17.06.2014 Views

M&A Litigation: You Sold the Company and Bought ... - RR Donnelley

M&A Litigation: You Sold the Company and Bought ... - RR Donnelley

M&A Litigation: You Sold the Company and Bought ... - RR Donnelley

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

M&A <strong>Litigation</strong>: <strong>You</strong> <strong>Sold</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Bought</strong> <strong>Litigation</strong>?<br />

Moderator<br />

Girard Miller, Shareholder, Leonard, Street <strong>and</strong> Deinard<br />

Panelists<br />

Bruce M. Engler, Partner, Faegre Baker Daniels LLP<br />

Terence M. Fruth, Fruth, Jamison & Elsass PLLC<br />

David L. Hallett, Managing Director, Lazard Middle Market<br />

• Overview of M&A Activity<br />

• Board Conduct during <strong>the</strong> M&A Process<br />

• M&A <strong>Litigation</strong> Trends<br />

• Recent case law<br />

• Typical litigation scenarios<br />

• Legal: Defense perspective<br />

• Panel Discussion


<strong>RR</strong> <strong>Donnelley</strong> SEC Hot Topics Institute<br />

Overview of M&A Activity<br />

Presented by:<br />

Dave Hallett, Managing Director<br />

Lazard Middle Market<br />

OVERVIEW OF M&A ACTIVITY<br />

1


M&A Deals by Year (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

16,000<br />

14,000<br />

12,000<br />

Number of Deals<br />

10,000<br />

8,000<br />

6,000<br />

4,000<br />

2,000<br />

0<br />

2<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

M&A Deals by Year (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

16,000<br />

14,000<br />

13,283<br />

14,308<br />

Number of Deals<br />

12,000<br />

10,000<br />

8,000<br />

6,000<br />

12,142142<br />

9,908<br />

10,521<br />

10,804 10,849<br />

4,000<br />

2,000<br />

0<br />

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012<br />

3<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

2


M&A Deals by Year (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

$2,500<br />

$2,000<br />

$1,967.3<br />

$2,106.5<br />

$ in Billions<br />

$1,500<br />

$1,000<br />

$1,299.6<br />

$892.5<br />

$1,039.5<br />

$1,349.1<br />

$1,027.3<br />

$500<br />

$0<br />

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012<br />

4<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

Middle Market M&A Deals by Year (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

Transaction size under $1 billion (includes undisclosed values)<br />

14,000<br />

12,000<br />

11,287<br />

11,982<br />

Number of Deals<br />

10,000<br />

8,000<br />

6,000<br />

4,000<br />

9,969<br />

7,678<br />

8,384<br />

8,695 8,690<br />

2,000<br />

0<br />

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012<br />

5<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

3


Middle Market M&A Deals by Year (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

Transaction size under $1 billion (includes undisclosed values)<br />

$600<br />

$500<br />

$434.5<br />

$475.9<br />

$ in Billions<br />

$400<br />

$300<br />

$276.7<br />

$318.1 $325.0 $318.6<br />

$200<br />

$188.5<br />

$100<br />

$0<br />

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012<br />

6<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

M&A Deals by Year (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

3,000<br />

2,500<br />

2,735<br />

2,631<br />

Number of Deals<br />

2,000<br />

1,500<br />

1,000<br />

1,994<br />

1,400<br />

1,783<br />

1,897 1,887<br />

500<br />

0<br />

265 271<br />

319<br />

201<br />

125 143 172 165 158 170 154 175<br />

85 106<br />

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012<br />

$10 million - $500 million $500 million - $1 billion > $1 billion<br />

7<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

4


M&A Deals by Year (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

$1,400<br />

$1,200<br />

$1,235.7<br />

$1,261.2<br />

$1,000<br />

$ in Billions<br />

$800<br />

$600<br />

$706.1<br />

$648.2<br />

$554.9<br />

$802.2<br />

$400<br />

$200<br />

$0<br />

$440.4<br />

$287.7 $277.4<br />

$197.6<br />

$213.6<br />

$187.2<br />

$196.6<br />

$209.4<br />

$143.7<br />

$130.3<br />

$122.3<br />

$88.9<br />

$110.5 $111.0<br />

$57.4<br />

2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012<br />

$10 million - $500 million $500 million to $1 billion > $1 billion<br />

8<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

M&A Deals by Quarter (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

4,000<br />

3,605<br />

3,500<br />

3,287<br />

3,000<br />

2,763<br />

Number of Deals<br />

2,500<br />

2,000<br />

2,402<br />

2,546<br />

2,494 2,524<br />

1,500<br />

1,000<br />

500<br />

0<br />

1Q07 2Q07 3Q07 4Q07 1Q08 2Q08 3Q08 4Q08 1Q09 2Q09 3Q09 4Q09 1Q10 2Q10 3Q10 4Q10 1Q11 2Q11 3Q11 4Q11 1Q12 2Q12 3Q12 4Q12 1Q13<br />

1Q13 deal volume down from 4Q12<br />

9<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

5


Number of Middle Market M&A Deals by Quarter<br />

Number of Transactions<br />

3,500<br />

3,000<br />

2,500<br />

2,000<br />

1,500<br />

1,000<br />

1Q07<br />

3,053<br />

1Q08<br />

2,778<br />

1Q09<br />

1,914<br />

1Q10<br />

2,002<br />

1Q11<br />

2,235<br />

1Q12<br />

2,072<br />

1Q13<br />

1,861<br />

500<br />

-<br />

1Q13 deal volume = 27% decrease from 4Q12<br />

10<br />

Source: Thomson Financial; transaction size under $1 billion; including undisclosed values<br />

M&A Deals by Deal Size, by Year (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

3500<br />

3,126<br />

3000<br />

2500<br />

2,158<br />

2000<br />

1500<br />

1000<br />

500<br />

0<br />

524<br />

1,114<br />

1,017<br />

664<br />

1,465<br />

1,207<br />

839<br />

487 404<br />

210<br />

$10M - $100M $100M - $500M >$500M<br />

11<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

6


M&A Deals by Deal Size, by Quarter (U.S. Buyer or Seller)<br />

600<br />

500<br />

475<br />

454<br />

400<br />

389<br />

300<br />

200<br />

100<br />

212<br />

99<br />

250<br />

89<br />

228<br />

120<br />

262<br />

126<br />

278<br />

169<br />

83<br />

0<br />

34<br />

1Q08 2Q08 3Q08 4Q08 1Q09 2Q09 3Q09 4Q09 1Q10 2Q10 3Q10 4Q10 1Q11 2Q11 3Q11 4Q11 1Q12 2Q12 3Q12 4Q12 1Q13<br />

$10M - $100M $100M - $500M >$500M<br />

81% of 1Q2013 deal volume < $500 million<br />

12<br />

Source: Thomson Financial<br />

Strategic vs. Financial Buyers in <strong>the</strong> Middle Market<br />

100%<br />

1992<br />

0.9%<br />

2007<br />

8.2%<br />

2012<br />

9.1%<br />

80%<br />

60%<br />

40%<br />

20%<br />

0%<br />

Strategic Buyers<br />

Financial Buyers<br />

Financial buyers executing a consistent share of middle market<br />

transactions – current high of 9.1% in 2012<br />

13<br />

Source: Thomson Financial; transaction size under $1 billion; including undisclosed values<br />

7


Private Equity Dem<strong>and</strong><br />

Private Equity Uninvested Capital<br />

$900<br />

$800<br />

$700<br />

$600<br />

($ in Billions)<br />

$500<br />

$400<br />

$428<br />

$501<br />

$481<br />

$433<br />

$373<br />

$348<br />

$300<br />

$200<br />

$150<br />

$198<br />

$230 $222 $232<br />

$263<br />

$292<br />

$100<br />

$0<br />

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012<br />

Estimated Cumulative Uninvested Capital Capital Invested Capital Raised<br />

14<br />

Source: Buyouts<br />

Source: Thomson Reuters & Pitchbook<br />

Strategic Buyers Flush with Cash<br />

• Corporate Cash of $2.0 trillion as of June 2012 was all-time record<br />

• Over 5% of total assets<br />

% of Total Assets<br />

2010 2011 2012<br />

Source: Wall Street Journal<br />

15<br />

8


Private Equity Portfolio <strong>Company</strong> Inventory<br />

Number of PE Backed Compan nies<br />

8,000<br />

7,000<br />

6,000<br />

5,000<br />

4,000<br />

3,000<br />

2,000<br />

2,244<br />

2,960<br />

3,796<br />

4,693<br />

5,347<br />

5,625<br />

6,031<br />

6,358<br />

6,665<br />

Year of<br />

Investment<br />

2009 - 2012*<br />

2005 - 2008<br />

2000 - 2004<br />

1,000<br />

0<br />

2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012*<br />

Private equity company inventory remains at record levels, with <strong>the</strong> majority of<br />

inventory still being held from investments made between 2005 <strong>and</strong> 2008<br />

16<br />

Source: Pitchbook<br />

Private vs. Public Targets in <strong>the</strong> Middle Market<br />

8,000<br />

7,000<br />

6,000<br />

Number of Transactions<br />

5,000<br />

4,000<br />

3,000<br />

2,000<br />

1,000<br />

0<br />

Public Target<br />

Private Target<br />

17<br />

Source: Thomson Financial; U.S. Target with transaction size under $1 billion; including undisclosed values<br />

9


SEC Hot Topics institute<br />

R.R. <strong>Donnelley</strong><br />

“M&A <strong>Litigation</strong>: <strong>You</strong> <strong>Sold</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Bought</strong> <strong>Litigation</strong>?”<br />

May 29, 2013<br />

I. Primary Areas of Emphasis<br />

A. Assumptions.<br />

1. Public company is <strong>the</strong> target.<br />

2. Target’s public shareholders are being cashed out.<br />

B. Frequency of M&A litigation.<br />

C. Deal process/terms.<br />

1. Board duties/process/advisable or required deal terms.<br />

2. Conflicts of interest – special considerations.<br />

D. Writing <strong>the</strong> script.<br />

1. Courts have referred to M&A lawyers as “writing <strong>the</strong> script” for litigation in an<br />

M&A deal.<br />

2. Creating a proper, convincing record is just as important as running a good<br />

process <strong>and</strong> negotiating appropriate deal terms.<br />

II. M&A <strong>Litigation</strong> Statistics 1<br />

A. Deals over $100 million (2012).<br />

1. 93% involved class action litigation.<br />

2. 4.8 lawsuits per deal.<br />

B. Deals over $500 million (2012).<br />

1. 96% involved class action litigation.<br />

2. 5.4 lawsuits per deal.<br />

C. <strong>Litigation</strong> outcomes.<br />

1. Majority (64%) settled.<br />

2. 33% dismissed.<br />

3. 3% voluntarily withdrawn.<br />

D. Settlement results.<br />

1. 81% involved additional disclosures only.<br />

2. In four cases, <strong>the</strong> deal termination fee was reduced.<br />

3. In six cases, an agreement regarding appraisal rights was reached.<br />

4. The parties acknowledged that litigation contributed to an increase in <strong>the</strong> merger<br />

price in only one deal.<br />

1 Source: Cornerstone Research, Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong> Involving Mergers & Acquisitions (February 2013).<br />

dms.us.52127568.01


5. Most of <strong>the</strong> largest settlements included allegations of significant conflicts of<br />

interest.<br />

6. The first step: “We are launching an investigation . . . .”<br />

E. Overall conclusion: <strong>Litigation</strong> is a virtual certainty in any public company M&A deal<br />

over $100 million.<br />

1. M&A deal lawyers should prepare for litigation but project confidence.<br />

2. Remind clients of litigation risk—early <strong>and</strong> often!<br />

3. Be prepared!<br />

III. Deal Process/Terms<br />

A. Director fiduciary duties.<br />

1. General.<br />

a. Duty of loyalty.<br />

b. Duty of care.<br />

2. Minnesota (Minnesota Business Corporation Act §302A.251): A director has a<br />

fiduciary duty:<br />

a. To act in good faith;<br />

b. In a manner reasonably believed to be in <strong>the</strong> corporation’s best interests; <strong>and</strong><br />

c. With <strong>the</strong> care an ordinarily prudent person in a like position would exercise<br />

under similar circumstances.<br />

3. Delaware – similar general fiduciary duty based on case law.<br />

4. Revlon duty.<br />

a. In change-of-control situations, courts have imposed a heightened st<strong>and</strong>ard on<br />

directors.<br />

b. Revlon, Inc. vs. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A. 2d 173 (Del.<br />

1986) held that when directors decide to sell <strong>the</strong> company in a cash-out<br />

merger, <strong>the</strong>ir role changes from protectors of <strong>the</strong> corporate entity to<br />

“auctioneers” whose duty is to get <strong>the</strong> best price for stockholders.<br />

c. Revlon duty applies to Delaware corporations <strong>and</strong>, by analogy, to Minnesota<br />

corporations.<br />

5. Multiple constituency statutes.<br />

a. Minnesota Business Corporation Act §302A.251, Subd. 5 permits a director to<br />

consider “o<strong>the</strong>r constituencies” such as <strong>the</strong> interests of <strong>the</strong> corporation’s<br />

employees, customers, suppliers, <strong>and</strong> creditors, among o<strong>the</strong>rs.<br />

b. Delaware has no multiple constituency statute.<br />

c. Even in Minnesota, <strong>the</strong> shareholders’ interest should be paramount.<br />

B. St<strong>and</strong>ard of judicial review.<br />

1. No conflict of interest – business judgment rule.<br />

2. Conflict of interest – “entire fairness” review.<br />

dms.us.52127568.01<br />

2


C. Identify conflicts of interest.<br />

1. Board.<br />

2. Lawyers.<br />

3. Financial advisers.<br />

4. Identify conflicts early for proper consideration <strong>and</strong> resolution.<br />

D. Deal considerations.<br />

1. Courts have emphasized that no “blueprint” exists for maximizing value <strong>and</strong><br />

satisfying <strong>the</strong> Revlon duty.<br />

2. Process/deal terms.<br />

a. No duty to auction.<br />

b. Consider pre-signing market check.<br />

c. Consider post-signing market check (“go shop” in Merger Agreement).<br />

d. Merger Agreement must include a “fiduciary out” that allows <strong>the</strong> Board to<br />

accept a superior offer.<br />

IV. Writing <strong>the</strong> Script<br />

A. Just as important as running a good process <strong>and</strong> getting appropriate deal terms.<br />

B. Formal Board minutes.<br />

1. Cases suggest increasing scrutiny.<br />

2. What is <strong>the</strong>re.<br />

3. What isn’t <strong>the</strong>re.<br />

4. Netsmart (keep timely minutes throughout <strong>the</strong> process).<br />

C. General guidelines for Board minutes. 2<br />

1. “Minutes should be drafted in a manner that reflects a process of conscientious<br />

<strong>and</strong> informed decision-making; <strong>the</strong>y should demonstrate that directors were<br />

active, engaged <strong>and</strong> fully informed <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong>y understood <strong>the</strong>ir obligations <strong>and</strong><br />

endeavored to carry <strong>the</strong>m out in a good faith <strong>and</strong> reasonably manner.”<br />

2. Minutes should be thorough ra<strong>the</strong>r than minimalist (even if that is <strong>the</strong> typical<br />

approach), but not a verbatim transcript.<br />

3. “Minutes should, among o<strong>the</strong>r things: (i) identify significant issues discussed <strong>and</strong><br />

important questions raised (<strong>and</strong> answered) during meetings; (ii) describe <strong>and</strong><br />

explain key decisions <strong>and</strong> strategic choices made by directors <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> reasons for<br />

<strong>the</strong>m; (iii) identify <strong>the</strong> information <strong>and</strong> advice <strong>the</strong> directors considered <strong>and</strong> relied<br />

upon in making critical decisions, including legal <strong>and</strong> financial advice; <strong>and</strong><br />

(iv) describe <strong>the</strong> specific decisions made or authorized at <strong>the</strong> meeting (including<br />

<strong>the</strong> vote by which <strong>the</strong>y were approved, whe<strong>the</strong>r unanimous or o<strong>the</strong>rwise).”<br />

4. Specific matters to be addressed: consideration of alternatives; terms of <strong>the</strong> deal;<br />

deliberation on important issues; debate, dissent <strong>and</strong> abstentions; legal advice; <strong>and</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r professional advice (such as financial advisors).<br />

2 M. Pittenger et al., “M&A Deal Counsel’s Role in Creating a Winning Written Record for Defending Breach of<br />

Fiduciary Duty <strong>Litigation</strong>” (2013 Section of Business Law Spring Meeting, April 4, 2013) at page 31.<br />

dms.us.52127568.01<br />

3


D. Advise clients early <strong>and</strong> often to undertake practices <strong>and</strong> procedures that will enhance<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir defense.<br />

1. <strong>Litigation</strong> is likely.<br />

2. Emphasize risks associated with personal notes <strong>and</strong> informal communications<br />

such as emails, texts, voicemails, etc.<br />

E. Attorney-client privilege.<br />

5. Easy to waive inadvertently.<br />

6. May be voluntarily waived in advice-of-counsel defense.<br />

7. Don’t rely on it to protect written statements you would not o<strong>the</strong>rwise make.<br />

E. Document preservation.<br />

1. Applies when litigation is “reasonably anticipated.”<br />

2. What does “reasonably anticipated” mean in a public company M&A deal in light<br />

of <strong>the</strong> litigation statistics described above?<br />

3. Consult with an experienced litigator throughout <strong>the</strong> M&A process.<br />

dms.us.52127568.01<br />

4


2013 Donnelly Conference: M&A <strong>Litigation</strong><br />

I. The Current Scene<br />

1. M&A litigation thrives. About 85% of all deals have litigation filed before<br />

closing, much of it within a week of announcement.<br />

2. Forum shopping is a major part of <strong>the</strong> problem. Most of <strong>the</strong> cases are filed in<br />

<strong>the</strong> state of domicile (usually <strong>the</strong> state where <strong>the</strong> headquarters is), <strong>and</strong> a<br />

significant percentage are filed in <strong>the</strong> Chancery Court in Delaware, a popular state<br />

for incorporation. Defendants generally prefer Delaware. Assigning a forum in<br />

<strong>the</strong> articles or by-laws is permitted by some state statutes. This practice is being<br />

challenged in <strong>the</strong> courts. It is too early to say where it will go. Public companies<br />

prefer to have <strong>the</strong>ir shareholder litigation in Delaware. Plaintiffs’ lawyers like<br />

Marshall County, Texas.<br />

The bigger <strong>the</strong> deal - <strong>the</strong> more <strong>the</strong> litigation <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> more forums. Plaintiffs like<br />

federal courts least of all. The federal courts are not as friendly to <strong>the</strong>se cases as<br />

<strong>the</strong>y once were. The PSLRA has created burdens <strong>and</strong> raised <strong>the</strong> bar for plaintiffs.<br />

3. Deference to <strong>the</strong> board of directors. The modern business corporation codes<br />

defer to <strong>the</strong> boards of directors. Gone are <strong>the</strong> days when courts would intervene<br />

in a proposed deal to substitute <strong>the</strong>ir own judgments. The courts are now much<br />

less likely to enjoin a transaction before closing – where <strong>the</strong> complaint is <strong>the</strong> price<br />

or <strong>the</strong> process.<br />

4. The law of director duty is now quite crystalized. There are <strong>the</strong> duties of care,<br />

loyalty <strong>and</strong> proportionality. Proportionality means that what a director must do in<br />

connection with an M&A transaction depends on <strong>the</strong> type of transaction, though<br />

<strong>the</strong> concept of a director as a fiduciary is <strong>the</strong> overlay. A fiduciary is independent,<br />

informed, acts in good faith <strong>and</strong> is prudent – he brings to bear <strong>the</strong> same diligence<br />

<strong>and</strong> care that he would in his own affairs. He puts <strong>the</strong> interests of his principal<br />

before his own.<br />

5. BFD Suits Against Directors. Suits against directors for breach of fiduciary<br />

duty, prosecuted after <strong>the</strong> closing, are <strong>the</strong> most effective weapons. The suits<br />

prosecuted to conclusion before closing are rare <strong>and</strong> usually based on process –<br />

claims of flawed disclosure <strong>and</strong> conflicts of interest. But process cases are<br />

usually settled before closing with some curative action, such as amendment of a<br />

proxy statement. Undisclosed conflicts of interest might result in an injunction<br />

before closing, but, again, conflicts allegations are cured by disclosure or removal<br />

of <strong>the</strong> conflict, e.g., a banker that is on both sides of a deal will have to resign one<br />

of <strong>the</strong> engagements. When judges enjoin a deal, <strong>the</strong>y run <strong>the</strong> deal. The parties<br />

are in <strong>the</strong>ir chambers <strong>and</strong> courtroom constantly. The heavy press of judicial<br />

business weighs heavily against a pre-closing injunction.


6. Directors Fiduciary Duty.<br />

Structure <strong>and</strong> complexity. A corollary of <strong>the</strong> growth of deferral of claims to postclosing<br />

is <strong>the</strong> growth of <strong>the</strong> notion of, <strong>and</strong> law of, directors’ fiduciary duty. The<br />

concepts have not changed so much as <strong>the</strong> application of <strong>the</strong> concepts, which have<br />

evolved ratable to <strong>the</strong> size, complexity <strong>and</strong> eccentricity of <strong>the</strong> deals. More<br />

regulation <strong>and</strong> more cross-border deals mean more litigation.<br />

Assessing Fairness. The more complex <strong>the</strong> deal, <strong>the</strong> more difficult <strong>the</strong> disclosure<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> more difficult <strong>the</strong> assessment of fairness. Discussion of director fiduciary<br />

duty is an academic exercise <strong>and</strong> takes a few minutes. The application of <strong>the</strong> duty<br />

to a complex deal is difficult even for <strong>the</strong> virtuous. Learning to make your virtue<br />

work for you as a director takes more than a pure heart. <strong>You</strong> have to be schooled<br />

in <strong>the</strong> law, which means have a working knowledge of <strong>the</strong> leading cases.<br />

II.<br />

Case Law Has Defined <strong>the</strong> Role of <strong>the</strong> Director in M&A - How<br />

Do Directors Discharge Their Duties of Care, Loyalty <strong>and</strong><br />

Proportionality?<br />

1. Be informed. An empty head <strong>and</strong> a pure heart is no longer a defense. But, <strong>the</strong><br />

business judgment rule can be a defense. It is in <strong>the</strong> exercise of an informed<br />

business judgment that <strong>the</strong> director reacts to <strong>the</strong> exigencies of <strong>the</strong> deal. It is likely<br />

to benefit <strong>the</strong> shareholders more than <strong>the</strong> continuation of <strong>the</strong> current business<br />

plan. If <strong>the</strong> answer is not one that would be obvious to a judge, <strong>the</strong>n proceed with<br />

care. An all cash offer for a significant premium over <strong>the</strong> current price, using<br />

metrics (price to sales, earnings, EBIDTA well above <strong>the</strong> norm, where <strong>the</strong>re is<br />

only one class of stock) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> creditors will be in <strong>the</strong> care of a stronger debtor,<br />

is <strong>the</strong> easy <strong>and</strong> plain vanilla. Easy to be a good fiduciary <strong>and</strong> exercise your<br />

informed business judgment.<br />

2. St<strong>and</strong>ard. A st<strong>and</strong>ard more rigorous than <strong>the</strong> business judgment st<strong>and</strong>ard is<br />

applied in certain circumstances: The entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard being <strong>the</strong> highest<br />

which applies when some directors will benefit personally from <strong>the</strong> transactions,<br />

e.g. an MBO.<br />

2


3. Del Monte, El Paso <strong>and</strong> Delphi. In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders Litig.,<br />

25 A.3d 813 (Del. Ch. 2011), In re El Paso Corp. S’holder Litig., 41 A.3d 432<br />

(Del. Ch. 2012) <strong>and</strong> In re Delphi Fin. Grp. S’holder Litig., CIV.A. 7144-VCG,<br />

2012 WL 729232 (Del. Ch. Mar. 6, 2012) cases are illustrative. This chart is<br />

helpful <strong>and</strong> is from <strong>the</strong> publication M&A <strong>Litigation</strong> 2012, from <strong>the</strong> Practicing<br />

Law Institute. These cases demonstrate how <strong>the</strong> facts <strong>and</strong> circumstances will<br />

determine what constitutes <strong>the</strong> proper exercise of director duties <strong>and</strong> when a Court<br />

will intervene. The proper use of proportionality in <strong>the</strong> exercise of business<br />

judgment is critical.<br />

III. The Special Committee has become a de facto m<strong>and</strong>ate in some<br />

deals, such as <strong>the</strong> MBO<br />

1. Special Committees. The Special Committee is a defensive device. It is very<br />

important when <strong>the</strong> “entire fairness” st<strong>and</strong>ard is applied----as distinguished from<br />

<strong>the</strong> Revlon or business judgment st<strong>and</strong>ards. See Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews &<br />

Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (Del. 1986).<br />

Case law defines what constitutes a proper special committee in form <strong>and</strong> in<br />

action. Both a fair price <strong>and</strong> a fair process must be <strong>the</strong> result. If <strong>the</strong> process is not<br />

fair, <strong>the</strong> shareholders can obtain a fair process <strong>and</strong> price from <strong>the</strong> court. In <strong>the</strong><br />

case of <strong>the</strong> ultimate conflict, <strong>the</strong> management led buy-out, <strong>the</strong> failure to appoint a<br />

special committee is itself evidence of a lack of fair dealing. When a committee<br />

is independent, gets competent <strong>and</strong> independent outside advice, is informed <strong>and</strong><br />

deliberate, dem<strong>and</strong>s a proper proxy statement, it has done its duty.<br />

2. Special Committee Process. The Special Committee process has received a lot<br />

of attention by <strong>the</strong> courts recently. See In re S. Peru Copper Corp. S’holder<br />

Derivative Litig., 52 A.3d 761 (Del. Ch. 2011), judgment entered sub nom.,<br />

CIV.A. 961-CS, 2011 WL 6382006 (Del. Ch. Dec. 20, 2011) vacated sub nom.,<br />

961-CS, 2011 WL 6476919 (Del. Ch. Dec. 22, 2011).<br />

In Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, <strong>the</strong> control group caused <strong>the</strong> controlled company to enter a<br />

transaction with a company related to <strong>the</strong> control group. The Chancery Court<br />

found <strong>the</strong> special committee fatally flawed because <strong>the</strong> committee was not<br />

enabled to shop, negotiate, consider alternatives or, to do anything except to find a<br />

way to make <strong>the</strong> deal work. Perhaps <strong>the</strong> most important factor was denying <strong>the</strong><br />

Committee <strong>the</strong> right to negotiate. Its charter was to approve or disapprove <strong>the</strong><br />

deal on <strong>the</strong> table <strong>and</strong> it set out to rationalize that deal.<br />

IV.<br />

Price Maximization<br />

1. Deal Protection. In a deal where <strong>the</strong>re are no conflicts, such as cash for stock,<br />

with no rival, when <strong>the</strong> target is a public company <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> price is at a premium,<br />

3


<strong>the</strong> Revlon (Delaware) <strong>and</strong> business judgment rules apply. The court will defer to<br />

<strong>the</strong> decision of <strong>the</strong> board.<br />

However, that does not mean that <strong>the</strong> directors can approve <strong>the</strong> first deal that<br />

comes along that is at or above <strong>the</strong> latest closing price. The buyer will always ask<br />

for protection on <strong>the</strong> deal, including protection from deal jumpers, topping bids,<br />

go-shop clauses <strong>and</strong> ask for no shop <strong>and</strong> no talk, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> like.<br />

The seller will want deal protection such as a break-up fee. This is where <strong>the</strong> rule<br />

of proportionality comes in. Even when Revlon or business judgment applies,<br />

provisions to protect <strong>the</strong> deal will be suspect as avoidance of shopping for <strong>the</strong> best<br />

price reasonably attainable. The record of <strong>the</strong> board’s deliberations should prove<br />

that <strong>the</strong> board was well informed <strong>and</strong> made a considered judgment as to <strong>the</strong><br />

alternatives to deal protection.<br />

2. Price Maximization for whom? When <strong>the</strong>re is only one class of stock <strong>the</strong><br />

enterprise valuation is <strong>the</strong> easy part. Allocating enterprise value along <strong>the</strong> classes<br />

- usually preferred vs. common - gets difficult. The preferred shareholders might<br />

deserve separate representation in <strong>the</strong> process. See LC Capital Master Fund vs.<br />

James, 990 A. 2d 435 (Del. Ch. 2010); Jedwab v. MGM Gr<strong>and</strong> Hotel, 509 A.2d<br />

584 (Del. Ch. 1986) (preferred shareholder claims implicated fiduciary duties).<br />

Depending on <strong>the</strong> preferred instrument, <strong>the</strong> common shareholders might argue<br />

that <strong>the</strong> preferred shareholders are debt holders <strong>and</strong> owed no duty under Revlon.<br />

If <strong>the</strong>re is a conversion provision, <strong>the</strong>n it starts to look more like equity.<br />

V. Appraisal Rights<br />

1. When triggered? These rights are triggered usually by a short form merger.<br />

The business setting is often <strong>the</strong> acquisition of <strong>the</strong> public company by a private<br />

equity company <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> buyer does not want to operate <strong>the</strong> target as a st<strong>and</strong>-alone<br />

public company. Also, appraisal rights can be triggered by a stock for stock deal.<br />

2. Valuation. Dissenters’ rights valuation practice is developing favorably for <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders. The traditional rule that only evidence existing at <strong>the</strong> valuation date<br />

is admissible is eroding in favor of consideration of subsequent developments if<br />

<strong>the</strong>y were based on what was known or knowable before <strong>the</strong> valuation dates.<br />

Most often this litigation involves business plans <strong>and</strong> projections which are not<br />

consistent with <strong>the</strong> valuation adopted by <strong>the</strong> board <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> price offered. See<br />

Gholl et al vs. EMACHINES, Inc., No. CIV.A. 19444-NC, 2004 WL 2847865<br />

(Del. Ch. Nov. 24, 2004), aff’d, 875 A.2d 632 (Del. 2005).<br />

In Minnesota, <strong>the</strong> courts in dissenters’ rights cases are likely, when faced with <strong>the</strong><br />

situation, to follow <strong>the</strong> approach in EMACHINES. All evidence, whe<strong>the</strong>r created<br />

before or after <strong>the</strong> valuation date should be considered if reasonably bearing on<br />

value.<br />

4


The problem for <strong>the</strong> company, of course, is that <strong>the</strong>re are, at any given time, more<br />

than one set of projections floating around with business plans as well. It should<br />

go to <strong>the</strong> weight, unless <strong>the</strong> document or statement occurs so long after or before<br />

<strong>the</strong> valuation date as to lack probative import on <strong>the</strong> question of value.<br />

VI. Derivative Cases<br />

1. Minnesota <strong>and</strong> Delaware. The rules are generally <strong>the</strong> same – tracking <strong>the</strong><br />

Federal Rules of Procedure.<br />

2. Derivative claims. The question is whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> plaintiff’s claims belong to <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders or <strong>the</strong> company. If <strong>the</strong> latter, <strong>the</strong> claims must be brought as<br />

derivative claims.<br />

3. MakeMusic. A recent Minnesota trial court decision in <strong>the</strong> Kruglick v.<br />

MakeMusic, Inc., No. 27CV13-5508, Fourth Judicial District for <strong>the</strong> State of<br />

Minnesota, suggests Minnesota law might be going a different direction. In<br />

MakeMusic, <strong>the</strong> deal involved a tender offer by a significant shareholder for cash.<br />

The Plaintiffs complained about <strong>the</strong> price <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> process. One of <strong>the</strong> complaints<br />

was that <strong>the</strong> proxy statement was misleading <strong>and</strong> inadequate.<br />

The gist of <strong>the</strong> disclosure claim was that <strong>the</strong>re was not enough information being<br />

given so that <strong>the</strong> shareholders could make an informed decision. On motion by<br />

<strong>the</strong> company, <strong>the</strong> court ordered a stay <strong>and</strong> referral to a special litigation committee<br />

after finding that <strong>the</strong> claims belong to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>.<br />

4. WWDHD? What would Delaware have done? Enjoin <strong>the</strong> vote, probably, but<br />

not make a referral to a special committee. The prescribed voting process is for<br />

<strong>the</strong> benefit of <strong>the</strong> shareholders. There is no relief afforded to a target company,<br />

financial or o<strong>the</strong>rwise, to be derived from a successful disclosure complaint.<br />

Disclosure is an obligation owed by <strong>the</strong> tender offeror to <strong>the</strong> shareholders. A<br />

misrepresentation is fraud on <strong>the</strong> shareholder who gets brought out.<br />

VII. Major Trends in M&A <strong>Litigation</strong> - forum shopping,<br />

shareholder activism, increased proxy access <strong>and</strong> increased<br />

regulatory intervention<br />

1. Forum. The Delaware Chancery Court has been, <strong>and</strong> still is, a hot spot for M&A<br />

litigation involving corporations incorporated under Delaware law, though most<br />

M&A litigation is in <strong>the</strong> federal courts in <strong>the</strong> state where <strong>the</strong> corporation is<br />

domiciled. Yet, <strong>the</strong>re is a trend toward multiple litigations over <strong>the</strong> same deal.<br />

This trend has created a significant increase in what was already a very expensive<br />

process. There seems no way to stop this. The federal courts cannot restrict a<br />

state court from taking jurisdiction over claims that state law has created <strong>and</strong> a<br />

state court cannot preempt a federal court’s jurisdiction.<br />

5


2. Forum Selection Clause in Bylaws. Some corporations are inserting provisions<br />

in <strong>the</strong> articles <strong>and</strong> bylaws limiting shareholder choice of forum. In Galavis v.<br />

Berg, No. C 10-3392 RS (N.D. Cal. Jan. 3, 2011), <strong>the</strong> federal district court for <strong>the</strong><br />

Nor<strong>the</strong>rn District of California denied a motion by Oracle to dismiss a shareholder<br />

action on <strong>the</strong> ground that its venue in federal court was prohibited by <strong>the</strong> articles<br />

<strong>and</strong> by-laws, which limited shareholder cases to a Delaware forum. The court<br />

applied federal law. Cases are pending which test <strong>the</strong> viability of forum choice by<br />

charter.<br />

VIII. Comparative Law: Minnesota <strong>and</strong> Delaware<br />

1. Minnesota <strong>and</strong> Delaware law. Much has been written on this subject. See <strong>the</strong><br />

Reporters Notes to <strong>the</strong> Minnesota Business Corporations Act at Chapter 302A as<br />

a starting point. The Minnesota Act is based, in large measure, on <strong>the</strong> Model Act,<br />

at least as to <strong>the</strong> general approach of regulating <strong>the</strong> corporation. See also Philip S.<br />

Garon et. al., Challenging Delaware’s Desirability As A Haven for Incorporation,<br />

32 Wm. Mitchell L. Rev. 769, 771 (2006). This article is a rejoinder to Bryn<br />

Vaaler, Scrap <strong>the</strong> Minnesota Business Corporation Act!, 28 Wm. Mitchell L. Rev.<br />

1365, 1366 (2002).<br />

2. Anti-takeover provisions. Anti-takeover provisions in Minnesota are not<br />

significantly different from Delaware <strong>and</strong> from a litigation point of view do not<br />

seem to be a factor. It appears that <strong>the</strong>re are work-arounds that do work around.<br />

Minnesota <strong>and</strong> Delaware have Business Combination Acts <strong>and</strong> Minnesota is one<br />

of twenty seven states that have a Control Share Acquisition Act. Delaware does<br />

not.<br />

3. Seven-Fifty-One. Minnesota has a minority shareholder protection statute like<br />

no o<strong>the</strong>r - Section 302A.751 of <strong>the</strong> MBCA. Garon et al. says .751 “may in itself<br />

be a reason to incorporate in Delaware.” It has been said that .751 means that<br />

shareholders are entitled to be treated more like partners than shareholders. The<br />

combination of a fiduciary duty of shareholders, one to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>and</strong> great<br />

equitable powers granted to <strong>the</strong> court to remedy a breach of duty, results in<br />

considerable litigation <strong>and</strong> litigation forced changes of ownership <strong>and</strong> even<br />

control. This is accomplished by what is called a “buy-out” order.<br />

While ordinarily <strong>the</strong> shareholder bought out is a minority shareholder, sometimes<br />

an equal shareholder, usually it is a minority shareholder who is also an employee<br />

– or was an employee. While <strong>the</strong> statute is not, to <strong>the</strong> letter, a no-fault divorce<br />

approach, it comes close, in practice.<br />

When properly administered this statute solves a major problem in small, often<br />

family businesses. No buy-out order should impair <strong>the</strong> balance sheet <strong>and</strong> so any<br />

buyout is to be on terms <strong>the</strong> business <strong>and</strong> its creditors can adapt to, without defeat<br />

of <strong>the</strong>ir reasonable expectations.<br />

6


4. Squeeze-outs <strong>and</strong> Split-outs. Minnesota, unlike Delaware, does not require a<br />

business purpose, to legally justify <strong>the</strong> elimination of unwanted minority<br />

shareholders. They can be eliminated by merger <strong>and</strong> have appraisal rights.<br />

In a recent Minnesota case, U.S. Bank N.A. v. Cold Spring Granite Co., 802<br />

N.W.2d 363, 371 (Minn. 2011), <strong>the</strong> control group family used <strong>the</strong> fractional<br />

shares reverse split statute to eliminate <strong>the</strong> minority shareholder group(s). This<br />

decision is controversial as it goes against <strong>the</strong> seeming policies codified in .751.<br />

The Minnesota Supreme Court, in its decision, seemed to recognize this problem,<br />

but said it is one <strong>the</strong> legislature must fix. Id. (“While <strong>the</strong> fairness of this approach<br />

is open to debate, <strong>the</strong>se policy decisions are within <strong>the</strong> province of <strong>the</strong><br />

Legislature.”).<br />

The result is that <strong>the</strong> minority, despite <strong>the</strong>ir expectations down <strong>the</strong> generations<br />

that <strong>the</strong>y would continue as owners, were squeezed out, not at fair value, as would<br />

be <strong>the</strong> case under .751, but at <strong>the</strong> price set as fair by <strong>the</strong> board, <strong>the</strong> board price<br />

being subject to judicial scrutiny only with proof of common law fraud. This case<br />

has probably sent many a control group in Minnesota scurrying to <strong>the</strong> share<br />

register to calculate whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> reverse split statute could be used to reduce, if<br />

not eliminate, <strong>the</strong> non-control group.<br />

In MakeMusic, <strong>the</strong> court’s decision that <strong>the</strong> claims were derivative suggests that<br />

<strong>the</strong> court was unaware that <strong>the</strong> merger would extinguish <strong>the</strong> derivative claims,<br />

<strong>the</strong>reby depriving <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs from having <strong>the</strong>ir claims of a flawed tender<br />

process extinguished. See In re Massey Energy Co., CIV.A. 5430-VCS, 2011 WL<br />

2176479 (Del. Ch. May 31, 2011) ( holding that failure of <strong>the</strong> corporate board to<br />

secure <strong>the</strong> derivative claims for corporation’s current stockholders did not justify<br />

<strong>the</strong> entry of a preliminary injunction against corporation’s merger); Kahn v.<br />

Kolberg Kravis Roberts & Co., 23 A.3d 831 (Del. 2011) (actual harm to a<br />

corporation was not required in order for stockholders to assert derivative claims<br />

for insider trading by fiduciaries).<br />

Again, it is <strong>the</strong> process <strong>the</strong> law is protecting – an honest market where all<br />

shareholders have access to <strong>the</strong> same information. In many M&A transactions <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiffs claim that <strong>the</strong> process approved by <strong>the</strong> board is calculated to injure <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholder. The company is not a juridical person in this context <strong>and</strong> cannot<br />

suffer injury.<br />

IX. Recent Developments<br />

1. Quasi appraisal rights. Quasi appraisal rights are a Delaware phenomenon<br />

which could catch on elsewhere. In denying pre-closing relief to a class attacking<br />

<strong>the</strong> process, <strong>the</strong> Courts have given <strong>the</strong> class “quasi appraisal rights”. After <strong>the</strong><br />

closing, <strong>the</strong> shareholders can opt into <strong>the</strong> class <strong>and</strong> pursue appraisal rights – or<br />

7


pursue <strong>the</strong> claim that <strong>the</strong>y have appraisal rights <strong>and</strong> if it is decided that <strong>the</strong>y do,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y will try <strong>the</strong> valuation issue.<br />

2. Quasi-Appraisal case law. These cases are highly idiosyncratic except <strong>the</strong><br />

dynamics are <strong>the</strong> same pre-closing. The companies are concerned that an<br />

injunction might issue <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>y fear exposing <strong>the</strong> deal to delay more than a<br />

successful attack on <strong>the</strong> price pre-closing. By agreeing to quasi-appraisal, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

get <strong>the</strong> stick away from <strong>the</strong> spokes of <strong>the</strong> deal, taking leverage from <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs.<br />

They get certainty of <strong>the</strong> deal in return for some uncertainty of <strong>the</strong> cost. Defense<br />

lawyers who do this have a high degree of confidence in <strong>the</strong> judge’s appraisal<br />

talents. See Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 703 (Del. 1983)(holding that<br />

appraisal is <strong>the</strong> remedy for minority shareholders in a cash-out merger); Krieger<br />

v. Wesco Fin. Corp., 30 A.3d 54, 60 (Del. Ch. 2011) (holding common<br />

shareholders did not have appraisal rights as a result of merger).<br />

This trend is ano<strong>the</strong>r symptom of <strong>the</strong> increasing reluctance of <strong>the</strong> courts to grant<br />

pre-closing injunctive relief.<br />

X. Can A Deal Be Made Bullet Proof?<br />

Yes, but only if you pay what <strong>the</strong>y ask for, plus attorneys’ fees. Short of that:<br />

1. Have a plan that is neutral. A plan full of anti-takeover measures but no price<br />

maximization measures is not neutral.<br />

2. Make it a practice to read all <strong>the</strong> filings to make sure you are current on what<br />

management <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> lawyers <strong>and</strong> auditors believe is material <strong>and</strong> that nothing<br />

material is omitted. Do not wait until your deposition is about to be taken.<br />

3. Be objective <strong>and</strong> test <strong>and</strong> verify management claims.<br />

4. Look at <strong>the</strong> special meeting dem<strong>and</strong> requirements in <strong>the</strong> charter documents. Is it<br />

too easy or too difficult for shareholders to call a meeting? Delaware does not<br />

require that shareholders be given <strong>the</strong> right to call a special meeting.<br />

5. Pay attention to Williams Act filings <strong>and</strong> Hart-Scott-Rodino letters.<br />

6. Do not destroy any evidence.<br />

7. Take care not to accidentally waive <strong>the</strong> attorney client privilege. Very often<br />

directors’ primary defense against claims of breach of fiduciary duty, at least as to<br />

process, is reliance on <strong>the</strong> advice of counsel, <strong>the</strong>reby waiving <strong>the</strong> attorney client<br />

privilege - at least in part. The use of regular corporate counsel to advise directors<br />

8


on a sale transaction often leads to <strong>the</strong> waiver of <strong>the</strong> privilege. This risk can be<br />

mitigated. 1<br />

1 Special thanks to Thomas J. Dougherty <strong>and</strong> his book The Director’s H<strong>and</strong>book, 101-146 (2011<br />

ed.), which was instrumental in creating <strong>the</strong>se materials.<br />

9


Proposed<br />

Transaction<br />

Premium<br />

Offered<br />

Alleged Process<br />

Flaws Relevant<br />

to Plaintiffs’<br />

Probability of<br />

Success on<br />

Breach of Duty<br />

Claims<br />

Preliminary<br />

Injunction?<br />

In re Del Monte Foods Co.<br />

S’holder Litig., 25 A.3d 813<br />

(Del. Ch. 2011)<br />

Merger of Del Monte Foods<br />

<strong>Company</strong> with Blue<br />

Acquisition Group, Inc.,<br />

owned by KKR, Centerview<br />

Partners, <strong>and</strong> Vestar Capital<br />

Partners.<br />

$19/share, a premium of<br />

40% over <strong>the</strong> average Del<br />

Monte closing price for <strong>the</strong><br />

three-month period prior to<br />

<strong>the</strong> announcement.<br />

• Del Monte’s financial<br />

advisor, Barclays, did not<br />

disclose that it intended to<br />

provide buy-side LBO<br />

financing.<br />

• Barclays did not disclose<br />

behind-<strong>the</strong>-scenes efforts<br />

to pair <strong>the</strong> two highest<br />

previous bidders (KKR<br />

<strong>and</strong> Vestar) toge<strong>the</strong>r,<br />

which <strong>the</strong> Court found to<br />

be in violation of<br />

confidentiality<br />

agreements.<br />

• Barclays ultimately<br />

succeeded in securing onethird<br />

of <strong>the</strong> buy-side<br />

financing without<br />

providing any added<br />

benefit to Del Monte.<br />

• Barclays ran <strong>the</strong> go-shop<br />

period unsupervised,<br />

despite its apparent<br />

conflicts.<br />

Yes. Defendants were<br />

enjoined from proceeding<br />

with a shareholder vote for<br />

20 days, during which <strong>the</strong><br />

parties were also<br />

enjoined from enforcing <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Agreement’s nosolicitation,<br />

match right <strong>and</strong><br />

certain termination fee<br />

provisions.<br />

In re El Paso Corp. S’holder<br />

Litig., 2012 WL 653845 (Del.<br />

Ch. Feb. 29, 2012)<br />

Merger of El Paso Corporation<br />

with Kinder Morgan, Inc.<br />

A combination of cash, Kinder<br />

Morgan stock, <strong>and</strong> warrants<br />

valued at $30.37 at <strong>the</strong> time of<br />

<strong>the</strong> court's ruling, a premium of<br />

47.8% over El Paso’s stock<br />

price 30 days before Kinder<br />

Morgan made its first bid.<br />

• El Paso CEO Doug Foshee<br />

was <strong>the</strong> sole El Paso<br />

negotiator despite his<br />

undisclosed intention to<br />

participate in a managementled<br />

buyout of <strong>the</strong> company's<br />

E&P business after <strong>the</strong><br />

merger with Kinder Morgan.<br />

• Goldman Sachs, El Paso’s<br />

financial advisor, owned 19%<br />

of Kinder Morgan (a $4<br />

billion value), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Court<br />

concluded that it was not<br />

effectively walled off from<br />

providing advice.<br />

• Despite its ownership interest<br />

in <strong>the</strong> acquiror, Goldman<br />

continued to advise El Paso<br />

on alternatives to <strong>the</strong><br />

proposed transaction.<br />

• Goldman’s lead banker failed<br />

to disclose his personal<br />

investment in Kinder<br />

Morgan.<br />

• Morgan Stanley, brought in to<br />

cleanse Goldman’s conflict,<br />

would not be paid unless El<br />

Paso adopted <strong>the</strong> proposed<br />

transaction with Kinder<br />

Morgan.<br />

No. Despite <strong>the</strong> “troubling<br />

behavior” of Foshee <strong>and</strong><br />

Goldman, <strong>the</strong> balance of<br />

equities weighed against a<br />

preliminary injunction in light<br />

of <strong>the</strong> premium offered <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

absence of any competing<br />

offers.<br />

In re Delphi Fin. Grp.<br />

S’holder Litig., 2012 WL<br />

729232 (Del. Ch. Mar. 6,<br />

2012)<br />

Merger of Delphi Financial<br />

Group with Tokio Marine<br />

Holdings, Inc.<br />

$44.875/share for Class A<br />

stockholders, a premium of<br />

76% over Delphi's closing<br />

price <strong>the</strong> day before<br />

announcement.<br />

• Delphi CEO Robert<br />

Rosenkranz, who held all<br />

Class B stock <strong>and</strong> 49.9% of<br />

<strong>the</strong> company's voting<br />

power, negotiated <strong>and</strong><br />

secured for himself an<br />

incremental premium for<br />

his Class B shares despite<br />

provisions in Delphi’s<br />

charter requiring that each<br />

class of stock receive equal<br />

consideration in a merger.<br />

• Given <strong>the</strong> Court’s<br />

assumption that this charter<br />

provision caused <strong>the</strong> initial<br />

offering price of Delphi<br />

shares to be higher than it<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise would have<br />

been, it held that<br />

Rosenkranz improperly<br />

secured a second control<br />

premium at <strong>the</strong> expense of<br />

public stockholders.<br />

No. Despite <strong>the</strong> incremental<br />

premium<br />

secured by Rosenkranz, <strong>the</strong><br />

balance of equities weighed<br />

against a preliminary<br />

injunction in light of <strong>the</strong><br />

“substantial”<br />

premium offered <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

absence of any competing<br />

offers.<br />

Provided by Practicing Law Institute, David R. Marriott, Chair, M&A <strong>Litigation</strong> 2012, 401-403 (2012).


Revlon, Inc.<br />

v.<br />

MacAndrews <strong>and</strong> Forbes Holdings, Inc.


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

506 A.2d 173<br />

Supreme Court of Delaware.<br />

REVLON, INC., a Delaware corporation, Michel C.<br />

Bergerac, Simon Aldewereld, S<strong>and</strong>er P. Alex<strong>and</strong>er,<br />

Jay I. Bennett, Irving J. Bottner, Jacob Burns, Lewis<br />

L. Glucksman, John Loudon, Aileen Mehle, Samuel<br />

L. Simmons, Ian R. Wilson, Paul P. Woolard,<br />

Ezra K. Zilkha, Forstmann Little & Co., a New<br />

York limited partnership, <strong>and</strong> Forstmann Little &<br />

Co. Subordinated Debt <strong>and</strong> Equity Management<br />

Buyout Partnership-II, a New York limited<br />

partnership, Defendants Below, Appellants,<br />

v.<br />

MacANDREWS & FORBES HOLDINGS, INC., a<br />

Delaware corporation, Plaintiff Below, Appellee.<br />

Submitted: Oct. 31, 1985. | Oral Decision:<br />

Nov. 1, 1985. | Written Opinion: March 13, 1986.<br />

Bidder for corporations stock brought action to enjoin certain<br />

defensive actions taken by <strong>the</strong> target corporation <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs.<br />

The Court of Chancery, New Castle County, 501 A.2d 1239,<br />

granted preliminary injunction <strong>and</strong> defendants appealed. The<br />

Supreme Court, 505 A.2d 454 affirmed, with an opinion to<br />

issue. The Supreme Court, Moore, J., held that: (1) lockups<br />

<strong>and</strong> related agreements are permitted under Delaware law<br />

where <strong>the</strong>ir adoption is untainted by director interest or o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

breaches of fiduciary duties; (2) actions taken by directors in<br />

<strong>the</strong> instant case did not meet that st<strong>and</strong>ard; (3) concern for<br />

various corporate constituencies is proper when addressing a<br />

takeover threat; (4) that principle is limited by <strong>the</strong> requirement<br />

that <strong>the</strong>re be some rationally related benefit accruing to <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders; (5) <strong>the</strong>re were no such benefits in <strong>the</strong> instant<br />

case; <strong>and</strong> (6) when sale of <strong>the</strong> company becomes inevitable,<br />

duty of board of directors changes from preservation of <strong>the</strong><br />

corporate entity to maximization of <strong>the</strong> company's value at a<br />

sale for <strong>the</strong> stockholders' benefits.<br />

Affirmed.<br />

Lockups <strong>and</strong> related agreements are permitted<br />

under Delaware law where <strong>the</strong>ir adoption is<br />

untainted by corporate director interest or o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

breaches of fiduciary duty.<br />

16 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[2] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

Concern for various corporate constituencies is<br />

proper when directors address a takeover threat<br />

but that principle is limited by <strong>the</strong> requirement<br />

that <strong>the</strong>re be some rationally related benefit<br />

accruing to <strong>the</strong> stockholders.<br />

5 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[3] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Duties of directors <strong>and</strong> officers in general;<br />

business judgment rule<br />

Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

In discharging duties to manage business <strong>and</strong><br />

affairs of a corporation, directors owe fiduciary<br />

duties of care <strong>and</strong> loyalty to <strong>the</strong> corporation<br />

<strong>and</strong> its shareholders; those principles apply with<br />

equal force when a board of directors approves<br />

a corporate merger <strong>and</strong> are <strong>the</strong> bedrock of <strong>the</strong><br />

law regarding corporate takeovers. 8 Del.C. §§<br />

141(a), 251(b).<br />

25 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[4] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

While <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule may be<br />

applicable to <strong>the</strong> actions of corporate directors<br />

responding to takeover threats, <strong>the</strong> principles of<br />

care, loyalty, <strong>and</strong> independence upon which it is<br />

founded must first be satisfied.<br />

13 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

West Headnotes (21)<br />

[1] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Lockups<br />

[5] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Actions by minority shareholders; judicial<br />

scrutiny<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 1


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

Potential for conflict when board of directors<br />

implements antitakeover measures places upon<br />

<strong>the</strong> directors <strong>the</strong> burden of proving that <strong>the</strong>y had<br />

reasonable grounds for believing that <strong>the</strong>re was<br />

a danger to corporate policy <strong>and</strong> effectiveness, a<br />

burden which is satisfied by showing good faith<br />

<strong>and</strong> reasonable investigation.<br />

16 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[6] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

Board of directors must analyze nature of<br />

proposed takeover <strong>and</strong> its effect on <strong>the</strong><br />

corporation in order to ensure that responsive<br />

action taken by <strong>the</strong> board is reasonable in relation<br />

to <strong>the</strong> threat posed to <strong>the</strong> corporation.<br />

corporation's stock exceeded <strong>the</strong> amount set as<br />

<strong>the</strong> target in <strong>the</strong> plan.<br />

2 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[10] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

When corporation exercises power to deal in<br />

its own stock in an effort to forestall a hostile<br />

takeover, <strong>the</strong> board of directors' actions are<br />

strictly held to <strong>the</strong> fiduciary st<strong>and</strong>ards requiring<br />

<strong>the</strong> directors to determine <strong>the</strong> best interest of <strong>the</strong><br />

corporation <strong>and</strong> its stockholders <strong>and</strong> to abjure<br />

any action that is motivated by considerations<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r than a good-faith concern for those<br />

interests. 8 Del.C. § 160(a).<br />

19 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[7] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Poison pills<br />

Board of directors had authority to adopt a<br />

“poison pill” plan by which shareholders would<br />

receive <strong>the</strong> right to be bought out by <strong>the</strong><br />

corporation at a substantial premium upon <strong>the</strong><br />

occurrence of a stated triggering event. 8 Del.C.<br />

§§ 141, 157.<br />

3 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[8] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Poison pills<br />

“Poison pill” plan which gave shareholders <strong>the</strong><br />

right to be bought out by <strong>the</strong> corporation at a<br />

substantial premium upon <strong>the</strong> occurrence of a<br />

stated triggering event was a reasonable plan for<br />

adoption by board of directors in response to<br />

impending hostile takeover bid at a price which<br />

<strong>the</strong> board reasonably concluded was grossly<br />

inadequate.<br />

29 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[9] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

Question of propriety of actions taken by<br />

board of directors to combat hostile takeover<br />

was mooted when all offers made for <strong>the</strong><br />

[11] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

Board of directors' adoption of exchange offer<br />

for ten million of corporation's own shares was<br />

a reasonable response to a hostile takeover bid<br />

which it considered grossly inadequate.<br />

2 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[12] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

When it became apparent that breakup of<br />

company was inevitable as result of takeover<br />

bids <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> board of directors recognized that<br />

<strong>the</strong> company was for sale, board's duties changed<br />

from <strong>the</strong> preservation of <strong>the</strong> company as a<br />

corporate entity to <strong>the</strong> maximization of <strong>the</strong><br />

company's value at a sale for <strong>the</strong> stockholders'<br />

benefits; directors' role changed from defenders<br />

of <strong>the</strong> corporate bastion to auctioneers charged<br />

with getting <strong>the</strong> best price for <strong>the</strong> stockholders at<br />

a sale of <strong>the</strong> company.<br />

108 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[13] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Lockups<br />

Where rights of noteholders needed no fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

protection, as <strong>the</strong>y were fixed by contract, board<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 2


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

of directors breached its primary duty of loyalty<br />

when it entered into a lockup agreement with<br />

a potential buyer on <strong>the</strong> basis of impermissible<br />

considerations of <strong>the</strong> noteholders' interests at <strong>the</strong><br />

expense of <strong>the</strong> shareholders.<br />

28 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

corporation was a breach of <strong>the</strong> board's<br />

fiduciary duties where <strong>the</strong> agreement to negotiate<br />

with only <strong>the</strong> one bidder ended, ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

intensifying, <strong>the</strong> board's involvement in a<br />

bidding contest for <strong>the</strong> corporation.<br />

4 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[14] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties as to Management of<br />

Corporate Affairs in General<br />

Concern for nonstockholder interest is<br />

inappropriate when <strong>the</strong>re is in progress an<br />

auction among active bidders for <strong>the</strong> company<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> object of <strong>the</strong> board of directors is<br />

no longer to protect or maintain <strong>the</strong> corporate<br />

enterprise but to sell it to <strong>the</strong> highest bidder.<br />

41 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[15] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

When a board of directors ends an intense<br />

bidding contest for <strong>the</strong> corporation on an<br />

insubstantial basis <strong>and</strong> a significant by-product<br />

of that action is to protect <strong>the</strong> directors against<br />

a perceived threat of personal liability for<br />

consequences stemming from <strong>the</strong> prior adoption<br />

of an antitakeover measure, <strong>the</strong> directors<br />

have breached <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary duties to <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders.<br />

10 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[16] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties of Directors <strong>and</strong> Officers<br />

No-shop provision adopted by a corporate board<br />

of directors in response to hostile takeover bid<br />

is impermissible when <strong>the</strong> board's primary duty<br />

has become that of an auctioneer responsible for<br />

selling <strong>the</strong> company to <strong>the</strong> highest bidder.<br />

76 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[18] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties as to Management of<br />

Corporate Affairs in General<br />

When bidders for corporation make relatively<br />

similar offers or dissolution of <strong>the</strong> company<br />

becomes inevitable, <strong>the</strong> directors cannot fulfill<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary duties by playing favorites among<br />

<strong>the</strong> contending factions <strong>and</strong> market forces must<br />

be allowed to operate freely to bring <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders <strong>the</strong> best price available for <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

equity.<br />

34 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[19] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties as to Management of<br />

Corporate Affairs in General<br />

When sale of corporation has become inevitable,<br />

directors' role remains an active one to obtain<br />

<strong>the</strong> highest price possible for <strong>the</strong> stockholders'<br />

benefit.<br />

10 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[20] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

Trial court did not abuse its discretion in<br />

enjoining payment of cancellation fee to one of<br />

two bidders for corporation pending a resolution<br />

of merits of o<strong>the</strong>r bidder's challenge to certain<br />

actions taken by <strong>the</strong> board of directors, including<br />

<strong>the</strong> cancellation fee agreement.<br />

5 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[17] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Lockups<br />

Lockup agreement entered into by board of<br />

directors with one of two bidders for <strong>the</strong><br />

[21] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 3


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

<strong>Company</strong> bidding for purchase of corporation<br />

showed likelihood of irreparable harm if it were<br />

not granted injunction against certain defensive<br />

measures taken by <strong>the</strong> target corporation <strong>and</strong> that<br />

possible harm outweighed any potential harm to<br />

<strong>the</strong> target corporation <strong>and</strong> ano<strong>the</strong>r bidder which<br />

might result from <strong>the</strong> grant of <strong>the</strong> injunction.<br />

40 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

*175 Upon appeal from <strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery.<br />

AFFIRMED.<br />

Attorneys <strong>and</strong> Law Firms<br />

A. Gilchrist Sparks, III (argued), Lawrence A. Hamermesh,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Kenneth Nachbar, of Morris, Nichols, Arsht &<br />

Tunnell, Wilmington, <strong>and</strong> Herbert M. Wachtell, Douglas S.<br />

Liebhafsky, Kenneth B. Forrest, <strong>and</strong> Theodore N. Mirvis, of<br />

Wachtell, Lipton, Rosen & Katz, New York City, of counsel,<br />

for appellant Revlon.<br />

Michael D. Goldman, James F. Burnett, Donald J. Wolfe,<br />

Jr., Richard L. Horwitz, of Potter, Anderson & Corroon,<br />

Wilmington, <strong>and</strong> Leon Silverman (argued), <strong>and</strong> Marc P.<br />

Cherno, of Fried, Frank, Harris, Shriver & Jacobson, New<br />

York City, of counsel, for appellant Forstmann Little.<br />

Bruce M. Stargatt (argued), Edward B. Maxwell, 2nd, David<br />

C. McBride, Josy W. Ingersoll, of <strong>You</strong>ng, Conaway, Stargatt<br />

& Taylor, Wilmington, <strong>and</strong> Stuart L. Shapiro (argued),<br />

Stephen P. Lamb, Andrew J. Turezyn, <strong>and</strong> Thomas P. White,<br />

of Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom, Wilmington, <strong>and</strong><br />

Michael W. Mitchell (New York City) <strong>and</strong> Marc B. Tucker,<br />

Washington, D.C., of Skadden, Arps, Slate, Meagher & Flom,<br />

for appellee.<br />

Before McNEILLY <strong>and</strong> MOORE, JJ., <strong>and</strong> BALICK, Judge<br />

(Sitting by designation pursuant to Del. Const., Art. IV, § 12.).<br />

Opinion<br />

MOORE, Justice:<br />

In this battle for corporate control of Revlon, Inc. (Revlon),<br />

<strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery enjoined certain transactions designed<br />

to thwart <strong>the</strong> efforts of Pantry Pride, Inc. (Pantry Pride) to<br />

acquire Revlon. 1 The defendants are Revlon, its board of<br />

directors, <strong>and</strong> Forstmann Little & Co. <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> latter's affiliated<br />

limited partnership (collectively, Forstmann). The injunction<br />

barred consummation of an option granted Forstmann to<br />

purchase certain Revlon assets (<strong>the</strong> lock-up option), a promise<br />

by Revlon to deal exclusively with Forstmann in <strong>the</strong> face<br />

of a takeover (<strong>the</strong> no-shop provision), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> payment<br />

of a $25 million cancellation fee to Forstmann if <strong>the</strong><br />

transaction was aborted. The Court of Chancery found that<br />

<strong>the</strong> Revlon directors had breached <strong>the</strong>ir duty of care by<br />

entering into <strong>the</strong> foregoing transactions *176 <strong>and</strong> effectively<br />

ending an active auction for <strong>the</strong> company. The trial court<br />

ruled that such arrangements are not illegal per se under<br />

Delaware law, but that <strong>the</strong>ir use under <strong>the</strong> circumstances<br />

here was impermissible. We agree. See MacAndrews &<br />

Forbes Holdings, Inc. v. Revlon, Inc., Del.Ch., 501 A.2d 1239<br />

(1985). Thus, we granted this expedited interlocutory appeal<br />

to consider for <strong>the</strong> first time <strong>the</strong> validity of such defensive<br />

measures in <strong>the</strong> face of an active bidding contest for corporate<br />

control. 2 Additionally, we address for <strong>the</strong> first time <strong>the</strong> extent<br />

to which a corporation may consider <strong>the</strong> impact of a takeover<br />

threat on constituencies o<strong>the</strong>r than shareholders. See Unocal<br />

Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., Del.Supr., 493 A.2d 946, 955<br />

(1985).<br />

[1] [2] In our view, lock-ups <strong>and</strong> related agreements<br />

are permitted under Delaware law where <strong>the</strong>ir adoption is<br />

untainted by director interest or o<strong>the</strong>r breaches of fiduciary<br />

duty. The actions taken by <strong>the</strong> Revlon directors, however, did<br />

not meet this st<strong>and</strong>ard. Moreover, while concern for various<br />

corporate constituencies is proper when addressing a takeover<br />

threat, that principle is limited by <strong>the</strong> requirement that <strong>the</strong>re be<br />

some rationally related benefit accruing to <strong>the</strong> stockholders.<br />

We find no such benefit here.<br />

Thus, under all <strong>the</strong> circumstances we must agree with<br />

<strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery that <strong>the</strong> enjoined Revlon defensive<br />

measures were inconsistent with <strong>the</strong> directors' duties to <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders. Accordingly, we affirm.<br />

I.<br />

The somewhat complex maneuvers of <strong>the</strong> parties necessitate<br />

a ra<strong>the</strong>r detailed examination of <strong>the</strong> facts. The prelude<br />

to this controversy began in June 1985, when Ronald O.<br />

Perelman, chairman of <strong>the</strong> board <strong>and</strong> chief executive officer<br />

of Pantry Pride, met with his counterpart at Revlon, Michel<br />

C. Bergerac, to discuss a friendly acquisition of Revlon by<br />

Pantry Pride. Perelman suggested a price in <strong>the</strong> range of $40–<br />

50 per share, but <strong>the</strong> meeting ended with Bergerac dismissing<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 4


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

those figures as considerably below Revlon's intrinsic value.<br />

All subsequent Pantry Pride overtures were rebuffed, perhaps<br />

in part based on Mr. Bergerac's strong personal antipathy to<br />

Mr. Perelman.<br />

Thus, on August 14, Pantry Pride's board authorized Perelman<br />

to acquire Revlon, ei<strong>the</strong>r through negotiation in <strong>the</strong> $42–$43<br />

per share range, or by making a hostile tender offer at $45.<br />

Perelman <strong>the</strong>n met with Bergerac <strong>and</strong> outlined Pantry Pride's<br />

alternate approaches. Bergerac remained adamantly opposed<br />

to such schemes <strong>and</strong> conditioned any fur<strong>the</strong>r discussions of<br />

<strong>the</strong> matter on Pantry Pride executing a st<strong>and</strong>still agreement<br />

prohibiting it from acquiring Revlon without <strong>the</strong> latter's prior<br />

approval.<br />

On August 19, <strong>the</strong> Revlon board met specially to consider<br />

<strong>the</strong> impending threat of a hostile bid by Pantry Pride. 3<br />

At <strong>the</strong> meeting, Lazard Freres, Revlon's investment *177<br />

banker, advised <strong>the</strong> directors that $45 per share was a<br />

grossly inadequate price for <strong>the</strong> company. Felix Rohatyn <strong>and</strong><br />

William Loomis of Lazard Freres explained to <strong>the</strong> board<br />

that Pantry Pride's financial strategy for acquiring Revlon<br />

would be through “junk bond” financing followed by a breakup<br />

of Revlon <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> disposition of its assets. With proper<br />

timing, according to <strong>the</strong> experts, such transactions could<br />

produce a return to Pantry Pride of $60 to $70 per share,<br />

while a sale of <strong>the</strong> company as a whole would be in <strong>the</strong><br />

“mid 50” dollar range. Martin Lipton, special counsel for<br />

Revlon, recommended two defensive measures: first, that <strong>the</strong><br />

company repurchase up to 5 million of its nearly 30 million<br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing shares; <strong>and</strong> second, that it adopt a Note Purchase<br />

Rights Plan. Under this plan, each Revlon shareholder would<br />

receive as a dividend one Note Purchase Right (<strong>the</strong> Rights)<br />

for each share of common stock, with <strong>the</strong> Rights entitling <strong>the</strong><br />

holder to exchange one common share for a $65 principal<br />

Revlon note at 12% interest with a one-year maturity. The<br />

Rights would become effective whenever anyone acquired<br />

beneficial ownership of 20% or more of Revlon's shares,<br />

unless <strong>the</strong> purchaser acquired all <strong>the</strong> company's stock for cash<br />

at $65 or more per share. In addition, <strong>the</strong> Rights would not<br />

be available to <strong>the</strong> acquiror, <strong>and</strong> prior to <strong>the</strong> 20% triggering<br />

event <strong>the</strong> Revlon board could redeem <strong>the</strong> rights for 10 cents<br />

each. Both proposals were unanimously adopted.<br />

Pantry Pride made its first hostile move on August 23 with a<br />

cash tender offer for any <strong>and</strong> all shares of Revlon at $47.50<br />

per common share <strong>and</strong> $26.67 per preferred share, subject to<br />

(1) Pantry Pride's obtaining financing for <strong>the</strong> purchase, <strong>and</strong><br />

(2) <strong>the</strong> Rights being redeemed, rescinded or voided.<br />

The Revlon board met again on August 26. The directors<br />

advised <strong>the</strong> stockholders to reject <strong>the</strong> offer. Fur<strong>the</strong>r defensive<br />

measures also were planned. On August 29, Revlon<br />

commenced its own offer for up to 10 million shares,<br />

exchanging for each share of common stock tendered one<br />

Senior Subordinated Note (<strong>the</strong> Notes) of $47.50 principal<br />

at 11.75% interest, due 1995, <strong>and</strong> one-tenth of a share of<br />

$9.00 Cumulative Convertible Exchangeable Preferred Stock<br />

valued at $100 per share. Lazard Freres opined that <strong>the</strong> notes<br />

would trade at <strong>the</strong>ir face value on a fully distributed basis. 4<br />

Revlon stockholders tendered 87 percent of <strong>the</strong> outst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

shares (approximately 33 million), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> company accepted<br />

<strong>the</strong> full 10 million shares on a pro rata basis. The new Notes<br />

contained covenants which limited Revlon's ability to incur<br />

additional debt, sell assets, or pay dividends unless o<strong>the</strong>rwise<br />

approved by <strong>the</strong> “independent” (non-management) members<br />

of <strong>the</strong> board.<br />

At this point, both <strong>the</strong> Rights <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Note covenants stymied<br />

Pantry Pride's attempted takeover. The next move came on<br />

September 16, when Pantry Pride announced a new tender<br />

offer at $42 per share, conditioned upon receiving at least<br />

90% of <strong>the</strong> outst<strong>and</strong>ing stock. Pantry Pride also indicated that<br />

it would consider buying less than 90%, <strong>and</strong> at an increased<br />

price, if Revlon removed <strong>the</strong> impeding Rights. While this<br />

offer was lower on its face than <strong>the</strong> earlier $47.50 proposal,<br />

Revlon's investment banker, Lazard Freres, described <strong>the</strong> two<br />

bids as essentially equal in view of <strong>the</strong> completed exchange<br />

offer.<br />

The Revlon board held a regularly scheduled meeting on<br />

September 24. The directors rejected <strong>the</strong> latest Pantry Pride<br />

offer <strong>and</strong> authorized management to negotiate with o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

parties interested in acquiring Revlon. Pantry Pride remained<br />

determined in its efforts <strong>and</strong> continued to make cash bids for<br />

<strong>the</strong> company, offering $50 per share on September 27, <strong>and</strong><br />

raising its bid to $53 on October 1, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n to $56.25 on<br />

October 7.<br />

*178 In <strong>the</strong> meantime, Revlon's negotiations with<br />

Forstmann <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> investment group Adler & Shaykin had<br />

produced results. The Revlon directors met on October 3<br />

to consider Pantry Pride's $53 bid <strong>and</strong> to examine possible<br />

alternatives to <strong>the</strong> offer. Both Forstmann <strong>and</strong> Adler &<br />

Shaykin made certain proposals to <strong>the</strong> board. As a result,<br />

<strong>the</strong> directors unanimously agreed to a leveraged buyout by<br />

Forstmann. The terms of this accord were as follows: each<br />

stockholder would get $56 cash per share; management would<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 5


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

purchase stock in <strong>the</strong> new company by <strong>the</strong> exercise of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

Revlon “golden parachutes”; 5 Forstmann would assume<br />

Revlon's $475 million debt incurred by <strong>the</strong> issuance of <strong>the</strong><br />

Notes; <strong>and</strong> Revlon would redeem <strong>the</strong> Rights <strong>and</strong> waive <strong>the</strong><br />

Notes covenants for Forstmann or in connection with any<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r offer superior to Forstmann's. The board did not actually<br />

remove <strong>the</strong> covenants at <strong>the</strong> October 3 meeting, because<br />

Forstmann <strong>the</strong>n lacked a firm commitment on its financing,<br />

but accepted <strong>the</strong> Forstmann capital structure, <strong>and</strong> indicated<br />

that <strong>the</strong> outside directors would waive <strong>the</strong> covenants in due<br />

course. Part of Forstmann's plan was to sell Revlon's Norcliff<br />

Thayer <strong>and</strong> Reheis divisions to American Home Products<br />

for $335 million. Before <strong>the</strong> merger, Revlon was to sell its<br />

cosmetics <strong>and</strong> fragrance division to Adler & Shaykin for $905<br />

million. These transactions would facilitate <strong>the</strong> purchase by<br />

Forstmann or any o<strong>the</strong>r acquiror of Revlon.<br />

When <strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>and</strong> thus <strong>the</strong> waiver of <strong>the</strong> Notes covenants,<br />

was announced, <strong>the</strong> market value of <strong>the</strong>se securities began to<br />

fall. The Notes, which originally traded near par, around 100,<br />

dropped to 87.50 by October 8. One director later reported (at<br />

<strong>the</strong> October 12 meeting) a “deluge” of telephone calls from<br />

irate noteholders, <strong>and</strong> on October 10 <strong>the</strong> Wall Street Journal<br />

reported threats of litigation by <strong>the</strong>se creditors.<br />

Pantry Pride countered with a new proposal on October 7,<br />

raising its $53 offer to $56.25, subject to nullification of <strong>the</strong><br />

Rights, a waiver of <strong>the</strong> Notes covenants, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> election of<br />

three Pantry Pride directors to <strong>the</strong> Revlon board. On October<br />

9, representatives of Pantry Pride, Forstmann <strong>and</strong> Revlon<br />

conferred in an attempt to negotiate <strong>the</strong> fate of Revlon, but<br />

could not reach agreement. At this meeting Pantry Pride<br />

announced that it would engage in fractional bidding <strong>and</strong><br />

top any Forstmann offer by a slightly higher one. It is also<br />

significant that Forstmann, to Pantry Pride's exclusion, had<br />

been made privy to certain Revlon financial data. Thus, <strong>the</strong><br />

parties were not negotiating on equal terms.<br />

Again privately armed with Revlon data, Forstmann met on<br />

October 11 with Revlon's special counsel <strong>and</strong> investment<br />

banker. On October 12, Forstmann made a new $57.25 per<br />

share offer, based on several conditions. 6 The principal<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> was a lock-up option to purchase Revlon's Vision<br />

Care <strong>and</strong> National Health Laboratories divisions for $525<br />

million, some $100–$175 million below <strong>the</strong> value ascribed<br />

to <strong>the</strong>m by Lazard Freres, if ano<strong>the</strong>r acquiror got 40% of<br />

Revlon's shares. Revlon also was required to accept a noshop<br />

provision. The Rights <strong>and</strong> Notes covenants had to<br />

be removed as in <strong>the</strong> October 3 agreement. There would<br />

be a $25 million cancellation fee to be placed in escrow,<br />

<strong>and</strong> released to Forstmann if <strong>the</strong> new agreement terminated<br />

or if ano<strong>the</strong>r acquiror got more than 19.9% of Revlon's<br />

stock. Finally, <strong>the</strong>re would be no participation by Revlon<br />

management in <strong>the</strong> merger. In return, Forstmann agreed to<br />

support <strong>the</strong> par value *179 of <strong>the</strong> Notes, which had faltered<br />

in <strong>the</strong> market, by an exchange of new notes. Forstmann also<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>ed immediate acceptance of its offer, or it would be<br />

withdrawn. The board unanimously approved Forstmann's<br />

proposal because: (1) it was for a higher price than <strong>the</strong> Pantry<br />

Pride bid, (2) it protected <strong>the</strong> noteholders, <strong>and</strong> (3) Forstmann's<br />

financing was firmly in place. 7 The board fur<strong>the</strong>r agreed to<br />

redeem <strong>the</strong> rights <strong>and</strong> waive <strong>the</strong> covenants on <strong>the</strong> preferred<br />

stock in response to any offer above $57 cash per share.<br />

The covenants were waived, contingent upon receipt of an<br />

investment banking opinion that <strong>the</strong> Notes would trade near<br />

par value once <strong>the</strong> offer was consummated.<br />

Pantry Pride, which had initially sought injunctive relief from<br />

<strong>the</strong> Rights plan on August 22, filed an amended complaint on<br />

October 14 challenging <strong>the</strong> lock-up, <strong>the</strong> cancellation fee, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> exercise of <strong>the</strong> Rights <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Notes covenants. Pantry<br />

Pride also sought a temporary restraining order to prevent<br />

Revlon from placing any assets in escrow or transferring <strong>the</strong>m<br />

to Forstmann. Moreover, on October 22, Pantry Pride again<br />

raised its bid, with a cash offer of $58 per share conditioned<br />

upon nullification of <strong>the</strong> Rights, waiver of <strong>the</strong> covenants, <strong>and</strong><br />

an injunction of <strong>the</strong> Forstmann lock-up.<br />

On October 15, <strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery prohibited <strong>the</strong><br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r transfer of assets, <strong>and</strong> eight days later enjoined<br />

<strong>the</strong> lock-up, no-shop, <strong>and</strong> cancellation fee provisions of<br />

<strong>the</strong> agreement. The trial court concluded that <strong>the</strong> Revlon<br />

directors had breached <strong>the</strong>ir duty of loyalty by making<br />

concessions to Forstmann, out of concern for <strong>the</strong>ir liability<br />

to <strong>the</strong> noteholders, ra<strong>the</strong>r than maximizing <strong>the</strong> sale price of<br />

<strong>the</strong> company for <strong>the</strong> stockholders' benefit. MacAndrews &<br />

Forbes Holdings, Inc. v. Revlon, Inc., 501 A.2d at 1249–50.<br />

II.<br />

To obtain a preliminary injunction, a plaintiff must<br />

demonstrate both a reasonable probability of success on <strong>the</strong><br />

merits <strong>and</strong> some irreparable harm which will occur absent<br />

<strong>the</strong> injunction. Gimbel v. Signal Companies, Del.Ch., 316<br />

A.2d 599, 602 (1974), aff'd, Del.Supr., 316 A.2d 619 (1974).<br />

Additionally, <strong>the</strong> Court shall balance <strong>the</strong> conveniences of <strong>and</strong><br />

possible injuries to <strong>the</strong> parties. Id.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 6


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

A.<br />

[3] [4] We turn first to Pantry Pride's probability of success<br />

on <strong>the</strong> merits. The ultimate responsibility for managing <strong>the</strong><br />

business <strong>and</strong> affairs of a corporation falls on its board of<br />

directors. 8 Del.C. § 141(a). 8 In discharging this function<br />

<strong>the</strong> directors owe fiduciary duties of care <strong>and</strong> loyalty to<br />

<strong>the</strong> corporation <strong>and</strong> its shareholders. Guth v. Loft, Inc., 23<br />

Del.Supr. 255, 5 A.2d 503, 510 (1939); Aronson v. Lewis,<br />

Del.Supr., 473 A.2d 805, 811 (1984). These principles apply<br />

with equal force when a board approves a corporate merger<br />

pursuant to 8 Del.C. § 251(b); 9 Smith v. Van Gorkom,<br />

Del.Supr., 488 A.2d 858, 873 (1985); <strong>and</strong> of course <strong>the</strong>y are<br />

<strong>the</strong> bedrock of our law regarding corporate takeover issues.<br />

Pogostin v. Rice, Del.Supr., 480 A.2d 619, 624 (1984);<br />

Unocal Corp. v. Mesa *180 Petroleum Co., Del.Supr.,<br />

493 A.2d 946, 953, 955 (1985); Moran v. Household<br />

International, Inc., Del.Supr., 500 A.2d 1346, 1350 (1985).<br />

While <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule may be applicable to <strong>the</strong><br />

actions of corporate directors responding to takeover threats,<br />

<strong>the</strong> principles upon which it is founded—care, loyalty <strong>and</strong><br />

independence—must first be satisfied. 10 Aronson v. Lewis,<br />

473 A.2d at 812.<br />

[5] [6] If <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule applies, <strong>the</strong>re is a<br />

“presumption that in making a business decision <strong>the</strong> directors<br />

of a corporation acted on an informed basis, in good faith<br />

<strong>and</strong> in <strong>the</strong> honest belief that <strong>the</strong> action taken was in <strong>the</strong> best<br />

interests of <strong>the</strong> company.” Aronson v. Lewis, 473 A.2d at 812.<br />

However, when a board implements anti-takeover measures<br />

<strong>the</strong>re arises “<strong>the</strong> omnipresent specter that a board may be<br />

acting primarily in its own interests, ra<strong>the</strong>r than those of <strong>the</strong><br />

corporation <strong>and</strong> its shareholders ...” Unocal Corp. v. Mesa<br />

Petroleum Co., 493 A.2d at 954. This potential for conflict<br />

places upon <strong>the</strong> directors <strong>the</strong> burden of proving that <strong>the</strong>y<br />

had reasonable grounds for believing <strong>the</strong>re was a danger to<br />

corporate policy <strong>and</strong> effectiveness, a burden satisfied by a<br />

showing of good faith <strong>and</strong> reasonable investigation. Id. at<br />

955. In addition, <strong>the</strong> directors must analyze <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong><br />

takeover <strong>and</strong> its effect on <strong>the</strong> corporation in order to ensure<br />

balance—that <strong>the</strong> responsive action taken is reasonable in<br />

relation to <strong>the</strong> threat posed. Id.<br />

B.<br />

[7] The first relevant defensive measure adopted by<br />

<strong>the</strong> Revlon board was <strong>the</strong> Rights Plan, which would be<br />

considered a “poison pill” in <strong>the</strong> current language of corporate<br />

takeovers—a plan by which shareholders receive <strong>the</strong> right to<br />

be bought out by <strong>the</strong> corporation at a substantial premium<br />

on <strong>the</strong> occurrence of a stated triggering event. See generally<br />

Moran v. Household International, Inc., Del.Supr., 500 A.2d<br />

1346 (1985). By 8 Del.C. §§ 141 <strong>and</strong> 122(13), 11 <strong>the</strong> board<br />

clearly had <strong>the</strong> power to adopt <strong>the</strong> measure. See Moran v.<br />

Household International, Inc., 500 A.2d at 1351. Thus, <strong>the</strong><br />

focus becomes one of reasonableness <strong>and</strong> purpose.<br />

[8] The Revlon board approved <strong>the</strong> Rights Plan in <strong>the</strong> face<br />

of an impending hostile takeover bid by Pantry Pride at<br />

$45 per share, a price which Revlon reasonably concluded<br />

was grossly inadequate. Lazard Freres had so advised <strong>the</strong><br />

directors, <strong>and</strong> had also informed <strong>the</strong>m that Pantry Pride<br />

was a small, highly leveraged company bent on a “bustup”<br />

takeover by using “junk bond” financing to buy Revlon<br />

cheaply, sell <strong>the</strong> acquired assets to pay <strong>the</strong> *181 debts<br />

incurred, <strong>and</strong> retain <strong>the</strong> profit for itself. 12 In adopting <strong>the</strong><br />

Plan, <strong>the</strong> board protected <strong>the</strong> shareholders from a hostile<br />

takeover at a price below <strong>the</strong> company's intrinsic value, while<br />

retaining sufficient flexibility to address any proposal deemed<br />

to be in <strong>the</strong> stockholders' best interests.<br />

To that extent <strong>the</strong> board acted in good faith <strong>and</strong> upon<br />

reasonable investigation. Under <strong>the</strong> circumstances it cannot<br />

be said that <strong>the</strong> Rights Plan as employed was unreasonable,<br />

considering <strong>the</strong> threat posed. Indeed, <strong>the</strong> Plan was a factor in<br />

causing Pantry Pride to raise its bids from a low of $42 to an<br />

eventual high of $58. At <strong>the</strong> time of its adoption <strong>the</strong> Rights<br />

Plan afforded a measure of protection consistent with <strong>the</strong><br />

directors' fiduciary duty in facing a takeover threat perceived<br />

as detrimental to corporate interests. Unocal, 493 A.2d at<br />

954–55. Far from being a “show-stopper,” as <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs<br />

had contended in Moran, <strong>the</strong> measure spurred <strong>the</strong> bidding to<br />

new heights, a proper result of its implementation. See Moran,<br />

500 A.2d at 1354, 1356–67.<br />

[9] Although we consider adoption of <strong>the</strong> Plan to have been<br />

valid under <strong>the</strong> circumstances, its continued usefulness was<br />

rendered moot by <strong>the</strong> directors' actions on October 3 <strong>and</strong><br />

October 12. At <strong>the</strong> October 3 meeting <strong>the</strong> board redeemed<br />

<strong>the</strong> Rights conditioned upon consummation of a merger with<br />

Forstmann, but fur<strong>the</strong>r acknowledged that <strong>the</strong>y would also be<br />

redeemed to facilitate any more favorable offer. On October<br />

12, <strong>the</strong> board unanimously passed a resolution redeeming <strong>the</strong><br />

Rights in connection with any cash proposal of $57.25 or<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 7


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

more per share. Because all <strong>the</strong> pertinent offers eventually<br />

equalled or surpassed that amount, <strong>the</strong> Rights clearly were no<br />

longer any impediment in <strong>the</strong> contest for Revlon. This mooted<br />

any question of <strong>the</strong>ir propriety under Moran or Unocal.<br />

C.<br />

[10] The second defensive measure adopted by Revlon<br />

to thwart a Pantry Pride takeover was <strong>the</strong> company's own<br />

exchange offer for 10 million of its shares. The directors'<br />

general broad powers to manage <strong>the</strong> business <strong>and</strong> affairs<br />

of <strong>the</strong> corporation are augmented by <strong>the</strong> specific authority<br />

conferred under 8 Del.C. § 160(a), permitting <strong>the</strong> company to<br />

deal in its own stock. 13 Unocal, 493 A.2d at 953–54; Cheff<br />

v. Ma<strong>the</strong>s, 41 Del.Supr. 494, 199 A.2d 548, 554 (1964); Kors<br />

v. Carey, 39 Del.Ch. 47, 158 A.2d 136, 140 (1960). However,<br />

when exercising that power in an effort to forestall a hostile<br />

takeover, <strong>the</strong> board's actions are strictly held to <strong>the</strong> fiduciary<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards outlined in Unocal. These st<strong>and</strong>ards require <strong>the</strong><br />

directors to determine <strong>the</strong> best interests of <strong>the</strong> corporation <strong>and</strong><br />

its stockholders, <strong>and</strong> impose an enhanced duty to abjure any<br />

action that is motivated by considerations o<strong>the</strong>r than a good<br />

faith concern for such interests. Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954–<br />

55; see Bennett v. Propp, 41 Del.Supr. 14, 187 A.2d 405, 409<br />

(1962).<br />

[11] The Revlon directors concluded that Pantry Pride's<br />

$47.50 offer was grossly inadequate. In that regard <strong>the</strong> board<br />

acted in good faith, <strong>and</strong> on an informed basis, with reasonable<br />

grounds to believe that <strong>the</strong>re existed a harmful threat to <strong>the</strong><br />

corporate enterprise. The adoption of a defensive measure,<br />

reasonable in relation to <strong>the</strong> threat posed, was proper <strong>and</strong><br />

fully accorded with <strong>the</strong> powers, duties, <strong>and</strong> responsibilities<br />

conferred upon directors under our law. Unocal, 493 A.2d at<br />

954; Pogostin v. Rice, 480 A.2d at 627.<br />

*182 D.<br />

[12] However, when Pantry Pride increased its offer to $50<br />

per share, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n to $53, it became apparent to all that<br />

<strong>the</strong> break-up of <strong>the</strong> company was inevitable. The Revlon<br />

board's authorization permitting management to negotiate<br />

a merger or buyout with a third party was a recognition<br />

that <strong>the</strong> company was for sale. The duty of <strong>the</strong> board had<br />

thus changed from <strong>the</strong> preservation of Revlon as a corporate<br />

entity to <strong>the</strong> maximization of <strong>the</strong> company's value at a sale<br />

for <strong>the</strong> stockholders' benefit. This significantly altered <strong>the</strong><br />

board's responsibilities under <strong>the</strong> Unocal st<strong>and</strong>ards. It no<br />

longer faced threats to corporate policy <strong>and</strong> effectiveness,<br />

or to <strong>the</strong> stockholders' interests, from a grossly inadequate<br />

bid. The whole question of defensive measures became moot.<br />

The directors' role changed from defenders of <strong>the</strong> corporate<br />

bastion to auctioneers charged with getting <strong>the</strong> best price for<br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholders at a sale of <strong>the</strong> company.<br />

III.<br />

This brings us to <strong>the</strong> lock-up with Forstmann <strong>and</strong> its emphasis<br />

on shoring up <strong>the</strong> sagging market value of <strong>the</strong> Notes in<br />

<strong>the</strong> face of threatened litigation by <strong>the</strong>ir holders. Such a<br />

focus was inconsistent with <strong>the</strong> changed concept of <strong>the</strong><br />

directors' responsibilities at this stage of <strong>the</strong> developments.<br />

The impending waiver of <strong>the</strong> Notes covenants had caused <strong>the</strong><br />

value of <strong>the</strong> Notes to fall, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> board was aware of <strong>the</strong><br />

noteholders' ire as well as <strong>the</strong>ir subsequent threats of suit. The<br />

directors thus made support of <strong>the</strong> Notes an integral part of<br />

<strong>the</strong> company's dealings with Forstmann, even though <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

primary responsibility at this stage was to <strong>the</strong> equity owners.<br />

[13] The original threat posed by Pantry Pride—<strong>the</strong> breakup<br />

of <strong>the</strong> company—had become a reality which even <strong>the</strong><br />

directors embraced. Selective dealing to fend off a hostile but<br />

determined bidder was no longer a proper objective. Instead,<br />

obtaining <strong>the</strong> highest price for <strong>the</strong> benefit of <strong>the</strong> stockholders<br />

should have been <strong>the</strong> central <strong>the</strong>me guiding director action.<br />

Thus, <strong>the</strong> Revlon board could not make <strong>the</strong> requisite showing<br />

of good faith by preferring <strong>the</strong> noteholders <strong>and</strong> ignoring its<br />

duty of loyalty to <strong>the</strong> shareholders. The rights of <strong>the</strong> former<br />

already were fixed by contract. Wolfensohn v. Madison Fund,<br />

Inc., Del.Supr., 253 A.2d 72, 75 (1969); Harff v. Kerkorian,<br />

Del.Ch., 324 A.2d 215 (1974). The noteholders required no<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r protection, <strong>and</strong> when <strong>the</strong> Revlon board entered into<br />

an auction-ending lock-up agreement with Forstmann on <strong>the</strong><br />

basis of impermissible considerations at <strong>the</strong> expense of <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders, <strong>the</strong> directors breached <strong>the</strong>ir primary duty of<br />

loyalty.<br />

[14] The Revlon board argued that it acted in good<br />

faith in protecting <strong>the</strong> noteholders because Unocal<br />

permits consideration of o<strong>the</strong>r corporate constituencies.<br />

Although such considerations may be permissible, <strong>the</strong>re<br />

are fundamental limitations upon that prerogative. A board<br />

may have regard for various constituencies in discharging<br />

its responsibilities, provided <strong>the</strong>re are rationally related<br />

benefits accruing to <strong>the</strong> stockholders. Unocal, 493 A.2d at<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 8


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

955. However, such concern for non-stockholder interests is<br />

inappropriate when an auction among active bidders is in<br />

progress, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> object no longer is to protect or maintain <strong>the</strong><br />

corporate enterprise but to sell it to <strong>the</strong> highest bidder.<br />

Revlon also contended that by Gilbert v. El Paso Co., Del.<br />

Ch., 490 A.2d 1050, 1054–55 (1984), it had contractual <strong>and</strong><br />

good faith obligations to consider <strong>the</strong> noteholders. However,<br />

any such duties are limited to <strong>the</strong> principle that one may not<br />

interfere with contractual relationships by improper actions.<br />

Here, <strong>the</strong> rights of <strong>the</strong> noteholders were fixed by agreement,<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re is nothing of substance to suggest that any of<br />

those terms were violated. The Notes covenants specifically<br />

contemplated a waiver to permit sale of <strong>the</strong> company at a<br />

fair price. The Notes were accepted by <strong>the</strong> holders on that<br />

basis, including <strong>the</strong> risk of an adverse market effect stemming<br />

from a waiver. Thus, nothing remained for Revlon *183 to<br />

legitimately protect, <strong>and</strong> no rationally related benefit <strong>the</strong>reby<br />

accrued to <strong>the</strong> stockholders. Under such circumstances we<br />

must conclude that <strong>the</strong> merger agreement with Forstmann was<br />

unreasonable in relation to <strong>the</strong> threat posed.<br />

A lock-up is not per se illegal under Delaware law. Its<br />

use has been approved in an earlier case. Thompson v.<br />

Enstar Corp., Del. Ch., –––A.2d ––– (1984). Such options<br />

can entice o<strong>the</strong>r bidders to enter a contest for control of<br />

<strong>the</strong> corporation, creating an auction for <strong>the</strong> company <strong>and</strong><br />

maximizing shareholder profit. Current economic conditions<br />

in <strong>the</strong> takeover market are such that a “white knight”<br />

like Forstmann might only enter <strong>the</strong> bidding for <strong>the</strong> target<br />

company if it receives some form of compensation to cover<br />

<strong>the</strong> risks <strong>and</strong> costs involved. Note, Corporations-Mergers<br />

—“Lock-up” Enjoined Under Section 14(e) of Securities<br />

Exchange Act—Mobil Corp. v. Marathon Oil Co., 669 F.2d<br />

366 (6th Cir.1981), 12 Seton Hall L.Rev. 881, 892 (1982).<br />

However, while those lock-ups which draw bidders into <strong>the</strong><br />

battle benefit shareholders, similar measures which end an<br />

active auction <strong>and</strong> foreclose fur<strong>the</strong>r bidding operate to <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders' detriment. Note, Lock-up Options: Toward a<br />

State Law St<strong>and</strong>ard, 96 Harv. L. Rev. 1068, 1081 (1983). 14<br />

Recently, <strong>the</strong> United States Court of Appeals for <strong>the</strong> Second<br />

Circuit invalidated a lock-up on fiduciary duty grounds<br />

similar to those here. 15 Hanson Trust PLC, et al. v. ML SCM<br />

Acquisition Inc., et al., 781 F.2d 264 (2nd Cir.1986). Citing<br />

Thompson v. Enstar Corp., supra, with approval, <strong>the</strong> court<br />

stated:<br />

In this regard, we are especially mindful that some lock-up<br />

options may be beneficial to <strong>the</strong> shareholders, such as those<br />

that induce a bidder to compete for control of a corporation,<br />

while o<strong>the</strong>rs may be harmful, such as those that effectively<br />

preclude bidders from competing with <strong>the</strong> optionee bidder.<br />

781 F.2d at 274.<br />

In Hanson Trust, <strong>the</strong> bidder, Hanson, sought control of<br />

SCM by a hostile cash tender offer. SCM management<br />

joined with Merrill Lynch to propose a leveraged buyout<br />

of <strong>the</strong> company at a higher price, <strong>and</strong> Hanson in turn<br />

increased its offer. Then, despite very little improvement in<br />

its subsequent bid, <strong>the</strong> management group sought a lock-up<br />

option to purchase SCM's two main assets at a substantial<br />

discount. The SCM directors granted <strong>the</strong> lock-up without<br />

adequate information as to <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> discount or <strong>the</strong><br />

effect <strong>the</strong> transaction would have on <strong>the</strong> company. Their<br />

action effectively ended a competitive bidding situation. The<br />

Hanson Court invalidated <strong>the</strong> lock-up because <strong>the</strong> directors<br />

failed to fully inform <strong>the</strong>mselves about <strong>the</strong> value of a<br />

transaction in which management had a strong self-interest.<br />

“In short, <strong>the</strong> Board appears to have failed to ensure that<br />

negotiations for alternative bids were conducted by those<br />

whose only loyalty was to <strong>the</strong> shareholders.” Id. at 277.<br />

The Forstmann option had a similar destructive effect on<br />

<strong>the</strong> auction process. Forstmann had already been drawn into<br />

<strong>the</strong> contest on a preferred basis, so <strong>the</strong> result of <strong>the</strong> lockup<br />

was not to foster bidding, but to destroy it. The board's<br />

stated reasons for approving <strong>the</strong> transactions were: (1) better<br />

financing, (2) noteholder *184 protection, <strong>and</strong> (3) higher<br />

price. As <strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery found, <strong>and</strong> we agree, any<br />

distinctions between <strong>the</strong> rival bidders' methods of financing<br />

<strong>the</strong> proposal were nominal at best, <strong>and</strong> such a consideration<br />

has little or no significance in a cash offer for any <strong>and</strong> all<br />

shares. The principal object, contrary to <strong>the</strong> board's duty of<br />

care, appears to have been protection of <strong>the</strong> noteholders over<br />

<strong>the</strong> shareholders' interests.<br />

[15] While Forstmann's $57.25 offer was objectively higher<br />

than Pantry Pride's $56.25 bid, <strong>the</strong> margin of superiority is<br />

less when <strong>the</strong> Forstmann price is adjusted for <strong>the</strong> time value<br />

of money. In reality, <strong>the</strong> Revlon board ended <strong>the</strong> auction<br />

in return for very little actual improvement in <strong>the</strong> final bid.<br />

The principal benefit went to <strong>the</strong> directors, who avoided<br />

personal liability to a class of creditors to whom <strong>the</strong> board<br />

owed no fur<strong>the</strong>r duty under <strong>the</strong> circumstances. Thus, when<br />

a board ends an intense bidding contest on an insubstantial<br />

basis, <strong>and</strong> where a significant by-product of that action is to<br />

protect <strong>the</strong> directors against a perceived threat of personal<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 9


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

liability for consequences stemming from <strong>the</strong> adoption of<br />

previous defensive measures, <strong>the</strong> action cannot withst<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

enhanced scrutiny which Unocal requires of director conduct.<br />

See Unocal, 493 A.2d at 954–55.<br />

[16] [17] In addition to <strong>the</strong> lock-up option, <strong>the</strong> Court<br />

of Chancery enjoined <strong>the</strong> no-shop provision as part of<br />

<strong>the</strong> attempt to foreclose fur<strong>the</strong>r bidding by Pantry Pride.<br />

MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc. v. Revlon, Inc., 501<br />

A.2d at 1251. The no-shop provision, like <strong>the</strong> lock-up option,<br />

while not per se illegal, is impermissible under <strong>the</strong> Unocal<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ards when a board's primary duty becomes that of an<br />

auctioneer responsible for selling <strong>the</strong> company to <strong>the</strong> highest<br />

bidder. The agreement to negotiate only with Forstmann<br />

ended ra<strong>the</strong>r than intensified <strong>the</strong> board's involvement in <strong>the</strong><br />

bidding contest.<br />

[18] [19] It is ironic that <strong>the</strong> parties even considered a noshop<br />

agreement when Revlon had dealt preferentially, <strong>and</strong><br />

almost exclusively, with Forstmann throughout <strong>the</strong> contest.<br />

After <strong>the</strong> directors authorized management to negotiate<br />

with o<strong>the</strong>r parties, Forstmann was given every negotiating<br />

advantage that Pantry Pride had been denied: cooperation<br />

from management, access to financial data, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> exclusive<br />

opportunity to present merger proposals directly to <strong>the</strong> board<br />

of directors. Favoritism for a white knight to <strong>the</strong> total<br />

exclusion of a hostile bidder might be justifiable when<br />

<strong>the</strong> latter's offer adversely affects shareholder interests, but<br />

when bidders make relatively similar offers, or dissolution<br />

of <strong>the</strong> company becomes inevitable, <strong>the</strong> directors cannot<br />

fulfill <strong>the</strong>ir enhanced Unocal duties by playing favorites with<br />

<strong>the</strong> contending factions. Market forces must be allowed to<br />

operate freely to bring <strong>the</strong> target's shareholders <strong>the</strong> best price<br />

available for <strong>the</strong>ir equity. 16 Thus, as <strong>the</strong> trial court ruled, <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders' interests necessitated that <strong>the</strong> board remain free<br />

to negotiate in <strong>the</strong> fulfillment of that duty.<br />

[20] The court below similarly enjoined <strong>the</strong> payment of <strong>the</strong><br />

cancellation fee, pending a resolution of <strong>the</strong> merits, because<br />

<strong>the</strong> fee was part of <strong>the</strong> overall plan to thwart Pantry Pride's<br />

efforts. We find no abuse of discretion in that ruling.<br />

[21] Having concluded that Pantry Pride has shown a<br />

reasonable probability of success on <strong>the</strong> merits, we address<br />

<strong>the</strong> issue of irreparable harm. The Court of Chancery ruled<br />

that unless <strong>the</strong> lock-up <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r aspects of <strong>the</strong> agreement<br />

were enjoined, Pantry Pride's opportunity to bid for Revlon<br />

was lost. The court also held that <strong>the</strong> need for both bidders to<br />

compete *185 in <strong>the</strong> marketplace outweighed any injury to<br />

Forstmann. Given <strong>the</strong> complexity of <strong>the</strong> proposed transaction<br />

between Revlon <strong>and</strong> Forstmann, <strong>the</strong> obstacles to Pantry Pride<br />

obtaining a meaningful legal remedy are immense. We are<br />

satisfied that <strong>the</strong> plaintiff has shown <strong>the</strong> need for an injunction<br />

to protect it from irreparable harm, which need outweighs any<br />

harm to <strong>the</strong> defendants.<br />

V.<br />

In conclusion, <strong>the</strong> Revlon board was confronted with a<br />

situation not uncommon in <strong>the</strong> current wave of corporate<br />

takeovers. A hostile <strong>and</strong> determined bidder sought <strong>the</strong><br />

company at a price <strong>the</strong> board was convinced was inadequate.<br />

The initial defensive tactics worked to <strong>the</strong> benefit of <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders, <strong>and</strong> thus <strong>the</strong> board was able to sustain its Unocal<br />

burdens in justifying those measures. However, in granting<br />

an asset option lock-up to Forstmann, we must conclude<br />

that under all <strong>the</strong> circumstances <strong>the</strong> directors allowed<br />

considerations o<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> maximization of shareholder<br />

profit to affect <strong>the</strong>ir judgment, <strong>and</strong> followed a course that<br />

ended <strong>the</strong> auction for Revlon, absent court intervention, to<br />

<strong>the</strong> ultimate detriment of its shareholders. No such defensive<br />

measure can be sustained when it represents a breach of <strong>the</strong><br />

directors' fundamental duty of care. See Smith v. Van Gorkom,<br />

Del.Supr., 488 A.2d 858, 874 (1985). In that context <strong>the</strong><br />

board's action is not entitled to <strong>the</strong> deference accorded it<br />

by <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule. The measures were properly<br />

enjoined. The decision of <strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery, <strong>the</strong>refore, is<br />

AFFIRMED.<br />

Parallel Citations<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

IV.<br />

Footnotes<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 10


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

1 The nominal plaintiff, MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., is <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder of Pantry Pride. For all practical purposes<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir interests in this litigation are virtually identical, <strong>and</strong> we hereafter will refer to Pantry Pride as <strong>the</strong> plaintiff.<br />

2 This appeal was heard on an expedited basis in light of <strong>the</strong> pending Pantry Pride offer <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Revlon-Forstmann transactions. We<br />

accepted <strong>the</strong> appeal on Friday, October 25, 1985, received <strong>the</strong> parties' opening briefs on October 28, <strong>the</strong>ir reply briefs on October 29,<br />

<strong>and</strong> heard argument on Thursday, October 31. We announced our decision to affirm in an oral ruling in open court at 9:00 a.m. on<br />

Friday, November 1, with <strong>the</strong> proviso that this more detailed written opinion would follow in due course.<br />

3 There were 14 directors on <strong>the</strong> Revlon board. Six of <strong>the</strong>m held senior management positions with <strong>the</strong> company, <strong>and</strong> two o<strong>the</strong>rs<br />

held significant blocks of its stock. Four of <strong>the</strong> remaining six directors were associated at some point with entities that had various<br />

business relationships with Revlon. On <strong>the</strong> basis of this limited record, however, we cannot conclude that this board is entitled to<br />

certain presumptions that generally attach to <strong>the</strong> decisions of a board whose majority consists of truly outside independent directors.<br />

See Polk v. Good & Texaco, Del.Supr., ––– A.2d ––––, –––– (1986); Moran v. Household International, Inc., Del.Supr., 500 A.2d<br />

1346, 1356 (1985); Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., Del.Supr., 493 A.2d 946, 955 (1985); Aronson v. Lewis, Del.Supr., 473<br />

A.2d 805, 812, 815 (1984); Puma v. Marriott, Del. Ch., 283 A.2d 693, 695 (1971).<br />

4 Like bonds, <strong>the</strong> Notes actually were issued in denominations of $1,000 <strong>and</strong> integral multiples <strong>the</strong>reof. A separate certificate was<br />

issued in a total principal amount equal to <strong>the</strong> remaining sum to which a stockholder was entitled. Likewise, in <strong>the</strong> esoteric parlance<br />

of bond dealers, a Note trading at par ($1,000) would be quoted on <strong>the</strong> market at 100.<br />

5 In <strong>the</strong> takeover context “golden parachutes” generally are understood to be termination agreements providing substantial bonuses<br />

<strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r benefits for managers <strong>and</strong> certain directors upon a change in control of a company.<br />

6 Forstmann's $57.25 offer ostensibly is worth $1 more than Pantry Pride's $56.25 bid. However, <strong>the</strong> Pantry Pride offer was immediate,<br />

while <strong>the</strong> Forstmann proposal must be discounted for <strong>the</strong> time value of money because of <strong>the</strong> delay in approving <strong>the</strong> merger <strong>and</strong><br />

consummating <strong>the</strong> transaction. The exact difference between <strong>the</strong> two bids was an unsettled point of contention even at oral argument.<br />

7 Actually, at this time about $400 million of Forstmann's funding was still subject to two investment banks using <strong>the</strong>ir “best efforts”<br />

to organize a syndicate to provide <strong>the</strong> balance. Pantry Pride's entire financing was not firmly committed at this point ei<strong>the</strong>r, although<br />

Pantry Pride represented in an October 11 letter to Lazard Freres that its investment banker, Drexel Burnham Lambert, was highly<br />

confident of its ability to raise <strong>the</strong> balance of $350 million. Drexel Burnham had a firm commitment for this sum by October 18.<br />

8 The pertinent provision of <strong>the</strong> statute is:<br />

(a) The business <strong>and</strong> affairs of every corporation organized under this chapter shall be managed by or under <strong>the</strong> direction of a<br />

board of directors, except as may be o<strong>the</strong>rwise provided in this chapter or in its certificate of incorporation. 8 Del.C. § 141(a).<br />

9 The statute provides in pertinent part:<br />

(b) The board of directors of each corporation which desires to merge or consolidate shall adopt a resolution approving an<br />

agreement of merger or consolidation. 8 Del.C. § 251(b).<br />

10 One eminent corporate commentator has drawn a distinction between <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule, which insulates directors <strong>and</strong><br />

management from personal liability for <strong>the</strong>ir business decisions, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> business judgment doctrine, which protects <strong>the</strong> decision itself<br />

from attack. The principles upon which <strong>the</strong> rule <strong>and</strong> doctrine operate are identical, while <strong>the</strong> objects of <strong>the</strong>ir protection are different.<br />

See Hinsey, Business Judgment <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> American Law Institute's Corporate Governance Project: The Rule, <strong>the</strong> Doctrine <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Reality, 52 Geo. Wash. L.Rev. 609, 611–13 (1984). In <strong>the</strong> transactional justification cases, where <strong>the</strong> doctrine is said to apply, our<br />

decisions have not observed <strong>the</strong> distinction in such terminology. See Polk v. Good & Texaco, Del.Supr., ––– A.2d ––––, –––– (1986);<br />

Moran v. Household International, Inc., Del.Supr., 500 A.2d 1346, 1356 (1985); Unocal Corp. v. Mesa Petroleum Co., Del.Supr.,<br />

493 A.2d 946, 953–55 (1985); Rosenblatt v. Getty Oil Co., Del.Supr., 493 A.2d 929, 943 (1985). Under <strong>the</strong> circumstances we do not<br />

alter our earlier practice of referring only to <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule, although in transactional justification matters such reference<br />

may be understood to embrace <strong>the</strong> concept of <strong>the</strong> doctrine.<br />

11 The relevant provision of Section 122 is:<br />

Every corporation created under this chapter shall have power to:<br />

(13) Make contracts, including contracts of guaranty <strong>and</strong> suretyship, incur liabilities, borrow money at such rates of interest<br />

as <strong>the</strong> corporation may determine, issue its notes, bonds <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r obligations, <strong>and</strong> secure any of its obligations by mortgage,<br />

pledge or o<strong>the</strong>r encumbrance of all or any of its property, franchises <strong>and</strong> income, ...”. 8 Del.C. § 122(13).<br />

See Section 141(a) in n. 8, supra. See also Section 160(a), n. 13, infra.<br />

12 As we noted in Moran, a “bust-up” takeover generally refers to a situation in which one seeks to finance an acquisition by selling off<br />

pieces of <strong>the</strong> acquired company, presumably at a substantial profit. See Moran, 500 A.2d at 1349, n. 4.<br />

13 The pertinent provision of this statute is:<br />

(a) Every corporation may purchase, redeem, receive, take or o<strong>the</strong>rwise acquire, own <strong>and</strong> hold, sell, lend, exchange, transfer or<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise dispose of, pledge, use <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rwise deal in <strong>and</strong> with its own shares. 8 Del.C. § 160(a).<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 11


Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173 (1986)<br />

66 A.L.R.4th 157, 54 USLW 2483, Fed. Sec. L. Rep. P 92,525<br />

14 For fur<strong>the</strong>r discussion of <strong>the</strong> benefits <strong>and</strong> detriments of lock-up options, also see: Nelson, Mobil Corp. v. Marathon Oil Co.—The<br />

Decision <strong>and</strong> Its Implications for Future Tender Offers, 7 Corp. L.Rev. 233, 265–68 (1984); Note, Swallowing <strong>the</strong> Key to Lock-up<br />

Options: Mobil Corp. v. Marathon Oil Co., 14 U.Tol.L.Rev. 1055, 1081–83 (1983).<br />

15 The federal courts generally have declined to enjoin lock-up options despite arguments that lock-ups constitute impermissible<br />

“manipulative” conduct forbidden by Section 14(e) of <strong>the</strong> Williams Act [15 U.S.C. § 78n(e) ]. See Buffalo Forge Co. v. Ogden Corp.,<br />

717 F.2d 757 (2nd Cir.1983), cert. denied, 464 U.S. 1018, 104 S.Ct. 550, 78 L.Ed.2d 724 (1983); Data Probe Acquisition Corp. v.<br />

Datatab, Inc., 722 F.2d 1 (2nd Cir.1983); cert. denied 465 U.S. 1052, 104 S.Ct. 1326, 79 L.Ed.2d 722 (1984); but see Mobil Corp.<br />

v. Marathon Oil Co., 669 F.2d 366 (6th Cir.1981). The cases are all federal in nature <strong>and</strong> were not decided on state law grounds.<br />

16 By this we do not embrace <strong>the</strong> “passivity” <strong>the</strong>sis rejected in Unocal. See 493 A.2d at 954–55, nn. 8–10. The directors' role remains<br />

an active one, changed only in <strong>the</strong> respect that <strong>the</strong>y are charged with <strong>the</strong> duty of selling <strong>the</strong> company at <strong>the</strong> highest price attainable<br />

for <strong>the</strong> stockholders' benefit.<br />

End of Document<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 12


Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

2012 WL 729232<br />

Only <strong>the</strong> Westlaw citation is currently available.<br />

UNPUBLISHED OPINION. CHECK<br />

COURT RULES BEFORE CITING.<br />

Court of Chancery of Delaware.<br />

In re DELPHI FINANCIAL GROUP<br />

SHAREHOLDER LITIGATION.<br />

C.A. No. 7144–VCG. | Submitted:<br />

March 2, 2012. | Decided: March 6, 2012.<br />

Attorneys <strong>and</strong> Law Firms<br />

Stuart M. Grant <strong>and</strong> Cynthia A. Calder, of Grant & Eisenhofer<br />

P.A., Wilmington, Delaware; Michael Hanrahan, Bruce E.<br />

Jameson, Paul A. Fioravanti, Jr., <strong>and</strong> Laina M. Herbert, of<br />

Prickett, Jones & Elliot, P.A., Wilmington, Delaware; of<br />

Counsel: Mark Lebovitch <strong>and</strong> Jeremy Friedman, of Bernstein<br />

Litowitz Berger & Grossman LLP, New York, New York;<br />

Samuel H. Rudman, Joseph Russello, Mark S. Reich, <strong>and</strong><br />

Christopher M. Barrett, of Robbins Geller Rudman & Dowd<br />

LLP, Melville, New York; R<strong>and</strong>all J. Baron, of Robbins<br />

Geller Rudman & Dowd LLP, San Diego, California; Marc<br />

A. Topaz, Lee D. Rudy, Michael C. Wagner, <strong>and</strong> J. Daniel<br />

Albert, of Kessler Topaz Meltzer & Check, LLP, Radnor,<br />

Pennsylvania, Attorneys for Plaintiffs.<br />

William M. Lafferty, Kevin M. Coen, <strong>and</strong> Bradley D. Sorrels,<br />

of Morris, Nichols, Arsht & Tunnell LLP, Wilmington,<br />

Delaware, Attorneys for Defendants Delphi Financial Group,<br />

Inc., Kevin R. Brine, Edward A. Fox, Steven A. Hirsh, James<br />

M. Litvack, James N. Meehan, Philip R. O'Connor, <strong>and</strong><br />

Robert F. Wright.<br />

Gary Bornstein <strong>and</strong> Kevin J. Orsini, of Cravath, Swaine &<br />

Moore LLP, New York, New York, Attorneys for Edward A.<br />

Fox, Steven A. Hirsh, James M. Litvack, James N. Meehan,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Philip R. O'Connor.<br />

Raymond J. DiCamillo <strong>and</strong> Kevin M. Gallagher, of Richards,<br />

Layton & Finger, P.A., Wilmington, Delaware; of Counsel:<br />

Brian T. Frawley, of Sullivan & Cromwell LLP, New York,<br />

New York, Attorneys for Defendants Tokio Marine Holdings<br />

Inc. <strong>and</strong> TM Investment (Delaware) Inc.<br />

Donald J. Wolfe, Jr., Mat<strong>the</strong>w E. Fischer, Breton W. Ashman,<br />

Jr., <strong>and</strong> Mat<strong>the</strong>w F. Davis, of Potter Anderson & Corroon<br />

LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; of counsel: Christopher P.<br />

Moore <strong>and</strong> Sara A. Sanchez, of Cleary Gottlieb Steen<br />

& Hamilton LLP, New York, New York, Attorneys for<br />

Defendant Robert Rosenkranz.<br />

Collins J. Seitz, Jr., Bradley M. Aronstam, <strong>and</strong> S. Michael<br />

Sirkin, of Seitz Ross Aronstam & Moritz LLP, Wilmington,<br />

Delaware, Attorneys for Defendants Donald A. Sherman,<br />

Stephan A. Kiratsous, <strong>and</strong> Harold F. Ilg.<br />

Andre G. Bouchard, of Bouchard Margules & Friedl<strong>and</strong>er,<br />

P.A., Wilmington, Delaware, Attorney for Defendant Chad<br />

W. Coulter.<br />

Opinion<br />

MEMORANDUM OPINION<br />

GLASSCOCK, Vice Chancellor.<br />

*1 This matter involves <strong>the</strong> proposed takeover of Delphi<br />

Financial Group, Inc. (“Delphi” or <strong>the</strong> “<strong>Company</strong>”), by Tokio<br />

Marine Holdings, Inc. (“TMH”). Delphi is an insurance<br />

holding company founded by Defendant Robert Rosenkranz.<br />

Rosenkranz took Delphi public in 1990. In so doing, he<br />

created two classes of stock, Class A, largely held by <strong>the</strong><br />

public, <strong>and</strong> Class B, retained by Rosenkranz. Although<br />

Rosenkranz retained less than 13% of <strong>the</strong> shares outst<strong>and</strong>ing,<br />

each share of Class B stock represented <strong>the</strong> right to ten votes<br />

in stockholder matters, while each share of Class A stock<br />

entitled <strong>the</strong> holder to one vote. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, Rosenkranz<br />

retained control of Delphi. Among <strong>the</strong> rights associated with<br />

control is <strong>the</strong> ability to seek a control premium should Delphi<br />

be sold. Rosenkranz could retain or bargain away that right;<br />

he chose to sell it to <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders. This was<br />

accomplished by a charter provision, which directed that,<br />

on sale of <strong>the</strong> company, each share of Class B stock would<br />

be converted to Class A, entitled to <strong>the</strong> same consideration<br />

as any o<strong>the</strong>r Class A stock. This concession to <strong>the</strong> Class A<br />

stockholders resulted, presumably, in a higher purchase price<br />

for Class A stock than would have been <strong>the</strong> case without <strong>the</strong><br />

provision.<br />

In 2011, TMH, through an intermediary, contacted<br />

Rosenkranz about <strong>the</strong> possible purchase of Delphi. While<br />

negotiating with TMH on behalf of Delphi, Rosenkranz<br />

at <strong>the</strong> same time made it clear to Delphi's board that,<br />

notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>the</strong> charter provision, he would not consent<br />

to <strong>the</strong> sale without a premium paid for his Class B stock.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> Delphi board was reluctant to recommend a<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 1


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

differential for <strong>the</strong> Class B stock, it also recognized that <strong>the</strong><br />

premium TMH was willing to pay over market was very<br />

large, <strong>and</strong> would probably be attractive to <strong>the</strong> stockholders.<br />

It <strong>the</strong>refore set up a committee of independent directors to<br />

negotiate a differential for <strong>the</strong> Class B stock. The committee<br />

was ultimately able to negotiate <strong>the</strong> per share price dem<strong>and</strong>ed<br />

by Rosenkranz from $59 down to $53.875. 1<br />

Meanwhile, Rosenkranz continued to negotiate with TMH on<br />

behalf of Delphi. TMH ultimately agreed to pay $46 per share<br />

for Delphi. TMH was <strong>the</strong>n informed that <strong>the</strong> deal would be<br />

structured to provide a differential: $44.875 per share for <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A shares; $53.875 per share for <strong>the</strong> Class B shares.<br />

The deal was conditioned on a majority of <strong>the</strong> publicly held<br />

Class A shares being voted in favor, <strong>and</strong> a successful vote to<br />

amend <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter to allow Rosenkranz to receive <strong>the</strong><br />

differential.<br />

Before creating Delphi, Rosenkranz had established an<br />

investment advising firm, Acorn Advisory Capital L.P.<br />

(“Acorn”), which provided investment services to third<br />

parties. After Rosenkranz founded Delphi, Delphi established<br />

a contractual relationship with Acorn under which Acorn<br />

would use Delphi employees <strong>and</strong> resources to provide<br />

services both to third parties <strong>and</strong> to Delphi. Acorn would <strong>the</strong>n<br />

reimburse Delphi for <strong>the</strong> use of its employees, office facilities,<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> like. Acorn provided investment advisory services<br />

to Delphi pursuant to contractual agreements (<strong>the</strong> “RAM<br />

Contracts”), under which Acorn would bill Delphi through<br />

ano<strong>the</strong>r Rosenkranz entity, Rosenkranz Asset Management,<br />

LLC (“RAM”). The RAM Contracts are terminable upon<br />

thirty days' notice from ei<strong>the</strong>r party. The revenue from <strong>the</strong><br />

sale of Acorn's services to third parties <strong>and</strong> to Delphi went to<br />

Rosenkranz.<br />

*2 During <strong>the</strong> negotiation of <strong>the</strong> Delphi/TMH deal,<br />

Rosenkranz discussed with TMH <strong>the</strong> retention of <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts by TMH for a period of years, or, alternatively,<br />

<strong>the</strong> purchase of RAM by TMH. While Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> TMH<br />

deny that any agreement was reached, Rosenkranz testified<br />

that he expects <strong>the</strong> parties to complete such an agreement<br />

shortly after <strong>the</strong> Delphi/TMH deal closes.<br />

The Plaintiff stockholders argue that Rosenkranz is not<br />

entitled to <strong>the</strong> stock price differential, that <strong>the</strong> Delphi Board<br />

breached its duty to <strong>the</strong> stockholders in structuring <strong>the</strong> deal<br />

to include such a differential at <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders'<br />

expense, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> fiduciary breaches of Rosenkranz<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board were aided wrongfully by TMH. They also<br />

argue that <strong>the</strong> RAM Contract was nothing but a device for<br />

Rosenkranz to skim money from Delphi for work Delphi<br />

could have provided for itself at lower cost, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong><br />

Acorn services sold to third parties represented an opportunity<br />

of Delphi's usurped by Rosenkranz. They argue that <strong>the</strong><br />

agreement discussed between TMH <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz to<br />

retain <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts for a term of years, or to buy<br />

RAM outright, really involved disguised consideration for<br />

Rosenkranz's assent to <strong>the</strong> Delphi/TMH deal, which <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

constituted additional consideration that should belong to <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders. The Plaintiffs seek to enjoin <strong>the</strong> stockholders'<br />

vote on <strong>the</strong> Delphi/TMH merger.<br />

Based upon <strong>the</strong> record developed through expedited<br />

discovery <strong>and</strong> presented at <strong>the</strong> preliminary injunction hearing,<br />

I find that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs have demonstrated a likelihood of<br />

success on <strong>the</strong> merits at least with respect to <strong>the</strong> allegations<br />

against Rosenkranz. However, because <strong>the</strong> deal represents<br />

a large premium over market price, because damages are<br />

available as a remedy, <strong>and</strong> because no o<strong>the</strong>r potential<br />

purchaser has come forth or seems likely to come forth to<br />

match, let alone best, <strong>the</strong> TMH offer, I cannot find that<br />

<strong>the</strong> balance of <strong>the</strong> equities favors an injunction over letting<br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholders exercise <strong>the</strong>ir franchise, <strong>and</strong> allowing <strong>the</strong><br />

Plaintiffs to pursue damages. Therefore, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' request<br />

for a preliminary injunction is denied.<br />

I. BACKGROUND 2<br />

A. Parties<br />

Delphi is a financial services holding company incorporated<br />

in Delaware. Delphi's subsidiaries are insurance <strong>and</strong><br />

insurance-related businesses that provide small- to midsized<br />

businesses with employee benefit services, including<br />

group coverage for long term <strong>and</strong> short term disability, life,<br />

travel accident, dental, <strong>and</strong> health insurance, <strong>and</strong> workers'<br />

compensation. Delphi was founded in 1987 by Defendant<br />

Robert Rosenkranz, who is Delphi's current CEO <strong>and</strong><br />

Chairman.<br />

Delphi's board comprises nine directors, all of whom<br />

are Defendants in this action. Seven of <strong>the</strong> directors are<br />

independent <strong>and</strong> do not hold officer positions within Delphi. 3<br />

They are Kevin R. Brine, Edward A. Fox, Steven A. Hirsh,<br />

James M. Litvack, James N. Meehan, Philip R. O'Connor,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Robert F. Wright. The Complaint also names Harold<br />

F. Ilg, a former director whose retirement was announced<br />

in January 2012, as a Defendant (toge<strong>the</strong>r with Brine, Fox,<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 2


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

Hirsh, Litvack, Meehan, O'Connor, <strong>and</strong> Wright, <strong>the</strong> “Director<br />

Defendants”). 4<br />

*3 Delphi's board also includes two directors who hold<br />

officer positions in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>: Rosenkranz, who is<br />

Chairman of <strong>the</strong> Board <strong>and</strong> CEO, <strong>and</strong> Donald A. Sherman,<br />

who has served as President <strong>and</strong> COO of Delphi since 2006<br />

<strong>and</strong> as a director since 2002. Sherman also serves as a<br />

director of Delphi's principal subsidiaries <strong>and</strong> as President<br />

<strong>and</strong> COO of Delphi Capital Management, Inc. (“DCM”), a<br />

wholly owned subsidiary of Delphi through which Delphi<br />

conducts its New York activities <strong>and</strong> which is involved in an<br />

expense allocation agreement, discussed below, with certain<br />

Rosenkranz-affiliated entities.<br />

The Complaint also names several of Delphi's non-director<br />

officers: Defendant Stephan A. Kiratsous, Executive Vice<br />

President <strong>and</strong> CFO of Delphi since June 2011, <strong>and</strong> Chad<br />

W. Coulter, General Counsel of Delphi since January 1998,<br />

Secretary since May 2003, <strong>and</strong> Senior Vice President since<br />

February 2007 (toge<strong>the</strong>r with Rosenkranz, Sherman, <strong>and</strong><br />

Kiratsous, <strong>the</strong> “Executive Defendants”). 5<br />

Defendant TMH is a Japanese holding company whose<br />

subsidiaries offer products <strong>and</strong> services in <strong>the</strong> global property<br />

<strong>and</strong> casualty insurance, reinsurance, <strong>and</strong> life insurance<br />

markets. TMH has no affiliation with Rosenkranz, Delphi, or<br />

any of <strong>the</strong> Director or Executive Defendants.<br />

power by voting agreement, <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter contains o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

restrictions on <strong>the</strong> Class B shares <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz's rights<br />

as <strong>the</strong> holder of those shares. Except for transfers to certain<br />

affiliates, <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter provides that <strong>the</strong> transfer of any<br />

Class B shares first effects a share-for-share conversion of<br />

those shares into Class A stock; 7 thus, while Rosenkranz<br />

exercises with his Class B voting power an effective veto<br />

right over any action requiring stockholder approval, he<br />

is unable to transfer that voting power. Moreover, <strong>the</strong><br />

Delphi Charter contains a provision prohibiting disparate<br />

consideration between Class A <strong>and</strong> B stock in <strong>the</strong> event of a<br />

merger:<br />

[I]n <strong>the</strong> case of any distribution or payment ... on Class<br />

A Common Stock or Class B Common Stock upon <strong>the</strong><br />

consolidation or merger of <strong>the</strong> Corporation with or into<br />

any o<strong>the</strong>r corporation ... such distribution payment shall be<br />

made ratably on a per share basis among <strong>the</strong> holders of <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A Common Stock <strong>and</strong> Class B Common Stock as a<br />

single class. 8<br />

*4 These Charter provisions were in force at Delphi's IPO,<br />

<strong>and</strong> while <strong>the</strong>y preserve Rosenkranz's voting power <strong>and</strong><br />

effective right of approval over all Delphi actions requiring<br />

a majority stockholder vote, <strong>the</strong>y severely limit Rosenkranz's<br />

ability to realize any o<strong>the</strong>r benefits by means of his Class B<br />

stock ownership, beyond those he of course possesses as a<br />

12.9% equity holder in Delphi.<br />

B. Delphi's Capital Structure <strong>and</strong> Relevant Charter<br />

Provisions<br />

Delphi first issued shares to <strong>the</strong> public in 1990. Following<br />

this IPO, Delphi's ownership was divided between holders<br />

of Class A common stock <strong>and</strong> Class B common stock.<br />

Delphi Class A shares are widely held, publicly traded,<br />

<strong>and</strong> entitled by <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter 6 to one vote per share.<br />

Class B shares are held entirely by Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> his<br />

affiliates <strong>and</strong> are entitled to ten votes per share; however,<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter caps <strong>the</strong> aggregate voting power of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Class B shares at 49.9%. Rosenkranz also owns Class A<br />

shares, but a voting agreement with Delphi caps Rosenkranz's<br />

total voting power, regardless of his stock ownership, at<br />

49.9%. Although Rosenkranz possesses 49.9% of <strong>the</strong> Delphi<br />

stockholder voting power due to his Class B shares, his stock<br />

ownership accounts for roughly 12.9% of Delphi's equity.<br />

In addition to <strong>the</strong> cap <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter places on Class B<br />

voting power <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> cap placed on Rosenkranz's total voting<br />

C. Delphi's Consulting Contracts with Rosenkranz–<br />

Affiliated Entities<br />

Before founding Delphi in 1987, Rosenkranz created in 1982<br />

a group of private investment funds to construct <strong>and</strong> manage<br />

investment portfolios. One such fund was Acorn Partners,<br />

L.P., which is managed by Acorn, a financial advisory firm<br />

registered with <strong>the</strong> U.S. Securities <strong>and</strong> Exchange Commission<br />

under <strong>the</strong> Investment Advisers Act of 1940. Since 1982,<br />

Acorn has provided consulting services to third parties.<br />

Pursuant to two contracts entered into in 1987 <strong>and</strong> 1988,<br />

Delphi <strong>and</strong> its largest subsidiary, Reliance St<strong>and</strong>ard, receive<br />

investment consulting services from Acorn under <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts. Although Acorn provides <strong>the</strong> services under <strong>the</strong>se<br />

contracts, payment under <strong>the</strong> contracts is made by Delphi<br />

to RAM, ano<strong>the</strong>r Rosenkranz-affiliated entity, in order to<br />

segregate <strong>the</strong> fees Acorn receives from Delphi from those it<br />

receives from o<strong>the</strong>r parties to which it provides services. 9<br />

This payment arrangement is purportedly for accounting<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 3


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

purposes <strong>and</strong> does not affect <strong>the</strong> economics of <strong>the</strong> contracts,<br />

as Rosenkranz is <strong>the</strong> beneficial owner of both Acorn <strong>and</strong><br />

RAM. 10 The RAM Contracts have been publicly disclosed<br />

in Delphi's SEC filings since <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>'s 1990 IPO.<br />

Additionally, <strong>the</strong>y are terminable by ei<strong>the</strong>r RAM or Delphi<br />

upon thirty days' notice.<br />

For <strong>the</strong> consulting services it provides to Delphi, Acorn<br />

operates through an Expense Allocation Agreement (“EAA”)<br />

with DCM, a wholly owned subsidiary of Delphi <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

entity through which Delphi conducts its New York activities.<br />

Under <strong>the</strong> EAA, DCM provides Acorn with office space,<br />

facilities, <strong>and</strong> personnel; in fact, Acorn's “employees” are on<br />

<strong>the</strong> DCM payroll. 11 Acorn <strong>the</strong>n reimburses DCM for <strong>the</strong>se<br />

personnel, facility, <strong>and</strong> office space costs. 12 Acorn itself does<br />

not actually own any assets beyond, according to Rosenkranz,<br />

proprietary trading systems <strong>and</strong> models developed by him that<br />

Acorn uses for its business. 13 At oral argument, Defendants'<br />

counsel seemed unclear as to exactly what tangible value<br />

<strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts bring to Delphi that Delphi could not<br />

provide to itself at cost. The nature of <strong>the</strong> benefit of <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts to Delphi remains unclear to me, perhaps because<br />

<strong>the</strong> contracts are, as <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs allege, sham agreements<br />

through which Rosenkranz has being skimming money from<br />

Delphi since <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>'s inception. That <strong>the</strong>ory, however,<br />

awaits factual development on a full record.<br />

D. TMH Approaches Delphi Regarding an Acquisition<br />

On July 20, 2011, TMH made an unsolicited approach,<br />

through its investment banker MacQuarie Capital<br />

(“MacQuarie”), to Delphi to express its interest in acquiring<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>. TMH had plans to exp<strong>and</strong> internationally<br />

<strong>and</strong> enter <strong>the</strong> property, casualty, <strong>and</strong> life insurance markets,<br />

<strong>and</strong> it had identified Delphi as a potential acquisition target<br />

in pursuit of that strategy. A MacQuarie representative<br />

called Rosenkranz to request a preliminary meeting between<br />

<strong>the</strong> senior management of Delphi <strong>and</strong> TMH. Rosenkranz's<br />

initial response was that he did not think Delphi was for<br />

sale. Eventually, however, Rosenkranz called <strong>the</strong> MacQuarie<br />

representative back <strong>and</strong> indicated that he would report TMH's<br />

interest to Delphi's Board at <strong>the</strong> upcoming quarterly meeting.<br />

Rosenkranz also tentatively scheduled a meeting between<br />

Delphi <strong>and</strong> TMH representatives for <strong>the</strong> day after <strong>the</strong> board<br />

meeting. 14<br />

*5 At <strong>the</strong> Delphi Board's August 3rd meeting, Rosenkranz<br />

informed <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r directors of <strong>the</strong> Delphi Board of<br />

TMH's interest in acquiring Delphi. The Director Defendants<br />

authorized preliminary discussions <strong>and</strong> disclosures with<br />

TMH. 15 The directors also discussed <strong>the</strong> seriousness of<br />

TMH's interest, <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz suggested 1.5–2.0 times<br />

book value as a reference point for an attractive deal, or $45–<br />

$60 per share, approximately an 80–140% premium over <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A stock price at <strong>the</strong> time.<br />

For most of August, senior management from Delphi<br />

<strong>and</strong> TMH had general discussions regarding a potential<br />

merger, with Rosenkranz representing Delphi with assistance<br />

from Delphi COO Sherman <strong>and</strong> CFO Kiratsous. Delphi<br />

began providing due diligence materials in late August <strong>and</strong><br />

continued to discuss potential synergies with TMH; however,<br />

no discussions of price or o<strong>the</strong>r specific terms occurred.<br />

During this time, Rosenkranz considered how he might<br />

receive a premium on his Class B shares above what <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A stockholders would receive in <strong>the</strong> Merger. Because<br />

<strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter prohibits disparate distributions of merger<br />

consideration through a provision that was in place when<br />

Delphi went public in 1990, Rosenkranz knew that any<br />

premium would require a charter amendment. Apparently<br />

undeterred by <strong>the</strong> fact that Section 7 of Delphi's Charter would<br />

likely be viewed by Delphi's public stockholders as expressly<br />

prohibiting <strong>the</strong> differential consideration he sought, <strong>and</strong> that<br />

<strong>the</strong> Delphi stock price paid by <strong>the</strong>se investors likely reflected<br />

a company in which <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder, though<br />

retaining voting control, had bargained away his right to be<br />

compensated disparately for his shares, Rosenkranz discussed<br />

with Sherman, Kiratsous, <strong>and</strong> Coulter, Delphi's General<br />

Counsel, how such a division of <strong>the</strong> merger proceeds might<br />

be accomplished. 16 The Executive Defendants obtained data<br />

on acquisitions of corporations with dual-class stock, <strong>and</strong><br />

Coulter advised Rosenkranz that a special committee should<br />

be formed <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> transaction should be conditioned<br />

on approval by a majority vote of <strong>the</strong> disinterested Class A<br />

stockholders. 17 Despite using Delphi resources in procuring<br />

this advice, Rosenkranz did not inform <strong>the</strong> Board of his<br />

desire for disparate consideration until a Board meeting in<br />

mid September.<br />

On September 7, 2011, at a meeting attended by <strong>the</strong><br />

Executive Defendants, Brimecome conveyed TMH's interest<br />

in acquiring Delphi at a price between $33–$35 per share (a<br />

50–59% premium over Delphi's <strong>the</strong>n-market price of $21.98).<br />

After initially responding that TMH's offer was inadequate,<br />

Rosenkranz later contacted Brimecome to reiterate his<br />

disappointment <strong>and</strong> convey his expectation of an opening<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 4


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

offer in <strong>the</strong> range of 1.5–2.0 times book value, or $45–$60 per<br />

share, which was consistent with <strong>the</strong> price he had suggested<br />

to Delphi's Board in early August. 18 Rosenkranz countered<br />

with this range despite <strong>the</strong> fact that he knew at <strong>the</strong> time that<br />

he was unwilling to sell at $45. Never<strong>the</strong>less, he thought $45<br />

per share might be attractive to <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders, as<br />

Delphi's stock was at <strong>the</strong> time trading around <strong>the</strong> low twenties,<br />

<strong>and</strong> he suspected that dem<strong>and</strong>ing his own desired price of<br />

$55–$60 at that stage of <strong>the</strong> negotiations would have turned<br />

off TMH <strong>and</strong> killed <strong>the</strong> discussions. 19 Several days later,<br />

Brimecome called <strong>and</strong> informed Rosenkranz that TMH, after<br />

hearing that $40 was a nonstarter for Delphi's controlling<br />

stockholder, was raising its offer to $45 per share, <strong>the</strong>n a<br />

106% premium over market. Rosenkranz advised Brimecome<br />

that he would take <strong>the</strong> offer to Delphi's Board.<br />

E. The Board Forms a Special Committee <strong>and</strong> Sub–<br />

Committee<br />

*6 On September 16, 2011, Rosenkranz presented<br />

TMH's $45 per share offer to <strong>the</strong> Board. 20 Rosenkranz<br />

acknowledged <strong>the</strong> offer's substantial premium over Delphi's<br />

stock price, but he disclosed to <strong>the</strong> Board that he none<strong>the</strong>less<br />

found it inadequate from his perspective as controlling<br />

stockholder, <strong>and</strong> that he would be unlikely to vote his Class<br />

B shares in favor of Merger at that price . 21 Because of <strong>the</strong><br />

conflict of interest Rosenkranz's position created between him<br />

<strong>and</strong> Delphi's public stockholders, Rosenkranz suggested, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> Board agreed, to form a Special Committee, comprising<br />

<strong>the</strong> Board's seven independent directors (<strong>the</strong> Director<br />

Defendants), to evaluate <strong>the</strong> proposal from TMH, direct<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r discussions with TMH, <strong>and</strong> consider alternatives<br />

to <strong>the</strong> TMH proposal. 22<br />

The members of <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee held Class A shares only, 23 aligning <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

financial interests with those of <strong>the</strong> public stockholders.<br />

The Special Committee retained Cravath, Swaine & Moore<br />

LLP (“Cravath”) as legal advisor <strong>and</strong> Lazard Frères & Co.<br />

LLC (“Lazard”) as financial advisor. 24 Cravath advised <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee of its fiduciary obligations, including<br />

its m<strong>and</strong>ate to represent only <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders,<br />

<strong>and</strong> interviewed <strong>the</strong> directors about <strong>the</strong>ir connections to<br />

Rosenkranz. 25 Based on <strong>the</strong>se interviews <strong>and</strong> per Cravath's<br />

advice, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee limited its membership to five<br />

directors—Fox, Hirsh, Litvack, Meehan, <strong>and</strong> O'Connor—<br />

each chosen for his relative business <strong>and</strong> industry experience<br />

<strong>and</strong> his lack of any connection, economic or social, to<br />

Rosenkranz.<br />

At a later board meeting, <strong>the</strong> full Delphi Board formally<br />

established <strong>the</strong> Special Committee <strong>and</strong> set forth its<br />

m<strong>and</strong>ate. 26 The Board charged <strong>the</strong> Special Committee with<br />

representing <strong>the</strong> best interests of <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders,<br />

granted <strong>the</strong> Special Committee full authority to take any<br />

action that would be available to <strong>the</strong> Board in connection<br />

with <strong>the</strong> transaction, <strong>and</strong> authorized <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

to pursue <strong>and</strong> consider alternative transactions to <strong>the</strong> TMH<br />

bid if it deemed such alternatives to be of interest to <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A stockholders. Additionally, <strong>the</strong> Board conditioned<br />

its approval or recommendation of <strong>the</strong> potential transaction<br />

on <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's affirmative recommendation<br />

<strong>the</strong>reof. The Special Committee <strong>the</strong>n met <strong>and</strong> created a<br />

Sub–Committee—comprising Fox, Meehan, <strong>and</strong> O'Connor<br />

—to act on <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's behalf with respect<br />

to any matters related to Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> differential<br />

merger consideration. 27 The Sub–Committee was given<br />

full authority with respect to <strong>the</strong>se matters. Finally, just as<br />

<strong>the</strong> Board conditioned its approval of any transaction on a<br />

favorable recommendation by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee conditioned its approval on <strong>the</strong> favorable<br />

recommendation of <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee.<br />

The Special Committee <strong>the</strong>n sought advice from its legal <strong>and</strong><br />

financial advisors on its obligations <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> valuation of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong>. Lazard advised <strong>the</strong> Special Committee that <strong>the</strong><br />

premium offered by <strong>the</strong> TMH proposal—more than 100%<br />

over Delphi's stock price at <strong>the</strong> time—was a tremendous deal,<br />

<strong>and</strong> that in light of <strong>the</strong> significant premium offered, Delphi<br />

was unlikely to see a comparable proposal from ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

buyer. 28 The Special Committee discussed Lazard's advice<br />

<strong>and</strong> considered whe<strong>the</strong>r to solicit additional offers, such as<br />

through an auction or a quiet shopping of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>.<br />

Ultimately, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee concluded that since TMH<br />

was <strong>the</strong> acquirer most likely to be interested in acquiring<br />

Delphi <strong>and</strong> had already offered a colossal premium over<br />

market price, shopping Delphi was not worth <strong>the</strong> impact such<br />

a course of action would have on negotiations with TMH<br />

or <strong>the</strong> risk of a potential leak disrupting Delphi's ongoing<br />

business. 29<br />

F. Price Differential Negotiations<br />

*7 Leading up to <strong>and</strong> simultaneously with <strong>the</strong> negotiations<br />

with TMH, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee negotiated with Rosenkranz<br />

regarding whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re would be any disparate allocation<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Merger consideration <strong>and</strong>, if so, what <strong>the</strong> differential<br />

would be. Rosenkranz opened <strong>the</strong> discussion with a request<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 5


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

of $59 per Class B share <strong>and</strong> $43 per Class A share,<br />

asserting to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee that he did not expect<br />

TMH to raise its offer price; that if TMH did raise its<br />

price, Rosenkranz expected that increase to be allocated<br />

evenly dollar-for-dollar on top of <strong>the</strong> $59/$43 split; that<br />

he was unequivocally not a seller at $45; <strong>and</strong> that if his<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>s were not met, he would have no qualms about<br />

walking away from <strong>the</strong> deal <strong>and</strong> continuing <strong>the</strong> status quo of<br />

running Delphi on a st<strong>and</strong>alone basis. 30 The Sub–Committee<br />

reviewed comparable acquisitions of companies with dualclass<br />

stock, <strong>and</strong>, after hearing from its financial <strong>and</strong> legal<br />

advisors that disparate consideration in such cases is unusual<br />

<strong>and</strong> problematic, attempted to persuade Rosenkranz, over<br />

a number of meetings <strong>and</strong> phone conversations, to accept<br />

<strong>the</strong> same price as <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders. 31 Never<strong>the</strong>less,<br />

Rosenkrantz remained obstinate, refusing to back down on<br />

his dem<strong>and</strong> for some level of disparate consideration.<br />

The Sub–Committee considered whe<strong>the</strong>r Rosenkrantz was<br />

truly willing to walk away from <strong>the</strong> merger ra<strong>the</strong>r than accept<br />

$45 per share, <strong>and</strong> it concluded, for several reasons, including<br />

Rosenkranz's plans for Delphi's expansion, that Rosenkranz<br />

was prepared to jettison <strong>the</strong> deal if he did not get his way.<br />

Thus, not wanting to deprive <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders of<br />

<strong>the</strong> opportunity to realize a circa–100% premium on <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

shares, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee decided to accept <strong>the</strong> idea of<br />

differential consideration but to fight for a reduction in <strong>the</strong><br />

consideration differential. 32<br />

The Sub–Committee engaged in a back-<strong>and</strong>-forth with<br />

Rosenkranz in <strong>the</strong> days leading up to an October 14, 2011,<br />

meeting with TMH representatives. The Sub–Committee<br />

informed Rosenkranz that it was willing to permit him<br />

differential consideration, but only if Rosenkranz's per share<br />

incremental premium was limited to less than 10%, to which<br />

Rosenkranz replied by reducing his request for disparate<br />

consideration to $55.50 per share for Class B shares <strong>and</strong><br />

$43.50 per share for <strong>the</strong> Class A shares. 33 Just days before<br />

<strong>the</strong> October 14th meeting with TMH, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee<br />

<strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz remained far apart on <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong><br />

differential. Still, nei<strong>the</strong>r side wanted to lose momentum in<br />

<strong>the</strong> negotiations with TMH or insult <strong>the</strong> TMH representatives<br />

who were flying in from Japan, <strong>and</strong> so both sides felt that it<br />

was important to keep <strong>the</strong> October 14th meeting date.<br />

There was also <strong>the</strong> issue of what role Rosenkranz should have<br />

in <strong>the</strong> upcoming meeting, given his <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee's<br />

concurrent sparring over <strong>the</strong> differential consideration. After<br />

consulting with Cravath, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee decided that<br />

it was best to allow Rosenkranz to remain <strong>the</strong> point<br />

person, subject to direction <strong>and</strong> oversight by <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee <strong>and</strong> Sub–Committee. 34 The Sub–Committee<br />

reasoned that Rosenkranz would be an effective negotiatior<br />

because, as Chairman, CEO, <strong>and</strong> founder of Delphi,<br />

Rosenkranz had intimiate knowledge of <strong>the</strong> business, <strong>and</strong><br />

that while Rosenkranz's interests were adverse to <strong>the</strong> Class<br />

A stockholders', both Classes' interests were aligned with<br />

respect to securing <strong>the</strong> highest total offer from TMH.<br />

Moreover, as TMH did not at that point know of <strong>the</strong> potential<br />

for differential consideration, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee did<br />

not want to spook TMH by replacing Rosenkranz, who<br />

had <strong>the</strong>retofore represented Delphi in <strong>the</strong> negotiations. The<br />

Special Committee thus agreed that Rosenkranz would<br />

remain <strong>the</strong> face of <strong>the</strong> negotiations <strong>and</strong> would attend <strong>the</strong><br />

October 14th meeting with TMH. Apparently not trusting<br />

Rosenkranz to act solely as a fiduciary for <strong>the</strong> stockholders,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee also directed Lazard to attend <strong>the</strong><br />

meeting. 35<br />

G. Merger Price Negotiations<br />

*8 The morning before <strong>the</strong> October 14th meeting, <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee met to decide on Delphi's position with<br />

respect to price. After a discussion with Lazard, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee directed Rosenkranz to request that TMH increase<br />

its offer to $48.50 <strong>and</strong> authorized Rosenkranz to convey to<br />

TMH that he would take a price of $47 or higher back to <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee if <strong>the</strong> circumstances warranted. 36 At <strong>the</strong><br />

meeting with TMH, Rosenkranz requested $48.50 per share,<br />

<strong>and</strong> TMH responded that it would consider whe<strong>the</strong>r it could<br />

increase its offer, although it expressed surprise that Delphi<br />

was asking for more money given that TMH had previously<br />

indicated that $45 was its maximum price. 37<br />

Several days later, Brimecome of TMH called Rosenkranz<br />

to inform him that $45 was TMH's best <strong>and</strong> final offer. 38<br />

Authorized by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee to drop Delphi's ask<br />

to $47 per share, Rosenkranz responded by proposing a $2<br />

special dividend per share at or around <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> closing<br />

(which would effectively increase <strong>the</strong> merger consideration<br />

to $47). Brimecome <strong>the</strong>n informed Rosenkranz that TMH<br />

would respond to this offer shortly. The next day, TMH<br />

contacted Rosenkranz to counter with a $1 special dividend;<br />

Rosenkranz agreed to take <strong>the</strong> offer to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 6


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

Rosenkranz immediately called Fox, <strong>the</strong> Chairman of <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee, <strong>and</strong> informed him of <strong>the</strong> call with<br />

TMH. 39 Rosenkranz relayed TMH's offer <strong>and</strong> indicated that<br />

he would not support a transaction based on TMH's revised<br />

offer unless <strong>the</strong> $1 special dividend was split evenly between<br />

Class A <strong>and</strong> Class B shares. Rosenkranz also warned Fox that<br />

he would refuse to entertain fur<strong>the</strong>r negotiations regarding<br />

<strong>the</strong> differential consideration, <strong>and</strong> that he would walk away<br />

from <strong>the</strong> transaction if he did not receive $56.50 for each<br />

of his Class B shares (with <strong>the</strong> Class A consideration being<br />

$44.50 per share). 40 The Special Committee <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sub–<br />

Committee thus decided to finish negotiating <strong>the</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong><br />

differential consideration before responding to TMH's revised<br />

offer.<br />

H. Agreement on Price <strong>and</strong> Remaining Merger Terms<br />

With TMH's offer of $46 per share ($45 plus <strong>the</strong> $1 special<br />

dividend) on <strong>the</strong> table, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz<br />

continued <strong>the</strong>ir negotiations regarding <strong>the</strong> division of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger consideration. Fox <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz engaged<br />

in extensive back-<strong>and</strong>-forth discussions, with Rosenkranz<br />

refusing to accept less than $56.50 for his Class B shares<br />

<strong>and</strong> Fox holding fast to his dem<strong>and</strong> for $45.25 for <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A shares, which would have left $51.25 per Class B<br />

share. Over <strong>the</strong> course of this back-<strong>and</strong>-forth, Rosenkranz's<br />

gamut of emotions confirmed that <strong>the</strong> Kübler–Ross Model 41<br />

indeed applies to corporate controllers whose attempts to<br />

divert merger consideration to <strong>the</strong>mselves at <strong>the</strong> expense of<br />

<strong>the</strong> minority stockholders are rebuked by intractable special<br />

committees. Rosenkranz began in denial of <strong>the</strong> fact that he<br />

might not receive his original request of $59 per share <strong>and</strong><br />

was isolated with <strong>the</strong> formation of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee,<br />

grew angry as <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee held firm to its original<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> of $45.25 for <strong>the</strong> Class A shares, 42 began to<br />

bargain <strong>and</strong> revised his proposal to $44.75 for <strong>the</strong> Class A<br />

shares, 43 plunged into depression when <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee<br />

only reduced its dem<strong>and</strong> to $45 per Class A share, 44 <strong>and</strong><br />

finally arrived at “acceptance” when Fox, believing <strong>the</strong> deal<br />

to be in jeopardy, proposed $44.875 for Class A <strong>and</strong> $53.875<br />

for Class B. 45<br />

*9 Fox brought this proposal to <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee,<br />

which approved <strong>the</strong> differential consideration of $53.875 <strong>and</strong><br />

$44.875, which fell on <strong>the</strong> low end of <strong>the</strong> range of differential<br />

consideration transactions presented by Lazard. The Sub–<br />

Committee brought <strong>the</strong> proposal to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee,<br />

which upon hearing Fox's report approved <strong>the</strong> differential <strong>and</strong><br />

agreed to accept TMH's $46 offer <strong>and</strong> move forward with<br />

<strong>the</strong> remaining terms of <strong>the</strong> transaction. On October 21, 2011,<br />

Rosenkranz relayed <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's acceptance to<br />

TMH <strong>and</strong> informed TMH for <strong>the</strong> first time of <strong>the</strong> differential<br />

consideration, toward which TMH reportedly did not express<br />

any concern. 46<br />

In <strong>the</strong> months following <strong>the</strong> agreement on price, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee <strong>and</strong> TMH negotiated <strong>the</strong> remaining terms of <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. One of <strong>the</strong> key provisions obtained by <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee was <strong>the</strong> non-waivable conditioning of <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

on <strong>the</strong> affirmative vote of a majority of <strong>the</strong> disinterested<br />

Class A stockholders. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> Merger must<br />

receive majority approval from a group of Class A shares that<br />

excludes Class A shares owned directly or indirectly by Class<br />

B stockholders (Rosenkranz), Delphi officers or directors,<br />

TMH, or any of <strong>the</strong>ir affiliates.<br />

In addition, since Section 7 of Delphi's Charter prohibits<br />

<strong>the</strong> unequal distribution of merger consideration, <strong>the</strong> parties<br />

agreed to condition <strong>the</strong> Merger on <strong>the</strong> approval of a<br />

charter amendment that explicitly excludes <strong>the</strong> Merger from<br />

that prohibition (<strong>the</strong> “Charter Amendment”). The Sub–<br />

Committee found such an amendment to be in <strong>the</strong> best<br />

interests of <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders as it was, in <strong>the</strong> view<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee <strong>and</strong> in light of Rosenkranz's dem<strong>and</strong>s,<br />

<strong>the</strong> only way to enable <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders to obtain a<br />

substantial premium on <strong>the</strong>ir shares. 47 The differential was<br />

necessary to secure Rosenkranz's approval of <strong>the</strong> deal, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Charter Amendment was necessary to allow that differential.<br />

I. Rosenkranz Tries to Hustle <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts<br />

On December 12, 2011, shortly before <strong>the</strong> signing of <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Agreement, Rosenkranz informed Cravath that he <strong>and</strong><br />

TMH had been discussing <strong>the</strong> possibility of having TMH<br />

acquire RAM, Rosenkranz's investment advising company<br />

that provides services to Delphi, immediately before <strong>the</strong><br />

closing for a price around $57 million. This development<br />

concerned <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee, as it realized that <strong>the</strong> $57<br />

million could be seen as additional Merger consideration<br />

being allocated to Rosenkranz, ra<strong>the</strong>r than as compensation<br />

for investment consulting services, if <strong>the</strong> transaction were<br />

structured as an up-front payment with no obligation for RAM<br />

or Acorn to continue to perform.<br />

As an alternative, TMH proposed an agreement to keep <strong>the</strong><br />

RAM Contracts in place for five years. This alternative also<br />

concerned <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee because <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 7


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

are terminable by Delphi on thirty days' notice, <strong>and</strong> an<br />

agreement by TMH to continue those contracts for five<br />

years would guarantee additional payments to Rosenkranz<br />

that might o<strong>the</strong>rwise be unavailable. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> Sub–<br />

Committee questioned <strong>the</strong> value of RAM's consulting<br />

services to TMH, which gave <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee concern<br />

that TMH was purchasing <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts to secure<br />

Rosenkranz's consent to <strong>the</strong> merger <strong>and</strong> not to obtain <strong>the</strong><br />

services <strong>the</strong>mselves.<br />

*10 Addressing its concerns, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee decided<br />

to push Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> TMH to postpone <strong>the</strong>ir negotiations<br />

regarding <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts until after <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement was signed, at which point Rosenkranz would<br />

be contractually obligated through a voting agreement to<br />

support <strong>the</strong> merger. 48 The Sub–Committee reasoned that<br />

such a postponement would effectively ensure that <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts purchase negotiations were based on <strong>the</strong> actual<br />

value TMH saw in RAM's services, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a need to<br />

induce Rosenkranz to support <strong>the</strong> merger.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee's proposition agitated<br />

Rosenkranz, he told <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee that he would<br />

postpone any renegotiation of <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts until<br />

after <strong>the</strong> merger <strong>and</strong> voting agreement were signed. 49<br />

The Sub–Committee also obtained <strong>the</strong> inclusion in <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Agreement of a contractual representation by TMH<br />

that <strong>the</strong>re were no agreements or underst<strong>and</strong>ings between<br />

TMH <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz o<strong>the</strong>r than those expressly set forth<br />

in <strong>the</strong> transaction documents. 50 Additionally, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee used this incident in an attempt to obtain a higher<br />

price from TMH, but TMH quickly rejected <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee's request <strong>and</strong> made clear that it was unwilling to<br />

reopen <strong>the</strong> issue of price. 51<br />

J. Merger Signing <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Purported “Gentlemen's<br />

Agreement”<br />

On December 20, 2011, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee, Special<br />

Committee, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> full Board held meetings to discuss <strong>the</strong><br />

finalized terms of <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. Lazard advised that<br />

<strong>the</strong> overall merger consideration was fair <strong>and</strong> represented a<br />

significant premium over market price. 52 Also, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee, considering data provided to it by Lazard,<br />

concluded that <strong>the</strong> consideration differential was well within<br />

<strong>and</strong> potentially at <strong>the</strong> low end of comparable precedent<br />

transactions. The Sub–Committee, Special Committee, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> Board <strong>the</strong>n approved <strong>the</strong> transaction, <strong>and</strong> Delphi <strong>and</strong><br />

TMH executed <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement on December 21,<br />

2011.<br />

Despite Rosenkranz's representations to <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee<br />

<strong>and</strong> TMH's contractual representations in <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement, it became apparent during discovery for this<br />

action that <strong>the</strong>re had been a non-binding underst<strong>and</strong>ing, or<br />

“Gentlemen's Agreement,” between TMH <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz<br />

that TMH would continue to pay Rosenkranz for five years<br />

of investment consulting services, ei<strong>the</strong>r under <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts or, if TMH terminated <strong>the</strong> contracts, directly to<br />

Rosenkranz. After reviewing a series of emails that revealed<br />

this Gentlemen's Agreement, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee decided<br />

to revise Delphi's Preliminary Proxy filed on January 13,<br />

2012, to disclose <strong>the</strong> content of <strong>the</strong> emails <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sub–<br />

Committee's conclusion that <strong>the</strong>y indicated <strong>the</strong> existence of<br />

a non-binding agreement between Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> TMH that<br />

existed before <strong>the</strong> signing of <strong>the</strong> Merger. The Sub–Committee<br />

also informed TMH <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz that it was considering<br />

exercising its termination rights due to TMH's breach of a<br />

contractual representation or changing its recommendation of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger to <strong>the</strong> stockholders.<br />

*11 TMH <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz responded by providing <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee with a letter agreement denying that any<br />

“Gentlemen's Agreement” existed <strong>and</strong> stating that, if <strong>the</strong>re<br />

had been such an agreement regarding <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts,<br />

TMH <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz “expressly <strong>and</strong> irrevocably repudiate,<br />

<strong>and</strong> waive any <strong>and</strong> all rights that [<strong>the</strong>y] may have pursuant to,<br />

any such Contract or underst<strong>and</strong>ing.” 53 After receiving <strong>the</strong><br />

letter, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee met again to decide on a course<br />

of action. The Sub–Committee determined that, despite <strong>the</strong><br />

denial in <strong>the</strong> letter agreement, a non-binding underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

had existed between TMH <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz, but that TMH <strong>and</strong><br />

Rosenkranz had repudiated <strong>the</strong> Gentlemen's Agreement with<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir letter. The Sub–Committee's conclusions were disclosed<br />

in Delphi's February 21, 2012, Definitive Proxy. 54<br />

The Special Committee <strong>and</strong> Sub–Committee <strong>the</strong>n reviewed<br />

anew whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y considered <strong>the</strong> proposed Merger <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> differential consideration to be fair to <strong>the</strong> Class A<br />

stockholders. They determined that <strong>the</strong> Merger was fair<br />

on both counts <strong>and</strong> thus decided against changing <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

recommendation to <strong>the</strong> stockholders, obviating <strong>the</strong> need to<br />

determine whe<strong>the</strong>r Delphi had <strong>the</strong> right to terminate <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Agreement on <strong>the</strong> basis of TMH's alleged breach.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 8


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

II. THE PLAINTIFFS' CLAIMS<br />

The wrongdoing alleged by <strong>the</strong> Plaintiff essentially falls<br />

under two areas. The Plaintiffs first challenge <strong>the</strong> negotiation<br />

process used with TMH, arguing that <strong>the</strong> Executive <strong>and</strong><br />

Director Defendants breached <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary duties in<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir efforts to obtain <strong>the</strong> best price reasonably available<br />

to <strong>the</strong> stockholders, in violation of <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary duties<br />

under <strong>the</strong> Revlon 55 doctrine. Second, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs attack<br />

<strong>the</strong> negotiations between <strong>the</strong> Director Defendants (through<br />

<strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee) <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz with respect to<br />

differential consideration. The Plaintiffs allege that <strong>the</strong><br />

Director Defendants <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz breached <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary<br />

duties to <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders in approving <strong>the</strong><br />

consideration differential. Additionally, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs assert<br />

that Rosenkranz breached his fiduciary <strong>and</strong> contractual<br />

obligations in seeking such a differential in <strong>the</strong> first instance<br />

because <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter prohibits <strong>the</strong> unequal distribution<br />

of merger consideration. Finally, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs contend—<br />

without, however, much enthusiasm—that Delphi's February<br />

2012 Proxy Statement omits or misrepresents material<br />

information in violation of <strong>the</strong> Board's disclosure obligations.<br />

With respect to <strong>the</strong> negotiations with TMH, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs<br />

point to several instances of wrongdoing on <strong>the</strong> part of<br />

Rosenkranz, <strong>the</strong> Executive <strong>and</strong> Director Defendants, <strong>and</strong><br />

TMH. 56 They contend that Rosenkranz, who holds a<br />

fiduciary position as Board member, CEO, <strong>and</strong> controlling<br />

stockholder, dominated <strong>the</strong> negotiation process with TMH<br />

against <strong>the</strong> interests of <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders. The<br />

Plaintiffs assert that Rosenkranz's interests were not aligned<br />

with <strong>the</strong> stockholders' when he negotiated with TMH because<br />

he knew that he would collect a higher price per share than <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A stockholders. The Plaintiffs contend that Rosenkranz<br />

intended from <strong>the</strong> outset to receive a premium on his Class B<br />

shares at <strong>the</strong> expense of <strong>the</strong> Class A shares, <strong>and</strong> is attempting,<br />

by tying <strong>the</strong> vote on <strong>the</strong> Charter Amendment with <strong>the</strong> vote on<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger, to coerce <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders into amending<br />

<strong>the</strong> provisions of Delphi's Charter that prohibit such disparate<br />

consideration, in violation of his fiduciary <strong>and</strong> contractual<br />

obligations. The Plaintiffs allege that <strong>the</strong> Board went along<br />

with this plan by allowing Rosenkranz to remain <strong>the</strong> face<br />

of Delphi in negotiations with TMH even after Rosenkranz<br />

disclosed his intent to procure disparate consideration <strong>and</strong> by<br />

allowing <strong>the</strong> Merger to be predicated on a coercive vote on<br />

<strong>the</strong> Charter Amendment.<br />

*12 Related to Rosenkranz's <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Director Defendants'<br />

failure to secure <strong>the</strong> best price available, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs<br />

present several allegations concerning Acorn <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts. The Plaintiffs contend that Rosenkranz has<br />

funneled money to himself through <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts,<br />

<strong>the</strong>reby depressing Delphi's share price, which caused Lazard<br />

to value Delphi at too low a price in its Fairness Opinion.<br />

Additionally, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs accuse Rosenkranz of usurping a<br />

corporate opportunity belonging to Delphi by using Delphi<br />

employees <strong>and</strong> resources to provide lucrative investment<br />

consulting services through Acorn to third parties, diverting<br />

a revenue stream that should have flowed to Delphi <strong>and</strong> that<br />

would have increased Delphi's value to potential bidders.<br />

The Plaintiffs also allege that Rosenkranz has obtained, or<br />

attempted to obtain, through negotiations with <strong>and</strong> aided <strong>and</strong><br />

abetted by TMH, disparate consideration by preserving <strong>the</strong><br />

income stream flowing from <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts.<br />

In addition to attacking <strong>the</strong> negotiation process with TMH,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs assert that <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee did not achieve<br />

a fair result with respect to <strong>the</strong> differential consideration.<br />

The Plaintiffs argue that Rosenkranz breached his fiduciary<br />

<strong>and</strong> contractual obligations to <strong>the</strong> stockholders by seeking<br />

disparate consideration in <strong>the</strong> first place, as <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter<br />

requires equal treatment of Class A <strong>and</strong> Class B shares in <strong>the</strong><br />

distribution of merger consideration. For <strong>the</strong> same reasons,<br />

argue <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs, <strong>the</strong> Director <strong>and</strong> Executive Defendants<br />

breached <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary duties in facilitating <strong>and</strong> approving<br />

<strong>the</strong> consideration differential. The Plaintiffs also contend that,<br />

even assuming that some level of disparate consideration is<br />

permissible, <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee members, in breach of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

fiduciary duties, failed to negotiate a fair price for <strong>the</strong> Class<br />

A stockholders. 57<br />

III. ANALYSIS<br />

I may issue a preliminary injunction only where I find that<br />

<strong>the</strong> moving party has demonstrated a reasonable likelihood<br />

of success on <strong>the</strong> merits, that failure to enjoin will result in<br />

irreparable harm to <strong>the</strong> moving party, <strong>and</strong> that a balancing<br />

of <strong>the</strong> equities discloses that any harm likely to result<br />

from <strong>the</strong> injunctive relief is outweighed by <strong>the</strong> benefit<br />

conferred <strong>the</strong>reby. 58 Although I find that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs<br />

have demonstrated a reasonable probability of success on<br />

<strong>the</strong> merits of some of <strong>the</strong>ir claims, I none<strong>the</strong>less find that<br />

injunctive relief here is inappropriate. The threatened harm<br />

here is largely, if not completely, remediable by damages, <strong>and</strong><br />

because <strong>the</strong> value of injunctive relief to <strong>the</strong> stockholder class<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 9


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

seems likely to be overwhelmed by <strong>the</strong> concomitant loss, I<br />

must deny <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' request for a preliminary injunction.<br />

A. Reasonable Probability of Success<br />

As discussed above, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' allegations essentially<br />

fall under two categories: those attacking <strong>the</strong> negotiation<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Merger price, <strong>and</strong> those attacking <strong>the</strong> differential<br />

consideration. Under <strong>the</strong> former category, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs<br />

challenge <strong>the</strong> negotiations with TMH <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz's<br />

involvement <strong>the</strong>rein, as well as <strong>the</strong> effect of <strong>the</strong> Acorn<br />

business <strong>and</strong> RAM Contracts on Delphi's value to potential<br />

bidders. Under <strong>the</strong> latter category, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs challenge<br />

Rosenkranz's entitlement to disparate consideration, <strong>the</strong><br />

effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee's negotiations with<br />

Rosenkranz, <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz's potential receipt of additional<br />

consideration not shared with <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders<br />

through an alleged agreement with TMH to maintain <strong>the</strong><br />

RAM Contracts. I address below <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' likelihood of<br />

success on <strong>the</strong>se arguments <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir allegations regarding<br />

disclosure violations.<br />

1. Challenges to <strong>the</strong> Negotiations with TMH <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Price<br />

Approved by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

*13 Once <strong>the</strong> Director Defendants decided to sell <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> for cash, <strong>the</strong>y assumed a duty under <strong>the</strong> Revlon<br />

doctrine to undertake reasonable efforts to obtain <strong>the</strong> highest<br />

price reasonably available in <strong>the</strong> sale of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>. 59 The<br />

so-called Revlon duty requires a board to “act reasonably,<br />

by undertaking a logically sound process to get <strong>the</strong> best<br />

deal that is realistically attainable.” 60 Thus, in evaluating<br />

<strong>the</strong> sale process of a company, ra<strong>the</strong>r than deferring to<br />

<strong>the</strong> board's informed, disinterested, <strong>and</strong> good faith actions<br />

under <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule, this Court instead<br />

examines <strong>the</strong> board's conduct with enhanced scrutiny using a<br />

reasonableness st<strong>and</strong>ard. 61 Specifically, <strong>the</strong> Court examines<br />

“<strong>the</strong> adequacy of <strong>the</strong> decision-making process” <strong>and</strong> “<strong>the</strong><br />

reasonableness of <strong>the</strong> directors' actions in light of <strong>the</strong><br />

circumstances <strong>the</strong>n existing.” 62<br />

The Plaintiffs argue that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee faltered when<br />

it allowed Rosenkranz to take <strong>the</strong> lead in negotiations despite<br />

his conflict of interest with <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders. The<br />

Plaintiffs contend that Rosenkranz was content to eschew<br />

<strong>the</strong> highest price per share because his personal interest<br />

was to ensure that <strong>the</strong> Merger was realized; he could <strong>the</strong>n<br />

turn <strong>and</strong> negotiate for disparate consideration for his shares.<br />

The Plaintiffs point out that <strong>the</strong> Board used Rosenkranz to<br />

negotiate <strong>the</strong> deal with TMH even after he disclosed his<br />

intention to dem<strong>and</strong> additional compensation for his Class<br />

B shares as a condition of his supporting <strong>the</strong> Merger. The<br />

Director Defendants explain that <strong>the</strong>y kept Rosenkranz as<br />

lead negotiator because, as CEO, he was <strong>the</strong> natural choice,<br />

<strong>and</strong> because replacing Rosenkranz with ano<strong>the</strong>r negotiator<br />

might have tipped TMH to <strong>the</strong> internal conflict or o<strong>the</strong>rwise<br />

alarmed TMH, potentially spawning negotiation difficulties<br />

or even jeopardizing <strong>the</strong> entire deal.<br />

As a negotiator, however, Rosenkranz's interests may not<br />

have been entirely aligned with those of <strong>the</strong> Class A<br />

stockholders. Rosenkranz was a fiduciary for Delphi, seeking<br />

to extract as much value for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> as possible for <strong>the</strong><br />

public shareholders. Never<strong>the</strong>less, though he was <strong>the</strong> holder<br />

of a class of stock relegated by <strong>the</strong> Charter to receiving, upon<br />

<strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>the</strong> same price per share as <strong>the</strong> publicly held<br />

stock, he firmly believed he was entitled to a control premium.<br />

Throughout <strong>the</strong> negotiations, he knew he was negotiating<br />

a price which he, as controlling stockholder, would not<br />

accept for his stock. Finally, Rosenkranz was <strong>the</strong> owner of<br />

a business, Acorn, which had a contractual relationship with<br />

Delphi. Thus, throughout <strong>the</strong> negotiations, Rosenkranz knew<br />

that he would also be negotiating <strong>the</strong> futures of those contracts<br />

with TMH.<br />

In addition to his conflicted roles, Rosenkranz's actions,<br />

<strong>and</strong> those of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r Executive Defendants, are troubling.<br />

Upon being approached by TMH, Rosenkranz did not<br />

immediately inform <strong>the</strong> Board that he would insist on<br />

differential consideration for his Class B stock. Instead,<br />

Rosenkranz consulted with Coulter, Sherman, <strong>and</strong> Kiratsous<br />

to formulate a plan, not to maximize, via <strong>the</strong> Merger, return<br />

to <strong>the</strong> stockholders, for whom <strong>the</strong>y are fiduciaries, but to<br />

maximize return to Rosenkranz himself.<br />

*14 I am not persuaded, however, by <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' <strong>the</strong>ory<br />

that because Rosenkranz knew he was going to receive<br />

disparate consideration, he lacked an incentive to extract<br />

<strong>the</strong> highest price from TMH. Regardless of whe<strong>the</strong>r he was<br />

able to achieve a premium for his shares, to <strong>the</strong> extent that<br />

Rosenkranz secured a higher overall price, <strong>the</strong>re would be a<br />

bigger pie from which Rosenkranz could cut an outsized slice.<br />

The Plaintiffs make <strong>the</strong> argument that Rosenkranz perhaps<br />

had an incentive to accept a smaller merger price so that<br />

TMH would have more funds available for <strong>the</strong> renegotiation<br />

of <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts, in which only Rosenkranz holds<br />

an interest. The Special Committee made an attempt to<br />

achieve a higher price from TMH after it learned of <strong>the</strong><br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 10


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

side negotiations between Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> TMH regarding<br />

<strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts, but was unsuccessful. On <strong>the</strong> current<br />

record, it seems unlikely that money was left on <strong>the</strong> table by<br />

Rosenkranz in anticipation of a lucrative renegotiation of <strong>the</strong><br />

RAM Contracts.<br />

The Plaintiffs also allege that <strong>the</strong> existence of Acorn <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts poisoned <strong>the</strong> sale process. As discussed<br />

earlier, after Rosenkranz formed Delphi, Delphi entered into<br />

contracts to purchase investment advising services from<br />

Acorn through RAM, both of which are Rosenkranz-affiliated<br />

entities. These contracts continued after Delphi went public<br />

<strong>and</strong> have been disclosed continuously. Under <strong>the</strong> Expense<br />

Allocation Agreement, Acorn would reimburse Delphi for<br />

Acorn's use of Delphi's employees, facilities, <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

resources to provide services to third parties as well as Delphi.<br />

When providing services to Delphi, Acorn would bill <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> through RAM, pursuant to <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts.<br />

These contracts were terminable at thirty days' notice by<br />

ei<strong>the</strong>r party.<br />

The Plaintiffs contend that <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts were a sham<br />

device through which Rosenkranz used Delphi employees<br />

<strong>and</strong> Delphi resources in order to charge Delphi for services<br />

that <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> could have provided in house, <strong>and</strong> to<br />

usurp an opportunity which Delphi could have seized to<br />

provide similar services to third parties. The Plaintiffs allege<br />

that Delphi's stock price was depressed as a result of this<br />

diverted income stream <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> stockholders will be<br />

misled by Lazard's Fairness Opinion, which does not take<br />

this into account. The Director Defendants <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz<br />

argue that <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts provided value for Delphi.<br />

The record regarding <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts remains largely<br />

undeveloped at this stage; such evidence as exists warrants<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r consideration, but it is insufficient to convince me<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs are likely to be able to demonstrate at trial<br />

that <strong>the</strong> existence of Acorn <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts depressed<br />

Delphi's stock price.<br />

2. Challenges to <strong>the</strong> Negotiations with Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Sub–Committee's Approval of Disparate Consideration<br />

The Plaintiffs' most persuasive argument, based on <strong>the</strong><br />

preliminary record before me, is that despite a contrary<br />

provision in <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter, Rosenkranz, in breach of<br />

his contractual <strong>and</strong> fiduciary duties, sought <strong>and</strong> obtained a<br />

control premium for his shares, an effort that was facilitated<br />

by <strong>the</strong> Executive <strong>and</strong> Director Defendants. As discussed<br />

above, Delphi's Charter contains two classes of stock: Class<br />

A, entitled to one vote per share, <strong>and</strong> Class B, entitled to ten<br />

votes per share. Rosenkranz holds all of <strong>the</strong> Class B shares;<br />

thus, even though he only owns 12.9% of Delphi's equity,<br />

he controls 49.9% of <strong>the</strong> stockholders' voting power. As a<br />

result, Rosenkranz can effectively block any merger or similar<br />

transaction that is not to his liking.<br />

*15 Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter contains certain<br />

restrictions on Rosenkranz's power. Though Rosenkranz<br />

can act as a controlling stockholder, <strong>the</strong> Charter provides<br />

that, in a merger, <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Class<br />

B stockholders must be treated equally. Additionally, if<br />

Rosenkranz attempts to transfer his Class B stock to anyone<br />

besides an affiliate of his, <strong>the</strong> Class B stock converts<br />

into Class A stock. The Merger here is conditioned, at<br />

Rosenkranz's insistence, on a Charter Amendment removing<br />

<strong>the</strong> requirement of equal distribution of merger consideration.<br />

Once <strong>the</strong> Charter is amended, Rosenkranz can receive a<br />

higher payment for his shares than <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> same time <strong>the</strong> disinterested Sub–Committee negotiated<br />

<strong>the</strong>se provisions with Rosenkranz, Rosenkranz took <strong>the</strong> lead<br />

in <strong>the</strong> negotiations with TMH, despite this apparent conflict<br />

with Delphi's public stockholders.<br />

Rosenkranz, in taking Delphi public, created, via <strong>the</strong><br />

Charter, a mechanism whereby he retained voting control<br />

of Delphi as <strong>the</strong> holder of <strong>the</strong> high-vote Class B stock. As<br />

Rosenkranz points out, a controlling stockholder is, with<br />

limited exceptions, entitled under Delaware law to negotiate<br />

a control premium for its shares. 63 Moreover, a controlling<br />

stockholder is free to consider its interests alone in weighing<br />

<strong>the</strong> decision to sell its shares or, having made such a decision,<br />

evaluating <strong>the</strong> adequacy of a given price. 64 Rosenkranz<br />

contends that as a stockholder he has <strong>the</strong> right to control <strong>and</strong><br />

vote his shares in his best interest, which generally includes<br />

<strong>the</strong> right to sell a controlling share for a premium at <strong>the</strong><br />

expense of <strong>the</strong> minority stockholders.<br />

The Plaintiffs argue that by including a provision in Delphi's<br />

Charter providing that Class B stockholders would accept <strong>the</strong><br />

same consideration as Class A stockholders in <strong>the</strong> case of<br />

a sale, Rosenkranz gave up his right to a control premium.<br />

They argue that by approving a merger conditioned on<br />

<strong>the</strong> Charter Amendment, which restores Rosenkranz's right<br />

to obtain disparate consideration for his shares, <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

<strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz are coercing <strong>the</strong> stockholders into choosing<br />

between approving <strong>the</strong> Merger at <strong>the</strong> cost of a substantial<br />

premium to Rosenkranz or voting against <strong>the</strong> Merger <strong>and</strong><br />

forgoing an o<strong>the</strong>rwise attractive deal (that could never<strong>the</strong>less<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 11


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

be more attractive sans <strong>the</strong> Rosenkranz premium). The<br />

Plaintiffs allege that <strong>the</strong> Charter Amendment is coercive<br />

because in order to realize <strong>the</strong> benefits of <strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders must induce Rosenkranz's consent by repealing<br />

a Charter provision that exists to protect <strong>the</strong>m from exactly<br />

this situation. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs contend that<br />

although Rosenkranz may sell his stock generally free of<br />

fiduciary concerns for <strong>the</strong> minority stockholders, he may not<br />

do so in a way that coerces <strong>the</strong> stockholders' concession of a<br />

right guaranteed under <strong>the</strong> Charter.<br />

Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board counter that <strong>the</strong> Charter<br />

specifically provides for amendment. The Director<br />

Defendants also argue that, notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>the</strong> Charter<br />

provision requiring <strong>the</strong> equal distribution of consideration to<br />

Class A <strong>and</strong> Class B stockholders in <strong>the</strong> event of a sale, <strong>the</strong><br />

sale to TMH involves a substantial premium over market<br />

<strong>and</strong> is a compelling transaction—one which <strong>the</strong> stockholders<br />

ought to have <strong>the</strong> opportunity to accept, even if <strong>the</strong>y must<br />

also approve <strong>the</strong> Charter Amendment to consummate <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. 65 The Director Defendants state:<br />

*16 [I]f stockholders like <strong>the</strong> transaction, <strong>the</strong>y will<br />

support <strong>the</strong> Certificate Amendment, <strong>and</strong> if <strong>the</strong>y don't<br />

like <strong>the</strong> transaction, <strong>the</strong>y won't. Amazingly, <strong>the</strong> supposed<br />

source of “coercion” is that <strong>the</strong> price being offered<br />

by [TMH] is so high that stockholders might actually<br />

want to accept it. By this definition, every good deal is<br />

“coercive.” 66<br />

The argument of <strong>the</strong> Director Defendants <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz<br />

reduces to this syllogism: Rosenkranz, in taking Delphi public<br />

in 1990, retained control. Notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing his retention of<br />

control, he gave up, through Section 7 of <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter,<br />

<strong>the</strong> right to receive a control premium. Consistent with<br />

Delaware law, 67 however, <strong>the</strong> Charter provided for its own<br />

amendment by majority vote of <strong>the</strong> stockholders. Thus,<br />

since Rosenkranz is, as a controlling stockholder, generally<br />

unconstrained by fiduciary duties when deciding whe<strong>the</strong>r to<br />

sell his stock, he is permitted to condition his approval of<br />

a sale on both a restoration of his right to receive a control<br />

premium <strong>and</strong> on actually receiving such a premium. I find this<br />

argument unpersuasive.<br />

Section 7 of <strong>the</strong> Charter gives <strong>the</strong> stockholders <strong>the</strong> right to<br />

receive <strong>the</strong> same consideration, in a merger, as received by<br />

Rosenkranz. I assume that <strong>the</strong> stockholders, in return for <strong>the</strong><br />

protection against differential merger consideration found in<br />

<strong>the</strong> Charter, paid a higher price for <strong>the</strong>ir shares. 68 In o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

words, though Rosenkranz retained voting control, he sold<br />

his right to a control premium to <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders<br />

via <strong>the</strong> Charter. The Charter provision, which prevents<br />

disparate consideration, exists so that if a merger is proposed,<br />

Rosenkranz cannot extract a second control premium for<br />

himself at <strong>the</strong> expense of <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders.<br />

Of course, <strong>the</strong> Charter provided for its own amendment.<br />

Presumably, Rosenkranz, clear of any impending sale, could<br />

have purchased <strong>the</strong> right to a control premium back from<br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholders through a negotiated vote in favor of a<br />

charter amendment. But to accept Rosenkranz's argument<br />

<strong>and</strong> to allow him to coerce such an amendment here would<br />

be to render <strong>the</strong> Charter rights illusory <strong>and</strong> would permit<br />

Rosenkranz, who benefited by selling his control premium<br />

to <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders at Delphi's IPO, to sell <strong>the</strong> same<br />

control premium again in connection with this Merger. That<br />

would amount to a wrongful transfer of merger consideration<br />

from <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders to Rosenkranz.<br />

What would have happened if Rosenkranz had respected <strong>the</strong><br />

Charter provision? He would still have had voting control. He<br />

may have insisted that no merger occur without consideration<br />

for all shares of at least $53.875, which likely would have<br />

killed <strong>the</strong> deal <strong>and</strong> restored <strong>the</strong> status quo. 69 Or, without<br />

his steadfast belief that he was entitled to a differential,<br />

Rosenkranz may have agreed to a deal for all shares at<br />

$46, representing as it does a substantial premium over<br />

market. Because Rosenkranz sought instead to exact a control<br />

premium he had already bargained away, <strong>the</strong> answer to <strong>the</strong><br />

question posed above is unknowable.<br />

*17 Our Supreme Court has stated that a corporate charter,<br />

along with its accompanying bylaws, is a contract between<br />

<strong>the</strong> corporation's stockholders. 70 Inherent in any contractual<br />

relationship is <strong>the</strong> implied covenant of good faith <strong>and</strong><br />

fair dealing. 71 This implied covenant “embodies <strong>the</strong> law's<br />

expectation that each party to a contract will act with good<br />

faith toward <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r with respect to <strong>the</strong> subject matter of<br />

<strong>the</strong> contract.” 72 A party breaches <strong>the</strong> covenant “by taking<br />

advantage of [its] position to control implementation of <strong>the</strong><br />

agreement's terms,” such that “[its] conduct frustrates <strong>the</strong><br />

‘overarching purpose’ of <strong>the</strong> contract.” 73<br />

The Plaintiffs argue that Rosenkranz has breached <strong>the</strong> implied<br />

covenant of good faith <strong>and</strong> fair dealing. They assert that <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders, <strong>the</strong>refore, have a remedy for breach of contract<br />

as well as fiduciary duty. They point out that, following <strong>the</strong><br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 12


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

Defendants' logic, <strong>the</strong> existence of <strong>the</strong> amendment procedure<br />

rendered <strong>the</strong> provision m<strong>and</strong>ating equal price on sale for <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A <strong>and</strong> B shares a sham, since Rosenkranz retained <strong>the</strong><br />

ability to coerce a charter amendment, <strong>and</strong> thus a control<br />

premium, in connection with any favorable merger offer.<br />

Implicit in <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' argument is that, had <strong>the</strong> purchasers<br />

of Delphi's public stock realized this, <strong>the</strong>y may not have<br />

purchased <strong>the</strong> stock, at least at <strong>the</strong> price paid.<br />

I need not decide at this preliminary stage whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> rights<br />

of <strong>the</strong> stockholder class here sound in breach of contract<br />

as well as breach of fiduciary duty. It suffices that I find<br />

on <strong>the</strong> present record that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs bought Delphi's<br />

stock with <strong>the</strong> underst<strong>and</strong>ing that <strong>the</strong> Charter structured<br />

<strong>the</strong> corporation in such a way that denied Rosenkranz a<br />

control premium, <strong>and</strong> that as a result, Rosenkranz effectively<br />

extracted a control premium from <strong>the</strong> initial sale of <strong>the</strong> Class<br />

A shares, while at <strong>the</strong> same time retaining his voting majority.<br />

I <strong>the</strong>refore find that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs are reasonably likely to be<br />

able to demonstrate at trial that in negotiating for disparate<br />

consideration <strong>and</strong> only agreeing to support <strong>the</strong> merger if he<br />

received it, Rosenkranz violated duties to <strong>the</strong> stockholders.<br />

Next, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs argue that Rosenkranz's attempts to<br />

preserve <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts after <strong>the</strong> Merger will result in<br />

a form of disparate consideration that would contravene <strong>the</strong><br />

Charter, to <strong>the</strong> detriment of <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders. As<br />

described below, <strong>the</strong> process by which Rosenkranz negotiated<br />

both as a fiduciary for Delphi <strong>and</strong>, at <strong>the</strong> same time, for<br />

himself as a controlling stockholder, is troubling. I note,<br />

however, that <strong>the</strong>se contracts can be canceled at thirty days'<br />

notice. Despite <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' arguments to <strong>the</strong> contrary,<br />

TMH has little incentive to pay more to Rosenkranz than<br />

<strong>the</strong> actual value of Acorn's services to TMH: Rosenkranz<br />

is contractually obligated to vote in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

per a voting agreement, thus obviating any reason for TMH<br />

to induce Rosenkranz's support through overpayment for<br />

Acorn's services. Therefore, despite Rosenkranz's potential<br />

conflict in negotiating both for Delphi <strong>and</strong> for Acorn, I do<br />

not find that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs have demonstrated a reasonable<br />

probability that a post-Merger contract involving RAM or<br />

Acorn will net Rosenkranz any disparate consideration in<br />

violation of Delphi's Charter.<br />

information relating to RAM <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz's consulting<br />

agreements, Macquarie's advisory relationship with Delphi,<br />

<strong>the</strong> sales process generally, Lazard's Fairness Opinion, <strong>and</strong><br />

cash bonuses reserved for <strong>the</strong> Executive Defendants. This<br />

information is of <strong>the</strong> “tell me more” variety, <strong>and</strong> given<br />

<strong>the</strong> quantity <strong>and</strong> quality of <strong>the</strong> disclosure provided in <strong>the</strong><br />

Definitive February 2012 Proxy, I find that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs are<br />

unlikely to succeed on <strong>the</strong> merits of <strong>the</strong>ir claims alleging<br />

disclosure violations.<br />

When a board seeks stockholder action, such as a vote on a<br />

proposed merger, <strong>the</strong> board has a “fiduciary duty to disclose<br />

fully <strong>and</strong> fairly all material information within <strong>the</strong> board's<br />

control.” 74 For an alleged omission or misrepresentation to<br />

constitute a breach of fiduciary duty, it must be substantially<br />

likely that “a reasonable shareholder would consider it<br />

important in deciding how to vote.” 75 This st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

contemplates a showing by <strong>the</strong> plaintiff that, “under all <strong>the</strong><br />

circumstances, <strong>the</strong> omitted [or misrepresented] fact would<br />

have assumed actual significance in <strong>the</strong> deliberations of<br />

a reasonable shareholder.” 76 Such is <strong>the</strong> case when <strong>the</strong><br />

information, if properly disclosed, “would have been viewed<br />

by a reasonable investor as having significantly altered <strong>the</strong><br />

total mix of information made available.” 77 In limiting<br />

<strong>the</strong> disclosure requirement to all “material” information,<br />

Delaware law recognizes that too much disclosure can be<br />

a bad thing. As this Court has repeatedly recognized, “a<br />

reasonable line has to be drawn or else disclosures in proxy<br />

solicitations will become so detailed <strong>and</strong> voluminous that <strong>the</strong>y<br />

will no longer serve <strong>the</strong>ir purpose.” 78 If anything, Delphi's<br />

Proxy is guilty of such informational bloatedness, <strong>and</strong> not, as<br />

<strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs contend, insufficient disclosure.<br />

The Plaintiffs, in any event, did not raise any disclosure issues<br />

at oral argument on <strong>the</strong>ir Motion for Preliminary Injunction,<br />

perhaps because <strong>the</strong> violations <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs allege are, at<br />

best, marginal. The February 2012 Proxy discloses in prolix<br />

fashion details of <strong>the</strong> Merger negotiations <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> process<br />

executed by <strong>the</strong> Board, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sub–<br />

Committee, warts <strong>and</strong> all. If disclosure is <strong>the</strong> best disinfectant,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Proxy is Clorox. As a result, I find little merit in <strong>the</strong><br />

allegations of disclosure violations.<br />

3. Alleged Disclosure Violations<br />

*18 The Plaintiffs allege that <strong>the</strong> Board has breached its<br />

fiduciary duty of disclosure through a series of material<br />

omissions in Delphi's February 2012 Proxy (<strong>the</strong> “Proxy”).<br />

The Plaintiffs contend that <strong>the</strong> Proxy fails to disclose<br />

B. Irreparable Harm <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Balance of <strong>the</strong> Equities<br />

A preliminary injunction is an “extraordinary remedy ... [<strong>and</strong>]<br />

is granted sparingly <strong>and</strong> only upon a persuasive showing that<br />

it is urgently necessary, that it will result in comparatively<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 13


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

less harm to <strong>the</strong> adverse party, <strong>and</strong> that, in <strong>the</strong> end, it is<br />

unlikely to be shown to have been issued improvidently.” 79<br />

To demonstrate irreparable harm, a plaintiff must show harm<br />

“of such a nature that no fair <strong>and</strong> reasonable redress may<br />

be had in a court of law <strong>and</strong> must show that to refuse <strong>the</strong><br />

injunction would be a denial of justice.” 80 A harm that can<br />

be remedied by money damages is not irreparable. 81<br />

*19 Additionally, in <strong>the</strong> context of a single-bidder merger,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Court when balancing <strong>the</strong> equities must be cognizant that<br />

if <strong>the</strong> merger is enjoined, <strong>the</strong> deal may be lost forever, a<br />

concern of particular gravity where, as here, <strong>the</strong> proposed deal<br />

offers a substantial premium over market price. In evaluating<br />

<strong>the</strong> appropriateness of enjoining a given merger, this Court<br />

has noted <strong>the</strong> difference between a single bidder situation<br />

<strong>and</strong> a situation where <strong>the</strong>re exists a competing, potentially<br />

superior, rival bid. 82<br />

This Court recently addressed a situation similar to <strong>the</strong> present<br />

action in In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>. 83<br />

In that case, <strong>the</strong> Chancellor identified numerous “debatable<br />

negotiating <strong>and</strong> tactical choices made by El Paso fiduciaries<br />

<strong>and</strong> advisors,” which were compounded by a lead negotiator<br />

<strong>and</strong> financial advisor with interests in conflict with those of<br />

<strong>the</strong> El Paso stockholders. 84 The proposed transaction offered<br />

a premium of 37% over El Paso's stock price, however,<br />

<strong>and</strong> was <strong>the</strong> only bid on <strong>the</strong> table. 85 The Chancellor,<br />

though troubled by <strong>the</strong> conduct of <strong>the</strong> El Paso fiduciaries<br />

<strong>and</strong> advisors, declined to enjoin <strong>the</strong> merger, finding that<br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholders were “well positioned to turn down <strong>the</strong><br />

[offeror's] price if <strong>the</strong>y [did] not like it,” noting that while<br />

damages were not a perfect remedy, <strong>the</strong> “stockholders should<br />

not be deprived of <strong>the</strong> chance to decide for <strong>the</strong>mselves about<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger.” 86<br />

Here, <strong>the</strong> 76% premium offered by TMH dwarfs <strong>the</strong> premium<br />

percentage in El Paso. Moreover, although I have found it<br />

reasonably likely that Rosenkranz violated a duty in his role<br />

as lead negotiator, his interests were at least in some respects<br />

aligned with those of <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders. 87 Given<br />

<strong>the</strong>se considerations, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that, as explained below,<br />

money damages can largely remedy <strong>the</strong> threatened harm, <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders' potential loss of a substantial premium on <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

shares outweighs <strong>the</strong> value of an injunction; <strong>the</strong>refore, I must<br />

deny <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' request for injunctive relief.<br />

Much of <strong>the</strong> alleged misconduct of which <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs<br />

complain is remediable by readily ascertainable damages.<br />

The Plaintiffs argue that <strong>the</strong> differential consideration<br />

negotiated between Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee is<br />

improper. If so, I may order disgorgement of <strong>the</strong> improper<br />

consideration. 88 The Plaintiffs allege that any post-Merger<br />

contract between RAM/Acorn <strong>and</strong> TMH would constitute<br />

additional merger consideration flowing to Rosenkranz, when<br />

such consideration rightly belongs to all of <strong>the</strong> stockholders.<br />

If so, such an amount would be recoverable in damages as<br />

well. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, if <strong>the</strong>se factors constitute harm to <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A stockholders, it is not irreparable harm.<br />

The Plaintiffs' allegations regarding past losses to <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> arising from Rosenkranz's operation of Acorn<br />

are more problematic. As described above, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs<br />

argue that Acorn, operated with borrowed Delphi employees,<br />

facilities, <strong>and</strong> resources, was a sham; that <strong>the</strong> investment<br />

advice it sold to Delphi under <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts could<br />

have been produced “in house” for a fraction of what Delphi<br />

paid for it; <strong>and</strong> that its third-party business was a corporate<br />

opportunity belonging to Delphi <strong>and</strong> usurped by Rosenkranz.<br />

According to <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs, this activity depressed Delphi's<br />

stock price, causing <strong>the</strong> Lazard Fairness Opinion to be of<br />

limited value, since Delphi was worth more than <strong>the</strong> analysis<br />

assumed. Stockholders, under this <strong>the</strong>ory, may be misled by<br />

<strong>the</strong> fairness opinion, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> recommendation of <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

based on that opinion, when choosing whe<strong>the</strong>r to vote for <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs argue, TMH may have been<br />

willing to pay more for a Delphi unencumbered by <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts, in an amount unknowable <strong>and</strong> thus irremediable<br />

by damages, <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz may have been willing to forgo<br />

<strong>the</strong> highest merger price in favor of maximizing <strong>the</strong> value<br />

available in <strong>the</strong> negotiations of <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts.<br />

*20 While <strong>the</strong> concerns above appear irreparable absent an<br />

injunction, I give <strong>the</strong> possibility of such harm little weight.<br />

First, it seems unlikely that TMH will feel itself significantly<br />

encumbered, let alone bound, by contracts terminable upon<br />

thirty days' notice with a sham entity returning no actual value<br />

to Delphi or TMH. 89 It is clear from <strong>the</strong> record that TMH<br />

has no legal obligation to keep such contracts in place, <strong>and</strong><br />

thus it is unlikely that <strong>the</strong> existence of <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts has<br />

depressed <strong>the</strong> price TMH is willing to pay for Delphi.<br />

Similarly, <strong>the</strong> risk that <strong>the</strong> stockholders will be misled by<br />

Lazard's Fairness Opinion because Delphi's stock price was<br />

depressed due to <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts is only speculative.<br />

The record is insufficient to demonstrate that those contracts,<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 14


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

in place since Delphi's IPO <strong>and</strong> disclosed continuously<br />

<strong>the</strong>reafter, were wrongful, <strong>and</strong> if so, to what extent <strong>the</strong>y may<br />

have affected Delphi's stock price, if at all. To <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>the</strong>y<br />

have, <strong>the</strong>y have similarly decreased <strong>the</strong> price each stockholder<br />

paid for his shares. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> existence of <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts, <strong>the</strong> Board's concern that negotiations over those<br />

contracts between Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> TMH might have involved<br />

hidden additional compensation for Rosenkranz, as well as<br />

<strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r circumstances I have set out above, are all disclosed<br />

in <strong>the</strong> February 2012 Proxy available to each stockholder.<br />

In that vein, I also find that <strong>the</strong> alleged disclosure violations<br />

provide no basis for injunctive relief. The February 2012<br />

Proxy fully informs <strong>the</strong> stockholders about <strong>the</strong> concerns<br />

detailed above. With respect to <strong>the</strong> differential consideration,<br />

which I view as <strong>the</strong> issue raised by Plaintiffs most likely<br />

to be successful, any recovery in damages will be on top<br />

of <strong>the</strong> amount at which <strong>the</strong> stockholders are being asked to<br />

tender <strong>the</strong>ir shares. In light of all <strong>the</strong> issues raised above, <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders have a fair if not perfect ability to decide whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

to tender <strong>the</strong>ir shares or seek appraisal rights under 8 Del. C.<br />

§ 262.<br />

I find <strong>the</strong> opportunity to exercise that franchise particularly<br />

important here. The price offered by TMH for <strong>the</strong> Class A<br />

shares, even though less than what Rosenkranz will receive<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Merger, is 76% above Delphi's stock price on <strong>the</strong><br />

day before <strong>the</strong> Merger was announced. 90 No party has<br />

suggested that ano<strong>the</strong>r suitor is in <strong>the</strong> wings or is likely<br />

to be developed at a greater, or even equal, price. Nothing<br />

beyond <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' speculation about <strong>the</strong> effects of <strong>the</strong><br />

Acorn business <strong>and</strong> RAM Contracts indicates that injunctive<br />

relief would lead to negotiation of a significant increase in<br />

price. In fact, it seems at least as likely that a renegotiated<br />

deal may yield a lower price, or a loss of <strong>the</strong> Merger entirely<br />

<strong>and</strong> a return to <strong>the</strong> status quo ante, including regarding stock<br />

price. Having determined that a judicial intervention at this<br />

point is unlikely to prove a net benefit to <strong>the</strong> plaintiff class,<br />

<strong>and</strong> may cause substantial harm, it is preferable to allow <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders to decide whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y wish to go forward with<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger despite <strong>the</strong> imperfections of <strong>the</strong> process leading<br />

to its formulation.<br />

*21 The Plaintiffs make a final argument that injunctive<br />

relief must be afforded here, based upon <strong>the</strong> deterrent effect<br />

of an injunction: <strong>the</strong>y argue that if I decide that <strong>the</strong> proffered<br />

deal is “good enough” to cause this Court to deny injunctive<br />

relief despite <strong>the</strong> wrongful differential <strong>the</strong>y see Rosenkranz<br />

as extorting from <strong>the</strong> stockholders, I will be, to paraphrase<br />

Chairman Mao, letting a thous<strong>and</strong> little Rosenkranzes bloom.<br />

It is obvious to me, however, that <strong>the</strong> available damages<br />

remedies, particularly in this case where damages may be<br />

easily calculated, will serve as a sufficient deterrent for <strong>the</strong><br />

behavior <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs allege here.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

Robert Rosenkranz founded Delphi, built its value, <strong>and</strong><br />

took <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> public. The complaints about <strong>the</strong> RAM<br />

Contracts notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs concede that, as a<br />

public company, Delphi has been well-run by Rosenkranz<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board. Having built Delphi, <strong>and</strong> having retained<br />

control of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> throughout, Rosenkranz clearly feels<br />

morally entitled to a premium for his stock. The Plaintiffs<br />

have demonstrated a reasonable likelihood that <strong>the</strong>y will be<br />

able to prove at trial that Rosenkranz is not so entitled,<br />

however.<br />

None<strong>the</strong>less, given that <strong>the</strong> meritorious allegations discussed<br />

above are remediable by damages, I find it in <strong>the</strong> best interests<br />

of <strong>the</strong> stockholders that <strong>the</strong>y be given <strong>the</strong> opportunity to<br />

decide for <strong>the</strong>mselves whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> Merger negotiated by<br />

Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Director Defendants offers an acceptable<br />

price for <strong>the</strong>ir shares. For <strong>the</strong> foregoing reasons, <strong>the</strong> Motion<br />

for Preliminary Injunction is denied.<br />

IT IS SO ORDERED.<br />

Footnotes<br />

1 The latter amount includes a $1 special dividend agreed to by TMH to be paid around <strong>the</strong> closing of <strong>the</strong> merger.<br />

2 I lay out below an abstraction of <strong>the</strong> events surrounding <strong>the</strong> negotiation <strong>and</strong> signing of <strong>the</strong> Delphi/TMH merger with <strong>the</strong> knowledge<br />

that <strong>the</strong> evidentiary record is at this point limited. Though <strong>the</strong> parties contest many of <strong>the</strong> facts, particularly those surrounding <strong>the</strong><br />

negotiation of Rosenkranz's differential consideration, those factual disputes do not affect my decision on <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' request for<br />

injunctive relief.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 15


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

3 Aside from comments made in passing in <strong>the</strong>ir Opening Brief, <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs have not challenged <strong>the</strong> independence of <strong>the</strong>se directors.<br />

Moreover, it appears unlikely to me that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' will be able to successfully challenge <strong>the</strong>se directors' independence upon a full<br />

evidentiary record. In any event, this issue is immaterial to my basis for denying <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' motion. See infra note 57. I recognize,<br />

however, that <strong>the</strong> issue remains open for trial.<br />

4 For clarity, references to <strong>the</strong> “Director Defendants” do not include Rosenkranz (who is a director), unless o<strong>the</strong>rwise stated.<br />

5 I note that both Sherman <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz are directors as well as officers; however, I include <strong>the</strong>m only under <strong>the</strong> label “Executive<br />

Defendants” to differentiate <strong>the</strong>ir roles in this action from those of <strong>the</strong> non-officer directors.<br />

6 Pl.'s Opening Br. Supp. Mot. Prelim. Inj. (“POB”) app. Ex. 1, Restated Certificate of Incorporation of Delphi Financial Group, Inc.<br />

[hereinafter “Delphi Charter”].<br />

7 Delphi Charter §§ A(3), A(4)(b).<br />

8 Delphi Charter § 7. Section 7 excludes from this equal distribution requirement certain dividend <strong>and</strong> liquidation payments that are<br />

not relevant here.<br />

9 Robert Rosenkranz Dep. 18:19–19:8 (Feb. 10, 2012).<br />

10 Id. at 20:22–24, 31:22–24.<br />

11 Id. at 24:11–17.<br />

12 See Delphi Defs.' Answering Br. (“DDAB”) Ex. 11, Delphi Fin. Group, Inc., Definitive Proxy Statement (Schedule 14A), at 111<br />

(Feb. 21, 2012) (“Pursuant to an expense allocation agreement, a subsidiary of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> received periodic payments from RAM,<br />

Acorn <strong>and</strong> various o<strong>the</strong>r entities in which Mr. Rosenkranz has personal financial interests in respect of expenses associated with<br />

certain shared office space, facilities <strong>and</strong> personnel.”).<br />

13 Rosenkranz Dep. 35:1–36:19.<br />

14 In <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' version of <strong>the</strong>se events, Rosenkranz scheduled <strong>the</strong> meeting with TMH during <strong>the</strong> initial phone call with MacQuarie,<br />

ra<strong>the</strong>r than sometime <strong>the</strong>reafter, thus setting up <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs' argument that Rosenkranz waited weeks before informing Delphi's<br />

Board of <strong>the</strong> meeting <strong>and</strong> implying that Rosenkranz intended to keep <strong>the</strong> Board in <strong>the</strong> dark until it was too late for it to have any<br />

input. See POB at 13. Although Plaintiffs' counsel's recounting of <strong>the</strong>se initial phone calls certainly fits <strong>the</strong>ir preferred narrative of<br />

a merger negotiation dominated from <strong>the</strong> outset by an autarchic controller, it is not supported by <strong>the</strong> current record. See Rosenkranz<br />

Dep. 212:9–15 (“I don't think <strong>the</strong> meeting was set up on July 20th, but somewhere in <strong>the</strong> interim [between Anderson's initial phone<br />

call <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> August 3rd board meeting] it was set up.”); James M. Anderson Dep. 72:17–23 (Feb. 9, 2012) (“[Rosenkranz's] initial<br />

reaction was that Delphi was not for sale, but he would think about it <strong>and</strong> call me back.”).<br />

15 The Plaintiffs contend that while <strong>the</strong> Board authorized preliminary negotiations at its August 3, 2011, meeting, it did not in fact<br />

authorize <strong>the</strong> Executive Defendants to engage in price negotiations. At this stage of <strong>the</strong> proceedings, <strong>the</strong> evidence in <strong>the</strong> record is<br />

insufficient to allow me to make such a finding. Regardless, this issue of fact is immaterial to my decision here on <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs'<br />

request for a preliminary injunction.<br />

16 Rosenkranz Dep. 95:23–97:23.<br />

17 Id. at 126:11–17; 320:18–321:3.<br />

18 Ian Brimecome Dep. 38:17–39:21 (Feb. 8, 2012).<br />

19 Rosenkranz Dep. 226:6–227:12.<br />

20 DDAB Ex. 15, at DELPHI00000289–90.<br />

21 Id. at DELPHI00000290.<br />

22 Id. at DELPHI00000293.<br />

23 Id. Ex. 3, Delphi Fin. Group, Definitive Proxy Statement (Schedule 14A), at 2 (Apr. 14, 2011).<br />

24 Id. Ex. 17, at DELPHI0000854.<br />

25 Id. at DELPHI0000854–88.<br />

26 See id. Ex. 20, at DELPHI00000295–300.<br />

27 See id. Ex. 18, at DEL_SCP00000001–09.<br />

28 See id. Ex. 21, at DEL_SCP00000012–87.<br />

29 See id. Ex. 22, at DEL_SCP00000092–94.<br />

30 See id. Ex. 28, at DEL_SCP00000090.<br />

31 See, e.g., id. Ex. 22, at DEL_SCP00000092–94 (“[Lazard's representative] ... discussed with <strong>the</strong> directors that differential<br />

consideration transactions were highly unusual.... [Lazard <strong>and</strong> Cravath's representatives] also discussed with members of <strong>the</strong> Sub–<br />

Committee <strong>the</strong> precedent transactions that involved differential consideration, including a detailed discussion of ... <strong>the</strong> ensuing<br />

litigation.... The Sub–Committee <strong>the</strong>n determined that Mr. Fox would initially engage with Mr. Rosenkranz <strong>and</strong> urge Mr. Rosenkranz<br />

to accept <strong>the</strong> same consideration as <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders.”); see also generally id. Exs. 23, 25–26, 28 (containing <strong>the</strong> board minutes<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 16


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

describing fur<strong>the</strong>r advice rendered to <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee <strong>and</strong> Special Committee by Cravath <strong>and</strong> Lazard); id. Ex. 31 (discussing<br />

conversations between Fox <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz regarding differential consideration).<br />

32 See id. at DEL_SCP00000104–05.<br />

33 See id. Ex. 34, at DEL_SCP00000114.<br />

34 See id. Ex. 22, at DEL_SCP00000093; id. Ex. 25, at DEL_ SCP00000139–40.<br />

35 Like Hamlet, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee appeared to trust Rosenkranz as it would an adder fanged. See WILLIAM SHAKESPEARE,<br />

HAMLET act 3, sc. 4., at 76 (Stanley Appelbaum & Shane Weller eds., Dover Publ'ns 1992) (“There's letters seal'd, <strong>and</strong> my two<br />

schoolfellows, / Whom I trust as I will adders fang'd, / They bear <strong>the</strong> m<strong>and</strong>ate. They must sweep my way / And marshal me to<br />

knavery.”).<br />

36 See DDAB Ex. 25, at DEL_SCP00000139–40.<br />

37 See id. Ex. 13, at DEL_SCP00000141.<br />

38 See id. Ex. 26, at DEL_SCP00000143.<br />

39 See id. at DEL_SCP00000143–44.<br />

40 These amounts include <strong>the</strong> $1 special dividend.<br />

41 See generally ELISABETH KÜBLER–ROSS, ON DEATH AND DYING 51–146 (Scribner 1997) (1969) (discussing <strong>the</strong> Kübler–<br />

Ross Model, or as it is commonly known, <strong>the</strong> Five Stages of Grief).<br />

42 See DDAB Ex. 38, at DEL_SCP00000165 (“Mr. Rosenkranz <strong>the</strong>n became extremely upset <strong>and</strong> angry <strong>and</strong> had stated that he could<br />

not underst<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> legal basis for <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee's dem<strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders receive $45.25 per share.”).<br />

43 See id. Ex. 37, at DEL_SCP00000155 (“Mr. Rosenkranz <strong>the</strong>n proposed to Mr. Fox that <strong>the</strong> Class A stockholders receive approximately<br />

$44.75 per share <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Class B stockholders receive approximately $54.81 per share.”).<br />

44 See id. Ex. 40, at DEL_SCP00000182 (“Mr. Rosenkranz sounded depressed” <strong>and</strong> told Fox that he “could not believe that <strong>the</strong> Sub–<br />

Committee was willing to threaten <strong>the</strong> deal <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> negotiation process had to be this financially painful for him.” Rosenkranz<br />

also told Fox that “he felt beaten up <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> Sub–Committee had h<strong>and</strong>led him harshly.”).<br />

45 See id. at DEL_SCP00000182 (discussing a phone call between Fox <strong>and</strong> Rosenkranz where Fox reduced his initial dem<strong>and</strong> of $45<br />

to $44.875, to which Rosenkranz responded “that he could live with such a transaction”).<br />

46 See id. Ex. 42, at DEL_SCP00000255–57.<br />

47 See id. Ex. 52, at DEL_SCP00000536.<br />

48 See id. Ex. 45, at DEL_SCP00000392–94.<br />

49 See id. Ex. 58, at DEL_SCP00000396.<br />

50 See id. Ex. 49, Delphi Fin. Group, Inc., Current Report (Form 8–K), Ex. 2.1 at 32 (Dec. 21, 2011).<br />

51 See id. Ex. 61.<br />

52 The unadjusted closing price of Delphi's publicly traded stock on December 20, 2011, <strong>the</strong> day before <strong>the</strong> merger was announced, was<br />

$25.43. See Yahoo! Finance, Delphi Financial Group Inc. Co. Historical Prices, http://finance.yahoo.com/q/hp?s=DFG (last visited<br />

Mar. 5, 2012). The consideration of $44.875 per Class A share offered by <strong>the</strong> Merger thus represents a 76% premium over market<br />

price.<br />

53 DDAB Ex. 67.<br />

54 See id. Ex. 11, Delphi Fin. Group, Inc., Definitive Proxy Statement (Schedule 14A), at 72–74 (Feb. 21, 2012).<br />

55 Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 179 (Del.1986).<br />

56 I need not at this stage of <strong>the</strong> proceedings address whe<strong>the</strong>r THM aided <strong>and</strong> abetted <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r Defendants' alleged misconduct.<br />

57 For <strong>the</strong> purposes of this Motion only, I assume, as <strong>the</strong> Director Defendants did, see DDAB at 47, that <strong>the</strong> entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

of review applies to <strong>the</strong> approval of <strong>the</strong> disparate Merger consideration. Under In re John Q. Hammons Hotels, Inc. Shareholder<br />

<strong>Litigation</strong>, 2009 WL 3165613 (Del. Ch. Oct. 2, 2009), this Court reviews transactions where a controlling stockholder st<strong>and</strong>s on one<br />

side under entire fairness unless (1) a disinterested, independent, <strong>and</strong> sufficiently empowered special committee recommends <strong>the</strong><br />

transaction to <strong>the</strong> board <strong>and</strong> (2) <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong> minority stockholders approve <strong>the</strong> transaction in a non-waivable vote. Id. at *12.<br />

“Threats, coercion, or fraud” on <strong>the</strong> part of <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder, however, may nullify ei<strong>the</strong>r procedural protection. Id. at *12<br />

n. 38. With <strong>the</strong> Hammons rule thusly framed, I never<strong>the</strong>less make no finding on <strong>the</strong> satisfaction of <strong>the</strong> relevant procedural protections,<br />

as I find that <strong>the</strong> Plaintiffs are reasonably likely to prove at trial that, per <strong>the</strong> obligations created by <strong>the</strong> Delphi Charter <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Director<br />

<strong>and</strong> Executive Defendants' duties to uphold <strong>the</strong>m, Rosenkranz was not entitled to differential consideration in any amount. Such a<br />

finding at trial would, of course, eliminate <strong>the</strong> need to determine whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> disparity in Merger consideration was “fair.”<br />

58 See Unitrin, Inc. v. Am. Gen. Corp., 651 A.2d 1361, 1371 (Del.1995); Revlon, 506 A.2d at 179.<br />

59 In re Netsmart Techs., Inc. S'holders Litig., 924 A.2d 171, 192 (Del. Ch.2007) (citing Revlon, 506 A.2d at 184); see also Paramount<br />

Commc'ns, Inc. v. QVC Network, Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 44 (Del.1994) (“In <strong>the</strong> sale of control context, <strong>the</strong> directors must focus on<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 17


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

one primary objective—to secure <strong>the</strong> transaction offering <strong>the</strong> best value reasonably available for <strong>the</strong> stockholders—<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>y must<br />

exercise <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary duties to fur<strong>the</strong>r that end.”).<br />

60 Netsmart, 924 A.2d at 192.<br />

61 See id. at 192 (“Unlike <strong>the</strong> bare rationality st<strong>and</strong>ard applicable to garden-variety decisions subject to <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Revlon st<strong>and</strong>ard contemplates a judicial examination of <strong>the</strong> reasonableness of <strong>the</strong> board's decision-making process.”); In re Toys<br />

“R” Us, Inc. S'holder Litig., 877 A.2d 975, 1000 (Del. Ch.2005) (“[In Revlon,] <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court held that courts would subject<br />

directors subject to ... a heightened st<strong>and</strong>ard of reasonableness review, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> laxer st<strong>and</strong>ard of rationality review applicable<br />

under <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule.”).<br />

62 QVC, 637 A.2d at 45.<br />

63 See Abraham v. Emerson Radio Corp., 901 A.2d 751, 753 (Del. Ch.2006) (“Under Delaware law, a controller remains free to sell its<br />

stock for a premium not shared with <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r stockholders except in very narrow circumstances.”); In re Sea–L<strong>and</strong> Corp. S'holders<br />

Litig., 1987 WL 11283, at *5 (Del. Ch. May 22, 1987) (“A controlling stockholder is generally under no duty to refrain from receiving<br />

a premium upon <strong>the</strong> sale of his controlling stock.”).<br />

64 See Hammons, 2009 WL 3165613, at *14 (“In <strong>the</strong> first instance, <strong>the</strong>re is no requirement that [a controller] sell his shares. Nor is<br />

<strong>the</strong>re a requirement that [a controller] sell his shares to any particular buyer or for any particular consideration, should he decide in<br />

<strong>the</strong> first instance to sell <strong>the</strong>m.”).<br />

65 In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> Director Defendants argue that <strong>the</strong>y faced <strong>the</strong> same issue this Court faces here in balancing <strong>the</strong> equities concerning<br />

injunctive relief: whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> proposed deal, despite its flaws, should be put before <strong>the</strong> stockholders for a vote on <strong>the</strong> grounds that<br />

it offers an attractive premium over <strong>the</strong> market price of <strong>the</strong> Class A stock.<br />

66 DDAB at 74–75.<br />

67 See 8 Del. C. § 242.<br />

68 At oral argument, nei<strong>the</strong>r Rosenkranz nor <strong>the</strong> Director Defendants provided a convincing explanation as to why a prohibition on<br />

disparate consideration would have been included o<strong>the</strong>r than to improve <strong>the</strong> marketability of Delphi's public shares. In his deposition,<br />

Rosenkranz claimed that <strong>the</strong> primary reason for having two stock classes was “to avoid <strong>the</strong> risk that Delphi would be sold at an<br />

inadequate price at an inopportune time, once it was publicly traded” <strong>and</strong> that he wanted to exit Delphi “at a time <strong>and</strong> on terms that<br />

were acceptable to [him].” Rosenkranz Dep. 58:10–59:21. With respect to <strong>the</strong> Charter Amendment, Rosenkranz argued that he was<br />

simply controlling when <strong>the</strong> stock was to be sold <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> Charter Amendment was really just an altruistic act that would give <strong>the</strong><br />

Class A stockholders “an opportunity to accept a proposal which [Rosenkranz would] o<strong>the</strong>rwise ... reject.” Id. at 80:8–16.<br />

69 See DDAB Ex. 13, at DEL_SCP00000141 (“[TMH] said that if <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> had asked for a price starting with a ‘5,’ [TMH] would<br />

have ended its discussions with <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> entirely.”).<br />

70 See Airgas, Inc. v. Air Prods. & Chems., Inc., 8 A.3d 1182, 1188 (Del.2010) (“Corporate charters <strong>and</strong> bylaws are contracts among<br />

a corporation's shareholders; <strong>the</strong>refore, our rules of contract interpretation apply.”).<br />

71 See Dunlap v. State Farm Fire & Cas. Co., 878 A.2d 434, 441–43 (Del.2005) (“Recognized in many areas of <strong>the</strong> law, <strong>the</strong> implied<br />

covenant attaches to every contract ....“ (footnote omitted)).<br />

72 Allied Capital Corp. v. GC–Sun Holdings, L.P., 910 A.2d 1020, 1032 (Del. Ch.2006) (internal quotation marks omitted).<br />

73 Dunlap, 878 A.2d at 442.<br />

74 In re Cogent, Inc. S'holder Litig., 7 A.3d 487, 509 (Del.2010) (emphasis added).<br />

75 Rosenblatt v. Getty Oil Co., 493 A.2d 929, 944 (Del.1985) (quoting TSC Indus. v. Northway, Inc., 426 U.S. 438, 449 (1976)).<br />

76 Getty Oil, 493 A.2d at 944 (quoting TSC Indus., 426 U.S. at 449) (emphasis added).<br />

77 Id. (emphasis added).<br />

78 TCG Sec., Inc. v. S. Union Co., 1990 WL 7525, at *7 (Del. Ch. Jan. 31, 1990).<br />

79 Cantor Fitzgerald, L.P. v. Cantor, 724 A.2d 571, 579 (Del. Ch.1998) (quoting DONALD J. WOLFE, JR. & MICHAEL A.<br />

PITTENGER, CORPORATE AND COMMERCIAL PRACTICE IN THE DELAWARE COURT OF CHANCERY § 10–2(a)).<br />

80 Aquila, Inc. v. Quanta Servs., Inc., 805 A.2d 196, 208 (Del. Ch.2002) (internal quotation marks removed).<br />

81 See Gradient OC Master, Ltd. v. NBC Universal, Inc., 930 A .2d 104, 131 (Del. Ch.2007) (“There is no irreparable harm if money<br />

damages are adequate to compensate Plaintiffs....”).<br />

82 See Netsmart, 924 A.2d at 208 (contrasting “cases where <strong>the</strong> refusal to grant an injunction presents <strong>the</strong> possibility that a higher,<br />

pending, rival offer might go away forever,” in which injunctive relief is often appropriate, with “cases [where] a potential Revlon<br />

violation occurred but no rival bid is on <strong>the</strong> table,” in which “<strong>the</strong> denial of injunctive relief is often premised on <strong>the</strong> imprudence of<br />

having <strong>the</strong> court enjoin <strong>the</strong> only deal on <strong>the</strong> table, when <strong>the</strong> stockholders can make that decision for <strong>the</strong>mselves”).<br />

83 2012 WL 653845 (Del. Ch. Feb. 29, 2012).<br />

84 Id. at *1.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 18


In re Delphi Financial Group Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, Not Reported in A.3d (2012)<br />

85 Id. at *1, *3 n. 9.<br />

86 Id. at * 13.<br />

87 Compare Rosenkranz to Doug Foshee, <strong>the</strong> CEO of El Paso, who, despite being <strong>the</strong> lead negotiator in <strong>the</strong> sale of <strong>the</strong> company, failed<br />

to disclose to El Paso's board his interest in pursuing a management buyout of a significant component of <strong>the</strong> company's business.<br />

See id. at *7 (“At a time when Foshee's <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board's duty was to squeeze <strong>the</strong> last drop of <strong>the</strong> lemon out for El Paso's stockholders,<br />

Foshee had a motive to keep juice in <strong>the</strong> lemon that he could use to make a financial Collins for himself <strong>and</strong> his fellow managers<br />

interested in pursuing an MBO of <strong>the</strong> E & P business.”).<br />

88 See generally Thorpe v. CERBCO, Inc., 676 A.2d 436, 437 (Del.1996) (“[T]he [defendants'] conceded breach of <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary<br />

duty renders <strong>the</strong>m liable to disgorge any benefits emanating from, <strong>and</strong> providing compensation for any damages attributable to, that<br />

breach.”).<br />

89 The Defendants hotly contest <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> RAM Contracts to Delphi, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> record is not at a stage where I can determine <strong>the</strong><br />

issue with confidence.<br />

90 See supra note 52.<br />

End of Document<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 19


El Paso Corporation Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

41 A.3d 432<br />

Court of Chancery of Delaware.<br />

In re EL PASO CORPORATION<br />

SHAREHOLDER LITIGATION.<br />

Civil Action No. 6949–CS. | Submitted:<br />

Feb. 9, 2012. | Decided: Feb. 29, 2012.<br />

Synopsis<br />

Background: Stockholders brought breach of fiduciary<br />

duties action in regard to proposed merger, <strong>and</strong> moved for a<br />

preliminary injunction to delay <strong>the</strong> merger.<br />

Duties of directors <strong>and</strong> officers in general;<br />

business judgment rule<br />

So long as a board of directors made reasonable<br />

decisions for a proper purpose in a change<br />

of control context, <strong>the</strong>y meet <strong>the</strong>ir duty under<br />

Revlon <strong>and</strong> a court must defer when shareholders<br />

challenge <strong>the</strong> transaction; by contrast, when<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is a reason to conclude that debatable<br />

tactical decisions were motivated not by a<br />

principled evaluation of <strong>the</strong> risks <strong>and</strong> benefits to<br />

<strong>the</strong> company's stockholders, but by a fiduciary's<br />

consideration of his own financial or o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

personal self-interests, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> core animating<br />

principle of Revlon is implicated.<br />

Holdings: The Court of Chancery of Delaware, Strine,<br />

Chancellor, held that:<br />

[1] stockholders had a reasonable probability of success<br />

on <strong>the</strong> merits, as required in order to obtain a preliminary<br />

injunction;<br />

[2] stockholders would likely suffer irreparable injury if <strong>the</strong><br />

merger proceeded; but<br />

[3] <strong>the</strong> balance of <strong>the</strong> equities did not favor <strong>the</strong> issuance of<br />

an injunction.<br />

Motion for preliminary injunction denied.<br />

West Headnotes (5)<br />

[1] Injunction<br />

Grounds in general; multiple factors<br />

In order to obtain a preliminary injunction,<br />

plaintiffs must demonstrate: (1) a reasonable<br />

probability of success on <strong>the</strong> merits; (2) that <strong>the</strong>y<br />

will suffer irreparable harm if an injunction does<br />

not issue; <strong>and</strong> (3) that <strong>the</strong> balance of <strong>the</strong> equities<br />

favors <strong>the</strong> issuance of an injunction.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[2] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

[3] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

Stockholders alleging that proposed merger was<br />

tainted by breaches of fiduciary duty had a<br />

reasonable probability of success on <strong>the</strong> merits,<br />

as required in order to obtain a preliminary<br />

injunction to delay merger, where lead banker<br />

in bank which was advising corporation on a<br />

proposed spin-off of exploration <strong>and</strong> production<br />

(E & P) business that triggered <strong>the</strong> merger<br />

bid had a concealed ownership interest in <strong>the</strong><br />

acquiring corporation, investment bank owned<br />

19% of <strong>the</strong> acquiring corporation but continued<br />

to advise corporation on proposed spin-off,<br />

conflict-cleansing bank hired to provide advice<br />

on <strong>the</strong> merger would only receive a fee if it<br />

approved <strong>the</strong> merger, <strong>and</strong> corporation's chief<br />

executive officer (CEO) who negotiated <strong>the</strong><br />

merger did not disclose that he approached <strong>the</strong><br />

acquiring corporation to propose a management<br />

buy-out (MBO) of corporation's E & P business,<br />

which acquiring corporation intended to sell to<br />

finance <strong>the</strong> merger.<br />

[4] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

Stockholders alleging that proposed merger was<br />

tainted by breaches of fiduciary duty would<br />

likely suffer irreparable injury if <strong>the</strong> merger<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 1


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

proceeded, as required in order to obtain a<br />

preliminary injunction to delay <strong>the</strong> merger,<br />

as <strong>the</strong> adequacy of monetary damages to<br />

<strong>the</strong>m as stockholders was not apparent; <strong>the</strong><br />

independent directors on corporation's board<br />

were not informed of key conflicts of interest<br />

<strong>and</strong> appeared to have acted in good faith,<br />

corporation's chief executive officer (CEO) who<br />

did not disclose that he had approached <strong>the</strong><br />

acquiring corporation to propose a management<br />

buy-out (MBO) of corporation's exploration <strong>and</strong><br />

production (E & P) business was unlikely to be<br />

good for a verdict of more than half a billion<br />

dollars, <strong>and</strong> it was not likely that acquiring<br />

corporation could be found liable as an aider <strong>and</strong><br />

abettor.<br />

[5] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

The balance of <strong>the</strong> equities did not favor <strong>the</strong><br />

issuance of an injunction, as required in order<br />

for stockholders who alleged that proposed<br />

merger was tainted by breaches of fiduciary<br />

duty to obtain a preliminary injunction to delay<br />

<strong>the</strong> merger in order to allow corporation to<br />

prospect for a higher bid; though stockholders<br />

had a reasonable probability of success on<br />

<strong>the</strong> merits <strong>and</strong> it was likely that stockholders<br />

would suffer irreparably injury if <strong>the</strong> merger<br />

proceeded, no rival bid for <strong>the</strong> corporation<br />

existed, <strong>the</strong> injunction would likely relieve<br />

acquiring corporation of any obligation to<br />

close, stockholder vote had not occurred <strong>and</strong><br />

stockholders had <strong>the</strong> right to reject <strong>the</strong> merger,<br />

<strong>and</strong>, though a monetary damages claim was not<br />

a perfect tool, it had some value as a remedial<br />

instrument.<br />

Attorneys <strong>and</strong> Law Firms<br />

*433 Stuart M. Grant, Esquire, Megan D. McIntyre,<br />

Esquire, Christine M. Mackintosh, Esquire, Grant &<br />

Eisenhofer P.A., Wilmington, Delaware; Christine S. Azar,<br />

Esquire, Charles B. Vincent, Esquire, Labaton Sucharow<br />

LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; Mark Lebovitch, Esquire,<br />

Jeremy Friedman, Esquire, Bernstein Litowitz Berger &<br />

Grossmann LLP, New York, New York, Ira Schochet,<br />

Esquire, Labaton Sucharow LLP, New York, New York,<br />

Attorneys for Plaintiffs.<br />

Donald J. Wolfe, Jr., Esquire, T. Brad Davey, Esquire,<br />

Samuel L. Closic, Esquire, Potter Anderson & Corroon LLP,<br />

Wilmington, Delaware; Paul K. Rowe, Esquire, Stephen<br />

R. DiPrima, Esquire, Bradley R. Wilson, Esquire, Michael<br />

Gerber, Esquire, Benjamin D. Schireson, Esquire, Wachtell,<br />

Lipton, Rosen & Katz, New York, New York, Attorneys for<br />

Defendants Juan Carlos Braniff, David W. Crane, Douglas L.<br />

Foshee, Robert W. Goldman, Anthony W. Hall, Jr., Thomas<br />

R. Hix, Ferrell P. McClean, Timothy J. Probert, Steven<br />

Shapiro, J. Michael Talbert, Robert F. Vagt, <strong>and</strong> John L.<br />

Whitmire.<br />

Collins J. Seitz, Jr., Esquire, Bradley R. Aronstam, Esquire,<br />

Seitz Ross Aronstam & Moritz LLP, Wilmington, Delaware;<br />

Joseph S. Allerh<strong>and</strong>, Esquire, Seth Goodchild, Esquire,<br />

Michael Bell, Esquire, Weil, Gotshal & Manges LLP, New<br />

York, New York, Attorneys for Defendants Kinder Morgan,<br />

Inc., Sherpa Merger Sub, Inc., <strong>and</strong> Sherpa Acquisition, LLC.<br />

Gregory V. Varallo, Esquire, Raymond J. DiCamillo,<br />

Esquire, Kevin M. Gallagher, Esquire, Richards, Layton &<br />

Finger, P.A., Wilmington, Delaware; John L. Hardiman,<br />

Esquire, Sullivan & Cromwell, LLP, New York, New York;<br />

Bruce D. Oakley, Esquire, Hogan Lovells U.S. LLP, Houston,<br />

Texas, Attorneys for The Goldman Sachs Group, Inc. <strong>and</strong><br />

Goldman, Sachs & Co.<br />

Opinion<br />

STRINE, Chancellor.<br />

OPINION<br />

I.<br />

Stockholder plaintiffs seek a preliminary injunction to enjoin<br />

a merger between El Paso Corporation <strong>and</strong> Kinder Morgan,<br />

Inc. (<strong>the</strong> “Merger”).<br />

The chief executive officer of El Paso, a public company,<br />

undertook sole responsibility for negotiating <strong>the</strong> sale of El<br />

Paso to Kinder Morgan in <strong>the</strong> Merger. Kinder *434 Morgan<br />

intended to keep El Paso's pipeline business <strong>and</strong> sell off El<br />

Paso's exploration <strong>and</strong> production, or “E & P,” business to<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 2


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

finance <strong>the</strong> purchase. The CEO did not disclose to <strong>the</strong> El Paso<br />

board of directors (<strong>the</strong> “Board”) his interest in working with<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r El Paso managers in making a bid to buy <strong>the</strong> E & P<br />

business from Kinder Morgan. He kept that motive secret,<br />

negotiated <strong>the</strong> Merger, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n approached Kinder Morgan's<br />

CEO on two occasions to try to interest him in <strong>the</strong> idea. In<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r words, when El Paso's CEO was supposed to be getting<br />

<strong>the</strong> maximum price from Kinder Morgan, he actually had an<br />

interest in not doing that.<br />

This undisclosed conflict of interest compounded <strong>the</strong> reality<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Board <strong>and</strong> management of El Paso relied in part<br />

on advice given by a financial advisor, Goldman, Sachs &<br />

Co., which owned 19% of Kinder Morgan (a $4 billion<br />

investment) <strong>and</strong> controlled two Kinder Morgan board seats.<br />

Although Goldman's conflict was known, inadequate efforts<br />

to cabin its role were made. When a second investment bank<br />

was brought in to address Goldman's economic incentive<br />

for a deal with, <strong>and</strong> on terms that favored, Kinder Morgan,<br />

Goldman continued to intervene <strong>and</strong> advise El Paso on<br />

strategic alternatives, <strong>and</strong> with its friends in El Paso<br />

management, was able to achieve a remarkable feat: giving<br />

<strong>the</strong> new investment bank an incentive to favor <strong>the</strong> Merger by<br />

making sure that this bank only got paid if El Paso adopted<br />

<strong>the</strong> strategic option of selling to Kinder Morgan. In o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

words, <strong>the</strong> conflict-cleansing bank only got paid if <strong>the</strong> option<br />

Goldman's financial incentives gave it a reason to prefer was<br />

<strong>the</strong> one chosen. On top of this, <strong>the</strong> lead Goldman banker<br />

advising El Paso did not disclose that he personally owned<br />

approximately $340,000 of stock in Kinder Morgan.<br />

The record is filled with debatable negotiating <strong>and</strong> tactical<br />

choices made by El Paso fiduciaries <strong>and</strong> advisors. Absent a<br />

conflict of interest, <strong>the</strong>se debatable choices could be seen as<br />

<strong>the</strong> sort of reasonable, if arguable, ones that must be made<br />

in a world of uncertainty. After discovery, however, <strong>the</strong>se<br />

choices now must be viewed more skeptically, as <strong>the</strong> key<br />

negotiator on behalf of <strong>the</strong> Board <strong>and</strong> a powerfully influential<br />

financial advisor each had financial motives adverse to <strong>the</strong><br />

best interests of El Paso's stockholders. In <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong><br />

CEO, he was <strong>the</strong> one who made most of <strong>the</strong> important tactical<br />

choices, <strong>and</strong> he never surfaced his own conflict of interest.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> case of Goldman, it claimed to step out of <strong>the</strong> process<br />

while failing to do so completely <strong>and</strong> while playing a key<br />

role in distorting <strong>the</strong> economic incentives of <strong>the</strong> bank that<br />

came in to ensure that Goldman's conflict did not taint <strong>the</strong><br />

Board's deliberations. This behavior makes it difficult to<br />

conclude that <strong>the</strong> Board's less than aggressive negotiating<br />

strategy <strong>and</strong> its failure to test Kinder Morgan's bid actively in<br />

<strong>the</strong> market through even a quiet, soft market check were not<br />

compromised by <strong>the</strong> conflicting financial incentives of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

key players.<br />

The record thus persuades me that <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs have a<br />

reasonable likelihood of success in proving that <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

was tainted by disloyalty. Because, however, <strong>the</strong>re is no<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r bid on <strong>the</strong> table <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> stockholders of El Paso,<br />

as <strong>the</strong> seller, have a choice whe<strong>the</strong>r to turn down <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger <strong>the</strong>mselves, <strong>the</strong> balance of harms counsels against a<br />

preliminary injunction. Although <strong>the</strong> pursuit of a monetary<br />

damages award may not be likely to promise full relief, <strong>the</strong><br />

record does not instill in me <strong>the</strong> confidence to deny, by grant<br />

of an injunction, El Paso's stockholders from accepting a<br />

transaction that <strong>the</strong>y may find desirable in current market<br />

conditions, despite <strong>the</strong> *435 disturbing behavior that led to<br />

its final terms.<br />

II.<br />

[1] The plaintiffs are stockholders of El Paso <strong>and</strong> seek to<br />

enjoin a vote on a proposed Merger with Kinder Morgan that<br />

offers El Paso a combination of cash, stock, <strong>and</strong> warrants<br />

now valued at $30.37 per share, or a 47.8% premium over El<br />

Paso's stock price thirty days before Kinder Morgan made its<br />

first bid. 1 At <strong>the</strong> time of signing, <strong>the</strong> Merger consideration<br />

was worth $26.87 per share, <strong>and</strong> has appreciated since <strong>the</strong><br />

announcement because Kinder Morgan's stock has grown<br />

in value. In order to obtain a preliminary injunction, <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiffs must demonstrate: (1) a reasonable probability of<br />

success on <strong>the</strong> merits; (2) that <strong>the</strong>y will suffer irreparable<br />

harm if an injunction does not issue; <strong>and</strong> (3) that <strong>the</strong> balance<br />

of <strong>the</strong> equities favors <strong>the</strong> issuance of an injunction. 2<br />

The Merger resulted from a non-public overture that Kinder<br />

Morgan made in <strong>the</strong> wake of El Paso's public announcement<br />

that it would spin off its E & P business. El Paso is an<br />

energy company composed of two main business segments:<br />

a pipeline business, which transports natural gas throughout<br />

<strong>the</strong> United States, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> E & P business, which looks for<br />

<strong>and</strong> exploits opportunities to drill <strong>and</strong> produce oil <strong>and</strong> natural<br />

gas. The market had reacted favorably to <strong>the</strong> May 24, 2011<br />

announcement of <strong>the</strong> spin-off, <strong>and</strong> El Paso's stock price had<br />

risen, although El Paso believed that its stock price would<br />

rise fur<strong>the</strong>r when <strong>the</strong> spin-off was actually effected. El Paso<br />

understood that Kinder Morgan was trying to preempt any<br />

competition by o<strong>the</strong>r bidders for what would be <strong>the</strong> separate<br />

pipeline business, which is <strong>the</strong> business Kinder Morgan<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 3


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

wanted to buy, by making a bid before El Paso divided into<br />

two companies. 3<br />

The first time after <strong>the</strong> spin-off announcement that Kinder<br />

Morgan expressed its interest in acquiring El Paso was on<br />

August 30, 2011, when Kinder Morgan offered El Paso<br />

$25.50 per share in cash <strong>and</strong> stock. 4 The El Paso Board<br />

fended this off weakly, despite believing that <strong>the</strong> price was<br />

not attractive <strong>and</strong> that Kinder Morgan was hoping to preempt<br />

any market competition for El Paso's pipeline business by<br />

acquiring all of El Paso before <strong>the</strong> spin-off was effected. On<br />

September 9, 2011, Kinder Morgan threatened to go public<br />

with its interest in buying El Paso. Ra<strong>the</strong>r than seeing this<br />

as a chance to force Kinder Morgan into an expensive public<br />

struggle, <strong>the</strong> Board entered into negotiations with Kinder<br />

Morgan. The Board looked to its longtime advisor Goldman<br />

Sachs (which as noted owns 19% of Kinder Morgan, fills two<br />

seats on <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan board under a voting agreement<br />

with Kinder Morgan's CEO <strong>and</strong> controlling stockholder,<br />

Rich Kinder, <strong>and</strong> is part of <strong>the</strong> control group which *436<br />

collectively holds 78.4% of <strong>the</strong> voting power of Kinder<br />

Morgan stock) 5 <strong>and</strong> a new advisor, Morgan Stanley & Co.,<br />

LLC, for financial <strong>and</strong> tactical advice in making that decision<br />

<strong>and</strong> for developing its negotiating strategy. On September<br />

16, 2011, El Paso asked Kinder Morgan for a bid of $28<br />

per share in cash <strong>and</strong> stock, deploying <strong>the</strong> company's CEO,<br />

Doug Foshee, as its sole negotiator. 6 Foshee reached an<br />

agreement in principle with Rich Kinder two days later on<br />

a deal at $27.55 per share in cash <strong>and</strong> stock, subject to<br />

due diligence by Kinder Morgan. The basic terms of <strong>the</strong><br />

agreement in principle were memorialized in a series of term<br />

sheets exchanged between <strong>the</strong> parties between September 20,<br />

2011 <strong>and</strong> September 22, 2011.<br />

Soon <strong>the</strong>reafter, on September 23, 2011, Kinder said “oops,<br />

we made a mistake. We relied on a bullish set of analyst<br />

projections in order to make our bid. Our bad. Although we<br />

were tough enough to threaten going hostile, we just can't<br />

st<strong>and</strong> by our bid.”<br />

Instead of telling Kinder where to put his drilling equipment,<br />

Foshee backed down. In a downward spiral, El Paso ended up<br />

taking a package that was valued at $26.87 as of signing on<br />

October 16, 2011, comprised of $25.91 in cash <strong>and</strong> stock, <strong>and</strong><br />

a warrant with a strike price of $40—some $13 above Kinder<br />

Morgan's <strong>the</strong>n-current stock price of $26.89 per share 7 —<strong>and</strong><br />

no protection against ordinary dividends. 8<br />

Still, <strong>the</strong> deal was at a substantial premium to market, 9 <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> Board was advised by Morgan Stanley (<strong>and</strong> also by <strong>the</strong><br />

analyses of Goldman—which had, <strong>and</strong> continued to, advise<br />

El Paso on <strong>the</strong> spin-off of <strong>the</strong> E & P business) that <strong>the</strong> offer<br />

was more attractive in <strong>the</strong> immediate term than doing <strong>the</strong> spinoff<br />

<strong>and</strong> had less execution risk, because Kinder Morgan had<br />

agreed to a great deal of closing certainty. Thus, <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

approved <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

On October 16, 2011, <strong>the</strong> parties entered into <strong>the</strong> “Merger<br />

Agreement.” The Merger Agreement contains a commitment<br />

from El Paso to assist Kinder Morgan in <strong>the</strong> sale of <strong>the</strong><br />

E & P business, which Kinder Morgan hoped could be<br />

accomplished before <strong>the</strong> closing of <strong>the</strong> Merger. 10 The *437<br />

Merger Agreement also contains a “no-shop” provision<br />

preventing El Paso from affirmatively soliciting higher bids,<br />

but gives <strong>the</strong> Board a fiduciary out in <strong>the</strong> event it receives<br />

a “Superior Proposal” from a third party for more than 50%<br />

of El Paso's equity securities or consolidated assets. 11 These<br />

measures preclude El Paso from ab<strong>and</strong>oning <strong>the</strong> Merger in<br />

order to pursue a sale of <strong>the</strong> E & P assets because <strong>the</strong> E &<br />

P assets make up less than 50% of El Paso's consolidated<br />

assets. 12 By contrast, El Paso could terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement to pursue a sale of <strong>the</strong> pipeline business (which<br />

makes up more than 50% of <strong>the</strong> company's consolidated<br />

assets), but Kinder Morgan has a right to match any such<br />

Superior Proposal. 13 In <strong>the</strong> event that <strong>the</strong> Board accepts<br />

a Superior Proposal, El Paso must pay a $650 million<br />

termination fee to Kinder Morgan. 14 In terms of <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

deal size, <strong>the</strong> termination fee represents 3.1% of <strong>the</strong> equity<br />

value <strong>and</strong> 1.69% of <strong>the</strong> enterprise value of El Paso as implied<br />

by <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. 15 Thus, to buy just <strong>the</strong> pipeline<br />

business, an interloper would have to pay a termination fee<br />

that was, say, 5.1% of <strong>the</strong> equity value <strong>and</strong> 2.5% of <strong>the</strong><br />

enterprise value of El Paso's pipeline business, assuming it<br />

comprised around 60.3% of El Paso's equity value <strong>and</strong> 67%<br />

of El Paso's enterprise value at <strong>the</strong> time of signing. 16<br />

Since <strong>the</strong> signing of <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement, <strong>the</strong> price of<br />

Kinder Morgan's shares has risen, increasing <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger consideration.<br />

III.<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong> premium to market, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs contend that<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger is tainted by <strong>the</strong> selfish motivations of both Doug<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 4


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

Foshee <strong>and</strong> Goldman Sachs. As <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs point out, <strong>the</strong>re<br />

were numerous decisions made by <strong>the</strong> El Paso Board during<br />

<strong>the</strong> process that could be seen as questionable. These include:<br />

• The failure of <strong>the</strong> Board to shop El Paso as a whole<br />

or its two key divisions separately to any o<strong>the</strong>r bidder<br />

after Kinder Morgan made its initial overture, despite<br />

knowing that Kinder Morgan was hoping to preempt<br />

competition by bidding for <strong>the</strong> whole company, 17 <strong>and</strong><br />

despite knowing that although <strong>the</strong>re would be a number<br />

of bidders for <strong>the</strong> company's two key divisions if<br />

marketed separately, <strong>the</strong>re was unlikely to be any rival<br />

to Kinder *438 Morgan willing to purchase El Paso as<br />

a whole; 18<br />

• The failure of <strong>the</strong> Board to reject Kinder Morgan's initial<br />

overtures <strong>and</strong> force it to go public <strong>and</strong> face <strong>the</strong> market<br />

pressure to raise its offer to a level where it could prevail<br />

in a hostile takeover bid;<br />

• Charging Foshee with h<strong>and</strong>ling all negotiations<br />

with Kinder Morgan without any presence or close<br />

supervision by an independent director or legal<br />

advisor;<br />

• Allowing Kinder Morgan (a supposedly tough,<br />

potential hostile bidder) to renege on an agreement<br />

in principle to pay cash <strong>and</strong> stock equal to $27.55<br />

entered into on September 18, 2011 (a package<br />

that would likely be worth $31.76 today assuming<br />

current market prices 19 ) based on <strong>the</strong> (arguably<br />

ludicrous) assertion that it had based its bid on<br />

<strong>the</strong> cash flow estimates of <strong>the</strong> most bullish analyst<br />

covering El Paso's stock;<br />

• Signing on to deal protection measures that would<br />

effectively preclude a post-signing market check for<br />

bids for <strong>the</strong> separate divisions because of <strong>the</strong> limited<br />

fiduciary out, which precludes <strong>the</strong> Board from accepting<br />

a topping bid for <strong>the</strong> E & P business, <strong>and</strong> which makes<br />

<strong>the</strong> emergence of a topping bid for <strong>the</strong> pipeline business<br />

difficult because of <strong>the</strong> $650 million termination fee <strong>and</strong><br />

Kinder Morgan's matching rights; <strong>and</strong><br />

• Eventually agreeing to a deal that only provided<br />

El Paso stockholders with cash <strong>and</strong> stock equal to<br />

$25.91 in value (excluding <strong>the</strong> warrant), far less<br />

than <strong>the</strong> $27.55 previously agreed to by Kinder<br />

Morgan.<br />

The plaintiffs also take issue with <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> final<br />

price of $25.91 in cash <strong>and</strong> stock was reached when Foshee,<br />

without Board approval, told Kinder Morgan that he would be<br />

open to a deal whereby Kinder Morgan would only pay $26<br />

per share in cash <strong>and</strong> stock, a full $0.50 per share less than <strong>the</strong><br />

counter-offer that <strong>the</strong> Board had authorized him to put on <strong>the</strong><br />

table. 20 Even <strong>the</strong>n, Foshee did not get $26 in cash <strong>and</strong> stock.<br />

Instead, he got only $25.91 in cash <strong>and</strong> stock, with Kinder<br />

Morgan adding in a warrant with a high strike price <strong>and</strong> weak<br />

protection against dividends to Kinder Morgan stockholders.<br />

*439 The Board valued this package at $26.87 on <strong>the</strong> date of<br />

signing, $0.68 below <strong>the</strong> $27.55 per share that Kinder Morgan<br />

had agreed to after threatening to go hostile just weeks earlier.<br />

Despite that, <strong>the</strong> Board decided that <strong>the</strong> lower price should<br />

be accepted <strong>and</strong> was more favorable to El Paso's stockholders<br />

than <strong>the</strong> strategic alternative, which involved <strong>the</strong> previously<br />

announced spin-off of El Paso's E & P business.<br />

IV.<br />

[2] Although a reasonable mind might debate <strong>the</strong> tactical<br />

choices made by <strong>the</strong> El Paso Board, <strong>the</strong>se choices<br />

would provide little basis for enjoining a third-party<br />

merger approved by a board overwhelmingly comprised<br />

of independent directors, many of whom have substantial<br />

industry experience. The Revlon doctrine, after all, does not<br />

exist as a license for courts to second-guess reasonable,<br />

but arguable, questions of business judgment in <strong>the</strong> change<br />

of control context, but to ensure that <strong>the</strong> directors take<br />

reasonable steps to obtain <strong>the</strong> highest value reasonably<br />

attainable <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong>ir actions are not compromised by<br />

impermissible considerations, such as self-interest. 21 So<br />

long as <strong>the</strong> directors made reasonable decisions for a proper<br />

purpose, <strong>the</strong>y meet <strong>the</strong>ir duty under Revlon <strong>and</strong> this court<br />

must defer. 22<br />

By contrast, when <strong>the</strong>re is a reason to conclude that debatable<br />

tactical decisions were motivated not by a principled<br />

evaluation of <strong>the</strong> risks <strong>and</strong> benefits to <strong>the</strong> company's<br />

stockholders, but by a fiduciary's consideration of his own<br />

financial or o<strong>the</strong>r personal self-interests, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> core<br />

animating principle of Revlon is implicated. 23 As Revlon<br />

itself made clear, <strong>the</strong> potential sale of a corporation has<br />

enormous implications for corporate managers <strong>and</strong> advisors,<br />

<strong>and</strong> a range of human motivations, including but by no means<br />

limited to greed, can inspire fiduciaries <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir advisors to<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 5


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

be less than faithful to <strong>the</strong>ir contextual duty to pursue <strong>the</strong> best<br />

value for <strong>the</strong> company's stockholders. 24<br />

how to respond to Kinder Morgan from September 15, 2011<br />

onwards. 30<br />

Here, <strong>the</strong> defendants allege that <strong>the</strong> current case fits neatly<br />

within that line of cases where this court deferred to boards<br />

that made reasonable, if questionable, decisions in deciding<br />

how to consummate a change of control transaction. 25 They<br />

argue *440 that a well-motivated board, with an excellent,<br />

well-motivated CEO, used <strong>the</strong> favorable market reaction to<br />

<strong>the</strong> company's announced spin-off to secure an even more<br />

favorable outcome: a sales transaction securing for El Paso<br />

a large premium to market with far less execution risk than<br />

<strong>the</strong> spin-off entailed. The defendants begrudgingly concede<br />

that El Paso's long-st<strong>and</strong>ing financial advisor, Goldman, had<br />

a “potential conflict” 26 because: (1) it owned approximately<br />

19%, or $4 billion worth, of Kinder Morgan stock; (2) it<br />

controlled two of Kinder Morgan's board seats; (3) it had<br />

placed two senior Goldman principals on <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan<br />

board who thus owed Kinder Morgan fiduciary duties; <strong>and</strong> (4)<br />

<strong>the</strong> lead Goldman banker working for El Paso, Steve Daniel,<br />

personally owned approximately $340,000 of Kinder Morgan<br />

stock. 27 But, <strong>the</strong> defendants argue that Goldman was walled<br />

off from giving strategic advice about <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan<br />

bid early in <strong>the</strong> process <strong>and</strong> ano<strong>the</strong>r top-tier bank, Morgan<br />

Stanley, came in <strong>and</strong> gave unconflicted advice.<br />

Regrettably for <strong>the</strong> defendants, <strong>the</strong> record developed in<br />

expedited discovery belies <strong>the</strong>ir argument that <strong>the</strong>re is no<br />

reason to question <strong>the</strong> motives behind <strong>the</strong> decisions made by<br />

El Paso in negotiating <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. Although it is<br />

true that measures were taken to cabin Goldman's conflict (for<br />

example, Goldman formally set up an internal “Chinese wall”<br />

between <strong>the</strong> Goldman advisors to El Paso <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Goldman<br />

representatives responsible for <strong>the</strong> firm's Kinder Morgan<br />

investment) 28 —which was actual <strong>and</strong> potent, not merely<br />

potential—those efforts were not effective. Goldman still<br />

played an important role in advising <strong>the</strong> Board by suggesting<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Board should avoid causing Kinder Morgan to go<br />

hostile <strong>and</strong> by presenting information about <strong>the</strong> value of<br />

pursuing <strong>the</strong> spin-off instead of <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan deal.<br />

Indeed, Goldman's advice to placate Kinder Morgan by<br />

entering into due diligence “raised [El Paso] management's<br />

concerns” that <strong>the</strong> Goldman team was “receiving pressure<br />

from o<strong>the</strong>r parts of Goldman Sachs to avoid a strategy that<br />

might result in [Kinder Morgan] going public <strong>and</strong> making<br />

a hostile approach on [El Paso],” 29 prompting El Paso to<br />

exclude Goldman from internal tactical discussions about<br />

*441 Even <strong>the</strong>n, though, Goldman was not out of <strong>the</strong><br />

picture entirely, as El Paso management only thought it<br />

was necessary to limit Goldman's involvement in <strong>the</strong> Kinder<br />

Morgan side of <strong>the</strong> advisory work. Goldman continued its<br />

role as primary financial advisor to El Paso for <strong>the</strong> spin-off,<br />

<strong>and</strong> was asked to continue to provide financial updates to <strong>the</strong><br />

Board that would enable <strong>the</strong> El Paso directors to compare <strong>the</strong><br />

spin-off to <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

The fact that Goldman continued to have its h<strong>and</strong>s in <strong>the</strong><br />

dough of <strong>the</strong> spin-off is important, because <strong>the</strong> Board was<br />

assessing <strong>the</strong> attractiveness of <strong>the</strong> Merger relative to <strong>the</strong><br />

attractiveness of <strong>the</strong> spin-off. That was critical because <strong>the</strong><br />

Board, at <strong>the</strong> recommendation of Foshee, Goldman, <strong>and</strong><br />

Morgan Stanley, decided not to risk Kinder Morgan going<br />

hostile <strong>and</strong> not to do any test of <strong>the</strong> market with o<strong>the</strong>r possible<br />

buyers of El Paso as a whole, or of ei<strong>the</strong>r or both of its<br />

two key business segments separately. Thus, <strong>the</strong> Board was<br />

down to two strategic options: <strong>the</strong> spin-off or a sale to Kinder<br />

Morgan. Therefore, because Goldman stayed involved as <strong>the</strong><br />

lead advisor on <strong>the</strong> spin-off, it was in a position to continue<br />

to exert influence over <strong>the</strong> Merger. The record suggests that<br />

<strong>the</strong>re were questionable aspects to Goldman's valuation of<br />

<strong>the</strong> spin-off <strong>and</strong> its continued revision downward that could<br />

be seen as suspicious in light of Goldman's huge financial<br />

interest in Kinder Morgan. 31<br />

*442 Heightening <strong>the</strong>se suspicions is <strong>the</strong> fact that Goldman's<br />

lead banker failed to disclose his own personal ownership<br />

of approximately $340,000 in Kinder Morgan stock, a very<br />

troubling failure that tends to undercut <strong>the</strong> credibility of his<br />

testimony <strong>and</strong> of <strong>the</strong> strategic advice he gave. 32<br />

Even worse, Goldman tainted <strong>the</strong> cleansing effect of Morgan<br />

Stanley. Goldman clung to its previously obtained contract<br />

to make it <strong>the</strong> exclusive advisor on <strong>the</strong> spin-off <strong>and</strong> which<br />

promised Goldman $25 million in fees if <strong>the</strong> spin-off was<br />

completed. Despite <strong>the</strong> reality that Morgan Stanley was<br />

retained to address Goldman's bias toward a suboptimally<br />

priced deal with Kinder Morgan <strong>and</strong> thus Morgan Stanley's<br />

work in evaluating whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> spin-off was a more valuable<br />

option was critical to its integrity-enforcing role, Goldman<br />

refused to concede that Morgan Stanley should be paid<br />

anything if <strong>the</strong> spin-off, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> Merger, was<br />

consummated. Goldman's friends in El Paso management—<br />

<strong>and</strong> that is what <strong>the</strong>y seem to have been—easily gave in to<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 6


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

Goldman. 33 This resulted in an incentive structure like this<br />

for Morgan Stanley:<br />

• Approve a deal with Kinder Morgan (<strong>the</strong> entity of which<br />

Goldman owned 19%)—get $35 million; or<br />

• Counsel <strong>the</strong> Board to go with <strong>the</strong> spin-off or to<br />

pursue ano<strong>the</strong>r option—get zilch, nada, zero. 34<br />

This makes more questionable some of <strong>the</strong> tactical advice<br />

given by Morgan Stanley <strong>and</strong> some of its valuation advice,<br />

which can be viewed as stretching to make Kinder Morgan's<br />

offers more favorable than o<strong>the</strong>r available options. 35 Then,<br />

despite *443 saying that it did not advise on <strong>the</strong> Merger—<br />

a claim that <strong>the</strong> record does not bear out in large measure<br />

—Goldman asked for a $20 million fee for its work on<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger. Of course, by <strong>the</strong> same logic it used to shut<br />

out Morgan Stanley from receiving any fee for <strong>the</strong> spinoff,<br />

Goldman should have been foreclosed from getting fees<br />

for working on <strong>the</strong> Merger when it supposedly was walled<br />

off from advising on that deal. But, Goldman's affectionate<br />

clients, more wed to Goldman than to logical consistency,<br />

quickly assented to this dem<strong>and</strong>. 36<br />

Worst of all was that <strong>the</strong> supposedly well-motivated <strong>and</strong><br />

expert CEO entrusted with all <strong>the</strong> key price negotiations<br />

kept from <strong>the</strong> Board his interest in pursuing a management<br />

buy-out of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>'s E & P business. Knowing that<br />

Kinder Morgan intended to sell <strong>the</strong> E & P business in order<br />

to finance its overall purchase of El Paso, Foshee spoke<br />

with fellow El Paso manager Brent Smolik, <strong>the</strong> head of <strong>the</strong><br />

E & P business, about approaching Kinder Morgan with a<br />

management bid for <strong>the</strong> E & P assets. The record does not<br />

make clear exactly when <strong>the</strong> idea of an MBO first occurred<br />

to Foshee, but an email exchange between Smolik <strong>and</strong> John<br />

Sult (<strong>the</strong> CFO of El Paso) suggests that Smolik <strong>and</strong> Foshee<br />

were discussing <strong>the</strong> MBO opportunity while Foshee was<br />

negotiating <strong>the</strong> Merger terms with Rich Kinder. 37 Ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than disclose that he was contemplating an MBO to <strong>the</strong> Board,<br />

Foshee kept this information to himself, <strong>and</strong> even told Smolik<br />

that he wanted to discuss <strong>the</strong> MBO “as late [in <strong>the</strong> process]<br />

as possible.” 38 After <strong>the</strong> Merger price was finally set <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Agreement entered into, Foshee went to Rich Kinder<br />

not once, but twice, to try to get Kinder interested in letting<br />

El Paso management bid. Although Kinder did not embrace<br />

Foshee's idea of an El Paso management led buy-out of <strong>the</strong><br />

E & P business, <strong>the</strong> reality is that Foshee was interested in<br />

being a buyer of a key part of El Paso at <strong>the</strong> same time<br />

he was charged with getting <strong>the</strong> highest possible price as a<br />

seller of that same asset. At no time did *444 Foshee come<br />

clean to his board about his self-interest, <strong>and</strong> he never sought<br />

permission from <strong>the</strong> Board before twice going to <strong>the</strong> CEO of<br />

<strong>the</strong> company's negotiating adversary.<br />

At a time when Foshee's <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board's duty was to squeeze<br />

<strong>the</strong> last drop of <strong>the</strong> lemon out for El Paso's stockholders,<br />

Foshee had a motive to keep juice in <strong>the</strong> lemon that he<br />

could use to make a financial Collins for himself <strong>and</strong> his<br />

fellow managers interested in pursuing an MBO of <strong>the</strong> E &<br />

P business. The defendants defend this by calling Foshee's<br />

actions <strong>and</strong> motivations immaterial <strong>and</strong> frivolous.<br />

It may turn out after trial that Foshee is <strong>the</strong> type of person who<br />

entertains <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n dismisses multi-billion dollar transactions<br />

at whim. Perhaps his interest in an MBO was really more of a<br />

passing fancy, a casual thought that he could have mentioned<br />

to Kinder over canapés <strong>and</strong> forgotten about <strong>the</strong> next day.<br />

It could be.<br />

Or it could be that Foshee is a very smart man, <strong>and</strong> very<br />

financially savvy. He did not tell anyone but his management<br />

confreres that he was contemplating an MBO because he<br />

knew that would have posed all kinds of questions about<br />

<strong>the</strong> negotiations with Kinder Morgan <strong>and</strong> how <strong>the</strong>y were to<br />

be conducted. Thus, he decided to keep quiet about it <strong>and</strong><br />

approach his negotiating counterpart Rich Kinder late in <strong>the</strong><br />

process—after <strong>the</strong> basic deal terms were set—to maximize<br />

<strong>the</strong> chance that Kinder would be receptive. Of course, for an<br />

MBO to be attractive to management <strong>and</strong> to Kinder Morgan,<br />

not forcing Kinder Morgan to pay <strong>the</strong> highest possible price<br />

for El Paso was more optimal than exhausting its wallet,<br />

because that would tend to cause Kinder Morgan to dem<strong>and</strong><br />

a higher price for <strong>the</strong> E & P assets. Not only that, a fist fight<br />

of a negotiation might leave a bloodied Kinder unreceptive to<br />

a bid from Foshee <strong>and</strong> his team. Admittedly, <strong>the</strong> defendants<br />

would have me consider incredible <strong>the</strong> notion that ideas like<br />

this would have crossed <strong>the</strong> mind of Foshee while he was<br />

negotiating. But <strong>the</strong>n again, <strong>the</strong> idea of an MBO had crossed<br />

his mind, he purposely decided not to tell <strong>the</strong> Board about it,<br />

he purposely decided to keep it quiet from Kinder Morgan<br />

until <strong>the</strong> deal was baked, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n had not one, but two<br />

discussions with his rival CEO in <strong>the</strong> negotiations seeking to<br />

pursue it. I do not find at this stage I can conclude it was a lark.<br />

[3] The concealed motives of Foshee, <strong>the</strong> concealed<br />

financial interest of Goldman's lead banker in Kinder Morgan,<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 7


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

Goldman's continued influence over <strong>the</strong> Board's assessment<br />

of <strong>the</strong> spin-off, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> distortion of Morgan Stanley's<br />

incentives that arose as a result of El Paso management's<br />

acquiescence to its Goldman friends' dem<strong>and</strong>s leave me<br />

persuaded that <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs have a reasonable probability of<br />

success on a claim that <strong>the</strong> Merger is tainted by breaches<br />

of fiduciary duty. The Board, <strong>and</strong> Foshee as key negotiator<br />

on behalf of <strong>the</strong> Board, made many questionable tactical<br />

decisions. Allowing Kinder to play <strong>the</strong> tough hostile bidder<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n back off <strong>the</strong> $27.55 per share price can certainly be<br />

seen by a rational mind as oddly timid, especially because<br />

once El Paso stockholders realized that Kinder Morgan—<br />

a supposedly mature market player making an unsolicited<br />

bid—had agreed to pay that price, <strong>the</strong>y would be reluctant<br />

to accept less. If, as seems to be <strong>the</strong> case, Kinder Morgan<br />

wanted El Paso's pipeline business badly, more backbone<br />

might well have resulted in a better result. Likewise, as<br />

mentioned, <strong>the</strong>re are odd aspects to some of <strong>the</strong> financial<br />

analyses presented, which seem to go some way to making<br />

<strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan bid look more favorable in comparison<br />

to o<strong>the</strong>r options *445 than perhaps a more consistent<br />

approach to valuation would have done. The failure to use<br />

<strong>the</strong> emergence of Kinder Morgan as a bidder to do a soft<br />

test of <strong>the</strong> market for El Paso's attractive business units is,<br />

of course, relevant to any Revlon inquiry, but particularly<br />

when questions of loyalty exist. 39 And that failure was<br />

compounded by a deal protection package that (1) precluded<br />

termination of <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement if a favorable bid for<br />

<strong>the</strong> E & P business emerged; <strong>and</strong> (2) made it very expensive<br />

for a bidder for <strong>the</strong> pipeline business to make an offer because<br />

of <strong>the</strong> $650 million termination fee <strong>and</strong> Kinder Morgan's<br />

matching rights. This is important because it was clear that<br />

<strong>the</strong> most valuable alternative to <strong>the</strong> Merger o<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong><br />

announced spin-off was likely a sale of El Paso's two main<br />

businesses to separate buyers (<strong>the</strong> kind of break-up that was<br />

de rigeur in <strong>the</strong> 1980s), or a sale of one business while<br />

retaining <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r as a st<strong>and</strong>alone public company (a twist<br />

on <strong>the</strong> spin-off).<br />

Perhaps most troubling is that Foshee's velvet glove<br />

negotiating strategy—which involved proffering counteroffers<br />

at levels below <strong>the</strong> level he was authorized by <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

to advance—can now be viewed as having been influenced by<br />

an improper motive. Ra<strong>the</strong>r than having only <strong>the</strong> best interests<br />

of El Paso's stockholders in mind, Foshee had something else<br />

important on his mind—his interest in working with some of<br />

his fellow managers on a bid for <strong>the</strong> E & P business, which<br />

had been valued between $6 billion <strong>and</strong> $10 billion at various<br />

times by Goldman during 2011. That sort of deal would<br />

allow him to monetize a large part of his company-specific<br />

investment in El Paso, while permitting him <strong>the</strong> chance to<br />

continue to participate in managing key assets he knew <strong>and</strong><br />

for ano<strong>the</strong>r equity pop in <strong>the</strong> future. That goal, however,<br />

gave him an incentive different from maximizing what Kinder<br />

Morgan would pay El Paso, because <strong>the</strong> more Kinder Morgan<br />

had to pay El Paso, <strong>the</strong> more it might want for <strong>the</strong> E & P<br />

assets. And as mentioned, <strong>the</strong> bloodier <strong>the</strong> negotiation, <strong>the</strong><br />

more Foshee risked having Kinder not wish to deal with him.<br />

When anyone conceals his self-interest—as both Foshee<br />

<strong>and</strong> Goldman banker Steve Daniel did—it is far harder to<br />

credit that person's assertion that that self-interest did not<br />

influence his actions. 40 That is particularly true when a<br />

court is reviewing <strong>the</strong> actions of businessmen <strong>and</strong> investment<br />

bankers. People like Foshee <strong>and</strong> Daniel get paid <strong>the</strong> big<br />

money because <strong>the</strong>y are masters of economic incentives, <strong>and</strong><br />

keenly aware of <strong>the</strong>m at all times.<br />

For similar reasons, <strong>the</strong> court is not swayed by Goldman's<br />

assertions that it was not influenced by its own economic<br />

incentives to maximize its $4 billion investment in Kinder<br />

Morgan by steering El Paso towards a deal with Kinder<br />

Morgan at a suboptimal price. Why? Goldman's claim that<br />

it was capable of putting aside its $4 billion investment<br />

in Kinder Morgan when advising El Paso on its strategic<br />

options is hard to square with <strong>the</strong> record *446 evidence<br />

demonstrating <strong>the</strong> lengths to which Goldman would go<br />

to secure an advisory fee of $20 million from El Paso<br />

—a fraction of <strong>the</strong> dollar size of its Kinder Morgan<br />

investment—in connection with <strong>the</strong> Merger. 41 For starters,<br />

Goldman maneuvered in <strong>the</strong> context of <strong>the</strong> Morgan Stanley<br />

fee negotiations to ensure that Goldman would not go<br />

uncompensated in <strong>the</strong> event <strong>the</strong> Board decided to ab<strong>and</strong>on<br />

<strong>the</strong> spin-off in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger. 42 What's more, earlier<br />

in <strong>the</strong> deal process, Goldman had Lloyd Blankfein, its CEO<br />

<strong>and</strong> Chairman, give Foshee a personal, obsequious phone call<br />

to thank him for El Paso's retention of Goldman over <strong>the</strong><br />

years <strong>and</strong> to try to secure a continuing role in working for El<br />

Paso during <strong>the</strong> pendency of <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan bid despite<br />

what Goldman deemed an “appearance of conflict.” 43 And<br />

despite now claiming that it was not a key strategic advisor<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan deal, Goldman sought credit as an<br />

advisor in <strong>the</strong> press release announcing <strong>the</strong> Merger, a move<br />

at self-promotion its rival Morgan Stanley called Goldman<br />

“at its most shameless.” 44 At this stage, I am unwilling to<br />

view Goldman as exemplifying an Emersonian non-foolishly<br />

inconsistent approach to greed, one that involves seeking<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 8


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

lucre in a conflicted situation while simultaneously putting<br />

<strong>the</strong> chance for greater lucre out of its “collective” mind. At<br />

this stage, I cannot readily accept <strong>the</strong> notion that Goldman<br />

would not seek to maximize <strong>the</strong> value of its multi-billion<br />

dollar investment in Kinder Morgan at <strong>the</strong> expense of El Paso,<br />

but, at <strong>the</strong> same time, be so keen on obtaining an investment<br />

banking fee in <strong>the</strong> tens of millions.<br />

Likewise, Daniel <strong>and</strong> Foshee each had an incentive to secure<br />

an undervalued bid for El Paso, <strong>and</strong> ra<strong>the</strong>r than disclose <strong>the</strong>se<br />

incentives, each chose to conceal <strong>the</strong>m. *447 Daniel knew<br />

about Goldman's conflict <strong>and</strong> he knew that his client El Paso<br />

knew about it. He also knew that he personally owned Kinder<br />

Morgan stock, but he did not disclose that fact. Foshee knew<br />

that he was discussing <strong>and</strong> considering an MBO of <strong>the</strong> E &<br />

P business when he was negotiating price terms with Kinder<br />

Morgan, but he did not disclose that fact. He did not even<br />

disclose his discussions with Kinder about an MBO after <strong>the</strong><br />

deal was baked to <strong>the</strong> Board.<br />

This kind of furtive behavior engenders legitimate concern<br />

<strong>and</strong> distrust. 45 Given that <strong>the</strong>re are numerous debatable<br />

tactical choices that now seem to have been made in<br />

large measure based on Foshee's advice <strong>and</strong> with important<br />

influence from Goldman, I believe that <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs have a<br />

probability of showing that more faithful, unconflicted parties<br />

could have secured a better price from Kinder Morgan. 46<br />

The question is what to do about it.<br />

The El Paso stockholders arguably have much to gain by<br />

seeing this Merger proceed. No one can tell what would have<br />

happened had unconflicted parties negotiated <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

That is beyond <strong>the</strong> capacity of humans.<br />

The price being offered by Kinder Morgan is one that<br />

reasonable El Paso stockholders might find very attractive.<br />

But it nags, of course, that it is not all that it might have<br />

been had things been done <strong>the</strong> way <strong>the</strong>y should have been.<br />

The absence of a pre-signing market check also grates,<br />

when <strong>the</strong> decision not to explore <strong>the</strong> market <strong>and</strong> instead do<br />

a safe, friendly deal ra<strong>the</strong>r than stretch for value or push<br />

Kinder Morgan into a public, hostile fight might have been<br />

influenced by selfish considerations, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> desire to<br />

strike <strong>the</strong> best risk-reward balance for El Paso's stockholders.<br />

In terms of <strong>the</strong> traditional analysis, <strong>the</strong> question is of course<br />

this: do <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs face a threat of irreparable injury, <strong>and</strong><br />

if so does <strong>the</strong> balance of <strong>the</strong> hardships tip in favor of an<br />

injunction? 47<br />

[4] Here, although <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs do not have <strong>the</strong> basis for<br />

claiming irreparable injury that exists when <strong>the</strong> plaintiff is a<br />

bidder, 48 <strong>the</strong> adequacy of monetary damages as a remedy to<br />

<strong>the</strong>m as stockholders is not apparent. 49 By way of example,<br />

<strong>the</strong> difference in value of Kinder Morgan's original agreement<br />

in principle bid of $27.55 in cash <strong>and</strong> stock <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> one agreed<br />

to of $26.87 equaled approximately *448 $534 million in<br />

value as of <strong>the</strong> time of signing, even giving full value to<br />

Morgan Stanley's less than certain estimate of <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong><br />

warrant component. 50<br />

On this record, it appears unlikely that <strong>the</strong> independent<br />

directors of El Paso—who are protected by an exculpatory<br />

charter provision—could be held liable in monetary damages<br />

for <strong>the</strong>ir actions. 51 Although <strong>the</strong>y should have been more<br />

keen to Goldman's conflict, <strong>the</strong>y were given reason to<br />

believe that that conflict had been addressed by <strong>the</strong> hiring<br />

of Morgan Stanley <strong>and</strong> by cabining Goldman's role. The<br />

extent to which <strong>the</strong> independent directors understood <strong>the</strong><br />

perverse incentives created for Morgan Stanley by Goldman<br />

<strong>and</strong> El Paso management by <strong>the</strong> terms of Morgan Stanley's<br />

engagement is not spelled out in <strong>the</strong> record <strong>and</strong> is <strong>the</strong> type<br />

of issue that independent directors tend to look to advisors to<br />

address. Most important, <strong>the</strong> independent directors' reliance<br />

upon Foshee seems to have been made in good faith. From<br />

<strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>point of <strong>the</strong> independent directors, Foshee seems to<br />

have been well positioned as a large holder of El Paso stock<br />

<strong>and</strong> as a trusted executive to get <strong>the</strong> best deal for El Paso's<br />

stockholders. 52 The independent directors were not trusted<br />

with <strong>the</strong> information that Foshee (<strong>and</strong> El Paso managers like<br />

Sult <strong>and</strong> Smolik) were mulling over a bid to Kinder Morgan<br />

for <strong>the</strong> E & P assets.<br />

Although Foshee is a wealthy man, it is unlikely that he would<br />

be good for a verdict of more than half a billion dollars. And<br />

although Goldman has been named as an aider <strong>and</strong> abettor<br />

<strong>and</strong> it has substantial, some might say even governmentinsured,<br />

financial resources, it is difficult to prove an aiding<br />

<strong>and</strong> abetting claim. 53 Given that Goldman's largest conflict<br />

was surfaced fully <strong>and</strong> addressed, albeit in incomplete <strong>and</strong><br />

inadequate ways, whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs could ultimately<br />

prove Goldman liable for any shortfall is, at best, doubtful,<br />

despite Daniel's troubling individual failure of disclosure.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 9


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

Nor do I find any basis to conclude that Kinder Morgan<br />

is likely to be found culpable as an aider <strong>and</strong> abettor. It<br />

bargained hard, as it was entitled to do. From its perspective,<br />

it appeared that steps were taken by El Paso <strong>and</strong> Goldman<br />

to address Goldman's conflict of interest. And Foshee's<br />

concealed interest in an MBO was not expressed by Foshee<br />

to Kinder until after <strong>the</strong> deal terms were firmed up <strong>and</strong> signed<br />

*449 into agreement, <strong>and</strong> it is not clear that Rich Kinder had<br />

any reason to know Foshee was acting without <strong>the</strong> consent of<br />

<strong>the</strong> El Paso Board.<br />

For present purposes, <strong>the</strong>refore, I am willing to accept that <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiffs have shown that <strong>the</strong>re is a likelihood of irreparable<br />

injury if <strong>the</strong> Merger is not enjoined.<br />

[5] That raises <strong>the</strong> hardest question, which is whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><br />

threat of irreparable injury justifies an injunction in light<br />

of <strong>the</strong> risks that an injunction itself would present to <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders of El Paso. Putting aside <strong>the</strong> expectations of<br />

Kinder Morgan, which is arguably stuck with <strong>the</strong> risk of<br />

having dealt with potentially faithless fiduciaries, 54 <strong>the</strong> real<br />

question is whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> court should intervene when <strong>the</strong> El<br />

Paso stockholders have a chance to turn down <strong>the</strong> Merger at<br />

<strong>the</strong> ballot box. Unlike a situation when this court will enjoin<br />

a transaction whose tainted terms are precluding ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

available option that promises higher value, 55 no rival bid<br />

for El Paso exists. 56<br />

The plaintiffs' own request for an injunction is oddly telling.<br />

In <strong>the</strong>ir many papers, <strong>the</strong>y do not seek a preliminary<br />

injunction against <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement in its traditional<br />

form, which is one that lasts until it is overturned on appeal.<br />

Such an injunction would likely persist beyond June 30, 2012,<br />

<strong>the</strong> drop-dead date in <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. That would<br />

allow Kinder Morgan to walk away on that date.<br />

Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs want an odd mixture of m<strong>and</strong>atory<br />

injunctive relief whereby I affirmatively permit El Paso to<br />

shop itself in parts or in whole during <strong>the</strong> period between now<br />

<strong>and</strong> June 30, 2012, in contravention of <strong>the</strong> no-shop provision<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement, <strong>and</strong> allow El Paso to terminate <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Agreement on grounds not permitted by <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement <strong>and</strong> without paying <strong>the</strong> termination fee set forth<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement, but <strong>the</strong>n to lift <strong>the</strong> injunction <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>n force Kinder Morgan to consummate <strong>the</strong> Merger “if no<br />

superior transactions emerge.” 57<br />

That is not a traditional negative injunction that can be<br />

done without an evidentiary hearing or undisputed facts. 58<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, *450 that sort of injunction would pose serious<br />

inequity to Kinder Morgan, which did not agree to be bound<br />

by such a bargain. 59 We all wish we could have it all ways.<br />

But that is not real life, nor is it equitable.<br />

The injunction <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs posit would be one that would<br />

sanction El Paso in breaching many covenants in <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement <strong>and</strong> that would bring about facts that would<br />

mean that El Paso could not satisfy <strong>the</strong> conditions required<br />

for Kinder Morgan to have an obligation to close. 60 The<br />

injunction <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs posit also illustrates that <strong>the</strong>y share<br />

<strong>the</strong> concern I have, which is that an injunction could pose<br />

more harm than good.<br />

They seek to keep Kinder Morgan bound but to allow El Paso<br />

to prospect for more. I underst<strong>and</strong> that, but <strong>the</strong>y are stuck with<br />

<strong>the</strong> requirements of equity, which is that <strong>the</strong>y accept <strong>the</strong> risks<br />

that come with enjoining <strong>the</strong> Merger, including <strong>the</strong> risk that<br />

Kinder Morgan will walk when <strong>the</strong> drop-dead date expires.<br />

At oral argument, however, upon questioning by <strong>the</strong> court,<br />

<strong>the</strong> plaintiffs clarified that <strong>the</strong>y would be willing to accept<br />

<strong>the</strong> traditional injunctive relief of preventing <strong>the</strong> stockholders<br />

from voting on <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

But <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs' underst<strong>and</strong>able reluctance in <strong>the</strong>ir papers to<br />

deny <strong>the</strong> El Paso stockholders <strong>the</strong> ultimate chance to take <strong>the</strong><br />

deal with Kinder Morgan despite <strong>the</strong> troubling behavior in <strong>the</strong><br />

record is one that I share. It is <strong>the</strong> stockholders' money, not<br />

mine, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs could not possibly bond <strong>the</strong> risk fully.<br />

I share <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs' frustration that <strong>the</strong> traditional tools<br />

of equity may not provide <strong>the</strong> kind of fine instrument that<br />

enables optimal protection of stockholders in this context.<br />

The kind of troubling behavior exemplified here can result<br />

in substantial wealth shifts from stockholders to insiders that<br />

are hard for <strong>the</strong> litigation system to police if stockholders<br />

continue to display a reluctance to ever turn down a premiumgenerating<br />

deal when that is presented. The negotiation<br />

process <strong>and</strong> deal *451 dance present ample opportunities for<br />

insiders to forge deals that, while “good” for stockholders,<br />

are not “as good” as <strong>the</strong>y could have been, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n to put<br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholders to a Hobson's choice. Think about some<br />

of <strong>the</strong> early management buyouts of <strong>the</strong> cappuccino market<br />

of 2006 <strong>and</strong> 2007 in that regard, where <strong>the</strong> early actions<br />

of poorly policed, conflicted CEOs in baking up deals with<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir favorite private equity sponsors before any market<br />

check (or often even board knowledge) likely dampened<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 10


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

<strong>the</strong> competition among private equity firms that could have<br />

generated <strong>the</strong> highest price if proper conduct occurred <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

right process had been used. The resulting deals might have<br />

been good for investors, but <strong>the</strong> suspicion that <strong>the</strong>y were not<br />

on <strong>the</strong> “best” terms available lingers for rational reasons.<br />

Be that as it may, that reality cannot justify <strong>the</strong> sort of<br />

odd injunction that <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs desire, which would violate<br />

accepted st<strong>and</strong>ards for <strong>the</strong> issuance of affirmative injunctions<br />

<strong>and</strong> attempt to force Kinder Morgan to consummate a<br />

different deal than it bargained for.<br />

Fundamentally, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs say that I can issue a preliminary<br />

injunction that allows El Paso a free option. It can shop any or<br />

all of itself, terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement without paying<br />

<strong>the</strong> break fee, <strong>and</strong> do what it wishes until <strong>the</strong> injunction<br />

expires. If something it likes comes along, El Paso should<br />

be able to take it, cost free. But if nothing does, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong><br />

injunction will expire <strong>and</strong> Kinder Morgan would somehow—<br />

by judicial compulsion, I assume—be forced to close, despite<br />

<strong>the</strong> pervasive breach of fundamental provisions of <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement, including <strong>the</strong> one requiring El Paso to help<br />

Kinder Morgan to sell for itself <strong>the</strong> same assets <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs<br />

seek to have El Paso market. If my assumption about judicial<br />

compulsion is right, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs do not seek a traditional<br />

negative injunction, but ra<strong>the</strong>r m<strong>and</strong>atory relief that can only<br />

be granted after a trial <strong>and</strong> a careful evaluation of Kinder<br />

Morgan's legitimate interests. 61 If <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs do not view<br />

<strong>the</strong> injunction as one involving <strong>the</strong> court compelling Kinder<br />

Morgan to close upon <strong>the</strong> injunction's expiration if <strong>the</strong> El<br />

Paso stockholders approve <strong>the</strong> Merger, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs are<br />

asking me to enter an injunction that, to my view, would likely<br />

relieve Kinder Morgan of any obligation to close because its<br />

contractual rights would have been materially breached.<br />

Given that <strong>the</strong> El Paso stockholders are well positioned to turn<br />

down <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan price if <strong>the</strong>y do not like it, I am not<br />

persuaded that I should deprive <strong>the</strong>m of <strong>the</strong> chance to make<br />

that decision for <strong>the</strong>mselves. 62 Although an after-<strong>the</strong>-fact<br />

monetary damages claim against <strong>the</strong> defendants *452 is not<br />

a perfect tool, it has some value as a remedial instrument, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> likely prospect of a damages trial is no doubt unpleasant<br />

to Foshee, o<strong>the</strong>r El Paso managers who might be added as<br />

defendants, <strong>and</strong> to Goldman. And, of course, <strong>the</strong> defendants<br />

<strong>the</strong>mselves should be mindful of <strong>the</strong> reality that in <strong>the</strong><br />

period of truncated, expedited discovery, troubling facts arose<br />

about <strong>the</strong> interests of certain key players in this M & A<br />

drama. After full discovery, it would hardly be unprecedented<br />

for additional troubling information to emerge, given <strong>the</strong><br />

suspicious instances of non-disclosure that have already been<br />

surfaced.<br />

For now, however, I reluctantly deny <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs' motion<br />

for a preliminary injunction, concluding that <strong>the</strong> El Paso<br />

stockholders should not be deprived of <strong>the</strong> chance to decide<br />

for <strong>the</strong>mselves about <strong>the</strong> Merger, despite <strong>the</strong> disturbing nature<br />

of some of <strong>the</strong> behavior leading to its terms.<br />

IT IS SO ORDERED.<br />

Footnotes<br />

1 Using Kinder Morgan's unadjusted closing stock price of $35.26 on February 28, 2012, <strong>and</strong> El Paso's unadjusted closing stock price<br />

of $20.55 on July 29, 2011. See Yahoo Finance, Kinder Morgan, Inc. Historical Stock Prices, http://finance.yahoo.com/q/hp?s=KMI<br />

+Historical+Prices (last visited Feb. 29, 2012).<br />

2 See Revlon v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 179 (Del.1986).<br />

3 Ps. Op. Br. Ex. 40 (h<strong>and</strong>written notes) at EP00013940 (“limit competition—pre ra<strong>the</strong>r than post spin.”), EP00013942 (“KM—wants<br />

to limit competition by doing pre-spin.”).<br />

4 In September 2010, when Kinder Morgan was still a private company, it made its first overture to acquire El Paso at a value of $16.50<br />

per share. The El Paso Board rejected this proposal, <strong>and</strong> no merger discussions took place between <strong>the</strong> two companies until Kinder<br />

Morgan renewed its interest in acquiring El Paso on August 30, 2011.<br />

5 See El Paso Corp. Schedule 14A filed on Jan. 31, 2011 (“Proxy Statement”), at 70. The Goldman directors on <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan<br />

board recused <strong>the</strong>mselves from Kinder Morgan discussions regarding <strong>the</strong> Merger once Rich Kinder made his intention to bid for El<br />

Paso known to <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan board before August 30, 2011.<br />

6 Foshee is <strong>the</strong> only non-independent director on El Paso's 12–person Board.<br />

7 See Yahoo Finance, Kinder Morgan, Inc. Historical Stock Prices, http://finance.yahoo.com/q/hp?s=KMI+Historical+Prices (last<br />

visited Feb. 29, 2012) (Kinder Morgan unadjusted closing stock price on October 14, 2011 of $26.89).<br />

8 The breakdown of <strong>the</strong> final per share Merger consideration is as follows: $14.65 in cash, 0.4187 in Kinder Morgan stock (for an<br />

aggregate cash/stock value of $25.91 reflecting Kinder Morgan's prior closing stock price of $26.89), <strong>and</strong> 0.640 of a warrant to<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 11


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

purchase Kinder Morgan stock, which for tax purposes has an indicative value of $0.96. Because <strong>the</strong> stock component of <strong>the</strong> deal is<br />

not fixed in dollar terms, <strong>and</strong> contains no collar, <strong>the</strong> Merger consideration will fluctuate depending on Kinder Morgan's stock price,<br />

subject to a 57%/43% proration between <strong>the</strong> cash/stock components of <strong>the</strong> aggregate consideration. See Proxy Statement at 7.<br />

9 El Paso's unadjusted closing stock price on October 14, 2011 was $19.59, implying a 37% premium. See Yahoo Finance, El Paso<br />

Corp. Historical Stock Prices, http://finance.yahoo.com/q/hp? s=EP+Historical+Prices (last visited Feb. 29, 2012).<br />

10 Ps. Op. Br. Ex. 3 (“Merger Agreement”) § 5.16. Recently, El Paso <strong>and</strong> Kinder Morgan announced that El Paso has agreed to sell <strong>the</strong><br />

E & P assets to a private equity group led by Apollo Global Management LLC for $7.15 billion. See Letter to <strong>the</strong> Court from Counsel<br />

for El Paso Defs. (Feb. 27, 2012) at Ex. A (El Paso Corp. Form 8–K) at 2.<br />

11 Merger Agreement §§ 5.3(a), (d), (f).<br />

12 El Paso Corp. Form 10–Q filed on Nov. 7, 2011, at 24 (El Paso had $24.078 billion total consolidated assets as of September 30,<br />

2011, of which $4.724 billion were E & P assets).<br />

13 See Merger Agreement § 5.3(d).<br />

14 Id. § 7.3(b).<br />

15 Assuming $12.8 billion in consolidated net debt as of August 31, 2011, <strong>and</strong> $4.5 billion in minority interest. See El Paso Defs. Ans.<br />

Br. Ex. 45 (Morgan Stanley Presentation (October 16, 2011)) at EP00021383.<br />

16 Using an approximate mid-point pipeline business enterprise valuation of $26 billion, <strong>and</strong> an approximate mid-point pipeline business<br />

equity valuation of $12.74 billion. See El Paso Defs. Ans. Br. Ex. 40 (Goldman Sachs Presentation (October 6, 2011)) at EP00000459<br />

(adjusting for certain planned debt deconsolidation of $1.5 billion in pipeline-related debt). These are rough approximations <strong>and</strong> I<br />

have applied my own training as a humanities major to arrive at <strong>the</strong> results. Rely upon <strong>the</strong>m with this caution in mind.<br />

17 Ps. Op. Br. Ex. 40 (h<strong>and</strong>written notes) at EP00013940 (“limit competition—pre ra<strong>the</strong>r than post spin.”), EP00013942 (“KM—wants<br />

to limit competition by doing pre-spin.”).<br />

18 See Foshee Tr. 167 (“[T]he collective wisdom of <strong>the</strong> group was that <strong>the</strong>re wasn't a natural ... o<strong>the</strong>r buyer for <strong>the</strong> whole that would<br />

compete within a short time window....”); Cox Tr. 196 (“In our view, those parties that would be most interested in ei<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> pipeline<br />

business or <strong>the</strong> [E & P] business, <strong>and</strong> principally <strong>the</strong> pipeline business, <strong>and</strong> those parties that were in a position to pay a significant<br />

price ... were parties that ... not only largely didn't have <strong>the</strong> financial means to acquire both, but in our judgment would, even if <strong>the</strong>y<br />

did in some cases have <strong>the</strong> financial means, would be disinclined to do so.”).<br />

19 The term sheet reflecting <strong>the</strong> $27.55 per share Merger price provided for a consideration breakdown of 60% cash <strong>and</strong> 40% stock. As<br />

of September 18, 2011, when <strong>the</strong> agreement in principle was reached, this translated to a cash/stock mix of $16.53 in cash <strong>and</strong> 0.4322<br />

shares of Kinder Morgan, reflecting Kinder Morgan's closing stock price of $25.50 as of its last trading day (September 16, 2011).<br />

Assuming that this cash/stock mix stayed constant, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> stock value would float with Kinder Morgan's prevailing market<br />

price, at today's prices this consideration would be worth $31.76.<br />

20 See El Paso Defs. Ans. Br. Ex. 36 (El Paso Corp. Board Minutes (Sept. 30, 2011)) at EP00000416 (“The Board ... re-iterated [to<br />

Foshee] that <strong>the</strong> floor value for <strong>the</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> stock consideration was $26.50 ....”); see also Foshee Tr. 293 (“Q. But <strong>the</strong>y said to you,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y reiterated that <strong>the</strong> floor value for <strong>the</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> stock consideration was 26.50; right? A. Uh-huh. Q. That wasn't expressed as a<br />

preference; right? A. No, <strong>the</strong>y reiterated that <strong>the</strong> floor value for <strong>the</strong> cash <strong>and</strong> stock was 26.50.”).<br />

21 See Paramount Commc'ns Inc. v. QVC Network Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 45 (Del.1994) (“[A] court applying enhanced judicial scrutiny<br />

should be deciding whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> directors made a reasonable decision, not a perfect decision. If a board selected one of several<br />

reasonable alternatives, a court should not second-guess that choice even though it might have decided o<strong>the</strong>rwise or subsequent events<br />

may have cast doubt on <strong>the</strong> board's determination.”).<br />

22 See In re Answers Corp. S'holders Litig., 2011 WL 1366780, at *3 (Del.Ch. Apr. 11, 2011) (“[D]irectors are generally free to select<br />

<strong>the</strong> path to value maximization, so long as <strong>the</strong>y choose a reasonable route to get <strong>the</strong>re.”) (internal quotation omitted).<br />

23 See In re Toys “R” Us, Inc. S'holder Litig., 877 A.2d 975, 1002 (Del.Ch.2005) (noting that <strong>the</strong> “paradigmatic context for a good<br />

Revlon claim ... is when a supine board under <strong>the</strong> sway of an overweening CEO bent on a certain direction [ ] tilts <strong>the</strong> sales process<br />

for reasons inimical to <strong>the</strong> stockholders' desire for <strong>the</strong> best price.”).<br />

24 Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 176 (Del.1986) (where Revlon's CEO, Michel Bergerac, rebuffed<br />

Pantry Pride's acquisition overtures in part because of <strong>the</strong> “strong personal antipathy” felt by Bergerac towards Pantry Pride's CEO,<br />

Ron Perelman, who was an upstart from Philly <strong>and</strong> not someone whom <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court believed Bergerac wanted running his<br />

storied company).<br />

25 See, e.g., In re OPENLANE, Inc., 2011 WL 4599662, at *6 (Del.Ch. Sept. 30, 2011); In re Dollar Thrifty S'holder Litig., 14 A.3d<br />

573, 616 (Del.Ch.2010); In re Lear Corp. S'holder Litig., 926 A.2d 94, 116–18 (Del.Ch.2007); Toys “R” Us, 877 A.2d at 975; In re<br />

Pennaco Energy, Inc., 787 A.2d 691, 705 (Del.Ch.2001); see also Barkan v. Amsted Indus., Inc., 567 A.2d 1279, 1288 (Del.1989).<br />

26 Indeed, Goldman's answering brief used <strong>the</strong> phrase “potential conflict” to describe its position fifteen times.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 12


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

27 Daniel owns shares issued by a Kinder Morgan affiliate with an estimated market value of at most $300,000 (as of <strong>the</strong> time of Daniel's<br />

deposition on December 22, 2011), see Daniel Tr. 15–16, <strong>and</strong> he holds an investment in a Goldman fund that is itself invested in<br />

Kinder Morgan shares, an indirect interest in Kinder Morgan worth approximately $39,000, see Schmidt Aff. 3.<br />

28 See Ps. Op. Br. Ex. 45 (Email from Metz–Dworkin to Sikhtian et. al. (September 6, 2011)).<br />

29 El Paso Defs. Ans. Br. Ex. 23 (El Paso Corp. Board Minutes (Sept. 15, 2011)) at EP00000392; see also Foshee Tr. 187 (testifying<br />

that “<strong>the</strong> thought crossed my mind” that Daniel getting pressured by o<strong>the</strong>r parts of Goldman “was a possibility.”). Goldman's advice<br />

was especially peculiar given that El Paso had a built-in defense to a hostile bid with <strong>the</strong> spin-off, which did not require a stockholder<br />

vote <strong>and</strong> was close to receiving approval by <strong>the</strong> S.E.C. Foshee Tr. 180–82. Thus, not even Foshee was worried about Kinder's threat<br />

to go public, because, as Foshee put it, “time was on our side.” Foshee Tr. 179.<br />

30 Interestingly, <strong>the</strong> record suggests that it was Goldman's close clients in El Paso management who suspected at times that Goldman<br />

was not honoring <strong>the</strong> Chinese wall <strong>and</strong> who decided that Goldman be walled off from Merger discussions <strong>and</strong> negotiations. The court<br />

is aware of <strong>the</strong> inconsistency that emerges from this evidence. On <strong>the</strong> one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>the</strong>re are many indications in <strong>the</strong> record that El Paso<br />

management was very close to Goldman, viewed Goldman as <strong>the</strong>ir trusted advisor, <strong>and</strong> wanted Goldman near <strong>the</strong> scene at all times.<br />

But, at <strong>the</strong> same time <strong>the</strong>re are indications that El Paso management was suspicious that Goldman's advice about how to react to<br />

Kinder Morgan's overture was tilted by its investment in Kinder Morgan <strong>and</strong> its desire to avoid Kinder Morgan having to go hostile.<br />

Because we are at a preliminary injunction stage with a limited factual record, it is not yet necessary or prudent to try to fully resolve<br />

<strong>the</strong>se inconsistencies in light of <strong>the</strong> benefit that a more developed factual record would afford.<br />

31 Goldman primarily used a comparable companies analysis to value <strong>the</strong> E & P business following <strong>the</strong> spin-off. Due to declining EV/<br />

EBITDA trading multiples of peer companies, Goldman indicated that <strong>the</strong> E & P business had lost $2 billion in value when valued<br />

under that method from <strong>the</strong> time <strong>the</strong> Board announced <strong>the</strong> spin-off in May 2011—before Kinder Morgan had come on <strong>the</strong> scene<br />

<strong>and</strong> presented a rival strategic option—<strong>and</strong> October 2011, when <strong>the</strong> Board ab<strong>and</strong>oned <strong>the</strong> spin-off in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger. In its final<br />

presentation to <strong>the</strong> Board on October 6, 2011, Goldman estimated that <strong>the</strong> E & P business had an enterprise value worth only $6–8<br />

billion, as opposed to its mid-September valuation at $7–9 billion, <strong>and</strong> its May valuation at $8–10 billion. By way of comparison,<br />

Kinder Morgan's investment banker estimated on September 28, 2011—only a week earlier—that it could sell <strong>the</strong> E & P assets for<br />

$7.846 billion.<br />

Goldman's valuation can be seen as questionable because <strong>the</strong>se market multiples were at depressed levels due to short-term<br />

volatility in commodity prices, <strong>and</strong> were not meant to provide a long-term indicator of <strong>the</strong> E & P business's value. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, as<br />

testified to by lead Goldman banker Steve Daniel, <strong>the</strong> analysis was only to serve as “a depiction of an estimate of <strong>the</strong> [enterprise<br />

value] range based on <strong>the</strong>n-market conditions, <strong>and</strong> again, assuming that <strong>the</strong> company was already out freely trading on its own....<br />

This is just a current [picture] at that time fixture of what [<strong>the</strong> value based on trades in minority blocks] looked like.” Daniel Tr.<br />

157. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, solely looking to market multiples to generate a hypo<strong>the</strong>tical trading value fails to take into account <strong>the</strong> control<br />

premium that could be achieved upon a sale of <strong>the</strong> E & P business. See Bradford Cornell, Corporate Valuation 49 (1993) (noting<br />

that valuations calculated using current market trading prices of stock are “based on <strong>the</strong> prices at which minority positions trade<br />

in <strong>the</strong> market,” <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore “will not take into account a ‘control premium.’ ”). It is unclear from <strong>the</strong> record whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

understood <strong>the</strong> limitations to Goldman's analysis.<br />

32 See Foshee Tr. 159–61; see also id. at 160 (“Q. Would [<strong>the</strong> fact that Daniel had a personal financial stake in Kinder Morgan] matter<br />

to you? A. It might. Q. Why?.... A. It would just be one more piece of information for <strong>the</strong> potential for conflict. That is not between<br />

two divisions, but between one person's brain.”).<br />

33 See Daniel Tr. 195 (“It was more like ... [Morgan Stanley] had asked—so [John Sult, El Paso's CFO] was asking but he was going to<br />

be okay with wherever we went with it.”); Sult Tr. 243 (“I wasn't going to force Goldman Sachs to [amend its exclusivity agreement].<br />

I signed an agreement <strong>and</strong> I would live by <strong>the</strong> agreement.”).<br />

34 In fairness to Morgan Stanley, it is not clear from <strong>the</strong> record when in <strong>the</strong> advisory process it was first made aware of this fee<br />

arrangement. But, it is clear that by at least October 5, 2011, Morgan Stanley was aware that it would only get a lucrative banking<br />

fee if El Paso did a deal with Kinder Morgan, <strong>and</strong> that it would get nothing if El Paso decided to move forward with <strong>the</strong> spinoff.<br />

Following October 5, 2011, Morgan Stanley met with <strong>the</strong> Board twice, <strong>and</strong> each time advised <strong>the</strong> Board that <strong>the</strong> final Merger<br />

consideration offered by Kinder Morgan was fair.<br />

35 The record includes evidence that supports a plausible argument that Morgan Stanley's analysis undervalued El Paso's stock <strong>and</strong><br />

overvalued Kinder Morgan's stock. For example, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs argue that Morgan Stanley used an unreasonably low terminal multiple<br />

for a portion of its discounted cash flow analysis of <strong>the</strong> pipeline business. Ra<strong>the</strong>r than use a perpetual growth model to calculate <strong>the</strong><br />

pipeline business's terminal value, Morgan Stanley used a mid-point exit EV/EBITDA multiple of 10x, which implied a perpetual<br />

growth rate of only 0.7%. That is, Morgan Stanley calculated that <strong>the</strong> pipeline business would grow only 0.7% from 2016 into<br />

perpetuity—a rate less than half of <strong>the</strong> estimated rate of inflation (2%)—an implication which is inconsistent with Foshee's testimony<br />

that <strong>the</strong> pipeline business had strong growth prospects, see Foshee Tr. 65–66, <strong>and</strong> with <strong>the</strong> projections prepared by El Paso's<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 13


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

management <strong>and</strong> used by Morgan Stanley, which included both maintenance <strong>and</strong> growth capital expenditures. See El Paso Defs.<br />

Ans. Br. Ex. 30 (Morgan Stanley Presentation (Sept. 26, 2011)) at EP00000687. Evidence also suggests that Morgan Stanley used<br />

values for Kinder Morgan's cost of equity in an internally inconsistent way, using a higher cost of equity (11.8%) when benchmarking<br />

El Paso's cost of equity, but a lower number (7.5%) when valuing Kinder Morgan directly. In this way, Morgan Stanley's analysis<br />

arguably skewed in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger by using a deflated cost of equity when valuing Kinder Morgan, in turn overvaluing <strong>the</strong><br />

Kinder Morgan stock portion of <strong>the</strong> Merger consideration.<br />

36 Indeed, key El Paso executives believed that Goldman deserved this $20 million fee for all of its work on <strong>the</strong> spin-off that would go<br />

unrewarded if <strong>the</strong> Board entered into <strong>the</strong> Merger with Kinder Morgan, thus depriving Goldman of its $25 million fee contingent on<br />

<strong>the</strong> consummation of <strong>the</strong> spin-off. See Foshee Tr. 198; Sult Tr. 242. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>se executives wanted to reward Goldman for its<br />

“eight [<strong>and</strong> a half] years worth of strategic advisory work for El Paso.” Foshee Tr. 199. Never mind that Goldman was paid $150,000<br />

annually through a retainer agreement it had in place with El Paso, <strong>and</strong> on top of that had received approximately $9.7 million in fees<br />

from El Paso between 2008 through May 2011 alone. See Sult Tr. 101.<br />

37 Although when Foshee <strong>and</strong> Smolik discussed <strong>the</strong> idea of an MBO is unclear, <strong>the</strong> October 11, 2011 email exchange between Sult <strong>and</strong><br />

Smolik, in which Sult expressed his interest in an MBO, <strong>and</strong> Smolik responded that he had “discussed [<strong>the</strong> possibility] with Doug<br />

[Foshee]” <strong>and</strong> Foshee “wants to hold <strong>the</strong> discussion as late as possible, but is willing (maybe even desires) to have <strong>the</strong> discussion<br />

with [Kinder Morgan],” Ps. Op. Br. Ex. 41 (Email Exchange between Sult <strong>and</strong> Smolik (October 11, 2011)), suggests that Sult caught<br />

on to an idea that Foshee <strong>and</strong> Smolik were already well along in exploring, but that Foshee wished to keep quiet until a deal with<br />

Kinder Morgan was solidified.<br />

38 Id.; see also Foshee Tr. at 271 (confirming that when Smolik brought up <strong>the</strong> idea of an MBO before <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement was<br />

signed, Foshee told Smolik, “now is probably not <strong>the</strong> time to have that conversation”).<br />

39 See In re Netsmart Techs., Inc. S'holders Litig., 924 A.2d 171, 199 (Del.Ch.2007); see also Barkan v. Amsted Indus., Inc., 567 A.2d<br />

1279, 1287 (Del.1989) (“When <strong>the</strong> board is considering a single offer <strong>and</strong> has no reliable grounds upon which to judge its adequacy,<br />

this concern for fairness dem<strong>and</strong>s a canvas of <strong>the</strong> market to determine if higher bids may be elicited.”).<br />

40 See Mills Acquisition Co. v. Macmillan, Inc., 559 A.2d 1261, 1282 (Del.1989) (stating that corporate officers' “knowing concealment<br />

of [a] tip at [a] critical board meeting ... utterly destroys <strong>the</strong>ir credibility,” <strong>and</strong> finding that “[g]iven <strong>the</strong>ir duty of disclosure under <strong>the</strong><br />

circumstances, this silence [was] an explicit acknowledgment of <strong>the</strong>ir culpability.”).<br />

41 E.g., In re El Paso Corp. S'holder Litig., C.A. No. 6949 at 242 (Del. Ch. Feb. 9, 2012) (TRANSCRIPT) (counsel for Goldman stating<br />

that “Goldman was asked to advise El Paso [on <strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan deal]” <strong>and</strong> that “Goldman wanted to get in on <strong>the</strong> [Kinder Morgan]<br />

deal. I'm not denying that.”).<br />

42 As illuminated by <strong>the</strong> testimony of Morgan Stanley's Jonathan Cox:<br />

And we were interested in having a letter signed with respect to [<strong>the</strong> spin-off], <strong>and</strong> we were told that Goldman was being asked as<br />

to whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y would amend <strong>the</strong> letter to remove <strong>the</strong> word “exclusive,” <strong>and</strong> you will see on October 12, that [El Paso's general<br />

counsel] says no, <strong>the</strong>y haven't given on <strong>the</strong> exclusive issue. They were accommodating on o<strong>the</strong>r issues, but not on exclusivity,<br />

to paraphrase. So I said, I see. Does that mean that we are exclusive on [<strong>the</strong> Merger?] Does that mean that what you are granting<br />

Goldman Sachs on [<strong>the</strong> spin-off] is something you would grant us on [<strong>the</strong> Merger?] And we were told no, it was a rhetorical<br />

question. I simply said, I underst<strong>and</strong>, we appreciate <strong>the</strong> business.<br />

Cox Tr. 190.<br />

43 According to Blankfein's draft script for <strong>the</strong> call, which was prepared by Steve Daniel, Blankfein was to tell Foshee <strong>the</strong> following:<br />

Hello Doug—it's been a long time since we have had <strong>the</strong> chance to visit/[I] wanted to reach out <strong>and</strong> say thank you for everything<br />

from [Goldman]..../<strong>You</strong> have been very good to [Goldman] in having us help on all kinds of transactions over <strong>the</strong> years..../And<br />

of course I was very pleased you reached out to us on this most recent matter [<strong>the</strong> Kinder Morgan proposal]—which I underst<strong>and</strong><br />

is very serious..../I know you are aware of [Goldman's] investment [in Kinder Morgan] <strong>and</strong> that we are very sensitive to <strong>the</strong><br />

appearance of conflict/We have asked our board members to recuse <strong>the</strong>mselves <strong>and</strong> I know you have taken on a second advisor..../<br />

Really just wanted to reach out <strong>and</strong> say thank you..../Please call me any time/I'll be watching this situation very closely....<br />

El Paso Defs. Ans. Br. Ex. 16 (Email from Daniel to Blankfein (Sept. 7, 2011)).<br />

44 El Paso Defs. Ans. Br. Ex 15 (Email Exchange between Cox <strong>and</strong> Munger (Oct. 16, 2011)).<br />

45 See Macmillan, 559 A.2d at 1282.<br />

46 For its part, Kinder Morgan characterizes <strong>the</strong> negotiations as hard fought, <strong>and</strong> it says that it was not willing to pay a penny more for<br />

El Paso. E.g., In re El Paso Corp. S'holder Litig., C.A. No. 6949 at 234 (Del. Ch. Feb. 9, 2012) (TRANSCRIPT) (Kinder Morgan's<br />

counsel stating that “<strong>the</strong> negotiations extracted, at least from us, <strong>the</strong> last pennies that we were prepared to pay.”). But, Kinder Morgan,<br />

of course, says this at a time when it has a powerful self-interest as a buyer <strong>and</strong> a defendant to portray <strong>the</strong> negotiations in that way.<br />

47 See Macmillan, 559 A.2d at 1278–79; Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 179 (Del.1986); Cantor<br />

Fitzgerald, L.P. v. Cantor, 724 A.2d 571, 579 (Del.Ch.1998).<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 14


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

48 Compare Revlon, 506 A.2d at 184–85 (agreeing with <strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery that “unless <strong>the</strong> lock-up <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r aspects of <strong>the</strong> agreement<br />

were enjoined, Pantry Pride's opportunity to bid for Revlon was lost,” <strong>and</strong> “<strong>the</strong> need for both bidders to compete in <strong>the</strong> marketplace<br />

outweighed any injury to Forstmann.”).<br />

49 The adequacy of money damages, of course, typically means that <strong>the</strong> irreparable injury required to grant an injunction is absent. E.g.,<br />

Gradient OC Master, Ltd. v. NBC Universal, Inc., 930 A.2d 104, 132 (Del.Ch.2007).<br />

50 $0.68 * approximately 786 million shares of El Paso on a diluted basis = $534,480,000. See El Paso Defs. Ans. Br. Ex. 45 (Morgan<br />

Stanley Presentation (October 16, 2011)) at EP00021383 (assuming 786 million fully diluted El Paso shares).<br />

51 See 8 Del. C. § 102(b)(7); see also In re Del Monte Foods Co. S'holders Litig., 25 A.3d 813, 838 (Del.Ch.2011) (“Exculpation under<br />

Section 102(b)(7) can render empty <strong>the</strong> promise of post-closing damages.”).<br />

52 Foshee st<strong>and</strong>s to receive approximately $90 million upon consummation of <strong>the</strong> Merger. Of that $90 million, approximately $55<br />

million would come from unrestricted stock <strong>and</strong> vested options, <strong>and</strong> ano<strong>the</strong>r approximately $26 million would come from unvested<br />

stock options, restricted shares <strong>and</strong> stock units that will vest as a result of <strong>the</strong> Merger. See Proxy Statement at 171–72; El Paso Defs.<br />

Ans. Br. Ex. 2 (El Paso Corp. Schedule 14A) at 27, 58–59; El Paso Defs. Ans. Br. Ex. 46 (El Paso Corp. Preliminary Form S–4)<br />

at 170–71.<br />

53 See Binks v. DSL.net, Inc., 2010 WL 1713629, at *10 (Del.Ch. Apr.29, 2010) (“The st<strong>and</strong>ard for an aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting claim is<br />

a stringent one, one that turns on proof of scienter of <strong>the</strong> alleged abettor.”); Allied Capital Corp. v. GC–Sun Holdings, L.P., 910<br />

A.2d 1020, 1039 (Del.Ch.2006) (“[T]he test for stating an aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting claim is a stringent one ...—a plaintiff must prove:<br />

(1) <strong>the</strong> existence of a fiduciary relationship, (2) a breach of <strong>the</strong> fiduciary's duty <strong>and</strong> (3) knowing participation in that breach by <strong>the</strong><br />

non-fiduciary.”).<br />

54 See Paramount Commc'ns Inc. v. QVC Network Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 51 (Del.1994) (“To <strong>the</strong> extent that a contract, or a provision<br />

<strong>the</strong>reof, purports to require a board to act or not act in such a fashion as to limit <strong>the</strong> exercise of fiduciary duties, it is invalid <strong>and</strong><br />

unenforceable.”); Restatement (Second) of Contracts § 193 (1981) (“A promise by a fiduciary to violate his fiduciary duty or a<br />

promise that tends to induce such a violation is unenforceable on grounds of public policy.”).<br />

55 See Revlon, Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Holdings, Inc., 506 A.2d 173, 184–85 (Del.1986) (granting a preliminary injunction<br />

against preclusive merger provisions that were impeding <strong>the</strong> ability of competing potential buyer to have its higher bid accepted);<br />

QVC Network, Inc. v. Paramount Commc'ns, Inc., 635 A.2d 1245, 1273 n. 50 (Del.Ch.1993), aff'd, 637 A.2d 34 (Del.1994) (“Since<br />

<strong>the</strong> opportunity for shareholders to receive a superior control premium would be irrevocably lost if injunctive relief were not granted,<br />

that alone would be sufficient to constitute irreparable harm.”).<br />

56 Although it is true that <strong>the</strong> absence of a pre-signing market check <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> presence of strong deal protections may explain <strong>the</strong> absence<br />

of a competing bid, <strong>the</strong> reality is that this is a high-profile transaction, litigation has been pending since early autumn 2011, <strong>and</strong> no<br />

bidder has emerged indicating that it would bid for any part of El Paso absent <strong>the</strong> deal protections. In <strong>the</strong> era in which Revlon was<br />

decided, bidders wishing to disrupt transactions actually made <strong>the</strong>ir presence known <strong>and</strong> litigated to achieve <strong>the</strong>ir objectives. Even<br />

in <strong>the</strong>se more genteel times, that happens.<br />

57 Ps. Op. Br. at 75.<br />

58 In re Toys “R” Us, Inc. S'holder Litig., 877 A.2d 975, 1022–23 (Del.Ch.2005).<br />

59 See NACCO Indus., Inc. v. Applica Inc., 997 A.2d 1, 35 (Del.Ch.2009) (“Delaware upholds <strong>the</strong> freedom of contract <strong>and</strong> enforces as<br />

a matter of fundamental public policy <strong>the</strong> voluntary agreements of sophisticated parties.”).<br />

60 The plaintiffs' desire for an injunction to allow El Paso to shop <strong>the</strong> E & P <strong>and</strong> pipeline businesses conflicts with several covenants<br />

<strong>and</strong> representations <strong>and</strong> warranties in <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. For example, <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement requires El Paso to help Kinder<br />

Morgan market <strong>the</strong> E & P assets so that Kinder Morgan can sell <strong>the</strong>m to help finance <strong>the</strong> purchase. Merger Agreement § 5.16. If<br />

El Paso sought to sell <strong>the</strong> E & P assets for itself, that would breach <strong>the</strong> covenant. El Paso also committed not to shop <strong>the</strong> company<br />

under <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. Id. § 5.3(a). See also id. § 5.2(a)(iii) (El Paso covenants not to sell any of its assets with a fair market<br />

value of more than $75 million); id. § 3.6(c) (El Paso represents <strong>and</strong> warrants that nei<strong>the</strong>r it nor its subsidiaries have taken <strong>the</strong> action<br />

described in § 5.2(a)(iii)); id. § 5.4(a) (El Paso agrees to use its reasonable best efforts to cause closing conditions to be “satisfied<br />

as promptly as practicable.”). El Paso also agreed not to terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement except on certain specified conditions,<br />

including its compliance with <strong>the</strong> match right <strong>and</strong> termination fee provisions, all of which <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs seek me to enjoin. Id. §<br />

7.1(d)(iii). El Paso's representations, warranties <strong>and</strong> covenants are brought down to <strong>the</strong> date of closing under §§ 6.2(a) <strong>and</strong> (b) of <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Agreement, <strong>and</strong> any incurred breach of <strong>the</strong>se provisions would give Kinder Morgan <strong>the</strong> right to walk. See id. § 7.1(c)(iii)<br />

(giving Kinder Morgan a termination right “if [El Paso] shall have breached or failed to perform any of its representations, warranties,<br />

covenants or agreements set forth in this Agreement ... which breach or failure ... would (if it occurred or was continuing as of <strong>the</strong><br />

Closing Date) give rise to <strong>the</strong> failure of a condition set forth in Section 6.2(a) or (b)” <strong>and</strong> such failure is not cured by El Paso within<br />

30 days of Kinder Morgan receiving notice of it.).<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 15


In re El Paso Corp. Shareholder <strong>Litigation</strong>, 41 A.3d 432 (2012)<br />

61 See Toys “R” Us, 877 A.2d at 1022–23 (refusing to “blue pencil” provisions in a merger agreement “before a trial has even been<br />

held,” noting that “[t]o grant that sort of m<strong>and</strong>atory relief would ... be inappropriate on disputed facts, <strong>and</strong> plaintiffs who seek such<br />

relief should move promptly, not for a preliminary injunction hearing, but for an expedited trial.”); Alpha Natural Res., Inc. v. Cliff's<br />

Natural Res., Inc., 2008 WL 4951060, at *2 (Del.Ch. Nov. 6, 2008) (noting that a m<strong>and</strong>atory preliminary injunction is “extraordinary<br />

relief of a sort that <strong>the</strong> court does not issue lightly” <strong>and</strong> “requires ... a showing that <strong>the</strong> petitioner is entitled as a matter of law to<br />

<strong>the</strong> relief it seeks based on undisputed facts.”); ID Biomedical Corp. v. TM Techs., Inc., 1995 WL 130743, at *15 (Del.Ch. Mar. 16,<br />

1995) (“The Court will only award a m<strong>and</strong>atory injunction in a clear case, free from doubt.”); Si–Lake, Inc. v. Conroy, 1994 WL<br />

728824, at *4 (Del.Ch. Dec. 16, 1994) (“To succeed on an application for a m<strong>and</strong>atory injunction, <strong>the</strong> burden on <strong>the</strong> moving party<br />

increases. The moving party must clearly establish it is legally entitled to relief.”).<br />

62 See, e.g., In re Netsmart Techs., Inc. S'holders Litig., 924 A.2d 171, 208 (Del.Ch.2007) (“In ... cases when a potential Revlon violation<br />

occurred but no rival bid is on <strong>the</strong> table, <strong>the</strong> denial of injunctive relief is often premised on <strong>the</strong> imprudence of having <strong>the</strong> court enjoin<br />

<strong>the</strong> only deal on <strong>the</strong> table, when <strong>the</strong> stockholders can make that decision for <strong>the</strong>mselves.”); Toys “R” Us, 877 A.2d at 1023 (“[T]he<br />

bottom line is that <strong>the</strong> public shareholders will have an opportunity ... to reject <strong>the</strong> merger if <strong>the</strong>y do not think <strong>the</strong> price is high enough<br />

in light of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>'s st<strong>and</strong>-alone value <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r options.”).<br />

End of Document<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 16


Del Monte Foods <strong>Company</strong> Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

25 A.3d 813<br />

Court of Chancery of Delaware.<br />

In re DEL MONTE FOODS COMPANY<br />

SHAREHOLDERS LITIGATION.<br />

C.A. No. 6027–VCL. | Submitted:<br />

Feb. 11, 2011. | Decided: Feb. 14, 2011.<br />

Synopsis<br />

Background: Shareholders brought action seeking<br />

injunction to delay shareholder vote on sale of corporation to<br />

high bidder.<br />

Holdings: The Court of Chancery, Laster, Vice Chancellor,<br />

held that:<br />

[1] evidence established a reasonable likelihood of success on<br />

<strong>the</strong> merits of shareholders' claim that directors failed to act<br />

reasonably in connection with process to sell corporation;<br />

[2] evidence established a reasonable likelihood of success on<br />

<strong>the</strong> merits of shareholders' claim that high bidder to purchase<br />

corporation aided <strong>and</strong> abetted breaches of fiduciary duty;<br />

[3] shareholders would suffer irreparable injury absent<br />

injunction;<br />

[4] corporation would be enjoined from conducting a<br />

stockholder vote on <strong>the</strong> merger for a period of only 20 days.<br />

So ordered.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[2] Injunction<br />

Likelihood of success on merits<br />

A showing of a reasonable probability of success<br />

on <strong>the</strong> merits, as required for issuance of a<br />

preliminary injunction, falls well short of that<br />

which would be required to secure final relief<br />

following trial.<br />

[3] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties as to Management of<br />

Corporate Affairs in General<br />

Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Business judgment rule in general<br />

Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Entire fairness in general<br />

Delaware has three tiers of review for evaluating<br />

director decision-making: <strong>the</strong> business judgment<br />

rule, enhanced scrutiny, <strong>and</strong> entire fairness.<br />

[4] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Conflicts of Interest <strong>and</strong> Self-Dealing in<br />

General<br />

Enhanced judicial scrutiny of director decisionmaking<br />

applies when directors face potentially<br />

subtle structural or situational conflicts that do<br />

not rise to a level sufficient to trigger entire<br />

fairness review, but also do not comfortably<br />

permit expansive judicial deference.<br />

West Headnotes (27)<br />

[1] Injunction<br />

Grounds in general; multiple factors<br />

To obtain a preliminary injunction, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs<br />

must demonstrate (1) a reasonable probability of<br />

success on <strong>the</strong> merits; (2) that <strong>the</strong>y will suffer<br />

irreparable injury if an injunction is not granted;<br />

<strong>and</strong> (3) that <strong>the</strong> balance of <strong>the</strong> equities favors <strong>the</strong><br />

issuance of an injunction.<br />

[5] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Evidence<br />

Under enhanced judicial scrutiny of director<br />

decision-making, <strong>the</strong> directors bear <strong>the</strong> burden of<br />

persuasion to show that <strong>the</strong>ir motivations were<br />

proper <strong>and</strong> not selfish.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[6] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Duties of directors <strong>and</strong> officers in general;<br />

business judgment rule<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 1


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

To show that <strong>the</strong>ir motivations were proper <strong>and</strong><br />

not selfish under enhanced judicial scrutiny in<br />

<strong>the</strong> mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions context, directors<br />

must show that <strong>the</strong>y sought to secure <strong>the</strong><br />

transaction offering <strong>the</strong> best value reasonably<br />

available for <strong>the</strong> stockholders.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[7] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties as to Management of<br />

Corporate Affairs in General<br />

Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Evidence<br />

To demonstrate that <strong>the</strong>ir actions were<br />

reasonable in relation to <strong>the</strong>ir legitimate<br />

objective under enhanced judicial scrutiny,<br />

directors bear <strong>the</strong> burden of proving that <strong>the</strong>y (1)<br />

followed a reasonable decision-making process<br />

<strong>and</strong> based <strong>the</strong>ir decisions on a reasonable body<br />

of information, <strong>and</strong> (2) acted reasonably in light<br />

of <strong>the</strong> circumstances <strong>the</strong>n existing.<br />

[8] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties as to Management of<br />

Corporate Affairs in General<br />

The reasonableness st<strong>and</strong>ard of objective<br />

component of enhanced judicial scrutiny of<br />

director decision-making permits a reviewing<br />

court to address inequitable action even when<br />

directors may have subjectively believed that<br />

<strong>the</strong>y were acting properly.<br />

[9] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties as to Management of<br />

Corporate Affairs in General<br />

Objective component of enhanced judicial<br />

scrutiny of director decision-making does not<br />

permit a reviewing court to freely substitute its<br />

own judgment for that of <strong>the</strong> directors.<br />

[10] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fiduciary Duties as to Management of<br />

Corporate Affairs in General<br />

Enhanced judicial scrutiny of director decisionmaking<br />

is not a license for law-trained courts to<br />

second-guess reasonable, but debatable, tactical<br />

choices that directors have made in good faith.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[11] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Duties of directors <strong>and</strong> officers in general;<br />

business judgment rule<br />

In evaluating <strong>the</strong> adequacy of <strong>the</strong> directors'<br />

decision-making <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> information <strong>the</strong>y had<br />

available in <strong>the</strong> mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions context,<br />

a reviewing court necessarily will consider <strong>the</strong><br />

extent to which a board has relied on expert<br />

advisors.<br />

[12] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Duties of directors <strong>and</strong> officers in general;<br />

business judgment rule<br />

Board of directors must take an active <strong>and</strong> direct<br />

role in <strong>the</strong> sale process in a change of control<br />

transaction.<br />

[13] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

Evidence established a reasonable likelihood of<br />

success on <strong>the</strong> merits of shareholders' claim that<br />

directors failed to act reasonably in connection<br />

with process to sell corporation, as would<br />

support issuance of preliminary injunction to<br />

delay sale for purposes of permitting o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

bidders to come forward; although board was<br />

misled by self-interested financial advisor,<br />

board's lack of involvement in sale process<br />

enabled financial advisor to engage in selfinterested<br />

dealing that tainted <strong>the</strong> sale process.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[14] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting<br />

The four elements of a claim of aiding <strong>and</strong><br />

abetting a breach of a corporate fiduciary's<br />

duty are (1) <strong>the</strong> existence of a fiduciary<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 2


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

relationship, (2) a breach of <strong>the</strong> fiduciary's duty,<br />

(3) knowing participation in that breach by <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants, <strong>and</strong> (4) damages proximately caused<br />

by <strong>the</strong> breach; <strong>the</strong> critical element is knowing<br />

participation.<br />

2 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[15] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting<br />

A third party's knowing participation in a<br />

fiduciary breach by board of directors, as is<br />

required to establish a claim of aiding <strong>and</strong><br />

abetting a breach of a corporate fiduciary's<br />

duty, requires that <strong>the</strong> third party act with <strong>the</strong><br />

knowledge that <strong>the</strong> conduct advocated or assisted<br />

constitutes such a breach.<br />

4 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[16] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Duties of directors <strong>and</strong> officers in general;<br />

business judgment rule<br />

A third-party bidder's attempts to reduce <strong>the</strong><br />

sale price of target corporation through arm'slength<br />

negotiations cannot give rise to liability<br />

for aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting a fiduciary breach by<br />

corporation's board of directors.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[17] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Duties of directors <strong>and</strong> officers in general;<br />

business judgment rule<br />

A third-party bidder may be liable to a<br />

target corporation's stockholders for aiding <strong>and</strong><br />

abetting a fiduciary breach by corporation's<br />

board of directors if <strong>the</strong> bidder attempts to create<br />

or exploit conflicts of interest in <strong>the</strong> board <strong>and</strong> if<br />

<strong>the</strong> bidder <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> board conspire in or agree to<br />

<strong>the</strong> fiduciary breach.<br />

2 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[18] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Duties of directors <strong>and</strong> officers in general;<br />

business judgment rule<br />

An acquirer is free to seek <strong>the</strong> lowest possible<br />

price through arms' length negotiations with<br />

<strong>the</strong> target corporation's board of directors, but<br />

acquirer may not knowingly participate in <strong>the</strong><br />

target board's breach of fiduciary duty by<br />

extracting terms which require <strong>the</strong> opposite party<br />

to prefer its interests at <strong>the</strong> expense of its<br />

shareholders.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[19] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

Evidence established a reasonable likelihood of<br />

success on <strong>the</strong> merits of shareholders' claim<br />

that high bidder to purchase corporation aided<br />

<strong>and</strong> abetted breaches of fiduciary duty that<br />

resulted from misconduct by bank facilitating<br />

sale of corporation, as would support issuance of<br />

preliminary injunction to delay sale for purposes<br />

of permitting o<strong>the</strong>r bidders to come forward;<br />

bidder knowingly participated in bank's selfinterested<br />

activities, <strong>and</strong> agreed with bank to<br />

keep ano<strong>the</strong>r bidder's involvement from <strong>the</strong><br />

corporation's board.<br />

[20] Injunction<br />

Equitable considerations in general<br />

Injunction<br />

Irreparable injury<br />

Injunction<br />

Adequacy of remedy at law<br />

Harm is irreparable, as would support issuance of<br />

a preliminary injunction, unless alternative legal<br />

redress is clearly available <strong>and</strong> is as practical <strong>and</strong><br />

efficient to <strong>the</strong> ends of justice <strong>and</strong> its prompt<br />

administration as <strong>the</strong> remedy in equity.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[21] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

Shareholders of corporation would suffer<br />

irreparable injury absent preliminary injunction<br />

to delay sale of corporation to high bidder;<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 3


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

because corporation had agreed to be purchased<br />

without directors' knowledge that <strong>the</strong> bank<br />

facilitating <strong>the</strong> transaction was engaging in<br />

self-interested dealing with <strong>the</strong> high bidder,<br />

stockholders would be deprived forever of <strong>the</strong><br />

unique opportunity to receive a pre-vote topping<br />

bid in a process free of taint from bank's improper<br />

activities.<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

[25] Fraud<br />

Persons liable<br />

When a party aids <strong>and</strong> abets a breach of fiduciary<br />

duty, <strong>the</strong> contract rights that <strong>the</strong> aider <strong>and</strong> abettor<br />

secures as a result of <strong>the</strong> interaction must give<br />

way to <strong>the</strong> superior equitable rights <strong>and</strong> interests<br />

of <strong>the</strong> beneficiaries.<br />

[22] Injunction<br />

Balancing or weighing hardship or injury<br />

A court must be cautious that its order for<br />

preliminary injunction does not threaten more<br />

harm than good; that is, a court in exercising its<br />

discretion to issue or deny such a remedy must<br />

consider all of <strong>the</strong> foreseeable consequences of<br />

its order <strong>and</strong> balance <strong>the</strong>m, <strong>and</strong> court cannot,<br />

in equity, risk greater harm to defendants, <strong>the</strong><br />

public, or o<strong>the</strong>r identified interests, in granting<br />

<strong>the</strong> injunction, than it seeks to prevent.<br />

[23] Injunction<br />

Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions; anti-takeover<br />

measures<br />

Corporation would be preliminarily enjoined<br />

from conducting a stockholder vote on <strong>the</strong><br />

merger for a period of 20 days, during which<br />

time <strong>the</strong> parties would be enjoined from<br />

enforcing deal protection measures, in action<br />

by shareholders alleging that bank facilitating<br />

sale of corporation engaged in self-interested<br />

dealing with high bidder; delay would provide<br />

ample time for a serious <strong>and</strong> motivated bidder<br />

to emerge, but would also leave ample time for<br />

<strong>the</strong> existing merger agreement to be concluded<br />

should no o<strong>the</strong>r bidders come forward.<br />

[24] Contracts<br />

Nature <strong>and</strong> grounds of contractual<br />

obligation<br />

Delaware upholds <strong>the</strong> freedom of contract <strong>and</strong><br />

enforces as a matter of fundamental public<br />

policy <strong>the</strong> voluntary agreements of sophisticated<br />

parties.<br />

[26] Injunction<br />

Wrongful or improper issuance in general<br />

Injunction<br />

Effect of bond or lack <strong>the</strong>reof; exclusivity<br />

of remedy<br />

A party that is wrongfully enjoined may recover<br />

damages resulting from <strong>the</strong> injunction, but that<br />

recovery is limited to <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>the</strong> bond.<br />

Chancery Court Rule 65(c).<br />

[27] Injunction<br />

Amount<br />

Chancery court would set injunction bond<br />

at $1.2 million, representing one percent of<br />

<strong>the</strong> enjoined termination fee that high bidder<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise would have received in <strong>the</strong> event of<br />

a topping bid, in connection with court's grant<br />

of preliminary injunction prohibiting corporation<br />

from conducting a stockholder vote on merger<br />

for a period of 20 days in order to provide<br />

time for a serious <strong>and</strong> motivated bidder to<br />

emerge, in shareholders' action alleging that<br />

bank facilitating sale of corporation engaged in<br />

self-interested dealing with high bidder; court<br />

was not enjoining <strong>the</strong> transaction from closing<br />

pending <strong>the</strong> outcome of a trial but ra<strong>the</strong>r was<br />

imposing a delay akin to a disclosure-based<br />

injunction, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> likelihood of a topping bid<br />

was low. Chancery Court Rule 65(c).<br />

1 Cases that cite this headnote<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 4


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

Attorneys <strong>and</strong> Law Firms<br />

*816 Stuart M. Grant, Michael J. Barry, Diane Zilka,<br />

Christine M. Mackintosh, Grant & Eisenhofer P.A.,<br />

Wilmington, Delaware; Hung G. Ta, Brenda F. Szydlo,<br />

Michele S. Carino, Grant & Eisenhofer P.A., New York,<br />

New York; R<strong>and</strong>all J. Baron, A. Rick Atwood, Jr.,<br />

David T. Wissbroecker, Edward M. Gergosian, David A.<br />

Knotts, Robbins Geller Rudman & Dowd LLP, San Diego,<br />

California; Plaintiffs' Co–Lead Counsel.<br />

Raymond J. DiCamillo, Rudolf Koch, Susan M. Hannigan,<br />

Richards, Layton & Finger P.A., Wilmington, Delaware;<br />

Mark A. Kirsch, Diana M. Feinstein, Gibson, Dunn &<br />

Crutcher LLP, New York, New York; Paul J. Collins, Joseph<br />

W. Guzzetta, Gibson, Dunn & Crutcher LLP, Palo Alto,<br />

California; Attorneys for Defendants Samuel H. Armacost,<br />

Timothy G. Bruer, Mary R. Henderson, Victor L. Lund,<br />

Terence D. Martin, Sharon L. McCollam, Joe L. Morgan,<br />

David R. Williams, <strong>and</strong> Richard G. Wolford.<br />

Kenneth J. Nachbar, John P. DiTomo, S. Michael Sirkin,<br />

Morris Nichols Arsht & Tunnell LLP, Wilmington,<br />

Delaware; Peter E. Kazanoff, Paul C. Gluckow, Simpson<br />

Thacher & Bartlett LLP, New York, New York; Attorney for<br />

Defendants Blue Acquisition Group, Inc., Blue Merger Sub<br />

Inc., Centerview Partners, Kohlberg Kravis *817 Roberts &<br />

<strong>Company</strong> LP, <strong>and</strong> Vestar Capital Partners.<br />

Opinion<br />

LASTER, Vice Chancellor.<br />

OPINION<br />

On November 24, 2010, Del Monte Foods <strong>Company</strong> (“Del<br />

Monte” or <strong>the</strong> “<strong>Company</strong>”) entered into an agreement <strong>and</strong><br />

plan of merger with Blue Acquisition Group, Inc. <strong>and</strong><br />

its wholly owned acquisition subsidiary, Blue Merger Sub<br />

Inc. (<strong>the</strong> “Merger Agreement” or “MA”). Blue Acquisition<br />

Group is owned by three private equity firms: Kohlberg,<br />

Kravis, Roberts & Co. (“KKR”), Centerview Partners<br />

(“Centerview”), <strong>and</strong> Vestar Capital Partners (“Vestar”).<br />

Because KKR is <strong>the</strong> lead firm, I generally refer to <strong>the</strong> sponsor<br />

group as “KKR.” The Merger Agreement contemplates a $5.3<br />

billion leveraged buyout of Del Monte (<strong>the</strong> “Merger”). If<br />

approved by stockholders, each share of Del Monte common<br />

stock will be converted into <strong>the</strong> right to receive $19 in cash.<br />

The consideration represents a premium of approximately<br />

40% over <strong>the</strong> average closing price of Del Monte's common<br />

stock for <strong>the</strong> three-month period ended on November 8, 2010.<br />

The $19 price is higher than Del Monte's common stock has<br />

ever traded.<br />

The stockholders of Del Monte are scheduled to vote on<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger on February 15, 2011. The plaintiffs seek a<br />

preliminary injunction postponing <strong>the</strong> vote. They originally<br />

asserted that <strong>the</strong> individual defendants, who comprise <strong>the</strong><br />

Del Monte board of directors (<strong>the</strong> “Board”), breached <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

fiduciary duties in two separate ways: first by failing to<br />

act reasonably to pursue <strong>the</strong> best transaction reasonably<br />

available, <strong>and</strong> second by disseminating false <strong>and</strong> misleading<br />

information <strong>and</strong> omitting material facts in connection with<br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholder vote. The defendants mooted <strong>the</strong> disclosure<br />

claims through an extensive proxy supplement released<br />

during <strong>the</strong> afternoon of February 4, 2011 (<strong>the</strong> “Proxy<br />

Supplement”).<br />

This case is difficult because <strong>the</strong> Board predominantly<br />

made decisions that ordinarily would be regarded as falling<br />

within <strong>the</strong> range of reasonableness for purposes of enhanced<br />

scrutiny. Until discovery disturbed <strong>the</strong> patina of normalcy<br />

surrounding <strong>the</strong> transaction, <strong>the</strong>re were only two Board<br />

decisions that invited serious challenge: first, allowing KKR<br />

to team up with Vestar, <strong>the</strong> high bidder in a previous<br />

solicitation of interest, <strong>and</strong> second, authorizing Barclays<br />

Capital, <strong>the</strong> financial advisor to Del Monte, to provide buyside<br />

financing to KKR.<br />

Discovery revealed a deeper problem. Barclays secretly<br />

<strong>and</strong> selfishly manipulated <strong>the</strong> sale process to engineer a<br />

transaction that would permit Barclays to obtain lucrative<br />

buy-side financing fees. On multiple occasions, Barclays<br />

protected its own interests by withholding information from<br />

<strong>the</strong> Board that could have led Del Monte to retain a different<br />

bank, pursue a different alternative, or deny Barclays a buyside<br />

role. Barclays did not disclose <strong>the</strong> behind-<strong>the</strong>-scenes<br />

efforts of its Del Monte coverage officer to put Del Monte into<br />

play. Barclays did not disclose its explicit goal, harbored from<br />

<strong>the</strong> outset, of providing buy-side financing to <strong>the</strong> acquirer.<br />

Barclays did not disclose that in September 2010, without<br />

Del Monte's authorization or approval, Barclays steered<br />

Vestar into a club bid with KKR, <strong>the</strong> potential bidder with<br />

whom Barclays had <strong>the</strong> strongest relationship, in violation of<br />

confidentiality agreements that prohibited Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR<br />

from discussing a joint bid without written permission from<br />

Del Monte.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 5


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

Late in <strong>the</strong> process, at a time when Barclays was ostensibly<br />

negotiating <strong>the</strong> deal price with KKR, Barclays asked<br />

KKR *818 for a third of <strong>the</strong> buy-side financing. Once<br />

KKR agreed, Barclays sought <strong>and</strong> obtained Del Monte's<br />

permission. Having Barclays as a co-lead bank was not<br />

necessary to secure sufficient financing for <strong>the</strong> Merger, nor<br />

did it generate a higher price for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>. It simply gave<br />

Barclays <strong>the</strong> additional fees it wanted from <strong>the</strong> outset. In fact,<br />

Barclays can expect to earn slightly more from providing buyside<br />

financing to KKR than it will from serving as Del Monte's<br />

sell-side advisor. Barclays' gain cost Del Monte an additional<br />

$3 million because Barclays told Del Monte that it now had<br />

to obtain a last-minute fairness opinion from a second bank.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> preliminary record presented in connection with<br />

<strong>the</strong> injunction application, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs have established<br />

a reasonable probability of success on <strong>the</strong> merits of a<br />

claim for breach of fiduciary duty against <strong>the</strong> individual<br />

defendants, aided <strong>and</strong> abetted by KKR. By failing to<br />

provide <strong>the</strong> serious oversight that would have checked<br />

Barclays' misconduct, <strong>the</strong> directors breached <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary<br />

duties in a manner reminiscent of Mills Acquisition Co. v.<br />

Macmillan, Inc., 559 A.2d 1261 (Del.1989). In that decision,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Delaware Supreme Court enjoined a transaction—<br />

ironically a leveraged buyout sponsored by KKR—when selfinterested<br />

management <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir financial advisor concealed<br />

information from <strong>the</strong> board. Like management's deal-specific,<br />

buy-side conflict in Mills, Barclays' deal-specific, buy-side<br />

conflict tainted <strong>the</strong> advice it gave <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> actions it took.<br />

To hold that <strong>the</strong> Del Monte directors breached <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary<br />

duties for purposes of granting injunctive relief does not<br />

suggest, much less pre-ordain, that <strong>the</strong> directors face a<br />

meaningful threat of monetary liability. On this preliminary<br />

record, it appears that <strong>the</strong> Board sought in good faith to<br />

fulfill its fiduciary duties, but failed because it was misled<br />

by Barclays. Unless fur<strong>the</strong>r discovery reveals different facts,<br />

<strong>the</strong> one-two punch of exculpation under Section 102(b)(7)<br />

<strong>and</strong> full protection under Section 141(e) makes <strong>the</strong> chances<br />

of a judgment for money damages vanishingly small. The<br />

same cannot be said for <strong>the</strong> self-interested aiders <strong>and</strong> abetters.<br />

But while <strong>the</strong> directors may face little threat of liability, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

cannot escape <strong>the</strong> ramifications of Barclays' misconduct. For<br />

purposes of equitable relief, <strong>the</strong> Board is responsible.<br />

To remedy (at least partially) <strong>the</strong> taint from Barclays'<br />

activities, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs ask that <strong>the</strong> vote on <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

be enjoined for a meaningful period (30 to 45 days) <strong>and</strong><br />

that <strong>the</strong> parties to <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement be enjoined from<br />

enforcing <strong>the</strong> deal protections during that time. They have<br />

not sought (nor would I grant) a decree enjoining <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

pending a post-trial adjudication. The plaintiffs argue that this<br />

limited injunctive relief will restore (albeit incompletely) <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders' unique opportunity to receive a topping bid free<br />

of fiduciary misconduct. Such an injunction would deprive<br />

KKR temporarily of <strong>the</strong> advantages it obtained by securing<br />

a deal through collusion with Barclays, while at <strong>the</strong> same<br />

time preserving <strong>the</strong> stockholders' ability to determine for<br />

<strong>the</strong>mselves whe<strong>the</strong>r to accept <strong>the</strong> $19 per share Merger price.<br />

The plaintiffs analogize this limited relief to an injunction<br />

conditioned on <strong>the</strong> making of corrective disclosures, which<br />

similarly imposes a temporary transactional delay <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n<br />

allows stockholders to decide for <strong>the</strong>mselves whe<strong>the</strong>r to<br />

accept a deal.<br />

For <strong>the</strong> reasons that follow, I grant <strong>the</strong> relief plaintiffs seek,<br />

although for a shorter time period that takes into account<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction's exposure to <strong>the</strong> market. The defendants<br />

are enjoined preliminarily from proceeding with <strong>the</strong> vote<br />

on <strong>the</strong> Merger *819 for a period of 20 days. Pending <strong>the</strong><br />

vote on <strong>the</strong> Merger, <strong>the</strong> parties to <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement<br />

are enjoined from enforcing <strong>the</strong> no-solicitation <strong>and</strong> matchright<br />

provisions in Section 6.5(b), (c) <strong>and</strong> (h), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

termination fee provisions relating to topping bids <strong>and</strong><br />

changes of recommendation in Section 8.5(b). The injunction<br />

is conditioned on <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs posting a bond in <strong>the</strong> amount<br />

of $1.2 million.<br />

I. FACTUAL BACKGROUND<br />

The facts are drawn from <strong>the</strong> record developed in connection<br />

with <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs' application for a preliminary injunction.<br />

The parties have submitted numerous documentary exhibits<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> deposition testimony of seven fact witnesses.<br />

With <strong>the</strong>ir answering briefs, <strong>the</strong> defendants lobbed in four<br />

affidavits from witnesses who were deposed. Each of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

lawyer-drafted submissions sought to replace <strong>the</strong> witnesses'<br />

sworn deposition testimony with a revised <strong>and</strong> frequently<br />

contradictory version. Had <strong>the</strong> differing averments been<br />

elicited by defense counsel during deposition, as <strong>the</strong>y readily<br />

could have been, <strong>the</strong>n plaintiffs' counsel could have tested <strong>the</strong><br />

witnesses' assertions through cross-examination. Except on<br />

routine or undisputed matters, I have discounted <strong>the</strong>se “nonadversarial<br />

proffers” 1 <strong>and</strong> relied on <strong>the</strong> deposition testimony<br />

<strong>and</strong> contemporaneous documents. What follows are <strong>the</strong> facts<br />

as <strong>the</strong>y are likely to be found after trial, based on <strong>the</strong> current<br />

record.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 6


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

A. Moses Works Behind The Scenes To Put Del Monte<br />

In Play.<br />

Investment banks generate large fees from doing deals. To<br />

facilitate transactional activity, investment bankers routinely<br />

pitch deals to parties <strong>the</strong>y hope might be interested. Coverage<br />

officers for investment banks regularly visit past, present, <strong>and</strong><br />

potential clients to suggest mergers, acquisitions, <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

strategic alternatives. Barclays is no exception.<br />

Barclays has a strong presence in <strong>the</strong> consumer food <strong>and</strong><br />

pet product sectors where Del Monte operates. Peter J.<br />

Moses is <strong>the</strong> Barclays managing director with coverage<br />

responsibility for Del Monte. Barclays <strong>and</strong> Del Monte have<br />

enjoyed a close relationship. In 2009, Barclays acted as joint<br />

book-runner on Del Monte's $450 million issuance of 7.5%<br />

senior subordinated notes <strong>and</strong> as joint dealer-manager <strong>and</strong><br />

solicitation agent on Del Monte's tender offer <strong>and</strong> consent<br />

solicitation for its 8 5/8 % senior subordinated notes. During<br />

late 2009, Barclays advised Del Monte on <strong>and</strong> arranged<br />

financing for its unsuccessful acquisition of Waggin' Train<br />

LLC. In January 2010, Barclays acted as co-lead arranger<br />

for Del Monte's $1.2 billion senior secured credit facility.<br />

Barclays understood that it was one of Del Monte's principal<br />

investment banks.<br />

Del Monte's stable businesses throw off large amounts of<br />

cash, a critical attribute for debt-fueled LBOs. In fiscal<br />

2010, for *820 example, Del Monte generated $3.7 billion<br />

in net sales <strong>and</strong> $250 million in cash flow. According<br />

to <strong>the</strong> bankers deposed in this case, <strong>the</strong> debt markets in<br />

late 2009 were again receptive to leveraged acquisitions,<br />

having shaken off <strong>the</strong> cobwebs from <strong>the</strong> concussive impact<br />

of Lehman Bro<strong>the</strong>rs' bankruptcy. Mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisitions<br />

activity in <strong>the</strong> canned food <strong>and</strong> pet products sectors had<br />

picked up. Investment bankers were busy pitching Del Monte<br />

on potential acquisitions <strong>and</strong> pitching potential acquirers on<br />

Del Monte.<br />

Like many large banks, Barclays has strong relationships with<br />

various LBO shops. KKR is one of Barclays' more important<br />

clients. Tarone Tr. 95. Over <strong>the</strong> past two years, KKR has<br />

paid Barclays over $66 million in fees. Barclays has worked<br />

with KKR on half a dozen projects in <strong>the</strong> consumer <strong>and</strong> retail<br />

space, including a large transaction where Barclays acted as<br />

both sell-side advisor <strong>and</strong> provided buy-side financing for<br />

KKR. Tarone Tr. 93–94.<br />

On December 17, 2009, Moses <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r Barclays bankers<br />

met with KKR to present various opportunities, including an<br />

acquisition of Del Monte. In early January 2010, Moses met<br />

with KKR again. KKR said it was ready “to take <strong>the</strong> next step”<br />

with Del Monte <strong>and</strong> planned to partner with Centerview on<br />

a bid. PX 16. Moses responded by outlining with prophetic<br />

clarity <strong>the</strong> process Del Monte would follow: a narrow, private<br />

solicitation of interest from a small group of approximately<br />

five sponsors with no strategic bidders. Moses made similar<br />

pitches during <strong>the</strong> same time period to o<strong>the</strong>r private equity<br />

firms, including Apollo Management.<br />

B. Apollo's Expression Of Interest And Del Monte's<br />

Process<br />

Before KKR could “take <strong>the</strong> next step,” Apollo sent Del<br />

Monte a written expression of interest in an acquisition at $14<br />

to $15 per share. After receiving <strong>the</strong> letter, Del Monte reached<br />

out to Barclays. Moses believed Del Monte was also reaching<br />

out to o<strong>the</strong>r banks, including Goldman Sachs, a firm that ran<br />

an earlier process for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>.<br />

Moses told Del Monte that Barclays was well-positioned<br />

to advise Del Monte because Barclays “knew many of <strong>the</strong><br />

entities that might be an interested buyer.” Ben. Tr. 59. Moses<br />

did not mention that he personally had been pitching Apollo,<br />

KKR, <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r private equity firms on acquiring Del Monte.<br />

The Board did not learn of Moses' efforts to stir up <strong>the</strong> initial<br />

LBO bid until discovery in this litigation.<br />

Moses also did not mention that Barclays planned from <strong>the</strong><br />

outset to seek a role in providing buy-side financing. Barclays'<br />

internal “Project Hunt [Del Monte] Screening Committee<br />

Memo” dated January 25, 2010, stated bluntly that “Barclays<br />

will look to participate in <strong>the</strong> acquisition financing once<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> has reached a definitive agreement with a<br />

buyer.” PX 54. A March 2010 version of <strong>the</strong> memo reiterated<br />

Barclays' intent. The Board did not learn that Barclays<br />

intended from <strong>the</strong> outset to have a buy-side role until<br />

discovery in this litigation.<br />

Barclays immediately began advising Del Monte on<br />

responding to Apollo's expression of interest <strong>and</strong> exploring<br />

strategic alternatives. Moses recommended that <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

pursue a targeted, non-public process that tracked precisely<br />

what Moses had previewed with KKR <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r private<br />

equity firms. There are sound <strong>and</strong> reasonable justifications for<br />

such an approach, including a desire to avoid market leaks<br />

that could disrupt company operations <strong>and</strong> spook employees.<br />

But a narrow, targeted process involving a few large private<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 7


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

equity firms also fur<strong>the</strong>red Barclays' goal of providing buyside<br />

financing. Private equity buyers are generally more<br />

*821 likely than strategic buyers to require financing, <strong>and</strong><br />

Barclays was one of a limited group of institutions with<br />

sufficient resources to h<strong>and</strong>le a transaction as large as <strong>the</strong> Del<br />

Monte LBO.<br />

Barclays <strong>the</strong>n identified <strong>the</strong> five LBO shops that would be<br />

invited to submit expressions of interest: KKR, Apollo, The<br />

Carlyle Group, CVC Partners, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Blackstone Group. The<br />

Board adopted Barclays' recommendation.<br />

Despite efforts to keep <strong>the</strong> process quiet <strong>and</strong> private, word<br />

leaked out. Vestar <strong>and</strong> Campbell's Soup contacted Barclays<br />

<strong>and</strong> asked to be included, which <strong>the</strong>y were. Blackstone<br />

dropped out, <strong>and</strong> Del Monte entered into confidentiality<br />

agreements with <strong>the</strong> six participants. Each of <strong>the</strong> participants<br />

agreed not to discuss <strong>the</strong> confidential information <strong>the</strong>y<br />

obtained from Del Monte or <strong>the</strong>ir bids with anyone, including<br />

each o<strong>the</strong>r. A critical provision stated:<br />

In addition, you agree that, without <strong>the</strong><br />

prior written consent of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>,<br />

you <strong>and</strong> your Representatives will<br />

not disclose to any o<strong>the</strong>r person<br />

(o<strong>the</strong>r than your Representatives)<br />

<strong>the</strong> fact that you are considering<br />

a possible transaction with <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong>, that this Agreement exists,<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Confidential Information<br />

has been made available to you,<br />

that discussions or negotiations are<br />

taking place concerning a possible<br />

transaction involving <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> or<br />

any of <strong>the</strong> terms, conditions, or o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

facts with respect <strong>the</strong>reto (including<br />

<strong>the</strong> status <strong>the</strong>reof).... Without limiting<br />

<strong>the</strong> generality of <strong>the</strong> foregoing,<br />

you fur<strong>the</strong>r agree that you will<br />

not, directly or indirectly, share <strong>the</strong><br />

Confidential Information with or enter<br />

into any agreement, arrangement or<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing, or any discussions<br />

which would reasonably be expected<br />

to lead to such an agreement,<br />

arrangement or underst<strong>and</strong>ing with<br />

any o<strong>the</strong>r person, including o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

potential bidders <strong>and</strong> equity or debt<br />

financing sources (o<strong>the</strong>r than your<br />

Representatives as permitted above)<br />

regarding a possible transaction<br />

involving <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> without<br />

<strong>the</strong> prior written consent of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> <strong>and</strong> only upon such person<br />

executing a confidentiality agreement<br />

in favor of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> with terms<br />

<strong>and</strong> conditions consistent with this<br />

Agreement.<br />

PX 18 at 2 (<strong>the</strong> “No Teaming Provision”). By securing this<br />

language, <strong>the</strong> Board ensured that Del Monte would have <strong>the</strong><br />

contractual right to control <strong>the</strong> competitive dynamics of <strong>the</strong><br />

process <strong>and</strong> determine whe<strong>the</strong>r any bidders would be allowed<br />

to work toge<strong>the</strong>r on a joint bid. The confidentiality agreement<br />

also contained a two-year st<strong>and</strong>still. Id. at 4.<br />

The confidentiality agreements provided a collateral benefit<br />

to Barclays. Absent <strong>Company</strong> consent, <strong>the</strong> signatories could<br />

not discuss potential financing with any source o<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

Barclays. Id. at 2. As with <strong>the</strong> decision to engage in a<br />

targeted, non-public canvass of private equity buyers, <strong>the</strong>re<br />

are sound <strong>and</strong> reasonable justifications for such a provision.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> limitation served Barclays' interests in<br />

obtaining a piece of <strong>the</strong> buy-side financing. Because of <strong>the</strong><br />

provision, Barclays would have <strong>the</strong> first crack at discussing<br />

financing with each bidder, its credit group would be familiar<br />

with <strong>the</strong> deal, <strong>and</strong> its bankers could more persuasively pitch<br />

for a piece of <strong>the</strong> action. See Tarone Tr. 129–31. The<br />

lead banker on Barclays' financing team acknowledged that<br />

Barclays would express interest in providing financing when<br />

discussing capital structures with bidders <strong>and</strong> that this put<br />

Barclays in <strong>the</strong> catbird seat for <strong>the</strong> business. See Id. at 89–93.<br />

After executing a confidentiality agreement, each potential<br />

bidder was provided *822 with access to non-public<br />

information <strong>and</strong> received presentations from Del Monte<br />

senior management. All potential bidders were directed to<br />

submit non-binding indications of interest by March 11,<br />

2010. Five did; Campbell's Soup did not. Carlyle proposed<br />

a transaction in a range of $15.50 to $17.00 per share<br />

<strong>and</strong> asked for permission to explore debt financing with<br />

Bank of America, JPMorgan, Deutsche Bank, <strong>and</strong> Credit<br />

Suisse. Apollo proposed a transaction in a range of $15.50<br />

to $17.00 per share <strong>and</strong> asked for permission to explore<br />

financing with Bank of America, JPMorgan, Morgan Stanley,<br />

Deutsche Bank, Credit Suisse, UBS, <strong>and</strong> BMO Capital<br />

Markets. CVC proposed a transaction at $15.00 to $16.50 per<br />

share, expressed interest in taking on an equity partner, <strong>and</strong><br />

proposed to raise financing through its internal debt financing<br />

team. KKR expressed interest in a transaction at $17 per<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 8


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

share. KKR did not ask for permission to talk to any banks <strong>and</strong><br />

stated only that <strong>the</strong>ir bid contemplated “newly raised debt in<br />

line with <strong>the</strong> guidance provided by Barclays.” PX 20 at 3. To a<br />

Barclays' banker seeking a buy-side role, KKR's letter would<br />

have been <strong>the</strong> most reassuring, particularly because KKR had<br />

worked with Barclays in a dual role before.<br />

Vestar's bid raised tactical issues. Vestar expressed interest in<br />

a transaction in a range of $17.00 to $17.50 per share, making<br />

it <strong>the</strong> high bidder. Everyone understood that Vestar would<br />

need to pair up with at least one o<strong>the</strong>r sponsor. Vestar had<br />

made clear from <strong>the</strong> outset, <strong>and</strong> confirmed in its expression<br />

of interest, that “[it] would expect to commit to half of <strong>the</strong><br />

required equity in this transaction <strong>and</strong> would look to partner<br />

with ano<strong>the</strong>r private equity firm to fill out <strong>the</strong> remaining<br />

portion.” PX 50 at 2. Vestar thus was not going to bid alone.<br />

Its advantage was expertise in <strong>the</strong> food business <strong>and</strong> its<br />

strength as an operator. James Ben, who led <strong>the</strong> Barclays M<br />

& A team, regarded Vestar as a valuable participant in <strong>the</strong><br />

sale process <strong>and</strong> expected that <strong>the</strong> firm would be a valuepromoting<br />

partner for ano<strong>the</strong>r bidder, though more for its<br />

operational expertise than as a source of capital. Ben Tr. 93–<br />

94. Moses suggested that Vestar consider pairing up with<br />

Carlyle. Ben considered pairing Vestar with Apollo. CVC had<br />

expressed interest in a second sponsor <strong>and</strong> was ano<strong>the</strong>r logical<br />

option. Internal KKR documents reflect concern about Vestar<br />

working with ano<strong>the</strong>r firm.<br />

During its regularly scheduled meeting on March 18, 2010,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Board considered <strong>the</strong> five indications of interest. The<br />

Board decided that <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>'s st<strong>and</strong>-alone growth<br />

prospects were sufficiently strong that it was not in <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders' best interests to proceed fur<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong><br />

process. The directors also concluded that Barclays had<br />

pushed too far, too fast, <strong>and</strong> that Barclays had not been hired<br />

to actually sell <strong>the</strong> company. See Martin Tr. 23–24. Moses<br />

blamed Richard Wolford, Del Monte's Chairman, President,<br />

<strong>and</strong> CEO. He believed Wolford turned against <strong>the</strong> LBO at <strong>the</strong><br />

last minute, spoke privately with <strong>the</strong> directors, <strong>and</strong> allowed<br />

Moses to walk into a hostile meeting unaware. KKR thought<br />

that “Barclays didn't do such a good job here w/ Wolford <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> board.” PX 23. When Barclays later kicked off <strong>the</strong> LBO<br />

process again, Moses would do a better job setting <strong>the</strong> table.<br />

C. KKR Continues To Pursue Del Monte.<br />

The Board specifically instructed Barclays “to shut [<strong>the</strong>]<br />

process down <strong>and</strong> let buyers know <strong>the</strong> company is not for<br />

sale.” PX 57. Over <strong>the</strong> ensuing months, KKR reached out to<br />

Del Monte on at least two occasions. In April 2010, KKR<br />

representatives met with Wolford <strong>and</strong> David Meyers, Del<br />

Monte's CFO. KKR said it wanted *823 to keep <strong>the</strong> lines<br />

of communication open about future opportunities. In May<br />

2010, KKR approached Del Monte about jointly pursuing<br />

acquisitions. Del Monte declined, both because KKR's capital<br />

was too expensive <strong>and</strong> because Del Monte had all <strong>the</strong> capital<br />

it needed. KKR also continued to meet with Barclays.<br />

D. Barclays Pairs Up Vestar With KKR.<br />

In September 2010, Moses sensed that <strong>the</strong> timing was right to<br />

put <strong>the</strong> Del Monte LBO back toge<strong>the</strong>r. Moses had lunch with<br />

Brian Ratzan of Vestar. Moses suggested that it might be “an<br />

interesting time to make ano<strong>the</strong>r approach to [Del Monte]”<br />

<strong>and</strong> that, if Vestar were interested, “<strong>the</strong> ideal partner would be<br />

KKR.” Ratzan Tr. 35. Moses said that it was an “opportune<br />

time” for approaching Del Monte because “[t]he company<br />

had missed its numbers for a couple of quarters [<strong>and</strong>] [t]he<br />

stock price was down.” Id. at 36. On September 14, Moses<br />

discussed <strong>the</strong> idea with KKR. After meeting with KKR,<br />

Moses called Ratzan. Moses <strong>the</strong>n emailed his colleagues that<br />

Vestar “is going to partner with KKR on [Del Monte]. So<br />

team wi[ll] be kkr, vestar <strong>and</strong> hooper (centerview). Obviously<br />

this is confidential.” PX 60.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> time, both Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR were bound by <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

confidentiality agreements with Del Monte. The No Teaming<br />

Provision prohibited Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR from entering into<br />

any “agreement, arrangement or underst<strong>and</strong>ing, or any<br />

discussions which would reasonably be expected to lead to<br />

such an agreement, arrangement or underst<strong>and</strong>ing with any<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r person, including o<strong>the</strong>r potential bidders <strong>and</strong> equity or<br />

debt financing sources (o<strong>the</strong>r than your Representatives as<br />

permitted above) regarding a possible transaction involving<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> without <strong>the</strong> prior written consent of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong>....” Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR did not have “prior written<br />

consent” from Del Monte. Nor did Barclays. In fact, Barclays<br />

was not authorized at that time to do anything on behalf of<br />

Del Monte. The Board had instructed Barclays “to shut [<strong>the</strong>]<br />

process down <strong>and</strong> let buyers know <strong>the</strong> company is not for<br />

sale.” PX 57.<br />

By pairing Vestar with KKR, Barclays put toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><br />

two highest bidders from March 2010, <strong>the</strong>reby reducing<br />

<strong>the</strong> prospect of real competition in any renewed process.<br />

There were o<strong>the</strong>r logical pairings that would have promoted<br />

competition. Teaming up Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR served Barclays'<br />

interest in fur<strong>the</strong>ring a deal with an important client<br />

(KKR) that previously had used Barclays for buy-side<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 9


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

financing. After Moses paired Vestar with KKR, Vestar never<br />

considered working with a different sponsor.<br />

E. KKR Makes Its Bid.<br />

On October 11, 2010, representatives of KKR asked to meet<br />

with Wolford. During <strong>the</strong> meeting, KKR delivered a written<br />

indication of interest from KKR <strong>and</strong> Centerview to acquire<br />

Del Monte for $17.50 in cash. The price represented a 28.7%<br />

premium over <strong>the</strong> closing price of Del Monte's common stock<br />

on <strong>the</strong> previous trading day. While nominally higher than <strong>the</strong><br />

$17 offered in March, it was a step back given intervening<br />

market developments. Del Monte <strong>and</strong> Barclays calculated<br />

that an equivalent bid would have been $18.32. See PX 72 (“I<br />

l<strong>and</strong>ed on $18.32/share as <strong>the</strong> equivalent offer relative to <strong>the</strong><br />

$17 previously”).<br />

The KKR letter did not mention Vestar, <strong>and</strong> Vestar<br />

representatives did not attend <strong>the</strong> meeting. In preparing for<br />

<strong>the</strong> meeting, KKR <strong>and</strong> Vestar agreed not to disclose Vestar's<br />

participation because “it's just ano<strong>the</strong>r thing Rick will have<br />

to go back to his board <strong>and</strong> explain. Will be *824 easier to<br />

bring in Vestar once we have traction with <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>.” PX<br />

24.<br />

After <strong>the</strong> October 11, 2010, meeting, Barclays worked with<br />

KKR to conceal Vestar's participation. For example, on<br />

October 31, Brown of KKR emailed his colleagues that<br />

Vestar would not attend a meeting with Del Monte because<br />

of <strong>the</strong> complications it would create. PX 26 (“delicate time<br />

for Board, don't want to upset matters potentially w[ith]<br />

a group change at a critical juncture. Vestar ultimately ok<br />

w[ith] this”). Moses agreed that it was best to keep Vestar's<br />

involvement hidden. See PX 62 (e-mail from Moses to<br />

Brown, dated Oct. 31, 2010, “agree at this point that we keep<br />

meeting to K[KR] <strong>and</strong> Centerview from your side.”).<br />

F. The Board Adopts A Single–Bidder Strategy.<br />

On October 13, 2010, <strong>the</strong> Board met to consider KKR's<br />

indication of interest. The Board met again on October<br />

25. Management discussed <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>'s long range<br />

plan <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> challenges <strong>and</strong> risks associated with its<br />

execution. Management suggested that a transaction with<br />

KKR potentially represented a “risk-free alternative” to<br />

<strong>the</strong> long range plan. On <strong>the</strong> question of whe<strong>the</strong>r to sell,<br />

management faced conflicts of its own. Wolford planned<br />

to retire in 2012 <strong>and</strong> was being pressed by <strong>the</strong> Board for<br />

a succession plan. Wolford was resisting <strong>and</strong> had said he<br />

would ra<strong>the</strong>r sell <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> than remake his team. From<br />

an economic st<strong>and</strong>point, Wolford would receive an additional<br />

$24 million if Del Monte was sold before his retirement. Del<br />

Monte CFO Meyers also planned to retire in 2012 <strong>and</strong> would<br />

receive an additional $5 million if <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> was sold<br />

before <strong>the</strong>n. See Proxy Supp. at 6–11.<br />

After deciding to pursue discussions with KKR, <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

considered whe<strong>the</strong>r to conduct a pre-signing market check.<br />

The Board concluded that none was needed. First, KKR's<br />

indication of interest at $17.50 per share was at <strong>the</strong> high end<br />

of <strong>the</strong> indications of interest that <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> had received<br />

in March 2010, although lower on a relative basis after<br />

adjusting for intervening market trends. Second, <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

felt that no o<strong>the</strong>r potential bidders were lurking in <strong>the</strong> wings,<br />

because only Campbell's Soup came forward when word of<br />

<strong>the</strong> private process leaked in early 2010. Third, no one o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than KKR had communicated with Del Monte in <strong>the</strong> eight<br />

months since <strong>the</strong> Board instructed Barclays to tell bidders that<br />

Del Monte was not for sale. Fourth, <strong>the</strong> Board was concerned<br />

that a renewed process could have detrimental effects on<br />

employees, customers, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> stock price, particularly if <strong>the</strong><br />

process did not result in a completed transaction. Finally, <strong>the</strong><br />

Board considered that <strong>the</strong> previous high bid of $17.50 had<br />

been submitted by Vestar, a firm that needed to partner with<br />

a larger sponsor to make a bid. At <strong>the</strong> time, <strong>the</strong> Board did not<br />

know that Barclays had teamed Vestar with KKR.<br />

The Board ultimately decided to adopt a single-bidder<br />

strategy of negotiating only with KKR. During <strong>the</strong> meeting,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Board formally authorized <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> to “re-engage”<br />

Barclays as its financial advisor. After <strong>the</strong> meeting, <strong>the</strong><br />

Chairman of <strong>the</strong> Strategic Committee, Terence Martin, met<br />

with Moses <strong>and</strong> Ben to negotiate Barclays' new engagement<br />

letter. Martin “personally directed that Barclays was not to<br />

speak or act on Del Monte's behalf until <strong>the</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong><br />

engagement letter had been finalized.” Martin Aff. 22. The<br />

Barclays representatives did not tell Martin that Moses had<br />

been communicating with Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR, put <strong>the</strong> two firms<br />

toge<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>and</strong> helped spur <strong>the</strong> KKR bid. Barclays *825 <strong>the</strong>n<br />

began advising Del Monte on <strong>the</strong> bid Moses engineered.<br />

G. The Initial Negotiations With KKR.<br />

Between October 26 <strong>and</strong> November 9, 2010, Barclays<br />

interacted with KKR. Barclays reported frequently to Del<br />

Monte management <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Strategic Committee, but<br />

Barclays was <strong>the</strong> principal point of contact for KKR.<br />

On October 27, 2010, <strong>the</strong> Board asked Barclays to tell<br />

KKR that <strong>the</strong> $17.50 per share offer was insufficient, but<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 10


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

that <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> was prepared to give KKR access to due<br />

diligence information to allow <strong>the</strong>m to submit a higher offer.<br />

On November 4, KKR attended a meeting with Del Monte<br />

management. Barclays <strong>and</strong> KKR agreed that Vestar would<br />

not attend <strong>and</strong> to keep Vestar's involvement secret from <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong><br />

On November 8, 2010, news of a potential Del Monte LBO<br />

leaked when <strong>the</strong> London Evening St<strong>and</strong>ard reported that KKR<br />

had offered to acquire <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> for $18.50 per share.<br />

Later in <strong>the</strong> day, KKR contacted <strong>the</strong> Board <strong>and</strong> raised its offer<br />

to $18.50 with a request for exclusivity. Vestar's participation<br />

still went unmentioned.<br />

On November 9, 2010, <strong>the</strong> Board met to discuss KKR's<br />

proposal. The Board declined to grant formal exclusivity,<br />

but did not reach out to any o<strong>the</strong>r bidders. The Board<br />

also declined to approve a transaction at $18.50 per share.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> Board signaled its receptivity by<br />

authorizing KKR to begin discussing financing commitments<br />

with lenders. According to an internal KKR email, “Barclays<br />

guidance was we should read real significance into <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

authorizing full access with instructions to get us to a point of<br />

being firm/done based on <strong>the</strong> price we raised to.” PX 29.<br />

H. Del Monte Finally Learns About Vestar's<br />

Involvement And Barclays' Buy–Side Desires.<br />

With momentum building towards a deal, <strong>the</strong> time had come<br />

for <strong>the</strong> repeat M & A players to hit up <strong>the</strong> Board with two<br />

unsavory requests. First, during <strong>the</strong> week of November 8,<br />

2010, KKR “formally approached Barclays Capital to request<br />

that <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> allow KKR/Centerview to include Vestar<br />

in <strong>the</strong> deal as an additional member of <strong>the</strong> sponsor group.”<br />

Proxy Supp. at 3. Note <strong>the</strong> artful phrasing. Barclays had<br />

paired Vestar with KKR in September, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>y had been<br />

de facto partners since at least October. Yet Barclays had<br />

never been “formally approached,” <strong>and</strong> technically Vestar<br />

had never been “included in <strong>the</strong> deal as an additional member<br />

of <strong>the</strong> sponsor group.”<br />

No one suggested that adding Vestar was necessary for<br />

KKR to proceed with its bid. There is no evidence that<br />

including Vestar firmed up a wavering deal. The Board was<br />

not told that Vestar in fact had been partnered with KKR<br />

since September, when Barclays put <strong>the</strong>m toge<strong>the</strong>r. The<br />

contemporaneous record does not reflect any consideration<br />

given to <strong>the</strong> ramifications of permitting KKR to team up with<br />

<strong>the</strong> firm who previously submitted <strong>the</strong> high bid <strong>and</strong> who could<br />

readily have teamed with Carlyle, Apollo, CVC, or ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

large buyout shop. The Board did not consider rejecting<br />

KKR's request, enforcing <strong>the</strong> confidentiality agreement, <strong>and</strong><br />

inviting Vestar to participate with a different sponsor to<br />

generate competition. The Board did not seek to trade<br />

permission for Vestar to pair with KKR for a price increase<br />

or o<strong>the</strong>r concession.<br />

The second unsavory request was when Barclays finally<br />

asked Del Monte if it could provide buy-side financing, as<br />

Barclays had been planning to do since at least January 2010.<br />

Barclays had long *826 been signaling KKR about its desire<br />

to participate. On November 8, Moses asked KKR to give<br />

Barclays one third of <strong>the</strong> debt. KKR agreed. The next day<br />

Brown reported by email to <strong>the</strong> KKR investment committee<br />

that Barclays had “asked us to use JPM, BofA <strong>and</strong> Barclays<br />

<strong>the</strong>mselves as <strong>the</strong> financing banks; we find that acceptable<br />

<strong>and</strong> will ask to add one more.” PX 29. Also on November<br />

9, Barclays asked Del Monte management for permission to<br />

provide buy-side financing to KKR. They agreed. See PX 40.<br />

On November 12, Brown reported to his KKR colleagues that<br />

“Barclays has been cleared to be a financing bank.” JX 30.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> time Barclays asked for <strong>and</strong> obtained Del Monte's<br />

permission to provide buy-side financing, Del Monte <strong>and</strong><br />

KKR had not yet agreed on price. Barclays' buy-side<br />

participation was not used to extract a higher price. Nor was<br />

it necessary to finance <strong>the</strong> deal. No one thought that KKR<br />

needed Barclays, <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r banks were already clamoring for<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir shares. Barclays simply wanted to double-dip. Through<br />

its buy-side role, Barclays will earn $21 to $24 million, as<br />

much <strong>and</strong> possibly more than <strong>the</strong> $23.5 million it will earn as<br />

<strong>the</strong> sell-side advisor.<br />

On November 23, 2010, Del Monte executed a letter<br />

agreement that formally authorized Barclays to provide<br />

financing to KKR. In contrast to <strong>the</strong> Barclays witnesses,<br />

who reluctantly admitted when pressed that providing buyside<br />

financing might create <strong>the</strong> appearance of a potential<br />

conflict, <strong>the</strong> November 23 letter acknowledged that Barclays'<br />

relationship became adverse to Del Monte <strong>and</strong> that if push<br />

came to shove, Barclays would look out for itself. In <strong>the</strong><br />

language of <strong>the</strong> letter, “[i]n <strong>the</strong> event that Barclays Capital<br />

is asked to provide acquisition financing to a buyer of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong>, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> should expect Barclays Capital to<br />

seek to protect its interests as a lender, which may be<br />

contrary to <strong>the</strong> interests of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>.” PX 35 at 1.<br />

Because of <strong>the</strong> conflict of interest, Barclays insisted in <strong>the</strong><br />

letter agreement that Del Monte obtain a second fairness<br />

opinion. Id. (“Barclays Capital believes that it is essential,<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 11


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

in addressing such conflicts of interest, for <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> to<br />

receive independent financial advice, including an additional<br />

fairness opinion, from an independent third party firm who<br />

is not involved in <strong>the</strong> acquisition financing....”). Not only<br />

did Del Monte fail to secure any benefits for itself or its<br />

stockholders as <strong>the</strong> price of Barclays' buy-side participation,<br />

but Del Monte actually incurred an additional $3 million for a<br />

second financial advisor. Del Monte hired Perella Weinberg<br />

Partners LP to fulfill this role. Perella Weinberg's fee is not<br />

contingent on closing. On <strong>the</strong> plus side, this helps make its<br />

work independent. On <strong>the</strong> minus side, Del Monte incurred<br />

a $3 million expense to help Barclays make ano<strong>the</strong>r $24<br />

million, <strong>and</strong> Del Monte will have to bear this expense even if<br />

<strong>the</strong> deal does not close.<br />

I. Barclays Continues To Negotiate With KKR.<br />

Between November 19 <strong>and</strong> 22, 2010, at <strong>the</strong> same time it<br />

was working with KKR to provide financing for <strong>the</strong> deal,<br />

Barclays ostensibly negotiated with KKR over <strong>the</strong> price. On<br />

November 22, Barclays reported that KKR was willing to<br />

consider paying $18.75 per share. Internally, Barclays already<br />

had evaluated a $19 price for KKR, <strong>and</strong> KKR had secured<br />

authority from its Investment Committee to bid up to $19 per<br />

share. The Board declined <strong>the</strong> $18.75 figure <strong>and</strong> instructed<br />

Barclays to go back to KKR.<br />

On November 24, 2010, Barclays reported that KKR had<br />

made its best <strong>and</strong> final offer of $19 per share. Later in<br />

<strong>the</strong> day, <strong>the</strong> Board met to consider <strong>the</strong> offer. Barclays<br />

*827 <strong>and</strong> Perella Weinberg delivered <strong>the</strong>ir fairness opinions.<br />

The Board reviewed <strong>the</strong> provisions of <strong>the</strong> proposed Merger<br />

Agreement that had been negotiated between outside counsel<br />

to <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> <strong>and</strong> KKR. After discussion <strong>and</strong> an executive<br />

session, <strong>the</strong> Board unanimously approved <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement.<br />

J. The Terms Of The Merger Agreement<br />

Section 6.5(a) of Merger Agreement provided for a 45–day<br />

post-signing go-shop period during which Del Monte had<br />

<strong>the</strong> right to “initiate, solicit <strong>and</strong> encourage any inquiry or<br />

<strong>the</strong> making of any proposal or offers that could constitute<br />

an Acquisition Proposal.” The Merger Agreement defines<br />

“Acquisition Proposal” broadly as<br />

any bona fide inquiry, proposal or<br />

offer from any person or group of<br />

persons o<strong>the</strong>r than Parent or one of its<br />

subsidiaries for, in one transaction or<br />

a series of related transactions, (A) a<br />

merger, reorganization, consolidation,<br />

share exchange, business combination,<br />

recapitalization, liquidation,<br />

dissolution or similar transaction<br />

involving an acquisition of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> (or any subsidiary or<br />

subsidiaries of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> whose<br />

business constitutes 15% or more of<br />

<strong>the</strong> net revenues, net income or assets<br />

of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> <strong>and</strong> its subsidiaries,<br />

taken as a whole) or (B) <strong>the</strong> acquisition<br />

in any manner, directly or indirectly,<br />

of over 15% of <strong>the</strong> equity securities<br />

or consolidated total assets of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> <strong>and</strong> its subsidiaries, in each<br />

case o<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

MA § 6.5(d)(i). Once <strong>the</strong> go-shop period ended, Del<br />

Monte was bound by a customary no-solicitation clause that<br />

prohibited Del Monte, among o<strong>the</strong>r things, from “initiat[ing],<br />

solicit[ing], or knowingly encourage[ing] any inquiries or <strong>the</strong><br />

making of any proposal or offer that constitutes or reasonably<br />

could be expected to lead to an Acquisition Proposal.” Id.<br />

§ 6.5(b). The no-solicitation clause permits Del Monte to<br />

respond to a Superior Proposal, defined generally as an<br />

Acquisition Proposal (but with <strong>the</strong> references to 15% changed<br />

to 50%) that <strong>the</strong> Board determines is “more favorable to <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong>'s stockholders from a financial point of view” than<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger <strong>and</strong> “is reasonably likely to be consummated.” Id.<br />

§ 6.5(d)(iii).<br />

During <strong>the</strong> go-shop period, Del Monte was authorized to,<br />

among o<strong>the</strong>r things, waive or release any party from any preexisting<br />

st<strong>and</strong>still agreements with <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>, <strong>and</strong> Del<br />

Monte could do so “at its sole discretion.” Id. § 6.5(a). This<br />

is a salutary provision that eliminates any argument from <strong>the</strong><br />

acquirer that it has an explicit or implicit contractual veto<br />

over <strong>the</strong> decision to grant a waiver or release. Exercising<br />

this authority, Del Monte released Carlyle, CVC, Apollo,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Campbell's Soup from <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>still provisions in <strong>the</strong><br />

confidentiality agreements <strong>the</strong>y executed in February 2010.<br />

Section 8.3(a) of <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement permits Del Monte<br />

to terminate its deal with KKR to accept a Superior Proposal<br />

prior to <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote on <strong>the</strong> merger if<br />

(i) <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> Board authorizes<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>, subject to complying<br />

with <strong>the</strong> terms of this Agreement,<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 12


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

to enter into one or more<br />

Alternative Acquisition Agreements<br />

with respect to a Superior Proposal; (ii)<br />

immediately prior to or substantially<br />

concurrently with <strong>the</strong> termination<br />

of this Agreement <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong><br />

enters into one or more Alternative<br />

Acquisition Agreements with respect<br />

to a Superior Proposal; <strong>and</strong> (iii)<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> immediately prior to<br />

or substantially concurrently with<br />

such termination pays to Parent or<br />

its designees in immediately *828<br />

available funds any fees required to be<br />

paid pursuant to Section 8.5.<br />

Id. § 8.3(a). Prior to exercising <strong>the</strong> termination right, Del<br />

Monte must have given KKR written notice describing <strong>the</strong><br />

material terms <strong>and</strong> conditions of <strong>the</strong> Superior Proposal <strong>and</strong><br />

negotiated with KKR in good faith for three business days<br />

to enable KKR to match <strong>the</strong> Superior Proposal. Id. § 6.5(h).<br />

The match right must be complied with for each change in<br />

<strong>the</strong> financial terms of or o<strong>the</strong>r material amendment to <strong>the</strong><br />

Superior Proposal, except that after <strong>the</strong> first match <strong>the</strong> three<br />

business day period becomes two business days. Id.<br />

If Del Monte terminates <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement to enter into<br />

a transaction with an Excluded Party—defined generally as a<br />

person or group who made an Acquisition Proposal during <strong>the</strong><br />

go-shop period—<strong>the</strong>n Del Monte owes KKR a termination<br />

fee in <strong>the</strong> amount of $60 million, representing 1.13% of total<br />

deal value <strong>and</strong> 1.5% of equity value, or approximately $0.312<br />

per share. Id. § 8.5(b). If Del Monte terminates <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement to enter into a transaction with a party o<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

an Excluded Party, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> termination fee increases to $120<br />

million, representing 2.26% of total deal value, 3.0% of <strong>the</strong><br />

total equity value, <strong>and</strong> approximately $0.624 per share. Id.<br />

The Board decided to let Barclays run <strong>the</strong> go-shop. In carrying<br />

out this assignment, Barclays had a direct financial conflict.<br />

In its role as sell-side financial advisor, Barclays had earned<br />

$2.5 million for its fairness opinion (despite <strong>the</strong> conflict of<br />

interest giving rise to <strong>the</strong> need for a second banker) <strong>and</strong> would<br />

earn ano<strong>the</strong>r $21 million if <strong>the</strong> deal closed. For its role in <strong>the</strong><br />

buy-side financing for KKR, Barclays stood to earn ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

$21 to $24 million. As Ben acknowledged, Barclays would<br />

earn substantially more for executing <strong>the</strong> LBO with KKR<br />

than it would for any o<strong>the</strong>r strategic alternative. If ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

bidder emerged that did not need financing or who chose<br />

not to use Barclays, <strong>the</strong>n Barclays would lose its buy-side<br />

financing fees. Martin testified that it “never occurred to us<br />

that [Barclays] wouldn't do a good job.” Martin Tr. 64.<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r advisors were available. Perella Weinberg had rendered<br />

<strong>the</strong> second fairness opinion necessitated by Barclays' conflict<br />

<strong>and</strong> could have h<strong>and</strong>led <strong>the</strong> process. Goldman Sachs had<br />

a prior relationship with Del Monte <strong>and</strong> independently<br />

approached Del Monte about managing <strong>the</strong> go-shop. Upon<br />

learning of Goldman's interest, Barclays told KKR that<br />

Goldman was trying to “scare up competition.” PX 32<br />

(“Goldman has been pushing <strong>the</strong> company to help run <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

go-shop <strong>and</strong> scare up competition against us (!)....”). Brown<br />

of KKR told Barclays that he would “manage it” directly<br />

with Goldman. Id. He solved <strong>the</strong> problem by letting Goldman<br />

participate in 5% of <strong>the</strong> syndication rights for <strong>the</strong> acquisition<br />

financing, which “squared things away <strong>the</strong>re.” PX 33. After<br />

that, Goldman dropped its efforts to conduct <strong>the</strong> go shop.<br />

During <strong>the</strong> go-shop period, Barclays contacted fifty-three<br />

parties, including thirty strategic buyers. Three requested <strong>and</strong><br />

were provided with confidentiality agreements. Two parties<br />

from <strong>the</strong> early 2010 process re-engaged. No one expressed<br />

interest.<br />

K. The Proxy Supplement<br />

On January 12, 2011, Del Monte issued its definitive<br />

proxy statement on Schedule 14A. Many of <strong>the</strong> disclosures<br />

about <strong>the</strong> background of <strong>the</strong> transaction were false <strong>and</strong><br />

misleading, in part because Barclays hid its behind-<strong>the</strong>scenes<br />

activities from <strong>the</strong> Board. On February 4, after <strong>the</strong><br />

completion of discovery in connection with <strong>the</strong> preliminary<br />

injunction application, Del *829 Monte issued <strong>the</strong> Proxy<br />

Supplement to moot <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs' disclosure claims. The<br />

Proxy Supplement disclosed that <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> learned<br />

significant facts about Barclays' role <strong>and</strong> interactions with<br />

KKR only as a result of this litigation.<br />

Among o<strong>the</strong>r things, <strong>the</strong> Proxy Supplement disclosed <strong>the</strong><br />

following:<br />

• “Since <strong>the</strong> filing of <strong>the</strong> Definitive Proxy Statement, <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> has learned that as early as January 2010,<br />

representatives of Barclays Capital had indicated <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

intent to seek to participate as a financing source in<br />

connection with any future transaction pursued by <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> subject to <strong>the</strong> internal approval of Barclays<br />

Capital <strong>and</strong> subject to <strong>the</strong> approval of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> if<br />

Barclays Capital were also acting as financial advisor to<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>.” Proxy Supp. at 2.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 13


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

• “Since <strong>the</strong> filing of <strong>the</strong> Definitive Proxy Statement by<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> has learned that financing<br />

sources o<strong>the</strong>r than Barclays Capital could have provided<br />

sufficient financing for <strong>the</strong> transaction at $19.00 per<br />

share without <strong>the</strong> participation of Barclays Capital.” Id.<br />

at 4.<br />

• “Since <strong>the</strong> filing of <strong>the</strong> Definitive Proxy Statement,<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> has learned that beginning in August<br />

2010 <strong>and</strong> September 2010, after Barclays Capital's<br />

engagement with <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> had formally concluded,<br />

Barclays Capital had routine business development<br />

discussions with, among o<strong>the</strong>rs, KKR <strong>and</strong> Vestar,<br />

concerning potential strategic opportunities, including a<br />

potential acquisition of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>. In <strong>the</strong> course of<br />

<strong>the</strong> discussions between Barclays Capital <strong>and</strong> Vestar,<br />

Barclays Capital <strong>and</strong> Vestar discussed that KKR/<br />

Centerview would be a good partner with Vestar <strong>and</strong><br />

a good strategic match with Vestar if <strong>the</strong> potential<br />

for a transaction involving <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> arose. At <strong>the</strong><br />

time of <strong>the</strong>se discussions, Barclays Capital believed that<br />

Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR/Centerview had prior discussions about<br />

potential opportunities in <strong>the</strong> consumer sector, including<br />

<strong>the</strong> possibility of an acquisition of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> if<br />

<strong>the</strong> opportunity reemerged. The <strong>Company</strong> also has<br />

learned since <strong>the</strong> filing of <strong>the</strong> Definitive Proxy Statement<br />

that, subsequent to <strong>the</strong> routine business development<br />

discussions in August <strong>and</strong> September 2010 discussed<br />

above, KKR/Centerview <strong>and</strong> Vestar had discussions<br />

about working toge<strong>the</strong>r on an indication of interest<br />

regarding a transaction with <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>.” Id. at 2–3.<br />

• “Since <strong>the</strong> filing of <strong>the</strong> Definitive Proxy Statement, <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> has learned that during <strong>the</strong> period between<br />

October 11, 2010 <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> week of November 8, 2010<br />

<strong>the</strong>re were discussions among <strong>the</strong> sponsors concerning<br />

<strong>the</strong> conversations between KKR/Centerview <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> <strong>and</strong> about potentially adding Vestar as an<br />

acquisition partner at a later point in time in <strong>the</strong> event<br />

negotiations progressed with <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>.” Id. at 3.<br />

The defendants released this information on <strong>the</strong> afternoon<br />

of Friday, February 4, 2011, apparently expecting that<br />

stockholders could digest it, determine how to vote, <strong>and</strong><br />

ei<strong>the</strong>r submit proxies or revocations or appear <strong>and</strong> vote at<br />

<strong>the</strong> special meeting on Tuesday, February 15. In light of <strong>the</strong><br />

relief granted, I need not separately consider whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><br />

timing <strong>and</strong> manner of dissemination were adequate under <strong>the</strong><br />

circumstances.<br />

II. LEGAL ANALYSIS<br />

[1] To obtain a preliminary injunction, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs must<br />

demonstrate (i) a reasonable probability of success on <strong>the</strong><br />

merits; *830 (ii) that <strong>the</strong>y will suffer irreparable injury if<br />

an injunction is not granted; <strong>and</strong> (iii) that <strong>the</strong> balance of<br />

<strong>the</strong> equities favors <strong>the</strong> issuance of an injunction. Revlon,<br />

Inc. v. MacAndrews & Forbes Hldgs., Co., 506 A.2d 173,<br />

179 (Del.1986). The plaintiffs have met <strong>the</strong> first <strong>and</strong> second<br />

elements. After due consideration of <strong>the</strong> third element, I find<br />

that <strong>the</strong> circumstances call for a limited injunction along <strong>the</strong><br />

lines <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs have requested.<br />

A. The Probability of Success on <strong>the</strong> Merits<br />

[2] The first element of <strong>the</strong> familiar injunction test requires<br />

that <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs establish a reasonable probability of success<br />

on <strong>the</strong> merits. This showing “falls well short of that which<br />

would be required to secure final relief following trial, since it<br />

explicitly requires only that <strong>the</strong> record establish a reasonable<br />

probability that this greater showing will ultimately be<br />

made.” Cantor Fitzgerald, L.P. v. Cantor, 724 A.2d 571, 579<br />

(Del.Ch.1998) (internal quotation marks omitted). Because<br />

<strong>the</strong> disclosure claims have been mooted, <strong>the</strong> pertinent claims<br />

are (i) breach of fiduciary duty against <strong>the</strong> director defendants<br />

<strong>and</strong> (ii) aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting by KKR.<br />

1. The Breach of Fiduciary Duty Claim<br />

[3] [4] “Delaware has three tiers of review for evaluating<br />

director decision-making: <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule,<br />

enhanced scrutiny, <strong>and</strong> entire fairness.” Reis v. Hazelett<br />

Strip–Casting Corp., 2011 WL 303207, at *8 (Del.Ch. Feb.<br />

1, 2011). Delaware applies enhanced scrutiny when directors<br />

face potentially subtle structural or situational conflicts that<br />

do not rise to a level sufficient to trigger entire fairness<br />

review, but also do not comfortably permit expansive judicial<br />

deference. Id. at *8–10; see Paramount Commc'ns Inc. v.<br />

QVC Network Inc., 637 A.2d 34, 42 (Del.1994) [hereinafter,<br />

“QVC ”] (“[T]here are rare situations which m<strong>and</strong>ate that<br />

a court take a more direct <strong>and</strong> active role in overseeing<br />

<strong>the</strong> decisions made <strong>and</strong> actions taken by directors. In <strong>the</strong>se<br />

situations, a court subjects <strong>the</strong> directors' conduct to enhanced<br />

scrutiny to ensure that it is reasonable.”).<br />

[5] [6] Enhanced scrutiny has both subjective <strong>and</strong><br />

objective components. Initially, <strong>the</strong> directors “bear <strong>the</strong> burden<br />

of persuasion to show that <strong>the</strong>ir motivations were proper<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 14


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

<strong>and</strong> not selfish.” Mercier v. Inter–Tel (Del.), Inc., 929 A.2d<br />

786, 810 (Del.Ch.2007). Adapted to <strong>the</strong> M & A context,<br />

<strong>the</strong> directors must show that <strong>the</strong>y sought “to secure <strong>the</strong><br />

transaction offering <strong>the</strong> best value reasonably available for<br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholders.” QVC, 637 A.2d at 44. The key verb is<br />

“sought.” Time-bound mortals cannot foresee <strong>the</strong> future. The<br />

test <strong>the</strong>refore cannot be whe<strong>the</strong>r, with hindsight, <strong>the</strong> directors<br />

actually achieved <strong>the</strong> best price. “Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> duty can only<br />

be to try in good faith, in such a setting, to get <strong>the</strong> best<br />

available transaction for <strong>the</strong> shareholders. Directors are not<br />

insurers.” Citron v. Fairchild Camera <strong>and</strong> Instrument Corp.,<br />

1988 WL 53322, at *16 n. 17 (Del.Ch. May 19, 1988) (Allen,<br />

C.); accord In re Dollar Thrifty S'holder Litig., 2010 WL<br />

3503471, at *32 (Del.Ch. Sept. 8, 2010).<br />

[7] [8] [9] [10] Having made <strong>the</strong> necessary subjective<br />

showing, <strong>the</strong> directors next must demonstrate that “<strong>the</strong>ir<br />

actions were reasonable in relation to <strong>the</strong>ir legitimate<br />

objective.” Mercier, 929 A.2d at 810. The directors bear<br />

<strong>the</strong> burden of proving that <strong>the</strong>y (i) followed a reasonable<br />

decision-making process <strong>and</strong> based <strong>the</strong>ir decisions on a<br />

reasonable body of information, <strong>and</strong> (ii) acted reasonably in<br />

light of <strong>the</strong> circumstances <strong>the</strong>n existing. QVC, 637 A.2d at<br />

45. The reasonableness st<strong>and</strong>ard permits a reviewing court<br />

to address inequitable action even when directors may have<br />

subjectively *831 believed that <strong>the</strong>y were acting properly. 2<br />

That said, <strong>the</strong> objective st<strong>and</strong>ard does not permit a reviewing<br />

court to freely substitute its own judgment for <strong>the</strong> directors'.<br />

[A] court applying enhanced judicial scrutiny should<br />

be deciding whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> directors made a reasonable<br />

decision, not a perfect decision. If a board selected one of<br />

several reasonable alternatives, a court should not secondguess<br />

that choice even though it might have decided<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise or subsequent events may have cast doubt on<br />

<strong>the</strong> board's determination. Thus, courts will not substitute<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir business judgment for that of <strong>the</strong> directors, but will<br />

determine if <strong>the</strong> directors' decision was, on balance, within<br />

a range of reasonableness.<br />

QVC, 637 A.2d at 45 (emphasis in original). Put differently,<br />

enhanced scrutiny “is not a license for law-trained courts<br />

to second-guess reasonable, but debatable, tactical choices<br />

that directors have made in good faith.” In re Toys “R”<br />

Us, Inc. S'holder Litig., 877 A.2d 975, 1000 (Del.Ch.2005);<br />

accord Dollar Thrifty, 2010 WL 3503471, at *17 (“[A]t<br />

bottom Revlon is a test of reasonableness; directors are<br />

generally free to select <strong>the</strong> path to value maximization, so<br />

long as <strong>the</strong>y choose a reasonable route to get <strong>the</strong>re.”). What<br />

typically drives a finding of unreasonableness is evidence<br />

of self-interest, undue favoritism or disdain towards a<br />

particular bidder, or a similar non-stockholder-motivated<br />

influence that calls into question <strong>the</strong> integrity of <strong>the</strong><br />

process. See Dollar Thrifty, 2010 WL 3503471, at *18–19;<br />

Toys “R” Us, 877 A.2d at 1000–01.<br />

[11] In evaluating <strong>the</strong> adequacy of <strong>the</strong> directors' decisionmaking<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> information <strong>the</strong>y had available, a reviewing<br />

court necessarily will consider <strong>the</strong> extent to which a board has<br />

relied on expert advisors. When responding to a takeover bid<br />

or considering a final-stage transaction, <strong>the</strong> directors' advisors<br />

play a pivotal role.<br />

Frequently, <strong>the</strong> outside directors who<br />

find <strong>the</strong>mselves in control of a<br />

corporate sale process have had little<br />

or no experience in <strong>the</strong> sale of a public<br />

company. They are in terra incognito<br />

[sic]. Naturally, <strong>the</strong>y turn for guidance<br />

to <strong>the</strong>ir specialist advisors who will<br />

typically have had a great deal of<br />

relevant experience.<br />

William T. Allen, Independent Directors In MBO<br />

Transactions: Are They Fact or Fantasy?, 45 Bus. Law.2055,<br />

2061 (1990). “It is obvious that no role is more critical<br />

with respect to protection of shareholder interests in <strong>the</strong>se<br />

matters than that of <strong>the</strong> expert lawyers [<strong>and</strong> here I add<br />

financial advisors] who guide sometimes inexperienced<br />

directors through <strong>the</strong> process.” *832 In re Fort Howard<br />

Corp. S'holders Litig., 1988 WL 83147, at *12 (Del.Ch. Aug.<br />

8, 1988) (Allen, C.).<br />

Because of <strong>the</strong> central role played by investment banks in<br />

<strong>the</strong> evaluation, exploration, selection, <strong>and</strong> implementation of<br />

strategic alternatives, this Court has required full disclosure<br />

of investment banker compensation <strong>and</strong> potential conflicts. 3<br />

This Court has not stopped at disclosure, but ra<strong>the</strong>r has<br />

examined banker conflicts closely to determine whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y<br />

tainted <strong>the</strong> directors' process. 4<br />

In Toys “R” Us, Vice Chancellor Strine considered whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

an investment bankers role in providing stapled financing<br />

created a conflict of interest that merited injunctive relief. At<br />

<strong>the</strong> outset of <strong>the</strong> sale process challenged in that case, <strong>the</strong> sellside<br />

investment banker, First Boston, asked about possibly<br />

providing buy-side financing for purchasers of a subsidiary.<br />

“The board promptly nixed that idea.” 877 A.2d at 1005.<br />

Then, following a lengthy process during which <strong>the</strong> form<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 15


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

of <strong>the</strong> transaction shifted from a sale of <strong>the</strong> subsidiary to a<br />

sale of <strong>the</strong> whole company, <strong>and</strong> two months after <strong>the</strong> process<br />

culminated in an executed merger agreement, First Boston<br />

again asked to be permitted to provide a portion of <strong>the</strong> buyside<br />

financing. This time <strong>the</strong> board agreed. Vice Chancellor<br />

Strine described that decision as “unfortunate, in that it tends<br />

to raise eyebrows by creating <strong>the</strong> appearance of impropriety,<br />

playing into already heightened suspicions about <strong>the</strong> ethics<br />

of investment banking firms.” Id. at 1006. He suggested it<br />

would have been “[f]ar better, from <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>point of instilling<br />

confidence, if First Boston had never asked for permission,<br />

<strong>and</strong> had taken <strong>the</strong> position that its credibility as a sell-side<br />

advisor was too important in this case, <strong>and</strong> in general, for it<br />

to simultaneously play on <strong>the</strong> buy-side in a deal when it was<br />

<strong>the</strong> seller's financial advisor.” Id. He likewise noted that “it<br />

might have been better, in view of First Boston's refusal to<br />

refrain, for <strong>the</strong> board of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> *833 to have declined<br />

<strong>the</strong> request, even though <strong>the</strong> request came on May 12, 2005,<br />

almost two months after <strong>the</strong> board had signed <strong>the</strong> merger<br />

agreement.” Id. Never<strong>the</strong>less, after reviewing in detail <strong>the</strong><br />

public, year-long, multi-phase process that <strong>the</strong> board <strong>and</strong> its<br />

banker conducted, Vice Chancellor Strine concluded “upon<br />

close scrutiny” that First Boston's appearance of conflict<br />

did not have “a causal influence” on <strong>the</strong> boards process.<br />

Id. He cautioned that “[i]n general, however, it is advisable<br />

that investment banks representing sellers not create <strong>the</strong><br />

appearance that <strong>the</strong>y desire buy-side work, especially when<br />

it might be that <strong>the</strong>y are more likely to be selected by some<br />

buyers for that lucrative role than by o<strong>the</strong>rs.” Id. at 1006 n. 46.<br />

Applying <strong>the</strong>se principles to <strong>the</strong> current case shows that<br />

Barclays' activities went far beyond what took place in Toys<br />

“R” Us. Barclays set out to provide acquisition financing,<br />

as established by <strong>the</strong> internal screening memos from January<br />

<strong>and</strong> March 2010. Barclays' Del Monte coverage officer<br />

pitched a Del Monte LBO to KKR, Apollo, <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

private equity firms that would be likely to use Barclays<br />

for acquisition financing. Once it secured <strong>the</strong> sell-side role,<br />

Barclays structured a small, private process that maximized<br />

<strong>the</strong> likelihood that it could provide acquisition financing.<br />

Barclays never disclosed to <strong>the</strong> Board its interactions with<br />

<strong>the</strong> private equity shops or its desire to provide acquisition<br />

financing.<br />

After <strong>the</strong> early 2010 process terminated, Barclays became<br />

more aggressive. In September, Barclays paired up Vestar <strong>and</strong><br />

KKR in violation of <strong>the</strong>ir confidentiality agreements with Del<br />

Monte. Barclays <strong>the</strong>n assisted Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR in preparing<br />

an indication of interest. After being re-engaged by Del<br />

Monte, Barclays again did not disclose its interactions with<br />

<strong>the</strong> banks or its plan to secure a buy-side role, <strong>and</strong> it actively<br />

concealed <strong>the</strong> fact that Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR were working<br />

toge<strong>the</strong>r. When KKR “formally requested” permission to<br />

make a joint bid with Vestar, Barclays did not come clean,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Del Monte agreed without seeking to extract any prostockholder<br />

concession or o<strong>the</strong>r advantage. Before <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement was signed <strong>and</strong> with price negotiations still ongoing,<br />

Barclays sought <strong>and</strong> obtained a buy-side role <strong>and</strong><br />

worked with KKR to develop financing. As a result, at <strong>the</strong><br />

same time Barclays ostensibly was negotiating to get KKR to<br />

pay more, Barclays had an incentive as a well-compensated<br />

lender to ensure that a deal was reached <strong>and</strong> that KKR did not<br />

overpay.<br />

But for Barclays' manipulations, <strong>the</strong> Del Monte process<br />

would have played out differently. If <strong>the</strong> directors had<br />

known at <strong>the</strong> outset of Barclays' intentions <strong>and</strong> activities,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Board likely would have hired a different banker. Del<br />

Monte had good relationships with Goldman Sachs <strong>and</strong><br />

Bank of America/Merrill Lynch, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board easily could<br />

have tapped ei<strong>the</strong>r firm. Even if <strong>the</strong> directors decided to<br />

proceed with Barclays, <strong>the</strong> Board <strong>and</strong> its experienced counsel<br />

doubtless would have taken steps to protect <strong>the</strong> integrity<br />

of <strong>the</strong> process. As soon as Barclays disclosed its buy-side<br />

aspirations, <strong>the</strong> Board likely would have followed Toys “R”<br />

Us <strong>and</strong> “nixed that idea.” The Board <strong>and</strong> its counsel likely<br />

also would have limited <strong>the</strong> role of Barclays lending group,<br />

chaperoned its discussions with bidders, or used ano<strong>the</strong>r bank<br />

to provide confidential feedback to <strong>the</strong> potential sponsors<br />

about leverage parameters <strong>and</strong> market expectations.<br />

Although Barclays' activities <strong>and</strong> non-disclosures in early<br />

2010 are troubling, what indisputably crossed <strong>the</strong> line was <strong>the</strong><br />

surreptitious <strong>and</strong> unauthorized pairing of Vestar with KKR.<br />

In doing so, Barclays materially reduced <strong>the</strong> prospect of price<br />

*834 competition for Del Monte. Vestar had been <strong>the</strong> high<br />

bidder in <strong>the</strong> early 2010 process, <strong>and</strong> although Vestar needed a<br />

partner, a non-conflicted financial advisor could have teamed<br />

Vestar with a different sponsor. It was to address precisely<br />

this risk of competition-limiting behavior that Del Monte<br />

secured <strong>the</strong> No Teaming Provision. Barclays' efforts caused<br />

Vestar <strong>and</strong> KKR to violate <strong>the</strong> No Teaming Provision. Most<br />

egregiously, Barclays actively concealed <strong>the</strong> pairing from <strong>the</strong><br />

Del Monte Board. It was not until <strong>the</strong> week of November<br />

8 that KKR “formally requested” to be allowed to partner<br />

with Vestar. Barclays continued to hide its involvement <strong>and</strong><br />

recommended that <strong>the</strong> pairing be permitted.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 16


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

The record does not reflect meaningful Board consideration<br />

or informed decision-making with respect to <strong>the</strong> Vestar<br />

pairing. There are no minutes that suggest hard thinking about<br />

how acceding to KKR's request might affect Del Monte.<br />

Martin testified about <strong>the</strong> issue as follows:<br />

Q. The next paragraph [of <strong>the</strong> proxy] starts off, it<br />

says, “Later during <strong>the</strong> week of November 8, 2010,<br />

KKR <strong>and</strong> Centerview approached Barclays Capital<br />

about <strong>the</strong> possibility of including Vestar in <strong>the</strong><br />

deal as an additional member of <strong>the</strong> sponsor group.<br />

Representatives of KKR indicated that Vestar's prior<br />

experience in <strong>the</strong> food industry would make <strong>the</strong>m an<br />

ideal partner for KKR/Centerview in connection with a<br />

potential investment in <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>. After discussions<br />

between KKR, Centerview <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong>, <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>Company</strong> permitted KKR <strong>and</strong> Centerview to approach<br />

Vestar to become an additional member of <strong>the</strong> sponsor<br />

group.” Do you see that?<br />

A. I do.<br />

Q. Did that happen at a Board meeting?<br />

A. I don't recall.<br />

Q. Do you recall <strong>the</strong> Board approving <strong>the</strong> concept of KKR<br />

contacting Vestar <strong>and</strong> getting <strong>the</strong>m involved as part of<br />

<strong>the</strong> KKR group?<br />

A. I don't recall that.<br />

Q. Do you recall how it happened?<br />

A. I do not.<br />

Q. When is <strong>the</strong> first time you heard about it?<br />

A. I don't remember.<br />

Q. Do you recall <strong>the</strong> Board ever authorizing KKR in<br />

writing at any time prior to <strong>the</strong> week of November 8,<br />

2010 to communicate with Vestar about teaming up to<br />

buy Del Monte?<br />

A. I do not recall anything of that nature.<br />

Q. Was <strong>the</strong>re any discussion at <strong>the</strong> Board level of whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

it was advisable to allow a company that previously had<br />

been bidding against KKR in <strong>the</strong> January, early January<br />

process, to now instead team up with KKR in <strong>the</strong> late<br />

2010 process?<br />

[DEFENSE COUNSEL]: Objection.<br />

A. I don't remember any conversations about that.<br />

Martin Tr. 49–51. It was not reasonable for <strong>the</strong> Board to<br />

accede to KKR's request <strong>and</strong> give up its best prospect for price<br />

competition without making any effort to obtain a benefit for<br />

Del Monte <strong>and</strong> its stockholders.<br />

Barclays similarly crossed <strong>the</strong> line with its late-stage request<br />

for permission to be one of KKR's lead banks. There was<br />

no deal-related reason for <strong>the</strong> request, just Barclays' desire<br />

for more fees. Del Monte did not benefit. The immediate<br />

consequence was to force Del Monte to spend $3 *835<br />

million to hire a second bank. The more serious consequence<br />

was to taint <strong>the</strong> final negotiations. At <strong>the</strong> time Barclays<br />

made its request, <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement was not yet signed,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Barclays <strong>and</strong> KKR were still negotiating over price.<br />

Barclays' internal documents from January <strong>and</strong> March 2010<br />

had stated that “Barclays will look to participate in <strong>the</strong><br />

acquisition financing once <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> has reached a<br />

definitive agreement with a buyer.” But Barclays could not<br />

wait.<br />

In considering Barclays' request, <strong>the</strong> Board again failed to<br />

act reasonably. The Board did not ask whe<strong>the</strong>r KKR could<br />

fund <strong>the</strong> deal without Barclays' involvement, <strong>and</strong> Del Monte<br />

did not learn until this litigation that Barclays was not<br />

needed on <strong>the</strong> buy-side. If <strong>the</strong> Board had refused Barclays'<br />

request, <strong>the</strong>n Del Monte could have had a non-conflicted<br />

(or at least not directly conflicted) negotiator bargain with<br />

KKR. Without some justification reasonably related to<br />

advancing stockholder interests, it was unreasonable for<br />

<strong>the</strong> Board to permit Barclays to take on a direct conflict<br />

when still negotiating price. It is impossible to know how<br />

<strong>the</strong> negotiations would have turned out if h<strong>and</strong>led by a<br />

representative that did not have a direct conflict. The burden<br />

of that uncertainty must rest with <strong>the</strong> fiduciaries who created<br />

it.<br />

Finally, Barclays' conflict tainted <strong>the</strong> go-shop process. What<br />

Barclays did looks good on <strong>the</strong> surface, but <strong>the</strong> “who” is as<br />

important as <strong>the</strong> “what.” As Vice Chancellor Strine explained<br />

in Netsmart, “body language” can be critical. In re Netsmart<br />

Techs., Inc. S'holder Litig., 924 A.2d 171, 188 (Del.Ch.2007).<br />

There, a special committee permitted <strong>the</strong> company's CEO<br />

to drive a sale process involving private equity bidders who<br />

likely would retain management.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 17


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

In easily imagined circumstances,<br />

this approach ... could be highly<br />

problematic. If management had an<br />

incentive to favor a particular bidder<br />

(or type of bidder), it could use <strong>the</strong> ...<br />

process to its advantage, by using<br />

different body language <strong>and</strong> verbal<br />

emphasis with different bidders.<br />

“She's fine” can mean different things<br />

depending on how it is said.<br />

Id. at 194. I recognize that <strong>the</strong> level of interaction in <strong>the</strong> due<br />

diligence meetings discussed in Netsmart differs from what<br />

takes place in a go-shop, particularly in <strong>the</strong> early outreach<br />

phase, but an analogous principle applies.<br />

The Strategic Committee delegated <strong>the</strong> task of running <strong>the</strong> goshop<br />

to Barclays <strong>and</strong> had no direct insight into how Barclays<br />

interacted with <strong>the</strong> parties it contacted. Barclays had a strong<br />

interest in ensuring that a particular kind of buyer (private<br />

equity) acquired Del Monte <strong>and</strong> a keen desire to see <strong>the</strong> deal<br />

close with KKR. In <strong>the</strong> last two years, Barclays has earned<br />

$66 million from KKR. If ano<strong>the</strong>r bidder declined or did not<br />

need Barclays' financing, <strong>the</strong> bank would lose half of <strong>the</strong><br />

approximately $44.5 to $47.5 million that Barclays st<strong>and</strong>s to<br />

earn from its dual role. To recoup <strong>the</strong> lost financing fees,<br />

Barclays would have had to find a bidder willing to pay<br />

between $24.25 <strong>and</strong> $26 per share, or an additional $1.2 <strong>and</strong><br />

$1.4 billion. Not likely.<br />

[12] Although <strong>the</strong> blame for what took place appears at this<br />

preliminary stage to lie with Barclays, <strong>the</strong> buck stops with <strong>the</strong><br />

Board. Delaware law requires that a board take an “active <strong>and</strong><br />

direct role in <strong>the</strong> sale process.” Citron v. Fairchild Camera<br />

& Instrument Corp., 569 A.2d 53, 66 (Del.1989). “[T]he<br />

role of outside, independent directors becomes particularly<br />

important because of <strong>the</strong> magnitude of a sale of control<br />

transaction <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> possibility, in *836 certain cases, that<br />

management [<strong>and</strong> here I add o<strong>the</strong>r contingently compensated<br />

professionals like investment banks] may not necessarily be<br />

impartial.” QVC, 637 A.2d at 44.<br />

This is a case like Mills Acquisition Co. v. Macmillan, Inc.,<br />

559 A.2d 1261 (Del.1989), in which <strong>the</strong> Delaware Supreme<br />

Court held that injunctive relief was required when a board's<br />

lack of involvement in a sale process enabled management<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir financial advisor to steer <strong>the</strong> deal to KKR, <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

preferred bidder. In Mills, management's conflict arose out<br />

of <strong>the</strong>ir buy-side interest in a leveraged buyout sponsored<br />

by KKR. Id. at 1272. Management tainted <strong>the</strong> sale process<br />

by communicating with KKR without board approval <strong>and</strong><br />

cl<strong>and</strong>estinely passing information to KKR about <strong>the</strong> bidding<br />

process. Id. at 1275. Despite <strong>the</strong>ir independence, <strong>the</strong> directors<br />

failed adequately to oversee <strong>the</strong> process <strong>and</strong> permitted <strong>the</strong><br />

conflicted management team <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir financial advisor to<br />

exploit <strong>the</strong> opportunities it presented. Id. at 1280–81, 1284 n.<br />

32.<br />

In enjoining <strong>the</strong> proposed transaction, <strong>the</strong> Delaware Supreme<br />

Court spoke directly to <strong>the</strong> implications of a board being<br />

misled by conflicted individuals:<br />

[W]hen corporate directors rely in<br />

good faith upon opinions or reports<br />

of officers <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r experts “selected<br />

with reasonable care,” <strong>the</strong>y necessarily<br />

do so on <strong>the</strong> presumption that <strong>the</strong><br />

information provided is both accurate<br />

<strong>and</strong> complete. Normally, decisions of<br />

a board based upon such data will<br />

not be disturbed when made in <strong>the</strong><br />

proper exercise of business judgment.<br />

However, when a board is deceived<br />

by those who will gain from such<br />

misconduct, <strong>the</strong> protections girding<br />

<strong>the</strong> decision itself vanish. Decisions<br />

made on such a basis are voidable<br />

at <strong>the</strong> behest of innocent parties to<br />

whom a fiduciary duty was owed<br />

<strong>and</strong> breached, <strong>and</strong> whose interests<br />

were <strong>the</strong>reby materially <strong>and</strong> adversely<br />

affected.<br />

Id. at 1283–84. The Delaware Supreme Court also addressed<br />

<strong>the</strong> role of management's financial advisor, finding that <strong>the</strong><br />

board's reliance on his advice “share[d] <strong>the</strong> same defects” as<br />

<strong>the</strong> board's reliance on conflicted management. Id. at 1284 n.<br />

33.<br />

[13] Here, <strong>the</strong> taint of self-interest came from a conflicted<br />

financial advisor ra<strong>the</strong>r than from management. Like <strong>the</strong><br />

directors in Mills, <strong>the</strong> Del Monte Board was deceived. At a<br />

minimum, Barclays withheld information about its buy-side<br />

intentions, its involvement with KKR, <strong>and</strong> its pairing of KKR<br />

<strong>and</strong> Vestar. As in Mills, “<strong>the</strong>re can be no dispute but that such<br />

silence was misleading <strong>and</strong> deceptive. In short, it was a fraud<br />

upon <strong>the</strong> board.” Id. at 1283. I <strong>the</strong>refore conclude that <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiffs have established a reasonable likelihood of success<br />

on <strong>the</strong> merits of <strong>the</strong>ir claim that <strong>the</strong> director defendants failed<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 18


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

to act reasonably in connection with <strong>the</strong> sale process. This<br />

does not mean that any director necessarily will face money<br />

damages. The question currently before <strong>the</strong> Court is whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is a sufficient likelihood of success on <strong>the</strong> merits to<br />

support injunctive relief, <strong>and</strong> that is all I address. See id. at<br />

1284 n. 32.<br />

2. The Aiding <strong>and</strong> Abetting Claim<br />

[14] The plaintiffs claim that KKR aided <strong>and</strong> abetted <strong>the</strong><br />

directors' breaches of fiduciary duty. “[T]he four elements<br />

of an aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting claim [are] (1) <strong>the</strong> existence<br />

of a fiduciary relationship, (2) a breach of <strong>the</strong> fiduciary's<br />

duty ... (3) knowing participation in that breach by <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants, <strong>and</strong> (4) damages proximately caused by <strong>the</strong><br />

breach.” Malpiede v. Townson, 780 A.2d 1075, 1096<br />

(Del.2001) (internal quotation omitted). The critical element<br />

is “knowing participation.”<br />

*837 [15] [16] A third-party bidder who negotiates<br />

at arms' length rarely faces a viable claim for aiding <strong>and</strong><br />

abetting. “Knowing participation in a board's fiduciary breach<br />

requires that <strong>the</strong> third party act with <strong>the</strong> knowledge that<br />

<strong>the</strong> conduct advocated or assisted constitutes such a breach.<br />

Under this st<strong>and</strong>ard, a bidder's attempts to reduce <strong>the</strong> sale<br />

price through arm's-length negotiations cannot give rise to<br />

liability for aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting.” Id. at 1097. The “longst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

rule that arm's-length bargaining is privileged <strong>and</strong><br />

does not, absent actual collusion <strong>and</strong> facilitation of fiduciary<br />

wrongdoing, constitute aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting helps to safeguard<br />

<strong>the</strong> market for corporate control by facilitating <strong>the</strong> bargaining<br />

that is central to <strong>the</strong> American model of capitalism.” Morgan<br />

v. Cash, 2010 WL 2803746, at *8 (Del.Ch. July 16, 2010)<br />

(internal footnotes omitted). See also Tomczak v. Morton<br />

Thiokol, Inc., 1990 WL 42607, at *16 (Del.Ch. Apr. 5, 1990)<br />

(granting summary judgment in favor of defendant Dow<br />

on claim of aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting breach of fiduciary duty<br />

because “what Dow essentially did [in <strong>the</strong> transaction] was to<br />

simply pursue arm's-length negotiations with Morton Thiokol<br />

through <strong>the</strong>ir respective investment bankers in an effort to<br />

obtain ... <strong>the</strong> best price that it could.”).<br />

[17] [18] Despite <strong>the</strong> general rule, “a bidder may be liable<br />

to <strong>the</strong> target's stockholders if <strong>the</strong> bidder attempts to create or<br />

exploit conflicts of interest in <strong>the</strong> board. Similarly, a bidder<br />

may be liable to a target's stockholders for aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting<br />

a fiduciary breach by <strong>the</strong> target's board where <strong>the</strong> bidder<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> board conspire in or agree to <strong>the</strong> fiduciary breach.”<br />

Malpiede, 780 A.2d at 1097–98 (internal footnotes omitted).<br />

An acquirer is free to seek <strong>the</strong> lowest possible price through<br />

arms' length negotiations with <strong>the</strong> target board, but “it may not<br />

knowingly participate in <strong>the</strong> target board's breach of fiduciary<br />

duty by extracting terms which require <strong>the</strong> opposite party to<br />

prefer its interests at <strong>the</strong> expense of its shareholders.” Gilbert<br />

v. El Paso Co., 490 A.2d 1050, 1058 (Del.Ch.1984), aff'd<br />

575 A.2d 1131 (Del.1990). Creating or exploiting a fiduciary<br />

breach is not part of legitimate arm's-length bargaining; it is<br />

an impermissible intrusion into <strong>the</strong> relationship between <strong>the</strong><br />

fiduciary <strong>and</strong> beneficiary.<br />

[19] KKR knowingly participated in Barclays' selfinterested<br />

activities. When Barclays secretly paired Vestar<br />

with KKR in September 2010, KKR knew it was bound by <strong>the</strong><br />

No Teaming Provision <strong>and</strong> was barred from discussing a Del<br />

Monte bid with anyone absent prior written permission from<br />

Del Monte. KKR never<strong>the</strong>less worked with Barclays <strong>and</strong><br />

Vestar on a joint bid <strong>and</strong> agreed to keep Vestar's involvement<br />

hidden from <strong>the</strong> Board. KKR also knowingly participated in<br />

<strong>the</strong> creation of Barclays' buy-side conflict. Before <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

had cleared Barclays to provide financing to KKR, Barclays<br />

<strong>and</strong> KKR had agreed that Barclays would be one of <strong>the</strong><br />

lead banks. KKR necessarily knew that Barclays would not<br />

push as hard in <strong>the</strong> price negotiations when it stood to earn<br />

substantial fees from both sides of a successful deal. KKR<br />

later ensured that a conflicted Barclays would run <strong>the</strong> go-shop<br />

when KKR “squared things away” with Goldman for 5% of<br />

<strong>the</strong> syndication, ending Goldman's interest in running <strong>the</strong> goshop<br />

process. On this record, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs have established a<br />

reasonable likelihood of success on <strong>the</strong> merits of <strong>the</strong>ir claim<br />

that KKR aided <strong>and</strong> abetted <strong>the</strong> breaches of fiduciary duty<br />

that resulted from Barclays' misconduct.<br />

B. Irreparable Harm<br />

[20] The second requirement for a preliminary injunction<br />

is a showing of irreparable *838 injury if <strong>the</strong> injunction is<br />

not granted. Revlon, 506 A.2d at 179. Harm is irreparable<br />

unless “alternative legal redress [is] clearly available <strong>and</strong><br />

[is] as practical <strong>and</strong> efficient to <strong>the</strong> ends of justice <strong>and</strong> its<br />

prompt administration as <strong>the</strong> remedy in equity.” T. Rowe<br />

Price Recovery Fund, L.P. v. Rubin, 770 A.2d 536, 557<br />

(Del.Ch.2000) (internal quotations <strong>and</strong> citations omitted).<br />

[21] Absent an injunction, <strong>the</strong> Del Monte stockholders will<br />

be deprived forever of <strong>the</strong> opportunity to receive a prevote<br />

topping bid in a process free of taint from Barclays'<br />

improper activities. The threatened foreclosure of this unique<br />

opportunity constitutes irreparable injury. See Hollinger<br />

Intern., Inc. v. Black, 844 A.2d 1022, 1090 (Del.Ch.2004)<br />

(“[T]here is no doubt International faces irreparable injury.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 19


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

Without an injunction, it will be practically impossible<br />

to rescind <strong>the</strong> Barclays Transaction, <strong>the</strong> Strategic Process<br />

will be undermined, <strong>and</strong> International will lose <strong>the</strong> unique<br />

opportunities <strong>the</strong> Process may develop.”).<br />

Absent an injunction, Del Monte's stockholders still could<br />

seek monetary damages. That inquiry, however, would “have<br />

to involve imprecise estimates,” such as deriving <strong>the</strong> price<br />

Del Monte's stockholders might have received in an untainted<br />

process <strong>and</strong> comparing that to what <strong>the</strong>y actually received.<br />

Id. Because of <strong>the</strong> obvious difficulties presented by this<br />

inquiry, stockholders “face a threat of irreparable harm when<br />

a seller's board breaches its Revlon duties by failing to<br />

adequately shop <strong>the</strong> company in advance of recommending<br />

that stockholders tender <strong>the</strong>ir shares to a chosen bidder.” In re<br />

Cogent, Inc. S'holder Litig., 7 A.3d 487, 515 (Del.Ch.2010).<br />

“No doubt <strong>the</strong>re is <strong>the</strong> chance to formulate a rational<br />

remedy down <strong>the</strong> line, but that chance involves great cost,<br />

time, <strong>and</strong>, unavoidably, a large degree of imprecision <strong>and</strong><br />

speculation. After-<strong>the</strong>-fact inquiries into what might have<br />

been had directors tested <strong>the</strong> market adequately ... necessarily<br />

involve[s] reasoned guesswork.” Netsmart, 924 A.2d at 207.<br />

Defenses to monetary damages fur<strong>the</strong>r weigh in favor of prevote<br />

relief. Exculpation under Section 102(b)(7) can render<br />

empty <strong>the</strong> promise of post-closing damages. See 8 Del. C.<br />

§ 102(b)(7); Lyondell Chem. Co. v. Ryan, 970 A.2d 235,<br />

244 (Del.2009). For directors who have relied on qualified<br />

advisors chosen with reasonable care, Section 141(e) provides<br />

ano<strong>the</strong>r powerful defense. See 8 Del. C. § 141(e); In re Walt<br />

Disney Co. Deriv. Litig., 906 A.2d 27, 59–60 (Del.2006).<br />

In such cases, “<strong>the</strong> shareholders' only realistic remedy for<br />

certain breaches of fiduciary duty in connection with a sale<br />

of control transaction may be injunctive relief.” Police &<br />

Fire Ret. Sys. of <strong>the</strong> City of Detroit v. Bernal, 2009 WL<br />

1873144, at *3 (Del.Ch. June 26, 2009). In this action, unless<br />

post-closing discovery reveals additional facts, <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs<br />

face a long <strong>and</strong> steep uphill climb before <strong>the</strong>y could recover<br />

money damages from <strong>the</strong> independent, outside directors on<br />

<strong>the</strong> Board. Admittedly o<strong>the</strong>r prospects for recovery are not so<br />

remote. By <strong>the</strong>ir terms, Sections 102(b)(7) <strong>and</strong> 141(e) do not<br />

protect aiders <strong>and</strong> abetters, <strong>and</strong> disgorgement of transactionrelated<br />

profits may be available as an alternative remedy. That<br />

said, <strong>the</strong> skilled lawyers who represent KKR <strong>and</strong> Barclays<br />

doubtless will have many arguments against liability.<br />

The unique nature of a sale opportunity <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> difficulty<br />

of crafting an accurate post-closing damages award counsel<br />

heavily in favor of equitable relief. The plaintiffs have shown<br />

<strong>the</strong> necessary threat of irreparable harm.<br />

*839 C. Balancing of Hardships<br />

[22] The final element of <strong>the</strong> injunction st<strong>and</strong>ard is <strong>the</strong><br />

balancing of hardships:<br />

[A] court must be cautious that its<br />

injunctive order does not threaten<br />

more harm than good. That is, a court<br />

in exercising its discretion to issue or<br />

deny such a ... remedy must consider<br />

all of <strong>the</strong> foreseeable consequences of<br />

its order <strong>and</strong> balance <strong>the</strong>m. It cannot, in<br />

equity, risk greater harm to defendants,<br />

<strong>the</strong> public or o<strong>the</strong>r identified interests,<br />

in granting <strong>the</strong> injunction, than it seeks<br />

to prevent.<br />

Lennane v. ASK Computer Sys., Inc., 1990 WL 154150, at *6<br />

(Del.Ch. Oct. 11, 1990) (Allen, C.). This element is by far <strong>the</strong><br />

most difficult.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> one h<strong>and</strong>, without an injunction, Del Monte's<br />

stockholders will lose forever <strong>the</strong> chance for a competitive<br />

process that could lead to a higher sale price for <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

company. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, granting an injunction<br />

jeopardizes <strong>the</strong> stockholders' ability to receive a premium for<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir shares. No one disputes, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> evidence establishes,<br />

that $19 is an attractive price. Any delay subjects <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

to market risk. All else equal, a longer delay means greater<br />

risk. There is also <strong>the</strong> difficult question of <strong>the</strong> parties' contract<br />

rights, which Delaware courts strive to respect.<br />

When <strong>the</strong>re is no competing proposal, this Court rarely<br />

will enjoin a premium transaction pending trial. See, e.g.,<br />

Kohls v. Duthie, 765 A.2d 1274, 1289 (Del.Ch.2000); In re<br />

Wheelabrator Techs., Inc. S'holders Litig., 1990 WL 131351,<br />

at *9 (Del.Ch. Sept. 6, 1990). To issue such an injunction<br />

requires both “a special conviction about <strong>the</strong> strength of <strong>the</strong><br />

legal claim asserted” <strong>and</strong> “a strong sense that <strong>the</strong> risks in<br />

granting <strong>the</strong> preliminary relief of a[n] untoward financial<br />

result from <strong>the</strong> stockholders' point of view [are] small.”<br />

Solash v. Telex Corp., 1988 WL 3587, at *13 (Del.Ch. Jan.<br />

19, 1988) (Allen, C.).<br />

At <strong>the</strong> same time, this Court has issued preliminary<br />

injunctions designed to cure pre-vote harm. Preliminary<br />

injunctions against merger votes pending <strong>the</strong> issuance of<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 20


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

curative disclosures offer <strong>the</strong> prime example. Injunctions<br />

of that sort subject transactions to incremental market risk.<br />

See Simonetti, 2008 WL 5048692, at *14. They likewise<br />

interfere, albeit to a minor degree, with <strong>the</strong> parties' st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

contract right to have <strong>the</strong> merger vote as soon as reasonably<br />

practicable. See, e.g., MA § 6.2. Never<strong>the</strong>less, this Court<br />

has been willing to issue disclosure-based injunctions that<br />

delay transactions for as much as twenty days. See La. Mun.<br />

Police Empls.' Ret. Sys. v. Crawford, 918 A.2d 1172, 1192<br />

(Del.Ch.2007).<br />

The plaintiffs ask me to enjoin <strong>the</strong> vote on <strong>the</strong> Merger for<br />

a meaningful period during which a competing bidder may<br />

come forward. The plaintiffs have proposed a delay of 30 to<br />

45 days, derived from <strong>the</strong> 45–day length of <strong>the</strong> earlier go-shop<br />

period. To fur<strong>the</strong>r remove <strong>the</strong> taint of Barclays' involvement,<br />

<strong>the</strong>y ask that <strong>the</strong> parties be enjoined from enforcing <strong>the</strong> deal<br />

protections in <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement during that period.<br />

At this stage, it is not possible to remedy fully <strong>the</strong> effects of<br />

Barclays' maneuvers without blocking <strong>the</strong> deal <strong>and</strong> sending<br />

<strong>the</strong> parties back to <strong>the</strong> drawing board. I cannot, for example,<br />

split up <strong>the</strong> Vestar/KKR team <strong>and</strong> induce a topping bid from<br />

Vestar <strong>and</strong> a different partner. An injunction along <strong>the</strong> lines<br />

requested by <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs does not perfectly remedy <strong>the</strong> harm<br />

Barclays caused, but it does go part of <strong>the</strong> way. The core<br />

injury inflicted on <strong>the</strong> stockholders was Barclays' steering <strong>the</strong><br />

deal to KKR. Barclays won by doubling up on fees. KKR<br />

won by getting Del Monte, free of meaningful competition,<br />

<strong>and</strong> securing *840 a leg-up on potential competing bidders<br />

through <strong>the</strong> defensive measures in <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement.<br />

The injunction sought by <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs partially cures this<br />

injury by limiting KKR's leg-up <strong>and</strong> providing a final window<br />

during which a topping bid could emerge.<br />

[23] I do not believe that a 30 to 45 day delay is warranted.<br />

A postponement of this length might be appropriate if Del<br />

Monte never had been exposed to <strong>the</strong> market. The reality<br />

is that although a conflicted banker conducted <strong>the</strong> go-shop<br />

process, <strong>the</strong> Del Monte transaction was shopped actively for<br />

45 days. Since <strong>the</strong> go-shop process ended on January 10,<br />

2011, <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong> has been subject to an additional passive<br />

market check. A fur<strong>the</strong>r delay of 30 to 45 days ignores <strong>the</strong><br />

fact that many potential bidders have already evaluated this<br />

opportunity. I will <strong>the</strong>refore enjoin <strong>the</strong> merger vote for a<br />

period of only 20 days, which should provide ample time for<br />

a serious <strong>and</strong> motivated bidder to emerge. The resulting delay<br />

is comparable to <strong>the</strong> disclosure injunction in Crawford.<br />

I agree with <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs that during <strong>the</strong> pre-vote period,<br />

<strong>the</strong> parties to <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement should be enjoined<br />

from enforcing <strong>the</strong> deal protection measures. These measures<br />

are not being enjoined because <strong>the</strong>y coerce stockholders,<br />

preclude any alternative to <strong>the</strong> board's chosen transaction, or<br />

o<strong>the</strong>rwise fall outside <strong>the</strong> range of reasonableness. The goshop<br />

lasted 45 days, during which <strong>the</strong> termination fee was $60<br />

million, or 1.13% of transaction value ($4 billion of equity<br />

plus $1.3 billion of debt). After <strong>the</strong> go-shop, <strong>the</strong> termination<br />

fee increases to $120 million, or 2.26% of total deal value.<br />

If included in an arms' length deal untainted by self-interest,<br />

<strong>the</strong> defensive measures would be quite reasonable. See Dollar<br />

Thrifty, 2010 WL 3503471, at *23–32 (discussing alleged<br />

preclusiveness of termination fee); Toys “R” Us, 877 A.2d at<br />

1015–22 (providing guidance on parameters for termination<br />

fees). 5<br />

Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> provisions are being enjoined because <strong>the</strong>y are <strong>the</strong><br />

product of a fiduciary breach that cannot readily be remedied<br />

post-closing after a full trial. KKR secured <strong>the</strong> deal protection<br />

measures as part of a negotiation that was tainted by Barclays'<br />

conflict. KKR should not benefit from <strong>the</strong> misconduct in<br />

which it participated.<br />

[24] The traditional deference given to agreements freely<br />

negotiated between sophisticated parties is limited by<br />

fiduciary principles. “Delaware upholds <strong>the</strong> freedom of<br />

contract <strong>and</strong> enforces as a matter of fundamental public<br />

policy <strong>the</strong> voluntary agreements of sophisticated parties.”<br />

*841 NACCO Indus., Inc. v. Applica Inc., 997 A.2d<br />

1, 35 (Del.Ch.2009). Sophisticated businesses can “make<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir own judgments about <strong>the</strong> risk <strong>the</strong>y should bear,”<br />

<strong>and</strong> those contractual expectations should be respected.<br />

Abry P'rs V, L.P. v. F&W Acq. LLC, 891 A.2d 1032,<br />

1061 (Del.Ch.2006). In <strong>the</strong> deal context, “[p]arties bargain<br />

for provisions in acquisition agreements because those<br />

provisions mean something.” NACCO, 997 A.2d at 19. It is<br />

“critical to our law that those bargained-for rights be enforced,<br />

both through equitable remedies such as injunctive relief <strong>and</strong><br />

specific performance, <strong>and</strong>, in <strong>the</strong> appropriate case, through<br />

monetary remedies including awards of damages.” Id.<br />

[25] When a party aids <strong>and</strong> abets a breach of fiduciary duty,<br />

however, <strong>the</strong> contract rights that <strong>the</strong> aider <strong>and</strong> abetter secures<br />

as a result of <strong>the</strong> interaction must give way to <strong>the</strong> superior<br />

equitable rights <strong>and</strong> interests of <strong>the</strong> beneficiaries. See QVC,<br />

637 A.2d at 50–51; ACE Ltd. v. Capital Re Corp., 747 A.2d 95<br />

(Del.Ch.1999); see also Restatement (Second) of Contracts §<br />

193 (1981) (“A promise by a fiduciary to violate his fiduciary<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 21


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

duty or a promise that tends to induce such a violation is<br />

unenforceable on grounds of public policy.”). In QVC, <strong>the</strong><br />

Delaware Supreme Court rejected <strong>the</strong> argument that vested<br />

contract rights took precedence over a fiduciary breach. 637<br />

A.2d at 51. The Supreme Court held that because <strong>the</strong> buyer<br />

knew it was participating in a breach of fiduciary duty when<br />

it negotiated <strong>the</strong> underlying deal, <strong>the</strong> buyer could not “be<br />

now heard to argue that it obtained vested contract rights by<br />

negotiating <strong>and</strong> obtaining contractual provisions from a board<br />

acting in violation of its fiduciary duties.” Id. The Supreme<br />

Court <strong>the</strong>refore preliminarily enjoined <strong>the</strong> no-shop provision<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> termination fee <strong>and</strong> affirmed <strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery's<br />

preliminary injunction against enforcement of a stock-option<br />

lockup. Id. at 36–37, 50–51.<br />

In ACE, Vice Chancellor Strine discussed <strong>the</strong> tension between<br />

contract rights <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> fiduciary duties owed to stockholders.<br />

In considering a buyer's attempt to enforce a no-shop<br />

clause, Vice Chancellor Strine noted that “<strong>the</strong>re are many<br />

circumstances in which <strong>the</strong> high priority our society places<br />

on <strong>the</strong> enforcement of contracts between private parties gives<br />

way to even more important concerns.” 747 A.2d at 104. He<br />

cited four factors that bear on <strong>the</strong> analysis:<br />

(1) whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> acquiror knew, or<br />

should have known, of <strong>the</strong> target<br />

board's breach of fiduciary duty; (2)<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> ... transaction remains<br />

pending or is already consummated<br />

at <strong>the</strong> time judicial intervention<br />

is sought; (3) whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> board's<br />

violation of fiduciary duty relates to<br />

policy concerns that are especially<br />

significant; <strong>and</strong> (4) whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><br />

acquiror's reliance interest under<br />

<strong>the</strong> challenged agreement merits<br />

protection in <strong>the</strong> event <strong>the</strong> court were<br />

to declare <strong>the</strong> agreement enforceable.<br />

Id. at 105–06 (citing Paul L. Regan, Great Expectations?<br />

A Contract Law Analysis for Preclusive Corporate Lockups,<br />

21 Cardozo L.Rev. 1, 116 (1999)). After balancing<br />

<strong>the</strong> factors, Vice Chancellor Strine held that <strong>the</strong> contract<br />

provision could not be enforced as <strong>the</strong> buyer advocated<br />

because <strong>the</strong> stockholders' interests would take precedence. Id.<br />

at 106–10.<br />

Applying <strong>the</strong> ACE factors to this case indicates that KKR's<br />

“bargained-for rights” should give way. First, as discussed<br />

above in <strong>the</strong> analysis of <strong>the</strong> aiding <strong>and</strong> abetting claim, KKR<br />

knew of <strong>and</strong> knowingly participated in <strong>the</strong> breach of duty.<br />

KKR knew that making Barclays one of its lead banks on<br />

<strong>the</strong> deal would give Barclays a direct conflict of interest at<br />

a time when KKR <strong>and</strong> Barclays were still *842 negotiating<br />

over price. KKR knew that Barclays paired it with Vestar<br />

in violation of both firms' confidentiality agreements with<br />

Del Monte. KKR knew that <strong>the</strong> No Teaming Provision only<br />

be could waived by Del Monte in writing, that consent had<br />

not been given, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> purpose of <strong>the</strong> provision was<br />

to prevent anticompetitive bidding alliances. KKR knew that<br />

Barclays subsequently concealed Vestar's involvement from<br />

Del Monte <strong>and</strong> agreed with Moses to keep Vestar out of<br />

meetings with Del Monte where Vestar's involvement would<br />

be discovered. KKR knew that <strong>the</strong> Vestar pairing served<br />

KKR's best interests. During <strong>the</strong> early 2010 process, Brown of<br />

KKR worried about Vestar partnering with ano<strong>the</strong>r firm <strong>and</strong><br />

wrote that KKR needed to be careful about this possibility.<br />

Second, <strong>the</strong> Merger is still pending. The stockholder vote<br />

is currently scheduled for February 15, 2011, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> dropdead<br />

date is May 22, 2011. As in ACE, “[t]he merger has<br />

not closed, <strong>the</strong> eggs have not been ‘scrambled,’ <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

court would not be in <strong>the</strong> position of unscrambling <strong>the</strong>m. Put<br />

ano<strong>the</strong>r way, <strong>the</strong> transaction has not gotten to <strong>the</strong> point where<br />

[KKR's] investment <strong>and</strong> settled expectations in <strong>the</strong> deal are<br />

so substantial that it is unfair for [its] contract rights to give<br />

way to <strong>the</strong> interests of [Del Monte's] shareholders.” 747 A.2d<br />

at 109.<br />

Third, “<strong>the</strong> board's violation of fiduciary duty relates to<br />

policy concerns that are especially significant.” Id. at 106.<br />

“[F]iduciary responsibilities are of special importance in<br />

situations where a board is entering into a transaction as<br />

significant as a merger affecting stockholder ownership<br />

rights.” Id. at 109. Delaware has a strong interest in<br />

policing <strong>the</strong> behavior of fiduciaries who agree to final-stage<br />

transactions. See McMullin v. Beran, 765 A.2d 910, 918<br />

(Del.2000). This is particularly so when <strong>the</strong> illicit behavior<br />

is secretive <strong>and</strong> subversive, yet appears to elicit yawns from<br />

Wall Street players who regard it as par for <strong>the</strong> course.<br />

After Vice Chancellor Strine's comments about buy-side<br />

participation in Toys “R” Us, investment banks were on<br />

notice. Delaware's strong interest in policing <strong>the</strong> behavior of<br />

fiduciaries <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir advisors is <strong>the</strong> “(sometimes unspoken)<br />

reason [that] our law has subordinated <strong>the</strong> contract rights<br />

of third party suitors to stockholders' interests in not being<br />

improperly subjected to a fundamental corporate transaction<br />

as a result of a fiduciary breach by <strong>the</strong>ir board.” ACE, 747<br />

A.2d at 109.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 22


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

The fourth factor is “whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> acquiror's reliance interest<br />

under <strong>the</strong> challenged agreement merits protection in <strong>the</strong> event<br />

<strong>the</strong> court were to declare <strong>the</strong> agreement unenforceable.” Id.<br />

at 106. It is intended to account for <strong>the</strong> reliance interests of a<br />

“wholly innocent” acquiror who “was without knowledge or<br />

constructive notice” of <strong>the</strong> breach. Regan, supra, at 107–08.<br />

KKR is not such a party.<br />

Lastly, in balancing <strong>the</strong> equities, I have considered whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

a preliminary injunction of this nature would give KKR<br />

<strong>the</strong> right to terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. If <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

Agreement is not consummated by May 22, 2011, <strong>the</strong>n both<br />

parties can walk. MA § 8.2(a). Prior to <strong>the</strong> drop-dead date,<br />

each party is obligated to use its reasonable best efforts to<br />

consummate <strong>the</strong> Merger. Id. § 6.8(a). The injunction will lift<br />

in twenty days, over two months before <strong>the</strong> drop-dead date.<br />

The preliminary injunction will not cause <strong>the</strong> deal to fail<br />

because a closing condition cannot be met by <strong>the</strong> dropdead<br />

date. Section 7.1(c) provides as a condition to closing<br />

that “[n]o court or o<strong>the</strong>r Government Entity of competent<br />

jurisdiction shall have enacted, issued, promulgated, enforced<br />

or entered any law (whe<strong>the</strong>r temporary, *843 preliminary or<br />

permanent) that is in effect <strong>and</strong> restrains, enjoins or o<strong>the</strong>rwise<br />

prohibits consummation of <strong>the</strong> Merger.” Id. § 7.1(c). Twenty<br />

days from now, <strong>the</strong> preliminary injunction will lift <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re<br />

will be no injunction <strong>the</strong>n “in effect” that would restrain,<br />

enjoin, or o<strong>the</strong>rwise prohibit consummation of <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

The preliminary injunction will not, itself, give ei<strong>the</strong>r party<br />

<strong>the</strong> right to terminate. Section 8.2 provides that ei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

party may terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement if “any Order<br />

permanently restraining, enjoining or o<strong>the</strong>rwise prohibiting<br />

consummation of <strong>the</strong> Merger shall become final <strong>and</strong><br />

non-appealable.” Id. § 8.2 (emphasis added). I have not<br />

permanently enjoined <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

The defendants have suggested that a preliminary injunction<br />

limiting <strong>the</strong> deal protection provisions might invalidate <strong>the</strong><br />

entire agreement because of <strong>the</strong> following non-severability<br />

language in Section 9.4: “[T]he parties intend that <strong>the</strong><br />

remedies <strong>and</strong> limitations <strong>the</strong>reon contained in Section 8.5(d)<br />

be construed as an integral provision of this Agreement <strong>and</strong><br />

that such remedies <strong>and</strong> limitations shall not be severable in<br />

any manner that increases a party's liability or obligations<br />

hereunder or under <strong>the</strong> Financing Commitments or <strong>the</strong><br />

Guarantees.” The short answer is that I am not enjoining<br />

Section 8.5(d), which is a sole <strong>and</strong> exclusive remedy<br />

provision, but ra<strong>the</strong>r Section 8.5(b). A longer answer would<br />

need to address <strong>the</strong> question of whe<strong>the</strong>r a proven aider <strong>and</strong><br />

abetter (<strong>and</strong> we are currently at a preliminary stage) could rely<br />

on such a provision.<br />

If KKR attempts to terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement, <strong>the</strong>n Del<br />

Monte has remedies. Under certain circumstances, KKR will<br />

owe Del Monte a reverse termination fee of $249 million. See<br />

id. § 8.4(c). Del Monte can also seek specific performance of<br />

KKR's obligations. See id. § 9.10.<br />

D. The Injunction Bond<br />

[26] [27] Under Court of Chancery Rule 65(c), “[n]o<br />

restraining order or preliminary injunction shall issue except<br />

upon <strong>the</strong> giving of security by <strong>the</strong> applicant, in such sum as<br />

<strong>the</strong> Court deems proper, for <strong>the</strong> payment of such costs <strong>and</strong><br />

damages as may be incurred or suffered by any party who is<br />

found to have been wrongfully enjoined or restrained.” As <strong>the</strong><br />

Delaware Supreme Court recently explained, “[a] party that is<br />

wrongfully enjoined may recover damages resulting from <strong>the</strong><br />

injunction, but that recovery is limited to <strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>the</strong><br />

bond.” Guzzetta v. Serv. Corp. of Westover Hills, 7 A.3d 467,<br />

469 (Del.Supr.2010). Because I am enjoining <strong>the</strong> defendants,<br />

Rule 65(c) requires that I focus on <strong>the</strong> costs <strong>and</strong> damages that<br />

may be incurred or suffered by <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

The parties have not presented evidence on this issue.<br />

Pointing to <strong>the</strong> magnitude of <strong>the</strong> deal premium over <strong>the</strong> preannouncement<br />

market price, <strong>the</strong> defendants seek a bond in<br />

<strong>the</strong> amount of $1,076,612,698.80. There is some irony in <strong>the</strong><br />

magnitude of <strong>the</strong> request, because <strong>the</strong> parties agreed in <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Agreement that “[a]ny party seeking an injunction<br />

or injunctions to prevent breaches of this Agreement <strong>and</strong><br />

to enforce specifically <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>and</strong> provisions of this<br />

Agreement shall not be required to provide any bond or o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

security in connection with any such order or injunction.”<br />

MA § 9.10. Admittedly that provision addressed a different<br />

species of claim, but it suggests how seriously <strong>the</strong> parties took<br />

<strong>the</strong> need for a billion-dollar bond.<br />

The premium over market price might well be one measure of<br />

damages to <strong>the</strong> stockholder class if <strong>the</strong> deal were lost, but that<br />

is a different question than <strong>the</strong> harm an improvidently granted<br />

injunction could inflict on <strong>the</strong> defendants. KKR necessarily<br />

*844 believes that Del Monte is or could be made to be<br />

worth more than $19 per share, o<strong>the</strong>rwise KKR would not<br />

have entered into <strong>the</strong> transaction. If <strong>the</strong> deal were lost, KKR<br />

would be deprived of that additional value. Although I have<br />

evidence of <strong>the</strong> healthy internal rates of return that KKR<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 23


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

thinks it can achieve, KKR has not quantified its anticipated<br />

profits for purposes of a bond. The individual defendants<br />

st<strong>and</strong> to receive some transaction-related benefits, but <strong>the</strong>y<br />

have not argued for a bond based on those amounts.<br />

Importantly, <strong>and</strong> consistent with Solash <strong>and</strong> its progeny, I<br />

am not enjoining <strong>the</strong> transaction from closing pending <strong>the</strong><br />

outcome of a trial. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, I am imposing a delay akin<br />

to a disclosure-based injunction. When those injunctions<br />

issue, this Court has required at most a nominal bond. See<br />

Simonetti, 2008 WL 5048692, at *14 n. 68(noting that a large<br />

bond for a disclosure injunction would be “unprecedented”).<br />

Even when transactions have been enjoined on substantive<br />

grounds, bonds traditionally have been small. See, e.g., Levco<br />

Alternative Fund, Ltd. v. Reader's Digest Ass'n, 2002 WL<br />

31835461, at *1 (Del.Ch. Aug. 14, 2002) (conditioning<br />

injunction against recapitalization on bond of $5,000);<br />

Solar Cells, Inc. v. True N. P'rs, LLC, 2002 WL 749163,<br />

at *8 (Del.Ch. Apr. 25, 2002) (conditioning injunction<br />

against merger on bond of $2,500). In one case, this Court<br />

conditioned a deal-blocking injunction on a $500,000 bond.<br />

See Emerald P'rs v. Berlin, 726 A.2d 1215, 1218 & n.<br />

1 (Del.1999) (describing bond). The outlier is Gimbel v.<br />

Signal Co., 316 A.2d 599 (Del.Ch.1974), aff'd, 316 A.2d 619<br />

(Del.1974). The Gimbel Court required a $25 million bond<br />

as a condition to a preliminary injunction blocking a $480<br />

million transaction where <strong>the</strong> transactional premium was $75<br />

million. Id. at 618.<br />

Although I have not enjoined <strong>the</strong> deal, I have enjoined <strong>the</strong><br />

$120 million termination fee that KKR o<strong>the</strong>rwise would<br />

receive in <strong>the</strong> event of a topping bid. That figure strikes me<br />

as <strong>the</strong> best starting point for pricing <strong>the</strong> risk of a wrongful<br />

injunction. The likelihood of a topping bid, however, is low. 6<br />

With KKR as <strong>the</strong> buyer <strong>and</strong> a market check (albeit a tainted<br />

one) already completed, a topping bid seems all <strong>the</strong> less likely.<br />

I will not be surprised if no one emerges. The amount of<br />

<strong>the</strong> bond should take into account <strong>the</strong> low probability of<br />

actual harm. There is likewise <strong>the</strong> need to balance <strong>the</strong> risk of<br />

chilling <strong>the</strong> socially-beneficial <strong>and</strong> wealth-enhancing efforts<br />

of responsible plaintiffs' counsel to remedy <strong>and</strong> deter breaches<br />

of fiduciary duty against <strong>the</strong> problem of over-incentivizing<br />

deal litigation by giving entrepreneurial law firms a free<br />

option to enjoin transactions. Lacking guidance from <strong>the</strong><br />

parties as to an alternative figure that reflects <strong>the</strong> threatened<br />

harm to <strong>the</strong> defendants, <strong>and</strong> having attempted to balance <strong>the</strong><br />

competing policy considerations in a rough <strong>and</strong> imperfect<br />

way, I set bond at $1.2 million, representing 1% of <strong>the</strong><br />

enjoined termination fee.<br />

III. CONCLUSION<br />

The defendants are enjoined from proceeding with <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholder vote on <strong>the</strong> Merger for a period of twenty days.<br />

To <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>the</strong> defendants wish to convene <strong>the</strong> meeting of<br />

stockholders on February 15, 2011, <strong>and</strong> adjourn it to a later<br />

date *845 without holding <strong>the</strong> vote, <strong>the</strong>y may freely do so.<br />

Pending <strong>the</strong> vote on <strong>the</strong> Merger, <strong>the</strong> defendants are enjoined<br />

from enforcing Section 6.5(b), (c) <strong>and</strong> (h), <strong>and</strong> Section 8.5(b)<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. The injunction is conditioned on<br />

plaintiffs posting bond in <strong>the</strong> amount of $1.2 million. IT IS<br />

SO ORDERED.<br />

Footnotes<br />

1 In re W. Nat. Corp. S'holders Litig., 2000 WL 710192, at *19 (Del.Ch. May 22, 2000) (describing witness affidavits <strong>and</strong> explaining<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery will “ordinarily attach little if any weight to such inherently self-serving <strong>and</strong> non-adversarial proffers”); see<br />

Cont'l Ins. Co. v. Rutledge & Co., 750 A.2d 1219, 1232 (Del.Ch.2000) (“To <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>the</strong> affidavits contradict <strong>the</strong> depositions, this<br />

Court will exclude <strong>the</strong> offending affidavit testimony.”); see also Chesapeake Corp. v. Shore, 771 A.2d 293, 302 & n. 7 (Del.Ch.2000)<br />

(expressing disappointment with <strong>the</strong> proffering of less-knowledgeable board members ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> chairman or top managers <strong>and</strong><br />

stating “ ‘[t]he production of weak evidence when strong is, or should have been, available can lead only to <strong>the</strong> conclusion that <strong>the</strong><br />

strong would have been adverse.’ ” (quoting Kahn v. Lynch Comm. Sys., Inc., 638 A.2d 1110, 1119 n. 7 (Del.1994))).<br />

2 See, e.g., Hubbard v. Hollywood Park Realty Enters., Inc., 1991 WL 3151, at *10 (Del.Ch. Jan. 14, 1991) (“[O]ccasions do arise<br />

where board inaction, even where not inequitable in purpose or design, may none<strong>the</strong>less operate inequitably.”); id. at *7 n. 9 (“To<br />

be ‘inequitable’, such conduct does not necessarily require a dishonest, selfish, or evil motive.”); Stahl v. Apple Bancorp, Inc., 579<br />

A.2d 1115, 1121 (Del.Ch.1990) (Allen, C.) (“Fiduciaries who are subjectively operating selflessly might be pursuing a purpose that a<br />

court will rule is inequitable.”); Blasius Indus., Inc. v. Atlas Corp., 564 A.2d 651, 663 (Del.Ch.1988) (Allen, C.) (holding that, where<br />

board acted with purpose of interfering with shareholder vote, “even finding <strong>the</strong> action taken was taken in good faith, it constituted<br />

an unintended violation of <strong>the</strong> duty of loyalty that <strong>the</strong> board owed to <strong>the</strong> shareholders” <strong>and</strong> noting “paren<strong>the</strong>tically that <strong>the</strong> concept of<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 24


In re Del Monte Foods Co. Shareholders <strong>Litigation</strong>, 25 A.3d 813 (2011)<br />

an unintended breach of <strong>the</strong> duty of loyalty is unusual but not novel”). Each of <strong>the</strong>se cases involved <strong>the</strong> question of injunctive relief;<br />

none addressed <strong>the</strong> separate issue of whe<strong>the</strong>r defendant directors could be held liable for monetary damages.<br />

3 See In re John Q. Hammons Hotels Inc. S'holder Litig., 2009 WL 3165613, at *16 (Del.Ch. Oct. 2, 2009) (emphasizing importance of<br />

disclosure of potential banker conflict of interest <strong>and</strong> explaining that “[t]here is no rule ... that conflicts of interest must be disclosed<br />

only where <strong>the</strong>re is evidence that <strong>the</strong> financial advisor's opinion was actually affected by <strong>the</strong> conflict”); David P. Simonetti Rollover<br />

IRA v. Margolis, 2008 WL 5048692, at *8 (Del.Ch. June 27, 2008) (“[I]t is imperative for <strong>the</strong> stockholders to be able to underst<strong>and</strong><br />

what factors might influence <strong>the</strong> financial advisor's analytical efforts.... For that reason, <strong>the</strong> ... benefits of <strong>the</strong> Merger to [<strong>the</strong> investment<br />

bankers,] beyond its expected fee, must also be disclosed to ... stockholders.”); see also In re Lear Corp. S'holder Litig., 926 A.2d<br />

94, 114 (Del.Ch.2007) (requiring disclosure of CEO conflict of interest where CEO acted as negotiator; “Put simply, a reasonable<br />

stockholder would want to know an important economic motivation of <strong>the</strong> negotiator singularly employed by a board to obtain <strong>the</strong><br />

best price for <strong>the</strong> stockholders, when that motivation could rationally lead that negotiator to favor a deal at a less than optimal price,<br />

because <strong>the</strong> procession of a deal was more important to him, given his overall economic interest, than only doing a deal at <strong>the</strong> right<br />

price.”).<br />

4 See Ortsman v. Green, 2007 WL 702475, at *1 (Del.Ch. Feb. 28, 2007) (ordering expedited discovery where target's financial advisor<br />

participated in <strong>the</strong> buy-side financing even though company retained a separate financial advisor to render a fairness opinion); Khanna<br />

v. McMinn, 2006 WL 1388744, at *25 (Del.Ch. May 9, 2006) (finding plaintiffs had raised facts sufficient to “create a reasonable<br />

doubt that <strong>the</strong> transaction was <strong>the</strong> product of a valid exercise of business judgment” where investment bank provided a bridge loan to<br />

<strong>the</strong> target <strong>and</strong> thus had an interest in ensuring <strong>the</strong> closing of <strong>the</strong> transaction); In re Prime Hospitality, Inc. S'holders Litig., 2005 WL<br />

1138738, at *12 (Del.Ch. May 4, 2005) (rejecting settlement of Revlon claim <strong>and</strong> questioning “how can <strong>the</strong> Court attribute weight<br />

to <strong>the</strong> notion that Bear Stearns [<strong>the</strong> allegedly conflicted banker] was retained by Prime to shop <strong>the</strong> company?”).<br />

5 That said, KKR's last two bid increases were 25 cents each. The Board has trumpeted its insistence on those increases as evidence<br />

of its (<strong>and</strong> implicitly Barclays') good faith. The go-shop period termination fee would require a competing bidder to top by more<br />

than a 25 cent increment. The post go-shop fee would require a bidder to top by over 50 cents. A strategic bidder that could generate<br />

incremental value from synergies might not be deterred. A private equity firm that uses <strong>the</strong> same models <strong>and</strong> strategies as KKR might<br />

view <strong>the</strong> fee differently. This in turn suggests (i) <strong>the</strong> importance of <strong>the</strong> pre-signing phase to developing price competition among<br />

private equity bidders, <strong>and</strong> (ii) <strong>the</strong> value of actual or de facto exclusivity to a private equity buyer. See Guhan Subramanian, Go–<br />

Shops vs. No–Shops in Private Equity Deals: Evidence <strong>and</strong> Implications, 63 Bus. Law. 729, 759 (2008) (arguing that exclusivity is<br />

a valuable benefit “<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore should be paid for”). When an independent <strong>and</strong> active board has been assisted by non-conflicted<br />

advisors, a Delaware court rarely will have cause to second guess this type of tactical decision. See Toys “R” Us, 877 A.2d at 1000.<br />

6 See Subramanian, Go–Shops vs. No–Shops, supra, 63 Bus. Law. at 747 (finding deal-jump rate in private equity deals of 8% where<br />

deal lacks a go-shop, 5% where deal involved private pre-signing market canvass plus go-shop, <strong>and</strong> 17% where single-bidder deal<br />

was followed by go-shop); John C. Coates IV & Guhan Subramanian, A Buy–Side Model of M & A Lockups: Theory <strong>and</strong> Evidence,<br />

53 Stan. L.Rev. 307, 371 (2000) (finding deal-jump rate of 3–7%).<br />

End of Document<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 25


Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corporation<br />

Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

52 A.3d 761<br />

Court of Chancery of Delaware.<br />

In re SOUTHERN PERU COPPER CORPORATION<br />

SHAREHOLDER DERIVATIVE LITIGATION.<br />

C.A. No. 961–CS. | Submitted: July 15, 2011. |<br />

Decided: Oct. 14, 2011. | Revised: Dec. 20, 2011.<br />

Synopsis<br />

Background: Plaintiff representing minority shareholder<br />

of corporation brought derivative suit against controlling<br />

shareholder, affiliated directors, <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>rs, alleging that<br />

merger with mining company that was owned by subsidiary<br />

of controlling shareholder was entirely unfair to corporation<br />

<strong>and</strong> its minority shareholders.<br />

Holdings: The Court of Chancery, Strine, Chancellor, held<br />

that:<br />

[1] plaintiff was adequate representative of minority<br />

shareholders;<br />

[2] burden of persuasion under entire fairness review was on<br />

defendants;<br />

Presumptions <strong>and</strong> burden of proof<br />

In challenging <strong>the</strong> adequacy of a derivative<br />

plaintiff, <strong>the</strong> defendant bears <strong>the</strong> burden to show<br />

a substantial likelihood that <strong>the</strong> derivative action<br />

is not being maintained for <strong>the</strong> benefit of <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders.<br />

[3] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Ability to represent o<strong>the</strong>r shareholders<br />

That derivative plaintiff became a plaintiff only<br />

because he inherited <strong>the</strong> claims as successor<br />

trustee upon <strong>the</strong> death of his fa<strong>the</strong>r, was absent<br />

from trial, lacked a fully developed knowledge<br />

about all of <strong>the</strong> litigation details, <strong>and</strong> engaged in<br />

a pattern of delay did not establish that <strong>the</strong>re was<br />

a substantial likelihood that <strong>the</strong> derivative action<br />

was not being maintained for <strong>the</strong> benefit of <strong>the</strong><br />

shareholders, as required to show that plaintiff<br />

was not adequate representative in suit arising<br />

from corporation's purchase of mining company<br />

owned by controlling shareholder's subsidiary,<br />

absent evidence of an economic conflict between<br />

<strong>the</strong> plaintiff <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r shareholders such that he<br />

would act in fur<strong>the</strong>rance of his own self-interest<br />

at <strong>the</strong>ir expense.<br />

[3] merger was unfair to corporation; <strong>and</strong><br />

[4] damage award of $1.263 billion was warranted.<br />

Ordered accordingly.<br />

West Headnotes (12)<br />

[1] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Ability to represent o<strong>the</strong>r shareholders<br />

A derivative plaintiff must be qualified to serve<br />

in a fiduciary capacity as a representative of<br />

<strong>the</strong> class of stockholders, whose interest is<br />

dependent upon <strong>the</strong> representative's adequate<br />

<strong>and</strong> fair prosecution of <strong>the</strong> action.<br />

[2] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

[4] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Dealings with corporation<br />

Under <strong>the</strong> entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard of review,<br />

when a controlling stockholder st<strong>and</strong>s on both<br />

sides of a corporate transaction, <strong>the</strong> interested<br />

defendants are required to demonstrate <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

utmost good faith <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> most scrupulous<br />

inherent fairness of <strong>the</strong> bargain; that is, <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants with a conflicting self-interest must<br />

demonstrate that <strong>the</strong> deal was entirely fair to <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r stockholders.<br />

[5] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fairness of transaction<br />

In considering a corporate merger under <strong>the</strong><br />

entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard of review, <strong>the</strong>re are<br />

two basic aspects of fairness: process (fair<br />

dealing), which embraces questions of when<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction was timed, how it was initiated,<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 1


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

structured, negotiated, disclosed to <strong>the</strong> directors,<br />

<strong>and</strong> how <strong>the</strong> approvals of <strong>the</strong> directors <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholders were obtained, <strong>and</strong> price (fair<br />

price), which relates to <strong>the</strong> economic <strong>and</strong><br />

financial considerations of <strong>the</strong> proposed merger,<br />

including <strong>the</strong> relevant factors of assets, market<br />

value, earnings, future prospects, <strong>and</strong> any o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

elements that affect <strong>the</strong> intrinsic or inherent value<br />

of a company's stock.<br />

[6] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Dealings with corporation<br />

When <strong>the</strong> entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard applies to<br />

review of a corporate transaction, controlling<br />

stockholders can never escape entire fairness<br />

review, but <strong>the</strong>y may shift <strong>the</strong> burden of<br />

persuasion by one of two means: <strong>the</strong>y may show<br />

that <strong>the</strong> transaction was approved ei<strong>the</strong>r by an<br />

independent board majority (or in <strong>the</strong> alternative,<br />

a special committee of independent directors) or,<br />

assuming certain conditions, by an informed vote<br />

of <strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong> minority shareholders.<br />

[7] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Entire fairness of transaction in general<br />

Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Evidence<br />

Under <strong>the</strong> entire fairness review of a decision<br />

of a board of directors, in order for <strong>the</strong><br />

defendant to obtain a shift in <strong>the</strong> burden<br />

of proof to <strong>the</strong> plaintiff based on <strong>the</strong> use<br />

of an independent special committee under<br />

circumstances in which <strong>the</strong> board is controlled<br />

by a controlling shareholder with an interest<br />

in <strong>the</strong> transaction, <strong>the</strong> special committee must<br />

function in a manner which indicates that<br />

<strong>the</strong> controlling shareholder did not dictate <strong>the</strong><br />

terms of <strong>the</strong> transaction <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> committee<br />

exercised real bargaining power at an armslength;<br />

<strong>the</strong> inquiry must focus on how <strong>the</strong> special<br />

committee actually negotiated <strong>the</strong> deal—was<br />

it well functioning—ra<strong>the</strong>r than just how <strong>the</strong><br />

committee was set up.<br />

[8] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fairness of transaction<br />

Burden of persuasion under entire fairness<br />

review, of decision by corporation's board<br />

to merge with a mining company owned<br />

by a controlling shareholder's subsidiary,<br />

remained on controlling shareholder <strong>and</strong><br />

affiliated directors, <strong>and</strong> did not shift to plaintiff<br />

representing minority shareholders, in derivative<br />

action challenging merger, although merger<br />

vote was approved by a vote of shareholders,<br />

where at time of vote it was known that<br />

majority shareholder held sufficient votes to<br />

approve merger, so <strong>the</strong> vote had little meaning,<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> proxy statement issued prior to <strong>the</strong><br />

vote omitted material information about <strong>the</strong><br />

negotiation process.<br />

[9] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Fairness of transaction<br />

Decision by corporation's board to merge with<br />

a mining company owned by a controlling<br />

shareholder was unfair, to extent value given<br />

by corporation was significantly more than<br />

mining company was worth; although special<br />

committee was formed to evaluate merger,<br />

committee's focus was on finding a way<br />

to justify terms proposed by controlling<br />

shareholder, committee reworked <strong>the</strong>ir approach<br />

to meet those terms <strong>and</strong> rationalize paying<br />

<strong>the</strong> asking price, corporation was effectively<br />

undervalued, controlling shareholder made only<br />

weak concessions that did not close fairness gap,<br />

<strong>and</strong> special committee did not update its analysis<br />

based on changed conditions.<br />

[10] Fraud<br />

Measure in General<br />

Fraud<br />

Elements of compensation<br />

Unlike <strong>the</strong> more exact process followed in<br />

an appraisal action, damages resulting from a<br />

breach of fiduciary duty are liberally calculated;<br />

as long as <strong>the</strong>re is a basis for an estimate of<br />

damages, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> plaintiff has suffered harm,<br />

ma<strong>the</strong>matical certainty is not required.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 2


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

[11] Interest<br />

Prejudgment Interest in General<br />

Interest<br />

Interest from date of judgment or decree<br />

In awarding damages resulting from a breach of<br />

fiduciary duty, in addition to an actual award<br />

of monetary relief, <strong>the</strong> court has <strong>the</strong> authority<br />

to grant prejudgment <strong>and</strong> post-judgment interest,<br />

<strong>and</strong> to determine <strong>the</strong> form of that interest.<br />

[12] Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations<br />

Damages or amount of recovery<br />

Damages award of $1.263 billion, representing<br />

difference between what corporation paid for<br />

controlling shareholder's mining company <strong>and</strong><br />

mining company's actual value at time of merger,<br />

was warranted in derivative action against<br />

controlling shareholder <strong>and</strong> affiliated directors,<br />

for breach of fiduciary duty of loyalty in agreeing<br />

to merger with mining company.<br />

Attorneys <strong>and</strong> Law Firms<br />

*763 Ronald A. Brown, Jr., Esquire, Marcus E. Montejo,<br />

Esquire, Prickett, Jones & Elliott, P.A., Wilmington,<br />

Delaware; Lee D. Rudy, Esquire, Eric L. Zagar, Esquire,<br />

James H. Miller, Esquire, Kessler Topaz Meltzer & Check,<br />

LLP, Radnor, Pennsylvania, Attorneys for Plaintiff.<br />

S. Mark Hurd, Esquire, Kevin M. Coen, Esquire, Morris,<br />

Nichols, Arsht & Tunnell LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; Alan<br />

J. Stone, Esquire, Douglas W. Henkin, Esquire, Mia C. Korot,<br />

Esquire, Milbank, Tweed, Hadley & McCloy LLP, New<br />

York, New York, Attorneys for Defendants.<br />

Opinion<br />

STRINE, Chancellor.<br />

OPINION<br />

I. Introduction<br />

This is <strong>the</strong> post-trial decision in an entire fairness case. The<br />

controlling stockholder of an NYSE-listed mining company<br />

came to <strong>the</strong> corporation's independent directors with a<br />

proposition. How about you buy my non-publicly traded<br />

Mexican mining company for approximately $3.1 billion of<br />

your NYSE-listed stock? A special committee was set up to<br />

“evaluate” this proposal <strong>and</strong> it retained well-respected legal<br />

<strong>and</strong> financial advisors.<br />

The financial advisor did a great deal of preliminary due<br />

diligence, <strong>and</strong> generated valuations showing that <strong>the</strong> Mexican<br />

mining company, when valued under a discounted cash flow<br />

<strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r measures, was not worth anything close to $3.1<br />

billion. The $3.1 billion was a real number in <strong>the</strong> crucial<br />

business sense that everyone believed that <strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed<br />

company could in fact get cash equivalent to its stock market<br />

price for its shares. That is, <strong>the</strong> cash value of <strong>the</strong> “give” was<br />

known. And <strong>the</strong> financial advisor told <strong>the</strong> special committee<br />

that <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> “get” was more than $1 billion less.<br />

Ra<strong>the</strong>r than tell <strong>the</strong> controller to go mine himself, <strong>the</strong><br />

special committee <strong>and</strong> its advisors instead did something<br />

that is indicative of <strong>the</strong> mindset that too often afflicts even<br />

good faith fiduciaries trying to address a controller. Having<br />

been empowered only to evaluate what <strong>the</strong> controller put<br />

on <strong>the</strong> table <strong>and</strong> perceiving that o<strong>the</strong>r options were off<br />

<strong>the</strong> menu because of <strong>the</strong> controller's own objectives, <strong>the</strong><br />

special committee put itself in a world where <strong>the</strong>re was<br />

only one strategic option to consider, <strong>the</strong> one proposed by<br />

<strong>the</strong> controller, <strong>and</strong> thus entered a dynamic where at best it<br />

had two options, ei<strong>the</strong>r figure out a way to do <strong>the</strong> deal <strong>the</strong><br />

controller wanted or say no. Ab<strong>and</strong>oning a focus on whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed mining company would get $3.1 billion in<br />

value in <strong>the</strong> exchange, <strong>the</strong> special committee embarked on<br />

a “relative valuation” approach. Apparently perceiving that<br />

its own company was overvalued <strong>and</strong> had a fundamental<br />

value less than its stock market trading price, <strong>the</strong> special<br />

committee assured itself that a deal could be fair so long<br />

as <strong>the</strong> “relative value” of <strong>the</strong> two companies was measured<br />

on <strong>the</strong> same metrics. Thus, its financial advisor *764<br />

generated complicated scenarios pegging <strong>the</strong> relative value<br />

of <strong>the</strong> companies <strong>and</strong> obscuring <strong>the</strong> fundamental fact that<br />

<strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed company had a proven cash value. These<br />

scenarios all suggest that <strong>the</strong> special committee believed that<br />

<strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>alone value of <strong>the</strong> Mexican company (<strong>the</strong> “get”)<br />

was worth far less than <strong>the</strong> controller's consistent dem<strong>and</strong><br />

for $3.1 billion (<strong>the</strong> “give”). Ra<strong>the</strong>r than reacting to <strong>the</strong>se<br />

realities by suggesting that <strong>the</strong> controller make an offer<br />

for <strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed company at a premium to what <strong>the</strong><br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 3


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

special committee apparently viewed as a plush market price,<br />

or making <strong>the</strong> controller do a deal based on <strong>the</strong> Mexican<br />

company's st<strong>and</strong>alone value, <strong>the</strong> special committee <strong>and</strong> its<br />

financial advisor instead took strenuous efforts to justify a<br />

transaction at <strong>the</strong> level originally dem<strong>and</strong>ed by <strong>the</strong> controller.<br />

Even on that artificial basis, <strong>the</strong> special committee had trouble<br />

justifying a deal <strong>and</strong> thus o<strong>the</strong>r measures were taken. The<br />

cash flows of <strong>the</strong> Mexican company, but not <strong>the</strong> NYSElisted<br />

company, were “optimized.” The facts that <strong>the</strong> Mexican<br />

company was having trouble paying its bills, that it could<br />

not optimize its cash flows with its current capital base, <strong>and</strong><br />

that, by comparison, <strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed company was thriving<br />

<strong>and</strong> nearly debt-free, were slighted. The higher multiple of<br />

<strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed company was used as <strong>the</strong> bottom range of<br />

an exercise to value <strong>the</strong> Mexican company, thus topping up<br />

<strong>the</strong> target's value by crediting it with <strong>the</strong> multiple that <strong>the</strong><br />

acquiror had earned for itself, an act of deal beneficence<br />

not characteristic of Jack Welch, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n ano<strong>the</strong>r dollop of<br />

multiple crème fraiche was added to create an even higher top<br />

range. When even <strong>the</strong>se measures could not close <strong>the</strong> divide,<br />

<strong>the</strong> special committee agreed to pay out a special dividend to<br />

close <strong>the</strong> value gap.<br />

But what remained in real economic terms was a transaction<br />

where, after a bunch of back <strong>and</strong> forth, <strong>the</strong> controller got what<br />

it originally dem<strong>and</strong>ed: $3.1 billion in real value in exchange<br />

for something worth much, much less—hundreds of millions<br />

of dollars less. Even worse, <strong>the</strong> special committee, despite<br />

perceiving that <strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed company's stock price would<br />

go up <strong>and</strong> knowing that <strong>the</strong> Mexican company was not<br />

publicly traded, agreed to a fixed exchange ratio. After falling<br />

when <strong>the</strong> deal was announced <strong>and</strong> when <strong>the</strong> preliminary<br />

proxy was announced, <strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed company's stock<br />

price rose on its good performance in a rising market<br />

for commodities. Thus, <strong>the</strong> final value of its stock to be<br />

delivered to <strong>the</strong> controller at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> actual vote<br />

on <strong>the</strong> transaction was $3.75 billion, much higher than <strong>the</strong><br />

controller's original dem<strong>and</strong>. Despite having <strong>the</strong> ability to<br />

rescind its recommendation <strong>and</strong> despite <strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed<br />

company having already exceeded <strong>the</strong> projections <strong>the</strong> special<br />

committee used for <strong>the</strong> most recent year by 37% <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Mexican company not having done so, <strong>the</strong> special committee<br />

maintained its recommendation <strong>and</strong> thus <strong>the</strong> deal was voted<br />

through.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> plaintiff in this case engaged in a pattern of<br />

litigation delay that compromised <strong>the</strong> reliability of <strong>the</strong> record<br />

to some extent <strong>and</strong> thus I apply a conservative approach to<br />

shaping a remedy, I am left with <strong>the</strong> firm conclusion that this<br />

transaction was unfair however one allocates <strong>the</strong> burden of<br />

persuasion under a preponderance of <strong>the</strong> evidence st<strong>and</strong>ard.<br />

A focused, aggressive controller extracted a deal that was<br />

far better than market, <strong>and</strong> got real, market-tested value of<br />

over $3 billion for something that no member of <strong>the</strong> special<br />

committee, none of its advisors, <strong>and</strong> no trial expert was<br />

willing to say was worth that amount of actual cash. Although<br />

directors are free in some situations to act on <strong>the</strong> belief that<br />

<strong>the</strong> market is wrong, <strong>the</strong>y are not free to believe that <strong>the</strong>y can<br />

in fact get $3.1 billion in cash for <strong>the</strong>ir own stock but <strong>the</strong>n<br />

use that stock to *765 acquire something that <strong>the</strong>y know is<br />

worth far less than $3.1 billion in cash or in “fundamental”<br />

or “intrinsic” value terms because <strong>the</strong>y believe <strong>the</strong> market is<br />

overvaluing <strong>the</strong>ir own stock <strong>and</strong> that on real “fundamental”<br />

or “intrinsic” terms <strong>the</strong> deal is <strong>the</strong>refore fair. In plain terms,<br />

<strong>the</strong> special committee turned <strong>the</strong> “gold” it was holding in<br />

trust into “silver” <strong>and</strong> did an exchange with “silver” on that<br />

basis, ignoring that in <strong>the</strong> real world <strong>the</strong> gold <strong>the</strong>y held had a<br />

much higher market price in cash than silver. That non-adroit<br />

act of commercial charity toward <strong>the</strong> controller resulted in a<br />

manifestly unfair transaction.<br />

I remedy that unfairness by ordering <strong>the</strong> controller to return<br />

to <strong>the</strong> NYSE-listed company a number of shares necessary<br />

to remedy <strong>the</strong> harm. I apply a conservative metric because<br />

of <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's delay, which occasioned some evidentiary<br />

uncertainties <strong>and</strong> which subjected <strong>the</strong> controller to lengthy<br />

market risk. The resulting award is still large, but <strong>the</strong> record<br />

could justify a much larger award.<br />

II. Factual Background<br />

An overview of <strong>the</strong> facts is perhaps useful.<br />

The controlling stockholder in this case is Grupo México,<br />

S.A.B. de C.V. The NYSE-listed mining company is<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corporation. 1 The Mexican mining<br />

company is Minera México, S.A. de C.V. 2<br />

In February 2004, Grupo Mexico proposed that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

buy its 99.15% stake in Minera. At <strong>the</strong> time, Grupo Mexico<br />

owned 54.17% of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's outst<strong>and</strong>ing capital stock<br />

<strong>and</strong> could exercise 63.08% of <strong>the</strong> voting power of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru, making it Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's majority stockholder.<br />

Grupo Mexico initially proposed that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru purchase<br />

its equity interest in Minera with 72.3 million shares of<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 4


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

newly-issued Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock. This “indicative” number<br />

assumed that Minera's equity was worth $3.05 billion,<br />

because that is what 72.3 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

stock were worth <strong>the</strong>n in cash. 3 By stark contrast with<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, Minera was almost wholly owned by Grupo<br />

Mexico <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore had no market-tested value.<br />

Because of Grupo Mexico's self-interest in <strong>the</strong> merger<br />

proposal, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru formed a “Special Committee” of<br />

disinterested directors to “evaluate” <strong>the</strong> transaction with<br />

Grupo Mexico. 4 The Special Committee spent eight months<br />

in an awkward back <strong>and</strong> forth with Grupo Mexico over <strong>the</strong><br />

terms of <strong>the</strong> deal before approving Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's acquisition<br />

of 99.15% of Minera's stock in exchange for 67.2 million<br />

newly-issued shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock (<strong>the</strong> “Merger”)<br />

on October 21, 2004. That same day, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's board<br />

of directors (<strong>the</strong> “Board”) unanimously approved <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

<strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Grupo Mexico entered into a definitive<br />

agreement (<strong>the</strong> “Merger Agreement”). On October 21, 2004,<br />

<strong>the</strong> market *766 value of 67.2 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru stock was $3.1 billion. When <strong>the</strong> Merger closed on April<br />

1, 2005, <strong>the</strong> value of 67.2 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru had<br />

grown to $3.75 billion.<br />

price as a measure of <strong>the</strong> true value of <strong>the</strong> give, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

substantially overpaid in <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

The defendants remaining in <strong>the</strong> case are Grupo Mexico<br />

<strong>and</strong> its affiliate directors who were on <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

Board at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger. 6 These defendants assert<br />

that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera are similar companies <strong>and</strong><br />

were properly valued on a relative basis. In o<strong>the</strong>r words,<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants argue that <strong>the</strong> appropriate way to determine<br />

<strong>the</strong> price to be paid by Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru in <strong>the</strong> Merger was<br />

to compare both companies' values using <strong>the</strong> same set<br />

of assumptions <strong>and</strong> methodologies, ra<strong>the</strong>r than comparing<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's market capitalization to Minera's DCF value.<br />

The defendants do not dispute that shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

stock could have been sold for <strong>the</strong>ir market price at <strong>the</strong> time<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Merger, but <strong>the</strong>y contend that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's market<br />

price did not reflect <strong>the</strong> fundamental value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

<strong>and</strong> thus could not appropriately be compared to <strong>the</strong> DCF<br />

value of Minera.<br />

With this brief overview of <strong>the</strong> basic events <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> parties'<br />

core arguments in mind, I turn now to a more detailed<br />

recitation of <strong>the</strong> facts as I find <strong>the</strong>m after trial. 7<br />

This derivative suit was <strong>the</strong>n brought against <strong>the</strong> Grupo<br />

Mexico subsidiary that owned Minera, <strong>the</strong> Grupo Mexicoaffiliated<br />

directors of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> members of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee, alleging that <strong>the</strong> Merger was entirely<br />

unfair to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> its minority stockholders. The<br />

parties agree that <strong>the</strong> appropriate st<strong>and</strong>ard of review is entire<br />

fairness.<br />

[1] [2] [3] The crux of <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's argument is that<br />

Grupo Mexico received something demonstrably worth more<br />

than $3 billion (67.2 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock)<br />

in exchange for something that was not worth nearly that<br />

much (99.15% of Minera). 5 The plaintiff points to <strong>the</strong> fact<br />

that Goldman Sachs, which served as <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's<br />

financial advisor, never derived a value for Minera that<br />

justified paying Grupo Mexico's asking price, instead relying<br />

on a “relative” valuation analysis that involved comparing<br />

<strong>the</strong> discounted cash flow (“DCF”) values of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

<strong>and</strong> Minera, <strong>and</strong> a contribution analysis that improperly<br />

applied Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's own market EBITDA multiple (<strong>and</strong><br />

even higher multiples) to Minera's EBITDA projections, to<br />

determine *767 an appropriate exchange ratio to use in<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger. The plaintiff claims that, because <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee <strong>and</strong> Goldman ab<strong>and</strong>oned <strong>the</strong> company's market<br />

*768 A. The Key Players<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru operates mining, smelting, <strong>and</strong> refining<br />

facilities in Peru, producing copper <strong>and</strong> molybdenum as<br />

well as silver <strong>and</strong> small amounts of o<strong>the</strong>r metals. Before<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru had two classes of stock:<br />

common shares that were traded on <strong>the</strong> New York Stock<br />

Exchange; <strong>and</strong> “Founders Shares” that were owned by Grupo<br />

Mexico, Cerro Trading <strong>Company</strong>, Inc., <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge<br />

Corporation (<strong>the</strong> “Founding Stockholders”). Each Founders<br />

Share had five votes per share versus one vote per share<br />

for ordinary common stock. Grupo Mexico owned 43.3<br />

million Founders Shares, which translated to 54.17% of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's outst<strong>and</strong>ing stock <strong>and</strong> 63.08% of <strong>the</strong> voting<br />

power. Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's certificate of incorporation <strong>and</strong> a<br />

stockholders' agreement also gave Grupo Mexico <strong>the</strong> right to<br />

nominate a majority of <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Board. The Grupo<br />

Mexico-affiliated directors who are defendants in this case<br />

held seven of <strong>the</strong> thirteen Board seats at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. Cerro owned 11.4 million Founders Shares (14.2%<br />

of <strong>the</strong> outst<strong>and</strong>ing common stock) <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge owned<br />

11.2 million Founders Shares (13.95% of <strong>the</strong> outst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

common stock). Among <strong>the</strong>m, <strong>the</strong>refore, Grupo Mexico,<br />

Cerro, <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge owned over 82% of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 5


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

Grupo Mexico is a Mexican holding company listed on <strong>the</strong><br />

Mexican stock exchange. Grupo Mexico is controlled by<br />

<strong>the</strong> Larrea family, <strong>and</strong> at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger defendant<br />

Germán Larrea was <strong>the</strong> Chairman <strong>and</strong> CEO of Grupo Mexico,<br />

as well as <strong>the</strong> Chairman <strong>and</strong> CEO of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. Before<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger, Grupo Mexico owned 99.15% of Minera's<br />

stock <strong>and</strong> thus essentially was Minera's sole owner. Minera<br />

is a company engaged in <strong>the</strong> mining <strong>and</strong> processing of<br />

copper, molybdenum, zinc, silver, gold, <strong>and</strong> lead through its<br />

Mexico-based mines. At <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger, Minera was<br />

emerging from—if not still mired in—a period of financial<br />

difficulties, 8 <strong>and</strong> its ability to exploit its assets had been<br />

compromised by <strong>the</strong>se financial constraints. 9 By contrast,<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was in good financial condition <strong>and</strong> virtually<br />

debt-free. 10<br />

B. Grupo Mexico Proposes That<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Acquire Minera<br />

In 2003, Grupo Mexico began considering combining its<br />

Peruvian mining interests with its Mexican mining interests.<br />

In *769 September 2003, Grupo Mexico engaged UBS<br />

Investment Bank to provide advice with respect to a potential<br />

strategic transaction involving Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera.<br />

Grupo Mexico <strong>and</strong> UBS made a formal presentation to<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's Board on February 3, 2004, proposing that<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru acquire Grupo Mexico's interest in Minera<br />

from AMC in exchange for newly-issued shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru stock. In that presentation, Grupo Mexico characterized<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction as “[Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] to acquire Minera [ ] from<br />

AMC in a stock for stock deal financed through <strong>the</strong> issuance<br />

of common shares; initial proposal to issue 72.3 million<br />

shares.” 11 A footnote to that presentation explained that <strong>the</strong><br />

72.3 million shares was “an indicative number” of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru shares to be issued, assuming an equity value of Minera<br />

of $3.05 billion <strong>and</strong> a Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru share price of $42.20<br />

as of January 29, 2004. 12 In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> consideration<br />

of 72.3 million shares was indicative in <strong>the</strong> sense that Grupo<br />

Mexico wanted $3.05 billion in dollar value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

stock for its stake in Minera, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> number of shares that<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would have to issue in exchange for Minera<br />

would be determined based on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's market price.<br />

As a result of <strong>the</strong> proposed merger, Minera would become<br />

a virtually wholly-owned subsidiary of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. The<br />

proposal also contemplated <strong>the</strong> conversion of all Founders<br />

Shares into a single class of common shares.<br />

C. Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Forms A Special Committee<br />

In response to Grupo Mexico's presentation, <strong>the</strong> Board met<br />

on February 12, 2004 <strong>and</strong> created a Special Committee to<br />

evaluate <strong>the</strong> proposal. The resolution creating <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee provided that <strong>the</strong> “duty <strong>and</strong> sole purpose” of <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee was “to evaluate <strong>the</strong> [Merger] in such<br />

manner as <strong>the</strong> Special Committee deems to be desirable<br />

<strong>and</strong> in <strong>the</strong> best interests of <strong>the</strong> stockholders of [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru],” <strong>and</strong> authorized <strong>the</strong> Special Committee to retain legal<br />

<strong>and</strong> financial advisors at Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's expense on such<br />

terms as <strong>the</strong> Special Committee deemed appropriate. 13 The<br />

resolution did not give <strong>the</strong> Special Committee express power<br />

to negotiate, nor did it authorize <strong>the</strong> Special Committee to<br />

explore o<strong>the</strong>r strategic alternatives.<br />

For <strong>the</strong> purposes relevant to this decision, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee's makeup as it was finally settled on March 12,<br />

2004 was as follows:<br />

• Harold S. H<strong>and</strong>elsman: H<strong>and</strong>elsman graduated from<br />

Columbia Law School <strong>and</strong> worked at Wachtell, Lipton,<br />

Rosen & Katz as an M & A lawyer before becoming an<br />

attorney for <strong>the</strong> Pritzker family interests in 1978. The<br />

Pritzker family is a wealthy family based in Chicago<br />

that owns, through trusts, a myriad of businesses.<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman was appointed to <strong>the</strong> Board in 2002<br />

by Cerro, which was one of those Pritzker-owned<br />

businesses.<br />

• Luis Miguel Palomino Bonilla: Palomino has a Ph.D in<br />

finance from <strong>the</strong> Wharton School at <strong>the</strong> University of<br />

Pennsylvania <strong>and</strong> worked as an economist, analyst <strong>and</strong><br />

consultant for various banks <strong>and</strong> financial institutions.<br />

Palomino was nominated to <strong>the</strong> Board by Grupo Mexico<br />

upon <strong>the</strong> recommendation of certain Peruvian pension<br />

funds that held a large portion of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's<br />

publicly traded stock.<br />

*770 • Gilberto Perezalonso Cifuentes: Perezalonso has<br />

both a law degree <strong>and</strong> an MBA <strong>and</strong> has managed multibillion<br />

dollar companies such as Grupo Televisa <strong>and</strong><br />

AeroMexico Airlines. Perezalonso was nominated to <strong>the</strong><br />

Board by Grupo Mexico.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 6


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

• Carlos Ruiz Sacristán: Ruiz, who served as <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee's Chairman, worked as a Mexican<br />

government official for 25 years before co-founding<br />

an investment bank, where he advises on M & A <strong>and</strong><br />

financing transactions. Ruiz was nominated to <strong>the</strong> Board<br />

by Grupo Mexico. 14<br />

D. The Special Committee Hires Advisors And<br />

Seeks A Definitive Proposal From Grupo Mexico<br />

The Special Committee began its work by hiring U.S. counsel<br />

<strong>and</strong> a financial advisor. After considering various options,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee chose Latham & Watkins LLP <strong>and</strong><br />

Goldman, Sachs & Co. The Special Committee also hired a<br />

specialized mining consultant to help Goldman with certain<br />

technical aspects of mining valuation. Goldman suggested<br />

consultants that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee might hire to aid<br />

in <strong>the</strong> process; after considering <strong>the</strong>se options, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee retained Anderson & Schwab (“A & S”).<br />

After hiring its advisors, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee set out to<br />

acquire a “proper” term sheet from Grupo Mexico. 15 The<br />

Special Committee did not view <strong>the</strong> most recent term sheet<br />

that Grupo Mexico had sent on March 25, 2004 as containing<br />

a price term that would allow <strong>the</strong> Special Committee to<br />

properly evaluate <strong>the</strong> proposal. For some reason <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee did not get <strong>the</strong> ra<strong>the</strong>r clear message that Grupo<br />

Mexico thought Minera was worth $3.05 billion.<br />

Thus, in response to that term sheet, on April 2, 2004,<br />

Ruiz sent a letter to Grupo Mexico on behalf of <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee in which he asked for clarification about, among<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r things, <strong>the</strong> pricing of <strong>the</strong> proposed transaction. On May<br />

7, 2004, Grupo Mexico sent to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee what<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee considered to be <strong>the</strong> first “proper”<br />

term sheet, 16 making even more potent its ask.<br />

E. The May 7 Term Sheet<br />

Grupo Mexico's May 7 term sheet contained more specific<br />

details about <strong>the</strong> proposed consideration to be paid in <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. It echoed <strong>the</strong> original proposal, but increased Grupo<br />

Mexico's ask from $3.05 billion worth of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock<br />

to $3.147 billion. Specifically, <strong>the</strong> term sheet provided that:<br />

The proposed value of Minera [ ] is<br />

US$4,3 billion, comprised of an equity<br />

value of US$3,147 million [sic] <strong>and</strong><br />

US$1,153 million [sic] of net debt<br />

as of April 2004. The number of<br />

[Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] shares to be issued in<br />

respect to <strong>the</strong> acquisition of Minera<br />

[ ] would be calculated by dividing<br />

98.84% of <strong>the</strong> equity value of Minera<br />

[ ] by <strong>the</strong> 20–day average closing<br />

share price of [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn *771 Peru]<br />

beginning 5 days prior to closing of <strong>the</strong><br />

[Merger]. 17<br />

In o<strong>the</strong>r words, Grupo Mexico wanted $3.147 billion in<br />

market-tested Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock in exchange for its stake in<br />

Minera. The structure of <strong>the</strong> proposal, like <strong>the</strong> previous Grupo<br />

Mexico ask, shows that Grupo Mexico was focused on <strong>the</strong><br />

dollar value of <strong>the</strong> stock it would receive.<br />

Throughout May 2004, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's advisors<br />

conducted due diligence to aid <strong>the</strong>ir analysis of Grupo<br />

Mexico's proposal. As part of this process, A & S visited<br />

Minera's mines <strong>and</strong> adjusted <strong>the</strong> financial projections of<br />

Minera management (i.e., of Grupo Mexico) based on <strong>the</strong><br />

outcome of <strong>the</strong>ir due diligence.<br />

F. Goldman Begins To Analyze Grupo Mexico's Proposal<br />

On June 11, 2004, Goldman made its first presentation<br />

to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee addressing <strong>the</strong> May 7 term<br />

sheet. Although Goldman noted that due diligence was still<br />

ongoing, it had already done a great deal of work <strong>and</strong><br />

was able to provide preliminary valuation analyses of <strong>the</strong><br />

st<strong>and</strong>alone equity value of Minera, including a DCF analysis,<br />

a contribution analysis, <strong>and</strong> a look-through analysis.<br />

Goldman performed a DCF analysis of Minera based on<br />

long-term copper prices ranging from $0.80 to $1.00 per<br />

pound <strong>and</strong> discount rates ranging from 7.5% to 9.5%, utilizing<br />

both unadjusted Minera management projections <strong>and</strong> Minera<br />

management projections as adjusted by A & S. The only<br />

way that Goldman could derive a value for Minera close<br />

to Grupo Mexico's asking price was by applying its most<br />

aggressive assumptions (a modest 7.5% discount rate <strong>and</strong> its<br />

high-end $1.00/lb long-term copper price) to <strong>the</strong> unadjusted<br />

Minera management projections, which yielded an equity<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 7


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

value for Minera of $3.05 billion. By applying <strong>the</strong> same<br />

aggressive assumptions to <strong>the</strong> projections as adjusted by A &<br />

S, Goldman's DCF analysis yielded a lower equity value for<br />

Minera of $2.41 billion. Goldman's mid-range assumptions<br />

(an 8.5% discount rate <strong>and</strong> $0.90/lb long-term copper price)<br />

only generated a $1.7 billion equity value for Minera when<br />

applied to <strong>the</strong> A & S-adjusted projections. That is, <strong>the</strong> midrange<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Goldman analysis generated a value for Minera<br />

(<strong>the</strong> “get”) a full $1.4 billion less than Grupo Mexico's ask<br />

for <strong>the</strong> give.<br />

The June 11 presentation clearly demonstrates that Goldman,<br />

in its evaluation of <strong>the</strong> May 7 term sheet, could not get <strong>the</strong><br />

get anywhere near <strong>the</strong> give. Notably, that presentation marked<br />

<strong>the</strong> first <strong>and</strong> last time that a give-get analysis appeared in<br />

Goldman's presentations to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee.<br />

*773 What <strong>the</strong>n happened next is curious. The Special<br />

Committee began to devalue <strong>the</strong> “give” in order to make <strong>the</strong><br />

“get” look closer in value.<br />

It made sense for Goldman to use <strong>the</strong> $0.90 per pound long<br />

term copper price as a mid-range assumption, because this<br />

price was being used at <strong>the</strong> time by both Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong><br />

Minera for purposes of internal planning. The median longterm<br />

copper price forecast based on Wall Street research at<br />

<strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger was also $0.90 per pound.<br />

Goldman's contribution analysis applied Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's<br />

market-based sales, EBITDA, <strong>and</strong> copper sales multiples to<br />

Minera. This analysis yielded an equity value for Minera<br />

ranging only between $1.1 <strong>and</strong> $1.7 billion. Goldman's lookthrough<br />

analysis, which was a sum-of-<strong>the</strong>-parts analysis of<br />

Grupo Mexico's market capitalization, generated a maximum<br />

equity value for Minera of $1.3 billion <strong>and</strong> a minimum equity<br />

value of only $227 million.<br />

Goldman summed up <strong>the</strong> import of <strong>the</strong>se various analyses<br />

in an “Illustrative Give/Get Analysis,” which made patent<br />

<strong>the</strong> stark disparity between Grupo Mexico's asking price <strong>and</strong><br />

Goldman's valuation of Minera: Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would “give”<br />

stock *772 with a market price of $3.1 billion to Grupo<br />

Mexico <strong>and</strong> would “get” in return an asset worth no more than<br />

$1.7 billion. 18<br />

The important assumption reflected in Goldman's June 11<br />

presentation that a bloc of shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru could yield<br />

a cash value equal to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's actual stock market price<br />

<strong>and</strong> was thus worth its market value is worth pausing over.<br />

At trial, <strong>the</strong> defendants disclaimed any reliance upon a claim<br />

that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock market price was not a reliable<br />

indication of <strong>the</strong> cash value that a very large bloc of shares—<br />

such as <strong>the</strong> 67.2 million paid to Grupo Mexico—could yield<br />

in <strong>the</strong> market. 19 Thus, <strong>the</strong> price of <strong>the</strong> “give” was always easy<br />

to discern. The question thus becomes what was <strong>the</strong> value<br />

of <strong>the</strong> “get.” Unlike Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, Minera's value was not<br />

<strong>the</strong> subject of a regular market test. Minera shares were not<br />

publicly traded <strong>and</strong> thus <strong>the</strong> company was embedded in <strong>the</strong><br />

overall value of Grupo Mexico.<br />

The DCF analysis of <strong>the</strong> value of Minera that Goldman<br />

presented initially caused concern. As H<strong>and</strong>elsman stated at<br />

trial, “when [<strong>the</strong> Special Committee] thought that <strong>the</strong> value of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was its market value <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> value of Minera<br />

[ ] was its discounted cash flow value ... those were very<br />

different numbers.” 20 But, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's view<br />

changed when Goldman presented it with a DCF analysis of<br />

<strong>the</strong> value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru on June 23, 2004.<br />

In this June 23 presentation, Goldman provided <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee with a preliminary DCF analysis for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru analogous to <strong>the</strong> one that it had provided for Minera<br />

in <strong>the</strong> June 11 presentation. But, <strong>the</strong> discount rates that<br />

Goldman applied to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's cash flows ranged from<br />

8% to 10% instead of 7.5% to 9.5%. Based on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru management's projections, <strong>the</strong> DCF value generated for<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru using mid-range assumptions (a 9% discount<br />

rate <strong>and</strong> $0.90/lb long-term copper price) was $2.06 billion.<br />

This was about $1.1 billion shy of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's market<br />

capitalization as of June 21, 2004 ($3.19 billion). Those<br />

values “comforted” <strong>the</strong> Special Committee. 21<br />

Again, one must pause over this. “Comfort” is an odd word in<br />

this context. What Goldman was basically telling <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee was that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was being overvalued<br />

by <strong>the</strong> stock market. That is, Goldman told <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee that even though Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock was<br />

worth an obtainable amount in cash, it really was not worth<br />

that much in fundamental terms. Thus, although Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru had an actual cash value of $3.19 billion, its “real,”<br />

“intrinsic,” 22 or “fundamental” value was only $2.06 billion,<br />

<strong>and</strong> giving $2.06 billion in fundamental value for $1.7 billion<br />

in fundamental value was something more reasonable to<br />

consider.<br />

Of course, <strong>the</strong> more logical reaction of someone not in <strong>the</strong><br />

confined mindset of directors of a controlled company may<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 8


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

have been that it was a good time to capitalize on <strong>the</strong> market<br />

multiple <strong>the</strong> company was getting <strong>and</strong> monetize <strong>the</strong> asset.<br />

A third party in <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's position might<br />

have sold at <strong>the</strong> top of <strong>the</strong> market, or returned cash to <strong>the</strong><br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stockholders by declaring a special dividend.<br />

For example, if it made long-term strategic sense for Grupo<br />

Mexico to consolidate Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera, <strong>the</strong>re was<br />

a logical alternative for <strong>the</strong> Special Committee: ask Grupo<br />

Mexico to make a premium to market offer for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru.<br />

Let Grupo Mexico be <strong>the</strong> buyer, not <strong>the</strong> seller. If <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee's distinguished bankers believed that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru was trading at a premium to fundamental value, why<br />

not ask Grupo Mexico to make a bid at a premium to that<br />

price? By doing so, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee would have also<br />

probed Grupo Mexico about its own weaknesses, including<br />

<strong>the</strong> fact that Minera seemed to be *774 cash-strapped,<br />

having trouble paying its regular bills, <strong>and</strong> thus unable to<br />

move forward with an acquisition of its own. That is, if Grupo<br />

Mexico could not buy despite <strong>the</strong> value it held in Minera, that<br />

would bespeak weakness <strong>and</strong> cast doubt on <strong>the</strong> credibility of<br />

its ask. And if it turned out that Grupo Mexico would buy at a<br />

premium, <strong>the</strong> minority stockholders of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would<br />

benefit.<br />

In o<strong>the</strong>r words, by acting like a third-party negotiator with its<br />

own money at stake <strong>and</strong> with <strong>the</strong> full range of options, <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee would have put Grupo Mexico back on its<br />

heels. Doing so would have been consistent with <strong>the</strong> financial<br />

advice it was getting <strong>and</strong> seemed to accept as correct. The<br />

Special Committee could have also looked to use its marketproven<br />

stock to buy a company at a good price (a lower<br />

multiple to earnings than Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n have its<br />

value rolled into Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's higher market multiple to<br />

earnings. That could have included buying Minera at a price<br />

equal to its fundamental value using Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's marketproven<br />

currency.<br />

Instead of doing any of <strong>the</strong>se things, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

was “comforted” by <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>y could devalue that<br />

currency <strong>and</strong> justify paying more for Minera than <strong>the</strong>y<br />

originally thought <strong>the</strong>y should. 23<br />

G. The Special Committee Moves<br />

Toward Relative Valuation<br />

After <strong>the</strong> June 23, 2004 presentation, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

<strong>and</strong> Goldman began to embrace <strong>the</strong> idea that <strong>the</strong> companies<br />

should be valued on a relative basis. In a July 8, 2004<br />

presentation to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, Goldman included<br />

both a revised st<strong>and</strong>alone DCF analysis of Minera <strong>and</strong> a<br />

“Relative Discounted Cash Flow Analysis” in <strong>the</strong> form of<br />

matrices presenting <strong>the</strong> “indicative number” of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

shares that should be issued to acquire Minera based on<br />

various assumptions. 24 The relative DCF analysis generated<br />

a vast range of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru shares to be issued in <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

of 28.9 million to 71.3 million. Based on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's July<br />

8, 2004 market value of $40.30 per share, 28.9 million shares<br />

of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock had a market value of $1.16 billion,<br />

<strong>and</strong> 71.3 million shares were worth $2.87 billion. 25 In o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

words, even <strong>the</strong> highest equity value yielded for Minera by<br />

this analysis was short of Grupo Mexico's actual cash value<br />

asking price.<br />

The revised st<strong>and</strong>alone DCF analysis applied <strong>the</strong> same<br />

discount rate <strong>and</strong> long-term copper price assumptions that<br />

Goldman had used in its June 11 presentation to updated<br />

projections. This time, by applying a 7.5% discount rate<br />

<strong>and</strong> $1.00 per pound long-term copper price to Minera<br />

management's projections, Goldman was only able to yield<br />

an equity value of $2.8 billion for Minera. Applying <strong>the</strong> same<br />

aggressive assumptions to <strong>the</strong> projections as adjusted by A<br />

& S generated a st<strong>and</strong>alone equity value for Minera of only<br />

$2.085 billion. Applying mid-range assumptions (a discount<br />

rate of 8.5% <strong>and</strong> $0.90/lb long- *775 term copper price) to<br />

<strong>the</strong> A & S-adjusted projections yielded an equity value for<br />

Minera of only $1.358 billion.<br />

H. The Special Committee Makes A Counterproposal<br />

And Suggests A Fixed Exchange Ratio<br />

After Goldman's July 8 presentation, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

made a counterproposal to Grupo Mexico that was (oddly)<br />

not mentioned in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's proxy statement describing<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger (<strong>the</strong> “Proxy Statement”). In this counterproposal,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee offered that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would<br />

acquire Minera by issuing 52 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

stock with a <strong>the</strong>n-current market value of $2.095 billion. 26<br />

The Special Committee also proposed implementation of a<br />

fixed, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a floating, exchange ratio that would set <strong>the</strong><br />

number of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru shares issued in <strong>the</strong> Merger. 27<br />

From <strong>the</strong> inception of <strong>the</strong> Merger, Grupo Mexico had<br />

contemplated that <strong>the</strong> dollar value of <strong>the</strong> price to be paid<br />

by Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would be fixed (at a number that was<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 9


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

always north of $3 billion), while <strong>the</strong> number of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru shares to be issued as consideration would float up or<br />

down based on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's trading price around <strong>the</strong> time<br />

of closing. But, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee was uncomfortable<br />

with having to issue a variable amount of shares in <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. H<strong>and</strong>elsman testified that, in its evaluation of Grupo<br />

Mexico's May 7 term sheet, “it was <strong>the</strong> consensus of <strong>the</strong><br />

[Special Committee] that a floating exchange rate was a<br />

nonstarter” because “no one could predict <strong>the</strong> number of<br />

shares that [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] would have to issue in order to<br />

come up with <strong>the</strong> consideration requested.” 28 The Special<br />

Committee wanted a fixed exchange ratio, which would set<br />

<strong>the</strong> number of shares that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would issue in <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger at <strong>the</strong> time of signing. The dollar value of <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

consideration at <strong>the</strong> time of closing would vary with <strong>the</strong><br />

fluctuations of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's market price. According to <strong>the</strong><br />

testimony of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee members, <strong>the</strong>ir reasoning<br />

was that both Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> copper market had<br />

been historically volatile, <strong>and</strong> a fixed exchange ratio would<br />

protect Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stockholders from a situation in which<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock price went down <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

would be forced to issue a greater number of shares for Minera<br />

in order to meet a fixed dollar value. 29 As I will discuss later,<br />

that position is hard to square with <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

<strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's purported bullishness about <strong>the</strong> copper<br />

market in 2004. 30<br />

I. Grupo Mexico Sticks To Its Dem<strong>and</strong><br />

In late July or early August, Grupo Mexico responded to<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee's counterproposal by suggesting that<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru should issue in excess of 80 million shares of<br />

common stock to purchase Minera. It is not clear on <strong>the</strong> record<br />

exactly when Grupo Mexico asked for 80 million shares,<br />

but given Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's trading history at that time, <strong>the</strong><br />

market value of that consideration would have been close to<br />

$3.1 billion, basically <strong>the</strong> same place where Grupo Mexico<br />

had started. *776 31 The Special Committee viewed Grupo<br />

Mexico's ask as too high, which is not surprising given that<br />

<strong>the</strong> parties were apparently a full billion dollars in value apart,<br />

<strong>and</strong> negotiations almost broke down.<br />

But, on August 21, 2004, after what is described as “an<br />

extraordinary effort” in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's Proxy Statement,<br />

Grupo Mexico proposed a new asking price of 67 million<br />

shares. 32 On August 20, 2004, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was trading at<br />

$41.20 per share, so 67 million shares were worth about $2.76<br />

billion on <strong>the</strong> market, a drop in Grupo Mexico's ask. 33 Grupo<br />

Mexico's new offer brought <strong>the</strong> Special Committee back to<br />

<strong>the</strong> negotiating table.<br />

After receiving two term sheets from Grupo Mexico that<br />

reflected <strong>the</strong> 67 million share asking price, <strong>the</strong> second<br />

of which was received on September 8, 2004, when 67<br />

million shares had risen to be worth $3.06 billion on<br />

<strong>the</strong> market, 34 Goldman made ano<strong>the</strong>r presentation to <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee on September 15, 2004. In addition<br />

to updated relative DCF analyses of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong><br />

Minera (presented only in terms of <strong>the</strong> number of shares<br />

of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock to be issued in <strong>the</strong> Merger), this<br />

presentation contained a “Multiple Approach at Different<br />

EBITDA Scenarios,” which was essentially a comparison of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera's market-based equity values, as<br />

derived from multiples of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's 2004 <strong>and</strong> 2005<br />

estimated (or “E”) EBITDA. 35 Goldman also presented<br />

<strong>the</strong>se analyses in terms of <strong>the</strong> number of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

shares to be issued to Grupo Mexico, ra<strong>the</strong>r than generating<br />

st<strong>and</strong>alone values for Minera. The range of shares to be issued<br />

at <strong>the</strong> 2004E EBITDA multiple (5.0x) was 44 to 54 million;<br />

at <strong>the</strong> 2005E multiple (6.3x) Goldman's analyses yielded a<br />

range of 61 to 72 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock. 36<br />

Based on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's $45.34 share price as of September<br />

15, 2004, 61 to 72 million shares had a cash value of $2.765<br />

billion to $3.26 billion. 37<br />

The Special Committee sent a new proposed term sheet<br />

to Grupo Mexico on September 23, 2004. That term sheet<br />

provided for a fixed purchase price of 64 million shares of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru (translating to a $2.95 billion market value<br />

based on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's <strong>the</strong>n-current closing price). 38 The<br />

Special Committee's proposal contained two terms that would<br />

protect <strong>the</strong> minority stockholders of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru: (1) a 20%<br />

collar around <strong>the</strong> purchase price, which gave both <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee <strong>and</strong> Grupo Mexico <strong>the</strong> right to walk away from<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger if Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock price went outside of <strong>the</strong><br />

collar before <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote; <strong>and</strong> (2) a voting provision<br />

requiring that a majority of <strong>the</strong> minority *777 stockholders<br />

of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru vote in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger. Additionally,<br />

<strong>the</strong> proposal called for Minera's net debt, which Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru was going to absorb in <strong>the</strong> Merger, to be capped at<br />

$1.105 billion at closing, <strong>and</strong> contained various corporate<br />

governance provisions.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 10


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

J. Grupo Mexico Rejects Many Of The<br />

Special Committee's Proposed Terms<br />

But The Parties Work Out A Deal<br />

On September 30, 2004, Grupo Mexico sent a<br />

counterproposal to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, in which Grupo<br />

Mexico rejected <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's offer of 64 million<br />

shares <strong>and</strong> held firm to its dem<strong>and</strong> for 67 million shares.<br />

Grupo Mexico's counterproposal also rejected <strong>the</strong> collar <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> majority of <strong>the</strong> minority vote provision, proposing instead<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Merger be conditioned on <strong>the</strong> vote of two-thirds of<br />

<strong>the</strong> outst<strong>and</strong>ing stock. Grupo Mexico noted that conditioning<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger on a two-thirds shareholder vote obviated <strong>the</strong> need<br />

for <strong>the</strong> walk-away right requested by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee,<br />

because Grupo Mexico would be prevented from approving<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger unilaterally in <strong>the</strong> event <strong>the</strong> stock price was<br />

materially higher at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote than at <strong>the</strong><br />

time of Board approval. Grupo Mexico did accept <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee's proposed $1.05 billion debt cap at closing, which<br />

was not much of a concession in light of <strong>the</strong> fact that Minera<br />

was already contractually obligated to pay down its debt <strong>and</strong><br />

was in <strong>the</strong> process of doing so. 39<br />

After <strong>the</strong> Special Committee received Grupo Mexico's<br />

September 30 counterproposal, <strong>the</strong> parties reached agreement<br />

on certain corporate governance provisions to be included<br />

in <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement, some of which were originally<br />

suggested by Grupo Mexico <strong>and</strong> some of which were first<br />

suggested by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee. Without saying <strong>the</strong>se<br />

provisions were of no benefit at all to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong><br />

its outside investors, let me just say that <strong>the</strong>y do not factor<br />

more importantly in this decision because <strong>the</strong>y do not provide<br />

any benefit above <strong>the</strong> protections of default law that were<br />

economically meaningful enough to close <strong>the</strong> material dollar<br />

value gap that existed.<br />

On October 5, 2004, members of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

met with Grupo Mexico to iron out a final deal. At that<br />

meeting, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee agreed to pay 67 million<br />

shares, dropped <strong>the</strong>ir dem<strong>and</strong> for <strong>the</strong> collar, <strong>and</strong> acceded to<br />

most of Grupo Mexico's dem<strong>and</strong>s. The Special Committee<br />

justified paying a higher price through a series of economic<br />

contortions. The Special Committee was able to “bridge <strong>the</strong><br />

gap” 40 between <strong>the</strong> 64 million <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> 67 million figures by<br />

decreasing Minera's debt cap by ano<strong>the</strong>r $105 million, <strong>and</strong><br />

by getting Grupo Mexico to cause Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru to issue<br />

a special dividend of $100 million, which had <strong>the</strong> effect of<br />

decreasing <strong>the</strong> value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock. According to<br />

Special Committee member *778 H<strong>and</strong>elsman, <strong>the</strong>se “bells<br />

<strong>and</strong> whistles” 41 made it so that “<strong>the</strong> value of what was<br />

being ... acquired in <strong>the</strong> merger went up, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong><br />

specie that was being used in <strong>the</strong> merger went down ...,” 42<br />

giving <strong>the</strong> Special Committee reason to accept a higher<br />

Merger price.<br />

The closing share price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was $53.16 on<br />

October 5, 2004, so a purchase price of 67 million shares had<br />

a market value of $3.56 billion, 43 which was higher than <strong>the</strong><br />

dollar value requested by Grupo Mexico in its February 2004<br />

proposal or its original May 7 term sheet.<br />

At that point, <strong>the</strong> main unresolved issue was <strong>the</strong> stockholder<br />

vote that would be required to approve <strong>the</strong> Merger. After<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r negotiations, on October 8, 2004, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee gave up on its proposed majority of <strong>the</strong> minority<br />

vote provision <strong>and</strong> agreed to Grupo Mexico's suggestion that<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger require only <strong>the</strong> approval of two-thirds of <strong>the</strong><br />

outst<strong>and</strong>ing common stock of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. 44 Given <strong>the</strong><br />

size of <strong>the</strong> holdings of Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge, 45 Grupo<br />

Mexico could achieve a two-thirds vote if ei<strong>the</strong>r Cerro or<br />

Phelps Dodge voted in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

K. The Multi–Faceted Dimensions Of Controlling<br />

Power: Large Stockholders Who Want To Get Out<br />

Support A Strategic, Long–Term Acquisition As<br />

A Prelude To Their Own Exit As Stockholders<br />

Human relations <strong>and</strong> motivations are complex. One of <strong>the</strong><br />

members of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, H<strong>and</strong>elsman, represented<br />

a large Founding Stockholder, Cerro. This might be seen in<br />

some ways to have ideally positioned H<strong>and</strong>elsman to be a<br />

very aggressive negotiator. But H<strong>and</strong>elsman had a problem<br />

to deal with, which did not involve Cerro having any selfdealing<br />

interest in <strong>the</strong> sense that Grupo Mexico had. Ra<strong>the</strong>r,<br />

Grupo Mexico had control over Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> thus over<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would take <strong>the</strong> steps necessary to<br />

make <strong>the</strong> Founding Stockholders' shares marketable under<br />

applicable securities regulations. 46 Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge,<br />

consistent with its name, wanted to monetize <strong>the</strong>ir investment<br />

in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> get out.<br />

Thus, while <strong>the</strong> Special Committee was negotiating <strong>the</strong> terms<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Merger, H<strong>and</strong>elsman was engaged in negotiations of<br />

his own with Grupo Mexico. 47 Cerro <strong>and</strong> *779 Phelps<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 11


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

Dodge had been seeking registration rights from Grupo<br />

Mexico (in its capacity as Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's controller) for <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock, which <strong>the</strong>y needed because of<br />

<strong>the</strong> volume restrictions imposed on affiliates of an issuer by<br />

SEC Rule 144. 48<br />

It is not clear which party first proposed liquidity <strong>and</strong><br />

support for <strong>the</strong> Founding Stockholders in connection with <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. But it is plain that <strong>the</strong> concept appears throughout<br />

<strong>the</strong> term sheets exchanged between Grupo Mexico <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee, <strong>and</strong> it is clear that H<strong>and</strong>elsman knew<br />

that registration rights would be part of <strong>the</strong> deal from <strong>the</strong><br />

beginning of <strong>the</strong> Merger negotiations <strong>and</strong> that thus <strong>the</strong><br />

deal would enable Cerro to sell as it desired. The Special<br />

Committee did not take <strong>the</strong> lead in negotiating <strong>the</strong> specific<br />

terms of <strong>the</strong> registration rights provisions—ra<strong>the</strong>r, it took <strong>the</strong><br />

position that it wanted to leave <strong>the</strong> back-<strong>and</strong>-forth over <strong>the</strong><br />

agreement details to Cerro <strong>and</strong> Grupo Mexico. H<strong>and</strong>elsman,<br />

however, played a key role in <strong>the</strong> negotiations with Grupo<br />

Mexico on Cerro's behalf. 49<br />

At trial, H<strong>and</strong>elsman explained that <strong>the</strong>re were two<br />

justifications for pursuing registration rights—one offered<br />

benefits exclusive to <strong>the</strong> Founding Stockholders, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r offered benefits that would inure to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's<br />

entire stockholder base. The first justification was that Cerro<br />

needed <strong>the</strong> registration rights in order to sell its shares<br />

quickly, <strong>and</strong> Cerro wanted “to get out” of its investment<br />

in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. 50 The second justification concerned <strong>the</strong><br />

public market for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock. Granting registration<br />

rights to <strong>the</strong> Founding Stockholders would allow Cerro <strong>and</strong><br />

Phelps Dodge to sell <strong>the</strong>ir shares, increasing <strong>the</strong> amount of<br />

stock traded on <strong>the</strong> market <strong>and</strong> thus increasing Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's somewhat thin public float. This would in turn improve<br />

stockholder liquidity, generate more analyst exposure, <strong>and</strong><br />

create a more efficient market for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru shares, all of<br />

which would benefit <strong>the</strong> minority stockholders. H<strong>and</strong>elsman<br />

thus characterized <strong>the</strong> registration rights situation as a “winwin,”<br />

because “it permitted us to sell our stock” <strong>and</strong> “it was<br />

good for [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] because <strong>the</strong>y had a better float <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>y had a more organized sale of shares.” 51<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman's t<strong>and</strong>em negotiations with Grupo Mexico<br />

culminated in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru giving Cerro registration rights<br />

for its shares on October 21, 2004, <strong>the</strong> same day that <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee approved <strong>the</strong> Merger. In exchange for<br />

registration rights, Cerro expressed its intent to vote its shares<br />

in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee recommended<br />

it. If <strong>the</strong> Special Committee made a recommendation against<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger, or withdrew its recommendation in favor of it,<br />

Cerro was bound by <strong>the</strong> agreement to vote against <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

Grupo Mexico's initial proposal, which H<strong>and</strong>elsman received<br />

on October 18, 2004—a mere three days before *780 <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee was to vote on <strong>the</strong> Merger—was that<br />

it would grant Cerro registration rights in exchange for<br />

Cerro's agreement to vote in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger. The Special<br />

Committee <strong>and</strong> H<strong>and</strong>elsman suggested instead that Cerro's<br />

vote on <strong>the</strong> Merger be tied to whe<strong>the</strong>r or not <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee recommended <strong>the</strong> Merger. After discussing <strong>the</strong><br />

matter with <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, Grupo Mexico agreed.<br />

On December 22, 2004, after <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

approved <strong>the</strong> Merger but well before <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote,<br />

Phelps Dodge entered into an agreement with Grupo Mexico<br />

that was similar to Cerro's, but did not contain a provision<br />

requiring Phelps Dodge to vote against <strong>the</strong> Merger if<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee did. By contrast, Phelps Dodge's<br />

agreement only provided that, [t]aking into account that <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee ... did recommend ... <strong>the</strong> approval of <strong>the</strong><br />

[Merger], Phelps Dodge “express[es] [its] current intent, to<br />

[ ] submit its proxies to vote in favor of <strong>the</strong> [Merger]....” 52<br />

Thus, in <strong>the</strong> event that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee later withdrew<br />

its recommendation to approve <strong>the</strong> Merger, Cerro would be<br />

contractually bound to vote against it, but Grupo Mexico<br />

could still achieve <strong>the</strong> two-thirds vote required to approve<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger solely with Phelps Dodge's cooperation. Under<br />

<strong>the</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

was free to change its recommendation of <strong>the</strong> Merger, but<br />

it was not able to terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement on <strong>the</strong><br />

basis of such a change. 53 Ra<strong>the</strong>r, a change in <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee's recommendation only gave Grupo Mexico <strong>the</strong><br />

power to terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. 54<br />

This issue again warrants a pause. Although I am not prepared<br />

on this record to find that H<strong>and</strong>elsman consciously agreed to a<br />

suboptimal deal for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru simply to achieve liquidity<br />

for Cerro from Grupo Mexico, <strong>the</strong>re is little doubt in my mind<br />

that Cerro's own predicament as a stockholder dependent on<br />

Grupo Mexico's whim as a controller for registration rights<br />

influenced how H<strong>and</strong>elsman approached <strong>the</strong> situation. That<br />

does not mean he consciously gave in, but it does means that<br />

he was less than ideally situated to press hard. Put simply,<br />

Cerro was even more subject to <strong>the</strong> dominion of Grupo<br />

Mexico than smaller holders because Grupo Mexico had<br />

additional power over it because of <strong>the</strong> unregistered nature of<br />

its shares.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 12


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

Perhaps most important, Cerro's desires when considered<br />

alongside <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's actions illustrate <strong>the</strong><br />

tendency of control to result in odd behavior. During <strong>the</strong><br />

negotiations of <strong>the</strong> Merger, Cerro had no interest in <strong>the</strong> longterm<br />

benefits to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru of acquiring Minera, nor did<br />

Phelps Dodge. Certainly, Cerro did not want any deal so<br />

disastrous that it would tank <strong>the</strong> value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

completely, but nor did it have a rational incentive to say<br />

no to a suboptimal deal if that risked being locked into its<br />

investments. Cerro wanted to sell <strong>and</strong> sell <strong>the</strong>n <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re.<br />

But as a Special Committee member, H<strong>and</strong>elsman did not act<br />

consistently *781 with that impulse for all stockholders. He<br />

did not suggest that Grupo Mexico make an offer for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru, but instead pursued a long-term strategic transaction in<br />

which Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was <strong>the</strong> buyer. A short-term seller of<br />

a company's shares caused that company to be a long-term<br />

buyer.<br />

L. After One Last Price Adjustment,<br />

Goldman Makes Its Final Presentation<br />

On October 13, 2004, Grupo Mexico realized that it owned<br />

99.15% of Minera ra<strong>the</strong>r than 98.84%, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> purchase price<br />

was adjusted to 67.2 million shares instead of 67 million<br />

shares to reflect <strong>the</strong> change in size of <strong>the</strong> interest being sold.<br />

On October 13, 2004, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was trading at $45.90<br />

per share, which meant that 67.2 million shares had a dollar<br />

worth of $3.08 billion. 55<br />

On October 21, 2004, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee met to consider<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r to recommend that <strong>the</strong> Board approve <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

At that meeting, Goldman made a final presentation to <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee. The October 21, 2004 presentation stated<br />

that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's implied equity value was $3.69 billion<br />

based on its <strong>the</strong>n current market capitalization at a stock price<br />

of $46.41 <strong>and</strong> adjusting for debt. Minera's implied equity<br />

value is stated as $3.146 billion, which was derived entirely<br />

from multiplying 67.2 million shares by Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's<br />

$46.41 stock price <strong>and</strong> adjusting for <strong>the</strong> fact that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru was only buying 99.15% of Minera.<br />

No st<strong>and</strong>alone equity value of Minera was included in<br />

<strong>the</strong> October 21 presentation. 56 Instead, <strong>the</strong> presentation<br />

included a series of relative DCF analyses <strong>and</strong> a “Contribution<br />

Analysis at Different EBITDA Scenarios,” both of which<br />

were presented in terms of a hypo<strong>the</strong>tical number of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru shares to be issued to Grupo Mexico for Minera. 57<br />

Goldman's relative DCF analyses provided various matrices<br />

showing <strong>the</strong> number of shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru that should<br />

be issued in exchange for Minera under various assumptions<br />

regarding <strong>the</strong> discount rate, <strong>the</strong> long-term copper price, <strong>the</strong><br />

allocation of tax benefits, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> amount of royalties that<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would need to pay to <strong>the</strong> Peruvian government.<br />

As it had in all of its previous presentations, Goldman used<br />

a range of long-term copper prices from $0.80 to $1.00 per<br />

pound. The DCF analyses generated a range of <strong>the</strong> number of<br />

shares to be issued in <strong>the</strong> Merger from 47.2 million to 87.8<br />

million. Based on <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n-current stock price of $45.92, this<br />

translated to $2.17 billion to $4.03 billion in cash value. 58<br />

Assuming <strong>the</strong> mid-range figures of a discount rate of 8.5%<br />

<strong>and</strong> a long-term copper price of $0.90 per pound, <strong>the</strong> *782<br />

analyses yielded a range of shares from 60.7 to 78.7 million.<br />

Goldman's contribution analysis generated a range of 42<br />

million to 56 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru to be issued<br />

based on an annualized 2004E EBITDA multiple (4.6x)<br />

<strong>and</strong> forecasted 2004E EBITDA multiple (5.0x), <strong>and</strong> a range<br />

of 53 million to 73 million shares based on an updated<br />

range of estimated 2005E EBITDA multiples (5.6x to 6.5x).<br />

Notably, <strong>the</strong> 2004E EBITDA multiples did not support <strong>the</strong><br />

issuance of 67.2 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock in <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. But, 67.2 million shares falls at <strong>the</strong> higher end of<br />

<strong>the</strong> range of shares calculated using Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's 2005E<br />

EBITDA multiples. As notable, <strong>the</strong>se multiples were not<br />

<strong>the</strong> product of <strong>the</strong> median of <strong>the</strong> 2005E EBITDA multiples<br />

of comparable companies identified by Goldman (4.8x).<br />

Instead, <strong>the</strong> multiples used were even higher than Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's own higher 2005E EBITDA Wall Street consensus<br />

(5.5x)—an adjusted version of which was used as <strong>the</strong> bottom<br />

end of <strong>the</strong> range. These higher multiples were <strong>the</strong>n attributed<br />

to Minera, a non-publicly traded company suffering from a<br />

variety of financial <strong>and</strong> operational problems.<br />

Goldman opined that <strong>the</strong> Merger was fair from a financial<br />

perspective to <strong>the</strong> stockholders of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, <strong>and</strong><br />

provided a written fairness opinion.<br />

M. The Special Committee And<br />

The Board Approve The Merger<br />

After Goldman made its presentation, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

voted 3–0 to recommend <strong>the</strong> Merger to <strong>the</strong> Board. At <strong>the</strong><br />

last-minute suggestion of Goldman, H<strong>and</strong>elsman decided not<br />

to vote in order to remove any appearance of conflict based<br />

on his participation in <strong>the</strong> negotiation of Cerro's registration<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 13


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

rights, despite <strong>the</strong> fact that he had been heavily involved in<br />

<strong>the</strong> negotiations from <strong>the</strong> beginning <strong>and</strong> his h<strong>and</strong>s had been<br />

deep in <strong>the</strong> dough of <strong>the</strong> now fully baked deal. 59<br />

The Board <strong>the</strong>n unanimously approved <strong>the</strong> Merger <strong>and</strong><br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru entered into <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement.<br />

N. The Market Reacts To The Merger<br />

The market reaction to <strong>the</strong> Merger was mixed <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> parties<br />

have not presented any reliable evidence about it. That is,<br />

nei<strong>the</strong>r party had an expert perform an event study analyzing<br />

<strong>the</strong> market reaction to <strong>the</strong> Merger. Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock<br />

price traded down by 4.6% when <strong>the</strong> Merger was announced.<br />

When <strong>the</strong> preliminary proxy statement, which provided more<br />

financial information regarding <strong>the</strong> Merger terms, became<br />

public on November 22, 2004, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock price<br />

again declined by 1.45%. But <strong>the</strong> stock price increased for<br />

two days after <strong>the</strong> final Proxy Statement was filed.<br />

Determining what effect <strong>the</strong> Merger itself had on this rise is<br />

difficult because, as <strong>the</strong> plaintiff points out, this was not, as<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants contend, <strong>the</strong> first time that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong><br />

Minera's financials were presented toge<strong>the</strong>r. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> same<br />

financial statements were in <strong>the</strong> preliminary Proxy Statement<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> stock price fell.<br />

But, as noted, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff also offers no evidence that<br />

<strong>the</strong>se stock market fluctuations provide a reliable basis for<br />

assessing *783 <strong>the</strong> fairness of <strong>the</strong> deal because it did not<br />

conduct a reliable event study.<br />

In fact, against a backdrop of strong copper prices, <strong>the</strong> trading<br />

price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock increased substantially by <strong>the</strong><br />

time <strong>the</strong> Merger closed. By April 1, 2005, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's<br />

stock price had a market value of $55.89 per share, an increase<br />

of approximately 21.7% over <strong>the</strong> October 21, 2004 closing<br />

price. But lest this be attributed to <strong>the</strong> Merger, o<strong>the</strong>r factors<br />

were in play. This includes <strong>the</strong> general direction of copper<br />

prices, which lifted <strong>the</strong> market price of not just Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru,<br />

but those of its publicly traded competitors. 60 Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's own financial performance was very strong,<br />

as will soon be discussed.<br />

O. Goldman Does Not Update Its Fairness Analysis<br />

Despite rising Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru share prices <strong>and</strong> performance,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee did not ask Goldman to update its<br />

fairness analysis at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote on <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger <strong>and</strong> closing—nearly five months after <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee had voted to recommend it. At trial, H<strong>and</strong>elsman<br />

testified that he called a representative at Goldman to ask<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> transaction was still fair, but H<strong>and</strong>elsman's phone<br />

call hardly constitutes a request for an updated fairness<br />

analysis. 61<br />

The Special Committee's failure to determine whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger was still fair at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger vote <strong>and</strong> closing<br />

is curious for two reasons.<br />

First, for whatever <strong>the</strong> reason, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock price<br />

had gone up substantially since <strong>the</strong> Merger was announced<br />

in October 2004. In March 2005, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock was<br />

trading at an average price of $58.56 a share. The Special<br />

Committee had agreed to a collarless fixed exchange ratio <strong>and</strong><br />

did not have a walk-away right. To my mind, an adroit Special<br />

Committee would have recognized <strong>the</strong> need to re-evaluate <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger in light of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's <strong>the</strong>n-current stock price.<br />

Second, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's actual 2004 EBITDA became<br />

available before <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote on <strong>the</strong> Merger took<br />

place, <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru had smashed through <strong>the</strong> projections<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee had used for it. 62 In <strong>the</strong> October<br />

*784 21 presentation, Goldman used a 2004E EBITDA for<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru of $733 million <strong>and</strong> a 2004E EBITDA for<br />

Minera of $687 million. Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's actual 2004 EBITDA<br />

was $1.005 billion, 37% more <strong>and</strong> almost $300 million more<br />

than <strong>the</strong> projections used by Goldman. Minera's actual 2004<br />

EBITDA, by contrast, was $681 million, 0.8% less than <strong>the</strong><br />

projections used by Goldman. As I mentioned earlier, in its<br />

contribution analysis Goldman relied on <strong>the</strong> values (measured<br />

in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru shares) generated by applying an aggressive<br />

range of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's 2005E EBITDA multiples to<br />

Minera's A & S-adjusted <strong>and</strong> unadjusted projections, not <strong>the</strong><br />

2004E EBITDA multiple, but <strong>the</strong> inaccuracy of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's estimated 2004 EBITDA should have given <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee serious pause. If <strong>the</strong> 2004 EBITDA<br />

projections of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru—which were not optimized <strong>and</strong><br />

had been prepared by Grupo Mexico-controlled management<br />

—were so grossly low, it provided reason to suspect that<br />

<strong>the</strong> 2005 EBITDA projections, which were even lower<br />

than <strong>the</strong> 2004 EBITDA projections, were also materially<br />

inaccurate, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> assumptions forming <strong>the</strong> basis of<br />

Goldman's contribution analysis should be reconsidered.<br />

Moreover, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru made $303.4 million in EBITDA<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 14


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

in <strong>the</strong> first quarter of 2005, over 52% of <strong>the</strong> estimate in<br />

Goldman's fairness presentation for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's 2005 full<br />

year performance. Although <strong>the</strong> first-quarter 2005 financial<br />

statements, which covered <strong>the</strong> period from January 1, 2005<br />

to March 31, 2005, would not have been complete by<br />

<strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote, I can reasonably assume<br />

that, as directors of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

had access to non-public information about Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's<br />

monthly profit <strong>and</strong> loss statements. Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru later beat<br />

its EBITDA projections for 2005 by a very large margin,<br />

135%, 63 a rate well ahead of Minera's 2005 performance,<br />

which beat <strong>the</strong> deal estimates by a much lower 45%. 64<br />

The Special Committee's failure to get a fairness update<br />

was even more of a concern because Cerro had agreed<br />

to vote against <strong>the</strong> Merger if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

changed its recommendation. The Special Committee failed<br />

to obtain a majority of <strong>the</strong> minority vote requirement, but it<br />

supposedly agreed to a two-thirds vote requirement instead<br />

because a two-thirds vote still prevented Grupo Mexico<br />

from unilaterally approving <strong>the</strong> Merger. This out was only<br />

meaningful, however, if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee took <strong>the</strong><br />

recommendation process seriously. If <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

maintained its recommendation, Cerro had to vote for <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger, <strong>and</strong> its vote combined with Grupo Mexico's vote<br />

would ensure passage. By contrast, if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

changed its recommendation, Cerro was obligated to vote<br />

against <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

The tying of Cerro's voting agreement to <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee's recommendation was somewhat odd, in ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

respect. In a situation involving a third-party merger sale<br />

of a company without a controlling stockholder, <strong>the</strong> third<br />

party will often want to lock up some votes in support of a<br />

deal. A large blocholder <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> target board might <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

negotiate a compromise, whereby <strong>the</strong> blocholder agrees to<br />

vote yes if <strong>the</strong> target board or special committee maintains a<br />

recommendation in favor of <strong>the</strong> transaction. In this situation,<br />

however, <strong>the</strong>re is a factor not present here. In an arm'slength<br />

deal, <strong>the</strong> target usually *785 has <strong>the</strong> flexibility to<br />

change its recommendation or terminate <strong>the</strong> original merger<br />

upon certain conditions, including if a superior proposal<br />

is available, or an intervening event makes <strong>the</strong> transaction<br />

impossible to recommend in compliance with <strong>the</strong> target's<br />

fiduciary duties. Here, by contrast, Grupo Mexico faced<br />

no such risk of a competing superior proposal because it<br />

controlled Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> fiduciary out<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee negotiated for in <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

agreement provided only that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee could<br />

change its recommendation in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger, not that<br />

it could terminate <strong>the</strong> Merger altoge<strong>the</strong>r or avoid a vote on<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger. The only utility <strong>the</strong>refore of <strong>the</strong> recommendation<br />

provision was if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee seriously considered<br />

<strong>the</strong> events between <strong>the</strong> time of signing <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> stockholder<br />

vote <strong>and</strong> made a renewed determination of whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> deal<br />

was fair. There is no evidence of such a serious examination,<br />

despite important emerging evidence that <strong>the</strong> transaction's<br />

terms were skewed in favor of Grupo Mexico.<br />

P. Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's Stockholders Approve The Merger<br />

On March 28, 2005, <strong>the</strong> stockholders of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru voted<br />

to approve <strong>the</strong> Merger. More than 90% of <strong>the</strong> stockholders<br />

voted in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger. The Merger <strong>the</strong>n closed on<br />

April 1, 2005. At <strong>the</strong> time of closing, 67.2 million shares of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru had a market value of $3.75 billion. 65<br />

Q. Cerro Sells Its Shares<br />

On June 15, 2005, Cerro, which had a basis in its stock<br />

of only $1.32 per share, sold its entire interest in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru in an underwritten offering at $40.635 per share. Cerro<br />

sold its stock at a discount to <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n-current market price,<br />

as <strong>the</strong> low-high trading prices for one day before <strong>the</strong> sale<br />

were $43.08 to $44.10 per share. This illustrates Cerro's<br />

problematic incentives.<br />

R. The Plaintiff Sues The Defendants<br />

And The Special Committee<br />

This derivative suit challenging <strong>the</strong> Merger, first filed in late<br />

2004, moved too slowly, <strong>and</strong> it was not until June 30, 2010<br />

that <strong>the</strong> plaintiff moved for summary judgment. 66 On August<br />

10, 2010, <strong>the</strong> defendants filed a cross-motion for summary<br />

judgment, or in <strong>the</strong> alternative, to shift <strong>the</strong> burden of proof<br />

to <strong>the</strong> plaintiff under <strong>the</strong> entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard. On August<br />

11, 2010, <strong>the</strong> individual Special Committee defendants crossmoved<br />

for summary judgment on all claims under Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's exculpatory provision adopted under 8 Del. C. § 102(b)<br />

(7). At a hearing held on December 21, 2010, I dismissed<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee defendants from <strong>the</strong> case because <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiff had failed to present evidence supporting a nonexculpated<br />

breach of <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary duty of loyalty, <strong>and</strong> I<br />

denied all o<strong>the</strong>r motions for summary judgment. This, of<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 15


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

course, did not mean that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee had acted<br />

adroitly or that <strong>the</strong> remaining defendants, Grupo Mexico <strong>and</strong><br />

its affiliates, were immune from liability.<br />

In contrast to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee defendants, precisely<br />

because <strong>the</strong> remaining directors were employed by Grupo<br />

Mexico, which had a self-dealing interest directly in conflict<br />

with Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, <strong>the</strong> *786 exculpatory charter provision<br />

was of no benefit to <strong>the</strong>m at that stage, given <strong>the</strong> factual<br />

question regarding <strong>the</strong>ir motivations. At trial, <strong>the</strong>se individual<br />

Grupo Mexico-affiliated director defendants made no effort<br />

to show that <strong>the</strong>y acted in good faith <strong>and</strong> were entitled<br />

to exculpation despite <strong>the</strong>ir lack of independence. In o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

words, <strong>the</strong> Grupo Mexico-affiliated directors did nothing<br />

to distinguish each o<strong>the</strong>r <strong>and</strong> none of <strong>the</strong>m argued that he<br />

should not bear liability for breach of <strong>the</strong> duty of loyalty if<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction was unfairly advantageous to Grupo Mexico,<br />

which had a direct self-dealing interest in <strong>the</strong> Merger. Their<br />

liability <strong>the</strong>refore rises or falls with <strong>the</strong> issue of fairness. 67<br />

In dismissing <strong>the</strong> Special Committee members on <strong>the</strong><br />

summary judgment record, I necessarily treated <strong>the</strong><br />

predicament faced by Cerro <strong>and</strong> H<strong>and</strong>elsman, which<br />

involved facing additional economic pressures as a minority<br />

stockholder as a result of Grupo Mexico's control, differently<br />

than a classic self-dealing interest. I continue, as you will<br />

see, to hold that view. Although I believe that Cerro, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>refore H<strong>and</strong>elsman, were influenced by Cerro's desire for<br />

liquidity as a stockholder, it seems to me counterproductive<br />

to equate a legitimate concern of a stockholder for liquidity<br />

from a controller into a self-dealing interest. 68 I <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

concluded that <strong>the</strong>re had to be a triable issue regarding<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r H<strong>and</strong>elsman acted in subjective bad faith to force<br />

him to trial. I concluded <strong>the</strong>n on that record that no such issue<br />

of fact existed <strong>and</strong> even on <strong>the</strong> fuller trial record (where <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiff actually made much more of an effort to pursue this<br />

angle), I still could not find that H<strong>and</strong>elsman acted in bad faith<br />

to purposely accept an unfair deal. But Cerro, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman, did have <strong>the</strong> sort of economic concern that<br />

ideally should have been addressed upfront <strong>and</strong> forthrightly<br />

in terms of whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> stockholder's interest well positioned<br />

its representative to serve on a special committee. Put simply,<br />

although I continue to be unpersuaded that one can *787<br />

label H<strong>and</strong>elsman as having acted with <strong>the</strong> state of mind<br />

required to expose him to liability given <strong>the</strong> exculpatory<br />

charter protection to which he is entitled, I am persuaded that<br />

Cerro's desire to sell influenced how H<strong>and</strong>elsman approached<br />

his duties <strong>and</strong> compromised his effectiveness.<br />

III. Legal Analysis<br />

A. The St<strong>and</strong>ard Of Review Is Entire Fairness<br />

[4] Consistent with <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court's decision in Kahn<br />

v. Tremont, both <strong>the</strong> plaintiff <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> defendants agree<br />

that <strong>the</strong> appropriate st<strong>and</strong>ard of review for <strong>the</strong> Merger is<br />

entire fairness, regardless of <strong>the</strong> existence of <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee. 69 Given this agreement, <strong>the</strong>re is no need to<br />

consider whe<strong>the</strong>r room is open under our law for use of<br />

<strong>the</strong> business judgment rule st<strong>and</strong>ard in a circumstance like<br />

this, if <strong>the</strong> transaction were conditioned upon <strong>the</strong> use of a<br />

combination of sufficiently protective procedural devices. 70<br />

Absent some argument by a party to that effect, judicial<br />

restraint counsels my accepting <strong>the</strong> parties' framework.<br />

Where, as here, a controlling stockholder st<strong>and</strong>s on both sides<br />

of a transaction, <strong>the</strong> interested defendants are “required to<br />

demonstrate <strong>the</strong>ir utmost good faith <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> most scrupulous<br />

inherent fairness of <strong>the</strong> bargain.” 71 In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants with a conflicting self-interest must demonstrate<br />

that <strong>the</strong> deal was entirely fair to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r stockholders. 72<br />

[5] The entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard is well-known <strong>and</strong> has “two<br />

basic aspects” of fairness: process (“fair dealing”) <strong>and</strong> price<br />

(“fair price”). 73 As explained by our Supreme Court, fair<br />

dealing “embraces questions of when <strong>the</strong> transaction was<br />

timed, how it was initiated, structured, negotiated, disclosed<br />

to <strong>the</strong> directors, <strong>and</strong> how <strong>the</strong> *788 approvals of <strong>the</strong> directors<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> stockholders were obtained,” <strong>and</strong> fair price “relates<br />

to <strong>the</strong> economic <strong>and</strong> financial considerations of <strong>the</strong> proposed<br />

merger, including all relevant factors: assets, market value,<br />

earnings, future prospects, <strong>and</strong> any o<strong>the</strong>r elements that affect<br />

<strong>the</strong> intrinsic or inherent value of a company's stock.” 74<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> concept of entire fairness has two components,<br />

<strong>the</strong> entire fairness analysis is not bifurcated. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> court<br />

“determines entire fairness based on all aspects of <strong>the</strong> entire<br />

transaction.” 75 Our Supreme Court has recognized, however,<br />

that, at least in non-fraudulent transactions, “price may be <strong>the</strong><br />

preponderant consideration....” 76 That is, although evidence<br />

of fair dealing may help demonstrate <strong>the</strong> fairness of <strong>the</strong> price<br />

obtained, what ultimately matters most is that <strong>the</strong> price was<br />

a fair one. 77<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 16


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

Of course, under our law, <strong>the</strong> defendants may shift <strong>the</strong> burden<br />

of persuasion on entire fairness to <strong>the</strong> plaintiff in certain<br />

circumstances. I now turn to <strong>the</strong> defendants' arguments about<br />

that issue.<br />

B. Are The Defendants Entitled To<br />

Shift The Burden Of Persuasion?<br />

[6] Having served as a trial judge for many years now,<br />

it is with some chagrin that I admit that I tried this case<br />

without determining in advance which side had <strong>the</strong> burden<br />

of persuasion. But I did not do so lightly. Under <strong>the</strong><br />

Lynch doctrine, 78 when <strong>the</strong> entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard applies,<br />

controlling stockholders can never escape entire fairness<br />

review, 79 but <strong>the</strong>y may shift <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion by<br />

one of two means: <strong>the</strong>y may show that <strong>the</strong> transaction was<br />

approved ei<strong>the</strong>r by an independent board majority (or in <strong>the</strong><br />

alternative, a special committee of independent directors)<br />

or, assuming certain conditions, by an informed vote of <strong>the</strong><br />

majority of <strong>the</strong> minority shareholders. 80<br />

1. Is The Burden Shifted Because<br />

Of The Special Committee Process?<br />

In this case, <strong>the</strong> defendants filed a summary judgment motion<br />

arguing that <strong>the</strong> *789 Special Committee process was<br />

entitled to dignity under Lynch <strong>and</strong> shifted <strong>the</strong> burden of<br />

persuasion under <strong>the</strong> preponderance st<strong>and</strong>ard to <strong>the</strong> plaintiff. I<br />

found <strong>the</strong> summary judgment record insufficient to determine<br />

that question for <strong>the</strong> following reason.<br />

Lynch <strong>and</strong> its progeny leave doubt in my mind about what<br />

is required of a Special Committee to obtain a burden shift.<br />

For <strong>the</strong>ir part, <strong>the</strong> defendants argue that what is required<br />

is a special committee comprised of independent directors<br />

who selected independent advisors <strong>and</strong> who had <strong>the</strong> ability<br />

to negotiate <strong>and</strong> reject a transaction. This is, of course,<br />

consistent with what one would expect in determining a<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of review that would actually be used in deciding<br />

a case. By contrast, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff stresses that only an<br />

effective special committee operates to shift <strong>the</strong> burden of<br />

persuasion, 81 <strong>and</strong> that a factual determination must be made<br />

regarding whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> special committee in fact operated with<br />

<strong>the</strong> degree of ardor <strong>and</strong> skill one would have expected of an<br />

arms-length negotiator with true bargaining power.<br />

[7] To my mind, which has pondered <strong>the</strong> relevant cases for<br />

many years, <strong>the</strong>re remains confusion. In <strong>the</strong> most relevant<br />

case, Tremont, <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court clearly said that to obtain<br />

a burden shift, however slight those benefits may be, 82<br />

<strong>the</strong> special committee must “function in a manner which<br />

indicates that <strong>the</strong> controlling shareholder did not dictate <strong>the</strong><br />

terms of <strong>the</strong> transaction <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> committee exercised<br />

real bargaining power ‘at an arms-length.’ ” 83 A close look<br />

at Tremont suggests that <strong>the</strong> inquiry must focus on how<br />

<strong>the</strong> special committee actually negotiated <strong>the</strong> deal—was it<br />

“well functioning” 84 —ra<strong>the</strong>r than just how <strong>the</strong> committee<br />

was set up. 85 The test, <strong>the</strong>refore, seems to contemplate<br />

a look back at <strong>the</strong> substance, <strong>and</strong> efficacy, of <strong>the</strong> special<br />

committee's negotiations, ra<strong>the</strong>r than just a look at <strong>the</strong><br />

composition <strong>and</strong> m<strong>and</strong>ate of <strong>the</strong> special committee. 86 That<br />

interpretation is confirmed by a closer look at <strong>the</strong> Supreme<br />

Court's treatment of <strong>the</strong> factors that <strong>the</strong> *790 Court found<br />

indicated that <strong>the</strong> special committee “did not operate in<br />

an independent or informed manner....” 87 Although <strong>the</strong><br />

notion of an “independent” <strong>and</strong> “informed manner” might<br />

suggest that <strong>the</strong> only relevant factors to that inquiry are<br />

those that speak to <strong>the</strong> special committee's ties with <strong>the</strong><br />

controlling stockholder (i.e., its independence) <strong>and</strong> its ability<br />

to retain independent advisors <strong>and</strong> say no, <strong>the</strong> majority <strong>and</strong><br />

concurring decisions in Tremont seem to reveal that was not<br />

<strong>the</strong> approach taken by <strong>the</strong> Court. Tremont seems to focus<br />

both on indicia of independence <strong>and</strong> indicia of procedural <strong>and</strong><br />

even substantive fairness. For example, <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court<br />

found problematic <strong>the</strong> supposedly outside directors' previous<br />

business relationships with <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder that<br />

resulted in significant financial compensation or influential<br />

board positions 88 <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir selection of advisors who were in<br />

some capacity affiliated with <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder, 89<br />

both of which are factors that speak to <strong>the</strong> special committee's<br />

facial independence.<br />

But, <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court also seems to call into question <strong>the</strong><br />

substance of <strong>the</strong> special committee's actual efforts, noting<br />

<strong>the</strong> special committee directors' heavy reliance on projections<br />

prepared by <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder, 90 <strong>the</strong>ir perfunctory<br />

effort at scheduling <strong>and</strong> attending committee meetings, 91<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> limitation on <strong>the</strong> exchange of ideas that resulted<br />

from <strong>the</strong> directors' failure to fully participate in an active<br />

process. 92<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 17


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

Judge Quillen's concurring opinion 93 most clearly<br />

contemplates a focus on both indicia of independence <strong>and</strong><br />

indicia of substantive fairness in <strong>the</strong> negotiation process.<br />

In confirming <strong>the</strong> majority's ruling to deny <strong>the</strong> defendants<br />

<strong>the</strong> benefit of <strong>the</strong> burden shift, Judge Quillen begins by<br />

reviewing <strong>the</strong> special committee's ties to <strong>the</strong> controlling<br />

stockholder <strong>and</strong> its selection of questionable advisors (i.e.,<br />

factors that could be applied early in a case to determine<br />

<strong>the</strong> burden allocation), but <strong>the</strong>n he moves into a discussion<br />

where he points to deficiencies in <strong>the</strong> substance of <strong>the</strong> special<br />

committee's negotiations, which cannot in any easy way be<br />

separated from an examination of fairness. The concurrence<br />

questions <strong>the</strong> special committee's failure to take advantage<br />

of certain opportunities to exert leverage over <strong>the</strong> controlling<br />

stockholder 94 as well as its failure to negotiate <strong>the</strong> price of<br />

<strong>the</strong> stock purchase downward when <strong>the</strong>re was indicia of price<br />

manipulation, *791 95 when <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder's<br />

chief negotiator knew that <strong>the</strong> stock was worth less than<br />

<strong>the</strong> market, 96<br />

<strong>and</strong> when <strong>the</strong> target's stock price dropped<br />

precipitously before <strong>the</strong> date of signing. 97 The concurrence<br />

also questions <strong>the</strong> ultimate fairness of <strong>the</strong> price <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

terms agreed to by <strong>the</strong> special committee, noting that <strong>the</strong><br />

substance of <strong>the</strong> negotiations is “not self-verifying on <strong>the</strong><br />

independence issue.” 98 These references in <strong>the</strong> concurrence<br />

echo <strong>the</strong> majority opinion itself, which uses phrases like “real<br />

bargaining power” 99 <strong>and</strong> “well functioning” 100 to describe<br />

what is required of <strong>the</strong> special committee to merit a burden<br />

shift, which seem to get at whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> special committee<br />

in fact simulated <strong>the</strong> role that a third-party with negotiating<br />

power would have played. 101 Thus, to my mind, Tremont<br />

implies that <strong>the</strong>re is no way to decide whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> defendant<br />

is entitled to a burden shift without taking into consideration<br />

<strong>the</strong> substantive decisions of <strong>the</strong> special committee, a factintensive<br />

exercise that overlaps with <strong>the</strong> examination of<br />

fairness itself.<br />

As a trial judge, I note several problems with such<br />

an approach. Assuming that <strong>the</strong> purpose of providing a<br />

burden shift is not only to encourage <strong>the</strong> use of special<br />

committees, 102 but also to provide a reliable pre-trial guide<br />

to <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion, 103 <strong>the</strong> factors that give rise to<br />

<strong>the</strong> burden shift must be determinable early in <strong>the</strong> litigation<br />

<strong>and</strong> not so deeply enmeshed in <strong>the</strong> ultimate fairness analysis.<br />

Thus, factors like <strong>the</strong> independence of <strong>the</strong> committee <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> adequacy of its m<strong>and</strong>ates (i.e., was it given blocking <strong>and</strong><br />

negotiating power) would be <strong>the</strong> trigger for <strong>the</strong> burden shift.<br />

Because <strong>the</strong> only effect of <strong>the</strong> burden shift is to make <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiff prove unfairness under a preponderance st<strong>and</strong>ard,<br />

<strong>the</strong> benefits of clarity in terms of trial presentation <strong>and</strong> for<br />

<strong>the</strong> formation of special committees would seem to outweigh<br />

<strong>the</strong> costs of such an upfront approach focusing on structural<br />

independence. To be clear, such an allocation would still<br />

allow <strong>the</strong> plaintiff to go to trial so long as <strong>the</strong>re was a triable<br />

issue regarding fairness. Fur<strong>the</strong>r, *792 because <strong>the</strong> burden<br />

becomes relevant only when a judge is rooted on <strong>the</strong> fence<br />

post <strong>and</strong> thus in equipoise, it is not certain that <strong>the</strong>re is really<br />

a cost. 104<br />

By contrast, <strong>the</strong> alternative approach leads to situations like<br />

this <strong>and</strong> Tremont itself, where <strong>the</strong> burden of proof has<br />

to be determined during <strong>the</strong> trial, <strong>and</strong> where that burden<br />

determination is enmeshed in <strong>the</strong> substantive merits. 105 As<br />

a trial judge, I take very seriously <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard of review<br />

as a prism through which to determine a case. When a<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard of review does not function as such, it is not clear<br />

what utility it has, <strong>and</strong> it adds costs <strong>and</strong> complication to<br />

<strong>the</strong> already expensive <strong>and</strong> difficult process of complex civil<br />

litigation. 106 Subsuming within <strong>the</strong> burden shift analysis<br />

questions of whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> special committee was substantively<br />

effective in its negotiations with <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder<br />

—questions fraught with factual complexity—will, absent<br />

unique circumstances, guarantee that <strong>the</strong> burden shift will<br />

rarely be determinable on <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>the</strong> pre-trial record<br />

alone. 107 If we take seriously <strong>the</strong> notion, as I do, that<br />

a st<strong>and</strong>ard of review is meant to serve as <strong>the</strong> framework<br />

through which <strong>the</strong> court evaluates <strong>the</strong> parties' evidence <strong>and</strong><br />

trial testimony in reaching a decision, <strong>and</strong>, as important, <strong>the</strong><br />

framework through which <strong>the</strong> litigants determine how best<br />

to prepare <strong>the</strong>ir cases for trial, 108 it is problematic to *793<br />

adopt an analytical approach whereby <strong>the</strong> burden allocation<br />

can only be determined in a post-trial opinion, after all <strong>the</strong><br />

evidence <strong>and</strong> all <strong>the</strong> arguments have been presented to <strong>the</strong><br />

court. 109<br />

But, I am constrained to adhere faithfully to Tremont as<br />

written, <strong>and</strong> I read it <strong>and</strong> some of its progeny 110 as requiring<br />

a factual look at <strong>the</strong> actual effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> special<br />

committee before awarding a burden shift. For that reason,<br />

I will, as you will see, find that <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion<br />

remained with <strong>the</strong> defendants, because <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

was not “well functioning.” 111 And I will also find, however,<br />

that this determination matters little because I am not stuck in<br />

equipoise about <strong>the</strong> issue of fairness. Regardless of who bears<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 18


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

<strong>the</strong> burden, I conclude that <strong>the</strong> Merger was unfair to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru <strong>and</strong> its stockholders.<br />

2. Did The Burden Of Persuasion Shift<br />

Because Of The Stockholder Vote?<br />

[8] With much less passion, <strong>the</strong> defendants also seek to<br />

obtain a burden shift by arguing that <strong>the</strong> Merger ultimately<br />

received super-majority support of <strong>the</strong> stockholders o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than Grupo Mexico, <strong>and</strong> a majority support of <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholders excluding all of <strong>the</strong> Founding Stockholders.<br />

The defendants have failed to earn a burden shift for <strong>the</strong><br />

following reasons. First, in a situation where <strong>the</strong> entire<br />

fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard applies because <strong>the</strong> vote is controlled by an<br />

interested stockholder, any burden-shifting should not depend<br />

on <strong>the</strong> after-<strong>the</strong>-fact vote result but should instead require that<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction has been conditioned up-front on <strong>the</strong> approval<br />

of a majority of <strong>the</strong> disinterested stockholders. Chancellor<br />

Ch<strong>and</strong>ler, in his Rabkin v. Olin Corp. decision, 112 took that<br />

view <strong>and</strong> was affirmed by our Supreme Court, <strong>and</strong> it remains<br />

sound to me in this context. 113 It is a very different thing<br />

for *794 stockholders to know that <strong>the</strong>ir vote is in fact<br />

meaningful <strong>and</strong> to have a genuine chance to disapprove a<br />

transaction than it is to be told, as <strong>the</strong>y were in this case, that<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction required a two-thirds vote, which would be<br />

satisfied certainly because Grupo Mexico, Cerro, <strong>and</strong> Phelps<br />

Dodge had <strong>the</strong> voting power to satisfy that condition <strong>and</strong> were<br />

clearly intent on voting yes. 114 In <strong>the</strong> latter situation, <strong>the</strong> vote<br />

has little meaning except as a form of protest, especially in a<br />

situation like this when <strong>the</strong>re were no appraisal rights because<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was <strong>the</strong> buyer.<br />

Second, <strong>the</strong> defendants have not met <strong>the</strong>ir burden to show<br />

that <strong>the</strong> vote was fully informed. 115 The Proxy Statement<br />

left out a material step in <strong>the</strong> negotiation process, to wit,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee's July counteroffer, offering to give<br />

Grupo Mexico only $2.095 billion worth of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

stock for Minera in response to Grupo Mexico's ask of<br />

$3.1 billion in its May 7, 2004 term sheet. What lends<br />

credibility to this counteroffer is that it was made after <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee's July 8, 2004 meeting with Goldman,<br />

where Goldman had presented to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

Minera's operating projections, metal price forecasts, <strong>and</strong><br />

o<strong>the</strong>r valuation metrics. After reviewing this information,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee was still $1 billion short of Grupo<br />

Mexico's ask with an offer that was at <strong>the</strong> high end of<br />

Minera's st<strong>and</strong>alone value but at <strong>the</strong> low end of its “relative”<br />

value. 116 This step showed how deep <strong>the</strong> value gap was<br />

in real cash terms. The minority stockholders were being<br />

asked to make an important voting decision 117 about an<br />

acquisition that would nearly double <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> <strong>Company</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> materially increase <strong>the</strong> equity stake of <strong>the</strong> controlling<br />

*795 stockholder 118 —<strong>the</strong>y should have been informed of<br />

<strong>the</strong> value that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee placed on Minera at<br />

a point in <strong>the</strong> negotiations when it had sufficient financial<br />

information to make a serious offer.<br />

That omission combines with less than materially clear<br />

disclosure about <strong>the</strong> method by which Goldman concluded<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger was fair. In particular, <strong>the</strong> Proxy Statement did<br />

not disclose <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>alone implied equity values for Minera<br />

generated by <strong>the</strong> DCF analyses performed in June 2004 <strong>and</strong><br />

July 2004, which look sound <strong>and</strong> generated mid-range values<br />

of Minera that were far less than what Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was<br />

paying in <strong>the</strong> Merger, 119 nor did it disclose <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>alone<br />

implied equity values of ei<strong>the</strong>r Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru or Minera<br />

that were implied by <strong>the</strong> inputs used in Goldman's relative<br />

DCF analysis underlying <strong>the</strong> fairness opinion. 120 The Proxy<br />

Statement thus obscured <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> implied equity value<br />

of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru that Goldman used to anchor <strong>the</strong> relative<br />

valuation of Minera was nearly $2 billion less than Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's actual market equity value at <strong>the</strong> time of signing. 121<br />

There were additional obscurities in connection with <strong>the</strong><br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru multiples that Goldman used to support its<br />

fairness opinion.<br />

The Proxy Statement did disclose that Minera was valued<br />

using multiples tied to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's own multiples,<br />

although it was less than clear as to what those multiples<br />

were. The Proxy Statement listed a Wall Street consensus<br />

EV/2005E EBITDA multiple for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru of 5.5x in<br />

Goldman's comparable companies chart, 122 but it did not<br />

disclose <strong>the</strong> full range of EV/2005E EBITDA multiples for<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru that Goldman actually used in its contribution<br />

analysis to justify <strong>the</strong> fairness of <strong>the</strong> relative valuation. The<br />

bottom of <strong>the</strong> range was 5.6x, or Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's EV/2005E<br />

multiple listed in <strong>the</strong> comparable companies analysis as<br />

apparently adjusted for <strong>the</strong> dividend, which itself was much<br />

higher than <strong>the</strong> median comparable companies multiple,<br />

which was listed at 4.8x 123 <strong>and</strong> critically absent from<br />

this generous bottom of <strong>the</strong> contribution analysis. *796<br />

The range of multiples <strong>the</strong>n proceeded northward, to 6.3x,<br />

6.4x, <strong>and</strong> 6.5x, with a median of 6.4x. 124 These inflated<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 19


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

multiples were based not on real market metrics, but on<br />

various scenarios using Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's internal pessimistic<br />

projections for its 2005E EBITDA. 125 By failing to disclose<br />

<strong>the</strong> full range of multiples used in <strong>the</strong> contribution analysis,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Proxy obscured <strong>the</strong> fact that only <strong>the</strong>se inflated multiples<br />

would justify an issuance of over 67 million shares in<br />

exchange for Minera, 126 multiples that were nearly 33%<br />

higher than <strong>the</strong> Wall Street consensus median multiple of<br />

<strong>the</strong> comparable companies used by Goldman for 2005, 127<br />

<strong>and</strong> 16% higher than <strong>the</strong> Wall Street consensus multiple for<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. 128<br />

Moreover, Grupo Mexico went on a road show to its<br />

investors, bankers, <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r members of <strong>the</strong> financial<br />

community in November 2004 to garner support for <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger, during which Grupo Mexico presented materials<br />

stating that a “Key Term” of <strong>the</strong> Merger was that <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

implied a Minera EV/2005E EBITDA of 5.6x. 129 This 5.6x<br />

multiple was derived from an enterprise value for Minera that<br />

itself was calculated by multiplying <strong>the</strong> 67.2 million shares<br />

to be issued by Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru by <strong>the</strong> stock price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru as of October 21, 2004, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n adding Minera's debt.<br />

This calculation obscures <strong>the</strong> fact that in order to justify<br />

<strong>the</strong> fairness of <strong>the</strong> 67.2 million share issuance in <strong>the</strong> first<br />

place, Goldman's fairness presentation did not rely on a 5.6x<br />

multiple, but a much higher median multiple of 6.4x. 130<br />

Also, <strong>the</strong> assumptions behind <strong>the</strong> road show's advertised 5.6x<br />

multiple were not consistent with <strong>the</strong> assumptions underlying<br />

Goldman's financial opinion. Namely, Grupo Mexico was<br />

able to “employ” (to use a non-loaded term) a Wall Street<br />

consensus multiple only by inflating Minera's estimated 2005<br />

EBITDA over what had been used in <strong>the</strong> Goldman fairness<br />

analysis, 131 a feat *797 accomplished by assuming a higher<br />

copper production than <strong>the</strong> production figures provided by<br />

<strong>the</strong> A & S adjusted projections as well as Minera's own<br />

unadjusted projections, both of which Goldman used in its<br />

final presentation to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee. 132 Put bluntly,<br />

Grupo Mexico went out to investors with information that<br />

made <strong>the</strong> total mix of information available to stockholders<br />

materially misleading.<br />

For <strong>the</strong>se reasons, I do not believe a burden shift because of<br />

<strong>the</strong> stockholder vote is appropriate, <strong>and</strong> in any event, even if<br />

<strong>the</strong> vote shifted <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion, it would not change<br />

<strong>the</strong> outcome I reach.<br />

C. Was The Merger Entirely Fair?<br />

[9] Whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> Merger was fair is <strong>the</strong> question that I now<br />

answer.<br />

I find, for <strong>the</strong> following reasons, that <strong>the</strong> process by which <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger was negotiated <strong>and</strong> approved was not fair <strong>and</strong> did not<br />

result in <strong>the</strong> payment of a fair price. Because questions as to<br />

fair process <strong>and</strong> fair price are so intertwined in this case, I do<br />

not break <strong>the</strong>m out separately, but ra<strong>the</strong>r treat <strong>the</strong>m toge<strong>the</strong>r<br />

in an integrated discussion.<br />

1. The Special Committee Gets Lost In<br />

The Perspective–Distorting World Of<br />

Dealmaking With A Controlling Stockholder<br />

I start my analysis of fairness with an acknowledgement.<br />

With one exception, which I will discuss, <strong>the</strong> independence<br />

of <strong>the</strong> members of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee has not been<br />

challenged by <strong>the</strong> plaintiff. The Special Committee members<br />

were competent, well-qualified individuals with business<br />

experience. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee was given <strong>the</strong><br />

resources to hire outside advisors, <strong>and</strong> it hired not only<br />

respected, top tier of <strong>the</strong> market financial <strong>and</strong> legal counsel,<br />

but also a mining consultant <strong>and</strong> Mexican counsel. Despite<br />

having been let down by <strong>the</strong>ir advisors in terms of record<br />

keeping, <strong>the</strong>re is little question but that <strong>the</strong> members of <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee met frequently. Their h<strong>and</strong>s were on <strong>the</strong><br />

oars. So why <strong>the</strong>n did <strong>the</strong>ir boat go, if anywhere, backward?<br />

This is a story that is, I fear, not new.<br />

From <strong>the</strong> get-go, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee extracted a narrow<br />

m<strong>and</strong>ate, to “evaluate” a transaction suggested by <strong>the</strong><br />

majority stockholder. 133 Although I conclude that <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee did in fact go fur<strong>the</strong>r <strong>and</strong> engage in<br />

negotiations, its approach to negotiations was stilted <strong>and</strong><br />

influenced by its uncertainty about whe<strong>the</strong>r it was actually<br />

empowered to negotiate. The testimony on <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee members' underst<strong>and</strong>ing of <strong>the</strong>ir m<strong>and</strong>ate, for<br />

example, evidenced <strong>the</strong>ir lack of certainty about whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee could do more than just evaluate <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. 134<br />

*798 Thus, from inception, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee fell<br />

victim to a controlled mindset <strong>and</strong> allowed Grupo Mexico<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 20


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

to dictate <strong>the</strong> terms <strong>and</strong> structure of <strong>the</strong> Merger. The Special<br />

Committee did not insist on <strong>the</strong> right to look at alternatives;<br />

ra<strong>the</strong>r, it accepted that only one type of transaction was on<br />

<strong>the</strong> table, a purchase of Minera by Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. As we shall<br />

see, this acceptance influences my ultimate determination of<br />

fairness, as it took off <strong>the</strong> table o<strong>the</strong>r options that would have<br />

generated a real market check <strong>and</strong> also deprived <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee of negotiating leverage to extract better terms.<br />

With this blinkered perspective, <strong>the</strong> first level of<br />

rationalization often begins. For Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, like most<br />

companies, it is good to have growth options. Was it rational<br />

to think that combining Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera might be<br />

such a growth option, if Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stronger balance<br />

sheet <strong>and</strong> operating capabilities could be brought to bear on<br />

Minera? Sure. And if no o<strong>the</strong>r opportunities are available<br />

because we are a controlled company, shouldn't we make<br />

<strong>the</strong> best of this chance? Already, <strong>the</strong> mindset has taken a<br />

dangerous path. 135<br />

The predicament of H<strong>and</strong>elsman helps to illustrate this<br />

point. Clearly, from <strong>the</strong> weak m<strong>and</strong>ate it extracted <strong>and</strong> its<br />

failure to push for <strong>the</strong> chance to look at o<strong>the</strong>r alternatives,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee viewed itself as dealing with a<br />

majority stockholder, Grupo Mexico, that would seek its own<br />

advantage. H<strong>and</strong>elsman, as a key representative of Cerro,<br />

was even more susceptible to Grupo Mexico's dominion,<br />

precisely because Cerro wanted to be free of its position as<br />

a minority stockholder in Grupo Mexico-controlled Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru. Although I am chary to conclude that <strong>the</strong> desire of a<br />

stockholder to be able to sell its shares like o<strong>the</strong>r holders is<br />

<strong>the</strong> kind of self-dealing interest that should deem someone<br />

like H<strong>and</strong>elsman interested in <strong>the</strong> Merger, 136 H<strong>and</strong>elsman<br />

was operating under a constraint that was not shared by<br />

all stockholders, which was his employer's desire to sell<br />

its holdings in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. 137 *799 It follows that<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman may not have been solely focused on paying <strong>the</strong><br />

best price in <strong>the</strong> Merger (even though all things being equal,<br />

Cerro, like any stockholder, would want <strong>the</strong> best possible<br />

price) because he had independent reasons for approving <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. That is, as between a Merger <strong>and</strong> no Merger at all,<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman had an interest in favoring <strong>the</strong> deal because it<br />

was clear from <strong>the</strong> outset that Grupo Mexico was using <strong>the</strong><br />

prospect of causing Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru to grant registration rights<br />

to Cerro (<strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge) as an inducement to get <strong>the</strong>m<br />

to agree to <strong>the</strong> Merger. 138 Thus, H<strong>and</strong>elsman was not wellincentivized<br />

to take a hard-line position on what terms <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee would be willing to accept, because as a<br />

stockholder over whom Grupo Mexico was exerting ano<strong>the</strong>r<br />

form of pressure, he faced <strong>the</strong> temptation to find a way to<br />

make <strong>the</strong> deal work at a sub-optimal price if that would<br />

facilitate liquidity for his stockholding employer. 139<br />

I thus face <strong>the</strong> question of whe<strong>the</strong>r Cerro's liquidity concern<br />

<strong>and</strong> short-term interests—ones not shared with <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong><br />

non-founding minority stockholders—should have disabled<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman from playing any role in <strong>the</strong> negotiation process.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> one h<strong>and</strong>, Cerro's sale of a majority of its shares<br />

at below market price shortly after it obtained registration<br />

rights suggests that its interest in liquidity likely dampened<br />

its concern for achieving a fair price for its shares, especially<br />

given its low tax basis in <strong>the</strong> shares. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r h<strong>and</strong>, as<br />

a large blocholder representative <strong>and</strong> experienced M & A<br />

practitioner, H<strong>and</strong>elsman had knowledge <strong>and</strong> an employer<br />

with an economic investment that in o<strong>the</strong>r respects made<br />

him a valuable Special Committee member. After hearing<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman's testimony at trial, I cannot conclude that he<br />

consciously acted in less than good faith. H<strong>and</strong>elsman was not<br />

in any way in Grupo Mexico's pocket, <strong>and</strong> I do not believe that<br />

he purposely tanked <strong>the</strong> negotiations. But, Cerro's important<br />

liquidity concern had <strong>the</strong> undeniable effect of extinguishing<br />

much of <strong>the</strong> appetite that one of <strong>the</strong> key negotiators of <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger had to say no. Saying no meant no liquidity.<br />

Likewise, Cerro had no intent of sticking around to benefit<br />

from <strong>the</strong> long-term benefits of <strong>the</strong> Merger, <strong>and</strong> thus<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman was in an odd place to recommend to o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

stockholders to make a long-term strategic acquisition. In<br />

sum, when all <strong>the</strong>se factors are considered, H<strong>and</strong>elsman<br />

was not <strong>the</strong> ideal c<strong>and</strong>idate to serve as <strong>the</strong> “defender of<br />

interests of minority shareholders *800 in <strong>the</strong> dynamics<br />

of fast moving negotiations.” 140 The fact that <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee's investment bankers pointed out <strong>the</strong> pickle he was<br />

in late in <strong>the</strong> game <strong>and</strong> that H<strong>and</strong>elsman abstained from voting<br />

fail to address this concern because <strong>the</strong> deal was already fully<br />

negotiated with H<strong>and</strong>elsman's active involvement.<br />

To my mind, <strong>the</strong> more important point that H<strong>and</strong>elsman's<br />

predicament makes plain is <strong>the</strong> narrow prism through which<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee viewed <strong>the</strong>ir role <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir available<br />

options. For example, consider <strong>the</strong> misalignment between<br />

Cerro's interest in selling its equity position in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

as soon as possible <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> Merger was billed<br />

as a long-term, strategic acquisition for <strong>the</strong> company. What<br />

would have been an obvious solution to this mismatch of<br />

interests—where both Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge wanted to get<br />

out of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> where Grupo Mexico wanted to<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 21


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

stay in—would have been for <strong>the</strong> Special Committee to say<br />

to Grupo Mexico: “Why don't you buy Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, since<br />

you want to increase your equity ownership in this company<br />

<strong>and</strong> everyone else wants to get out?” This simple move<br />

would have immediately aligned <strong>the</strong> interests <strong>and</strong> investment<br />

horizons of Cerro <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> minority shareholders,<br />

thus positioning H<strong>and</strong>elsman as <strong>the</strong> ideal Special Committee<br />

c<strong>and</strong>idate with a maximized level of negotiating gusto. But,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee did not suggest such a transaction, nor<br />

did it even appear to cross <strong>the</strong> directors' mind as a possibility.<br />

Why was this so? Because <strong>the</strong> Special Committee was<br />

trapped in <strong>the</strong> controlled mindset, where <strong>the</strong> only options<br />

to be considered are those proposed by <strong>the</strong> controlling<br />

stockholder. 141 When a special committee confines itself<br />

to this world, it engages in <strong>the</strong> self-defeating practice<br />

of negotiating with itself—perhaps without even realizing<br />

it—through which it nixes certain options before even<br />

putting <strong>the</strong>m on <strong>the</strong> table. Even if <strong>the</strong> practical reality is<br />

that <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder has <strong>the</strong> power to reject<br />

any alternate proposal it does not support, <strong>the</strong> special<br />

committee still benefits from a full exploration of its<br />

options. What better way to “kick <strong>the</strong> tires” of <strong>the</strong> deal<br />

proposed by <strong>the</strong> self-interested controller than to explore<br />

what would be available to <strong>the</strong> company if it were not<br />

constrained by <strong>the</strong> controller's dem<strong>and</strong>s? Moreover, <strong>the</strong> very<br />

process of <strong>the</strong> special committee asking <strong>the</strong> controlling<br />

stockholder to consider alternative options can change <strong>the</strong><br />

negotiating dynamic. That is, when <strong>the</strong> special committee<br />

engages in a meaningful back-<strong>and</strong>-forth with <strong>the</strong> controlling<br />

stockholder to discuss <strong>the</strong> feasibility of alternate terms, <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee might discover certain weaknesses of<br />

<strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder, thus creating an opportunity for<br />

<strong>the</strong> committee to use this new-found negotiating leverage to<br />

extract benefits for <strong>the</strong> minority.<br />

Here, for instance, if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee had proposed to<br />

Grupo Mexico that it buy out Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru at a premium<br />

to its rising stock price, it would have opened up <strong>the</strong> deal<br />

dynamic in a way that gave <strong>the</strong> Special Committee leverage<br />

<strong>and</strong> that was consistent with <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's sense<br />

of <strong>the</strong> market. Perhaps Grupo Mexico would have been<br />

open to <strong>the</strong> prospect <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re would have been a valuable<br />

chance for all of <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stockholders to obtain<br />

liquidity at a premium to a Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru market price<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee saw as was high in comparison<br />

to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's fundamental value. At <strong>the</strong> very least, it<br />

would force *801 Grupo Mexico to explain why it—<strong>the</strong><br />

party that proposed putting <strong>the</strong>se assets toge<strong>the</strong>r under its<br />

continued control—could not itself be <strong>the</strong> buyer <strong>and</strong> finance<br />

such a transaction. Was that because it was cash-strapped <strong>and</strong><br />

dealing with serious debt problems, in part because Minera<br />

was struggling? If you need to be <strong>the</strong> seller, why? And why<br />

are you in a position to ask for a high price? If Minera is<br />

so attractive, why are you seeking to reduce your ownership<br />

interest in it? Part of <strong>the</strong> negotiation process involves probing<br />

<strong>and</strong> exposing weaknesses, <strong>and</strong> as a result putting <strong>the</strong> opponent<br />

back on his heels.<br />

In sum, although <strong>the</strong> Special Committee members were<br />

competent businessmen <strong>and</strong> may have had <strong>the</strong> best of<br />

intentions, <strong>the</strong>y allowed <strong>the</strong>mselves to be hemmed in<br />

by <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder's dem<strong>and</strong>s. Throughout <strong>the</strong><br />

negotiation process, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's <strong>and</strong> Goldman's<br />

focus was on finding a way to get <strong>the</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

structure proposed by Grupo Mexico to make sense, ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than aggressively testing <strong>the</strong> assumption that <strong>the</strong> Merger was<br />

a good idea in <strong>the</strong> first place.<br />

2. The Special Committee Could Never Justify The<br />

Merger Based On St<strong>and</strong>alone Valuations Of Minera<br />

This mindset problem is illustrated by what happened when<br />

Goldman could not value <strong>the</strong> “get”—Minera—anywhere near<br />

Grupo Mexico's asking price, <strong>the</strong> “give.” From a negotiating<br />

perspective, that should have signaled that a strong response<br />

to Grupo Mexico was necessary <strong>and</strong> incited some effort to<br />

broaden, not narrow, <strong>the</strong> lens. Instead, Goldman <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee went to strenuous lengths to equalize<br />

<strong>the</strong> values of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera. The onus should<br />

have been on Grupo Mexico to prove Minera was worth<br />

$3.1 billion, but instead of pushing back on Grupo Mexico's<br />

analysis, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee <strong>and</strong> Goldman devalued<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> topped up <strong>the</strong> value of Minera. The<br />

actions of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee <strong>and</strong> Goldman undermine<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants' argument that <strong>the</strong> process leading up to <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger was fair <strong>and</strong> lend credence to <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's contention<br />

that <strong>the</strong> process leading up to <strong>the</strong> Merger was an exercise in<br />

rationalization.<br />

The plaintiff argues that, ra<strong>the</strong>r than value Minera so as<br />

to obtain <strong>the</strong> best deal possible for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> its<br />

minority stockholders, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee “worked <strong>and</strong><br />

reworked” <strong>the</strong>ir approach to <strong>the</strong> Merger to meet Grupo<br />

Mexico's dem<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> rationalize paying Grupo Mexico's<br />

asking price. 142 The defendants concede that, before settling<br />

on relative valuation, Goldman performed a number of o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 22


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

financial analyses of Minera to determine its value, including<br />

a st<strong>and</strong>alone DCF analysis, a sum-of-<strong>the</strong>-parts analysis, a<br />

contribution analysis, comparable companies analysis <strong>and</strong><br />

an ore reserve analysis, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> results of all of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

analyses were substantially lower than Grupo Mexico's<br />

asking price of $3.1 billion.<br />

A reasonable special committee would not have taken <strong>the</strong><br />

results of those analyses by Goldman <strong>and</strong> bli<strong>the</strong>ly moved on<br />

to relative valuation, without any continuing <strong>and</strong> relentless<br />

focus on <strong>the</strong> actual give-get involved in real cash terms.<br />

But, this Special Committee was in <strong>the</strong> altered state of<br />

a controlled mindset. Instead of pushing Grupo Mexico<br />

into <strong>the</strong> range suggested by Goldman's analysis of Minera's<br />

fundamental value, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee went backwards to<br />

accommodate Grupo Mexico's asking price—an asking price<br />

that never really changed. As part of its backwards shuffle,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee compared unstated DCF values of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera <strong>and</strong> applied Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's own<br />

EBITDA multiples to Minera's *802 projections to justify a<br />

higher share issuance.<br />

3. The Relative Valuation Technique Is Not Alchemy<br />

That Turns A Sub–Optimal Deal Into A Fair One<br />

The defendants portray relative valuation as <strong>the</strong> only way<br />

to perform an “apples-to-apples” comparison of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera. 143 But, <strong>the</strong> evidence does not persuade<br />

me that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee relied on truly equal inputs<br />

for its analyses of <strong>the</strong> two companies. When performing<br />

<strong>the</strong> relative valuation analysis, <strong>the</strong> cash flows for Minera<br />

were optimized to make Minera an attractive acquisition<br />

target, but no such dressing up was done for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru. 144 Grupo Mexico hired two mining engineering firms,<br />

Winters, Dorsey & <strong>Company</strong> <strong>and</strong> Mintec, Inc., to update<br />

Minera's life-of-mine plans <strong>and</strong> operations. When A & S<br />

began conducting due diligence on Minera, it tested <strong>the</strong><br />

plans prepared by Winters <strong>and</strong> Mintec for reasonableness. 145<br />

After A & S knocked down some of Minera's projections,<br />

Mintec revised its analyses to produce a new optimization<br />

plan for Minera's Cananea mine (“Alternative 3”) that added<br />

material value to Minera's projections. 146 By contrast, no<br />

outside consultants were hired to update Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's lifeof-mine<br />

plans, although A & S did review Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

management's projections. 147 Goldman's presentations to<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee indicate that any A & S adjustments<br />

to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru projections were relatively minor. 148 The<br />

record does not reveal any comparable effort to update <strong>and</strong><br />

optimize Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's projections as if it were being sold,<br />

as was being done for Minera. In fact, <strong>the</strong>re is evidence to <strong>the</strong><br />

contrary: no additional analyses were performed on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru despite A & S informing <strong>the</strong> Special Committee that<br />

<strong>the</strong>re was “expansion potential” at Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's Toquepala<br />

<strong>and</strong> Cuajone mines <strong>and</strong> “<strong>the</strong> conceptual studies should be<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ed, similar to Alternative 3 ... There is no *803 doubt<br />

optimization that can be done to <strong>the</strong> current thinking that<br />

will add value at lower capital expenditures.” 149 Also, as<br />

of <strong>the</strong> relevant time period, Minera was emerging from—if<br />

not still in—a period of financial distress. 150 The Minera<br />

projections used in Goldman's final fairness evaluation were<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r optimized in that <strong>the</strong>y assumed that <strong>the</strong> deal would<br />

take place, 151 which meant that <strong>the</strong> projections took into<br />

account <strong>the</strong> benefits that Minera would gain by becoming part<br />

of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> process was one where<br />

an aggressive seller was stretching to show value in what<br />

it was selling, <strong>and</strong> where <strong>the</strong> buyer, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee,<br />

was not engaging in a similar exercise regarding its own<br />

company's value despite using a relative valuation approach,<br />

where that mattered.<br />

As is relevant in o<strong>the</strong>r respects, too, before <strong>the</strong> Merger vote,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee had evidence that this approach had<br />

resulted in estimated cash flows for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru that were<br />

too conservative. For 2004, Goldman projected EBITDA for<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru that turned out to be almost $300 million lower<br />

than <strong>the</strong> EBITDA that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru actually attained. By<br />

contrast, Minera's were close to, but somewhat lower than,<br />

<strong>the</strong> mark.<br />

As ano<strong>the</strong>r technique of narrowing <strong>the</strong> value gap, Goldman<br />

shifted from using Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's 2004E EBITDA multiple<br />

to a range of its 2005E EBITDA multiples in <strong>the</strong> contribution<br />

analyses of <strong>the</strong> Merger, which also helped to level out <strong>the</strong><br />

“give” <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> “get” <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>reby rationalize Grupo Mexico's<br />

asking price. As described previously, applying Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's 2004E EBITDA multiples did not yield a range of<br />

values encompassing 67.2 million shares. Instead, Goldman<br />

relied on applying Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's higher 2005E multiples to<br />

Minera to justify such a figure.<br />

Goldman's decision to apply Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's EBITDA<br />

multiples to Minera was questionable in <strong>the</strong> first place.<br />

Valuing Minera by applying Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's multiple<br />

was a charitable move on <strong>the</strong> part of <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee, <strong>and</strong> reasonable third-party buyers are generally<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 23


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

not charitable toward <strong>the</strong>ir acquisition targets. 152 Unlike<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, a Delaware corporation listed on <strong>the</strong> New<br />

York Stock Exchange, Minera was unlisted, subject to<br />

Mexican accounting st<strong>and</strong>ards, <strong>and</strong> was not being regulated<br />

<strong>and</strong> overseen by <strong>the</strong> Securities <strong>and</strong> Exchange Commission.<br />

Moreover, Minera was not in sound financial condition.<br />

Why did <strong>the</strong> Special Committee top up Minera's multiple to<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's own, instead of exploiting for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

<strong>the</strong> market-tested value of its acquisition currency? One of <strong>the</strong><br />

advantages of overvalued stock is that it is cheap acquisition<br />

currency; if an acquiror is trading at a higher multiple than<br />

<strong>the</strong> target, it generally takes advantage of that multiple in<br />

<strong>the</strong> acquisition. The Special Committee's charitable multiple<br />

migration is highly suspicious given <strong>the</strong> involvement of a<br />

controlling stockholder on both sides of <strong>the</strong> deal.<br />

*804 In <strong>the</strong>se respects, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee was not<br />

ideally served by its financial advisors. Goldman dropped<br />

any focus on <strong>the</strong> value of what Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was giving<br />

from its analyses. Taking into account all <strong>the</strong> testimony <strong>and</strong><br />

record evidence, both Goldman <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

believed that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's market price was higher than its<br />

fundamental value. But instead of acting on that belief, <strong>the</strong>y<br />

did something very unusual, in which Goldman shifted its<br />

client's focus to an increasingly non-real world set of analyses<br />

that obscured <strong>the</strong> actual value of what Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was<br />

getting <strong>and</strong> that was inclined toward pushing up, ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

down, <strong>the</strong> value in <strong>the</strong> negotiations of what Grupo Mexico<br />

was seeking to sell. In fairness, I cannot attribute Goldman's<br />

behavior to a fee incentive, because Goldman did not have<br />

a contingent fee right based on whe<strong>the</strong>r or not <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

was consummated. 153 But Goldman appears to have helped<br />

its client rationalize <strong>the</strong> one strategic option available within<br />

<strong>the</strong> controlled mindset that pervaded <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's<br />

process.<br />

4. The Special Committee Should Not Have<br />

Discounted Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's Market Price<br />

A reasonable third-party buyer free from a controlled mindset<br />

would not have ignored a fundamental economic fact that is<br />

not in dispute here—in 2004, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock could have<br />

been sold for price at which it was trading on <strong>the</strong> New York<br />

Stock Exchange. That is, for whatever reasons, <strong>the</strong> volatile<br />

market in which public companies trade was generating<br />

a real-world cash value for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's acquisition<br />

currency. The defendants concede that whatever bloc of stock<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru gave to Grupo Mexico could have been sold<br />

for its market price in American currency, i.e., dollars. Grupo<br />

Mexico knew that. The record is clear that Grupo Mexico<br />

itself relied on <strong>the</strong> market price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru all along<br />

—during <strong>the</strong> negotiation process, Grupo Mexico kept asking<br />

again <strong>and</strong> again to be paid in approximately $3.1 billion worth<br />

of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock measured at its market price.<br />

It has, of course, been said that under Delaware law fair<br />

value can be determined “by any techniques or methods<br />

which are generally considered acceptable in <strong>the</strong> financial<br />

community,” 154 <strong>and</strong> “[i]t is not a breach of faith for directors<br />

to determine that <strong>the</strong> present stock market price of shares is<br />

not representative of true value or that <strong>the</strong>re may indeed be<br />

several market values for any corporation's stock.” 155 As<br />

former Chancellor Allen wrote in his Time–Warner decision,<br />

which was affirmed by <strong>the</strong> Delaware Supreme Court, “[J]ust<br />

as <strong>the</strong> Constitution does not enshrine Mr. Herbert's social<br />

statics, nei<strong>the</strong>r does <strong>the</strong> common law of directors' duties<br />

elevate <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>ory of a single, efficient capital market to <strong>the</strong><br />

dignity of a sacred text.” 156 But, <strong>the</strong>re are critical differences<br />

between this case <strong>and</strong> Time–Warner. In Time–Warner, <strong>the</strong><br />

board of Time, however wrongly, believed that <strong>the</strong> value<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Time–Warner combination would exceed <strong>the</strong> value<br />

offered by <strong>the</strong> $200 per share Paramount tender offer when<br />

<strong>the</strong> dust on <strong>the</strong> Texas deal range ultimately settled. 157<br />

Here, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee did not believe that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru was being undervalued *805 by <strong>the</strong> stock market.<br />

To <strong>the</strong> contrary, its financial advisor Goldman, after months<br />

of study, rendered analyses suggesting that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

was being overvalued by <strong>the</strong> market. The corresponding<br />

fundamental analyses of Minera showed that Minera was<br />

worth nowhere close to <strong>the</strong> $3.1 billion in real value that<br />

Grupo Mexico was dem<strong>and</strong>ing. This was not a situation<br />

where Goldman <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Special Committee believed that<br />

Minera was being undervalued even more than Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would be getting more than<br />

$3.1 billion in value for giving up stock it could sell for $3.1<br />

billion in real cash.<br />

In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee did not respond to<br />

its intuition that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was overvalued in a way<br />

consistent with its fiduciary duties or <strong>the</strong> way that a thirdparty<br />

buyer would have. As noted, it did not seek to have<br />

Grupo Mexico be <strong>the</strong> buyer. Nor did it say no to Grupo<br />

Mexico's proposed deal. What it did was to turn <strong>the</strong> gold<br />

that it held (market-tested Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock worth in cash<br />

its trading price) into silver (equating itself on a relative<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 24


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

basis to a financially-strapped, non-market tested selling<br />

company), <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>reby devalue its own acquisition currency.<br />

Put bluntly, a reasonable third-party buyer would only go<br />

behind <strong>the</strong> market if it thought <strong>the</strong> fundamental values were<br />

on its side, not retreat from a focus on market if such a<br />

move disadvantaged it. If <strong>the</strong> fundamentals were on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's side in this case, <strong>the</strong> DCF value of Minera would have<br />

equaled or exceeded Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's give. But Goldman <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee could not generate any responsible<br />

estimate of <strong>the</strong> value of Minera that approached <strong>the</strong> value of<br />

what Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was being asked to h<strong>and</strong> over.<br />

Goldman was not able to value Minera at more than $2.8<br />

billion, no matter what valuation methodology it used,<br />

even when it based its analysis on Minera management's<br />

unadjusted projections. 158 As <strong>the</strong> plaintiff points out,<br />

Goldman never advised <strong>the</strong> Special Committee that Minera<br />

was worth $3.1 billion, or that Minera could be acquired at,<br />

or would trade at, a premium to its DCF value if it were a<br />

public company. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> defendants' expert did not<br />

produce a st<strong>and</strong>alone equity value for Minera that justified<br />

issuing shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock worth $3.1 billion at <strong>the</strong><br />

time <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement was signed.<br />

5. Can It All Be Explained By The<br />

Mysterious $1.30 Long–Term Copper Price?<br />

At trial, <strong>the</strong>re emerged a defense of great subtlety that went<br />

like this. In reality, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee <strong>and</strong> Goldman did<br />

believe that Minera was worth more than $3.1 billion. Deep<br />

down, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee believed that <strong>the</strong> long-term<br />

direction of copper prices was strongly northward, <strong>and</strong> that as<br />

of <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> deal were more like $1.30 per pound than<br />

<strong>the</strong> $1.00 that was <strong>the</strong> high range of Goldman's analysis for<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee. This was, of course, a full $0.40 per<br />

pound higher than <strong>the</strong> $0.90 number used by Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru in<br />

its own internal planning documents <strong>and</strong> its publicly disclosed<br />

financial statements, higher than <strong>the</strong> $0.90 used by Minera in<br />

its internal planning process, *806 <strong>and</strong> higher than <strong>the</strong> $0.90<br />

median of analyst price estimates identified by Goldman <strong>and</strong><br />

relied on by Goldman in issuing its fairness opinion.<br />

According to <strong>the</strong> defendants, as effective negotiators, <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee <strong>and</strong> Goldman perceived that if one applied<br />

this “real” long-term copper price trend to Minera, it would<br />

generate very high st<strong>and</strong>alone values for Minera <strong>and</strong> thus be<br />

counterproductive from a negotiating st<strong>and</strong>point. Hence, <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee did not use <strong>the</strong>se prices, but ra<strong>the</strong>r focused<br />

on a relative valuation approach, not because it obscured that<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was not obtaining a get as good as <strong>the</strong> give, but<br />

so Grupo Mexico would not recognize how great a deal that<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was getting.<br />

In support of this <strong>the</strong>ory, <strong>the</strong> defendants presented a qualified<br />

academic, Eduardo Schwartz, who testified that if one valued<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera on a relative valuation basis using<br />

<strong>the</strong> ultimate Goldman assumptions <strong>and</strong> a $1.30 copper price,<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru actually paid far too little. 159 The <strong>the</strong>ory<br />

of this expert <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> defendants is that a rising copper<br />

price would have benefited Minera far more than it did<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. 160 Schwartz also says that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's<br />

stock market trading price had to be explained by <strong>the</strong> fact<br />

that <strong>the</strong> stock market was actually using a long-term copper<br />

price of $1.30, despite <strong>the</strong> lower long term price that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru, o<strong>the</strong>r companies, <strong>and</strong> market analysts were using at <strong>the</strong><br />

time. 161<br />

But what <strong>the</strong> defendants' expert did not do is telling. Despite<br />

his eminent qualifications, Schwartz would not opine on <strong>the</strong><br />

st<strong>and</strong>alone value of Minera, he would not lay his marker<br />

down on that. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> implication that Minera<br />

would benefit more than Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru from rising copper<br />

prices resulted from taking <strong>the</strong> assumptions of <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee process itself, 162 in which great efforts had<br />

been made by Grupo Mexico <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Special Committee to<br />

optimize Minera's value <strong>and</strong> nothing comparable had been<br />

done to optimize Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's value. The defendants'<br />

expert appears to have given no weight to <strong>the</strong> nearly $300<br />

million EBITDA underestimate in <strong>the</strong> 2004 Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

cash flow estimates, or to <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> 2005 estimates<br />

for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru also turned out to be close to $800 million<br />

less than estimated, whereas Minera did not outperform <strong>the</strong><br />

2004 estimates used in <strong>the</strong> deal <strong>and</strong> outperformed <strong>the</strong> 2005<br />

estimates *807 by a far lower percentage than Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru. The defendants' position that <strong>the</strong> Merger was fair in light<br />

of rising copper prices is also, as we shall see, undermined<br />

by evidence that <strong>the</strong>y <strong>the</strong>mselves introduced regarding <strong>the</strong><br />

competitive performance of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera from<br />

2005 onward to 2010. That evidence illustrates that in terms<br />

of generating EBITDA, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru continued to be <strong>the</strong><br />

company with <strong>the</strong> comparatively strong performance, while<br />

Minera lagged behind.<br />

Even more important, I can find no evidence in <strong>the</strong> actual<br />

record of deal negotiations of any actual belief by <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee or Goldman that long-term copper prices were in<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 25


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

fact $1.30, that it would be easy to rationalize a deal at <strong>the</strong><br />

price Grupo Mexico suggested at copper prices of $1.30, but<br />

that for sound negotiating reasons, <strong>the</strong>y would not run DCF<br />

analyses at that price, but instead move to a relative valuation<br />

approach. There is just nothing in <strong>the</strong> record that supports<br />

this as a contemporaneous reality of <strong>the</strong> negotiating period,<br />

as supposed to an after-<strong>the</strong>-fact rationalization conceived of<br />

for litigation purposes. 163<br />

The Special Committee members who testified admitted that<br />

<strong>the</strong>y were taken aback by Goldman's analysis of Minera's<br />

st<strong>and</strong>alone value. None said that <strong>the</strong>y insisted that Goldman<br />

run models based on higher long-term copper prices or that<br />

<strong>the</strong>y believed <strong>the</strong> long-term price that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was<br />

using in its public filings was too low. It is hard to believe<br />

that if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee felt deep in its deal bones<br />

that <strong>the</strong> long-term copper price was higher than $1.00, it<br />

would not have asked Goldman to perform a DCF analysis<br />

on those metrics. Importantly, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru continued to<br />

use a long-term copper price of $0.90 per pound for internal<br />

planning purposes until December 31, 2007, when it changed<br />

to $1.20. 164 In terms of <strong>the</strong> negotiating record itself, <strong>the</strong> only<br />

evidence is that a long-term copper price of $1.00 was deemed<br />

aggressive by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee <strong>and</strong> its advisors <strong>and</strong><br />

$0.90 as <strong>the</strong> best estimate. 165 Thus, Schwartz's conclusion<br />

that <strong>the</strong> market was assuming a long-term copper price of<br />

$1.30 in valuing Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru appears to be based entirely<br />

on post-hoc speculation. Put simply, <strong>the</strong>re is no credible<br />

evidence of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, in <strong>the</strong> heat of battle,<br />

believing that <strong>the</strong> long-term copper price was actually $1.30<br />

per pound but using $0.90 instead to give Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru an<br />

advantage in <strong>the</strong> negotiation process.<br />

Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee engaged in no serious<br />

analysis of <strong>the</strong> differential effect, if any, on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

<strong>and</strong> Minera of higher copper prices. 166 That is *808 a<br />

dynamic question that involves many factors <strong>and</strong>, as I have<br />

found, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee did not attempt to “optimize”<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's cash flows in <strong>the</strong> way it did Minera's. The<br />

plaintiff argues that by simply re-running his DCF analyses<br />

using a long-term copper price assumption of $1.30, Schwartz<br />

glosses over key differences in <strong>the</strong> effect of an increase<br />

in long-term copper prices on <strong>the</strong> reserves of Minera <strong>and</strong><br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. Primarily, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff argues that if <strong>the</strong> longterm<br />

copper price assumption is increased to $1.30, <strong>the</strong>n<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's reserves would have increased far more<br />

dramatically than Minera's <strong>and</strong>, <strong>the</strong>refore, <strong>the</strong> relative value<br />

of <strong>the</strong> two companies would not remain constant at a higher<br />

long-term copper price. The defendants, as discussed above,<br />

respond that Minera, not Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was more sensitive<br />

to increases in copper price assumptions, <strong>and</strong> thus, if higher<br />

copper prices are used <strong>the</strong> deal becomes even more favorable<br />

for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. It is not clear if anybody really knew, at<br />

<strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger, <strong>the</strong> extent to which <strong>the</strong> projections of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru or Minera would have changed in <strong>the</strong> event that<br />

<strong>the</strong> companies regarded $1.30 per pound as a reliable longterm<br />

copper price. But, <strong>the</strong> parties' arguments with respect<br />

to <strong>the</strong> relative effects of changes in <strong>the</strong> long-term copper<br />

price on Minera <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's reserves end up being of<br />

little importance, because <strong>the</strong>re is no evidence in <strong>the</strong> record<br />

that suggests that anyone at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger was<br />

contemplating a $1.30 long-term copper price.<br />

The idea that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee <strong>and</strong> Goldman believed<br />

that copper prices were going steeply higher also makes its<br />

decision to seek a fixed exchange ratio odd, because <strong>the</strong> likely<br />

result of such price movements would have been, as things<br />

turned out, to result in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru delivering more, not<br />

less, in value to Grupo Mexico as a result of stock market<br />

price movements. Remember, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee said<br />

it sought such a ratio to protect against a downward price<br />

movement. 167 Perhaps this could be yet ano<strong>the</strong>r indication of<br />

just how deeply wise <strong>and</strong> cl<strong>and</strong>estine <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's<br />

negotiating strategy was. If <strong>the</strong> Committee asked for a collar<br />

or o<strong>the</strong>r limitation on <strong>the</strong> cash value it would pay in its<br />

stock, it would tip off Grupo Mexico that Minera was really<br />

worth much more than Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was paying. This sort of<br />

concealed motivation <strong>and</strong> contradiction is usually <strong>the</strong> stuff of<br />

international espionage, not M & A practice. I cannot say that<br />

I find a rational basis to accept that it existed here. To find that<br />

<strong>the</strong> original low st<strong>and</strong>alone estimates, <strong>the</strong> aggressive efforts<br />

at optimizing cash flows, <strong>the</strong> charitable sharing of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's own multiples, <strong>and</strong>, as we shall next discuss, <strong>the</strong> lastgasp<br />

measures to close <strong>the</strong> resulting value gap that yet still<br />

remained were simply a cover for a brilliant, but necessarily<br />

secret, negotiating strategy by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee <strong>and</strong><br />

Goldman is difficult for a mind required to apply secular<br />

reasoning, ra<strong>the</strong>r than conspiracy <strong>the</strong>ories or mysticism, to <strong>the</strong><br />

record before me. 168<br />

*809 6. Grupo Mexico's “Concessions” Were<br />

Weak And Did Not Close The Fairness Gap<br />

In <strong>the</strong>ir briefs, <strong>the</strong> defendants point to certain deal terms<br />

agreed to by Grupo Mexico as evidence of <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee's negotiating prowess. These provisions include<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 26


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

(1) <strong>the</strong> commitment from Grupo Mexico to reduce Minera's<br />

net debt at closing to $1 billion; (2) <strong>the</strong> $100 million special<br />

transaction dividend paid out by Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru as part of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger's closing; (3) post-closure corporate governance<br />

changes at Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru designed to protect minority<br />

stockholders, including a requirement for review of relatedparty<br />

transactions; (4) <strong>the</strong> super-majority vote required to<br />

approve <strong>the</strong> Merger; <strong>and</strong> (5) <strong>the</strong> fixed exchange ratio.<br />

But, <strong>the</strong>se so-called “concessions” did little to justify <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger terms. Grupo Mexico was contractually obligated<br />

to pay down Minera's debt because of rising copper prices,<br />

<strong>and</strong> it had already paid down its debt to $1.06 million<br />

as of June 30, 2004. 169 The dividend both reduced <strong>the</strong><br />

value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock price, allowing <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee to close <strong>the</strong> divide between its 64 million<br />

share offer <strong>and</strong> Grupo Mexico's 67.2 million share asking<br />

price <strong>and</strong> paid out cash to Grupo Mexico, which got<br />

54% of <strong>the</strong> dividend. Many of <strong>the</strong> corporate governance<br />

provisions were first proposed by Grupo Mexico, including<br />

<strong>the</strong> review of related party transactions, so that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

would remain compliant with applicable NYSE rules <strong>and</strong><br />

Delaware law. 170 Correctly, Grupo Mexico did not regard<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee's corporate governance suggestions as<br />

differing much from <strong>the</strong> “status quo.” 171 After proposing a<br />

$500,000 threshold for review of related-party transactions<br />

by an independent committee of <strong>the</strong> board, 172 <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee accepted Grupo Mexico's counterproposal for a<br />

$10 million threshold. 173 This was more a negotiation defeat<br />

than victory.<br />

As for <strong>the</strong> two-thirds supermajority vote, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee assented to it after asking for <strong>and</strong> not obtaining<br />

a majority of <strong>the</strong> minority vote provision. The Special<br />

Committee knew that Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge wanted to<br />

sell, <strong>and</strong> that along with Grupo Mexico, <strong>the</strong>se large holders<br />

would guarantee <strong>the</strong> vote. At best, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

extracted <strong>the</strong> chance to potentially block <strong>the</strong> Merger if postsigning<br />

events convinced it to change its recommendation<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore wield Cerro's vote against <strong>the</strong> Merger. 174 But,<br />

as I will *810 discuss in <strong>the</strong> next section, <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee did not do any real thinking in <strong>the</strong> period between<br />

its approval of <strong>the</strong> Merger <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote on <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, as has been noted, several key material<br />

facts regarding <strong>the</strong> fairness of <strong>the</strong> Merger were not, in my<br />

view, fairly disclosed.<br />

The Special Committee's insistence on a fixed exchange<br />

ratio, as discussed, is difficult to reconcile with its purported<br />

secret belief that copper prices were on <strong>the</strong> rise. O<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

protection against a falling Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock price, <strong>the</strong><br />

only justification for using a fixed versus floating exchange<br />

ratio in <strong>the</strong> Merger was one often cited to when two public<br />

companies that are both subject to market price fluctuations<br />

announce a merger, which is that because <strong>the</strong>y are similar<br />

companies <strong>and</strong> proposing to merge, <strong>the</strong> values of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera would rise <strong>and</strong> fall toge<strong>the</strong>r after <strong>the</strong> market<br />

reacts initially to <strong>the</strong> exchange ratio. H<strong>and</strong>elsman referred to<br />

this justification in his testimony. 175 In o<strong>the</strong>r words, if <strong>the</strong><br />

stock price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru went up, <strong>the</strong> value of Minera<br />

would go up as well, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> relative valuation would stay <strong>the</strong><br />

same. This would make more sense in a merger between two<br />

companies in <strong>the</strong> same industry with publicly traded stock,<br />

because both companies would have actual stock prices that<br />

might change because of some of <strong>the</strong> same industry-wide<br />

forces <strong>and</strong> because both stocks might trade largely on <strong>the</strong> deal,<br />

after <strong>the</strong> initial exchange ratio is absorbed into <strong>the</strong>ir prices.<br />

Here, by contrast, only Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock had a price that<br />

was subject to market movement. These were not two public<br />

companies—changes in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock price were in<br />

an important sense a one-sided risk. A rising market would<br />

only lift <strong>the</strong> market-tested value of one side of <strong>the</strong> transaction,<br />

<strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru side. And, of course, <strong>the</strong> switch to a fixed<br />

exchange ratio turned out to be hugely disadvantageous to<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. 176<br />

*811 7. The Special Committee Did Not Update Its<br />

Fairness Analysis In The Face of Strong Evidence<br />

That The Bases For Its Decision Had Changed<br />

The Special Committee had negotiated for <strong>the</strong> freedom to<br />

change its recommendation in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger if its<br />

fiduciary duties so required, <strong>and</strong> had <strong>the</strong> vote of a major<br />

minority stockholder (Cerro) tied to a withdrawal of its<br />

recommendation, but instead treated <strong>the</strong> Merger as a foregone<br />

conclusion from <strong>the</strong> time of its October 21, 2004 vote to<br />

approve <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement. There is no evidence to<br />

suggest that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee or Goldman made any<br />

effort to update its fairness analysis in light of <strong>the</strong> fact that<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru had blown out its EBITDA projections for<br />

2004 <strong>and</strong> its stock price was steadily rising in <strong>the</strong> months<br />

leading up to <strong>the</strong> stockholder vote (perhaps because it had<br />

greatly exceeded its projections), even though it had agreed<br />

to pay Grupo Mexico with a fixed number of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru shares that had no collar. To my mind, <strong>the</strong> fact that<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 27


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

none of <strong>the</strong>se developments caused <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

to consider renegotiating or re-evaluating <strong>the</strong> Merger is<br />

additional evidence of <strong>the</strong>ir controlled mindset. O<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman's phone call to Goldman, no member of <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee made any effort to inquire into an update<br />

on <strong>the</strong> fairness of <strong>the</strong> Merger. The Special Committee's failure<br />

to get a reasoned update, taken toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong> negotiation<br />

process <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> terms of <strong>the</strong> Merger, was a regrettable <strong>and</strong><br />

important lapse.<br />

Although an obvious point, it is worth reiterating that <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee was comprised of directors of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru. Thus, from internal information, <strong>the</strong>y should have<br />

been aware that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was far outperforming <strong>the</strong><br />

projections on which <strong>the</strong> deal was based. This should have<br />

given <strong>the</strong>m pause that <strong>the</strong> exercise in optimizing Minera<br />

had in fact optimized Minera (which essentially made its<br />

numbers for 2004) but had undervalued Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, which<br />

had beaten its 2004 EBITDA estimates by 37%, some $300<br />

million. This reality is deepened by <strong>the</strong> fact that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru beat its 2005 estimates by 135%, while Minera's 2005<br />

EBITDA was only 45% higher than its estimates. These<br />

numbers suggest that it was knowable that <strong>the</strong> deal pressures<br />

had resulted in an approach to valuation that was focused<br />

on making Minera look as valuable as possible, while<br />

shortchanging Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, to justify <strong>the</strong> single deal that<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee was empowered to evaluate.<br />

Despite this, Goldman <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Special Committee did<br />

not reconsider <strong>the</strong>ir contribution analysis, even though<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's blow-out 2004 performance would suggest<br />

that reliance on even lower 2005 projections was<br />

unreasonable. 177 Indeed, *812 <strong>the</strong> Merger vote was held<br />

on March 28, 2005, when <strong>the</strong> first quarter of 2005 was<br />

almost over. In that quarter alone, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru made $303.4<br />

million in EBITDA, over 52% of what Goldman estimated<br />

for <strong>the</strong> entire year.<br />

This brings me to a final, big picture point. In justifying <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

arguments, each side pointed in some ways to post-Merger<br />

evidence. Specifically, <strong>the</strong> defendants subjected a chart in<br />

support of <strong>the</strong>ir argument that rising copper prices would have<br />

disproportionately benefited Minera over Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru in<br />

<strong>the</strong> form of having greater reserves, <strong>and</strong> that this justified <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants' use of a relative valuation technique, <strong>and</strong> undercut<br />

<strong>the</strong> notion that Minera's value was dressed up, <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's wea<strong>the</strong>r beaten during <strong>the</strong> Special Committee process.<br />

The problem for this argument is that reserves are relevant to<br />

value because <strong>the</strong>y should generate cash flow. As has been<br />

mentioned, Goldman stretched to justify <strong>the</strong> deal by using a<br />

range of multiples that started at <strong>the</strong> bottom with Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's Wall Street consensus multiple for 2005E EBITDA <strong>and</strong><br />

ended at <strong>the</strong> top with a management-generated multiple of<br />

6.5x. Both of <strong>the</strong>se were well north of <strong>the</strong> 4.8x median of<br />

Goldman's comparables. And, of course, Goldman estimated<br />

that Minera would earn nearly as much as Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru in<br />

2004, <strong>and</strong> more than Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru in 2005. Nei<strong>the</strong>r estimate<br />

turned out to be even close to true. Indeed, <strong>the</strong> Merger was<br />

premised on <strong>the</strong> notion that over <strong>the</strong> period from 2005 to<br />

2010, Minera would generate $1.35 of EBITDA for every<br />

$1.00 of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. Using <strong>the</strong> underlying evidence cited<br />

in <strong>the</strong> defendants' own chart, 178 which came from <strong>the</strong> public<br />

financials of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, a company under <strong>the</strong>ir continued<br />

control, after <strong>the</strong> Merger, my non-ma<strong>the</strong>matician's evaluation<br />

of this estimate reveals that it turned out to be very far off<br />

<strong>the</strong> mark, with Minera generating only $0.67 for every dollar<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru made in EBITDA. Put simply, even in a rising<br />

copper price market, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru seemed to more than hold<br />

its own <strong>and</strong>, if anything, benefit even more than Minera from<br />

<strong>the</strong> general rise in copper prices.<br />

The charts below addressing <strong>the</strong> companies' performance in<br />

generating EBITDA in comparison to <strong>the</strong> deal assumptions,<br />

if anything, confirms my impression that *813 Minera's<br />

value was optimized <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's slighted to come<br />

to an exchange price no reasonable third party would have<br />

supported:<br />

2005 179 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 Sum<br />

Minera $ 971.6 $1405.5 $1731.2 $ 856.5 $ 661.9 $1078.3 $ 6705.0<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru $1364.8 $1918.4 $2085.4 $1643.5 $1144.8 $1853.8 $10010.7<br />

Ratio MM/SP .71 .73 .83 .52 .58 .58 .67<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 28


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

For all <strong>the</strong>se reasons, I conclude that <strong>the</strong> Merger was unfair,<br />

regardless of which party bears <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion.<br />

The Special Committee's cramped perspective resulted in a<br />

strange deal dynamic, in which a majority stockholder kept<br />

its eye on <strong>the</strong> ball—actual value benchmarked to cash—<strong>and</strong> a<br />

Special Committee lost sight of market reality in an attempt to<br />

rationalize doing a deal of <strong>the</strong> kind <strong>the</strong> majority stockholder<br />

proposed. After this game of controlled mindset twister <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> contortions it involved, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee agreed<br />

to give away over $3 billion worth of actual cash value in<br />

exchange for something worth demonstrably less, <strong>and</strong> to do<br />

so on terms that by consummation made <strong>the</strong> value gap even<br />

worse, without using any of its contractual leverage to stop<br />

<strong>the</strong> deal or renegotiate its terms. Because <strong>the</strong> deal was unfair,<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants breached <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary duty of loyalty.<br />

I now fix <strong>the</strong> remedy for this breach.<br />

IV. Determination Of Damages<br />

A. Introduction<br />

The plaintiff seeks an equitable remedy that cancels or<br />

requires <strong>the</strong> defendants to return to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>the</strong> shares<br />

that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru issued in excess of Minera's fair value. In<br />

<strong>the</strong> alternative, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff asks for rescissory damages in<br />

<strong>the</strong> amount of <strong>the</strong> present market value of <strong>the</strong> excess number<br />

of shares that Grupo Mexico holds as a result of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru paying an unfair price in <strong>the</strong> Merger. The plaintiff<br />

claims, based on Beaulne's expert report, that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

issued at least 24.7 million shares in excess of Minera's fair<br />

value. 181 The plaintiff asserts that, because *814 Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru effected a 2–for–1 stock split on October 3, 2006 <strong>and</strong> a<br />

3–for–1 stock split on July 10, 2008, those 24.7 million shares<br />

have become 148.2 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock,<br />

<strong>and</strong> he would have me order that each of those 148.2 million<br />

shares be cancelled or returned to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, or that <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants should pay fair value for each of those shares.<br />

Measured at a market value of $27.25 per Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru share<br />

on October 13, 2011, 148.2 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

stock are worth more than $4 billion.<br />

The plaintiff also argues that $60.20 in dividends have<br />

been paid on each of <strong>the</strong> 24.7 million Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

shares (adjusted for stock-splits), <strong>and</strong> to fully remedy <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants' breach of fiduciary duty <strong>the</strong> court must order<br />

that <strong>the</strong> defendants must pay additional damages in <strong>the</strong><br />

amount of approximately $1.487 billion. Finally, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff<br />

requests pre <strong>and</strong> postjudgment interest compounded monthly,<br />

a request that seems to ignore <strong>the</strong> effect of <strong>the</strong> dividends just<br />

described.<br />

By contrast, <strong>the</strong> defendants say that no damages at all are<br />

due because <strong>the</strong> deal was more than fair. Based on <strong>the</strong> fact<br />

that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's market value continued on a generally<br />

upward trajectory in <strong>the</strong> years after <strong>the</strong> Merger—even though<br />

it dropped in response to <strong>the</strong> announcement of <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

exchange ratio <strong>and</strong> at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> preliminary proxy—<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants say that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stockholders should<br />

be grateful for <strong>the</strong> deal. At <strong>the</strong> very least, <strong>the</strong> defendants<br />

say that any damage award should be at most a fraction of<br />

<strong>the</strong> amounts sought by <strong>the</strong> plaintiff, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> plaintiff<br />

has waived <strong>the</strong> right to seek rescissory damages because of<br />

his lethargic approach to litigating <strong>the</strong> case. The defendants<br />

contend that it would be unfair to allow <strong>the</strong> plaintiff to benefit<br />

from increases in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock price that occurred<br />

during <strong>the</strong> past six years, because Grupo Mexico bore <strong>the</strong><br />

market risk for so long due to <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's own torpor.<br />

The defendants also argue that <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's delays warrant<br />

elimination of <strong>the</strong> period upon which pre-judgment interest<br />

might o<strong>the</strong>rwise be computed, <strong>and</strong> that plaintiff should not be<br />

entitled to compounded interest.<br />

[10] [11] This court has broad discretion to fashion<br />

equitable <strong>and</strong> monetary relief under <strong>the</strong> entire fairness<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard. 182 Unlike <strong>the</strong> more exact process followed in an<br />

appraisal action, damages resulting from a breach of fiduciary<br />

duty are liberally calculated. 183 As long as <strong>the</strong>re is a basis for<br />

an estimate of damages, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> plaintiff has suffered harm,<br />

“ma<strong>the</strong>matical certainty is not required.” 184 In addition to an<br />

actual award of monetary relief, this court has <strong>the</strong> authority<br />

to grant pre-<strong>and</strong> post-judgment interest, <strong>and</strong> to determine <strong>the</strong><br />

form of that interest. 185<br />

The task of determining an appropriate remedy for <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiff in this case is difficult, for several reasons. First,<br />

as <strong>the</strong> defendants point out, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff caused this case<br />

to languish <strong>and</strong> as a result this litigation has gone on<br />

for six years. Second, both parties took an odd approach<br />

to presenting valuation evidence, particularly *815 <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants, whose expert consciously chose not to give an<br />

estimate of Minera's value at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger. Although<br />

<strong>the</strong> plaintiff's expert gave no opinion on <strong>the</strong> fundamental<br />

value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, that did not matter as much as<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants' expert's failure to give such an opinion,<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 29


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

because <strong>the</strong> defendants <strong>the</strong>mselves conceded that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's acquisition currency was worth its stock market value.<br />

Third, <strong>the</strong> parties devoted comparatively few pages of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

briefs to <strong>the</strong> issue of <strong>the</strong> appropriate remedy. Finally, <strong>the</strong><br />

implied st<strong>and</strong>alone DCF values of Minera <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

that were used in Goldman's final relative valuation of <strong>the</strong><br />

companies are hard to discern <strong>and</strong> have never been fully<br />

explained by <strong>the</strong> source.<br />

These problems make it more challenging than it would<br />

already be to come to a responsible remedy. But, I will, as I<br />

must, work with <strong>the</strong> record I have.<br />

In coming to my remedy, I first address a few of <strong>the</strong><br />

preliminary issues. For starters, I reject <strong>the</strong> defendants'<br />

argument that <strong>the</strong> post-Merger performance of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's stock eliminates <strong>the</strong> need for relief here. As noted,<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants did not bo<strong>the</strong>r to present a reliable event<br />

study about <strong>the</strong> market's reaction to <strong>the</strong> Merger, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is evidence that <strong>the</strong> market did not view <strong>the</strong> Merger as fair<br />

in spite of material gaps in disclosure about <strong>the</strong> fairness of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Merger. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore, even if Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock has<br />

outperformed comparable companies since <strong>the</strong> Merger, <strong>the</strong><br />

company may have performed even better if <strong>the</strong> defendants<br />

had not overpaid for Minera based on its own fundamentals.<br />

Notably, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru markedly outperformed <strong>the</strong> EBITDA<br />

estimates used in <strong>the</strong> deal for both 2004 <strong>and</strong> 2005, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

ratio of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's EBITDA to Minera's EBITDA over<br />

<strong>the</strong> six years since <strong>the</strong> Merger suggests that <strong>the</strong> assumptions<br />

on which <strong>the</strong> Merger was based were biased in Minera's favor.<br />

A transaction like <strong>the</strong> Merger can be unfair, in <strong>the</strong> sense that<br />

it is below what a real arms-length deal would have been<br />

priced at, while not tanking a strong company with sound<br />

fundamentals in a rising market, such as <strong>the</strong> one in which<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was a participant. That remains my firm sense<br />

here, <strong>and</strong> if I took into account <strong>the</strong> full range of post-Merger<br />

evidence, my conclusion that <strong>the</strong> Merger was unfair would be<br />

held more firmly, ra<strong>the</strong>r than more tentatively.<br />

By contrast, I do agree with <strong>the</strong> defendants that <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's<br />

delay in litigating <strong>the</strong> case renders it inequitable to use a<br />

rescission-based approach. 186 Rescissory damages are <strong>the</strong><br />

economic equivalent of rescission <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>refore if rescission<br />

itself is unwarranted because of <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's delay, so<br />

are rescissory damages. 187 Instead of entering a rescissionbased<br />

remedy, I will craft from <strong>the</strong> “panoply of equitable<br />

remedies” within this court's discretion a damage award<br />

that approximates <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> price that <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee would have approved had <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

been entirely fair (i.e., absent a breach of fiduciary duties)<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> price that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee actually agreed to<br />

pay. 188 In o<strong>the</strong>r words, I will take <strong>the</strong> difference between<br />

this fair price <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> market value of 67.2 million shares<br />

*816 of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock as of <strong>the</strong> Merger date. 189 That<br />

difference, divided by <strong>the</strong> average closing price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru stock in <strong>the</strong> 20 trading days preceding <strong>the</strong> issuance<br />

of this opinion, will determine <strong>the</strong> number of shares that<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants must return to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. Fur<strong>the</strong>rmore,<br />

because of <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's delay, I will only grant simple<br />

interest on that amount, calculated at <strong>the</strong> statutory rate since<br />

<strong>the</strong> date of <strong>the</strong> Merger.<br />

In all my analyses, I fix <strong>the</strong> fair value of Minera at October<br />

21, 2004, <strong>the</strong> date on which <strong>the</strong> Merger Agreement was<br />

signed. I do not believe it fair to accord Grupo Mexico any<br />

price appreciation after that date due to its own fixation on<br />

cash value, <strong>the</strong> fact that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru outperformed Minera<br />

during this period, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> overall conservatism I employ<br />

in my remedial approach, which already reflects leniency<br />

toward Grupo Mexico, given <strong>the</strong> serious fairness concerns<br />

evidenced in <strong>the</strong> record.<br />

B. The Damages Valuation<br />

[12] Having determined <strong>the</strong> nature of <strong>the</strong> damage award, I<br />

must next determine <strong>the</strong> appropriate valuation for <strong>the</strong> price<br />

that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee should have paid. Of course,<br />

this valuation is not a straightforward exercise <strong>and</strong> inevitably<br />

involves some speculation. There are many ways to fashion<br />

a remedy here, given that <strong>the</strong> parties have provided no real<br />

road map for how to come to a value, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> analyses<br />

performed by Goldman <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Special Committee do not<br />

lend <strong>the</strong>mselves to an easy resolution. I will attempt to do my<br />

best on <strong>the</strong> record before me.<br />

Given <strong>the</strong> difference between <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>alone equity values of<br />

Minera derived by Goldman <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's expert <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

actual cash value of <strong>the</strong> $3.75 billion in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock<br />

that was actually paid to Grupo Mexico in <strong>the</strong> Merger, this<br />

record could arguably support a damages award of $2 billion<br />

or more. My remedy calculation will be more conservative,<br />

<strong>and</strong> in that manner will intentionally take into account some<br />

of <strong>the</strong> imponderables I previously mentioned, which notably<br />

include <strong>the</strong> uncertainties regarding <strong>the</strong> market's reaction to <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> reality that <strong>the</strong> Merger did not stop Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's stock price from rising over <strong>the</strong> long term. 190<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 30


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

To calculate a fair price for remedy purposes, I will<br />

balance three values: (1) a st<strong>and</strong>alone DCF value of Minera,<br />

calculated by applying <strong>the</strong> most aggressive discount rate used<br />

by Goldman in its DCF analyses (7.5%) <strong>and</strong> a long-term<br />

copper price of $1.10 per pound to <strong>the</strong> DCF model presented<br />

by <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's expert, Beaulne; (2) <strong>the</strong> market value of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee's 52 million share counteroffer made<br />

in July 2004, which was sized *817 based on months of<br />

due diligence by Goldman about Minera's st<strong>and</strong>alone value,<br />

calculated as of <strong>the</strong> date on which <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

approved <strong>the</strong> Merger; <strong>and</strong> (3) <strong>the</strong> equity value of Minera<br />

derived from a comparable companies analysis using <strong>the</strong><br />

comparable companies identified by Goldman.<br />

1. A St<strong>and</strong>alone DCF Value<br />

The only st<strong>and</strong>alone DCF value for Minera in <strong>the</strong> record<br />

that clearly takes into account <strong>the</strong> projections for Minera<br />

that Goldman was using on October 21, 2004 is Beaulne's<br />

DCF analysis of Minera, which yielded an equity value as<br />

of October 21, 2004 of $1.838 billion. 191 Beaulne used <strong>the</strong><br />

same A & S-adjusted projections for Minera that Goldman<br />

used in its October 21, 2004 presentation to calculate his<br />

st<strong>and</strong>alone DCF value for Minera. 192 He assumes a longterm<br />

copper price of $0.90 per pound, which was also relied<br />

on by Goldman. 193 The major difference between Beaulne's<br />

DCF analysis <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Goldman DCF analysis, o<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong><br />

fact that Goldman gave up on deriving a st<strong>and</strong>alone equity<br />

value for Minera, is that Beaulne uses a lower discount rate<br />

than Goldman did—6.5% instead of 8.5%. 194<br />

Because Beaulne used <strong>the</strong> same underlying projections in his<br />

analysis, <strong>and</strong> his inputs are not disputed by <strong>the</strong> defendants<br />

or <strong>the</strong> defendants' expert, I am comfortable using his DCF<br />

valuation model. But, I am not at ease with using his discount<br />

rate of 6.5%, because it is outside <strong>the</strong> range of discount<br />

rates used by Goldman <strong>and</strong> seems unrealistically low. Instead,<br />

I will apply Goldman's lowest discount rate, 7.5%. In <strong>the</strong><br />

spirit of being conservative in my remedy, I will, by contrast,<br />

apply a long-term copper price of $1.10 per pound, which<br />

is $0.10 more than <strong>the</strong> highest long-term copper price used<br />

by Goldman in its valuation matrices ($1.00) <strong>and</strong> is halfway<br />

between Goldman's mid-range copper price assumption of<br />

$0.90 <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> $1.30 per pound long-term copper price that<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants contend was <strong>the</strong>ir secretly held assumption at<br />

<strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> Merger. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, I use <strong>the</strong> discount<br />

rate assumption from <strong>the</strong> Goldman analyses that is most<br />

favorable to <strong>the</strong> defendants <strong>and</strong> a long-term copper price<br />

assumption that is even more favorable to <strong>the</strong> defendants than<br />

Goldman's highest long-term copper price, <strong>and</strong> apply <strong>the</strong>m to<br />

<strong>the</strong> optimized cash flow projections of Minera. Under <strong>the</strong>se<br />

defendant-friendly assumptions, a st<strong>and</strong>alone equity value for<br />

Minera as of October 21, 2004 of $2.452 billion results. 195<br />

*818 2. The Value Of The<br />

Special Committee's July Proposal<br />

The counteroffer made by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee in July<br />

2004, in which <strong>the</strong>y proposed to pay for Grupo Mexico's stake<br />

in Minera with 52 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock, is<br />

arguably <strong>the</strong> last proposal made by <strong>the</strong> Special Committee<br />

while <strong>the</strong>y still had some vestige of a “give/get” analysis<br />

in mind that a reasonable, uncontrolled Special Committee<br />

would have remained in during <strong>the</strong> entire negotiation process.<br />

I <strong>the</strong>refore believe that <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n-current value of 52 million<br />

shares is indicative of what <strong>the</strong> Special Committee thought<br />

Minera was really worth.<br />

The Special Committee's July proposal was made between<br />

July 8, 2004 <strong>and</strong> July 12, 2004. The stock price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru on July 8, 2004 was $40.30 per share, so <strong>the</strong> 52 million<br />

shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock <strong>the</strong>n had a market price of<br />

$2.095 billion. Because Grupo Mexico wanted a dollar value<br />

of stock, I fix <strong>the</strong> value at what 52 million Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

shares were worth as of October 21, 2004, <strong>the</strong> date on<br />

which <strong>the</strong> Special Committee approved <strong>the</strong> Merger, $2.388<br />

billion, 196 giving Minera credit for <strong>the</strong> price growth to that<br />

date.<br />

3. A Comparable Companies Approach<br />

In its October 21, 2004 presentation, Goldman identified<br />

comparable companies <strong>and</strong> deduced a mean <strong>and</strong> median<br />

2005 EBITDA multiple (4.8x) that could have been<br />

applied Minera's EBITDA projections to value Minera. The<br />

comparable companies used by Goldman were Antofagasta,<br />

Freeport McMoRan, Grupo Mexico itself, Phelps Dodge <strong>and</strong><br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. Goldman did not use this multiple to value<br />

Minera. As discussed earlier in this opinion, Goldman instead<br />

opted to apply a range of pumped-up Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru 2005E<br />

EBITDA multiples to Minera's EBITDA projections so as to<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 31


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

generate a value expressed only in terms of <strong>the</strong> number of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru shares to be issued. 197<br />

that premium to <strong>the</strong> value derived from my comparable<br />

companies analysis yields a value of $2.45 billion.<br />

Applying <strong>the</strong> median 2005E EBITDA multiple for <strong>the</strong><br />

comparable companies identified by Goldman to Minera's<br />

2005 EBITDA projections as adjusted by A & S ($622<br />

million) 198 was <strong>the</strong> reasonable <strong>and</strong> fair valuation approach.<br />

Doing so yields a result of $1.986 billion. 199<br />

When using <strong>the</strong> comparable companies method, it is usually<br />

necessary to adjust for <strong>the</strong> fact that what is being sold is<br />

different (control of <strong>the</strong> entire company <strong>and</strong> thus over its<br />

business plan <strong>and</strong> full cash flows) than what is measured<br />

by <strong>the</strong> multiples (minority trades in which <strong>the</strong> buyer has no<br />

expectancy of full control over <strong>the</strong> company's strategy <strong>and</strong><br />

thus influence over <strong>the</strong> strategy to maximize <strong>and</strong> spend its<br />

cash flows). 200 That is, <strong>the</strong> comparable companies method<br />

of analysis produces an equity valuation that includes an<br />

inherent minority trading discount because all of <strong>the</strong> data used<br />

for purposes of comparison is derived from minority trading<br />

values of <strong>the</strong> companies being used. 201 In appraisal cases,<br />

<strong>the</strong> court, in determining <strong>the</strong> fair value of <strong>the</strong> equity under<br />

a comparable companies method, must correct this minority<br />

discount by adding back a premium. 202<br />

*819 An adjustment in <strong>the</strong> form of a control premium<br />

is generally applied to <strong>the</strong> equity value of <strong>the</strong> company<br />

being valued to take into account <strong>the</strong> reality that healthy,<br />

solvent public companies are usually sold at a premium to <strong>the</strong><br />

unaffected trading price of everyday sales of <strong>the</strong> company's<br />

stock. This method must be used with care, especially as<br />

to unlisted companies that have not proven <strong>the</strong>mselves as<br />

st<strong>and</strong>alone companies. For that reason, it is conservative<br />

that I add a control premium for Minera, given its financial<br />

problems <strong>and</strong> its lack of history as an independent public<br />

company. Using <strong>the</strong> median premium for merger transactions<br />

in 2004 calculated by Mergerstat of 23.4%, 203 <strong>and</strong> applying<br />

4. The Resulting Damages<br />

Giving <strong>the</strong> values described above equal weight in my<br />

damages analysis (($2.452 billion + $2.388 billion + $2.45<br />

billion) / 3), results in a value of $2.43 billion, which I <strong>the</strong>n<br />

adjust to reflect <strong>the</strong> fact that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru bought 99.15%,<br />

not 100%, of Minera, which yields a value of $2.409 billion.<br />

The value of 67.2 million Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru shares as of <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger Date was $3.756 billion. 204 The remedy, <strong>the</strong>refore,<br />

amounts to $1.347 billion. 205 The parties shall implement<br />

my remedy as follows. They shall add interest at <strong>the</strong> statutory<br />

rate, without compounding, to <strong>the</strong> value of $1.347 billion<br />

from <strong>the</strong> Merger date, <strong>and</strong> that interest shall run until time of<br />

<strong>the</strong> judgment <strong>and</strong> until payment.<br />

Grupo Mexico may satisfy <strong>the</strong> judgment by agreeing to return<br />

to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru such number of its shares as are necessary<br />

to satisfy this remedy. Any attorneys' fees shall be paid out<br />

of <strong>the</strong> award. 206<br />

Within fifteen days, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff shall present an<br />

implementing order, approved as to form, or <strong>the</strong> parties'<br />

proposed plan to reach such an order. Too much delay has<br />

occurred in this case, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> parties are expected to bring this<br />

case to closure promptly, at least at <strong>the</strong> trial court level.<br />

V. Conclusion<br />

For all <strong>the</strong>se reasons, <strong>the</strong> defendants breached <strong>the</strong>ir fiduciary<br />

duty of loyalty <strong>and</strong> judgment will be entered against <strong>the</strong>m on<br />

<strong>the</strong> basis outlined in this decision.<br />

Footnotes<br />

1 On October 11, 2005, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru changed its name to “Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Copper Corporation” <strong>and</strong> is currently traded on <strong>the</strong> NYSE under<br />

<strong>the</strong> symbol “SCCO.”<br />

2 Grupo Mexico held—<strong>and</strong> still holds—its interest in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru through its wholly-owned subsidiary Americas Mining Corporation<br />

(“AMC”). Grupo Mexico also held its 99.15% stake in Minera through AMC. AMC, not Grupo Mexico, is a defendant to this action,<br />

but I refer to <strong>the</strong>m collectively as Grupo Mexico in this opinion because that more accurately reflects <strong>the</strong> story as it happened.<br />

3 JX–108 (UBS presentation to <strong>the</strong> Board (February 3, 2004)) at AMC0019912.<br />

4 JX–16 (resolutions on <strong>the</strong> establishment of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee (February 12, 2004)) at SP COMM 000441.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 32


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

5 The remaining plaintiff in this action is Michael Theriault, as trustee of <strong>and</strong> for <strong>the</strong> Theriault Trust. The defendants contend that <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiff does not qualify as an adequate fiduciary representative. This argument is premised largely on what <strong>the</strong> defendants see as <strong>the</strong><br />

plaintiff's lack of familiarity with <strong>and</strong> underst<strong>and</strong>ing of <strong>the</strong> case. The plaintiff's less than active role in connection with this case, as<br />

evidenced by his absence at trial <strong>and</strong> lack of a fully developed knowledge about all of <strong>the</strong> litigation details, can in part be explained,<br />

though not be excused, by <strong>the</strong> protracted nature of <strong>the</strong>se proceedings. This case lurched forward over a period of six years largely<br />

because of <strong>the</strong> torpor of <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's counsel, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> passage of time has had <strong>the</strong> regrettable effect of producing some turnover<br />

within <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs' ranks. Two of <strong>the</strong> original plaintiffs are no longer parties, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> remaining plaintiff, Michael Theriault, only<br />

became a party in 2008 because he inherited <strong>the</strong> claims as successor trustee upon <strong>the</strong> death of his fa<strong>the</strong>r, an original plaintiff who had<br />

brought suit in his trustee capacity. It is against this regrettable backdrop that <strong>the</strong> defendants challenge Michael Theriault's adequacy<br />

as a derivative plaintiff.<br />

A derivative plaintiff “must be qualified to serve in a fiduciary capacity as a representative of <strong>the</strong> class of stockholders, whose<br />

interest is dependent upon <strong>the</strong> representative's adequate <strong>and</strong> fair prosecution of <strong>the</strong> action.” Emerald Partners v. Berlin, 564 A.2d<br />

670, 673 (Del.Ch.1989) (citation omitted). The defendant, however, bears <strong>the</strong> burden to show “a substantial likelihood that <strong>the</strong><br />

derivative action is not being maintained for <strong>the</strong> benefit of <strong>the</strong> shareholders.” Id. at 674. Although a number of factors may be<br />

relevant to <strong>the</strong> adequacy determination, see In re Fuqua Indus., S'holder Litig., 752 A.2d 126, 130 (Del.Ch.1999) (citing factors),<br />

our Supreme Court has made clear that this is a very difficult burden unless <strong>the</strong> plaintiff has an actual economic conflict of<br />

interest or has counsel who is incompetent <strong>and</strong> suffers from such a conflict. See In re Infinity Broad. Corp. S'holders Litig.,<br />

802 A.2d 285, 291 (Del.2002); see also In re Fuqua Indus., S'holder Litig., 752 A.2d at 130 (expressing principle); Kahn v.<br />

Household Acquisition Corp., 1982 WL 8778 (Del.Ch. Jan. 19, 1982); see generally Donald J. Wolfe, Jr. & Michael A. Pittenger,<br />

Corporate <strong>and</strong> Commercial Practice in <strong>the</strong> Delaware Court of Chancery, § 9.02(b)(1), at 9–32 (2009). The defendants have not<br />

met this burden. The defendants offer no evidence of an economic conflict between <strong>the</strong> plaintiff <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

stockholders such that he would act in fur<strong>the</strong>rance of his own self-interest at <strong>the</strong>ir expense. Although <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's failure to get<br />

himself up to speed is not laudable, nei<strong>the</strong>r was it such an egregious abdication of his role to supply a basis for disqualification,<br />

especially given <strong>the</strong> absence of facts suggesting an o<strong>the</strong>rwise improper motive for maintaining <strong>the</strong> suit <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> vigor with which<br />

his counsel have prosecuted <strong>the</strong> case since it was transferred to my docket.<br />

6 These individual defendants are Germán Larrea Mota–Velasco, Genaro Larrea Mota–Velasco, Oscar González Rocha, Emilio Carrillo<br />

Gamboa, Jaime Fern<strong>and</strong>ez Collazo Gonzalez, Xavier García de Quevedo Topete, Arm<strong>and</strong>o Ortega Gómez <strong>and</strong> Juan Rebolledo Gout.<br />

7 The record in this case was made less reliable by <strong>the</strong> conduct of both sides. On <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's side, <strong>the</strong> prosecution moved slowly.<br />

Eventually, <strong>the</strong> banker from Goldman who worked for <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, Martin Sanchez, refused to come to Delaware to testify<br />

at trial, even though he had sat for a deposition in New York in 2009. Although one would hope that an investment banker would<br />

recognize a duty to a former client to come <strong>and</strong> testify, that expectation might be thought a bit unreasonable as Sanchez, who lives<br />

in Latin America, was being asked to testify in 2011 about a deal that closed in 2005, <strong>and</strong> he had left <strong>the</strong> employ of Goldman in<br />

2006. His absence is as much or more <strong>the</strong> fault of <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's slow pace as it is of <strong>the</strong> defendants. Ano<strong>the</strong>r issue seems more <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants' fault, or at least <strong>the</strong> fault of <strong>the</strong> former defendants, who were members of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee. Many of <strong>the</strong> minutes of<br />

<strong>the</strong> Special Committee meetings, including all minutes of any Special Committee meeting held after July 20, 2004, were not admitted<br />

into evidence by agreement of <strong>the</strong> parties. The defendants failed to produce minutes of <strong>the</strong>se Special Committee meetings during fact<br />

discovery in this case, which ended on March 1, 2010. Then, on January 23, 2011, <strong>the</strong> defendants produced nearly all of <strong>the</strong> minutes<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee meetings that took place between July 20, 2004 <strong>and</strong> October 21, 2004. These minutes were ra<strong>the</strong>r obviously<br />

responsive to <strong>the</strong> discovery requests made by <strong>the</strong> plaintiff <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re was no reasonable excuse for <strong>the</strong>ir non-production, which seems<br />

to have resulted from <strong>the</strong> migration of an attorney for <strong>the</strong> Special Committee to ano<strong>the</strong>r job <strong>and</strong> a lack of diligence, ra<strong>the</strong>r than a lack<br />

of good faith, in <strong>the</strong> production process. The plaintiff moved to strike this post cut-off production, <strong>and</strong> an oral argument was held on<br />

<strong>the</strong> motion to strike on April 25, 2011. In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru S'holders Litig., C.A. No. 961 (Del. Ch. Apr. 25, 2011) (TRANSCRIPT).<br />

At argument, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's counsel admitted that he had not pressed for discovery of <strong>the</strong> missing minutes because <strong>the</strong> defendants'<br />

failure to produce <strong>the</strong>m was advantageous to his case. Because <strong>the</strong> defendants produced <strong>the</strong> additional Special Committee meeting<br />

minutes only a few months before trial <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> plaintiff was unwilling to re-depose witnesses <strong>and</strong> depose new witnesses based on this<br />

new information, <strong>the</strong> parties agreed to stipulate that such meetings occurred but not to admit <strong>the</strong>m into evidence. The defendants never<br />

produced minutes for meetings of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee that defendants allege took place on August 5, 2004 <strong>and</strong> August 25, 2004.<br />

I am <strong>the</strong>refore missing important evidence which may have helped to inform my analysis of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's deliberations.<br />

8 See JX–125 (Mining Mexico Form 20–F (July 14, 2004)) at 9 (“Our results were adversely affected in 2001 <strong>and</strong> 2002 by decreases<br />

in copper prices ... [U]nder pressure due to low metals prices <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> resulting drop in liquidity, we restructured our debt in 2003<br />

because of our failure to make scheduled payments <strong>and</strong> our noncompliance with certain financial covenants contained in our credit<br />

agreements.”); id. at 19 (stating that in <strong>the</strong> “several year period prior to 2004,” Minera's “competitive <strong>and</strong> financial position had<br />

been negatively influenced” by low metal prices <strong>and</strong> that Minera had “changed its business plan, including <strong>the</strong> cessation of all but<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 33


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

critically necessary capital expenditures ... <strong>and</strong> took several steps to downsize its operations in order to preserve cash resources,” but<br />

noting that <strong>the</strong> copper market had improved, which allowed Minera to “increase [its] levels of capital expenditures to levels consistent<br />

with [its] anticipated increased earnings growth.”); see also Tr. at 98 (Palomino) ( “Minera [ ] had been in pretty difficult financial<br />

conditions until 2002 or beginning of 2003.”).<br />

9 Parker Dep. at 50 (“It was apparent that <strong>the</strong> Minera properties had been severely cash constrained. There were large pieces of<br />

equipment that were parked because <strong>the</strong>y were broken down <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re weren't spare parts to repair <strong>the</strong>m.”).<br />

10 See JX–105 (Goldman presentation to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee (September 15, 2004)) at SP COMM 006787 (showing net debt of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was $15 million).<br />

11 JX–108 at AMC0019912.<br />

12 Id.<br />

13 JX–16 at SP COMM 000441.<br />

14 Although both Perezalonso <strong>and</strong> Ruiz were appointed to <strong>the</strong> Board by Grupo Mexico, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff does not contest that <strong>the</strong>y were<br />

independent <strong>and</strong> unaffiliated with Grupo Mexico. See Aronson v. Lewis, 473 A.2d 805, 816 (Del.1984) (“[I]t is not enough to charge<br />

that a director was nominated by or elected at <strong>the</strong> behest of those controlling <strong>the</strong> outcome of a corporate election. That is <strong>the</strong> usual<br />

way a person becomes a corporate director. It is <strong>the</strong> care, attention <strong>and</strong> sense of individual responsibility to <strong>the</strong> performance of one's<br />

duties, not <strong>the</strong> method of election, that generally touches on independence.”).<br />

15 See Tr. at 21 (Palomino); see also JX–83 (minutes of Special Committee meeting (April 1, 2004)) (discussing <strong>the</strong> problems with <strong>the</strong><br />

term sheet that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee had received on March 25, 2004).<br />

16 Tr. at 27 (Palomino).<br />

17 JX–156 (term sheet from Grupo Mexico to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee (May 7, 2004)) at SP COMM 007078. At this point in <strong>the</strong><br />

negotiation process, Grupo Mexico mistakenly believed that it only owned 98.84% of Minera. As I will note, it later corrects for this<br />

error, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> final Merger consideration reflected Grupo Mexico's full 99.15% equity ownership stake in Minera.<br />

18 JX–101 (Goldman presentation to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee (June 11, 2004)) at SP COMM 003381.<br />

19 See Tr. at 221–222 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“Q [<strong>the</strong> court].... But again I just want to be clear, I am not here—when I am ultimately looking at<br />

<strong>the</strong>m, I am not looking at <strong>the</strong>re is some sort of thing where, you know, <strong>the</strong> market was somehow overvaluing Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> that<br />

you have to sort of normalize for that. That's not what <strong>the</strong> committee ever considered. A. No. Q. Right. I just want you to underst<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong>re is obviously arguments you can make with respect to a thinly traded security like Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru with <strong>the</strong> overhang of control<br />

that <strong>the</strong> trading price might not be as informative as something where <strong>the</strong>re is a much more liquid float. A. Oh, I think <strong>the</strong>re would<br />

have been a robust market for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper in <strong>the</strong> copper industry at or better than <strong>the</strong> price that it traded at.”). Even though<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman testified that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee did not “seriously” consider whe<strong>the</strong>r Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru could have sold 67 million<br />

shares into <strong>the</strong> market for some amount of money, because 67 million shares was close to 85% of <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n outst<strong>and</strong>ing Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

stock, id. at 202 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman), when questioned by <strong>the</strong> court, he conceded that <strong>the</strong> market price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was a reliable<br />

measure of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's worth. At <strong>the</strong> post-trial oral argument, <strong>the</strong> defendants' counsel fur<strong>the</strong>r clarified H<strong>and</strong>elsman's belief that<br />

<strong>the</strong> market price was reliable. See In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru S'holders Litig., C.A. No. 961, at 98 (Del. Ch. July 12, 2011) (TRANSCRIPT)<br />

(“A. [T]he [market] price [of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] was what it was <strong>and</strong> [H<strong>and</strong>elsman] believed it ...”). In fur<strong>the</strong>r exchange with <strong>the</strong> court,<br />

<strong>the</strong> defendants' counsel never contested that <strong>the</strong> market price was not a reliable indicator of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's value. See e.g., id. at 99<br />

(“Q. ... [I]f your clients basically tell me <strong>the</strong> market price is <strong>the</strong> market price, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> market price is 3.1 billion <strong>and</strong> you are only up to<br />

2.7 billion, <strong>and</strong> you are trading at a multiple to DCF <strong>and</strong> you are buying something else at a multiple to DCF, that sounds like a pretty<br />

classic dumb deal. A. That's not what my clients believed ... [t]hey believed, as <strong>the</strong>y testified, that <strong>the</strong>y were getting a bargain; that<br />

Minera was worth more than <strong>the</strong> consideration that Grupo [Mexico] received.); id. at 105 (“Q. Let me just say my simplistic view of<br />

this is if your clients are not going to challenge, as <strong>the</strong>y did not challenge, <strong>the</strong> market value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock, <strong>the</strong>n Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru, <strong>the</strong> stock <strong>the</strong>y gave up was basically worth <strong>the</strong> market price ... A. Right ...”). It is also worth noting that <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's<br />

advisors never advised it that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock should be valued at a discount to its market value, that <strong>the</strong> defendants do not<br />

challenge <strong>the</strong> market price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru in <strong>the</strong>ir briefs, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> defendants' trial expert did nothing to question <strong>the</strong> reliability<br />

of <strong>the</strong> <strong>the</strong>n-current market price. See Tr. at 464 (Schwartz) (“I didn't look at <strong>the</strong> liquidity, I didn't look at <strong>the</strong> control issues, I didn't<br />

look at o<strong>the</strong>r issues. I didn't look at o<strong>the</strong>r corporate companies that were trading.”).<br />

20 Tr. at 157 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman).<br />

21 Tr. at 159 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“I think <strong>the</strong> committee was somewhat comforted by <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> DCF analysis of Minera [ ] <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

DCF analysis of [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] were not as different as <strong>the</strong> discounted cash flow analysis of Minera [ ] <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> market value of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru.”).<br />

22 This is a word I do not use when I have to conduct a necessarily imperfect valuation of an asset. The word itself implies a certainty<br />

better attributed to an omniscient creator than a flawed human.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 34


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

23 See Tr. at 42 (Palomino) (“Q. ... [A]s of ... June 11, 2004, what was <strong>the</strong> special committee's view of <strong>the</strong> transaction that had been<br />

proposed by Grupo Mexico? A. That <strong>the</strong> figures that <strong>the</strong>y were asking were too high ...”); Tr. at 156–57 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“Q. What<br />

did you learn from <strong>the</strong>se preliminary analyses that Goldman Sachs performed? A. That <strong>the</strong>ir results showed that <strong>the</strong> value of Minera<br />

[ ] was substantially less than <strong>the</strong> asked price of Grupo Mexico by a substantial margin ...”).<br />

24 JX–103 (Goldman presentation to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee (July 8, 2004)) at SP COMM 006896–SP COMM 006898.<br />

25 JX–18 (list of historical stock prices of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru) at 9 ($40.30 x 28,900,000 = $1,164,670,000; $40.30 x 71,300,000 =<br />

$2,873,390,000).<br />

26 Id. ($40.30 x 52,000,000 = $2,095,600,000).<br />

27 The exact terms of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's proposed fixed exchange ratio are unclear on this record.<br />

28 Tr. at 155 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman).<br />

29 Id.<br />

30 See id. at 48 (Palomino) (explaining that his impression at <strong>the</strong> time negotiations began was that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was doing well in<br />

<strong>the</strong> market because “<strong>the</strong> market was estimating higher ore grades <strong>and</strong> higher copper prices than we thought were in fact going to be<br />

maintained in <strong>the</strong> long run”); id. at 313 (Jacob) (discussing rising copper prices in 2004).<br />

31 Between July 20, 2004 <strong>and</strong> August 21, 2004, <strong>the</strong> average closing price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock was $38.28. JX–18 at 8–9 ($38.28<br />

x 80,000,000 = $3,062,400,000).<br />

32 JX–129 (Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corporation Schedule 14A (February 25, 2005) (Proxy Statement)) at 22.<br />

33 JX–18 at 8 ($41.20 x 67,000,000= $2,760,400,000).<br />

34 Id. ($45.72 x 67,000,000 = $3,063,240,000).<br />

35 JX–105 at SP COMM 006805.<br />

36 The EV/2005E EBITDA multiple of 6.3x used in this presentation was not a real market multiple, or even a Wall Street analysis<br />

consensus multiple, but an internal Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru management number supposedly based on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's internal projections<br />

for its 2005E EBITDA, unadjusted for royalty tax owed to <strong>the</strong> Peruvian government. As will be discussed, it seems aggressive, at<br />

<strong>the</strong> very least.<br />

37 JX–18 at 8 ($45.34 x 61,000,000 = $2,765,740,000; $45.34 x 72,000,000 = $3,264,480,000).<br />

38 Id. at 8 ($46.22 x 64,000,000 million = $2,958,080,000).<br />

39 Minera was contractually obligated to make m<strong>and</strong>atory prepayments on its long-term credit facilities when, among o<strong>the</strong>r things,<br />

<strong>the</strong> price of copper exceeded $0.88 per pound. See JX–125 at 55 (“when <strong>the</strong> price[ ] of copper ... exceed[s] $0.88 per pound ... we<br />

will pay an amount equal to 75% of <strong>the</strong> excess cash flow generated by <strong>the</strong> sales of such metals at <strong>the</strong> higher metal price, which<br />

will be applied first, to <strong>the</strong> amortization of Tranche B, <strong>the</strong>n to <strong>the</strong> amortization of Tranche A.”). The price of copper went north of<br />

$0.88 per pound on October 15, 2003. The record shows that Minera was paying down its debt, presumably in compliance with its<br />

prepayment obligation. See JX–103 at SP COMM 006861 (Minera's net debt as of May 31, 2004 was $1.189 million); JX–107 (road<br />

show presentation (November 2004)) at SP COMM 006674 (Minera's net debt as of June 30, 2004 was $1.06 billion).<br />

40 Tr. at 175 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman).<br />

41 Id. at 185 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman).<br />

42 Id. at 176 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman).<br />

43 JX–18 at 8 ($53.16 x 67,000,000 = $3,561,720,000).<br />

44 The parties fur<strong>the</strong>r agreed that for <strong>the</strong> purposes of <strong>the</strong> two-thirds vote, each share would only be entitled to one vote. Thus, Grupo<br />

Mexico could only vote its 54.17% equity ownership, not <strong>the</strong> 63.08% voting power it ordinarily held due to <strong>the</strong> super-voting rights<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Founders Shares.<br />

45 14.2% <strong>and</strong> 13.95% respectively.<br />

46 The Founders Shares held by Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge were unregistered <strong>and</strong> thus could not be publicly sold in <strong>the</strong> marketplace.<br />

Securities Act of 1933 § 5(a), 15 U.S.C. § 77e(a) (2010). SEC Rule 144 provides an exemption from <strong>the</strong> registration requirements<br />

<strong>and</strong> allows public resale of restricted securities if certain conditions are met. But, Rule 144 contains volume restrictions that made it<br />

impossible for Cerro or Phelps Dodge to sell a bloc of <strong>the</strong>ir shares. Specifically, Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge, as “affiliates” of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru, were prevented from selling an amount greater than one percent of <strong>the</strong> outst<strong>and</strong>ing Founders Shares in any three-month period.<br />

17 C.F.R. § 230.144(e) (2010). Absent registration, Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge faced a prolonged goodbye.<br />

47 Tr. at 182 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“I had talked to <strong>the</strong> general counsel both of Grupo Mexico <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru about registration rights from<br />

<strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> first term sheet that Grupo Mexico sent.”).<br />

48 Id. at 167 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“[W]e were all long-term holders, <strong>and</strong> we all had directors, so we were all affiliates. So none of us could<br />

really sell our shares.”); cf. id. at 184 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (discussing market difficulties of selling stock even if Cerro could cease to be<br />

an affiliate for purposes of <strong>the</strong> volume restrictions of Rule 144).<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 35


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

49 See id. at 205 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“Q. Do you know whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>re were o<strong>the</strong>r people on behalf of Cerro that were speaking to Mr. Larrea<br />

at about that time [of <strong>the</strong> agreement to vote Cerro's shares in accordance with <strong>the</strong> Special Committee in exchange for registration<br />

rights] about Cerro's interest in selling its shares? A. I am sure <strong>the</strong>re weren't.”).<br />

50 Id. at 168 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“And both we <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge wanted to get out.”); id. at 167 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“And quite frankly, we<br />

had an interest in selling our shares.”).<br />

51 Id. at 184–85 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman).<br />

52 JX–15 (letter agreement between AMC <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge (December 22, 2004)) at AMC0024877.<br />

53 JX–13 (Agreement <strong>and</strong> Plan of Merger (October 21, 2004)) § 5.9(b) ( “In <strong>the</strong> event that, prior to <strong>the</strong> Effective Time <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee believes, in its good faith judgment, after receiving <strong>the</strong> advice of its outside legal counsel, that failing to do so would<br />

create a reasonable likelihood of breaching its fiduciary duties under applicable law, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee ... may ... withdraw or<br />

modify its approval or recommendation in favor of <strong>the</strong> [Merger].”).<br />

54 Id.<br />

* * *<br />

55 JX–18 at 7 ($45.90 x 67,200,000 = $3,084,480,000).<br />

56 During discovery, two Microsoft Excel worksheets were unear<strong>the</strong>d that appear to suggest <strong>the</strong> implied equity values of Minera <strong>and</strong><br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru that underlie Goldman's October 21 presentation. One worksheet, which contains <strong>the</strong> Minera model, indicates an<br />

implied equity value for Minera of $1.25 billion using a long-term copper price of $0.90/lb <strong>and</strong> a discount rate of 8.5%. The o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

worksheet, which contains <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru model, indicates an implied equity value for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru of $1.6 billion using a<br />

copper price of $0.90 <strong>and</strong> a discount rate of 9.0%, <strong>and</strong> assuming a royalty tax of 2%. Both <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's expert <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> defendants'<br />

expert relied on <strong>the</strong> projections contained in <strong>the</strong>se worksheets in <strong>the</strong>ir reports. The defendants have also not contested <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's<br />

expert's contention that <strong>the</strong>se worksheets include Goldman's discounted cash flow estimates as of October 21, 2004.<br />

57 JX–106 (Goldman presentation to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee (October 21, 2004)).<br />

58 JX–18 at 7 ($45.92 x 47,200,000 = $2,167,424,000; $45.92 x 87,800,000 = $4,031,776,000).<br />

59 See Tr. at 181–82 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“We were sitting in Goldman Sachs' office in Mexico City on this October day, <strong>and</strong> a lawyer from<br />

Goldman's counsel called Goldman <strong>and</strong> said that—did <strong>the</strong>y recognize that I had something that was <strong>the</strong> appearance of a conflict. And<br />

everybody looked at each o<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>and</strong> it was sort of incredulous about this <strong>and</strong> how it would come up on <strong>the</strong> morning of <strong>the</strong> date that<br />

<strong>the</strong> committee was supposed to vote. And I looked at it <strong>and</strong> I said, Well, if I have a conflict or <strong>the</strong>y think I have a conflict or this is<br />

a potential for a conflict or <strong>the</strong>re is an appearance of a conflict, <strong>the</strong>n I won't vote.”).<br />

60 See, e.g., List of Historical Stock Prices of Antofagasta (October 21, 2004 to April 1, 2005), http://uk.finance.yahoo.com/q/hp?<br />

s=ANTO. L&b=21&a=09&c=2004&e=1&d=03&f =2005&g=d; List of Historical Stock Prices of FreeportMcMoRan (October 21,<br />

2004 to April 1, 2005), http:// finance.yahoo. com/q/hp?s=FCX&a=09&b=21&c=2004&d=03&e=1&f=2005&g=d; List of Historical<br />

Stock Prices of Grupo Mexico (October 21, 2004 to April 1, 2005), http:// finance.yahoo.com/q/hp?s=GMEXICOB. MX&a=09&b<br />

=21&c =2004&d=03&e=1&f=2005&g=d.<br />

61 Tr. at 187 (“Q. ... [b]efore <strong>the</strong> transaction closed at <strong>the</strong> end of April 2005, did <strong>the</strong> special committee do anything to determine whe<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction was still fair? A. Well, I don't know what <strong>the</strong> special committee did, but I called a representative at Goldman <strong>and</strong> said,<br />

Has anything happened since <strong>the</strong> transaction was approved by <strong>the</strong> board that would suggest to you that this transaction was not fair?<br />

And I got <strong>the</strong> answer, no, nothing like that has happened.”).<br />

62 Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's 2004 full financial performance was publicly disclosed in its 2004 10–K, which was filed on March 16, 2005; <strong>the</strong><br />

stockholder vote took place on March 28, 2005. Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's previously filed quarterly reports did not indicate that it would achieve<br />

such a high EBITDA. See, e.g., Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corporation 10–Q for <strong>the</strong> quarter ending September 30, 2004 (November 9,<br />

2004) at 3, available at http://sec. gov/Archives/edgar/data/1001838/000110465904034621/a04–13088_110q.htm, (showing 2004<br />

EBITDA for <strong>the</strong> last nine months of $597.8 million). But, <strong>the</strong> members of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee, as directors of <strong>the</strong> company, would<br />

have had access to <strong>the</strong> basic information contained in <strong>the</strong> 2004 10–K before it became public. Ei<strong>the</strong>r way, <strong>the</strong> results were out 12<br />

days before <strong>the</strong> Merger vote.<br />

63 Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's actual 2005 EBITDA was $1.365 billion, as compared to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's 2005E EBITDA based on unadjusted<br />

management projections of $581 million.<br />

64 Minera's actual 2005 EBITDA was $971.6 million, as compared to Minera's 2005E EBITDA based on unadjusted management<br />

projections of $672 million.<br />

65 JX–18 at 5 ($55.89 x 67,200,000 = $3,755,808,000).<br />

66 When Vice Chancellor Lamb left <strong>the</strong> Court in 2009, this case was reassigned to me. By that time, Vice Chancellor Lamb had already<br />

admonished <strong>the</strong> plaintiff for its torpid pace in prosecuting <strong>the</strong> case. In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru S'holders Litig., C.A. No. 961 at 20 (Del.<br />

Ch. July 1, 2009) (TRANSCRIPT) (“I can't quite strongly enough express my displeasure at how delayed this litigation has been <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>the</strong> fact that it wasn't prepared for trial two or three years ago.”).<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 36


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

67 Cf. In re Loral Space & Commc'ns Inc., 2008 WL 4293781, at *33 (Del.Ch. Sept. 19, 2008) (“For example, being a non-independent<br />

director who approved a conflict transaction found unfair does not make one, without more, liable personally for <strong>the</strong> harm caused.<br />

Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> court must examine that director's behavior in order to assess whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> director breached her fiduciary duties <strong>and</strong>, if a<br />

§ 102(b)(7) clause is in effect, acted with <strong>the</strong> requisite state of mind to have committed a non-exculpated breach.”).<br />

68 I recognize that this is a close question. The bottom line requirement of loyalty is that a director act in <strong>the</strong> best interests of <strong>the</strong> company<br />

<strong>and</strong> its stockholders, ra<strong>the</strong>r than for any o<strong>the</strong>r reason. See In re RJR Nabisco, Inc. S'holders Litig., 1989 WL 7036, at *15 (Del.Ch.<br />

Jan. 31, 1989). Myriad interests have caused fiduciaries to stray from <strong>the</strong> straight path. What I struggle with here is that a director<br />

would be considered interested because he (or in this case, his employer) desired <strong>the</strong> liquidity available to <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r stockholders.<br />

Although I do not struggle with finding that a stockholder-representative in this situation has difficult incentives, I believe it would<br />

be mistaken to consider this sort of interest as constituting an interest in <strong>the</strong> formal sense of imposing liability for breach of <strong>the</strong> duty<br />

of loyalty absent a showing that <strong>the</strong> director in bad faith subordinated <strong>the</strong> best interests of <strong>the</strong> company in getting a fair price to his<br />

desire to have <strong>the</strong> liquidity available to o<strong>the</strong>r stockholders. Given that summary judgment in H<strong>and</strong>elsman's favor has already been<br />

granted <strong>and</strong> given <strong>the</strong> resources of Grupo Mexico <strong>and</strong> its affiliated defendants, this interesting question does not seem likely to have<br />

a real world effect. In view of that, I am even more reluctant to call a stockholder's desire for liquidity an interest, because <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is likely utility in having directors who represent stockholders with a deep financial stake that gives <strong>the</strong>m an incentive to monitor<br />

management <strong>and</strong> controlling stockholders closely. In a real way, Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge were seeking <strong>the</strong> same liquidity as o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

minority stockholders, although I realize H<strong>and</strong>elsman's service on <strong>the</strong> board was a choice that exacerbated Cerro's problem.<br />

69 See Kahn v. Tremont Corp., 694 A.2d 422, 428–29 (Del.1997) (applying entire fairness review to an interested transaction where <strong>the</strong><br />

controlling shareholder of a corporation caused it to purchase shares of a second controlled corporation); Emerald Partners v. Berlin,<br />

726 A.2d 1215, 1221 (Del.1999) (applying entire fairness review to a merger whereby a controlled corporation acquired thirteen<br />

corporations controlled by <strong>the</strong> same shareholder); Leo E. Strine, Jr., The Inescapably Empirical Foundation of <strong>the</strong> Common Law of<br />

Corporations, 27 Del. J. Corp. L. 499, 510 (2002).<br />

70 In In re Pure Res., Inc., S'holders Litig., 808 A.2d 421, 443–46 (Del.Ch.2002); In re Cysive, Inc. S'holders Litig., 836 A.2d 531, 547–<br />

51 (Del.Ch.2003), In re Cox Commc'ns, Inc. S'holders Litig., 879 A.2d 604, 617 (Del.Ch.2005), <strong>and</strong> more recently, In re CNX Gas<br />

Corp. S'holders Litig., 4 A.3d 397, 406–14 (Del.Ch.2010), <strong>the</strong> Court of Chancery has explained why <strong>the</strong>re might be utility to having<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r guidance from <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court in this sensitive area of <strong>the</strong> law <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> reasons why <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard articulated in Kahn v. Lynch<br />

Communication Systems, Inc., 638 A.2d 1110, 1117 (Del.1994), makes it difficult for parties to actually present questions regarding<br />

<strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard to <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court. See In re Cox Commc'ns, Inc. S'holders Litig., 879 A.2d at 619–22 (explaining why this is so).<br />

71 Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 710 (Del.1983) (citation omitted).<br />

72 Caution is required here. The entire fairness st<strong>and</strong>ard ill suits <strong>the</strong> inquiry whe<strong>the</strong>r disinterested directors who approve a self-dealing<br />

transaction <strong>and</strong> are protected by an exculpatory charter provision authorized by 8 Del. C. § 102(b)(7) can be held liable for breach<br />

of fiduciary duties. Unless <strong>the</strong>re are facts suggesting that <strong>the</strong> directors consciously approved an unfair transaction, <strong>the</strong> bad faith<br />

preference for some o<strong>the</strong>r interest than that of <strong>the</strong> company <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> stockholders that is critical to disloyalty is absent. The fact that<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction is found to be unfair is of course relevant, but hardly sufficient, to that separate, individualized inquiry. In this sense,<br />

<strong>the</strong> more stringent, strict liability st<strong>and</strong>ard applicable to interested parties such as Grupo Mexico is critically different than that which<br />

must be used to address directors such as those on <strong>the</strong> Special Committee.<br />

73 See Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 711.<br />

74 Id.<br />

75 In re John Q. Hammons Hotels Inc. S'holder Litig., 2009 WL 3165613, at *13 (Del.Ch. Oct. 2, 2009) (citing Valeant Pharm. Int'l<br />

v. Jerney, 921 A.2d 732, 746 (Del.Ch.2007)).<br />

76 Weinberger, 457 A.2d at 711.<br />

77 See, e.g., Valeant Pharm. Int'l, 921 A.2d at 746 (“The two components of <strong>the</strong> entire fairness concept are not independent, but ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> fair dealing prong informs <strong>the</strong> court as to <strong>the</strong> fairness of <strong>the</strong> price obtained through that process.”).<br />

78 Kahn v. Lynch Commc'n Sys., Inc., 638 A.2d 1110 (Del.1994).<br />

79 See id. at 1117 (“Never<strong>the</strong>less, even when an interested cash-out merger transaction receives <strong>the</strong> informed approval of a majority of<br />

minority stockholders or an independent committee of disinterested directors, an entire fairness analysis is <strong>the</strong> only proper st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

of review.”); see also In re Pure Res., Inc., S'holders Litig., 808 A.2d 421, 435–36 (Del.Ch.2002) (explaining this reality); In re Cox<br />

Commc'ns, Inc. S'holders Litig., 879 A.2d 604, 617 (Del.Ch.2005) (same); see also id. at 617 (“All in all, it is perhaps fairest <strong>and</strong> more<br />

sensible to read Lynch as being premised on a sincere concern that mergers with controlling stockholders involve an extraordinary<br />

potential for <strong>the</strong> exploitation by powerful insiders of <strong>the</strong>ir informational advantages <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir voting clout. Facing <strong>the</strong> proverbial 800<br />

pound gorilla who wants <strong>the</strong> rest of <strong>the</strong> bananas all for himself, chimpanzees like independent directors <strong>and</strong> disinterested stockholders<br />

could not be expected to make sure that <strong>the</strong> gorilla paid a fair price. Therefore, <strong>the</strong> residual protection of an unavoidable review of<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 37


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

<strong>the</strong> financial fairness whenever plaintiffs could raise a genuine dispute of fact about that issue was thought to be a necessary final<br />

protection.”) (citations omitted).<br />

80 See Lynch, 638 A.2d at 1117 (citation omitted).<br />

81 See Pl. Op. Post–Tr. Br. at 14 (citing Kahn v. Tremont Corp., 694 A.2d 422, 429 (Del.1997); Gesoff v. IIC Indus., 902 A.2d 1130,<br />

1148 (Del.Ch.2006); Rabkin v. Olin Corp., 1990 WL 47648, at *6 (Del.Ch. Apr. 17, 1990)).<br />

82 As I have noted before, it is unclear to me if <strong>the</strong>re is much, if any, practical implication of a burden shift. See In re Cysive, Inc.<br />

S'holders Litig., 836 A.2d 531, 548 (Del.Ch.2003) (“The practical effect of <strong>the</strong> Lynch doctrine's burden shift is slight. One reason<br />

why this is so is that shifting <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion under a preponderance st<strong>and</strong>ard is not a major move, if one assumes, as I do,<br />

that <strong>the</strong> outcome of very few cases hinges on what happens if ... <strong>the</strong> evidence is in equipoise.”).<br />

83 Tremont, 694 A.2d at 429 (Del.1997) (citation omitted).<br />

84 Id. at 428.<br />

85 In re Cox Commc'ns, Inc. S'holders Litig., 879 A.2d 604, 617 (Del.Ch.2005) (“But, in order to encourage <strong>the</strong> use of procedural devices<br />

such as special committees <strong>and</strong> Minority Approval Conditions that tended to encourage fair pricing, <strong>the</strong> Court [in Lynch ] did give<br />

transactional proponents a modest procedural benefit—<strong>the</strong> shifting of <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion on <strong>the</strong> ultimate issue of fairness to<br />

<strong>the</strong> plaintiffs—if <strong>the</strong> transaction proponents proved, in a factually intensive way, that <strong>the</strong> procedural devices had, in fact, operated<br />

with integrity.”) (emphasis added) (citation omitted).<br />

86 Accord Kahn v. Lynch Commc'n Sys., Inc., 638 A.2d 1110, 1121 (“[U]nless <strong>the</strong> controlling or dominating shareholder can demonstrate<br />

that it has not only formed an independent committee but also replicated a process ‘as though each of <strong>the</strong> contending parties had in<br />

fact exerted its bargaining power at arm's length,’ <strong>the</strong> burden of proving entire fairness will not shift.”) (citing Weinberger v. UOP,<br />

Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 709–10 n. 7 (Del.1983)).<br />

87 Tremont, 694 A.2d at 424.<br />

88 Id. at 426 (“Although <strong>the</strong> three men were deemed ‘independent’ for purposes of this transaction, all had significant prior business<br />

relationships with Simmons or Simmons' controlled companies.”); id. at 429–30 (exploring <strong>the</strong> significance of <strong>the</strong> ties).<br />

89 Id. at 426–27 (discussing that <strong>the</strong> financial advisor was affiliated with <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder, that <strong>the</strong> legal advisor was selected<br />

by <strong>the</strong> general counsel of both <strong>the</strong> company <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder, that <strong>the</strong> conflict check was performed by <strong>the</strong> general<br />

counsel, <strong>and</strong> that <strong>the</strong> legal advisor had represented <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder's company in prior business deals).<br />

90 Id. at 427.<br />

91 Id. (noting that <strong>the</strong> special committee only met four times, that only one director was able to attend all <strong>the</strong> meetings, <strong>and</strong> that he was<br />

also <strong>the</strong> only director to attend <strong>the</strong> review sessions with <strong>the</strong> advisors).<br />

92 Id. at 430.<br />

93 Judge Quillen was <strong>the</strong>n a member of <strong>the</strong> Superior Court <strong>and</strong> was sitting on <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court by designation. Id. at 423 n. *.<br />

94 Id. at 433 (Quillen, J., concurring) (noting <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> deal to <strong>the</strong> controlling stockholder, <strong>the</strong> difficulties <strong>the</strong> controlling<br />

stockholder would face in trying to accomplish a similar deal with a non-affiliated entity, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> time constraint <strong>the</strong> controlling<br />

stockholder was under to achieve <strong>the</strong> tax savings).<br />

95 Id.<br />

96 Id.<br />

97 Id. (falling from $16 per share to $12.75 per share).<br />

98 Id.<br />

99 Id. (majority opinion) at 429.<br />

100 Id. at 428.<br />

101 See also Kahn v. Lynch Commc'n Sys., Inc., 638 A.2d 1110, 1121 (Del.1994) (discussing with approval <strong>the</strong> Supreme Court's<br />

conclusion in Rabkin v. Philip A. Hunt Chem. Corp. that “<strong>the</strong> majority stockholder's ‘attitude towards <strong>the</strong> minority,’ coupled with<br />

<strong>the</strong> ‘apparent absence of any meaningful negotiations as to price,’ did not manifest <strong>the</strong> exercise of arm's length bargaining by <strong>the</strong><br />

independent committee” <strong>and</strong> that “<strong>the</strong> burden on entire fairness would not be shifted by <strong>the</strong> use of an independent committee which<br />

concluded its processes with ‘what could be considered a quick surrender’ to <strong>the</strong> dictated terms of <strong>the</strong> controlling shareholder.”)<br />

(citing Rabkin v. Philip A. Hunt Chem. Corp., 498 A.2d 1099, 1106 (Del.1985)).<br />

102 See, e.g., In re Cysive, Inc. S'holders Litig., 836 A.2d 531, 548 (Del.Ch.2003) (“Because <strong>the</strong>se devices are thought, however, to be<br />

useful <strong>and</strong> to incline transactions towards fairness, <strong>the</strong> Lynch doctrine encourages <strong>the</strong>m by giving defendants <strong>the</strong> benefits of a burden<br />

shift if ei<strong>the</strong>r one of <strong>the</strong> devices is employed.”).<br />

103 See William T. Allen et. al., Function Over Form: A Reassessment of St<strong>and</strong>ards of Review in Delaware Corporation Law, 56 Bus.<br />

L. 1287, 1297 (2001) (explaining that st<strong>and</strong>ards of review should be functional, in that <strong>the</strong>y should serve as a “useful tool that aids<br />

<strong>the</strong> court in deciding <strong>the</strong> fiduciary duty issue” ra<strong>the</strong>r than merely “signal <strong>the</strong> result or outcome.”).<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 38


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

104 Obviously, if a more important shift was contingent upon this factor, <strong>the</strong> cost-benefit analysis would be closer. In part for that reason<br />

<strong>and</strong>, as importantly, because <strong>the</strong> role of an independent negotiating agent is different from that of an approving principal (to use<br />

economic, not legal concepts), see In re John Q. Hammons Hotels Inc. S'holder Litig., 2009 WL 3165613, at *12 (Del.Ch. Oct. 2,<br />

2009); In re Cox Commc'ns, Inc. S'holders Litig., 879 A.2d 604, 645 (Del.Ch.2005), <strong>and</strong> because our statute often contemplates<br />

both <strong>the</strong> requirements of board <strong>and</strong> stockholder approval in third-party mergers, 8 Del. C. § 251, I am more comfortable according<br />

business judgment rule st<strong>and</strong>ard of review treatment to an interested transaction only if a transaction is contingent in advance on<br />

both: i) <strong>the</strong> negotiation, approval <strong>and</strong> veto authority of an independent board majority or special committee; <strong>and</strong> ii) <strong>the</strong> approval<br />

of a majority of <strong>the</strong> uncoerced, fully informed, <strong>and</strong> disinterested stockholders. In re Cox Commc'ns, Inc. S'holders Litig., 879 A.2d<br />

at 643 (noting that such an alteration would “mirro[r] what is contemplated in an arms-length merger under § 251—independent,<br />

disinterested director <strong>and</strong> stockholder approval.”) (footnote omitted). Absent <strong>the</strong> assurance that <strong>the</strong> stockholders <strong>the</strong>mselves have <strong>the</strong><br />

opportunity to turn down <strong>the</strong> transaction freely, <strong>the</strong> costs of such a move would seem to outweigh <strong>the</strong> benefits. With a st<strong>and</strong>ard that<br />

would systemically encourage both <strong>the</strong> employment of an active independent negotiating agent <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> empowerment of disinterested<br />

stockholders to protect <strong>the</strong>mselves <strong>and</strong> hold those agents accountable, <strong>the</strong> benefits to investors could be considerable <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>re would<br />

be a better chance to focus litigation on those transactions that are most questionable, which would also make <strong>the</strong> cost-benefit ratio<br />

of <strong>the</strong> representative litigation process better for diversified investors. See id. at 643–45 (discussing how this reform would eliminate<br />

perverse litigation incentives <strong>and</strong> “encourage <strong>the</strong> filing of claims only by plaintiffs <strong>and</strong> plaintiffs' lawyers who genuinely believed<br />

that a wrong had been committed.”).<br />

105 See In re Cysive, Inc. S'holders Litig., 836 A.2d at 548–49 (explaining why this more searching approach tends to conflate <strong>the</strong> burdenshifting<br />

analysis with that of procedural fairness).<br />

106 See Allen et. al., supra note 103, at 1297–98.<br />

107 Cf. In re Cysive, Inc. S'holders Litig., 836 A.2d at 549 (noting that “it is unsurprising that few defendants have sought a pre-trial<br />

hearing to determine who bears <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion on fairness” given “<strong>the</strong> factually intense nature of <strong>the</strong> burden-shifting<br />

inquiry” <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> “modest benefit” gained from <strong>the</strong> shift).<br />

108 See Allen et. al., supra note 103, at 1303–04 n. 63 (noting <strong>the</strong> practical problems litigants face when <strong>the</strong> burden of proof <strong>the</strong>y are<br />

forced to bear is not made clear until after <strong>the</strong> trial); cf. In re Cysive, Inc. S'holders Litig., 836 A.2d at 549 (“[I]n order to prove that a<br />

burden shift occurred because of an effective special committee, <strong>the</strong> defendants must present evidence of a fair process. Because <strong>the</strong>y<br />

must present this affirmatively, <strong>the</strong>y have to act like <strong>the</strong>y have <strong>the</strong> burden of persuasion throughout <strong>the</strong> entire trial court process.”).<br />

109 See In re Cysive, Inc. S'holders Litig., 836 A.2d at 549 (noting that it is inefficient for defendants to seek a pre-trial ruling on <strong>the</strong><br />

burden-shift unless <strong>the</strong> discovery process has generated a sufficient factual record to make such a determination).<br />

110 See Emerald Partners v. Berlin, 726 A.2d 1215, 1222–23 (Del.1999) (describing that <strong>the</strong> special committee must exert “real<br />

bargaining power” in order for defendants to obtain a burden shift); see also Beam v. Stewart, 845 A.2d 1040, 1055 n. 45 (Del.2004)<br />

(citing Kahn v. Tremont Corp., 694 A.2d 422, 429–30 (Del.1997)) (noting that <strong>the</strong> test articulated in Tremont requires a determination<br />

as to whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> committee members “in fact ” functioned independently).<br />

111 Tremont, 694 A.2d at 428.<br />

112 Rabkin v. Olin Corp., 1990 WL 47648, at *6 (Del.Ch. Apr. 17, 1990), aff'd, 586 A.2d 1202 (Del.1990) (TABLE) (“If an informed<br />

vote of a majority of <strong>the</strong> minority shareholders has approved a challenged transaction, <strong>and</strong> in fact <strong>the</strong> merger is contingent on such<br />

approval, <strong>the</strong> burden entirely shifts to <strong>the</strong> plaintiffs to show that <strong>the</strong> transaction was unfair to <strong>the</strong> minority.” (emphasis added)); see<br />

also In re Wheelabrator Techs., Inc. S'holders Litig., 663 A.2d 1194, 1203 (Del.Ch.1995) (same).<br />

113 In a merger where <strong>the</strong>re is no controller <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> disinterested electorate controls <strong>the</strong> outcome from <strong>the</strong> get go, <strong>the</strong>re is no need to<br />

bargain over this element. In such a situation, it has long been my underst<strong>and</strong>ing of Delaware law, that <strong>the</strong> approval of an uncoerced,<br />

disinterested electorate of a merger (including a sale) would have <strong>the</strong> effect of invoking <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule st<strong>and</strong>ard of review.<br />

See, e.g., In re Wheelabrator Techs., Inc. S'holders Litig., 663 A.2d at 1201 n. 4, 1202–03 (describing <strong>the</strong> effect of an informed,<br />

uncoerced, <strong>and</strong> disinterested stockholder approval of a merger not involving a controlling stockholder <strong>and</strong> finding that such approval<br />

invokes <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule st<strong>and</strong>ard of review). It may be that a vote in that context does not involve “pure ratification,” see<br />

Gantler v. Stephens, 965 A.2d 695, 712–13 (Del.2009), but I have long understood that under our law it would invoke <strong>the</strong> business<br />

judgment rule st<strong>and</strong>ard of review. See Harbor Fin. Partners v. Huizenga, 751 A.2d 879, 890, 895–900 (Del.Ch.1999) (discussing<br />

history of <strong>the</strong> long tradition to invoking <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule st<strong>and</strong>ard when informed, disinterested stockholders approve a<br />

third-party merger <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> limited waste exception to this effect); Solomon v. Armstrong, 747 A.2d 1098, 1113–17 (Del.Ch.1999),<br />

aff'd, 746 A.2d 277 (Del.2000) (citing cases to this effect); see also Allen et. al., supra note 103, at 1307–09 (expressing <strong>the</strong> policy<br />

rationale for giving full “ratification” effect to an uncoerced, disinterested shareholder vote). Perhaps a more nuanced nomenclature<br />

is needed to describe <strong>the</strong> traditional effect that a disinterested stockholder vote has had on <strong>the</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ard of review used to evaluate<br />

a challenge to an arm's length, third-party merger <strong>and</strong> to distinguish it from “classic” or “pure ratification.” See Harbor Finance<br />

Partners, 751 A.2d at 900 n. 78 (“For want of better nomenclature, I use <strong>the</strong> term [“ratification”] as describing a stockholder vote<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 39


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

sufficient to invoke <strong>the</strong> business judgment rule st<strong>and</strong>ard of review.”). The key is not what you call it, but ra<strong>the</strong>r preserving <strong>the</strong> utility<br />

of a long-st<strong>and</strong>ing doctrine of our law.<br />

114 See In re John Q. Hammons Hotels Inc. S'holder Litig., 2009 WL 3165613, at *13 (Del.Ch. Oct. 2, 2009) (“Moreover, a clear<br />

explanation of <strong>the</strong> pre-conditions to <strong>the</strong> Merger is necessary to ensure that <strong>the</strong> minority stockholders are aware of <strong>the</strong> importance of<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir votes <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>ir ability to block a transaction <strong>the</strong>y do not believe is fair.”).<br />

115 See Bershad v. Curtiss–Wright Corp., 535 A.2d 840, 846 (Del.1987) (citations omitted).<br />

116 See JX–103 at SP COMM 006886 (generating a high-end st<strong>and</strong>alone value of Minera of $2.085 billion, using <strong>the</strong> A & S-adjusted<br />

projections, a 7.5% discount rate, <strong>and</strong> a long-term copper price of $1.00/lb); id. at SP COMM 006898 (generating a mid-range relative<br />

value of 58.8 shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, using A & S-adjusted projections, a 9.0% discount rate, <strong>and</strong> a long-term copper price of<br />

$0.90/lb).<br />

117 The vote is of no less importance for purposes of <strong>the</strong> disclosure analysis simply because <strong>the</strong> result of <strong>the</strong> vote was effectively a<br />

lock. O<strong>the</strong>rwise, <strong>the</strong> defendants would reap an analytical benefit from <strong>the</strong>ir decision not to condition <strong>the</strong> Merger on a majority of<br />

<strong>the</strong> minority vote.<br />

118 Grupo Mexico's equity share of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru increased from 54.2% to 75.1% as a result of <strong>the</strong> Merger. See JX–107.<br />

119 In its June 11, 2004 presentation, Goldman presented a DCF analysis that generated a midrange implied equity value for Minera of<br />

$1.7 billion, using an 8.5% discount rate, $0.90/lb long-term copper prices, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> A & S adjusted projections. JX–101 at SP COMM<br />

003375. In its July 8, 2004 presentation, Goldman presented a revised DCF analysis, which generated a mid-range implied equity<br />

value for Minera of $1.358 billion, using <strong>the</strong> same 8.5% discount rage, $0.90/lb long-term copper prices, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> A & S adjusted<br />

projections. JX–103 at SP COMM 006886.<br />

120 According to Goldman's spreadsheets produced by <strong>the</strong> plaintiff in discovery, Goldman arrived at a mid-range implied equity value<br />

of $1.254 billion for Minera, using an 8.5% discount rate <strong>and</strong> a $0.90 long-term copper price. The spreadsheets show that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru's mid-range implied equity value was $1.6 billion, assuming a 9.5% discount rate, a $0.90 long-term copper price, <strong>and</strong> a royalty<br />

tax rate of 2%.<br />

121 At <strong>the</strong> time of signing on October 21, 2004, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru shares were trading at $45.92. Given its capitalization of 80 million issued<br />

shares, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's actual market equity value was $3.67 billion.<br />

122 JX–129 at 34. Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's EV/2005E EBITDA multiple of 5.5x was based on estimates of future results contained in selected<br />

Wall Street research reports, id. at 33, <strong>and</strong> appears to have been unadjusted for <strong>the</strong> $100 million dividend. Compare JX–106 at 24 n.<br />

1 (adjusting <strong>the</strong> multiple to account for <strong>the</strong> dividend, which increases Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's EV/2005E EBITDA multiple based on Wall<br />

Street consensus to 5.6x).<br />

123 Id. at 34. The comparable company EV/2005E EBITDA multiples were all based on median estimates published by <strong>the</strong> Institutional<br />

Brokers Estimate System. Id. at 33.<br />

124 JX–106 at SP COMM 004926. As discussed above, <strong>the</strong> 5.6x multiple (5.5x if unadjusted for <strong>the</strong> dividend) used by Goldman was<br />

based on estimates of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's 2005E EBITDA as contained in Wall Street research reports. The materially higher 6.3x, 6.4x,<br />

<strong>and</strong> 6.5x multiples, however, were based on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's internal projections for its 2005E EBITDA, which reduced <strong>the</strong> 2005E<br />

EBITDA figures to questionably low levels, given its strong performance in 2004 coupled with <strong>the</strong> incentives to decrease <strong>the</strong> figures<br />

in order to arrive at a higher multiple to support a 67.2 million share issuance for Minera.<br />

125 JX–106 at SP COMM 004926 (internal 2005E EBITDA projections ranging from $570 million to $592 million, where Wall Street<br />

projections were $664 million <strong>and</strong> its 2004 YTD annualized EBITDA was at that point $801 million).<br />

126 Id. (showing that at minimum, ei<strong>the</strong>r a combination of a 6.4x multiple multiplied by management's unadjusted 2005E EBITDA for<br />

Minera or a 6.5x multiple multiplied by <strong>the</strong> A & S adjusted 2005E EBITDA for Minera was needed to justify an issuance of over<br />

67 million shares).<br />

127 The 2005E Wall Street consensus median multiple of <strong>the</strong> comparable companies used by Goldman for 2005 was 4.8x. JX–129 at 34.<br />

128 The 2005E Wall Street consensus multiple of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn was 5.5x (unadjusted for <strong>the</strong> dividend) or 5.6x (adjusted for <strong>the</strong> dividend).<br />

JX–129 at 34; JX–106 at 24 n. 1<br />

129 JX–107 (Road Show Presentation) at SP COMM 006674. As I will discuss, this multiple was derived from an enterprise value of<br />

Minera of $4.1 billion.<br />

130 JX–106 at SP COMM 004926.<br />

131 Goldman's contribution analysis assumed that Minera's estimated 2005 EBITDA would be $622 million (as adjusted by A & S) or<br />

$672 (per <strong>the</strong> unadjusted management figures). The road show, however, implied an estimated 2005 EBITDA for Minera of $732<br />

million (derived by dividing <strong>the</strong> listed $4.1 billion enterprise value by <strong>the</strong> 5.6x EV/2005E EBITDA multiple). JX–107 at SP COMM<br />

006674.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 40


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

132 The road show assumed an estimated 2005 copper production of 365.4 Mt, JX–107 at SP COMM 006674, whereas, as of October<br />

21, 2004, A & S projected an estimated 2005 copper production of 329.1 Mt, <strong>and</strong> Minera itself projected an estimated 2005 copper<br />

production of 355.0 Mt. JX–106 at SP COMM 004918.<br />

133 JX–16 at SP COMM 000441.<br />

134 See Tr. at 14 (Palomino) (“Q. To what extent did <strong>the</strong> Special Committee have <strong>the</strong> authority to negotiate with Grupo Mexico? A.<br />

Well ... we had to evaluate in any way that deems to be desirable, in such manner as deems to be desirable. While we did not try to<br />

make our own proposals to Grupo Mexico, we could negotiate with <strong>the</strong>m in <strong>the</strong> sense of telling <strong>the</strong>m what it is that we don't agree<br />

with; <strong>and</strong> if we are going to evaluate this in a way that makes this transaction move forward, <strong>the</strong>n you're going to have to change<br />

<strong>the</strong> things that we don't agree with or we won't be able to recommend it.”); id. at 143–44 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“Q. To what extent was <strong>the</strong><br />

Special Committee empowered to negotiate with Grupo Mexico? A. Well, <strong>the</strong> way I looked at this was that ... <strong>the</strong> committee was to<br />

educate itself <strong>and</strong> determine whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y believe that <strong>the</strong> proposed transaction was a good or bad one. If good, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> transaction<br />

would progress in its normal course. And if <strong>the</strong> committee found that <strong>the</strong> transaction was not beneficial to <strong>the</strong> shareholders o<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

Grupo Mexico of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> committee would say no. And that if Grupo Mexico determined that it wanted to negotiate<br />

in <strong>the</strong> face of a no, it could do so.”); Palomino Dep. at 39–40 (“Our m<strong>and</strong>ate was to evaluate <strong>the</strong> transaction <strong>and</strong> to—provided that<br />

<strong>the</strong> transaction was beneficial to all shareholders of [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] <strong>and</strong> to minority shareholders in particular, to recommend to<br />

<strong>the</strong> board that <strong>the</strong> transaction be approved.”); id. at 106 (“Our m<strong>and</strong>ate was to evaluate <strong>and</strong> recommend to <strong>the</strong> board, so we did ...<br />

I don't recall exactly what, if any, responsibilities were left or any purpose of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee was left after that.”); see also<br />

H<strong>and</strong>elsman Dep. at 34–35 (acknowledging that <strong>the</strong> resolution creating <strong>the</strong> Special Committee did not say “negotiate”).<br />

135 See In re Loral Space & Commc'ns Inc., 2008 WL 4293781, at *9 (Del.Ch. Sept. 19, 2008).<br />

136 But cf. Venoco, Inc. v. Eson, 2002 WL 1288703, at *7 (Del.Ch. June 7, 2002) (“The primary concern for directors, even if <strong>the</strong>y<br />

are minority directors <strong>and</strong> significant shareholders, must be <strong>the</strong> best interests of <strong>the</strong> corporation ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong>ir own interests as<br />

shareholders.”).<br />

137 The defendants suggest that H<strong>and</strong>elsman's interest in liquidity had less to do with Cerro's wish for registration rights <strong>and</strong> more with<br />

improving Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's public float for <strong>the</strong> benefit of all minority shareholders. I have no doubts that H<strong>and</strong>elsman rationalized that<br />

granting <strong>the</strong> registration rights would create a better public float <strong>and</strong> more efficient market for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru shareholders, but this<br />

seems to me more of a high-minded justification ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> driving reason why H<strong>and</strong>elsman pursued such rights. H<strong>and</strong>elsman<br />

has been an attorney for <strong>the</strong> Pritzker interests since 1978 <strong>and</strong> has represented <strong>the</strong>m in various business transactions, <strong>and</strong> he admitted<br />

that it was very clear to him that <strong>the</strong> Pritzkers wanted to sell <strong>the</strong>ir shares <strong>and</strong> liquidate <strong>the</strong>ir ownership position in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru.<br />

Put simply, I do not decide <strong>the</strong> case on <strong>the</strong> inference that H<strong>and</strong>elsman, with <strong>the</strong> prospect of registration rights as part of <strong>the</strong> Merger<br />

dangling in front him, put <strong>the</strong> Pritzkers' interest wholly aside <strong>and</strong> only considered <strong>the</strong> benefit <strong>the</strong> registration rights created for <strong>the</strong><br />

minority shareholders.<br />

138 The August 21, 2004 term sheet sent by Grupo Mexico to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee included “Liquidity <strong>and</strong> Support” provisions that<br />

would provide registration rights necessary to allow Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge to liquidate <strong>the</strong>ir holdings in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru after <strong>the</strong><br />

close of <strong>the</strong> Merger. JX–157 at SP COMM 010487. The September 23, 2004 term sheet from <strong>the</strong> Special Committee stated that<br />

as to <strong>the</strong> possibility of Cerro <strong>and</strong> Phelps Dodge receiving registration rights for <strong>the</strong> sale of <strong>the</strong>ir shares in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, <strong>the</strong> term<br />

sheet provided that such rights would be “[a]s determined in good faith by agreement among <strong>the</strong> Founding Stockholders, with <strong>the</strong><br />

consultation of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee.” JX–159 at AMC 0027547.<br />

139 Cf. Merritt v. Colonial Foods, Inc., 505 A.2d 757, 765 (Del.Ch.1986) (“[T]he law, sensitive to <strong>the</strong> weakness of human nature <strong>and</strong><br />

alert to <strong>the</strong> ever-present inclination to rationalize as right that which is merely beneficial, will accord scant weight to <strong>the</strong> subjective<br />

judgment of an interested director concerning <strong>the</strong> fairness of a transaction that benefits him.” (citation omitted)).<br />

140 Kahn v. Tremont Corp., 694 A.2d 422, 429 (Del.1997).<br />

141 See In re Loral Space & Commc'ns Inc., 2008 WL 4293781, at *9, *24–25 (Del.Ch. Sept. 19, 2008).<br />

142 Pl. Op. Pre–Tr. Br. at 3.<br />

143 See Tr. at 49 (Palomino) (“[I]f you used <strong>the</strong>se same numbers for Minera [ ] <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru [ ] <strong>and</strong> on <strong>the</strong> same parameters, <strong>the</strong>n<br />

you were comparing apples to apples.”); see also Def. Op. Post–Tr. Br. at 17 (explaining that one of <strong>the</strong> major reasons <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee used relative valuation was that it allowed Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> Minera to be evaluated using <strong>the</strong> same set of assumptions,<br />

“i.e., an apples-to-apples comparison.”).<br />

144 See JX–74 (summary of Grupo Mexico/UBS/GS meeting (March 9, 2004)) at SPCOMM 010049 (noting that “mine studies have<br />

recently been completed by third party experts for all of [Minera]'s mines to support <strong>the</strong>ir life <strong>and</strong> quality arguments ... [Grupo<br />

Mexico] is aware of no recent reports on [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] mines”); see also Tr. at 355–56 (Beaulne) (discussing <strong>the</strong> differences<br />

between Minera's updated <strong>and</strong> optimized life-of-mine plan <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stale life-of-mine plan).<br />

145 Parker Dep. at 41.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 41


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

146 Compare JX–103 at SP COMM 006883 (discussing Minera projections <strong>and</strong> noting that “[n]ew optimization plan for Cananea<br />

(‘Alternative 3’), recently developed by [Grupo Mexico] <strong>and</strong> Mintec was not included in <strong>the</strong> projections at this point. According<br />

to Mintec, such a plan could yield US $240mm in incremental value on a pre-tax net present value basis prior to any potential<br />

adjustments by [A & S], using a 8.76% real discount rate as per [Minera] management”) with JX–106 at SP COMM 004917 (noting<br />

that Minera projections “include new optimization plan for Cananea (‘Alternative 3’) developed by [Grupo Mexico] <strong>and</strong> Mintec.”).<br />

147 Parker Dep. at 44.<br />

148 See, e.g., JX–102 (Goldman presentation to <strong>the</strong> Special Committee (June 23, 2004)) at SP COMM 006976 (discussing Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

projections <strong>and</strong> noting that “[A & S] changes to [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] Case limited to CapEx assumptions; overall NPV impact of [A &<br />

S] changes to <strong>the</strong> model is about 70mm assuming 9% discount rate”).<br />

149 JX–75 (A & S comments to Goldman following its meeting with Mintec <strong>and</strong> Minera (June 25, 2004)) at SP COMM 006957.<br />

150 See Parker Dep. at 50; Tr. at 98 (Palomino); see also JX–47 (expert report of Daniel Beaulne) (March 16, 2010) (“Beaulne Report”)<br />

at 17 (discussing adverse effects of depressed metal prices <strong>and</strong> lower sales volumes on Minera's financial performance in 2001, 2002,<br />

<strong>and</strong> 2003).<br />

151 JX–106 at SP COMM 004917 (noting that Minera projections used in <strong>the</strong> fairness analysis “assume[ ] that [<strong>the</strong> Merger] closes on<br />

December 31, 2004.”).<br />

152 See In re Loral Space & Commc'ns Inc., 2008 WL 4293781, at *24 (Del.Ch. Sept. 19, 2008) (criticizing <strong>the</strong> special committee for<br />

its failure “to respond to <strong>the</strong> realities as an aggressive negotiator seeking advantage would have”).<br />

153 JX–33 (Goldman engagement letter (March 2, 2004)) at SP COMM 014786–SP COMM 014787 (providing for a flat fee structure).<br />

154 Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 712–13 (Del.1983).<br />

155 Paramount Commc'ns, Inc. v. Time Inc., 571 A.2d 1140, 1150 n. 12 (Del.1989).<br />

156 Paramount Commc'ns, Inc. v. Time Inc., 1989 WL 79880, at *19 (Del.Ch. July 14, 1984), aff'd, 571 A.2d 1140 (Del.1989).<br />

157 Time, 571 A.2d at 1149.<br />

158 See JX–103 at SP COMM 006886. This value was calculated by applying Goldman's most aggressive assumptions (a $1.00 long-term<br />

copper price <strong>and</strong> 7.5% discount rate) to unadjusted projections provided by Minera management. I am not taking into account <strong>the</strong> $3<br />

billion valuation that was produced under <strong>the</strong> same assumptions in Goldman's June 11 presentation because at that point due diligence<br />

on Minera was still very much a work in progress. See also JX–101 at SP COMM 003338 (“Due diligence process is still ongoing ...”).<br />

159 Tr. at 445 (Schwartz). In his report, Schwartz, who used <strong>the</strong> same relative valuation methodology as Goldman did, sets forth a<br />

continuum of valuation results ranging from those based on <strong>the</strong> $0.90/lb long-term copper price used by Goldman to <strong>the</strong> $1.30/lb<br />

long-term copper price that he considered to be a reasonable assumption at <strong>the</strong> time. At $0.90/lb Minera was worth approximately<br />

67.6 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock, with a <strong>the</strong>n-current market value of $1.7 billion; at $1.30 it was worth approximately<br />

80 million shares, with a <strong>the</strong>n-current market value of $3.7 billion. JX–48 (expert report of Eduardo Schwartz) (April 21, 2010)<br />

(“Schwartz Report”) 25 at Ex. 2. These dollar values are derived from determining <strong>the</strong> number of shares that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would<br />

issue for Minera under a relative DCF analysis using <strong>the</strong>se copper price assumptions, multiplied by <strong>the</strong> $45.92 closing price of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru on October 21, 2004.<br />

160 Tr. at 437 (Schwartz) (“In this case, Minera [ ] was more sensitive to <strong>the</strong> price of copper. When we increase <strong>the</strong> price of copper, <strong>the</strong><br />

value, <strong>the</strong> present value of Minera [ ] went higher than [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] ...”); Schwartz Report 45 (“[A] lower copper price causes<br />

<strong>the</strong> calculated value of Minera to decrease to a greater extent than <strong>the</strong> value of [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] using <strong>the</strong> same assumptions.”).<br />

161 Schwartz Report 36–43.<br />

162 Tr. at 481 (Schwartz) (“I got <strong>the</strong> Excel file from Goldman Sachs as modified by [A & S], <strong>and</strong> that's <strong>the</strong> data that I used to value<br />

both Minera [ ] <strong>and</strong> [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru].”).<br />

163 Defendants point to <strong>the</strong> testimony of Palomino as evidence of <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's bargaining strategy. Palomino testified that<br />

“strategically, it was to our advantage to try to be conservative with copper prices, because o<strong>the</strong>rwise, <strong>the</strong> relative valuations would<br />

be altered in favor of Minera ... [t]he fact that <strong>the</strong> lower <strong>the</strong> price, <strong>the</strong> better for us, that was quite clear from <strong>the</strong> beginning.” Tr. at<br />

41 (Palomino). But nowhere does any piece of written evidence support this as being a genuine deal dynamic.<br />

164 JX–143 at 66 (Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Copper Corporation Form 10–K (February 29, 2008)).<br />

165 JX–101; JX–102; JX–103; JX–105; JX–106.<br />

166 The value of copper mining companies is basically related to <strong>the</strong> reserves <strong>the</strong>y have. A copper mining company's reserves are not<br />

fixed based on <strong>the</strong> amount of ore in <strong>the</strong> ground, but are ra<strong>the</strong>r a representation of how much of that ore can be mined at a profit. That<br />

calculation, of course, turns in large part on <strong>the</strong> long-term copper price. When <strong>the</strong> long-term copper price goes up, <strong>the</strong> company's<br />

reserves will increase without any new ore being discovered because at a higher price more ore can be taken from <strong>the</strong> mine at a<br />

profit. Accordingly, in <strong>the</strong> long term, <strong>the</strong> company will take more copper out of <strong>the</strong> ground <strong>and</strong> its projections may change to reflect<br />

an increase in its reserves.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 42


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

167 Tr. at 155 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman).<br />

168 In contrast to Schwartz, <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's expert Daniel Beaulne determined a st<strong>and</strong>alone fair value for Minera. Using a DCF analysis,<br />

Beaulne came up with an enterprise value for Minera of $2.785 billion as of October 21, 2004. See Beaulne Report at 42. Using<br />

a comparable companies analysis, Beaulne came up with an enterprise value for Minera of $2.831 billion as of October 21, 2004.<br />

Beaulne <strong>the</strong>n took <strong>the</strong> average of <strong>the</strong> two enterprise values from each of <strong>the</strong> valuation approaches <strong>and</strong> added Minera's cash balance<br />

<strong>and</strong> subtracted Minera's debt, concluding that <strong>the</strong> “indicated equity value” of Minera was $1.854 billion as of October 21, 2004.<br />

Operating under <strong>the</strong> assumption that <strong>the</strong> “publicly traded share price of [Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru] is a fair <strong>and</strong> accurate representation of <strong>the</strong><br />

market value of a share of its common stock,” Beaulne multiplied <strong>the</strong> $1.854 billion equity value of Minera by <strong>the</strong> 99.15% interest that<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was purchasing <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong>n divided that amount by <strong>the</strong> publicly-available share price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru as of October 21,<br />

2004 adjusted by <strong>the</strong> $100 million transaction dividend (which translated to $1.25 per share). Out of conservatism, I adopt a different<br />

valuation for remedy purposes, but, if I had to make a binary choice, I would favor Beaulne's DCF analysis as more reliable than<br />

<strong>the</strong> Schwartz approval, which largely accepted (without any gumption check for, say, <strong>the</strong> $300 million in extra EBITDA Sou<strong>the</strong>rn<br />

Peru earned in 2004) <strong>the</strong> defendant-friendly inputs of a flawed process <strong>and</strong> used an after-<strong>the</strong> fact generated copper price along with<br />

<strong>the</strong>m to come to a determination of fairness.<br />

169 JX–125 at 55; JX–107 at SP COMM 006674.<br />

170 JX–156 at SP COMM 007080.<br />

171 JX–118 (UBS presentation to Grupo Mexico (July 2004)) at UBS–SCC00005558.<br />

172 JX–159 at AMC0027547.<br />

173 Compare JX–160 at SP COMM 010497 (offering $10 million threshold) with Pre–Tr. Stip at 15 (stipulating that parties agreed to<br />

$10 million threshold).<br />

174 Cerro's voting agreement required it to vote in accordance with <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's recommendation, but Phelps Dodge's voting<br />

agreement, which was entered into two months after <strong>the</strong> Merger was signed, did not have a similar provision. Ra<strong>the</strong>r, <strong>the</strong> agreement<br />

provided that, given <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's recommendation in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Board's approval of <strong>the</strong> Merger, Phelps<br />

Dodge expressed its current intention to vote in favor of <strong>the</strong> Merger. Although it seems that Phelps Dodge would be contractually<br />

entitled to vote against <strong>the</strong> Merger if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee had subsequently withdrawn its recommendation, nowhere does <strong>the</strong><br />

agreement require such a result. Given Phelps Dodge's independent interest in obtaining <strong>the</strong> liquidity rights that were tied to <strong>the</strong><br />

Merger, it is unclear how it would have voted if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee had changed its mind. Thus, because Phelps Dodge's vote<br />

by itself would be sufficient to satisfy <strong>the</strong> two-thirds supermajority vote condition, it is equally unclear what power <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee actually had to stop <strong>the</strong> Merger once it was signed.<br />

175 Tr. at 175 (H<strong>and</strong>elsman) (“I thought <strong>the</strong> collar had some meaning, but I thought that it was less important because I believed—based<br />

on my feeling that a relative value of <strong>the</strong> two companies made sense, that ships rise with a rising tide <strong>and</strong> ships fall with a falling tide;<br />

<strong>and</strong>, <strong>the</strong>refore, <strong>the</strong> chances of <strong>the</strong> value of one getting out of sync with <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r was a chance that was worth taking,<br />

although it certainly would have been better to have <strong>the</strong> collar.”).<br />

176 The switch to a fixed exchange ratio turned out to be hugely disadvantageous to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru. If <strong>the</strong> Special Committee had instead<br />

accepted Grupo Mexico's original May 7, 2004 proposal for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru to issue $3.1 billion dollars worth of stock with <strong>the</strong> number<br />

of shares to be calculated based on <strong>the</strong> 20–day average closing price of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru starting five days before <strong>the</strong> Merger closed,<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would have only had to issue 52.7 million shares of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru stock, based on <strong>the</strong> 20–day average price at that<br />

time of $59.75 per share. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, if <strong>the</strong> Special Committee had done no negotiating at all <strong>and</strong> had simply accepted Grupo<br />

Mexico's first ask, Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru would have issued about 14.5 million fewer shares to purchase Minera than it did after <strong>the</strong> Special<br />

Committee was finished negotiating.<br />

177 In <strong>the</strong>ir papers, both <strong>the</strong> plaintiff <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> defendants point to evidence post-dating <strong>the</strong> Merger to support <strong>the</strong>ir arguments. See, e.g., Pl.<br />

Op. Post–Tr. Br. at 7–9, 18 (discussing post-Merger evidence of reported ore reserves for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> post-Merger completion<br />

of a significant exploration program relating to Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's mines); Pl. Ans. Post–Tr. Br. at 12 (citing to evidence of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

<strong>and</strong> Minera's 2005 EBITDA performance); Def. Op. Post–Tr. Br. at 22 (including chart that shows investment return in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

<strong>and</strong> selected comparable companies from October 21, 2004 to June 27, 2011). Def. Ans. Post–Tr. Br. at Ex. A. As <strong>the</strong>ir supplemental<br />

letters after post-trial argument show, our law is not entirely clear about <strong>the</strong> extent to which such evidence can be considered. In an<br />

appraisal case, it is of course important to confine oneself to only information that was available as of <strong>the</strong> date of <strong>the</strong> transaction<br />

giving rise to appraisal. 8 Del. C. § 262(h) (“[T]he [c]ourt shall determine <strong>the</strong> fair value of <strong>the</strong> shares exclusive of any element of<br />

value arising from <strong>the</strong> accomplishment or expectation of <strong>the</strong> merger or consolidation.”). But even in appraisal, <strong>the</strong>re are situations<br />

when post-transaction evidence has relevance. Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc., 758 A.2d 485, 499 (Del.2000) (holding that postmerger<br />

evidence that validated a pre-merger forecast was admissible “to show that plans in effect at <strong>the</strong> time of <strong>the</strong> merger have born<br />

fruition.” (citation omitted)); Cavalier Oil Corp. v. Harnett, 1988 WL 15816, at *14 (Del.Ch. Feb. 22, 1988), aff'd, 564 A.2d 1137<br />

(Del.1989) (“[p]ost-merger data may be considered” if it meets <strong>the</strong> Weinberger st<strong>and</strong>ard pertaining to non-speculative evidence);<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 43


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

see generally R. Franklin Balotti & Jesse A. Finkelstein, The Delaware Law of Corporations <strong>and</strong> Business Organizations § 9.45<br />

(3d ed.1998) (discussing <strong>the</strong> court's ability to consider post-merger evidence in <strong>the</strong> appraisal context). In an entire fairness case,<br />

where <strong>the</strong> influence of control is important, <strong>the</strong>re is a sucker insurance purpose to such evidence. See Gentile v. Rossette, 2010 WL<br />

2171613, at *2 (Del.Ch. May 28, 2010) (noting that “[s]ome rumination upon <strong>the</strong> outcome of <strong>the</strong> fair price <strong>and</strong> process dynamic ...<br />

cannot be avoided”); Ryan v. Tad's Enters., Inc., 709 A.2d 682, 697 (Del.Ch.1996) (considering post-merger events in determining<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r merger price was fair). In this case, for example, <strong>the</strong> estimated cash flows for Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru, which were not optimized, were<br />

important in setting <strong>the</strong> transaction price. As of <strong>the</strong> Merger date, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee <strong>and</strong> Grupo Mexico had access to results of<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru that showed that <strong>the</strong> estimates for 2004 had been exceeded by a large amount <strong>and</strong> that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru was running well<br />

ahead of <strong>the</strong> 2005 estimate, suggesting that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's non-optimized cash flow estimates might have been too low, whereas<br />

Minera's optimized cash flows seemed about right. The ultimate results from 2005 also cast serious doubt on <strong>the</strong> fairness of <strong>the</strong><br />

relative valuation exercise that was used to justify <strong>the</strong> transaction.<br />

178 Def. Ans. Post–Tr. Br. at Ex. A.<br />

179 All actual EBITDA numbers are drawn from Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's post-Merger annual reports, which continue to report <strong>the</strong> results of <strong>the</strong><br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Minera businesses separately as operating segments. JX–138; JX–142; JX–143; JX–144; JX–146; JX–147.<br />

All numbers are in millions.<br />

180<br />

2005E 2006E 2007E 2008E 2009E 2010E Sum<br />

Minera $622.0 $530.0 $627.0 $497.0 $523.0 $567.0 $3366.0<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru $581.0 $436.0 $415.0 $376.0 $350.0 $329.0 $2487.0<br />

Ratio MM/SP 1.07 1.22 1.51 1.32 1.49 1.72 1.35<br />

180 All estimated EBITDA numbers are based on <strong>the</strong> A & S-adjusted projections used in Goldman's October 21, 2004 presentation.<br />

The 2005E EBITDA numbers are based on <strong>the</strong> A & S-adjusted estimates in Goldman's contribution analysis, JX–106 at SP COMM<br />

004926 (which assume a 2% royalty tax on Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru <strong>and</strong> certain o<strong>the</strong>r additional adjustments) <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> 2006E–2010E EBITDA<br />

numbers are based on <strong>the</strong> A & S-adjusted projections underlying Goldman's final relative DCF analyses. Id. at SP COMM004918;<br />

SP COMM004920.<br />

* * *<br />

181 See Beaulne Report at 45. The 24.7 million figure is based on calculations as of <strong>the</strong> date of closing (April 1, 2005), ra<strong>the</strong>r than as of<br />

<strong>the</strong> date of Goldman's fairness opinion <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's approval of <strong>the</strong> Merger (October 21, 2004).<br />

182 Int'l Telecharge, Inc. v. Bomarko, Inc., 766 A.2d 437, 439 (Del.2000) (noting that <strong>the</strong> Delaware Supreme Court “defer[s] substantially<br />

to <strong>the</strong> discretion of <strong>the</strong> trial court in determining <strong>the</strong> proper remedy....”); Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 715 (Del.1983)<br />

(noting “<strong>the</strong> broad discretion of <strong>the</strong> Chancellor to fashion such relief as <strong>the</strong> facts of a given case may dictate”).<br />

183 Thorpe v. CERBCO, Inc., 676 A.2d 436, 444 (Del.1996).<br />

184 Bomarko, Inc. v. Int'l Telecharge, Inc., 794 A.2d 1161, 1184 (Del.Ch.1999), aff'd, 766 A.2d 437 (Del.2000).<br />

185 Summa Corp. v. Trans World Airlines, Inc., 540 A.2d 403, 409 (Del.1988).<br />

186 Ryan v. Tad's Enters., Inc., 709 A.2d 682, 699 (Del.Ch.1996) (highlighting <strong>the</strong> principle of equity that a plaintiff waives <strong>the</strong> right<br />

to rescission by excessive delay in seeking it, <strong>and</strong> extending that principle to rescissory damages, based on <strong>the</strong> policy reason that<br />

excessive delay allows plaintiffs to see whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> defendants achieve an increase in <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> company before deciding to<br />

assert a claim).<br />

187 Gotham Partners, L.P. v. Hallwood Realty Partners, L.P., 855 A.2d 1059, 1072 (Del.Ch.2003).<br />

188 Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 714 (Del.1983); Ryan, 709 A.2d at 699.<br />

189 As discussed earlier in this opinion, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee should have re-evaluated <strong>the</strong> Merger between signing <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> stockholder<br />

vote due to changes in Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's stock price <strong>and</strong> Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru's projection-shattering 2004 EBITDA <strong>and</strong> 2005 year to date<br />

performances. Instead, <strong>the</strong> Special Committee's decision to treat <strong>the</strong> Merger as a foregone conclusion was a-failure in terms of fair<br />

process. For this <strong>and</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r related reasons, I am <strong>the</strong>refore calculating damages with respect to <strong>the</strong> market value of Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru<br />

shares as of <strong>the</strong> Merger date, April 1, 2005.<br />

190 I say did not stop ra<strong>the</strong>r than did not slow, because <strong>the</strong>y are different. By being conservative in my approach to a remedy, I give <strong>the</strong><br />

defendants credit for some of <strong>the</strong>ir market-based arguments, in a manner that one could even say I should not in a duty of loyalty<br />

case. See Thorpe v. CERBCO, Inc., 676 A.2d 436, 444 (Del.1996) (“Delaware law dictates that <strong>the</strong> scope of recovery for a breach of<br />

<strong>the</strong> duty of loyalty is not to be determined narrowly.”). But I think this is responsible because <strong>the</strong> record suffers from some issues,<br />

including <strong>the</strong> absence of a Goldman trial witness <strong>and</strong> likely diminished memories, that are properly laid at <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's door.<br />

191 Beaulne Report at 44.<br />

192 Id. at 21.<br />

193 Tr. at 340–341 (Beaulne).<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 44


In re Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru Copper Corp. Shareholder Derivative <strong>Litigation</strong>, 52 A.3d 761 (2011)<br />

194 Beaulne Report at 36. Like Beaulne, I disregard <strong>the</strong> potential tax benefits of $0–131 million for Minera that Goldman factored in to<br />

its valuations as of <strong>the</strong> date of <strong>the</strong> fairness opinion. JX106 at SP COMM 004917. The schedules <strong>and</strong> estimates provided by Minera<br />

management to Goldman on <strong>the</strong> potential tax benefits are not in <strong>the</strong> record, making <strong>the</strong>m difficult to evaluate. Moreover, Schwartz<br />

also disregards <strong>the</strong>se potential tax benefits in his relative valuation analysis, Schwartz Report 22, <strong>and</strong> <strong>the</strong> defendants do not take<br />

issue with Beaulne's exclusion of <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

195 Beaulne's model, adjusted to reflect my inputs, yields an enterprise value for Minera of $3.452 billion, from which I subtracted <strong>the</strong> $1<br />

billion in debt that Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Peru assumed in <strong>the</strong> Merger. To <strong>the</strong> extent <strong>the</strong> defendants' gripe about <strong>the</strong> remedy, using <strong>the</strong> $0.90 per<br />

pound long-term copper price <strong>the</strong>y told <strong>the</strong> investing public was <strong>the</strong> right number, <strong>the</strong> equity value of Minera would be only $1.512<br />

million. At <strong>the</strong> high end of <strong>the</strong> long-term copper prices used in Goldman's st<strong>and</strong>alone DCF model, or $1.00 per per pound, Minera's<br />

value was only $1.982 million. This underscores <strong>the</strong> conservatism of my approach, given <strong>the</strong> record evidence.<br />

196 $45.92 closing price x 52,000,000 = $2,387,840,000.<br />

197 See JX–106 at SP COMM 004913, SP COMM 004925.<br />

198 Id. at SP COMM 004925.<br />

199 $1.986 billion = (4.8 x 622 million)—$1 billion net debt.<br />

200 Andaloro v. PFPC Worldwide, Inc., 2005 WL 2045640, at *16 (Del.Ch. Aug. 19, 2005).<br />

201 Borruso v. Commc'ns Telesystems Int'l, 753 A.2d 451, 458 (Del.Ch.1999).<br />

202 Agranoff v. Miller, 791 A.2d 880, 893 (Del.Ch.2001).<br />

203 2006 Mergerstat ® Review (Santa Monica: FactSet Mergerstat, LLC, 2006) at 24.<br />

204 $55.89 closing price x 67,200,000 = $3,755,808,000.<br />

205 $3.756 billion - $2.409 billion = $1.347 billion.<br />

206 The plaintiff has not sought to have <strong>the</strong> defendants pay his attorneys' fees. The parties shall confer regarding whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y can reach<br />

agreement on a responsible fee that <strong>the</strong> court can consider awarding, with <strong>the</strong> plaintiff's counsel taking into account <strong>the</strong> reality <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

own delays affected <strong>the</strong> remedy awarded <strong>and</strong> are a basis for conservatism in any fee award.<br />

End of Document<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works.<br />

© 2013 Thomson Reuters. No claim to original U.S. Government Works. 45

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!