Investment in the Czech<br />

and Slovak Republics.” Regional Studies 32(7): 619-638.<br />

Škoda (2005). Tarifvertrag für den Zeitraum 01.04.2005-<br />

31.03.2008.<br />

page 102<br />

Sperling, H.-J. (2004). Going East - a Volkswagen Version of<br />

Globalization. European Industrial Restructuring in a Global<br />

Economy: Fragmentation and Relocation of Value<br />

Chains. M. Faust, Voskamp, U., Wittke, V. (eds.).<br />

Göttingen, SOFI: 181-200.


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

1. GLOBAL CHANGES IN THE WORLD ECONO-<br />

MY: EMERGING SERVICE ECONOMY<br />

6<br />

ORGANISATIONAL INNOVATIONS IN THE<br />

HUNGARIAN KNOWLEDGE-INTENSIVE<br />

BUSINESS SERVICE SECTOR:<br />

LESSONS FROM A COMPANY SURVEY<br />

In the last few decades, the world economy<br />

has undergone a structural transformation<br />

process that can be described by an<br />

increasing role of the service sector within the<br />

national economies at the expense of manufacturing.<br />

According to the OECD, in 2005<br />

the contribution of services to the GDP in the<br />

developed economies was around 70% with remarkable<br />

country differences (OECD 2007).<br />

The proportion of services in the economic<br />

output in the case of the USA is close to 80%,<br />

while it remains below 60% in South-Korea.<br />

In Hungary, services produce 65% of the<br />

GDP, which is around the European average.<br />

The position of the country is better than the<br />

Czech Republic or Slovakia but lags behind the<br />

Benelux-states and the Nordic countries. Table<br />

1 illustrates the growing economic role of the<br />

service sector in some OECD-countries.<br />

Péter Csizmadia<br />

When evaluating the growing international<br />

importance of services, it is important to call<br />

attention to the changing internal structure<br />

of the sector, e.g. the increasing share of<br />

business services representing higher valueadded<br />

activities. Another important factor<br />

shaping the global economy is the different<br />

development dynamics of the manufacturing<br />

and service sectors. Globally, the service sector<br />

achieved 23.6% productivity growth<br />

accompanied by a 20.2 % employment<br />

increase. On the other hand, 28.8 %<br />

productivity growth and a 22.8 %<br />

employment decline were registered<br />

in the manufacturing sector (Sako, 2006).<br />

Seite page 103<br />

Another important tendency is that the


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

development ICT facilitates changes in<br />

the inherent characteristics of services.<br />

The majority of the former theoretical<br />

contributions emphasized the following three<br />

basic features of services in distinguishing<br />

them from manufacturing activities: (1)<br />

service is intangible and, therefore, cannot be<br />

accumulated; (2) production and consumption<br />

are simultaneous activities; and (3) services<br />

are produced jointly with the customer (as the<br />

customer represents a basic input for services)<br />

(Kuusisto & Meyer 2003, Chesbrough &<br />

Spohrer 2006). The changing role of ICT<br />

has resulted in a standardisation of services.<br />

Some services are becoming more similar to<br />

manufacturing products: they are standardised,<br />

storable and deliverable (Sundbo 2002). These<br />

changes 1 , which are labelled “productising of<br />

services”, are visible in the increasing weight of<br />

services in the international trade (Sako 2005).<br />

A similar tendency has also taken place in the<br />

manufacturing sector. The basic idea here is to<br />

utilise economy of scale of mass production<br />

and, simultaneously, the greater value added<br />

by the costumer-specialisation of products. As<br />

a consequence, there is a growing interest in<br />

modularisation of products, on the one hand,<br />

and a development of services related to the<br />

products or a shift of activities in direction of<br />

services, on the other (e.g. IBM or Siemens).<br />

This process is often called “servicising<br />

products”. (Sundbo 1999, Kuusisto & Meyer<br />

2003, Sako 2005).<br />

Seite page 104<br />

The changes presented briefly<br />

above, e.g. the standardisation<br />

and “productising” of services, the<br />

modularisation and “servicising” of products<br />

and the blurring boundaries between service<br />

and manufacturing sector, caused radical<br />

changes in the economic weight of services.<br />

In this relation it is important to stress the<br />

increasing role of knowledge-intensive services<br />

in innovation, knowledge development and<br />

transfer that are of particular importance<br />

in opening a new development path for an<br />

economy.<br />

1.1 Distinguishing characteristic of the<br />

service sector: extreme heterogeneity<br />

The aggregated data presented in Table 1<br />

do not provide information on the internal<br />

composition of the service sector nor on its<br />

changes, although it is composed of very<br />

heterogeneous activities representing diverse<br />

productivity, employment, working conditions<br />

and patterns of knowledge use. There have been<br />

several attempts to classify the different service<br />

activities focused characteristics of the sector<br />

such as role of technology, the intangibility of<br />

outputs and modes of innovation (Pavitt 1984,<br />

Porter 1990, Evangelista 2000, Miozzo-Soete<br />

2001, Hollenstein 2003). Salter and Tether<br />

(2006) differentiate three basic types of services<br />

firms in their classification based on economic<br />

function: traditional services, system firms and<br />

knowledge-intensive business services.<br />

Traditional service firms are small and serve<br />

local needs. These firms suffer from poor<br />

technology base, weak managerial and labour<br />

force skills, and a lack of abilities to provide<br />

high value-added services. Traditional service<br />

firms often have no full-time employees and<br />

rely on self-employment or part-time staff.<br />

They are often associated with a “low-skill<br />

equilibrium” in their manpower use.<br />

System firms, on the other hand, are large and


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

complex organisations providing sophisticated<br />

services both on domestic and international<br />

markets. These firms typically operate in<br />

such industries as banking and insurance,<br />

airlines, infrastructural services (gas or water<br />

supply) and supermarket retailing and are<br />

characterised by a well-developed internal<br />

division of labour, sophisticated operational<br />

processes and intensive use of technology,<br />

especially Information and Communication<br />

Technologies (ICT).<br />

The third group of service providers is knowledgeintensive<br />

business service firms (KIBS). KIBS<br />

provide professional services, such as legal and<br />

accounting services, management consultancy,<br />

engineering and R&D activities, and play<br />

a crucial role in creating and transferring<br />

new knowledge and technologies. They rely<br />

intensively on the expertise of their highly<br />

skilled professional employees, often carry out<br />

their activities in projects and are dependent<br />

on close connections to their clients. The firms<br />

belonging to this particularly rapidly growing<br />

area of services are of crucial importance in<br />

economic growth, as they provide intermediary<br />

services to other actors of the economy and<br />

constitute important inputs to the modern<br />

production process (Salter-Tether 2006).<br />

The knowledge-intensive business service sector<br />

is, however, composed of firms that are very<br />

diverse regarding characteristics of the services<br />

they provide, their innovation capacities and<br />

modes of manpower use. Partly due to this<br />

heterogeneous composition, there is no widely<br />

accepted definition of KIBS. According to the<br />

very general definition by Tovoinen (2006:2),<br />

KIBS are “expert companies that provide services<br />

to other companies and organizations”. In contrast,<br />

den Hertog (2000:505) provides a wider<br />

definition that focuses on the characteristics<br />

of knowledge used and created in the service<br />

process and emphasises the importance of the<br />

cooperation between the clients and service<br />

providers: “Private companies or organizations<br />

who rely heavily on professional knowledge,<br />

i.e. knowledge or expertise related to a specific<br />

(technical) discipline or (technical) functionaldomain<br />

to supply intermediate products and<br />

services that are knowledge based”. Miles et al<br />

(1995) identified three basic characteristics of<br />

KIBS: (1) they rely heavily upon professional<br />

knowledge; (2) they either are themselves<br />

primary sources of information and knowledge<br />

or they use knowledge to produce intermediate<br />

services for their clients’ production processes;<br />

and (3) they are of competitive importance and<br />

supply primarily to businesses. Based on these<br />

characteristics, Miles et al (1995) defines KIBS<br />

as “services that involved economic activities which<br />

are intended to result in the creation, accumulation<br />

or dissemination of knowledge”. In addition, the<br />

authors differentiate between the so-called<br />

“traditional professional services” (P-KIBS)<br />

– intensive technology users (business and<br />

management services, legal and accounting<br />

activities, market research, etc.) – and “newtechnology-based<br />

services” (T-KIBS) relying<br />

on ICT and technical activities. The former<br />

group of KIBS is sometimes referred to as<br />

“operational business services” (Viitamo<br />

2007). In their contribution, Müller<br />

and Doloreux (2007) identified three<br />

common elements in the various<br />

classification attempts:<br />

<br />

The term „business services” refers to<br />

services that are provided in order to<br />

satisfy the demands of firms and public<br />

Seite page 105


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

<br />

<br />

companies and are not produced for<br />

private consumers.<br />

„Knowledge-intensive” is defined either<br />

in terms of the reliance on highly qualified<br />

labour or in terms of the complex<br />

transaction between client and service<br />

provider.<br />

„Knowledge-intensive firms” are companies<br />

carrying out intellectual activities<br />

where human capital plays a significant<br />

role.<br />

Although, as presented above, the widely<br />

accepted definition on KIBS is still missing,<br />

there is a consensus regarding the labelling<br />

of categories within the classification of<br />

economic activities as knowledge-intensive<br />

business activities. In general, mainly nonroutine<br />

services provided to firms and public<br />

organisations and based on intensive utilisation<br />

of knowledge, e.g. IT services (both hardware<br />

and software), administrative-legal services,<br />

R&D, etc. belong to this category. Concerning<br />

the NACE 2 -categories, the following activities<br />

usually count as KIBS:<br />

Table 1. NACE codes of knowledge-intensive business services<br />

NACE code<br />

Activity<br />

62 Computer programming, consultancy, and related activities<br />

63 Information service activities<br />

649 Other financial service activities, except insurance and pension funding<br />

661 Activities auxiliary to financial services, except insurance and pension funding<br />

662 Activities auxiliary to insurance and pension funding<br />

69 Legal and accounting activities<br />

70 Activities of head offices; management consultancy activities<br />

71 Architectural and engineering activities; technical testing and analysis<br />

72 Scientific research and development<br />

73 Advertising and market research<br />

743 Translation and interpretation activities<br />

773 Renting and leasing of other machinery, equipment, and tangible goods<br />

Seite page 106<br />

78 Employment activities<br />

8110 Combined facility support activities<br />

8122 Other building and industrial cleaning activities<br />

8220 Activities of call centres<br />

855 Other educational activity


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

1.2 Changing role of manufacturing and<br />

services in the Hungarian economy<br />

Similar to global trends, the economic<br />

performance of the service sector in Hungary<br />

increased significantly in the last decade.<br />

Since 1990, the gross output of agriculture<br />

and mining has massively decreased, while<br />

in manufacturing contradictory tendencies<br />

have taken place and the output of the service<br />

sectors has permanently increased. In 2007,<br />

almost two-thirds of the GDP was generated<br />

by the service sector (KSH 2007a). The<br />

economic performance of the manufacturing<br />

sector measured by the gross value added by<br />

industries was different in the various industries.<br />

The performance of the textile and clothing<br />

industry has been steadily decreasing since the<br />

end of the 1990s, while growing tendencies<br />

were registered in the machinery, electronics<br />

and pharmaceutical industries, however, at a<br />

different rate (KSH 2007a).<br />

Between 1990 and 1998, the general level of<br />

employment decreased. In 1998 this tendency<br />

reversed but not in all sectors of the economy.<br />

The agriculture and mining sectors experienced<br />

dramatic job loss. Until 1998 the number of<br />

employees decreased in manufacturing and<br />

construction as well; yet between 1998 and<br />

2002, permanent employment growth was<br />

registered. Since 2002 the number of employees<br />

in manufacturing has been decreasing, while the<br />

opposite tendency was observed in the service<br />

sector. The most dynamic employment growth<br />

has taken place in the categories of “real estate<br />

and other business services” and “retail trade<br />

and repair” (40% and 30%). In general between<br />

1995 and 2006, 90 % of new jobs were created<br />

in the service sector; and, interestingly enough,<br />

more than every second new job (57 %) was<br />

created in the knowledge intensive business<br />

services (KIBS) (ERM Report, 2008).<br />

Besides its role in employment generation and<br />

stabilization, another important indicator of<br />

the service sector’s economic performance is<br />

productivity as a source of competitiveness.<br />

Between 1992 and 2002, the productivity<br />

measured by gross value-added per capita in<br />

the service sector exceeded the one registered<br />

in manufacturing. In addition, when<br />

evaluating firm level performance indicators<br />

such as turnover, export and profitability<br />

during this period, business service and IT<br />

firms performed better that services as a whole<br />

(Hamar, 2005).<br />

We can summarise the tendencies presented<br />

briefly above as follows. The economic<br />

modernisation of the manufacturing sector was<br />

controversial. There are only a few subsectors,<br />

like machinery, electronics or pharmaceutical<br />

industry that were successful in increasing<br />

their economic performance as well as in<br />

integrating themselves in a global division<br />

of labour. The modernisation of these sectors<br />

was based on the leading role of the FDI,<br />

which had positive effects such as increasing<br />

productivity, export growth, diffusion of<br />

leading-edge management practices, etc.<br />

However, as a negative consequence, the<br />

asymmetric character of the economic<br />

modernisation can also be observed,<br />

which is partially reflected in the Seite page 107<br />

growing gap between the innovative<br />

performance of the foreign-owned<br />

and Hungarian companies and the weak<br />

integration of SMEs into the international<br />

division of labour (Makó & Illéssy 2007).


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

On the contrary, there is a steady tendency of<br />

growth in the service sector in terms of both<br />

its economic performance and employment<br />

capacity. In other words, services in general<br />

and especially business services represent a<br />

potential sustainable development path in the<br />

Hungarian economic modernisation.<br />

2. INNOVATION IN SERVICES<br />

There is a wide consensus in both the academic<br />

and professional communities that innovation<br />

is at the hearth of economic development and<br />

wealth. The literature dealing with the issues of<br />

innovation makes a distinction of two types of<br />

innovation. The first is often labelled the linear<br />

model of innovation. This model describes<br />

innovation as a linear chain of discrete R&D<br />

activities in which each development stage<br />

is separated from the others. Innovation<br />

is driven by scientific research or direct<br />

market demands. In this model, of particular<br />

importance is codified knowledge, which<br />

originates in scientific research and flows<br />

in one direction. Critiques of this approach<br />

often claim that a linear form of innovation<br />

represents the exception rather than the rule in<br />

practice (Schienstock & Hamalainen 2001).<br />

The second approach is the recursive model<br />

of innovation, which describes innovation<br />

as a novel combination of existing<br />

knowledge. In this model, innovation<br />

Seite page 108<br />

is driven by market needs and new<br />

knowledge is an unintended result<br />

of the complex interdependent<br />

relationship between the various actors.<br />

Multiple feedback mechanisms are important<br />

here, as is the intensive cooperation between<br />

different actors (firms, clients, suppliers,<br />

scientific institutions), as well (Schienstock &<br />

Hamalainen 2001). In this regard, innovation<br />

is open and happens dominantly in complex<br />

networks rather than in individual firms, while<br />

the institutional environment plays a crucial<br />

facilitating role.<br />

In the Hungarian discourse on innovation, the<br />

linear model plays a dominant role, although<br />

the recursive model better suits to the real<br />

characteristics of the innovation process,<br />

especially in the case of service innovation. The<br />

former model places emphasis on technology<br />

largely embodied in machinery, and equipment<br />

as well as the processes involved in the<br />

development and commercial introduction<br />

of new, technologically advanced goods. In<br />

addition, this model neglects such “soft”<br />

elements of innovation such as cooperation,<br />

collective knowledge development and sharing,<br />

trust relations, etc.<br />

According to Salter and Tether (2006:2),<br />

“services were long thought to be laggards with<br />

regard to innovation – they were assumed to be<br />

uninteresting adopters of existing technologies<br />

rather than producers of new technology.” 3<br />

Since the beginning of the 1980s, however,<br />

there has been a shift in this rather one-sided<br />

approach of service innovation. The authors<br />

identified the following four generations of<br />

innovation research in services.<br />

The period of neglecting service innovations<br />

can be characterised by narrow perception<br />

of innovation primarily focusing on the<br />

creation of new technologies, while diffusion<br />

and adaptation of new technologies was<br />

seen as either unproblematic or of secondary


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

importance. The main focus of innovation<br />

research here was the creation rather than use<br />

of new technologies. According to the authors,<br />

this perspective has remained dominant until<br />

today.<br />

The second generation is labelled as the period<br />

of assimilation. In this phase researchers tended<br />

to examine service innovation using the<br />

conceptual framework developed to understand<br />

innovation in manufacturing. They assumed<br />

that innovation shows universal patterns<br />

that should exist both in manufacturing and<br />

services.<br />

The distinction approach in service innovation<br />

appeared in the 1990s as a critique of the<br />

assimilation period. Authors representing<br />

this line of innovation research argued<br />

that innovation in services differs from the<br />

manufacturing sector. Researchers in this<br />

period focused on organisational innovations<br />

and the “soft” skills playing a dominant role<br />

in knowledge-intensive business services, such<br />

as management consultancy, and regarded the<br />

role of “hard” technologies to be less dominant<br />

in the innovation activities.<br />

role of organisational innovations in shaping<br />

the service innovation process.<br />

The latest results of service innovation research<br />

suggest that service innovations are highly<br />

dependent on organisational practices and<br />

represent and open and networked form of<br />

innovation (Salter – Tether 2006). In addition,<br />

in the case of service innovation the different<br />

forms of innovation – product, process and<br />

organisational – are more closely connected<br />

than in manufacturing, which implies that the<br />

economic value of service innovation heavily<br />

relies on the combination of the different<br />

forms of innovation (Hipp et al. 2000).<br />

Finally, Gann and Salter (2000) identified<br />

the following basic characteristics of service<br />

innovations:<br />

<br />

<br />

the role of highly skilled labour in<br />

the creation and exploitation of new<br />

solutions;<br />

the importance of new organisational<br />

practices in supporting the realisation of<br />

new innovative opportunities;<br />

The latest stream of service innovation research,<br />

however, intents to synthesise the experiences<br />

of the traditional innovation research as well<br />

as the experiences stemming from a deeper<br />

understanding of the special characteristics<br />

of services. These researchers highlight the<br />

complex and multidimensional character<br />

of modern services and manufacturing and<br />

focus on such issues as organisational change,<br />

social networks and other, mainly institutional<br />

mechanisms that support innovation in services.<br />

In this approach special attention is paid to the<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

the cooperation between clients and<br />

producers;<br />

the key role of social networks in generating<br />

and supporting knowledge<br />

creation and exchange; and<br />

Seite page 109<br />

the ‘ad hoc’ or ‘informal’ organisational<br />

form of most knowledge-intensive<br />

service firms.


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Seite page 110<br />

2.1 Organisational innovations<br />

Despite the growing interest in understanding<br />

the main characteristics of organisational<br />

innovations as well as its role in economic<br />

development, there is no single coherent<br />

conceptual framework for the term. The<br />

Oslo Manual distinguishes product, process<br />

organisational and marketing innovations<br />

and defines organisational innovation as<br />

follows: “Organisational innovations refer to<br />

the implementation of new organisational<br />

methods. These can be changes in business<br />

practices, in workplace organisation or in the<br />

firm’s external relations” (OECD 2005:49).<br />

Lam (2005) suggests a more general definition<br />

where organisational innovation is equal to the<br />

creation or adoption of an idea or behaviour<br />

new to the organisation.<br />

In their research, Armbruster et al (2008:646)<br />

define organisational innovation as “the use<br />

of new managerial and working concepts and<br />

practices”. They provide a further classification<br />

that distinguishes between structural and<br />

procedural organisational innovation and the<br />

intra-organisational and inter-organisational<br />

features. Their categories are as follows:<br />

1. Structural organisational innovation, which<br />

may modify the divisional structure of<br />

organisational functions, hierarchical<br />

levels, and information flow, or,<br />

in general, the organisational<br />

architecture of the firm.<br />

2. Procedural organisational<br />

innovation, which may change the<br />

process and operation routines within the<br />

firms, such as improving the flexibility<br />

of manpower and the use of knowledge<br />

through the implementation of team<br />

work, just-in-time (Kan-Ban in Japanese),<br />

or quality circles.<br />

3. Intra-organisational innovation that is<br />

taking place within an organisation, and<br />

4. Inter-organisational aspects of innovation,<br />

which refer to new organisational forms<br />

and processes that exist beyond the<br />

organisational boundaries of the firm.<br />

In the “learning economy”, where the pace<br />

of knowledge erosion is accelerated and the<br />

key source of the economic growth is the<br />

individuals’, firms’, regions’ and national<br />

economies’ capabilities to learn continuously,<br />

organisational innovations are becoming<br />

increasingly important in fostering the actors’<br />

collective learning capabilities (Lundvall<br />

1996).<br />

3. ORGANISATION INNOVATIONS IN THE HUN-<br />

GARIAN KNOWLEDGE-INTENSIVE BUSINESS<br />

SECTOR: LESSONS FROM A COMPANY SURVEY<br />

In the following sections, the preliminary<br />

results of a company-level empirical survey<br />

will be presented with the aim to provide a<br />

general overview on the diffusion and drivers<br />

of organisational innovations and knowledge<br />

development practices in both the Hungarian<br />

manufacturing and knowledge-intensive<br />

business sectors. The survey was carried out<br />

in 2008 by the Institute of Sociology at the<br />

Hungarian Academy of Sciences.


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

3.1 Sample description<br />

In the first quarter of 2008, according to the<br />

National Register of Economic Organisations<br />

compiled by the Hungarian Central Statistical<br />

Office, 4 049 companies with 10 or more<br />

employees were registered in the field of<br />

business services. In order to statistically<br />

represent the organisational population, 200<br />

companies were selected based on the multistage<br />

stratified sampling method. Here, the<br />

basic economic activity of the firms captured by<br />

the NACE code was used as the stratification<br />

variable. This sampling method ensured equal<br />

selection chances to all companies belonging<br />

to the population surveyed and reflected the<br />

heterogeneity of the organisational population,<br />

as well. In other words, the sampling method<br />

takes into consideration the fact that the<br />

number of the companies operating in different<br />

economic activity categories varies within the<br />

population surveyed. For instance, there are<br />

more IT companies within the field of business<br />

services than facility management providers.<br />

The sampling frame was restricted to companies<br />

employing at least 10 persons. Firms with 0 to<br />

9 employees were excluded because, according<br />

to previous research experience, these firms<br />

are rarely available for surveys. In addition,<br />

since the division of labour within these<br />

firms is rather underdeveloped, organisational<br />

innovation characterizing larger firms is absent<br />

(Valeyre et al., 2009).<br />

established between 2000 and 2003 and only<br />

6.5% prior to 1990. The majority of companies<br />

investigated belongs to the so-called de novo<br />

segment of the Hungarian economy, e.g. they<br />

were established after the collapse of state<br />

socialism (Martin 2008). As for the ownership<br />

structure, the share of foreign ownership<br />

among business service firms is considerably<br />

low (20%). The KIBS sector is dominated by<br />

small firms - companies employing less than<br />

50 people have a share of 78.7%.<br />

The survey questionnaire contained questions<br />

regarding the market share and structure,<br />

e.g. the share and location of the primary<br />

and secondary markets within the total sales.<br />

Domestic markets play a crucial role in the<br />

KIBS sector. Hungarian business firms<br />

merchandise their services almost exclusively<br />

in the Hungarian market (95 %).<br />

3.2.1 Diffusion of organisational innovations<br />

According to the theoretical classification of<br />

organisational innovations presented earlier, the<br />

following types of organisational innovations<br />

were distinguished in the questionnaire:<br />

1) Structural organisational innovation:<br />

<br />

<br />

Project-based work;<br />

Lean or flat organisation;<br />

3.2 Basic characteristics of the Hungarian<br />

KIBS sector<br />

<br />

Inter-professional<br />

working groups.<br />

(functional)<br />

Seite page 111<br />

The Hungarian KIBS sector is relatively young.<br />

21.1% of firms have been established in the<br />

last four years, while a further 24.7% were<br />

2) Procedural organisational innovation:<br />

<br />

Quality assurance or continuous improve-


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

ment process (e.g., ISO, TQM);<br />

Collecting suggestions from workers;<br />

Teamwork;<br />

Benchmarking;<br />

Job rotation; and<br />

Delegation of quality assurance to workers<br />

(decentralization).<br />

In assessing the managerial practices in the firms<br />

investigated, it is visible that procedural forms of<br />

organisational innovation (OI), such as quality<br />

assurance systems, collecting suggestions from<br />

employees, team work, etc., are more widely<br />

used than the structural forms of OI. The<br />

project-based work organisation representing<br />

a structural/radical form of OI is, however,<br />

relatively widespread in the KIBS sector. In the<br />

case of procedural organisational innovation,<br />

the collecting of the employees’ proposals,<br />

team work and benchmarking are the most<br />

organisational practices among KIBS firms.<br />

Table 2. Diffusion of organisational innovations<br />

Types of Organisational Innovation<br />

Share within the KIBS sector<br />

(%)<br />

I. Structural organisational innovation:<br />

Project-based work 34.9<br />

Flat or lean organisation 10.3<br />

Inter-professional (inter-disciplinary) working groups 13.4<br />

II. Procedural organisational innovation:<br />

Quality Assurance and Auditing Systems (e.g., ISO and TQM) 21.9<br />

Collecting suggestions from employees 49.7<br />

Team work 41.7<br />

Benchmarking 37.3<br />

Quality control carried out by rank-and-file employees 23.7<br />

Job rotation 9.7<br />

Seite page 112<br />

Source: Makó et al (2009)<br />

3.2.3 Special focus on differences<br />

within the KIBS sector<br />

In Section 1.1, I have already referred to<br />

attempts that recognized the heterogeneity of<br />

different activities in the knowledge intensive<br />

business sector and attempted to classify the<br />

sector on that basis. Miles et al. (1995) made<br />

a distinction between “traditional professional<br />

services” (P-KIBS) that are intensive technology


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

users (business and management services, legal<br />

and accounting activities, market research, etc.)<br />

and “new-technology-based services” (T-KIBS)<br />

relying on ICT and technical activities. The<br />

former group of KIBS is sometimes referred to as<br />

“operational business services” (Viitamo 2007).<br />

There is a breadth of literature that calls attention<br />

to the importance of production strategies in<br />

the firms’ manpower and knowledge utilisation<br />

practices, innovative capacity and adaptation<br />

to the market requirements. Regini (1995),<br />

however, in analysing the flexible production,<br />

found that a set of different competitive and<br />

production strategies were being adopted by<br />

the European firms’ managements and that<br />

not all of these were consistent with the Post-<br />

Fordist production, which gains competitive<br />

advantage on the basis of quality, product<br />

differentiation and customisation and flexibility.<br />

In this relation, Lampel and Mintzberg (1996)<br />

emphasise the importance of standardisation<br />

and customisation of products and services as<br />

the two dominant strategies in the economic<br />

development of the past 100 years. The authors<br />

refer to these two logics not as “alternative<br />

models of strategic actions but, rather, as<br />

poles of a continuum of real world strategies.<br />

(Lampel & Mintzberg 1996:21)<br />

Mason (2005), in investigating the<br />

competitiveness and skill requirements of the<br />

British plastic processing, printing, logistics<br />

and insurance industries, analyses how product<br />

strategies are developed and implemented<br />

within UK companies as well as the nature of<br />

any barriers that may inhibit companies from<br />

moving to high value added products and<br />

services. He concludes that high value added<br />

production strategies, e.g. attempts to capture<br />

choices made by enterprises regarding product<br />

or service differentiation within particular<br />

markets, take on very different forms in each<br />

industry. In addition, high levels of skill and<br />

knowledge are prerequisites for success in<br />

high value added production along with the<br />

strategic capability of the management to<br />

combine different resources effectively in<br />

implementing new production strategies.<br />

In the following, I intend to examine which<br />

production strategies can be identified in the<br />

Hungarian KIBS sector and how these can<br />

be linked to organisational innovations and<br />

firms’ knowledge of development practices.<br />

In order to classify the production strategies,<br />

two dimensions were applied. The first<br />

one concerns the composition of the firms’<br />

service portfolios, e.g. to what extent they<br />

provide a large or narrow scale of services.<br />

The other dimension intends to capture the<br />

degree of service standardisation. Following<br />

this categorisation, two types of practices<br />

were identified depending on the proportion<br />

of standardised and tailor-made services the<br />

firms dominantly provide. I hypothesize that<br />

diversification of the service portfolio and<br />

customisation of services are the dominant<br />

strategies in the Hungarian KIBS sector. On<br />

the other hand, I assume that firms following<br />

these strategies rely more intensively on the<br />

external knowledge sources and application of<br />

organisational practices that support<br />

the integration of these knowledge<br />

sources as well as the organisationallevel<br />

learning process. Figure 1 sum-<br />

Seite page 113<br />

marises the two dimensions. It must<br />

be stressed here that only the standardisation<br />

versus customisation of services and not that<br />

of the operating processes were examined.


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Figure 1. Typology of the production strategies in the KIBS sector<br />

Based on the two distinctive dimensions<br />

presented above, four types of production<br />

strategies can be identified. The firms providing<br />

a narrow set of standardised services follow the<br />

strategy labelled “simple standardisation” (18%<br />

of firms). The second group was composed<br />

of firms providing different routine services<br />

(diversified service portfolio); their strategy<br />

is called “diversified standardisation” (15.3%<br />

of firms). The third strategic category, “simple<br />

customisation”, includes the firms providing<br />

a narrow set of tailor-made solutions (16.8%<br />

of firms). The last and largest group of firms,<br />

which follow the strategy labelled “diversified<br />

customisation”, provide tailor made services<br />

in different fields (49.5% of firms). The<br />

distribution of various types of activities<br />

moderately correlates with classification.<br />

IT service firms (“New technology<br />

providers”) are overrepresented in the<br />

Seite page 114<br />

group of diversified customisation<br />

strategy, while service diversification<br />

seems to be the dominant strategy<br />

in the case of legal and financial service firms<br />

(“Operational service providers”) independent<br />

from the degree of standardisation.<br />

Engineering and R&D firms (“Science-based<br />

service providers”) also have high prevalence<br />

in the category of “diversified customisation”,<br />

but their production strategies are more diverse<br />

and balanced than the ones of the IT service<br />

providers. Professional service providers (e.g.<br />

management consulting, HRM, call centres,<br />

etc.) represent a rather heterogeneous group:<br />

their dominant strategy is providing diverse<br />

and tailor-made solutions; however, the share<br />

of those who implement simple standardisation<br />

strategies is important, as well (see Table 3).


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

Table 3. The distribution of firms by type of activity and production strategy<br />

Type of activities<br />

Simple<br />

standardisation<br />

Diversified<br />

standardisation<br />

Simple<br />

customisation<br />

Diversified<br />

customisation<br />

IT services 0.0% 13.8% 20.6% 65.6%<br />

Legal and financial services 12.9% 35.5% 12.9% 38.7%<br />

Engineering, R&D 22.5% 10.0% 27.5% 40.0%<br />

Professional services 23.1% 7.7% 10.3% 58.9%<br />

In the following, the connections between<br />

the various production strategies and the<br />

implementation of some organisational<br />

innovations will be examined. Project-based<br />

work organisation represents a structural<br />

organisational innovation that allows firms<br />

to control their costs more efficiently, on one<br />

hand, and support knowledge creation, sharing,<br />

transfer and utilisation, on the other, therefore<br />

creating more space for organisational-level<br />

collective learning (Whitley 2004). There is no<br />

linear correlation between the implementation<br />

of project-based work and the production<br />

strategies. However, the rate of its use is<br />

significantly lower among companies applying<br />

simple standardisation strategies than those<br />

applying other strategies. A similar tendency<br />

could be identified in the case of implementation<br />

of formal knowledge management. Firms<br />

representing the less flexible production<br />

strategy seem to be less reliant on the use<br />

of radical organisational innovations and<br />

systematic knowledge management than firms<br />

following more flexible practices in choosing<br />

their production strategies. In addition, firms<br />

representing a more flexible production<br />

strategy, especially those who follow diversified<br />

customisation, invest more in renewal of<br />

their external relations, which increases their<br />

capability to use external sources of knowledge<br />

more intensively.<br />

Table 4. The distribution of some organisational innovations by type of production strategy<br />

Type of organisational<br />

innovation<br />

Simple<br />

standardisation<br />

Diversified<br />

standardisation<br />

Simple<br />

customisation<br />

Diversified<br />

customisation<br />

Project-based work 9.4% 30.8% 48.3% 38.7%<br />

Seite page 115<br />

Knowledge management<br />

system<br />

6.3% 36.0% 16.7% 16.3%<br />

Renewal of external relations 18.8% 28.0% 26.7% 38.0%


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

There are also differences between the<br />

knowledge development practices of the<br />

KIBS firms representing different production<br />

strategies. The share of the followers of simple<br />

standardisation strategies in the different<br />

training practices is significantly lower than<br />

for other categories, which implies that more<br />

flexible production strategies require more<br />

investment in knowledge development (see<br />

Table 5).<br />

Table 5. Knowledge development practice and production strategies<br />

Type of knowledge<br />

development<br />

Simple<br />

standardisation<br />

Diversified<br />

standardisation<br />

Simple<br />

customisation<br />

Diversified<br />

customisation<br />

Courses organized and<br />

financed by the firm<br />

Courses selected by an employee<br />

but financed by the firm<br />

Courses supported by<br />

working time reduction<br />

Relying on customer<br />

knowledge<br />

18.8% 36.0% 33.3% 37.0%<br />

6.3% 6.9% 13.3% 15.2%<br />

1.7% 4.9% 13.8% 3.3%<br />

50.0% 68.0% 65.5% 67.4%<br />

4. CONCLUDING REMARKS AND FUTURE<br />

RESEARCH CHALLENGES<br />

In this paper, I attempted to briefly present the<br />

paradigmatic changes in the world economy that<br />

can be labelled as the rise of the post-industrial<br />

service economy. These changes, which can<br />

be captured by the increasing importance of<br />

the service sector in the performance of the<br />

national economies, has also taken place in<br />

Hungary over the last two decades. According<br />

to global trends, the weight of services<br />

in the Hungarian economy has been<br />

Seite page 116<br />

growing steadily, especially in the case<br />

of the knowledge-intensive business<br />

services (KIBS). The modernisation<br />

of the manufacturing sector was controversial<br />

and affected only a few subsectors. In this<br />

situation, KIBS may represent a possible<br />

new development path for the continued<br />

modernisation of the Hungarian economy. In<br />

fulfilling this role, firm-level facilitators such<br />

as learning and networking capability and the<br />

implementation of organisational practices<br />

as well as the innovations supporting them<br />

play a crucial role in addition to an adequate<br />

institutional environment.<br />

In the second part of this paper, the results<br />

of a company-level questionnaire survey were<br />

presented that was carried out in 2008 among<br />

the Hungarian knowledge-intensive business<br />

firms. The KIBS sector is relatively young<br />

and dominated by Hungarian-owned small<br />

and medium sized firms that provide service<br />

mainly to the domestic market. Examining the<br />

service production strategies that Hungarian<br />

firms apply suggests that knowledge-intensive


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

business firms following flexible and customised<br />

production strategies and providing diversified<br />

service portfolios are overrepresented among<br />

KIBS firms, especially in the case of IT and<br />

professional services. Firms implementing such<br />

production strategies invest more in the various<br />

forms of knowledge development and rely to a<br />

greater extent on the use of such radical forms<br />

of organisational innovation like project-based<br />

work that supports them in integrating external<br />

knowledge sources.<br />

The results presented briefly above call attention<br />

to the necessity of further investigation of the<br />

role of both KIBS and more traditional services<br />

in the economic modernisation of Hungary. In<br />

doing so, researchers should focus on both firmand<br />

institutional level facilitators and inhibitors<br />

of the service sector development. This requires<br />

a combination of research methods: there is a<br />

need for company-level case studies in order to<br />

better understand the internal dynamics of the<br />

service sector as a whole.<br />

NOTES<br />

1<br />

These changes, however, are not observable in the case of several,<br />

mainly personal services, such as hotels and restaurants,<br />

health and social services, etc.<br />

2<br />

NACE: ‘Statistical Classification of Economic Activities’ – an<br />

international statistical system for classification and registration<br />

of economic activities. Source: http://ec.europa.eu/competition/<br />

mergers/cases/index/nace_all.html<br />

3<br />

This view is still dominant in the Hungarian discourse on<br />

innovation.<br />

Seite page 117


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Seite page 118<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Armbruster, H. – Bikfalvi, A. – Kinkel, S. – Lay, G. (2008)<br />

Organizational Innovation: The Challenge of Measuring Non-<br />

Technical Innovation in Large-Scale Surveys, Science Direct<br />

– Technovation no. 28, pp. 644-657.<br />

Chesbrough, H. (2003). “The era of open innovation.” Sloan<br />

Management Review, Summer: 35-41.<br />

Chesbrough, H. – Shpohrer, J. (2006) Service Science: A Research<br />

Manifesto, Berkeley: Haas School of Business – University<br />

of California.<br />

den Hertog, P. (2000) Knowledge-Intensive Business Services<br />

as Co-Producers of Innovation, International Journal of Innovation<br />

Management, 4, pp. 491-528.<br />

DiBella, A. – Nevis, E.C. – Gould, J.M. (1996) Understanding<br />

Organizational Learning Capability, Journal of Management<br />

Studies, 33:3 May, pp. 361-369<br />

ERM Report (2008) More and better jobs: Patterns of employment<br />

expansion in Europe, European Foundation of the Improvement<br />

of Living and Working Conditions, Luxembourg: Office<br />

for Official Publications of the European Communities, p. 97.<br />

Evangelista, R. (2000) “Sectoral Patterns of Technological<br />

Change in Services”, Economics of Innovation and New Technology,<br />

9(3), 183-222.<br />

Gann, D. M. – Salter, A. (2000) Innovation in project-based,<br />

service-enhanced firms: The construction of complex products<br />

and systems, Research Policy, Vol: 29, 952-975<br />

Hage, J. (1999) Organizational Innovation and<br />

Organizational Change, Annual Review of Sociology,<br />

25: 597-622<br />

Hamar, J. (2005) Üzleti szolgáltatások Magyarországon.<br />

(Business services in Hungary), Közgazdasági Szemle, LII. évf.,<br />

2005. november, 881–904. o.<br />

Hipp, C., Tether, B. S. and Miles, I. D. (2000) “The Incidence<br />

and Effects of Innovation in Services: Evidence from Germany”,<br />

International Journal of Innovation Management, 4(4), 417-<br />

454.<br />

Hollenstein, H. (2002) Innovation Modes int he Swiss Service<br />

Sector: a Cluster Analysis Based on Firm-level Data, Research<br />

Policy, 32, pp. 845-863.<br />

KSH (2007a) Magyar statisztikai évkönyv 2006, (Statistical<br />

Yearbook of Hungary 2006) Budapest: Központi Statisztikai<br />

Hivatal.<br />

KSH (2007b) Foglalkoztatottság és kereseti arányok (1998-<br />

2005), (Employment and Earnings in Hungary 1998-2005)<br />

Budapest: Központi Statisztikai Hivatal.<br />

Kuusisto, J. and Meyer, M. (2003) ‘Insights into services and<br />

innovation in the knowledge intensive economy’, Technology<br />

Review 134/2003, Tekes, Helsinki<br />

Lam, A. (2005) Organizational Innovation, In: Fagerberg. J.<br />

– Mowery, D. C. –Nelson, R.R. (eds.) The Oxford Handbook of<br />

Innovation, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 115-147.<br />

Lampel, J. – Mintzberg, H. (1996) Customizing Customization,<br />

MIT Sloan Management Review, Vol. 38, No. 1, pp. 21-30.<br />

Lane, Ch. (2001) Organizational Learning in Supplier<br />

Networks, In: Dierkes, M., – Berthoin Antal, A., – Child, J.,<br />

– Nonaka, I. (eds) Handbook of Organizational Learning and<br />

Knowledge, New York: Oxford University Press, pp.599-715.<br />

Lundvall, B.-A. (1996) The Social Dimension of The Learning<br />

Economy, DRUID Working Paper No. 96-1, p. 29.<br />

Makó, Cs. – Csizmadia, P. –Illéssy, M. (2006): Does EU-<br />

Integration Help the SMEs to Explore New Development Path?<br />

Lessons from an International Comparative Project. Warsaw:<br />

Instytut Pracy i Spraw Socjalnych, p. 163.


PÉTER LITERATUR CSIZMADIA<br />

Makó, Cs. – Illéssy, M. (2007) Economic Modernization in<br />

Hungary: between Path Dependency and Path Creation, In:<br />

Moerel, H. – Illéssy, M. – Csizmadia, P.(eds), Working It Out?<br />

The Labour Process and Employment Relations in the New<br />

Economy, Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó, pp. 29-46.<br />

OECD (2005) Oslo Manual: The Measurement of Scientific<br />

and Technical Activities, Paris: OECD<br />

OECD (2007) OECD in Figures. Paris: OECD.<br />

Makó, Cs. – Csizmadia, P. – Illéssy, M. – Iwasaki, I. – Szanyi,<br />

M. (2009) Organisational Innovation in the Manufacturing<br />

Sector and Knowledge-Intensive Business Services, Center for<br />

Economic Institutions - Research Paper Series, No. 2009-1,<br />

Tokyo: Institute of Economic Research - Hitotsubashi University,<br />

p. 66.<br />

Martin, R. (2008) Post-socialist segmented capitalism: The case<br />

of Hungary. Human Relations, Vol 61 (1), pp. 131-159.<br />

Mason, G. (2005) In Search of High Value Added Production:<br />

How Important are Skills? Research Report RR663, London:<br />

Department for Education and Skills<br />

Miles, I. (2000). “Services Innovation: Coming of Age in the<br />

Knowledge-Based Economy.” International Journal of Innovation<br />

Management 4(4): 371-389.<br />

Miles, I., Kastrinos, N., Flanagan, K., Bilderbeek, R., den Hertog,<br />

P., Huntink, W., Bouman, M. (1995), Knowledge-Intensive<br />

Business Services: Users, Carriers and Sources of Innovation,<br />

European Innovation Monitoring System, Luxembourg, EIMS<br />

Publication No. 15<br />

Miozzo, M. and Soete, L. (2001) “Internationalization of Services:<br />

A Technological Perspective”, Technological Forecasting and<br />

Social Change, 67(2/3), 159-185.<br />

Müller, E –Doloreux, D (2007) The key dimensions of<br />

knowledge-intensive business services (KIBS) analysis: a decade<br />

of evolution. Working Papers Firms and Region No. U1/2007<br />

Karlsruhe: Fraunhofer Institute Systems and Innovation Research<br />

Pavitt, K. (1984). “Sectoral Patterns of Technical Change:<br />

Towards a Taxonomy and a Theory”, Research Policy 13(6):<br />

343-373.<br />

Porter, M. E. (1990) Competitive Advantage: Creating and<br />

Sustaining Superior Performance, New York: Free Press<br />

Regini, M. (1995) Firms and Institutions: Demands for Skills<br />

and Their Social Production in Europe, European Journal of<br />

Industrial Relations, 1-2: 191-202.<br />

Sako, M. (2005) Outsourcing and Offshoring: Key Trends and<br />

Issues, Bacground paper prepared for the Emerging Markets<br />

Forum, Oxford: Oxford University Said Business School, November.<br />

Sako, M. (2006) Outsourcing and Offshoring: Implications for<br />

Productivity of Business Services, Oxford Review of Economic<br />

Policy, Vol. 22, No. 4., Oxford: Said Business School- Oxford<br />

University, November.<br />

Salter, A. – Tether, B. S. (2006) Innovation in Services (Through<br />

the Looking Glass of Innovation Studies), Background Paper for<br />

Advanced Institute of Management –Researchs` Grand Challenge<br />

in Service Science.<br />

Schienstock, G. – Hamalainen, T. (2001): Transformation<br />

of the Finnish Innovation System. SITRA Reports Series 7,<br />

Helsinki.<br />

Sundbo, J. (1999) The Manual Service Squeeze,<br />

Forsknings Rapport, 99:2, Roskilde University<br />

Seite page 119<br />

Nielsen, P. (2006) The Human Side of Innovation System. (Innovation,<br />

New Organization Forms and Competence Building),<br />

Aalborg: Aalborg University Press<br />

Sundbo, J. (2002), The Service Economy: Standardisation or<br />

Customisation?, The Service Industries Journal, vol. 22, no. 4,<br />

p. 93-116


ORGANISATIONAL LITERATUR INNOVATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Tovoinen, M. (2006): Future prospects of knowledge-intensive<br />

business services (KIBS) and implications to regional economies,<br />

ICFAI Journal of Knowledge Management, Vol 4, No 3<br />

Valeyre, A. – Lorenz, E. – Cartron, D. – Csizmadia, P. – Illessy,<br />

M. – Gollac, M. – Mako, Cs. (2009) Working Conditions in<br />

the European Union: Work Organization, European Foundation<br />

for the Improvement of Living and Working Conditions,<br />

Luxemburg: ffice for Official Publications of the European<br />

Communities, p. 59.<br />

Viitamo, E. (2007) Productivity of Business Services – Towards<br />

a New Taxonomy. Research Report 188, Lappeenranta University<br />

of Technology<br />

Whitley, R. (2004) Project-based Firms: New organisational<br />

form or variations on a theme. Manchester: University of Manchester<br />

– Rotterdam: Erasmus University<br />

Seite page 120


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND.<br />

TRAJECTORY OF POLICY REFORM, POLITICS<br />

OF SOCIAL CHANGE AND EMERGING WELFARE<br />

REGIME. 1<br />

Catherine Spieser<br />

7<br />

Labour market adjustment is constructed<br />

by the policies that set the rules for the<br />

governance of employment and unemployment.<br />

Therefore, labour market polices<br />

have redistributive implications. Their orientations<br />

are defined in a process involving various<br />

socio-political actors (unions, employers associations,<br />

government with a partisan orientation).<br />

This has been particularly salient in Central<br />

and Eastern Europe given the pressure for<br />

adaptation to new market conditions resulting<br />

from economic liberalisation. Starting with a<br />

critical review of Esping-Andersen’s concept<br />

of welfare regimes, which places emphasis on<br />

the politics of social risk redistribution, this<br />

paper explores the policies and politics of labour<br />

market adjustment in Poland since 1989.<br />

It builds on original and secondary material<br />

and has a strong empirical component. The<br />

aim is twofold: (i) to identify which welfare<br />

regime (if any) is gradually taking shape and<br />

(ii) to uncover the socio-political compromise<br />

on which it rests. While policies have generally<br />

tended to become minimalist over time,<br />

retracing the trajectory of policy reform in two<br />

domains - unemployment compensation, on<br />

the one hand, and the rules governing employment<br />

relationship, on the other - reveals<br />

that there are two contrasted worlds of ‘labour<br />

market politics’.<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

page 121<br />

The breakdown of authoritarian communist<br />

regimes consecutive to the fall of the<br />

Berlin wall twenty years ago had one uncontested<br />

immediate effect: it gave rise to a wave


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

page 122<br />

of hope and high expectations for material improvement<br />

as well as improved living conditions<br />

in many of the countries concerned. In<br />

Poland particularly, the free market was seen as<br />

the solution to bring to end the consumption<br />

restrictions that marked the years of shortage<br />

economy (Mazurek 2010). As Leszek Balcerowicz<br />

led the way to macroeconomic stabilisation<br />

while pursuing his ‘shock therapy’ plan<br />

of anti-inflationary policies and quick privatisation,<br />

however, it soon became obvious that<br />

the rise of a capitalist, free market economy<br />

would not take place without another type of<br />

pain: rapidly expanding unemployment. Some<br />

feared that this would trigger labour unrest,<br />

union opposition to the course of reform or a<br />

risk of electoral backlash resulting in former<br />

communist parties returning to power and attempting<br />

to restore the former political order.<br />

None of this happened in Poland, even when<br />

mass dismissals became common in sectors<br />

undergoing privatisation and unemployment<br />

peaked at 20% at the end of the 1990s. More<br />

strikingly, social pains rarely translated into<br />

political mobilisation against new policies,<br />

which suggests that other channels of interest<br />

representation and compensation came into<br />

play. Contrary to the argument of a quick retreat<br />

of the state, I argue that policies – both<br />

new and old undergoing reform as well as both<br />

discourses and effective instruments - played<br />

a major role in establishing the conditions for<br />

a peaceful transition from a centrally<br />

administered universal employment<br />

system to a capitalist labour market in<br />

which individual fates are widely differentiated.<br />

The transformations of the work – welfare<br />

nexus in post-communist Central and Eastern<br />

European countries can be analysed along the<br />

same dimensions as historical developments<br />

that, I argue, are comparable in scope: the<br />

emergence of welfare policies in rising capitalist<br />

states in Western Europe over the last century,<br />

which has been the subject of a wide array of<br />

research. Confronting welfare state theories<br />

within a new setting, the fast changing political<br />

system, economy and society in Poland (and<br />

other Central and Eastern European countries)<br />

allows for further testing of their explanatory<br />

power and validity. Conversely, comparing the<br />

profound, multidimensional transformations<br />

observed in fast-changing environments, such<br />

as Poland and the rest of Central and Eastern<br />

Europe in the aftermath of 1989, with more<br />

established theories of welfare policy-making<br />

offers analytical rigour to the study of this<br />

seemingly unique phenomenon and reintegrates<br />

it into the field of comparative politics. 2 The<br />

aim of this paper is thus to examine what the<br />

theories of the welfare state originally derived<br />

from the study of ‘mature’ welfare states in<br />

Western Europe tell us about labour market<br />

policy formation in emerging capitalism, and<br />

what the latter tell us about the former.<br />

In both cases, regardless of the gap in time,<br />

what is at stake is a radical redefinition of the<br />

respective responsibilities of the individual<br />

and the political community of citizens, while<br />

state administration consolidates itself as an<br />

interface between both in times of profound<br />

industrial and economic transformations. These<br />

are best captured through the process of labour<br />

market adjustment, which in turn is governed<br />

not only by firms but also by the institutional<br />

framework available to them, and in which<br />

they are embedded. Placing the emphasis<br />

on policies organising work, employment


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

and unemployment allows for observing the<br />

transformations of the work-welfare nexus<br />

and the way in which change is negotiated (or<br />

not).<br />

This paper focuses on the explicit part of the<br />

work-welfare nexus at the macro-level, i.e.<br />

the body of rules and institutions governing<br />

employment and unemployment, which are<br />

shaped by distinct policy-making processes in<br />

specific arenas. It also explores cross-sectional<br />

and cross-time variation in a single country,<br />

Poland, and builds on a comparison of policy<br />

dynamics in two domains, unemployment and<br />

employment policy. Unemployment policy<br />

is defined as the composite sphere of labour<br />

market policies addressing unemployment<br />

and the unemployed, whether they aim to<br />

alleviate or counter unemployment or facilitate<br />

employment (as return to employment or<br />

accession to a first job). Employment policy<br />

is the regulation of work and employment,<br />

applying to hiring and firing and designed<br />

to foster equitable employer-employee<br />

relationships while striking a balance between<br />

flexibility and security.<br />

Section one presents a conceptual framework<br />

for the study of a shift in welfare regime. Section<br />

two and three trace the trajectory of policy<br />

reform in the area of employment regulation<br />

and unemployment insurance, respectively.<br />

Section four concludes the paper by comparing<br />

findings and drawing conclusions for the study<br />

of welfare reform politics.<br />

1. A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK BASED ON THE<br />

COMPARATIVE WELFARE STATE LITERATURE<br />

A large portion of studies on social policy<br />

development in the CEECs that attempt to<br />

establish a connection with works on other<br />

geographical areas and theories focus on the<br />

role of path dependency and legacies from<br />

pre-1989 regimes (e.g. Inglot 2003 & 2008).<br />

This tends to provide a misleading picture on<br />

two points: first, it emphasises stability while<br />

the distinctive feature of developments in the<br />

CEECs compared with Western Europe lies<br />

in the extensiveness of the transformations<br />

at stake; and second, it disregards the role of<br />

domestic politics and excessively de-politicises<br />

the process of reforming welfare entitlements,<br />

neglecting the salience of the politics of labour<br />

market adjustment in times of systemic change.<br />

In the search for an alternative framework, I<br />

argue that the comparative literature on welfare<br />

states provides some interesting insights and<br />

ways to overcome these pitfalls. On the one<br />

hand, the typology of welfare regimes allows<br />

for mapping change over time when the<br />

objectives, instruments and institutions of<br />

social policies are all simultaneously at stake<br />

in a process of policy formation and reform.<br />

On the other hand, the welfare state literature<br />

provides a conceptual framework for the study<br />

of political conflicts, bargaining processes and<br />

reform coalitions.<br />

1.1. Mapping a change of welfare<br />

regime in one country over time<br />

page 123<br />

The typologies of welfare systems<br />

(Esping-Andersen 1990 & 1999) help us<br />

understand the nature of the transformation of<br />

the work-welfare nexus in post-1989 Poland,


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

because they facilitate the identification of a<br />

shift of welfare regime. The idea of ‘welfare<br />

regime’ entails a societal and socio-political<br />

embeddedness resulting from the politics of<br />

social policy in modern democratic welfare<br />

states. The concept is heavily contextualised,<br />

however. The development of the welfare state<br />

is closely linked to the rise of the industrial<br />

society in Western Europe when ‘its promise<br />

was not merely social policy to alleviate social<br />

ills and redistribute basic risks, but an effort to<br />

rewrite the social contract between government<br />

and the citizenry’ (Esping-Andersen 1999: 33).<br />

With a view to represent the limited crosscountry<br />

diversity of welfare capitalism, and<br />

building on an earlier distinction between the<br />

residual and the institutional welfare state by<br />

Titmuss (1958), Esping-Andersen (1990)<br />

identified ‘three worlds of welfare capitalism’.<br />

In a residual welfare state, the state assumes<br />

responsibility only when the family or the<br />

market fails; it seeks to limit commitments<br />

to marginal and deserving social groups.<br />

On the contrary, the institutional welfare<br />

state addresses the entire population, is<br />

universalistic and embodies an institutionalised<br />

commitment to welfare; therefore, in principle,<br />

it extends welfare commitments to all<br />

areas of distribution necessary for societal<br />

welfare. The divide between Bismarckian and<br />

Beveridgean systems is often used to contrast<br />

two fundamentally opposed ways of<br />

organising social protection: work-<br />

page 124 related entitlements based on statute<br />

that reproduce income differentials<br />

in the former, and universal flat-rate<br />

benefits that equalise income, especially upon<br />

retirement, in the latter (Arza 2006: 2). While<br />

several waves of reforms in many European<br />

countries from the 1990s onward have blurred<br />

these institutional differences, the two types of<br />

welfare systems remain useful as a cognitive<br />

and historical reference, including in the minds<br />

of contemporary actors. Besides, these regimes<br />

provide a conceptual framework for the analysis<br />

of other empirical cases.<br />

Situating Central and Eastern European<br />

welfare regimes with respect to these seminal<br />

categories is often problematic. On the one<br />

hand, some historical features of their welfare<br />

arrangements dating back to the interwar<br />

period were inspired by Bismarckian welfare<br />

states: Polish territories belonging to the<br />

German Empire inherited Bismarckian-type<br />

social insurance. On the other hand, eligibility<br />

and benefits became universal with socialistera<br />

full employment after 1945. Nevertheless,<br />

in the 1990s, the dependence of welfare rights<br />

upon employment or occupation was still<br />

reflected in the relatively high share of social<br />

expenditure financed through contributions.<br />

The most recent reforms, however, tended<br />

to mirror post-industrial welfare reforms<br />

in Western Europe and a liberal-oriented<br />

perspective emphasizing benefits targeting and<br />

social safety nets (Barr 1994 & 2005). Given<br />

generally poor achievements of the welfare<br />

state in the CEECs, social outcomes may<br />

instead resemble some observations made on<br />

Southern Europe (Ferrera 1996).<br />

The macro-typology is most useful when<br />

understood as a frame of reference of idealtypical<br />

configurations or a repertory of<br />

possible ways in which social protection<br />

may be organized (Palier 2005a), rather<br />

than a classification in which all empirical<br />

cases should fit. 3 One key assumption in the


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

welfare regime literature is that policies and<br />

institutions develop in a relatively consistent<br />

manner across the different policy domains,<br />

so as to constitute, as an outcome, a coherent<br />

policy regime. ‘Short-term policies, reforms,<br />

debates and decision-making take place within<br />

frameworks of historical institutionalization<br />

that differ qualitatively between countries’<br />

(Esping-Andersen 1990: 80, my emphasis).<br />

Nevertheless, we can extract the functional<br />

logic of ideal-typical welfare regimes in order<br />

to build a conceptual grid for the analysis of<br />

a shift of regime, and more generally, policy<br />

change over time in a given setting.<br />

A change of welfare regime may take place on<br />

the occasion of a radical reform involving an<br />

explicit shift of paradigm (as occured in the<br />

Polish pension reform in 1995-1996, with the<br />

introduction of funded pensions based on the<br />

actuarial principle). It may also happen in a<br />

more gradual way, through the cumulative effect<br />

of successive reforms that, taken in isolation,<br />

seem limited to a recalibration of existing<br />

instruments or minor institutional change,<br />

but considered together and combined lead to<br />

major transformations questioning the general<br />

objectives and principles of the welfare system<br />

(Palier 2005b & 2007). In order to identify such<br />

a shift of welfare regime, we need to trace the<br />

trajectory of successive policy reforms focusing<br />

on in-depth case studies and using a processtracing<br />

methodology (Hall 2003, George and<br />

Bennett 2005, Vennesson 2008).<br />

1.2. Regime politics, risk communities and<br />

reform outcomes<br />

It is in its conceptualisation of the relationship<br />

between welfare institutions and social<br />

outcomes that the theory of welfare regimes<br />

makes its most decisive contribution. Esping-<br />

Andersen (1999: 36) stressed that ‘social policy<br />

means public management of social risks’. Two<br />

kinds of risk – defined as a contingency or the<br />

higher-than-average likelihood of seeing one’s<br />

individual situation worsen through no fault<br />

of one’s own – connected to work or lack of<br />

work are particularly significant in the process<br />

of economic and social adjustment. The first<br />

risk that individuals in employment face is<br />

increasing uncertainty and a deterioration<br />

of their working conditions. The second risk<br />

is losing paid work in circumstances that are<br />

beyond one’s control: unemployment as the<br />

unexpected and involuntary loss of income<br />

from work due to external factors affecting the<br />

employer.<br />

The communist regime eradicated<br />

unemployment by achieving artificial full<br />

employment as it imposed central state control<br />

over the allocation of work and welfare while<br />

eliminating free markets. By contrast, welfare<br />

policies in the capitalist world try to reduce the<br />

exposure to and consequences of labour market<br />

risks in several ways: re-arranging who bears<br />

and manages socioeconomic risks, establishing<br />

collective risk-pooling arrangements and<br />

providing social protection mechanisms<br />

to alleviate the impact on individuals. This<br />

implies providing security over a wide range<br />

of possible aspects: participation in<br />

the labour market, employment, skill<br />

formation and recognition, income, page 125<br />

and representation (Standing<br />

1999: 52). Thus, the welfare state is<br />

‘reapportioning the costs of risk and mischance’<br />

(Baldwin 1990: 1), i.e. redistributing the<br />

capacity to cope with labour market risks.


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

Table 1. Risk-pooling arrangements in selected policy areas<br />

Redistribution of risk /<br />

policy domain<br />

More risk-sharing<br />

Less risk-sharing<br />

Unemployment policy<br />

Passive Active ‘Activated’<br />

Pension system<br />

Employment relationship<br />

Predominant level of risk<br />

management, insecurity<br />

and uncertainty<br />

Social security<br />

(defined benefit, state provision)<br />

Protected and regulated<br />

Collective<br />

Actuarial<br />

(defined contribution,<br />

state or private provision)<br />

Flexible and deregulated<br />

Individual<br />

In that perspective, the defining feature of a<br />

welfare regime is ‘how risks are pooled’, i.e.<br />

‘how social risks are managed and distributed<br />

between the state, market and families’ (Esping-<br />

Andersen 1999: 33-36) as well as how they<br />

are distributed among unequal individuals.<br />

The system of social protection defines the<br />

eligibility or non-eligibility of citizens for<br />

benefits and services (‘the boundaries of rights<br />

and claims’ and the ‘range of human needs that<br />

are given the status of a social right’ in Esping-<br />

Andersen 1990: 80), thereby delimiting<br />

various groups in society. The major dimension<br />

of variation across regimes is the nature of the<br />

(institutional) arrangement that enables social<br />

risks to be pooled - or not.<br />

Labour market adjustment in a<br />

context of systemic transformations<br />

page 126 is also a highly redistributive process,<br />

triggering increased inequality as a<br />

result of ‘the transition from a world<br />

of jobs that were equally good (or equally bad)<br />

to a world of jobs that differ considerably in<br />

terms of job security and reward’ (Rutkowski<br />

1998a: 17). It is a reshuffling process in the<br />

most basic sense: it involves the reorganisation<br />

of job allocation and the redefinition of both<br />

private and collective roles, as well as individual<br />

and state responsibilities. Many individuals are<br />

exposed to a high risk of a loss or a deterioration<br />

of their income and job, but they are affected to<br />

a varying extent.<br />

In a consolidating democratic political<br />

system, the politics of welfare reform can be<br />

interpreted as regime politics. The logic of<br />

conflict combines both politics of transition, i.e.<br />

extraordinary politics of large-scale adjustment<br />

in times of systemic change, and social politics<br />

that approach the ‘politics as usual’, i.e. ordinary<br />

political games that have been a characteristic<br />

of reform processes in Western European<br />

welfare states since the retreat of Keynesianism.<br />

Uncovering the underlying power game,<br />

or compromise, allows for explaining the<br />

orientation of the welfare regime that results<br />

from cumulative, successive reforms, which<br />

together define a policy trajectory in terms<br />

of whether it has become more, or less,


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

redistributive, and whether it is pooling risks<br />

(and to what extent). This assumes a certain<br />

consistency across branches or policy areas, or<br />

at least that the actors interpret it as such.<br />

Comparative welfare studies provide models for<br />

the explicit or implicit political compromises that<br />

are underlying solidaristic- or individualisticoriented<br />

welfare regimes and ensure their<br />

stability over time. Welfare state generosity<br />

is often thought to be rooted in a democratic<br />

class struggle in which the social democratic<br />

parties and unions prove particularly powerful<br />

(Korpi 1983). However, class is a problematic<br />

concept in Poland where there is little empirical<br />

evidence of class consciousness (Meardi 2000;<br />

Ost & Crowley 2001 and Ost 2005) and<br />

widespread aversion to class-based ideology.<br />

Baldwin’s (1990) idea of risk communities is<br />

more enlightening to explain the emergence<br />

of institutions providing risk-pooling, or their<br />

absence. Social insurance, he argues, introduced<br />

a distinctive political dimension in that ‘the<br />

terms of misfortune’s reapportionment were<br />

determined not privately, but by society as a<br />

whole in accordance with commonly accepted<br />

standards of equity’, a process through which<br />

‘concerns that had formerly been individual<br />

became political’ (ibid.: 2).<br />

Redistributive policies such as welfare<br />

programmes (or income tax) tend to create<br />

‘haves and have-nots’ (Lowi 1964: 691),<br />

redistributive winners and losers. Social<br />

insurance redistributes the cost of managing<br />

socioeconomic risks rather than resources<br />

(Baldwin 1990: 19). Policies respond and give<br />

rise to demands for protection and support,<br />

expressed by certain categories of individuals,<br />

while other groups are satisfied by the primary<br />

distribution of socioeconomic capacities and<br />

security. The ‘risk categories’ group ‘actors<br />

identified and given interests in common by<br />

their shared relations to the means of security,<br />

by their stake in or against the redistribution<br />

of risk promised by social insurance’, in<br />

accordance with ‘the interaction of (...) (1)<br />

the simple incidence of risk as it afflicts the<br />

group in question, and (2) the group’s ability<br />

to shoulder its burdens unaided, its capacity<br />

for self-reliance’ (Baldwin 1990: 11-12). The<br />

simple incidence of risk relates to the effect of<br />

market mechanisms in the allocation of work<br />

and income, especially in the extraordinary<br />

politics of adjustment. The capacity for selfreliance<br />

is evaluated prior to the intervention<br />

of social policies. Therefore, ‘social security<br />

demands are best understood in terms of how<br />

risk communities coalesce. Risk communities<br />

are defined in terms of their relations to the<br />

means of security, and they may or, more likely,<br />

may not coincide with class identity’ (Esping-<br />

Andersen 1991: 225).<br />

Support for social protection is rooted in the<br />

amalgamation of a relatively high exposure to<br />

economic uncertainty, a low capacity for selfreliance<br />

and a capacity for collective action<br />

or political representation. 4 Universal social<br />

democratic welfare states and policies, which<br />

exhibit the highest level of risk-pooling,<br />

arise in the presence of a strong risk-pooling<br />

coalition. Only when such a risksharing<br />

coalition exists can solidaristic<br />

policies be pursued. Conversely, page 127<br />

residual or minimal welfare policies,<br />

placing an emphasis on individual<br />

responsibility, are adopted when the capacity<br />

for self-reliance of risk communities prevails<br />

at the expense of solidarity among them.


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

Finally, Bismarckian policies, or conservativecorporatist<br />

policies, are based on an insider<br />

status enjoyed by a category of individuals<br />

who contribute to social insurance in exchange<br />

for future entitlements. Therefore, they tend to<br />

emphasise the link between contributions and<br />

social security, or individual fairness, rather<br />

than universal solidarity.<br />

The inherited ‘state of entitlements’ (Inglot<br />

2003) in Poland in the early 1990s combined<br />

universal and Bismarckian aspects. With<br />

respect to a shift of welfare regime, three<br />

hypotheses can be formulated. First, generous<br />

universalistic policies tend to become<br />

minimalist residual ones when there is a shift<br />

in, or a breakdown of the coalition among risk<br />

communities in favour of self-reliant ones.<br />

Second, redistributive politics characterised<br />

by a recurrent two-side conflict are likely<br />

to be observed primarily in areas in which<br />

entitlements pre-exist. Third, as a consequence,<br />

Bismarckian (conservative-corporatist) policies<br />

are unlikely to be easily replaced by minimalist<br />

residual ones because they are supported by<br />

identifiable categories of beneficiaries who<br />

gained rights and entitlements in return for<br />

resources invested in the system, and seek<br />

to maintain these benefits. The dynamics of<br />

adjustment in Poland and policies connected<br />

with labour market risks provide new grounds<br />

on which to examine the validity of these<br />

hypotheses.<br />

page 128 With a view to testing these propositions,<br />

sections 2 and 3 trace the trajectory<br />

of successive reforms of un/<br />

employment policy with a focus on two institutions<br />

that can be considered cornerstones of<br />

the post-industrial capitalist welfare state: the<br />

employment relationship and unemployment<br />

insurance.<br />

2. UNEMPLOYMENT POLICY BY DEFAULT: THE<br />

WEAKNESS OF SOCIAL INSURANCE AND THE IM-<br />

PORTANCE OF PARTICULARISTIC REGIMES.<br />

This section reviews the policies that<br />

contributed to the institutionalization (and to a<br />

lesser extent the alleviation) of unemployment,<br />

the management of mass dismissals through<br />

exit to inactivity and the slow emergence of a<br />

broader government program of action against<br />

unemployment, including active labour market<br />

policies eventually seeking to add obligations<br />

to social rights.<br />

2.1. The recent institutionalisation of<br />

unemployment<br />

Unlike other social problems, unemployment<br />

really appeared on the political agenda in 1990<br />

as a result of the first transition measures and<br />

was to be addressed with little experience to<br />

build upon. Unemployment compensation and<br />

labour market policies more generally do not<br />

have a long history in Poland. 5<br />

Unemployment as a new social problem<br />

Prior to 1989, everyone had a constitutional<br />

right to work; and unemployment had been<br />

made illegal (Mlonek 1999). As a result, the<br />

concept of unemployment was rarely used as<br />

an analytical category and was inexistent as a<br />

category of public intervention. While at a<br />

marginal level a form of frictional unemployment<br />

(the gap between one’s job and the<br />

successive one, when one changes jobs) could


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

be found, the number of people explicitly<br />

unemployed was never significant, as few remained<br />

without a job for long. 6 In that context,<br />

the definition of unemployment was written<br />

in the law only in 1989. The fact that such a<br />

conception of unemployment was the only existing<br />

one in the analyses of labour allocation<br />

carried out before 1989 probably explains the<br />

somewhat prolonged belief of many Polish analysts<br />

and policy-makers that unemployment<br />

was a natural side effect of transition that would<br />

resolve itself through market mechanisms.<br />

In 1989, the initial government proposal for<br />

an unemployment benefit scheme forecasted a<br />

moderate increase in the number of unemployed<br />

(300 000). In reality, registered unemployment<br />

jumped from 55,000 people (0.2%) to<br />

1,125,000 (6.1%) within twelve months; more<br />

than one million people became unemployed<br />

in 1990 alone. The registered unemployment<br />

rate increased steadily during the 1990s and<br />

peaked at 20% in 2002-2003 (see table 2). By<br />

2003, more than one in two registered jobseekers<br />

had been without a paid job for more<br />

than a year. The trend only reversed with EU<br />

accession. In 2005, unemployment started to<br />

decrease, which is explained both by the large<br />

numbers of Poles who emigrated to other<br />

EU countries, which had opened their labour<br />

markets in 2004 (UK, Ireland and Sweden),<br />

and to an increase in job creation in Poland<br />

itself.<br />

The Employment Act of 1989, revised in 1991, set<br />

the basis for new labour market governance and<br />

institutions compatible with a capitalist market<br />

economy and the conditions of eligibility for<br />

unemployment compensation. It introduced<br />

an initially broad definition of unemployment,<br />

which was subsequently restricted on several<br />

occasions in later years. Unemployment grew<br />

as a result of the combination of uncertain<br />

economic conditions, wide-scale economic<br />

restructuring, adaptation to a changing market<br />

environment, hardening budget constraints on<br />

large state-owned enterprises, and dismissals<br />

becoming an option to adjust workforce thanks<br />

to the changing governance of work.<br />

page 129


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

Table 2. Employment and unemployment in Poland (% of active population)<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

2008<br />

Registered<br />

unemployment<br />

rate<br />

Employment<br />

rate<br />

(LFS)<br />

6.1 11.4 14.3 16.4 16 14.9 13.2 10.3 10.4 13.1 15.1 17.5 20 20 19.0 17.6 14.8 11.2 9.5<br />

n/a n/a 53.3 52.1 51 50.7 51.2 51.5 51 48 47.4 45.5 44.1 44 45.1 45.9 47.5 49.5 51<br />

Source: employment services (data end of year) and labour force survey (Q4)<br />

page 130<br />

The introduction and erosion of the<br />

unemployment benefit<br />

In the early 1990s, policy-makers were<br />

concerned that the surge of unemployment<br />

and a temporary deterioration of economic<br />

conditions could put regime change at<br />

risk. An unemployment benefit was swiftly<br />

introduced as the major instrument in view<br />

of alleviating the consequence of losing one’s<br />

job. While the government response included<br />

both passive and active labour market policies,<br />

the first largely prevailed. The Employment<br />

Act, which became the Act on Employment and<br />

Unemployment in 1991, established a network of<br />

public employment offices, an unemployment<br />

compensation scheme, a dedicated Labour<br />

Fund, and limited active labour programmes 7 .<br />

The Labour Fund, which served to<br />

finance them, was relying primarily on<br />

state subsidies (up to three-quarters<br />

of the total) and, to a lesser extent, on<br />

social contributions.<br />

The first measures could appear generous<br />

in the context. The level of benefit was<br />

initially calculated on the basis of the last<br />

remuneration and length of unemployment<br />

with a starting level of 70% (within the limit<br />

of the average wage) during the first three<br />

months, subsequently falling but unlimited in<br />

time. When a significant rise of unemployment<br />

was expected, this was a generous and<br />

costly scheme, which would quickly become<br />

unsustainable. It is highly likely that the initial<br />

generosity of the scheme aimed to achieve a<br />

peaceful institutionalization of unemployment<br />

in Poland: ‘the government, seeking to gain<br />

social acceptance for its far-reaching reforms,<br />

was more interested in a temporary solution’<br />

(Gardawski 2002c: 2). This law contained some<br />

peculiarities: there was no condition related<br />

to previous employment and young graduates<br />

entering the labour market were granted a<br />

preferential unemployment benefit which could<br />

reach up to 200% of the minimum wage, even<br />

in the absence of employment history 8 (MPiPS<br />

1995: 9; Gardawski 2002c).<br />

Quite logically, from 1991 onwards, a number<br />

of successive measures aimed to impose an<br />

increasing number of restrictions on the


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

general conditions of eligibility and length<br />

of unemployment benefit. First, a 12-month<br />

limit was introduced, with the possibility of<br />

extending the benefit to 18 months in total<br />

for people with a long employment history.<br />

The level of the benefit was linked to the<br />

local unemployment situation. Both the lower<br />

and upper limit of the benefit amount were<br />

lowered drastically: it could be as low as 33%<br />

of the average wage but not higher than the<br />

average wage. Restrictions on the benefit for<br />

unemployed graduates were also introduced<br />

in parallel. The relationship between the<br />

level of the benefit and one’s wage in the last<br />

job was completely eliminated in 1992: the<br />

unemployment benefit became a flat 36% of<br />

the average wage in the national economy. As<br />

a result, it was perceived as a measure of social<br />

assistance, rather than an entitlement deriving<br />

from one’s contributions paid to a social<br />

insurance fund. In 1996, the mode of calculation<br />

of the benefit level was reformed so that it<br />

would allow for adjustment independently of<br />

a set level of the average wage, which made<br />

it possible for further lowering of the benefit<br />

to wage ratio (Gardawski 2002c). In 2004 the<br />

rules were amended again. Although the Polish<br />

system is formally an unemployment insurance<br />

with obligatory contributions calculated as<br />

a percentage of salary, the benefit has, over<br />

the years, become a flat amount that varies<br />

only slightly according to work experience. 9<br />

Generally speaking, the unemployment<br />

benefit is granted for six months, but this can<br />

be extended in districts (powiats) marked by<br />

a level of unemployment higher for people<br />

who have a long working career behind them.<br />

In 2004, the Act on employment promotion and<br />

labour market institutions also introduced tighter<br />

conditions of eligibility for the unemployment<br />

status. To qualify, one needed to be a Polish<br />

or EU citizen between 18 and 60 (women)<br />

or 65 (men) years of age, not employed, not<br />

involved in training nor in any kind of paid<br />

work, not entitled to an old-age or invalidity<br />

pension, not owning more than two hectares<br />

of land, but willing and available to start full<br />

time work immediately, and registered with<br />

the local employment office.<br />

page 131


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

Table 3. Unemployment benefit coverage and replacement rate<br />

1990<br />

1991<br />

1992<br />

1993<br />

1994<br />

1995<br />

1996<br />

1997<br />

1998<br />

1999<br />

2000<br />

2001<br />

2002<br />

2003<br />

2004<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

Entitled to benefit<br />

(% of the unemployed<br />

registered)<br />

79 79 52 48 50 59 52 30 23 24 20 20 17 15 14 14 14 14<br />

Unemployment<br />

benefit (% of Polish<br />

average wage)<br />

19.6 34.2 37.9 36 37 36.7 33.4 32 30.5 23.8 23.3 23.1 23.4 22.9 22 21.9 21.5 20<br />

Source: Ministry of Economy and Labour (data end of year)<br />

While 79% of the unemployed received<br />

income support from the unemployment<br />

insurance in 1990-1991, the proportion of<br />

the unemployed covered by the benefit started<br />

to decrease significantly from 1992 (table 3).<br />

In 1999 there were 2.3 million unemployed,<br />

out of which 554 000 (almost one in four)<br />

received an unemployment benefit. In 2002 by<br />

comparison, there were 3.2 million unemployed<br />

(almost one million more) while the number<br />

of recipients of the unemployment benefit<br />

had slightly decreased, with only 539 000<br />

being eligible. The proportion of unemployed<br />

people entitled to the benefit sunk to 14%<br />

in 2004 and has remained at that level since.<br />

Such a drastic reduction of the eligibility<br />

for unemployment benefits was triggered<br />

by the combination of the limited duration<br />

of the benefit and an increasing<br />

unemployment duration. With many<br />

page 132 unemployed remaining jobless for a<br />

long time (more than half for longer<br />

than a year from 2002), the number<br />

of beneficiaries declined mechanically over<br />

the years to become a marginal proportion of<br />

the unemployed, falling below one in five in<br />

2005. The people who stopped being eligible<br />

for benefits over time are unlikely to receive<br />

any other form of income replacement and<br />

may only qualify for basic social assistance like<br />

food aid. As Gardawski (2002c) noted, in 2000,<br />

the average annual subsistence allowance paid<br />

by the social services barely amounted to one<br />

month of the average wage. Survey data on the<br />

economic means of the unemployed confirms<br />

that social assistance is not a source of income<br />

for those left without benefit (ISSP 1997).<br />

Meanwhile, the level of the unemployment<br />

benefit, which is determined by the Ministry<br />

of Labour and Social Policy, decreased in a<br />

severe manner (table3). The replacement rate,<br />

an indicator showing the level of the benefit<br />

in relation to wages 10 , stood at 76% of the<br />

minimum wage and 30.5% of the average<br />

wage in 1998, whereas one decade later it<br />

accounted for only 49% of the minimum wage<br />

(2008) and 20% of the average wage (2007) 11 .<br />

Both developments had an important social<br />

impact: further impoverishment of those who<br />

remained in unemployment for a long time.<br />

In 1997, according to survey data, only 22% of


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

the unemployed mentioned the unemployment<br />

benefit as their main source of economic<br />

support. 50% relied primarily on partner or<br />

family support and only 5% on social assistance<br />

(ISSP 1997).<br />

2.2. Measures facilitating labour market exit<br />

while bypassing the unemployment status<br />

Neither the worsening economic situation of<br />

the unemployed nor the reforms restricting<br />

the unemployment benefit triggered specific<br />

collective mobilization in Poland. These issues<br />

were not among the priorities on the agenda of<br />

trade unions, except in a few specific instances.<br />

Things differed when a large number of workers<br />

with a strong tradition of mobilization faced a<br />

deterioration of their work situation. In effect,<br />

‘the political threat posed by unemployment’<br />

(Baxandall 2003: 253) was primarily in the<br />

discontent of politically influential workers<br />

still in employment who risked losing their<br />

jobs. There were two major instances: the<br />

process of restructuring of strategic sectors in<br />

which workers had enjoyed a privileged status<br />

and workers with a long career behind them<br />

and no future in the new market society were<br />

concerned. In view of avoiding social conflict,<br />

these categories of people were often granted<br />

special compensation that not only bypassed but<br />

also undermined the standard unemployment<br />

benefit.<br />

This resulted in a segmentation of policies<br />

addressing unemployment: the jobless were not<br />

covered by one universal scheme, but split among<br />

a variety of compensation or social security<br />

mechanisms, which some saw as a deliberate<br />

government strategy to ‘divide and pacify’<br />

groups opposing market reforms (Vanhuysse<br />

2006). Without going that far, these policy<br />

choices clearly gave more favourable conditions<br />

to the groups that had the greatest capacity to<br />

mobilize against economic transformations,<br />

workers with a long career under the previous<br />

regime who had no future in the capitalist<br />

economy, and workers in strongly unionized<br />

sectors such as heavy industry and mining.<br />

Aside these particularistic schemes, the<br />

universal unemployment benefit set up as early<br />

as 1990 quickly became marginal as a result<br />

of successive reforms. The unemployed, hardly<br />

identifiable as a social group, neither developed<br />

a collective consciousness nor uniform<br />

interests in the face of welfare reforms; the few<br />

instances of mobilisation concerned primarily<br />

the conditions of collective dismissals and early<br />

retirement for workers in specific industrial<br />

sectors.<br />

Collective dismissals and severance payments<br />

Trade unions, which gathered the workers<br />

facing the threat of becoming unemployed,<br />

were potentially the strongest organized<br />

opposition group and retained a significant<br />

mobilization capacity in sectors like steel or<br />

mining 12 . In a few cases of large company<br />

or sector restructuring, the conditions of<br />

unemployment, or more precisely, the conditions<br />

of dismissal led to intense negotiations. The<br />

Act on Dismissals of 1989 set the rules of large<br />

workforce reductions and measures<br />

to protect affected employees and<br />

imposed some obligations on the page 133<br />

employer (notification of the trade<br />

unions in advance; stating the reasons<br />

for redundancies and the number of people<br />

concerned; informing the local employment<br />

office; and developing a program for retraining


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

and re-employment). Dismissed employees<br />

would receive redundancy payments of up to<br />

three months wage. Under the influence of<br />

powerful unions, restructuring plans involved<br />

intense negotiations and complex agreements.<br />

As an example, in the years 1994-1997,<br />

under the threat that the miners’ unions<br />

would block the restructuring of the whole<br />

sector, particularly generous social packages<br />

were granted in the form of significant<br />

one-off severance payments 13 . The mining<br />

sector provides an interesting illustration of<br />

negotiated compensation. Concentrated in<br />

Upper Silesia, 14 the mines and steelworks<br />

had a tradition of strong local trade unions<br />

and better than average welfare entitlements;<br />

they enjoyed more state support than<br />

elsewhere. Restructuring was contentious,<br />

for employees were strongly attached to the<br />

mines, which gave access to various benefits<br />

and social institutions. As a result, dialogue<br />

and coordination among the social partners<br />

was high on the agenda. In spring of 1995,<br />

representatives of socio-political, professional,<br />

local government and economic circles agreed<br />

to cooperate in a program for restructuring<br />

and development in Upper Silesia. A fouryear<br />

reform plan prepared by the Ministry<br />

of Industry in 1996 granted special social<br />

transfers and other subsidies. The regional<br />

leader of Solidarność presented an alternative<br />

scenario calling for more involvement<br />

of the national government and a<br />

page 134 wider consultation of regional and<br />

local actors. The outcome reflected<br />

the traditional power structure of<br />

actors in the region, i.e. the prominence of<br />

industrial actors linked to the largest plants,<br />

which made it difficult to envisage innovative<br />

solutions. Half a dozen successive restructuring<br />

plans were drawn up, but most were never<br />

fully implemented due to industrial conflict.<br />

Nevertheless, the workforce was reduced from<br />

a million people in the 1980’s to a quarter of<br />

this by 2003. Conflicts over collective dismissals<br />

were eventually avoided by granting generous<br />

packages, reflecting the bargaining power of<br />

the miners unions: there were reports of sums<br />

exceeding 10,000 euros to secure a definitive<br />

exit of mining employment (Gardawski 2003).<br />

This contrasts with the steel industry, where<br />

employment was reduced in the same proportion,<br />

but under very different conditions. Until 1998,<br />

jobs were lost principally to retirement or<br />

disability benefits, or transfer to other entities.<br />

In 1999 a social package led to further jobs<br />

reductions, among which slightly less than half<br />

were transferred to other companies and the<br />

rest made redundant (Towalski 2003). In 2003,<br />

a second social package for steelworks, focusing<br />

on activation, was adopted by the government<br />

and endorsed by the sectoral tripartite team.<br />

Its major innovation was to facilitate reemployment<br />

in other industries, by linking<br />

severance payments to enrolment in training<br />

contracts. By Polish standards, restructuring in<br />

the steel sector is an unusually positive example<br />

of working social dialogue in a developmental<br />

perspective. In comparison to the mining sector,<br />

this process was also remarkably peaceful and<br />

conflicts were scarce 15 ; a contrast that can be<br />

traced back both to the different role played<br />

by the unions (obstructing restructuring of the<br />

mines while accepting restructuring in the steel<br />

sector), and to the ultimate objective (closing<br />

down the mines as opposed to reducing<br />

workforce to build smaller, competitive steelmelting<br />

plants).


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

Organizing exit from employment and<br />

the labour market at once: paths to early<br />

retirement<br />

As in Western Europe in the past (Kohli et<br />

al. 1991, Ebbinghaus 2006), early retirement<br />

provided a widely-used alternative to manage<br />

mass dismissals, reducing their visibility by<br />

the same token. While it existed as a privilege<br />

before 1989, its function changed as it became<br />

a mechanism for employment adjustment.<br />

In addition, after 1990, the pension system<br />

continued to allow a long list of professions<br />

to retire earlier with full pension rights<br />

(Czepulis-Rutkowska 1999: 152). Social<br />

plans accompanying firm restructuring made<br />

extensive use of measures allowing to peacefully<br />

get rid of redundant workers and put them on<br />

the two kinds of inactivity pensions available:<br />

old-age retirement and disability. In 1991,<br />

a regulation targeting people who would be<br />

unable to find new employment allowed those<br />

who had been working for 35 (women) or 40<br />

years (men) to retire with full rights regardless<br />

of age if they had been made redundant (ibid.).<br />

An additional pre-retirement benefit financed<br />

by the labour fund, was later created to bridge<br />

the period between becoming unemployed and<br />

reaching the legal retirement age, targeting<br />

especially the long-term unemployed.<br />

Evidence of the scope of early retirement<br />

in practice is provided by several indicators<br />

regarding people moving from work or<br />

unemployment to retirement before the legal<br />

retirement age. The number of people retiring<br />

significantly exceeded those reaching retirement<br />

age in several given years. In 1991 and 1992,<br />

around 40% of all pensioners had not yet<br />

reached the legal retirement age (Golinowska<br />

1994: 33-35; Orenstein 1995: 191). In 1996<br />

again, 39.5% of all men and 28% of women<br />

who retired had not yet reached retirement<br />

age (ZUS, in Müller 1999: 101). In 1999, one<br />

third of the male workers who retired were<br />

below 60, declining to one fourth in 2001<br />

(ZUS figures). In 1999, still, more than 10%<br />

of men receiving an old-age pension were<br />

below 60. While the number of employed<br />

people fell by 14% between 1989 and 1996,<br />

the number of pensioners (including those<br />

on disability benefits) rose simultaneously by<br />

34%. Pensions clearly played the role of an<br />

additional unemployment benefit scheme. In<br />

2003, according to the Ministry of Economy<br />

and Labour, out of around one million of<br />

unemployed who were receiving some kind<br />

of benefit (less than 30%), slightly more<br />

than half received a pre-retirement benefit,<br />

while only the remaining portion received a<br />

proper unemployment benefit. In 2003, over<br />

half a million people were receiving a preretirement<br />

benefit or allowance. Similarly,<br />

the high rate of certified disability suggests<br />

that disability benefits were in part used as<br />

a functional equivalent of pre-retirement<br />

despite the medical examination required<br />

to certify unfitness to work. In 2002, they<br />

were distributed to 13% of the working-age<br />

population (20-64), and up to 18% of those<br />

aged between 40-55 (Burns and Kowalski<br />

2004: 6-7). The government attempt to reform<br />

the scheme and strengthen controls<br />

in 2003 met with little success.<br />

page 135<br />

Therefore, the standard unemployment<br />

benefit was only one of<br />

several policy instruments used to address<br />

rising unemployment, and not necessarily<br />

the prevailing one. With the heavy reliance


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

page 136<br />

on severance payment to ease dismissals in<br />

strategic sectors, on the one hand, and on<br />

inactivity pensions (early retirement and<br />

disability) to ease the exit from the labour<br />

market of a generation of workers with<br />

outdated skills, on the other, governments<br />

privileged selective schemes at the expense of<br />

universal ones. This contributed to the lack of<br />

visibility of the unemployed.<br />

3. THE CHANGING GOVERNANCE OF WORK AND<br />

THE REVIVAL OF LABOUR LAWS<br />

The shift from universal, centrally managed,<br />

protected standard employment towards more<br />

flexible and decentralised labour relations<br />

involved the retreat of the state from certain<br />

aspects of labour regulation (as part of setting<br />

the institutional foundations for a capitalist<br />

economy), a change of regulatory regime,<br />

and a diversification of forms of work and<br />

employment. Pre-1989 institutions and<br />

employment relations played a significant<br />

role. Unlike the issue of unemployment, the<br />

sphere of employment regulation tended to<br />

be perceived as a redistributive policy arena<br />

(Lowi 1964) in which interests were organized<br />

and represented around the opposition of two<br />

sides.<br />

3.1. Institutionalizing a labour market<br />

The end of the employer-state and<br />

the revival of the Labour Code<br />

Polish labour legislation dated back<br />

to the interwar period and was remodelled<br />

into a Labour Code in 1974, but the text had<br />

lost its role in the ‘command economy’ where<br />

unemployment was banned. The 1974 Code<br />

included the right to work (a formal guarantee<br />

of full employment) and kept some elements<br />

of the early codification: an employment<br />

relationship supposedly based on the freedom<br />

to contract, a distinction between the contract<br />

of indefinite duration, the norm, that of predetermined,<br />

short duration, the exception, and<br />

finally rules for employee dismissal (Surdej<br />

2004b: 13). The small number of modifications<br />

of the Labour Code between 1945 and 1989,<br />

ten at most 16 , testifies that it was a rather<br />

inactive piece of legislation (Gardawski 2002a),<br />

which was revived only after 1989.<br />

At the end of 1989, re-institutionalising<br />

market mechanisms for the allocation of work<br />

and jobs became a necessity, especially with<br />

respect to hiring and firing. However, at the<br />

outset of economic transformations, changing<br />

labour law was a lesser priority as ‘there [was]<br />

a prevailing belief that the government should<br />

take care of the economy first and then try to<br />

develop the legal superstructure’ (Swiatkowski<br />

1990: 45). The major laws needed to prepare the<br />

ground for economic restructuring and labour<br />

market adjustment were passed within the last<br />

four days of 1989 with little involvement of<br />

the parliament: the Act on Collective Dismissals<br />

on 28 December 1989, the Act on Employment<br />

and Unemployment on 29 December 1989,<br />

immediately followed by the programme of<br />

macroeconomic stabilization, also referred to<br />

as ‘Balcerowicz plan’ on 31 December 1989/1 st<br />

January 1990. This first series of laws decidedly<br />

set in motion the process of labour adjustment,<br />

by allowing dismissals, re-establishing<br />

the market and defining employment and<br />

unemployment.


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

From centralised control on wages to plantlevel<br />

wage bargaining<br />

The second major aspect of the state<br />

disengagement from administrating the<br />

workforce was the liberation of salaries and the<br />

withering away of state control on the level of<br />

wages. While wages were centrally fixed prior<br />

to 1989, the liberalisation of the labour market<br />

and the launch of privatisation brought this to<br />

an end in the rapidly expanding private sector.<br />

Following price liberalisation, the necessity<br />

to fight inflation justified the persistence of<br />

state control on wages through tax-based<br />

policies (ILO 1995a). Excess wage increases<br />

were penalised by a progressive taxation 17 to<br />

avoid fuelling inflation, which led to a real<br />

wage decline. Regulation was mainly targeting<br />

the public sector, thus virtually all workers<br />

initially, and then a decreasing share of them.<br />

The potential for union pressure on wages<br />

was considerably restricted as a consequence.<br />

Tax-based income policies were abandoned in<br />

1995-1996, leaving wage determination to the<br />

social partners.<br />

The Tripartite Commission, in its first version,<br />

provided a forum for wage negotiations<br />

primarily in the state sector. It established<br />

common positions on the growth of average<br />

monthly wages in enterprises during the<br />

third and fourth quarters of 1994; the level of<br />

resources to be allocated to wages in budget<br />

sector institutions in 1995; the maximum<br />

annual growth rate of average monthly wages<br />

in enterprises for 1995, 1996 and 1997; the<br />

expected level of average pay in budget sector<br />

and pay differential in sub sectors (Casale 2001:<br />

10). Union leverage was strengthened by voting<br />

powers which equalled those of government<br />

and employers representatives taken together<br />

(Pankow 1996), but it was undermined by<br />

a lack of cooperation between OPZZ and<br />

Solidarity and the self-restraining behaviour<br />

of the latter. Negotiations were suspended<br />

at the end of 1996. The Commission had<br />

practically no influence on wages in the private<br />

sector, where the absence of both unions and<br />

minimum standards allowed for employer<br />

opportunism and unilaterally imposed wages<br />

and employment conditions. In the mid 1990’s,<br />

wage-bargaining was taking place at the local<br />

plant level in more than 80% of Polish firms<br />

(ILO 1997), often without the presence of a<br />

shopfloor union.<br />

The minimum wage was formally recognised<br />

by the Polish Constitution in 1997 and set at<br />

a uniform rate by the Ministry of Labour and<br />

Social Policy. The government had planned to<br />

differentiate it according to regions in order to<br />

match the variation of average wages, but this<br />

was not adopted (Surdej 2004b: 11). Solidarnosc<br />

stood for a higher level set at 40 % of the average<br />

wage (Solidarity 2001) while opposing the<br />

indexation of the minimum wage on inflation<br />

and the introduction of a lower separate<br />

minimum wage for labour markets entrants<br />

(Casale 2001). A reform of the minimum<br />

wage in October 2002 increased the amount,<br />

changed the way it is set, and established<br />

a lower rate for school leavers 18 (Czarstaty<br />

2002b). According to the new law,<br />

from 2003 onwards the minimum<br />

wage is subject to negotiation in the page 137<br />

Tripartite Commission on the basis<br />

of a government proposal. It is one<br />

of the few subjects on which the trade unions<br />

always managed to cooperate (Kruszczinski,<br />

interview), with little result however. Since


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

page 138<br />

2000, the minimum wage has been wavering<br />

between 35% and 37% of average wage, one<br />

of the lowest rates among EU countries,<br />

nearing the pre-poverty income level which is<br />

estimated at 30% of average wage 19 .<br />

3.2. Successive reforms of the Labour Code:<br />

flexibility po-polsku<br />

They took place in four stages. In 1995-1996, a<br />

first, limited attempt to modify the text aimed<br />

at adapting it further to the new economic<br />

context. Between 1997 and 2001, the second<br />

attempt to modify the labour code was subject<br />

to trade union pressure to protect standard<br />

employment against deregulation. From 2001,<br />

a clear move toward de-regulation and greater<br />

institutionalised flexibility signalled a revival<br />

of the Labour Code reform. Nevertheless,<br />

interestingly, the government stepped<br />

backwards on some issues in 2003-2004 when<br />

it had to align rules with European framework<br />

legislation and policy guidelines in accordance<br />

with the EU accession process.<br />

A limited move to further adapt the old<br />

Labour Code (1995-1996)<br />

The issue of a fundamental reform of the<br />

labour code came back on the political<br />

agenda in 1995 as it became clear that the<br />

existing labour code did not provide a suitable<br />

framework; for instance, it did not<br />

impose any limitation on the renewal<br />

of fixed-term contracts, which came<br />

to be widely used.<br />

In 1996, the initiative for changes in the labour<br />

law came from a government supported by a<br />

centre-left coalition (SLD-Labour Union<br />

[UP]-Polish People’s Party [PSL]). To prepare<br />

for this, an Extraordinary Parliamentary<br />

Commission for the Modification of Labour<br />

Law worked from July 1994 until February<br />

1996 under the guidance of Wit Majewski, an<br />

SLD representative. However, most proposed<br />

modifications were elaborated by an expert<br />

committee for the reform of the labour law<br />

composed mainly of labour law professors,<br />

operating as a standing advisory body to the<br />

Ministry of labour and social policy since<br />

1990, with the implicit mission to design a new<br />

labour law for a social market economy (Surdej<br />

2004a). The Parliamentary Commission, acting<br />

to draft an acceptable reform compromise,<br />

held meetings with the participation of<br />

representatives of the major trade unions<br />

(OPZZ and Solidarnosc), employers associations<br />

(the KPP confederation, Business Centre Club<br />

[BCC], Polish Business Roundtable [PRB])<br />

and two public institutions closely involved<br />

in the matter: the Social Security Institution<br />

(ZUS) and the National Labour Inspectorate<br />

(PIP). A law was voted that eliminated<br />

outdated legal provisions and brought greater<br />

uniformity of regulation for employment in the<br />

public and private sectors (Kwiatkowski et al.,<br />

2001: 25; Czarzasty 2002a).<br />

The most contentious issue was the definition<br />

of the employment contract. The spreading<br />

practice of bypassing the labour code by using<br />

task-based contracts for assignments that, given<br />

their regularity and a unique employer, would<br />

normally require more binding employment<br />

contracts, had revealed loopholes in the<br />

existing legislation. This happens at the expense<br />

of worker’s protection: the Labour Code by<br />

definition only governs employment contracts,<br />

while contracts covering the execution of a


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

precise task within a specific, limited time<br />

frame (the so-called Polish civil contracts)<br />

fall under the rules of the Civil Code, which<br />

means that the contractor is neither considered<br />

an employee nor protected against employers’<br />

abuse (Streeck 2005). In an attempt to remedy<br />

the situation, the Extraordinary Parliamentary<br />

Commission put forward a proposal to modify<br />

the legal definition of employment (Surdej<br />

2004a, 30).<br />

The trade unions, the labour inspectorate<br />

(PIP) and the Social Insurance Institution<br />

(ZUS) called for the introduction of a legal<br />

provision stating that every job automatically<br />

implied an employment contract unless the<br />

employer proved that it qualified for an agency<br />

contract. The proposal was opposed by the<br />

Ministry of Labour and Social Policy and<br />

eventually rejected with the argument that<br />

it would have created legal uncertainty and<br />

high implementation costs. The compromise<br />

consisted in adopting a solution that defined<br />

the employment contract as ‘a work under<br />

principal’s supervision’ (Surdej 2004a: 30-31),<br />

as opposed to task-based contracts designed<br />

in principle for independent workers. This<br />

seems an insufficient measure given that some<br />

enterprises were already using civil contracts<br />

in abnormal situations. A few other changes<br />

were introduced in the Labour Code, without<br />

putting its continuity into question. The most<br />

important of these is a restriction on multiplying<br />

fixed-term contracts: only two such contracts<br />

between a given employee and a given employer<br />

can succeed to each other, with a renewal for a<br />

third contract automatically taking the shape<br />

of an undetermined, long-term one.<br />

While the two main trade union federations<br />

proved satisfied with the changes, the Labour<br />

Code in general continued to be criticised by<br />

employers for being too employee-friendly, too<br />

rigid for small businesses, and insufficiently<br />

amended (Czarzasty 2002a; Surdej 2004a). In<br />

effect, the lack of radical changes to the Code<br />

at this stage could be seen as a union-friendly<br />

compromise of the ruling coalition composed<br />

of the Democratic Left Alliance (SLD) and<br />

the Polish People’s Party (PSL) (Czarzasty<br />

2002a).<br />

Trade unions, the protection of standard<br />

employment and the defeat of reform attempts<br />

(1997-2001)<br />

By 1997, the SLD and PSL coalition had<br />

thus introduced some non-radical revisions<br />

to the labour code while keeping the bulk of<br />

it unchanged, which was seen as damaging<br />

for business and interpreted as an indication<br />

of both union power and employers’ failure<br />

to organize and lobby efficiently for their<br />

interests. With rising unemployment, labour<br />

law reform was taken more seriously; it was<br />

on the agenda of the AWS coalition (Electoral<br />

Action Solidarity), which returned to power<br />

in 1997. Employers also became more active,<br />

putting forward a large number of proposals<br />

to amend the labour code. Two reform projects<br />

were especially significant: the union proposal<br />

for shortening the work week and a series<br />

of liberalising measures proposed<br />

by businesses; they triggered an<br />

ongoing battle over labour law reform page 139<br />

opposing the two sides for several<br />

years (McMenamin 2005: 224) 20 .<br />

The Labour Code reform was also put<br />

on the political agenda by a coalition of


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

business associations that brought together<br />

the Confederation of Polish Employers<br />

(Konfederacja Polskich Pracodawcow – KPP) 21 ,<br />

the Business Centre Club, the Polish Chamber<br />

of Commerce, and the Association of Polish<br />

Artisans, which represented small-sized craft<br />

businesses. This was a well-coordinated effort<br />

benefiting from the administrative support and<br />

technical analysis of the Business Centre Club.<br />

The coalition worked to prepare a detailed<br />

and radical draft bill, aiming to significantly<br />

increase flexibility and reduce labour costs.<br />

Their first proposal was a draft bill focusing on<br />

improving conditions for small and medium<br />

enterprises (SMEs) 22 , a theme to which both<br />

the Freedom Union, the party of Leszek<br />

Balcerowicz, and AWS were attached; but, in<br />

fact, a number of measures adopted within this<br />

frame concerned all enterprises and were aimed<br />

at reforming the labour market in general. The<br />

draft included measures concerning overtime<br />

and fixed-term contracts, which were of<br />

interest to all employers (ibid.: 229-230).<br />

The way in which the bill was presented<br />

largely explains its rejection. Unions saw it as a<br />

provocation. The text had been shown neither<br />

to the government nor to the trade union<br />

Solidarnosc before reaching parliament. It was<br />

discussed only in a specific SME committee, a<br />

favourable audience a priori, but a committee<br />

with no history of passing legislation and no<br />

political weight (ibid.: 232). AWS<br />

and SLD were committed to rejecting<br />

page 140 the proposal. After the SME bill was<br />

rejected in its first parliamentary<br />

reading, business associations and<br />

their political allies turned to a more efficient<br />

active lobbying strategy, i.e. talking to<br />

politicians of the opposite side to see which<br />

elements could become acceptable and trying<br />

to persuade them, lobbying the government<br />

directly and using personal channels rather<br />

than institutional ones (ibid.: 232-234).<br />

In the meantime, a distinct project explicitly<br />

aiming to reform the Labour Code was taking<br />

shape. During the debate on the SME bill,<br />

both left- and right-wing political forces were<br />

publicising proposals concerned with the<br />

duration of the working week and working<br />

time, primarily aiming to satisfy union demands<br />

for a shorter working week. This led to two<br />

draft bills: one from the governing coalition<br />

and one from the opposition, both appearing<br />

sympathetic to unions’ concerns.<br />

The first draft bill was proposed in the Senate<br />

by Solidarnosc and only supported by a faction<br />

of the related political party. It focused on two<br />

measures: reducing the 42-hour working week<br />

to forty hours with no reduction in pay and free<br />

Saturdays in place of old designated free days.<br />

The proposal also included practical provisions<br />

for the implementation of these changes in a<br />

worker-friendly way, and other pro-union or<br />

pro-worker adjustments to regulations (ibid.:<br />

235-236).<br />

The second draft bill was proposed by SLD in<br />

the Sejm. It was supported by the leadership<br />

of the party and was more likely to represent<br />

a compromise between the pro-union and<br />

pro-business factions. The bill ‘was designed<br />

to ensure that AWS could not take the<br />

credit amongst workers, as the party that had<br />

shortened the working week. However, it also<br />

had something to offer employers and was, to<br />

some extent, inspired by the small enterprise<br />

bill. The bill simply declared a 40-hour week


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

and increased the overtime limit from 150 to<br />

200 hours per year’ (ibid.: 236). In comparison<br />

with the former, the proposal of the left would<br />

have raised the cost of labour significantly, but<br />

it was less of a threat to employers since it did<br />

not provide for free Saturdays and raised the<br />

overtime limit. Both proposals, however, were<br />

leading to more uniform working conditions<br />

across industries (in many state sectors, such as<br />

steel, energy and mining, the shorter 40-hour<br />

week already existed).<br />

Taking its time, the government published a<br />

unique draft in September 1999 attempting<br />

to bring together the three previous proposals,<br />

a ‘compromise between the pro-union bills of<br />

AWS and SLD and the pro-business bill of the<br />

SME committee’ (ibid.: 240). Workers had free<br />

Saturdays, a gradual implementation of the 40-<br />

hour work week, plus two extra days off on the<br />

annual minimum leave. Employers obtained<br />

an extension of maximum overtime allowed, a<br />

cut by half of overtime pay, and the abolition<br />

of restrictions on sequential temporary<br />

contracts. The unions were strongly opposed to<br />

most measures, arguing that not all measures<br />

involved had been discussed in the Tripartite<br />

Commission; and the proposal was buried in<br />

October 1999 as the unions announced that<br />

the MPs connected with them would vote<br />

against the bill (ibid.: 241).<br />

After this failure, the government decided to<br />

limit itself to implementing what the unions<br />

called for: the 40 hour and five-day week, with<br />

a two-year phase-in for the former. This was<br />

passed without the support of the Freedom<br />

Union, while two renewed attempts to pass<br />

bills that would liberalise the labour code were<br />

defeated: a resurrection of the failed SME bill<br />

by the Freedom Union, and a bill introducing<br />

a specific, more liberal labour code for SMEs<br />

aside the regular one (ibid.: 243). Finally, a bill<br />

banning work on Sunday in firms employing<br />

more than 5 people, proposed by a faction<br />

of AWS, was passed with the support of the<br />

Peasant party, small parties and independents.<br />

In the face of many opposing voices, the<br />

law, probably aimed at the foreign-owned<br />

hypermarket chains, was eventually vetoed by<br />

the president.<br />

In conclusion, the period of the third Sejm<br />

was marked by repeated attempts to liberalise<br />

or bypass the labour code, but the continued<br />

pressure of trade unions (in particular<br />

Solidarity, given its strong link to the AWS<br />

coalition) and business lobbying inefficiency,<br />

led to a consolidation of the standard<br />

employment contract. Conditions even<br />

improved with a shortened work week, while<br />

new legal or administrative burdens fell on<br />

employers, such as the requirement to establish<br />

internal company bylaws and social funds<br />

(Gardawski 2002a). SMEs remained subject<br />

to the same requirements as large companies.<br />

Nevertheless, the debate had clearly moved:<br />

the “left” had made some significant steps<br />

towards a more business-friendly position, at<br />

times departing even from the pro-workers<br />

movements of some parts of AWS. Thus, two<br />

increasingly separate types of cleavage were<br />

emerging on the issue of labour law<br />

reform: the usual left-right divide and<br />

a workers-business opposition, while page 141<br />

the Left and workers’ side, on the one<br />

hand, and the Right and employers’<br />

side, on the other hand, were not necessarily<br />

overlapping.


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

The Labour Code and the institutionalisation<br />

of flexibility (2001-2003)<br />

Following general elections in 2001, in the face<br />

of rapidly rising unemployment, the new left<br />

coalition government taking office in autumn<br />

made boosting economic development the<br />

highest priority on the agenda. 23 To achieve<br />

its agenda, the government planned reforms<br />

aiming at a combination of improving<br />

flexibility of the labour market and supporting<br />

SMEs. When Jerzy Hausner (SLD) took up<br />

his post of Minister of Labour and Social<br />

Policy, he declared his intention of introducing<br />

profound changes to the Labour Code in view<br />

of reducing financial costs and administrative<br />

burden for enterprises 24 .<br />

Although the right-wing incumbent<br />

government had been defeated, altogether,<br />

business forces appeared to be better represented<br />

in both the government and parliament.<br />

While a number of trade unionists lost their<br />

seat, a group of deputies representing private<br />

businesses appeared in the Sejm. Jacek<br />

Piechota’s (SLD) nomination as Minister for<br />

Economy – he had previously chaired the<br />

parliamentary committee on SMEs – was a clear<br />

signal: his first intervention was to draw up<br />

and circulate a list of demands from SME<br />

owners (Gardawski 2002a).<br />

A renewal of the government’s<br />

approach to law-making also contri-<br />

page 142 buted to changing the political<br />

climate. In contrast to earlier government<br />

practices, Hausner signalled<br />

his commitment to pursuing such a serious<br />

reform in consultation with all the significant<br />

institutional partners. His first task was,<br />

therefore, to revive the Tripartite Commission,<br />

the institution for social dialogue paralysed<br />

since OPZZ’s withdrawal. The innovative<br />

method was initially welcomed by the trade<br />

unions, since it appeared to be radically<br />

different from the way in which the previous<br />

government had prepared a law – behind closed<br />

doors, without consulting all sides involved.<br />

Measures geared towards enterprises were<br />

grouped in the programme ‘Enterprise above<br />

all’, which was approved in the beginning of<br />

2002. The title of the document clearly reflects<br />

the strong belief of government elites that easing<br />

the burden for entrepreneurs would speed<br />

up economic growth and ultimately increase<br />

the number of jobs available. A proposal for<br />

changes to the labour code was prepared by the<br />

Ministry of Labour and Social Policy.<br />

The package of labour law changes was<br />

presented and discussed with the social<br />

partners in a Tripartite Commission meeting<br />

on 28 January 2002. 25 The initial negotiations<br />

appeared to be promising, with media reports<br />

in early 2002 stating that agreement seemed<br />

imminent between the leadership of OPZZ<br />

and Solidarnosc. The two main trade unions<br />

seemed to agree on measures aiming to reduce<br />

administrative costs falling on enterprises,<br />

although they rejected the measures aiming to<br />

reduce the role and function of trade unions in<br />

collective agreements (a right for employers to<br />

dissolve collective agreements against unions)<br />

(Gardawski 2002b). The course of events took<br />

another direction, however, with Solidarnosc<br />

eventually rejecting the proposal.<br />

Nevertheless, the trade union OPZZ, the<br />

employers associations PKPP and the Polish


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

Craft Association (ZRP) worked out a<br />

common position, stating their reservations on<br />

several aspects, ranging from the dissolution of<br />

collective agreements and conditions of leave,<br />

to severance and overtime pay (Gardawski<br />

2002b). Two agreements were signed on 19<br />

April and 8 May 2002, without Solidarnosc.<br />

The union demonstrated in Warsaw against<br />

the government proposal 26 . However, the<br />

consequences of this opposition were limited as<br />

the union had lost parliamentary representation<br />

and protest remained circumscribed 27 . The<br />

government made some changes to the<br />

proposal consistent with trade unions’ demands<br />

and decided to move forward and submit<br />

the project to Parliament, despite the lack of<br />

unified support of the social partners.<br />

The Sejm adopted the law modifying the<br />

Labour Code on 26 July 2002 with the votes<br />

of the governing social-democratic coalition<br />

supported by the Civic Platform (PO),<br />

following which it was passed at the Senate<br />

on 7 August 2002 (Surdej 2004a: 34). For this<br />

success, and his reactivation of social dialogue<br />

at the national level, Hausner was deeply lauded<br />

by Gazeta Wyborcza, one of Poland’s most<br />

influential (liberal) daily newspaper, which<br />

praised him in the following terms: ‘rather<br />

than endlessly reminding all and sundry about<br />

social justice, Minister Hausner has created<br />

a language in which he combines economic<br />

slogans with ones about the building of civil<br />

society, with academic knowledge thrown in<br />

for good measure. (…) he has gained standing<br />

(if not necessarily affinity) among trade union<br />

people’ (18 October 2002, cited by Gardawski<br />

2002a). Unions, on the other hand, seemed<br />

to have fully internalised the constraints of a<br />

market economy and given the unemployment<br />

climate, started to buy the argument that a<br />

limited degree of de-regulation was beneficial<br />

to counter unemployment, and in the final<br />

analysis, employment-friendly (Kruszczinski<br />

interview, OPZZ interview).<br />

Meanwhile, before the government proposal<br />

was to be examined by parliament, PO<br />

had presented its own, more radical project<br />

which was subsequently abandoned. It<br />

contained many business-friendly measures:<br />

the elimination of rule limiting the number<br />

of successive fixed-term contracts, the right<br />

to terminate the employment contract of an<br />

employee absent for longer than a month,<br />

a reduction of sick pay entitlements and a<br />

lowering of the employer burden in sick pay<br />

to the first week, a significant increase of<br />

overtime allowance (from 150 to 240 hours<br />

per worker per year), and finally the right<br />

for an enterprise in danger of bankruptcy to<br />

suspend some provisions of the Labour Code<br />

(Czarzasty, 2002a).<br />

The actual changes introduced by the law of<br />

2002 are well captured by the redefinition of<br />

the employment relationship, aiming to limit<br />

the substitution of the employment contract<br />

by task-based contracts not subject to the<br />

Labour Code. The employment relationship<br />

exists ‘irrespective of the name of contract<br />

made by the parties’ (article 22.1.1) and<br />

establishes that ‘the employee agrees<br />

to perform a specified type of work<br />

for and under the directions of the page 143<br />

employer, in a place and at times<br />

designated by the employer, and the<br />

employer agrees to employ the employee in<br />

return for remuneration’ (Labour Code, article<br />

22.1). Furthermore, a ban on abusive civil


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

contracts is spelt out as follows: ‘a contract of<br />

employment shall not be replaced by a civil<br />

law contract on the same terms of performing<br />

work as those specified’ (article 22.1.1). While<br />

the aim was to render illegal the practice<br />

of dependent self-employment based on<br />

unprotected civil contracts, these rules remain<br />

insufficient to grant an effective protection<br />

given weak enforcement.<br />

Aside this, a considerable amount of measures<br />

introduced by these new laws had the effect<br />

of increasing the flexibility of labour. First, the<br />

law of 2002 suspended, until the day of EU<br />

accession, the rule imposing that after two<br />

fixed-term contract an employee should be<br />

offered a undetermined one 28 . This can be seen<br />

as a way to increase numerical flexibility, but it<br />

is detrimental to employment stability since it<br />

allows for an indefinite number of short-term<br />

contracts in a row. Secondly, by modifying<br />

the law on collective dismissals of 1989, it<br />

diminished both their cost, as it introduced<br />

more restrictive conditions for being granted<br />

severance payment, and their visibility by<br />

limiting the consultation requirement to<br />

the enterprise union instead of, previously,<br />

the regional office. Procedures for collective<br />

dismissals were also shortened and simplified.<br />

However, as the next session will show, new<br />

legislation in 2003 had to step back on some<br />

of these measures. Thirdly, the law expanded<br />

working time flexibility as it modified<br />

the way in which working hours are<br />

page 144 calculated, allowing for more flexible<br />

arrangements in the organisation of<br />

work and making maximum working<br />

time less of a constraint. Furthermore, it<br />

cut significantly the level of overtime pay,<br />

for which the employer can from then on<br />

also grant free time. In accordance with the<br />

government objective of facilitating economic<br />

activity, SMEs were granted an exemption<br />

from a number of internal company regulations<br />

considered bureaucratic and cumbersome<br />

procedures of little use in these small units<br />

(working and remuneration codes), while<br />

health and safety regulations and procedures<br />

were simplified for all employers.<br />

The synergy between the government objective<br />

of stimulating economic development and<br />

labour and social reforms was reinforced when<br />

the Ministry of Economy and the Ministry<br />

of Labour and Social Policy were merged as<br />

one single portfolio placed in the hands of<br />

Jerzy Hausner in July 2003.29 In the summer<br />

2002, a special legal commission for the<br />

revision of the Labour Code (Commission<br />

for the Codification of Labour Law - Komisja<br />

Kodyfikacyjna Prawa Pracy) was instituted for a<br />

duration of four years 30 . An independent body<br />

gathering experts in the matter of labour law, it<br />

was headed by Michal Sewerynski, a recognized<br />

Law professor (who later became Minister of<br />

education in 2005). While such commissions<br />

are regularly instituted in Poland to reform a<br />

wide body of laws constituting a Code, this<br />

intensified the technical character of both<br />

labour law reform and the transposition of the<br />

EU acquis into national law. In sum, it resulted<br />

in further de-politicizing the process. In reality,<br />

the commission had an implicit objective to<br />

rewrite the Labour Code entirely: its primary<br />

mission was to elaborate the foundations for a<br />

‘re-codification of individual labour law’ and a<br />

‘codification of collective labour law’, as well as<br />

drafting legal projects to meet EU standards<br />

with a view to accelerate the integration of EU<br />

provisions into Polish law.


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

Legislative changes induced by EU accession:<br />

limits on flexibility? (2003-2004)<br />

Although this was at the margin of legislative<br />

alignment with the EU acquis, labour market<br />

regulation was affected by the preparation for<br />

EU membership 31 . The requirement to integrate<br />

the EU acquis into national law applied in two<br />

areas that relate to employment regulation: a<br />

large body of detailed and binding rules needed<br />

to implement the free movement of persons<br />

and, more of interest, selected provisions<br />

concerning employment and social policy<br />

(negotiation chapter 13), which contained little<br />

binding regulations at the time, but a number<br />

of directives requiring transposition into Polish<br />

law.<br />

Therefore, the terms of the debate on lawmaking<br />

slightly changed, taking a more<br />

technical character with the urgent necessity to<br />

bring Polish legislation in line with European<br />

norms as accession became a tangible and<br />

proximate deadline set on the 1 st of May 2004.<br />

The accession negotiations were closed at the<br />

Copenhagen Council on 13 th December 2002.<br />

In 2003, legislative work focused on completing<br />

the integration of the acquis in the area of free<br />

movement and social policy and employment,<br />

leading to the adoption of three texts: the<br />

Act of 13 March 2003 on special rules for<br />

terminating labour relations for reasons not<br />

tied to the employees, 32 the Act of 9 July 2003<br />

on the hiring of temporary workers 33 and the<br />

Act of 14 November 2003 on amendments to<br />

the Labour Code and related laws, 34 aiming to<br />

refine certain aspects of labour legislation and<br />

finalise the adaptation of individual labour law<br />

to EU requirements.<br />

The impact of this legislation in terms of<br />

flexibility and security is a mixed picture. On the<br />

one hand, it is a step backwards in comparison<br />

with previously adopted measures aiming<br />

at greater flexibility. The ban on more than<br />

two consecutive fixed-term contracts was reintroduced,<br />

albeit with a list of exclusions. The<br />

Act of 13 March 2003 on collective dismissals<br />

considerably expanded the requirement for<br />

information and consultation of employees<br />

in the case of mass layoffs: the right could be<br />

exercised even in the absence of a union within<br />

the enterprise concerned; a 30-day notice<br />

should be respected; all employees dismissed<br />

for reasons beyond their control were eligible<br />

for severance payment without exceptions; and<br />

the labour office should also be notified. On<br />

the other hand, the rules concerning working<br />

time were in some respect changed again,<br />

introducing a more flexible calculation and an<br />

increase in the daily working hours, along with<br />

new rules facilitating work during the weekend<br />

(Saturday and Sunday). The latter, however,<br />

was better specified, allowing for separate<br />

contracts to be created for weekend work.<br />

More decisively, the Act on temporary work<br />

formally institutionalised this type of flexible<br />

work, thereby, giving temporary workers a real<br />

status by providing them with protection under<br />

the labour law. It also defined their rights and<br />

obligations, introduced a desperately needed<br />

regulation for temporary work agencies and<br />

regulated the relationship between<br />

the last employer, the temporary<br />

worker and the agency.<br />

page 145<br />

Altogether, elements from thirty<br />

different directives were integrated into<br />

the Polish Labour Code in preparation for<br />

membership of the European Union 35 . In the


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

page 146<br />

majority of cases, the coordination, monitoring<br />

of, and information on these legal changes were<br />

carried out by a small legal office responsible<br />

for labour law within the Ministry of Labour<br />

and Social Policy. On the eve of accession,<br />

the last ‘Comprehensive Monitoring Report<br />

on Poland’s preparations for membership’<br />

published by the European Commission in<br />

October 2003, reported two areas where further<br />

attention and action was deemed necessary.<br />

First, it stressed that the combination of high<br />

unemployment and low employment rates<br />

constituted a key economic issue that the<br />

government needed to address. Secondly, the<br />

Commission assessment reported as follows<br />

on the state of legal readiness: ‘Poland’s<br />

Labour Code is only partially aligned with<br />

the acquis on labour law and completion of<br />

transposition must be prioritized. Legislative<br />

alignment still needs to be completed in the<br />

fields of working time (including sectoral<br />

working time), part-time work, transfer of<br />

undertakings and posting of workers’ (EC<br />

2003: 39). Some of these issues were simply<br />

remedied in the law passed in November 2003.<br />

However, since Poland joined the EU in May<br />

2004, the pressure of conditionality and the<br />

objective of accession have disappeared and the<br />

transposition of European norms has become<br />

a more politicized process. This was illustrated,<br />

for instance, by the negotiations surrounding<br />

the drafting of the law on information and<br />

consultation of employees, which<br />

required the design of institutions<br />

for employee representation at the<br />

enterprise level (a particularly salient<br />

issue for unions).<br />

4. POLICY OUTCOMES, EMERGING WELFARE RE-<br />

GIME AND THE POLITICS OF REFORM<br />

For the past twenty years, Polish labour<br />

market policies were being put on the agenda<br />

with varying degrees of priority, introduced,<br />

reformed and fine-tuned. In the early 1990s,<br />

a mix of universal and corporatist features<br />

could be identified: an insurance-based income<br />

replacement scheme with universal eligibility,<br />

but decreasing levels of benefits. In later years,<br />

policies concerning unemployment resemble<br />

those in a minimalist welfare state: more<br />

restrictive eligibility criteria, unemployment<br />

benefits of shorter duration and lower coverage<br />

rate. The social insurance logic is fading and<br />

income support to the unemployed failed to<br />

become a legitimate part of the welfare state.<br />

Unemployment was institutionalized as a<br />

social status giving limited rights while policies<br />

heavily relied on inactivity benefits to ease exits<br />

of the labour market, addressing primarily the<br />

political threat posed by unemployment rather<br />

than seeking to provide a universal support<br />

to alleviate social deprivation associated<br />

with joblessness. In 2002-2004, formal<br />

and discursive compliance with European<br />

guidelines and instruments served to reestablish<br />

labour market policies as a central area<br />

of public policy and triggered a re-orientation<br />

in favour of activation measures. Despite this,<br />

policies addressing labour market risks remain<br />

essentially minimalist and residual; priority was<br />

given to the fight against unemployment, as the<br />

debate on reforming labour law exemplify.<br />

Employment regulation, primarily based on<br />

labour law, was gradually aligned with the<br />

functioning of a capitalist labour market before<br />

encountering the challenge of organising flex-


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

ibility that other European countries have<br />

faced. The early reforms of labour law consisted<br />

in re-establishing market mechanisms for the<br />

allocation of work, adjustment of the workforce<br />

and wage setting. The re-commodification of<br />

labour triggered a decentralisation of decisions<br />

on hiring and firing, but also of the governance<br />

of work more generally, starting with the<br />

negotiation of pay and working conditions.<br />

The issue of ‘deregulation’ then dominated the<br />

debate and the search for the most adequate<br />

legal framework, and flexibility became a major<br />

policy objective toward the end of the 1990s.<br />

The successive attempts to reform the Labour<br />

Code sought to achieve, even if some targeted<br />

the objective more explicitly than others. The<br />

employment contract was redefined. From<br />

2002, various provisions increased working<br />

time flexibility and simplified conditions and<br />

procedures to the advantage of employers.<br />

Overall, however, the rules governing standard,<br />

full-time employment changed less than the<br />

conditions applicable to atypical forms of<br />

work: flexibility was achieved primarily by a<br />

rapidly growing share of workers not covered<br />

by standard employment contracts, but rather,<br />

for instance, work-based contracts ruled by civil<br />

law. While these practices initially developed in<br />

a relatively spontaneous manner, in more recent<br />

years a number of acts were adopted with a<br />

view to providing minimal regulation of the<br />

flexible forms of work (for instance, temporary<br />

workers in 2003), largely with the impulse<br />

of European directives. We are left with a<br />

‘permissive regulation of working conditions’<br />

and ‘permissive labour relations through<br />

deviation’ (Bluhm 2008: 67).<br />

With respect to Esping-Andersen’s welfare<br />

regimes, referred to as ideal-typical<br />

configurations, Poland followed a trajectory<br />

marked by several shifts of regime: a shortlived<br />

universalistic welfare state (initially,<br />

extensive eligibility and unconditional generous<br />

benefits) quickly became unsustainable and<br />

turned into a corporatist system privileging<br />

certain branches (eligibility restricted mainly<br />

to certain well-organised and well-represented<br />

categories), and eventually into a minimalistresidual<br />

welfare state (stricter eligibility and less<br />

generous benefit, accompanied with a discourse<br />

emphasizing greater control and obligations).<br />

The inherited contributory regime in the area<br />

of pensions was consistent with universal<br />

benefits so long as universal employment<br />

with little income differentiation was the<br />

rule; however, it appeared as a contradiction<br />

when this was no longer the case, fostering<br />

the agenda for reform. Some features recall<br />

Southern European welfare systems, which are<br />

based on social contributions but marked by a<br />

high level of segmentation, missing a universal<br />

anti-poverty safety net and concentrating a<br />

high share of expenditures on pensions (Ferrera<br />

1996). They are also known to be impaired by<br />

clientelism and fiscal or contribution evasion<br />

and low administrative capacities, all of which<br />

are well illustrated in Poland, too. Finally, a<br />

fragmentation of social protection replicates<br />

the differentiation of labour market situations<br />

- another distortion typically observed in<br />

Bismarckian and Southern European welfare<br />

states. The whole population is no<br />

longer covered by the same principles<br />

and institutions. Instead, insiders with page 147<br />

full-time, permanent jobs continue<br />

to enjoy relatively good protection<br />

and significant benefits, while ‘outsiders’ with<br />

atypical jobs become increasingly marginalised<br />

by the welfare system.


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

In the original analysis, a welfare regime is<br />

also understood as a stable socio-political<br />

configuration revealing a particular kind<br />

of social contract and consistent policy<br />

orientations across all branches of the<br />

welfare state. In this perspective, the striking<br />

contrast between, on the one hand, the active<br />

involvement of the trade unions in the debate<br />

over labour law reform and, on the other,<br />

their complete absence in the face of the<br />

retrenchment of unemployment compensation<br />

is puzzling. The idea of a consistent ‘welfare<br />

regime’ is undermined by the co-existence of<br />

two worlds of ‘labour market politics’ involving<br />

distinct configurations of actors, which tend to<br />

constitute two separate ‘public policy arenas’. 36<br />

entitlements, is hardly politicised at all. Political<br />

conflict tends to be restricted to particular<br />

regional or sectoral arenas, and what is at stake<br />

is a particularistic compensation rather than<br />

a universal solution. In theory, the actors who<br />

are explicitly involved in the decision-making<br />

process are very similar to those found in the<br />

employment policy arena, but the salience of<br />

policy reform is not, since the unemployed are<br />

not well represented by the union side. The<br />

political salience of unemployment was high<br />

only when it appeared as a threat to workers<br />

in highly unionised sectors, while the general<br />

debate focused on the issue of employment<br />

creation, and thus the flexibility of employment<br />

conditions.<br />

page 148<br />

In what could be termed the ‘arena of employment<br />

regulation’, we can observe something<br />

that resembles ‘a stable and continual conflict<br />

that can only be understood in class terms’<br />

(Lowi 1964: 715), in other words, a typical<br />

configuration of redistributive politics. Two<br />

sides can be identified, as employers and trade<br />

unions were actively negotiating the orientation<br />

and reform of rules governing labour relations,<br />

in terms of a trade-off between flexibility<br />

and employee protection (security). However,<br />

rising unemployment resulted in a convergence<br />

of the seemingly antagonistic policy preferences<br />

of the two sides in a compromise in favour<br />

of more flexibility. The Tripartite Commission<br />

was an important deliberative forum<br />

in which to discuss such compromises,<br />

although in effect agreements were<br />

rarely reached there.<br />

By contrast, in the ‘unemployment policy arena’,<br />

defining the conditions of income support to<br />

the unemployed, even in the face of reducing


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

NOTES<br />

1<br />

Revised version of the paper presented at the workshop “What<br />

capitalism? Socio-economic change in Central Eastern Europe”,<br />

<strong>Jena</strong>, 29-30 October 2009. I wish to thank the participants for<br />

comments and suggestions.<br />

2<br />

Kornai (2006) gives a good account of the unprecedented and<br />

multidimensional nature of post-communist transformations<br />

3<br />

The issue arises out of ‘a confusion between ideal-types and cases,<br />

with the latter being seen as exemplifiers of the former, rather<br />

than the former being seen as constituents of the latter’ (Crouch<br />

2005: 23).<br />

4<br />

The capacity for self-reliance is seen as a stronger determinant<br />

of a group’s stance on social policy reform than ideological motives<br />

(Baldwin 1990).<br />

5<br />

The experience of unemployment in Polish history in the 1930’s<br />

is only referred to by academic observers, it is not part of the<br />

cognitive frame in which policy-makers and other actors reason<br />

two or more generations later.<br />

9<br />

In practice, the Ministry fixes the amount of the standard<br />

unemployment benefit for people who have worked between 5<br />

and 20 years; those who have worked less than 5 years receive<br />

80% of the standard benefit and those with more than 20 years<br />

work experience are entitled to 120%.<br />

10<br />

Because the unemployment benefit is calculated as a flat<br />

amount unrelated to one’s previous wage, the reference indicators<br />

are the minimum wage and the average wage in the Polish<br />

economy. This should not be confused with the replacement rate<br />

used in contexts where the benefit is calculated on the basis of<br />

one’s previous individual wage, which takes into account individual<br />

wages.<br />

11<br />

These figures are useful indicator for the purpose of crosscountry<br />

comparisons. They should be interpreted in relation to<br />

the growth of real wages before drawing conclusions on their<br />

evolution over time.<br />

12<br />

The illegitimate character of mass dismissals is reflected in<br />

public opinion surveys which reveal a broad consensus on the<br />

idea that ‘the government should provide jobs for everyone’,<br />

as compared to an important divide on the provision of an<br />

unemployment benefits, which is supported by only half of the<br />

respondents (ISSP 1997 and 2006).<br />

6<br />

Frictional unemployment was estimated as not exceeding half<br />

a percentage point in the people’s Republic of Poland (Mlonek<br />

1999). However, universal employment was achieved at the<br />

price of a higher number of workers than needed in many productive<br />

units.<br />

13<br />

In counterpart, they lost their rights to unemployment benefits<br />

(Gardawski 2002c).<br />

14<br />

At the outset of transition, 64 out of Poland’s 66 deep coalmines<br />

and one of the two major steelworks were located in Upper<br />

Silesia (Blazyca 2002: 26).<br />

7<br />

Small business loans, loans to employers for creating jobs, training,<br />

public service employment, and wage subsidy programs.<br />

15<br />

Most strikes in this sector date back to the first<br />

half of the 1990s.<br />

page 149<br />

8<br />

The special benefit was lowered (though not cancelled) in 1991;<br />

yet it remained higher than the standard unemployment benefit<br />

(MPiPS 1995: 9).<br />

16<br />

To be compared with 20 amendments between 1989 and<br />

2002.


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

17<br />

The tax on wage increase (popiwek), was initially targeting<br />

the total wage bill of enterprises, which came at the expense of<br />

employment. It was revised in 1991 to target average individual<br />

wages.<br />

24<br />

Changes in labour law in 2002 ‘were meant to reduce bureaucracy<br />

in labour relations, reduce the costs associated with hiring of<br />

workers, and to increase the flexibility of working time.’ (MEL<br />

2004: 20)<br />

18<br />

Such a measure aimed to foster youth employment, at a time<br />

when unemployment was exceeding 40% for people in the 15-24<br />

age range.<br />

19<br />

To be compared with 34% in Spain (lowest in the EU) and<br />

37% in the UK, where the minimum wage is a relatively recent<br />

introduction. In Poland, the 1997-1998 pension reform<br />

established an anti-poverty social safety net by introducing a<br />

minimum pension fixed at a level of 35% of the average wage.<br />

20<br />

This sub-section draws on McMenamin (2005) who specifically<br />

studied business lobbying in relation to the reform of<br />

the labour code in this period. Given the difficulty to reconstruct<br />

a policy process ex post as time passes, since it implies tracing<br />

the individuals who were involved and relying on their possibly<br />

distorted memories, his work based on a series of interviews<br />

carried out closer to the events provides extremely valuable<br />

information.<br />

25<br />

Prime Minister Marek Belka presented a document on the<br />

government projected economic strategy, Marek Kossowski,<br />

undersecretary of State of the Ministry of Economy presented<br />

the ‘Entreprise above all’ programme and Minister of Economy<br />

Jerzy Hausner presented the ‘First job’ programme (Communiqué<br />

of the Tripartite Commission 28.01.02)<br />

26<br />

On this occasion, it seems that the representative of NSZZ<br />

Solidarność, J. Sniadek, who was sitting at the Tripartite Commission<br />

on behalf of his organization took a stance that was<br />

invalidated by the rest of the union leadership. His position was<br />

rejected by the Presidium.<br />

27<br />

Between several thousands and several tens of thousands<br />

people demonstrated on 26 April 2002, depending on sources<br />

(Gardawski 2002b).<br />

21<br />

The Confederation of Private Employers (Polska Konfederacja<br />

Pracodawcow Prywatnych – PKPP Leviatan), which later<br />

became the leading employers organization, was founded only<br />

in 1999.<br />

28<br />

This could only be done until the date of accession since it<br />

breaches European rules defining minimum employment<br />

standards, including a restriction on the number of consecutive<br />

fixed-term contracts.<br />

22<br />

SMEs are an important segment of the Polish economy: they<br />

constituted 95% of all enterprises and employed 50% of the<br />

working population in 2002<br />

29<br />

Later, however, Hausner expressed his difficulty to work<br />

with the new Prime Minister Marek Belka, who, an economist<br />

himself, kept challenging the decisions and views of the super-<br />

Ministry of Economy.<br />

page 150<br />

23<br />

The economic programme of the new government<br />

consisted of three packages: ‘Enterprise above all’<br />

(Przede wszystkim przedsiebiorczosc), ‘First Job’<br />

(Pierwsza Praca) and ‘Infrastructure – the key to<br />

development’ (Infrastruktura- klucz do rozwoju).<br />

The latter is not directly of interest. ‘First Job’ is a<br />

programme to support jobs for young labour market<br />

entrants.<br />

30 Regulation of the Council of Ministers on the creation of the<br />

Commission for the Codification of Labour Law, 20 August<br />

2002 (Dz U 2002/139 item 1167).


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

31<br />

The number of transposition acts needed in the area of labour<br />

and social security was lower than in many other domains<br />

covered more extensively by the acquis: according to transposition<br />

commitments as expressed in the National Pre-Accession<br />

Programmes, four acts related to labour regulation were scheduled<br />

for adoption in 2000, another four in 2001 and only three in<br />

2002 (Zubek 2005).<br />

32<br />

Dz U 90 item 844.<br />

33<br />

DZ U 166, item 1608.<br />

34<br />

Dz U 213, item 2081.<br />

35<br />

To name a few: the Directive on employment contract information<br />

(91/533/EEC), working time (93/104/EC), parental leave<br />

(96/34/EC), part-time work (97/81/EC), etc. The complete list<br />

can be found in any recent edition of the Code (Kodeks 2004:<br />

257).<br />

36<br />

I developped this argument further in my PhD thesis (Spieser<br />

2009).<br />

page 151


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

REFERENCES<br />

BALDWIN, P. (1990) The Politics of Social Solidarity. Class<br />

Bases of the European Welfare State 1875 - 1975, Cambridge,<br />

UK, Cambridge University Press.<br />

BARR, N. A. (2005) From Transition to Accession IN BARR,<br />

N. A. (Ed.) Labor Markets and Social Policy in Central and<br />

Eastern Europe. Washington, World Bank.<br />

BARR, N. A. (Ed.) (1994) Labor Market and Social Policy<br />

in Central and Eastern Europe. The Transition and Beyond,<br />

Oxford, Oxford University Press / World Bank.<br />

BAXANDALL, P. (2003) Postcommunist Unemployment<br />

Politics. Historical Legacies and the Curious Acceptance of Job<br />

Loss. IN EKIERT, G. & HANSON, S. E. (Eds.) Capitalism<br />

and Democracy in Central and Eastern Europe. Assessing the<br />

Legacy of the Communist Rule. Cambridge, Cambridge University<br />

Press, 248-288.<br />

CROUCH, C. (2005) Capitalist diversity and change: recombinant<br />

governance and institutional entrepreneurs, Oxford ; New<br />

York, Oxford University Press.<br />

CZARZASTY, J. (2002b) New minimum wage legislation<br />

criticised by unions. EIROnline, 28/11/2002.<br />

CZARZASTY, J. (2002a). Amended Labour Code adopted.<br />

EIROnline, 10/09/2002.<br />

CZEPULIS-RUTKOWSKA, Z. (1999) The Polish Pension<br />

System and its Problems. IN MÜLLER, K., RYLL, A. &<br />

WAGENER, H.-J. E. (Eds.) Transformation of social security:<br />

pensions in Central-Eastern Europe Heidelberg ; New York<br />

Physica-Verlag.<br />

ESPING-ANDERSEN, G. (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare<br />

Capitalism, Polity Press.<br />

BLAZYCA, G. (Ed.) (2002)Restructuring regional and local<br />

economies: economies: towards acomparative study of Scotland<br />

and Upper Silesia. Aldershot: Ashgate.<br />

ESPING-ANDERSEN, G. (1991) Review of: The Politics of<br />

Social Solidarity, by Peter Baldwin. American Journal of Sociology,<br />

97, 224-226.<br />

BLUHM, K. (2008) Resolving Liberalisation Dilemma.<br />

Labour Relations in East-Central Europe and the Impact of<br />

European Union. IN MOREAU, M.-A. & BLAS-LOPEZ,<br />

E. (Eds)Restructuring in the New EU Member States. Social<br />

Dialogue,Firms Relocation and Social Treatment of Restructuring.<br />

Brussels, P.I.E. Peter Lang, 59-80.<br />

ESPING-ANDERSEN, G. (1999) Social foundations of<br />

postindustrial economies, New York, Oxford University Press.<br />

FERRERA, M. (1996) The Southern Model of Welfare in Social<br />

Europe. Journal of European Social Policy, 6, 17-37.<br />

BURNS, A. & KOWALSKI, P. (2004) The Jobs Challenge in<br />

Poland: Policies to raise Employment. Economics Department<br />

Working Papers.Paris, OECD.<br />

GARDAWSKI, J. (2002a) More flexible Labour Code comes<br />

into force. EIROnline.16/1/2003 <br />

page 152<br />

CASALE, G. (2001) Social Dialogue and Tripartism<br />

in Poland: Evolution and Trends. InFocus<br />

Programme on Strengthening Social Dialogue.<br />

Working Paper WP.2. International Labour Organisation,<br />

Geneva, ILO.<br />

GARDAWSKI, J. (2002b). Tripartite Commission discusses<br />

amendments to Labour Code. EIROnline. 20/06/2002<br />

GARDAWSKI, J. (2002c) Unemployment benefits examined.<br />

EIROnline. 29/10/2002.


CATHERINE SPIESER<br />

GARDAWSKI, J. (2003) Difficult restructuring of coal mining<br />

continues. EIROnline, 1/10/2003<br />

KWIATKOWSKI, E., SOCHA, M. W. & SZTANDERSKA,<br />

U. (2001) Labour Market Flexibility and Employment Security.<br />

Poland. Employment Paper 2001/28. Geneva, ILO.<br />

GEORGE, A. L. & BENNETT, A. (2005) Case studies and<br />

theory development in the social sciences, Cambridge, Mass.,<br />

MIT Press.<br />

HALL, P. (1993) Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the<br />

State. The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain.<br />

HALL, P. (2003) Aligning Ontology and Methodology in Comparative<br />

Research. In MAHONEY, J. & RUESCHEMEYER,<br />

D. (Eds) Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences.<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 373-404.<br />

INGLOT, T. (2003) Historical Legacies, Institutions, and the<br />

Politics of Social Policy in Hungary and Poland 1989-1999.<br />

IN EKIERT, G. & HANSON, S. E. (Eds.) Capitalism and<br />

democracy in Central and Eastern Europe : assessing the legacy<br />

of Communist rule. Cambridge, UK ; New York, Cambridge<br />

University Press., 210-247.<br />

INTERNATIONAL LABOUR ORGANISATION (ILO)<br />

(1997) Trade Union Experiences in Collective Bargaining in<br />

Central Europe. Report of an ILO survey in Bulgaria, Czech<br />

Republic, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia., Geneva, ILO.<br />

INTERNATIONAL SOCIAL SURVERY PRO-<br />

GRAMME (ISSP) (1997) Role of Government III. Data<br />

extracted 10/12/08, http://zacat.gesis.org/webview/index.jsp<br />

INTERNATIONAL SOCIAL SURVERY PRO-<br />

GRAMME (ISSP) (2006) Role of Government IV. Data<br />

extracted 10/12/08, http://zacat.gesis.org/webview/index.jsp<br />

LOWI, T. (1964) American Business, Public Policy, Case-<br />

Studies, and Political Theory. World Politics, 16, 677-715.<br />

MARTIN, C. & PALIER, P. (2008) From ‚a Frozen Landscape‘<br />

to Structural Reforms: The Sequential Transformation of<br />

Bismarckian Welfare Systems. IN MARTIN, C. & PALIER,<br />

P. (Eds) Reforming the Bismarckian Welfare Systems. Oxford:<br />

Blackwell, 1-20.<br />

MAZUREK, M. (2010) Les droits des consommateurs en<br />

Pologne communiste. Presentation at the ESOPE seminar ‘La<br />

protection sociale en regime autoritaire’, Paris, Ecole des Hautes<br />

Etudes en Sciences Sociales, 10 February 2010.<br />

MCMENAMIN, K. I. (2002) Polish Business Associations:<br />

Flattened Civil Society or Super Lobbies? Business and Politics,<br />

4.<br />

MCMENAMIN, K. I. (2005) The ‚Soft State‘: Business-<br />

Government Relations in Post-Communist Poland. PhD<br />

Thesis, Department of Government. London, London School of<br />

Economics and Political Science.<br />

MEARDI, G. (2000) Trade union activists, East and West :<br />

comparisons in multinational companie, Aldershot, Ashgate.<br />

MINISTERSTWO PRACY I POLITYKI SOCJAL-<br />

NEJ (MPIPS) (1995) Promocja aktywnosci zawodowej<br />

mlodziezy. Program przeciwdzialania bezrobociu wsrod<br />

mlodziezy. Warszawa, Ministerstwo Pracy i Polityki Socjalnej<br />

- Krajowy Urzad Pracy.<br />

KORNAI (2006) The great transformation of Central Eastern<br />

Europe. Economics of transition, 14, 207-244.<br />

KORPI, W. (1983) The democratic class struggle, London ;<br />

Boston, Routledge & K. Paul.<br />

MINISTRY OF ECONOMY AND LA-<br />

BOUR (MEL) (2005) Employment in Poland<br />

2005 (English translation of: Zatrudnienia w<br />

Polsce 2005). Warsaw, MEL.<br />

MLONEK, K. (1999) Bezrobocie w Polsce w XX wieku w<br />

swietle badan, Warsaw, Krajowy Urzad Pracy .<br />

page 153


THE POLITICS OF LABOUR MARKET ADJUST-<br />

MENT IN POST-1989 POLAND<br />

MÜLLER, K (1999) The political economy of pension reform<br />

in Central-Eastern Europe, Cheltenham England, Northampton,<br />

MA, Edward Elgar.<br />

NSZZ SOLIDARNOŚĆ (SOLIDARITY) (2001) XIVth<br />

National Assembly of Delegates of NSZZ „Solidarność“, Resolutions,<br />

Statements, Appeals and related Information.<br />

STANDING, G. (1999) Global Labour Flexibility, Palgrave<br />

Macmillan.<br />

STREECK, W. (2005) The Sociology of Labour Markets and<br />

Trade Unions. IN SMELSER, N. & SWEDBERG, R. (Eds.)<br />

Handbook of Economic Sociology. Princeton University Press,<br />

254-284.<br />

OST, D. & CROWLEY, S. (Eds.) (2001) Workers after Workers‘<br />

States. Labor Politics in Postcommunist Europe, Boston<br />

and Oxford, Rowman & Littlefield.<br />

SURDEJ, A. (2004a) Managing Labor Market Reforms: Case<br />

Study of Poland. Background Paper for the World Development<br />

Report 2005 (Draft).<br />

page 154<br />

OST, D. (2005) The Defeat of Solidarity. Anger and Politics in<br />

Postcommunist Europe, Ithaca, Cornell University Press.<br />

PALIER, B.(2005a) Gouverner la sécurité sociale : Les réformes<br />

du système français de protection sociale depuis 1945. Paris:<br />

Presses universitaires de France.<br />

PALIER, B. (2005b) Ambiguous Agreement, Cumulative<br />

Change: French Social Policy in the 1990s. IN STREEK, W. &<br />

THELEN, K. (Eds.) Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change<br />

in Advanced Political Economies Oxford, Oxford University<br />

Press, 127-144.<br />

PALIER, B. (2007) Tracking the Evolution of a Single Intrument<br />

Can Reveal Profound Changes: the Case of Funded<br />

Pensions in France. Governance, 20, 85-107.<br />

PANKOW, I. (1996) The Main Actors on the Political Scene<br />

in Poland. IN AGH, A. & ILONSZKI, G. (Eds.) Parliaments<br />

and Organized Interests: The Second Steps. Budapest, Hungarian<br />

Centre for Democracy Studies, 130-146.<br />

RUTKOWSKI, J. J. (1998a) Welfare and the labor market in<br />

Poland : social policy during economic transition,<br />

Washington, DC, World Bank.<br />

SPIESER, C. (2009) Institutionalising market<br />

society in times of systemic change. The construction<br />

and reform of social and labour market policies in Poland in a<br />

comparative perspective (1989-2004). PhD Thesis, Political<br />

and Social Science, European University Institute, Florence.<br />

SURDEJ, A. (2004b) The judiciary and the Development of<br />

Employment Regulations in Poland / Changes in Employment<br />

Regulations in Poland: What has been the Role of the Judiciary?<br />

Second Pan-European Conference of the ECPR Standing Group<br />

on EU Politics. John Hopkins University Bologna Centre.<br />

TITMUS (1958) Essays on the welfare state, London, Allen &<br />

Unwin.<br />

TOWALSKI, R. (2003) ‘Activation package’ agreed to acompany<br />

iron and steel restructuringEIROnline. 30/10/2003<br />

VANHUYSSE, P. (2006) Divide and Pacify: Strategic Social<br />

Policies and Political Protests in Post-Communist Democracies.,<br />

Budapest, Central European University Press.<br />

VENNESSON, P. (2008) Case studies and process tracing:<br />

theories and practices. IN DELLA PORTA, D. & KEATING,<br />

M. (Eds.) Approaches and Methodologies in the Social Sciences. A<br />

pluralist perspective. . Cambridge, Cambridge University Press,<br />

223-239.<br />

ZUBEK, R. (2005) Complying with Transposition Commitments<br />

in Poland: Collective Dilemmas, Core Executive and<br />

Legislative Outcomes. West European Politics, 28, 592-619.


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

8<br />

ANALYSIS OF THE HUNGARIAN LABOR<br />

MARKET BY DELIBERATIVE METHODS<br />

Szalma Ivett and Szél Bernadett<br />

European welfare states are under<br />

increasing pressure from a number<br />

of directions. Population ageing<br />

and shifts in family patterns increase needs,<br />

while the pressures of globalization on national<br />

competitiveness restrict the capacity to<br />

finance expansive welfare policies. In comparison<br />

to other EU member states, Hungary is<br />

characterized by a low employment rate, high<br />

inactivity and moderate unemployment. Hungary<br />

is a post-socialist country in which the<br />

capitalist regime has been around for almost<br />

20 years. As Dahrendorf (1994) elaborated<br />

upon this, different spheres pass through the<br />

transition phase with different speeds: while<br />

the fundamentals and institutions of political<br />

democracy can, in principle, be enforced<br />

in six months, and transition to the market<br />

economy can be carried out in six years, the<br />

(re)emergence of the values and norms takes<br />

a whole generation (60 years). It is a question<br />

whether the heritage of the socialist regime is<br />

still vivid in Hungary, in addition to whether<br />

people expect the government to take care of<br />

them in several aspects or whether they are<br />

ready to take care of themselves and have<br />

lower expectations of the state. It is another<br />

question what other European, non-postsocialist<br />

countries think about the role of the<br />

state and what connections can be detected<br />

between current expectations and a<br />

nation’s past.<br />

page 155<br />

In Hungary several national studies<br />

show that people hold a paternalistic<br />

state ideal (Ferge, 1996; Utasi, 2008). This<br />

phenomenon is said to have its roots in the<br />

socialist regime, because the state ensured


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

workplace for all its citizens; thus, the<br />

responsibility of the individual was much lower<br />

than it is now. In 1989-91 the change of the<br />

political era brought many new development in<br />

this area: the dissolution of heavy industry, the<br />

closing of factories and privatizations. These<br />

kinds of changes triggered unemployment ;<br />

and employees began to worry about losing<br />

their jobs. At the same time, there is a vivid<br />

discussion about how to make the economy<br />

competitive. Nevertheless, as competitiveness<br />

improved, it resulted in many cases in cutting<br />

back the paternalistic state. The peak time of<br />

changes was in 1993 when the unemployment<br />

rate reached 17% among the active population.<br />

After this period, the unemployment rate<br />

decreased. Unemployment means financial and<br />

psychological difficulties for the individuals.<br />

Moreover, in Hungary there is a large chance<br />

of remaining unemployed for a long time (Sági,<br />

1997). Those people who cannot find a job for<br />

a long time are usually have little education,<br />

live in unfavorable regions and come from<br />

larger families (Spéder, 2002). Some authors<br />

call them underclass, which refers to their<br />

social status: they are poor, uneducated and do<br />

not have the chance to find a job, also, their<br />

norms and values differ from those of the<br />

main society. Their only chance to survive is<br />

by registering at the Regional Employment<br />

Office, which provides for some social benefits<br />

(Laky, 2001).<br />

The current paper examines what<br />

page 156 expectations EU-nations have towards<br />

their governments regarding<br />

employment and social services and<br />

seeks answers concerning whether a coherent<br />

European answer can be given to the problem<br />

of state involvement in job market<br />

disequilibrium. Related to this problem area,<br />

the second chapter explores the job market<br />

related expectations Hungarians have towards<br />

the government to date. An explanation is<br />

given to the observed attitudes. Finally, a<br />

deliberative analysis is presented showing<br />

how the participants’ opinion about the labor<br />

market related role of the state changes upon<br />

dissemination of relevant information.<br />

1. EXPECTATIONS TOWARDS GOVERNMENTS AT<br />

THE EUROPEAN LEVEL<br />

The goal of this chapter is to explore the kind<br />

of expectations the European population<br />

has towards governments as well as how<br />

the accomplishment of welfare measures is<br />

evaluated. Europe has been facing the problem<br />

of the contradiction between economic<br />

efficiency and social supportiveness for decades.<br />

The main four types of critiques opponents of<br />

the social state usually emphasize are as follows<br />

(Tomka, 2009). The neoliberal conservatives’<br />

criticism focuses on restrictions of individual<br />

liberty that are imposed for the sake of societal<br />

equity. The second perspective points out that<br />

state-owned institutions are not efficient –<br />

they do not allocate resources in the optimum<br />

way, while wasting resources and providing<br />

opportunities for misuse. Moreover, as another<br />

typical criticism echoes, the social state<br />

influences economic performance in a negative<br />

way: the labor force will not be motivated to<br />

work because of the unemployment benefits;<br />

in addition, taxes imposed to finance social<br />

expenditures reduce savings and investments<br />

and, with that, the activity of enterprises and<br />

employment, as well. Finally, factors beyond<br />

financing social politics threaten the operation


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

of the system - mainly demographic changes<br />

and the effects of globalization.<br />

Based on the economic rationale, both in<br />

the OECD-countries as well as in the EU-<br />

15, welfare expenditures – in proportion of<br />

GDP – were increasing until 1995. Since<br />

then, they have been decreasing (Table 1). It is<br />

an important point how people relate to this<br />

process: how they interpret social welfare, what<br />

they expect form the government, and how they<br />

perceive the contradiction between economic<br />

and social aspects. In the following chapter,<br />

these questions will be addressed empirically.<br />

Table 1. In proportion of GDP welfare expenditures in the OECD-countries and the EU, 1980-2001<br />

1980 1985 1990 1995 2001<br />

OECD-21 17,7 19,6 20,5 22,5 21,9<br />

EU-15 20,6 22,9 23,4 25,6 24,0<br />

Source: OECD Social Expenditure Database [www.oecd.org]<br />

The fourth wave of the European Social<br />

Survey was conducted in 2008. For the<br />

current analyses, the following 20 countries<br />

are included in the comparison: Belgium,<br />

Bulgaria, Cyprus, Denmark, Estonia, Finland,<br />

France, Germany, Hungary, Norway, Poland,<br />

Portugal, Romania, Russia, Slovakia, Slovenia,<br />

Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and the UK;<br />

34949 respondents were surveyed. The fourth<br />

block of questionnaires is a rotating module<br />

addressing questions regarding welfare and,<br />

more specifically, attitudes towards welfare<br />

provision, size of claimant groups, views on<br />

taxation, attitudes towards service delivery and<br />

likely future dependence on welfare.<br />

In our empirical analysis four questions are<br />

addressed.<br />

1.<br />

Expectations European citizens have from<br />

their governments;<br />

2. Perception of social measure efficiency;<br />

3. Regional differences;<br />

4. Beyond the regional aspect what else may<br />

influence the attitude towards social<br />

measures and institutions; here particularly<br />

information-awareness is measured via<br />

education and Internet use.<br />

1.1. Expectations towards the governments<br />

When measuring attitudes on the European<br />

level, it is visible that the majority of respondents<br />

expect the state to be present and<br />

take care of employees on the job<br />

market. Table 2, 3 and 4 reinforce<br />

page 157<br />

this conclusion; they show that, in<br />

terms of avoiding unemployment,<br />

taking care of the unemployed and ensuring<br />

adequate child care services, the majority of<br />

respondents are rather explicit in this respect.


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 2. It is the responsibility of the state to ensure a job for everyone who wants one<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

It is not the responsibility of the state. 5890 18.3<br />

It is party the responsibility of the state. 12583 39.1<br />

It is the responsibility of the state. 13741 42.7<br />

Total 32214 100.0<br />

Missing 1191<br />

Total 33405<br />

Table 3. It is the responsibility of the state to ensure a reasonable standard of living for the unemployed<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

It is not the responsibility of the state. 3906 11.9<br />

It is party the responsibility of the state. 14880 45.5<br />

It is the responsibility of the state. 13910 42.5<br />

Total 32696 100.0<br />

Missing 709<br />

Total 33405<br />

Table 4. It is the responsibility of the state to ensure sufficient child care services for working parents<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

It is not the responsibility of the state. 1775 5.4<br />

It is party the responsibility of the state. 9779 30.0<br />

page 158<br />

It is the responsibility of the state. 21028 64.5<br />

Total 32582 100.0<br />

Missing 823<br />

Total 33405


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

However, when examining how people would<br />

choose between tax decreases and a drop in<br />

social services and benefits or a tax increase and<br />

spending more on social measures, we see that<br />

the majority (63.5%) would prefer the former<br />

(Table 5). This result shows that expectations<br />

for social services exist, but when it comes<br />

to the individual budget, citizens are careful<br />

about how resources should be allocated.<br />

Table 5. Government should decrease taxes and spend less on social services and benefits<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

Disagree 10768 36.5<br />

Agree 18726 63.5<br />

Total 29494 100.0<br />

Missing 3911<br />

Total 33405<br />

1.2. The efficiency of social measures<br />

Respondents were asked to judge to what<br />

extent they agree with the following statements.<br />

Social services and benefits in the respondent’s<br />

county:<br />

1.<br />

2.<br />

3.<br />

4.<br />

5.<br />

place too great a strain on the economy.<br />

prevent widespread poverty.<br />

lead to a more equal society.<br />

encourage people from other countries to<br />

come and live here.<br />

cost businesses too much in taxes and<br />

charges.<br />

Agreement with the first, fourth and fifth<br />

statements reflects a conservative attitude,<br />

while agreement with the second, third and<br />

sixth statements indicates that the respondent<br />

is closer to a social approach.<br />

Based on Table 6, we can see that the majority<br />

of respondents – 39.5 percent – disagree<br />

with the statement that social services and<br />

benefits in the respondent’s county place too<br />

great a strain on the economy. One third of<br />

respondents agree with this statement and<br />

more than one quarter of the sample would<br />

not give an exact answer.<br />

page 159<br />

6.<br />

make it easier for people to combine work<br />

and family life.


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 6. Social services and benefits in the respondent’s county place too great a strain on the economy<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

Agree 10542 33.6<br />

Neither agree nor<br />

disagree<br />

8436 26.9<br />

Disagree 12402 39.5<br />

Total 31380 100.0<br />

Missing 2025<br />

Total 33405<br />

Table 7 shows that the majority of respondents<br />

(58%) consider social services and benefits as<br />

an efficient tool in preventing the spread of<br />

poverty. On the other hand, 21% believes that<br />

poverty cannot be stopped by social measures,<br />

while a further 21% is undecided.<br />

Table 7. Social services and benefits in the respondent’s county prevent widespread poverty<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

Agree 18705 58.0<br />

Neither agree nor<br />

disagree<br />

6765 21.0<br />

Disagree 6797 21.1<br />

Total 32267 100.0<br />

Missing 1138<br />

Total 33405<br />

page 160<br />

The majority of respondents (50.9%)<br />

believe that social services and<br />

benefits will lead to a more equal<br />

society. Around one quarter do not<br />

trust in developing social equity via social<br />

expenditures, while almost a quarter does not<br />

have an explicit opinion (Table 8)


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Table 8. Social services and benefits in the respondent’s county lead to a more equal society<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

Agree 16359 50.9<br />

Neither agree nor<br />

disagree<br />

7711 24.0<br />

Disagree 8087 25.1<br />

Total 32157 100.0<br />

Missing 1248<br />

Total 33405<br />

The relative majority of respondents - 39.6%<br />

- believe that businesses are overburdened by<br />

social measures. On the other hand, almost<br />

one third disagrees with this statement, while<br />

28.2% is undecided regarding the relation<br />

between businesses and social welfare<br />

expenditures (Table 9).<br />

Table 9. Social services and benefits in the respondent’s county cost businesses<br />

too much in taxes and charges<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

Agree 12014 39.6<br />

Neither agree nor<br />

disagree<br />

8567 28.2<br />

Disagree 9761 32.2<br />

Total 30342 100.0<br />

Missing 3063<br />

Total 33405<br />

According to the majority of respondents<br />

(56.7%), social measures help to establish<br />

work-life balance; only 16.8% believe that<br />

social services and benefits do not have<br />

such a positive effect in this sense.<br />

Again, more than one quarter of the<br />

respondents do not have an explicit<br />

answer (Table 10).<br />

page 161


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 10. Social services and benefits in the respondent’s county make it easier<br />

for people to combine work and family life<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

Agree 17828 56.7<br />

Neither agree nor<br />

disagree<br />

8331 26.5<br />

Disagree 5284 16.8<br />

Total 31443 100.0<br />

Missing 1962<br />

Total 33405<br />

The majority of the respondents (55%) believe<br />

that immigrants are attracted by the social<br />

expenditures; one quarter oppose this statement,<br />

while almost 19% are undecided (Table 11).<br />

Table 11. Social services and benefits in the respondent’s county encourage people<br />

from other countries to come and live here<br />

Frequency<br />

Valid Percent<br />

Agree 17278 55.0<br />

Neither agree or<br />

disagree<br />

5945 18.9<br />

Disagree 8220 26.1<br />

Total 31443 100.0<br />

Missing 1962<br />

Total 33405<br />

Based on analyses of European<br />

countries as a whole, we may conclude<br />

page 162 that Europeans usually believe that<br />

social measures are efficient in terms<br />

of creating social balance in the<br />

population. In addition, they believe that these<br />

services and benefits would also attract people<br />

from other countries.<br />

1.3. Regional differences in terms of<br />

perceiving social services and benefits<br />

It should not be assumed that Europe as a<br />

whole considers the relationship between social<br />

expenditures and economic rationale univocally.<br />

In order to examine differences in how the<br />

diverse regions of the continent think about


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

these questions, a hierarchical cluster analysis<br />

was performed. The averages of respondent’s<br />

opinions were adjusted to each question in<br />

case of each country before the algorithm was<br />

applied.<br />

Based on this analysis, the following three<br />

clusters were identified (Figure 1).<br />

1.<br />

The Northern dimension and Switzerland,<br />

Cyprus: Finland, Norway, Sweden,<br />

Denmark, Switzerland and Cyprus.<br />

2.<br />

3.<br />

The Western dimension: Germany, the<br />

UK, Spain, Belgium and France.<br />

The Eastern dimension and Portugal:<br />

Bulgaria, the Russian Federation,<br />

Slovenia, Estonia, Poland, Slovakia, and<br />

Portugal.<br />

The only country that could not be assigned to<br />

the above clusters was Hungary.<br />

Figure 1. Dendrogram using Average Linkage<br />

The opinion of 19 European countries’ citizens on the efficiency of social welfare expenditures<br />

1= Belgium; 2=Bulgaria; 3= Cyprus; 4= Denmark; 5=Estonia; 6=Finland; 7=France; 8=Germany; 9=Hungary;<br />

10=Norway; 11=Poland; 12=Portugal; 13=Russia; 14=Slovakia; 15=Slovenia; 16=Spain; 17=Sweden;<br />

18= Switzerland; 19=UK<br />

page 163


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

1.4. The effect of information-awareness on<br />

expecting and perceiving social services and<br />

benefits<br />

The empirical analysis between the level<br />

of education and expectations from the<br />

government shows that, in case of higher<br />

education, expectations from the state<br />

decrease. Both in the cases of job market<br />

regulation [“It is the responsibility of the<br />

state to ensure a job for everyone who wants<br />

one”] and unemployment services [“It is the<br />

responsibility of the state to ensure a<br />

reasonable standard of living for the<br />

unemployed”], respondents with advanced level<br />

tertiary education expect less from the state:<br />

significantly fewer highly educated respondents<br />

say that social services and benefits are the duty<br />

of the state than less educated respondents<br />

(Table 12 and 13). The opposite is also true:<br />

among highly educated respondents, more<br />

explicitly say that the state is not responsible<br />

for the given social measure than respondents<br />

with only a basic level of education.<br />

Table 12. Crosstabulation between the level of education and<br />

“It is the responsibility of the state to ensure a job for everyone who wants one”<br />

It is the responsibility of the state to ensure a job for<br />

everyone who wants one<br />

It is not the<br />

responsibility of<br />

the state<br />

It is partly the<br />

responsibility<br />

of the state<br />

It is the<br />

responsibility<br />

of the state<br />

Total<br />

Basic level education 12.2% 36.1% 51.7% 100.0%<br />

Intermediate level<br />

education<br />

Advanced level<br />

tertiary education<br />

19.2% 39.3% 41.5% 100.0%<br />

25.0% 42.6% 32.4% 100.0%<br />

p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

In the case of childcare services, the same<br />

tendency as above exists but is much milder<br />

in the sense that even respondents with higher<br />

education expect more from the state (Table<br />

14). A possible explanation is that childcare<br />

services enhance being present on the job<br />

market. Respondents with higher education<br />

invested a lot for a successful job carrier and<br />

can feel that they deserve some governmental<br />

assistance when it comes to their children.<br />

Table 14. Crosstabulation between the level of education and “It is the<br />

responsibility of the state to ensure sufficient child care services for working parents”<br />

It is the responsibility of the state to ensure sufficient<br />

child care services for working parents<br />

It is not the<br />

responsibility<br />

of the state<br />

It is partly the<br />

responsibility<br />

of the state<br />

It is the<br />

responsibility<br />

of the state<br />

Total<br />

Basic level education 4.7% 29.4% 65.8% 100.0%<br />

Intermediate level<br />

education<br />

Advanced level tertiary<br />

education<br />

5.8% 29.3% 64.9% 100.0%<br />

5.8% 31.8% 62.3% 100.0%<br />

p


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 16. Crosstabulation between the level of education and “Social services<br />

and benefits in the respondent’s county cost businesses too much in taxes and charges”<br />

Disagree<br />

Neither agree,<br />

nor disagree<br />

Agree<br />

Total<br />

Basic level education 25.7% 28.6% 45.7% 100.0%<br />

Intermediate level<br />

education<br />

Advanced level tertiary<br />

education<br />

33.0% 28.7% 38.3% 100.0%<br />

38.5% 27.2% 34.3% 100.0%<br />

p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Table 19. Crosstabulation between the level of education and “Social services and benefits<br />

in the respondent’s county make it easier for people to combine work and family life”<br />

Disagree<br />

Neither agree,<br />

nor disagree<br />

Agree<br />

Total<br />

Basic level education 15.6% 26.2% 58.2% 100.0%<br />

Intermediate level<br />

education<br />

Advanced level tertiary<br />

education<br />

17.6% 28.1% 54.4% 100.0%<br />

17.2% 24.4% 58.5% 100.0%<br />

p


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 21. Crosstabulation between the level of education and<br />

“Government should decrease taxes and spend less on social services and benefits”<br />

Agree Disagree Total<br />

Basic level education 63.9% 36.1% 100.0%<br />

Intermediate level<br />

education<br />

Advanced level tertiary<br />

education<br />

64.8% 35.2% 100.0%<br />

61.0% 39.0% 100.0%<br />

p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Table 23. Crosstabulation between Internet penetration and “It is the<br />

responsibility of the state to ensure a reasonable standard of living for the unemployed”<br />

It is the responsibility of the state to ensure<br />

a reasonable standard of living for the unemployed<br />

Has Internet access<br />

at home<br />

Does not have<br />

Internet access at home<br />

It is not the<br />

responsibility of<br />

the state<br />

It is partly the<br />

responsibility<br />

of the state<br />

It is the<br />

responsibility<br />

of the state<br />

Total<br />

12.4% 46.8% 40.9% 100.0%<br />

10.0% 39.7% 50.3% 100.0%<br />

p


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 25. Crosstabulation between Internet penetration and “Social services<br />

and benefits in the respondent’s county place too great a strain on the economy”<br />

Social services and benefits in the respondent’s county<br />

place too great a strain on the economy<br />

Has Internet access<br />

at home<br />

Does not have<br />

Internet access at home<br />

Disagree<br />

Neither agree,<br />

nor disagree<br />

Agree<br />

Total<br />

38.9% 27.2% 34.0% 100.0%<br />

42.8% 25.4% 31.8% 100.0%<br />

p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Table 27. Crosstabulation between Internet penetration and “Social services<br />

and benefits in the respondent’s county lead to a more equal society”<br />

“Social services and benefits in the respondent’s<br />

county lead to a more equal society”<br />

Has Internet access<br />

at home<br />

Does not have<br />

Internet access at home<br />

Disagree<br />

Neither agree,<br />

nor disagree<br />

Agree<br />

Total<br />

23.8% 24.0% 52.2% 100.0%<br />

31.2% 24.0% 44.8% 100.0%<br />

p


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

The majority of respondents cannot say<br />

explicitly whether social measures should be<br />

diminished and, with that, the taxation level.<br />

This is valid both among those with private<br />

Internet access as well as those who do not<br />

have Internet at home (Table 30). There are<br />

slightly fewer respondents in the former group<br />

saying that taxes should be decreased. On<br />

the other hand, there are more respondents<br />

who disagree with decreasing the level of<br />

social services and benefits among those with<br />

private Internet access, even though they know<br />

that the level of taxation would also decrease.<br />

Both a higher level of education and Internet<br />

access available in private homes are related to<br />

a positive attitude towards the effects of social<br />

services and benefits.<br />

Table 30. Crosstabulation between Internet penetration and<br />

“Government should decrease taxes and spend less on social services and benefits”<br />

Government should decrease taxes and spend<br />

less on social services and benefits<br />

Has Internet access<br />

at home<br />

Does not have<br />

Internet access at home<br />

Disagree<br />

Neither agree,<br />

nor disagree<br />

Agree<br />

Total<br />

25.9% 37.6% 36.5% 100.0%<br />

23.7% 39.5% 36.8% 100.0%<br />

p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

In this research, the state role is measured by the<br />

following questions: What do people think about<br />

the deregulation of the labor market? What do<br />

people think about the following statements?:<br />

Finding a job is one’s own responsibility or the<br />

government should provide jobs for all citizens;<br />

Unemployment cannot be totally avoided vs.<br />

unemployment should be avoided at all cost;<br />

The government should prevent all illegal work<br />

vs. the government should not do anything<br />

against illegal work; The government should<br />

cut taxes vs. the government should not spend<br />

more on education, health care and pensions.<br />

Not only descriptive statistics (answers given in<br />

percentages) will be discussed. We also attempt<br />

to uncover differences among the social groups<br />

(based on demographic character, cultural<br />

capital and employment status) regarding these<br />

items through logistic regression modelling 1 .<br />

The qualitative method is carried out by<br />

analyzing two group conservations. The focus<br />

is on what people think about the role of the<br />

state , and how their opinions have changed<br />

during deliberation. Finally, we compare the<br />

results of the two methods.<br />

rate among the 15-64 year old population,<br />

Hungary came before Poland and Malta in the<br />

EU. In the same year, the mean activity rate<br />

was 64.5% in the EU. The activity rate exceeds<br />

the target set in the Lisbon Agreement -<br />

70% - in the following countries: Denmark,<br />

the Netherlands, Sweden, Great-Britain and<br />

Austria. In international comparison, the low<br />

activity rate in Hungary is explained by the<br />

fact that less educated people have a smaller<br />

chance of obtaining employment and the rate<br />

of less educated people is higher than the EU<br />

mean (Girasek-Sík, 2006).<br />

In Hungary, there are great differences in<br />

unemployment rates between the different<br />

regions. The first chapter of this paper contains<br />

a deliberative analysis of the expected role<br />

of the government regarding the job market.<br />

Somogy County, where the deliberationprocess<br />

took place, is part of Southern Transdanubia<br />

where unemployment rates are the highest in<br />

the more developed Transdanubian part of<br />

Hungary (Table 31).<br />

2.1. Unemployment and activity in Hungary.<br />

Distinguishing factors about County<br />

Somogy<br />

It is important to note that the activity rate in<br />

Hungary is low. Therefore, the real problem is<br />

not so much the high unemployment rate but<br />

rather the low activity rate. This characterizes<br />

the Hungarian labor market in comparison to<br />

other member states of the EU. In 2006 the<br />

unemployment rate was 7.5% in Hungary,<br />

while the mean unemployment rate of the EU<br />

members was 8.2%. With its 53.7% activity<br />

page 173


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 31. Number of employed persons of the population aged 15-74 (in thousands of persons)<br />

NUTS1, NUTS2 2000 2006 2007 2008<br />

Central Hungary 64.4 66.7 62.1 60.2<br />

Central Transdanubia 22.7 30.1 24.6 28.4<br />

Western Transdanubia 19.0 26.1 22.8 22.1<br />

Southern Transdanubia 30.4 34.7 37.2 38.6<br />

Transdanubia 72.1 90.9 84.6 89.1<br />

Northern Hungary 48.0 52.3 59.4 63.3<br />

Northern Great Plain 51.5 65.1 63.2 69.7<br />

Southern Great Plain 27.7 41.8 42.6 46.9<br />

Great Plain and North 127.2 159.2 165.2 179.9<br />

Country total 263.7 316.8 311.9 329.2<br />

Without Central Hungary 199.3 250.1 249.8 269.0<br />

Source: Labour Force Survey, HCSO<br />

The rate of unemployment was 17% in<br />

Somogy County at the end of the 2007, while<br />

the national average was 10%. In Figure 2, the<br />

South Transdanubian region where Somogy<br />

County is situated is marked in red. The<br />

figure shows that – in terms of unemployment<br />

– the NUTS3 region is one of the most<br />

problematic in Hungary and is in the least<br />

favorable situation in the relatively more<br />

developed West. The position of Somogy is<br />

the 4th worst in the country in this respect.<br />

Furthermore, one third of unemployment<br />

cases lasts more than one year, which again is<br />

a very unfavorable condition (Summary of the<br />

Results, 2008).<br />

Figure 2. Unemployment rate of population aged 15-74, 2008<br />

page 174


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

2.2. Who attended the deliberation<br />

weekend?<br />

First, 1514 people were polled on the targeted<br />

issue in May of 2008 (T1). This sample<br />

represented the population of the Kaposvár<br />

Region. In this paper, this survey will be<br />

referred to as the representative survey research.<br />

At the end of the questionnaire, the respondents<br />

indicated whether they wished to participate in<br />

a deliberation event. 350 people indicated their<br />

intention to participate. All were invited to the<br />

DP weekend on 21st – 22nd June, 2008. Finally,<br />

108 people attended the event. During the<br />

deliberation weekend, participants completed<br />

the questionnaire of May twice. First, they filled<br />

in the questionnaire when they arrived (T2).<br />

We told them that they did not have to recall<br />

their answers of the representative survey of<br />

May. We will call this survey research the predeliberation<br />

poll. Then they filled in the same<br />

questionnaires for the third time following<br />

deliberation (T3). This makes it possible to<br />

measure the effects of the deliberation. We will<br />

call this survey the post-deliberation poll.<br />

The sample who filled in the pre- and postdeliberative<br />

polls will be called deliberation<br />

weekend participants / small groups (as the 108<br />

participants were assigned to one of 15 groups<br />

during the weekend). There was no significant<br />

difference in the gender and age structure or<br />

educational background between the two<br />

samples (representative survey research; small<br />

groups). However, the deliberation weekend<br />

participants have more unfavorable positions:<br />

60% are economically inactive. Those living in<br />

Kaposvár are also overrepresented.<br />

According to the theory of deliberative opinion<br />

polling, the resulting changes inopinion represent<br />

the conclusions the public would reach<br />

if people had the opportunity to become more<br />

informed and more engaged in the issues.<br />

2.3. Hypothesis<br />

H1 People in unfavorable positions (women,<br />

less educated people, those who are out of the<br />

labor market, the old and those who do not use<br />

the internet or speak any foreign language) 2<br />

will object to the deregulation of the labor<br />

market. They are more likely to believe that<br />

the state should provide job opportunities for<br />

every citizen.<br />

H2 Risk groups will support the passive policies<br />

(social benefits) to tackle unemployment.<br />

Those of higher social status will prefer active<br />

policies (encouraging job creation) to tackle<br />

unemployment.<br />

H3 As for illegal work, we believe that those<br />

in favorable positions (men, those who are in<br />

the labor market, the young and those who are<br />

supplied with cultural capital) will more likely<br />

believe that illegal work should be eliminated.<br />

H4 Related to tax reduction, we assume that<br />

those in favorable positions will be supportive,<br />

while those in unfavorable positions will prefer<br />

tax increases in order to keep social<br />

benefits.<br />

page 175<br />

H5 The fifth hypothesis is related<br />

to the change of opinion caused by<br />

the deliberation. We generally expect that,<br />

following deliberation, people will have more<br />

information about deregulation and the state


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

role. The information gained during the<br />

deliberation will decrease the effects of socialdemographic<br />

position on the opinion about<br />

liberalization of the labor market, employment<br />

policies, illegal work, and tax cuts. The various<br />

points of views will get closer to each other.<br />

H1, H2, H3 and H4 refer to all of the survey<br />

polls, while H5 refers only to the pre-and<br />

post- deliberation polls.<br />

2.4. Regulation versus liberalization of the<br />

labor market<br />

First, we will discuss the issue of labor market<br />

deregulation. This question was measured on a<br />

seven degree scale. The first degree means the<br />

respondent strongly agrees with the following<br />

statement: Governments should let employers<br />

hire and fire as they see fit. The seventh degree<br />

means that the respondent strongly agrees with<br />

the following statement: Governments should<br />

make it very difficult for employers to fire. The<br />

results of each questioning session are shown<br />

in Table 32.<br />

Table 32. What do people think about the deregulation of the labor market?<br />

Measured on a 7 degree scale<br />

1-7 degree scale%<br />

Governments should let<br />

employers hire and fire<br />

as they see fit. (1-3)<br />

The middle of<br />

the scale (4)<br />

Governments should<br />

make it very difficult<br />

for employers to fire<br />

(5-7)<br />

Mean<br />

In the survey research<br />

(T1)<br />

Pre-deliberation in<br />

the small (T2) groups<br />

Post-deliberation in<br />

the small groups (T3)<br />

8.4% 17.6% 74% 5.7150<br />

12.8% 18.3% 68.8% 5.6422<br />

5.5% 16.5% 78% 5.9907<br />

T1 – T2: Statistically non-significant change (t=1.161, p>0.05) 3<br />

T2 – T3: Statistically significant change (t=-2.87 p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

no significant changes occurred. However,<br />

the deliberation caused significant changes in<br />

the way the weekend participants think about<br />

the deregulation of labor market. Before the<br />

deliberation, twice as many people said that<br />

the government should have let employers hire<br />

and fire as they see fit than afterwards. After<br />

the deliberation, the percentage of those<br />

who thought that government should make it<br />

very difficult for employers to fire increased by<br />

10 percent. The author believes this change<br />

occured because people often talked about the<br />

importance of keeping their jobs during the<br />

deliberation.<br />

Table 33 shows which social-demographic<br />

variables have significant effects on choosing<br />

one of the statements in the logistic regression<br />

model.<br />

page 177


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 33. Determinants of the probability of supporting regulation versus deregulation<br />

of labor market in logistic regression model (Q5)<br />

All<br />

N=1462 (1514)<br />

Pre- Deliberative Poll<br />

N=108<br />

Post- Deliberative Poll<br />

N=107<br />

Independent Variables B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B)<br />

Gender (Women) .164 .143 1.178 1.333 .017 3.791 .316 .547 1.371<br />

Level of education* .036 .017 .028<br />

Vocational school .081 .590 1.084 .828 .247 2.289 -.302 .676 .739<br />

Completed Secondary<br />

General School<br />

Tertiary Degree<br />

(BA or MA)<br />

.121 .443 1.129 -.982 .153 .375 -1.209 .085 .298<br />

-.406 .055 .666 -1.770 .062 .170 -2.656 .006 .070<br />

Employment status** .002 .375 .862<br />

Working full-time -.294 .117 .746 .064 .924 1.066 .532 .430 1.703<br />

Not working:<br />

Unemploymen<br />

.264 .275 1.302 .177 .807 1.194 .492 .511 1.636<br />

Not working: any<br />

other reason 5 -.676 .008 .509 -1.726 .129 .178 .667 .607 1.948<br />

Using Internet (Yes=1) -.392 .007 .676 -.845 .158 .430 -.689 .232 .502<br />

Speaking foreign<br />

language (Yes=1)<br />

-.180 .209 .835 .231 .730 1.260 .066 .919 1.068<br />

Age Group *** .025 .261 .730<br />

30-55 -.392 .034 .676 -.962 .378 .382 -.413 .694 .662<br />

Over 55 -.643 .007 .526 1.813 .177 6.126 .023 .985 1.023<br />

Constant .766 .004 2.151 .397 .788 1.487 1.436 .270 4.203<br />

-2Log Likelihood. initial 2025.052 144.342 140.375<br />

-2Log Likelihood. model 1969.174 111.641 115.320<br />

Model Chi-square 55.878 32.701 25.054<br />

Degree of freedom 11 11 11<br />

Significance 0.00 0.01 0.021<br />

Nagelkerke R Square 0.050 0.337 0.259<br />

page 178<br />

*Reference Category=Maximum Completed Primary School; **Reference category= Not working: Retired permanent<br />

job; ***Reference Category=under 30<br />

Recoding of variables: Values between 1 and 6 were recoded into 0. Value 7 was recoded into 1 in order to apply the<br />

recoded variable as a dependent variable in the logistic regression model. 6


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

The first observation to be made from the table<br />

above is that much more dependent variables<br />

have significant effects in the representative<br />

survey than in the small groups. Those holding<br />

a tertiary degree prefer the liberalization<br />

of the labor market in comparison to the<br />

reference groups in each of the sessions. In<br />

the representative sample, using internet has<br />

the same effect as holding a tertiary degree. It<br />

seems that those who have more cultural capital<br />

are more likely to support the de-regularization<br />

of the labor market. This finding corresponds<br />

to our expectations. Surprisingly, most of<br />

the oldest age group (over 55) supports the<br />

liberalization of the labor market. The author<br />

supposes the explanation may be that the<br />

labor market status of the youngest age group<br />

(under 30) is the most uncertain. They might<br />

not have obtained enough experience due to<br />

their age. The members of the oldest age group<br />

must be retired, so they do not take any risk<br />

if they support the liberalization of the labor<br />

market. The same mechanism can be found<br />

behind the fact that those who are not working<br />

for some other reason (mostly students or<br />

people on maternity leave) mostly support the<br />

liberalization of the labor market.<br />

In the pre-deliberation groups, there are two<br />

significant variables: gender and educational<br />

level. Women seem to object to liberalization<br />

as compared to men. As for educational level:<br />

highly-educated people prefer liberalization<br />

compared to the reference group.<br />

In the post-deliberation groups, the only<br />

variable found to be significant was educational<br />

level: those who completed higher education<br />

support liberalization of the labor market most.<br />

2.5. One’s own responsibility to get a job<br />

versus the state should provide jobs for every<br />

citizen<br />

This question refers to the role of the state<br />

similar to the previous one. Respondents had<br />

to express to what extent they agree with the<br />

given statement on a seven degree scale. The<br />

first degree signifies that the respondent totally<br />

agrees with the following statement: ‘Finding<br />

a job is one’s own responsibility’. The seventh<br />

degree indicates that a person completely agrees<br />

with the following statement: ‘Providing jobs<br />

for all citizens is the government’s responsibility’.<br />

The results of each survey session are shown<br />

in Table 34.<br />

page 179


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 34. What do people think: finding a job is one’s own responsibility or<br />

the government should provide jobs for all citizens? Measured on a 7 degree scale<br />

1-7 degree<br />

scale %<br />

In the survey<br />

research<br />

Pre-deliberation<br />

in the small groups<br />

Post-deliberation<br />

in the small groups<br />

Finding a job is one’s<br />

own responsibility. (1-3)<br />

The middle of the<br />

scale (4)<br />

Providing jobs for all<br />

citizens is the government’s<br />

responsibility. (5-7)<br />

Mean<br />

32.9% 31.5% 35.6% 4.0596<br />

33.9% 26.6% 39.4% 4.0917<br />

46.2% 33.6% 20.2% 3.2920<br />

T1 – T2 Statistically not significant change (t=0.656, p>0.05) T2 –T3 Statistically significant change (t=3.689, p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Table 35. Determinants of the probability of considering it one’s own responsibility to<br />

find a job versus the sate has to ensure jobs (responsibility for finding a job Q9)<br />

All<br />

N=1485 (1520)<br />

Pre- Deliberative Poll<br />

N=108<br />

Post- Deliberative Poll<br />

N=112<br />

Independent Variables B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B)<br />

Gender (Men=1) .357 .002 1.429 .940 .055 2.560 -.203 .722 .816<br />

Level of education* .080 .176 .072<br />

Vocational school -.005 .975 .995 -.251 .672 .778 -.852 .197 .427<br />

Completed Secondary<br />

General School<br />

Tertiary degree<br />

(BA or MA)<br />

-.144 .366 .866 -1.271 .048 .280 -1.568 .041 .209<br />

-.562 .015 .570 -.165 .841 .848 -2.939 .020 .053<br />

Employment status** .408 .106 .894<br />

Working full-time .017 .931 1.017 -.456 .468 .634 -.328 .674 .721<br />

Not working:<br />

Unemployment<br />

.325 .176 1.384 .841 .201 2.318 .043 .956 1.044<br />

Not working: any<br />

other reason 7 .176 .497 1.192 -1.344 .218 .261 .530 .677 1.699<br />

Using Internet (No=1) -.421 .006 .657 .483 .386 1.620 1.198 .077 3.312<br />

Speaking foreign<br />

language (No=1)<br />

.000 1.000 1.000 -.083 .895 .921 -.750 .375 .472<br />

Age Group **** .653 .680 .226<br />

30-55 -.167 .375 .846 .567 .575 1.763 1.732 .154 5.652<br />

Over 55 -.190 .437 .827 .167 .883 1.182 1.028 .459 2.796<br />

Constant -.449 .101 .638 -.886 .455 .412 -1.812 .209 .163<br />

-2Log Likelihood. initial 1934.116 145.207 114.310<br />

-2Log Likelihood. model 1885.644 131.817 98.572<br />

Model Chi-square 47.198 13.390 15.162<br />

Degree of freedom 11 11 11<br />

Significance 0.00 .269 .175<br />

Nagelkerke R Square .043 .158 .199<br />

*Reference Category=Maximum Completed Primary School; **Reference category= Not working: Retired permanent job;<br />

***Reference Category=under 30<br />

Recoding of variables: Values between 1 and 4 were recoded into 0. Values between 5 and 7 were recoded into 1 in order<br />

to apply the recoded variable as a dependent variable in the logistic regression model. 8<br />

page 181


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Women are more likely to think that providing<br />

jobs for all citizens is the government’s<br />

responsibility in both the representative sample<br />

and the pre-deliberation group. However,<br />

in the post-deliberation session, the effect of<br />

gender disappeared: agreeing with the statement<br />

that it is the individuals’ responsibility<br />

to find a job is independent of gender in the<br />

post-deliberation group.<br />

The effect of educational background was<br />

almost constant, which means that those who<br />

have a higher level of education emphasize<br />

more the responsibility of the individual in<br />

finding jobs than the reference group in each of<br />

the sections. Those who use the internet tend<br />

to agree with the statement that ‘Finding a<br />

job is one’s own responsibility’ than those who<br />

do not use the internet in the representative<br />

sample and the post deliberation group. These<br />

results confirmed our first hypotheses: those<br />

who are in a favorable position are more<br />

likely to support the liberalization of the labor<br />

market.<br />

2.6. Unemployment cannot be avoided versus<br />

it should be avoided at any cost<br />

We will now discuss what people think about<br />

unemployment; respondents were asked to<br />

tell how much they agree with the given<br />

statements on a 7 degree scale. One indicates<br />

that the respondent totally agrees with the<br />

following statement: Unemployment cannot<br />

be avoided totally. Seven means that the<br />

respondent totally agrees with the following<br />

statement: Unemployment should be avoided at<br />

any cost. The other degrees show the relation<br />

to the statements. The results of each round are<br />

shown in Table 36.<br />

Table 36. What do people think: unemployment cannot be totally avoided<br />

vs. unemployment should be avoided at any cost? Measured on a 7 degree scale<br />

1-7 degree<br />

scale %<br />

Unemployment cannot<br />

be avoided totally. (1-3)<br />

The middle of the<br />

scale (4)<br />

Unemployment should be<br />

avoided at any cost. (5-7)<br />

Mean<br />

In the survey<br />

research<br />

Pre-deliberation in<br />

the small groups<br />

Post-deliberation in<br />

the small groups<br />

37% 18.7% 44.3% 4.17<br />

37% 15.7% 47.2% 4.15<br />

49.6% 13.7% 36.8% 3.52<br />

T1 – T2: Statistically not significant change (t=1.004, p>0.05) T2 – T3: Statistically significant change (t=2.021, p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

This is an important question, because<br />

people’s lives have been organized by work in<br />

industrialized societies. However, substantial<br />

changes have taken place in many ways.<br />

According to Claus Offe (1991), the developed<br />

countries have entered a new stage of the<br />

economy, where the growth of the economy<br />

does not mean that everybody has work. The<br />

forms of flexible work are spreading (parttime,<br />

temporary contracts, self-employment),<br />

which predicts that the essence of life should<br />

not be work. It seems that deliberation helped<br />

participants to understand that we have<br />

to live together with the phenomenon of<br />

unemployment.<br />

Table 37 presents which social-demographic<br />

variables have significant effects on choosing<br />

one of the statements using the logistic<br />

regression model.<br />

page 183


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 37. Determinants of the probability of thinking whether the<br />

unemployment can be dissolved or not (Q17)<br />

All<br />

N=1484 (1520)<br />

Pre- Deliberative Poll<br />

N=107<br />

Post- Deliberative Poll<br />

N=111<br />

Independent Variables B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B)<br />

Gender (Men=1) .248 .026 1.281 .867 .070 2.380 .363 .441 1.438<br />

Level of education* .366 .361 .668<br />

Vocational school .250 .090 1.285 -.554 .368 .575 -.227 .706 .797<br />

Completed Secondary<br />

General School<br />

Tertiary degree<br />

(BA or MA)<br />

.106 .492 1.112 -1.111 .083 .329 -.540 .394 .582<br />

.032 .878 1.033 -1.085 .206 .338 -1.004 .236 .366<br />

Employment status** .649 .911 .139<br />

Working full-time -.197 .291 .822 .263 .662 1.301 1.221 .048 3.390<br />

Not working:<br />

Unemployment<br />

-.156 .505 .856 .267 .690 1.306 .212 .760 1.236<br />

Not working: any<br />

other reason 9 -.017 .948 .984 -.331 .760 .718 1.667 .165 5.298<br />

Using Internet (No=1) -.153 .287 .858 .187 .738 1.206 .603 .300 1.827<br />

Speaking foreign<br />

language (No=1)<br />

-.443 .002 .642 -1.251 .069 .286 -1.043 .130 .353<br />

Age Group **** .197 .112 .220<br />

30-55 -.289 .110 .749 -1.997 .066 .136 1.687 .157 5.405<br />

Over 55 -.396 .092 .673 -1.417 .242 .242 2.244 .086 9.430<br />

Constant .078 .767 1.081 1.784 .170 5.956 -2.688 .045 .068<br />

-2Log Likelihood. initial 2037.744 148.100 147.247<br />

-2Log Likelihood. model 2007.478 130.776 131.785<br />

Model Chi-square 30.165 15.832 15.460<br />

Degree of freedom 11 11 11<br />

Significance .001 .148 .162<br />

Nagelkerke R Square .027 .184 .177<br />

page 184<br />

*Reference Category=Maximum Completed Primary School; **Reference category= Not working: Retired<br />

permanent job; ***Reference Category=under 30<br />

Recoding of variables: Values between 1 and 4 were recoded into 0. Values between 5 and 7 were recoded into 1 in order<br />

to apply the recoded variable as a dependent variable in the logistic regression model. 10


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Gender has a significant effect on both the<br />

representative sample and the pre-deliberation<br />

group. After deliberation the gender-effect<br />

disappeared. The educational background<br />

influenced the answers of respondents in T1<br />

and T2. Those who completed vocational school<br />

are the most likely to agree with the statement<br />

‘Unemployment should be avoided at any cost’<br />

than the reference group in the representative<br />

sample. While those who completed secondary<br />

school are less likely to agree with the statement<br />

‘Unemployment cannot be totally avoided’ than<br />

the reference group in the pre-deliberation<br />

group. Nevertheless, the educational effect<br />

also vanishes in the post-deliberation group.<br />

At the same time, employment status has a<br />

significant effect only on the post-deliberation<br />

group: those who are working full-time are<br />

more than three times as likely to think that<br />

‘Unemployment cannot be avoided totally’<br />

than the reference group.<br />

Those who speak a foreign language are more<br />

likely to believe that unemployment cannot be<br />

totally avoided than those who do not speak<br />

a foreign language in T1 and T2. However,<br />

this difference also disappears in T3. The age<br />

variable has a significant effect on the small<br />

groups: those between 30-55 years are most<br />

likely to think that unemployment cannot be<br />

avoided in T2, while those over 55 are most<br />

likely to believe that unemployment should be<br />

avoided in T3. These results also verify our first<br />

hypotheses.<br />

2.7. Employment policies<br />

Employment policies are regulatory activities<br />

of the state to tackle unemployment.<br />

Theoretically, employment policies are usually<br />

divided into two groups: active employment<br />

policies and passive employment policies. The<br />

aim of passive employment policies is to take<br />

care of people who lost their jobs. On the<br />

contrary, the intention of active employment<br />

policies is to help the unemployed find a job.<br />

First, we examined whether the theoretical<br />

structure of employment policies (active<br />

and passive) exists in the minds of people in<br />

the representative survey. In the T1 and T2<br />

interview sessions, factor analyses did not<br />

suggest that the theoretical structure could be<br />

found in the minds of participants. However,<br />

we found a factor structure (active and passive<br />

employment policies) in the post-deliberative<br />

session. We think that the existence of<br />

theoretical structure in the post-deliberation<br />

session is due to the fact that the moderators<br />

aggregated the employment policies several<br />

times during the deliberation, so people<br />

learn of the employment policies during the<br />

deliberation. The results of T3 interview are<br />

shown in Table 38.<br />

page 185


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 38. The grouping of the employment policies in the post-deliberation group<br />

How strongly would you favor or<br />

oppose each of the following as ways<br />

of dealing with unemployment?<br />

Active Policies<br />

Factors<br />

Passive Policies<br />

Labor market services<br />

.681<br />

.055<br />

Training support<br />

.834<br />

.002<br />

Wage-and contribution-type subsidies 11<br />

.555<br />

.317<br />

Support for self-employment<br />

.282<br />

.162<br />

Job search allowance and benefit<br />

.111<br />

.777<br />

Regular social aid<br />

.149<br />

.879<br />

Maximum Likelihood factor analyses, with Varimax rotation<br />

KMO indicator value:0.650,<br />

Bartlett test value: 144.975; Sig.:0.00<br />

This question was measured by on a 5 degree scale where the first degree means oppose it strongly and fifth degree<br />

means favor it strongly.<br />

We can see that there are two factors in table<br />

38. The first includes the following items:<br />

labor market services, training support, and<br />

support for self-employment. The mentioned<br />

policies belong to the active employment<br />

policies, so we call this factor Active Policies.<br />

The second factor includes the following<br />

items: job search allowance, benefit and regular<br />

social aid. The two mentioned items belong to<br />

the passive employment policies, so we called<br />

this factor Passive Policies. Table 39 presents<br />

which social-demographic groups prefer the<br />

applying of the active and the passive policies.<br />

page 186


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Table 39. Effects of dependent variables on choosing between active and passive employment policies<br />

Independent variables<br />

Gender<br />

Mean of the Active employment<br />

policies in the postdeliberation<br />

session<br />

Mean of the Passive employment<br />

policies in the postdeliberation<br />

session<br />

Men .0160243* -.0745066*<br />

Women -.0121785* .0566250*<br />

Age group<br />

Under 30 .0458470 .6137456<br />

30-55 .1489792 .1232090<br />

Over 55 -.1593003 -.2025254<br />

Educational level<br />

Max. completed primary schools -.1194293 .1172068<br />

Vocational school .1568382 .0234950<br />

Grammar school .0346563 .0869121<br />

Tertiary school -.3193728 -.4701077<br />

Employment status<br />

Having a job -.0882782 .0252327*<br />

Unemployed .2053722 .5046878*<br />

Retired -.0731706 -.2320810*<br />

Not working for any other reason .2923586 .1865640*<br />

Using internet<br />

Yes .1209967 -.0440701<br />

No -.0772680 .0055342<br />

Speaking a foreign language<br />

Yes .1914047 .0547550<br />

No -.0415927 -.0183208<br />

*Statistically significant change ( p


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

active policies than women, while women<br />

are more likely to support the passive policies<br />

than men. The results supported the second<br />

hypotheses.<br />

2.8. Liquidation vs. toleration of illegal<br />

work 12<br />

If the labor market is regulated too rigidly<br />

and the cost of hiring or laying off is too<br />

high while the supervision of the labor market<br />

is weak, some people will be employed<br />

without paying taxes. The issue of illegal<br />

work is extremely relevant in Hungary, as the<br />

main problem is not the high unemployment<br />

rate, but the low activity rate (the number of<br />

legally employed people). With its 53.7%<br />

activity rate among 15-64 year olds, Hungary<br />

is lagging behind the EU members, where the<br />

mean activity rate is 64.5%.<br />

The following question concerns what<br />

people think of illegal work. This question<br />

was measured on a seven degree scale. One<br />

indicates that the respondent strongly agrees<br />

with the following statement: ‘Government<br />

should prevent all illegal work’. Seven means the<br />

respondent strongly agrees with the following<br />

statement: ‘Government should not do anything<br />

against illegal work’. The results of each<br />

questioning session are shown in Table 40.<br />

Table 40. What do people think: government should prevent all illegal<br />

work vs. government should not do anything against illegal work? Measured on a 7 degree scale<br />

1-7 degree<br />

scale %<br />

Government should<br />

prevent all illegal work<br />

(1-3)<br />

The middle of the<br />

scale (4)<br />

Government should not do<br />

anything against<br />

illegal work (5-7)<br />

Mean<br />

In the survey<br />

research<br />

Pre-deliberation<br />

in the small groups<br />

Post-deliberation in<br />

the small groups<br />

61.8% 18.3% 19.8% 2.78<br />

65.4% 20.2% 14.4% 2.61<br />

64.6% 20.4% 15% 2.57<br />

T1 – T2: Statistically not significant change (t=-0.932, p>0.05)<br />

T2 – T3: Statistically not significant change (t=0.292, p>0.05)<br />

The deliberation did not bring any<br />

page 188 significant change in this issue, as<br />

we can see in table 40. In all three<br />

sessions, more than 60% of the people<br />

said that the government should prevent all<br />

illegal work, while less than 20% declared that<br />

the government should not do anything against<br />

illegal work. Table 41 shows which socialdemographic<br />

variables have significant effects<br />

on choosing one of the statements.


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Table 41. Determinants of the probability of agreeing with ‘Government<br />

should prevent all illegal work’ vs. ‘Government should no do anything against illegal work’.<br />

All<br />

N=1455 (1520)<br />

Pre -Deliberative Poll<br />

N=103<br />

Post -Deliberative Poll<br />

N=107<br />

Independent Variables B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B)<br />

Gender (Men=1) .132 .241 1.141 -.401 .411 .670 .093 .845 1.098<br />

Level of education* .019 .890 .270<br />

Vocational school .368 .014 1.445 -.457 .453 .633 -.286 .646 .751<br />

Completed Secondary<br />

General School<br />

Tertiary degree<br />

(BA or MA)<br />

-.026 .871 .975 -.179 .779 .836 .502 .430 1.652<br />

-.108 .612 .898 -.391 .646 .677 -.854 .329 .426<br />

Employment status** .370 .227 .170<br />

Working in full time .206 .273 1.229 -1.184 .079 .306 -.599 .358 .549<br />

Not working:<br />

Unemployment<br />

.415 .077 1.515 -.287 .675 .751 .787 .246 2.196<br />

Not working: any<br />

other reason 13 .188 .462 1.207 .352 .741 1.422 1.160 .326 3.190<br />

Using Internet (No=1) -.091 .533 .913 .836 .144 2.306 .332 .563 1.393<br />

Speaking foreign<br />

language (No=1)<br />

.059 .681 1.061 -1.358 .044 .257 -.582 .363 .559<br />

Age Group **** .013 .515 .106<br />

30-55 -.462 .011 .630 -.311 .734 .733 -2.286 .061 .102<br />

Over 55 -.656 .005 .519 -.966 .367 .381 -1.596 .221 .203<br />

Constant -.050 .851 .951 .980 .378 2.664 1.397 .284 4.044<br />

-2Log Likelihood. initial 1996.915 139.264 145.621<br />

-2Log Likelihood. model 1952.339 128.509 128.070<br />

Model Chi-square 44.576 10.755 17.551<br />

Degree of freedom 11 11 11<br />

Significance .000 .464 .093<br />

Nagelkerke R Square .040 .134 .203<br />

*Reference Category=Maximum Completed Primary School; **Reference category= Not working: Retired<br />

permanent job; ***Reference Category=under 30<br />

Recoding of variables: Values between 1 and 3 were recoded into 0. Values between 4 and 7 were recoded into 1 in order<br />

to apply the recoded variable as a dependent variable in the logistic regression model. 14<br />

page 189


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

The first observation to be made from the<br />

table above is that gender does not influence<br />

the answers of the participants in any interview<br />

period. Educational background, however, had<br />

a significant effect in T1 period: those who<br />

completed vocational school are more likely<br />

to agree with the statement ‘Government<br />

should no do anything against illegal work’<br />

than the reference group. Employment status<br />

influenced answers in the T1 and T2 periods:<br />

the unemployed are more likely to agree<br />

with the statement ‘Government should not<br />

do anything against illegal work’ than the<br />

reference group. While those who are working<br />

full- time are more likely to agree with the<br />

statement ‘Government should prevent all<br />

illegal work’ than the reference group. The<br />

effect of the employment status disappears in<br />

the T3 session.<br />

Regarding age, those over 55 are more likely to<br />

agree with the statement ‘Government should<br />

prevent all illegal work’ than young people in<br />

the representative sample.<br />

We can notice that fewer variables have a<br />

significant effect in the small groups than in the<br />

representative sample. In the pre-deliberation<br />

session, only full-time work and the knowledge<br />

of a foreign language have significant effects<br />

on the dependent variables. Those who speak a<br />

foreign language are more likely to agree with<br />

the statement ‘Government should<br />

prevent all illegal work’ than those<br />

page 190 who do not speak a foreign language.<br />

In the post- deliberation group, only<br />

the 30-55 age group has a significant<br />

effect: they are more likely to agree with the<br />

statement ‘Government should prevent all<br />

illegal work’ than the reference group. The third<br />

hypothesis has been confirmed by these results.<br />

We can draw the conclusion that working<br />

illegally is a defensive strategy of people whose<br />

status is unfavorable in the Hungarian society.<br />

2.9. Government should cut taxes versus<br />

spend more on education, health care and<br />

pensions<br />

Hungary is among the countries where the tax<br />

rates are high. Tax awareness is very low and<br />

people do not know much about the tax system.<br />

In addition, voters in Hungary falsely perceive<br />

the state role in the social sector and the cost<br />

of state programs (Csontos, Kornai, & Tóth,<br />

1996). For example, the majority of people<br />

underestimate the cost of pensions and medical<br />

services, while they overestimate the cost of<br />

social benefits. Sometimes they do perceive the<br />

relationship between social benefits and the<br />

tax rate. This question examined what people<br />

think the government should do: decrease taxes<br />

or spend more on education, health care and<br />

pensions. The respondents were asked to what<br />

extent they agree with the given statement on<br />

a seven degree scale. One indicates that the<br />

respondent totally agrees with the following<br />

statement: Government should decrease taxes even<br />

if this means less funding for education, health care<br />

and pension. Seven means that one totally agrees<br />

with the following statement: Government<br />

should spend more on education, health care and<br />

pension. The results of each questioning session<br />

are shown in Table 42.


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

Table 42. What do people think: Government should cut taxes vs. Government<br />

should no spend more on education, health care and pension? Measured on a 7 degree scale.<br />

1-7 degree<br />

scale %<br />

Government should<br />

decrease taxes even if this<br />

means less funding for education,<br />

health care and pension. (1-3)<br />

The middle of<br />

the scale (4)<br />

Government should spend<br />

more on education, health<br />

care and pension. (5-7)<br />

Mean<br />

In the survey<br />

research<br />

Pre-deliberation<br />

in the small groups<br />

Post-deliberation<br />

in the small groups<br />

39.2% 34.9% 25.9%<br />

3.61<br />

30.5% 34.3% 35.2%<br />

4.14<br />

29.8% 35.6% 34.6% 4.14<br />

T1 – T2: Statistically significant change (t=-2.717, p0.05)<br />

Table 42 proves that there are significant<br />

differences between the T1 and T2 sessions.<br />

Deliberation did not bring significant changes<br />

in this issue, as we can see in table 42. Both in<br />

the pre- and post- deliberation small groups,<br />

around 30% of respondents prefered decreased<br />

taxes, even if this means less funding for<br />

education, health care and pensions. On the<br />

other hand, 35% declared that the government<br />

should spend more on education, health care<br />

and pension. It is surprising that the deliberation<br />

did not bring any significant changes, because<br />

the most important result of earlier research<br />

on the tax awareness (Csontos, Kornai, &<br />

Tóth, 1996) was that if the citizens know<br />

more about the cost of the state programs they<br />

will change their opinion about the role of<br />

the state, subsequently prefering to decrease<br />

the role of the state and emphasizing more the<br />

role of the market.<br />

The differences between T1 and T2 might<br />

be due to the composition effect and/or the<br />

briefing materials. The composition effect can<br />

be excluded by focusing the analyses on those<br />

people who took part in the small group conversation<br />

(Table 43). In Table 43 the component<br />

effect has been excluded because answers<br />

of the same people can be found there. Still,<br />

the significant differences between T1 and T2<br />

remain. Consequently, it is assumed that the<br />

variance is caused by the briefing materials.<br />

page 191


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Table 43. What do people think: government should cut taxes vs. government should no spend more<br />

on education, health care and pension? Measured on a 7 degree scale.<br />

(Focusing only those who participated in small groups as well)<br />

1-7 degree<br />

scale %<br />

Government should<br />

decrease taxes even if this means<br />

less funding for education, health<br />

care and pension. (1-3)<br />

The middle of<br />

the scale (4)<br />

Government should spend<br />

more on education, health<br />

care and pension. (5-7)<br />

Mean<br />

In the survey<br />

research<br />

Pre-deliberation<br />

in the small groups<br />

46.2% 27.4% 26.4% 3.36<br />

29.4% 35.3% 36.4% 4.16<br />

T1 – T2: Statistically significant change (t=-2.826, p


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

All<br />

N=1416 (1520)<br />

Pre- Deliberative Poll<br />

N=104<br />

Post- Deliberative Poll<br />

N=102<br />

Independent Variables B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B) B Sig. Exp(B)<br />

Gender (Men=1) .205 .112 1.228 .852 .146 2.344 1.079 .058 2.943<br />

Level of education* .321 .019 .031<br />

Vocational school -.283 .101 .753 -.554 .436 .575 .494 .455 1.640<br />

Completed Secondary<br />

General School<br />

Tertiary degree<br />

(BA or MA)<br />

-.087 .622 .917 -2.498 .003 .082 -1.702 .026 .182<br />

.049 .834 1.050 -1.801 .066 .165 -.552 .544 .576<br />

Employment status** .544 .095 .136<br />

Working full-time -.289 .178 .749 .171 .795 1.186 .549 .394 1.731<br />

Not working:<br />

Unemployment<br />

-.280 .307 .756 -2.614 .023 .073 -1.591 .080 .204<br />

Not working: any<br />

other reason 15 -.357 .221 .700 .517 .679 1.677 -.295 .798 .744<br />

Using Internet (No=1) .018 .915 1.018 -.040 .953 .960 -.380 .548 .684<br />

Speaking foreign<br />

language (No=1)<br />

Table 44. Determinants of the probability of agreeing with<br />

‘Government should decrease the taxes versus should increase the tax’ (Q19)<br />

-.003 .985 .997 -.474 .569 .623 .<strong>580</strong> .421 1.786<br />

Age Group **** .340 .423 .262<br />

30-55 -.295 .157 .745 .613 .649 1.845 -1.002 .352 .367<br />

Over 55 -.170 .525 .844 1.386 .336 3.999 -.084 .944 .920<br />

Constant -.709 .018 .492 -.638 .648 .529 -.280 .816 .756<br />

-2Log Likelihood. initial 1624.609 134.177 131.202<br />

-2Log Likelihood. model 1604.400 100.998 108.788<br />

Model Chi-square 18,163 33.628 22.404<br />

Degree of freedom 11 11 11<br />

Significance .078 .000 .021<br />

Nagelkerke R Square .019 .381 .272<br />

*Reference Category=Maximum Completed Primary School; **Reference category= Not working: Retired<br />

permanent job; ***Reference Category=under 30<br />

Recoding of variables: Values between 1 and 3 were recoded into 0. Values between 4 and 7 were recoded into 1 in order to<br />

apply the recoded variable as a dependent variable in the logistic regression model. 16<br />

page 193


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

Astonishingly, none of the independent<br />

variables have a significant effect on the<br />

representative sample. In the small group,<br />

almost the same variable has a significant<br />

effect: those who completed secondary general<br />

school tend to think that the government<br />

should decrease taxes in comparison with<br />

reference group. The unemployed are more<br />

likely to agree that the government should<br />

decrease taxes than the reference group. In<br />

the post-deliberation session, gender also has<br />

a significant effect: women are more likely to<br />

agree with the statement ‘Government should<br />

spend more on education, health care and<br />

pension’ than men.<br />

2.10. A Qualitative Analysis<br />

We conducted a qualitative analysis based on<br />

conversations in two groups 17 (groups 10 and<br />

14). There were 4 pensioners, 1 employee and<br />

1 student in group 10. As for the gender ratio,<br />

there were 2 men and 4 women. In group<br />

14, there were 1 unemployed, 1 mother on<br />

maternity leave, 1 employee, 2 pensioners and<br />

1 disabled pensioners. Of these participants, 1<br />

was male and 5 female.<br />

In group 14, the moderator asked participants<br />

directly how the state regulated the labor<br />

market and whether they preferred a strong<br />

or weak state influence on the labor market.<br />

It seems that participants are aware of<br />

the fact that a strong state influence<br />

page 194 restricts the labor market, while a<br />

weak state influence makes employees<br />

defenseless. The participants believe<br />

that role of the state should be somewhere in<br />

between. They also understand the operation<br />

of the tax system. In both groups there are<br />

some people who are against the high tax rate,<br />

which makes the situation of the entrepreneurs<br />

difficult: ‘There are a lot of forced entrepreneurs<br />

who are almost up to their neck in taxes. Less<br />

tax should be imposed’ (group 10). At the same<br />

time, they realize that the missing amount<br />

should be supplied from other sources: ‘The<br />

state has to take money from somewhere in<br />

order to decrease the tax rate; money must be<br />

taken from where it is wasted’ (Group 14).<br />

Participants emphasized job security, which<br />

they miss on many levels. First of all in the<br />

training: People should be trained (given such a<br />

profession) so that they can also find a job in 5 to<br />

10 years (Group 10). At the same time, they<br />

speak a lot about life-long learning, meaning<br />

that people must continually invest in their<br />

human capital in order to stay competitive on<br />

the labor market.<br />

The expectation that people gain knowledge<br />

in public schools, which will guarantee them<br />

fa job decades after they left school without<br />

a need to obtain new skills or qualifications<br />

continually required by the labor market is not<br />

realistic. This is shown by the fact that, among<br />

less educated people, the activity rate is very<br />

low, since the skills required by the labor market<br />

(for example, readiness to study) are missing.<br />

The following example is the reaction of an<br />

unemployed woman in group 14 who was asked<br />

if she attended a retraining program supported<br />

by the job center. Her answer was: „I have not<br />

learned for 30 years; I am afraid I might not be able<br />

to”. The negative opinion about training and<br />

education makes the situation even worse. They<br />

believe it is not worth learning and obtaining<br />

a higher education level, since the situation of<br />

highly educated people is even more difficult:


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

„Even those who have qualifications cannot get a<br />

job. Even more people with more than one degree<br />

are not wanted by the labor market” (group 10).<br />

We are past the society of work (Offe, 1991;<br />

Beck, 1999), which means that it is not<br />

guaranteed that everybody can find a job.<br />

Therefore, we do not let individuals to judged<br />

by their work. We should not let the society<br />

be split in two parts: the majority, who has a<br />

job according to the traditional norms, and the<br />

remarkable minority, which is out of the labor<br />

market. Although, the participants value work,<br />

as they regard it as the essence of life: ‘It is not<br />

good if people live without work and they do not<br />

have job opportunities” (group 14).<br />

They miss the security of workplaces: ‘The<br />

employers get support if they employ unemployed<br />

people, but they will just employ them until they<br />

get the support, then they are going to fire them.<br />

It is not worth doing this procedure. The employers<br />

will not invest anything in their skills. Why do<br />

employees train themselves? This is not a longterm,calculable<br />

job opportunity. The employers<br />

should employ the employees for at least 5 years, so<br />

the employees would be secure for at least 5 years,<br />

in this case they would be able to plan” (group<br />

10). The only solution for people to find or<br />

keep their jobs is to be ready to adapt to the<br />

new situations (job, position and environment<br />

changing). Project work is spreading, which<br />

means that employees get temporary job<br />

contracts. Yet, it seems that most of the people<br />

are not yet ready for flexible employment.<br />

The participants are not against illegal work.<br />

Even more, they commiserate with illegal<br />

workers: ‘People accept illegal jobs, because they<br />

have to live on something” (group 10). At the<br />

same time, they do not feel the same solidarity<br />

with the employers. They believe employers<br />

are the beneficiaries of illegal work by tax<br />

evasion: ‘Employers are always searching for<br />

loopholes. You (employee) are defenseless, but<br />

you have to undertake this game” (group 14).<br />

They emphasize that the defenseless position<br />

forces employees to accept illegal work: ‘You<br />

know this is not correct but you do not have any<br />

other choice” (group 14). In accordance with<br />

quantitative analysis, we can find that people<br />

who are in unfavorable position in society use<br />

the illegal sector.<br />

3. SUMMARY<br />

In the deliberative analysis, the first hypothesis<br />

was partly supported. Those who posses more<br />

cultural capital (higher education, access<br />

to internet) are more likely to support the<br />

deregulation of the labor market. Concerning<br />

educational level, those who completed<br />

tertiary school are more likely to agree<br />

with the deregulation of the labor market<br />

than the less educated people. Educational<br />

background had a significant effect in each of<br />

the sections. Those who use internet prefer the<br />

liberalization of the labor market in T1. The<br />

fact that older people are more likely to agree<br />

with the liberalization of the labor market<br />

than the young is exactly the opposite of what<br />

we had expected. We believe that this<br />

is due to the fact that those who are<br />

over 55 are mostly out of the labor<br />

page 195<br />

market. Thus, if the labor market was<br />

more deregulated than it is today, it<br />

would not mean any uncertainty for them, but<br />

would mean uncertainty for people in their<br />

active age. As for the employment status, I


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

page 196<br />

could show that the unemployed demanded<br />

the regulation of the labor market. The effect<br />

of gender and the ability to speak a foreign<br />

language were not significant.<br />

Our hypothesis concerning employment<br />

policies was also partly supported. We could<br />

find the theoretical structure in the postdeliberation<br />

group. We also showed that<br />

women and unemployed people are more likely<br />

to support passive employment policies than<br />

men and those who are on the labor market. We<br />

assumed that people over 55 support passive<br />

employment policies. It has been revealed<br />

that people over 55 oppose both employment<br />

policies. Pensioners are the ones who oppose<br />

passive employment policies the most. One<br />

explanation can be that they might be afraid<br />

that greater support for the unemployed may<br />

decrease their benefits. The effects of other<br />

independent variables (using the internet,<br />

speaking a foreign language, education level<br />

and age group) were not significant.<br />

Our hypothesis regarding illegal work was also<br />

supported. Regarding the effect of educational<br />

level, we found that those who completed<br />

vocational school are more tolerant regarding<br />

illegal work than other educational groups.<br />

The effect of other independent variables<br />

(using internet, speaking a foreign language,<br />

employment status) was not significant.<br />

However, we found that unemployed<br />

people are very tolerant towards<br />

illegal work, as we expected it in our<br />

hypotheses in the post-deliberation<br />

poll.<br />

Our fourth hypotheses was not entirely<br />

supported either. We found that pensioners do<br />

not want to cut taxes. Concerning educational<br />

level, we supposed that highly-educated people<br />

are most likely to want tax decreases. On the<br />

contrary, in the representative survey session<br />

we found that those who completed vocational<br />

school were most likely to be in favor of<br />

decreasing taxes. However, this tendency<br />

became non-significant in the post-deliberation<br />

session, while the effect of completed tertiary<br />

school became significant. They are more likely<br />

to be in favor of decreasing taxes. Surprisingly,<br />

those who do not use the internet are more<br />

likely to agree with the decrease of taxes<br />

than those who use the internet. The effects<br />

of other independent variables (speaking a<br />

foreign language, gender, age groups) were not<br />

significant.<br />

We can accept our last overall hypotheses, as<br />

we found that in the post-deliberation the<br />

opinions of the participants converged. For<br />

example, the effect of gender disappeared in<br />

the liberalization of the labor market issue and<br />

the effect of employment status disappeared in<br />

the tax rate issue. We obtained the same results<br />

from the qualitative analyses. We did not find<br />

any contradictions between the results of the<br />

qualitative and quantitative research.<br />

As a conclusion, based on the deliberative<br />

analysis perfomed in Hungary, we can see that<br />

– in a post-socialist country – the population<br />

would expect a patronizing state, but has little<br />

consideration about how the necessary funding<br />

can be secured for the preferred social measures.<br />

We have also learned that education or any<br />

kind of authentic and efficient information<br />

dissemination can help people understand<br />

interrelations between welfare measures and<br />

taxation, but can also generate a more plausible


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

picture of how governmental institutions work.<br />

A remarkable sociological research showed<br />

that people in Hungary considered the role<br />

of the state to be very important in the 1990s<br />

(Ferge, 1996).<br />

Based on our research, it is visible that this<br />

expectation still exists, not only in postsocialist<br />

Hungary, but also in the majority of<br />

the EU. It has also been shown that not every<br />

citizen expects the same level of state care and<br />

influence on markets. The current sociological<br />

research in Hungary shows that risk groups<br />

and individuals with less education require<br />

more state support: they would prefer greater<br />

state influence while putting less emphasis<br />

on the responsibility of the individuals. They<br />

expect the state to provide job opportunities<br />

and financial security (Utasi, 2008). On the<br />

European level, it has been shown that the<br />

majority of citizens prefer a strong social<br />

perspective in their country as well as tax<br />

decreases. Citizens with a higher education<br />

level believe in the efficiency of social measures<br />

to a greater extent as well as that businesses<br />

suffer on expenditures related to social services<br />

and benefits to a certain extent.<br />

page 197


ATTITUDES TOWARDS LABOUR MARKET<br />

REGULATION IN HUNGARY<br />

NOTES<br />

1<br />

I decided to use logistic regression instead of ordinal regression,<br />

because, while results do not differ substantially between the two<br />

methods, those of logistic regression are easier to interpret.<br />

12<br />

Illegal work means that taxes and social insurance are not<br />

paid.<br />

13 People in this category are mostly students or mothers on maternity<br />

leave.<br />

2<br />

Women’s position on the labour market is more uncertain than<br />

men because, when they have small children, they must be out<br />

of the labour market due to a lack of child care services and<br />

part-time jobs. Those who are over 50 belong to the risk group<br />

because employers prefer to employ younger people. Those who<br />

do not have enough cultural capital (do not use internet, do not<br />

speak any foreign language and are less educated) are also in<br />

unfavourable position on the labour market.<br />

3<br />

Measured by Paired Samples T-test.<br />

14<br />

The method of recoding was chosen according to the mean and<br />

distribution of the variable.<br />

15<br />

People in this category are mostly students or women on maternity<br />

leave.<br />

16<br />

The method of recoding was chosen according to the mean and<br />

the distribution of the variable.<br />

4<br />

Measured by Paired Samples T-test.<br />

17<br />

The author choose 10 th and 14 th groups for analysing.<br />

5<br />

People in this category are mostly students or women on maternity<br />

leave.<br />

6<br />

The method of recoding was chosen according to the mean and<br />

distribution of the variable.<br />

7<br />

People in this category are mostly students or women on maternity<br />

leave.<br />

8<br />

The method of recoding was chosen according to the mean and<br />

distribution of the variable.<br />

9<br />

People in this category are mostly students or mothers on maternity<br />

leave.<br />

page 198<br />

10<br />

The method of recoding was chosen according to<br />

the mean and distribution of the variable.<br />

11<br />

The only items that were part of both dimensions<br />

are wage and contribution subsidiaries. It can be assumed that<br />

participants were confused by the phrase.


SZALMA IVETT / SZEL BERNADETT<br />

REFERENCES<br />

Beck, Ulrich (1999) Túl renden és osztályon? [Beyond Class and<br />

States] In. Angelusz Róbert (szerk.): A társadalmi rétegződés<br />

komponensei. [The Components of Social Stratification] Új<br />

Mandátum Könyvkiadó, Budapest<br />

Csontos László – Kornai János – Tóth István György (1996)<br />

Adótudatosság és fiskális illúziók.[Tax-awareness and fiscal<br />

illusions] In. Társadalmi Riport 1996<br />

Dahrendorf (1994) A modern társadalmi konfliktus.[The Modern<br />

Social Conflict] Gondolat<br />

Kiadó, Budapest<br />

Spéder Zsolt (2002) A szegénység változó arcai. [The Changing<br />

Faces of Poverty] Századvég Kiadó, Budapest<br />

Summary of the Results – Deliberative Poll about Unemployment<br />

and Job Creation in the Area of Kaposvár, 2008<br />

Tomka Béla (2009): Jóléti államok az ezredfordulón: válságjelek<br />

vagy válságmítoszok? [Welfare States at the Turning Point<br />

of the Millennium: Signs of Crisis or Myths of Crisis?] Magyar<br />

Tudomány, 2009/02, pp.197.<br />

URL: http://www.matud.iif.hu/09feb/10.html<br />

Utasi Ágnes (2008) Éltető kapcsolatok. [Life-source relations]<br />

Új Mandátum Könyvkiadó, Budapest<br />

Ferge Zsuzsa (1996) A rendszerváltás megítélése. [The Perception<br />

of Transition] In. Szociológiai Szemle 1996/1.<br />

Girasek Edmond – Sík Endre (2006) Munkaerőpiac és<br />

informális jövedelem.[ Job market nad informal income] In.<br />

Társadalmi Riport 2006.<br />

Laky Teréz (2002) Munakerőpiaci tükör Magyarországn 2001-<br />

ben.[The Job Market in Hungary in 2001] In Fazekas Károly et.<br />

al. Munkaerőpiaci Tükör 2002.<br />

MTA Közgazdaságtdományi Kutatóközpont, Országos Foglalakozatási<br />

Közalapítvány, Budapest<br />

Offe, Claus (1991) A szociális állam és a foglalkoztatási válság:<br />

a biztosítás biztosításának problémái. In. Ferge Zs. – Lévai K.<br />

(szerk.): A jóléti állam. T – Twins Kiadó, Budapest<br />

Sági Matild (1997): Társadalmi folyamatok a rendszerváltás<br />

után.[Social Processes after the Change of<br />

the Regime] Budapest, Országos Közoktatási Intézet<br />

URL: http://www.oki.hu/oldal.php?tipus=cikk&kod=Jelentes<br />

97-hatter-Sagi-Tarsadalmi<br />

downloaded: 10/17/2008<br />

page 199


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

SOME EVIDENCE FROM UKRAINE<br />

(1991-2009)<br />

Abel Polese<br />

9<br />

Drawing evidence from participant<br />

observations and informal interviews<br />

between 2003 and 2009, when the<br />

author spent around four years working in<br />

Ukraine as a lecturer and consultant in the non<br />

governmental sector, this article explores the<br />

conditions that make the informal sector blossom<br />

in transitional countries. In this respect, it<br />

will be suggested, informal economies originate<br />

from tensions between citizens and the state,<br />

in which the former feels compelled to respect<br />

decisions and policies imposed from the latter<br />

with no possibility to express their opinions or<br />

react politically.<br />

In such a context, the only way to react is to<br />

use informal economies as weapons of the weak<br />

(Scott 1984). Through informal payments,<br />

(petty) fiscal fraud or suitcase smuggling,<br />

people may reverse the effects of state decisions<br />

that are not tailored to a local context. This, in<br />

turn, may allow people to participate politically<br />

even when a participatory democracy is not<br />

immediately available (Gupta 1995).<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

page 200<br />

Ukraine gained independence in 1991. Coming<br />

out of a period of nationalist movements, worker<br />

and student strikes as well as an attempted<br />

golpe, the future president Leonid Kravchuk<br />

played the card of a radical rupture with the<br />

past in the hope to rapidly gain stability and<br />

sustainability.<br />

Although a full republic within the USSR,<br />

Ukraine still lacked some of the international


ABEL POLESE<br />

institutions that a sovereign country needs. The<br />

Ministry of Foreign Affairs had been based in<br />

Moscow as well as the national bank, both of<br />

which would have to be created ex novo and<br />

based in Kiev.<br />

In an effort to gain credibility and international<br />

recognition, the country initiated a number of<br />

political and economic reforms at domestic and<br />

international levels. As a first step, the country<br />

became a presidential republic in 1991and<br />

Leonid Kravchuk was elected as the first president.<br />

In addition, the communist party was<br />

formally banned (though re-admitted into<br />

politics in 1993) and its property nationalized.<br />

In spite of this, a consistent number of communists<br />

remained in politics by adopting a new<br />

political identity (most went into the Socialist<br />

Party, while others have run as independent<br />

candidates or found themselves distributed in a<br />

number of other parties, Polese 2008).<br />

Because of Russian proximity and claims (on<br />

gas and foreign debts, the Ukrainian territory<br />

and domestic politics due to consistent Russian<br />

minorities in the country), international recognition,<br />

assistance and support were also sought<br />

to counterbalance these pressures. The country<br />

applied and was accepted into the Council of<br />

Europe in 1995 ; and a partnership and cooperation<br />

agreement with the EU entered into<br />

force in 1998, one year before the Common<br />

Strategy on Ukraine (and Russia) was put<br />

forward by the EU Commission. Programmes<br />

of assistance like TACIS or IREX were set up<br />

and Ukraine was allowed to become a main<br />

recipient. The IMF and World Bank were also<br />

welcome to give advice and collaborate with<br />

the local government in an attempt to protect<br />

the country from harsh crises.<br />

However, this international attention had a<br />

double effect. On the one hand, the transfer<br />

of knowledge enabled domestic companies<br />

and public industries to potentially catch up<br />

with the rest of the world. On the other, it<br />

exposed the very essence of a society based on<br />

informal exchanges and social networks that,<br />

consolidating in Soviet times, had become a<br />

main feature of the country’s economy after<br />

the end of socialism. If, on the one hand,<br />

macroeconomic reforms and performance of<br />

the Ukrainian economy was a main concern<br />

(Kravchuk 2002, Van Zon 2000), an increasing<br />

number of firms mentioned informal practices<br />

and suggested that their liquidation would<br />

have a positive effect on the country’s transition<br />

(Aslund 2009, Aslund and Mesnil 1999, De<br />

Cornelius and Lenain 1997, Kuzio 1998).<br />

Researchers focusing on economic development<br />

in Ukraine could be divided into two<br />

mainstreams. Some assess informal transactions<br />

as harmful for the country (Freedom<br />

House, Transparency International, World<br />

Bank) and hold the opinion that the economic<br />

transition should pass through a cultural transition<br />

from Soviet deltsi (equivalent of businessman<br />

in Russian but with a different moral<br />

attitude) to businessmen (Papava 2001, Papava<br />

and Khaduri 1997). Others, however, argue for<br />

a dinstinction between pure corruption and<br />

the informal sector, suggesting that the most<br />

effective way to deal with extralegal<br />

activities was to integrate them into<br />

the official economy (Kaliberda and page 201<br />

Kaufmann 1996, Kaufmann 1994).<br />

The account on corruption given by most<br />

international organizations, and sometimes<br />

diligently adopted by local actors (Zerkalo


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

page 202<br />

nedeli), might have several weakenesses. One<br />

is that ‘international standards’ do not always<br />

take into account the local cultural and social<br />

context, especially when dealing with corruption<br />

(Polese 2008, Werner 2003). Legal systems,<br />

if allowed to develop autonomously, may also<br />

generate definitions that differ radically. 1<br />

A further weakness arises in the case of small<br />

transactions, happening on a daily or regular<br />

basis, that allow common people to survive<br />

once the state is unable to secure their needs.<br />

In such contexts, the very word ‘bribe’ and its<br />

meaning may be questioned (Humphrey 2002,<br />

Patico 2002, Polese 2008).<br />

A commonly agreed upon definition of<br />

corruption is as follows: ‘corruption is the use<br />

of a public function for a private advantage’.<br />

However, if the public function (a doctor, a<br />

teacher, a civil servant), that is, the fact that an<br />

individual works for the state, is not supported<br />

by the state (de facto, either because the state<br />

is not paying salaries or is paying too little<br />

to survive) then the very meaning of public<br />

function should be re-discussed and, with it, the<br />

meaning of corruption (Polese 2008, 2006b).<br />

Drawing evidence from participant observation<br />

and informal interviews between<br />

2003 and 2009, when I spent around four<br />

years working in Ukraine as a lecturer and<br />

consultant in the non governmental<br />

sector, I explore in this article the<br />

relationship between the state and<br />

the citizen in order to understand the<br />

origin of such informal transactions.<br />

In particular, I address the questions what<br />

conditions encourage or discourage success of<br />

an informal economy. In this respect, I suggest<br />

that informal economies originate from tensions<br />

between citizens and the state, in which<br />

the former feels compelled to respect decisions<br />

and policies imposed from the latter with no<br />

possibility to express their opinions or react<br />

politically.<br />

In such a context, the only way to react is to<br />

use informal economies as weapons of the weak<br />

(Scott 1984). Through informal payments,<br />

(petty) fiscal fraud or suitcase smuggling people<br />

may reverse the effects of state decisions that<br />

are not tailored to a local context. This, in turn,<br />

may allow people to participate politically even<br />

when a participatory democracy is not immediately<br />

available (Gupta 1995). To support this<br />

argument, the next sections will narrow down<br />

the concept of informal economies, as defined<br />

in this article, and discuss how informal transactions<br />

are performed.<br />

DISCUSSING THE INFORMAL SECTOR AND THE<br />

ILLEGAL-LEGAL BOUNDARY<br />

Agreement to consider the informal sector<br />

within a national economy is relatively recent.<br />

The informal sector was first defined as ‘unregulated<br />

economic enterprises or activities’<br />

(Hart 1973) until, in 1993, the International<br />

Conference of Labour Statisticians (ICLS<br />

1993) decided to include all unregistered<br />

enterprises below a certain size – for example,<br />

micro-enterprises owned by informal employers<br />

as well as entrepreneurial operations owned by<br />

individuals who may employ family members<br />

or employees on an occasional basis.<br />

This definition, however, may fail to include


ABEL POLESE<br />

persons engaged in very small-scale or casual<br />

self-employment activities. In addition,<br />

anthropologists objected this perception of<br />

labour. In her work on women labour in Turkey,<br />

for example, White (2004) pointed out that<br />

activities such as child caring or piecework<br />

production, generating revenue according to<br />

Western legal codes, is generally not perceived<br />

by women themselves as work but rather as<br />

their duties as mothers and wives to contribute<br />

to household survival.<br />

A main result of this international debate is<br />

that the informal sector is no longer considered<br />

separate from the formal economy (ILO, 1972;<br />

Sethuraman, 1976; Tokman, 1978), representing<br />

only small scale activities (Moser, 1978;<br />

Castells and Portes, 1989) or large enterprises<br />

attempting to fraud the government (de Soto,<br />

1989). Also, the idea of a transitional informal<br />

sector has been challenged. The sector might<br />

survive long enough so that it is no longer a<br />

subject for economic policy (Maloney 2004)<br />

but a persisting and lasting part of the national<br />

economy with an impact on the GDP. In this<br />

way, this definition would subsequently include<br />

non-standard wage workers as well as the self<br />

employed, which might prompt governments<br />

to reconsider it use when deciding on a political<br />

and economic development strategy (Chen,<br />

Martha, Joann Vanek and Marilyn Carr. 2004).<br />

Because the definition of informal economies,<br />

or the informal sector, might come to include<br />

virtually anything, a study on informal economy<br />

should, as the first task, explain what part of the<br />

informal sector will be the focus of analysis.<br />

A distinction that might be worthy of use is the<br />

one between illegal, unreported, unrecorded<br />

and informal economies (Feige 1990:7). Illegal<br />

economies refer to those perpetuated in<br />

violation of legal statutes defining the scope of<br />

legitimate forms of commerce (1990:8), which,<br />

at least in principle, should be of interest for<br />

criminologists or law students. Unreported<br />

economies consist of activities that circumvent<br />

or evade the institutionally established fiscal<br />

rules so that tax authorities are not informed<br />

of the activity. Finally, unrecorded economies<br />

are all activities producing income that<br />

the state does not consider to be revenue<br />

producing, such as household production.<br />

In developed countries, it is estimated that<br />

such activities account for between 25 and<br />

50 percent of the GDP (Feige 1990: 9) and<br />

can strongly bias data on unemployment<br />

and production. Finally, according to Feige<br />

informal economies include all activities that<br />

circumvent costs and are excluded from the<br />

benefits and rights incorporated in the laws<br />

and administrative rules governing property<br />

relationships, commercial licensing, labour<br />

contracts, torts, financial credit and social<br />

security systems (1990:10). This illegal-legal<br />

boundary is difficult to trace and might be<br />

mobile: for example, how should politically<br />

motivated embargoes or bans be handled that<br />

directly affect traders who become smugglers<br />

overnight?<br />

Accepting that the boundary between legal<br />

and illegal is much more fluid in reality than<br />

in theory, I will use, as narrative of<br />

this paper, transactions that one could<br />

call ‘illegal-legal’ or ‘potentiallylegal-illegal’.<br />

Illegal-legal refers to<br />

page 203<br />

deeds that may be considered illegal<br />

in a given context, for they are not regulated,<br />

registered, or fully recorded, but could also be<br />

considered legal in a different context or when


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

performed by different people. As the desire to<br />

remain covert is often due to the incapacity of<br />

the state to invite people out of extralegality<br />

(Bovi 2001, de Cornelius and Lenain 1999,<br />

de Soto 2002), illegal-legal transactions may<br />

be illegal in a given moment (and context) but<br />

potentially legal if only the state would modify<br />

the legal framework – i.e. a businessman<br />

whose company is not registered because the<br />

registration procedure is too complex, or someone<br />

importing a product that is temporarily<br />

banned. Conversely, this classification excludes<br />

covert operations that would be very difficult<br />

to consider legal even by the most liberal government,<br />

such as selling narcotics.<br />

Another distinction between illegal-legal and<br />

fully illegal may be found when examining the<br />

beneficiaries of as well as those harmed by an<br />

action. Smuggling, selling with no licence, or<br />

failing to pay taxes may harm the state directly<br />

but might benefit the fellow citizen, who is<br />

able to buy things not available on the market<br />

otherwise or simply at a lower price (Polese<br />

2006). Citizens are, in this case, only indirectly<br />

harmed as they may not benefit from services<br />

the state might put at disposal with a higher<br />

budget. However, actions like selling or<br />

trafficking narcotics or burglary directly harm<br />

the fellow citizen and the state (directly or<br />

indirectly) and are harder to be considered<br />

legal or even potentially-legal.<br />

Potentially legal transactions are<br />

page 204 ambivalently considered in literature<br />

on post-Soviet transition. In Ukraine<br />

there have been some efforts to<br />

integrate informal economies in an economic<br />

framework to understand their impact on the<br />

economic transition (Kaufman 1994, Schneider<br />

and Enste 2000) as well as explore whether<br />

they can be integrated into the legal sphere of<br />

economic life (Hussmanns 2004, Kaliberda<br />

and Kaufmann 1997). However there is a<br />

portion of the literature, in Ukraine as in other<br />

former USSR republics, suggesting that we<br />

can understand the reasons behind those informal<br />

economies by understanding how they<br />

work, the way people survive in post-socialism<br />

(Humphrey 2002, Pavlovskaya 2004, Polese<br />

2006, 2006b, 2006c, 2008, Wanner 2005) and<br />

how, in particular, the relation state citizen may<br />

affect the relevent action (Patico 2002, Polese<br />

2008, 2010, Sebinova Peter 2005). This may<br />

be due to the fact that people participate in a<br />

whole range of economic practices on a daily<br />

basis, many of which can be defined in noncapitalism<br />

terms (Pavlovskaya 2004: 334). By<br />

exploring not only the way the state address<br />

citizen’s needs but also the perception of the<br />

state by the citizens (i.e. whether or not they<br />

feel their needs are met), we can understand the<br />

way and the extent to which informal economies<br />

are formed and the reason why they may<br />

persist over time.<br />

Informal economies, as explored in this paper,<br />

seem to show a partially transitory or nonpermanent<br />

nature. They exist because citizens<br />

need to survive in their daily life and not<br />

because of a desire for fullfillment through a<br />

maximization of profits. In this we can see the<br />

Weberian distinction between consumption and<br />

acquisition (Schluchter Weber [1908] 1998)<br />

that helps to narrow our sphere of investigation<br />

to the consumption-oriented actions.<br />

However, priority of consumer interests<br />

normally characterize traditional economic<br />

structures, which is in line with the fact that


ABEL POLESE<br />

informal economies tend to deny the role of the<br />

state as social or economic mediator among citizens.<br />

Informal transactions take place directly<br />

between two or more citizens and either leave<br />

no place for the role of the state or occur in a<br />

context in which the state is superfluous.<br />

Currently it might difficult to find a national<br />

territory in which the state is absent, although<br />

there may be cases in which it is partially absent<br />

in spatial or temporal terms. That is, the state<br />

might be absent ‘sometimes’ or ‘in some places’.<br />

I refer here to the possibility that the state, while<br />

attempting to regulate economic life, might fail<br />

to do so in some cases (e.g. for some sectors or<br />

industries or in some regions) or in some time<br />

periods (e.g. during an economic crisis).<br />

Alternatively, the state might be unable to<br />

boost even regional development by neglecting<br />

some regions, thus encouraging engagement<br />

in informal transitions. The more often this<br />

occurs, in temporary and spatial terms, the<br />

more the state might be considered a failure.<br />

This perception may occur despite the fact<br />

that the actual situation likely falls somewhere<br />

between a failed and a perfect state; and<br />

informal economies are present in virtually<br />

every country irrespective of development<br />

status (Williams 2005).<br />

In Ukraine there is a tendency to renegotiate<br />

state policies and informally tailor them to a<br />

local reality in terms of language and identity<br />

policies (Polese 2009). In this context, the<br />

very presence of a state, as well as its work,<br />

generates tensions between habits, structures<br />

and dynamics consolidated over time, which in<br />

a Weberian perspective are the very source of<br />

power. The state attempts to regulate economic<br />

life and the relations between citizens.<br />

However, citizens may feel they are already<br />

able to regulate themselves on their own and<br />

feel unable or unwilling to further participate<br />

in the life of a given state. Those willing to<br />

participate, but at the same time feel somehow<br />

excluded, may provide informal transactions<br />

another meaning, in that they become a way to<br />

participate in the country’s political life (Gupta<br />

1995). Every action aimed at contrasting<br />

what the state imposes on citizens becomes a<br />

weapon (Scott 1984), so that informality may<br />

be seen as a way to reshape political decisions<br />

that were not accurately tailored for a given<br />

context (Polese 2010). To find confirmation<br />

of this statement, we need to look at the way<br />

informal economies function, their genesis<br />

and their perceptions by actors other than the<br />

state.<br />

WHERE WILL ALL THE BABUSHKI BE GOING?<br />

Kiev, a Wednesday afternoon, one of the<br />

hundreds of podzemnyj perekhod (subterranean<br />

passages used to cross wide roads that offer<br />

protection from the weather, especially in<br />

winter) of the city.<br />

Ukrainians, as they often do, are shopping.<br />

Sellers (mainly elderly women, but also<br />

some younger sellers) have arrived from the<br />

countryside or the neighbourhoods<br />

to sell their goods. Some offer a pot<br />

of marinated cucumbers, others have page 205<br />

collected and dried wild mushrooms,<br />

and still others sell apples. The more<br />

organized have a whole stand and a wider<br />

range of products. Some sell clothes, others<br />

biscuits and sweets or several kind of nuts.


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

Perekhody are crossing places, used to go home<br />

or change connections, so that Kievlyans, while<br />

busy going home, may hurriedly stop at some<br />

stands to buy whatever they might need for<br />

dinner or the evening. This type of shopping<br />

is not time consuming and can be done in the<br />

time between transfering buses.<br />

Suddenly several police officers arrive and<br />

ask the sellers to leave. They are in the right:<br />

none of the sellers have a permit to be there. In<br />

addition, since Soviet times there is a strong<br />

inhibition (and diffidence) when dealing with<br />

the police, so resisting is not an option.<br />

However, conversely to what might happen<br />

elsewhere, the police officers are not keen<br />

to fine the sellers or confiscate their goods.<br />

They simply order them to leave. Some<br />

of the elderly women may ask for mercy,<br />

adding that this is the only way they can<br />

earn money. The officers will reply that<br />

they cannot do anything, that their job is<br />

to implement orders received from the state.<br />

To the accidental observer, this situation is<br />

perfectly logical. There is a group of people<br />

acting illegaly, while another group is paid to<br />

re-establish order and keep things under the<br />

control of the state, so that the state can get its<br />

revenue and take care of its citizens. However,<br />

following an approach suggested by Geertz<br />

(1973) it might be worthwhile to<br />

explore this situation and its context,<br />

page 206 in order to understand who the street<br />

sellers and police officers are as well<br />

as why people engage in such transactions<br />

and challenge the state to such degree.<br />

The reason why those babushki (grandmothers,<br />

elders) are there and the policemen chase<br />

them is a main issue in Ukrainian transition<br />

nowadays and a main conflict. The women<br />

are there because, in most cases, they have no<br />

better choice. The policemen go there because<br />

the government is pursuing a strategy to crack<br />

down on informal transactions and increase<br />

hygienic standards.<br />

There are several motivations for regulation.<br />

Informal shops in the street take revenue out<br />

of the taxable transactions and, thus, from the<br />

state budget. In a world in which the state must<br />

provide citizens with certain services, money<br />

must be obtained from several sources. With<br />

fewer taxes, there are less funds at disposal.<br />

Second, this is unfair competition for those<br />

who pay taxes; it damages their businesses by<br />

causing higher costs in turn for operating legally.<br />

This, in turn, encourages more individuals<br />

to leave the legal and enter the illegal sector.<br />

Finally, there is an issue of quality control.<br />

How can the state have control over quality of<br />

what is offered to the citizens if those sellers,<br />

who do not exist officially, buy from unknown<br />

producers or produce at home? As far as the<br />

state knows, the mushrooms and berries sold<br />

in such contexts might have been collected in<br />

radioactive areas; yet in the case of unregistered<br />

sellers who are at that particular location only<br />

temporarily, there is no accountability. Sellers<br />

would not have to respond to anybody should<br />

their products cause someone harm; and the<br />

state would bear the costs of hospitalization<br />

and loss of labour.<br />

Following this logic, Ukrainian politicians, and<br />

especially those in charge of Kiev, have started<br />

a crusade against ‘unhealthy food’, banning<br />

shaurma (kebab) and fried cakes on the ground<br />

that they are prepared in unhealthy conditions.


ABEL POLESE<br />

The same is happening to dairy sections of<br />

several bazaars in Kiev where, for fear of unhygienic<br />

conditions, the simplest solution seems<br />

to be a ban on selling of dairy products and a<br />

push for citizens to buy only in supermarkets.<br />

However, as street food is something available<br />

almost everywhere in the world, it is sufficient<br />

to regulate it. Why is it not possible to apply<br />

some form of control on street food so that<br />

people can know what they are eating, thus<br />

making it unnecessary to deny work to street<br />

vendors? And more, where do the babushki go<br />

after they are kicked out of a passage?<br />

Further questions would then be why such<br />

street vendors are there as well as why people<br />

tend to sell what they have at home and do<br />

so without a licence? A first point is that, to<br />

differing degrees, all those living on state<br />

pensions have seen both their savings and their<br />

income eroded by inflation. It is sufficient to<br />

think of all those already retired in 1991 to ask<br />

what has happened to their ruble-calculated<br />

pension after inflation skyrocketed and the<br />

national currency was changed. In addition,<br />

the inflation has been relatively high even after<br />

1996 and depends on the exchange rate, which<br />

has been highly unstable, even in recent years, so<br />

that even wages have proved unable to keep up<br />

with the price of living. This is why it is almost<br />

impossible to find someone who is comfortably<br />

living, after a life of hard work, on their statepaid<br />

pensions; and pensioners have to take up<br />

odd jobs to supplement their incomes. Some<br />

work in real estate, some as concierges, some do<br />

little reparations and some sell on the street. If<br />

elderly citizens live alone and have no relatives<br />

but needs money, the cost of their labour/time<br />

is extremely low. Thus, even selling a couple of<br />

kilos of self produced apples might be enough<br />

to finance their day to day lives.<br />

Registering a business requires an initial capital<br />

that most of these people do not have. Simply<br />

to obtain a permit or purchase a vendor outlet<br />

on the street to sell goods is not a possiblity,<br />

not to mention the bureaucratic complications<br />

of registering a business, which is often<br />

complicated further by those very same state<br />

officers with the goal of obtaining personal<br />

benefits. In addition, elderly citizens, who<br />

typically lived most of their life in the USSR,<br />

have less capacity to learn new regulations,<br />

especially in such a fast changing environment<br />

like Ukraine. Without support, they might get<br />

lost in all the necessary steps of registering a<br />

business, as we will see in the next case study.<br />

Alexei is a businessman. During the 1980s he<br />

completed his PhD in engineering and began<br />

working at a university but rapidly understood<br />

that this was not leading far. As soon as the<br />

country became Independent, he started his<br />

own business with a colleague from the university.<br />

His life in the business environment<br />

of the 1990s is reminiscent of the novel by<br />

Andrei Kurkov ‘The Penguin’. He had to hide<br />

several times outside the city, often with his<br />

own family. Although he was able to register<br />

his business, he was often operating between<br />

legality and illegality. One day he lost his<br />

company. His partner had falsified<br />

documents stating that Alexei had<br />

sold his share of the business to his page 207<br />

partner and then threatened to harm<br />

his family if he attempted any retaliation.<br />

Alexei began from zero again and, moving


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

from one business to the other, slipped so far<br />

into illegality that he got arrested and convicted<br />

for a petty crime (exchanging money<br />

on the black market). This was also due to<br />

the fact that somebody was after him and his<br />

apartment in the centre of the city, which he<br />

eventually sold to bear his legal costs.<br />

Released from prison, he was unable to get<br />

a job and started working as a taxi driver.<br />

Anybody can work as taxi driver in Ukraine,<br />

as long as they have a car. There are registered<br />

taxi companies with official fares as well as private<br />

citizens who supplement their salaries by<br />

accepting to give lifts to other fellow citizens.<br />

He finally got a job in a communication<br />

company and acted as managing director of a<br />

department but was fired after approximately<br />

two years. The story of his employment in<br />

the company is an interesting outlook on the<br />

business world in Ukraine. Alexei was paid a<br />

thousand dollars a month, a respectible salary<br />

for somebody over forty in Ukraine. However,<br />

his official stipend was only two hundred<br />

dollars, paid directly into his bank account. The<br />

bulk of this money was paid to him in a white<br />

envelop. This is also a method, imposed from<br />

companies, to avoid paying income taxes; and<br />

employees tend to agree with this practice, as<br />

the services offered by the state in exchange for<br />

the taxes are very poor. Either way, employees<br />

have little choice.<br />

page 208 One of the drawbacks was that, once<br />

he applied for a bank loan, he could<br />

not prove he was earning enough to<br />

pay the loan back so that his wife (working for<br />

the state and thus declaring the whole of her<br />

revenue) had to guarantee for him.<br />

The director of his department was a<br />

relative of the company’s president, and thus<br />

almost untouchable, despite the fact that<br />

his management was far from being honest.<br />

When purchasing electronic components from<br />

abroad, he would inflate the price and pocket<br />

the difference. When the company decided on<br />

a salary increase for the employees, he would<br />

also pocket the difference, as no control over<br />

the white envelop was exercisable. As a result,<br />

Alexei and his colleagues had the lowest salary<br />

at the company (with no promotion in 2 years)<br />

and no right to protest.<br />

During this period, Alexei rediscovered his<br />

entrepreneur skills and registered a company.<br />

This time he used his in-laws as owners and<br />

distributed the assets so that it was not possible<br />

to steal it as a whole. He started repairing electronic<br />

devices that his employer threw away and<br />

sold them using his contacts in the company<br />

network. Several of his colleagues in different<br />

Ukrainian cities, unhappy with their salary or<br />

working conditions, helped him to create a<br />

national network able to dispatch anywhere in<br />

Ukraine. Meanwhile, he tried to convince his<br />

colleagues to denounce the abuses of their boss<br />

to the president. The director, probably expecting<br />

this, decided to get rid of him and waited<br />

until Alexei went abroad for a holiday to fire<br />

him and forbid his colleagues to talk with him.<br />

Alexei could not take any immediate actions<br />

and, probably tired of the situation, let things<br />

go, also reassured by the fact that his small firm<br />

was doing well.<br />

Today, he is still struggling to consolidate his<br />

position on the market but is able to survive.<br />

He says that the business environment has<br />

improved since the 1990s and no one has ever


ABEL POLESE<br />

tried to step on his way, not least because his<br />

business is too small to bother (which would<br />

not have been a deterrent in the 1990s).<br />

Here is a difference to some years ago. Because<br />

the economic situation has improved, and there<br />

seem to be more controls, people are less willing<br />

to take risks for few dollars. If, on the one hand,<br />

this seems to be an improvement, on the other<br />

it is not. Ukraine is an extremely bureaucratic<br />

country and very often legal acts are impossible<br />

because of the cumbersome bureaucracy.<br />

Think of a truck transporting animals or fresh<br />

fish at the border. If they have to wait 4-5 days,<br />

the load is lost. Especially after the 2004 Orange<br />

Revolution, the pro-Western direction of<br />

Ukraine and the compliance with international<br />

standards and control has made people afraid<br />

of getting caught. This means truck drivers<br />

have to play fair and wait until the custom<br />

officers are able to process the documents,<br />

which means the food might spoil. Or, because<br />

there is more risk involved in accepting informal<br />

payments, now officers expect you also to<br />

pay for their risk (so there is an extra tax on<br />

bribes) – either because they have to bribe their<br />

superior so that they will not be reported, or<br />

because prices are also higher with greater risk.<br />

One illuminating example is what happened to<br />

Alexei once he tried to import electronic components<br />

from China. Because they are trying<br />

to expand and produce in Ukraine, and some<br />

electronic devices are very expensive to import,<br />

he has been looking for a factory that produces<br />

radio components that can be assembled in<br />

Ukraine, allowing him to be more competitive<br />

on the market. He ordered one component to<br />

try to mount it and check whether it would<br />

be worth buying a whole lot. When this was<br />

shipped through DHL to Kiev, he found<br />

himself in a paradoxical situation: to be able to<br />

pay the exact custom duty, the product had to<br />

be registered by customs. However, to register<br />

the product, one had to go to the Ministry of<br />

Trade and produce that very same good, so<br />

government experts could evaluate it. How<br />

was it possible to register a good before import<br />

if, to register a good, one had to have already<br />

imported it?<br />

The custom rejected his parcel and he found<br />

it more convenient to send it to Moldova,<br />

where the DHL office had no trouble with<br />

the regulations, then send it to Odessa by bus,<br />

where there is a price for everything, registered<br />

or not, and then handle it to a train inspector<br />

who, in exchange for a small tip, brought it to<br />

him in Kiev.<br />

We could discuss whether Alexei and his colleagues<br />

are victims or accomplices, as Miller<br />

(et al. 2000) debate. However, there are several<br />

things that would not happen in a more<br />

transparent environment. The problem is not<br />

only the pressure of regulations defending the<br />

worker. For one thing, eager to attract foreign<br />

investments, Ukraine has tried to make some<br />

concessions to investors and simplify their life,<br />

although this might mean a worsening of workers’<br />

lives. Moreover, even if trade unions are a<br />

long time tradition in former Soviet countries,<br />

their role was quite ambiguous in the<br />

past and they might not be truly used<br />

to lobby for the good of the workers page 209<br />

as they claim.<br />

Dimitry is a university professor – that is,<br />

teaching at the university is one of his many<br />

jobs, as his university salary is not enough to


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

pay his bills. Normally, university professors<br />

are paid for their teaching hours, conducting<br />

research and writing in their leisure time. A<br />

salary package would start at 200 US dollars,<br />

increasing with the workload (for instance<br />

if some administrative or teaching tasks are<br />

undertaken). In his case, he is willing to do several<br />

other jobs at the same time and, when we<br />

meet, I usually have to accompany him around<br />

the city to meet the most diverse people before<br />

we can finally sit to drink a tea and chat.<br />

Dimitry is not against accepting ‘presents’ from<br />

students. He says: ‘if the student comes to me<br />

and wants to pass my exam, I know that, if I<br />

fail them, they will bounce around until they<br />

finally pass another exam. Why shall I complicate<br />

things if those people were not born to<br />

study? In exchange, if after the exam they want<br />

to give me a bottle of kon’yak (brandy) or wine,<br />

I shall not refuse’.<br />

Dimitry is not alone, most university professors<br />

have to face the problem of low salaries and<br />

motivation. Some can tap from international<br />

programmes like IREX, CEP (now AFP),<br />

USAID and, more recently, Marie Curie and<br />

receive money for traveling or their research.<br />

However, the majority of them, and especially<br />

those who do not know English and thus<br />

cannot connect with the Western world, are in<br />

a more critical situation. They might<br />

look for a number of remedies: they<br />

page 210 might get a second job at a private<br />

university, using the prestige of the<br />

public one they work for. They might<br />

give private lessons to their students. Or they<br />

might accept informal payments in different<br />

ways and modalities.<br />

Under pressures from the international community,<br />

Ukraine has come to outlaw flowers<br />

and chocolate, a traditional present from<br />

students to the teachers but defined as bribes<br />

in a desperate effort to limit corruption at universities.<br />

However, I have argued that the main<br />

problem is low salaries, rather than greedy<br />

teachers (Polese 2008).<br />

A further question, however, would be why a<br />

student who does not want to study is at the<br />

university. Why are hundreds of such cases<br />

found at the university? The answer is that,<br />

with no university degree, it would be extremely<br />

hard to find a job that is decently paid. With<br />

a high unemployment rate, competition for any<br />

kind of job is great. To succeed, it is necessary<br />

to have higher qualifications than the others,<br />

even to work in a shop or as a cleaner.<br />

Aware of such conditions, parents are willing<br />

to do anything to secure their children a future<br />

and invest their savings into an university<br />

education. With an increasing number of<br />

students willing to enter a university, the first<br />

consequence is that universities accept more<br />

students than they should and classes become<br />

overcrowded. Once a limit is reached, the old<br />

law of supply and demand applies and prices<br />

to enter a university rise. I am not talking of<br />

official prices but, rather, the extra costs parents<br />

will have to pay to secure a place for their<br />

children.<br />

The most prestigious universities become<br />

places where prices are exceedingly high; and<br />

even universities with no real perspective on<br />

the Ukrainian job market (like ethnography or<br />

history) are in demand. Some meritocracy still<br />

applies, but what university is not willing to


ABEL POLESE<br />

obtain extra money from students in times of<br />

economic crisis when university expenditures<br />

are low? This also means that students,<br />

becoming a source of revenue for the university,<br />

are untouchable. To fail a student means to get<br />

into trouble as a professor, who would even<br />

risk being fired. This is an extra motivation to<br />

allow cheating on exams. The result is a huge<br />

fraud to the state, with universities producing<br />

unprepared students, while professors and<br />

faculty receive extra money and many students<br />

enter the job market with a (fake) degree. All<br />

this occurs while the state is trying to persuade<br />

universities to implement the Bologna process<br />

and teachers to use ‘interactive teaching’<br />

methods during their classes. The main looser is<br />

the job market. Students might learn a job even<br />

with little university education. The problem<br />

is that they learn that such behaviours like<br />

paying for an exam or cheating are tolerated in<br />

society and might continue this tradition when<br />

working.<br />

THE INFORMAL SECTOR: PROBLEM OR SOLUTION<br />

OF TRANSITION?<br />

What do the actors mentioned above have<br />

in common? The first element is a desire or<br />

necessity to engage in informal transactions<br />

with other fellow citizens. The nature of those<br />

relationships is always fluid, oscillating between<br />

the legal and the illegal, depending on the point<br />

of view (and on the moral code) adopted.<br />

However, they also have in common a conflictual<br />

relationship with the state or its subordinates.<br />

In the case of a public worker, this is all<br />

the more visible, as it is direct: the state either<br />

does not pay enough, pays late, or does not pay<br />

at all (Polese 2006b, 2008). The case of the<br />

pensioners is also similar, with the state not<br />

providing enough to live on. Where we have<br />

a doctor in a hospital or a teacher accepting<br />

informal payments, we have somebody else<br />

paying. The fates of the above mentioned<br />

people are, thus, entangled, each receives and<br />

gives money depending on the situation and<br />

the economy turns. Perhaps not the way the<br />

government would like, but we have circulation<br />

of liquidity and a quasi functioning economic<br />

system.<br />

The case of the private worker is less direct, but<br />

it is important to remember here that, where<br />

the state is in charge of the management of a<br />

country, it normally has two options – it either<br />

takes care of all the sectors (central planned<br />

economy) or creates the conditions for external<br />

institutions to regulate the economic life of<br />

the country. Neither of the mentioned options<br />

applies to Ukraine, where employees have little<br />

defence against their employers, who in turn<br />

have little defence against larger companies<br />

and so on.<br />

The case studies explored are situations generating<br />

tensions, directly or indirectly, between<br />

the citizen and the state. However, because of<br />

the political situation in Ukraine, it might not<br />

always be possible to directly oppose political<br />

decisions or confront the political elites, as it<br />

might happen in a country with more<br />

interaction between the political<br />

class and the people. The best way page 211<br />

people can cope is to officially accept<br />

the change but then de facto reject<br />

it. Informal economies, thus, may be seen as<br />

generated by tensions between the state and<br />

the citizen. But change, the shift of an equi-


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

librium, always generates tension, the level of<br />

which will depend on how hard it will be for<br />

citizens to adapt to the new rules. If people<br />

can live with this change, they will slowly pass<br />

from one stage to the other. If people cannot<br />

live with it, they will oppose it through civil<br />

society, political or other actions popular in<br />

a given context. Either a government will<br />

understand that it will loose popularity and<br />

revoke the measure or it will loose popularity<br />

and political power and most likely some other<br />

elites will use this to gain power.<br />

During the adjustment phase, tensions between<br />

what the state wants and the citizens<br />

are willing to give will generate tensions that<br />

may, in turn, develop into informal economies.<br />

We may see informal economies, thus, as<br />

something transitory that will disappear once<br />

the tension will be solved in one or another<br />

direction.<br />

However, there is another situation, in which<br />

people are captured between adaptation and<br />

political struggle, which does not move for the<br />

better or worst. Should this persist, informal<br />

economies would, as well.<br />

The question would then be ‘how long is transitory’.<br />

Is there a way to distinguish informal<br />

economies created to make up for a temporary<br />

state inefficiency from those that will stay?<br />

Informal economies can act as a buffer<br />

page 212 between the state and the citizen and<br />

shall be seen as something moving<br />

and fluctuating but existing in every<br />

single country in the world. When they are<br />

strong, it means there is much tension between<br />

the state and the citizen. When they are weak,<br />

it means the state is more able to meet the<br />

needs of its citizens.<br />

The informal sector may be seen, not as the<br />

problem or the solution, but as an indicator of<br />

the wealth of a society and the performance of a<br />

state. The more active it is, that is the more the<br />

society is based on social network rather than<br />

on state-led actions, the more room there is for<br />

a change of state attitudes that should be revisited,<br />

because it means the state does not address<br />

the needs to which citizens give priority.<br />

CONCLUDING REMARKS<br />

Informal economies may be generated either<br />

by a lack of a state or by its incompetence. I<br />

have suggested that in Ukraine the small<br />

amount of money allocated for hospitals has<br />

made informal payments the rule rather than<br />

the exception and this is the only way doctors<br />

and nurses can survive on the wages the state<br />

allocates (Polese 2006, 2006b, 2008).<br />

In this respect, informal transactions are not<br />

the disease but the solution, as de Soto (1989,<br />

2002) suggested. The main problem, according<br />

to the Peruvian economist, is that Western<br />

capitalist models of development, in particular<br />

property laws and practices, were drawn from<br />

practical experience rather than blindly imposed<br />

on the citizens (when trying to do so, the<br />

authorities faced open or hidden resistance).<br />

But those very models, practices and rules,<br />

elaborated through historical experience, are<br />

now imposed on transitional countries in the<br />

credo that, as long as they work in the West,<br />

they must work everywhere.


ABEL POLESE<br />

Recently, mainly anthropologists have started<br />

questioning the imposition from the top of<br />

such normative categories that limit domestic<br />

initiatives and are bound to shame politicians<br />

or people for failing to line up with capitalist<br />

standards. When talking of gift exchange<br />

practices in Kazakhstan, hurriedly classified as<br />

corruption by Western organizations (Transparency<br />

International or the World Bank),<br />

Werner (2003) suggested that it might be useful<br />

to compare the definition of international<br />

organizations with local and cultural standards,<br />

agreeing with other scholars that a contextual<br />

analysis is needed when theorising informal<br />

economies (Rasanayagam 2003). This might<br />

ultimately lead to an acceptance that standards<br />

depend on a particular economic situation<br />

(Wanner 2005) before trying to separate the<br />

formal from the informal, the legal from the<br />

illegal.<br />

In a context where decisions are imposed from<br />

above, informal economies become a way to<br />

react to economic measures with which citizens<br />

cannot comply. Once an unorganized struggle<br />

challenges an economic policy, by simply failing<br />

to comply with the economic instructions of<br />

the government, this failure may become a sign<br />

or way to respond to decisions and have a voice<br />

in the political arena (Gupta 2005, Thompson<br />

2003, Scott 1977, 1985, Tarrow 2005) to oppose<br />

too abstract rules that would make life<br />

impossible to anyone willing to survive. In a<br />

number of countries, registering a business<br />

following the official legal procedures could<br />

take several years and is much more expensive<br />

than remaining in the shadow. The drawback<br />

is that even accumulation of capital becomes<br />

informal and, thus, the country remains ‘poor’.<br />

In Ukraine, as in many other countries, laws<br />

often contradict themselves and come to reject<br />

social practices that people need to survive.<br />

Social and economic interactions, with the<br />

subsequent indebtedness, become a way to<br />

maintain relations and be able to ask for help<br />

when needed (Lolinka 2002, White 2004).<br />

On their side, international organizations,<br />

by proposing an international standard to all<br />

contexts, sometimes come to deny historical<br />

practices and the very social fact of the gift,<br />

as Werner (2003) has remarked for the World<br />

Bank.<br />

NOTE<br />

1<br />

Perhaps the most striking example is quoted by<br />

Robert Whiting in his book Tokyo Underworld. The<br />

authors describe tensions between American and Japanese<br />

anti-corruption authorities due to the fact that in Japan<br />

corruption involves a direct favour and a counterfavour by the<br />

other part, otherwise it is a simple gift that helps maintain social<br />

relationships.<br />

page 213


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

BIBLIOGRAPHY<br />

Aslund, A. (2009) How Ukraine Became a Market Democracy,<br />

Institute for International Economics<br />

Aders A. and G. de Menil (1999) Economic Reform in Ukraine:<br />

the Unfinished Agenda<br />

Geertz C. (1973) The Interpretation of Cultures, New York:<br />

Basic Books<br />

Gorodnichenko Y and K. Sabrianova Peter, ‘Public Sector and<br />

Corruption: Measuring Bribery from Micro Data’ IZA Discussion<br />

Paper No. 1987 (2006), available online at http://www-<br />

personal.umich.edu/~ygorodni/private-public-Gorodnichenko-<br />

Peter-2006-01-25.pdf, last accessed 13 March 2007<br />

Bovi, M. (2003), ‘The Nature of the Underground Economy-<br />

Some Evidence from OECD Countries’, JIIDT, no. 7, 60-70<br />

Gupta A. (2005) Narratives of Corruption, Ethnography 6(1),<br />

5-34.<br />

Castells, M. and A. Portes (1989) ‘World Underneath: The<br />

Origins, Dynamics, and Effects of the Informal Economy.’ In<br />

Alejandro Portes, Manuel Castells, and Lauren A. Benton, Eds.,<br />

The Informal Economy: Studies in Advanced and Less Advanced<br />

Developed Countries. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University<br />

Press.<br />

Chen M., J. Vanek and M. Carr (2004) Mainstreaming<br />

Informal Employment and Gender in Poverty Reduction: A<br />

Handbook for Policy Makers and Other Stakeholders, London:<br />

Commonwealth Secretariat.<br />

De Cornelius P. and P. Lenain (eds) (1997) Ukraine: Accelerating<br />

the Transition to Market : Proceedings of an IMF/World<br />

Bank Seminar. Washington: International Monetary Fund<br />

Gupta A. (1995) ‘Blurred Boundaries: The discourse of Corruption,<br />

the Culture of Politics, and the Imagined State’, American<br />

Ethnologist 22(2), 375-402<br />

Hart, K. (1973) ‘Informal Income Opportunities and Urban<br />

Employment in Ghana.’ The Journal of Modern African Studies,<br />

11(1), 61-89<br />

Hussmanns, R. (2004) Measuring the informal economy: From<br />

employment in the informal sector to informal employment, ILO<br />

Working Paper No. 53<br />

ILO (2002) Women and Men in the Informal Economy: A<br />

Statistical Picture. Geneva: ILO<br />

De Soto H. 2002. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism<br />

Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York:<br />

Basic Books.<br />

ILO (1993) Report of the Fifteenth International Conference of<br />

Labour Statisticians Geneva, 19-28 January. Doc. ICLS/15/D.6<br />

(rev.1), Geneva<br />

De Soto H. (1989) The Other Path: the Economic Answer to<br />

Terrorism. New York: Basic Books<br />

ILO (1972) Employment, Incomes and Equality: A Strategy for<br />

Increasing Productive Employment in Kenya. Geneva: ILO<br />

page 214<br />

Feige E. L. (1990) ‘Defining and Estimating<br />

Underground and Informal Economies: The New<br />

Institutional Economics Approach’ World Development,<br />

18 (7), 989-1002<br />

Kaliberda, A. and D. Kauffman (1996) Integrating the Unofficial<br />

Economy into the Dynamics of Post-Socialist Economics: A<br />

Framework of Analysis and Evidence. The World Bank: Policy<br />

Research Working Paper 1691<br />

Freedom House (2009) Nations in Transit: Ukraine. Budapest:<br />

Freedom House<br />

Kaufmann, D. (1994) ‘Diminishing returns to administrative<br />

controls and the emergence of the unofficial economy: a framework<br />

of analysis and applications to Ukraine, Economic Policy<br />

9(19), 52-69


ABEL POLESE<br />

Kravchuk, R. (2002) Ukraine Economic Reforms: the First Ten<br />

Years, New York: Basinstoke<br />

Kuzio, T. (1997) Ukraine Under Kuchma, New York: St.<br />

Martin’s Press<br />

Ledeneva, A. (1998), Russia’s Economy of Favours: ‘Blat’,<br />

Networking and Informal Exchange (Cambridge: Cambridge<br />

University Press)<br />

Lonkila, M. (1997), ‘Informal Exchange Relations in Post-<br />

Soviet Russia: A Comparative Perspective’, Sociological Research<br />

Online 2 no.3, www.socresonline.org.uk/socresonline/2/2/9.<br />

html<br />

Maloney, W. (2004) Informality Revisited World Development,<br />

32(7), 1159-1178<br />

Pavlovskaya, M. (2004) Other Transitions: Multiple Economies<br />

of Moscow Households in the 1990s Annals of the Association<br />

of American Geographers 94(2), 329-351<br />

Polese, A. (2010) ‘The formal and the informal: Exploring<br />

‘Ukrainian’ Education in Ukraine, Scenes from Odessa, Comparative<br />

Education 46 (1), forthcoming<br />

Polese, A. (2008) ‘Ukraine 1991-2006: Where are all the<br />

Communists Gone?’ in Uwe Backes and Patrick Moreau (eds.)<br />

Communist Parties in Eastern Europe after 1989. V&R:<br />

Gottingen<br />

Polese, A. (2008) ‘‘If I Receive it, it is a Gift; if I Demand it,<br />

then it is a Bribe’ on the Local Meaning of Economic Transactions<br />

in Post-soviet Ukraine’ Anthropology in Action special<br />

issue: ‘Reflections on Gift Exchange in the Contemporary World’<br />

edited by Denise Carter and Michaela Benson 5(3)<br />

Marin D., D. Kaufmann, B. Gorochowskij (2000) Barter in<br />

Transition Economics: Competing Explanations Confront Ukrainian<br />

Data, Discussion Paper 2000-6 University of Munich<br />

http://epub.ub.uni-muenchen.de<br />

Miller, W. L., A. B. Grodeland and T. Y. Koshechkina (2000),<br />

‘Victims or Accomplices? Extortion and bribery in Eastern Europe’,<br />

in Ledeneva, A. And Kurkchiyan, M. (eds.), Economic Crime<br />

in Russia (London: Kluwer Law International): 113-128<br />

Moser, C. N. (1978) ‘Informal Sector or Petty Commodity<br />

Production: Dualism or Independence in Urban Development?’<br />

World Development 6 (9-10), 1041-1064<br />

Papava V. (2001) ‘Necronomics - A Phenomenon of the Post-<br />

Communist Transition Period’, Problems of Economic Transition<br />

44(8), 77-89<br />

Polese, A. (2006), ‘Border Crossing as a Daily Strategy of Post<br />

Soviet Survival: the Odessa-Chisinau Elektrichka’, Eastern<br />

European Anthropology Review 24(1), 28-37<br />

Polese, A. (2006b) ‚De jure oder de facto? Die Gesundheits- und<br />

Bildungssektoren in der Ukraine’ Ukraine Analysen no. 16,<br />

2-4<br />

Polese, A. (2006c), ‘Paying for a Free Education’, Transitions<br />

Online (8 August)<br />

Raiser, M. (2001) Informal Institutions, Social Capital, and<br />

Economic Transition: Reflections on a Neglected Dimension, in<br />

Giovanni Andrea Cornia and Vladimir Popov (eds.) Transition<br />

and institutions: the experience of gradual and late reformers,<br />

Oxford: Oxford University Press<br />

Papava, V. and N. Khaduri (1997). ‘On the Shadow Political<br />

Economy of the Post Communist Transformation, an Institutional<br />

Analysis’, Problems of Economic Transitions 40(6), 15-34<br />

Rasanayagam, J. (2003), ‘Market, State and<br />

Community in Uzbekistan: Reworking the Concept<br />

of the Informal Economy’, Max Planck Working<br />

Papers no.59<br />

page 215<br />

Patico, J. (2002), ‘Chocolate and Cognac: Gifts and the Recognition<br />

of Social Worlds in Post-Soviet Russia’, Ethnos 67 (3),<br />

345-368<br />

Sethuraman, S. V. (1976) ‘The Urban Informal Sector: Concept,<br />

Measurement and Policy.’ International Labour Review<br />

114(1), 68-91


AT THE ORIGINS OF INFORMAL ECONOMIES:<br />

THE UKRAINIAN CASE<br />

Schneider F. and Enste D. H. (2000), Shadow Economies: Size,<br />

Causes, and Consequences, Journal of Economic Literature,<br />

XXXVIII, 77-114.<br />

Scott, J. (1985) Weapons of the Weak. New Haven and London:<br />

Yale University Press<br />

Schluchter, W. (1989) Modes of Capitalism: Imperial Rome and<br />

Imperial Germany in Rationalism Religion and Domination,<br />

LA: University of California Press, 281-314<br />

Shen, R. (1996) Ukraine’s Economic Reform Obstacles, Errors,<br />

Lessons, Greenwood<br />

Tanzi V. (1998), ‘Corruption Around the World: Causes, Consequences,<br />

Scopes and Cures’, IMF Working Paper (Washington<br />

DC: International Monetary Fund)<br />

Van Zon, H. (2000) The Political Economy of Independent<br />

Ukraine New York: St Martin’s Press<br />

Weber, M. ([1908] 1998) Agrarian Sociology of Ancient Civilizations.<br />

London: Verso<br />

Werner, C. A. (2002), ‘Gifts, Bribes and Development in Post-<br />

Soviet Kazakhstan’ in Jeffrey H. Cohen and Norbert Dannhaeuser<br />

(eds.) Economic Development: an Anthropological Approach<br />

(Walnut Creek, Lanham, New York, Oxford: Altamira Press),<br />

183-208<br />

Williams, C. (2005) A Commodified World? mapping the limits<br />

of capitalism, Zed, London<br />

White, J. B. (2004) Money Makes us Relatives; Women’s Labor<br />

in Turkey, London and New York: Routledge<br />

Tarrow, S. (2005) The New Transational Activism, Cambridge<br />

University Press<br />

World Bank Country Data Report 1996-2008 for Ukraine,<br />

Washington, World Bank<br />

Temple, P. and G. Petrov (2004). ‘Corruption in Higher Education:<br />

Some Findings from the States of the Former Soviet<br />

Union’. Higher Education Management and Policy 16, no.1:<br />

83-99<br />

Thompson, M. (2004) Democratic Revolutions, London and<br />

New York: Routledge<br />

Tokman, V. (1978) ‘An Exploration into the Nature of the<br />

Informal-Formal Sector Relationship.’ World Development 6<br />

(9-10), 1065-1075<br />

Transparency International (2009) Global Corruption Barometer,<br />

Berlin Transparency International<br />

page 216<br />

Transparency International (2009) Bribe Payers<br />

Index 2008, Berlin: Transparency International<br />

Wanner, C. (2005), ‘Money, Morality and New Forms of Exchange<br />

in Postsocialist Ukraine’ Ethnos 70 (4), 515-537


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

ABSTRACT<br />

10<br />

IINDUSTRIAL RELATIONS AND POST-SOCIALIST<br />

TRANSFORMATION:<br />

THE CASE OF UKRAINE<br />

Organized interest representation<br />

is central for transformation processes<br />

(incl. economic, political<br />

and social systems) to be completed. Unless<br />

workers’ interest is articulated in an organized<br />

manner, the prospects for democracy and a<br />

market economy in Ukraine, like elsewhere,<br />

are threatened. The complex structuring of<br />

industrial relations (IR) under the conditions<br />

of emerging capitalism in Ukraine embraces<br />

changes at all possible levels: arenas, legal and<br />

institutional settings, actors and their agency.<br />

Together with the enterprise-related restructuring,<br />

it leads to the segmentation of the IR<br />

systems. From the actor-centred perspective,<br />

this article demonstrates how unions-related<br />

changes (conceptualized as formative processes)<br />

have shaped the differences across<br />

enterprises and segments of IR in Ukraine.<br />

Lyudmyla Volynets<br />

INTRODUCTION: SEGMENTED INDUSTRIAL RE-<br />

LATIONS SYSTEMS<br />

The structuring of business systems in the<br />

countries of Central and Eastern Europe<br />

(CEE) led to the emergence of segmented<br />

capitalisms (Martin (2008)) 1 . Industrial Relations<br />

(hereafter IR) constitute one element<br />

of such business systems and are understood<br />

here in terms of the shifting frontier<br />

of control over working conditions<br />

between workers and their unions Seite page 217<br />

and employers. Accordingly, the<br />

low integrity and incoherency of<br />

the emergent IR systems within the present<br />

segmented business systems (Martin und<br />

Christescu-Martin 2006) resulted in the rise


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

of certain segments operating according to<br />

different IR dynamics. Hence, each of the segments<br />

(state budget sector, privatized or about<br />

to be privatized enterprises, emergent private<br />

sector, and Transnational Corporations) were<br />

claimed to produce a different pattern of IR<br />

(Kabalina und Komarovsky 1997, Martin und<br />

Cristescu-Martin 2004, 2006, Sidenko und<br />

Kuziakiv 2003, Slomp, van Hoof und Moerel<br />

1996, Peng 2000) 2 .<br />

It should be recognized that while certain<br />

segments are conducive to certain types of IR,<br />

these arguments do not apply in full for the<br />

example of Ukraine. In education and medical<br />

services in Ukraine workers and independent<br />

unions were quite assertive in terms of their<br />

rights and demands. In contrast, unions remained<br />

salient in many privatized enterprises;<br />

and IR followed old-style paternalistic logic.<br />

Similarly, the continuity in the original IR<br />

practices in foreign companies was questioned<br />

elsewhere (e.g. Cooke 2006, Tholen 2007).<br />

Hence, the segmentation of the business systems<br />

alone is not sufficient in explaining IR<br />

outcomes. Rather, some insights are necessary<br />

into how the new IR system is structured and<br />

institutionalized. Whereas its institutional<br />

design is driven much by international practices<br />

and principles, the bottom-level change<br />

in enterprises, employers and unions proceeds<br />

more slowly. Here IR actors, in particular, still<br />

find themselves in the processes of<br />

formation, while their agency does<br />

Seite page 218<br />

not always conform to the patterns of<br />

action imposed institutionally. I argue<br />

that the dynamic perspective of actors’<br />

formative processes and their interaction is<br />

superior in explaining the local segmentation<br />

of IR.<br />

IR INSTITUTIONAL DESIGN AND ACTORS’<br />

FORMATION<br />

Such unique simultaneous re-building of postsocialist<br />

IR arenas and actors can be addressed<br />

as the evolution of IR arenas in the sense of<br />

Müller-Jentsch’s actor-centered institutionalism<br />

(Müller-Jentsch 1996). On the one hand,<br />

the new institutional design is developed<br />

across former Soviet countries (hereafter<br />

FSU) in convergence with the principles<br />

of the International Labour Organization<br />

(ILO) and the European Social Model 3 . Such<br />

institutionalization from above (and from<br />

outside) is difficult in its deterministic view of<br />

the local processes (Burawoy und Verdery 1999,<br />

Grabher und Stark 1997, Stark 1998, Wollmann<br />

1997). Not least because the newly imposed set<br />

of rules regulates the patterns of interest and<br />

prescribes patterns of action that are still to<br />

emerge. As the construction of autonomous<br />

interest organizations is not completed (Slomp,<br />

van Hoof und Moerel 1996, Schienstock 1992),<br />

actors find themselves in the processes of (re)<br />

defining their roles and functions (Rippe 1985,<br />

Schienstock, Thompson und Traxler 1997).<br />

Therefore, it is not surprising that the new<br />

rules of the game laid down with international<br />

assistance cannot be institutionalized. This is<br />

confirmed by deficits in the functionality of<br />

law, collective bargaining and social dialogue in<br />

the region 4 .<br />

In the process of the institutionalization,<br />

currently fluid and contested IR arenas will<br />

be re-shaped during the processes of actors’<br />

formation and their capacity to mobilize the<br />

resources providing for their strength. From<br />

the perspective of the actor-centered institutionalism,<br />

institutions are treated in terms


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

of actors’ interest and cultural ideas being the<br />

building blocks of institutions. IR arenas are<br />

addressed as “a complex institutional system<br />

that determines which interests and actors are<br />

to be admitted … [and which] set boundaries<br />

for the courses of action open to the actors…”<br />

(Müller-Jentsch 1996: 31). Such an approach<br />

allows one to address the linkages between the<br />

progress of the institutionalization and actors’<br />

formation, on the one hand, and the tensions<br />

between the macro-level (system) and microlevel<br />

(actors) institutionalization (Wollmann<br />

1997) on the other. It further advances the<br />

understanding of the IR segmentation.<br />

Advancing such a perspective pre-supposes the<br />

recognition of actors’ strategic choices as well<br />

as the scope of changes they go through. Firstly,<br />

those authors highlighting the role of union<br />

discretion over IR (Trif und Koch 2005a,b,<br />

Huzzard, Gregory und Scott 2005, Hanke und<br />

Mense-Petermann 2001) show that even under<br />

the present constraints, unions still have been<br />

able to impose strategic choices on employers.<br />

In spite of union weaknesses, they could be<br />

effective in some IR areas. For example, on<br />

the national level Avgadic (2003) develops an<br />

understanding of union effectiveness that has<br />

resulted from the pre-history of state-unions<br />

interactions and their learning processes. A<br />

similar, process oriented concept was developed<br />

by Frege (2002) pointing that a process of unionmanagement<br />

relationships is determinant<br />

for union effectiveness. It facilitates longterm<br />

union transformation and goes back to<br />

unions’, members’ and managers’ attitudes and<br />

perceptions. Thus, sorting out unions’ choices<br />

in the processes of their relationships with<br />

the management is helpful in tracing unions’<br />

formative processes and the linkages between<br />

the institutional and behavioral aspects of IR<br />

institutionalization.<br />

Secondly, union formative processes go beyond<br />

a solely organizational formation of unions to<br />

their roles and functions. Structural reforms<br />

alone would not be enough to re-constitute<br />

unions’ roles as workers’ representatives 5 . In<br />

this dilemma, unions’ choices are more embracing.<br />

Unions can either resist or collaborate<br />

(subordinate) with employers and the state<br />

(Clarke 2005). Which way unions follow<br />

depends on how they address changes in the<br />

course of their formative processes, meaning<br />

in relation to union identity, agenda, structure,<br />

relationships with members, employers, and<br />

conflict articulation. Such a scope of necessary<br />

changes allows one to capture them as formative<br />

processes. Depending on the progress of<br />

union formative processes, the latter is a part<br />

of the explanation of a variety of enterprisebased<br />

IR ranging from subordination through<br />

union-management cooperation against state<br />

to cases of resistance and contestation. The<br />

formative processes of unions are directly<br />

affected by union embeddedness into interactions<br />

with employers and, in broader terms, by<br />

transformation.<br />

THE INTERACTIONS OF MANAGERS AND UNIONS<br />

ACROSS FSU<br />

Transformation exposes IR actors<br />

to significant challenges originating Seite page 219<br />

from the interplay of the socialist<br />

past and present choices, external<br />

and endogenous factors, as well as those that<br />

come from the interplay between the formal<br />

dimension of policy-making and its informal


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

dimension referring to actors’ behaviours.<br />

Both independent and ex-official unions find<br />

themselves at the intersection of these three<br />

dimensions of post-socialist transformation.<br />

Whereas actors have not grown up to the<br />

roles the new IR framework prescribes, they<br />

continue to structure their interactions outside<br />

the formal framework. In their formative<br />

processes, they combine the results of learning<br />

with experiences accumulated in the past. The<br />

learning of managers and unions is facilitated<br />

by the integration of the IR into the broader<br />

processes of globalization. Approaching actors<br />

from such a dynamic perspective (as formative<br />

processes offer) means to understand the<br />

scope and advance of choices they make. The<br />

complexity of changes on different dimensions<br />

of union formation (identity, agenda, structure,<br />

resources, relationships and conflicts management)<br />

defines union positioning in relation to<br />

IR. A trade union is likely to commit to the<br />

democratic model of unionism (on all dimensions)<br />

depending on its positioning within<br />

the current formal and informal settings and<br />

arenas, union origin and evolution, and the<br />

degree of insertion into the international trade<br />

union movement.<br />

Certainly, union positioning within the IR<br />

arenas is not a sole determinant of the final<br />

shape of IR, as unions are embedded in the<br />

interactions with employers meaning that<br />

local IR patterns reflect the process<br />

of interactions of both actors. For<br />

Seite page 220<br />

example, where employers remain authoritarian-paternalistic<br />

(as in many<br />

state and privatized enterprises), they<br />

will be likely to remain aggressive to independent<br />

unions, but will pursue cooperative<br />

relationships with the subordinate unions.<br />

As ownership and enterprise strategies diversify,<br />

so do managerial approaches to IR.<br />

The structuring of economic elites across<br />

FSU follows intra-entrepreneurial cleavages<br />

between old-style (administrators of former<br />

state enterprises) and new (newly emerging<br />

entrepreneurs) (Kabalina und Komarovsky<br />

1997). Respectively, traditional, Soviet-type IR<br />

patterns are most likely to be insulated within<br />

enterprises managed by old elites and leaving<br />

union structure intact. Change is rather unlikely<br />

here, as the inflows of new human capital<br />

remain low (Barberis, Boycko, Shleifer und<br />

Tsukanova 1996). This “conservatism” has been<br />

paralleled by informalization and individualization<br />

of work relations, often accompanied<br />

by the strengthening of the authoritarian style<br />

of management. Here management is increasingly<br />

hostile to trade unions “in anything<br />

other than their former role as accessories to<br />

management” (Pollert 1999: 214). In such a<br />

view, IR segmentation embraces the insulation<br />

of traditional IR in some segments and their<br />

individualization in the others.<br />

If managerial agency 6 is linked to the business<br />

system structuring, then the segmentsrelated<br />

IR dynamics can be better explained.<br />

It becomes clear that one or another business<br />

system segment is more conducive to certain<br />

managerial styles than the other and is able to<br />

explain outcomes in IR related to the assertiveness<br />

of trade unions. The differences within<br />

unions’ and managers’ approaches to IR impact<br />

the shape of IR and, for trade unions, the form<br />

of unionism they want to institutionalize.


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

VARIETIES OF UNIONISMS IN FSU<br />

Despite the introduction of pluralist principles<br />

across FSU countries, IR arenas do in fact<br />

continue to be dominated by previously existing<br />

(ex-official) trade unions. This situation hinges<br />

on differences in labour’s formative processes.<br />

Existing unions across FSU adapted their roles<br />

and conducted “cosmetic” reforms (Kabalina<br />

und Komarovsky 1997). Newly established<br />

unions, in order to develop their roles, initially<br />

embark on the contestation of arenas by means<br />

of collective action and strikes. As independent<br />

unions emerge, even if they fail to break the<br />

dominance of ex-official unions, they challenge<br />

their adaptive role which leads to rivalry and<br />

incoherence of labour movement across CIS 7 .<br />

The initial position from which ex-official<br />

unions in CIS countries entered the formation<br />

process was characterized by subordination, a<br />

“transmission-belts” identity, pro-management<br />

interest, and dependence on the resources<br />

provided by the state and management. New<br />

unions were established in protest to continuing<br />

subordination and a pro-management position<br />

of unions at the point when workers’ grievances<br />

multiplied (also Kubicek 2004). Both<br />

membership and resources were absorbed by<br />

former official unions and must be established<br />

from scratch by new unions. In fragile, semidemocratic<br />

regimes, democratic principles of<br />

unionism appear as embarrassing. Here, independent<br />

unions are viewed with suspicion by<br />

the presiding authorities and ex-official unions 8<br />

and are opposed by both.<br />

From these somewhat different starting conditions,<br />

there emerge different trajectories of<br />

union formation. For ex-official unions, striving<br />

to ensure their institutional survival and<br />

retaining their dominance becomes a priority.<br />

Ideally, in order to sustain long-term they<br />

need to break from subordination and acquire<br />

independence. For newly established unions,<br />

the formative processes are about the contestation<br />

of arenas dominated at present by the<br />

ex-official unions. They are about gaining recognition<br />

and extension of membership base. In<br />

the view of above mentioned differences, the<br />

kind and sources of union weaknesses cannot<br />

be generalized in the same manner for both<br />

former official and newly established unions.<br />

WEAKNESSES OF THE TRADE UNION MOVE-<br />

MENT IN THE CONDITIONS OF POST-SOCIALIST<br />

TRANSFORMATION<br />

Crowley (2001) and Crowley und Ost (2001)<br />

shaped the definition of union weaknesses<br />

while arguing that “… workers and unions<br />

were unable to shape conditions of work and<br />

public policy in accord with their interests…<br />

it has been the object and not the subject of<br />

the postcommunist reform” (Crowley und Ost<br />

2001: 219-220). In terms of aggregate macro<br />

indicators (e.g. membership decline, low wages<br />

and weak union input to policy-making),<br />

unions are correctly argued to remain weak.<br />

However, locally the issues of union weaknesses<br />

play out differently as the conditions of<br />

the same severities local IR outcomes vary 9 .<br />

For example, whereas union membership<br />

decline could be explained by Seite page 221<br />

structural factors 10 , notable is that former<br />

official and independent unions<br />

do not reveal similar membership dynamics.<br />

Here, the drastic fall in ex-official union density<br />

was contrasted by slow but steady growth


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

of independent unions. Similarly, in the CEE<br />

countries data on unions’ membership loss<br />

(Pollert 1999) demonstrate the variance in the<br />

degree of union revitalization. In particular,<br />

in Ukraine the former official unions loose<br />

around a million of members each year. Even<br />

if slow, newly established unions succeed in<br />

extending their membership rates in a sustainable<br />

manner. As regards weaknesses in union<br />

militancy, one can apply a similar logic of argumentation.<br />

In spite of a low record of strikes<br />

already in 1993, more strikes were recorded in<br />

Ukraine than in Russia, whereas the number<br />

of days lost during strikes also exceeded those<br />

in Russia 11 . The distribution of strikes demonstrates<br />

that independent unions more actively<br />

cultivate mobilization and striking activities<br />

within the settings of social partnership (e.g.<br />

Crowley 2000) than the ex-official unions do.<br />

The dimensions of transformation vary in<br />

their effects on the kinds of unionism. Informal<br />

politics used by ex-official unions for the<br />

purposes of exclusion and marginalization of<br />

independent unions pre-emptively preclude<br />

the contestation of arenas by new trade unions.<br />

The most recent examples of a bill “on social<br />

dialogue” in Ukraine submitted by the exofficial<br />

union federation clearly explicate it<br />

in that it strived to marginalize and exclude<br />

the majority of newly established independent<br />

trade union organizations out of official IR<br />

mechanisms. This is in spite of principles<br />

of pluralism enshrined in law.<br />

Seite page 222<br />

Legacies of the past, as the second<br />

impacting factor, find probably the<br />

strongest expression in the case of unions.<br />

Legacies might no longer be so evident on<br />

the level of identity and mission as all unions<br />

declared themselves independent. However,<br />

further levels of ex-official union choices and<br />

operations demonstrate the continuity with<br />

the past, and with it - how symbolic a change<br />

in the unions’ mission was. The scope of union<br />

activities and services (social and welfare<br />

benefits) still too greatly resembles socialist<br />

practices, even though meets workers’ demands<br />

on unions for the time being.<br />

Independent unions relying on mobilization<br />

and collective action have to struggle with<br />

such workers’ legacies. On the one hand, bizarre<br />

co-existence of socialist collectivity and<br />

individualism and passivity does not express<br />

itself into workers’ effective collective action<br />

and self-organization (Ashwin 1996). On the<br />

other hand, deep cultural limits to the role of<br />

interest representation in workers’ perceptions<br />

re-enforce a legalistic and individualized approach<br />

of workers to articulate their grievances,<br />

which is, indeed, spread across CEE (Pollert<br />

1999). Such legacies constrains new unions’<br />

opportunities to extend their major resource<br />

– militant membership. So, where ex-official<br />

unions inherit resources (membership and<br />

property) facilitating their survival, newly established<br />

unions are attacked in the resources<br />

that would ensure their successes.<br />

External influences are catalysts in that they<br />

pressure unions for renewal (Ashwin 2007).<br />

The discourse of social partnership facilitated<br />

the establishment of union freedoms and<br />

pluralism, at least on the constitutional and<br />

legislative levels. In institutional terms, it basically<br />

opened arenas of IR for newly emergent<br />

unions and provided a necessary degree of relegitimizing<br />

unions (Pollert 2000) as interestrepresenting<br />

institutions. Emerging and still


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

fighting for recognition, unions could have<br />

extracted further benefits, as social partnership<br />

provided for room for control and pressure<br />

mechanisms (e.g. ILO) on the implementation<br />

of pluralist principles in the area of IR.<br />

Independent unions could also draw on bilateral<br />

cooperation with European and American<br />

unions. However, social partnership precluded<br />

the articulation of workers’ interest by means<br />

other than conciliation. Thus far, the rhetoric<br />

of social partnership “was no more consistent<br />

with independent forms of workers’ organization<br />

than had been the rhetoric of “socialism”<br />

before it” (Clarke und Fairbrother 1994: 379).<br />

It prescribed conciliatory and concessiondriven<br />

activities for all IR actors on the cost of<br />

increasing their strength by collective action.<br />

The prospects of the trade union movement<br />

in CIS might not look promising. The prevailing<br />

response of unions was “to exchange the<br />

subservience to management and the state<br />

in the name of “socialism” for subservience<br />

to management and the state in the name of<br />

“social partnership” (Mandel 2004: 59). Indeed,<br />

prospects are provided by the consequent development<br />

of the independent trade unions.<br />

THE STATE OF IR IN UKRAINE<br />

At the onset of transformation, Ukraine was assumed<br />

to quickly catch up with Western living<br />

standards (Mandel 2004). Later on, however,<br />

Ukraine was identified as the slow transformation<br />

country (Wittkowsky 1998) compared to<br />

the others. The lack of transformation progress<br />

was attributed to a lack of political will of<br />

then-Ukrainian governments, strong embeddedness<br />

of the rent-seeking interests (e.g.<br />

Aslund 2002, Wittkowsky 1998), and heavy<br />

economic dependence of Ukraine on Russia<br />

(Mandel 2004). The following section, firstly,<br />

suggests a brief overview of the economic and<br />

political developments since Ukraine gained<br />

its independence in 1991 as well as the social<br />

consequences. It is then followed by a review<br />

of the institutional re-arrangement of IR and<br />

the regulation of union activities. It is once this<br />

Ukrainian context of IR is set that differences<br />

in emerging unionisms are outlined.<br />

POLITICAL AND SOCIO-ECONOMIC SITUATION<br />

Ukraine declared its independence in 1991,<br />

but the advance of economic reforms hardly<br />

took place until the late 1990s. Notably, as no<br />

clear rules were laid down in the first years<br />

of the transformation, rent-seeking interests<br />

that have originated from nomenklatura<br />

(party top positions) acquired strong positions<br />

in both economics and politics. This tight<br />

overlapping of economic and political<br />

interests resulted in the promotion of reforms<br />

and corrupt privatization serving the profit<br />

and power-oriented needs of wealthy elites.<br />

Business elites that consolidated in 1990s were<br />

identified as oligarchs 12 , clans, and financialindustrial<br />

groups 13 (Kowall und Zimmer<br />

2002). The symbiotic relationships between<br />

the political and economic core actors (and<br />

businesses direct representation in<br />

the Parliament and ministries) led to<br />

the blockade of the economic reforms Seite page 223<br />

(e.g. Pleines 2006, 2008) and “region<br />

capture” (Zimmer 2002). Hence,<br />

prior to 2004 one speaks about Ukraine as<br />

the system in the form of oligarchy (Kowall<br />

und Zimmer 2002) and autocracy (Franzen,


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

Haarland und Niessen 2005).<br />

In 1994 the neo-liberal programme of<br />

reforms (embracing standardized IMF’s<br />

policy prescriptions) was adopted under then-<br />

President Leonid Kuchma with the assistance<br />

of the International Monetary Fund (IMF)<br />

and the World Bank. Neo-liberal reforms<br />

exacerbated the structural economic problems<br />

Ukraine inherited 14 and led to a steep economic<br />

decline. “Ukraine is the only transition country<br />

to have known nine consecutive years of<br />

economic decline” (1991-9) (van Zon 2002).<br />

The first signs of economic growth appeared<br />

only in 2000 (Merkel 2008). Then Ukraine<br />

showed the highest performance in Europe<br />

with the growth of 15.8% and 12.5% in the<br />

years 2003 and 2004, respectively (Chernyshev<br />

2006). Meanwhile, subsidies and social<br />

spending were reduced and wages and their<br />

increase freezed (Mandel 2004). Until growth<br />

resumed, official employment declined by<br />

one-third between 1990 and 1999, given the<br />

40% reductions in industry and agriculture<br />

employment (Chernyshev 2006).<br />

By 2001, three fourths of the economy (as<br />

of 2005, 78.3%) was claimed to be private.<br />

However, these estimations also included the<br />

enterprises in which the state retained its share<br />

(Franzen, Haarland und Niessen 2005). They<br />

employed 73.8% of the total workforce (Statistics<br />

Annual of Ukraine – 2005 cited<br />

in CASE 2007). However, by value of<br />

Seite page 224<br />

the assets, the state and communal<br />

authorities still retained over one half<br />

– 54.8% - of the assets (CASE 2007),<br />

mainly huge strategic enterprises that have been<br />

excluded from the privatization, but which play<br />

a significant role in the Ukrainian economy.<br />

The Ukrainian governments were anything<br />

but successful in developing socially oriented<br />

responses to the economic decline. In the<br />

period of hyper-inflation, the indexation of<br />

wages was ceased between 1992 and 1997 15 ,<br />

leading to a significant fall in workers’ real<br />

wages. Even though the government regulated<br />

wages through legally-set minimum wage, it<br />

failed to increase it to the levels of the legally<br />

set subsistence minimum, thus violating its<br />

own laws. Workers’ earnings were far from<br />

adequate 16 . Even after the freeze of wages was<br />

abolished, both insolvent and economically active<br />

enterprises continued to accumulate wage<br />

debts. Wage increases driven by improved<br />

economic performance still left one fourth of<br />

the population below the poverty line in 2004<br />

(Chernyshev 2006).<br />

Corrupt and rent-driven policy making<br />

were interrupted by the mass protest of 2004<br />

identified under the term “Orange Revolution”.<br />

Caused by the vote frauds during the<br />

presidential elections, these protests resulted in<br />

the election of expectedly more democratically<br />

oriented President Yushchenko. Whereas his<br />

Presidency allowed for more freedoms (not<br />

least, media and independent union freedoms),<br />

he has been consistently criticized for his inability<br />

to overcome intra-governmental cleavages<br />

and a failure to advance the socio-economic<br />

development of Ukraine. The slight increase in<br />

living standards brought on by the economic<br />

growth of recent years (since around 2005) was,<br />

however, anything else than long-term and sustainable,<br />

as achievements were soon smashed<br />

away by the global financial crisis. Since 2008<br />

the Ukrainian economy, together with the<br />

living standards of the population, entered a<br />

downturn again.


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

There is no need to stress that living conditions<br />

of the Ukrainian population have deteriorated<br />

enormously since Ukraine gained<br />

independence. The transformation towards<br />

capitalism in its Ukrainian version has led to a<br />

deterioration in working conditions and workers’<br />

earnings, facilitating an erosion of social<br />

security. According to the People’s Security<br />

Survey conducted by the International Labour<br />

Organization and the State Statistics Committee<br />

of Ukraine in 2003, a monthly income<br />

per capita amounted to less than $100, 40% of<br />

wage earners suffered from wage arrears, over<br />

two-thirds were dissatisfied with their wages,<br />

and about 85% of adults could not even cover<br />

their healthcare needs.<br />

INSTITUTIONAL FRAMEWORK OF IR IN<br />

UKRAINE<br />

In spite of pressures, the institutional framework<br />

in Ukraine is generously supportive of workers<br />

and unions. It allocates a broad scope of rights<br />

to trade unions to regulate employment, working<br />

conditions and workers’ pay. Surprisingly,<br />

unions have failed to derive maximum benefits<br />

from this. The inability to assert workers’ interest<br />

and interest antagonism and give effects to<br />

the collective bargaining represent their major<br />

failures. But the regulation of workers’ rights<br />

has been under attack and the processes of deregulation<br />

already begun. As the labour market<br />

is changing, so are the forms of employment. In<br />

contrast to full-time employment of indefinite<br />

duration, civil-law, self-employment, employment<br />

by small entrepreneurs and informal employment<br />

were introduced. All these emerging<br />

forms of work have hardly found any relevance<br />

with trade unions.<br />

LABOUR CODE<br />

The central piece of the codification of labour<br />

rights has been the Soviet Labour Code<br />

adopted in 1971. As in socialism, current<br />

labour legislation remains pre-conditioned on<br />

the employment contract and implicitly on<br />

trade union membership, thus leaving workers<br />

without the written labour contract and<br />

unions outside. Such conditionality goes back<br />

to the socialist regulatory traditions. The most<br />

detailed legal and administrative regulation of<br />

IR ever, the Soviet labour law, was designed<br />

in part to strengthen labour discipline and<br />

increase productivity (as opposed to defend<br />

workers). State paternalism implicitly excluded<br />

the voluntary regulation of work by workers<br />

and employers. Workers felt responsible for<br />

regulating everyday small issues but delegated<br />

all other responsibilities to the state. This is<br />

the case even today, as only less than ten per<br />

cent of workers would go to unions in cases<br />

of violations of their labour rights (Razumkov<br />

Centre 2001).<br />

With the background of influx economic<br />

developments and enterprise-specific changes,<br />

labour rights have remained heavily regulated<br />

through the Labour Code of 1971. The initial<br />

amendments of the Labour Code did not<br />

go beyond formal and superficial changes.<br />

A more intensive revision process that has<br />

been on-going since 2003 prompted<br />

a degree of the de-regulation. Summarized<br />

in the new draft and adopted Seite page 225<br />

in the first reading in 2008, the new<br />

Labour Code aimed to adjust labour<br />

legislation to market conditions, according to<br />

its initiators – surprisingly – from trade union<br />

leaders 17 . The adoption of this draft was post-


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

poned by union pressure until certain amendments<br />

by trade unions were incorporated<br />

(KVPU, new release of 27.05.2009). Unlike<br />

in Russia, where a strongly neo-liberal Labour<br />

Code has been in place since 2000, Ukrainian<br />

trade unions were more pro-active in delaying<br />

the de-regulation process 18 .<br />

The effects of the new labour legislation will<br />

be deteriorating for workers and weaken trade<br />

unions in their protective capacity. The work<br />

day will be prolonged to 10 hours (compared<br />

to 8 hour-days at present). Employers will dismiss<br />

workers within two weeks without union<br />

approval. They will regulate enterprise-based<br />

IR by means of their own internal provisions.<br />

The new code no longer obliges employers to<br />

sign collective agreements nor report on their<br />

implementation. For disputes related to agreements<br />

they can no longer be taken to labour<br />

courts. In a similar manner, employers will no<br />

longer be obliged to provide unions with office<br />

premises or check-off systems of dues 19 .<br />

COLLECTIVE BARGAINING<br />

Collective bargaining in the existing form has<br />

been present in Ukraine since 1993 20 . It was<br />

introduced as an institution aiming at the<br />

regulation of labour relations and socio-economic<br />

interest of both workers and employers<br />

and extended to all levels and forms<br />

of ownership. First in the history of<br />

Seite page 226<br />

its existence, bargaining was designed<br />

according to the principles (Conventions<br />

and Recommendations) of the<br />

ILO. As a result, in 1995 a mechanism was set<br />

to increase wages through the development of<br />

negotiatable coefficients.<br />

However, in spite of the growing number<br />

of collective agreements, its effectiveness<br />

remained low. Workers did not consider<br />

bargaining to be their responsibility; and collective<br />

bargaining remained an act to be done<br />

between the administration and trade union<br />

committee. Yet both parties revealed a low<br />

degree of responsibility for the promotion of<br />

workers’ interests by means of collective agreements.<br />

Firstly, whereas the Federation of Trade<br />

Unions of Ukraine (FPU) alone unites around<br />

120,000 primary organizations, the total number<br />

of signed collective agreements as of 2007<br />

constituted only 95,781, almost half of which<br />

are in state administering (the highest number<br />

of agreements by sector), education, and health<br />

and social assistance (State Statistics Committee<br />

of Ukraine 2008). Respectively, collective<br />

agreements cover slightly under 10 million<br />

workers, only 82.4% of pay-roll workers and<br />

hardly extends to those not on pay-rolls.<br />

Secondly, employers spent (as of 2007) only 283<br />

hryvnya (equivalent to ca. 30 Euro) per worker<br />

as a result of additional benefits set by bargaining.<br />

Upom closer examination, it appears that<br />

collective agreements mostly re-state legal<br />

provisions, as the minimum tariff scales are the<br />

same as that in law in 70.8%, and in only 26.6%<br />

are they higher (State Statistics Committee of<br />

Ukraine 2008). 2.6% of agreements even set the<br />

tariff coefficient lower than those in law, while<br />

5.6% of agreements set lower tariff coefficients<br />

than in the Sectoral Agreement (the same<br />

source). Thirdly, officially the compliance with<br />

the collective agreements amounts to 94-96%<br />

in average (the same source). However, according<br />

to the Chief State Labour Inspector, Ihor<br />

Sumovs’ky, violations are detected in 90-95%<br />

of audited enterprises 21 . As these data demon-


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

strate, collective bargaining is ineffective.<br />

Beyond the weaknesses in union ability to<br />

enforce the regulation of IR, collective agreements<br />

can be considered arena of contestation<br />

between different trade unions. In particular,<br />

in the case that more unions exist at the same<br />

enterprise, they must establish a joint representation<br />

body to negotiate and sign agreements.<br />

Respectively, if unions fail to establish such<br />

a body (a quite probable case in light of the<br />

intra-union rivalries), employers can choose<br />

the union to negotiate with. This allocates<br />

some advantages to the ex-official unions and<br />

basically marginalizes or excludes independent<br />

trade unions from the arena of such regulation<br />

of working conditions.<br />

COLLECTIVE LABOUR DISPUTES AND SETTLE-<br />

MENT PROCEDURES<br />

The institutions of dispute settlement were<br />

implemented in Ukraine only in 1998. They<br />

are based on the procedure of conciliation between<br />

the contractual parties, and envisage the<br />

disputes solution by labour arbitrary and National<br />

Service of Mediation and Conciliation.<br />

The latter is responsible for the registration of<br />

disputes and issues non-binding recommendation<br />

to solve the relevant issues. Interestingly,<br />

the facilitation of the collective disputes by the<br />

national conciliation service acquired the forms<br />

of the suppression of protest actions undertaken<br />

in cases of disputes. Only in the case that the<br />

parties to the dispute have completed all mediation<br />

and conciliation procedures can strikes<br />

be declared. Otherwise, strikes are illegal. Thus,<br />

the legislative regulation of labour disputes, in<br />

fact, prompts the individualization of labour<br />

conflicts and their resolution through long,<br />

drawn-out judicial procedures rather than on<br />

the basis of mobilization 22 .<br />

This kind of regulation originates from the<br />

promotion of social partnership in Ukraine<br />

by ILO. The benefits of the consensus-driven<br />

policy process are undeniable - the articulation<br />

of labour disputes is channelled into an<br />

arbitrary sphere by law in a way that creates<br />

obstacles for workers’ collective action at<br />

times where interests can be pursued solely<br />

in a militant manner. Many union leaders<br />

explain the lack of strikes by these legal preconditions<br />

23 . In particular, major obstacles<br />

arise out of this for independent trade unions.<br />

Whereas the emergence of many unions is<br />

conflict-driven, independent trade unions are<br />

established in cases where conflicts that arise<br />

are not absorbed by any mechanisms of their<br />

institutional articulation. Until the conciliation<br />

procedures are completed, unions are all<br />

too often pressured and destroyed. The spread<br />

of such experiences among new trade unions<br />

makes the further establishment of independent<br />

trade unions more difficult 24 .<br />

THE SCOPE OF UKRAINIAN TRADE UNIONISMS<br />

Notably, in early socialism trade unions were<br />

basically imposed on workers: membership<br />

was automatic, trade unionism was<br />

modelled on the monolithic principles,<br />

and workers’ relationships to Seite page 227<br />

the unions were structured along<br />

distributor-consumer principles. Instead<br />

of articulating workers’ concerns (other<br />

than the violation of the law) through trade<br />

unions, workers were disciplined by them.


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

And instead of receiving increases in wages,<br />

workers received discounted holiday vouchers<br />

and holiday presents. Here trade unions<br />

appeared as an entity external to workers and<br />

in which workers’ involvement and participation<br />

was restricted to the obedience to labour<br />

discipline and productivity targets. Workers<br />

find points of contact with the unions only in<br />

relation to their social and welfare interests.<br />

Hence, beyond atomizing workers (Ashwin<br />

1996, 1999), system legacies find its expression<br />

in structuring union-workers’ relationships not<br />

along representation but rather consumerism.<br />

This nature of the linkages between unions<br />

and workers also continues, to a large extent,<br />

to structure union-workers relationships post-<br />

1991 25 .<br />

Shortly before the collapse of the Soviet Union,<br />

there appeared the signs of the activization<br />

of the union movement outside the existing<br />

union structures. These predictions of union<br />

change were initially inspired miners’ strikes<br />

of late 80-s in Russia and Ukraine. Notably,<br />

workers’ militancy resulted in the emergence<br />

of alternative union-like structures, giving the<br />

first split to the monolithic unionism model<br />

existing so far. Initially identified as striking<br />

committees, workers’ self-organizations are<br />

developed later on into trade union organizations<br />

(interviews).<br />

As unions’ militancy over time has<br />

decline and current wage levels signalled<br />

unions’ inability in these areas,<br />

Seite page 228<br />

it became clear that neither ex-official<br />

nor alternative trade unions were<br />

ready to fully overtake the function of workers’<br />

protection. In the literature, alternative unions<br />

were perceived as playing no significant role<br />

in IR, facing marginalization or slipping back<br />

into a traditional mould (Clarke und Fairbrother<br />

1994). Meanwhile, the Ukrainian cases<br />

deserves attention, as the share of trade unions<br />

affiliated with the ex-official Federation of<br />

Trade Unions of Ukraine (FPU) shrank from<br />

100 per cent in 1993 to claimed 55.8 per cent<br />

in 2004. In contrast, trade union organizations<br />

belonging to other trade union federations<br />

increased threefold during 2000-2004 (Chernyshev<br />

2006).<br />

Upon closer examination, it becomes clear<br />

that in case of Ukraine one speaks not about<br />

pure fragmentation of union movements along<br />

old-style ex-official and newly established<br />

alternative unions, but indeed, along different<br />

visions of unionisms. In particular, on the way<br />

towards finding their role and niche in the patterns<br />

of organized interest representation, one<br />

finds unionisms in Ukraine differentiating in<br />

terms of their ideologies and identities, organizational<br />

structures, prioritized resources, and<br />

a set of relationships with members, employers<br />

and the state. Sometimes (e.g. in case of conflict<br />

articulation as Kozina (2005) shows) they<br />

even oppose each other. As the processes of the<br />

searches on such dimensions are still on-going<br />

(and the framework of IR is still in making),<br />

such formative processes of different unionisms<br />

provide useful insights into the prospects of<br />

the transformation of IR in Ukraine. Notably,<br />

both unionisms are placed into a set of different<br />

immediate external conditions (defined by<br />

relationships with employers and authorities);<br />

and managers are more likely to deal with exofficial<br />

than independent unions.<br />

The current union density in Ukraine still constitutes<br />

approximately 50% of the workforce


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

according to unions themselves (down from<br />

almost 100 % in late 1990s) (interviews). Notably,<br />

behind it is formal membership. According<br />

to survey results (e.g. Razumkov Centre 2001)<br />

in 2001, 43.7% of members have remained in<br />

the union by tradition from the Soviet days,<br />

and 20.2% members joined because it was customary<br />

at their enterprise. In addition, 12.2%<br />

reported that trade unions were established at<br />

their enterprises in a centralized manner and<br />

no one had ever asked for their consent to be a<br />

trade union member (the same sources).<br />

Stronger than structural reasons of union<br />

decline, workers’ disillusionment with trade<br />

unions and their withdrawal (sometimes in<br />

whole organizations) are better placed to explain<br />

membership drops. Only 18.7% of union<br />

members believed in unions as an institution<br />

protecting their rights (Razumkov Centre<br />

2001). This trend was hardly countervailed<br />

by unions with a comprehensive organizing<br />

strategy, as organizing was unfamiliar to them.<br />

Surprisingly though, in the view that the institutional<br />

preconditions were conducive for<br />

expanding their activities, unions were guided<br />

by own self-interests. Not least, this also explains<br />

their reluctance to recognize and address<br />

the employment effects brought about by the<br />

economic structuring processes and the consequent<br />

loosening of work regulation.<br />

Remarkably, membership as a resource (as<br />

unions are normally dependent on membership<br />

for financial means in the form of dues) lost its<br />

relevance for ex-official trade unions. Whereas<br />

under socialism unions were imposed on workers<br />

as an external body (see this argument in<br />

the previous section), they were provided with<br />

resources and their recognition and power was<br />

granted by the Party. As all the financial and<br />

material resources could have been retained<br />

by the Federation of Trade Unions of Ukraine<br />

(FPU), organizing as such lost its importance.<br />

The assets inherited from the predecessor’<br />

trade union amounted to approximately 3<br />

billion dollars (interviews); and commercial<br />

activities could be launched. In 1993 then-<br />

FPU President Olexandr Stoyan declared that<br />

it is necessary for the FPU to strengthen the<br />

financial base of the trade union federation by<br />

means of commercial activities (“Trade unions’<br />

newspaper”, 6 February 1993) 26 . Consequently,<br />

the Federation came out of socialism as an<br />

organization that has been independent of its<br />

members. Its existence (at least in financial<br />

terms) is no longer contingent on members<br />

and dues. By means of such choices, however,<br />

the FPU put itself into the dependence<br />

relationship in relation to the government,<br />

as the legitimacy of the FPU’s ownership of<br />

these resources was questioned and attacked<br />

elsewhere.<br />

The structuring dynamic looks different in<br />

these regards in the case of the trade unions<br />

emerging bottom up from workers’ selforganization.<br />

Remarkably, an impetus for this<br />

organization became the invalidity of existing<br />

trade unions in the area of workers’ representation<br />

and protection (interviews). In arising<br />

conflicts the existing unions took the part<br />

of the management, including the<br />

public discussion of labour disputes<br />

in courts (interviews). The spread of Seite page 229<br />

this kind of unionism allowed for a<br />

structural consolidation of different<br />

alternative unions into the Association of<br />

Free Trade Unions of Ukraine (1997) and its<br />

reform in 1998 into the Confederation of Free


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

Trade Unions of Ukraine (hereafter KVPU).<br />

At this starting point, the KVPU united only<br />

two sectoral and one regional union and was<br />

basically founded on the initiative and base of<br />

the Independent Trade Union of Miners of<br />

Ukraine (NPGU). In total, the then 90 000<br />

members within the KVPU were certainly<br />

non-comparable to the declared 14-million<br />

in the FPU (that had already almost halved at<br />

that point in time). However, it placed in the<br />

centre of unions’ activities the need for expansive<br />

strategy and spured the solidarity over the<br />

frontiers of the enterprise and sectors. Now,<br />

ten years later, the KVPU has slowly, but in a<br />

sustainable manner, expanded to unite 275,000<br />

members through the establishment of the<br />

further all-Ukrainian unions. Even though<br />

this number still appears non-comparable to<br />

the now around 10 million members left in<br />

the FPU, the dynamic of extending unionisms<br />

across the branches, professions and enterprises<br />

speaks for a more sustainable formative strategy.<br />

Notably, the model of unionism to which<br />

the KVPU commits is closer to the class-based<br />

union ideology in the classical understanding<br />

of unions.<br />

As the legalization procedure for unions was<br />

simplified, the certificate from authorities was<br />

not enough to gain recognition from workers,<br />

employers, and authorities. Moreover, the very<br />

notion of unionism was already discredited.<br />

Neither was the social partnership<br />

able to ensure a degree of recognition<br />

Seite page 230<br />

of these organizations. In particular,<br />

newly emerging bottom up structures<br />

had to frequently turn to the collective<br />

action as a means of recognition and<br />

subsequent consolidation of the specific workers’<br />

interest (also mentioned by Kabalina and<br />

Komarovsky 1997) and so recommended itself<br />

as more militant organizations.<br />

EX-OFFICIAL UNIONS<br />

The structuration process of ex-official trade<br />

unions includes the reforms of then-existing<br />

Council of Trade Unions of the Ukrainian<br />

Soviet Socialist Republic into the Federation<br />

of the Independent Trade Unions of Ukraine<br />

(in 1990). In the course of the further developments,<br />

the latter was renamed the Federation<br />

of Trade Unions of Ukraine (hereafter FPU), as<br />

it is still known today. In spite of reforms, the<br />

FPU was characterized as “a largely conservative<br />

organization that did little more than issue<br />

hollow proclamations while millions of workers<br />

were pushed into poverty” (Kubicek 2004:<br />

29). The reforms undertaken by the FPU were<br />

criticized in public as cosmetic, as they did not<br />

go beyond the organizational restructuring on<br />

the principles of confederation or federation<br />

(interviews). The decentralization of the organizational<br />

and membership-dues structures<br />

(as opposite to previously practiced democratic<br />

centralism) resulted in a disconnection between<br />

different levels of union activities. For example,<br />

enterprise-based unions find themselves in isolation<br />

in the face of employers (interviews) 27 ;<br />

and regional and national unions can no longer<br />

impose their decisions, also concerning the<br />

transfer of membership dues to the top.<br />

Structural reform did not go beyond the statements<br />

of the re-establishment of the FPU as<br />

workers’ organization. Whereas the principles<br />

of democratic centralism were abolished and<br />

the organizational structure decentralized, it<br />

still has not reflected the clear demarcation


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

of the FPU from employers. In particular, the<br />

FPU “preserved a Soviet trade union tradition<br />

of simultaneous membership of hired workers<br />

and employers” (National Security and Defence<br />

2001, 8: 28). Symbolically in relation to<br />

reforms is the fact that the FPU removed the<br />

symbols of socialism (hammer and sickle) from<br />

the front of its headquarters only in 2003 28 .<br />

Prior to 2001, the formative processes of the<br />

FPU embraced its attempts to preserve its<br />

withdrawing membership. However, the preservation<br />

strategy was hardly complemented by<br />

attempts at expansion in response to the restructuring<br />

of the labour market. Respectively,<br />

its membership density further declined with<br />

the growth of the private sector, newly established<br />

enterprises and mushrooming small<br />

firms.<br />

The activities of the Federation have been<br />

characterized by frequent changes in political<br />

position the 1990s. Declaratory criticism of the<br />

politics has never resulted in national strikes<br />

or protests. Meanwhile, the government policy<br />

was criticized and challenged by ad hoc actions<br />

of some enterprise-based union organizations<br />

in their effort to protect their enterprises, quite<br />

often jointly with employers. For example, in<br />

response to the President’s decree dated 16<br />

March 1995 on the strengthening of the financial<br />

discipline, workers of the ship construction<br />

plant in Mykolaiv went on strike against the<br />

decree even though it did not have any direct<br />

effects for workers’ interests. Workers striked<br />

after the ship plant director informed them<br />

that, due to the decree, they will no longer get<br />

their wages (interviews).<br />

The lack of cohesion between different levels<br />

of union activities is demonstrated by the positioning<br />

of the top-level FPU and its regional<br />

and branch structures. At the background of<br />

the deteriorating living standards throughout<br />

1990s, branch and regional unions associations<br />

demand concessions for their branches<br />

or regions, yet their demands lag behind<br />

class-driven. Some regional councils of unions<br />

(e.g. Donets’k, Kharkiv and Dnipropetrovs’k)<br />

even went on to declare pre-strike situations<br />

demanding that minimum wages increase<br />

up to the subsistence level. At this time, the<br />

President of the Federation publicly declared<br />

that “trade unions of Ukraine support the<br />

President’s request to retreat from strikes”<br />

(UTN, 4.04.1994). In December 1995, Olexandr<br />

Stoyan, then-President of the FPU,<br />

received together with then-Prime Minister of<br />

Ukraine, the award of the Foundation ”Social<br />

Partnership” for the ”particular contribution<br />

to the conclusion of the General Agreement,<br />

the social partnership development and peace”<br />

(Mist, 29.10-05.11, 1995).<br />

The FPU’s legitimacy was meanwhile questioned<br />

and challenged elsewhere. In 1996<br />

many miners’ strikes took place in Ukraine<br />

with demands for payment of wages arrears.<br />

The FPU was forced to act but was cautious<br />

about damaging its relationships with the<br />

government and authorities. It declared the<br />

country-wide strikes against the general<br />

fall in the living standards and<br />

stopped work at enterprises for one Seite page 231<br />

hour. As one could have imagined,<br />

it is much easier to sustain one hour<br />

stoppage than a normal strike. Such tactics<br />

were used by the FPU on a regular basis for<br />

some time throughout 1990s.


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

Shortly before the Presidential elections of<br />

2004, the FPU concluded the alliance with<br />

then-Prime Minister and candidate for<br />

presidency, Viktor Yanukovych, who was<br />

alleged of vote frauds once the elections took<br />

place. The FPU, nevertheless, remained loyal<br />

to its candidate. During the mass protests<br />

against the vote fraud and this candidate,<br />

identified later on as the Orange Revolution,<br />

PU Olexandr Stoyan publicly appealed to the<br />

President of Ukraine to use all possible means<br />

to insure peace and prevent people from<br />

protesting. In response, workers occupied the<br />

central FPU building and Stoyan flee.<br />

The new FPU President, Olexandr Yurkin,<br />

initiated some reforms within FPU. As he told<br />

in one of the interviews, the FPU embarked on<br />

the process of the “internal reforms” bringing<br />

the Federation out of the organizational forms<br />

of the old Soviet unions’ association VTsRPS,<br />

including the strengthening of the primary<br />

organizations, branch trade unions, oblast<br />

(provincial) union councils, and broadening of<br />

their authorities. “Either we all modernize, or<br />

die”, stated the FPU President 29 . The structural<br />

reforms have hardly ever beenrealized, partly<br />

because the activities of the trade unions were<br />

often concentrated on retaining its property<br />

and partly due to the resistance of the union<br />

leaders of the regional and branch trade<br />

unions.<br />

Meanwhile, great efforts were put<br />

Seite page 232<br />

into the enhancement of the public<br />

image and PR-policy. Under his<br />

presidency, a new concept of the FPU<br />

development 30 and a detailed plan of actions 31<br />

come out. Both set an extensive scope of quite<br />

ambitious goals for the FPU over the next<br />

five years, including the creation of 4 million<br />

workplaces, wage increases of four or five<br />

minimum wage levels 32 , and the increase of<br />

the living standards of workers up the Western<br />

European ones. Unions committed themselves<br />

to reform the medical and education spheres,<br />

and facilitate the growth of the housing<br />

markets. FPU also committed itself to finally<br />

establish cooperation with other trade unions<br />

and coordinate union activities across the<br />

country 33 .<br />

Following Yurkin’s resignation, the new congress<br />

of the FPU, in spite of its announcement, has<br />

never taken place. In November 2008, the FPU<br />

Council elected the Party of Regions MP and<br />

the President of the Donetsk regional council<br />

of trade unions, Vasyl’ Khara, as the FPU<br />

President. The FPU remained committed to<br />

its previously adopted concept of development<br />

and a plan of action under Khara’s Presidency.<br />

But Khara’s presidency has been constantly<br />

surrounded by numerous controversies. As he<br />

was elected by the FPU Council and not by its<br />

Congress (as the FPU Constitution stipulates),<br />

the court of the city of Kyiv cancelled the decree<br />

and legal findings issued earlier by the Ministry<br />

of Justice confirming the legitimacy of Khara’s<br />

election and presidency 34 . Meanwhile, the FPU<br />

refused to cooperate with other trade unions<br />

and concentrated on the preservation and<br />

further commercialization of its properties.<br />

In this light, the activities of the Federation<br />

cannot be identified as those representing and<br />

defending workers. Rather reforms of some<br />

enterprise-based unions and attempts within<br />

the branch unions remind us that the FPU<br />

structure is far from being homogeneous and<br />

coherent.


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

INDEPENDENT TRADE UNIONS<br />

Since 1989 in the Eastern region of Ukrainian<br />

Donbass there have emerged first striking<br />

committees among miners giving rise to<br />

independent bottom-up unions. These unions<br />

emerged in the opposition to the activities of<br />

the existing miners’ trade unions that proved<br />

indefinite to workers’ growing complaints.<br />

As no trade union law existed at that point<br />

of time in the Soviet Union, miners’ unions<br />

acquired legitimacy and recognition by the<br />

scale of their collective action. Miners’ strikes<br />

across the Donbass were partly responsible for<br />

the collapse of the socialist system (Crowley<br />

2000). Similar initiatives emerged among<br />

transportation workers.<br />

The years before 1998 became the years of<br />

establishment, structuring and consolidation<br />

of the oppositional trade union movement<br />

of Ukraine identified in the literature as new,<br />

independent, free, or alternative. The overall<br />

situation within trade unions made it clear<br />

that a solely sectoral unionism has hardly<br />

any prospects in the view of the continuing<br />

dominance of the ex-official trade unions.<br />

Hence, it was necessary to structure and improve<br />

the shape and expand this unionism into other<br />

sectors. Such understanding prompted leaders<br />

of independent unions to launch quite early the<br />

debate on spurring workers’ solidarity across<br />

the mining sector frontiers. Significant in this<br />

regard was the training on organizing provided<br />

by the Solidarity centre of the American unions<br />

AFL-CIO.<br />

In the course of the structural consolidation<br />

of the independent trade union movement,<br />

the lack of the united vision of how this<br />

unionism should look became evident.<br />

The crisis originated in the split among the<br />

leaders of different independent unions 35 in<br />

their negotiations of the all-Ukrainian strike<br />

planned on 18 January 1994 that aimed at<br />

the retreat of the then Prime-Minister. This<br />

resulted in the withdrawal of some unions from<br />

the first Free Trade Unions Association; and<br />

the Association dissolved. Upcoming actions<br />

and strikes were organized by separate branch<br />

trade unions in an uncoordinated manner, first<br />

of all by miners and railway drivers.<br />

Meanwhile, as the economic situation<br />

worsened and workers’ wages could not even<br />

ensure the necessary food for workers, miners<br />

again went on strike. In the course of the<br />

miners’ march to Kiev in 1996, organized<br />

by the Independent Miners’ Union, workers<br />

walked 600 km to the capital city of Ukraine<br />

and demanded the payment of wages arrears.<br />

Afterward, under the autocratic Presidency<br />

of Kuchma, the leaders of the march were<br />

threatened with imprisonment. Under threat<br />

of a new strike, the government had to stop<br />

the criminal allegations against union leaders.<br />

However, independent unions offices were<br />

illegally searched, their safes seized and their<br />

documentation stolen. In answer to this<br />

persecution, miners went on hunger strike.<br />

In October 1996, new attempts to consolidate<br />

independent unions were undertaken.<br />

Leaders of some independent unions<br />

established Consultative Council of Seite page 233<br />

trade unions (miners, railway workers,<br />

metro workers, textile workers) that<br />

grew in 1997 in the Association, and changed<br />

in 1998 into the Confederation of Free Trade<br />

Unions of Ukraine (KVPU). It spread its


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

Seite page 234<br />

presence to five branches (teachers, miners,<br />

transportations, medical workers and football<br />

players) but remained too small to break the<br />

dominance of ex-official unions.<br />

Remarkably, throughout 1994-1996 the leaders<br />

of independent trade unions could not work<br />

out an effective work strategy in conditions<br />

of economic crises (Razumkov Centre 1997).<br />

With the background of harsh economic<br />

conditions, these unions lacked organizational<br />

experience and technical capacities except<br />

organizing militant actions. While the FPU<br />

employed one of the best economists and<br />

lawyers, independent unions could employ<br />

experts only – mostly those who could not find<br />

another job. However, financial resources of<br />

these unions were limited (interviews). It also<br />

lacked experienced leaders in newly emerging<br />

enterprise-based unions, as the capacity of the<br />

KVPU to educate all new-comers was also<br />

restricted. It should be recognized that such<br />

a disadvantage originates from the initially<br />

unequal starting conditions of both – ex-official<br />

and independent unions. While the former<br />

retained and expanded their financial base (as<br />

described in the previous section), alternative<br />

trade unions could solely offer their members<br />

benefits of the solidarity-driven struggle for<br />

better life but none of immediate material<br />

benefits implicitly expected by workers.<br />

Meanwhile, the non-agreement of these unions<br />

with the prevailing consumerist-like<br />

union-worker relationships makes<br />

further attempts at expansion more<br />

resource-demanding.<br />

The expansion of independent trade unions<br />

within the traditional core branches of the<br />

economy (coal-mining and metallurgy)<br />

coincide with the consolidation of oligarchies<br />

and financial-industrial groups. The resulting<br />

harassment and persecution of the free<br />

trade unions intensified in the late 1990s<br />

under Kuchma’s Presidency. Between 2002<br />

and 2004, the KVPU President was beaten<br />

five times by the police in public places. His<br />

family members were persecuted and in 2004<br />

his son was kidnapped and heavily beaten.<br />

Leaders of regional and local trade union<br />

organizations were persecuted, as well. Many<br />

newly established local union organizations<br />

were literally immediately destroyed either by<br />

local authorities or employers and independent<br />

unions (interviews and the numerous KVPU’s<br />

complaints to the ILO). Because of the heavy<br />

persecution and harassment, the KVPU filed a<br />

complaint to the ILO Committee on Freedom<br />

of Association (Case 2388). While it took<br />

the ILO and the government several years to<br />

investigate the complaint, the government<br />

tried to deny any assaults and kept excluding<br />

the KVPU representatives from the delegations<br />

to the annual ILO conferences. It is only after<br />

2004 when Yushenko came to be elected<br />

President of Ukraine did the constraints on<br />

the Confederation’s activities on the part of the<br />

government became looser.<br />

As the example of independent miners’ unions<br />

demonstrates, the prospects of the collective<br />

action, more common in the independent than<br />

ex-official trade unions, have been constrained,<br />

as no law on industrial protests was adopted<br />

and no procedures for their solution put in<br />

place. At that point of time, making actions<br />

illegal appears an easy means to prevent them.<br />

It is worth noting that the adoption of the<br />

law on collective labour disputes (see above)<br />

correlated with the decline in union militancy.


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

One explanation could be the legal procedure<br />

that makes any protest prior to the longlasting<br />

solution procedure illegal. The second<br />

explanation originates from the persecution of<br />

independent trade unions.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

This paper explained the segmentation of IR in<br />

Ukraine through analysis of the development<br />

and impact of unions into the IR outcome. It<br />

was argued that, with the background of the enterprise-specifics<br />

developments, IR are shaped<br />

by the interactions between management and<br />

unions. As Ukrainian unions find themselves<br />

in the formative processes, two kinds of unionism<br />

are emerging in Ukraine that contribute to<br />

different IR outcomes.<br />

Such ideological incoherency and a divide<br />

within labour movement are central to explain<br />

labour dynamics and its formative processes.<br />

Former official unions seem to have little<br />

prospects for reform, at least at the current<br />

stage of development. Locally, many former<br />

official unions on the enterprise-level succeed<br />

in breaking away from such subordination<br />

relationships. But this has not taken on a<br />

broader scale so far. Independent unions offer<br />

more prospects for workers’ interest articulation.<br />

But they also face serious barriers to their<br />

development, as they threaten established<br />

informal order both nationally and locally.<br />

The development from transmission belts to<br />

social partnership demonstrates very little<br />

progress of labour revitalization, because the<br />

contestation of IR arenas is still much more<br />

constrained for independent union development<br />

and, not least, the agency imposed by<br />

external settings is not enough to challenge<br />

the current state of things. On both trajectories<br />

of developments, one may speak of dependencies.<br />

In the case of ex-official unions,<br />

it is dependency on the management and the<br />

state. In the case of independent unions, it is<br />

dependency on members that are at this point<br />

passive, individualistic, and consumerist.<br />

The review of the developmental trajectories<br />

of the FPU and KVPU in Ukraine confirmed<br />

the arguments advanced earlier. Major<br />

centres of union activities are put in place<br />

and identifiable in terms of two different<br />

models of unionism. They embody the two<br />

differentiating logics of unionism they follow.<br />

Whereas the FPU pursues conciliatory politics<br />

and strives to preserve its membership on the<br />

basis of its commercial activities, the KVPU<br />

commits itself to the vision of unionism<br />

structured along the lines of class antagonism.<br />

Militancy and action are more likely in case of<br />

independent unions. Although the autonomy<br />

of the ex-official Federation is limited,<br />

it still finds itself in the more supportive<br />

settings, originating from its dominance and<br />

collaborative relationships with employers<br />

and government. In contrast, independent<br />

trade unions originate from worthier starting<br />

conditions (in terms of resources) and initially<br />

find themselves in more constraining settings<br />

determining their further development, than<br />

do ex-official unions.<br />

The consistent decline in the FPU Seite page 235<br />

membership still does not allow any<br />

conclusions on the prospects of the exofficial<br />

unions; and the bottom-level processes<br />

within the FPU are often contradictory. At this<br />

point, it is evident that national-level union


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

approaches to some extent constrains the<br />

bottom-up formation of its affiliated unions<br />

(as also claimed by Mandel 2004). Whereas<br />

from 1989 on independent trade unions<br />

have consistently increased their presence,<br />

they have still remained under-resourced in<br />

their capacities and too small to break the<br />

dominance of the FPU. They are recognized<br />

by the state and could have influenced certain<br />

policy areas (e.g. the new law on miners’ work<br />

allocating many additional privileges to miners<br />

was initiated by the independent miners’<br />

union). However, much needs to be changed<br />

to ensure the implementation of their trade<br />

union vision.<br />

NOTES<br />

1<br />

Here, the four “critical axes of structural change” were argued<br />

to have shaped the simultaneous changes in IR and their institutions<br />

(Martin 2008: 141).<br />

2<br />

For example, in the public budget sector, IR are in crisis and<br />

workers’ interest is hardly articulated. In contrast, in the privatized<br />

sector IR are found turbulent as a result of the bargaining<br />

power of actors. Yet in the new private sector no unions exist; IR,<br />

thus, are informalized. Lastly, foreign companies were claimed to<br />

follow their international IR practices.<br />

3<br />

Once socialism collapses, the countries of the former Soviet<br />

block legally commit to the freedoms of association and collective<br />

bargaining, as well as establish procedure for strikes and wages<br />

determination in convergence or resemblance of those found in<br />

established capitalist economies and formalized in the form of<br />

the ILO International Labour Standards and European Social<br />

Model.<br />

4<br />

See, for example, Ashwin (2004), Borisov und Clarke (2006),<br />

Casale (1997), Cox und Mason (2000), Gerchikov (1995), Hethy<br />

(1994), Kabalina und Komarovsky (1997), Mason (1995),<br />

Meardi (2007), Ost (2000), Schroeder (2004).<br />

5<br />

As well known, unions in the socialist system had different functions<br />

(related to productivity and social and welfare benefits).<br />

The degree of differences between socialist and capitalist unions<br />

(even if they appear similar) was so high that Vyshnevs’ky,<br />

Mishenko, Pivnyevet al. (1997), for example, when comparing<br />

different dimensions of unionism, define socialist unions as “antiunions”.<br />

6<br />

Managerial agency can be directive (authoritarian), directive but<br />

welfare-oriented (paternalistic), negotiational (constitutional),<br />

or participative (Schienstock 1992 in reference to Poole 1988).<br />

Seite page 236<br />

7<br />

Certainly, such a strict distinction cannot be made in practice.<br />

Within the formerly socialist Federation of Trade Unions of Ukraine<br />

(FPU), for example, there are progressive leaders and local,<br />

or sectoral, unions that already succeeded, or that are on the way to<br />

reconstitution. Given the constraints imposed by non-progressive<br />

and traditionally-oriented leaders in such cases, it is still too<br />

early to speak about a broad-scaled, successful transformation of<br />

ex-official unions.


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

8<br />

Independent leaders were harassed and persecuted in socialist<br />

(Grancelli 1988) and post-independence regimes (examples are<br />

listed in Kubicek 2004).<br />

9<br />

In many enterprises, workers suffer from wages arrears and<br />

administrative leaves. In others, they succeeded in gaining wage<br />

increases and more social protection even in spite of the generally<br />

poor economic conditions.<br />

10<br />

Decline in production and outputs, employment shedding, the<br />

emergence of private sector, and the abolishment of “universal<br />

membership”.<br />

11<br />

Kubicek cites ILO data: 462 strikes and 260,400 strikers in<br />

1993 (in comparison to 264 strikes and 120,000 strikers in<br />

Russia) and 1,269 strikes and 171,400 strikers in 1996 (in comparison<br />

to 8,278 and 662,000 in Russia, respectively). Another<br />

interesting detail is the number of days lost due to strikes, whereas<br />

this number remains quite high in Ukraine (10.28, 12.45, and<br />

10.54 in 1993, 1996, and 1999, respectively) and significantly<br />

higher than those in Russia (1.97, 6.04, and 7.66, respectively)<br />

(ILO 2000 in Kubicek 2004).<br />

12<br />

The term „oligarchs“ appeared in the second half of the 1990s. It<br />

referred to different economic actors who obtained economic and<br />

political power and gained influence on the process of the political<br />

decision-making in Russia under El’tsyn (Kowall und Zimmer<br />

(2002) and in Ukraine under the Presidency of Kravchuk and<br />

Kuchma. In particular, in Ukraine, their consolidation proceeded<br />

in an unrestricted manner until 2004.<br />

13<br />

The financial capital that the groups initially accumulated<br />

from the gas trade is further channeled into the other branches,<br />

like metal processing, coal mining, energy, banks, food processing,<br />

and media. The financial industrial groups develop vertically<br />

integrated structures along the value chains (Zimmer 2002:<br />

45-46).<br />

14<br />

Its economy was concentrated around the heavy metallurgy and<br />

was dependent on the Russian economy for supplies. It possessed a<br />

huge agricultural sector that had not been modernized for years,<br />

even though Ukraine used to be the bread basket of the Soviet<br />

Union. And finally, the Ukrainian economy was heavily dependent<br />

on Russia for energy supply.<br />

15<br />

According to the law on the temporary seize of income indexation<br />

nr. 7-92 dated of 9 December 1992.<br />

16<br />

The depth of the problem is demonstrated by the fact that,<br />

until recently, the gap between the legally set minimum wages<br />

and the minimum subsistence level could not be overcome. It is<br />

only in October 2009 that the minimum wages were set higher<br />

then the subsistence minimum. However, it hardly changes the<br />

situation, as this time the subsistence level was decreased in real<br />

terms. The originally suggested minimum wage for 2010 (before<br />

the government increased it to 3 Euro under pressure of trade<br />

unions) was even below the official poverty line according to the<br />

Federation of Trade Unions of Ukraine (FPU, 22 September<br />

2009).<br />

17<br />

The draft was submitted by the current President of the largest<br />

trade union association FPU Vasyl’ Khara, the former President<br />

of the same Association Stoyan, and the MP Sukhyi, see „Кодекс<br />

рабовласника“ (The Code of the Owner of Slaves), Glavred,<br />

online-news, dated of 08.07.08, available at http://glavred.<br />

info/archive/2008/07/08/131548-5.html, last visited on 5<br />

October 2009.<br />

18<br />

The new discussion of the draft Labour Code is scheduled for<br />

the beginning of 2010.<br />

19<br />

All remarks taken from KVPU appeal to the ILO, dated of<br />

11.06.2008, KVPU news-release dated of 28.11.2009, Glavred,<br />

08.07.08, as well as “Новий Трудовий кодекс опинився<br />

«під слідством“ (The new Labour Code under investigation),<br />

KVPU news-release, dated of 28.11.2009, available at http://<br />

www.kvpu.org.ua/ua/news/112, last visited on 5 October<br />

2009.<br />

20<br />

Notably, collective agreements also existed in the Soviet Union.<br />

Then, bargaining was addressed as “an economic-political<br />

measure to mobilize workers and servants around the successful<br />

fulfilment and over-fulfilment of the people’s<br />

economic plan” (Council of Ministers of the USSR,<br />

6.03.1966). In this form collective agreements did<br />

not serve as IR regulating mechanisms and were of<br />

symbolic nature.<br />

21<br />

Interview with Ihor Sumovs’ky, State Chief Labour Inspector<br />

of Ukraine, Kyiv, 27 August 2009.<br />

Seite page 237


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

22<br />

Ashwin und Clarke (2003) make similar conclusions for<br />

Russia.<br />

23<br />

E.g. Interview with S.Ponomarchuk, the Vice-President of<br />

the Donetsk Oblast Council of the Construction and Building<br />

Materials Industry Workers’ Union of Ukraine (CBMIWUU),<br />

Donetsk, 22 August 2009.<br />

24<br />

Interview with the KVPU President, Kyiv.<br />

31<br />

Програма Дій Федерації професійних спілок України<br />

(2006-2011 роки) (A plan of actions of the Federation of Trade<br />

Unions of Ukraine (2006-2012), № 5з-3, adopted by the Vth<br />

FPU Congress on 05.04.2006, available at http://www.fpsu.<br />

org.ua/images/stories/images/2009/August/programa.doc, last<br />

visited on 10 October 2009.<br />

32<br />

As compared to minimum wages amounting to 80-90% of the<br />

subsistence minimum at that point of time.<br />

25<br />

E.g. the interview with the President of the Mykolaiv Oblast<br />

Trade Union Committee of the Agro-Industrial Workers’ Unions,<br />

Mykolaiv, 2008.<br />

26<br />

Later investigations into unions’ properties uncovered the ownership<br />

by the Federation of joint American-Ukrainian firms<br />

and a lot of premises. The office premises of the FPU are even<br />

today rent to different firms.<br />

27<br />

E.g. Interview with the President of the DBK-4 trade union<br />

committee, Krychkevych, Kyiv, 27 August 2009.<br />

28<br />

“The big cover-up”, Kyiv Post, web-news, dated of 28 August<br />

2003, available at http://www.kyivpost.com/nation/17797/<br />

print, last visited on 15 October 2009.<br />

33<br />

The same sources.<br />

34<br />

“Court cancels election of Khara as chairman of Trade Union<br />

Federation of Ukraine”, Kyivpost, issues dated of 03.10.2009,<br />

available at http://www.kyivpost.com/city/50022, last visited<br />

on 12 October 2009.<br />

35<br />

The negotiating unions included the Associations Free trade<br />

Unions, Free trade Unions of railway drivers, Trade Union<br />

Association of the pilots, Federation-Trade Union of the aviation<br />

dispatchers of Ukraine, Independent Trade Union of the textile<br />

workers of the Donetsk cotton factory, trade union of the aviation<br />

of engineers and technicians of Ukraine, Independent Trade<br />

Union of the Illichivsk see commercial port and Solidar Trade<br />

Unions of Ukraine.<br />

29<br />

„Олександр ЮРКІН: «Угода важливіша за вибори»<br />

(Olexandr Yurkin: the Agreement is more important than elections“,<br />

Дзеркало тижня», № 8 (587), dated 4 — 10 March<br />

2006, available at http://www.dt.ua/2000/2650/52762/, last<br />

visited on 10 October 2009.<br />

Seite page 238<br />

30<br />

Концепція розвитку Федерації професійних<br />

спілок України (The conception of the development of<br />

the FPU), NP-4-5 , adopted by the FPU<br />

Council on 09.12.2005, available at http://<br />

www.fpsu.org.ua/index.php?option=com_<br />

content&view=article&id=26%3A2009-07-<br />

14-17-36-08&catid=10%3A2009-07-06-16-<br />

44-54&Itemid=36&lang=uk, last visited on 10<br />

October 2009.


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

SELECTED REFERENCES<br />

Ashwin, Sara (1996): Forms of Collectivity in a Non-Monetary<br />

Society, in: Sociology, 30 (1): 21-39.<br />

Ashwin, Sara (2004): Social Partnership or a ‘’Complete Sell-<br />

Out’’? Russian Trade Unions’ Responses to Conflict, in: British<br />

Journal of Industrial Relations, 42 (1): 23-46.<br />

Ashwin, Sarah (2007): Russian Trade Unions: Stuck in the<br />

Soviet-Style Subordination, in: Trade union revitalisation -<br />

trends and prospects in 34 countries, C. Phelan (eds.), Oxford<br />

[u.a.]: Lang, 319-333.<br />

Ashwin, Sarah und Clarke, Simon (2003): Russian trade unions<br />

and industrial relations in transition. Basingstoke, Hampshire<br />

[u.a.]: Palgrave Macmillan, XII, 293.<br />

Barberis, Nicholas, Boycko, Maxim, Shleifer, Andrei und Tsukanova,<br />

Natalia (1996): How Does Privatization Work? Evidence<br />

from the Russian Shops, in: Journal of Political Economy,<br />

104 (4):.<br />

Borisov, Vadim und Clarke, Simon (2006): The rise and fall of<br />

social partnership in postsocialist Europe: the Commonwealth of<br />

Independent States, in: 37 (6): 607–629.<br />

Burawoy, Michael und Verdery, Katherine (1999): Uncertain<br />

transition. ethnographies of change in the postsocialist world, in:<br />

based on the papers presented at the Conference ‘’Ethnographies<br />

in Transition’’, Lanham [u.a.]: Rowman und Littlefield, VII,<br />

322.<br />

Casale, Giuseppe (1997): Recent trends and issues in industrial<br />

relations in Central and Eastern Europe, in: Central and<br />

Eastern Europe: industrial relations and the market economy, J.<br />

Brady (eds.), Dublin: Oak Tree Press, 1-14.<br />

Chernyshev, Ihor (2006): Socio-economic security and decent<br />

work in Ukraine: A comparative view and statistical findings,<br />

in: Policy Integration Department Statistical Development and<br />

Analysis Group International Labour Office Geneva, 77.<br />

Clarke, Simon (2005): Post-socialist trade unions: China and<br />

Russia, in: Industrial Relations Journal, 36 (1): 2-18.<br />

Clarke, Simon und Fairbrother, Peter (1994): Postcommunism<br />

and the Emergence of Industrial Relations in the Workplace, in:<br />

New Frontiers in European Industrial Relations, R. Hyman<br />

und A. Ferner (eds.), Oxford: Blackwell, 368-398.<br />

Cooke, William N. (2006): Multinationals, globalisation and<br />

industrial relations, in: Global Industrial Relations, M. Morley,<br />

P. Gunnigle und D. Collings (eds.), Routledge, 326-345.<br />

Cox, Terry und Mason, Bon (2000): Interest Groups and the<br />

Development of Tripartism in East Central Europe, in: European<br />

Journal of Industrial Relations, 6 (3): 325 - 347.<br />

Crowley, Stephen (2001): The Social Explosion That Wasn’t:<br />

Labor Quiescence in Postcommunist Russia, in: Workers after<br />

workers’ states - labor and politics in postcommunist Eastern<br />

Europe, S. Crowley und D. Ost (eds.), Lanham, Md. [u.a.]:<br />

Rowman und Littlefield, 199-218.<br />

Crowley, Stephen und Ost, David (2001): Workers after workers’<br />

states. labor and politics in postcommunist Eastern Europe,<br />

Lanham, Md. [u.a.]: Rowman und Littlefield, IX, 241 S.<br />

Frege, Carola (2002): Understanding Union Effectiveness in<br />

Central Eastern Europe: Hungary and Slovenia, in: European<br />

Journal of Industrial Relations, 8 (1): 53-76.<br />

Gerchikov, Vladimir (1995): Russia, in: Labour Relations and<br />

Political Change in Eastern Europe: A Comparative Perspective,<br />

J. E. Thirkell, R. Scase und S. Vickerstaff (eds.), London:<br />

UCL Press, 137-168.<br />

Grabher, Gernot und Stark, David (1997): Restructuring<br />

networks in post-socialism. Legacies,<br />

Linkages, and Localities, Oxford: Oxford Univ.<br />

Press, 349.<br />

Hanke, Jens und Mense-Petermann, Ursula (2001): Industrial<br />

relations in the transformation process - the cases of Poland and<br />

the Czech Republic, in: Selected country studies, G. Széll (eds.),<br />

Aldershot [u.a.]: Gower, 131-148.<br />

Seite page 239


INDUSTRIAL RELATIONS REFERENCES LITERATUR IN THE UKRAINE<br />

Seite page 240<br />

Hethy, Lajos (1994): Tripartism in Eastern Europe, in: New<br />

frontiers in European industrial relations, R. Hyman und A.<br />

Ferner (eds.), Oxford: Blackwell, 312-355.<br />

Huzzard, Tony, Gregory, Denis und Scott, Regan (2005): Strategic<br />

unionism and partnership. boxing or dancing? Basingstoke,<br />

Hampshire [u.a.]: Palgrave Macmillan, XXIII, 362.<br />

Kabalina, Veronika und Komarovsky, Viktor (1997): Transformation<br />

of industrial relations and trade-union reform in<br />

Russia, in: Industrial relations between command and market:<br />

a comparative analysis of eastern Europe and China, 195-238.<br />

Kozina, Irina (2001): Profsoyuzi v kollektivnykh trudovikh<br />

konfliktakh (Trade unions in collective labour conflicts), in:<br />

Sociologicheskie issledovaniya, (5): 49-56.<br />

Kubicek, Paul (2004): Organized labor in postcommunist states.<br />

from solidarity to infirmity, Pittsburgh, Pa: Univ. of Pittsburgh<br />

Press, 256.<br />

Mandel, David (2004): Labour after communism: Autoworkers<br />

and their Trade Unions in Russia, Ukraine and Belarus. Black<br />

Rose Books, 283.<br />

Martin, Roderik (2008): Post-socialist segmented capitalism:<br />

The case of Hungary. Developing business systems theory, in:<br />

Human Relations, 61 (1): 131-159.<br />

Martin, Roderik und Christescu-Martin, R.A. (2006): Industrial<br />

Relations in Central and Eastern Europe, in: Global<br />

industrial relations, M. Morley, P. Gunnigle und D. Collings<br />

(eds.), London: Routledge, 86-105.<br />

Mason, Bob (1995): Industrial Relations in an Unstable Environment:<br />

The Case of Central and Eastern Europe,<br />

in: European Journal of Industrial Relations, 1 (3):<br />

341-367.<br />

Meardi, Guglielmo (2007): More voice after more<br />

exit? Unstable industrial relations in Central Eastern Europe,<br />

in: Industrial Relations Journal, 38 (6): 503-523.<br />

Müller-Jentsch, Walther (1996): Theorien Industrieller Beziehungen,<br />

in: Industrielle Beziehungen, 3 (1): 36 - 64.<br />

Ost, David (2000): Illusory Corporatism in East Central Europe:<br />

Neoliberal Tripartism and Postcommunist Class Identities,<br />

in: Politics and Society, 28 (4): 503-530.<br />

Peng, Michael W. (2000): Business strategies in transition economies.<br />

Thousand Oaks, Calif. [u.a.]: Sage Publications, XX, 322.<br />

Pollert, Anna (1999): Trade Unionism in Transition in Central<br />

and Eastern Europe, in: European Journal of Industrial Relations,<br />

5 (2): 209-234.<br />

Pollert, Anna (2000): Ten years of post-communist Central<br />

Eastern Europe, in: Economic and Industrial Democracy, 21 (2):<br />

183-210.<br />

Razumkov Centre (2001): The State of the Trade Union Movement<br />

in Ukraine, in: National Security and Defence, 8 (20)<br />

3-62.<br />

Rippe, Wolfgang (1985): Arbeitsbeziehungen in kapitalistischen<br />

und sozialistischen Systemen, in: Handbuch der Arbeitsbeziehungen,<br />

G. e. a. Endruweit (eds.), Berlin:.<br />

Schienstock, Gerd (1992): Einige Anmerkungen zur Untersuchung<br />

von Arbeitsbeziehungen in ehemals sozialistischen<br />

Ländern, in: er Wandel industrieller Beziehungen in Osteuropa,<br />

E. J. Dittrich (eds.), Frankfurt am Main: Campus-Verlag, 121<br />

- 141.<br />

Schienstock, Gerd, Thompson, Paul G. und Traxler, Franz<br />

(1997): Industrial relations between command and market. A<br />

comparative analysis of Eastern Europe and China, New York:<br />

Nova Science Publ, VIII, 323.<br />

Schroeder, Wolfgang (2004): Arbeitsbeziehungen in Mittel- und<br />

Osteuropa: Weder wilder Osten noch europäisches Sozialmodel,<br />

in: Europäische Politik / Politikinformationen Osteuropa, 6<br />

1-16.


LYUDMYLA REFERENCES LITERATUR VOLYNETS<br />

Slomp, Hans, van Hoof, Jackues und Moerel, Hans (1996):<br />

The transformation of industrial relations in some Central and<br />

Eastern European countries, in: Industrial Relations in Europe:<br />

Traditions and Transitions, J. Van Ruysseveldt und J. Visser<br />

(eds.), London: Sage, 337-357.<br />

Zimmer, Kerstin (2006): Formal Institutions and Informal Politics<br />

in Ukraine, in: Formal Institutions and Informal Politics<br />

in Central and Eastern Europe, G. Meyer (eds.), Leverkusen:<br />

Budrich.<br />

Stark, D. and Bruszt, L. (1998): Postsocialist pathways.<br />

Transforming politics and property in East Central Europe,<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 284.<br />

Thelen, Kathelen (1999): Historical Institutionalism in Comparative<br />

Politics, in: Annual Review of Political Science, 2 (1):<br />

369-404.<br />

Tholen, Jochen (2007): Labour Relations in Central Europe. The<br />

impact of Multinationals’ Money. Hampshire: Ashgate, 186.<br />

Trif, Aurora und Koch, Karl (2005a) Strategic Unionism in<br />

Eastern Europe: The Case of Romania, Max-Planck Institute<br />

für Gesellschaftsforschung (MPIfGF) Working papers, July 2005,<br />

26.<br />

Trif, Aurora und Koch, Karl (2005b): Romania: Learning to<br />

Dance, in: Strategic unionism and partnership - boxing or dancing?,<br />

T. Huzzard, D. Gregory und R. Scott (eds.), Basingstoke,<br />

Hampshire [u.a.]: Palgrave Macmillan, 179 - 198.<br />

Vyshnevs’ky, Yuri, Mishenko, Olexandr, Pivnyev, Yevgeni,<br />

Pylypchuk, Romana und Masalova, Lyudmyla (1997): ????<br />

?????????? ? ??????? ??????? ? ???????? [Trade union role<br />

in Ukraine: pretended and real]. Kyiv: Democracy Foundation,<br />

300.<br />

Wollmann, Hellmut (1996): Institutionenbildung in Ostdeutschland:<br />

Rezeption, Eigenentwicklung oder Innovation?<br />

in: Institutionenbildung in Ostdeutschland: zwischen externer<br />

Steuerung und Eigendynamik, A. Eisen und H. Wollman (eds.),<br />

Opladen: Leske & Budrich, 79-112.<br />

Seite page 241<br />

Wollmann, Hellmut (1997): Between Institutional Transfer<br />

and Legacies: Local Administrative Transformation in Eastern<br />

Germany, in: Restructuring networks in post-socialism - Legacies,<br />

Linkages, and Localities, G. Grabher und D. Stark (eds.),<br />

Oxford: Oxford Univ. Press, 324-342.


AUTHORS<br />

Agnieszka Cianciara (1981) is a PhD candidate at the Institute of Political<br />

Studies, Polish Academy of Sciences and Academic Assistant in the<br />

College of Europe, Warsaw/ Natolin Campus. Main research areas: EU<br />

governance and institutional reforms, lobbying in EU and CEEC, European<br />

Neighbourhood Policy.<br />

Contact: a.cianciara@wp.eu<br />

Péter Csizmadia (1973) is a researcher at the Institute of Sociology of the<br />

Hungarian Academy of Sciences. Main areas of research: non-technical<br />

innovations, organisational learning, knowledge-intensive business services.<br />

Contact: pcsizmadia@socio.mta.hu<br />

Alexandra Janovskaia is a PhD student at the London School of Economics,<br />

UK. Main areas of research: political economy of transition, varieties of<br />

capitalism, MNCs.<br />

Contact: sasha.janovskaia@gmail.com<br />

Kathrin Loer (M.A. in European Studies) is a research associate for<br />

Comparative Social Sciences and lecturer in European Studies at the<br />

University of Osnabrück. Her research interests include economic sociology<br />

with a focus on the automotive sector as well as welfare state politics within<br />

the European Union. She previously worked for the German Bundestag, the<br />

Ministry of Economics, Technology and Transport and several consulting<br />

agencies.<br />

Contact: kathrin.loer@uni-osnabrueck.de<br />

page 242<br />

Martin Mendelski is a research fellow at the Private University of Applied<br />

Sciences in Göttingen and a Ph.D. candidate at Goethe University<br />

Frankfurt. He holds two Master‘s degrees, one in European Studies from<br />

the European University Viadrina Frankfurt (Oder) and one in Business<br />

Studies from Mannheim University. His current research addresses market<br />

economies in Eastern Europe and the role of institutional complementarities<br />

in economic performance. He was visiting researcher at several universities<br />

(Bilkent University, Harvard University, European University Institute) and<br />

research institutes (Max Planck Institute for the Study of Societies in Köln,<br />

CEPS/INSTEAD in Luxembourg).<br />

Contact : mmendelski@hotmail.com


AUTHORS<br />

Abel Polese is Marie Curie Fellow at the Institute of Geography of the<br />

University of Edinburgh and Research Fellow at the Institute of Sociology of the<br />

Ukrainian Academy of Sciences. Main areas of research: informal economies,<br />

nation building and identity policies, civil society and democratisation<br />

contact: apolese@ed.ac.uk<br />

Catherine Spieser is a post-doctoral researcher at the centre for the study<br />

of employment and labour market policy (Centre d‘études de l‘emploi)<br />

in Paris. She completed her PhD at the European University Institute in<br />

Florence in 2009. Main areas of research: comparative social and labour<br />

market policy, politics of socio-economic policies, political sociology of the<br />

welfare state.<br />

Contact: catherine.spieser@eui.eu<br />

Ivett Szalma (* 1980) is a researcher at the Hungarian Academy of Sciences<br />

(HAS), Institute of Sociology and Ph.D. candidate at the Corvinus<br />

University of Budapest. Main areas of research: labour market, deliberative<br />

polling, social policy, partnership formation, childbearing<br />

Contact : szalma@socio.mta.hu<br />

Bernadett Szél (* 1977) is a Doctoral Candidate in Sociology at the Institute<br />

of Sociology and Social Policy at the Corvinus University of Budapest<br />

and Leader Councilor of the Hungarian Central Statistical Office. Main<br />

areas of research: Identifying and measuring patterns and mechanisms<br />

supporting partnership cohesion, consequences of labor market uncertainties<br />

on partnership formation, corruption research<br />

Contact: bernadett.szel@uni-corvinus.hu<br />

Lyudmyla Volynets (1982) previously worked as International Secretary<br />

at the Confederation of Free Trade Unions of Ukraine and is currently<br />

working on her PhD in political sciences at the Free University of Berlin<br />

(Germany). Her research interests lie in different aspects of Industrial<br />

Relations, collective action, and trade unions.<br />

Contact: lyudmyla.volynets@gmx.de<br />

page 243


AUTHORS<br />

Alexandra Krause is assistant professor at the University <strong>Jena</strong> and associate<br />

at the Collaborative Research Centre <strong>580</strong> in <strong>Jena</strong>. Main areas of research:<br />

Employment systems, flexible labour markets, social inequality and social<br />

justice.<br />

Contact: alexandra.krause@uni-jena.de<br />

Vera Trappmann is assistant professor at the University Osnabrück and<br />

associate at the Colloborative Research Centre <strong>580</strong> in <strong>Jena</strong>. Main areas of<br />

research: Employment, labour politics and welfare states in Eastern and<br />

Western Europe.<br />

Contact: vera.trappmann@uos.de<br />

page 244


<strong>SFB</strong> <strong>580</strong> - GESCHÄFTSFÜHRUNG (2010) ISSN 1619-6171

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!