30.04.2014 Views

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

Essays on supplier responsiveness and buyer firm value - Nyenrode ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ISBN 978-90-8980-055-8<br />

© M. Abrahim Zaka, 2013<br />

All rights reserved. Save excepti<strong>on</strong>s stated by the law, no part of this publicati<strong>on</strong> may<br />

be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system of any nature, or transmitted in any form<br />

or by any means, electr<strong>on</strong>ic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, included a<br />

complete or partial transcripti<strong>on</strong>, without the prior written permissi<strong>on</strong> of the author, applicati<strong>on</strong><br />

for which should be addressed to author.


ISBN 978-90-8980-055-8<br />

© M. Abrahim Zaka, 2013<br />

All rights reserved. Save excepti<strong>on</strong>s stated by the law, no part of this publicati<strong>on</strong> may<br />

be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system of any nature, or transmitted in any form<br />

or by any means, electr<strong>on</strong>ic, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, included a<br />

complete or partial transcripti<strong>on</strong>, without the prior written permissi<strong>on</strong> of the author, applicati<strong>on</strong><br />

for which should be addressed to author.


Examinati<strong>on</strong> Committee<br />

Supervisor: Prof. dr. Henry Robben<br />

Co-Supervisor: Prof dr. Kees Van M<strong>on</strong>tfort<br />

Other members: Prof dr. ing. Jacques Reijniers MBA<br />

Prof dr. R<strong>on</strong> Tuninga<br />

Dr. W.G. (Wim) Biemans


Table of C<strong>on</strong>tents<br />

CHAPTER 1 14<br />

1.1 INTRODUCTION 14<br />

1.2 OUTLINE OF THE DISSERTATION 14<br />

1.3 RESEARCH QUESTIONS 15<br />

1.4 SCOPE PHD THESIS 18<br />

1.5 RESEARCH METHODOLOGY BASED ON THE RESEARCH QUESTIONS 18<br />

1.5.1 Sample <strong>and</strong> data collecti<strong>on</strong> 19<br />

1.6 DATA ANALYSIS 19<br />

1.6.1 Data analysis, Chapter 2 19<br />

1.6.2 Data analysis, Chapter 3 19<br />

1.6.3 Data analysis, Chapter 4 20<br />

1.7 LIMITATIONS 20<br />

CHAPTER 2 21<br />

2.1 INTRODUCTION 22<br />

2.2 MARKET ORIENTATION 25<br />

2.2.1 Cultural Perspective of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> 26<br />

2.2.2 Can a Culture be Developed? Is it Within Management’s C<strong>on</strong>trol 27<br />

2.2.3 The Cultural Perspective of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Ability to Take Risks 27<br />

2.2.4 A Cultural Perspective of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Innovati<strong>on</strong> 28<br />

2.2.5 What Do We Learn from the Cultural Perspective of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong>? 28<br />

2.2.6 The Process-Based View of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> 29<br />

2.2.7 Business-to-Business Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> 30<br />

2.2.8 Moderators of the Market Orientati<strong>on</strong>-Performance Link 30<br />

2.2.9 What We Learn from the Prior Studies of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> 32<br />

2.2.10 Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Marketing Accountability 32<br />

2.2.11 Measuring the Marketing Orientati<strong>on</strong> – Finance Link 33<br />

2.2.12 C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s 33


2.3 DEVELOPMENT OF THE CONCEPTUAL MODEL 35<br />

2.4 METHODOLOGY 40<br />

2.4.1 Questi<strong>on</strong>naire Design <strong>and</strong> Scale Development 40<br />

2.4.2 Sample 55<br />

2.4.3 Multicollinearity 56<br />

2.5 MEASUREMENT MODEL 59<br />

2.6 THE STRUCTURAL MODEL 64<br />

2.7 DISCUSSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS 66<br />

2.7.1 H 1 : Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> IdRR 67<br />

2.7.2 H 2 : Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> H 3 : Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Buyer Firm Value 68<br />

2.7.3 H 4 : IdRR <strong>and</strong> Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value 68<br />

2.7.4 H 5 : Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value <strong>and</strong> Buyer Firm Value 69<br />

2.8 MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS 70<br />

2.9 LIMITATIONS AND FUTURE DIRECTIONS 72<br />

2.10 CONCLUSIONS 72<br />

CHAPTER 3 74<br />

3.1 INTRODUCTION 75<br />

3.1.1 Different Results of Studies of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United<br />

States 76<br />

3.1.2 Cultural C<strong>on</strong>text 78<br />

3.1.3 C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to Chapter 2 79<br />

3.1.4 Hypotheses Generati<strong>on</strong> 79<br />

3.2 METHODOLOGY 83<br />

3.2.1 Sample Descripti<strong>on</strong> 83<br />

3.2.3 Normality of Data 86<br />

3.2.4.1 Model 1 87<br />

3.2.4.2 Model 2 87<br />

3.2.4.3 Model 3 88


3.3 DISCUSSION 90<br />

3.4 RECOMMENDATIONS 92<br />

3.5 CONCLUSIONS 93<br />

CHAPTER 4 95<br />

4.1 INTRODUCTION 96<br />

4.2 INTENDED THEORETICAL CONTRIBUTION 98<br />

4.3 SPECIFIC CONTRIBUTION TO CHAPTER 2 98<br />

4.4 HYPOTHESIS DEVELOPMENT 99<br />

4.5 RESEARCH DESIGN 101<br />

4.5.1 Sample 101<br />

4.5.2 Descriptive Statistics 101<br />

4.5.3 Normality of the Data 102<br />

4.5.4 Data Analysis 102<br />

4.5.5 Measurement Model 102<br />

4.6 SEM 104<br />

4.7 DISCUSSION 107<br />

4.7.1 Measurement Model Hypothesis 107<br />

4.7.2 SEM Model Hypotheses 108<br />

4.7.3 Some Insights from Informal Discussi<strong>on</strong>s 110<br />

4.7.4 Managerial Implicati<strong>on</strong>s 111<br />

4.8 LIMITATIONS 112<br />

4.9 FUTURE DIRECTIONS 112<br />

4.10 CONCLUSIONS 113<br />

CHAPTER 5 114


5.1 RESEARCH FINDINGS 114<br />

5.2 OVERALL GLOBAL RESEARCH QUESTION ANSWER 114<br />

5.3 OVERALL CONCLUSIONS 116<br />

5.4 THEORETICAL IMPLICATIONS 117<br />

5.5 PRACTICAL IMPLICATIONS 119<br />

5.6 CLOSING WORDS 120<br />

SUMMARY IN ENGLISH 121<br />

SAMENVATTING 128<br />

REFERENCES 136<br />

APPENDIX A 146<br />

APPENDIX B 161


List of Figures<br />

Figure 2.1 C<strong>on</strong>ceptual Model 35<br />

Figure 3.1 The Netherl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the U.S. Compared <strong>on</strong> the Hofstede Dimensi<strong>on</strong>s 79


List of Tables<br />

Table 2.1 Representative Studies of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Their Focus 25<br />

Table 2.2 Modified Items of the MARKOR Scale 43-46<br />

Table 2.3 Factor Analysis Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness 47<br />

Table 2.4 Items Measuring IdRR 49<br />

Table 2.5 Rotated IdRR Comp<strong>on</strong>ent Matrix 50<br />

Table 2.6 List of Modified Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> Items 52<br />

Table 2.7 Comp<strong>on</strong>ent Matrix Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> 53<br />

Table 2.8 Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value 53<br />

Table 2.9 Matrix of Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value Comp<strong>on</strong>ents 54<br />

Table 2.10 Buyer Firm Value 54<br />

Table 2.11 Matrix of Buyer Firm Value Comp<strong>on</strong>ents 54<br />

Table 2.12 Descriptive Statistics 56<br />

Table 2.13 Multicollinearity Statistics 57<br />

Table 2.14 Multicollinearity Statistics 57<br />

Table 2.15 Multicollinearity Statistics 57<br />

Table 2.16 Multicollinearity Statistics 57<br />

Table 2.17 Inter-item Correlati<strong>on</strong>s 58<br />

Table 2.18 Questi<strong>on</strong>naire Items <strong>and</strong> Codes 60<br />

Table 2.19 Average Variance Extracted 61<br />

Table 2.20 C<strong>on</strong>struct Reliability 62<br />

Table 2.21 Measurement Model Indices 63<br />

Table 2.22 St<strong>and</strong>ardized Residual Covariances 63<br />

Table 2.23 Structural Model Indices 65<br />

Table 3.1 The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s Investment in the United States 75<br />

Table 3.2 Descriptive Statistics USA <strong>and</strong> Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 84<br />

Table 3.3 Kurtosis <strong>and</strong> Skewness 86<br />

Table 3.4 Summary of Goodness of Fit Statistics, SE Hypotheses Results 89<br />

Table 4.1 Sample Descripti<strong>on</strong> 101<br />

Table 4.2 St<strong>and</strong>ardized Regressi<strong>on</strong> Weights for CFA 103<br />

Table 4.3 Average Variance Extracted 103<br />

Table 4.4 C<strong>on</strong>struct Reliability 103<br />

Table 4.5 SEM Results 105<br />

Table 4.6 Summary of Goodness of Fit Statistics, SE Hypotheses Results 106<br />

Table 4.7 Measurement Model Indices 108


To the loving memory of my aunt<br />

Shahima Karim-Ilyas


PREFACE<br />

Oscar Wilde <strong>on</strong>ce said, “I am not young enough to know everything.” As my life progresses I<br />

see more truth in this statement. My life illustrates how a formerly self-professed know-it-all<br />

eventually realized that there is always much to learn. Beginning with my school days, when I<br />

believed I knew everything, <strong>and</strong> my belief was not without merit, after all, my sources were<br />

indisputable: Disney <strong>and</strong> DC comics. This belief in my knowledge was still with me at the start<br />

of my PhD. I believed back then that I would revoluti<strong>on</strong>ize marketing, but alas, then I met the<br />

arch nemesis of every PhD c<strong>and</strong>idate, the critics. Critics who knew the field better than I ever<br />

imagined they would. Indeed, every step of the PhD process has been humbling as I realized<br />

there was so little I knew. So the questi<strong>on</strong> some of you might ask is what do I know now?<br />

I know that without the help of my supervisor Henry Robben <strong>and</strong> co-supervisor Kees Van<br />

M<strong>on</strong>tford my thesis would never have been completed. Their support has been unwavering <strong>and</strong><br />

to them I am greatly indebted. Henry <strong>and</strong> Kees, I couldn’t have asked for better supervisors.<br />

Henry you truly are a marketing guru! And Kees you are a statistician par excellence! I will miss<br />

the time spent in l<strong>on</strong>g discussi<strong>on</strong>s with the both of you about my PhD. I know that without the<br />

help extended to me by Kitty Koleijmier I would not have completed this PhD. To her I am<br />

extremely thankful. In additi<strong>on</strong>, I owe a great deal to Ed Peelen as he never refused to help me,<br />

despite the fact I wasn’t his PhD student! I am also obliged to Henry’s dear friend Peter Gouw.<br />

Peter, thank you for all the help with the data in the PhD process!<br />

I know that it was not <strong>on</strong>ly faculty members who helped me complete my dissertati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

but also many others who supported me throughout the process. If I was to rank them, I think my<br />

brother Fasi Zaka would be <strong>on</strong> the top of the list. He believed in me when I didn’t believe in<br />

myself <strong>and</strong> he was instrumental in prodding <strong>and</strong> cajoling me <strong>on</strong> a flight back to The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

from Pakistan when I was thinking of quitting my PhD. I am also grateful for all the financial<br />

support he has provided me throughout my life. Though, I must add, that being his brother I hope<br />

he never asks me to repay him. I am beholden to my mother who has always supported me. I<br />

know that I have bothered her unduly at times when the stress of the PhD overwhelmed me, <strong>and</strong><br />

for that I seek her forgiveness. I would never have loved educati<strong>on</strong> so much if it were not for her<br />

proselytizati<strong>on</strong> that I must always strive to ameliorate myself. I would also like to thank my<br />

father for his moral support. In additi<strong>on</strong>, I am also grateful to my maternal uncle Amin Jan<br />

(Meno Mama) whose c<strong>on</strong>stant support to me <strong>and</strong> my family has been unswerving. Though there<br />

are many other relatives I could thank, I will briefly name the most important <strong>on</strong>es, namely:<br />

Abdul Karim Jan Khan, Gul Rang Bibi, Nazli Ayub, Saleem Jan Khan, Asif Ayub, Ihsanullah<br />

Kaka, Ali Ayub, Anwar Ayub, beloved Junaid (the last true Khan of Uthmanzai), <strong>and</strong> Kunat Jan.<br />

I am also grateful to all my friends <strong>and</strong> colleagues in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Pakistan, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

U.S. Especially, Dr.Cyrus M.D. <strong>and</strong> Dr.Asad M.D., the two people who inspired me to get a<br />

‘doctor’ title. Even though Cyrus may never agree that I’m a real doctor, however, I think we<br />

should agree to disagree. I am also grateful to Nies <strong>and</strong> Javed Khan for all their encouragement<br />

<strong>and</strong> help.<br />

Most importantly, I would like to acknowledge he who needs no menti<strong>on</strong>, Almighty God.<br />

I know that He has blessed me with more than I could ever ask for in this life. I pray that the


Almighty c<strong>on</strong>tinues to shower me with His mercy <strong>and</strong> allows me to serve my fellow human<br />

beings.


Chapter 1<br />

Introducti<strong>on</strong> to the Thesis<br />

1.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong><br />

This dissertati<strong>on</strong> focuses <strong>on</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between strategic <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. The mediators of the relati<strong>on</strong>ship that are specifically c<strong>on</strong>sidered include:<br />

idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Moreover, when it<br />

comes to market orientati<strong>on</strong>, most previous studies have assumed the seller <strong>firm</strong>’s perspective. In<br />

this dissertati<strong>on</strong>, we have added to prior studies of market orientati<strong>on</strong> by: (1) adopting the<br />

customer’s perspective, (2) introducing a new market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance mediator<br />

called IdRR, (3) <strong>and</strong> questi<strong>on</strong>ing the positive relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk.<br />

The implicati<strong>on</strong>s of this study for management are: (1) that the market orientati<strong>on</strong> of a <strong>supplier</strong><br />

can be used as a criteri<strong>on</strong> for minimizing risks where it is not possible to create a portfolio of<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s for risk minimizati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> (2) that insulati<strong>on</strong> to idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk can<br />

be used as an indicator of the <strong>value</strong> created for the customer, in additi<strong>on</strong> to <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The aforementi<strong>on</strong>ed c<strong>on</strong>cepts do not have st<strong>and</strong>ardized definiti<strong>on</strong>s, as various researchers<br />

have often given their own definiti<strong>on</strong>s. Market orientati<strong>on</strong> has many <strong>and</strong> varied definiti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Indeed, Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) observed,<br />

Given its (market orientati<strong>on</strong>) widely acknowledged importance, <strong>on</strong>e might expect the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cept to have a clear meaning, a rich traditi<strong>on</strong> of theory development, <strong>and</strong> a related<br />

body of empirical findings. On the c<strong>on</strong>trary, a close examinati<strong>on</strong> of the literature reveals<br />

a lack of clear definiti<strong>on</strong>, little careful attenti<strong>on</strong> to measurement issues, <strong>and</strong> virtually no<br />

empirically based theory.<br />

Since then, more research <strong>on</strong> the subject of market orientati<strong>on</strong> has been c<strong>on</strong>ducted, but there has<br />

been no c<strong>on</strong>vergence toward the adopti<strong>on</strong> of a st<strong>and</strong>ardized definiti<strong>on</strong>. However, for the purpose<br />

of this thesis, market orientati<strong>on</strong> is defined as the implementati<strong>on</strong> of a marketing c<strong>on</strong>cept (Kohli<br />

& Jaworski, 1990). The sec<strong>on</strong>d c<strong>on</strong>cept in this dissertati<strong>on</strong> is idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk (IdRR),<br />

a term borrowed primarily from the finance literature, where idiosyncratic risk in the stock<br />

market is the risk that can be diversified away by creating a portfolio of stocks (Angelidis &<br />

Tessaromatis, 2008; Goyal & Santa-Clara, 2003). In this dissertati<strong>on</strong>, IdRR is defined as the risk<br />

to which <strong>buyer</strong>s are exposed to by entering into a relati<strong>on</strong>ship with a strategic <strong>supplier</strong><br />

(Srivastava, Shervani, & Fahey, 1998). The third c<strong>on</strong>cept we deal with is satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, defined as<br />

the cumulative <strong>buyer</strong> evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s performance against the <strong>buyer</strong>’s expectati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

(Oliver, 1993). The fourth c<strong>on</strong>cept that this dissertati<strong>on</strong> deals with is the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is defined as the <strong>buyer</strong>’s loyalty to the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong>. The fifth<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cept in this dissertati<strong>on</strong> is the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>’s <strong>value</strong>. The <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> refers to the <strong>buyer</strong>’s<br />

future cash flows (Srivastava et al., 1998).<br />

The rest of this chapter is organized as follows. Below, we present an outline of this<br />

dissertati<strong>on</strong>. Next, we introduce our research questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the goals of this dissertati<strong>on</strong>. We also<br />

elaborate <strong>on</strong> the theories that we use <strong>and</strong> a descripti<strong>on</strong> of the methodology employed in this<br />

dissertati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

1.2 Outline of the Dissertati<strong>on</strong><br />

This dissertati<strong>on</strong> has five chapters. In this secti<strong>on</strong>, we present an outline of the chapters. In<br />

Chapter 1, we introduce the variables in this dissertati<strong>on</strong>: <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

14


(resp<strong>on</strong>siveness), relati<strong>on</strong>al idiosyncratic risk, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. We discuss the motivating factors behind the dissertati<strong>on</strong>, present our<br />

research questi<strong>on</strong>s, explain the research methodology, <strong>and</strong>, finally, provide a review of the<br />

dissertati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In Chapter 2, we present our first study, an empirical investigati<strong>on</strong> into whether the<br />

strategy of resp<strong>on</strong>sive strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s pays off for the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> the seller. This study also<br />

compares two mediating variables: the first is the relati<strong>on</strong>al indicator of <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

the sec<strong>on</strong>d is the objective indicator of <strong>buyer</strong> idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk. The theoretical<br />

underpinnings of this study are derived from the market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature, financial theories,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the market-based assets theory. These theories are used to provide the rati<strong>on</strong>ale for the five<br />

hypotheses. The findings of this study are that strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness mitigates risk<br />

<strong>and</strong> leads to positive outcomes for both the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong>. The data used in this study<br />

were collected from 164 purchasing managers in publically listed <strong>and</strong> unlisted <strong>firm</strong>s from the<br />

U.S. The <strong>firm</strong>s included in the study operated in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets, business markets, or a<br />

combinati<strong>on</strong> of both.<br />

In Chapter 3, we examine the model generated in Chapter 2 across nati<strong>on</strong>al borders. This<br />

study compares how strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness importance varies across cultural <strong>and</strong><br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al borders. The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, a more feminine culture, holds both relati<strong>on</strong>al indicators <strong>and</strong><br />

objective indicators in equal importance, whereas, in the United States, <strong>on</strong>ly objective indicators<br />

matter. The implicati<strong>on</strong>s of this finding are important for <strong>firm</strong>s looking to form transatlantic<br />

alliances. We include, in additi<strong>on</strong> to the data from the U.S., data from The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. The<br />

sample from The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s included both publically listed <strong>and</strong> unlisted <strong>firm</strong>s. The total sample<br />

size from The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s was 92. The <strong>firm</strong>s included in the study, like those in the prior study,<br />

operated in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets, business markets, or a combinati<strong>on</strong> of both.<br />

In Chapter 4, we compare objective <strong>and</strong> subjective performance measures of strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. For objective measures, we use the net income for <strong>firm</strong>s from Google<br />

financials that uses input data from the Reuters database. For subjective measures, we use<br />

managerial indicators from our surveys. We find that, although the models fit in both cases,<br />

when accounting are data used our hypotheses linking <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness with <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> are insignificant. This holds important implicati<strong>on</strong>s for managers<br />

as to whether they should trust mental heuristics when judging their organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance.<br />

Finally, in Chapter 5, we c<strong>on</strong>clude the dissertati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> discuss our findings.<br />

1.3 Research Questi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Over the course of the last two decades, a global trend has involved collaborating with <strong>and</strong><br />

growing closer to <strong>supplier</strong>s. One example of the importance of key <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships is the<br />

Malcolm Balridge award competiti<strong>on</strong>, in which participants are assessed <strong>on</strong> their key <strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships. Moreover, as illustrated in Figure 1.1, in the future, stable <strong>and</strong> reliable <strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships will become more valuable because 68 percent of the resp<strong>on</strong>dents in a McKinsey<br />

survey expected the supply risk to increase over the next five years (McKinsey, 2010).<br />

Furthermore, global supply markets, in general, are increasingly becoming more competitive <strong>and</strong><br />

riskier. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, to reduce uncertainty about the <strong>firm</strong>’s future market positi<strong>on</strong>, <strong>firm</strong>s<br />

need adaptable <strong>supplier</strong>s, as exemplified by Toyota’s supply pyramid (Reeves & Deimler, 2011).<br />

15


Figure 1.1<br />

Mckinsey Survey Results<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>cept of greater interacti<strong>on</strong> with <strong>supplier</strong>s has been adopted from Japan. The<br />

Japanese Keiretsu c<strong>on</strong>cept is a network of distributors that closely collaborate with their<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s (Reeves & Deimler, 2011). Numerous manufacturers in the United States have<br />

attempted to emulate this c<strong>on</strong>cept, but for many it did not work out <strong>and</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>s with<br />

distributors are now worse than before (Reeves & Deimler, 2011). For example, Ford has<br />

introduced reverse aucti<strong>on</strong>s to make the <strong>supplier</strong>s minimize their prices (Reeves & Deimler,<br />

2011).<br />

At the same time, the informati<strong>on</strong> technology revoluti<strong>on</strong> has made it easier for <strong>firm</strong>s such<br />

as Wal-Mart to collect informati<strong>on</strong> about their customers <strong>and</strong> share it with their <strong>supplier</strong>s. These<br />

new technologies include ECR, VMI, QR, EDI, RFID, etc. These new technologies give a<br />

greater real-time underst<strong>and</strong>ing of what is happening to market dem<strong>and</strong>. However, in t<strong>and</strong>em,<br />

Wal-Mart imposes harsh supply terms in its c<strong>on</strong>tracts with <strong>supplier</strong>s (Schmitt, 2009). One<br />

example of Wal-Mart’s harsh terms is the <strong>supplier</strong>’s paying shelf rent for products that do not<br />

sell as quickly as required. Although there is greater <strong>buyer</strong> or distributor willingness <strong>and</strong><br />

preference to share informati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>supplier</strong>s, there seems to be comparatively less willingness<br />

to share risk.<br />

The reas<strong>on</strong> for the mixed <strong>supplier</strong>-<strong>buyer</strong> love-hate relati<strong>on</strong>ship in the strategic c<strong>on</strong>text is<br />

the complex reality of today. Take Apple <strong>and</strong> Samsung as an example: Apple is reliant <strong>on</strong><br />

Samsung’s superior chip manufacturing facilities but still pursues litigati<strong>on</strong> to raise potential<br />

sales barriers in various markets to protect its market share. Strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s, to some degree,<br />

16


always remain potential threats <strong>and</strong> competitors. The logic of Porter’s (1985) five forces<br />

framework still applies in the strategic c<strong>on</strong>text because the five forces still compete for the same<br />

profit pie. For example, Samsung a strategic <strong>supplier</strong> of comp<strong>on</strong>ent processors to Apple moved<br />

into Apple’s market of mobile devices. Despite the mixed relati<strong>on</strong>ship between some strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s <strong>and</strong> their <strong>buyer</strong>s, other <strong>buyer</strong>s use ingenuous ways to leverage their <strong>supplier</strong>s’ marketbased<br />

strengths. For instance, Dell, Toshiba, Acer, <strong>and</strong> HP are some <strong>firm</strong>s that employ the<br />

ingredient br<strong>and</strong>ing strategy, <strong>and</strong> by doing so, they leverage their chip <strong>supplier</strong>’s strength to<br />

increase their own products’ attractiveness. Hence, a powerful <strong>supplier</strong> is not always viewed as a<br />

threat, <strong>and</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between a strategic <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> can be mutually beneficial.<br />

However, the underpinning of success in the marketplace is an underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the<br />

customer’s needs (market orientati<strong>on</strong>) (Cane, 2010). The detractors of the market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

philosophy have claimed that it leads to a narrow focus <strong>and</strong> ignores potential future customer<br />

needs. In additi<strong>on</strong>, Collins (2009) argues that <strong>on</strong>e of the reas<strong>on</strong>s that many previously identified<br />

“good to great” companies have failed is expansi<strong>on</strong> to too many customer industries rather than<br />

focusing <strong>on</strong> the customer’s needs. Given the muddled nature of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>-<strong>buyer</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship, what is unclear is whether focusing <strong>on</strong> the customer’s needs pays off for the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong>. Therefore, this dissertati<strong>on</strong> focuses <strong>on</strong> the following research global<br />

questi<strong>on</strong>:<br />

“What is the impact of <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> through idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk,<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>?”<br />

To further answer this global research questi<strong>on</strong> we have three sub-questi<strong>on</strong>s. They are as<br />

follows:<br />

To answer our global research questi<strong>on</strong>, we followed a stepwise process, organizing our<br />

research questi<strong>on</strong> into three sets of problems. Chapter 2 addresses the following questi<strong>on</strong>:<br />

“Does it make relati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong> financial sense to be a resp<strong>on</strong>sive strategic <strong>supplier</strong>?”<br />

Chapter 3 addresses whether, in this age of globalizati<strong>on</strong>, whether the model proposed in<br />

Chapter 2 would hold true in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s because, as stated earlier, many <strong>firm</strong>s have<br />

attempted to adopt truly close <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships, <strong>and</strong> these differences are nati<strong>on</strong>specific.<br />

Given the importance of The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States as two major trading<br />

partners, we therefore, investigate whether the model developed in Chapter 2 would hold in The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. Therefore, our sec<strong>on</strong>d research questi<strong>on</strong> is:<br />

“Does our model of strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness hold across nati<strong>on</strong>al/cultural<br />

borders?”<br />

The final issue is how we measure performance. Chapter 4 deals with the methodological<br />

issue of whether perceptual or objective performance measures should be used. In the past, many<br />

studies <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> have used perceptual performance measures. However, they have<br />

often not correlated well with subjective performance measures. We investigate whether there is<br />

empirical evidence for the correlati<strong>on</strong> between subjective <strong>and</strong> objective measures, in the c<strong>on</strong>text<br />

of purchasing managers when dealing with strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s, based <strong>on</strong> the model developed in<br />

Chapter 2. Therefore, our third research questi<strong>on</strong> is:<br />

“What are the differences between <strong>firm</strong>-level perceptual measures of performance <strong>and</strong><br />

accounting measures of performance?”<br />

17


1.4 Scope PhD thesis<br />

This thesis focuses <strong>on</strong> answering the research questi<strong>on</strong> about how a marketing focus influences<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al idiosyncratic risk <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequently <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. The primary motivati<strong>on</strong> behind<br />

the research questi<strong>on</strong>s is the gap in marketing literature because of a scholarly focus <strong>on</strong> the intraorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

perspective of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk relati<strong>on</strong>ship. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence of a<br />

focus <strong>on</strong> intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al perspective of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk scholars have ignored the<br />

inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al perspective, specifically in the strategic <strong>buyer</strong>-<strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship c<strong>on</strong>text.<br />

Therefore, this thesis focuses <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk in the interorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text.<br />

Moreover, strategic <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships have been extensively researched in<br />

many domains in additi<strong>on</strong> to marketing, such as, sales <strong>and</strong> purchasing. Indeed, sales <strong>and</strong><br />

purchasing have made important c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s to the topic of strategic <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships, but as the main c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of this thesis is an academic <strong>on</strong>e, therefore, it is<br />

important to make a clear academic c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to scientific literature. Hence, as the research<br />

area of interest is in the marketing domain, namely market orientati<strong>on</strong>, the theoretical lens<br />

chosen for this dissertati<strong>on</strong> is a marketing <strong>on</strong>e. However, this does lead to a limitati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

focusing <strong>on</strong> marketing, <strong>and</strong> as a c<strong>on</strong>sequence sales <strong>and</strong> purchasing literature have not<br />

substantially cross-pollinated the current study.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, as menti<strong>on</strong>ed earlier this thesis focuses <strong>on</strong> the strategic <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship c<strong>on</strong>text. The primary reas<strong>on</strong> for choosing this c<strong>on</strong>text is because organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> is an expensive <strong>and</strong> time c<strong>on</strong>suming exercise. Therefore, for a <strong>supplier</strong> to be<br />

market oriented the <strong>buyer</strong> needs to be committed to c<strong>on</strong>tinuing the relati<strong>on</strong>ship for the l<strong>on</strong>g-term<br />

period in order to regain the initial investment in the relati<strong>on</strong>ship. This this thesis deals with<br />

those relati<strong>on</strong>ships that are strategic, meaning the product or service supplied is high in terms of<br />

financial risk <strong>and</strong> supply risk. But focusing <strong>on</strong> strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships means that this thesis does<br />

not cover n<strong>on</strong>-strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<br />

This thesis focuses primarily <strong>on</strong> strategic <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> its impact <strong>on</strong><br />

their <strong>buyer</strong> in the c<strong>on</strong>text of two countries, namely the United States <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Although, there are many other countries that could have been included such as China or Japan,<br />

the primary research interest of the researchers involved in this thesis was in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

<strong>and</strong> the United States. Moreover, because of time <strong>and</strong> budget c<strong>on</strong>straints a including a larger<br />

number of countries was not possible. In additi<strong>on</strong>, as stated in Chapter 3 The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the<br />

United States are similar <strong>on</strong> all dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of the Hofstede index except masculinity <strong>and</strong><br />

femininity. Therefore, it was of interest to determine whether <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness would<br />

achieve the same effect in both countries <strong>and</strong> whether this effect would be channeled through<br />

similar mediators.<br />

This thesis was primarily c<strong>on</strong>ducted for an academic objective. Therefore, we have not<br />

explicitly focused <strong>on</strong> practical outcomes. However, the theoretical insights from this dissertati<strong>on</strong><br />

can be used by managers to c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> or disc<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> beliefs they may have. Moreover, the<br />

introducti<strong>on</strong> of IdRR as a metric could be c<strong>on</strong>sidered a practical c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of this thesis.<br />

1.5 Research Methodology Based <strong>on</strong> the Research Questi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

This secti<strong>on</strong> reviews the sample used in this dissertati<strong>on</strong>, the data collecti<strong>on</strong> procedure, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

statistical method used for the analysis of the data. Throughout this dissertati<strong>on</strong>, the methodology<br />

18


is comm<strong>on</strong> to all papers because the surveys used for the United States <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s are<br />

identical <strong>and</strong> the data were collected in the same time frame.<br />

1.5.1 Sample <strong>and</strong> data collecti<strong>on</strong><br />

The resp<strong>on</strong>ses we have used in this dissertati<strong>on</strong> were collected from a professi<strong>on</strong>al panel of<br />

purchasing managers. The resp<strong>on</strong>dents worked for both publically <strong>and</strong> privately listed companies<br />

from the U.S. <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. We use key informant methodology in selecting our<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>dents (Philips, 1981). On average, the resp<strong>on</strong>dents were purchasing managers with more<br />

than seven years of experience with strategic purchases. The data collecti<strong>on</strong> employed an<br />

Internet survey because of speed, cost, <strong>and</strong> efficiency c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

We initially c<strong>on</strong>sulted academics about our survey. We then c<strong>on</strong>ducted a test survey with<br />

students <strong>on</strong> campus to check the robustness of the instrument. This survey took place during the<br />

spring of 2009. We collected data during the summer of 2009. In Chapter 2 we collected<br />

publically listed <strong>and</strong> unlisted U.S. <strong>firm</strong>s’ data. In Chapter 3, we used both U.S. <strong>and</strong> Dutch data.<br />

In Chapter 4, we used a sub-sample of the sample used in Chapter 2. We selected <strong>on</strong>ly those<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>dents who worked for publically listed companies. We then used the difference in net<br />

income over a three-year period (2009-2011) as a source of objective <strong>firm</strong> earnings. We acquired<br />

the net income data from Google financials, powered by the Reuters database.<br />

1.6 Data Analysis<br />

We used quantitative <strong>and</strong> qualitative data analysis. In our quantitative analysis, we used factor<br />

analysis, c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory factor analysis, <strong>and</strong> structural equati<strong>on</strong> modeling. For the qualitative data<br />

analysis, we c<strong>on</strong>ducted a textual analysis of the interviews we c<strong>on</strong>ducted. In the following three<br />

paragraphs, we explain the data analysis used in Chapters 2, 3, <strong>and</strong> 4.<br />

1.6.1 Data analysis, Chapter 2<br />

In Chapter 2, we c<strong>on</strong>ducted an exploratory factor analysis based <strong>on</strong> data collected from the<br />

United States. We applied a factor analysis to five of our scales: <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, IdRR, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Based <strong>on</strong> the results of the factor<br />

analysis, we chose the most appropriate items for each scale. In additi<strong>on</strong>, we checked for<br />

multicollinearity by running a series of linear regressi<strong>on</strong> equati<strong>on</strong>s in SPSS with our independent<br />

variables <strong>and</strong> mediators. The VIF for all four equati<strong>on</strong>s was less than ten, meaning that<br />

multicollinearity was not an issue with our data (Hair, Anders<strong>on</strong>, Tatham, & Black, 2006).<br />

We then c<strong>on</strong>ducted a c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory factor analysis with AMOS 17. We used 39 items<br />

from our original questi<strong>on</strong>naire. After a number of iterati<strong>on</strong>s, we achieved model fit with 10<br />

items. The st<strong>and</strong>ardized residual covariances were all less than plus two or greater than minus<br />

two <strong>and</strong> all the inter-item correlati<strong>on</strong>s were above plus 0.3 or less than minus 0.3. We also<br />

achieved c<strong>on</strong>struct reliability <strong>and</strong> acceptable levels of average variance extracted.<br />

We finally analyzed our data analysis using a structural equati<strong>on</strong> model using our 10<br />

items <strong>and</strong> 5 c<strong>on</strong>structs. We used the maximum likelihood estimati<strong>on</strong> method in AMOS 17. The<br />

results indicated that four of our hypotheses were supported <strong>and</strong> <strong>on</strong>e hypothesis was not<br />

supported. The goodness of fit indices were within acceptable range.<br />

1.6.2 Data analysis, Chapter 3<br />

We c<strong>on</strong>ducted a factor analysis based <strong>on</strong> data from The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s of publically listed <strong>and</strong><br />

privately owned companies with the 10 items used in Chapter 2 <strong>and</strong> 5 c<strong>on</strong>structs (n=92). We<br />

analyzed the model of Chapter 2 using structural equati<strong>on</strong> modeling <strong>and</strong> data from The<br />

19


Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. We used the maximum likelihood estimati<strong>on</strong> method. Because of sample size<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong>s (described in detail in Chapter 3) we decided to split the model tested in Chapter 2<br />

into two sub-models, Model 2 <strong>and</strong> Model 3. Model 2 includes the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> variables. Model 3 includes the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, IdRR<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> variables. We found that the fit statistics were<br />

acceptable for both models <strong>and</strong> that the data supported all our hypotheses. Furthermore, we<br />

compared <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>trasted the hypotheses’ significance with the hypotheses in Chapter 2.<br />

1.6.3 Data analysis, Chapter 4<br />

We analyzed the two models in Chapter 2 based <strong>on</strong> 87 resp<strong>on</strong>dents who worked for publically<br />

listed companies in the United States. We initially c<strong>on</strong>ducted a c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory factor analysis<br />

(CFA). The fit statistics were all within the acceptable range for the model. Next, we analyzed<br />

the data using structural equati<strong>on</strong> models <strong>and</strong> applied the maximum likelihood estimati<strong>on</strong><br />

procedure. In our subjective data model, four of our hypotheses were supported by the data,<br />

whereas in our objective data model, <strong>on</strong>ly three of our hypotheses gained support.<br />

1.7 Limitati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Many additi<strong>on</strong>al future research directi<strong>on</strong>s can be suggested <strong>on</strong> the basis of the limitati<strong>on</strong>s of the<br />

current research. The following are some of the limitati<strong>on</strong>s of this dissertati<strong>on</strong>:<br />

L<strong>on</strong>gitudinal research design. Our cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al study allowed us to draw associati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

at best but not c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s about causality. To further improve this design, data collected for a<br />

time series analysis could allow the deducti<strong>on</strong> of evidence regarding causality. However, there<br />

has been some recent evidence that inferences from cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al studies about causality may<br />

not be much different from inferences about l<strong>on</strong>gitudinal studies (Rindfleisch et al., 2008).<br />

Limited sample of industries for depth. We traded off depth for width in our industry<br />

sectors. However, specific sectors may vary more with <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness than others. For<br />

instance, in the commodities industry, price may be more of a determining factor, whereas, in the<br />

technical goods industrial sector, the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>se may be a key determining factor as to<br />

whether relati<strong>on</strong>ships c<strong>on</strong>tinue. Future studies could c<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>on</strong> a few sectors <strong>and</strong> check the<br />

robustness of our findings across various moderators, such as market turbulence <strong>and</strong> increased<br />

technological risk.<br />

Narrow cultural comparis<strong>on</strong>. Although the US <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s are different in some<br />

respects, they share similarities as well. Both are industrialized nati<strong>on</strong>s, both are vibrant<br />

democracies, both have capitalist ec<strong>on</strong>omies, both have a degree of similar occidental culture,<br />

<strong>and</strong> both nati<strong>on</strong>s are internati<strong>on</strong>ally competitive ec<strong>on</strong>omies (Deshp<strong>and</strong>e & Webster, 1989). Some<br />

cultural idiosyncrasies do occur, such as acceptance of boasting <strong>on</strong> job interviews in the United<br />

States <strong>and</strong> the preference for modesty in job interviews in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, but nevertheless,<br />

they both can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered western cultures. On the other h<strong>and</strong> comparis<strong>on</strong> with an Asian<br />

culture in Chapter 3 would have provided a more diverse cultural comparis<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> insights into<br />

whether the model proposed in Chapter 2 holds across more diverse cultural settings.<br />

Existing relati<strong>on</strong>ships. In the current study we <strong>on</strong>ly examined existing relati<strong>on</strong>ships. It is<br />

possible that the current study could be improved up<strong>on</strong> by examining different stages in a<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship <strong>and</strong> examine whether the importance of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> idiosyncratic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al risk varies across nati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> in different stages of the relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

20


Chapter 2<br />

In Pursuit of the Buyer: Does it Make Relati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong> Financial Sense to be a Resp<strong>on</strong>sive<br />

Strategic Supplier?<br />

Abstract<br />

Do resp<strong>on</strong>sive strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s create substantial <strong>value</strong> in the <strong>buyer</strong>-<strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship? The evidence from the marketing literature is mixed. Closer collaborati<strong>on</strong> with a<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong> is known to influence risk <strong>and</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>al outcomes, but this influence does not<br />

always generate substantial benefits for the <strong>buyer</strong> as well as for the <strong>supplier</strong>. For business-tobusiness<br />

(B2B) strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships, substantial benefits are important; if channel partners do<br />

not receive reas<strong>on</strong>able benefits from a relati<strong>on</strong>ship, then the partnership could suffer. In this<br />

study, we examine how strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness creates meaningful <strong>value</strong> for both the<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong> through the mediator of idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk.<br />

We used survey data (n=164) from listed <strong>and</strong> unlisted companies in the United States <strong>and</strong><br />

employed structural equati<strong>on</strong> modeling for our analysis. The primary finding of interest is that a<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness (i.e., market orientati<strong>on</strong>) is negatively associated with a <strong>buyer</strong>’s<br />

idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk. This challenges the widely held belief that risk <strong>and</strong> market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> are positively related. In t<strong>and</strong>em, the results show that being resp<strong>on</strong>sive reduces the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s risk in terms of the repurchase likelihood by their strategic <strong>buyer</strong>. At the end of this<br />

paper, we discuss the managerial <strong>and</strong> academic implicati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Keywords: <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

21


2.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong><br />

A central tenant of marketing is market orientati<strong>on</strong>. The most important facet of market orientati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

a business-to-business (B2B) c<strong>on</strong>text is the <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>se to the <strong>buyer</strong>’s needs (Kohli &<br />

Jaworski, 1990). This resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is described from the seller or <strong>supplier</strong>’s perspective as a<br />

business philosophy by McNamara (1972). Other scholars have c<strong>on</strong>ceptualized it as a business<br />

strategy with performance implicati<strong>on</strong>s (Narver & Slater, 1990), whereas some argue that it is an<br />

approach with which to reduce business relati<strong>on</strong>al idiosyncratic risk. From a customer’s perspective,<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> is the perceived <strong>supplier</strong>’s market resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to their needs, both latent <strong>and</strong><br />

explicit (Slater & Narver, 1998). 1 Both the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> customer recognize market orientati<strong>on</strong> as an<br />

important framework for remaining competitive.<br />

The importance of market orientati<strong>on</strong> in the academic marketing domain can be gauged by the<br />

3,835 instances in which, according to Google Scholar, Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski’s (1990) article has been<br />

cited. From a managerial perspective, it can be judged by the performance of highly market-oriented<br />

companies such as Apple (iPod/iPh<strong>on</strong>e), S<strong>on</strong>y (Walkman), Philips (Senseo coffee machines) <strong>and</strong><br />

Google (search engines). These companies illustrate the positive link between a <strong>firm</strong>’s market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> market performance.<br />

Despite the importance that market orientati<strong>on</strong> has in both academic <strong>and</strong> business c<strong>on</strong>texts, the<br />

influence of strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>on</strong> customer marketplace performance is an academic<br />

area that is in its nascent stages. In this regard, recent evidence from the business world suggests that a<br />

lack of strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or market orientati<strong>on</strong> could be disastrous for the customer.<br />

Toyota is <strong>on</strong>e such example; the automobile manufacturer’s strategy of leaner <strong>and</strong> more efficient<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s was a global managerial mantra. However, its <strong>supplier</strong>’s recent breaking system fiasco in the<br />

United States caused Toyota to lose a fifth of its market <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> prompted an expensive automobile<br />

recall (Kim & Krolicki, 2010). The current study investigates whether <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness reduces<br />

idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk (IdRR) <strong>and</strong> if it generates <strong>value</strong> for both the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong>. We<br />

use two different sets of metrics to assess the <strong>value</strong> that is generated for the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong>. For the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>, we assess whether the <strong>value</strong> that is generated ameliorates intangible market-based intellectual<br />

assets. This is because in times of trouble, intangible n<strong>on</strong>-financial benefits usually bind <strong>buyer</strong>s to their<br />

sellers (Naray<strong>and</strong>as, 2005). Therefore, such n<strong>on</strong>-financial tangible assets provide the <strong>firm</strong> with<br />

valuable resources. For the <strong>buyer</strong>, we assess the expected cash flow, which is a widely accepted <strong>and</strong><br />

frequently used measure of <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. In the next secti<strong>on</strong> we define the five key c<strong>on</strong>structs of this<br />

paper, namely: IdRR, <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong>.<br />

The first c<strong>on</strong>struct is IdRR. We borrow the term idiosyncratic risk from the finance literature<br />

<strong>and</strong> modify it to IdRR. Two kinds of risk are explored within the finance literatures. One form is<br />

diversifiable, which means that adopting a portfolio strategy in which companies may invest can<br />

eliminate idiosyncratic risk. The mechanism that eliminates the investor’s risk is that some of the<br />

security prices of their portfolio may fall, whereas other companies’ prices will rise. Overall, this leads<br />

to a reducti<strong>on</strong> in the investor’s risk, as he has avoided placing all eggs in a single investment basket.<br />

Hence, the idea of diversifiability is essentially the act of diversifying investments so that risk can be<br />

1 For the purpose of this dissertati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness refers to the customer’s perspective of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

22


educed. Another kind of risk is <strong>on</strong>e that cannot be diversified by a portfolio strategy, <strong>and</strong> that<br />

phenomen<strong>on</strong> affects all <strong>firm</strong>s within the market. An example of such undiversifiable risk would be the<br />

threat of sudden fuel price increases. An undiversifiable risk that affects the whole market is called a<br />

systematic risk, <strong>and</strong> the other form a diversifiable risk that affects individual <strong>firm</strong>s but not the whole<br />

market, is called idiosyncratic risk (Sharpe, 1964). Idiosyncratic risk is the more important of the two<br />

kinds of risk because it typically comprises eighty percent of the risk that <strong>firm</strong>s face <strong>on</strong> the stock<br />

market (Srinivasan & Hanssens, 2009). We refer to <strong>buyer</strong> IdRR as the risk that exists because of<br />

entering into a specific relati<strong>on</strong>ship with another company. On the c<strong>on</strong>tinuum of customer <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships that range from transacti<strong>on</strong>al to strategic alliances, those that are strategic involve the<br />

most customer risk (Kraljic, 1983). The reas<strong>on</strong> why the risk in strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships is mostly<br />

idiosyncratic is because it is reduced by an underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the partner’s idiosyncratic business needs<br />

<strong>and</strong> willingness to take steps to meet those needs or in other words, it can be diversified. This<br />

perspective is different from systematic risk, where the <strong>firm</strong> has no ability to c<strong>on</strong>trol such risk. In a<br />

way, our c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizati<strong>on</strong> is parallel to the c<strong>on</strong>cept of idiosyncratic risk <strong>on</strong> the stock market.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d c<strong>on</strong>struct is <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Broadly speaking,<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> is the implementati<strong>on</strong> of the marketing c<strong>on</strong>cept (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990). There<br />

are two widely accepted c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizati<strong>on</strong>s of market orientati<strong>on</strong> in the extant literature; the first<br />

c<strong>on</strong>siders market orientati<strong>on</strong> to be a process that is composed of three core comp<strong>on</strong>ents: intelligence<br />

generati<strong>on</strong>, disseminati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>se (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990). The <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>se or<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is c<strong>on</strong>sidered the most important of the three because it is the sum of all of the market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> efforts by the <strong>supplier</strong> to provide the <strong>buyer</strong> with a soluti<strong>on</strong> (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990). The<br />

sec<strong>on</strong>d approach c<strong>on</strong>siders market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a <strong>firm</strong> culture which gives rise to market-oriented<br />

behaviors. For instance, Narver <strong>and</strong> Slater’s (1990) cultural perspective of market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>siders three sets of market-oriented behavior, namely customer orientati<strong>on</strong>, competitor orientati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

<strong>and</strong> interfuncti<strong>on</strong>al coordinati<strong>on</strong>. These behaviors are linked to the <strong>firm</strong>’s profitability. In spite of the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ceptual differences of both approaches, they are geared towards the same goal of creating superior<br />

customer <strong>value</strong> through a resp<strong>on</strong>se that is based <strong>on</strong> market intelligence.<br />

Moreover, <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is the <strong>on</strong>ly comp<strong>on</strong>ent by which a customer can judge the<br />

level of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong>. The other two comp<strong>on</strong>ents of intelligence generati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

intelligence disseminati<strong>on</strong> are not always visible to the customer; hence, the customer cannot directly<br />

assess the quality of intelligence generati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong>. But the customer can judge it indirectly<br />

through the <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. Therefore, for the purpose of our research, we c<strong>on</strong>sider <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness as the accumulative <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>se that is created by internal <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

intelligence generati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong> processes to meet their <strong>buyer</strong>’s needs.<br />

Our third c<strong>on</strong>struct is <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, which is an important relati<strong>on</strong>al outcome of the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990). An analysis of the strategic c<strong>on</strong>text of the <strong>buyer</strong><strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship is incomplete without c<strong>on</strong>sidering the customer’s evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se. Customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> represents the customer’s evaluati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> some scholars c<strong>on</strong>sider<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as a measurement of the cumulative <strong>buyer</strong> experience. Thus, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> has been<br />

defined as “an overall evaluati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> the total purchase <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> experience with a good<br />

or service over time" (Anders<strong>on</strong>, Fornell, & Lehmann, 1994). This study uses cumulative <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> instead of measuring transacti<strong>on</strong>al satisfacti<strong>on</strong> because we are interested in the overall<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> assessment of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>. The drawback of a transacti<strong>on</strong>al definiti<strong>on</strong> is that it would<br />

23


<strong>on</strong>ly provide an assessment of the satisfacti<strong>on</strong> from the most recent transacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> not from the whole<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Oliver, 1993). Furthermore, within the channel management literature, satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct is classified in two subtypes. The first form is ec<strong>on</strong>omic satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, which is the overall<br />

positive affective resp<strong>on</strong>se to the ec<strong>on</strong>omic benefits that flow from the <strong>buyer</strong> towards the seller from<br />

the relati<strong>on</strong>ship with its channel partner (Geyskens, Steenkamp, & Kumar, 1999). The sec<strong>on</strong>d type is<br />

n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, which is defined as the overall affective resp<strong>on</strong>se to the n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

aspects of a channel relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Geyskens et al., 1999). Although some scholars treat both ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

<strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as distinct c<strong>on</strong>structs, the relati<strong>on</strong>ship of both c<strong>on</strong>structs with <strong>firm</strong><br />

performance is positive (Geyskens et al., 1999). Therefore, this study uses the term <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

to imply the <strong>buyer</strong>’s cumulative ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with its strategic <strong>supplier</strong><br />

<strong>firm</strong> (Dwyer & Gassenheimer, 1992).<br />

Our fourth c<strong>on</strong>struct is <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. According to Keller (1993), customer-based br<strong>and</strong><br />

knowledge is comprised of two comp<strong>on</strong>ents: br<strong>and</strong> image <strong>and</strong> br<strong>and</strong> awareness. Br<strong>and</strong> image<br />

encompasses the collective neural associati<strong>on</strong>s about the memory of a br<strong>and</strong>. From the perspective of a<br />

strategic buying center team, we define this as the shared collective memories about the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

br<strong>and</strong>, which provides it with leverage because of customer preference that it would otherwise not<br />

have without the br<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Our fifth c<strong>on</strong>struct is <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Prior studies have assessed <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> by discounting<br />

expected cash flows to evaluate the impact of marketing strategy <strong>on</strong> the <strong>firm</strong>’s <strong>value</strong>. This perspective<br />

has been widely adopted in the finance, <strong>and</strong> marketing literatures (Srinivasan & Hanssens, 2009). The<br />

more stable <strong>and</strong> greater the <strong>firm</strong>’s current cash flows, the greater the expectati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>firm</strong>’s <strong>value</strong>.<br />

Furthermore, <strong>firm</strong> growth drives cash flows <strong>and</strong>, hence, <strong>value</strong> (Srivastava, Shervani, & Fahey, 1999).<br />

Therefore, we take growth <strong>and</strong> stability in cash flows (i.e., both current <strong>and</strong> expected percepti<strong>on</strong>s) as a<br />

measure of the <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> (Koller, Goedhart, & Wessels, 2005).<br />

This c<strong>on</strong>cludes the brief descripti<strong>on</strong> of the c<strong>on</strong>structs that are used in this chapter. In summary,<br />

prior research has suggested the relevance of investigating the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of market orientati<strong>on</strong> or<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness by using three of the previously discussed c<strong>on</strong>structs, namely <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. A new additi<strong>on</strong> to the literature is the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct of IdRR, which we have propounded by synthesizing previous research. In the current<br />

research, we integrate the new proposed c<strong>on</strong>struct of IdRR <strong>and</strong> the other four c<strong>on</strong>structs into our<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ceptual model. In the next secti<strong>on</strong>, we discuss prior studies of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> examine the<br />

major themes that they have covered so far. Afterwards, we build up<strong>on</strong> these previous studies through<br />

our c<strong>on</strong>ceptual model.<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>texts in which market orientati<strong>on</strong> has been studied are wide <strong>and</strong> varied. Some<br />

frameworks include different market types, such as B2B <strong>and</strong> business to c<strong>on</strong>sumer (B2C) (Kirca,<br />

Jayach<strong>and</strong>ran, & Bearden, 2005; Siguaw, Simps<strong>on</strong>, & Baker, 1998). 2 Different methodological<br />

approaches have also been used, including qualitative methodologies such as theory in use, <strong>and</strong><br />

grounded theory, <strong>and</strong> quantitative survey data (Gebhardt, Carpenter, & Sherry, 2006; Narver & Slater,<br />

1990; Siguaw et al., 1998).<br />

2 For a detailed examinati<strong>on</strong> of the various kinds of market orientati<strong>on</strong>–performance studies, please refer to the meta<br />

analysis by Kirca et al. (2005).<br />

24


2.2 Market Orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

In this secti<strong>on</strong>, we will describe purposefully selected prior studies <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong>. The<br />

criteria <strong>on</strong> which we based our choice of articles are whether the studies represented the<br />

important theoretical streams of the market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature. We introduce two important<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizati<strong>on</strong>s of market orientati<strong>on</strong>: the process-based perspective <strong>and</strong> the culture-based<br />

perspective. We then discuss whether a market-oriented culture is a resource <strong>and</strong> the linkage<br />

between the cultural perspective of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk. Next, we discuss the link<br />

between the cultural perspective of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> innovati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> eventually we discuss<br />

what we have learned from the prior literature synthesis <strong>on</strong> the cultural perspective of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>. We then commence our discussi<strong>on</strong> about the process-based view of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>. Afterwards, we discuss market orientati<strong>on</strong> in B2B c<strong>on</strong>texts <strong>and</strong> different moderators<br />

of the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance link. Furthermore, we discuss the link between market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> marketing accountability <strong>and</strong> finance. Finally, we discuss the c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> that<br />

our current study makes to the literature.<br />

As previously described in this chapter, there is a broad bifurcati<strong>on</strong> in the market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

literature al<strong>on</strong>g two lines, <strong>on</strong>e that c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizes market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a process <strong>and</strong> another that<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizes it as a culture (Langerak, Hultink, & Robben, 2004a). Both streams have linked it to<br />

<strong>firm</strong> performance (see Table 2.1).<br />

Table 2.1<br />

Representative Studies of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Their Focus<br />

Emphasis of Paper<br />

Study Number<br />

Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness as the Most Important Comp<strong>on</strong>ent of Market<br />

Orientati<strong>on</strong> 4,3,13<br />

Market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a culture 2,3,4,5,6,7,8,9,10,11,12<br />

Market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a process 1,13<br />

B2B market orientati<strong>on</strong> 5<br />

Market orientati<strong>on</strong> from a systems approach 3<br />

NPD as an antecedent to market orientati<strong>on</strong> 12<br />

NPD as a mediator of the market orientati<strong>on</strong> performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

Market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance moderators:<br />

1) Technology 4<br />

2) Market turbulence 4<br />

3) Competiti<strong>on</strong> 4<br />

Narver <strong>and</strong> Slater (1990) 1<br />

Gebhardt, Carpenter, <strong>and</strong> Sherry Jr. (2006) 2<br />

Homburg, Grozdanovic, <strong>and</strong> Klarmann (2007) 3<br />

Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) 4<br />

Siguaw, Simps<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> Baker (1998) 5<br />

Grewal <strong>and</strong> Tansuhaj (2001) 6<br />

Slater <strong>and</strong> Narver (1995) 7<br />

Voss <strong>and</strong> Voss (2000) 8<br />

Atuahene-Gima (1996) 9<br />

Marinova (2004) 10<br />

Zhou, Yim, <strong>and</strong> Tse (2005) 11<br />

Verhoef <strong>and</strong> Leeflang (2009) 12<br />

Jaworski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993) 13<br />

25


Table 2.1 highlights several prominent studies that focus <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong>. For example,<br />

the work of Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) is <strong>on</strong>e of the most highly cited market orientati<strong>on</strong> studies; it is<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>ceptual basis for much market orientati<strong>on</strong> research. Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) c<strong>on</strong>sider<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness as the most important comp<strong>on</strong>ent of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> their positi<strong>on</strong> has been<br />

widely accepted in research. Furthermore, Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) theorize about the impact of<br />

three comp<strong>on</strong>ents of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> business performance. Gebhardt et al. (2006) use grounded<br />

theory methodology to provide four stages of how to develop a market-oriented culture in an<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>. Homburg, Grozdanovic, <strong>and</strong> Klarmann (2007) examine the drivers of resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

towards the customer <strong>and</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness towards the competitor. Narver <strong>and</strong> Slater (1990) investigate<br />

the influence of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> business performance in both commodity <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-commodity<br />

businesses. Sigauw et al. (1998) investigate the mechanism by which manufacturing <strong>firm</strong>s influence<br />

their distributors to become more market oriented. Grewal <strong>and</strong> Tansuhaj (2001) examined the impact<br />

of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> strategic flexibility <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance after an ec<strong>on</strong>omic crisis. Slater <strong>and</strong><br />

Narver (1995) propose that market orientati<strong>on</strong> combined with an entrepreneurial drive <strong>and</strong> the right<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>al climate produces the learning organizati<strong>on</strong>. Voss <strong>and</strong> Voss (2000) examine the role of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> product orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. Marinova (2004) evaluates the impact<br />

of market knowledge diffusi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> innovati<strong>on</strong>s within organizati<strong>on</strong>s at a micro level. Zhou, Yim, <strong>and</strong><br />

Tse (2005) examine the impact of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance via the mediators of<br />

technological <strong>and</strong> market innovati<strong>on</strong>s. Verhoef <strong>and</strong> Leeflang (2009) examine whether marketing<br />

accountability increases the motivati<strong>on</strong> for <strong>firm</strong>s to be market oriented. Jaworski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993)<br />

empirically examine the impact of a market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. In the following secti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

(i.e., 2.2.1 through 2.2.11), we explain the studies in Table 1 in detail.<br />

2.2.1 Cultural Perspective of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

The cultural perspective of market orientati<strong>on</strong> put forth by Narver <strong>and</strong> Slater (1990) is widely<br />

accepted. They argued that <strong>firm</strong>s are motivated to acquire sustainable competitive advantages <strong>and</strong>, as a<br />

result, develop a culture that would help them to meet that end. They argue that this culture gives rise<br />

to three sets of market-oriented behavior, namely customer orientati<strong>on</strong>, competitor orientati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

interfuncti<strong>on</strong>al coordinati<strong>on</strong>. Customer <strong>and</strong> competitor orientati<strong>on</strong> are c<strong>on</strong>cerned with acquiring<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> about both the former <strong>and</strong> latter, whereas interfuncti<strong>on</strong>al coordinati<strong>on</strong> involves<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>-wide resources to be used for the creati<strong>on</strong> of superior <strong>value</strong> for their customers (Narver &<br />

Slater, 1990). They also examine two decisi<strong>on</strong> criteria, namely l<strong>on</strong>g-term orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> profitability.<br />

They c<strong>on</strong>sider profits to be a part of the process of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> profitability to be a<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequence of that process. They find that market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>firm</strong> size have an inverse<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship, meaning that the greater the <strong>firm</strong>’s size, the less market orientati<strong>on</strong> matters. This is<br />

because of the efficiencies they enjoy in the marketplace as a result of ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. Similarly,<br />

they find that <strong>firm</strong>s with few market orientated competitors face low barriers of entry into their target<br />

markets. However, their study was limited to a commodities market. They were unsuccessful in<br />

developing valid measures for profit <strong>and</strong> l<strong>on</strong>g-term focus, but they do find a link between market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the profitability of a business. On the c<strong>on</strong>trary, their study does not focus <strong>on</strong> specific<br />

attitudes that cause behavior, but rather <strong>on</strong> the end product that is behavior. This is a disc<strong>on</strong>nect,<br />

because if the attitude that causes the behavior has not been measured, then how could the researchers<br />

26


c<strong>on</strong>clude that the culture or attitude geared towards acquiring sustainable competitive advantages leads<br />

to these specific behaviors?<br />

2.2.2 Can a Culture be Developed? Is it Within Management’s C<strong>on</strong>trol<br />

Qualitative evidence suggests that an organizati<strong>on</strong> can become more market oriented if it desires <strong>and</strong><br />

can purposefully develop the required culture to maintain such an orientati<strong>on</strong> (Gebhardt et al., 2006).<br />

Gebhardt et al. (2006) outline the steps that are involved in developing a market orientati<strong>on</strong>, namely<br />

initiati<strong>on</strong>, rec<strong>on</strong>stituti<strong>on</strong>, instituti<strong>on</strong>alizati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> maintenance. The sec<strong>on</strong>d step of the process of<br />

creating a market orientati<strong>on</strong> involves <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> norm development, the removal of dissenters within<br />

the organizati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> hiring of believers. On the <strong>on</strong>e h<strong>and</strong>, according to Gebhardt et al. (2006), the<br />

development of a market-oriented culture falls within the locus of management c<strong>on</strong>trol, therefore<br />

making it valid to collect informati<strong>on</strong> from resp<strong>on</strong>dents about the <strong>firm</strong>’s culture. On the other h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

Slater <strong>and</strong> Narver (1995) suggest that generative organizati<strong>on</strong>al learning that is a part of the learning<br />

process of market orientati<strong>on</strong> is bey<strong>on</strong>d the locus of organizati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>trol; hence, developing a<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> is not fully in the locus of c<strong>on</strong>trol of a <strong>firm</strong>.<br />

The inherent difference in the literature can be resolved by incorporating the c<strong>on</strong>cept of IdRR<br />

into the market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature. IdRR is the c<strong>on</strong>sequence of risk caused by <strong>value</strong>-creating<br />

business processes. By reducing IdRR, the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong> is adding certainty <strong>and</strong> st<strong>and</strong>ardizing some of<br />

the critical or core business processes that are involved in creating customer <strong>value</strong>. Hence, the more<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ardized a process is, the more c<strong>on</strong>trol the <strong>supplier</strong> has over it. In turn, c<strong>on</strong>trol is thought to enable<br />

the <strong>supplier</strong> to easily launch remedial measures when necessary.<br />

2.2.3 The Cultural Perspective of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Ability to Take Risks<br />

Slater <strong>and</strong> Narver suggest that market orientati<strong>on</strong> is “inherently entrepreneurial” when it focuses<br />

<strong>on</strong> latent customer needs, but the entrepreneurial <strong>value</strong>s must be clear in the seller’s organizati<strong>on</strong><br />

(1995, p. 68). In essence, they suggest that if the seller focuses <strong>on</strong> the customer’s latent needs,<br />

then the seller requires a tolerance for taking risks. Furthermore, Slater <strong>and</strong> Narver (1995)<br />

reinforce the perspective of the process-based view that market orientati<strong>on</strong> involves innovati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> the willingness to take risk bey<strong>on</strong>d the normal level that is involved with regular business<br />

activities. Moreover, they argue in favor of c<strong>on</strong>tinuous investment in business innovati<strong>on</strong>s, as<br />

any new innovati<strong>on</strong> will eventually be imitated. Salter <strong>and</strong> Narver’s perspective of innovati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

are similar to the arguments regarding creative destructi<strong>on</strong> by Schumpter (1942). Meaning a <strong>firm</strong><br />

must be willing to cannibalize its own innovati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tinuously reinvest in the producti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

new developments in order to remain competitive (p.81). In our opini<strong>on</strong>, creative destructi<strong>on</strong> is<br />

risky because the new innovati<strong>on</strong> may not always pay off as much as did the old cannibalized<br />

product. However, Slater <strong>and</strong> Narver (1995) provide examples about innovati<strong>on</strong>s that are low<br />

risk <strong>and</strong> high return <strong>and</strong>, in their opini<strong>on</strong>, a market orientati<strong>on</strong> encourages <strong>firm</strong>s to find such<br />

opportunities. For example, they believe that user-generated innovati<strong>on</strong> reduces risk <strong>and</strong><br />

increases <strong>firm</strong> educati<strong>on</strong> about markets <strong>and</strong> new technologies. Furthermore, they argue that <strong>firm</strong>s<br />

that are meeting the customers’ latent needs attempt to use low-cost market experiments,<br />

implying that the risk involved with m<strong>on</strong>etary losses when <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong>s’ resp<strong>on</strong>ses do not work<br />

out is not too high. Whether the seller <strong>firm</strong>s’ risk-taking during innovati<strong>on</strong> through market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> is more than when <strong>firm</strong>s do not innovate or are not market oriented are elements that<br />

they do not discuss. In summati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e h<strong>and</strong> Slater <strong>and</strong> Narver (1995) agree with the process<br />

perspective that market orientati<strong>on</strong> needs organizati<strong>on</strong>al risk tolerance <strong>and</strong> risk taking. On the<br />

27


other h<strong>and</strong>, they later argue that market orientati<strong>on</strong> encourages <strong>firm</strong>s to innovate by using lowrisk<br />

<strong>and</strong> high-return strategies. The c<strong>on</strong>tradicti<strong>on</strong> in their explanati<strong>on</strong> is about whether market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> involves increased or diminished risk taking for the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong>. In<br />

additi<strong>on</strong>, they also do not investigate how market orientati<strong>on</strong> influences idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk, or the risk attributed to the <strong>buyer</strong>-<strong>and</strong>-seller relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Such a perspective is <strong>on</strong>e<br />

shortcoming that we investigate in the current chapter.<br />

2.2.4 A Cultural Perspective of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Innovati<strong>on</strong><br />

Atuahene-Gima (1996) found that market orientati<strong>on</strong> positively influences the exploitati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong> competencies <strong>and</strong> the ability to replace existing competencies with those that are new.<br />

However, the latter choice is also positively moderated by perceived market opportunities or, in<br />

other words, the greater the market opportunity to launch a new corporate competency, the more<br />

likely the <strong>firm</strong> is to launch it. New <strong>firm</strong> competencies are also more likely to lead to radical<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong>s, whereas the use of old <strong>firm</strong> competencies will negatively influence <strong>firm</strong> radical<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong>. Vice versa, existing competencies are likely to lead to incremental innovati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

whereas new competencies will negatively influence incremental capabilities. Furthermore,<br />

interfuncti<strong>on</strong>al coordinati<strong>on</strong> positively moderates the overall influence of competence<br />

exploitati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> explorati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> radical innovati<strong>on</strong>s. Overall, what this study shows is that a<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> is a necessary culture which gives rise to the behaviors leading to incremental<br />

<strong>and</strong> radical innovati<strong>on</strong>s in <strong>firm</strong>s.<br />

Similarly, Marinova (2004) finds that market knowledge diffusi<strong>on</strong> (i.e., informati<strong>on</strong><br />

generati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong> about customers <strong>and</strong> competitors), positively influences the<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong> effort that is exerted by a <strong>firm</strong> <strong>and</strong> its performance. In the absence of knowledge<br />

diffusi<strong>on</strong>, the innovati<strong>on</strong> effort does not influence the <strong>firm</strong>’s performance in terms of market<br />

share or earnings. Hence, market orientati<strong>on</strong> seems to be a necessary antecedent to successful<br />

market innovati<strong>on</strong> endeavor within <strong>firm</strong>s.<br />

2.2.5 What Do We Learn from the Cultural Perspective of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong>?<br />

There is a broad c<strong>on</strong>sensus within the extant literature that market orientati<strong>on</strong> can be c<strong>on</strong>ceptualized as<br />

a cultural phenomen<strong>on</strong>. Despite this recogniti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the relative difficulty <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>troversy in how to<br />

measure a culture, many researchers have assessed behaviors that are caused by a culture rather than<br />

attempting to measure the culture itself. This seems to be an effective way to counter the difficulty in<br />

measuring cultures directly, since behaviors serve as a useful proxy of the attitudes that comprise a<br />

culture (Deshp<strong>and</strong>e & Webster, 1989).<br />

There are other fundamental questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> which our prior synthesis provides c<strong>on</strong>flicting<br />

evidence. There are four main issues, namely:<br />

• Can a market orientati<strong>on</strong> be developed?<br />

• Is market orientati<strong>on</strong> a cultural marketing resource?<br />

• Is it possible to identify latent needs?<br />

• Is market orientati<strong>on</strong> a c<strong>on</strong>tinuous process or <strong>firm</strong>-level culture?<br />

Below we will discuss there four issues:<br />

i) Can it be developed? The perspectives <strong>on</strong> this outlook vary, with some scholars arguing that<br />

it can be developed whereas other scholars argue that it cannot (Deshp<strong>and</strong>e & Webster, 1989).<br />

However, in our opini<strong>on</strong>, the reality seems to be somewhere in between. Some elements of a marketoriented<br />

culture can be developed, but some elements, which require esoteric knowledge of the<br />

28


customer, can <strong>on</strong>ly be developed over time <strong>and</strong> as a part of a general learning curve. This lack of<br />

esoteric customer knowledge is because the <strong>firm</strong> may not know that such knowledge exists, <strong>and</strong> what<br />

overall benefit it would be to the <strong>firm</strong> culture. ii) Is a cultural market orientati<strong>on</strong> a resource? The<br />

learning up<strong>on</strong> which a customer’s underst<strong>and</strong>ing is based is not always something that the <strong>firm</strong> can<br />

intenti<strong>on</strong>ally develop. Hence, it qualifies <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e of the important tests of a resource, namely that it is<br />

inimitable (Srivastava, Shervani, & Fahey, 1998). iii) Taking this argument a step further, then the<br />

latent needs identificati<strong>on</strong>, which is an outcome of the cultural process of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, cannot<br />

always be purposefully developed, since the required insights may be just a functi<strong>on</strong> of pure<br />

coincidence. iv) Market orientati<strong>on</strong> is viewed as a c<strong>on</strong>tinuous process or a culture of innovati<strong>on</strong> (Kohli<br />

& Jaworski, 1990; Langerak et al., 2004a; Langerak et al., 2004b). Firms <strong>and</strong> managers want to avoid<br />

sunk costs or the cannibalizati<strong>on</strong> of existing product markets. Therefore, in our opini<strong>on</strong>, a culture must<br />

exist within the <strong>firm</strong> to allow a focus <strong>on</strong> innovati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> that fosters a managerial set of measurement<br />

tools that will allow them to differentiate themselves in the marketplace. Overall, although the<br />

evidence <strong>on</strong> the cultural perspective of market orientati<strong>on</strong> varies, there is some support for the noti<strong>on</strong><br />

that it does have a link to <strong>firm</strong> performance.<br />

2.2.6 The Process-Based View of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

The process-based view of marketing orientati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>siders it to be the implementati<strong>on</strong> of the<br />

marketing c<strong>on</strong>cept (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990). As menti<strong>on</strong>ed earlier, there are three comp<strong>on</strong>ents<br />

of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Each comp<strong>on</strong>ent of market orientati<strong>on</strong> sequentially paves the way for the<br />

next step in the process of marketing orientati<strong>on</strong>. Hence, intelligence is generated, disseminated,<br />

<strong>and</strong>, finally, a resp<strong>on</strong>se is created. But managers discriminate between trustworthy <strong>and</strong><br />

untrustworthy sources of intelligence before issuing a resp<strong>on</strong>se that is based <strong>on</strong> the intelligence<br />

(Kohli & Jaworski, 1990). Therefore, all intelligence available will never be paid attenti<strong>on</strong> to <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>on</strong>ly trustworthy sources of intelligence will generate a resp<strong>on</strong>se. In order to be c<strong>on</strong>tinuously<br />

trusted, the resp<strong>on</strong>sibility lies with the intelligence provider to be accurate because faulty<br />

intelligence could erode the trust that the intelligence provider enjoys. In a strategic <strong>supplier</strong>-<strong>and</strong><strong>buyer</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship, a customer’s trust in the <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship is important because it has<br />

positive c<strong>on</strong>sequences, such as customer committment (Siguaw et al., 1998).<br />

Besides intelligence sharing, there are other ways of building customer goodwill, such as<br />

through innovati<strong>on</strong>s. Being market-oriented, by default, leads to innovati<strong>on</strong>s; according to Kohli<br />

<strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990), “a market orientati<strong>on</strong> involves something new or different in resp<strong>on</strong>se to<br />

market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s, it can be viewed as a form of innovative behavior” (p. 11). The process-based<br />

view holds that market orientati<strong>on</strong> corresp<strong>on</strong>ds with the process of innovating (Kohli &<br />

Jaworski, 1990). Therefore, market orientati<strong>on</strong> involves trying new or innovative soluti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong><br />

target markets, <strong>and</strong> such is an inherently risky endeavor. Hence, according to the process-based<br />

view of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, managers must be tolerant of risk taking if they are to be market<br />

oriented (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990).<br />

Is there really a difference between the process-based versus cultural-based view of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong>? Although Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) do recognize that market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

can be a plan or philosophy, they do not explicitly recognize market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a part of an<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>al culture. The authors eventually recognized that both the cultural perspective <strong>and</strong><br />

process-based perspective are of significance. Likewise, the cultural perspective of Slater <strong>and</strong><br />

Narver (1990) operati<strong>on</strong>alizes the culture as specific behaviors or a series of activities.<br />

29


Therefore, there is a c<strong>on</strong>vergence in both streams that a market orientati<strong>on</strong> is implemented by<br />

behaviors.<br />

2.2.7 Business-to-Business Market Orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

The <strong>on</strong>e study that examined the influence of <strong>supplier</strong>s’ market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> B2B distributors’<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> suffers from a c<strong>on</strong>ceptual limitati<strong>on</strong> in that, first, it does not articulate the<br />

mechanism which would motivate a <strong>supplier</strong> to choose a market-oriented <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong>, sec<strong>on</strong>d, the<br />

ways in which the <strong>supplier</strong> influences the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>’s culture (Siguaw et al., 1998). Regarding<br />

the latter limitati<strong>on</strong>, Siguaw et al. (1998) use reference group theory to explain how <strong>supplier</strong><br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> influences distributor market orientati<strong>on</strong>. They also c<strong>on</strong>sider <strong>on</strong>ly two<br />

situati<strong>on</strong>s: In the first, <strong>supplier</strong>s are more powerful <strong>and</strong> more market-oriented than distributors.<br />

As a result, distributors become increasingly market oriented with the hope of pleasing their<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s <strong>and</strong> thus, c<strong>on</strong>tinuing the existing relati<strong>on</strong>ship. The sec<strong>on</strong>d situati<strong>on</strong> is where the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> distributor are of equal power. Then, a distributor or <strong>supplier</strong> would benchmark<br />

against the channel partners’ superior performance <strong>and</strong> optimize his or her own performance in<br />

order to meet the channel partners’ superior performance. The explanati<strong>on</strong>s for both situati<strong>on</strong>s, in<br />

our opini<strong>on</strong>, are inadequate. First, having a market-oriented <strong>supplier</strong> does not necessarily mean<br />

that they would want to have market-oriented distributors unless the distributor market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> influences the <strong>supplier</strong>’s own profits <strong>and</strong> has the potential to increase their market<br />

share (the link to market share is disputed by some authors, such as Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski’s 1993<br />

work). These are links which the authors do not explore; such is an important oversight because<br />

they ignore that possibility that if the flow of <strong>supplier</strong> benefits was c<strong>on</strong>tingent up<strong>on</strong> a channel<br />

partner’s market orientati<strong>on</strong>, then this, in turn, would motivate a <strong>supplier</strong> to look for market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> in their channel partner. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, they could have measured the ‘<strong>supplier</strong>’s desire for a<br />

market oriented <strong>buyer</strong>,’ which would have been an attitudinal indicator measuring their desire to<br />

have distributors who are market oriented. This approach would have been similar to attitudinal<br />

measures used in other domains of marketing, such as innovati<strong>on</strong>s (Tellis, Prabhu, & Ch<strong>and</strong>y,<br />

2009), which have shed light <strong>on</strong> internal <strong>firm</strong> motivators towards the introducti<strong>on</strong> of radical<br />

market innovati<strong>on</strong>s. In c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>, the literature <strong>on</strong> B2B inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> its effects are limited. The theoretical explanati<strong>on</strong> provided by Siguaw et al. (1998) leaves<br />

key questi<strong>on</strong>s unanswered (i.e., as discussed above). Furthermore, in our opini<strong>on</strong> for a model to<br />

be str<strong>on</strong>g, there needs to be some direct measure of <strong>value</strong> created for the <strong>buyer</strong> or distributor as<br />

well as the <strong>supplier</strong>. These c<strong>on</strong>cerns are addressed later in this chapter when our c<strong>on</strong>ceptual<br />

model is developed where we discuss the c<strong>on</strong>cept of IdRR insulati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

2.2.8 Moderators of the Market Orientati<strong>on</strong>-Performance Link<br />

Most studies in the market orientati<strong>on</strong> framework highlight three important moderators regarding<br />

the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship: technological turbulence, competitive intensity,<br />

<strong>and</strong> envir<strong>on</strong>mental turbulence (Jaworski & Kohli, 1993; Grewal & Tansuhaj, 2001; Pulendran,<br />

Speed, & Widing, 2000). These external envir<strong>on</strong>mental moderators influence the level of a<br />

<strong>firm</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the market orientati<strong>on</strong>s’ linkage with performance (Jaworski &<br />

Kohli, 1993). In the following secti<strong>on</strong>, we examine the studies that have examined the influence<br />

of the envir<strong>on</strong>mental factors <strong>on</strong> the <strong>firm</strong>s’ market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance linkage.<br />

The first envir<strong>on</strong>mental moderator of the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance linkage is<br />

technological turbulence. Technological turbulence has little evidence to support its role as a<br />

30


moderator of the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Most studies have found that<br />

technological turbulence is of insignificant influence <strong>on</strong> the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship, whereas some have found that it positively moderates the relati<strong>on</strong>ship <strong>and</strong> fewer<br />

have found that it negatively moderates the relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Kirca et al., 2005). The study that does<br />

find evidence of moderati<strong>on</strong> finds it in technologically turbulent export markets (Kirca et al.,<br />

2005). Most studies have found an insignificant relati<strong>on</strong>ship, perhaps due to the rarity of<br />

technological shocks within their samples. A study that has found a positive influence is Grewal<br />

<strong>and</strong> Tansuhaj (2001). However, their sample is taken from an Asian ec<strong>on</strong>omy, specifically<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship may not hold for other settings in European <strong>and</strong> North American<br />

countries. Furthermore, they propose that market orientati<strong>on</strong>, in times of market turbulence,<br />

negatively influences performance because a <strong>firm</strong>’s market underst<strong>and</strong>ing is built <strong>on</strong> knowledge<br />

that no l<strong>on</strong>ger applies to the currently changing market scenario. Another study which finds that<br />

partial support for low technological turbulence influencing the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship is that c<strong>on</strong>ducted by Slater <strong>and</strong> Narver (1994). They have similar findings to Grewal<br />

<strong>and</strong> Tansuhaj (2001), in that market orientati<strong>on</strong> is more important in times of low technological<br />

turbulence than in times of higher technological turbulence. Most studies, however, find that<br />

technological turbulence has an insignificant influence <strong>on</strong> the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Kirca et al., 2005). This result is not surprising since, unless technological<br />

turbulence can influence the knowledge capabilities of the <strong>firm</strong>, it would not be expected to<br />

moderate the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance. Our stance <strong>on</strong> this issue<br />

is that, in technology driven markets, market orientati<strong>on</strong> matters less as the new technology<br />

could cause disrupti<strong>on</strong>s in c<strong>on</strong>sumer-buying patterns. As a result, this makes it difficult for the<br />

market-sensing mechanism (e.g., intelligence generati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong>) to determine <strong>and</strong><br />

predict what the future needs of the customers will be. Therefore, market orientati<strong>on</strong> has a<br />

limited impact <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d moderator that is comm<strong>on</strong>ly cited in the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship is market turbulence. The evidence for it as a positive versus insignificant moderator<br />

is almost evenly split. There is less evidence for it as a negative moderator, which could be<br />

because <strong>firm</strong>s which have ‘strategic flexibility’ are able to change their internal processes to<br />

meet adverse situati<strong>on</strong>s (Grewal & Tansuhaj, 2001). In situati<strong>on</strong>s where it is insignificant, it<br />

could be that market orientati<strong>on</strong> is an immutable part of the <strong>firm</strong>’s culture but that it does not<br />

possess strategic flexibility or the ability to change in time. Our stance <strong>on</strong> this issue is that<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> gives insights according to customer underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> takes time to develop;<br />

in rapidly changing envir<strong>on</strong>ments, it is not possible for <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong>s to underst<strong>and</strong> how their<br />

customers’ needs are changing. Therefore, we c<strong>on</strong>cur with the finding of previous scholars that<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> has limited applicability in the c<strong>on</strong>text of high market turbulence.<br />

The third moderator is competitive intensity. Extant literature suggests that customer<br />

insights provided by market orientati<strong>on</strong> become more important as competitive rivalry increases<br />

(Kirca et al., 2005). The evidence <strong>on</strong> whether competitive intensity moderates the market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship is mixed in prior literature (Kirca et al., 2005). We agree<br />

with the view that as competitive rivalry increases, the <strong>firm</strong> must be more market oriented.<br />

Because greater competiti<strong>on</strong> means that customers have more choices <strong>and</strong> in order to maintain<br />

31


usiness performance, <strong>firm</strong>s need to resp<strong>on</strong>d to customers’ needs with offerings that are based <strong>on</strong><br />

unique insights that the competiti<strong>on</strong> does not know.<br />

2.2.9 What We Learn from the Prior Studies of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

The prior secti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> focused <strong>on</strong> a few core issues. First, it addressed market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> as a culture <strong>and</strong> a set of activities or processes within the <strong>firm</strong>. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, it explored the<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> its role in generating sustainable <strong>and</strong> valuable<br />

resources for the <strong>firm</strong>. Finally, it examined the role of innovati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Then a<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> would lead to an organizati<strong>on</strong>al culture that encourages the development of<br />

sustainable competitive advantages for the <strong>firm</strong>.<br />

2.2.10 Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Marketing Accountability<br />

There has been a tremendous call for marketing accountability with the need for marketing<br />

managers to speak the language of finance (Bolt<strong>on</strong>, Lem<strong>on</strong>, & Verhoef, 2004). Verhoef <strong>and</strong><br />

Leeflang (2009) investigated which variables lead to the creati<strong>on</strong> of marketing’s influence within<br />

the <strong>firm</strong>. They found that a c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong> with the customer <strong>and</strong> creativity do not have a significant<br />

amount of influence <strong>on</strong> marketing’s importance within the <strong>firm</strong>. However, accountability <strong>and</strong><br />

innovativeness do. Then, they find that the greater the marketing department’s influence within<br />

the <strong>firm</strong>, the more likely it will be that the <strong>firm</strong> is market oriented. Although they do accept the<br />

process-based perspective of marketing orientati<strong>on</strong> (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990), their<br />

c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizati<strong>on</strong> suffers from a fundamental flaw. Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) state that market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> is a process of c<strong>on</strong>tinuous innovati<strong>on</strong>s, whereas Verhoef <strong>and</strong> Leeflang (2009) define<br />

marketing innovativeness as the degree to which the marketing department c<strong>on</strong>tributes to the<br />

development of new products within the <strong>firm</strong>. Verhoef <strong>and</strong> Leeflang (2009) then c<strong>on</strong>ceptualize a<br />

sub-comp<strong>on</strong>ent of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, innovativeness, as an antecedent to market orientati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

which is in serious theoretical c<strong>on</strong>flict with existing c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizati<strong>on</strong>s. Their definiti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

marketing department innovativeness is as the degree to which it c<strong>on</strong>tributes to the developed<br />

new products within the <strong>firm</strong>. For example, new product development has been documented as a<br />

mediator between the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance linkage (Langerak et al., 2004a).<br />

Verhoef <strong>and</strong> Leeflang (2009) also include customer c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong> or, in other words, the ability to<br />

translate customer needs into soluti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> communicate them to cross-functi<strong>on</strong>al departments<br />

as an indirect antecedent to market orientati<strong>on</strong>. This c<strong>on</strong>cept is very similar to the intelligence<br />

generati<strong>on</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong> (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990) <strong>and</strong> cross-functi<strong>on</strong>al alignment c<strong>on</strong>cepts<br />

(Narver & Slater, 1990). Given that this is another redundant comp<strong>on</strong>ent of their model, its effect<br />

is underst<strong>and</strong>ably insignificant. But the <strong>value</strong> of Verhoef <strong>and</strong> Leeflang’s (2009) model is that<br />

they were able to show that accountability, meaning being accountable within the organizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

<strong>and</strong> having the right metrics to measure that performance leads to a motivati<strong>on</strong> to be market<br />

oriented. This result develops because of the belief that performance improves through a market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>. Therefore, studies that examine the role of market orientati<strong>on</strong> in different c<strong>on</strong>texts<br />

should also include measures that lead to corporate accountability so that managers can then<br />

correctly measure their performance. This mechanism, in turn, could act as an objective<br />

motivator for organizati<strong>on</strong>s to be market oriented.<br />

In essence, what we learn from Verhoef <strong>and</strong> Leelang (2009) is that accountability of the<br />

marketing department increases its influence within the <strong>firm</strong>. In turn, this leads to the <strong>firm</strong> being<br />

more market oriented <strong>and</strong> that positively influences <strong>firm</strong> performance. Hence, marketing <strong>firm</strong>s<br />

32


need to measure the <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk that market orientati<strong>on</strong> creates for a <strong>firm</strong> which, in turn, gives<br />

the marketing department greater influence in the <strong>firm</strong>.<br />

2.2.11 Measuring the Marketing Orientati<strong>on</strong> – Finance Link<br />

The market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance link has typically been measured by seller’s self-reported<br />

perceptual performance metrics, such as profitability, profits, <strong>and</strong> market share (Kohli &<br />

Jaworski, 1990; Narver & Slater, 1990). However, these metrics have largely ignored how<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> affects customer risk percepti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> performance metrics that lead us to the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> that this is an area within the literature than needs further inquiry. Prior studies have<br />

examined management aversi<strong>on</strong> to risk as an antecedent to organizati<strong>on</strong>al market orientati<strong>on</strong>, but<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>sequences of market orientati<strong>on</strong> for relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, to our knowledge, have not been<br />

examined (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990). This lack of focus <strong>on</strong> risk within the market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

literature may be because many managers assume risk assessments as incomprehensible <strong>and</strong><br />

these include complex financial models which are better left off to the financial services industry<br />

<strong>and</strong> investment professi<strong>on</strong>als (Buehler, Freeman, & Hulme, 2008). To address the lack of focus<br />

<strong>on</strong> risk in the extant market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature, we examine the role of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> in generating risk insulati<strong>on</strong> for their customers. This is c<strong>on</strong>sistent with prior research<br />

in marketing that examines the role of market-based assets in creating insulati<strong>on</strong> from stock<br />

market risk. However, we examine whether a <strong>supplier</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong> generates risk<br />

insulati<strong>on</strong> for customers at the <strong>firm</strong> level.<br />

2.2.12 C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

To our knowledge, ours is the first study in the marketing literature to examine the process of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> with the focus <strong>on</strong> the mediating role of idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk. In the<br />

current study, we aim to make four c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s. First, we examine the role of <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness in creating <strong>value</strong> in an <strong>on</strong>going channel relati<strong>on</strong>ship. According to some scholars,<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong>, with its str<strong>on</strong>g c<strong>on</strong>ceptual <strong>and</strong> empirical support, has become an important<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct that affects a <strong>firm</strong>’s strategies (Zhou et al., 2005). Other research has shown that when<br />

dynamics of disequilibrium exist in the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between a <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> seller, they could lead<br />

to a deteriorati<strong>on</strong> of the relati<strong>on</strong>ship, provided that positive relati<strong>on</strong>al sentiments do not prevent<br />

such a deteriorati<strong>on</strong> (Kumar, Scheer, & Steenkamp, 1995). In situati<strong>on</strong>s where the dynamics of<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al disequilibrium exist al<strong>on</strong>g any relati<strong>on</strong>ship dimensi<strong>on</strong> (i.e., power, trust, etc.), <strong>buyer</strong>s<br />

need cues to indicate to them how likely a <strong>supplier</strong> is to meet their needs <strong>and</strong> create <strong>value</strong>. We<br />

propose that a <strong>supplier</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong> can provide <strong>buyer</strong>s with such a cue. The effect of<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>on</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong>’s profitability is a measure of the <strong>value</strong> that is created by the<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Our sec<strong>on</strong>d c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> is that we focus <strong>on</strong> IdRR. Prior<br />

research <strong>on</strong> channel relati<strong>on</strong>ships has focused <strong>on</strong> intangible relati<strong>on</strong>al benefits but not IdRR. We<br />

assess whether market orientati<strong>on</strong> can insulate strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships from IdRR. We believe that<br />

ours is the first study that focuses <strong>on</strong> the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-idiosyncratic risk link at the <strong>firm</strong><br />

level. Our third c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> is that we challenge the assumpti<strong>on</strong> that market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

risk are positively related; we propose that they are negatively related in the strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text. This is a unique <strong>and</strong> counterintuitive insight because the current dominant logic is that<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> is syn<strong>on</strong>ymous with innovating (i.e., excluding radical innovati<strong>on</strong>s).<br />

Innovating means taking risks. However, we find that innovating based <strong>on</strong> an idiosyncratic<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the other party’s business processes mitigates idiosyncratic risk. What this<br />

33


means is that the more better a strategic <strong>supplier</strong> knows their customer, the more they know how<br />

<strong>and</strong> what to innovate. The effect of this is risk reducti<strong>on</strong>, rather than enhanced risk taking. Our<br />

fourth c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> is that prior studies of market orientati<strong>on</strong> have focused <strong>on</strong> intra-<strong>firm</strong> benefits<br />

from market orientati<strong>on</strong>. We focus <strong>on</strong> inter-<strong>firm</strong> benefits of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. The classic<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature assesses the performance of the <strong>firm</strong> implementing the market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> philosophy or strategy (Jaworski & Kohli, 1993; Kohli & Jaworski, 1990; Narver &<br />

Slater, 1990). The perspective in most studies that we have reviewed is that of the seller, but<br />

some scholars have advocated using the customer’s perspective (Steinman, Deshp<strong>and</strong>e, &<br />

Farley, 2000). The aim of having a market orientati<strong>on</strong> is to generate superior customer <strong>value</strong><br />

(Narver & Slater, 1990). Moreover, the customer is the best to judge whether the <strong>value</strong> that is<br />

created by a seller market orientati<strong>on</strong> (Steinman et al., 2000). Furthermore, the use of a customer<br />

perspective helps <strong>supplier</strong>s to avoid a perceptual gap that might exist between their percepti<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> the customer’s percepti<strong>on</strong> of how market-oriented the <strong>supplier</strong> is (Steinman et al., 2000). In<br />

additi<strong>on</strong>, using the customer’s perspective reveals the degree to which the customer benefits, in<br />

terms of <strong>value</strong>, from the <strong>supplier</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong> efforts (Steinman et al., 2000). In t<strong>and</strong>em,<br />

the customer perspective also reveals how much customers would be willing to pay for the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s product or relati<strong>on</strong>ship; in other words, it allows us to measure the <strong>value</strong> that the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> generates for the relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Hence, using the customer’s perspective allows us to<br />

measure <strong>value</strong> or benefits for the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong>, rather than the <strong>value</strong> or benefits acquired by<br />

<strong>on</strong>e entity al<strong>on</strong>e in the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

In the current study, we incorporate the customer’s perspective of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

highlight the benefits that the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong> can acquire from a <strong>supplier</strong>’s market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>. This customer perspective in our opini<strong>on</strong> is more meaningful because it is a marketbased<br />

perspective rather than an experiential reflecti<strong>on</strong> of a sales manager or executive.<br />

The rest of this chapter is organized as follows: First, we develop our hypotheses, then<br />

we describe our research design <strong>and</strong> present our findings. Finally, we discuss the academic <strong>and</strong><br />

managerial implicati<strong>on</strong>s, general discussi<strong>on</strong>s, limitati<strong>on</strong>s, future research directi<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

34


2.3 Development of the C<strong>on</strong>ceptual Model<br />

Figure 2.1<br />

C<strong>on</strong>ceptual Model<br />

Figure 2.1 depicts the c<strong>on</strong>ceptual model for this study. It shows the hypotheses for the present<br />

research.<br />

In the following paragraphs, we have set out to synthesize the literature <strong>and</strong> develop our<br />

rati<strong>on</strong>ale for the first hypothesis. IdRR is a c<strong>on</strong>struct we have developed <strong>and</strong> up<strong>on</strong> which we will<br />

expound in this thesis as a mediator of the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship. We will<br />

first c<strong>on</strong>sider the literature <strong>on</strong> general marketing risk <strong>and</strong> the market orientati<strong>on</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Next we<br />

will explicitly focus <strong>on</strong> IdRR <strong>and</strong> state our first hypothesis.<br />

35


Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or market orientati<strong>on</strong>’s fundamental purpose is the creati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

maintenance of superior customer <strong>value</strong> (Narver & Slater, 1990). Moreover, market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

encourages a focus <strong>on</strong> the customer’s needs. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence of customer focus, the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

develops an idiosyncratic underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the current needs of the <strong>buyer</strong>. Furthermore, customer<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing helps the <strong>supplier</strong> avoid risk taking <strong>and</strong> provides the <strong>buyer</strong> with reliable soluti<strong>on</strong>s for<br />

their current needs.<br />

Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness involves generating market resp<strong>on</strong>ses in the form of products,<br />

services, <strong>and</strong> strategic informati<strong>on</strong>. Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness also positively influences the relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

factors of a B2B <strong>supplier</strong>-<strong>and</strong>-<strong>buyer</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Narver & Slater, 1990; Siguaw et al., 1998). In<br />

additi<strong>on</strong>, channel partners are willing to share strategic informati<strong>on</strong> with their <strong>supplier</strong> when<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships are healthy <strong>and</strong> of a strategic nature (Frazier, Maltz, Antia, & Rindfleisch, 2009). This<br />

informati<strong>on</strong>-sharing process is important, as such informati<strong>on</strong> allows the <strong>supplier</strong> to come up with low<br />

risk <strong>and</strong> high use soluti<strong>on</strong>s. For example, a <strong>supplier</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong> affords them the ability to<br />

identify expert or lead users of a product. These lead users, in turn, provide valuable intelligence <strong>on</strong><br />

breakthrough innovati<strong>on</strong>s which are used in the <strong>supplier</strong>’s products. Some studies have suggested that<br />

the lead users have invented up to 80% of breakthrough innovati<strong>on</strong>s (V<strong>on</strong> Hippel, 1976). Hence, the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> needs to invest very little in the development of new products, besides investing in a good<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> process. A c<strong>on</strong>sequence of this investment is that the risk associated with user<br />

adopti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> product failure is very low. Furthermore, an employee of a c<strong>on</strong>sulting company observed<br />

that “most of our profits come from <strong>value</strong> co-creati<strong>on</strong> activities. The customer’s inputs are essential to<br />

creating soluti<strong>on</strong>s which are low in risk <strong>and</strong> which offer high returns.”<br />

Not all comp<strong>on</strong>ents of a market orientati<strong>on</strong> are negatively associated with managerial risk<br />

averseness, specifically intelligence generati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> intelligence disseminati<strong>on</strong> (Jaworski & Kohli,<br />

1993). This is observable when seller <strong>firm</strong>s have the necessary technology in place to launch a<br />

successful innovati<strong>on</strong>, but do not do so. For instance, c<strong>on</strong>sider Xerox, which had most of the knowhow<br />

for the first pers<strong>on</strong>al computers but did not launch them (USC, 2008). Thus, although the<br />

knowledge existed, the resp<strong>on</strong>se element was lacking. Hence, we infer from the results presented by<br />

Jaworski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993) that managers who are risk averse are indifferent to developing new<br />

knowledge, but they do have c<strong>on</strong>cerns when it comes to launching or resp<strong>on</strong>ding to market needs<br />

based <strong>on</strong> new knowledge.<br />

Some scholars suggest that <strong>on</strong>e way of perceived customer risk reducti<strong>on</strong> is by enhancing<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> tolerance for <strong>supplier</strong> risk taking (Roselius, 1971). Supplier market orientati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness increases <strong>buyer</strong> tolerance for risk taking by strengthening the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Siguaw et al., 1998). Supplier market orientati<strong>on</strong> causes the <strong>supplier</strong> to collaborate with<br />

the <strong>buyer</strong> to a greater degree <strong>and</strong> share important informati<strong>on</strong> with the <strong>buyer</strong>. As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, the<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> is more likely to accept the <strong>supplier</strong>’s motives as being a genuine expressi<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

interest in their welfare (Siguaw et al., 1998). Overall, the result here is an increase in the <strong>buyer</strong>’s level<br />

of trust in the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> that, in turn, allows the <strong>supplier</strong> to take greater risks without a negative<br />

reacti<strong>on</strong> from the customer (Siguaw et al., 1998).<br />

Furthermore, risk reducti<strong>on</strong> is an important aim of both the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong> (Roselius,<br />

1971). A risk reducti<strong>on</strong> tactic used by the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong> is called ‘risk relievers’ <strong>and</strong> refers to<br />

the implementati<strong>on</strong> of any marketing acti<strong>on</strong> or c<strong>on</strong>cept which causes the probability of a purchase loss<br />

to decrease (Roselius, 1971). Stated another way, the implementati<strong>on</strong> of the marketing c<strong>on</strong>cept or<br />

36


market orientati<strong>on</strong> reduces risk for the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong>. The risk reducti<strong>on</strong> occurs when acti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

based <strong>on</strong> the knowledge about the customer <strong>and</strong> marketplace in general, is taken. Inherently, market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> includes a learning organizati<strong>on</strong> that involves producing soluti<strong>on</strong>s or resp<strong>on</strong>ses based <strong>on</strong><br />

envir<strong>on</strong>mental learning (Slater & Narver, 1995). Hence, the <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>se must be based <strong>on</strong> the<br />

implementati<strong>on</strong> of the marketing c<strong>on</strong>cept (i.e., <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness), in order to reduce the specific<br />

risk for both the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong> in their relati<strong>on</strong>ship or in their transacti<strong>on</strong>s (i.e., idiosyncratic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al risk). Hence, our first hypothesis is:<br />

H1: Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness negatively influences IdRR.<br />

Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. The aim of a market orientati<strong>on</strong> is to satisfy<br />

the customer’s needs with a l<strong>on</strong>g-term focus <strong>on</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship with the customer (Steinman,<br />

Deshp<strong>and</strong>e, & Farley, 2000; Kalwani & Nary<strong>and</strong>as, 1995; Kotler & Armstr<strong>on</strong>g, 1991; Day,<br />

1998). A market orientati<strong>on</strong> is also a measure of the <strong>supplier</strong> satisfying customer needs through<br />

market-sensing capabilities (Day, 1994).<br />

Buyer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with their <strong>supplier</strong> is the result of positive expectati<strong>on</strong> disc<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> dissatisfacti<strong>on</strong> with their <strong>supplier</strong> is when negative expectati<strong>on</strong> disc<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ati<strong>on</strong> occurs<br />

(Oliver, 1980). Buyer expectati<strong>on</strong>s are influenced by three factors: (i) the product or service<br />

itself, past experiences with the <strong>supplier</strong> that set the norm for future exchanges, <strong>and</strong> symbolic<br />

expectati<strong>on</strong>s the br<strong>and</strong> (Oliver, 1980); (ii) the communicati<strong>on</strong>s from sales pers<strong>on</strong>nel or<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>al spanners (Oliver, 1980); sales pers<strong>on</strong>nel’s influence <strong>on</strong> the customer’s<br />

expectati<strong>on</strong>s by their promise of delivering a certain level of a <strong>supplier</strong>’s offering. If the sales<br />

pers<strong>on</strong>nel’s organizati<strong>on</strong> is not market-oriented enough, then there could be a lack of<br />

communicati<strong>on</strong> from the salespers<strong>on</strong> to the <strong>firm</strong>s operati<strong>on</strong>s about the customer’s expectati<strong>on</strong>; in<br />

turn, that will lead to customer dissatisfacti<strong>on</strong> when the customer’s needs are not met. Another<br />

scenario is that the salespers<strong>on</strong> could not be fully informed about his organizati<strong>on</strong>’s delivery<br />

capability, specifically in the case of services; as a result, he or she could overextend promises to<br />

the customer. Then, the customer will be dissatisfied when expectati<strong>on</strong>s are not met. (iii) The<br />

third aspect to c<strong>on</strong>sider is comprised of individual factors, including persuadability <strong>and</strong><br />

intellectual distorti<strong>on</strong> (Oliver, 1980).<br />

However, in a market orientati<strong>on</strong> philosophy, it is not enough to meet customer<br />

expectati<strong>on</strong>s; instead, the ability to exceed customer expectati<strong>on</strong>s is required in order to create<br />

superior <strong>value</strong> (Narver & Slater, 1990; Anders<strong>on</strong>, Fornell, & Lehmann, 1994). Such superior<br />

<strong>value</strong> is delivered by: i) operati<strong>on</strong>al excellence, which involves providing better channel <strong>and</strong><br />

business process management while maintaining close customer links; ii) customer intimacy,<br />

which involves customizing resp<strong>on</strong>ses to customer needs <strong>and</strong> implementing early warning<br />

systems for detecting changes in the market place; <strong>and</strong> iii) product leadership, which involves<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tinuous product <strong>and</strong> service innovati<strong>on</strong> through market-sensing capabilities to achieve a<br />

positi<strong>on</strong> of leadership in the market. In additi<strong>on</strong>, market sensing capabilities allow <strong>firm</strong>s to<br />

identify potential product leadership opportunities early <strong>on</strong> (Treacy & Wiersema, 1993).<br />

Some authors criticize market orientati<strong>on</strong> for encouraging too narrow a focus <strong>and</strong> the<br />

percepti<strong>on</strong> that it leads <strong>supplier</strong>s to ignore upcoming markets <strong>and</strong> potential new entrants (Hamel &<br />

Prahald, 1994). As a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, this narrow focus may lead to customer dissatisfacti<strong>on</strong>. However,<br />

focusing <strong>on</strong> markets allows <strong>supplier</strong>s to acquire idiosyncratic knowledge about how their specific<br />

clientele operates <strong>and</strong>, therefore, they are able to drive down costs for customers (Kalwani &<br />

37


Nary<strong>and</strong>as, 1995). Further, idiosyncratic underst<strong>and</strong>ing or knowledge allows the <strong>supplier</strong> to surpass<br />

the customers’ expectati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> results in greater customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. It also leads to greater<br />

profitability for the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> that profitability serves as a motivating factor for <strong>supplier</strong>s to<br />

focus <strong>on</strong> their customers’ needs (Kalwani & Nary<strong>and</strong>as, 1995). This reas<strong>on</strong>ing leads to our sec<strong>on</strong>d<br />

hypothesis:<br />

H2: Strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness positively influences <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Buyer Firm Value. In the channel management c<strong>on</strong>text, <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is an affective evaluati<strong>on</strong> of accumulative ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic benefits from a<br />

business relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Gyskens et al., 1999). Extant literature has focused <strong>on</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the resulting <strong>supplier</strong>’s profits (Gyskens et al., 1999). This focus is<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>able, as marketing managers need to provide finance managers with return <strong>on</strong> investment<br />

measures (Bolt<strong>on</strong> et al., 2004). Yet this focus <strong>on</strong> the return of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s investment causes<br />

researchers to neglect whether a <strong>buyer</strong>’s satisfacti<strong>on</strong> increases the <strong>buyer</strong>’s own profits. A <strong>buyer</strong>’s<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> would matter more to a <strong>supplier</strong> if it has a verifiable link to the <strong>buyer</strong>’s own profits, as<br />

B2B <strong>buyer</strong>s increase business with <strong>supplier</strong>s who have a direct impact <strong>on</strong> their sales. For example,<br />

premium <strong>buyer</strong>s, such as Audi, use OEM manufacturers of comp<strong>on</strong>ents that complement their<br />

premium positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> increase their sales, <strong>on</strong>e example of such a comp<strong>on</strong>ent <strong>supplier</strong> to Audi is Bose<br />

(Ghosh & John, 2009). Therefore, for <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> to be meaningful, it must bring ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

<strong>value</strong> to the <strong>supplier</strong>. Therefore, we formulate the following hypothesis:<br />

H3: Buyer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is positively associated with <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

Buyer Idiosyncratic Risk <strong>and</strong> Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value. Risk has been approached within extant<br />

marketing literature at different levels, namely: i) a financial market level, ii) a customer percepti<strong>on</strong><br />

level, <strong>and</strong> iii) a managerial perceptual risk at the <strong>firm</strong> level. All three levels of risk include supply risk<br />

percepti<strong>on</strong>s. Generally, supply risk is thought to be highest when a <strong>buyer</strong> purchases strategic items<br />

from a <strong>supplier</strong> or, in other words, strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s provide those items which involve the greatest<br />

supply risk (Kraljic, 1983). For clarificati<strong>on</strong>, we refer to this <strong>supplier</strong>-associated risk in strategic<br />

c<strong>on</strong>texts as IdRR.<br />

Buyers are usually willing to make idiosyncratic investments <strong>and</strong>, hence, acquire exposure to<br />

idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk if any <strong>on</strong>e of three c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are fulfilled: a) the product is rare, b) the<br />

manufacturing is complex, or c) they are able to buffer against technological uncertainty (Bensaou &<br />

Anders<strong>on</strong>, 1999). For example, from the perspective of a financial instituti<strong>on</strong> such as a bank, the<br />

efficiency of the strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ship determines the level of idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk. The more<br />

calibrated the processes are, the less the idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk <strong>and</strong> costs of borrowing from a<br />

bank become. Reducti<strong>on</strong>s in the liability of <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>s imply that the financial<br />

leverage ratio for them improves <strong>and</strong> that they can borrow more m<strong>on</strong>ey at lower rates. This reducti<strong>on</strong><br />

occurs because risk determines the cost of capital for an organizati<strong>on</strong> (Srivastava et al., 1998 ). A<br />

<strong>firm</strong>’s reputati<strong>on</strong> is also dependent up<strong>on</strong> their alliances <strong>and</strong> strategic partners. This dependence<br />

becomes visible by market reacti<strong>on</strong>s to <strong>firm</strong> mergers <strong>and</strong> acquisiti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> alliance announcements. For<br />

instance, the Porsche <strong>and</strong> Volkswagen merger was motivated by Porsche’s attempt to secure its<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> from a takeover by rivals (Bost<strong>on</strong>, 2009). This move elicited a positive reacti<strong>on</strong> from the<br />

market, which viewed this maneuver as a merger with a positively reputed <strong>supplier</strong>. Therefore,<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships with <strong>supplier</strong>s who have a good market reputati<strong>on</strong> lead to an increase in <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. In<br />

turn, this increase causes a decrease in the cost of capital as the <strong>firm</strong> exhibits a greater ability to pay<br />

38


ack loans <strong>and</strong> the forced sale <strong>value</strong> of the <strong>firm</strong> increases in the eyes of the lenders. From another<br />

customer’s perspective, this also holds true. When customers do borrow from financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s, the<br />

better their own reputati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the lower the cost of capital is for them. If the debt is secured by<br />

issuing corporate b<strong>on</strong>ds then less risky <strong>firm</strong>s pay a lower rate of interest to their debtors since they are<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidered a more secure investment (Rego, Billet, & Morgan 2009). Hence, a financial benefit of<br />

having a lower idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk drives down the cost of capital.<br />

Askari Commercial Bank Limited’s (ACBL) lending practices exemplify the benefits of having<br />

a positive market reputati<strong>on</strong>. Prior to giving loans at the corporate level, banking officers are required<br />

to check both hard <strong>and</strong> soft indicators. Soft indicators include an evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>firm</strong>’s strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s. If key <strong>supplier</strong>s have positive relati<strong>on</strong>al assets <strong>and</strong> a good working relati<strong>on</strong>ship with the<br />

customer, a customer’s costs of borrowing go down.<br />

In an effort to generate lower <strong>buyer</strong> idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s must take<br />

<strong>on</strong> greater risk. In other words, increases in strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness are accompanied by<br />

increases in business risk for the <strong>supplier</strong> (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990). Why should a strategic <strong>supplier</strong><br />

make an effort to reduce <strong>buyer</strong>’s IdRR? This reducti<strong>on</strong> is justified because lowering a <strong>buyer</strong>’s risk<br />

gives rise to positive <strong>buyer</strong> evaluati<strong>on</strong>s of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong>. This increase in evaluati<strong>on</strong> is important<br />

for the <strong>supplier</strong> because intangible n<strong>on</strong>-financial <strong>and</strong> financial benefits keep the <strong>buyer</strong> loyal to the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> (Nary<strong>and</strong>as, 2005). Br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is measured by how much the customer <strong>value</strong>s the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

br<strong>and</strong> or, in other words, customer-based br<strong>and</strong> equity. It follows that <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong>s which offer<br />

greater tangible <strong>and</strong> intangible <strong>value</strong> will be more highly <strong>value</strong>d than those who do not. One aspect of<br />

acquiring positive customer br<strong>and</strong> evaluati<strong>on</strong> is by idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk reducti<strong>on</strong>. Such a<br />

reducti<strong>on</strong> can be achieved through providing customers with reliable, unique, rare, <strong>and</strong> inimitable<br />

skills <strong>and</strong> networks (Srivastava et al., 1998) or, in other words, through unique resources. In additi<strong>on</strong>,<br />

br<strong>and</strong>s reduce a customer’s risk by the quality security that they provide when purchasing or using a<br />

br<strong>and</strong>ed product (McQuist<strong>on</strong>, 2004). Moreover, the impact of the br<strong>and</strong> is not limited to the customers<br />

al<strong>on</strong>e, but can also be transmitted to the financial marketplace to generate <strong>value</strong> for shareholders via<br />

quality informati<strong>on</strong> signals (Aaker & Jacobs<strong>on</strong>, 1994). Furthermore, <strong>buyer</strong>s in the general marketplace<br />

search for <strong>supplier</strong>s according to their reputati<strong>on</strong> (Saxt<strong>on</strong>, 1997). For marketing managers, purchasing<br />

managers <strong>and</strong> company executives are under pressure to justify their marketing expenditures. A<br />

reducti<strong>on</strong> in IdRR provides them a metric to justify such expenditures or investments. Strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s who are resp<strong>on</strong>sive will have a positive marketplace reputati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> will positively influence<br />

the financial market’s evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>buyer</strong>’s marketing expenditure <strong>on</strong> their strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<br />

In turn, this positive financial market evaluati<strong>on</strong> will lead to customers further positively assessing <strong>and</strong><br />

valuing their strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s. The greater the reliance of the <strong>buyer</strong>, the more important the <strong>supplier</strong><br />

becomes <strong>and</strong> the greater their br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Therefore:<br />

H4: The lower the IdRR, the higher the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

Strategic Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value <strong>and</strong> Buyer Firm Value. Different individuals will decipher a<br />

meaning differently depending <strong>on</strong> the associati<strong>on</strong>s that they have in their minds. The two kinds of<br />

br<strong>and</strong> associati<strong>on</strong>s are pertinent to our current study: symbolic <strong>and</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>al associati<strong>on</strong>s. Functi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

associati<strong>on</strong>s are based <strong>on</strong> the intrinsic benefits of the product (Keller, 1993). Functi<strong>on</strong>al benefits are<br />

involved in meeting a customer’s problem avoidance c<strong>on</strong>cerns (Keller, 1993). Symbolic benefits refer<br />

to ‘badge’ associati<strong>on</strong>s that provide the organizati<strong>on</strong> with some extrinsic benefit (Keller, 1993). These<br />

benefits are typically used to signal some informati<strong>on</strong> to the outside world, such as financial markets.<br />

39


They might also include the ease with which a marketing department could justify marketing<br />

expenditures <strong>on</strong> a strategic <strong>supplier</strong> because of their str<strong>on</strong>g marketplace reputati<strong>on</strong>, prior performance<br />

in areas such as customer profit improvement, or help them to avoid risk through the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

superior knowledge networks (Hague & Jacks<strong>on</strong>, 1994). Hence, being associated with a good <strong>supplier</strong><br />

br<strong>and</strong> has both tangible <strong>and</strong> intangible benefits for the <strong>buyer</strong>. Furthermore, in B2B markets, <strong>buyer</strong>s are<br />

likely to choose well-known br<strong>and</strong>s if either <strong>on</strong>e of the following c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s exists: (a) when product<br />

failure has serious repercussi<strong>on</strong>s for the enterprise, (b) the product requires substantial service support,<br />

or (c) the product is complex (Hutt<strong>on</strong>, 1997). The first of the three c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s always exists in the case<br />

of strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s. Furthermore, in B2B markets, psychological factors such as the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong><br />

reputati<strong>on</strong> may matter more than the physical product attributes (Shaw, Giglierano, & Kallis, 1991).<br />

Hence, well-known br<strong>and</strong>s would be a logical choice for B2B purchase managers. From the above<br />

evidence, we can c<strong>on</strong>clude that a <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> strength through the mechanism of functi<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong><br />

symbolic br<strong>and</strong> associati<strong>on</strong>s positively influences the <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Therefore:<br />

H5: The higher the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> (percepti<strong>on</strong>s) the greater will be the <strong>buyer</strong>’s<br />

<strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

2.4 Methodology<br />

2.4.1 Questi<strong>on</strong>naire Design <strong>and</strong> Scale Development<br />

Churchill (1979) suggests that items for a survey should be generated by using literature surveys,<br />

experience surveys, critical incidents, focus groups, <strong>and</strong> insight-stimulating examples. We used a<br />

literature survey <strong>and</strong> an experience survey because literature was readily available via the EBSCO<br />

database <strong>and</strong> key academics who have taught purchasing managers <strong>and</strong> were easily accessible.<br />

Furthermore, we needed unique insights that would give us a perspective <strong>on</strong> the idiosyncratic working<br />

of organizati<strong>on</strong>s. Such insights provide researchers with a deeper underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the phenomen<strong>on</strong><br />

they are investigating. Therefore, focus groups were ruled out because they generate breadth but not<br />

depth of insights (Barabba & Zaltman, 1991), <strong>and</strong> insight-stimulating examples were used, albeit<br />

indirectly, when interviewees narrated some examples. For the literature review, we analyzed the<br />

relevant papers <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong>, market-based assets theory, <strong>and</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> literature.<br />

Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or Market Orientati<strong>on</strong>. The first step of developing measures for<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> is domain specificati<strong>on</strong>. This has been addressed in the definiti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> page 22,<br />

where resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is identified as the most important comp<strong>on</strong>ent of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. The main<br />

criteri<strong>on</strong> for proposing a new definiti<strong>on</strong> in marketing is if existing definiti<strong>on</strong>s do not suffice for an<br />

investigati<strong>on</strong> (Churchill, 1979). Following that dictum, we do not add any unnecessary new<br />

definiti<strong>on</strong>s. In this chapter, we do, however, adapt the market orientati<strong>on</strong> scale (MARKOR)<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structed by Kohli, Jaworski, <strong>and</strong> Kumar (1993). In the remainder of this secti<strong>on</strong>, we first discuss<br />

whether market orientati<strong>on</strong> should be measured by <strong>on</strong>e general factor or three sub-comp<strong>on</strong>ent factors.<br />

Sec<strong>on</strong>d, we discuss the reas<strong>on</strong>s why we left out some questi<strong>on</strong>s of the MARKOR scale <strong>and</strong> the<br />

motives of why we adapted the remaining items of the scale.<br />

As our c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizati<strong>on</strong> of market orientati<strong>on</strong> is based up<strong>on</strong> the Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990)<br />

paper, we selected the MARKOR scale that Kohli et al. (1993) developed to measure the c<strong>on</strong>cept of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) c<strong>on</strong>ceptualized market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a process that<br />

included three distinct comp<strong>on</strong>ents. These comp<strong>on</strong>ent factors of market orientati<strong>on</strong> lack discriminant<br />

validity when measured by MARKOR, <strong>and</strong> that means that the c<strong>on</strong>structs are not truly distinct from<br />

<strong>on</strong>e another (Kohli et al., 1993). Furthermore, the lack of discriminant validity increases when<br />

40


esp<strong>on</strong>dents from functi<strong>on</strong>s besides marketing are asked. As the comp<strong>on</strong>ents of the MARKOR scales<br />

lack discriminant validity, it is an issue of c<strong>on</strong>cern as market orientati<strong>on</strong> involves resp<strong>on</strong>ding to the<br />

customer’s needs by generating, disseminating, <strong>and</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>ding to informati<strong>on</strong> throughout the<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> not specifically <strong>on</strong>ly within the marketing department. Hence, when offering their<br />

assessments of market orientati<strong>on</strong> regardless of their functi<strong>on</strong>al duties, resp<strong>on</strong>dents should be able to<br />

distinguish between the comp<strong>on</strong>ents of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. If they cannot distinguish between the<br />

comp<strong>on</strong>ents of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, a single general market orientati<strong>on</strong> factor should be used. The<br />

results presented by Kohli et al. (1993) improved when the items of the MARKOR scales <strong>and</strong> latent<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structs were reduced. The best results they presented were with <strong>on</strong>e general latent factor of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> two latent comp<strong>on</strong>ent factors of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. However, even the best results<br />

presented by Kohli et al. (1993) were not within the acceptable goodness of fit statistics range.<br />

Therefore, further item reducti<strong>on</strong> would be necessary to improve the goodness of fit statistics when we<br />

use their scale.<br />

The first issue that we had to address was whether to adopt a comp<strong>on</strong>ent-wise approach or a<br />

general factor approach of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. We informally interviewed fellow academics <strong>and</strong> MBA<br />

students with work experience about what they viewed as the most important comp<strong>on</strong>ent of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> from the customer’s perspective, <strong>and</strong> it was agreed that the resp<strong>on</strong>se comp<strong>on</strong>ent was the<br />

most important. In additi<strong>on</strong>, some of the academics <strong>and</strong> students were of the opini<strong>on</strong> that the<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness factor was representative of the general market orientati<strong>on</strong> factor from the customer’s<br />

perspective, as the customer is not involved in the <strong>supplier</strong>’s internal operati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> every marketoriented<br />

acti<strong>on</strong> is a resp<strong>on</strong>se from the customer’s perspective. In additi<strong>on</strong> to previously menti<strong>on</strong>ed<br />

reas<strong>on</strong>s for focusing <strong>on</strong> the customer, informal c<strong>on</strong>versati<strong>on</strong>s with academics motivated us, in part, to<br />

focus <strong>on</strong> the customer, <strong>and</strong> to some extent we were motivated by the call of Kohli et al. (1993) to<br />

“assess the soundness of the measures” of the MARKOR scale (pg. 473).<br />

In the next stage, we modified the MARKOR scale items. Some of the 32 items of scale were<br />

modified to reflect the customer’s perspective. We did this by first selecting those questi<strong>on</strong>s about<br />

which we suspected the customer would have knowledge. This resulted in 20 items being selected.<br />

Next, we reworded the questi<strong>on</strong>s in order to adapt them to the customer’s perspective of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or market orientati<strong>on</strong>. This was d<strong>on</strong>e in order to meet Churchill’s (1979) requirements<br />

that items are able to “c<strong>on</strong>vey different shades of meaning” (p. 68). Furthermore, slightly changing the<br />

original scale allows us to create better measures, as Churchill (1979) states, “By incorporating<br />

slightly different nuances of meaning in statements in the item pool, the researcher provides a better<br />

foundati<strong>on</strong> for the eventual measure.” (p. 68).<br />

Table 2.2 provides the original scale of items <strong>and</strong> our modificati<strong>on</strong>s to them. We eliminated the<br />

items <strong>on</strong> which we c<strong>on</strong>cluded that customers could not provide an accurate assessment. Therefore, we<br />

did not include the following MARKOR questi<strong>on</strong>s in our questi<strong>on</strong>naire: 4, 8, 10, 12, 13, 16, 17, 18,<br />

20, 24, 27, <strong>and</strong> 30. Questi<strong>on</strong> 4 states that, “We are slow to detect changes in our customers’ product<br />

preferences.” It was excluded because we came to the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> that no customer could decide the<br />

accurate level of research that a <strong>supplier</strong> c<strong>on</strong>ducted in house. Many internal <strong>supplier</strong> processes are kept<br />

secret <strong>and</strong>, therefore, the customer would not have the required knowledge to answer questi<strong>on</strong> 4.<br />

Similarly, questi<strong>on</strong> 8 <strong>on</strong> the MARKOR scale is, “In our business unit, intelligence <strong>on</strong> our competitors<br />

is generated independently by several departments;” customers would not know the inner working of<br />

several departments. In additi<strong>on</strong>, Questi<strong>on</strong>s 8 <strong>and</strong> 10 of the MARKOR scale were excluded because<br />

41


they ask about intimate <strong>supplier</strong> informati<strong>on</strong> of which a customer would not be aware. Although some<br />

colleagues argued that, in a close <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship, the <strong>buyer</strong> would know about the<br />

quality of the <strong>supplier</strong>s’ processes, but our colleagues agreed that the exact inner workings of the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s organizati<strong>on</strong>s may not be that transparent. Questi<strong>on</strong>s 12 <strong>and</strong> 13 <strong>on</strong> the MARKOR scale are<br />

about interdepartmental meetings. These questi<strong>on</strong>s are meant for the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong> rather than the<br />

customer so, therefore, we excluded them. Questi<strong>on</strong>s 16, 17, <strong>and</strong> 18 <strong>on</strong> the MARKOR scale relate to<br />

the disseminati<strong>on</strong> of informati<strong>on</strong> within the <strong>supplier</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong>. We c<strong>on</strong>cluded that the customer is not in a<br />

positi<strong>on</strong> to be able to reliably resp<strong>on</strong>d to informati<strong>on</strong> about <strong>supplier</strong> informati<strong>on</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong> as the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> internal informati<strong>on</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong> process does not involve any interacti<strong>on</strong> with the<br />

customer. Questi<strong>on</strong> 20 <strong>on</strong> the MARKOR scale was that the principles of market segmentati<strong>on</strong> guided<br />

the new product development, but it is a questi<strong>on</strong> meant for the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong> rather than the customer<br />

<strong>firm</strong> because <strong>on</strong>ly a <strong>supplier</strong> employee would be able to reas<strong>on</strong>ably answer this questi<strong>on</strong>. Questi<strong>on</strong> 24<br />

<strong>on</strong> the MARKOR scale is about the frequency of <strong>supplier</strong> cross-functi<strong>on</strong>al department meetings, a<br />

process of which the customer would not be aware. Likewise, questi<strong>on</strong> 27 again addresses internal<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> coordinati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> we do not believe that the customer will have knowledge of such a process.<br />

Finally, questi<strong>on</strong> 30 was c<strong>on</strong>sidered to be similar to questi<strong>on</strong> 26 <strong>on</strong> the MARKOR scale, so we omitted<br />

it in order to avoid redundancy.<br />

Table 2.2 provides the questi<strong>on</strong>s that were revised <strong>on</strong> the original MARKOR scales. The<br />

revised questi<strong>on</strong>s include 1, 2, 3, 5, 6, 7, 9, 11, 14, 15, 19, 21, 22, 23, 25, 26, 28, 29, 31, <strong>and</strong> 32. The<br />

questi<strong>on</strong>s were reworded to measure the customer’s assessment of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. In<br />

order to reword these questi<strong>on</strong>s, we placed the focus <strong>on</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong>, whereas the original MARKOR<br />

scale was a self-assessment measure for the customer. For example, questi<strong>on</strong> 3 of the MARKOR scale<br />

states that “In this business unit we do a lot of in house market research.” We modified questi<strong>on</strong> 3 to<br />

focus <strong>on</strong> the customers’ assessment as follows, “The <strong>supplier</strong> seems to have good internal market<br />

intelligence capabilities.” Similarly, questi<strong>on</strong> 15 stated that, ”When something important happens to a<br />

major market customer, the whole business unit knows about it within a short period.” We modified<br />

questi<strong>on</strong> 15 to focus <strong>on</strong> the customer’s assessment as follows, ”We just need to communicate our<br />

needs to <strong>on</strong>e of the various functi<strong>on</strong>al departments (e.g., marketing, manufacturing, operati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

finance) <strong>and</strong> every<strong>on</strong>e c<strong>on</strong>cerned (cross functi<strong>on</strong>ally) within the <strong>supplier</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> will immediately<br />

updated <strong>on</strong> our new situati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

42


Table 2.2<br />

Modified Items of the MARKOR Scale<br />

Original Item Need <strong>and</strong> Reas<strong>on</strong> for change of item Revised Item<br />

1.In this business unit, we<br />

meet with customers at least <strong>on</strong>ce<br />

a year to find out what<br />

products or services they will<br />

need in the future.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> meets with us<br />

at least <strong>on</strong>ce a year to find<br />

out what products <strong>and</strong><br />

services we will need in the future.<br />

2. Individuals from our<br />

manufacturing department<br />

interact directly with customers to<br />

learn how to better serve them.<br />

3. In this business unit, we do a<br />

lot of in house market research.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

Individuals from the <strong>supplier</strong>s’<br />

manufacturing department interact<br />

directly with us to inquire as to how<br />

they can improve their services or<br />

products.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> seems to have good<br />

internal market intelligence generati<strong>on</strong><br />

capabilities.<br />

4. We are slow to detect changes in our customers’ product preferences.<br />

5. We poll end users at least The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

<strong>on</strong>ce a year to assess the<br />

reworded to include the<br />

quality of our products <strong>and</strong> customer’s perspective<br />

services.<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> regularly c<strong>on</strong>tacts us to<br />

assess the quality of their products <strong>and</strong><br />

services.<br />

6. We often talk with or survey<br />

those who can influence<br />

our end users’ purchases<br />

(e.g., retailers <strong>and</strong> distributors).<br />

7. We collect industry informati<strong>on</strong><br />

through an informal means.<br />

8. In our business unit, intelligence<br />

<strong>on</strong> our competitors is<br />

independently generated by several<br />

departments.<br />

9. We are slow to detect<br />

changes in our industry.(R)<br />

10. We periodically review<br />

changes in business envir<strong>on</strong>ment.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

This <strong>supplier</strong> has high quality<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> regarding their channel<br />

partners (e.g., retailers, distributors <strong>and</strong><br />

us).<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> often interacts with us in<br />

informal meetings (e.g., lunch with our<br />

managers) to collect informati<strong>on</strong> about<br />

our business.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> is slow to detect<br />

fundamental shifts in our industry (e.g.,<br />

competiti<strong>on</strong>, technology, regulati<strong>on</strong>).<br />

43


Table 2.2<br />

Modified Items of the MARKOR Scale (C<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Original Item<br />

Need <strong>and</strong> Reas<strong>on</strong> for<br />

change of item<br />

Revised Item<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

11. A lot of informal “hall talk”<br />

in this business c<strong>on</strong>cerns our<br />

competitors’ tactics or strategy.<br />

12. We have interdepartmental<br />

meetings at least <strong>on</strong>ce a quarter to<br />

discuss market trends <strong>and</strong><br />

developments.<br />

13. Marketing pers<strong>on</strong>nel in<br />

our business unit spend more<br />

time discussing customers’ future<br />

needs with other functi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

departments.<br />

A lot of the informal c<strong>on</strong>versati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

with our <strong>supplier</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cern the<br />

market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> our<br />

competitors’ strategies.<br />

14. Our business unit periodically<br />

circulates documents<br />

(e.g. reports <strong>and</strong> newsletters) that<br />

provide informati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> our customers.<br />

15. When something important<br />

happens to a major market<br />

customer, the whole business<br />

unit knows about it within a<br />

short period of time.<br />

16. Data <strong>on</strong> customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

are disseminated at all levels in<br />

this business unit <strong>on</strong> a regular<br />

basis.<br />

17. There is a minimum<br />

communicati<strong>on</strong> between<br />

marketing <strong>and</strong> manufacturing<br />

departments c<strong>on</strong>cerning market<br />

developments. (R)<br />

18. When <strong>on</strong>e department finds out<br />

something important about<br />

Competitors, it is slow to alert other<br />

departments. (R)<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> provides us with<br />

periodic market intelligence<br />

(e.g. newsletters <strong>and</strong> reports) with<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tent of interest to many<br />

cross-functi<strong>on</strong>al departments<br />

within our <strong>firm</strong>.<br />

We simply need to communicate our<br />

needs to <strong>on</strong>e of the various functi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

departments (e.g., marketing,<br />

manufacturing, operati<strong>on</strong>s, finance)<br />

<strong>and</strong> every<strong>on</strong>e c<strong>on</strong>cerned (cross<br />

functi<strong>on</strong>ally) within the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

<strong>firm</strong> will be immediately updated <strong>on</strong><br />

our new situati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

44


Table 2.2<br />

Modified Items of the MARKOR Scale (C<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Original Item<br />

Need <strong>and</strong> Reas<strong>on</strong> for<br />

change of item<br />

Revised Item<br />

19. It takes us forever to decide how to<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>d to our competitor's price<br />

changes. (R)<br />

20.Principles of market segmentati<strong>on</strong><br />

drive new product development efforts<br />

in this business unit.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> takes a very<br />

l<strong>on</strong>g time to resp<strong>on</strong>d to<br />

changes in their competitors’<br />

pricing strategies.<br />

21. For <strong>on</strong>e reas<strong>on</strong> or another, we tend<br />

to ignore changes in our customer's<br />

product or service needs. (R)<br />

22. We periodically review our product<br />

development efforts to ensure that they<br />

are in line with what customers want.<br />

23. Our business plans are driven more<br />

by technological advances than by<br />

market research. (R)<br />

24. Several departments get<br />

together periodically to<br />

plan a resp<strong>on</strong>se to<br />

changes occurring in our<br />

business envir<strong>on</strong>ment.<br />

25. The product lines we sell depend<br />

more <strong>on</strong> internal politics than real<br />

market needs. (R)<br />

26. If a major competitor were to launch<br />

an intensive campaign targeted at our<br />

customers, we would immediately<br />

implement a resp<strong>on</strong>se.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

For <strong>on</strong>e reas<strong>on</strong> or another, the <strong>supplier</strong><br />

tends to ignore changes in your<br />

product or service needs.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> seems to be driven<br />

by the customers (your) perspective in<br />

new product development efforts.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong>'s business plans seem to<br />

be driven more by technological<br />

advances than by market research.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong>'s resp<strong>on</strong>se to us is often<br />

not aligned with our needs because of<br />

internal <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong> politics.<br />

If the <strong>supplier</strong>'s major competitor<br />

were to launch an intensive campaign<br />

targeted at you, then the <strong>supplier</strong><br />

would normally implement a counter<br />

campaign directed towards you.<br />

45


Table 2.2<br />

Modified Items of the MARKOR Scale (C<strong>on</strong>tinued)<br />

Original Item<br />

Need <strong>and</strong> Reas<strong>on</strong> for<br />

Revised Item<br />

change of item<br />

27. The activities of the different<br />

departments in this business unit are<br />

well coordinated.*<br />

28. Customer complaints fall <strong>on</strong><br />

deaf ears in this business unit. (R)*<br />

29. Even if we came up with a<br />

great marketing plan, we probably<br />

would not be able to implement<br />

it in a timely fashi<strong>on</strong>. (R)*<br />

30. We are quick to resp<strong>on</strong>d to<br />

significant changes in our<br />

competitors' pricing structures. *<br />

31. When we find out that<br />

customers are unhappy with the<br />

quality of our service, we<br />

immediately take corrective<br />

acti<strong>on</strong>.*<br />

32. When we find that customers<br />

would like us to modify a product<br />

or service, the departments<br />

involved make c<strong>on</strong>certed efforts<br />

to do so.*<br />

(R) Reverse worded scales.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customer’s perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customers’ perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customers perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The questi<strong>on</strong> needed to be<br />

reworded to include the<br />

customers’ perspective<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong>s do not heed your<br />

complaints.<br />

The <strong>supplier</strong> sometimes has excellent<br />

marketing plans, but they seem to be<br />

implemented too slowly or too late.<br />

If the <strong>supplier</strong> were to find out that<br />

you are unhappy with the quality of<br />

their service, they would immediately<br />

take corrective acti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

If the <strong>supplier</strong>s find out that you would<br />

like them to modify a product or<br />

service, they would make c<strong>on</strong>certed<br />

efforts to do so.<br />

We c<strong>on</strong>ducted an exploratory factor analysis of the modified market orientati<strong>on</strong> scales<br />

that we use in this study <strong>and</strong> the results are shown in Table 2.3. In SPSS 17, we selected an<br />

factor analysis with VARIMAX rotati<strong>on</strong>. We exclude the factor analysis coefficient <strong>value</strong>s that<br />

were less than 0.5. The resulting soluti<strong>on</strong> gave us two factors for the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> scale. All of the items that were reverse worded <strong>and</strong> coded <strong>on</strong> the original<br />

MARKOR scale were <strong>on</strong>e factor, <strong>and</strong> we called this factor the n<strong>on</strong>-resp<strong>on</strong>siveness comp<strong>on</strong>ent<br />

since the questi<strong>on</strong>s were measuring whether there was a lack of resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. The other factor<br />

measured the degree of resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> we called this the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness factor. In<br />

the current research, we <strong>on</strong>ly use the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness factor scale since it corresp<strong>on</strong>ds<br />

with our current research needs. Moreover, the KMO test <strong>value</strong> is 0.858 that means that the data<br />

is suitable for a factor analysis <strong>and</strong> more than the minimum level of 0.5. In additi<strong>on</strong>, the <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness scale also qualifies <strong>on</strong> the Bartlett’s test of sphericity with a significant result at p<br />

46


IdRR: We will briefly address the IdRR definiti<strong>on</strong> again to make the domain specificati<strong>on</strong><br />

unequivocal. IdRR is the specific risk that arises as a c<strong>on</strong>sequence of the <strong>supplier</strong>/<strong>buyer</strong> business<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship. A business relati<strong>on</strong>ship involves the <strong>value</strong> created by the marketing process as well as all<br />

of the core business processes which create customer <strong>value</strong> (Srivastava, Shervani, & Fahey, 1999). To<br />

be specific, there are three core processes: new product development process (NPD), supply chain<br />

management process (SCM), <strong>and</strong> customer relati<strong>on</strong>ship management (CRM), which is also referred to<br />

as marketing process. Hence, IdRR incorporates the idiosyncratic risk that is generated by all three<br />

aforementi<strong>on</strong>ed core business processes, while trying to generate <strong>value</strong> in a <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

There is a c<strong>on</strong>vergence of opini<strong>on</strong> in the marketing literature about the three core business<br />

processes as primary creators of <strong>value</strong> for a business enterprise. For instance, Porter (1985) terms them<br />

primary activities in the <strong>value</strong> chain. Three of the primary activities of Porter’s <strong>value</strong> chain, namely<br />

inbound logistics, operati<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> outbound logistics, corresp<strong>on</strong>d with the SCM <strong>and</strong> NPD business<br />

processes, whereas sales, marketing <strong>and</strong> service corresp<strong>on</strong>d with CRM. Similarly, Lehmann <strong>and</strong> Jocz<br />

(1997) agree that these three core business activities, in additi<strong>on</strong> to market orientati<strong>on</strong>, are the focus of<br />

marketing or <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> for the customer. In summati<strong>on</strong>, based <strong>on</strong> the above literature synthesis,<br />

the three core business activities involved in customer <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> are NPD, SCM, <strong>and</strong> CRM.<br />

Therefore, we also accept them as the core business activities in this dissertati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The next step is to determine whether IdRR is composed of three sub-comp<strong>on</strong>ents or <strong>on</strong>e<br />

general factor that measures idiosyncratic risk because of NPD, SCM, <strong>and</strong> CRM. Srivastava et al.<br />

(1999) suggest that the three core business processes are “not independent” of each other while<br />

creating <strong>value</strong> for the customer (p. 169). Moreover, all of the core business processes must be<br />

interdependent up<strong>on</strong> each other in order to create customer <strong>value</strong> (Srivastava et al., 1999). Hence, the<br />

three core business processes create <strong>value</strong> by a shared mutual process. Furthermore, the mutual<br />

process of <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> involves a mutually shared idiosyncratic risk that threatens <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> by<br />

the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Therefore, we measure IdRR by <strong>on</strong>e comm<strong>on</strong> latent factor for the<br />

risk that results from all three core business processes. In additi<strong>on</strong>, informal c<strong>on</strong>versati<strong>on</strong>s with some<br />

customers revealed a lack of face validity for three separate sub-comp<strong>on</strong>ent IdRR processes, but face<br />

validity was present for a single general IdRR factor. Hence, in this research, we use a single latent<br />

factor to measure IdRR.<br />

Subsequently, we generate scale items that comprise the domain of IdRR. Based <strong>on</strong> a literature<br />

review, we selected comp<strong>on</strong>ents of the three core business processes to measure IdRR. From the<br />

literature review, we selected two studies with which to create a measure of IdRR, namely Day (1994)<br />

<strong>and</strong> Srivastava et al. (1999). We decided to use the Srivastava et al. (1999) study for item generati<strong>on</strong><br />

because it explicitly focused <strong>on</strong> the linkage of <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> by business processes <strong>and</strong> the resulting<br />

risk. Our next step was to create the items that measured IdRR <strong>and</strong> were caused by the CRM, SCM,<br />

<strong>and</strong> NPD <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> processes. The SCM processes that measure IdRR are c<strong>on</strong>trolling<br />

manufacturing costs, inventory management, resoluti<strong>on</strong> of problems that arise in the relati<strong>on</strong>ship,<br />

simplifying processes <strong>and</strong> reducing uncertainty by investments. Similarly, the NPD processes that<br />

measure IdRR <strong>supplier</strong> investments in the <strong>buyer</strong>s’ NPD capabilities, <strong>and</strong> the sharing of market<br />

intelligence about markets where the <strong>buyer</strong>s operate. The CRM processes that involve IdRR are the<br />

service quality, resolving relati<strong>on</strong>al problems caused by the <strong>supplier</strong>, investment in technology for<br />

efficiency, channel <strong>and</strong> distributi<strong>on</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong>s, cooperati<strong>on</strong> in the reducti<strong>on</strong> of sales costs, sharing of<br />

48


market intelligence, offering flexible payment schedules, power in the relati<strong>on</strong>ships, <strong>and</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

stability. Table 2.4 presents the aforementi<strong>on</strong>ed items that are used in measuring IdRR.<br />

Table 2.4<br />

Items Measuring IdRR<br />

IdRR Items<br />

Business process<br />

1.To what extent does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you reduce your factory or SCM<br />

manufacturing costs?<br />

2.To what extent does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you increase your<br />

CRM<br />

product or service quality?<br />

3.In the past, has your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> been willing to invest in technology that SCM <strong>and</strong> CRM<br />

would improve your supply chain cost efficiency?<br />

4.In the past, has your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> been willing to invest in technology that NPD<br />

would improve your research <strong>and</strong> development <strong>and</strong> engineering cost efficiency?<br />

5.To what extent does you strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your channel or distributi<strong>on</strong> CRM<br />

costs?<br />

6.Does the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you to reduce your sales cost?<br />

CRM<br />

7.Does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> also provide you with intelligence <strong>on</strong> the markets in<br />

which you operate?<br />

8. To what extent does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your inventory management? SCM<br />

9.Does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> offer you flexible payment schedules?<br />

CRM<br />

10.To what extent does your <strong>supplier</strong> help you manage your inventory?<br />

11.To what degree does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your cash c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> cycle?<br />

12.A definiti<strong>on</strong>al clarificati<strong>on</strong>: The cash c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> cycle is the time durati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

which a <strong>firm</strong> is able to c<strong>on</strong>vert its resources into cash. It is actually the total time<br />

period required to first c<strong>on</strong>vert resources into inventories, then inventories into<br />

finished goods, then goods into sales, <strong>and</strong> then sales into cash.<br />

NPD <strong>and</strong><br />

CRM<br />

General Questi<strong>on</strong><br />

13.To what extent have your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s tried to simplify your<br />

SCM<br />

supply chain processes?<br />

14.To what extent do those strategic investments give you power in negotiati<strong>on</strong>s over y SCM <strong>and</strong> CRM<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s?<br />

15.To what degree do those specific investments make it difficult for the strategic SCM <strong>and</strong> CRM<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> to end their relati<strong>on</strong>ship with you?<br />

Following the same procedure as was applied to the factor analysis of <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, we factor-analyzed the IdRR scale. Table 2.5 presents the factor analysis results<br />

with a Varimax rotati<strong>on</strong> since factor 2 c<strong>on</strong>sists of less than three items, which is less than the<br />

minimum requirement for a reliable scale (Hair et al., 2006). Therefore, we <strong>on</strong>ly use factor 1 to<br />

measure IdRR in our analysis <strong>and</strong> drop out item 14 in Table 2.5.<br />

49


Table 2.5<br />

Rotated IdRR Comp<strong>on</strong>ent Matrix<br />

IdRR Items 1 2<br />

1.To what extent does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you reduce your factory .731<br />

or manufacturing costs?<br />

2.In the past has your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> been willing to invest in technology that<br />

would improve your supply chain cost efficiency?<br />

.645<br />

3.In the past has your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> been willing to invest in technology that<br />

would improve your research <strong>and</strong> development <strong>and</strong> engineering cost efficiency?<br />

.646<br />

4.To what extent does you strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your channel or<br />

distributi<strong>on</strong> costs?<br />

.627<br />

5.Does the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you in reducing your sales cost? .563<br />

6.Does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> also provide you with intelligence <strong>on</strong> the markets<br />

in which you operate?<br />

.736<br />

7.To what extent does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your inventory<br />

management?<br />

.777<br />

8.Does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> offer you flexible payment schedules? .607<br />

9.To what extent does your <strong>supplier</strong> help you manage your inventory? .723<br />

10.To what degree does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your cash c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong><br />

cycle? A definiti<strong>on</strong>al clarificati<strong>on</strong>: The cash c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> cycle is the time<br />

durati<strong>on</strong> in which a <strong>firm</strong> is able to c<strong>on</strong>vert its resources into cash. It is actually<br />

.684<br />

the total time period.<br />

11.To what extent does using your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your ability to<br />

minimize the time needed for your <strong>firm</strong> to provide soluti<strong>on</strong>s for your customers?<br />

.519<br />

12.To what extent have your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s tried to simplify your supply<br />

chain processes?<br />

.732<br />

13.To what extent do your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s correctly invoice your company? .686<br />

14.To what degree do those specific investments make it difficult for the<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong> to end their relati<strong>on</strong>ship with you?<br />

.836<br />

15.To what extent does the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you increase your products or<br />

service quality?<br />

.695<br />

Extracti<strong>on</strong> Method: Principal Comp<strong>on</strong>ent Analysis. KMO=0.910, Chi-Suaqre=1056, p


We c<strong>on</strong>sidered several scales before arriving at a c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong> about which scale was best <strong>and</strong><br />

whether we should use <strong>on</strong>e unified or two separate c<strong>on</strong>structs to measure ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. We first c<strong>on</strong>sidered the scale developed by Rukert <strong>and</strong> Churchill (1984), which they used<br />

to measure satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the following dimensi<strong>on</strong>s: product, financial, assistance, <strong>and</strong> social<br />

interacti<strong>on</strong>. The product dimensi<strong>on</strong> assesses the dem<strong>and</strong>, quality, <strong>and</strong> awareness of a <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

offering (Rukert & Churchill, 1984). The financial dimensi<strong>on</strong> evaluates the financial attractiveness of<br />

the <strong>supplier</strong>’s offering (Rukert & Churchill, 1984). The assistance dimensi<strong>on</strong> evaluates how much<br />

assistance the channel member or customer receives from the <strong>supplier</strong> in promoting their products<br />

(Rukert & Churchill, 1984), while the social interacti<strong>on</strong> dimensi<strong>on</strong> evaluates the interacti<strong>on</strong>s between<br />

the <strong>supplier</strong>’s sales representatives <strong>and</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong> (Rukert & Churchill, 1984). Moreover, Rukert <strong>and</strong><br />

Churchill (1984) measured satisfacti<strong>on</strong> through what they termed direct <strong>and</strong> indirect measurement,<br />

specifically they reworded the questi<strong>on</strong>s in the direct measurement scale to directly inquire about<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> from the customer <strong>and</strong> in the indirect scale to indirectly acquire satisfacti<strong>on</strong> informati<strong>on</strong><br />

from the customer. Only seven items <strong>on</strong> the indirect scale passed the 0.7 Chr<strong>on</strong>bach’s alpha threshold<br />

<strong>value</strong> (Hair et al., 2006). In effect, <strong>on</strong>ly the social interacti<strong>on</strong> dimensi<strong>on</strong> of the satisfacti<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>struct<br />

had reliable item measurements. Similarly, when Rukert <strong>and</strong> Churchill (1984) measured satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

directly, they <strong>on</strong>ly had two items that were reliable. Although Rukert <strong>and</strong> Churchill (1984) do present<br />

some scale results that have sufficient Chr<strong>on</strong>bach’s alpha <strong>value</strong>s, they doubt their own results when<br />

they state that “<strong>on</strong>e should not put much faith in an alpha computed <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly two or three items” (p.<br />

229). Hence, drawing from this analysis, we can c<strong>on</strong>clude that <strong>on</strong>ly a few items reliably measure<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> that they are not loading in enough quantity to warrant a separate dimensi<strong>on</strong><br />

measurement or a sec<strong>on</strong>dary factor analysis.<br />

Some scholars, such as Ganesan (1994), have used a single reliable c<strong>on</strong>struct for the<br />

measurement of channel member satisfacti<strong>on</strong> (Chr<strong>on</strong>bach’s alpha of 0.94). But Ganesan (1994)<br />

focuses <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong> the emoti<strong>on</strong>al or n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, whereas we have specified the domain to<br />

include both ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic evaluati<strong>on</strong>s by the customer. Therefore, this scale was ruled<br />

out for use in our research.<br />

The scale created by Dwyer <strong>and</strong> Gassenheimer (1992) measures ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic<br />

distributors or <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with their <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e latent variable. Moreover, the scale that<br />

they c<strong>on</strong>structed is reliable <strong>and</strong> covers the four dimensi<strong>on</strong>s given by Rukert <strong>and</strong> Churchill (1984).<br />

Therefore, we decided to use the scale specified by Dwyer <strong>and</strong> Gassenheimer (1992). We slightly<br />

modified the sentences to suit our study, as detailed in Table 2.6 <strong>and</strong> included an additi<strong>on</strong>al questi<strong>on</strong><br />

generated by ourselves, “what is your overall satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with this <strong>supplier</strong>?”<br />

51


Table 2.6<br />

List of Modified Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> Items<br />

Original Item<br />

Dwyer <strong>and</strong> Gassenheimer (1992)<br />

1.Profits generated from manufacturer's<br />

(A, B, C) product lines.<br />

Modified Items<br />

How satisfied are you with the profits<br />

generated from carrying the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

products lines, if any?<br />

2.Overall manner in which you were treated by the<br />

manufacturer's regi<strong>on</strong>al office or headquarters.<br />

3.Overall “sales support”/relati<strong>on</strong>ship with<br />

the manufacturer's local sales representative.<br />

4.New product market opportunities that the<br />

manufacturer provides you.<br />

How satisfied are you with the overall<br />

manner with which the strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s representatives (regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

or head office) treat you?<br />

How satisfied are you with the sales<br />

support provided by the manufacturer's<br />

local sales representative?<br />

How satisfied are you with the new<br />

product market opportunities the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> provides you?<br />

5.Sales growth potential from carrying manufacturer's produHow satisfied are you with the sales growth potential from<br />

lines.<br />

carrying the <strong>supplier</strong>’s products lines, if any?<br />

6.Fairness <strong>and</strong> h<strong>on</strong>esty of the<br />

manufacturer.<br />

7. Interest <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cern manufacturer has<br />

displayed in helping you to accomplish your<br />

goals <strong>and</strong> objectives.<br />

How satisfied are you with this<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s overall fairness <strong>and</strong> h<strong>on</strong>esty<br />

while dealing with you?<br />

How satisfied are you with the<br />

interest <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cern that this <strong>supplier</strong> has in<br />

helping you meet your objectives?<br />

We analyzed the satisfacti<strong>on</strong> scale by means of a principal comp<strong>on</strong>ent factor analysis.<br />

The factor analysis gave us <strong>on</strong>e factor, <strong>and</strong> therefore, SPSS 17 gave us the message that a<br />

Varimax rotati<strong>on</strong> was not possible with <strong>on</strong>e comp<strong>on</strong>ent. The scale is very good with a KMO of<br />

0.909 <strong>and</strong> qualifies <strong>on</strong> the Bartlett’s test of sphericity. The results are presented in Table 2.7.<br />

52


Table 2.7<br />

Comp<strong>on</strong>ent Matrix Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

Comp<strong>on</strong>ent<br />

1. What is your overall satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with this <strong>supplier</strong>? 0.730<br />

2.How satisfied are you with the new product market<br />

0.774<br />

opportunities that the <strong>supplier</strong> provides to you?<br />

3.How satisfied are you with this <strong>supplier</strong>’s overall<br />

0.708<br />

fairness <strong>and</strong> h<strong>on</strong>esty while dealing with you?<br />

4.How satisfied are you with the interest <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cern<br />

0.765<br />

that the <strong>supplier</strong> exhibited in helping you to meet your<br />

objectives?<br />

5.How satisfied are you with the profits generated from<br />

0.714<br />

carrying the <strong>supplier</strong>'s product lines, if any?<br />

6.How satisfied are you with the sales growth potential<br />

0.706<br />

from carrying the <strong>supplier</strong>'s product lines, if any?<br />

7.How satisfied are you with the overall manner with<br />

0.763<br />

which the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>'s representatives (regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

or head office) treat you?<br />

Extracti<strong>on</strong> Method: Principal comp<strong>on</strong>ent analysis. KMO =0.903, Chi Square = 556, df= 28 p


Table 2.9<br />

Matrix of Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value Comp<strong>on</strong>ents<br />

Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value<br />

1.To what extent does being associated with your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>'s br<strong>and</strong> give you leverage with<br />

your customers?<br />

Comp<strong>on</strong>ent<br />

2.How likely are you to repurchase from these <strong>supplier</strong>s? .744<br />

3.How likely are you to tolerate a price increase by your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>? .583<br />

Extracti<strong>on</strong> Method: Principal Comp<strong>on</strong>ent Analysis. KMO = 0.574, Chi-Square= 22.576, p


een m<strong>on</strong>itored to make sure they gave the most accurate reply possible. However, since it was an<br />

Internet survey, we were able to look at whether informants rapidly clicked through a survey by<br />

examining the time it took them to complete the survey <strong>and</strong> whether they just choose <strong>on</strong>e opti<strong>on</strong> as an<br />

answer throughout the survey. Hence, we removed those resp<strong>on</strong>ses that had resp<strong>on</strong>ses that had <strong>on</strong>e<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se filled throughout the questi<strong>on</strong>naire. For example, if resp<strong>on</strong>dents just choose the opti<strong>on</strong> 1 for<br />

all the answers. This, as a result, reduces the potential CMV bias in our sample resp<strong>on</strong>se.<br />

Two comm<strong>on</strong> survey procedures that were particularly pr<strong>on</strong>e to CMV are single-point format<br />

(i.e., using a five- or seven-point scale throughout the survey) <strong>and</strong> comm<strong>on</strong> scale anchors (for<br />

example, 1= str<strong>on</strong>gly agree <strong>and</strong> 5= str<strong>on</strong>gly disagree). For the first c<strong>on</strong>cern, we had to make a trade off<br />

<strong>and</strong> accept a single point format almost throughout the survey. There were two main reas<strong>on</strong>s for our<br />

decisi<strong>on</strong>, such as time c<strong>on</strong>cerns (i.e., since we needed a number of questi<strong>on</strong>s answered in a limited<br />

amount of time <strong>and</strong> the use of a different point format would increase the amount of time required per<br />

survey filling) <strong>and</strong> the fact that our use of panel data would significantly increase the per resp<strong>on</strong>se<br />

cost. For the comm<strong>on</strong> scale anchors, we decided to use different terminology throughout the survey,<br />

hence reducing the error caused by these anchors (Rindfleisch et al., 2009).<br />

Marketing has lower CMV error than other social science disciplines (Rindfleisch et al., 2009).<br />

CMV is a cause for c<strong>on</strong>cern because it reduces the researchers’ ability to correctly critically infer<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> from the data (Rindfleisch et al., 2009). Specifically, it increases the probability of type I<br />

<strong>and</strong> type II errors.<br />

One important way in which comm<strong>on</strong> method variance increases is as the level of c<strong>on</strong>struct<br />

abstracti<strong>on</strong> increases (Rindfleisch et al., 2009). Some scholars have suggested a three-level tax<strong>on</strong>omy<br />

for categorizing the level of c<strong>on</strong>struct abstracti<strong>on</strong> (Crampt<strong>on</strong> & Wagner, 1994; Rindfleisch et al.,<br />

2009). The first <strong>and</strong> least abstract levels of c<strong>on</strong>structs are those that can be externally verified, for<br />

example, advertising expenditure. The sec<strong>on</strong>d <strong>and</strong> middle level of abstracti<strong>on</strong> are the outer expressi<strong>on</strong><br />

of internal states. For example, <strong>firm</strong> experience in high technology markets. The third <strong>and</strong> most<br />

abstract level is an internal state, such as customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. Based <strong>on</strong> this tax<strong>on</strong>omy, we have <strong>on</strong>e<br />

variable that is at the most abstract level (i.e., <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>); we have two variables that are<br />

moderately abstract (i.e., market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> IdRR), <strong>and</strong> two variables that are at the least abstract<br />

level (i.e., <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>). Therefore, we tried to find existing scales<br />

wherever possible, as they have been tried <strong>and</strong> tested, <strong>and</strong> help minimize any fears of CMV error in<br />

our study.<br />

2.4.2 Sample<br />

Table 2.12 provides a descripti<strong>on</strong> of the sample. Our sample was collected by using the GMI <strong>on</strong>line<br />

panel <strong>and</strong> we received a resp<strong>on</strong>se rate of 6% in the United States. Firms were chosen <strong>on</strong> the basis of<br />

whether they were situated in the United States. Whenever possible we tried to collect <strong>firm</strong>s that were<br />

publically listed. Although the <strong>firm</strong>s in our sample have a variety of products <strong>and</strong> have had<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships that range from transacti<strong>on</strong>al to strategic in nature, we <strong>on</strong>ly investigated their strategic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships. The sample frame was comprised of 164 purchasing managers of strategic products. We<br />

sent out the questi<strong>on</strong>naire via email to the GMI panel in three waves according to D<strong>on</strong>ney <strong>and</strong> Can<strong>on</strong>’s<br />

(1997) recommendati<strong>on</strong>s. Specifically, the entire list (N=2800) was mailed a questi<strong>on</strong>naire <strong>and</strong> a letter<br />

requesting their participati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>on</strong>e week later, a reminder was sent via email to those participants<br />

who had not resp<strong>on</strong>ded. A total of 194 resp<strong>on</strong>ses were received; of that total, 164 were finally used in<br />

our analysis. Thirty were discarded because they were incomplete or incorrectly filled. For instance,<br />

55


some resp<strong>on</strong>dents would not provide their company name; instead, they typed in r<strong>and</strong>om letters or<br />

scant informati<strong>on</strong> regarding their line of business. Therefore, such resp<strong>on</strong>ses were discarded. We used<br />

the list wise deleti<strong>on</strong> method which involves selecting those cases that were incompletely filled.<br />

The <strong>buyer</strong>’s primary business was most frequently menti<strong>on</strong>ed as both industrial <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer<br />

markets 49%, then c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets 32.3%, <strong>and</strong> industrial markets <strong>on</strong>ly 18.7%. Most <strong>buyer</strong>s in our<br />

sample stated an average of 9.72 years of buying experience, out of which 7.36 years were spent as<br />

strategic <strong>buyer</strong>s for their current employers. Of our sample, 30.9% worked for upper management<br />

meaning senior managers <strong>and</strong> above, whereas 53.1% worked for mid-management. Approximately<br />

<strong>on</strong>e-third (i.e., 35.4%) of the strategic <strong>buyer</strong>s provided service-based market offerings, 23.1%<br />

provided goods as market offerings, <strong>and</strong> the remaining 41.5% offered a mixture of both goods <strong>and</strong><br />

services as their market offering.<br />

Table 2.12<br />

Descriptive Statistics<br />

Sample Descripti<strong>on</strong><br />

Percentage<br />

n=164<br />

Type of Market<br />

Percentage<br />

Industrial <strong>and</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumer Markets 49.0<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Markets 32.3<br />

Industrial Markets 18.7<br />

Number of Years of Buying Experience<br />

Years<br />

Average Buying Experience 9.72<br />

Average Strategic Buying Experience 7.36<br />

Level of Management<br />

Percentage<br />

Upper Management 30.9<br />

Middle Management 53.1<br />

Type of Market Offering<br />

Percentage<br />

Service Based Market offering 35.4<br />

Goods Based Market offering 23.1<br />

Goods <strong>and</strong> Service based market offering 41.5<br />

Resp<strong>on</strong>se rate 6.0<br />

In order to assess n<strong>on</strong>-resp<strong>on</strong>se bias, early <strong>and</strong> late resp<strong>on</strong>ses were compared (D<strong>on</strong>ney &<br />

Cann<strong>on</strong>, 1997). About 80% of our initial resp<strong>on</strong>ses came during the first panel request to fill out our<br />

questi<strong>on</strong>naire. The aspects al<strong>on</strong>g which early <strong>and</strong> late resp<strong>on</strong>ses were compared were by the following<br />

descriptive variables: the number of years of purchasing experience, role <strong>and</strong> level in the organizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

<strong>and</strong> familiarity with the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>. There were no statistically significant differences between<br />

early <strong>and</strong> late resp<strong>on</strong>ses. Therefore, n<strong>on</strong>-resp<strong>on</strong>se bias is not a serious c<strong>on</strong>cern for this study.<br />

For issues regarding normality of the current data set please refer to appendix B. We had some<br />

issues with skewness, but that was rectified by a square root transformati<strong>on</strong> of the data.<br />

2.4.3 Multicollinearity<br />

We check for multicollinearity by using the VIF statistic <strong>and</strong> ran four linear regressi<strong>on</strong>s with a new<br />

dependent variable each time. The dependent variables in order were <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, IdRR,<br />

56


satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> strategic <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. As becomes evident from Tables 2.13-2.16, n<strong>on</strong>e<br />

crossed over the <strong>value</strong> of VIF=10. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, n<strong>on</strong>e of the tolerance levels is less than .10, which means<br />

that multicollinearity is not a serious c<strong>on</strong>cern for the current study (Hair et al., 2006, p. 193).<br />

Table 2.13<br />

Multicollinearity Statistics<br />

Model<br />

Collinearity Statistics<br />

Tolerance VIF<br />

1 Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness .463 2.696<br />

Strategic Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value .491 2.037<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> .371 2.161<br />

a. Dependent Variable: IdRR<br />

Table 2.14<br />

Multicollinearity Statistics<br />

Model<br />

Collinearity Statistics<br />

Tolerance<br />

VIF<br />

2 Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness .475 2.107<br />

Strategic Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value .542 1.864<br />

IdRR .439 2.278<br />

a.Dependent Variable: Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

Table 2.15<br />

Multicollinearity Statistics<br />

Model<br />

Collinearity Statistics<br />

Tolerance<br />

VIF<br />

3 Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness .429 2.329<br />

IdRR .378 2.648<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> .352 2.837<br />

a.Dependent Variable: Strategic Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value<br />

Table 2.16<br />

Multicollinearity Statistics<br />

Model<br />

Collinearity<br />

Tolerance<br />

Statistics<br />

VIF<br />

4 IdRR .400 2.499<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> .347 2.884<br />

Strategic Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value .482 2.073<br />

a. Dependent Variable: Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

57


Table 2.17<br />

Inter-item Correlati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

SIQ CustNPD CF CCC IM AssBr<strong>and</strong> RP. Sales. Fair. BFV<br />

SIQ 1.00<br />

CustNPD 0.50 1.00<br />

CF 0.52 0.35 1.00<br />

CCC -0.39 -0.35 -0.38 1.00<br />

IM -0.40 -0.37 -0.33 0.54 1.00<br />

AssBr<strong>and</strong> 0.34 0.39 0.26 -0.43 -0.51 1.00<br />

RP 0.49 0.31 0.26 -0.25 -0.32 0.33 1.00<br />

Sales 0.44 0.43 0.40 -0.40 -0.49 0.50 0.45 1.00<br />

Fair 0.31 0.34 0.40 -0.28 -0.43 0.44 0.36 0.58 1.00<br />

BFV 0.38 0.38 0.38 -0.44 -0.37 0.45 0.26 0.36 0.34 1.00<br />

*Please look at Table 2.18 for interpretati<strong>on</strong> of the abbreviati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

58


2.5 Measurement Model<br />

For creating our measurement model, we followed the steps used by Hair et al.<br />

(2006). We (1) specified, (2) identified, (3) estimated, (4) evaluated, <strong>and</strong> (5)<br />

respecified the model. We used AMOS versi<strong>on</strong> 17 for our analysis. The four variables<br />

in the measurement model are <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk,<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. As <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> is represented by a single<br />

observed variable it is not included in the measurement model as AMOS 17 cannot<br />

h<strong>and</strong>le a latent c<strong>on</strong>struct measured by a single observed item. Although there is a<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard procedure of fixing the regressi<strong>on</strong> weight to 1 of the latent variable for single<br />

item factor, but as it is an artificial procedure recognized by many scholars as being<br />

based <strong>on</strong> an unrealistic assumpti<strong>on</strong> (Hair et al., 2006, p. 599). Therefore, in order not<br />

to compromise our results we did not include it in the measurement model.<br />

We had a total of 48 items <strong>and</strong> we used 38 items of our survey to create our<br />

measurement model; specifically, the survey c<strong>on</strong>sisted of 12 items that measured<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, 14 items that addressed IdRR, 8 items that focused <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, 3 items to assess <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> 1 item to c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong>. We employed AMOS 17 to draw covariati<strong>on</strong>s between all of the latent<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structs <strong>and</strong> observed items. We assessed our model by using several criteria,<br />

namely the magnitude of each items’ error variance estimate, item cross-loadings<br />

indicated by large modificati<strong>on</strong> indices, <strong>and</strong> significant residual covariati<strong>on</strong> (Kohli et<br />

al., 1993). Our initial model, which was entitled MOD1, was unidentifiable. Using<br />

modificati<strong>on</strong> indices, we deleted items to improve the model’s fit <strong>and</strong> achieve<br />

identificati<strong>on</strong>. Finally, we achieved an excellent model fit with 10 items following the<br />

instructi<strong>on</strong>s of AMOS modificati<strong>on</strong> indices to improve the fit statistics. The questi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

representing the 10 items are provided in Table 2.18.<br />

59


Table 2.18<br />

Questi<strong>on</strong>naire Items <strong>and</strong> Codes<br />

Item Resp<strong>on</strong>se Scale Code<br />

1.This <strong>supplier</strong> has high quality informati<strong>on</strong> regarding<br />

their channel partners (e.g., retailers, distributors, <strong>and</strong><br />

us).<br />

2.The <strong>supplier</strong> seems to be driven by the customer’s<br />

(your) perspective in new product development efforts.<br />

Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3,<br />

Disagree=4, Extremely disagree=5<br />

Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3,<br />

Disagree=4, Extremely disagree=5<br />

SIQ<br />

CustNPD<br />

3.The <strong>supplier</strong>’s strategy in the marketplace optimally<br />

utilizes all of its various functi<strong>on</strong>al departments.<br />

4.How satisfied are you with this <strong>supplier</strong>’s overall<br />

fairness <strong>and</strong> h<strong>on</strong>esty while dealing with you?<br />

5.How satisfied are you with the sales support provided<br />

by the manufacturer's local sales representative?<br />

6.To what extent does being associated with the strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> give you leverage with your customers?<br />

7.How likely are you to repurchase from these <strong>supplier</strong>s?<br />

8.To what extent does your <strong>supplier</strong> help you manage<br />

your inventory?<br />

Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3,<br />

Disagree=4, Extremely disagree=5<br />

Extremely satisfied=1, Satisfied=2,<br />

Neutral=3, Dissatisfied=4, Extremely<br />

dissatisfied=5<br />

Extremely satisfied=1, Satisfied=2,<br />

Neutral=3, Dissatisfied=4, Extremely<br />

dissatisfied=5<br />

Highly positive=1, Positive=2,<br />

Neutral=3, Negative=4, Highly<br />

negative=5<br />

Extremely likely=1, Likely=2, Neutral=3,<br />

Unlikely=4, Extremely unlikely=5<br />

Highly helps=5, Helps=4, Neutral=3,<br />

Problematic=2, Highly problematic=1<br />

CF<br />

Fair<br />

Sales<br />

AssBr<strong>and</strong><br />

RP<br />

IM<br />

9.To what degree does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence<br />

your cash c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> cycle? Definiti<strong>on</strong>al clarificati<strong>on</strong>:<br />

The cash c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> cycle is the time durati<strong>on</strong> in which a<br />

<strong>firm</strong> is able to c<strong>on</strong>vert its resources into cash. It is<br />

actually the total time period required to first c<strong>on</strong>vert<br />

resources into inventories, then inventories into finished<br />

goods, then goods into sales, <strong>and</strong> then sales into cash.<br />

Highly positively=5, Positively=4,<br />

Neutral=3, Negatively=2, Highly<br />

negatively=1<br />

CCC<br />

10.To what extent will your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence<br />

your future cash flow growth <strong>and</strong> stability?<br />

Extremely positive influence=1 Positive<br />

influence=2, Neutral=3, Negative<br />

influence=4, Extremely negatively=5.<br />

BFV<br />

In the sec<strong>on</strong>d step, we investigated the model’s identificati<strong>on</strong>. The initial full,<br />

38-item model was unidentifiable. However, after a repeated process of reducing the<br />

number of observed variables, we finally achieved a good model fit <strong>and</strong> identificati<strong>on</strong><br />

with 10 items. Model identificati<strong>on</strong> is measured by the difference between the number<br />

of distinct sample moments (45) <strong>and</strong> the distinct parameters to be estimated (23). The<br />

resulting degrees of freedom are 22, indicating that the model has been identified. The<br />

reducti<strong>on</strong> was attained by looking at the modificati<strong>on</strong> indices <strong>and</strong> low st<strong>and</strong>ardized<br />

regressi<strong>on</strong> weights. Table 2.21 presents the recommended fit indices <strong>and</strong> our<br />

measurement model’s actual fit indices. Our model fit indices are excellent.<br />

60


In the third step, we used maximum likelihood estimati<strong>on</strong> in AMOS to<br />

estimate the model. The recommended sample size is between 100-150, but valid<br />

results have also been found with smaller sample sizes of up to 50 (Hair et al.,<br />

2006).Therefore, since our sample size of 164 is over the 100 threshold <strong>and</strong> well<br />

above the minimum size of 50, we decided to use the maximum likelihood opti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Another technique that we could have used was asymptomatically distributi<strong>on</strong> free,<br />

which offers an advantage over all other techniques since it does not require normally<br />

distributed data. However, as the data we are using is within the acceptable range of<br />

the normal limit, this issue is not a c<strong>on</strong>siderati<strong>on</strong> for us. In additi<strong>on</strong>, asymptomatically<br />

distributi<strong>on</strong> free requires larger sample sizes than our current sample size of 164.<br />

Therefore, we decided not to use it. We also used the opti<strong>on</strong>s of fitting the saturated<br />

<strong>and</strong> independence models, minimizati<strong>on</strong> history, st<strong>and</strong>ardized estimates, <strong>and</strong> squared<br />

multiple correlati<strong>on</strong>s. The latter two comp<strong>on</strong>ents would eventually help us to estimate<br />

the average variance that was extracted <strong>and</strong> the reliability of the findings. The<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ardized residual covariances are less than two, which means the measurement<br />

model is acceptable.<br />

Another criteri<strong>on</strong> is that the st<strong>and</strong>ardized regressi<strong>on</strong> weights should be above<br />

0.5 (i.e., preferably 0.7). All of our measures, as presented in Table 2.19, fulfill this<br />

criteria. A close examinati<strong>on</strong> of the st<strong>and</strong>ardized regressi<strong>on</strong> weights within the CFA<br />

model indicates that n<strong>on</strong>e is extremely close to <strong>on</strong>e. This result provides evidence that<br />

multicollinearity is not a problem with our data. The highest st<strong>and</strong>ardized regressi<strong>on</strong><br />

weight we have is 0.838.<br />

Table 2.19 represents the average variance extracted (AVE) for each the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structs in the model tested. AVE is the shared amount of variance indicators have<br />

with a c<strong>on</strong>struct. The minimal acceptable level as a rule of thumb is 50%. Two of our<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structs <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> IdRR pass the 50% threshold. Supplier<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is close to the 50% threshold <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> does has bad<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct validity. However, in Chapter 4 when we repeat this analysis using a sub<br />

sample of publically listed companies from the data used in Chapter 2 <strong>and</strong> we find<br />

that the c<strong>on</strong>struct <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> satisfies the criteria of surpassing the 0.5<br />

threshold for AVE.<br />

Table 2.19 Average Variance Extracted<br />

C<strong>on</strong>struct Observed Variable (SRW) Squared Multiple Correlati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness SIQ (.773) .598<br />

Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness CustNPD (.643) .414<br />

Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness CF (.631) .398<br />

Average Variance Extracted 47 %<br />

IdRR CCC (.682) .465<br />

IdRR IM (.796) .633<br />

Average Variance Extracted 54 %<br />

Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value AssBr<strong>and</strong> (.645) .415<br />

Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value RP (.579) .335<br />

Average Variance Extracted 37.5%<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> Sales (.838) .703<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> Fairness (695) .483<br />

Average Variance Extracted 59.2 %<br />

SRW=St<strong>and</strong>ardized Regressi<strong>on</strong> Weights.<br />

61


Table 2.20 represented the reliability for the c<strong>on</strong>structs in our model. The<br />

<strong>value</strong>s are above 0.7, <strong>and</strong> for exploratory scales lower <strong>value</strong>s of c<strong>on</strong>struct reliability<br />

are acceptable. In light of the exploratory nature of the <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> scale as it<br />

created by us we have decided to keep it in the model. Therefore, as per Table 2.20<br />

our c<strong>on</strong>structs are reliable (Hair et al., 2006,p. 612).<br />

Table 2.20<br />

C<strong>on</strong>struct Reliability<br />

C<strong>on</strong>struct Name<br />

C<strong>on</strong>struct Reliability<br />

1.Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness 0.72<br />

2.Idiosyncratic Relati<strong>on</strong>al Risk 0.71<br />

3.Strategic Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value 0.54<br />

4.Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> 0.74<br />

In the fourth step, we assessed our model; the results of this process are<br />

presented in Table 2.21. One of the first tests to check for model fit in this stage is the<br />

χ 2 test. The χ 2 tests whether the estimated covariance index is equal to the observed<br />

covariance index. Ideally our estimated model should be exactly the same as our<br />

predicted model, showing no difference between the χ 2 mean <strong>value</strong> for the null <strong>and</strong><br />

estimated models. The null hypothesis is that there is no difference between the<br />

observed <strong>and</strong> estimated matrices. The χ 2 shows that the matrices are different in our<br />

model as the null hypothesis is supported at the 0.001 level (Hair et al., 2006). This<br />

means that our predicted model does fit the observed model. Although the χ 2 statistic<br />

is a powerful indicator, it al<strong>on</strong>e is not enough to indicate the model fit (Joreskog &<br />

Sorbom, 1984). This is because of χ 2 sensitivity to sample size. For example, as the<br />

sample size increases above 200, the χ 2 test tends to show significance because an<br />

increased sample size inflated the χ 2 <strong>value</strong>s. As it approaches or moves away from<br />

100, it tends to indicate insignificance (Hair et al., 2006). Since our sample size is<br />

164, we rely <strong>on</strong> the χ 2 indicator as <strong>on</strong>e test of whether our model shows a relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

between the variables in the model. Our findings are c<strong>on</strong>sistent with the<br />

recommendati<strong>on</strong>s of Hair et al. (2006), who specified that the models should be<br />

insignificant. However, Hair et al. (2006) also state that SEM has no single fit statistic<br />

that best describes the overall model fit or strength of its predicti<strong>on</strong>s. Therefore,<br />

below we use a number of absolute <strong>and</strong> relative fit measures to assess our<br />

c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory factor model.<br />

GFI is a widely accepted absolute fit measure. A model is c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

acceptable when it has a GFI <strong>value</strong> of ≥.9. Our model meets this limit with a <strong>value</strong> of<br />

0.951 as shown in Table 2.21.<br />

RMSEA is sometimes called a badness-of-fit measure <strong>and</strong> is an absolute fit<br />

measure. RMSEA measures how good a model fits the whole populati<strong>on</strong> rather than<br />

just the sample. It is typically a good indicator for larger samples. The RMSEA is<br />

used to avoid a Type II error, which occurs when a model that actually fits the data is<br />

rejected. Acceptable <strong>value</strong>s for RMSEA are between .05 <strong>and</strong> .08; less than .05<br />

indicates a good fit. By this st<strong>and</strong>ard, our current model is acceptable with a RMSEA<br />

of 0.068. The sec<strong>on</strong>d category of fit indices are incremental fit measures. These<br />

indices compare our proposed model with the null model (Hair et al., 2006). The<br />

62


incremental fit index (IFI) is <strong>on</strong>e from the range of incremental fit measures. Our<br />

model has an incremental fit index (IFI) <strong>value</strong> of .966 indicating a good fit. The next<br />

incremental fit index that we use is the comparative fit index (CFI) <strong>and</strong> it is<br />

specifically meant for samples with small sizes (Hair et al., 2006). We surpass the<br />

minimum level of 0.9 with our model score of 0.965, which is c<strong>on</strong>sidered a good fit.<br />

Moreover, the Tucker Lewis index (TLI) has a <strong>value</strong> of 0.942 <strong>and</strong> that is above the<br />

minimal level of 0.90. Since our model meets the criteria of the goodness of fit<br />

measures, we accept the measurement model.<br />

Table 2.21<br />

Measurement Model Indices<br />

Goodness of fit index Recommended Values Values<br />

χ 2 /degrees of freedom ≤ 3.00 1.76<br />

Tucker Lewis Index (TLI) ≥ 0.90 0.94<br />

Goodness-of-Fit Index<br />

≥ 0.90 0.95<br />

(GFI)<br />

Incremental Fit Index (IFI) ≥ 0.90 0.96<br />

Comparative Fit Index<br />

≤ 0.90 0.96<br />

(CFI)<br />

Root Mean Square Error<br />

of Approximati<strong>on</strong><br />

(RMSEA)<br />

≤ 0.08 0.06<br />

In Table 2.22, we examine the st<strong>and</strong>ardized residual covariance. Table 2.22<br />

presents the results of the difference between the sample <strong>and</strong> implied covariances.<br />

Each residual covariance has been divided by an estimate of its st<strong>and</strong>ard error<br />

(Jöreskog & Sörbom, 1984). The remaining 9 items in Table 2.22 st<strong>and</strong>ardized<br />

residual covariances have a st<strong>and</strong>ard normal distributi<strong>on</strong>, as n<strong>on</strong>e of the items has a<br />

<strong>value</strong> that exceeds two in absolute <strong>value</strong>.<br />

Table 2.22<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ardized Residual Covariances<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9<br />

IM 0<br />

Sales -0.08 0<br />

Fair -0.39 0.00 0<br />

RP 0.78 0.12 -0.09 0.75<br />

AssBr<strong>and</strong> -0.76 -0.15 0.19 -0.39 0<br />

CCC 0.00 0.12 0.71 1.00 -0.52 0<br />

CF 0.29 0.18 1.07 -0.39 -0.95 -0.85 0<br />

CustNPD -0.13 0.52 0.20 0.10 0.55 -0.43 -0.63 0<br />

SIQ 0.44 -0.29 -0.89 1.61 -0.93 -0.21 0.38 -0.03 0<br />

63


2.6 The Structural Model<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d part in our model estimati<strong>on</strong> is assessing the structural model. The SEM<br />

technique was chosen because it is an important tool for academic research as well as<br />

for analyzing survey data <strong>and</strong> covariance structures in data (Hair et al., 2006). We<br />

follow the seven stages of structural equati<strong>on</strong> modeling that were developed by Hair<br />

et al. (2006).<br />

The first stage is developing a modeling strategy. We had two alternative<br />

strategies from which to choose while developing our modeling strategy. The first<br />

alternative is developing a single model development strategy (i.e., also called a<br />

c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory model strategy) <strong>and</strong> the sec<strong>on</strong>d alternative is developing a competing<br />

model strategy. The benefit of the first alternative is that it leads a researcher to focus<br />

<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>e model <strong>and</strong>, in turn, this leads to a rigorous applicati<strong>on</strong> of the SEM technique.<br />

In t<strong>and</strong>em, a single model development strategy suffers from the lack of identificati<strong>on</strong><br />

of alternative models (Hair et al., 2006). The benefit of the sec<strong>on</strong>d alternative is that it<br />

allows a researcher to assess alternative theories, but we had already evaluated<br />

alternative theories during our literature review <strong>and</strong> synthesis. Moreover, we have<br />

already arrived at a specific model that we wanted to test. Hence, a single model<br />

strategy best suited our current needs.<br />

We also dealt with whether we had enough evidence to determine causality.<br />

The most important criteri<strong>on</strong> is a sound theoretical reas<strong>on</strong>ing that we have developed<br />

in the earlier secti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> our hypotheses development <strong>and</strong> literature synthesis. Supplier<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, IdRR, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong><br />

have statistical associati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> cause <strong>and</strong> effect antecedence based <strong>on</strong> prior research<br />

that was covered in the literature synthesis. We chose the most important variables<br />

after our literature synthesis, thus significantly reducing the possibility of a lack of<br />

alternative causal variables. A limitati<strong>on</strong> of this approach is that we are not able to<br />

investigate all other possible models that our research might include. While<br />

specifying the initial model we had to adhere to the rule of five observati<strong>on</strong>s for each<br />

measured variable in the model (Hair et al., 2006, p. 166). Our initial model with 39<br />

items <strong>and</strong> four latent c<strong>on</strong>structs <strong>and</strong> <strong>on</strong>e observed c<strong>on</strong>struct did not meet this criteri<strong>on</strong>.<br />

With the help of modificati<strong>on</strong> indices, this was later reduced to 10 measured variables<br />

<strong>and</strong> five c<strong>on</strong>structs. This gave us a ratio of about 16 resp<strong>on</strong>dents for every variable<br />

(164/10), which exceeds the minimum recommended limit of five resp<strong>on</strong>dents for<br />

every item (Hair et al., 2006, p. 166). Our four latent c<strong>on</strong>cepts <strong>and</strong> <strong>on</strong>e observed<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct are fewer than the maximum recommended of 20 for using the SEM<br />

technique.<br />

In the sec<strong>on</strong>d <strong>and</strong> third stages, we c<strong>on</strong>structed a path diagram of causal<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships. We have <strong>on</strong>e exogenous c<strong>on</strong>struct, which is <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness.<br />

We have four endogenous c<strong>on</strong>structs, namely IdRR, satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. We also tested for unidimensi<strong>on</strong>ality. Our results<br />

indicated that our c<strong>on</strong>structs load <strong>on</strong> more than <strong>on</strong>e factor <strong>and</strong>, therefore,<br />

unidimensi<strong>on</strong>ality is not a c<strong>on</strong>cern in the current study.<br />

In the fourth stage of our research, we determined the input matrix type <strong>and</strong><br />

estimated the proposed model. We choose the covariance matrix because it is a true<br />

test of theory (Hair et al., 2006, p. 603). The correlati<strong>on</strong> matrix is not suited for theory<br />

testing as it <strong>on</strong>ly represents a pattern of relati<strong>on</strong>ships. We used the maximum<br />

likelihood estimati<strong>on</strong> method <strong>and</strong> our sample size of 164 was above the recommended<br />

64


ange of 100-150 (Hair et al., 2006, p. 605). In AMOS we also selected covariance<br />

supplied <strong>and</strong> to be analyzed as the maximum likelihood opti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> we selected the<br />

opti<strong>on</strong> r<strong>and</strong>om permutati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

In the fifth stage, we assessed our structural model. Model identificati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

measured in AMOS by the difference between the number of distinct sample<br />

moments (55) <strong>and</strong> the distinct parameters to be estimated (25). The resulting degrees<br />

of freedom 30 indicate that the model has been identified. We achieved a good model<br />

fit <strong>and</strong> identificati<strong>on</strong> with 10 items, as shown in Table 2.23:<br />

Table 2.23<br />

Structural Model Indices<br />

Goodness of fit index Recommended Values Values<br />

χ 2 /degrees of freedom ≤ 3.00 1.83<br />

Tucker Lewis Index (TLI) ≥ 0.90 0.93<br />

Goodness-of-Fit Index (GFI) ≥ 0.90 0.94<br />

Incremental Fit Index (IFI) ≥ 0.90 0.95<br />

Comparative Fit Index (CFI) ≤ 0.90 0.95<br />

Root Mean Square Error of<br />

Approximati<strong>on</strong><br />

(RMSEA)<br />

≤ 0.08 0.072<br />

In stage six, we interpret our model. The fit statistics for our model are good.<br />

The data supported our first hypothesis <strong>and</strong> show that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is an<br />

antecedent to IdRR. The c<strong>on</strong>structs are negatively related: β=-0.988, p


influences <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Our fifth hypothesis is supported by the data with a<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ardized regressi<strong>on</strong> weight of β=0.976, p < .01.<br />

2.7 Discussi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Although market orientati<strong>on</strong> is a central tenant of marketing, the inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al risk<br />

implicati<strong>on</strong>s of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to the customer’s needs has never been examined in<br />

a systematic manner. We introduced the c<strong>on</strong>cept of IdRR, which indicates to what extent<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness reduces relati<strong>on</strong>al risk <strong>and</strong> results in positive relati<strong>on</strong>al outcomes<br />

for both the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong>. The results provide c<strong>on</strong>siderable support for our<br />

model. In the following secti<strong>on</strong>s, we first discuss our c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s to theory <strong>and</strong> practice<br />

<strong>and</strong> then we generally discuss the results of the tests of the five hypotheses by comparing<br />

them with extant literature.<br />

We make several c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s to marketing theory <strong>and</strong> practice. First, we shed new<br />

light <strong>on</strong> the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk relati<strong>on</strong>ship <strong>and</strong> build a comprehensive model that<br />

enunciates the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, IdRR, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

Our findings challenge the status quo belief that market orientati<strong>on</strong> is an inherently risky<br />

endeavor by providing some evidence that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness negatively influences<br />

IdRR. Moreover, we c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the marketing domain by extending the scope of the<br />

current market orientati<strong>on</strong> models, which to date have mostly focused <strong>on</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> perspective <strong>and</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong>’s marketplace performance. Furthermore,<br />

extant literature has not addressed the issue of incorporating the customer’s perspective<br />

<strong>and</strong> the customer’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> in market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance models.<br />

Sec<strong>on</strong>d, we introduce IdRR as a new c<strong>on</strong>struct in the literature <strong>and</strong> an important<br />

mediator of the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Using IdRR, academics <strong>and</strong><br />

businesses will be able to estimate whether market orientati<strong>on</strong> increases or reduces the<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al risk between a <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong>. Furthermore, at a time when there is an<br />

increased need for accountability within <strong>firm</strong>s, IdRR as a measure allows managers to<br />

communicate some of the <strong>value</strong> that the relati<strong>on</strong>ship has accrued due to market orientati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Hence, by using IdRR to explain the benefits of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, it adds clarity to the<br />

returns <strong>on</strong> investment from market orientati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Third, we provide evidence that market orientati<strong>on</strong> is a single unified general<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct <strong>and</strong> not three separate general factors. The market orientati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>struct has<br />

lacked discriminant validity in some important studies, but scholars still c<strong>on</strong>tinue to model<br />

it as sub-comp<strong>on</strong>ents rather than a general factor (Kohli et al., 1993; Narver & Slater,<br />

1990). In the current study, we revisited it as a general factor <strong>and</strong> we have found that<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is a single factor rather than three distinct<br />

comp<strong>on</strong>ents.<br />

Fourth, we find that <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is not related to a <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. In the<br />

extant literature, scholars so far have focused <strong>on</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong><br />

business performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Gyskens et al., 1999). Despite this focus, scholars have<br />

found limited evidence of a <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

(Gyskens et al., 1999). Although the <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship is important, even more important is the issue as to whether <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

is a meaningful indicator. As satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in channel c<strong>on</strong>texts has an ec<strong>on</strong>omic aspect, it<br />

should be related to a <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> in order to be meaningful as an indicator. If the<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> is satisfied with the ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>value</strong> provided by the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>, it in turn<br />

should increase the <strong>buyer</strong>’s cash flow, <strong>and</strong> therefore, <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

Fifth, our model provides preliminary evidence that IdRR reducti<strong>on</strong> is a reliable<br />

66


indicator that has a link to customer <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. For managers, this<br />

finding provides a framework for thought. However, it may not be possible or desirable to<br />

solely focus <strong>on</strong> those activities that reduce IdRR because some market orientati<strong>on</strong> activities<br />

may influence both IdRR <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, but a <strong>firm</strong> should rely more <strong>on</strong> IdRR<br />

measures than customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> measures. In the course of this research we found that<br />

some <strong>firm</strong>s, such as Fabory in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, regularly survey their <strong>supplier</strong>s for risk <strong>and</strong><br />

their satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with the <strong>supplier</strong>. Fabory does not discriminate between risk <strong>and</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> measures while making decisi<strong>on</strong>s. Our research dictates that <strong>firm</strong>s should focus<br />

<strong>on</strong> IdRR measures.<br />

2.7.1 H 1 : Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> IdRR<br />

Since we have developed the c<strong>on</strong>struct of IdRR ourselves, we have not been able to find<br />

other comparable studies that have used this c<strong>on</strong>struct. Moreover, we look for the closest<br />

comparable c<strong>on</strong>structs, <strong>and</strong> that is managerial risk aversi<strong>on</strong> in the market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

literature. There is <strong>on</strong>e additi<strong>on</strong>al difference between managerial risk aversi<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> IdRR:<br />

Managerial risk aversi<strong>on</strong> is measured from an intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al perspective, whereas<br />

IdRR is measured from an inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al perspective.<br />

Our research challenges the traditi<strong>on</strong>al assumpti<strong>on</strong> in marketing that risk <strong>and</strong> market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> are positively related (Jaworski & Kohli, 1993). We find that market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> IdRR are negatively related in an inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text. This finding is relevant<br />

because it sheds new light up<strong>on</strong> the dynamics of inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al IdRR in relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

exchanges, in comparis<strong>on</strong> with the intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

risk. Linamar (LNR) <strong>and</strong> Caterpillar exemplify this hypothesis in the B2B c<strong>on</strong>text.<br />

Caterpillar chose LNR because of its expertise in making diesel engines <strong>and</strong> since then<br />

Caterpillar’s marketplace performance has improved as its risk has decreased (Marketwire,<br />

2007). Eventually, this outcome caused LNR to be awarded the status of a strategic <strong>supplier</strong><br />

for Caterpillar (Marketwire, 2007).<br />

Our findings are different from studies that examine the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> top management risk aversi<strong>on</strong> in an intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text.<br />

Jaworski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993) found that risk aversi<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness are negatively<br />

related in an intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text, but they find insignificant relati<strong>on</strong>ships for the<br />

other dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, namely, intelligence generati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> disseminati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In other words, they find that risk percepti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness are positively related <strong>and</strong><br />

an insignificant relati<strong>on</strong>ship between top management risk aversi<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the overall<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Alternatively, we find that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong><br />

IdRR, which are both measured by perceptual metrics, are negatively related in the interorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text. Similarly, the strength of the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> IdRR is str<strong>on</strong>ger in our study with a st<strong>and</strong>ardized regressi<strong>on</strong> weight of<br />

β=-0.98, p


top management risk aversi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the resp<strong>on</strong>siveness comp<strong>on</strong>ent of market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

could be weak. In additi<strong>on</strong>, another study has also found an insignificant relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

between top management risk aversi<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> (Pulendran et al., 2000). The<br />

Pulendran et al. (2000) study reinforces our belief that there could be an alternative<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk, whether risk is measured from a<br />

managerial or an IdRR perspective. Our findings provide such an alternative relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

<strong>and</strong> we have found that market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> IdRR are negatively related.<br />

However, some additi<strong>on</strong>al issues warrant a discussi<strong>on</strong> in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Our findings offer an additi<strong>on</strong>al mechanism to <strong>supplier</strong><br />

diversificati<strong>on</strong> for organizati<strong>on</strong>al IdRR reducti<strong>on</strong>. The portfolio approach that marketing<br />

has adopted from finance for dealing with idiosyncratic risk through <strong>supplier</strong>, product, <strong>and</strong><br />

service diversificati<strong>on</strong> is not the <strong>on</strong>ly effective mechanism for reducing risk. An additi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

effective mechanism of relati<strong>on</strong>al risk reducti<strong>on</strong> is through market-oriented strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s. Usually, in strategic items, it is not possible to have numerous <strong>supplier</strong>s because<br />

of the unique nature of the product that they supply. Therefore, this limits the use of the<br />

aforementi<strong>on</strong>ed portfolio approach. Alternatively, a strategic <strong>supplier</strong> may provide tailormade,<br />

specific market-based soluti<strong>on</strong>s for the <strong>buyer</strong> then, as a c<strong>on</strong>sequence, the <strong>buyer</strong>’s<br />

IdRR is reduced as well. The business world is rife with examples of companies that use<br />

market-oriented strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s. For instance, Hoeschst, the German petrochemical<br />

giant, has a strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ship with Kuwait petroleum (Kraljic, 1983). Dow Chemicals in<br />

the United States <strong>and</strong> BASF in Europe follow similar strategies (Kraljic, 1983). Overall, the<br />

importance of our findings is that we have been able to show, to some extent, that in an<br />

inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text market orientati<strong>on</strong> is a relati<strong>on</strong>al risk-reducing rather than<br />

enhancing, mechanism.<br />

2.7.2 H 2 : Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> H 3 : Buyer<br />

Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Buyer Firm Value<br />

We c<strong>on</strong>sider hypotheses 2 <strong>and</strong> 3 together because they form a chain of antecedent mediator<br />

<strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequence. We find that between <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> a positive<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship exists. This finding reinforces previous intra-<strong>firm</strong> research that shows that<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or market orientati<strong>on</strong> creates <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> (Kohli & Jaworski,<br />

1990; Narver & Slater, 1990). Managers do judge <strong>supplier</strong> performance against their own<br />

predispositi<strong>on</strong>s of what is expected. We also find that <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is not linked to the<br />

<strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. This finding relates to other similar observati<strong>on</strong>s by Naray<strong>and</strong>as (2005).<br />

Other researchers have found that satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is a distinct process from customer <strong>value</strong><br />

creati<strong>on</strong> in B2B (Eggert & Ulaga, 2002). Hence, an increase in <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is not an<br />

indicator that <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>value</strong> has been created in B2B. This is inline with our finding that<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does not influence <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

2.7.3 H 4 : IdRR <strong>and</strong> Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value<br />

We find that IdRR is inversely related to <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. This finding is c<strong>on</strong>sistent<br />

with a theory posited by Kotler <strong>and</strong> Pfoertsch (2006) that states that for B2B br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>,<br />

<strong>on</strong>e core functi<strong>on</strong> is to reduce risk. We take that analysis a step further by showing that a<br />

reducti<strong>on</strong> of customer risk also leads to an increase in <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> in a B2B<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text. This is also similar to other marketing studies that postulate that market-based<br />

assets are inversely related to financial risk (McAlister et al., 2007). One study examines<br />

the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between negative customer experience (i.e., which is measured by a<br />

negative experience with a corporate br<strong>and</strong>) <strong>and</strong> the positive associati<strong>on</strong> with an<br />

idiosyncratic <strong>firm</strong> level (Luo, 2007). Another study compares three portfolios of different<br />

68


<strong>and</strong> strengths <strong>and</strong> their stock market returns (Singh, Faircloth, & Nejadmalayeri, 2005).<br />

Portfolios with the str<strong>on</strong>gest br<strong>and</strong>s performed the best in terms of returns <strong>and</strong> risk<br />

insulati<strong>on</strong>. What their finding seems to suggest is that the customer ranking of br<strong>and</strong>s has<br />

direct c<strong>on</strong>sequences for the seller’s or <strong>supplier</strong>’s financial market performance. Hence, our<br />

finding that reducing IdRR produces higher <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> reinforces such<br />

perspectives <strong>and</strong> is significant for the <strong>supplier</strong> if they wish to increase their br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

However, our findings also differ from previous studies. On <strong>on</strong>e h<strong>and</strong>, previous<br />

research has focused <strong>on</strong> customer experience <strong>and</strong> seller idiosyncratic risk (Luo, 2007). On<br />

the other h<strong>and</strong>, we have focused <strong>on</strong> IdRR <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong> intangible assets. We examine<br />

the effect directly from customer percepti<strong>on</strong>s, whereas prior studies have used the financial<br />

markets to measure seller risk exposure (Luo, 2007; McAlister et al., 2007). Our approach<br />

is superior to the prior studies as the latter are based <strong>on</strong> the efficient market hypothesis <strong>and</strong><br />

assume that financial markets perfectly transmit real-world happenings to investors.<br />

However, in reality, markets are at best moderately efficient, but never perfectly efficient<br />

(Cassidy, 2009). So we can never be very certain about what caused an increase in<br />

idiosyncratic risk <strong>on</strong> the stock market while basing inferences <strong>on</strong> the efficient market<br />

hypothesis. However, as a resp<strong>on</strong>dent, the customer’s answers reflect what the customer is<br />

thinking <strong>and</strong> such a perspective offers a greater deal of certainty than the efficient market<br />

hypothesis. Therefore, using the customer perspective provides str<strong>on</strong>ger reas<strong>on</strong>ing for the<br />

effect of <strong>supplier</strong> or seller marketing activities <strong>on</strong> customer risk.<br />

A company that exemplifies the causal effect of hypothesis 4 is the <strong>firm</strong> Liveops.<br />

The <strong>firm</strong> reduces its customer’s idiosyncratic risk by collecting intelligence <strong>on</strong> its agent’s<br />

performance while serving customer queries (Girotra & Netessine, 2011). As a result, <strong>on</strong>ly<br />

those agents who best meet the needs of the clients remain employed by the company. This<br />

ensures that the relati<strong>on</strong>ship c<strong>on</strong>tinues <strong>and</strong> implies that, as the <strong>supplier</strong>, Liveops’s cash flow<br />

has less variability or risk.<br />

2.7.4 H 5 : Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value <strong>and</strong> Buyer Firm Value<br />

The data provide evidence for our fifth hypothesis that <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> positively<br />

influences <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Our finding is similar to those by Ghosh <strong>and</strong> John (2009).<br />

They found that in a B2B c<strong>on</strong>text, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong>s with str<strong>on</strong>g equity provide leverage to a<br />

customer’s br<strong>and</strong> via differentiati<strong>on</strong>. Such differentiati<strong>on</strong> helps the customer to maintain<br />

their competitive positi<strong>on</strong> in the marketplace <strong>and</strong>, hence, affects the customer’s earnings.<br />

Our results c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> their findings that indeed a <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> does provide leverage to<br />

the <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> earnings <strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

The mechanism for this identificati<strong>on</strong> in fr<strong>on</strong>t of the end customer (i.e., the <strong>buyer</strong>’s<br />

customers) is br<strong>and</strong> associati<strong>on</strong>. This is similar to other studies in which some authors find<br />

that br<strong>and</strong>ing is the essence of differentiati<strong>on</strong> in B2B markets <strong>and</strong> serves as a means of<br />

reducing uncertainty or risk (Mudambi, Doyle, & W<strong>on</strong>g, 1997). Risk in marketing implies<br />

the probability of incurring a loss. So, insulati<strong>on</strong> or a reducti<strong>on</strong> in risk means an increase in<br />

cash flow stability <strong>and</strong>, hence, an increase in <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. The support for our<br />

hypothesis reinforces this perspective.<br />

69


2.8 Managerial Implicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

The following points include practical examples to illustrate the managerial implicati<strong>on</strong>s of<br />

our research.<br />

2.8.1 Findings Apply to Both Heterogeneous <strong>and</strong> Homogeneous Competitive<br />

Markets<br />

In today’s marketplace, increasing complexity <strong>and</strong> competiti<strong>on</strong> make it imperative for<br />

businesses to differentiate their offerings in terms of competitive advantages (Day, 1994).<br />

One important source of such strategic supply competitive edge is market-oriented<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s. For instance, c<strong>on</strong>sider Porsche C<strong>on</strong>sulting’s services. It operates in the<br />

heterogeneous c<strong>on</strong>sulting services market (J. D. Power, 2010). Porsche, the automobile<br />

manufacturer, has c<strong>on</strong>sistently ranked at the top of J. D. Powers <strong>and</strong> Associate’s annual<br />

initial quality study (J. D. Power, 2010). Porsche has perfected its underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the<br />

automotive <strong>and</strong> supply chain management processes. It has internalized the philosophy of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> up to an extreme degree to identify latent needs. As a result, customers<br />

of its c<strong>on</strong>sultancy services enjoy increased earnings <strong>and</strong> avoid crisis or risk (Kotler &<br />

Pfoertsch, 2006, p. 87; Scholz, 2009). Examples of customers who have enjoyed such<br />

benefits include Lufthansa AG, Meyer Werft AG, <strong>and</strong> Strabag AG. Lufthansa reduced the<br />

time that was required to inspect aircraft by 30%, Strabag significantly improved its<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> processes, <strong>and</strong> Meyer Werft introduced a new learning academy to ensure that<br />

they fully internalized the suggesti<strong>on</strong>s from Porsche. Such experiences are reflected by<br />

Lufthansa’s air services chief who said, “Porsche is an interesting partner for us” (Cremer,<br />

2010, para. 3).<br />

The degree of customer c<strong>on</strong>fidence in Porsche’s abilities is reflected by the<br />

statement of Porsche’s c<strong>on</strong>sulting services chief officer, Eberhard Weilben: “Many of our<br />

clients come <strong>and</strong> say please turn us into the Porsches of our industries” (Cremer, 2010,<br />

para. 14).<br />

Mr. Weilben’s quote reflects the importance that such strategic customers<br />

place <strong>on</strong> the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Hence, our example illustrates that resp<strong>on</strong>sive<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s do create <strong>value</strong> in such heterogeneous competitive marketplaces by reducing<br />

risk <strong>and</strong> improving performance.<br />

We have sampled data from diversified companies such as Google, Apple,<br />

Microsoft, YUM br<strong>and</strong>s, Chippolette, Caterpillar, <strong>and</strong> Red Roof Inns. Our sample<br />

includes 86 publically listed <strong>firm</strong>s. The remaining 78 are privately owned companies.<br />

These companies operate in a variety of competitive heterogeneous to homogeneous<br />

marketplaces. Hence, we advise managers in both forms of marketplace to implement<br />

a <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness strategy to reduce IdRR. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, we realize that<br />

many <strong>firm</strong>s are c<strong>on</strong>cerned by their ec<strong>on</strong>omies of scale. Thus, in our opini<strong>on</strong>, a<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness strategy should <strong>on</strong>ly be applied in strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships. The payoffs<br />

will <strong>on</strong>ly be great enough for the idiosyncratic resp<strong>on</strong>se costs that are incurred when<br />

the volume of transacti<strong>on</strong>s is substantial. This is normally the case in strategic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<br />

2.8.2 Innovati<strong>on</strong> Does Not Increase Relati<strong>on</strong>al Risk <strong>and</strong> Increases Supplier<br />

Br<strong>and</strong> Value<br />

We c<strong>on</strong>sider that any kind of resp<strong>on</strong>se to an idiosyncratic need is a market innovati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Since it is based <strong>on</strong> specific knowledge for a specific <strong>firm</strong>, it is in a sense, therefore, new to<br />

the world. However, resp<strong>on</strong>ses to idiosyncratic needs do not necessarily involve an extreme<br />

degree of innovati<strong>on</strong>; as a result, all resp<strong>on</strong>ses need not be resource intensive. But risk<br />

70


accompanies any innovati<strong>on</strong>, according to the extant marketing literature (Kohli &<br />

Jaworski, 1990). Our findings are that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness does reduce IdRR. This is an<br />

important insight for managers because of the widespread management assumpti<strong>on</strong> that<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong> or market orientati<strong>on</strong> is positively associated with risk (Slater & Narver, 1995).<br />

This insight can be used by marketing managers to communicate to senior management the<br />

dual benefits of being market oriented. First, for the <strong>buyer</strong>s <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong>s it is a means of<br />

reducing their own IdRR; sec<strong>on</strong>d, for <strong>supplier</strong>s it is a means of increasing br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

third, for <strong>buyer</strong>s it is a means of increasing their profits. Further, both <strong>supplier</strong>s <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong>s<br />

can c<strong>on</strong>vince management to give marketing managers greater budgets for market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

From our review of the literature, we have found that innovati<strong>on</strong> is generally<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidered to be a process that is involved with risk. Evidence from the business world in<br />

an inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text suggests otherwise. C<strong>on</strong>sider the list of br<strong>and</strong>s <strong>on</strong> both the<br />

Interbr<strong>and</strong> B2B br<strong>and</strong> rankings <strong>and</strong> BusinessWeek’s innovati<strong>on</strong> index (BusinessWeek,<br />

2012). Br<strong>and</strong>s such as Intel that follow an ingredient br<strong>and</strong>ing strategy through accelerated<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong>s not <strong>on</strong>ly secure a competitive positi<strong>on</strong> in the marketplace, but also add<br />

customer <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> insulati<strong>on</strong> from risk. But not all br<strong>and</strong>s follow an ingredient br<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

strategy. In that case, we suggest that <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>s choose those ingredient <strong>supplier</strong>s who<br />

reduce their IdRR. A strategic <strong>supplier</strong> status is normally c<strong>on</strong>ferred after a thorough<br />

examinati<strong>on</strong> of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>’s capabilities, we believe that IdRR is an important<br />

indicator to check for potential <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> from the relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

2.8.3 Underst<strong>and</strong> the Customer Business Process Specifically Related to IdRR<br />

For business managers, an oft-repeated mantra is underst<strong>and</strong>ing their customers. At a<br />

general level, this is an expensive <strong>and</strong> time-c<strong>on</strong>suming exercise. Therefore, as a rule of<br />

thumb, for <strong>supplier</strong>s it should represent a sustainable business volume from which they can<br />

acquire their returns. The next step would be to focus <strong>on</strong> IdRR. Managers need to map the<br />

business processes which cause the most potential risk to their relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Trade-offs need<br />

to be made in terms of time <strong>and</strong> cost effectiveness. For instance, c<strong>on</strong>sider the Caterpillar<br />

<strong>and</strong> Linamar strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Linamar is an expert in “collaborative design,<br />

development <strong>and</strong> manufacture of precisi<strong>on</strong> metallic comp<strong>on</strong>ents, modules <strong>and</strong> systems for<br />

global vehicle markets” (Marketwire, 2007). Through their market-sensing mechanism<br />

Linamar has been able to c<strong>on</strong>siderably reduce Caterpillar’s IdRR <strong>and</strong> help them to maintain<br />

the quality they offer to the market. Likewise, Caterpillar has a “partners in quality”<br />

program by which it ensures regular interacti<strong>on</strong> with its key customers to facilitate the<br />

smooth flow of operati<strong>on</strong>s. To summarize, customer underst<strong>and</strong>ing is a key comp<strong>on</strong>ent to<br />

reducing IdRR <strong>and</strong> ensuring relati<strong>on</strong>al benefits.<br />

2.8.4 Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness as a Strategy for Sustainable Br<strong>and</strong> Equity<br />

Strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is an investment in creating idiosyncratic market-based<br />

assets. As illustrated by our model, strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness reduces IdRR. In turn,<br />

IdRR positively effects <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Hence, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is increased by<br />

idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk reducti<strong>on</strong>. From the <strong>buyer</strong>’s perspective, it is difficult to find an<br />

immediate replacement for the <strong>supplier</strong> because IdRR is reduced by the idiosyncratic<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>ses of the <strong>supplier</strong>. These are developed over time by the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> are unique.<br />

According to the resource-based view of the <strong>firm</strong>, assets that are inimitable, rare, valuable,<br />

lack perfect substitutes can be sources of competitive advantages for the <strong>firm</strong>. Following<br />

that line of thought, the br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> that is created for the <strong>supplier</strong> is a competitive<br />

resource. It is sustainable because of the difficulty that competitors would have in creating<br />

71


a similar offering. Hence, this locks the customer to the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> makes such br<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong> sustainable.<br />

2.9 Limitati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Future Directi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Many additi<strong>on</strong>al directi<strong>on</strong>s for future research can be suggested <strong>on</strong> the basis of the of the<br />

current research. The first <strong>and</strong> arguably the most fundamental limitati<strong>on</strong> deals with the<br />

research design. For instance, l<strong>on</strong>gitudinal managerial percepti<strong>on</strong> may not be c<strong>on</strong>sistent<br />

across the time period of measurement, which could imply that the relati<strong>on</strong>ships that we<br />

measured are not linear. The research design suggesti<strong>on</strong>s that future studies could utilize in<br />

order to improve up<strong>on</strong> our study are:<br />

L<strong>on</strong>gitudinal research design. Our cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al study allowed us to draw<br />

associati<strong>on</strong>s at best but not c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s about causality. To further improve this design,<br />

data collected for a time series analysis could allow the deducti<strong>on</strong> of evidence regarding<br />

causality. However, there has been some recent evidence that inferences from crosssecti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

studies about causality may not be much different from inferences about<br />

l<strong>on</strong>gitudinal studies (Rindfleisch et al., 2008).<br />

Limited sample of industries for depth. We traded off depth for width within our<br />

industry sectors. However, specific sectors may vary more with <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

than others. For instance, in the commodities industry, price may be more of a determining<br />

factor, whereas in the technical goods industrial sector the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>se may be a key<br />

determining factor as to whether relati<strong>on</strong>ships c<strong>on</strong>tinue. Future studies could c<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>on</strong><br />

a few sectors <strong>and</strong> check the robustness of our findings across various moderators, such as<br />

market turbulence <strong>and</strong> increased technological risk.<br />

Quasi-experimental design using financial <strong>and</strong> perceptual data in t<strong>and</strong>em. Prior<br />

studies of market orientati<strong>on</strong> have found c<strong>on</strong>flicts between objective <strong>and</strong> subjective<br />

measures of performance (Narver & Slater, 1990). To determine whether our findings<br />

actually reflect real financial market sentiments <strong>and</strong> accounting data, future studies can use<br />

financial data in t<strong>and</strong>em with perceptual data.<br />

Other additi<strong>on</strong>s which might be added to the prior suggesti<strong>on</strong>s include:<br />

Wider comparis<strong>on</strong> of measurement metrics. In the current study, we <strong>on</strong>ly use<br />

idiosyncratic risk, which within itself is a important indicator of the potential returns<br />

involved with any relati<strong>on</strong>ship. However, risk is not the sole metric in the literature. Future<br />

studies might include a wider array of metrics to examine which are better indicators than<br />

others <strong>and</strong> why. For instance, examining idiosyncratic risk in comparis<strong>on</strong> to inventory<br />

turnover metrics or debt leverage metrics could be an interesting avenue.<br />

Comparis<strong>on</strong> of more strategies with <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness for reducing<br />

idiosyncratic risk. We <strong>on</strong>ly examine <strong>on</strong>e strategy, which is market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a means of<br />

reducing idiosyncratic risk. However, there are other strategies <strong>and</strong> orientati<strong>on</strong>s, such as a<br />

technology orientati<strong>on</strong> or a market leadership strategy. The ways in which these strategies<br />

<strong>and</strong> orientati<strong>on</strong>s influence strategic <strong>supplier</strong>-<strong>buyer</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships <strong>and</strong> their idiosyncratic risk<br />

outcomes could be of potential interest.<br />

2.10 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

In summati<strong>on</strong>, we have empirically investigated a model that proposes a link between<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> cash flows in an inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>text. We<br />

have found that, to a certain extent, <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness indirectly affects <strong>buyer</strong><br />

cash flows through the moderating of IdRR <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Specifically, we<br />

found that market orientati<strong>on</strong> has a negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship with IdRR. This is an<br />

72


important finding because it provides counterintuitive evidence to the extant literature<br />

that market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> perceived risk are positively linked. Furthermore, being<br />

market oriented or resp<strong>on</strong>sive pays off for the <strong>supplier</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong> as their br<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong> increases. In additi<strong>on</strong>, we also found that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness influences<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, but <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does not have a relati<strong>on</strong>ship with their cash<br />

flows. This perspective reinforces prior studies’ findings that satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

performance do not have the same relati<strong>on</strong>ship as is comm<strong>on</strong>ly reported in the B2C<br />

literature.<br />

Future researchers could focus <strong>on</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong><br />

performance in other c<strong>on</strong>texts, such as cross-nati<strong>on</strong>al c<strong>on</strong>texts. Does the mediating<br />

role of IdRR hold in such c<strong>on</strong>texts? Or would it differ? Answering such questi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

would provide a better underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> the full spectrum under which a market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness strategy would yield best results. This has<br />

added significance in a time of recessi<strong>on</strong> when markets are under increased pressure<br />

to provide their managers with tangible marketing expenditure ROI (Bolt<strong>on</strong>, 2004).<br />

Moreover, it would also follow the c<strong>on</strong>cerns of some researchers, who state that<br />

models based <strong>on</strong> U.S. data need not st<strong>and</strong> for other countries (Hofstede, 1980). An<br />

additi<strong>on</strong>al pertinent questi<strong>on</strong> worth investigating would be whether our model would<br />

hold if subjective indicators are used. Another important research avenue is the<br />

moderating role of c<strong>on</strong>tract type in the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Since c<strong>on</strong>tracts are a staple means of governing relati<strong>on</strong>ships in B2B<br />

markets, it would be interesting to underst<strong>and</strong> how different c<strong>on</strong>tract types influence<br />

<strong>buyer</strong>s’ percepti<strong>on</strong>s of the usefulness of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. For example, do<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tracts that have stiff <strong>and</strong> steep penalty clauses reduce the influence of the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> performance, as the <strong>buyer</strong> expects nothing but the<br />

best? Or does it reduce the <strong>supplier</strong>’s willingness to be extremely resp<strong>on</strong>sive because<br />

they do not want to risk being penalized?<br />

The two major c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s from our current study are: First, <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is a mechanism that involves relati<strong>on</strong>al risk reducti<strong>on</strong>. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in strategic c<strong>on</strong>texts will not result in increased <strong>buyer</strong> profits. Hence,<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s should not rely up<strong>on</strong> it as an indicator of relati<strong>on</strong>al health.<br />

73


Chapter 3<br />

To Be or Not to Be? Does it Make Relati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong> Financial Sense<br />

to be a Resp<strong>on</strong>sive Strategic Supplier? An Internati<strong>on</strong>al Comparis<strong>on</strong><br />

Abstract<br />

This study investigates the role strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness plays in reducing<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al idiosyncratic risk <strong>and</strong> increasing customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, in two countries.<br />

The role of <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships as a metric varies across<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al cultures. However, the role of idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk as a metric<br />

remains c<strong>on</strong>stant. The findings will be of use to marketing managers <strong>and</strong> sales teams,<br />

who can use them for determining the degree of market orientati<strong>on</strong> they should<br />

implement to meet their customers’ needs. It will also help to identify those processes<br />

that make them more resp<strong>on</strong>sive in areas of key customer c<strong>on</strong>cern, thus increasing a<br />

<strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> enhancing <strong>buyer</strong> percepti<strong>on</strong>s about their br<strong>and</strong>. In the end, we<br />

discuss the managerial <strong>and</strong> academic implicati<strong>on</strong>s of the research.<br />

Keywords: <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, cross nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

comparis<strong>on</strong>s<br />

74


3.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong><br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, despite its limited natural resources, is <strong>on</strong> the forefr<strong>on</strong>t of world<br />

commerce, with companies such as Philips <strong>and</strong> Unilever to its credit. Furthermore,<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s is <strong>on</strong>e of the major trading partners of the United States of America<br />

("U.S. Trade Balance," 2012). It also happens to be <strong>on</strong>e of the largest foreign<br />

investors in the US ("Foreign Direct Investment," 2010). A large part of the Dutch<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omy is based <strong>on</strong> B2B trade. For example, they are the world’s third largest<br />

agricultural exporter, <strong>and</strong> they have the world’s seventh largest port <strong>and</strong> terminal<br />

facilities <strong>and</strong> Europe’s largest port (Nightingale, 2009; "Rotterdam’s Ec<strong>on</strong>omy,"<br />

2011).<br />

On the <strong>on</strong>e h<strong>and</strong>, there are important differences between the US <strong>and</strong> The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. U.S. attitudes, be they at the c<strong>on</strong>sumer level or the nati<strong>on</strong>al level, differ<br />

towards different issues. For instance, the US is more welcoming of foreign<br />

investments <strong>and</strong> less ecologically c<strong>on</strong>cerned than The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. Even the laws<br />

regulating corporate governance are different (ING, 2010). The c<strong>on</strong>sequence of the<br />

above menti<strong>on</strong>ed differences are that different markets require different marketing<br />

strategies <strong>and</strong> tactics. Therefore, in this chapter we will investigate whether the model<br />

proposed in Chapter 2 will yield similar results as it did in the last chapter.<br />

Table 3.1<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s Investment in the United States<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, in this era of c<strong>on</strong>vergence of dem<strong>and</strong> via globalizati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

many similarities now exist between customers or business partners in different<br />

countries, <strong>and</strong> many businesses create products that cater to the needs of global<br />

customers <strong>and</strong> cut across nati<strong>on</strong>al boundaries (Holt, Quelch, & Taylor, 2004). For<br />

example, Caterpillar’s c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> equipment <strong>and</strong> after-sales service <strong>and</strong> Intel’s<br />

ingredient br<strong>and</strong>ing strategy are product resp<strong>on</strong>ses that cater to the needs <strong>and</strong> wants of<br />

segments of customers across nati<strong>on</strong>al boundaries. Then, given the importance of The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States as two major trading partners <strong>and</strong> the individual<br />

<strong>firm</strong> level B2B relati<strong>on</strong>ships that make this trade possible, what is the role of<br />

idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk in <strong>firm</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships? On an abstract ec<strong>on</strong>omic level, at<br />

the start of the recent credit crisis, The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s was less affected when compared<br />

75


to other EU members because The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s is a competitive ec<strong>on</strong>omy as a result<br />

of its flexible labor market <strong>and</strong> limited dependency <strong>on</strong> foreign capital (Masselink &<br />

Noord, 2009). Other scholars argue the Dutch ec<strong>on</strong>omy is more prudent because of<br />

their culture (B.Dys<strong>on</strong>, pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong>, October, 2010). The Hofstede<br />

cultural index is a useful measure for marketing purposes to examine how to measure<br />

different nati<strong>on</strong>al cultures (Tellis, Prabhu, & Ch<strong>and</strong>y, 2009). Scores <strong>on</strong> the Hofstede<br />

index for the US <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s are very similar <strong>on</strong> many cultural dimensi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

However, prior research has provided some evidence to indicate that <strong>firm</strong>s act<br />

independently of some nati<strong>on</strong>al cultural traits (Tellis et al., 2009). This is important<br />

because findings in marketing academia from <strong>on</strong>e country may not be applicable to<br />

other counties with similar cultures. Hence, based <strong>on</strong> the importance of our findings<br />

in Chapter 2, a pertinent questi<strong>on</strong> to ask is whether the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong><br />

performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship will hold across nati<strong>on</strong>al cultures <strong>and</strong> borders.<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of this study is that we test the robustness of our previously<br />

developed c<strong>on</strong>ceptual model across nati<strong>on</strong>al borders in Chapter 2. We investigate<br />

whether the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship mediated by<br />

Idiosyncratic Relati<strong>on</strong>al Risk (IdRR) holds true across the different cultures we<br />

employ our model. Moreover, this study adds to the limited number of B2B market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> studies in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> sheds new light <strong>on</strong> the resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

mechanics in the Dutch c<strong>on</strong>text.<br />

3.1.1 Different Results of Studies of Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

the United States<br />

The impact of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance varies across the<br />

world (Ellis, 2006). Ellis (2006) used a meta-analysis to analyze 58 market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

studies. He finds that the managerial <strong>value</strong> of market orientati<strong>on</strong> diminished the<br />

str<strong>on</strong>ger a nati<strong>on</strong>al culture varied from U.S. culture. Furthermore, Ellis (2006) found<br />

that the United States had the str<strong>on</strong>gest effect size for market orientati<strong>on</strong> (r=0.36),<br />

followed by Western Europe (r= 0.25). The effect of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong><br />

performance is sizably higher in the United States than in Western Europe. In light of<br />

these variati<strong>on</strong>s in results in the impact of market orientati<strong>on</strong> across nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

boundaries <strong>and</strong> cultures, it is relevant for this study to examine the comparable<br />

existing studies of market orientati<strong>on</strong> in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States. This<br />

will allow us to underst<strong>and</strong> al<strong>on</strong>g which dimensi<strong>on</strong>s prior studies have differed <strong>and</strong><br />

possibly give us insights into how our sample from The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United<br />

States may differ. The following five studies represent some of the important<br />

comparable research that exists.<br />

The first study by Langerak (2003) finds in a sample of <strong>firm</strong>s from The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s that market orientati<strong>on</strong> influences organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance <strong>and</strong> is<br />

mediated by a differentiati<strong>on</strong> strategy but not a low cost strategy. A differentiati<strong>on</strong><br />

strategy <strong>and</strong> a low cost strategy are two important generic positi<strong>on</strong>ing strategies<br />

(Langerak, 2003). To the c<strong>on</strong>trary, a study in the United States by Narver <strong>and</strong> Slater<br />

(1990) provides evidence that both a differentiati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> a low cost strategy are<br />

positively influenced by market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Furthermore, Narver <strong>and</strong> Slater (1990)<br />

find that market orientati<strong>on</strong> positively influences organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

effect is channeled through a differentiati<strong>on</strong> strategy <strong>and</strong> a low cost strategy. One of<br />

the limitati<strong>on</strong>s of Langerak’s (2003) study was the small size of the <strong>firm</strong>s in the<br />

sample, with 76% of the <strong>firm</strong>s having fewer than 200 employees. This leaves open the<br />

76


possibility that <strong>firm</strong> size may influence the outcomes of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly,<br />

as his sample is mainly from the medical <strong>and</strong> electr<strong>on</strong>ics industry, it is also possible<br />

that the results may vary across industries. To address these shortcomings in the<br />

current study, we use a sample with a greater variati<strong>on</strong> of industries <strong>and</strong> a larger<br />

number of employees.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d to fourth studies in our literature synthesis are by Langerak,<br />

Hultink, <strong>and</strong> Robben. In their first study, Langerak, Hultink, <strong>and</strong> Robben (2004b) find<br />

in a sample from The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s that market orientati<strong>on</strong> has an insignificant,<br />

positive, direct effect <strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance. However, they do find that<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> has an indirect, positive effect <strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance,<br />

channeled in the following order: (1) market orientati<strong>on</strong> positively influences strategic<br />

planning <strong>and</strong> idea generati<strong>on</strong>; (2) strategic planning <strong>and</strong> idea generati<strong>on</strong> positively<br />

influence new product development, <strong>and</strong>; (3) new product development positively<br />

influences market orientati<strong>on</strong>. In a sec<strong>on</strong>d study, Langerak, Hultink, <strong>and</strong> Robben<br />

(2007) investigate the mediating role of new product development between market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance. They test three structural equati<strong>on</strong><br />

models with varying results. In their first model they achieve a poor structural fit;<br />

however, in c<strong>on</strong>trast to their 2004 study (Langerak et al., 2004b) they find that market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> has a direct positive influence <strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance. A poor<br />

structural fit indicates that the model is misspecified (Hair, Anders<strong>on</strong>, Tatham, &<br />

Black, 2006). This implies that the model may not be theoretically justified, as the<br />

observed data does not fit the hypothetical model. The final model that Langerak et al.<br />

(2007) test show a good fit, but it <strong>on</strong>ly includes an indirect effect of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance channeled through new product<br />

development mediators. In essence, their findings suggest that a direct effect of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance is not supported. In their third<br />

study, Langerak, Hultink, <strong>and</strong> Robben (2004a) find in a sample of Dutch <strong>firm</strong>s that<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> does not directly positively influence organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance,<br />

but rather it does so indirectly through NPD activities. The findings of these three<br />

studies are inc<strong>on</strong>sistent with prior studies that used U.S. samples (Slater & Narver,<br />

1994; Pelham & Wils<strong>on</strong>, 1996). These studies provide some evidence that the process<br />

of market orientati<strong>on</strong> in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s indirectly influences <strong>firm</strong> performance via<br />

new product development mediators, whereas results from other studies suggest that<br />

in the United States both direct <strong>and</strong> indirect effects exist (Han, Kim, & Srivastava,<br />

1998; Slater & Narver, 1994).<br />

In the fifth study of our literature synthesis, Verhees <strong>and</strong> Meulenberg (2004)<br />

split the c<strong>on</strong>struct of market orientati<strong>on</strong> into two comp<strong>on</strong>ents, behavioral market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> attitudinal market orientati<strong>on</strong>. They find that in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s,<br />

behavioral market orientati<strong>on</strong> does directly <strong>and</strong> positively influence <strong>firm</strong><br />

performance, whereas attitudinal market orientati<strong>on</strong> does not. C<strong>on</strong>sistent with<br />

previous studies menti<strong>on</strong>ed above, they do find that the overall c<strong>on</strong>struct of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> does influence organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance through the mediator of<br />

product innovati<strong>on</strong>. Their findings may not be generalizable to all organizati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

within The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, as they <strong>on</strong>ly study small enterprises within the flower<br />

market.<br />

The above studies provide some evidence that the pathway from market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> to organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance differs in the United States <strong>and</strong> The<br />

77


Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. Moreover, the above studies are all from the intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

perspective <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>e are from the inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al perspective. In light of the<br />

important findings of Chapter 2 from the <strong>buyer</strong>’s perspective, regarding the role of<br />

IdRR, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> as moderators of the <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship, it is pertinent to<br />

examine whether those findings will hold across nati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

3.1.2 Cultural C<strong>on</strong>text<br />

There are a number of theories that describe nati<strong>on</strong>al culture within the marketing <strong>and</strong><br />

management literatures, <strong>and</strong> the Hofstede index is <strong>on</strong>e of the most widely used<br />

(Hofstede, 1980; Hofstede, 1984; House, Javidan, Hanges, & Dorfman, 2002;<br />

Schwartz, 1994; Trompenaars, 1994). The Hofstede index is based <strong>on</strong> IBM data<br />

collected from 82 countries. This makes the Hofstede index the largest index in terms<br />

of the number of countries from which data is collected <strong>and</strong> the most widely used <strong>on</strong>e.<br />

There are other indexes, such as Schwartz, which uses data from 31 countries; the<br />

globe framework, which uses data from 58 countries; <strong>and</strong> Trompenaars’s framework,<br />

which uses data from 54 countries. Furthermore, the Hofstede index is based <strong>on</strong> IBM<br />

data, <strong>and</strong> IBM acquires a substantial percentage of its revenues from B2B activities.<br />

Because of the Hofstede index’s widespread use as an index in the marketing<br />

literature, we use it as an explanatory framework in this paper, but we do not<br />

specifically test any of its dimensi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

To compare the United States <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, we first need to<br />

underst<strong>and</strong> the nati<strong>on</strong>al cultures of both countries <strong>and</strong> how they affect decisi<strong>on</strong>making.<br />

The Hofstede index was initially composed of four dimensi<strong>on</strong>s, namely,<br />

power distance, uncertainty avoidance, masculinity-femininity, <strong>and</strong> individualismcollectivism<br />

(Hofstede, 1984). A fifth dimensi<strong>on</strong>, l<strong>on</strong>g-term orientati<strong>on</strong>, was later<br />

added when it was observed that in some Asian cultures uncertainty avoidance was<br />

not a suitable measure (Hofstede & B<strong>on</strong>d, 1988). As is reflected in Figure 3.1 below,<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States are similar <strong>on</strong> all dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

culture except masculinity-femininity. The United States is a masculine culture,<br />

whereas The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s is a feminine culture. This implies that managers within the<br />

United States should be competitive, be ambitious when it comes to career<br />

aspirati<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> that there is general difference when it comes to gender roles, with<br />

fewer women present in upper management. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s,<br />

managers are expected to be competitive, yet they can use their intuiti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> gut<br />

feeling while reaching decisi<strong>on</strong>s. Managers are expected to have modest career<br />

ambiti<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> there is more gender egalitarianism within organizati<strong>on</strong>s (Hofstede,<br />

2001, p.318).<br />

78


Figure 3.1<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> United States Compared <strong>on</strong> the Hofstede Dimensi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

3.1.3 C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to Chapter 2<br />

The model described in Chapter 2 makes a c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the literature by providing<br />

evidence that market orientati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is negatively related to<br />

IdRR. However, since the model has <strong>on</strong>ly been based <strong>on</strong> US data, it remains to be<br />

tested whether that model is applicable to cross-cultural c<strong>on</strong>texts. For any theory to be<br />

generalizable, it has to be applicable in a wide variety of situati<strong>on</strong>s. Our current study<br />

builds <strong>on</strong> the research presented in Chapter 2 by testing it across two nati<strong>on</strong>s. We find<br />

that the main hypothesis <strong>and</strong> theoretical c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> regarding the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-<br />

Idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk-performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship holds true across nati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

However, we find that there is a difference in soft relati<strong>on</strong>al indicators of <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. We explain these differences in light of the Hofstede index, suggesting<br />

that nati<strong>on</strong>al culture may moderate the soft indicator-performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship. In<br />

sum, the current paper validates the main findings of the Chapter 2 model by<br />

providing some evidence that IdRR matters across nati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

3.1.4 Hypotheses Generati<strong>on</strong><br />

Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> IdRR. The influence of a <strong>firm</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>firm</strong> performance transcends borders, <strong>and</strong> evidence of it exists in countries other than<br />

the United States, such as The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (Langerak, Hultink, & Robben, 2004a;<br />

Langerak, Hultink & Robben, 2004b; Langerak, Hultink, & Robben, 2007). These<br />

prior studies have also hypothesized that the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship is mediated by NPD activities (Han et al., 1998; Langerak et al., 2004a;<br />

Langerak et al., 2004b; Langerak et al., 2007). However, in the light of some of these<br />

studies, market orientati<strong>on</strong> seems to have similar outcomes in the United States <strong>and</strong><br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. Furthermore, as discussed earlier, the nati<strong>on</strong>al risk averseness of<br />

79


The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s is similar to the United States. Therefore, we expect that market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> will have a similar impact <strong>on</strong> IdRR in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United<br />

States.<br />

H1: Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness negatively influences idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk, both in the USA <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is a process of<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> evaluati<strong>on</strong> in hindsight. After a comprehensive literature review of satisfacti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

we did not come across any studies that specifically suggest that the process of<br />

cerebral satisfacti<strong>on</strong> evaluati<strong>on</strong> varied because of culture. However, some studies did<br />

suggest the level of satisfacti<strong>on</strong> varied across nati<strong>on</strong>s; for instance, job satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

between employees in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Spain (Carb<strong>on</strong>ell & Praag, 2006).<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States when compared <strong>on</strong> the project global<br />

leadership <strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al behavior effectiveness cultural index (GLOBE), differ<br />

significantly <strong>on</strong> two important dimensi<strong>on</strong>s (House et al., 2002). These are<br />

assertiveness <strong>and</strong> performance orientati<strong>on</strong>. US managers are more assertive <strong>and</strong><br />

performance oriented than Dutch managers (House et al., 2002). By that logic then,<br />

hard performance indicators should matter more in the US than soft indicators such as<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. Furthermore, this does not imply that there is a difference in the cerebral<br />

process by which managers or customers in different countries make evaluative<br />

judgments, such as satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, because human beings from diverse ethnic<br />

backgrounds have the same biological cerebral capabilities <strong>and</strong> thought processes<br />

(Zaltman, 2003). Human beings, however, differ al<strong>on</strong>g the lines of their cultural<br />

interpretati<strong>on</strong> of informati<strong>on</strong> (Hofstede, 1980). This is because cultures are the<br />

collective mental programming of the envir<strong>on</strong>ment. As the envir<strong>on</strong>ment changes from<br />

<strong>on</strong>e nati<strong>on</strong> to another so do the elements of collective mental programming change<br />

(Hofstede, 1980). These changes result in different nati<strong>on</strong>al cultures.<br />

In terms of <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, there is no evidence within the extant literature<br />

that the cerebral process of purchase evaluati<strong>on</strong> differs across nati<strong>on</strong>s, but there is<br />

evidence to suggest that the criteria against which customers evaluate purchases<br />

differ. These can be attributed to changes because of nati<strong>on</strong>al culture. For instance, in<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Germany, greater formality in business communicati<strong>on</strong>s would<br />

be expected in c<strong>on</strong>trast to business transacti<strong>on</strong>s within the United States. A lack of<br />

such formality could lead to customer dissatisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> cause problems in strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships. Further, satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships can vary because<br />

of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>se (Chapter 2), <strong>and</strong> the influence of the <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>se <strong>on</strong><br />

the intensity of satisfacti<strong>on</strong> varies because of cultural factors. For example, retail<br />

br<strong>and</strong> Tanoli from The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>value</strong>s European-based strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s more<br />

because their resp<strong>on</strong>ses meet the current fashi<strong>on</strong> trends or supply market offerings<br />

that anticipate latent fashi<strong>on</strong> trends. On a different note, American <strong>supplier</strong>s are<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>sive in certain dimensi<strong>on</strong>s, such as delivery time <strong>and</strong> payment dates but not in<br />

areas such as customizati<strong>on</strong> of designs. This difference is because fashi<strong>on</strong> trends vary<br />

in the United States as compared to Europe. United States <strong>supplier</strong>s provide resp<strong>on</strong>ses<br />

based <strong>on</strong> their own cultural envir<strong>on</strong>ment, whereas the trends in Europe are diverse<br />

<strong>and</strong> more differentiated. This results in significant <strong>buyer</strong> dissatisfacti<strong>on</strong> for retailers in<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (Tanoli, pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong>, 2010). In both situati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>supplier</strong>s<br />

are resp<strong>on</strong>sive, but not all acti<strong>on</strong>s of resp<strong>on</strong>siveness c<strong>on</strong>tribute to <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

When a <strong>buyer</strong> forms a strategic partnership with a <strong>supplier</strong>, they have reached a<br />

80


comprehensive agreement <strong>on</strong> each other’s requirements. Hence, strategic <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>ses should generate <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> across The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> United<br />

States. Therefore:<br />

H2: Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness positively influences <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, both in<br />

USA <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

In the extant marketing literature, the hypothesized relati<strong>on</strong>ship between<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance has focused <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. Various<br />

measures such as loyalty, increased product usage levels, secure future revenues, <strong>and</strong><br />

increased customer percepti<strong>on</strong>s of quality are positively related to customer<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. However, this is evidence from a B2C setting <strong>and</strong> the role of customer<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in B2B relati<strong>on</strong>ships is disputed. In B2C c<strong>on</strong>texts, an individual’s<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> reflects their own experience with the product <strong>and</strong> will likely influence<br />

their future purchase intenti<strong>on</strong>s. In a B2B setting, the purchase center does not<br />

directly have any experience with the product <strong>and</strong> may have a number of indicators to<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sider besides satisfacti<strong>on</strong> reports while making the purchase decisi<strong>on</strong> (Kotler,<br />

Armstr<strong>on</strong>g, Saunders, & W<strong>on</strong>g 2008, p.292). Another c<strong>on</strong>trast with the B2C<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> measurement is that in large buying centers, often the purchasers even<br />

lack direct c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> experience (Kotler et al., 2008, p.292).<br />

Because of differences like these, Naray<strong>and</strong>as (2005) is of the opini<strong>on</strong> that<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does not have the same influence <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> profitability or customer loyalty<br />

in B2B markets as it does in B2C markets. However, from a cultural perspective,<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> may have a different importance in different societies. C<strong>on</strong>sider the<br />

example of The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States. The positi<strong>on</strong> of The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

<strong>on</strong> the Hofstede index is similar to that of the United States, except <strong>on</strong> their cultural<br />

dimensi<strong>on</strong> of masculinity. The US represents a masculine society, where there is less<br />

emphasis up<strong>on</strong> caring for others as compared with more feminine countries such as<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. It then could be argued that intangible indicators such as satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

would have more influence in feminine societies than in masculine <strong>on</strong>es, because in<br />

such cultures soft or feminine indicators <strong>and</strong> behaviors matter more (Hofstede, 1998,<br />

pp.4-27). At the macro level this difference between masculine <strong>and</strong> feminine societies<br />

can also be observed by the amount of m<strong>on</strong>ey they give to charity. Feminine societies<br />

give more than masculine societies, <strong>and</strong> this reflects their compassi<strong>on</strong> for humanity<br />

(Hofstede, 1998, pp.4-27). Furthermore, masculine countries are more m<strong>on</strong>etary<br />

oriented than feminine <strong>on</strong>es. In masculine countries, employees generally would opt<br />

for higher salaries compared to shorter working hours, whereas in feminine countries<br />

the opposite holds true (Hofstede, 1998, pp.4-27). Hence, we would expect that within<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>s in feminine countries like The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s relati<strong>on</strong>al indicators such as<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> would matter more than in masculine countries like the United States.<br />

Another reas<strong>on</strong> could be the homogeneity in society. Since the US is a heterogeneous<br />

society, the emphasis of a soft metric such as satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the overall purchase<br />

decisi<strong>on</strong> could be less direct, resulting in diverse expectati<strong>on</strong>s. Hence, in the United<br />

States, focusing <strong>on</strong> performance-based measures could possibly provide clarity to<br />

channel partners about customer expectati<strong>on</strong>s when compared with relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

performance factors. The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, more cultural homogeneity could imply that<br />

soft cultural factors such as satisfacti<strong>on</strong> would have <strong>on</strong> the <strong>firm</strong> level performance.<br />

Hence, we expect the following hypotheses across countries:<br />

81


H3: Buyer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> positively influences <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> more str<strong>on</strong>gly<br />

in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s than in the United States.<br />

Idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Some aspects of an<br />

individual’s risk-taking behavior are influenced by their nati<strong>on</strong>al culture. One<br />

example of this is the popular cushi<strong>on</strong> hypothesis (Weber & Hsee, 1999). Individual<br />

investors take more risk if they feel that their collectivist society will take care of<br />

them if things were to go wr<strong>on</strong>g (Weber & Hsee, 1999). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, in<br />

societies that are individualistic, investors will take less risk because no <strong>on</strong>e is there to<br />

bail them out in case things go wr<strong>on</strong>g (Weber & Hsee, 1999). Indeed, nati<strong>on</strong>al culture<br />

does matter when individuals are making decisi<strong>on</strong>s with regards to risk (Weber &<br />

Hsee, 1999). Nati<strong>on</strong>al culture also influences their risk preference. The Dutch shoe<br />

manufacturer Van Bommel is a case in point. They offer a fifteen-year guarantee with<br />

every high quality pair of shoes, yet they chose the slightly costlier opti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

producing in the UK rather than in China or Portugal, because of quality c<strong>on</strong>cerns <strong>and</strong><br />

risk avoidance. Many other high quality manufacturers do produce in Portugal (Zara)<br />

<strong>and</strong> China (Apple). But Van Bommel’s decisi<strong>on</strong> is a case of traditi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

manufacturers’ c<strong>on</strong>cerns leading them to what they perceive to be a safe decisi<strong>on</strong><br />

(Dys<strong>on</strong>, pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong>, 2010).<br />

As risk preferences vary across nati<strong>on</strong>s, it would follow in turn that customer’s<br />

risk preference would influence their preference of channel partners. Some managers<br />

may prefer riskier business partners because of the potential higher fluctuati<strong>on</strong> in<br />

profits. Others may want more stability in their earnings (Weber & Hsee, 1999).<br />

Although much research exists <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer br<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> risk preference<br />

(Erdem, Zhao, & Valenzuela, 2004; Mitchell, 1999), there is limited research in the<br />

B2B br<strong>and</strong>ing domain <strong>on</strong> the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between B2B br<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> risk. Our literature<br />

search revealed limited evidence in the marketing literature available <strong>on</strong> risk-taking<br />

behavior, buying centers, <strong>and</strong> br<strong>and</strong> preferences. However, we did find <strong>on</strong>e B2B<br />

br<strong>and</strong>ing text that dealt with the issue by Kotler <strong>and</strong> Pfoertsch (2006, p.9). They<br />

indicate that B2B br<strong>and</strong> functi<strong>on</strong>ality is negatively related to customer risk. Therefore,<br />

we expect:<br />

H4: Idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk negatively influences <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> in<br />

the USA <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Supplier br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. A <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is likely<br />

to have a spillover effect <strong>on</strong> a <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> future <strong>value</strong> if they add unique <strong>value</strong> to the<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>. For instance, Ghosh <strong>and</strong> John (2009) found that the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> was<br />

more likely to be preferred in the future when the <strong>supplier</strong>’s comp<strong>on</strong>ents added<br />

unique <strong>value</strong> to the <strong>buyer</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong>. Such unique <strong>value</strong> has a financial dimensi<strong>on</strong> for<br />

the <strong>buyer</strong> through increased marketplace performance. Intel is a stellar example of<br />

such a strategy, <strong>and</strong> it has a spillover <strong>on</strong> any product it is a comp<strong>on</strong>ent of (Whitwell,<br />

2005). C<strong>on</strong>sider NutraSweet, whose patent ran out but is still able to charge a<br />

premium for its br<strong>and</strong> because of the public c<strong>on</strong>fidence in NutraSweet. C<strong>on</strong>sumers are<br />

willing to pay more for products with NutraSweet logos or as an ingredient (Norris,<br />

1992). Other examples of <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> which add <strong>value</strong> to the customers br<strong>and</strong><br />

include Dup<strong>on</strong>t with nyl<strong>on</strong> for clothes, Rayth<strong>on</strong>’s Lycra <strong>and</strong> Good Year tires <strong>on</strong><br />

Adidas shoe soles. Harvard Business School professor Jack Quelch describes it best in<br />

a rhetorical questi<strong>on</strong>:<br />

82


Why do we pay more for an orange with a Sunkist sticker? Because inspecting<br />

the outside of the orange doesn’t guarantee the quality of what’s inside. We<br />

need the assurance of the Sunkist br<strong>and</strong>. A variant <strong>on</strong> this theme is ingredient<br />

br<strong>and</strong>ing: putting the br<strong>and</strong> of an ingredient <strong>on</strong> the outside of a product to<br />

increase its appeal (Quelch, 2007, para 1).<br />

One thing that is comm<strong>on</strong> to all these br<strong>and</strong>s is that they are global br<strong>and</strong>s<br />

with their origins in the United States. They all sell well within The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

After a comprehensive literature search, we could find no evidence to suggest that a<br />

spillover effect of being associated with a <strong>supplier</strong>s’ br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> does not occur<br />

within The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. Therefore, we expect the following hypothesis:<br />

H5: Supplier br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> positively influences a <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>’s <strong>value</strong> in the<br />

USA <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

3.2 Methodology<br />

3.2.1 Sample Descripti<strong>on</strong><br />

The data for this study were collected in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States in the<br />

year 2009. As is reflected by Table 3.2, both samples’ descriptive statistics are<br />

similar. The type of market from which data was collected in the USA had 49% of the<br />

<strong>firm</strong>s catering to both industrial <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets, whereas in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

the figure was 41.7%. Firms operating exclusively in industrial markets in the USA<br />

were 18.7%, whereas in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s the figure was 35.5%. Firms operating<br />

solely in c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets in the USA were 32.3%, <strong>and</strong> the figure for The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s was 33.3%. We collected sample resp<strong>on</strong>ses from industrial <strong>buyer</strong>s in<br />

both countries. The average number of years of buying experience in the USA was<br />

9.72 years, <strong>and</strong> strategic buying experience was 7.36 years, whereas in The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, the average buying experience was 7.56 years <strong>and</strong> strategic buying<br />

experience was 5.96 years. The percentage of resp<strong>on</strong>dents from upper management in<br />

the USA was 30.9%, <strong>and</strong> middle management was 53.1%, <strong>and</strong> 16% were <strong>firm</strong><br />

employees, whereas in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s the percentage of resp<strong>on</strong>dents from upper<br />

management was 20.8%, <strong>and</strong> 55.2% were from middle management, <strong>and</strong> 24% were<br />

<strong>firm</strong> employees. The type of <strong>firm</strong> market offerings in the USA was 35.4% for servicebased,<br />

23.1% for goods-based, <strong>and</strong> 41.5% for both goods <strong>and</strong> service-based market<br />

offering. In The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 46.9% was service-based market offering, 21.9% was<br />

goods-based <strong>and</strong> 31.2% for both goods <strong>and</strong> service-based market offering.<br />

83


Table 3.2<br />

Descriptive Statistics<br />

USA<br />

Sample Descripti<strong>on</strong><br />

n=164 Resp<strong>on</strong>se Rate = 6%<br />

Type of Market<br />

Percentage<br />

Industrial <strong>and</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumer Markets 49<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Markets 32.3<br />

Industrial Markets 18.7<br />

Number of Years of Buying Experience<br />

Years<br />

Average Buying Experience 9.72<br />

Average Strategic Buying Experience 7.36<br />

Level of Management<br />

Percentage<br />

Upper Management 30.9<br />

Middle Management 53.1<br />

Type of Market Offering<br />

Percentage<br />

Service-Based Market offering 35.4<br />

Goods-Based Market offering 23.1<br />

Goods <strong>and</strong> Service-Based Market offering 41.5<br />

Sample Descripti<strong>on</strong><br />

n=92 Resp<strong>on</strong>se Rate=3%<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Type of Market<br />

Percentage<br />

Industrial <strong>and</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumer Markets 41.7<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Markets 33.3<br />

Industrial Markets 36.5<br />

Number of Years of Buying Experience<br />

Years<br />

Average Buying Experience 7.56<br />

Average Strategic Buying Experience 5.96<br />

Level of Management<br />

Percentage<br />

Upper Management 20.8<br />

Middle Management 55.2<br />

Type of Market Offering<br />

Percentage<br />

Service-Based Market offering 46.9<br />

Goods-Based Market offering 21.9<br />

Goods <strong>and</strong> Service-Based Market offering 31.2<br />

3.2.2 Variables<br />

We checked for regi<strong>on</strong>al variati<strong>on</strong>s in the definiti<strong>on</strong>s of the original model.<br />

We first comprehensively searched the literature for different definiti<strong>on</strong>s of the five<br />

84


c<strong>on</strong>structs, for cross-cultural factors. We could find n<strong>on</strong>e specific to The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

We then proceeded to informally discuss with academics <strong>and</strong> practiti<strong>on</strong>ers/industry<br />

specialists about their interpretati<strong>on</strong>s of each of the five variables’ definiti<strong>on</strong>s. The<br />

results are discussed below.<br />

Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. The definiti<strong>on</strong> provided in Chapter 2 was<br />

“accumulative market resp<strong>on</strong>se generated by internal <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong> processes to meet<br />

their <strong>buyer</strong> needs.” This definiti<strong>on</strong> is based <strong>on</strong> a synthesis of the definiti<strong>on</strong>s of Kohli<br />

<strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) <strong>and</strong> Narver <strong>and</strong> Slater (1990) of the c<strong>on</strong>cept of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>. However, from our discussi<strong>on</strong>s with fellow academics three major themes<br />

occurred. First, a <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness includes a market offering comp<strong>on</strong>ent<br />

(goods <strong>and</strong> services). The sec<strong>on</strong>d comp<strong>on</strong>ent was the speed of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se or timeliness. The third comp<strong>on</strong>ent was market intelligence sharing<br />

exemplified by activities such as potential market lead sharing. These c<strong>on</strong>cepts<br />

c<strong>on</strong>verge with our definiti<strong>on</strong>; therefore, we used the original survey scale for <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness employed in Chapter 2. Chapter 2 used the MARKOR scale<br />

developed by Kohli et al. (1993) for our analysis. Since the purpose of this chapter is<br />

to test whether the model in Chapter 2 applies in different markets.<br />

Idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk. The definiti<strong>on</strong> provided in Chapter 2 was “the<br />

risk which exists because of entering into a specific relati<strong>on</strong>ship with another<br />

company.” This definiti<strong>on</strong> was postulated because of the c<strong>on</strong>fluence of two<br />

perspectives, namely: financial market underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the c<strong>on</strong>cept of idiosyncratic<br />

risk <strong>and</strong> management perspective of <strong>supplier</strong> risk (Sharpe, 1964; Krajlic, 1983).<br />

Central to this c<strong>on</strong>cept is the tenet that idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk is avoidable by<br />

preempting the risk via marketing measures the <strong>supplier</strong> enacts. Our informal<br />

discussi<strong>on</strong>s with fellow academics <strong>and</strong> peers reinforced the face validity of the scales<br />

used in Chapter 2 for relati<strong>on</strong>al idiosyncratic risk measurement in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

Therefore, we used the scales used in Chapter 2.<br />

Buyer satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. Chapter 2 defined <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as “an overall<br />

evaluati<strong>on</strong> based <strong>on</strong> the total purchase <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumpti<strong>on</strong> experience with a good or<br />

service over time” (Anders<strong>on</strong>, Fornell, & Lehmann, 1994). They include both<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in their c<strong>on</strong>ceptualizati<strong>on</strong>. Our informal<br />

discussi<strong>on</strong>s reinforced this underst<strong>and</strong>ing, <strong>and</strong> therefore, we used the same scale for<br />

this paper. We used the four items the original scale used in Chapter 2. These were<br />

adapted from the original satisfacti<strong>on</strong> scale used by Ruekert <strong>and</strong> Churchill (1984).<br />

Supplier br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. The <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is defined in Chapter 2 from<br />

the perspective of the strategic buying center team as the shared collective memories<br />

about the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong>, which provide it leverage that it would otherwise not have<br />

without the br<strong>and</strong>. Therefore, we used the two original items developed in Chapter 2.<br />

There was no difference in our underst<strong>and</strong>ing of <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> from the<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cept in the literature.<br />

Buyer <strong>firm</strong> future <strong>value</strong>. Buyer <strong>firm</strong> future <strong>value</strong> is computed by a single<br />

measure that is composed of volatility <strong>and</strong> variability in the future cash flows because<br />

of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>. The informal discussi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> literature review lead us to<br />

believe that volatility <strong>and</strong> variability in <strong>buyer</strong> cash flows are important measures for<br />

measuring <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> in both the United States <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. The items<br />

used in this chapter for measuring the c<strong>on</strong>structs are the same as those in Chapter 2.<br />

Please refer to Table 2.18 for the items used <strong>and</strong> the codes.<br />

85


3.2.3 Normality of Data<br />

Table 3.3 presents the results for the normality of the distributi<strong>on</strong> of the variables in<br />

our model based <strong>on</strong> the Dutch data. As recommended by Baumgartner <strong>and</strong> Homburg<br />

(1996), we first c<strong>on</strong>ducted tests of normality <strong>on</strong> our data. We found that two variables<br />

in our data SIQ <strong>and</strong> RP did exhibit skewness. The criteria we used to assess for<br />

skewness <strong>and</strong> kurtosis was whether the skewness or kurtosis ratio to its respective<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ard error was less than 2 (Bachman, 2004, p. 74). We transformed SIQ <strong>and</strong> RP<br />

variables by taking their square root computed by SPSS 17, under the compute new<br />

variable tab. The result was that the new computed variables SIQ <strong>and</strong> RP were<br />

normally distributed.<br />

Table 3.3<br />

Kurtosis <strong>and</strong> Skewness<br />

N Mean Std. Dev Skewness Kurtosis<br />

Stat Stat Stat Stat Std.<br />

Error<br />

Ratio<br />

1**<br />

Stat<br />

Std.<br />

Error<br />

Ratio<br />

2**<br />

SIQ 92 2.27 0.77 0.51 0.25 2.04 0.92 0.50 1.86<br />

CustNPD 92 2.35 0.84 0.38 0.25 1.52 0.20 0.50 0.41<br />

CF 92 2.49 0.76 -0.04 0.25 -0.15 -0.31 0.50 -0.62<br />

RP 92 2.11 0.91 0.77 0.25 3.08 0.85 0.50 1.71<br />

Fairness 92 2.30 0.77 0.46 0.25 1.84 0.87 0.50 1.75<br />

SALES 92 2.30 0.82 0.35 0.25 1.39 0.35 0.50 0.69<br />

IM 92 3.53 0.88 -0.20 0.25 -0.79 0.28 0.50 0.56<br />

CCC 92 3.51 0.83 -0.15 0.25 -0.61 0.67 0.50 1.35<br />

AssBr<strong>and</strong> 92 2.27 0.80 0.26 0.25 1.02 0.40 0.50 0.80<br />

BV 92 2.33 0.70 0.01 0.25 0.05 -0.22 0.50 -0.44<br />

SIQ (***) 92 1.48 0.26 -0.08 0.25 -0.33 0.26 0.50 0.51<br />

RP (***) 92 1.41 0.39 0.22 0.25 0.88 -0.39 0.48 -0.62<br />

***SIQ <strong>and</strong> RP. SIQ <strong>and</strong> RP are transformed by taking the square root of SIQ <strong>and</strong> RP in order to<br />

correct for the skewness of both variables.<br />

**The Ratio 1 column represents the skewness statistic to its st<strong>and</strong>ard error ratio. The ratio 2 column<br />

represents the kurtosis statistic to its st<strong>and</strong>ard error ratio. Each ratio <strong>value</strong> should be less than 2 in<br />

absolute <strong>value</strong>.<br />

3.2.4 SEM<br />

We estimated two SEM models in our analysis for comparis<strong>on</strong> with the model in<br />

chapter 2. The reas<strong>on</strong> we estimated two models is because of the rule that a 10<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>dents are required per measured item in a SEM model (Hair et al., 2006, p.<br />

604). Our sample size of 92 resp<strong>on</strong>dents <strong>and</strong> 10 observed variables did not let us meet<br />

that ratio. Our sec<strong>on</strong>d model in this chapter labeled Model 2 c<strong>on</strong>sists of the variables<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, IdRR, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Our third<br />

model in this chapter labeled Model 3 c<strong>on</strong>sists of the variables <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. For a large model with 10<br />

observed variables we normally should have about 150-200 resp<strong>on</strong>dents <strong>and</strong><br />

recommended of 10 resp<strong>on</strong>dents per item (Hair et al, 2006, p. 604). The two models<br />

(2 <strong>and</strong> 3) fulfill the criteria of 10 resp<strong>on</strong>dents per item. In the rest of this secti<strong>on</strong> we<br />

86


will discuss the SEM analysis of these two models. We present the models’ goodness<br />

of fit statistics <strong>and</strong> hypotheses results in Table 3.4.<br />

3.2.4.1 Model 1<br />

Model 1 is a replica of the model in Chapter 2. However, as it does not fulfill the<br />

criteria of 10 resp<strong>on</strong>dents per variable we have tested it in two smaller models called<br />

models 2 <strong>and</strong> 3. Therefore we do no discuss Model 1 in further detail in this chapter.<br />

For details of the fit statistics <strong>and</strong> hypotheses tests please refer to Table 3.4 of this<br />

chapter.<br />

3.2.4.2 Model 2<br />

We have <strong>on</strong>e exogenous c<strong>on</strong>struct, which is <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. We have three<br />

endogenous c<strong>on</strong>structs, IdRR, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. We then<br />

tested for unidimensi<strong>on</strong>ality. Thus the current model has a total of 8 items. Moreover,<br />

our results indicated that our factors load <strong>on</strong> more than <strong>on</strong>e factor, <strong>and</strong> therefore,<br />

unidimensi<strong>on</strong>ality is not a c<strong>on</strong>cern in the current study.<br />

In the next stage of our research we determined the input matrix type <strong>and</strong><br />

estimated the proposed model. We chose the covariance matrix because it is a true test<br />

of theory (Hair et al., 2006 p.603). The correlati<strong>on</strong> matrix is not suited for theory<br />

testing as it <strong>on</strong>ly represents the pattern of relati<strong>on</strong>ships. We used the maximum<br />

likelihood estimati<strong>on</strong> method <strong>and</strong> our sample size of 92 was slightly below the<br />

recommended 100-150 (Hair et al., 2006, p 605). In AMOS, we also selected<br />

covariance supplied <strong>and</strong> to be analyzed as the maximum likelihood opti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> we<br />

selected the opti<strong>on</strong> r<strong>and</strong>om permutati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Further, we estimated our structural model in AMOS. Model identificati<strong>on</strong> is<br />

measured by the difference between the number of distinct sample moments (36) <strong>and</strong><br />

the distinct parameters to be estimated (16). The resulting degrees of freedom are 20,<br />

indicating that the model has been identified. We achieved a good model fit <strong>and</strong><br />

identificati<strong>on</strong> with 9 items. Our model exceeds the minimum GFI limit of > 0.9 with a<br />

<strong>value</strong> of 0.945, <strong>and</strong> this is better than the Chapter 2 model with 0.939. The RMSEA<br />

<strong>value</strong>s are acceptable between .05 <strong>and</strong> .08, with an upper threshold limit of 0.1(Hair et<br />

al., 2006, p.634). By this st<strong>and</strong>ard, our current model is good with a RMSEA of<br />

0.040, <strong>and</strong> it is better than Chapter 2 structural model’s RMSEA of 0.072 3 . The<br />

sec<strong>on</strong>d category of fit indices are incremental fit measures. Our model has a Tucker-<br />

Lewis index (TLI) <strong>value</strong> of 0.981 <strong>and</strong> is more than the minimum acceptable level of<br />

0.9, whereas the model of Chapter 2 had a <strong>value</strong> of 0.930. The last incremental fit<br />

index we use is the comparative fit index (CFI) <strong>and</strong> it is specifically meant for<br />

samples with small sizes (Hair et al., 2006). We surpass the minimum level of 0.9<br />

with our model score of 0.987, slightly better than the Chapter 2 <strong>value</strong> of 0.953.<br />

Moreover, the model has a χ 2 /degrees of freedom ratio of 1.14 <strong>and</strong> that is c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

good. Since model 2 meets the criteria of the goodness of fit measures we accept the<br />

measurement model. The fit statistics for model 2 overall were very good.<br />

Hypothesis 1 is significant. It indicates also that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is<br />

indeed an antecedent to IdRR <strong>and</strong> that both the c<strong>on</strong>structs are negatively related. The<br />

β= -0.993, <strong>and</strong> this is similar to the β= -0.980 in the model in Chapter 2. This<br />

indicates a str<strong>on</strong>g negative effect of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>on</strong> IdRR. This finding<br />

supports our hypothesis that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness negatively influences IdRR,<br />

3 Please look at Table 3.4 for Chapter 2 structural model fit indices.<br />

87


since it is significant at p


BFV<br />

Hypothesis 4<br />

IdRR->SBV<br />

Hypothesis 5<br />

SBV->BFV<br />

Not Supported -3.837* Not Tested 0.500***<br />

-0.992*** -0.993*** -0.993*** Not Tested<br />

0.976*** 3.942*** 0.590*** Not Tested<br />

Note. ***significant at the .001 level, *significant at the .01 level, SE=St<strong>and</strong>ardized Estimates,<br />

Insig=Insignificant, S.R.= Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, IdRR=Idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, BS=Buyer<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, SBV=Supplier br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, BFV= Buyer <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

89


3.3 Discussi<strong>on</strong><br />

The main objective of this study was to underst<strong>and</strong> whether the model developed in<br />

Chapter 2 would be robust <strong>and</strong> hold across nati<strong>on</strong>s. To that end we were interested in<br />

finding whether IdRR is an important mediator as stated in Chapter 2 <strong>and</strong> whether<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> (relati<strong>on</strong>al indicator) is linked to <strong>buyer</strong> profits.<br />

We first tested a full replica of the model in Chapter 2. Model 1 did not was<br />

too large for our small sample size; therefore, we decided to split the model into two<br />

smaller models (the satisfacti<strong>on</strong> mediator route <strong>and</strong> the IdRR <strong>and</strong> Supplier br<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong> mediator route) <strong>and</strong> rerun the analysis.<br />

As reflected by Table 3.4, Model 2 has better fit statistics <strong>on</strong> four indices<br />

namely, GFI (0.945), CFI (0.987), TLI (0.981) <strong>and</strong> RMSEA (0.040), than the model<br />

in Chapter 2. Whereas, model 3 is <strong>on</strong>ly better <strong>on</strong> GFI (0.95) than the model in Chapter<br />

2. This is probably because there are fewer items <strong>and</strong> more data points to estimate<br />

those items, which results in a better fit. The effects for hypotheses 1 <strong>and</strong> 4 are<br />

str<strong>on</strong>ger in model 2 than in the model in Chapter 2. For hypothesis 5 the effects are<br />

str<strong>on</strong>ger in the Chapter 2 model. For hypothesis 1 we c<strong>on</strong>jecture that as The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s is culturally homogeneous, it is easier for <strong>supplier</strong>s to reduce their IdRR,<br />

as they better underst<strong>and</strong> each other’s needs. As Hofstede (2003) states,<br />

heterogeneous societies can have great variati<strong>on</strong>s al<strong>on</strong>g their cultural dimensi<strong>on</strong>s. On<br />

the other h<strong>and</strong>, the US managers tend to score higher in uncertainty avoidance than<br />

Dutch managers do <strong>on</strong> the Hofstede index (Figure 3.1). But as The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s is<br />

relatively ethnically homogeneous, we underst<strong>and</strong> that managers believe that their<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s are more attuned to their needs because of cultural underst<strong>and</strong>ing.<br />

This results in the effect of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness of IdRR being slightly str<strong>on</strong>ger in<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. An alternative explanati<strong>on</strong> could be that, in essence, reducing IdRR<br />

involves creating an idiosyncratic resp<strong>on</strong>se <strong>and</strong> that does not have much applicati<strong>on</strong><br />

to other customers of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>. As the United States is highly masculine<br />

<strong>and</strong> oriented towards achieving maximum profits, it is possible that <strong>supplier</strong>s are<br />

willing to create an idiosyncratic resp<strong>on</strong>se to a degree, <strong>and</strong> when diminishing returns<br />

start setting in they stop further investments in such resp<strong>on</strong>ses. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, in<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, with its greater focus <strong>on</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships because of its feminine<br />

culture, no attenti<strong>on</strong> is paid to this point of diminishing returns. For hypotheses 4 we<br />

find that the effect of IdRR <strong>on</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is marginally str<strong>on</strong>ger in The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s than the model Chapter 2.<br />

There is not much in the extant literature <strong>on</strong> this hypothesis for comparis<strong>on</strong> in<br />

B2B c<strong>on</strong>texts. However, risk reducti<strong>on</strong> has been identified as an important functi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

B2B br<strong>and</strong>s (Sanzo et al., 2003). What makes our finding unique is that we have<br />

proposed risk reducti<strong>on</strong> as an antecedent to purchasing B2B br<strong>and</strong>s in The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States. This is similar to findings from c<strong>on</strong>sumer research<br />

where risk reducti<strong>on</strong> is a motivating factor for c<strong>on</strong>sumer to purchase a br<strong>and</strong> (Kotler,<br />

& Pfoertsch, 2006). This direct experience ensures that customer IdRR will be<br />

reduced, <strong>and</strong> hence, our findings are pertinent as they provide evidence that B2B<br />

<strong>buyer</strong>s are also motivated by risk reducti<strong>on</strong> factors. Hypothesis 5 provides evidence<br />

that being associated with a strategic <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> increases the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>’s<br />

<strong>value</strong>. This could be because of <strong>on</strong>e of two mechanisms. One could be because of the<br />

benefits of ingredient br<strong>and</strong>ing. And the other reas<strong>on</strong> could be because of a networked<br />

effect that signals to external customers that the <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> produces high quality<br />

90


products. Overall, the effects of <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is str<strong>on</strong>ger in the United States<br />

than in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s.<br />

In hypothesis 3 we find that <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> has a positive influence <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> in model 2, but in the model in Chapter 2 it does not. In the United<br />

States at a more granular level it might be that relati<strong>on</strong>al metrics al<strong>on</strong>e (satisfacti<strong>on</strong>)<br />

do not influence the <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>, or indeed the customer’s intenti<strong>on</strong> to<br />

repurchase from the <strong>supplier</strong>. This reinforces the existing perspective that customer<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as a metric is of little or no significance in B2B strategic c<strong>on</strong>texts in the<br />

United States. Furthermore, this also adds a new dimensi<strong>on</strong> to the intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

perspective by Ghosh <strong>and</strong> John (2009) <strong>and</strong> Drucker (1984) that <strong>firm</strong> commitment to<br />

customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> would lead to superior <strong>firm</strong> performance. Firms in the strategic<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text seem to be committed to measurable <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong> rather than generating<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> al<strong>on</strong>e. But Bowman <strong>and</strong> Naray<strong>and</strong>as (2004) find that in the United States,<br />

high volume customers have a lower baseline satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> that large customers<br />

are less likely to change their vendors because of specific investments they have made<br />

with their vendors <strong>and</strong> a l<strong>on</strong>g-term profit focus. Our findings are partially in line with<br />

what they found as in the United States customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does not matter in<br />

strategic c<strong>on</strong>texts. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s because of its more<br />

feminine culture, we find that satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does matter. A major c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of this<br />

research is that we have highlighted that the role of satisfacti<strong>on</strong> varies across nati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in B2B c<strong>on</strong>texts. Furthermore, we have also added to prior research in The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s that showed customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> positively influences <strong>supplier</strong>s’<br />

financial performance by adding a new perspective that <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> positively<br />

influences the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>s own <strong>value</strong>.<br />

The role risk played in the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> customer<br />

performance is different in different nati<strong>on</strong>al cultural c<strong>on</strong>texts. In general, we were<br />

able to provide some evidence that a strategic <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness influences the<br />

customer’s idiosyncratic risk <strong>and</strong> transcends nati<strong>on</strong>al borders in industrialized<br />

countries. Furthermore, this influences the customer’s future <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> loyalty<br />

towards the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong>. This is an important finding because in traditi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

marketing thought (Kohli & Jaworski, 1993), the <strong>firm</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is positively<br />

associated with the <strong>firm</strong>’s risk. However, our study dem<strong>on</strong>strates that in the c<strong>on</strong>text of<br />

strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships the <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is associated with a lower risk<br />

profile, since the customer’s variati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> volatility in their cash flows <strong>and</strong> profits<br />

decreases.<br />

Bowman <strong>and</strong> Nary<strong>and</strong>as (2004) find that high volume customers have a lower<br />

baseline satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. They argue that large customers are less likely to change their<br />

vendors because of specific investments they have made with their vendors <strong>and</strong> a<br />

l<strong>on</strong>g-term profit focus. Our findings are partially in line with what they found. We<br />

find that indeed customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does not matter in strategic c<strong>on</strong>texts; however,<br />

it is not <strong>on</strong>ly because of a l<strong>on</strong>g-term focus, but rather because of their idiosyncratic<br />

risk. In other words, relati<strong>on</strong> specific investments or costs are just <strong>on</strong>e comp<strong>on</strong>ent of<br />

the overall idiosyncratic risk. Likewise the l<strong>on</strong>g-term focus linkage to a market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> is a widely recognized, yet empirically disputed link (Slater & Narver,<br />

1990; Grewal & Tansuhaj, 2001). But even in studies where evidence for market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> influencing the <strong>firm</strong>’s profitability was found, evidence for a linkage to<br />

l<strong>on</strong>g-term orientati<strong>on</strong> has been scant. However, since we examine strategic<br />

91


elati<strong>on</strong>ship, which in their nature are l<strong>on</strong>g term, it would be safe to c<strong>on</strong>clude that it<br />

does play a role within the choice of market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a strategic choice.<br />

Soft measures that gauge the experience of a br<strong>and</strong> are more meaningful in<br />

buying center c<strong>on</strong>texts where such soft measures have comm<strong>on</strong>ly shared meaning<br />

am<strong>on</strong>gst its members. It would be possible to have such comm<strong>on</strong>ly shared percepti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

in a culture where there is more cultural homogeneity as compared with<br />

heterogeneity. One of the benefits of having a solid metric to measure against such as<br />

insulati<strong>on</strong> from idiosyncratic risk is that it helps avoid the communicati<strong>on</strong>s pitfall<br />

which can occur with other soft measures whose <strong>value</strong> may differ in the perspective<br />

of different team members.<br />

Furthermore, c<strong>on</strong>trary to existing thought our findings offer evidence that<br />

res<strong>on</strong>ance does not exist between n<strong>on</strong>-financial relati<strong>on</strong>al outcomes <strong>and</strong> risk-based<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al outcomes in the United States. However, within The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s we do<br />

find evidence for such a relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Therefore, from our evidence the managers<br />

within the United States should look for two independent sets of metrics, whereas in<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s it may be possible to use idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk as a proxy<br />

measure for satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with the relati<strong>on</strong>ship. However, even in that case it would be<br />

better to have independent metrics because the magnitude of satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

idiosyncratic risk may not be the same. The final decisi<strong>on</strong> of which metric to use is<br />

for every organizati<strong>on</strong> to gauge for itself, depending <strong>on</strong> which resp<strong>on</strong>sive maneuvers<br />

will reduce their customers’ risks <strong>and</strong>, in turn, increase the <strong>value</strong> of their br<strong>and</strong>. Since<br />

every customer is unique <strong>and</strong> represents a significant volume of the seller’s sales<br />

volume, then our perspective is that the <strong>supplier</strong> should develop unique resp<strong>on</strong>ses to<br />

each strategic customer or segment to reduce their risk.<br />

3.4 Recommendati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Our current study is not free from limitati<strong>on</strong>s. For example, our research design could<br />

be improved up<strong>on</strong>. Some researchers have indicated that ethnographies should be<br />

employed to research issues related to culture (Langerak, 2001). The advantage in<br />

their opini<strong>on</strong> is that organizati<strong>on</strong>al culture can be better documented by l<strong>on</strong>g-term<br />

observati<strong>on</strong> techniques, such as ethnographies. They c<strong>on</strong>sider <strong>on</strong>e of the shortcomings<br />

of questi<strong>on</strong>naires to be that they are culturally biased. However, to overcome this<br />

shortcoming, we formed a team of two researchers from diverse nati<strong>on</strong>al cultural<br />

backgrounds while framing the questi<strong>on</strong>s. This step enabled us to cross-check<br />

questi<strong>on</strong>s for any cultural biases. Some cultural biases may be present in more than<br />

<strong>on</strong>e culture but the process of cross-checking involved checking for biases comm<strong>on</strong> to<br />

both cultures, documenting them while framing our questi<strong>on</strong>s in the questi<strong>on</strong>naire,<br />

<strong>and</strong> taking care to avoid the biases. We do recognize that we may have not eliminated<br />

all cultural biases, but we were able to do so to the best of our ability.<br />

Another limitati<strong>on</strong> is the narrow cultural comparis<strong>on</strong> we have at the moment.<br />

Although the US <strong>and</strong> The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s are different in some respects, they share<br />

similarities as well. Both are industrialized nati<strong>on</strong>s, both are vibrant democracies,<br />

both have capitalist ec<strong>on</strong>omies, both have a degree of similar occidental culture, <strong>and</strong><br />

both nati<strong>on</strong>s are internati<strong>on</strong>ally competitive ec<strong>on</strong>omies (Deshp<strong>and</strong>e & Webster,<br />

1989). Some cultural idiosyncrasies do occur, such as acceptance of boasting <strong>on</strong> job<br />

interviews in the United States <strong>and</strong> the preference for modesty in job interviews in<br />

The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, but nevertheless, they both can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered western cultures.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong> comparis<strong>on</strong> with an Asian culture would have provided a<br />

92


more diverse comparis<strong>on</strong>. China is a growing world trade power, it is a communist<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> it has a collectivist culture <strong>and</strong> a C<strong>on</strong>fucian <strong>value</strong> system (Hofstede,<br />

2003). These cultural differences result in different risk preferences in individual<br />

members of society. For instance, the Chinese have a greater risk preference than<br />

Americans, because their collectivist culture cushi<strong>on</strong>s them from losses. Future<br />

researchers could investigate how <strong>firm</strong>s from societies with extremely different risk<br />

preferences react to <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. This would also add a new dimensi<strong>on</strong> to<br />

the problem we studied as to whether cultural risk preference is a moderating factor in<br />

the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

In some Eurasian <strong>and</strong> Asian ec<strong>on</strong>omies, relati<strong>on</strong>al practices such as Blat <strong>and</strong><br />

Gaunxi are an integral part of the business culture. However, in western cultures such<br />

practices may be viewed as unethical <strong>and</strong> detrimental to the corporate interests <strong>and</strong><br />

reputati<strong>on</strong>. Specifically, when forming strategic <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships with<br />

corporati<strong>on</strong>s that find such cultural practices acceptable, <strong>buyer</strong>s may fear a negative<br />

spillover <strong>on</strong> their br<strong>and</strong> reputati<strong>on</strong>. Such cultural effects have been overlooked in our<br />

current study. Further examples include questi<strong>on</strong>s such as: Does IdRR vary because<br />

of nati<strong>on</strong>al culture? Or should culture specific practices such as Blat or Guanxi be<br />

c<strong>on</strong>sidered a part of IdRR?<br />

Another limitati<strong>on</strong> of our current study is that we <strong>on</strong>ly c<strong>on</strong>sidered percepti<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Indeed, do percepti<strong>on</strong>s reinforce objective measures across cultures? Are some<br />

cultures more pr<strong>on</strong>e to be overly jubilant when it comes to redirecting earnings from<br />

investments? Are some cultures overly pessimistic when predicting losses which may<br />

across from strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships? Do cultures influence the relative importance of<br />

<strong>firm</strong> percepti<strong>on</strong> of marketing strategies such as market orientati<strong>on</strong>?<br />

Another way to improve up<strong>on</strong> our current research could be to use a<br />

dashboard of risk metrics to neutralize cultural biases. Experts have advocated<br />

dashboards as a means of ending managerial biases in informati<strong>on</strong> processing <strong>and</strong><br />

decisi<strong>on</strong> making in businesses (Hofstede, 2003). Furthermore, some managers, when<br />

faced with an overload of data, tend to take risky shortcuts that can lead to managerial<br />

biases (Pauwels et al., 2008). In our current study we do not cover a dashboard of<br />

metrics <strong>and</strong> whether a dashboard of metrics is a tool for insulati<strong>on</strong> for making<br />

culturally biased evaluati<strong>on</strong>s in cross-nati<strong>on</strong>al studies of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>buyer</strong> performance. Moreover, a dashboard of metrics that includes idiosyncratic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al risk would also be worthwhile investigating, as it would lead to insights in<br />

whether the dashboard of metrics is truly capturing the impact of market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

expenditure <strong>and</strong> would further expound the usefulness of IdRR as a metric.<br />

Finally, we examined <strong>on</strong>ly existing relati<strong>on</strong>ships. It is possible that the current<br />

study could be improved up<strong>on</strong> by examining different stages in a relati<strong>on</strong>ship <strong>and</strong><br />

examine whether the importance of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> idiosyncratic risk varies<br />

across nati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> in different stages of the relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

3.5 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

To c<strong>on</strong>clude, we explored the role of idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk <strong>and</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as<br />

mediators of <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> customer performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship in<br />

two different cultural settings. In this course, we c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ed that idiosyncratic risk<br />

insulati<strong>on</strong> was a pivotal part of a <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship across cultural<br />

boundaries. Our findings suggest that <strong>supplier</strong>s pay attenti<strong>on</strong> to calibrating their<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se mechanisms so as to reduce their strategic customer’s risk, regardless of<br />

93


their country of operati<strong>on</strong>. However, we do recognize that we studied it in North<br />

American <strong>and</strong> European c<strong>on</strong>texts, <strong>and</strong> our findings may not hold true in different<br />

cultural settings, such as Asia or Africa.<br />

Our results also show that certain earned relati<strong>on</strong>al outcomes, such as<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, may be of little significance to the <strong>firm</strong> across nati<strong>on</strong>al cultures. The<br />

practical implicati<strong>on</strong> for businesses is that they have to adroitly choose which<br />

outcomes they wish to create or accumulate as market-based “assets.” Another<br />

implicati<strong>on</strong> is that changes in the cultural setting change the relative importance of<br />

metrics. As most metrics have been developed in the United States, it might be that<br />

those metrics are irrelevant in other cultural settings (Wierenga & Van Bruggen,<br />

1997). To summarize, there are two major c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s from our current study. Firstly,<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> is a strategy that is <strong>value</strong>d across a variety of nati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

cultural spectrums. Sec<strong>on</strong>dly, businesses need culturally adapted, relati<strong>on</strong>al, process,<br />

<strong>and</strong> performance indicators to accurately gauge the performance of their marketing<br />

initiatives <strong>and</strong> strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<br />

94


Chapter 4<br />

The Quest for Performance Substitutes:<br />

The Case of Objective <strong>and</strong> Subjective Performance Measures<br />

Abstract<br />

A recent study about strategic <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> has made two challenging<br />

asserti<strong>on</strong>s. The first is the negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship between idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong>’s <strong>value</strong>. The sec<strong>on</strong>d is that relati<strong>on</strong>al indicators are not a predictor of a<br />

<strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>, but insulati<strong>on</strong> to idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk is. However,<br />

managerial percepti<strong>on</strong>s are a limitati<strong>on</strong> of the data set used in Chapter 2. Using<br />

objective data from the Reuters database <strong>and</strong> subjective data from Chapter 2, we find<br />

that results from the objective model do not c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> the results of the subjective<br />

model. This has important implicati<strong>on</strong>s for businesses, primarily because there is a<br />

trend for managers to rely <strong>on</strong> their own heuristics <strong>and</strong> in strategic c<strong>on</strong>texts, heuristics<br />

may be misleading. The c<strong>on</strong>sequences include potentially damaged strategic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<br />

Keywords: <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, subjective<br />

<strong>and</strong> objective performance<br />

95


“It is <strong>on</strong>e of the comm<strong>on</strong>est of mistakes to c<strong>on</strong>sider that the limit of our power<br />

of percepti<strong>on</strong> is also the limit of all there is to perceive.”<br />

—C. W. Leadbeater (n.d.)<br />

"On the face of it, shareholder <strong>value</strong> is the dumbest idea in the world."<br />

—Jack Welch<br />

Former CEO, General Electric (Guerrera,<br />

2009).<br />

4.1 Introducti<strong>on</strong><br />

The financial crisis of 2009 is an example of the inc<strong>on</strong>gruence between subjective <strong>and</strong><br />

objective measurement. Prior to the financial crisis, many <strong>firm</strong>s had benefitted because of<br />

investors’ irrati<strong>on</strong>al exuberance about financial markets (Akerlof & Shiller, 2010). This<br />

benefit occurred even though many <strong>firm</strong>’s objective financial indicators did not reflect such<br />

exuberance. The outcome of the diss<strong>on</strong>ance between subjective <strong>and</strong> objective measurement<br />

can be grave, as is illustrated by the large number of bankruptcies in 2009. Similarly, in the<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature, numerous studies have included objective <strong>and</strong> subjective or<br />

perceptual measures <strong>and</strong> have c<strong>on</strong>tradictory or different results (Jaworski & Kohli, 1993;<br />

Narver & Slater, 1990). We define subjective metrics as those based <strong>on</strong> managerial<br />

heuristics <strong>and</strong> objective metrics as those based <strong>on</strong> some externally verifiable accounting or<br />

financial procedure.<br />

All subjective or perceptual data are based <strong>on</strong> human percepti<strong>on</strong>s. Human<br />

percepti<strong>on</strong>s are notoriously fickle <strong>and</strong> not necessarily a representative of market realities<br />

(Cassidy, 2009, pp. 10-11). This is not because people or managers are irrati<strong>on</strong>al, but rather<br />

because their limited mental capabilities do not at times allow them to process all the<br />

complicated factors or indicators (Cassidy, 2009, pp. 10-11). Furthermore, managers 4<br />

usually <strong>on</strong>ly remember more recent events (Foer, 2011). This is a weakness when<br />

measuring <strong>supplier</strong> performance because the relati<strong>on</strong>ship is based <strong>on</strong> a c<strong>on</strong>tinuum of<br />

interacti<strong>on</strong>s, not just the most recent interacti<strong>on</strong>s. Tversky <strong>and</strong> Kahneman (1974)<br />

investigated heuristics or mental short cuts. The first mental short cut is representativeness,<br />

meaning that managers generalize with insufficient evidence (Cassidy, 2009, p. 195;<br />

Tversky & Kahneman, 1974). Even when experimental subjects were provided with<br />

statistical data to guide their decisi<strong>on</strong>s, they still jumped to c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s for which they did<br />

not have much evidence (Cassidy, 2009, pp. 195-196). This jumping to c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s also<br />

leads to the phenomen<strong>on</strong> of overc<strong>on</strong>fidence, which has led to many financial fiascos<br />

(Cassidy, 2009, pp. 195-196). Managers who are overc<strong>on</strong>fident take short-term relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

trends with strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s as indicators of the l<strong>on</strong>g-term trends. This overc<strong>on</strong>fidence<br />

could have serious repercussi<strong>on</strong>s if <strong>firm</strong>s get stuck with adverse l<strong>on</strong>g-term c<strong>on</strong>sequences<br />

they did not anticipate. The sec<strong>on</strong>d mental short cut is the availability of scenarios (Tversky<br />

& Kahneman, 1974). Managers' experiences dictate how likely they are to perceive that an<br />

event is to occur (Cassidy, 2009, pp. 196-197). For instance, many reinsurance 5 companies<br />

will not insure for a calamity after it has occurred (Greeley, 2011). Even though the<br />

likelihood of another natural disaster is extremely low in an area in which <strong>on</strong>e has already<br />

occurred, managerial percepti<strong>on</strong>s sway reinsurance managers from providing coverage for<br />

such disasters in the future because this is an extreme situati<strong>on</strong> that they fear. This means<br />

that they exclude a lucrative potential market from which they could generate future<br />

4 The terms "people" <strong>and</strong> "managers" are used interchangeably in this Chapter.<br />

5 Reinsurance companies insure insurance companies.<br />

96


insurance premiums. Hence, perceptual judgments (that are the basis for perceptual data) do<br />

not always accurately represent reality. The third mental short cut is an adjustment from an<br />

anchor (Cassidy, 2009, p. 197; Tversky & Kahneman, 1974), which means that managers<br />

use reference points for decisi<strong>on</strong>s. If, for instance, current market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s are the<br />

reference point, then managers would assume that market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s will not change a lot<br />

in the future. This mental adjustment because of an anchor leads to c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ati<strong>on</strong> biases or<br />

interpreting evidence to c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> their predispositi<strong>on</strong>s based <strong>on</strong> their reference points<br />

(Cassidy, 2009, pp. 196-197). Alternatively, it can be counter argued that B2B managers,<br />

humans will think laterally (Zaltman, 2003), use mental short cuts, <strong>and</strong> rely <strong>on</strong> perceptual<br />

metrics. However, most <strong>firm</strong>s at the end of the day have to justify their marketing<br />

expenditures to the finance department, <strong>and</strong> unless performance shows up <strong>on</strong> financial or<br />

objective metrics, it is unlikely that a relati<strong>on</strong>ship will c<strong>on</strong>tinue (Bolt<strong>on</strong>, 2004; Srivastava,<br />

Shervani, & Fahey, 1998). Hence, using perceptually based measures or evaluati<strong>on</strong>s has<br />

many weaknesses.<br />

Objective metrics have some advantages over subjective metrics. Objective metrics<br />

are suitable for a l<strong>on</strong>g-term focus, whereas subjective metrics can at best be used for the<br />

short term (Rajan & Reichelstein, 2006). Moreover, objective metrics are externally<br />

verifiable, whereas subjective metrics are not (Rajan & Reichelstein, 2006). External<br />

verificati<strong>on</strong> makes objective metrics more transparent <strong>and</strong> reliable than subjective metrics.<br />

For strategic <strong>buyer</strong>s, this objectivity would mean that an income statement would reflect a<br />

manager’s positi<strong>on</strong> that a certain <strong>supplier</strong> is reducing its costs <strong>and</strong> therefore increasing its<br />

profits. Objective metrics are st<strong>and</strong>ardized by procedures such as generally accepted<br />

accounting principles (GAAP). This st<strong>and</strong>ardizati<strong>on</strong> should make it easier for channel<br />

partners <strong>and</strong> strategic customers to communicate the <strong>value</strong> generated to external<br />

stakeholders who underst<strong>and</strong> how these st<strong>and</strong>ardized performance measures were<br />

calculated. Furthermore, it makes it easier to benchmark <strong>supplier</strong>s against each other <strong>and</strong><br />

see who is generating more <strong>value</strong> for the <strong>firm</strong>. Objective measures are comparatively<br />

readily accepted by financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s compared to subjective metrics. Therefore, it is<br />

easier to acquire access to capital when a company can prove performance via objective<br />

metrics. Hence, objective indicators are important to business, <strong>and</strong> any marketing<br />

investment (e.g., in relati<strong>on</strong>ships or philosophies such as market orientati<strong>on</strong>) by the <strong>firm</strong><br />

needs to be translated into financial language. This ensures that marketing keeps receiving a<br />

fair allocati<strong>on</strong> of the <strong>firm</strong>’s overall budget (Bolt<strong>on</strong>, 2004).<br />

The study in Chapter 2 has made a significant c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the underst<strong>and</strong>ing of<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> marker orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk (IdRR). The study posited that<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> IdRR are negatively <strong>and</strong> not positively associated. The findings<br />

are based <strong>on</strong> subjective or perceptual data. Against the background of the study in Chapter<br />

2, we questi<strong>on</strong> whether the results are robust <strong>and</strong> would st<strong>and</strong> if both subjective <strong>and</strong><br />

objective performance measures are used. Thus, we use a structural model based <strong>on</strong><br />

accounting data <strong>and</strong> compare it with the original perceptual data model in Chapter 2.<br />

We define subjective performance measures as heuristic individual evaluati<strong>on</strong>s of a<br />

<strong>firm</strong>’s performance. Such evaluati<strong>on</strong>s are not as static for the <strong>firm</strong> at the corporate level as<br />

accounting or financial results are; they vary from resp<strong>on</strong>dent to resp<strong>on</strong>dent. Subjective<br />

evaluati<strong>on</strong>s or measures reflect the general underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the manager. We assume that<br />

the reliability of such measures increases when managers acquire experience <strong>and</strong> an<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the markets in which they operate. Objective performance measures are<br />

calculated using st<strong>and</strong>ardized accounting <strong>and</strong> financial procedures. Objective measures also<br />

97


have their own limitati<strong>on</strong>s. Some of these limitati<strong>on</strong>s have to do with the way in which data<br />

are collected <strong>and</strong> employee motivati<strong>on</strong> while compiling them. For instance, San Miguel<br />

(1997) has argued that they may not be very reliable since many times, the data have been<br />

complied by people who do not have sufficient training or familiarity with accounting such<br />

data. Furthermore, he argues that some managers may lack interest when such data are<br />

being compiled, which may adversely affect their reliability.<br />

We also use the definiti<strong>on</strong>s delineated in Chapter 2 to define the five variables in the<br />

model. 6 This is because the model in Chapter 2 is the basis for comparis<strong>on</strong> of objective <strong>and</strong><br />

subjective measures in the current study. We <strong>on</strong>ly modify the way we measure the variable<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. For the current model, we use the net income difference between the<br />

years 2009 <strong>and</strong> 2011 in the SEM model instead of the subjective measures used in Chapter<br />

2.<br />

4.2 Intended Theoretical C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong><br />

To our knowledge, this is the first study to examine the issue of objective versus<br />

subjective performance measures in the c<strong>on</strong>text of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> IdRR. In the current study, we aim to make four c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

First, we provide evidence that the type of data used for <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>sivenessidiosyncratic<br />

risk-performance analysis can change the strength <strong>and</strong> directi<strong>on</strong> of the<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships in the Chapter 2 model. We were able to show that to some extent, there<br />

is a disc<strong>on</strong>nect between key indicators when subjective <strong>and</strong> objective data are used.<br />

We believe this is because of a lack of metric substitutability rather than a problem<br />

with the model itself. Sec<strong>on</strong>d, we explain why managers’ evaluati<strong>on</strong>s may not be in<br />

line with the objective data indicators. For example, because objective data are<br />

calculated at a macro-organizati<strong>on</strong>al level, they may not reflect the performance of the<br />

various functi<strong>on</strong>s at different levels within the organizati<strong>on</strong>. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, a<br />

manager’s heuristic ability can shed light <strong>on</strong> latent areas of performance that<br />

traditi<strong>on</strong>al objective performance measures cannot. Third, we explain that financial<br />

managers often fail to see the <strong>value</strong> of marketing initiatives because they do not<br />

underst<strong>and</strong> the intangible <strong>value</strong> such initiatives create. Fourth, from a managerial<br />

perspective, our study suggests specific steps that businesses can implement to avoid<br />

the diss<strong>on</strong>ance between subjective <strong>and</strong> objective measures.<br />

4.3 Specific C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to Chapter 2<br />

The model in Chapter 2 c<strong>on</strong>tributes to the literature by providing evidence that market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is negatively related to IdRR. However, since<br />

the model is <strong>on</strong>ly based <strong>on</strong> perceptual data (for both market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

performance), it remains to be seen whether the model in Chapter 2 is applicable if<br />

objective performance data are used in t<strong>and</strong>em with subjective market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

data. For any model to be generalizable, its findings should be replicated with both<br />

subjective <strong>and</strong> objective data sources. One of the strengths of a theory is fulfilling this<br />

criteri<strong>on</strong>. Our current study elaborates the model in Chapter 2 by testing it using<br />

perceptual <strong>and</strong> objective performance data. We believe that the main hypothesis <strong>and</strong><br />

6 One issue is that our perceptual measures for <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> objective measure of accounting profits<br />

are not the same. However, since accounting profits are indicators of the <strong>firm</strong>’s <strong>value</strong>, we have used<br />

them for this analysis. Moreover, cash flows <strong>and</strong> accounting profits are positively correlated. Current<br />

accounting indicators signal to the market how well the company is doing <strong>and</strong> would be an incentive<br />

for investors to purchase stocks if profits are good. This would in turn drive up the <strong>value</strong> of the stock<br />

because the market would anticipate increased future earnings.<br />

98


theoretical c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> regarding the market orientati<strong>on</strong>-IdRR-performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship is supported by objective accounting data. We found differences in the<br />

significance of the hypothesis tests in Chapter 2, which we explain these differences<br />

by observing that numerous previous studies with arrived at different results between<br />

subjective <strong>and</strong> objective indicators. This may have more to do with the inherently<br />

different nature of objective metrics rather than a rati<strong>on</strong>ale flaw in the model. In<br />

summati<strong>on</strong>, the current study has tested whether the model developed in Chapter 2 is<br />

more likely to hold true when subjective performance data are used compared to<br />

objective performance data.<br />

The rest of this study is organized as follows. We first present the different<br />

focuses of previous studies that have examined the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship. Next, we present the three categories of previous studies.<br />

Then we generate hypotheses from a literature synthesis. We describe our data<br />

collecti<strong>on</strong> process <strong>and</strong> analyze the data. We compare our hypothesized model with the<br />

model developed in chapter 2. Finally, we discuss the results <strong>and</strong> the academic<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> managerial implicati<strong>on</strong>s of our research. In the end, we describe<br />

limitati<strong>on</strong>s of our current research <strong>and</strong> present our c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

4.4 Hypothesis Development<br />

In the marketing literature, three kinds of market orientati<strong>on</strong> performance studies<br />

exist. The first <strong>on</strong>ly use subjective measures, the sec<strong>on</strong>d <strong>on</strong>ly use objective measures,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the third use both objective <strong>and</strong> subjective measures.<br />

The first category often finds that market orientati<strong>on</strong> is positively associated<br />

with subjective performance measures (Anders<strong>on</strong> et al., 1994). Subjective indicators<br />

are used most often to validate the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

(G<strong>on</strong>zalez-Benito & G<strong>on</strong>zalez-Benito, 2005). It is expected that if the same<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>dent is used for perceptual as well as performance measures, these measures<br />

should be aligned with <strong>on</strong>e another. Since the model in chapter 2 uses subjective<br />

process <strong>and</strong> performance measures, it falls within this first category of studies.<br />

However, this also is a weakness of the model because whether it would hold true if<br />

tested with objective data has not been examined.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d category of studies finds that market orientati<strong>on</strong> is positively<br />

associated with objective measures (Jaworski & Kohli, 1993). We c<strong>on</strong>ducted held<br />

informal c<strong>on</strong>versati<strong>on</strong>s with B2B managers to find out why objective metrics<br />

mattered when measuring the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance linkage. Managers<br />

believed that objective metrics mattered because they were developed by a rigorous<br />

scientific process that was communicable to employees. Furthermore, in their opini<strong>on</strong>,<br />

objective metrics were less susceptible to misinterpretati<strong>on</strong> because of their<br />

widespread use. Third, they helped communicate a company’s performance to<br />

financial markets, but their relevance within the <strong>firm</strong> was not of the same magnitude<br />

as it was for the financial markets. Fourth, since many objective measures are<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ardized, they can be used for benchmarking against competitors. Fifth, they<br />

believe that objective metrics have greater sway with external stakeholders such as<br />

financial instituti<strong>on</strong>s. Despite numerous advantages of objective metrics, managers<br />

did not believe that objective metrics could truly capture all the intangible n<strong>on</strong>financial<br />

<strong>value</strong> created by marketing investments <strong>and</strong> maneuvers. The implicati<strong>on</strong>s of<br />

these opini<strong>on</strong>s are that subjective <strong>and</strong> objective measures will not always reinforce<br />

each other. This trend is also reflected within the literature. For instance, Esslem<strong>on</strong>t<br />

99


<strong>and</strong> Lewis (1991) used the objective measures of ROI growth <strong>and</strong> profit margins.<br />

They found no relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, Hooley et al. (1990) used the same subjective measure of ROI <strong>and</strong> found a<br />

positive relati<strong>on</strong>ship for market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance. Why is there a<br />

difference between studies about the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

when they are using similar performance measures? In this specific case, it could that<br />

Hooley et al. (1990) used the chief marketing officer as a resp<strong>on</strong>dent, <strong>and</strong> his vast<br />

knowledge gave him strategic perspective of what was going <strong>on</strong> in the organizati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Therefore, their subjective assessment was aligned with the objective of ROI. In<br />

Esslem<strong>on</strong>t <strong>and</strong> Lewis' (1991) study, resp<strong>on</strong>dents replied differently because of their<br />

lack of underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the objective measures. However, with the model in Chapter<br />

2, we expect that since the managers <strong>on</strong> average have over seven years of experience<br />

in their current positi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> are relatively senior in their respective organizati<strong>on</strong>s,<br />

their resp<strong>on</strong>ses would reinforce objective indicators.<br />

The third category of studies use identical measures of performance, but they<br />

find different results between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance linkage. On the <strong>on</strong>e<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, Tse (1995) found no relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the objective<br />

performance measure of hotel occupancy rates. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, Naidu <strong>and</strong><br />

Narayana (1991) found that in hospitals, market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> occupancy rates have<br />

a positive relati<strong>on</strong>ship. In the case of Tse (1995), it could be said that the customers of<br />

the lodges are looking for c<strong>on</strong>venient accommodati<strong>on</strong> rather than a market-oriented<br />

lodge. In the case of hospitals, because of their high interest in pers<strong>on</strong>al well-being,<br />

customers assess hospitals <strong>on</strong> their market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Alternatively, motor lodges are<br />

assessed <strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>venience of locati<strong>on</strong> rather than as a place to spend a pleasure<br />

vacati<strong>on</strong>, so market orientati<strong>on</strong> does not matter. In the model in Chapter 2, the<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al setting are strategic; hence, we expect market orientati<strong>on</strong> would matter to<br />

the customer because a more market-oriented <strong>supplier</strong> would be more in tune with<br />

their latent <strong>and</strong> explicit needs.<br />

In the case of companies listed or unlisted <strong>on</strong> the stock exchange, an<br />

alternative explanati<strong>on</strong> might c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the variance in subjective <strong>and</strong> objective<br />

measurement. Listed <strong>and</strong> unlisted companies vary <strong>on</strong> a number of dimensi<strong>on</strong>s such as<br />

their approach toward risk, financial leverage, <strong>and</strong> access to capital. Moreover, the<br />

corporate earnings requirements differ for listed <strong>and</strong> unlisted companies. This<br />

difference could be why the correlati<strong>on</strong> between earnings estimates for listed <strong>and</strong><br />

unlisted <strong>firm</strong>s differ. Since the model in Chapter 2 used a mixed sample of both listed<br />

<strong>and</strong> unlisted companies, a comparis<strong>on</strong> with a group of listed companies might lead to<br />

potential diss<strong>on</strong>ance in results.<br />

Two streams of research can be used to explain why at times subjective <strong>and</strong><br />

objective measurement may not reinforce each other. The first stream emphasizes<br />

optimal choices by management because of heightened informati<strong>on</strong> utilizati<strong>on</strong>. The<br />

sec<strong>on</strong>d emphasizes that managers are not adept at making optimal choices with all the<br />

informati<strong>on</strong> they have (Porter & Millar, 1985; Cyret & March, 1963). In the c<strong>on</strong>text<br />

of objective <strong>and</strong> subjective measurement of the model in Chapter 2, the decisi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

were strategic. Strategic decisi<strong>on</strong>s imply that they were high involvement decisi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Hence, evaluating any specific investment in <strong>firm</strong> processes by <strong>supplier</strong>s will be<br />

detailed <strong>and</strong> comprehensive. Under such circumstances, any subjective evaluati<strong>on</strong><br />

100


should reinforce objective measures because of the relative importance it has for the<br />

<strong>firm</strong> <strong>and</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>crete efforts that go into evaluating such investments.<br />

Therefore, we expect that we would replicate the findings of the model in<br />

Chapter 2 if we use objective data. Therefore:<br />

H1(a): The fit statistics are for the objective <strong>and</strong> subjective models are similar<br />

(b) the strength <strong>and</strong> directi<strong>on</strong> of the effects of the perceptual model are similar<br />

to the strength <strong>and</strong> directi<strong>on</strong> of objective <strong>and</strong> subjective measurement models;<br />

4.5 Research Design<br />

4.5.1 Sample<br />

We used a subsample of the data used in Chapter 2 that was composed of 87<br />

publically listed companies. Our resp<strong>on</strong>se rate was 6% for the United States<br />

(N=2800). For the objective data, we used the difference in net income earnings<br />

between 2011 <strong>and</strong> 2009. We collected the data from Google financials, which is<br />

powered by the Reuters database.<br />

4.5.2 Descriptive Statistics<br />

The <strong>buyer</strong>s’ primary business was most frequently menti<strong>on</strong>ed as both industrial <strong>and</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets (47.6%), c<strong>on</strong>sumer markets (27%), <strong>and</strong> industrial markets (25.4%).<br />

Buyers in our sample were experienced, with an average of 9.6 years of experience,<br />

out of which 7.9 years were spent as strategic <strong>buyer</strong>s for their current employers. 31.3<br />

% of our sample worked for upper management, whereas 54.6 % worked for midmanagement.<br />

25.6 % of the strategic <strong>buyer</strong>s provided service-based market offerings,<br />

24.4 % provided goods as market offerings, <strong>and</strong> the remaining 40% offered a mixture<br />

of both goods <strong>and</strong> services as their market offering. The average market <strong>value</strong> of all<br />

the <strong>firm</strong>s used in this analysis was over $1 billi<strong>on</strong> U.S. Table 4.1 presents the sample<br />

descripti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Table 4.1<br />

Sample Descripti<strong>on</strong><br />

Type of Market n=87<br />

Percentage<br />

Industrial <strong>and</strong> C<strong>on</strong>sumer Markets 47.6<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer Markets 27<br />

Industrial Markets 25.4<br />

Number of Years of Buying Experience<br />

Years<br />

Average Buying Experience 9.6<br />

Average Strategic Buying Experience 7.9<br />

Level of Management<br />

Percentage<br />

Upper Management 31.3<br />

Middle Management 54.6<br />

Type of Market Offering<br />

Percentage<br />

Service-based Market Offering 25.6<br />

Goods-based Market Offering 24.4<br />

Goods- <strong>and</strong> Service-Based Market<br />

40<br />

Offering<br />

101


4.5.3 Normality of the Data<br />

We checked for skewness <strong>and</strong> kurtosis to determine whether the data were normally<br />

distributed in Chapter 2. For details <strong>on</strong> items skewness <strong>and</strong> kurtosis please refer to<br />

Appendix B.<br />

4.5.4 Data Analysis<br />

We followed a two-step model for comparis<strong>on</strong> with the model in Chapter 2. Therefore, we<br />

tried to emulate the methodology of the Chapter 2 model as far as possible. Below, we<br />

discuss the measurement model that was our first step <strong>and</strong> then discuss the structural<br />

model.<br />

4.5.5 Measurement Model<br />

For the measurement model, we used the seven steps specified by Hair et al. (2006).<br />

First, we specified the model, then we identified the model, next we estimated the<br />

model, later we evaluated it, <strong>and</strong> finally, we respecified the model.<br />

Our specified model was a replica of the model in Chapter 2 using its scale.<br />

We used AMOS versi<strong>on</strong> 17 for our analysis. The four latent variables in the<br />

measurement model are <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, IdRR, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong><br />

br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. We used all the items of the original model in Chapter 2. The items were<br />

later <strong>on</strong> reduced to 9 items following the instructi<strong>on</strong>s of the AMOS modificati<strong>on</strong><br />

indices to improve the fit statistics.<br />

We achieved a good model fit <strong>and</strong> identificati<strong>on</strong> with 9 items, 45 distinct<br />

sample moments, 25 distinct sample parameters, <strong>and</strong> hence 20 degrees of freedom.<br />

Our sample size of 87 is above of the bare minimum of 50 needed to estimate<br />

a maximum likelihood model (MLE) (Hair et al., 2006). However, because of<br />

persistent Heywood cases that is a comm<strong>on</strong> problem when small sample sizes are<br />

used with MLE, we switched to generalized least squares for the c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory models<br />

estimati<strong>on</strong> (Lisrel, 2012). We also used the opti<strong>on</strong>s of fitting the saturated <strong>and</strong><br />

independence models, minimizati<strong>on</strong> history, st<strong>and</strong>ardized estimates, <strong>and</strong> squared<br />

multiple correlati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Another criteri<strong>on</strong> is that the squared average variance or st<strong>and</strong>ardized<br />

regressi<strong>on</strong> weights should be above 0.5 <strong>and</strong> preferably 0.7. All our measures as<br />

reflected in Table 4.2 fulfill this criteria. Examining the st<strong>and</strong>ardized regressi<strong>on</strong><br />

weights of the CFA model closely, we find that n<strong>on</strong>e is very close to <strong>on</strong>e. This<br />

implies that multicollinearity is not a problem with our data. The highest st<strong>and</strong>ardized<br />

regressi<strong>on</strong> weight is 0.849. From Table 4.3, we can observe that all the average<br />

variance extracted is above the 50% mark, which means that it is acceptable.<br />

102


Table 4.2<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ardized Regressi<strong>on</strong> Weights for CFA<br />

Latent Variable Items Estimate<br />

Strategic Supplier<br />

Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

CF 0.736<br />

SIQ 0.846<br />

CustNPD 0.866<br />

IdRR IM 0.849<br />

CCC 0.739<br />

Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value AssBr<strong>and</strong> 0.812<br />

RP 0.758<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> Sales 0.804<br />

Fair 0.772<br />

Table 4.3<br />

Average Variance Extracted<br />

Item<br />

Squared multiple correlati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

CF 0.542<br />

SIQ 0.715<br />

CustNPD 0.750<br />

Average Variance Extracted 66.90 %<br />

IM 0.721<br />

CCC 0.546<br />

Average Variance Extracted 63.35 %<br />

AssBr<strong>and</strong> 0.659<br />

RP 0.574<br />

Average Variance Extracted 61.65 %<br />

Fair<br />

Sales<br />

0.596<br />

0.646<br />

Average Variance Extracted 62.12 %<br />

In Table 4.4, the c<strong>on</strong>struct reliabilities are presented. All are above the 0.7<br />

Alpha Chr<strong>on</strong>bach <strong>value</strong> recommended by Hair et al. (2006).<br />

Table 4.4<br />

C<strong>on</strong>struct Reliability<br />

C<strong>on</strong>struct<br />

C<strong>on</strong>struct Reliability<br />

Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness .857<br />

IdRR .774<br />

Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value .762<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> .766<br />

Our chi square statistic is 2 = 24.34, p>.228 with 20 degrees of freedom. The<br />

2 to degrees of freedom rati<strong>on</strong> is 1.2. Our chi square results are within the acceptable<br />

range as delineated by Hair et al. (2006). The model has a GFI <strong>value</strong> of 0.937, which<br />

is c<strong>on</strong>sidered good. The RMSEA <strong>value</strong> is good at 0.050. The CFI <strong>value</strong> is acceptable<br />

at 0.906, <strong>and</strong> so is the IFI <strong>value</strong> at 0.930.<br />

103


4.6 SEM<br />

The SEM model was identified with a good fit with 10 measured variables. This gave<br />

us a ratio of about eight resp<strong>on</strong>dents for every observed variable (87/10), which is<br />

below the recommended limit of ten resp<strong>on</strong>dents for every item (Hair et al., 2006, p.<br />

166). We have five c<strong>on</strong>structs, which is less than the maximum recommended of 20<br />

for using the SEM technique. The results of the SEM are presented in Table 4.5.<br />

We have <strong>on</strong>e exogenous c<strong>on</strong>struct, <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. We have four<br />

endogenous c<strong>on</strong>structs: IdRR, satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong>. We also tested for unidimensi<strong>on</strong>ality. Our results indicated that our factors load<br />

<strong>on</strong> more than <strong>on</strong>e factor, so unidimensi<strong>on</strong>ality is not a c<strong>on</strong>cern. We used the<br />

maximum likelihood opti<strong>on</strong> for estimating our model. The model has 55 distinct<br />

sample moments, 35 distinct parameters to estimate, <strong>and</strong> 30 degrees of freedom. A<br />

good model fit is achieved with 10 items. Our model has a good GFI <strong>value</strong> of 0.909.<br />

Our current model is acceptable with a RMSEA of 0.087. The sec<strong>on</strong>d category of fit<br />

indices is incremental fit measures. Our model has a TLI <strong>value</strong> of.923 an incremental<br />

fit index, which is c<strong>on</strong>sidered good. The comparative fit index (CFI) is an indices<br />

specifically meant for samples with small sizes (Hair et al., 2006). The objective<br />

model scores well with 0.949 <strong>and</strong> is a very good fit.<br />

The hypothesis <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness negatively influences IdRR is<br />

supported. It indicates also that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is indeed an antecedent to<br />

IdRR with a β=-0.957, p


Table 4.5<br />

SEM Results<br />

C<strong>on</strong>struct Directi<strong>on</strong> C<strong>on</strong>struct St<strong>and</strong>ardized<br />

Estimate<br />

P Values Hypothesis C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong><br />

IdRR Supplier Res -.957 *** 1 Supported<br />

Satisfacti<strong>on</strong> Supplier Res .863 *** 2 Supported<br />

Supplier Br<strong>and</strong><br />

Value<br />

Buyer Firm<br />

Profit<br />

Buyer Firm<br />

Profit<br />

IdRR -.995 *** 4 Supported<br />

Buyer<br />

Satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

Supplier Br<strong>and</strong><br />

Value<br />

.339 .259 3 Not Sup.<br />

-.361 .243 5 Not Sup.<br />

105


Table 4.6<br />

Summary of Goodness of Fit Statistics <strong>and</strong> SE Hypotheses Results<br />

U.S. Data Model Chapter 2 Objective Model Chapter 4<br />

GFI 0.939 0.909<br />

CFI 0.953 0.949<br />

TLI 0.930 0.923<br />

RMSEA 0.072 0.087<br />

Hypothesis 1 (S.R->IdRR) -0.980*** -.957***<br />

Hypothesis 2 (S.R->B.S) 0.873*** .863***<br />

Hypothesis 3 (B.S.->BFV) Insignificant Insignificant<br />

Hypothesis 4 (IdRR->SBV) -0.992*** -.995***<br />

Hypothesis 5 (SBV->BFV or BFP) 0.976*** Insignificant<br />

***significant at the.0001 level. *significant at the.01 level. SE=St<strong>and</strong>ard Estimates<br />

N.B. Buyer <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> is measured based <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> percepti<strong>on</strong>s; therefore, the model in chapter 2 is called in the subjective model whereas the model in this chapter measures<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> using accounting data <strong>and</strong> therefore is called the objective model. S.R.= Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, IdRR=Idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, BS=Buyer satisfacti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

SBV=Supplier br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, BFV= Buyer <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>/Buyer <strong>firm</strong> profits (objective).<br />

106


4.7 Discussi<strong>on</strong><br />

We start this discussi<strong>on</strong> secti<strong>on</strong> with an important clarificati<strong>on</strong>. The purpose of this<br />

current paper was not to take an absolute positi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> whether objective or subjective<br />

measurement was superior, nor was the intenti<strong>on</strong> to enter into a philosophical debate<br />

about whether any measures could ever be c<strong>on</strong>sidered objective. Rather, it was to<br />

determine whether objective <strong>and</strong> subjective performance measures reinforce each other.<br />

We have not found evidence to indicate that this occurs in our current data set.<br />

For this paper, we adopt the theoretical lens of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. We argue that<br />

both objective <strong>and</strong> subjective data can be used in t<strong>and</strong>em for the model in Chapter 2.<br />

Hence, we expected to find that regardless of the data type used in the model, <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness reduces IdRR <strong>and</strong> results in improved <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. Our<br />

current research draws <strong>on</strong> prior research in market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> B2B literature, <strong>and</strong> our<br />

results c<strong>on</strong>tribute to both literature streams. In the rest of this secti<strong>on</strong>, we discuss the<br />

measurement model hypothesis results <strong>and</strong> the structural model hypothesis results.<br />

4.7.1 Measurement Model Hypothesis<br />

In our hypothesis 1(a), we predicted that our measurement model would be similar to the<br />

model in Chapter 2. At least in terms of fit statistics, our predicti<strong>on</strong> was correct. Overall,<br />

our fit statistics were acceptable. The objective model has a slightly worse RMSEA (0.5)<br />

than the model in chapter 2 RMSEA (0.67). The model in this Chapter has a GFI <strong>and</strong> CFI<br />

of .937 <strong>and</strong> .906, whereas the Chapter 2 has a .95 for GFI <strong>and</strong> .96 for CFI. The<br />

differences are minor differences between both CFAs in terms of goodness of fit indices.<br />

This is because the data used in the CFA in Chapter 4 is a subsample of the data used in<br />

Chapter 2. Furthermore, our c<strong>on</strong>struct reliability <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>struct validity are acceptable for<br />

the CFA of Chapter 4. The c<strong>on</strong>struct reliability <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>struct validity are also acceptable<br />

for the CFA of Chapter 2 except for the variable <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. This difference in<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct validity can be explained as managers publically listed <strong>firm</strong>s underst<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> as a variable of importance whereas this importance is not of such a<br />

great c<strong>on</strong>cern to managers of unlisted companies. For <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness in Chapter<br />

4 the average variance extracted (AVE) was 66.90% <strong>and</strong> our c<strong>on</strong>struct reliability (CR)<br />

was 0.857 compared with the 47% AVE of the model in Chapter 2 <strong>and</strong> a CR of 0.72. For<br />

IdRR, we got an AVE of 63.35% <strong>and</strong> CR of 0.774 compared with the AVE of 54% of the<br />

model in Chapter 2 <strong>and</strong> CR of 0.71. For <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> the AVE is 62.12% in Chapter<br />

4 <strong>and</strong> a CR of 0.76, whereas the model in chapter 2 had an AVE of 59.2% <strong>and</strong> a CR of<br />

0.74. For <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, we had an AVE of 61.65% <strong>and</strong> a CR of 0.76 compared<br />

with the model in Chapter 2 that had an AVE of 37.5% <strong>and</strong> a CR of 0.54.<br />

Finding c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory factor analysis studies for comparis<strong>on</strong> has been challenging<br />

because of the limited number of similar studies. At a general level, numerous intraorganizati<strong>on</strong><br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> studies have been undertaken, but inter-organizati<strong>on</strong><br />

studies are very scarce, <strong>and</strong> studies examining objective <strong>and</strong> subjective data in marketing<br />

with c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory factor analysis are even more limited (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990;<br />

Kohli et al., 1993). In additi<strong>on</strong> to the c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory factor analysis, we also c<strong>on</strong>ducted a<br />

bivariate correlati<strong>on</strong> analysis between subjective <strong>and</strong> objective measures for comparis<strong>on</strong><br />

purposes. Like Jaworski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993), we found an insignificant correlati<strong>on</strong> between<br />

107


oth measures. Although Jaworski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993) attributed this to a lagged effect that<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> has <strong>on</strong> performance, we took care to use objective performance, which<br />

measured the difference in corporate earnings over a three-year period. Hence, our<br />

findings suggest that it is not because of a lagged effect that subjective <strong>and</strong> objective<br />

measures do not reinforce each other. Our findings also c<strong>on</strong>tradict the findings of Dawes<br />

(1999), Jayach<strong>and</strong>ran <strong>and</strong> Varadarajan (2006), <strong>and</strong> Naman <strong>and</strong> Slevin (1993), who found<br />

that objective <strong>and</strong> subjective measures are str<strong>on</strong>gly <strong>and</strong> positively linked. Rather, our<br />

findings reinforce to some extent the findings of Harris (2001) that objective measures<br />

may work for a narrower range of items than subjective measures do.<br />

Table 4.7<br />

Measurement Model Indices<br />

Goodness of fit index Chapter 2 Model Chapter 4 Model<br />

χ 2 /degrees of freedom 1.76 1.217<br />

Tucker Lewis Index (TLI) 0.94 0.83<br />

Goodness-of-Fit Index<br />

0.95 0.93<br />

(GFI)<br />

Incremental Fit Index (IFI) 0.96 0.93<br />

Comparative Fit Index<br />

0.96 0.90<br />

(CFI)<br />

Root Mean Square Error<br />

0.06 0.05<br />

of Approximati<strong>on</strong><br />

(RMSEA)<br />

4.7.2 SEM Model Hypotheses<br />

Our hypothesis 1 (b) was related to the structural model <strong>and</strong> predicted a fit between the<br />

objective data (Chapter 4) <strong>and</strong> the subjective data models (Chapter 2). For this purpose,<br />

we will discuss each of the five hypotheses of the model in Chapter 2 that we tested in the<br />

current chapter using the objective data dependent variable <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> (measured<br />

by the difference in net income between the years 2009 <strong>and</strong> 2011).<br />

Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to IdRR.<br />

To be marketing oriented is not to be safe because you’re running a risk. You<br />

have to invest in your ideas. To not be market oriented is to be safe. [It means<br />

doing nothing] the same old [thing]. You’re not investing in your business, not<br />

[taking] risks.<br />

—president of an industrial services<br />

company (adapted from Kohli &<br />

Jaworski, 1990)<br />

108


Jaowrski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993) provided an intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al perspective <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>supplier</strong> or seller resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> managerial risk percepti<strong>on</strong>s. Numerous other studies<br />

have reflected their findings. However, to our knowledge, few studies examine <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al risk (Baker, Simps<strong>on</strong>, & Siguaw, 1999). For<br />

instance, Baker et al. (1999) focused <strong>on</strong> positive relati<strong>on</strong>al indicators, but did not focus<br />

specifically <strong>on</strong> IdRR. To the best of our knowledge, aside from the Chapter 2 <strong>and</strong> Chapter<br />

3 studies, <strong>on</strong>ly our current study solely examines the influence of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

<strong>on</strong> IdRR in the c<strong>on</strong>text of publically listed <strong>firm</strong>s. The Chapter 2 sample was a mixture of<br />

publically <strong>and</strong> privately held companies. Normally, publically <strong>and</strong> privately listed <strong>firm</strong>s<br />

differ <strong>on</strong> a number of issues, including corporate accountability, risk averseness, <strong>and</strong><br />

innovativeness. Therefore, the c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of our current study is that it provides<br />

evidence that publically listed <strong>firm</strong>s have the mediator of IdRR in <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

<strong>and</strong> performance linkage. This means that being a publically listed <strong>firm</strong> does not reduce<br />

the importance of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness in insulating it from IdRR. However, this<br />

effect is str<strong>on</strong>ger in the model in Chapter 2. Hence, we believe that privately listed <strong>firm</strong>s<br />

are more susceptible to the acti<strong>on</strong>s of their strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s because of their smaller<br />

size <strong>and</strong> limited resources.<br />

IdRR to <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. The hypothesis examines the influence of IdRR <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Prior research has indicated that B2B br<strong>and</strong>s help customers<br />

evaluate whether a br<strong>and</strong> choice reduces their perceived organizati<strong>on</strong>al risk (Baker et al.,<br />

1999). In a way, our results are similar to Mudambi, Doyle, & W<strong>on</strong>g, (1997) c<strong>on</strong>tenti<strong>on</strong><br />

that risk reducti<strong>on</strong> leads to greater perceived <strong>value</strong> for the <strong>supplier</strong>s' br<strong>and</strong>. But our study<br />

offers an additi<strong>on</strong>al insight because risk reducti<strong>on</strong> is an outcome of the process of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> rather than direct br<strong>and</strong>ing efforts by the <strong>firm</strong>. Furthermore, in line with<br />

Mudambi et al. (1997), we assume that this <strong>value</strong> is created because of intangible <strong>value</strong> or<br />

benefits from the relati<strong>on</strong>ship. This means that idiosyncratic processes that are not visible<br />

to the competitors serve as unique generators of <strong>value</strong> that would be difficult to replicate.<br />

This is important because <strong>firm</strong>s that are competent at creating unique br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> have<br />

higher returns (Mudambi et al., 1997). For B2B managers, this could be a str<strong>on</strong>g selling<br />

point when they are arguing for a greater emphasis <strong>on</strong> br<strong>and</strong>ing in fr<strong>on</strong>t of top<br />

management. Compared to the study in Chapter 2, we find that the st<strong>and</strong>ardized<br />

regressi<strong>on</strong> weight for this hypothesis is weaker in the objective model. In line with our<br />

prior suggesti<strong>on</strong> that smaller <strong>firm</strong>s are more susceptible to <strong>supplier</strong> acti<strong>on</strong>s than larger<br />

<strong>firm</strong>s are, the effects are str<strong>on</strong>ger in Chapter 2, which is based <strong>on</strong> a sample of both<br />

publically <strong>and</strong> privately traded <strong>firm</strong>s.<br />

Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness to <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> to <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong><br />

profit, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> to <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> profit. Our next set of hypotheses deal with the<br />

influence of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

influence <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> profits. Supplier resp<strong>on</strong>siveness results in <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. In<br />

turn, we found that satisfacti<strong>on</strong> did not positively influence objective <strong>firm</strong> earning data or<br />

profits. There could be <strong>on</strong>e of two explanati<strong>on</strong>s for these results. The first is that objective<br />

<strong>and</strong> subjective performance data are imperfect substitutes, so the results differ. However,<br />

we overrule this explanati<strong>on</strong> because the subjective model also did not c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> this<br />

109


hypothesis. Hence, we offer an alternative explanati<strong>on</strong> that arises from a rhetorical<br />

questi<strong>on</strong>. Does customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> hold meaning for a B2B <strong>supplier</strong>? The literature is<br />

muddled about the role of satisfacti<strong>on</strong> (Nary<strong>and</strong>as, 2005). Our research adds to this<br />

because we find no relati<strong>on</strong>ship between <strong>buyer</strong>s' satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> their own profits. This<br />

implies that satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is not a valid indicator of <strong>firm</strong> profits in business markets. Even<br />

though we define satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as an evaluati<strong>on</strong> of the ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>ec<strong>on</strong>omic aspects<br />

of a relati<strong>on</strong>ship, our c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>atory factor analysis greatly reduced the number of<br />

measures we had <strong>and</strong> limited them to items measuring <strong>on</strong>ly the relati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong><br />

n<strong>on</strong>ec<strong>on</strong>omic aspects of satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. Therefore, it is possible that our current model has<br />

<strong>on</strong>ly captured the n<strong>on</strong>ec<strong>on</strong>omic porti<strong>on</strong> of customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> that is not linked to<br />

customer profits.<br />

Our fifth hypothesis is insignificant, which c<strong>on</strong>trasts with the model in Chapter 2<br />

that found a significant positive effect. We believe this is because of the incompatibility<br />

of subjective <strong>and</strong> objective measures. It seems that subjective measures do not fully<br />

capture the entirety of what objective measures do. Hence, we find an insignificant<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

4.7.3 Some Insights from Informal Discussi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

We c<strong>on</strong>ducted informal discussi<strong>on</strong>s with academics <strong>and</strong> practiti<strong>on</strong>ers to further explain<br />

the results of our model. We focused <strong>on</strong> determining the reas<strong>on</strong> for the disc<strong>on</strong>nect<br />

between managers' reported self-measures <strong>and</strong> accounting measures? The first<br />

explanati<strong>on</strong> could be that managers tend to be overly optimistic about the future <strong>and</strong><br />

accounting measures of the past do not reinforce their underst<strong>and</strong>ing. The sec<strong>on</strong>d<br />

explanati<strong>on</strong> could be that managers do not underst<strong>and</strong> their business models fully. This is<br />

because relevant informati<strong>on</strong> may not be diffused within the organizati<strong>on</strong>. (Indeed, this<br />

could lead future researchers to questi<strong>on</strong> the relevance of resp<strong>on</strong>sive <strong>supplier</strong>s when <strong>firm</strong>s<br />

themselves are not market-oriented). The third possibility could be that managers lack the<br />

overall accounting background to come to judgments about profitability that reflects<br />

accounting measures. The fourth explanati<strong>on</strong> could be that the complexity of the<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship makes it difficult for an individual to heuristically decide which directi<strong>on</strong> it is<br />

going in. The fifth explanati<strong>on</strong> could be that current accounting measures are inadequate<br />

for measuring the <strong>value</strong> created by such relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<br />

But the discrepancy between employee percepti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> financial measures is not<br />

something unique. For instance, our sample included many big name <strong>firm</strong>s such as<br />

Microsoft. A recent venture by Microsoft to be the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> to Nokia of<br />

Windows 7 has been received negatively by investors, plummeting their stock prices<br />

downward. Although representatives of both <strong>firm</strong>s are enthusiastic <strong>and</strong> optimistic about<br />

the current alliance, the financial markets do not share their enthusiasm.<br />

We also did not assume that purchasing managers had never been exposed to<br />

accounting measures. From discussi<strong>on</strong>s we engaged in we learned that they had been<br />

exposure to financial measures. Such measures most probably are taken into account<br />

when purchasing managers make financial judgments or predicti<strong>on</strong>s. But in all likelihood,<br />

purchasing managers' evaluati<strong>on</strong>s differ from objective measures because of <strong>on</strong>e of the<br />

above five possibilities.<br />

110


Using the findings of our current studies, <strong>firm</strong>s could be motivated to implements<br />

programs that bring managers' percepti<strong>on</strong>s more in line with accounting performance<br />

data. One positive outcome of such a maneuver is that it could improve the <strong>buyer</strong><strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships since it would make their expectati<strong>on</strong>s of each other more realistic.<br />

4.7.4 Managerial Implicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

The findings of this study that the model in Chapter 2 is not validated when objective<br />

data are used for <strong>buyer</strong>-<strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> causes us some c<strong>on</strong>cern. We decided to collect some<br />

managerial opini<strong>on</strong>s about subjective <strong>and</strong> objective assessments. We c<strong>on</strong>ducted informal<br />

discussi<strong>on</strong>s with four current or former managers in B2B <strong>and</strong> B2C <strong>firm</strong>s. The<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>dents were from mid-management with experience in channel <strong>and</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship<br />

management. On average, the managers had more than <strong>on</strong>e decade of experience in a<br />

managerial capacity. We now synthesize the resp<strong>on</strong>ses to the two key questi<strong>on</strong>s asked<br />

during the interviews: (1) From your experience, do managers' subjective assessments<br />

(e.g., estimating risk or profit by a guess or experience) differ substantially from actual<br />

accounting or performance data? If so, why? (2) Does the impact of a managerial model<br />

diminish if it <strong>on</strong>ly supports perceptual data <strong>and</strong> not objective data?<br />

Our interviews revealed that managers do find variati<strong>on</strong>s in subjective <strong>and</strong> accounting<br />

data. A main reas<strong>on</strong> for this was the lack of substitutability of both measures. Another<br />

important issue was that many targets do not have objective measures. Furthermore, most<br />

assessments are time-bound. It normally is quicker to c<strong>on</strong>duct a subjective assessment<br />

compared to an objective assessment. Managers believed that objective indicators are<br />

most effective when used in t<strong>and</strong>em with subjective indicators. Likewise, they argued<br />

that many objective indicators were too broad <strong>and</strong> not <strong>firm</strong>-specific, so they c<strong>on</strong>sidered<br />

them difficult to comprehend <strong>and</strong> not suitable at times. But percepti<strong>on</strong>s of the usefulness<br />

of subjective <strong>and</strong> objective indicators also varied by functi<strong>on</strong>al department. The<br />

prop<strong>on</strong>ents of both subjective <strong>and</strong> objective indicators were managers from marketing,<br />

whereas, the primary opp<strong>on</strong>ents were from accounting. The c<strong>on</strong>sensus of the managers<br />

was that objective <strong>and</strong> subjective measures were not used solely based <strong>on</strong> their reliability,<br />

but rather depending up<strong>on</strong> the top managements' inclinati<strong>on</strong> toward certain categories of<br />

metrics. This was especially the case with marketing within the creative industries.<br />

Another issue was that perceptual metrics allowed <strong>firm</strong>s to measure their own<br />

idiosyncratic processes that gave them a competitive edge in the marketplace. As l<strong>on</strong>g as<br />

a model focused <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong>-level idiosyncrasies, a perceptual model would be fine.<br />

However, if they were to measure more widespread <strong>and</strong> general performance aspects,<br />

then a model that works with objective indicators might be required.<br />

In summati<strong>on</strong>, the implicati<strong>on</strong>s of the answers of our two questi<strong>on</strong>s for the model<br />

in Chapter 2 are: i) subjective assessment <strong>and</strong> objective assessment do matter; ii) <strong>on</strong>e<br />

metric is <strong>on</strong>ly better than the other depending up<strong>on</strong> the situati<strong>on</strong> in which the metric is<br />

used; iii) subjective metrics are more versatile than objective metrics; iv) <strong>firm</strong>s often do<br />

not expect subjective <strong>and</strong> objective metrics to reinforce each other; <strong>and</strong> v) models that<br />

measure idiosyncratic process can use perceptual metrics because objective metrics<br />

normally are not specific enough. Therefore, despite its lack of verificati<strong>on</strong> by objective<br />

indicators, the perceptual performance-based model by Chapter 2 would matter to<br />

111


managers because of the insights it offers.<br />

4.8 Limitati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

The first limitati<strong>on</strong> of this paper is that we do not c<strong>on</strong>sider the moderator of market<br />

turbulence. Although the data were collected during the financial recessi<strong>on</strong>, we did not<br />

wait for a post-recessi<strong>on</strong> window or sample to check whether market turbulence<br />

influenced the customers' evaluati<strong>on</strong>s of resp<strong>on</strong>sive or market-oriented strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s. Prior research (Grewal & Tansuhaj, 2001) has provided some evidence to<br />

indicate that market orientati<strong>on</strong> during recessi<strong>on</strong>s may actually exacerbate a decline in the<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship since the <strong>supplier</strong>s' or sellers' resp<strong>on</strong>se is based <strong>on</strong> knowledge structure built<br />

<strong>on</strong> a market prior to the changes brought about by the recessi<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d limitati<strong>on</strong> is the tradeoff we had to make between cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong><br />

l<strong>on</strong>gitudinal data. Therefore, we could not shed light <strong>on</strong> the causality of the relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<br />

This shortcoming could be overcome by c<strong>on</strong>structing an index of resp<strong>on</strong>dents over a<br />

number of years or periods (Diamantopoulos & Winklhofer, 2001). It is possible that in<br />

future studies, further additi<strong>on</strong>s could be made to the model we have proposed.<br />

The third limitati<strong>on</strong> is that we do not compare IdRR <strong>on</strong> both the perceptual <strong>and</strong><br />

objective data levels. This shortcoming is hard to overcome because there are no readily<br />

available objective measures for this c<strong>on</strong>struct. However, a composite measure could be<br />

created by future researchers based <strong>on</strong> accounting <strong>and</strong> financial data.<br />

The fourth limitati<strong>on</strong> is that we could have added more <strong>value</strong> measurement<br />

variables rather than <strong>on</strong>ly IdRR insulati<strong>on</strong>. This would have provided us the opportunity<br />

to benchmark <strong>on</strong> a dashboard <strong>and</strong> examine how IdRR insulati<strong>on</strong> performs against similar<br />

measures of <strong>value</strong> creati<strong>on</strong>. This is important because a measure needs to be<br />

benchmarked against similar measures to determine whether it is a valid indicator.<br />

The fifth limitati<strong>on</strong> is that we <strong>on</strong>ly had objective data <strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly <strong>on</strong>e variable. We do<br />

not receive any variati<strong>on</strong> of the prior three hypotheses because the data are identical. In<br />

future studies, all variables could be objective, which would give a further indicati<strong>on</strong> of<br />

how well the data fit.<br />

The sixth limitati<strong>on</strong> of this paper is its research design. We use a survey, which<br />

limits the amount of c<strong>on</strong>trol we have over the variables. An experimental design would<br />

have allowed us to test for a wider variety of metrics <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>trol variables. This could<br />

reveal whether some objective <strong>and</strong> subjective metrics do reinforce each other.<br />

4.9 Future Directi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Although there are many possible future directi<strong>on</strong>s, we had to limit ourselves to<br />

those which we felt were most important. These are listed below.<br />

i) One course for future researchers could be to examine the role of <strong>firm</strong><br />

culture in accepting subjective or objective measures as valid indicators of<br />

performance. This is important because it could also explain why<br />

resources are misdirected because of inaccurate percepti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> their<br />

reliability as valid measurement tools.<br />

ii) In the current study, we used corporate-level objective indicators. Using<br />

department-level specific metrics instead could res<strong>on</strong>ate better with<br />

managers' underst<strong>and</strong>ing of how much profit their departments produce.<br />

112


iii)<br />

iv)<br />

Indeed, there may not be much difference between objective <strong>and</strong><br />

subjective measurement indicators at the same level throughout the<br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

We based our analysis <strong>on</strong> the assumpti<strong>on</strong> that the purchase manager had<br />

the most influence. However, as Gord<strong>on</strong>, Calat<strong>on</strong>e, <strong>and</strong> Di Bennetto<br />

(1993) predicted, the most influential is not necessarily the most senior<br />

pers<strong>on</strong> in a buying center. Future researchers could examine whether the<br />

most influential pers<strong>on</strong> has greater accuracy in predicting objective<br />

measures.<br />

Another interesting avenue for future studies could be investigating why<br />

some employees are better than others at providing percepti<strong>on</strong>s that<br />

reinforce objective measures. Could this possibly be because of a better<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of <strong>firm</strong> processes, or is it because of a relevant educati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

background?<br />

4.10 C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

The litmus test for marketing metrics is the insights they generate. Do the insights<br />

matter <strong>and</strong> can the findings be replicated by similar metrics?<br />

——Fasi Zaka, Marketing Director at the British<br />

Council (pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong>, 2011)<br />

In many B2B markets, strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s can differentiate their offerings by<br />

customer-centric strategies such as market orientati<strong>on</strong>. But market orientati<strong>on</strong> involves<br />

substantial investment <strong>and</strong> effort by the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong>. Therefore, measuring the<br />

<strong>buyer</strong>s' returns <strong>on</strong> such investments is of interest for the <strong>supplier</strong>s to gauge how<br />

successful they have been. We examined two broad categories of measurement metrics,<br />

namely objective <strong>and</strong> subjective performance metrics. C<strong>on</strong>sequently, we identified an<br />

important flaw in current management assumpti<strong>on</strong>s: Despite managements' assumpti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

that their heuristic or subjective judgments should reinforce objective performance<br />

measurements of key <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships, they do not. Qualitative data showed that this<br />

was not because of a problem with the logic of the Chapter 2 model. Rather, it was<br />

because of the limitati<strong>on</strong>s of managers <strong>and</strong> current metrics.<br />

We proposed the following steps to overcome this problem: first, instituting<br />

programs for marketing managers to equip them with the skills needed for c<strong>on</strong>ducting<br />

heuristic evaluati<strong>on</strong>s that are more in line with accounting evaluati<strong>on</strong>s; sec<strong>on</strong>d, educating<br />

finance managers about the intangible <strong>value</strong> that marketing creates; third, creating new<br />

hybrid measures that represent both the marketing <strong>and</strong> accounting perspectives; <strong>and</strong><br />

fourth, simplifying existing objective measurement procedures <strong>and</strong> methods so managers<br />

can comprehend what the core elements are in calculating market returns. Once such<br />

measures have been instituted, we believe that the measurement gap between objective<br />

<strong>and</strong> subjective performance measures for key <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships will diminish.<br />

113


Chapter 5<br />

C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

This final chapter presents the c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> managerial <strong>and</strong> academic implicati<strong>on</strong>s of<br />

the research. Secti<strong>on</strong> 5.1 presents a short synopsis of the three studies in the dissertati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The subsequent secti<strong>on</strong> 5.2 presents the answers of the research questi<strong>on</strong>s. The following<br />

secti<strong>on</strong>, 5.3, c<strong>on</strong>tains a discussi<strong>on</strong> of the general c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s derived from this research.<br />

The next secti<strong>on</strong>, secti<strong>on</strong> 5.4, provides the theoretical implicati<strong>on</strong>s of the studies, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

chapter ends with c<strong>on</strong>cluding remarks.<br />

5.1 Research Findings<br />

The first essay of this dissertati<strong>on</strong> examines the influence of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance based <strong>on</strong> a sample of 164 business–to-business (B2B) <strong>firm</strong>s in<br />

the United States. In this study, it is emphasized that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness creates<br />

dyadic <strong>value</strong> by reducing idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk (IdRR). IdRR is risk that exists<br />

because of entering into a specific relati<strong>on</strong>ship with another company. IdRR reducti<strong>on</strong> is<br />

the mechanism by which market-based assets are created for the <strong>supplier</strong>. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, soft indicators such as satisfacti<strong>on</strong> have shown no link to dyadic <strong>value</strong> or <strong>buyer</strong><br />

<strong>firm</strong> profits al<strong>on</strong>e. This study challenges the l<strong>on</strong>g-held assumpti<strong>on</strong> that market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> risk are positively related <strong>and</strong>, at least in strategic B2B c<strong>on</strong>texts, we find evidence to<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>trary.<br />

The sec<strong>on</strong>d essay looks at differences between the applicati<strong>on</strong> of the model<br />

presented in the Chapter 2 in different cultural c<strong>on</strong>texts. The research sample included 92<br />

<strong>firm</strong>s from the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the original 164 from the U.S. The core emphasis of this<br />

study was determining whether the mediators of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance were the same across nati<strong>on</strong>al cultural boundaries. Using the<br />

Hofstede index as the driving logic behind the comparis<strong>on</strong> of the two samples, our model<br />

showed significant differences. In the United States, soft indicators did not present a link<br />

to <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance, whereas they did in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. The implicati<strong>on</strong> for<br />

management is that, when developing marketing strategy, they have to adopt periscopic<br />

perspectives bey<strong>on</strong>d their own cultural spheres. This might include adopting a regi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

br<strong>and</strong>ing strategy where stark nati<strong>on</strong>al differences cannot be served by a single br<strong>and</strong><br />

message.<br />

The third essay is motivated by the need to examine whether different<br />

performance measures would reinforce each other in the model outlined in Chapter 2.<br />

Managers habitually trust their heuristic judgments. The extant literature <strong>on</strong> the accuracy<br />

of such judgments is mixed. Such judgments are often formed as a result of cumulative<br />

background informati<strong>on</strong>, both objective <strong>and</strong> subjective. We anticipated that, since<br />

strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships involve a great degree of cooperati<strong>on</strong>, a manager’s assessment<br />

would be aligned with objective performance measures. However, we found that<br />

subjective <strong>and</strong> objective performance measures did not provide similar results.<br />

5.2 Overall Global Research Questi<strong>on</strong> Answer<br />

To our global level research questi<strong>on</strong> that “What is the impact of <strong>supplier</strong> market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> through idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>?” we find, indeed <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> does influence<br />

114


uyer <strong>firm</strong> performance through a series of mediators. However, not all mediators have a<br />

significant influence <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Particularly, in the c<strong>on</strong>text of the U.S. <strong>and</strong> The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. We find that <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does not matter in the U.S., but it does<br />

matter in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. We argue that this is a result of the different nati<strong>on</strong>al cultures,<br />

specifically a Dutch feminine culture focuses more <strong>on</strong> soft factors, such as informal<br />

interacti<strong>on</strong> between the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong>. However, the U.S. is a more masculine<br />

society where hard factors matter more such as factors related to the bottom line such as<br />

IdRR. Given, this importance of hard or objective factors in the United States, led us to<br />

questi<strong>on</strong> whether perceptual metrics would reinforce objective factors because marketers<br />

use many heuristic measures in decisi<strong>on</strong> making. Moreover, we were motivated in part<br />

<strong>on</strong> recent research findings that the marketing department’s influence in the <strong>firm</strong><br />

increases when they are more accountable for the m<strong>on</strong>ey that they have spent (Verhoef &<br />

Leeflang, 2009). Hence, for the <strong>supplier</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> to learn about their <strong>buyer</strong>’s needs, <strong>and</strong><br />

later formulate a resp<strong>on</strong>se to those <strong>buyer</strong>’s needs the <strong>supplier</strong>’s marketing department<br />

requires a sizeable marketing budget. And in order to be allocated adequate budgets the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s marketing department needs to be able to communicate the <strong>value</strong> created by<br />

them to their own financial department <strong>and</strong> their <strong>buyer</strong>’s financial departments.<br />

Therefore, we investigated whether perceptual metrics based <strong>on</strong> managerial percepti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

would be c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ed by metrics preferred by financial managers namely, objective<br />

accounting metrics. However, we find that they are not. The primary reas<strong>on</strong> we suggest is<br />

that perceptual metrics are not perfectly substitutable by objective accounting metrics.<br />

Hence, we recommend that <strong>firm</strong>s to develop substitutable perceptual metrics.<br />

In summati<strong>on</strong>, we have found that strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness does<br />

influence <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>, although this effect does not always flow through the same<br />

channel. On the <strong>on</strong>e h<strong>and</strong>, in the case of the United States a <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

must reduce IdRR <strong>and</strong> then c<strong>on</strong>sequently creates <strong>value</strong> for the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> through<br />

br<strong>and</strong> preference exhibited by the <strong>buyer</strong>, whereas for the <strong>buyer</strong> it creates <strong>value</strong> through<br />

stable <strong>and</strong> accelerated cash flows. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, in countries with a feminine culture<br />

like The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s we find an additi<strong>on</strong>al way of increasing <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>and</strong> that is<br />

through increasing <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. Hence, an implicati<strong>on</strong> for managers is that they<br />

should rely <strong>on</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly if satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is a reliable indicator in the nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

cultural c<strong>on</strong>text. In additi<strong>on</strong>, IdRR is a preferable metric as it is applicable in more<br />

c<strong>on</strong>texts than <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. This is because IdRR measures idiosyncratic risk, <strong>and</strong><br />

risk has its origins in the field of finance which makes it a more easy to relate to financial<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cepts, <strong>and</strong> therefore, is more acceptable to managers. Moreover, we recommend that<br />

managers develop perceptual measures for marketing <strong>and</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance that are<br />

substitutable with financial measures because based <strong>on</strong> our data we found that currently<br />

managers use performance measures that are not substitutable. Hence, though marketing<br />

may generate <strong>value</strong> for <strong>buyer</strong>s through strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, it does not show<br />

up <strong>on</strong> balance sheet measures, <strong>and</strong> hence, the marketing effort is difficult to justify to the<br />

customers.<br />

In c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>, strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is an important mechanism of<br />

creating <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

115


5.3 Overall C<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

This dissertati<strong>on</strong> focuses <strong>on</strong> strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, also known as B2B market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>, idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk, cross-cultural comparis<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> subjective <strong>and</strong><br />

objective performance measurement. The extant literature <strong>on</strong> business-to-business market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> includes limited research focusing primarily <strong>on</strong> interesting questi<strong>on</strong>s such as<br />

whether market orientati<strong>on</strong> cultures can be diffused across organizati<strong>on</strong>al boundaries<br />

(Siguaw et al., 1998). However, the B2B market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a research domain has<br />

many more interesting questi<strong>on</strong>s that need to be answered. In line with market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

from the intra-<strong>firm</strong> perspective, the mediators between the market orientati<strong>on</strong> or<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness strategy <strong>and</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong> performance implicati<strong>on</strong>s are <strong>on</strong>e such avenue.<br />

Particularly, am<strong>on</strong>g the wide array of questi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong>e could chose from, risk was a<br />

comp<strong>on</strong>ent that was enticing because of the macroec<strong>on</strong>omic factors that have made risk a<br />

key topic of interest <strong>and</strong> because market orientati<strong>on</strong> is thought to exacerbate intraorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk. Then, would it logically also apply in the inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

c<strong>on</strong>text? Therefore, our primary research questi<strong>on</strong> investigated in Chapter 2 was:<br />

“Does it Make Relati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong> Financial Sense to be a Resp<strong>on</strong>sive Strategic Supplier?”<br />

Our primary research questi<strong>on</strong> examined whether the much-touted philosophy of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> mattered in B2B c<strong>on</strong>texts. Our study led us to c<strong>on</strong>clude that it does matter.<br />

Unlike the intra-<strong>firm</strong> c<strong>on</strong>texts where market orientati<strong>on</strong> is positively related to top<br />

management risk-taking, in strategic B2B c<strong>on</strong>texts, we found that it is negatively related<br />

to IdRR. To <strong>buyer</strong>s, any <strong>supplier</strong> maneuver matters that reduces their risk; as <strong>on</strong>e<br />

manager remarked, “No <strong>buyer</strong> penalizes a <strong>supplier</strong> for making him safe unless he is<br />

completely irrati<strong>on</strong>al” (Tanoli, pers<strong>on</strong>al communicati<strong>on</strong>, 2012). Our results provide<br />

evidence that a strategic <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> reduced a specific type of relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk, IdRR. The importance of the identificati<strong>on</strong> of this linkage is that, in the marketing<br />

literature, a lot of emphasis is placed <strong>on</strong> reducing overall relati<strong>on</strong>al risk but not IdRR, the<br />

risk comp<strong>on</strong>ent that matters the most because of its positive influence <strong>on</strong> intangible<br />

market-based <strong>supplier</strong> assets <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. Overall, the current chapter<br />

has, to an extent, provided evidence to indicate that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness has str<strong>on</strong>g<br />

performance implicati<strong>on</strong>s for the <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>and</strong>, in additi<strong>on</strong>, implicati<strong>on</strong>s for the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

market-based assets.<br />

In Chapter 3, we deal with the questi<strong>on</strong> of whether <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

mattered across nati<strong>on</strong>al cultural barriers. We found that, even with relatively similar<br />

cultures, there are relatively significant changes. For example, in the United States, soft<br />

indicators such as customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> do not seem to matter much, whereas they do in<br />

the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. However, the core finding that remains c<strong>on</strong>sistent is that IdRR matters<br />

across borders. The c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s of the sec<strong>on</strong>d paper are far-reaching. Primarily, it is<br />

avoiding the familiarity trap. Even though markets may seem the same, peculiar cultural<br />

idiosyncrasies do exist. For a marketing manager sitting in Washingt<strong>on</strong> or Amsterdam,<br />

this could mean the difference between keeping a client account or losing it. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, this finding may seem simplistic to some scholars, but it matters because many<br />

mistakes that do have far reaching results are simplistic. Overall, Chapter 3 has<br />

116


specifically highlighted the importance of nati<strong>on</strong>al cultural barriers while employing a<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> strategy.<br />

In Chapter 4, we investigate both subjective <strong>and</strong> objective indicators for<br />

evaluating the <strong>buyer</strong>’s performance as a result of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>siveness.<br />

As most managers use perceptual judgments or evaluati<strong>on</strong>s when they face complex tasks<br />

(Cassidy, 2009), it is significant to underst<strong>and</strong> whether such judgments reinforce each<br />

other. We find that they do not reinforce each other. This is important because there is a<br />

disc<strong>on</strong>nect between what managers perceive to be important <strong>and</strong> what existing metrics<br />

measure. Firms need to streamline their performance measurement <strong>and</strong> ensure that<br />

existing metrics reinforce what managers with experience believe is important for the<br />

<strong>firm</strong>. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>firm</strong>s can institute training programs to ensure that managers<br />

evaluate al<strong>on</strong>g those performance dimensi<strong>on</strong>s that matter to the <strong>firm</strong>. This could ensure<br />

that subjective <strong>and</strong> objective performance measurements reinforce each other. This is<br />

important because managers have to make day-to-day decisi<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> if they make<br />

decisi<strong>on</strong>s against criteria that are not shared by the <strong>firm</strong>, then it will not show up during<br />

objective performance measurement.<br />

5.4 Theoretical Implicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Regarding market orientati<strong>on</strong> theory, the emphasis is <strong>on</strong> the intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

perspective <strong>and</strong> an IdRR reducti<strong>on</strong> mechanism. These are new insights in the B2B<br />

literature. The market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature has so far had two major limitati<strong>on</strong>s, in our<br />

opini<strong>on</strong>. The first is that the market orientati<strong>on</strong> literature has focused solely <strong>on</strong> the intraorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

perspective. The customer’s input is absent in the extant literature model<br />

testing (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990; Kohli et al., 1993; Narver & Slater, 1990; Slater &<br />

Narver, 1994). Sec<strong>on</strong>d, the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>al risk has<br />

been overlooked by many studies (Langerak, 2001; Langerak et al., 2004; Langerak et al.,<br />

2007). Starting with the latter limitati<strong>on</strong>, we have highlighted the c<strong>on</strong>cept of IdRR.<br />

Rather than focus <strong>on</strong> management predispositi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> predictive percepti<strong>on</strong>s, we cut to<br />

the chase <strong>and</strong> asked buying center managers to reflect up<strong>on</strong> their experiences with their<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s. Our results <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to this literature stream is that we have<br />

brought forth a hitherto latent relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> idiosyncratic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al risk. We have brought a counter-intuitive relati<strong>on</strong>ship to light. It is just a start,<br />

but we have identified a negative relati<strong>on</strong>ship that has been assumed to be positive so far.<br />

As a result, risk-taking companies were <strong>on</strong>ly thought to be more likely to be marketoriented.<br />

This has had far-reaching c<strong>on</strong>sequences, <strong>on</strong>e of which has been to delay<br />

launching new products in times of enhanced risk, such as during recessi<strong>on</strong>s. However,<br />

truly market-oriented companies that underst<strong>and</strong> the latent needs comp<strong>on</strong>ent of the<br />

market have been launched during recessi<strong>on</strong>s. Apple is at the top of the list of these<br />

companies. As <strong>on</strong>e analyst remarked, “Apple is an industry, not a company” (Farzad,<br />

2011, para10).<br />

Given the recent aversi<strong>on</strong> to risk-taking because of the Wall Street sc<strong>and</strong>als,<br />

philosophies such as market orientati<strong>on</strong> have been described in some business circles as a<br />

bad philosophy. Our current c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> is a step in removing this stain from market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> we believe that we have provided some supporting evidence.<br />

117


Regarding the resource-based view <strong>and</strong> market-based assets theory, market-based<br />

assets are those assets that fulfill the requirements of the resource-based view (Srivastava,<br />

Shervani, & Fahey, 1998). Primarily, these are whether the assets are inimitable, hold<br />

<strong>value</strong>, are rare, <strong>and</strong> lack perfect substitutes. The link is discussed in chapter two in terms<br />

of building up market-based assets through internal processes. A key antecedent of<br />

building market-based assets that was not previously identified is IdRR. IdRR qualifies<br />

<strong>on</strong> all four of the resource-based view tests. Furthermore, a reducti<strong>on</strong> in IdRR can be<br />

detected by the external marketplace by increased <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. This leads to<br />

a positi<strong>on</strong> of prestige for the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> adds <strong>value</strong> to the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> that is<br />

difficult to replicate because this increase in br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> is based <strong>on</strong> knowledge that the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> has, <strong>and</strong> it can <strong>on</strong>ly be gained by working in a specific sector <strong>and</strong> with a specific<br />

customer. Linimar is a case in point. It has recently outperformed market expectati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

because of its resp<strong>on</strong>siveness as a <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong>, as a result, it has acquired a positi<strong>on</strong> of<br />

prestige in the market (Marketwire, 2007).<br />

Similar to the c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> to the market orientati<strong>on</strong> theory of this dissertati<strong>on</strong>,<br />

market-based assets theory has focused <strong>on</strong> the inter-<strong>firm</strong> perspective rather than the intra<strong>firm</strong><br />

perspective. By focusing <strong>on</strong> the benefits that both the <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong> acquire<br />

via IdRR reducti<strong>on</strong>, this study adds a new dimensi<strong>on</strong> to the theory.<br />

Regarding br<strong>and</strong> theory, in business-to-business br<strong>and</strong>ing, some scholars have<br />

argued that successful B2B br<strong>and</strong>s require risk reducti<strong>on</strong>, increased informati<strong>on</strong><br />

efficiency, <strong>and</strong> image benefit creati<strong>on</strong> (Kotler, & Pfoertsch, 2006). Though these facets<br />

have been highlighted, how the different processes work <strong>and</strong> the sequence of br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong><br />

creati<strong>on</strong> through these various mechanisms has not been explored. In chapter two of this<br />

dissertati<strong>on</strong>, we explore the sequence of activities that creates br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. This led to the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness/IdRR/<strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>/customer <strong>value</strong> sequence. This<br />

dissertati<strong>on</strong> is a clarificati<strong>on</strong> of how the activities of br<strong>and</strong> building interact with each<br />

other to create <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> customer performance <strong>value</strong>.<br />

Regarding performance measurement theory, in the fourth chapter of this<br />

dissertati<strong>on</strong>, we deal with the thorny issue of performance measures. In the tax<strong>on</strong>omy of<br />

marketing performance measures, a broad categorizati<strong>on</strong> that is applied is the distincti<strong>on</strong><br />

between subjective <strong>and</strong> objective performance measures. Though some scholars have<br />

recognized that subjective <strong>and</strong> objective performance measures are imperfect substitutes<br />

for <strong>on</strong>e another, other scholars expect that such measures should reinforce each other<br />

because they measure similar phenomena. One of our findings is straightforward:<br />

subjective <strong>and</strong> objective performance measures do not reinforce each other in the c<strong>on</strong>text<br />

of the model outlined in Chapter 2. However, our qualitative interviews revealed<br />

auxiliary insights, <strong>on</strong>e of which was that managers do not expect such measures to<br />

reinforce each other. This could be because subjective <strong>and</strong> objective measurement differ.<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> of our research is that we recognize that, although marketing initiatives<br />

have a positive influence <strong>on</strong> performance, revealing the performance of all types of<br />

measurement is not suitable.<br />

118


5.5 Practical Implicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

From a managerial perspective, we provide insights into how investments in market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> affect IdRR. If we c<strong>on</strong>sider the risk impact, our results suggest that an<br />

increase in market orientati<strong>on</strong> by <strong>on</strong>e st<strong>and</strong>ard deviati<strong>on</strong> reduces IdRR by 0.98 st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviati<strong>on</strong>s. In other words, an increase in marketing focus idiosyncratic reduces relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk by 0.98 st<strong>and</strong>ard deviati<strong>on</strong>s. Suppliers can use this reducti<strong>on</strong> in idiosyncratic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al risk as justificati<strong>on</strong> towards <strong>buyer</strong>s for charging higher prices. In these difficult<br />

times of recessi<strong>on</strong>, when sales are difficult to come across cost saving is a preferred<br />

alternative to finding new clients. Moreover, it would also serve the purpose of internal<br />

justificati<strong>on</strong> to the financial department as how marketing investment produces returns<br />

<strong>and</strong> higher margins.<br />

Market orientati<strong>on</strong> is a process of c<strong>on</strong>tinuous innovati<strong>on</strong> (Kohli & Jaworski,<br />

1990). More risk is typically involved in the case of commercializing innovati<strong>on</strong>s. In<br />

terms of risk of introducing innovati<strong>on</strong>s risk increases as the degree of newness of the<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong> increases (Ch<strong>and</strong>y & Tellis, 2000). Launching extremely new to the world<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong>s are a high risk <strong>and</strong> high return endeavor. However, involving the strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> can reduce the cost by up to 18% of launching the innovati<strong>on</strong> (Siemens, 2013).<br />

Our research indicates that as a unique <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>se is based <strong>on</strong> the underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

of a specific client that is highly involved with the customer be it producing an innovati<strong>on</strong><br />

or otherwise, leads to a reducti<strong>on</strong> idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk resulting in accelerated <strong>and</strong><br />

stable cash flows for the <strong>buyer</strong>. Hence, from a strategy perspective we propose that<br />

marketing managers focus <strong>on</strong> spending marketing budgets <strong>on</strong> those strategic activities<br />

where they can possibly reduce the IdRR. However, we recognize that this may not<br />

always be a possibility, but <strong>supplier</strong>’s should try their utmost to reduce IdRR as much as<br />

is possible.<br />

Another practical c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> is the difference in the role of satisfacti<strong>on</strong> strategic<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the United States. Our data indicates<br />

that <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does have a relati<strong>on</strong>ship with the <strong>buyer</strong>’s own profits in The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, but not in the United States. Our findings were c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ed by an informal<br />

c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ati<strong>on</strong> with a senior manager at the HMG group (a strategic <strong>supplier</strong> of bean bags<br />

to Leenbakker <strong>and</strong> Hema). Our findings are of relevance because many managers in The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s hold satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as an important metric when evaluating their relati<strong>on</strong>ships.<br />

But when they want to exp<strong>and</strong> their business to the US or vice versa they have to develop<br />

more hard core metrics, <strong>on</strong>e of which we have expounded in this thesis, namely IdRR.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, our research investigates perceptual <strong>and</strong> objective or accounting based<br />

performance measure. We find that all perceptual measures cannot be c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ed by<br />

accounting measures. The practical implicati<strong>on</strong> of this research finding is that businesses<br />

should focus <strong>on</strong> bridging the gap between perceptual <strong>and</strong> accounting measures. Firms<br />

could adopt measures that are likely translatable into financial measures or adopt a<br />

dashboard strategy that show financial managers the <strong>value</strong> marketing is creating.<br />

119


5.6 Closing Words<br />

This dissertati<strong>on</strong> has examined the role of strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness in interorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk reducti<strong>on</strong>, its influence <strong>on</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>, the<br />

mediating role of satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, cross-cultural comparis<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> the difference in<br />

evaluati<strong>on</strong>s based <strong>on</strong> subjective <strong>and</strong> performance indicators. The true <strong>value</strong> of this<br />

research lies in its fundamental challenging of the link between <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

<strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al risk. To a degree, we have provided evidence that this link is negative<br />

<strong>and</strong> not positive as assumed by many prior studies. However, further research will<br />

c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> whether or not our findings can be applied in a wide variety of c<strong>on</strong>texts.<br />

120


Summary in English<br />

This dissertati<strong>on</strong> focuses <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> in the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship c<strong>on</strong>text <strong>and</strong> further focuses <strong>on</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>cepts of idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong> risk<br />

(IdRR), <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> as mediators of that relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

Moreover, this dissertati<strong>on</strong> adopts an inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al perspective as opposed to intraorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

perspectives in previous studies (Kohli & Jaworski, 1990; Narver &<br />

Slater, 1990; Slater & Narver, 1995). In the next secti<strong>on</strong>s we will cover the key<br />

definiti<strong>on</strong>s, the literature gaps, the research questi<strong>on</strong>s, a synopsis of each chapter,<br />

theoretical implicati<strong>on</strong>s, practical implicati<strong>on</strong>s, future research directi<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> a closing<br />

word.<br />

The key c<strong>on</strong>cepts in this study are <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

IdRR, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>and</strong> subjective <strong>and</strong> objective performance<br />

measures. The term <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is defined as the accumulative <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>se that is created by internal <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong> intelligence generati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

disseminati<strong>on</strong> processes to meet their <strong>buyer</strong>’s needs. The c<strong>on</strong>cept of <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is<br />

defined as the <strong>buyer</strong>’s cumulative ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-ec<strong>on</strong>omic satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with its<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong>. The term of IdRR is defined as the risk that exists because of<br />

entering into a specific relati<strong>on</strong>ship with another company. The c<strong>on</strong>cept of <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>value</strong> is defined from the perspective of a strategic buying center team, <strong>and</strong> is defined as<br />

the shared collective memories about the <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong>, which provides it with<br />

leverage because of customer preference that it would otherwise not have without the<br />

br<strong>and</strong>. The term <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> is defined as growth <strong>and</strong> stability in <strong>buyer</strong> cash flows.<br />

The c<strong>on</strong>cept of subjective performance measures is defined as heuristic individual<br />

evaluati<strong>on</strong>s of a <strong>firm</strong>’s performance <strong>and</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>cept of objective performance measures<br />

are defined as those measures which are calculated using st<strong>and</strong>ardized accounting <strong>and</strong><br />

financial procedures.<br />

So far in the extant literature a general approach has been to focus <strong>on</strong> the intraorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong>-mediators-performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Kohli & Jaworski,<br />

1990; Narver & Slater, 1990; Slater & Narver, 1995). For example, Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski<br />

(1990) theorize about the impact of three comp<strong>on</strong>ents of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> business<br />

performance. Whereas, Jaworski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993) empirically examine the impact of a<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. Furthermore, Narver <strong>and</strong> Slater (1990)<br />

investigate the influence of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> business performance in both<br />

commodity <strong>and</strong> n<strong>on</strong>-commodity businesses. In additi<strong>on</strong>, Grewal <strong>and</strong> Tansuhaj (2001)<br />

examined the impact of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> strategic flexibility <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance<br />

after an ec<strong>on</strong>omic crisis. Moreover, Slater <strong>and</strong> Narver (1995) propose that market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> combined with an entrepreneurial drive <strong>and</strong> the right organizati<strong>on</strong>al climate<br />

produces the learning organizati<strong>on</strong>. Further, Voss <strong>and</strong> Voss (2000) examine the role of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> product orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. Alternatively,<br />

Zhou et al. (2005) examine the impact of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance via the<br />

mediators of technological <strong>and</strong> market innovati<strong>on</strong>s. Whereas, Verhoef <strong>and</strong> Leeflang<br />

(2009) examine whether marketing accountability increases the motivati<strong>on</strong> for <strong>firm</strong>s to be<br />

market oriented. In summati<strong>on</strong>, the above studies <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> examine the<br />

121


intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al impact of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. Few studies such<br />

as Kohli <strong>and</strong> Jaworski (1990) <strong>and</strong> Jaworski <strong>and</strong> Kohli (1993) examine the impact of risk<br />

aversi<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong>. But what is not covered is the inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al impact<br />

of <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>al risk <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance. This is an<br />

important oversight as <strong>on</strong>e of the motives for selecting a <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> is their ability<br />

to reduce the <strong>buyer</strong>’s risk in business to business c<strong>on</strong>texts Kotler <strong>and</strong> Pfoertsch (2006).<br />

Neither have the previous studies explicitly modeled <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as a mediator in<br />

the inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> setting. This is<br />

important as many previous studies <strong>and</strong> marketing texts menti<strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as a<br />

desired outcome of market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Moreover, to the best of our knowledge <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> has not been empirically tested in most studies from an inter-organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

perspective. Nor have previous studies covered the mediating role of a <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong><br />

plays in the <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. This is an important<br />

oversight as a marketing philosophy or market orientati<strong>on</strong> is pointless unless it creates<br />

some market based assets such as br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> to store the <strong>value</strong> created for the <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, the <strong>supplier</strong>’s market orientati<strong>on</strong> must result in benefits for the <strong>buyer</strong> such as<br />

improved cash flows in order for the relati<strong>on</strong>ship to c<strong>on</strong>tinue. Therefore, at a global level<br />

our core research questi<strong>on</strong> for this dissertati<strong>on</strong> is:<br />

“What is the impact of <strong>supplier</strong> market orientati<strong>on</strong> through idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk, <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance?”<br />

Chapter 1 presents an introducti<strong>on</strong> to the research topics of <strong>supplier</strong> market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> also presents the motivati<strong>on</strong> for this dissertati<strong>on</strong>. Further, this chapter<br />

presents research questi<strong>on</strong>s, research methodology, an overview of the remaining<br />

chapters <strong>and</strong> the research’s limitati<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

Chapter 2 of this thesis examines the influence of <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance based <strong>on</strong> a sample of 164 business–to-business (B2B) <strong>firm</strong>s in<br />

the United States. In this study, it is emphasized that <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness creates<br />

dyadic <strong>value</strong> by reducing idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk (IdRR). IdRR is risk that exists<br />

because of entering into a specific relati<strong>on</strong>ship with another company. IdRR reducti<strong>on</strong> is<br />

the mechanism by which market-based assets are created for the <strong>supplier</strong>. On the other<br />

h<strong>and</strong>, soft indicators such as satisfacti<strong>on</strong> have shown no link to dyadic <strong>value</strong> or <strong>buyer</strong><br />

<strong>firm</strong> profits al<strong>on</strong>e. This study challenges the l<strong>on</strong>g-held assumpti<strong>on</strong> that market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> risk are positively related <strong>and</strong>, at least in strategic B2B c<strong>on</strong>texts, we find evidence to<br />

the c<strong>on</strong>trary.<br />

Chapter 3 looks at differences between the applicati<strong>on</strong> of the model presented in<br />

the Chapter 2 in different cultural c<strong>on</strong>texts. The research sample included 92 <strong>firm</strong>s from<br />

the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the original 164 from the U.S. The core emphasis of this study was<br />

determining whether the mediators of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong><br />

<strong>firm</strong> performance were the same across nati<strong>on</strong>al cultural boundaries. Using the Hofstede<br />

index as the driving logic behind the comparis<strong>on</strong> of the two samples, our model showed<br />

significant differences. In the United States, soft indicators did not present a link to <strong>buyer</strong><br />

<strong>firm</strong> performance, whereas they did in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. The implicati<strong>on</strong> for management<br />

122


is that, when developing marketing strategy, they have to adopt periscopic perspectives<br />

bey<strong>on</strong>d their own cultural spheres.<br />

Chapter 4 is motivated by the need to examine whether different performance<br />

measures would reinforce each other in the model outlined in Chapter 2. Managers<br />

habitually trust their heuristic judgments. The extant literature <strong>on</strong> the accuracy of such<br />

judgments is mixed. Such judgments are often formed as a result of cumulative<br />

background informati<strong>on</strong>, both objective <strong>and</strong> subjective. We anticipated that, since<br />

strategic relati<strong>on</strong>ships involve a great degree of cooperati<strong>on</strong>, a manager’s assessment<br />

would be aligned with objective performance measures. However, we found that<br />

subjective <strong>and</strong> objective performance measures did not provide similar results.<br />

Chapter 5 is our final chapter of this dissertati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> commences by presenting a<br />

short synopsis of the three studies in the dissertati<strong>on</strong>. In the following secti<strong>on</strong> there is a<br />

discussi<strong>on</strong> of the general c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s derived from this research. And next the theoretical<br />

implicati<strong>on</strong>s of the studies are discussed, <strong>and</strong> the chapter ends with c<strong>on</strong>cluding remarks.<br />

Theoretical C<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

In chapter 2 we shed new light <strong>on</strong> the market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> risk relati<strong>on</strong>ship <strong>and</strong> build a<br />

comprehensive model that enunciates the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness,<br />

IdRR, <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Our findings challenge the status quo belief that market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> is an inherently risky endeavor by providing evidence that <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness negatively influences IdRR. Moreover, we c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the<br />

marketing domain by extending the scope of the current market orientati<strong>on</strong> models,<br />

which to date have mostly focused <strong>on</strong> the intra-organizati<strong>on</strong>al perspective. Furthermore,<br />

the extant literature has not addressed the issue of incorporating the<br />

customer’s perspective <strong>and</strong> the customer’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> in market orientati<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> performance models <strong>and</strong> we c<strong>on</strong>tribute to the literature by incorporating these<br />

perspectives.<br />

Sec<strong>on</strong>d, we introduce IdRR as a new c<strong>on</strong>struct in the literature <strong>and</strong> an important<br />

mediator of the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>. Using IdRR, academics <strong>and</strong><br />

businesses will be able to estimate whether market orientati<strong>on</strong> increases or reduces the<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al risk between a <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong>. Furthermore, at a time when there is an increased<br />

need for accountability within <strong>firm</strong>s, IdRR as a measure allows managers to communicate<br />

some of the <strong>value</strong> that the relati<strong>on</strong>ship has accrued due to market orientati<strong>on</strong>. Hence, by using<br />

IdRR to explain the benefits of market orientati<strong>on</strong>, it adds clarity to the returns <strong>on</strong> investment<br />

from market orientati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Third, we provide evidence that market orientati<strong>on</strong> is a single unified general c<strong>on</strong>struct<br />

<strong>and</strong> not three separate general factors. The market orientati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>struct has lacked discriminant<br />

validity in some important studies, but scholars still c<strong>on</strong>tinue to model it as sub-comp<strong>on</strong>ents<br />

rather than a general factor (Kohli et al., 1993; Narver & Slater, 1990). In the current study, we<br />

revisited it as a general factor <strong>and</strong> we have found that market orientati<strong>on</strong> or <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness is a single factor rather than three distinct comp<strong>on</strong>ents.<br />

Fourth, we find that <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is not related to a <strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> in the U.S.<br />

In the extant literature, scholars so far have focused <strong>on</strong> the <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong><br />

business performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Gyskens et al., 1999). Despite this focus, scholars have<br />

123


found limited evidence of a <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship (Gyskens<br />

et al., 1999). Although the <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship is<br />

important, even more important is the issue as to whether <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong> is a meaningful<br />

indicator. As satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in channel c<strong>on</strong>texts has an ec<strong>on</strong>omic aspect, it should be related to a<br />

<strong>buyer</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> in order to be meaningful as an indicator. If the <strong>buyer</strong> is satisfied with the<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic <strong>value</strong> provided by the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>, it in turn should increase the <strong>buyer</strong>’s cash<br />

flow, <strong>and</strong> therefore, <strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>.<br />

Fifth, our model provides preliminary evidence that IdRR reducti<strong>on</strong> is a reliable<br />

indicator that has a link to customer <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>. For managers, this<br />

finding provides a framework for thought. However, it may not be possible or desirable to<br />

solely focus <strong>on</strong> those activities that reduce IdRR because some market orientati<strong>on</strong> activities<br />

may influence both IdRR <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, but a <strong>firm</strong> should rely more <strong>on</strong> IdRR measures<br />

than customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> measures.<br />

Chapter 3 builds <strong>on</strong> the research presented in Chapter 2 by testing it across two<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>s. We find that the main hypothesis <strong>and</strong> theoretical c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> regarding the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness-idiosyncratic risk-performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship holds true across<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>s. However, we find that there is a difference in soft relati<strong>on</strong>al indicators of <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. We explain these differences in light of the Hofstede index, suggesting that<br />

nati<strong>on</strong>al culture may moderate the soft indicator-performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship. In sum, the<br />

current paper validates the main findings of the Chapter 2 model by providing evidence<br />

that IdRR matters across nati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

In chapter 4 to the best of our knowledge is the first study to examine the issue of<br />

objective versus subjective performance measures in the c<strong>on</strong>text of strategic <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness or market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>buyer</strong> IdRR. In Chapter 4 we make three<br />

theoretical c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

First, we provide evidence that the type of data used for <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>sivenessidiosyncratic<br />

risk-performance analysis can change the strength <strong>and</strong> directi<strong>on</strong> of the<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships in the Chapter 2 model. We were able to show that there is a disc<strong>on</strong>nect<br />

between key indicators when subjective <strong>and</strong> objective data are used. We believe this is<br />

because of a lack of metric substitutability rather than a problem with the model itself.<br />

Sec<strong>on</strong>d, we explain why managers’ evaluati<strong>on</strong>s may not be in line with the<br />

objective data indicators. For example, because objective data are calculated at a macroorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

level, they may not reflect the performance of the various functi<strong>on</strong>s at<br />

different levels within the organizati<strong>on</strong>. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, a manager’s heuristic ability<br />

can shed light <strong>on</strong> latent areas of performance that traditi<strong>on</strong>al objective performance<br />

measures cannot.<br />

Third, we explain that financial managers often fail to see the <strong>value</strong> of marketing<br />

initiatives because they do not underst<strong>and</strong> the intangible <strong>value</strong> such initiatives create.<br />

Practical Implicati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

From a managerial perspective, we provide insights into how investments in market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> affect IdRR. If we c<strong>on</strong>sider the financial impact, our results suggest that an<br />

increase in market orientati<strong>on</strong> by <strong>on</strong>e st<strong>and</strong>ard deviati<strong>on</strong> reduces IdRR by 0.98 st<strong>and</strong>ard<br />

deviati<strong>on</strong>s. In other words, an increase in marketing focus reduces idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

124


isk by 0.98 st<strong>and</strong>ard deviati<strong>on</strong>s. Suppliers can use this reducti<strong>on</strong> in idiosyncratic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>al risk as justificati<strong>on</strong> towards <strong>buyer</strong>s for charging higher prices. In these difficult<br />

times of recessi<strong>on</strong>, when sales are difficult to come across cost saving is a preferred<br />

alternative to finding new clients. Moreover, it would also serve the purpose of internal<br />

justificati<strong>on</strong> to the financial department as how marketing investment produces returns<br />

<strong>and</strong> higher margins.<br />

Market orientati<strong>on</strong> is a process of c<strong>on</strong>tinuous innovati<strong>on</strong> (Kohli & Jaworski,<br />

1990). More risk is typically involved in the case of commercializing innovati<strong>on</strong>s. In<br />

terms of risk of introducing innovati<strong>on</strong>s risk increases as the degree of newness of the<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong> increases (Ch<strong>and</strong>y & Tellis, 2000). Launching extremely new to the world<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong>s are a high risk <strong>and</strong> high return endeavor. However, involving the strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> can reduce the cost by up to 18% of launching the innovati<strong>on</strong> (Siemens, 2013).<br />

Our research indicates that as a unique <strong>supplier</strong>’s resp<strong>on</strong>se is based <strong>on</strong> the underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

of a specific client that is highly involved with the customer be it producing an innovati<strong>on</strong><br />

or otherwise, leads to a reducti<strong>on</strong> idiosyncratic relati<strong>on</strong>al risk resulting in accelerated <strong>and</strong><br />

stable cash flows for the <strong>buyer</strong>. Hence, from a strategy perspective we propose that<br />

marketing managers focus <strong>on</strong> spending marketing budgets <strong>on</strong> those strategic activities<br />

where they can possibly reduce the IdRR. However, we recognize that this may not<br />

always be a possibility, but <strong>supplier</strong>’s should try their utmost to reduce IdRR as much as<br />

is possible.<br />

Another practical c<strong>on</strong>tributi<strong>on</strong> is the difference in the role of satisfacti<strong>on</strong> strategic<br />

<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the U.S. Our data indicates that <strong>buyer</strong><br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> does have a relati<strong>on</strong>ship with the <strong>buyer</strong>’s own profits. However, in The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s it does. Our findings were c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ed by an informal c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ati<strong>on</strong> with a<br />

senior manager at the HMG group (a strategic <strong>supplier</strong> of bean bags to Leenbakker <strong>and</strong><br />

Hema). Our findings are of relevance because many managers in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s hold<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> as an important metric when evaluating their relati<strong>on</strong>ships. But when they<br />

want to exp<strong>and</strong> their business to the US or vice versa they have to develop more hard<br />

core metrics, <strong>on</strong>e of which we have expounded in this thesis, namely IdRR.<br />

In additi<strong>on</strong>, our research investigates perceptual <strong>and</strong> objective or accounting based<br />

performance measure. We find that all perceptual measures cannot be c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong>ed by<br />

accounting measures. The practical implicati<strong>on</strong> of this research finding is that businesses<br />

should focus <strong>on</strong> bridging the gap between perceptual <strong>and</strong> accounting measures. Firms<br />

could adopt measures that are likely translatable into financial measures or adopt a<br />

dashboard strategy that show financial managers the <strong>value</strong> marketing is creating.<br />

Future Research Directi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Although we have tried in this thesis to address the research questi<strong>on</strong>s as<br />

comprehensively as possible, but there are still many possible future research directi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

open to future researchers. Below, we have summarized <strong>and</strong> organized some interesting<br />

research avenues for future researchers:<br />

i) L<strong>on</strong>gitudinal research design. Our cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al study allowed us to draw associati<strong>on</strong>s at<br />

best but not c<strong>on</strong>clusi<strong>on</strong>s about causality. To further improve this design, data collected for a<br />

time series analysis could allow the deducti<strong>on</strong> of evidence regarding causality. However, there<br />

125


has been some recent evidence that inferences from cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al studies about causality may<br />

not be much different from inferences about l<strong>on</strong>gitudinal studies (Rindfleisch et al., 2008).<br />

ii) Limited sample of industries for depth. We traded off depth for width within our industry<br />

sectors. However, specific sectors may vary more with <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness than others. For<br />

instance, in the commodities industry, price may be more of a determining factor, whereas in<br />

the technical goods industrial sector the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>se may be a key determining factor as<br />

to whether relati<strong>on</strong>ships c<strong>on</strong>tinue. Future studies could c<strong>on</strong>centrate <strong>on</strong> a few sectors <strong>and</strong> check<br />

the robustness of our findings across various moderators, such as market turbulence <strong>and</strong><br />

increased technological risk.<br />

iii) Quasi-experimental design using financial <strong>and</strong> perceptual data in t<strong>and</strong>em. Prior studies of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> have found c<strong>on</strong>flicts between objective <strong>and</strong> subjective measures of<br />

performance (Narver & Slater, 1990). To determine whether our findings actually reflect real<br />

financial market sentiments <strong>and</strong> accounting data, future studies can use financial data in<br />

t<strong>and</strong>em with perceptual data.<br />

iv) Wider comparis<strong>on</strong> of measurement metrics. In the current study, we <strong>on</strong>ly use idiosyncratic<br />

risk, which within itself is a important indicator of the potential returns involved with any<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship. However, risk is not the sole metric in the literature. Future studies might include<br />

a wider array of metrics to examine which are better indicators than others <strong>and</strong> why. For<br />

instance, examining idiosyncratic risk in comparis<strong>on</strong> to inventory turnover metrics or debt<br />

leverage metrics could be an interesting avenue.<br />

v) Comparis<strong>on</strong> of more strategies with <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness for reducing idiosyncratic risk.<br />

We <strong>on</strong>ly examine <strong>on</strong>e strategy, which is market orientati<strong>on</strong> as a means of reducing<br />

idiosyncratic risk. However, there are other strategies <strong>and</strong> orientati<strong>on</strong>s, such as a technology<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> or a market leadership strategy. The ways in which these strategies <strong>and</strong> orientati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

influence strategic <strong>supplier</strong>-<strong>buyer</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships <strong>and</strong> their idiosyncratic risk outcomes could be<br />

of potential interest.<br />

vi) Use of various research methods other than surveys. The research design could be<br />

improved up<strong>on</strong> specifically with reference to Chapter 3. Some researchers have indicated that<br />

ethnographies should be employed to research issues related to culture (Langerak, 2001). The<br />

advantage in their opini<strong>on</strong> is that organizati<strong>on</strong>al culture can be better documented by l<strong>on</strong>g-term<br />

observati<strong>on</strong> techniques, such as ethnographies. Therefore, future researchers could employ an<br />

ethnography for a deeper underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness-<strong>buyer</strong> <strong>firm</strong> performance<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

vii) Comparis<strong>on</strong> of more diverse countries. In chapter 3 although the US <strong>and</strong> The<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s are different in some respects, they share similarities as well. Both are<br />

industrialized nati<strong>on</strong>s, both are vibrant democracies, both have capitalist ec<strong>on</strong>omies, both<br />

have a degree of similar occidental culture, <strong>and</strong> both nati<strong>on</strong>s are internati<strong>on</strong>ally<br />

competitive ec<strong>on</strong>omies (Deshp<strong>and</strong>e & Webster, 1989). Some cultural idiosyncrasies do<br />

occur, such as acceptance of boasting <strong>on</strong> job interviews in the United States <strong>and</strong> the<br />

preference for modesty in job interviews in The Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, but nevertheless, they both<br />

can be c<strong>on</strong>sidered western cultures.<br />

However a comparis<strong>on</strong> with an Asian culture would have provided a more diverse<br />

comparis<strong>on</strong>. China is a growing world trade power, it is a communist nati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> it has a<br />

126


collectivist culture <strong>and</strong> a C<strong>on</strong>fucian <strong>value</strong> system (Hofstede, 2003). These cultural<br />

differences result in different risk preferences in individual members of society. For<br />

instance, the Chinese have a greater risk preference than Americans, because their<br />

collectivist culture cushi<strong>on</strong>s them from losses. Future researchers could investigate how<br />

<strong>firm</strong>s from societies with extremely different risk preferences react to <strong>supplier</strong><br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness. This would also add a new dimensi<strong>on</strong> to the problem we studied as to<br />

whether cultural risk preference is a moderating factor in the <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>buyer</strong> performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship.<br />

In some Eurasian <strong>and</strong> Asian ec<strong>on</strong>omies, relati<strong>on</strong>al practices such as Blat <strong>and</strong><br />

Gaunxi are an integral part of the business culture. However, in western cultures such<br />

practices may be viewed as unethical <strong>and</strong> detrimental to the corporate interests <strong>and</strong><br />

reputati<strong>on</strong>. Specifically, when forming strategic <strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ships with corporati<strong>on</strong>s<br />

that find such cultural practices acceptable, <strong>buyer</strong>s may fear a negative spillover <strong>on</strong> their<br />

br<strong>and</strong> reputati<strong>on</strong>. Such cultural effects have been overlooked in our current study. Further<br />

examples include questi<strong>on</strong>s such as: Does IdRR vary because of nati<strong>on</strong>al culture? Or<br />

should culture specific practices such as Blat or Guanxi be c<strong>on</strong>sidered a part of IdRR?<br />

ix) Use of both subjective <strong>and</strong> objective metrics for internati<strong>on</strong>al comparis<strong>on</strong>s. Another<br />

limitati<strong>on</strong> of our current study is that we <strong>on</strong>ly c<strong>on</strong>sidered percepti<strong>on</strong>s. Indeed, do<br />

percepti<strong>on</strong>s reinforce objective measures across cultures? Are some cultures more pr<strong>on</strong>e<br />

to be overly jubilant when it comes to redirecting earnings from investments? Are some<br />

cultures overly pessimistic when predicting losses which may across from strategic<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships? Do cultures influence the relative importance of <strong>firm</strong> percepti<strong>on</strong> of<br />

marketing strategies such as market orientati<strong>on</strong>?<br />

x) Role of <strong>firm</strong> culture: One course for future researchers could be to examine the<br />

role of <strong>firm</strong> culture in accepting subjective or objective measures as valid indicators of<br />

performance. This is important because it could also explain why resources are<br />

misdirected because of inaccurate percepti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> their reliability as valid measurement<br />

tools.<br />

xi) Using department-level specific metrics: In the current study, we used<br />

corporate-level objective indicators. Using department-level specific metrics instead<br />

could res<strong>on</strong>ate better with managers' underst<strong>and</strong>ing of how much profit their departments<br />

produce. Indeed, there may not be much difference between objective <strong>and</strong> subjective<br />

measurement indicators at the same level throughout the organizati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Closing Word<br />

This dissertati<strong>on</strong> has examined the role of strategic <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness in interorganizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk reducti<strong>on</strong>, its influence <strong>on</strong> satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, <strong>supplier</strong> br<strong>and</strong> <strong>value</strong>, <strong>buyer</strong><br />

<strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>, cross-cultural comparis<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> the difference in evaluati<strong>on</strong>s based <strong>on</strong><br />

subjective <strong>and</strong> performance indicators. The true <strong>value</strong> of this research lies in its<br />

fundamental challenging of the link between <strong>supplier</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>siveness <strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

risk. To a degree, we have provided evidence that this link is negative <strong>and</strong> not positive as<br />

assumed by many prior studies. However, further research will c<strong>on</strong><strong>firm</strong> whether or not<br />

our findings can be applied in a wide variety of c<strong>on</strong>texts.<br />

127


Samenvatting<br />

Dit proefschrift richt zich op marktgerichtheid in de strategische leverancier en koper<br />

relatie c<strong>on</strong>text en verder vestigt het de a<strong>and</strong>acht op de c<strong>on</strong>cepten van idiosyncratisch<br />

relatie risico (IdRR), klanttevredenheid en leverancier merkwaarde als mediatoren van<br />

die relatie. Bovendien gaat dit proefschrift uit van een inter-organisatorisch perspectief, in<br />

tegenstelling tot de intra-organisatorische perspectieven in eerdere studies (Kohli &<br />

Jaworski, 1990; Narver & Slater, 1990; Slater & Narver, 1995). In de volgende<br />

paragrafen zullen we de belangrijkste definities , de hiaten in de literatuur, de<br />

<strong>on</strong>derzoeksvragen, een overzicht van elk hoofdstuk, theoretische implicaties, praktische<br />

implicaties, richtingen voor toekomstig <strong>on</strong>derzoek en een afsluitende woord bespreken.<br />

De belangrijkste c<strong>on</strong>cepten in dit <strong>on</strong>derzoek zijn leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit,<br />

klanttevredenheid, IdRR, leverancier merkwaarde, koper vaste waarde, en subjectieve en<br />

objectieve prestatie-indicatoren. De term leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit wordt gedefinieerd als<br />

de cumulatieve leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>s die wordt gecreëerd door interne leverancier stevige<br />

intelligentie <strong>on</strong>twikkeling en verspreidingsprocessen om de behoeften van de koper<br />

tevreden te stellen. Het c<strong>on</strong>cept van klanttevredenheid wordt gedefinieerd als de<br />

cumulatieve ec<strong>on</strong>omische en niet-ec<strong>on</strong>omische tevredenheid van de koper met zijn<br />

strategische leverancier. De term IdRR wordt gedefinieerd als het risico dat bestaat als<br />

gevolg van het aangaan van een specifieke relatie met een <strong>and</strong>er bedrijf. Het c<strong>on</strong>cept van<br />

de leverancier merkwaarde wordt gedefinieerd vanuit het perspectief van een strategische<br />

aankoop centrumteam, en wordt gedefinieerd als de gedeelde collectieve herinneringen<br />

aan het merk van de leverancier, die het kracht geven als gevolg van voorkeur van de<br />

klant dat het <strong>and</strong>ers niet zouden hebben z<strong>on</strong>der het merk. De term koper bedrijfswaarde<br />

wordt gedefinieerd als groei en stabiliteit in koper kasstromen. Het c<strong>on</strong>cept van<br />

subjectieve prestatiemaatstaven wordt gedefinieerd als heuristisch individuele evaluaties<br />

van de prestaties van een bedrijf en het c<strong>on</strong>cept van objectieve prestatie-indicatoren<br />

wordt gedefinieerd als die maatregel die wordt berekend met behulp van<br />

gest<strong>and</strong>aardiseerde boekhoudkundige en financiële procedures.<br />

Tot nu toe is in de besta<strong>and</strong>e literatuur een algemene oriëntatie steeds gericht geweest op<br />

de intra-organisatorische marktoriëntatie-bemiddelaars-prestatierelatie (Kohli &<br />

Jaworski, 1990; Narver & Slater, 1990; Slater & Narver, 1995). Bijvoorbeeld, Kohli en<br />

Jaworski (1990) theoretiseren over de impact van drie comp<strong>on</strong>enten van marktgerichtheid<br />

op de bedrijfsprestaties. Overwegende dat, Jaworski en Kohli (1993) empirisch de<br />

invloed van een markt oriëntatie op bedrijfsprestaties <strong>on</strong>derzoeken. Bovendien<br />

<strong>on</strong>derzoeken Narver en Slater (1990) de invloed van marktoriëntatie op de<br />

bedrijfsprestaties in zowel gr<strong>on</strong>dstoffen-en n<strong>on</strong>-commodity bedrijven. Daarenboven<br />

<strong>on</strong>derzoeken Grewal en Tansuhaj (2001) de invloed van marktoriëntatie en strategische<br />

flexibiliteit op bedrijfsprestatie na een ec<strong>on</strong>omische crisis. Slater en Narver (1995) stellen<br />

voor dat de marktgerichtheid in combinatie met een <strong>on</strong>dernemende drijfveer en het juiste<br />

organisatieklimaat de lerende organisatie produceert. Verder, <strong>on</strong>derzoeken Voss en Voss<br />

(2000) de rol van de marktgerichtheid en productoriëntatie op bedrijfsprestaties. Als<br />

alternatief <strong>on</strong>derzoeken Zhou, Yim, en Tse (2005) de invloed van marktoriëntatie op<br />

bedrijfsprestaties via de bemiddelaars van technologische en marktinnovaties.<br />

128


Overwegende dat Verhoef en Leeflang (2009) <strong>on</strong>derzoeken of marketing verantwoording<br />

de motivatie voor bedrijven om marktgericht te denken verhoogt. Ter samenvatting, de<br />

bovensta<strong>and</strong>e studies over marktgerichtheid <strong>on</strong>derzoeken de intra-organisatorische<br />

impact van marktgerichtheid op bedrijfsprestaties. Weinig studies zoals Kohli en<br />

Jaworski (1990) en Jaworski en Kohli (1993) <strong>on</strong>derzoeken de impact van de risicoaversie<br />

op marktgerichtheid. Maar wat niet besproken wordt, is de interorganisatorische<br />

impact van de leverancier marktoriëntatie op relati<strong>on</strong>ele risico's en koper<br />

bedrijfsprestaties. Dit is een belangrijke fout aangezien één van de motieven voor het<br />

selecteren van een leveranciermerk het vermogen is om het risico van de koper in een<br />

business to business c<strong>on</strong>text te verminderen Kotler en Pfoertsch (2006).Noch hebben de<br />

eerdere studies klanttevredenheid als bemiddelaar in de inter-organisatorische<br />

leveranciermarktgerichtheid en koper bedrijfswaarde setting expliciet gemodelleerd. Dit<br />

is belangrijk omdat veel eerdere studies en marketingteksten klanttevredenheid<br />

vermelden als een gewenste uitkomst van marktgerichtheid. Bovendien werd naar <strong>on</strong>ze<br />

kennis klanttevredenheid in de meeste studies nog niet empirisch getoetst vanuit een<br />

inter-organisatorisch perspectief. Noch hebben eerdere studies de bemiddelende rol dat<br />

het merk van een leverancier speelt in de leverancier marktoriëntatie en koper<br />

bedrijfswaarde besproken. Dit is een belangrijke fout aangezien een marketing filosofie<br />

of marktoriëntatie zinloos is, tenzij het een aantal op de markt gebaseerde activa creëert ,<br />

zoals merkwaarde om de waarde die voor de leverancier gecreëerd werd te bewaren.<br />

Bovendien moet de leverancier marktgerichtheid voordelen opleveren voor de koper<br />

zoals verbeterde kasstromen zodat de relatie blijft voortduren. Daarom op m<strong>on</strong>diaal<br />

niveau is de kern van <strong>on</strong>ze vraagstelling voor dit proefschrift:<br />

"Wat is de impact van de leverancier marktoriëntatie via idiosyncratisch<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>eel risico, klanttevredenheid, en leverancier merkwaarde op koper<br />

bedrijfsprestaties?"<br />

Hoofdstuk 1 geeft een inleiding tot de <strong>on</strong>derzoeksthema's van van leverancier<br />

marktoriëntatie en presenteert ook de motivatie voor dit proefschrift. Verder worden in<br />

dit hoofdstuk de <strong>on</strong>derzoeksvragen gecreëerd, <strong>on</strong>derzoeksmethoden, een overzicht van de<br />

resterende hoofdstukken en het <strong>on</strong>derzoek van de beperkingen besproken.<br />

Hoofdstuk 2 van dit proefschrift <strong>on</strong>derzoekt de invloed van de leverancier<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit op de bedrijfsprestaties op basis van een steekproef van 164 business-tobusiness<br />

(B2B) bedrijven in de Verenigde Staten. In deze studie wordt benadrukt dat<br />

leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit een dyadische waarde creëert door het verminderen van het<br />

idiosyncratische relati<strong>on</strong>eel risico (IdRR). IdRR is een risico dat bestaat als gevolg van<br />

het aangaan van een specifieke relatie met een <strong>and</strong>er bedrijf. IdRR reductie is het<br />

mechanisme waarmee het markt gebaseerde vermogen wordt gemaakt voor de<br />

leverancier. Aan de <strong>and</strong>ere kant, hebben zachte indicatoren, zoals de tevredenheid<br />

aangeto<strong>on</strong>d dat er geen link is met dyadische waarde of koper bedrijfswinst alleen. Deze<br />

studie daagt de lang gekoesterde ver<strong>on</strong>derstelling dat marktgerichtheid en risico positief<br />

gerelateerd zijn uit en, althans in strategische B2B c<strong>on</strong>text, vinden we bewijzen van het<br />

tegendeel.<br />

129


Hoofdstuk 3 gaat in op de verschillen tussen de toepassing van het model gepresenteerd<br />

in de Hoofdstuk 2 in verschillende culturele c<strong>on</strong>texten. De steekproef omvat 92 bedrijven<br />

uit Nederl<strong>and</strong> en de oorspr<strong>on</strong>kelijke 164 uit de VS. De kern nadruk van deze studie was<br />

het bepalen van de vraag of de bemiddelaars van de strategische leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit<br />

en koper bedrijfsprestaties hetzelfde waren over de nati<strong>on</strong>ale culturele grenzen. Met de<br />

Hofstede index als drijvende logica achter de vergelijking van de twee m<strong>on</strong>sters, to<strong>on</strong>de<br />

<strong>on</strong>s model significante verschillen. In de Verenigde Staten, hebben zachte indicatoren<br />

geen link naar koper bedrijfsprestaties naar voren gebracht, terwijl ze dat wel deden in<br />

Nederl<strong>and</strong>. De gevolgen voor het management zijn dat, bij het <strong>on</strong>twikkelen van een<br />

marketingstrategie, ze periscopische perspectieven moeten aannemen die verder reiken<br />

dan hun eigen cultureel gebied.<br />

Hoofdstuk 4 is geïnspireerd door de noodzaak om te <strong>on</strong>derzoeken of de verschillende<br />

prestatie-indicatoren elkaar zouden versterken in het model beschreven in hoofdstuk<br />

2.Managers vertrouwen gewo<strong>on</strong>lijk op hun heuristische oordelen. De besta<strong>and</strong>e literatuur<br />

over de nauwkeurigheid van dergelijke uitspraken is gemengd. Dergelijke oordelen zijn<br />

vaak gevormd als gevolg van cumulatieve achtergr<strong>on</strong>dinformatie, zowel objectieve als<br />

subjectieve. We verwachten dat, aangezien strategische relaties leiden tot een grote mate<br />

van samenwerking, een manager beoordeling zou worden afgestemd op objectieve<br />

prestatie-indicatoren. We v<strong>on</strong>den echter dat subjectieve en objectieve<br />

prestatiemaatregelen leveren geen vergelijkbare resultaten.<br />

Hoofdstuk 5 is het laatste hoofdstuk van dit proefschrift en begint met het presenteren<br />

van een korte samenvatting van de drie studies in het proefschrift. De volgende paragraaf<br />

is een bespreking van de algemene c<strong>on</strong>clusies uit dit <strong>on</strong>derzoek. En vervolgens worden<br />

de theoretische implicaties van de studies besproken, en het hoofdstuk eindigt met een<br />

slotbeschouwing.<br />

Theoretische bijdragen<br />

In hoofdstuk 2 werpen we een nieuw licht op de marktgerichtheid. de risicorelatie en het<br />

opbouwen van een omvattend model dat de relatie tussen leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit, IdRR<br />

formuleert, en de koper bedrijfswaarde.Onze bevindingen betwisten het status quo<br />

geloof dat marktgerichtheid een inherente riskante <strong>on</strong>derneming is door het verstrekken<br />

van het bewijs dat leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit IdRR negatief beïnvloedt. Bovendien dragen<br />

we bij aan het marketing domein door de uitbreiding van de werkingssfeer van de huidige<br />

marktoriëntatie modellen, die zich tot nu toe vooral hebben gericht op een intraorganisatorisch<br />

perspectief. Bovendien heeft de besta<strong>and</strong>e literatuur het vraagstuk van de<br />

integratie van het klantperspectief en van de klant bedrijfswaarde in marktoriëntatie en<br />

de prestatiemodellen niet aangesproken en dragen we daarbij bij aan de literatuur door het<br />

opnemen van deze perspectieven.<br />

Ten tweede, we introduceren IdRR als een nieuwe c<strong>on</strong>structie in de literatuur en<br />

een belangrijke mediator van de leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit en koper bedrijfswaarde. Met<br />

behulp van IdRR, zullen academici en het bedrijfsleven in staat zijn om in te schatten of<br />

de marktgerichtheid het relati<strong>on</strong>ele risico tussen een leverancier en afnemer verhoogt of<br />

verlaagt. Bovendien, op een moment dat er een verhoogde behoefte aan verantwoording<br />

nodig is binnen bedrijven, stelt IdRR als een maatregel beheerders in staat om een deel<br />

130


van de waarde te communiceren dat de relatie heeft opgebouwd als gevolg van<br />

marktgerichtheid. V<strong>and</strong>aar dat, door gebruik te maken van IdRR om de voordelen van<br />

marktoriëntatie uit te leggen, het rendement op de investering van marktgerichtheid<br />

verhelderd wordt.<br />

Ten derde, leveren we het bewijs dat marktgerichtheid een eengemaakt algemeen<br />

c<strong>on</strong>struct is en geen drie afz<strong>on</strong>derlijke algemene factoren. Het marktgerichtheid c<strong>on</strong>struct<br />

<strong>on</strong>tbrak validiteit in belangrijke studies, maar academici modelleren het nog steeds<br />

veeleer als subcomp<strong>on</strong>enten dan een algemene factor (Kohli et al., 1993;. Narver en<br />

Slater, 1990). In de huidige studie hebben we het herzien als een algemene factor en<br />

hebben we gec<strong>on</strong>stateerd dat marktgerichtheid of leverancierresp<strong>on</strong>siviteit een enkele<br />

factor in plaats van drie aparte comp<strong>on</strong>enten is.<br />

Ten vierde zien we dat klanttevredenheid niet gerelateerd is aan een koper bedrijfswaarde<br />

in de VS. In de besta<strong>and</strong>e literatuur, hebben academici tot nu toe zich gericht op de<br />

klanttevredenheid en leverancier bedrijfsprestatierelatie (Gyskens et al.., 1999). Ondanks<br />

deze focus, hebben <strong>on</strong>derzoekers <strong>on</strong>voldoende bewijs gev<strong>on</strong>den van een koper<br />

tevredenheid en prestaties en leverancierprestatierelatie (Gyskens et al.., 1999). Hoewel<br />

de klanttevredenheid en de leverancierprestatierelatie belangrijk is, is de vraag of<br />

klanttevredenheid een belangrijke indicator is nog belangrijker. Zoals de tevredenheid in<br />

kanaal c<strong>on</strong>texten een ec<strong>on</strong>omisch aspect heeft, dient het te worden gerelateerd aan een<br />

koper bedrijfswaarde om een zinvolle indicator te zijn. Indien de koper tevreden is met de<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omische waarde die gegeven wordt door de strategische leverancier, zou het op zijn<br />

beurt de koper cash flow, en daarom, de koper bedrijfswaarde moeten verhogen.<br />

Ten vijfde, <strong>on</strong>s model levert voorlopig bewijs dat IdRR reductie een betrouwbare<br />

indicator is die een link tussen klant bedrijfswaarde en leverancier merkwaarde legt. Voor<br />

managers, biedt deze bevinding een manier van denken. Het kan echter niet mogelijk of<br />

wenselijk zijn om zich uitsluitend te richten op die activiteiten die IdRR verminderen<br />

omdat sommige marktgerichtheid activiteiten zowel IdRR en klanttevredenheid kunnen<br />

beïnvloeden, maar een bedrijf moet meer vertrouwen op IdRR maatregelen dan<br />

klanttevredenheid maatregelen.<br />

Hoofdstuk 3 bouwt voort op het <strong>on</strong>derzoek dat in hoofdstuk 2 wordt<br />

gepresenteerd doorheen de twee l<strong>and</strong>en. We hebben bev<strong>on</strong>den dat de belangrijkste<br />

hypothese en theoretische bijdrage van de leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit-idiosyncratische riskperformance<br />

relatie geldt voor alle l<strong>and</strong>en. We zien echter dat er een verschil is in zachte<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ele indicatoren van klanttevredenheid. We leggen deze verschillen uit in het licht<br />

van de Hofstede-index, wat suggereert dat de nati<strong>on</strong>ale cultuur de zachte indicatoren<br />

prestatierelatie kan beïnvloeden. Kortom, de huidige paper valideert de belangrijkste<br />

bevindingen van het hoofdstuk 2 model door aan te t<strong>on</strong>en dat IdRR belangrijk is over alle<br />

l<strong>and</strong>en.<br />

Hoofdstuk 4 is naar <strong>on</strong>ze wetenschap de eerste studie om de kwestie van de objectieve<br />

versus subjectieve prestatiemaatstaven te <strong>on</strong>derzoeken in het kader van strategische<br />

leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit of marktoriëntatie en de koper IdRR. In hoofdstuk 4 maken we<br />

drie theoretische bijdragen.<br />

131


Ten eerste, leveren we het bewijs dat de aard van de gegevens die worden gebruikt voor<br />

de leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit-idiosyncratische risico-performance-analyse de sterkte en de<br />

richting van de relaties in het Hoofdstuk 2 model ver<strong>and</strong>eren. We waren in staat om aan<br />

te t<strong>on</strong>en dat er sprake is van een discrepantie tussen de belangrijkste indicatoren als<br />

subjectieve en objectieve gegevens worden gebruikt. Wij geloven dat dit komt door een<br />

gebrek aan metrische substitueerbaarheid in plaats van een probleem met het model zelf.<br />

Ten tweede verklaren we waarom managerevaluaties niet in lijn kunnen zijn met de<br />

objectieve gegevens indicatoren. Bijvoorbeeld omdat objectieve gegevens zijn berekend<br />

op een macro-organisatorisch niveau, kunnen zij niet de prestaties van de verschillende<br />

functies op verschillende niveaus binnen de organisatie reflecteren. Aan de <strong>and</strong>ere kant<br />

kunnen de heuristische mogelijkheden van een manager licht werpen op latente gebieden<br />

van de prestaties die de traditi<strong>on</strong>ele objectieve prestatie-indicatoren niet kunnen<br />

aangeven.<br />

Ten derde, leggen we uit dat financiële managers vaak de waarde van marketing<br />

initiatieven niet inzien, omdat ze de immateriële waarde die dergelijke initiatieven<br />

creëren niet begrijpen.<br />

Praktische implicaties<br />

Vanuit een bestuurlijk perspectief, proberen we inzicht te bieden in de wijze waarop de<br />

investeringen in marktoriëntatie de IdRR beïnvloeden. Als we kijken naar de financiële<br />

gevolgen, suggereren <strong>on</strong>ze resultaten dat een toename van de marktgerichtheid met een<br />

st<strong>and</strong>aarddeviatie de IdRR vermindert met 0,98 st<strong>and</strong>aarddeviaties. Met <strong>and</strong>ere woorden<br />

betekent dit dat een toename in marketingfocus het idiosyncratische relati<strong>on</strong>ele risico<br />

vermindert met 0,98 st<strong>and</strong>aardafwijkingen. De vermindering van het idiosyncratische<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ele risico kan worden gebruikt door leveranciers als rechtvaardiging voor het<br />

vragen van hogere prijzen. Door aan de klant aan de voordelen door kostenbesparing aan<br />

te t<strong>on</strong>en. In deze moeilijke tijden van recessie, wanneer verkoop moeilijk is, is<br />

kostenbesparing een voorkeursalternatief op het vinden van nieuwe klanten. Bovendien<br />

zou het ook het doel van interne verantwoording aan de financiële afdeling kunnen<br />

dienen om te laten zien hoe marketing investering rendement levert en hogere marges.<br />

Marktgerichtheid is een proces van c<strong>on</strong>tinue innovatie (Kohli & Jaworski,<br />

1990).Meer risico is meestal betrokken in het geval van commercialiseringsinnovaties. In<br />

termen van risico in het introduceren van innovaties, neem het risico toe naarmate de<br />

mate van nieuwheid van de innovatie toeneemt (Ch<strong>and</strong>y & Tellis, 2000).De lancering van<br />

zeer nieuwe wereldlijke innovaties zijn een hoog risico en streven naar een hoog<br />

rendement. Echter, de kosten met betrekking tot de strategische leverancier kan de kost<br />

tot en met 18% van de lancering van de innovatie verminderen (Siemens, 2013). Ons<br />

<strong>on</strong>derzoek geeft aan dat als de reactie van een unieke leverancier gebaseerd is op het<br />

begrip van een specifieke klant die zeer betrokken is bij de klant zij het in de productie<br />

van een innovatie of op enigzins <strong>and</strong>ere wijze, leidt dit tot een vermindering van het<br />

idiosyncratische relati<strong>on</strong>ele risico wat resulteert in een versnelde en stabiele kasstroom<br />

voor de koper . V<strong>and</strong>aar dat, vanuit een strategie perspectief wij voorstellen dat<br />

marketing managers zich richten op de besteding van marketingbudgetten op die<br />

strategische activiteiten waar ze eventueel het IdRR kunnen verminderen Echter, we<br />

132


erkennen dat dit niet altijd een mogelijkheid is, maar de leverancier moet zijn uiterste best<br />

proberen om de IdRR zo klein mogelijk te houden.<br />

Een <strong>and</strong>ere praktische bijdrage is het verschil in de rol van tevredenheid<br />

strategische koper leveranciersrelaties in Nederl<strong>and</strong> en de VS Uit <strong>on</strong>ze gegevens blijkt<br />

dat klanttevredenheid wel een relatie heeft met de eigen winst van de koper. Echter, in<br />

Nederl<strong>and</strong> is dit wel het geval. Onze bevindingen werden bevestigd door een informele<br />

bevestiging met een senior manager bij de HMG-groep (een strategische leverancier van<br />

zitzakken aan Leenbakker en Hema).Onze bevindingen zijn van belang, omdat veel<br />

managers in Nederl<strong>and</strong> tevredenheid als een belangrijke maatstaf bij de beoordeling van<br />

hun relaties beschouwen. Maar wanneer ze hun activiteiten willen uitbreiden naar de<br />

Verenigde Staten of omgekeerd moeten ze meer harde kern metrics <strong>on</strong>twikkelen,<br />

waarvan wij er één in dit proefschrift hebben uiteengezet, namelijk IdRR .<br />

Daarnaast <strong>on</strong>derzoekt dit proefschrift perceptuele en objectieve of op<br />

boekhoudkundige gebaseerde prestatie-maatregels. We hebben bev<strong>on</strong>den dat alle<br />

perceptuele maatregelen niet kunnen worden bevestigd door boekhoudkundige<br />

maatregelen. De praktische implicatie van de bevinding van dit <strong>on</strong>derzoek is dat<br />

bedrijven zich moeten richten op het overbruggen van de kloof tussen perceptuele en<br />

boekhoudkundige maatregelen. Bedrijven kunnen maatregelen nemen die waarschijnlijk<br />

vertaalbaar zijn in financiële maatregelen of nemen een dashboard strategie aan die<br />

financiële managers de waarde laten zien die marketing kan creëren.<br />

Toekomstige <strong>on</strong>derzoeksrichtingen<br />

Hoewel we hebben geprobeerd in dit proefschrift de <strong>on</strong>derzoeksvragen zo gr<strong>on</strong>dig<br />

mogelijk aan te pakken, liggen er nog steeds veel mogelijke toekomstige<br />

<strong>on</strong>derzoeksrichtingen open voor toekomstige <strong>on</strong>derzoekers. Hier<strong>on</strong>der hebben we enkele<br />

interessante <strong>on</strong>derzoekmogelijkheden samengevat en gestructureerd voor toekomstige<br />

<strong>on</strong>derzoekers:<br />

i) L<strong>on</strong>gitudinaal <strong>on</strong>derzoeks<strong>on</strong>twerp. Onze cross-secti<strong>on</strong>ele studie liet <strong>on</strong>s toe om<br />

associaties te maken, maar niet om enige c<strong>on</strong>clusies over causaliteit te maken. Ter<br />

verbetering van dit <strong>on</strong>twerp, kan verzamelde gegevens voor een tijdreeks analyse<br />

mogelijk te maken van de aftrek van bewijs met betrekking tot causaliteit. Toch is er<br />

sprake van recent bewijs dat gevolgtrekkingen uit cross-secti<strong>on</strong>ele studies over causaliteit<br />

niet veel verschillen van c<strong>on</strong>clusies over l<strong>on</strong>gitudinale studies (Rindfleisch et al., 2008).<br />

ii) Beperkte steekproef van bedrijven voor diepte. We hebben diepte voor breedte<br />

afgewogen binnen <strong>on</strong>ze industrie sectoren. Echter specifieke sectoren variëren meer met<br />

leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit dan <strong>and</strong>eren. Bijvoorbeeld, in de gr<strong>on</strong>dstoffen-industrie, kan de<br />

prijs een bepalende factor zijn, terwijl in de technische goederen industriële sector het<br />

antwoord van de leverancier een belangrijke bepalende factor kan zijn in de vraag of<br />

relaties voort duren. Toekomstige studies zouden zich kunnen c<strong>on</strong>centreren op een klein<br />

aantal sectoren en de sterkte van <strong>on</strong>ze bevindingen nagaan over verschillende moderators,<br />

zoals marktturbulentie en verhoogd technologisch risico.<br />

iii) Quasi-experimenteel <strong>on</strong>twerp met behulp van financiële en perceptuele gegevens in<br />

t<strong>and</strong>em. Eerdere studies van marktgerichtheid hebben c<strong>on</strong>flicten tussen objectieve en<br />

subjectieve maatstaven voor de prestaties gev<strong>on</strong>den (Narver & Slater, 1990).Om te<br />

133


epalen of <strong>on</strong>ze bevindingen daadwerkelijk echte financiële marktsentimenten en<br />

boekhoudkundige gegevens weergeven, kunnen toekomstige studies gebruik maken van<br />

financiële gegevens in combinatie met perceptuele gegevens.<br />

iv) Bredere vergelijking van de meting metrics. In de huidige studie hebben we alleen<br />

gebruik gemaakt van het idiosyncratisch risico, wat op zich een belangrijke indicator van<br />

de potentiële rendementen die betrokken bij elke relatie kan zijn. Echter, het risico is niet<br />

de enige metriek in de literatuur. Toekomstige studies kunnen <strong>on</strong>der meer een breder<br />

scala aan statistieken <strong>on</strong>derzoeken die betere indicatoren zijn dan <strong>and</strong>eren en waarom. Zo<br />

kan het <strong>on</strong>derzoek van het idiosyncratische risico in vergelijking met inventaris omzet<br />

statistieken of schuld leverage metrics een interessante invalshoek zijn.<br />

v) Vergelijking van meer strategieën met leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit voor het verminderen<br />

van idiosyncratische risico. We <strong>on</strong>derzoeken slechts één strategie namelijk die van<br />

marktgerichtheid als middel om idiosyncratisch risico te verminderen. Echter, er zijn<br />

<strong>and</strong>ere strategieën en oriëntaties, zoals een technologische oriëntatie of een<br />

marktleiderschap strategie. De wijze waarop deze strategieën en oriëntaties strategische<br />

leverancier-afnemer relaties beïnvloeden en hun idiosyncratisch risico uitkomsten zouden<br />

van potentieel belang kunnen zijn.<br />

vi) Het gebruik van <strong>on</strong>derzoeksmethoden <strong>and</strong>ers dan enquêtes. De <strong>on</strong>derzoeksopzet kan<br />

worden verbeterd met name met verwijzing naar hoofdstuk 3. Sommige <strong>on</strong>derzoekers<br />

hebben aangegeven dat etnografieën moeten gebruikt worden bij <strong>on</strong>derzoekskwesties die<br />

verb<strong>and</strong> houden met cultuur (Langerak, 2001).Het voordeel in hun opinie is dat<br />

organisatiecultuur beter kan worden gedocumenteerd door langdurige<br />

observatietechnieken, zoals etnografieën. Daarom zouden toekomstige <strong>on</strong>derzoekers<br />

gebruik kunnen maken van een etnografie voor een beter begrip van de leverancier<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit-koper bedrijfsprestaties relatie.<br />

vii) Vergelijking van meer diverse l<strong>and</strong>en. In hoofdstuk 3 hoewel de VS en Nederl<strong>and</strong><br />

verschillend zijn in sommige opzichten,delen ze ook overeenkomsten. Beide zijn<br />

geïndustrialiseerde l<strong>and</strong>en, ze hebben levendige democratieën, kapitalistische<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omieën, een zekere mate van soortgelijke westerse cultuur, en beide l<strong>and</strong>en zijn<br />

internati<strong>on</strong>aal c<strong>on</strong>currerende ec<strong>on</strong>omieën ( Deshp<strong>and</strong>e & Webster, 1989 ).Sommige<br />

culturele eigenaardigheden doen zich voor, zoals de aanvaarding van opscheppen over<br />

sollicitatiegesprekken in de Verenigde Staten en de voorkeur voor bescheidenheid in<br />

sollicitatiegesprekken in Nederl<strong>and</strong>, maar toch, kunnen ze beide worden beschouwd als<br />

westerse culturen. Echter, een vergelijking met een Aziatische cultuur is een meer diverse<br />

vergelijking. China is een groeiende wereldmacht, het is een communistische natie, en het<br />

heeft een collectivistische cultuur en een c<strong>on</strong>fucianistisch waardesysteem (Hofstede,<br />

2003).Deze culturele verschillen leiden tot verschillende risico voorkeuren bij individuele<br />

leden van de samenleving. Bijvoorbeeld, de Chinezen hebben een groter risico voorkeur<br />

dan de Amerikanen, omdat hun collectivistische cultuur hen beschermt tegen<br />

verlies. Toekomstige <strong>on</strong>derzoekers kunnen <strong>on</strong>derzoeken hoe bedrijven uit samenlevingen<br />

met extreem verschillende risico voorkeuren reageren op leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit. Dit<br />

zou ook een nieuwe dimensie kunnen toevoegen aan het probleem dat we bestudeerden<br />

134


ij de vraag of cultureel risico voorkeur een matigende factor in de leverancier<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit en koper prestatie-verhouding is.<br />

In sommige Euraziatische en Aziatische ec<strong>on</strong>omieën, vormen relati<strong>on</strong>ele praktijken zoals<br />

Blat en Gaunxi een integraal <strong>on</strong>derdeel van de bedrijfscultuur. Echter, in westerse<br />

culturen kunnen dergelijke praktijken worden beschouwd als <strong>on</strong>ethisch en schadelijk<br />

voor de zakelijke belangen en reputatie. In het bijz<strong>on</strong>der bij het vormen van strategische<br />

leveranciersrelaties met bedrijven die vinden dat dergelijke culturele praktijken<br />

aanvaardbaar zijn, kunnen kopers een negatieve spill-over op hun merkreputatie<br />

vrezen. Dergelijke culturele effecten zijn over het hoofd gezien in <strong>on</strong>ze huidige<br />

studie. Andere voorbeelden zijn vragen als: Variëert IdRR door de nati<strong>on</strong>ale cultuur? Of<br />

moet cultuur specifieke praktijken , zoals die van Blat of Guanxi als een deel van IdRR<br />

worden beschouwd?<br />

ix) gebruik van zowel subjectieve als objectieve maatstaven voor internati<strong>on</strong>ale<br />

vergelijkingen. Een <strong>and</strong>ere beperking van <strong>on</strong>ze huidige studie is dat we alleen percepties<br />

overwegen. Versterken percepties objectieve metingen tussen culturen? Zijn sommige<br />

culturen meer geneigd om overdreven blij te zijn als het gaat om omgeleide inkomsten uit<br />

beleggingen? Zijn sommige culturen te pessimistisch bij het voorspellen van verliezen die<br />

uit strategische relaties kunnen komen? Beïnvloeden culturen het relatieve belang van<br />

bedrijfsperceptie van marketing strategieën, zoals marktoriëntatie?<br />

x) De rol van bedrijfscultuur: Een cursus voor toekomstige <strong>on</strong>derzoekers zou kunnen zijn<br />

om de rol van de bedrijfscultuur te <strong>on</strong>derzoeken in het aanvaarden van subjectieve of<br />

objectieve metingen als geldige prestatie-indicatoren. Dit is belangrijk omdat het kan ook<br />

verklaren waarom middelen fout worden besteed als gevolg van <strong>on</strong>juiste percepties en<br />

hun betrouwbaarheid als geldige meetinstrumenten.<br />

xi) Het gebruik van afdeling-niveau specifieke statistieken: In de huidige studie,<br />

gebruikten we corporate-niveau objectieve indicatoren. Het gebruik van afdeling-niveau<br />

specifieke statistieken zou kunnen beter res<strong>on</strong>eren met managers inzicht in hoeveel winst<br />

hun afdelingen kunnen produceren. Het kan inderdaad zo zijn dat er niet veel verschilis<br />

tussen de objectieve en subjectieve meting indicatoren op hetzelfde niveau in de<br />

organisatie.<br />

Slotwoord<br />

Dit proefschrift heeft de rol van strategische leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit in interorganisatorische<br />

risicobeperking <strong>on</strong>derzocht, de invloed ervan op de tevredenheid, koper<br />

bedrijfswaarde, de bemiddelende rol van tevredenheid, cross-culturele vergelijkingen, en<br />

het verschil in evaluaties op basis van subjectieve prestatie-indicatoren. De werkelijke<br />

waarde van dit <strong>on</strong>derzoek ligt in de fundamentele uitdaging van het verb<strong>and</strong> tussen<br />

leverancier resp<strong>on</strong>siviteit en organisatorische risico's. Tot op zekere hoogte hebben we<br />

aangeto<strong>on</strong>d dat deze link negatief en niet positief aangenomen wordt door vele eerdere<br />

studies. Echter, verder <strong>on</strong>derzoek zal bevestigen dat <strong>on</strong>ze bevindingen kunnen worden<br />

toegepast in een grote verscheidenheid van c<strong>on</strong>texten.<br />

135


References<br />

Angelidis, T., & Tessaromatis, N. (2008). Does idiosyncratic risk matter? Evidence from<br />

European stock markets. Applied Financial Ec<strong>on</strong>omics, 18(2), 125-137.<br />

Aaker, D. A., & Jacobs<strong>on</strong>, R. (1994). The financial informati<strong>on</strong> c<strong>on</strong>tent of perceived<br />

quality. Journal of Marketing Research, 31(May), 191-201.<br />

Akerlof, G. A., & Shiller, R. J. (2010). Animal spirits: How human psychology drives<br />

the ec<strong>on</strong>omy, <strong>and</strong> why it matters for global capitalism. New Jersy: Princet<strong>on</strong><br />

Univsity Press.<br />

Anders<strong>on</strong>, Fornell, C., & Lehmann, D. R. (1994). Customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong>, market share,<br />

<strong>and</strong> profitability: findings from Sweden. Journal of Marketing, 58(3), 53-66.<br />

Anders<strong>on</strong>, E. W., Fornell, C., & Mazvancheryl, S. K. (2004). Customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

shareholder <strong>value</strong>. Journal of Marketing, 68 (4), 172-185.<br />

<br />

<br />

Bachman, L. F. (2004). Statistical analyses for language assessment. Cambridge:<br />

Cambridge University Press.<br />

Baker, T. L., Simps<strong>on</strong>, P. M., & Siguaw, J. A. (1999). The impact of <strong>supplier</strong>sí<br />

percepti<strong>on</strong>s of reseller market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> key relati<strong>on</strong>ship c<strong>on</strong>structs. Journal<br />

of the Academy of Marketing Science, 27 (1), 50-57.<br />

Barabba, V. P., & Zaltman, G. (1991). Hearing the voice of the market: competitive<br />

advantage through creative use of market informati<strong>on</strong>. Bost<strong>on</strong>, MA: Harvard<br />

Business School Press.<br />

Barney, J. B. (1986). Organizati<strong>on</strong>al culture: can it be a source of sustained competitive<br />

advantage? Academy of Management Review, 11(3), 656-665.<br />

Baumgartner, H., & Homburg, C. (1996). Applicati<strong>on</strong>s of structural equati<strong>on</strong> modeling in<br />

marketing <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sumer research: a review. Internati<strong>on</strong>al Journal of Research in<br />

Marketing, 13(2), 139-161.<br />

Bensaou, M., & Anders<strong>on</strong>, E. (1999). Buyer-<strong>supplier</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>s in industrial markets:<br />

when do <strong>buyer</strong>s risk making idiosyncratic investments? Organizati<strong>on</strong> Science, 10<br />

(4), 460-481.<br />

Bolt<strong>on</strong>, R. N., Lem<strong>on</strong>, K. N., & Verhoef, P. C. (2004). The theoretical underpinnings of<br />

customer asset management: a framework <strong>and</strong> propositi<strong>on</strong>s for future research.<br />

Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 32(3), 271-292.<br />

Bost<strong>on</strong>, W. (2009). Porsche <strong>and</strong> VW agree to a merger. Time Magazine Retrieved 1-11-<br />

2011, 2011, from http://www.time.com/time/business/article/<br />

0,8599,1896714,00.html<br />

Bowman, D., & Naray<strong>and</strong>as, D. (2004). Linking customer management effort to<br />

customer profitability in business markets. Journal of Marketing Research, 41(4),<br />

433-447.<br />

Buehler, K., Freeman, A., & Hulme, R. (2008). The new arsenal of risk management.<br />

Harvard Business Review, 86(9), 93-100.<br />

136


Businessweek. (2012). S&P/BusinessWeek Global Innovati<strong>on</strong> Index. Retrieved 20,12-<br />

2012 from http://www.businessweek.com/innovate/global_index/<br />

company_list.htm<br />

Carb<strong>on</strong>ell, F.A., & Praag, V.B. M. (2006). Insecurity in the Labor market: The impact of<br />

the type of c<strong>on</strong>tract <strong>on</strong> job satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in Spain <strong>and</strong> the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. Retrieved <strong>on</strong><br />

20-10-2012, from http://www.iae.csic.es/investigatorsMaterial/<br />

a71312152535archivoPdf75897.pdf.<br />

Cane, Mike. (2010, June, 8). Steve Jobs Insult Resp<strong>on</strong>se [Video file]. Retrieved from<br />

http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=FF-tKLISfPE<br />

Cassidy, J. (2009). How markets fail: The logic of ec<strong>on</strong>omic calamities: Farrar Straus &<br />

Giroux.<br />

Ch<strong>and</strong>y, R. K., & Tellis, G. J. (2000). The incumbent's curse? Incumbency, size, <strong>and</strong><br />

radical product innovati<strong>on</strong>. The Journal of Marketing, 1-17.<br />

Churchill Jr, G. A. (1979). A paradigm for developing better measures of marketing<br />

c<strong>on</strong>structs. Journal of Marketing Research, 16 (February), 64-73.<br />

Collins, J. (2009). How the mighty fall: And why some companies never give in. Collins<br />

Business Essentials<br />

Cremer, Andreas. (2010). Porsche `Shock Therapy' Spurs Improved Efficiency at<br />

Lufthansa, Volkswagen. Retrieved 9-12-2011, from http://www.bloomberg.com/<br />

news/2010-12-08/porsche-shock-therapy-spurs-vw-lufthansa-efficiency<br />

drive.html.<br />

Cyert, R. M., & March, J. G., (1963). A Behavioral Theory of the Firm. Englewood<br />

Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.<br />

Dawes, J. (1999). The relati<strong>on</strong>ship between subjective <strong>and</strong> objective company<br />

performance measures in market orientati<strong>on</strong> research: further empirical evidence.<br />

Marketing Bulletin-Department Of Marketing Massey University, 10, 65-75.<br />

Day, G. S. (1994). The capabilities of market-driven organizati<strong>on</strong>s. Journal of<br />

Marketing, 58 (October), 37-52.<br />

Day, G. S. (1998). What Does it Mean to be Market-Driven? Business Strategy<br />

Review, 9 (1), 1-14.<br />

Deshp<strong>and</strong>e, R., & Webster, F. E. (1989). Organizati<strong>on</strong>al culture <strong>and</strong> marketing: defining<br />

the research agenda. Journal of Marketing, 53 (January), 3-15.<br />

Diamantopoulos, A., & Winklhofer, H. M. (2001). Index c<strong>on</strong>structi<strong>on</strong> with formative<br />

indicators: an alternative to scale development. Journal of Marketing Research,<br />

17(4), 269-277.<br />

D<strong>on</strong>ey P. M. <strong>and</strong> Cann<strong>on</strong> J. P. (1997). An examinati<strong>on</strong> of the nature of trust in <strong>buyer</strong>seller<br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships. Journal of Marketing, Vol.61, pp. 35-51.<br />

Drucker, P. F. (1984). The new meaning of corporate social resp<strong>on</strong>sibility. California<br />

Management Review, 40(2), 8-17.<br />

Dwyer, F. R., & Gassenheimer, J. B. (1992). Relati<strong>on</strong>al roles <strong>and</strong> triangle dramas: effects<br />

<strong>on</strong> power play <strong>and</strong> sentiments in industrial channels. Marketing Letters, 3(2), 187-<br />

200.<br />

137


Eggert, A., & Ulaga, W. (2002). Customer perceived <strong>value</strong>: a substitute for satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in<br />

business markets? Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing, 17(2/3), 107-118.<br />

Ellis, P. D. (2006). Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Performance: A Meta Analysis <strong>and</strong> Cross<br />

Nati<strong>on</strong>al Comparis<strong>on</strong>s. Journal of Management Studies, 43(5), 1089-1107.<br />

Erdem, T., Zhao, Y., & Valenzuela, A. (2004). Performance of store br<strong>and</strong>s: A crosscountry<br />

analysis of c<strong>on</strong>sumer store-br<strong>and</strong> preferences, percepti<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> risk.<br />

Journal of Marketing Research, 41(1), 86-100.<br />

Esslem<strong>on</strong>t, D., & Lewis, T. (1991). Some empirical tests of the marketing c<strong>on</strong>cept.<br />

Marketing Bulletin, 2, 1-7.<br />

Farzad, R. (July 29, 2011). Apple’s earnings power befuddles Wall Street. Businessweek.<br />

Retrieved <strong>on</strong> January 15, 2012 from http://www.nbcnews.com/id/43946621/<br />

ns/business-us_business/?ocid=twitter<br />

Foer, J. (2011). Mo<strong>on</strong>walking with Einstein: the art <strong>and</strong> science of remembering<br />

everything. New York: Penguin Press.<br />

Foreign Direct Investment. (2010). Retrieved 7-10-2011, 2011, from<br />

http://www.census.gov/compendia/statab/2012/tables/12s1291.pdf<br />

Fornell, C., Johns<strong>on</strong>, M. D., Anders<strong>on</strong>, E. W., Cha, J., & Bryant, B. E. (1996). The<br />

American customer satisfacti<strong>on</strong> index: nature, purpose, <strong>and</strong> findings. Journal of<br />

Marketing, 60(4), 7-18.<br />

Frazier, G. L., Maltz, E., Antia, K. D., & Rindfleisch, A. (2009). Distributor sharing of<br />

strategic informati<strong>on</strong> with <strong>supplier</strong>s. Journal of Marketing, 73(4), 31-43.<br />

Gebhardt, G. F., Carpenter, G. S., & Sherry Jr, J. F. (2006). Creating a market orientati<strong>on</strong>:<br />

A l<strong>on</strong>gitudinal, multi<strong>firm</strong>, grounded analysis of cultural transformati<strong>on</strong>. Journal<br />

of Marketing, 70(4), 37-55.<br />

Geyskens, I., Steenkamp, J. B. E. M., & Kumar, N. (1999). A meta-analysis of<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> in marketing channel relati<strong>on</strong>ships. Journal of Marketing Research,<br />

36 (2), 223-238.<br />

Ghosh, M., & John, G. (2009). When Should Original Equipment Manufacturers Use<br />

Br<strong>and</strong>ed Comp<strong>on</strong>ent C<strong>on</strong>tracts with Suppliers? Journal of Marketing Research,<br />

46(5), 597-611.<br />

Girotra, K., & Netessine, S. (2011). How to build risk into your business model. Harvard<br />

Business Review, 89 (5),100-105.<br />

G<strong>on</strong>zalez-Benito, O., & G<strong>on</strong>z·lez-Benito, J. (2005). Cultural vs. operati<strong>on</strong>al market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> objective vs. subjective performance: perspective of producti<strong>on</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> operati<strong>on</strong>s. Industrial Marketing Management, 34(8), 797-829.<br />

Gord<strong>on</strong>, G. L., Calant<strong>on</strong>e, R. J., & Di Benedetto, C. A. (1993). Br<strong>and</strong> equity in the<br />

business-to-business sector: an exploratory study. Journal of Product & Br<strong>and</strong><br />

Management, 2(3), 4-16.<br />

Goyal, A., & Santa‐Clara, P. (2003). Idiosyncratic risk matters! The Journal of Finance,<br />

58(3), 975-1008.<br />

Greeley, B. (2011, September 01). The God Clause <strong>and</strong> the Reinsurance Industry<br />

Weekly. Businessweek. Retrieved 1-11, 2011, from<br />

http://www.businessweek.com/magazine/the-god-clause-<strong>and</strong>-the-reinsurance<br />

138


-industry-09012011.html<br />

Grewal, R., & Tansuhaj, P. (2001). Building organizati<strong>on</strong>al capabilities for managing<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic crisis: The role of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> strategic flexibility. Journal of<br />

Marketing, 65(2), 67-80.<br />

Guerrera, F. (2009, March 13). Welch denounces corporate obsessi<strong>on</strong>s, Financial Times.<br />

Retrieved November 30, 2009 from http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/3ca8ec2e-<br />

0f70-11de-ba10-0000779fd2ac.html - axzz1eLYiVbPI<br />

Hague, P. N., & Jacks<strong>on</strong>, P. (1994). The power of industrial br<strong>and</strong>s: an effective route to<br />

competitive advantage. Columbus, Ohio: McGraw-Hill.<br />

Hair, J. F., Anders<strong>on</strong>, R. E., Tatham, R. L., & Black, W. C. (2006). Multivariate analysis.<br />

L<strong>on</strong>d<strong>on</strong>: Pears<strong>on</strong>-Prentice Hall.<br />

Hamel, G., & Prahalad, C. K. (1994). Competing for the Future. Cambridge, MA:<br />

Harvard Business School Press.<br />

Han, J. K., Kim, N., & Srivastava, R. K. (1998). Market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

performance: is innovati<strong>on</strong> a missing link? Journal of Marketing, 62 (October),<br />

30-45.<br />

Harris, L. C. (2001). Market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance: objective <strong>and</strong> subjective<br />

empirical evidence from UK companies. Journal of Management Studies, 38(1),<br />

17-43.<br />

Hofstede, G. (1980). Motivati<strong>on</strong>, leadership, <strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>: Do American theories<br />

apply abroad. Organizati<strong>on</strong>al dynamics, 9(1), 42-63.<br />

Hofstede, G. H. (1984). Culture's c<strong>on</strong>sequences: Internati<strong>on</strong>al differences in workrelated<br />

<strong>value</strong>s (Vol. 5). Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage Publicati<strong>on</strong>s, Inc.<br />

Hofstede, G.H. & B<strong>on</strong>d, M. H. (1988). The C<strong>on</strong>fucius c<strong>on</strong>necti<strong>on</strong>: From cultural roots to<br />

ec<strong>on</strong>omic growth. Organizati<strong>on</strong>al dynamics, 16(4), 4-21.<br />

Hofstede, G. H. (1998). Masculinity <strong>and</strong> femininity: The taboo dimensi<strong>on</strong> of nati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

cultures. Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage Publicati<strong>on</strong>s, Inc.<br />

Hofstede, G. H. (2003). Culture's c<strong>on</strong>sequences: Comparing <strong>value</strong>s, behaviors,<br />

instituti<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>s across nati<strong>on</strong>s. Thous<strong>and</strong> Oaks, CA: Sage<br />

publicati<strong>on</strong>s, Inc.<br />

Holt, D. B., Quelch, J. A., & Taylor, E. L. (2004). How global br<strong>and</strong>s compete. Harvard<br />

Business Review, 82(9), 68-75.<br />

<br />

<br />

<br />

Hooley, G. J., Lynch, J. E., & Shepherd, J. (1990). The marketing c<strong>on</strong>cept: putting the<br />

theory into practice. European Journal of Marketing, 24(9), 7-24.<br />

House, R., Javidan, M., Hanges, P., & Dorfman, P. (2002). Underst<strong>and</strong>ing cultures<br />

<strong>and</strong> implicit leadership theories across the globe: an introducti<strong>on</strong> to project<br />

GLOBE. Journal of World Business, 37(1), 3-10.<br />

Hutt<strong>on</strong>, J. G. (1997). A study of br<strong>and</strong> equity in an organizati<strong>on</strong>al-buying c<strong>on</strong>text.<br />

Journal of Product & Br<strong>and</strong> Management, 6(6), 428-439.<br />

139


ING. (2010). Corporate governance differences. Retrieved September 10, 2011, from<br />

http://www.ing.com/Our-Company/About-us/Corporate-Governance/Corporategovernance-<strong>and</strong>-the-NYSE-listing-st<strong>and</strong>ards.htm<br />

J.D.POWER. (2010) Press release. Retrieved September 10, 2011, from<br />

http://businesscenter.jdpower.com/news/pressrelease.aspx?ID=2010099<br />

Jaworski, B. J., & Kohli, A. K. (1993). Market orientati<strong>on</strong>: antecedents <strong>and</strong><br />

c<strong>on</strong>sequences. Journal of Marketing, 57(3), 53-70.<br />

Jayach<strong>and</strong>ran, S., & Varadarajan, R. (2006). Does success diminish competitive<br />

resp<strong>on</strong>siveness? Rec<strong>on</strong>ciling c<strong>on</strong>flicting perspectives. Journal of the<br />

Academy of Marketing Science, 34(3), 284-294.<br />

Joreskog, K. G., & Sorbom, D. (1984). LISREL VI user's guide. Mooresville, IN:<br />

Scientific Software.<br />

Kalwani, M. U., & Naray<strong>and</strong>as, N. (1995). L<strong>on</strong>g-term manufacturer-<strong>supplier</strong><br />

relati<strong>on</strong>ships: do they pay off for <strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong>s? The Journal of Marketing, 59<br />

(January) 1-16.<br />

Keh, H. T., Chu, S., & Xu, J. (2006). Efficiency, effectiveness <strong>and</strong> productivity of<br />

marketing in services. European Journal of Operati<strong>on</strong>al Research, 170(1), 265-<br />

276.<br />

Keller, K. L. (1993). C<strong>on</strong>ceptualizing, measuring, <strong>and</strong> managing customer-based br<strong>and</strong><br />

equity. Journal of Marketing, 57 (January), 1-22.<br />

Kim, R.C. & Krolicki, K. (2010, February 5) Apologetic Toyota looking to outside<br />

quality input, Reuters, Retrieved from http://www.reuters.com/article/2010/02/05/<br />

us-toyota-idUSTRE6133U820100205<br />

Kirca, A. H., Jayach<strong>and</strong>ran, S., & Bearden, W. O. (2005). Market orientati<strong>on</strong>: a metaanalytic<br />

review <strong>and</strong> assessment of its antecedents <strong>and</strong> impact <strong>on</strong> performance.<br />

Journal of Marketing, 69(2), 24-41.<br />

Kohli, A. K., & Jaworski, B. J. (1990). Market orientati<strong>on</strong>: the c<strong>on</strong>struct, research<br />

propositi<strong>on</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> managerial implicati<strong>on</strong>s. Journal of Marketing, 54(2), 1-18.<br />

Kohli, A. K., Jaworski, B. J., & Kumar, A. (1993). MARKOR: a measure of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>. Journal of Marketing Research, 30 (November), 467-477.<br />

Koller, T., Goedhart, M. H., Wessels, D., Copel<strong>and</strong>, T. E., & McKinsey <strong>and</strong> Company.<br />

(2010). Valuati<strong>on</strong> : Measuring <strong>and</strong> Managing the Value of Companies (5 th ed.).<br />

Hoboken, N.J.: John Wiley & S<strong>on</strong>s, Inc.<br />

Kotler, P., & Armstr<strong>on</strong>g, G. (2001). Principals of Marketing. (9 th ed.). Harlow: Prentice<br />

Hall.<br />

Kotler, P., Armstr<strong>on</strong>g, G., Saunders, J., & W<strong>on</strong>g,V. (2008). Principles of Marketing.<br />

(5 th European ed.). Harlow: Prentice Hall.<br />

Kotler, P., & Pfoertsch, W. (2006). B2B Br<strong>and</strong> Management. New York: Springer.<br />

Kraljic, P. (1983). Purchasing must become supply management. Harvard Business<br />

Review, 61(5), 109-117.<br />

Kumar, N., Scheer, L. K., & Steenkamp, J. B. E. M. (1995). The effects of perceived<br />

interdependence <strong>on</strong> dealer attitudes. Journal of Marketing Research, 32 (August),<br />

348-356.<br />

140


Langerak, F. (2001). Effects of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> the behaviors of salespers<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong><br />

purchasers, channel relati<strong>on</strong>ships, <strong>and</strong> performance of manufacturers.<br />

Internati<strong>on</strong>al Journal of Research in Marketing, 18(3), 221-234.<br />

Langerak, F. (2003). The effect of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> positi<strong>on</strong>al advantage <strong>and</strong><br />

organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance. Journal of Strategic Marketing, 11(2), 93-115.<br />

Langerak, F., Hultink, E. J., & Robben, H. S. J. (2004a). The impact of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>, product advantage, <strong>and</strong> launch proficiency <strong>on</strong> new product<br />

performance <strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al performance. Journal of Product Innovati<strong>on</strong><br />

Management, 21(2), 79-94.<br />

Langerak, F., Hultink, E. J., & Robben, H. S. J. (2004b). The role of predevelopment<br />

activities in the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> performance. R&D<br />

Management, 34(3), 295-309.<br />

Langerak, F., Hultink, E. J., & Robben, H. S. J. (2007). The mediating role of new<br />

product development in the link between market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al<br />

performance. Journal of Strategic Marketing, 15(4), 281-305.<br />

Leadbeater. C.W., (n.d). Retrieved November 20, 2011, from http://www<br />

.notable-quotes.com/p/percepti<strong>on</strong>_quotes.html<br />

Lehmann, D<strong>on</strong>ald R. <strong>and</strong> Katherine E. Jocz, eds. (1997), Reflecti<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong> the Futures of<br />

Marketing. Cambridge, MA: Marketing Science Institute.<br />

Lisrel. (2012) Retrived August 10, 2012, from<br />

http://ssc.utexas.edu/software/faqs/lisrel#lisrel_2<br />

Luo, X. (2007). C<strong>on</strong>sumer negative voice <strong>and</strong> <strong>firm</strong>-idiosyncratic stock returns. Journal of<br />

Marketing, 71(3), 75-88.<br />

Lukas, B. A., & Ferrell, O. C. (2000). The effect of market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> product<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong>. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 28(2), 239-247.<br />

MacCallum, R. C., Browne, M. W., & Sugawara, H. M. (1996). Power analysis <strong>and</strong><br />

determinati<strong>on</strong> of sample size for covariance structure modeling. Psychological<br />

Methods, 1(2), 130.<br />

Marinova, D. (2004). Actualizing innovati<strong>on</strong> effort: the impact of market knowledge<br />

diffusi<strong>on</strong> in a dynamic system of competiti<strong>on</strong>. Journal of Marketing, 68 (July), 1-<br />

20.<br />

Marketwire. (2007, July 6). Linamar Gains Strategic Supplier Status with Caterpillar Inc.<br />

Retrieved 8-11, 2011, from http://www.marketwire.com/press-release/linamargains-strategic-<strong>supplier</strong>-status-with-caterpillar-inc-tsx-lnr-748870.htm<br />

Masselink, M. & Noord D.V.P. (2009). The global financial crisis <strong>and</strong> its effects <strong>on</strong> the<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s. ECFIN Country Focus, 6 (10), 1-7.<br />

McAlister, L., Srinivasan, R., & Kim, M. C. (2007). Advertising, research <strong>and</strong><br />

development, <strong>and</strong> systematic risk of the <strong>firm</strong>. Journal of Marketing, 71(1), 35-48.<br />

McKinsey. (2010). The challenges ahead for supply chains: McKinsey Global Survey<br />

results. McKinsey Quarterly Retrieved May 1, 2012, from http://www<br />

.mckinseyquarterly.com/Operati<strong>on</strong>s/Supply_Chain_Logistics/The_challenges_ahe<br />

ad_for_supply_chains_McKinsey_Global_Survey_results_2706<br />

141


McNamara, C. P. (1972). The present status of the marketing c<strong>on</strong>cept. Journal of<br />

Marketing, 36 (January), 50-57.<br />

McQuist<strong>on</strong>, D. H. (2004). Successful br<strong>and</strong>ing of a commodity product: The case of<br />

RAEX LASER steel. Industrial Marketing Management, 33(4), 345-354.<br />

Mitchell, V. W. (1999). C<strong>on</strong>sumer perceived risk: c<strong>on</strong>ceptualisati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>and</strong> models.<br />

European Journal of Marketing, 33(1/2), 163-195.<br />

Morgan, N. A., Anders<strong>on</strong>, E. W., & Mittal, V. (2005). Underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>firm</strong>s' customer<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> informati<strong>on</strong> usage. Journal of Marketing, 69(3), 131-151.<br />

Mudambi, S. M. D., Doyle, P., & W<strong>on</strong>g, V. (1997). An explorati<strong>on</strong> of br<strong>and</strong>ing in<br />

industrial markets. Industrial Marketing Management, 26(5), 433-446.<br />

Mudambi, S. (2002). Br<strong>and</strong>ing Importance in Business-to-Business Markets: Three<br />

Buyer Clusters. Industrial Marketing Management, 31 (6), 525-533.<br />

Naidu, G., & Narayana, C. L. (1991). How marketing oriented are hospitals in a declining<br />

market? Journal of Health Care Marketing, 11(1), 23.<br />

Naman, J. L., & Slevin, D. P. (1993). Entrepreneurship <strong>and</strong> the c<strong>on</strong>cept of fit: A model<br />

<strong>and</strong> empirical tests. Strategic Management Journal, 14(2), 137-153.<br />

Naray<strong>and</strong>as, D. (2005). Building loyalty in business markets. Harvard Business Review,<br />

83(9), 131-139.<br />

Narver, J. C., & Slater, S. F. (1990). The effect of a market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> business<br />

profitability. Journal of Marketing, 54(4), 20-35.<br />

Nightingale, A. (2009, April 29, 2009). Oil Floods Rotterdam, Europe's Largest Port, as<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> drops, Bloomberg. Retrieved from http://www.bloomberg.com/<br />

apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=ae.YS7TBN0jY<br />

Norris, D. G. (1992). Ingredient br<strong>and</strong>ing: a strategy opti<strong>on</strong> with multiple beneficiaries.<br />

Journal of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Marketing, 9(3), 19-31.<br />

Oliver, R. L. (1980). A cognitive model of the antecedents <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequences of<br />

satisfacti<strong>on</strong> decisi<strong>on</strong>s. Journal of Marketing Research, 17, 460-469.<br />

Oliver, R. L. (1993). Cognitive, affective, <strong>and</strong> attribute bases of the satisfacti<strong>on</strong> resp<strong>on</strong>se.<br />

Journal of C<strong>on</strong>sumer Research, 20 (3), 418-430.<br />

Pauwels, K., Ambler, T., Clark, B., LaPointe, P., Reibstein, D., Skiera, B.,Wiesel, T.<br />

(2008). Dashboards <strong>and</strong> Marketing: why, what, how <strong>and</strong> what research is needed?<br />

Marketing Science Institute, 08-203.<br />

Pelham, A. M., & Wils<strong>on</strong>, D.T. (1996). A L<strong>on</strong>gitudinal Study of the Impact of Market<br />

Structure, Firm Structure, Strategy, <strong>and</strong> Market Orientati<strong>on</strong> Culture <strong>on</strong><br />

Dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of SmallFirm Perf<strong>on</strong>nance. Journal of the Academy of Marketing<br />

Science, 24 (1),27-A3.<br />

Phillips, L. W. (1981). Assessing measurement error in key informant reports: A<br />

methodological note <strong>on</strong> organizati<strong>on</strong>al analysis in marketing. Journal of<br />

Marketing Research, 18(4), 395-415.<br />

Porter, M. E., & Millar, V. E. (1985). How informati<strong>on</strong> gives you competitive advantage.<br />

Harvard Business Review, 63(4), 149-160.<br />

Pulendran, S., Speed, R., & Widing, R. E. (2000). The antecedents <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>sequences of<br />

market orientati<strong>on</strong> in Australia. Australian Journal of Management, 25(2), 119.<br />

142


Quelch, J. (2007). How to br<strong>and</strong> an ingredient. HBR Blog Network. Retrieved from<br />

http://blogs.hbr.org/quelch/2007/10/how_to_br<strong>and</strong>_an_ingredient_1.html<br />

Rajan, M. V., & Reichelstein, S. (2006). Subjective performance indicators <strong>and</strong><br />

discreti<strong>on</strong>ary b<strong>on</strong>us pools. Journal of Accounting Research, 44(3), 585-618.<br />

Reeves, M., & Deimler, M. (2011). Adaptability: The new competitive advantage.<br />

Harvard Business Review, 89(7/8), 134-141.<br />

Rego, L. L., Billet, M. T. <strong>and</strong> Morgan, N. A. (2009) C<strong>on</strong>sumer-Based Br<strong>and</strong> Equity <strong>and</strong><br />

Firm Risk. Journal of Marketing, 73(6): 47-60.<br />

Rindfleisch, A., Malter, A. J., Ganesan, S., & Moorman, C. (2008). Cross-secti<strong>on</strong>al<br />

versus l<strong>on</strong>gitudinal survey research: c<strong>on</strong>cepts, findings, <strong>and</strong> guidelines. Journal of<br />

Marketing Research, 45(3), 261-279.<br />

Roselius, T. (1971). C<strong>on</strong>sumer rankings of risk reducti<strong>on</strong> methods. Journal of Marketing,<br />

35(1), 56-61.<br />

Rotterdam's Ec<strong>on</strong>omy. (2011) Retrieved 7-10-2011, 2011, from<br />

http://www.macalester.edu/courses/geog261/Otte_Rotterdam/Rotterdam<br />

Ec<strong>on</strong>omy.html<br />

Ruekert, R. W., & Churchill Jr, G. A. (1984). Reliability <strong>and</strong> validity of alternative<br />

measures of channel member satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. Journal of Marketing Research, 21(2),<br />

226-233.<br />

San Miguel, J. G. (1977). The reliability of R&D data in Compustat <strong>and</strong> 10-K reports.<br />

The Accounting Review, 52(3), 638-641.<br />

Sanzo, M. J., Santos, M. L., Vazquez, R., & Alvarez, L. I. (2003). The effect of market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> <strong>buyer</strong>-seller relati<strong>on</strong>ship satisfacti<strong>on</strong>. Industrial Marketing<br />

Management, 32(4), 327-345.<br />

Saxt<strong>on</strong>, T. (1997). The effects of partner <strong>and</strong> relati<strong>on</strong>ship characteristics <strong>on</strong> alliance<br />

outcomes. Academy of Management Journal, 443-461.<br />

Schlegelmilch, B. B., & Ram, S. (2000). The Impact of Organizati<strong>on</strong>al <strong>and</strong><br />

Envir<strong>on</strong>mental Variables <strong>on</strong> Strategic Market Orientati<strong>on</strong>. Journal of Global<br />

Marketing, 13(3), 111-127.<br />

Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, socialism <strong>and</strong> democracy. New York: Harper & Row.<br />

Schmitt, E. (2009). The Profits <strong>and</strong> Perils of Supplying to Wal-Mart. Businessweek<br />

Retrieved May 20, 2012, from http://www.businessweek.com/smallbiz/<br />

c<strong>on</strong>tent/jul2009/sb20090714_270767.htm<br />

Scholz, R. (2009). The C<strong>on</strong>stant Hit. Porsche C<strong>on</strong>sulting Magazine. Retrieved November<br />

5, 2011, from http://www.porschec<strong>on</strong>sulting.com/pco/en/press/<br />

porschec<strong>on</strong>sultingmagazine/issue08/<br />

Schwartz, S. H. (1994). Bey<strong>on</strong>d individualism/collectivism: New cultural dimensi<strong>on</strong>s of<br />

<strong>value</strong>s: Sage Publicati<strong>on</strong>s, Inc.<br />

Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under<br />

c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s of risk. The Journal of Finance, 19(3), 425-442.<br />

Shaw, J., Giglierano, J., & Kallis, J. (1991). Marketing complex technical products: the<br />

importance of intangible attributes. ISA Transacti<strong>on</strong>s, 30(3), 45-53.<br />

143


Siemans (2013) Leveraging strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s for strategic innovati<strong>on</strong>. Retrieved January<br />

11, 2013, from http://www.plm.automati<strong>on</strong>.siemens.com/<br />

zh_cn/Images/7562_tcm78-4602.pdf<br />

Siguaw, J. A., Simps<strong>on</strong>, P. M., & Baker, T. L. (1998). Effects of <strong>supplier</strong> market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> distributor market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the channel relati<strong>on</strong>ship: the<br />

distributor perspective. Journal of Marketing, 62(3), 99-111.<br />

Singh, M., Faircloth, S., & Nejadmalayeri, A. (2005). Capital market impact of product<br />

marketing strategy: evidence from the relati<strong>on</strong>ship between advertising expenses<br />

<strong>and</strong> cost of capital. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science, 33(4), 432-444.<br />

Slater, S. F., & Narver, J. C. (1994). Does competitive envir<strong>on</strong>ment moderate the market<br />

orientati<strong>on</strong>-performance relati<strong>on</strong>ship? Journal of Marketing, 58 (January), 46-55.<br />

Slater, S. F., & Narver, J. C. (1995). Market orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> the learning organizati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

The Journal of Marketing, 59 (July), 63-74.<br />

Slater, S. F., & Narver, J. C. (1998). Customer led <strong>and</strong> market oriented: let's not c<strong>on</strong>fuse<br />

the two. Strategic Management Journal, 19(10), 1001-1006.<br />

Srinivasan, S., & Hanssens, D. M. (2009). Marketing <strong>and</strong> <strong>firm</strong> <strong>value</strong>: Metrics, methods,<br />

findings, <strong>and</strong> future directi<strong>on</strong>s. Journal of Marketing Research, 46(3), 293-312.<br />

Srivastava, R. K., Shervani, T. A., & Fahey, L. (1998). Market-based assets <strong>and</strong><br />

shareholder <strong>value</strong>: A framework for analysis. Journal of Marketing, 62(1), 2-18.<br />

Srivastava, R. K., Shervani, T. A., & Fahey, L. (1999). Marketing, business processes,<br />

<strong>and</strong> shareholder <strong>value</strong>: an organizati<strong>on</strong>ally embedded view of marketing activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> the discipline of marketing. Journal of Marketing, 63 (Special Issue), 168-<br />

179.<br />

Steinman, C., Deshp<strong>and</strong>e, R., & Farley, J. U. (2000). Bey<strong>on</strong>d market orientati<strong>on</strong>: when<br />

customers <strong>and</strong> <strong>supplier</strong>s disagree. Journal of the Academy of Marketing<br />

Science, 28(1), 109-119.<br />

Tellis, G. J., Prabhu, J. C., & Ch<strong>and</strong>y, R. K. (2009). Radical innovati<strong>on</strong> across nati<strong>on</strong>s:<br />

the preeminence of corporate culture. Journal of Marketing, 73(1), 3-23.<br />

Treacy, M., & Wiersema, F. (1993). Customer intimacy <strong>and</strong> other <strong>value</strong><br />

disciplines. Harvard Business Review, 71, 84-84.<br />

Trompenaars, F. (1994). Riding the waves of culture: Underst<strong>and</strong>ing diversity in global<br />

business. New York: Irwin.<br />

TSE, C. B. L. (1995). The effect of marketing orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong> company performance in the<br />

service sector: a comparative study of the hotel industry in H<strong>on</strong>g K<strong>on</strong>g <strong>and</strong> New<br />

Zeal<strong>and</strong>. Journal of Internati<strong>on</strong>al C<strong>on</strong>sumer Marketing, 8(2), 77-87.<br />

Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics <strong>and</strong> biases.<br />

Science, 185(4157), 1124-1131.<br />

USC Marshall. (2008, August 5). Gerard Tellis - Innovati<strong>on</strong> [Video file]. Retrieved from<br />

https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=xRwy6n-XcmA<br />

U.S. Trade Balance. (2012). U.S. Trade Balance, by Partner Country 2012<br />

in descending order of trade turnover (imports plus exports). Retrieved October 7,<br />

2012, from http://dataweb.usitc.gov/scripts/cy_m3_run.asp<br />

144


Verhoef, P. C., & Leeflang, P. S. H. (2009). Underst<strong>and</strong>ing the marketing department's<br />

influence within the <strong>firm</strong>. Journal of Marketing, 73(2), 14-37.<br />

Verhees, F.J.H.M., & Meulenberg, M.T.G. (2004). Market Orientati<strong>on</strong>, Innovativeness,<br />

Product Innovati<strong>on</strong>, <strong>and</strong> Performance in Small Firms. Journal of Small Business<br />

Management. Vol. 42 (2), pp.134–54.<br />

V<strong>on</strong> Hippel, E. A. (1976). The dominant role of users in the scientific instrument<br />

innovati<strong>on</strong> process. Research Policy 5, no. 3, 212–239.<br />

Voss, Glenn B. <strong>and</strong> Zannie G. Voss (2000), Strategic Orientati<strong>on</strong> <strong>and</strong> Firm Performance<br />

in an Artistic Envir<strong>on</strong>ment, Journal of Marketing, 64 (January), 67-83.<br />

Weber, E., & Hsee, C. (1999). Cross-nati<strong>on</strong>al differences in risk preference <strong>and</strong> lay<br />

predicti<strong>on</strong>s. Journal of Behavioral Decisi<strong>on</strong> Making, 12, 165-179.<br />

Whitwell, S. (2005). Ingredient br<strong>and</strong>ing case study: Intel. Retrieved January 22, 2011,<br />

from http://www.intangiblebusiness.com/Br<strong>and</strong>-Services/Marketingservices/News/Ingredient-br<strong>and</strong>ing-case-study-Intel~466.html<br />

Wierenga, B., & Van Bruggen, G. H. (1997). The integrati<strong>on</strong> of marketing problemsolving<br />

modes <strong>and</strong> marketing management support systems. Journal of<br />

Marketing, 61(3), 21-37.<br />

Zaltman, G. (2003). How customers think: Essential insights into the mind of the market:<br />

Harvard Business Press.<br />

Zhou, K. Z., Yim, C. K., & Tse, D. K. (2005). The effects of strategic orientati<strong>on</strong>s <strong>on</strong><br />

technology-<strong>and</strong> market-based breakthrough innovati<strong>on</strong>s. Journal of Marketing,<br />

69(2), 42-60.<br />

145


Appendix A<br />

Appendix A provides an overview of all questi<strong>on</strong>s that were used in the final analyses in<br />

this thesis. The questi<strong>on</strong>s relate to the five variables in this thesis. The questi<strong>on</strong>s are<br />

provided beneath the name of the variable they are measuring. The scale for each<br />

questi<strong>on</strong> has been provided. The original questi<strong>on</strong>naire collected data <strong>on</strong> three strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>s, but in this dissertati<strong>on</strong> <strong>on</strong>ly data <strong>on</strong> the most important strategic <strong>supplier</strong> has<br />

been used (strategic <strong>supplier</strong> A). For an unabridged versi<strong>on</strong> of the questi<strong>on</strong>naire, please<br />

email the author <strong>on</strong> abrahimx@yahoo.com.<br />

General Directi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Directi<strong>on</strong>s<br />

Our main aim is to uncover how the <strong>value</strong> of your <strong>firm</strong> can be influenced by the acti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

of your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s.<br />

The following informati<strong>on</strong> is important when answering this questi<strong>on</strong>naire:<br />

• Please answer all questi<strong>on</strong>s. You cannot proceed to the next page if you do not answer<br />

all the questi<strong>on</strong>s.<br />

• For the sake of the scientific validity of our findings, we ask you to give an h<strong>on</strong>est <strong>and</strong><br />

realistic evaluati<strong>on</strong> of your situati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

• All data are treated c<strong>on</strong>fidentially. The strictest an<strong>on</strong>ymity is c<strong>on</strong>stantly guaranteed.<br />

• A management summary of the research report will be sent to you <strong>on</strong>ce it has been<br />

compiled.<br />

Professor Dr. Henry Robben<br />

<strong>Nyenrode</strong> Business Universiteit<br />

h.robben@nyenrode.nl<br />

Mr. Abrahim Zaka<br />

<strong>Nyenrode</strong> Business Universiteit<br />

a.zakakhan@nyenrode.nl<br />

146


1. The name of the company where you currently work:<br />

Parent company<br />

Strategic business<br />

unit<br />

2. What percentage of total profit of your company does your strategic business unit<br />

represent inside the group of the parent company? Please state the percentage as a whole<br />

number between1 <strong>and</strong> 100.<br />

3. We sell the products or services of this line-of-business to (please check <strong>on</strong>e box):<br />

Industrial markets (other companies or organizati<strong>on</strong>s)<br />

C<strong>on</strong>sumer markets (individual end customers <strong>and</strong> households)<br />

Both<br />

4. This product line is oriented towards (please check <strong>on</strong>e box):<br />

Services<br />

Goods<br />

A combinati<strong>on</strong> of both<br />

5. What type of resp<strong>on</strong>sibility center is your company?<br />

Revenue center. Company unit is assessed <strong>on</strong> sales performance.<br />

Expense center. Company unit is assessed <strong>on</strong> the basis of its costs.<br />

Profit center. Company unit is assessed <strong>on</strong> the basis of profits.<br />

Investment center. Company unit is assessed <strong>on</strong> return <strong>on</strong> investment.<br />

147


6. Please state the names of the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s of your <strong>firm</strong>. Please remember the<br />

symbol (A, B <strong>and</strong> C) assigned to each separate <strong>supplier</strong>. A should be your str<strong>on</strong>gest<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong>, B should be your average strategic <strong>supplier</strong>, <strong>and</strong> C should be your<br />

weakest strategic <strong>supplier</strong>. IMPORTANT! PLEASE STATE THE NAME OF SPECIFIC<br />

COMPANIES. For example write Delta airlines <strong>and</strong> do not write all North American<br />

airlines.<br />

A) Str<strong>on</strong>gest<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

B) Average<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong>.<br />

C) Weakest<br />

strategic <strong>supplier</strong><br />

Supplier Resp<strong>on</strong>siveness<br />

7. The <strong>supplier</strong> meets with us at least <strong>on</strong>ce a year to find out what products <strong>and</strong><br />

services we will need in the future.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

8. Individuals from the <strong>supplier</strong>s’ manufacturing department interact directly with us to<br />

inquire as to how they can improve their services or products.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

148


9.The <strong>supplier</strong> seems to have good internal market intelligence generati<strong>on</strong> capabilities.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

10. The <strong>supplier</strong> regularly c<strong>on</strong>tacts us to assess the quality of their products <strong>and</strong> services.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

11. This <strong>supplier</strong> has high quality informati<strong>on</strong> regarding their channel partners (e.g.,<br />

retailers, distributors <strong>and</strong> us).<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

12. The <strong>supplier</strong> often interacts with us in informal meetings (e.g., lunch with our<br />

managers) to collect informati<strong>on</strong> about our business.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

149


13. A lot of the informal c<strong>on</strong>versati<strong>on</strong>s with our <strong>supplier</strong>s c<strong>on</strong>cern the market c<strong>on</strong>diti<strong>on</strong>s<br />

<strong>and</strong> our competitors’ strategies.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

14. The <strong>supplier</strong> is slow to detect fundamental shifts in our industry (e.g., competiti<strong>on</strong>,<br />

technology, regulati<strong>on</strong>).<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

15. The <strong>supplier</strong> provides us with periodic market intelligence (e.g. newsletters <strong>and</strong><br />

reports) with c<strong>on</strong>tent of interest to many cross-functi<strong>on</strong>al departments within our <strong>firm</strong>.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

16. We simply need to communicate our needs to <strong>on</strong>e of the various functi<strong>on</strong>al<br />

departments (e.g., marketing, manufacturing, operati<strong>on</strong>s, finance) <strong>and</strong> every<strong>on</strong>e<br />

c<strong>on</strong>cerned (cross functi<strong>on</strong>ally) within the <strong>supplier</strong>’s <strong>firm</strong> will be immediately updated <strong>on</strong><br />

our new situati<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

150


17. The <strong>supplier</strong> takes a very l<strong>on</strong>g time to resp<strong>on</strong>d to changes in their competitors’<br />

pricing strategies.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

18. For <strong>on</strong>e reas<strong>on</strong> or another, the <strong>supplier</strong> tends to ignore changes in your product or<br />

service needs.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

19. The <strong>supplier</strong> seems to be driven by the customers (your) perspective in new product<br />

development efforts.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

20. The <strong>supplier</strong>'s business plans seem to be driven more by technological advances than<br />

by market research.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

151


21. The <strong>supplier</strong>'s resp<strong>on</strong>se to us is often not aligned with our needs because of internal<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> <strong>firm</strong> politics.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

22. If the <strong>supplier</strong>'s major competitor were to launch an intensive campaign targeted at<br />

you, then the <strong>supplier</strong> would normally implement a counter campaign directed towards<br />

you.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

23.The <strong>supplier</strong>s do not heed your complaints.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

24. The <strong>supplier</strong> sometimes has excellent marketing plans, but they seem to be<br />

implemented too slowly or too late.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

152


25. If the <strong>supplier</strong> were to find out that you are unhappy with the quality of their service,<br />

they would immediately take corrective acti<strong>on</strong>.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

26. If the <strong>supplier</strong>s find out that you would like them to modify a product or service, they<br />

would make c<strong>on</strong>certed efforts to do so.<br />

Extremely<br />

agree<br />

Agree Neutral Disagree Extremely<br />

disagree<br />

Scale: Extremely agree =1, Agree=2, Neutral=3, Disagree=4, Extremely<br />

disagree=5<br />

IdRR<br />

27.To what extent does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you reduce your factory or<br />

manufacturing costs?<br />

Highly<br />

reduces<br />

Reduces Neutral Increases Highly<br />

Increases<br />

Scale: Highly reduces =5, Reduces=4, Neutral=3, Increases=2, Highly Increases=1<br />

28.To what extent does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you increase your<br />

product or service quality?<br />

Highly<br />

increases<br />

quality<br />

Increases<br />

quality<br />

Neutral<br />

Reduces<br />

quality<br />

Highly<br />

reduces<br />

quality<br />

Scale: Highly reduces =5, Reduces=4, Neutral=3, Increases=2, Highly Increases=1<br />

153


29.In the past, has your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> been willing to invest in technology that would<br />

improve your supply chain cost efficiency?<br />

Highly<br />

willing<br />

Willing Neutral Unwilling Highly<br />

unwilling<br />

Scale: Highly willing =5, Willing=4, Neutral=3, Unwilling=2, Highly unwilling=1<br />

30.In the past, has your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> been willing to invest in technology that would<br />

improve your research <strong>and</strong> development <strong>and</strong> engineering cost efficiency?<br />

Highly<br />

willing<br />

Willing Neutral Unwilling Highly<br />

unwilling<br />

Scale: Highly willing =5, Willing=4, Neutral=3, Unwilling=2, Highly unwilling=1<br />

31.To what extent does you strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your channel or distributi<strong>on</strong><br />

costs?<br />

Highly<br />

reduces<br />

Reduces Neutral Increases Highly<br />

increases<br />

Scale: Highly reduces =5, Reduces=4, Neutral=3, Increases=2, Highly increases=1<br />

32.Does the strategic <strong>supplier</strong> help you to reduce your sales cost?<br />

Highly<br />

reduces<br />

Reduces Neutral Increases Highly<br />

increases<br />

Scale: Highly reduces =5, Reduces=4, Neutral=3, Increases=2, Highly increases=1<br />

154


33.Does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> also provide you with intelligence <strong>on</strong> the markets in<br />

which you operate?<br />

Always<br />

provides<br />

Sometime<br />

provides<br />

Neutral<br />

Sometimes<br />

does not<br />

provide<br />

Often does<br />

not provide<br />

Scale: Highly reduces =5, Reduces=4, Neutral=3, Increases=2, Highly increases=1<br />

34. To what extent does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your inventory management?<br />

Highly<br />

positively<br />

Positively Neutral Negatively Highly<br />

negatively<br />

Scale: Highly positively =5, Positively=4, Neutral=3, Negatively=2, Highly<br />

negatively=1<br />

35.Does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> offer you flexible payment schedules?<br />

Highly<br />

flexible<br />

Flexible Neutral Inflexible Highly<br />

inflexible<br />

Scale: Highly flexible =5, Flexible=4, Neutral=3, Inflexible=2, Highly<br />

inflexible=1<br />

36.To what extent does your <strong>supplier</strong> help you manage your inventory?<br />

Highly<br />

helps<br />

Helps Neutral Problematic Highly<br />

problematic<br />

Scale: Highly helps =5, Helps=4, Neutral=3, Problematic=2, Highly<br />

problematic=1<br />

155


37.To what degree does your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your cash c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> cycle?<br />

A definiti<strong>on</strong>al clarificati<strong>on</strong>: The cash c<strong>on</strong>versi<strong>on</strong> cycle is the time durati<strong>on</strong> in which a<br />

<strong>firm</strong> is able to c<strong>on</strong>vert its resources into cash. It is actually the total time period required<br />

to first c<strong>on</strong>vert resources into inventories, then inventories into finished goods, then<br />

goods into sales, <strong>and</strong> then sales into cash.<br />

Highly<br />

positively<br />

Positively Neutral Negatively Highly<br />

negatively<br />

Scale: Highly positively =5, Positively=4, Neutral=3, Negatively=2, Highly<br />

negatively=1<br />

38.To what extent have your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s tried to simplify your<br />

supply chain processes?<br />

Highly<br />

simplified<br />

Simplified Neutral Increased<br />

complexity<br />

Highly<br />

negatively<br />

Scale: Highly simplified =5, Simplified=4, Neutral=3, Increased complexity=2, Highly<br />

negatively=1<br />

39. To what extent does using your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your ability to minimize<br />

the time needed for your <strong>firm</strong> to provide soluti<strong>on</strong>s for your customers?<br />

Highly<br />

reduces<br />

Reduces Neutral Increases Highly<br />

increases<br />

Scale: Highly reduces =5, Reduces=4, Neutral=3, Increases=2, Highly increases=1<br />

40. To what extent do your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>s correctly invoice your company?<br />

Always<br />

correctly<br />

Moderately<br />

correctly<br />

Neutral<br />

Moderately<br />

incorrectly<br />

Always<br />

incorrectly<br />

Scale: Highly Correctly =5, Moderately correctly =4, Neutral=3, Moderately<br />

incorrectly =2, Always incorrectly=1<br />

156


41.To what degree do those specific investments make it difficult for the strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> to end their relati<strong>on</strong>ship with you?<br />

Very<br />

difficult<br />

Moderately<br />

Difficult<br />

Neutral<br />

Moderately<br />

easy<br />

Highly<br />

easy<br />

Scale: Very difficult =5, Moderately difficult=4, Neutral=3, Moderately easy=2, Highly<br />

easy=1<br />

Buyer Satisfacti<strong>on</strong><br />

42. How satisfied are you with the profits generated from carrying the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

products lines, if any?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

43. How satisfied are you with the overall manner with which the strategic<br />

<strong>supplier</strong>’s representatives (regi<strong>on</strong>al or head office) treat you?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

44. How satisfied are you with the sales support provided by the manufacturer's<br />

local sales representative?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

45. How satisfied are you with the new product market opportunities the<br />

<strong>supplier</strong> provides you?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

157


46.How satisfied are you with the sales growth potential from carrying the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

products lines, if any?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

47.How satisfied are you with this <strong>supplier</strong>’s overall fairness <strong>and</strong> h<strong>on</strong>esty<br />

while dealing with you?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

48.How satisfied are you with the interest <strong>and</strong> c<strong>on</strong>cern that this <strong>supplier</strong> has in<br />

helping you meet your objectives?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

49. What is your overall satisfacti<strong>on</strong> with this <strong>supplier</strong>?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

50.How satisfied are you with the sales growth potential from carrying the <strong>supplier</strong>’s<br />

product lines, if any?<br />

Highly<br />

satisfied<br />

Satisfied Neutral Dissatisfied Highly<br />

dissatisfied<br />

Scale: Highly Satisfied =1, Satisfied=2, Neutral=3, Satisfied=4, Dissatisfied=5<br />

158


Supplier Br<strong>and</strong> Value<br />

51.How likely are you to repurchase from these <strong>supplier</strong>s?<br />

Extremely<br />

likely<br />

Likely Neutral Unlikely Extremely<br />

unlikely<br />

Scale: Extremely likely =1, Likely=2, Neutral=3, Unlikely=4, Extremely<br />

unlikely=5<br />

52.How likely are you to tolerate a price increase by your strategic <strong>supplier</strong>?<br />

Extremely<br />

tolerant<br />

Tolerant Neutral Intolerant Extremely<br />

intolerant<br />

Scale: Extremely tolerant =1, Tolerant=2, Neutral=3, Intolerant=4, Extremely<br />

intolerant=5<br />

53. To what extend does being associated with the strategic <strong>supplier</strong>’s br<strong>and</strong> give you<br />

leverage with your customers?<br />

Highly<br />

positive<br />

Positive Neutral Negative Highly<br />

negative<br />

Scale: Highly positive =1, Positive =2, Neutral=3, Negative =4, Highly negative=5<br />

Buyer Firm Value<br />

54.To what extent will your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> influence your future cash flow growth?<br />

Extremely<br />

positive<br />

influence<br />

Positive<br />

influence<br />

Neutral<br />

Negative<br />

influence<br />

Extremely<br />

negative<br />

influence<br />

Scale: Extremely positive influence =1, Positive influence=2, Neutral=3, Negative<br />

influence=4, Extremely negative influence=5<br />

159


55. To what extent do you think your strategic <strong>supplier</strong> will influence the stability of your<br />

future cash flows?<br />

Extremely<br />

positive<br />

influence<br />

Positive<br />

influence<br />

Neutral<br />

Negative<br />

influence<br />

Extremely<br />

negative<br />

influence<br />

Scale: Extremely positive influence =1, Positive influence=2, Neutral=3, Negative<br />

influence=4, Extremely negative influence=5<br />

160


Appendix B<br />

Scatter Plot Diagrams for Chapter 2:<br />

161


162


163


SKEWNESS AND KURTOSIS CHAPTER 2<br />

N Min Max Mean Std.Dev Skewness Kurtosis<br />

Ratio<br />

Ratio Statistic Std.<br />

Error<br />

Statistic Statistic Statistic Statistic Statistic Statistic Std.<br />

Error<br />

SIQ 164.00 1.00 5.00 1.95 0.84 0.78 0.19 4.11 0.55 0.38 1.46<br />

CUSTNPD 164.00 1.00 4.00 2.07 0.87 0.76 0.19 4.03 0.14 0.38 0.37<br />

CF 164.00 1.00 5.00 2.10 0.77 0.55 0.19 2.89 0.66 0.38 1.76<br />

RP 164.00 1.00 5.00 1.76 0.79 0.98 0.19 5.17 1.16 0.38 3.08<br />

Fairness 164.00 1.00 5.00 1.95 0.79 0.70 0.19 3.67 0.70 0.38 1.86<br />

Sales 164.00 1.00 5.00 2.06 0.81 0.51 0.19 2.72 0.27 0.38 0.72<br />

IM 164.00 1.00 5.00 3.72 0.87 -0.39 0.19 -2.04 0.37 0.38 0.99<br />

CCC 164.00 1.00 5.00 3.71 0.77 -0.04 0.19 -0.22 0.01 0.38 0.02<br />

AssBr<strong>and</strong> 164.00 1.00 4.00 2.10 0.83 0.21 0.19 1.08 -0.75 0.38 -2.00<br />

BFV 164.00 1.00 4.00 2.17 0.71 0.08 0.19 0.42 -0.36 0.38 -0.96<br />

SIQ.Sqr 164.00 1.00 2.24 1.36 0.30 0.32 0.19 1.70 -0.45 0.38 -1.19<br />

CUST.NPD.sqr 164.00 1.00 2.00 1.40 0.30 0.32 0.19 1.69 -0.37 0.38 -0.99<br />

CF.Sqr 164.00 1.00 2.24 1.42 0.27 0.03 0.19 0.15 -0.13 0.38 -0.34<br />

Fair.Sqr 164.00 1.00 2.24 1.36 0.28 0.23 0.19 1.21 -0.43 0.38 -1.14<br />

Sales.Sqr 164.00 1.00 2.24 1.40 0.29 0.07 0.19 0.37 -0.53 0.38 -1.41<br />

RP.Sqr 164.00 1.00 2.24 1.29 0.29 0.54 0.19 2.87 -0.35 0.38 -0.92<br />

As we can see from the Table above the following items are skewed: SIQ, Cust.NPD, CF, Fair, Sales<br />

RP. To correct for the skewness we took a square root of the above variables. After the squareroot transformati<strong>on</strong> the skewness to st<strong>and</strong>ard error<br />

ratio is acceptable. The new variables are labeled as follows: SIQ.Sqr, CUST.NPD.sqr, CF.Sqr, Fair.Sqr, Sales.Sqr,<br />

RP.Sqr.<br />

164

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!