11.03.2014 Views

Participation and Democracy: Dynamics, Causes ... - Jacobs University

Participation and Democracy: Dynamics, Causes ... - Jacobs University

Participation and Democracy: Dynamics, Causes ... - Jacobs University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Participation</strong> <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>:<br />

<strong>Dynamics</strong>, <strong>Causes</strong> <strong>and</strong> Consequences of<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

by<br />

Franziska Deutsch<br />

a Thesis submitted in partial fulfillment<br />

of the requirements for the degree of<br />

Doctor of Philosophy in<br />

Political Science<br />

Approved Dissertation Committee<br />

Prof. Dr. Christian Welzel<br />

Prof. Dr. Klaus Boehnke<br />

Prof. Dr. Ferdin<strong>and</strong> Müller-Rommel<br />

Date of Defense: 29.06.2009<br />

School of Humanities <strong>and</strong> Social Sciences


Acknowledgement<br />

Writing this PhD thesis was a long process that would not have been possible without the<br />

help <strong>and</strong> support of many others:<br />

First <strong>and</strong> foremost, I’d like to thank Chris Welzel for encouraging me to pursue an<br />

academic career <strong>and</strong> a PhD under his supervision. His generous support <strong>and</strong> his curiosity<br />

<strong>and</strong> enthusiasm for research have been motivation <strong>and</strong> inspiration. Most valuably, he has<br />

introduced me to the potentials of survey research <strong>and</strong> especially to the fascinating world<br />

of the World Values Survey.<br />

I also want to thank Klaus Boehnke <strong>and</strong> Ferdin<strong>and</strong> Müller-Rommel for their support <strong>and</strong><br />

for agreeing to become members of my dissertation committee.<br />

Furthermore, I thank my colleagues Nicola Bücker, Yuliya Salauyova, Daniel Fuss <strong>and</strong><br />

Bernhard Gißibl for their encouragement <strong>and</strong> friendship <strong>and</strong> for sharing this special time<br />

in our lives. I’d like to thank Julian Wucherpfennig for his assistance <strong>and</strong> our stimulating<br />

discussions. I am also grateful to Matthijs Bogaards for his encouraging words <strong>and</strong><br />

helpful academic advice.<br />

Finally, I want to thank my family <strong>and</strong> friends: Over the past years, Jana Steinert, Claus<br />

Hilgetag, Holger Kenn, Antonia Gohr <strong>and</strong> Steffi Markert have supported, consoled,<br />

advised <strong>and</strong> encouraged me. I am grateful for their friendship.<br />

My family has been my greatest source of comfort <strong>and</strong> strength. I would like to thank my<br />

parents <strong>and</strong> brothers for their unbelievable unconditional love <strong>and</strong> support.


Declaration:<br />

I herewith declare that this thesis is my own work <strong>and</strong> that I have used only the sources<br />

listed. No part of this thesis has been accepted or is currently being submitted for any<br />

degree or other qualification at this university or elsewhere.<br />

Franziska Deutsch Bremen, 04 June 2009


CONTENTS<br />

Figures <strong>and</strong> Tables<br />

Introduction 1<br />

A<br />

Theoretical Considerations<br />

1 Elite-Challenging Activities as Political <strong>Participation</strong> 9<br />

2 Theoretical Framework: What Explains <strong>Dynamics</strong>, <strong>Causes</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Consequences of Elite-Challenging Activities? 15<br />

2.1 Modernization <strong>and</strong> Value Change 15<br />

2.2 Organizational Changes <strong>and</strong> Social Capital 21<br />

2.2.1 Organizational Changes 21<br />

2.2.2 Declining Social Capital <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities 25<br />

2.3 Resources, Motivation <strong>and</strong> the Question of Political Equality 30<br />

2.3.1 Political Equality 30<br />

2.3.2 Resources, Equality <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities 33<br />

2.3.3 Motivation, Equality <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities 35<br />

2.4 Opportunity Structures <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities 38<br />

2.5 Crisis of <strong>Democracy</strong>: Government Overload <strong>and</strong> Elite-<br />

Challenging Activities 41<br />

3 Hypotheses 44<br />

B<br />

Methods <strong>and</strong> Data<br />

4 Methodological Background, Data <strong>and</strong> Measures 50<br />

4.1 Survey Research <strong>and</strong> Alternative Ways to Measure<br />

<strong>Participation</strong> 51<br />

4.2 Country Selection 56<br />

4.3 Data Sets <strong>and</strong> Measures of Elite-Challenging Behavior 61<br />

4.4 Measurement of Elite-Challenging Political Action (dependent<br />

variable) 66


C<br />

Empirical Analyses<br />

5 “The Rise <strong>and</strong> Fall” of Elite-Challenging Political <strong>Participation</strong>?<br />

Trends <strong>and</strong> Cross-Country Differences in Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities 70<br />

5.1 Cross-Country Differences in Levels <strong>and</strong> Forms of Elite-<br />

Challenging Activities 70<br />

5.2 Trends in Elite-Challenging Activities 81<br />

6 Common Patterns of Complement or Displacement? Elite-<br />

Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Other Forms of Political Activism 89<br />

6.1 Voting 91<br />

6.2 Conventional <strong>Participation</strong> 95<br />

6.3 Civic Activism 98<br />

7 Down <strong>and</strong> Down We Go? Social Capital <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities 107<br />

7.1 The Structural Component: Voluntary Associations <strong>and</strong><br />

Informal Networks 109<br />

7.2 The Motivational or Cultural Component: Social Trust 121<br />

7.3 Networks or Trust: Which Component of Social Capital<br />

Generates Elite-Challenging Activities? 126<br />

8 Individual Characteristics or Context Factors: What Matters for<br />

Elite-Challenging <strong>Participation</strong>? 135<br />

8.1 Elite-Challenging <strong>Participation</strong> <strong>and</strong> Individual-Level<br />

Resources <strong>and</strong> Motivation: The Question of Inequality 136<br />

8.2 Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Context Factors 143<br />

8.3 The Multilevel Model: What Determines Elite Challenging<br />

Activities? 155<br />

9 Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong> 167<br />

9.1 The Societal Level: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> 167<br />

9.1.1 Measures of <strong>Democracy</strong> 168<br />

9.1.2 Measures of Elite Integrity 173<br />

9.2 The Individual Level: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Democratic Orientations 178


9.2.1 Support for <strong>Democracy</strong> 178<br />

9.2.2 Political Involvement 184<br />

9.2.3 Liberal Orientations 187<br />

Conclusion 194<br />

Bibliography 201<br />

Appendix 226


Figures <strong>and</strong> Tables<br />

Figure 2-1 Change in Party Membership (1980-2000, in %) 23<br />

Figure 4-1 Thresholds in Unconventional <strong>Participation</strong> 67<br />

Figure 5-1 <strong>Participation</strong> in Elite-Challenging Activities, by Country in %<br />

(pooled WVS/EVS 2000-02/2005-07) 71<br />

Figure 5-2<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Various Societies, in %, pooled<br />

WVS/EVS 1999-2001 <strong>and</strong> WVS 2005-07 73<br />

Figure 5-3 Elite-Challenging Activities in Various Societies, in %<br />

(WVS/EVS 1999-2002) 75<br />

Figure 5-4 Signed Petition during the past 12 Months, ESS 2004, in % 77<br />

Figure 5-5 Attended Demonstration during the past 12 Months, ESS 2004,<br />

in % 78<br />

Figure 5-6 Political Consumerism, ESS 2002, in % 80<br />

Figure 5-7<br />

Figure 5-8a<br />

Figure 5-8b<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities 1974-1999 in Six Postindustrial<br />

Democracies, in % 81<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Postindustrial Democracies:<br />

English-Speaking Societies <strong>and</strong> Japan, in %, WVS/EVS 81<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Postindustrial Democracies:<br />

Western European Societies, in %, WVS/EVS 81<br />

Figure 5-9 Elite-Challenging Activities in Ex-Communist Societies, in %,<br />

WVS/EVS 85<br />

Figure 5-10<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Ex-Communist Post-Soviet<br />

Societies, in %, WVS/EVS 86<br />

Figure 5-11 Elite-Challenging Activities in Other Societies, in %, WVS 87<br />

Figure 6-1 Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Voting (ESS 2002) 93<br />

Figure 6-2<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Conventional <strong>Participation</strong><br />

(ESS 2002) 96<br />

Figure 6-3 Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Activity in Interest 100


Organizations (WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

Figure 6-4<br />

Figure 6-5<br />

Figure 7-1<br />

Figure 7-2<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Activity in Citizen Action<br />

Groups (WVS/EVS 1999-2001) 101<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Civic Activism in Selected<br />

Postindustrial Democracies 1981-1999 (WVS/EVS) 105<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Membership in Associations<br />

(ESS 2002) 112<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Active Membership in<br />

Associations (ESS 2002) 114<br />

Figure 7-3 Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Social Activity (ESS 2002) 115<br />

Figure 7-4<br />

Figure 7-5<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Average Membership in<br />

European Societies (ESS 2002) 116<br />

Informal Networks in European Societies <strong>and</strong> Elite-<br />

Challenging Activities (ESS 2002) 119<br />

Figure 7-6 Trust Level <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities (ESS 2002) 123<br />

Figure 8-1<br />

Figure 8-2<br />

Figure 8-3<br />

Figure 8-4<br />

Figure 8-5<br />

Figure 8-6<br />

Figure 9-1<br />

Figure 9-2<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> Voice &<br />

Accountability 145<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> Stock 147<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> National<br />

Affluence 148<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> Inequality<br />

in a Society 149<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong><br />

Tertiarization 151<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Happiness Level in a Society 152<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Institutional <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

(POLITY I-IV, 2001-2004) 169<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>: Freedom House<br />

(2000-2006) 171


Figure 9-3<br />

Figure 9-4<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Perception of Corruption<br />

(Transparency International, 2001-2006) 173<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Control of Corruption (World<br />

Bank, 2002-2006) 175<br />

Table 3-1 Summary of Hypotheses 48<br />

Table 4-1<br />

Democratic Societies Included in the Survey Projects: Political<br />

Action Study (PA), World Values Survey/European Values<br />

Survey (WVS/EVS) <strong>and</strong> European Social Survey (ESS) 59<br />

Table 4-2 Factor Analysis for Elite-Challenging Activities 68<br />

Table 5-1 Elite-Challenging Activities, in %, ESS 2002, 2004 76<br />

Table 6-1<br />

Table 6-2<br />

Table 6-3<br />

Individual-Level Correlations between Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities <strong>and</strong> Voting (ESS 2002) 94<br />

Individual-Level Correlations between Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities <strong>and</strong> Conventional <strong>Participation</strong> (ESS 2002) 97<br />

Individual-Level Correlation between Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> Civic Activism (WVS/EVS 1999-2001) 103<br />

Table 7-1 Factor Analyses for Measures of Informal Networks (ESS 2002) 118<br />

Table 7-2<br />

Table 7-3<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Measures of Social Capital’s<br />

Structural Components <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities (ESS<br />

2002) 121<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Social Trust <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities (ESS 2002) 125<br />

Table 7-4 Individual-Level, Binary Logistic Regression (ESS 2002) 127<br />

Table 7-5<br />

Table 8-1<br />

Multi-Level (Hierarchical Generalized Linear) Model of Social<br />

Capital <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities (ESS 2002) 133<br />

Binary-Logistic Regression: Resources <strong>and</strong> <strong>Participation</strong> (Political<br />

Action Study 1974 <strong>and</strong> ESS 2004) 138


Table 8-2<br />

Table 8-3a<br />

Table 8-3b<br />

Binary-Logistic Regression: Resources, Motivation <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Participation</strong> (Political Action Study 1974 <strong>and</strong> ESS 2004) 141<br />

T-Test for Electoral System <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

(WVS 2000-2005) 154<br />

T-Test for System of Governance <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

(WVS 2000-2005) 154<br />

Table 8-4 Correlation Effects Among Level-2 Variables 157<br />

Table 8-5<br />

Table 9-1<br />

Table 9-2<br />

Table 9-3<br />

Table 9-4<br />

Table 9-5<br />

Multi-Level Model (HGLM): Individual-Level <strong>and</strong> Contextual<br />

Determinants of Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) 163<br />

Zero-Order <strong>and</strong> Partial Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong> 177<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Support for <strong>Democracy</strong> (WVS/EVS 1999-2001) 179<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Underst<strong>and</strong>ing of <strong>Democracy</strong> (WVS/EVS 2005-07) 183<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Political Involvement (WVS/EVS 1999-2001) 186<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Liberal Orientation (WVS/EVS 1999-2001) 189<br />

Table 9-6 Binary-Logistic Regression Analysis (WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

(dependent variable: Elite-Challenging Activities) 192<br />

Table C1 Results of Hypotheses Testing 196


Introduction<br />

“The effective isolation of protest to the materialist grievances of the poorer <strong>and</strong><br />

less-educated will restore unconventional politics pretty much to the position it<br />

occupied before the rise of the 1960s protest movements: largely confined to<br />

groups whose loyalty to the system is most questionable, to marginal groups,<br />

<strong>and</strong> to situationally generated protests whose rationales may be relatively<br />

difficult to identify <strong>and</strong> which are therefore always susceptible to being labeled<br />

‘irrational’. From that point it is but a short step to the progressive<br />

delegitimation of protest” (Rootes 1981: 428).<br />

When Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al. (1979) published their l<strong>and</strong>mark empirical study on the<br />

expansion of the participation repertoire in Western democracies 30 years ago, the<br />

authors faced harsh criticism by fellow scholars. The critique was mostly directed at one<br />

essential result of the comparative study: the future role of unconventional participation.<br />

In sharp contrast to the above statement, Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al. (1979) predicted a<br />

permanent change in Western societies, considering the rise in protest activism not to be<br />

a short-term, anecdotal event: “We interpret this increase in potential for protest to be a<br />

lasting characteristic of democratic mass publics <strong>and</strong> not just a sudden surge in political<br />

involvement bound to fade away as time goes by” (Kaase <strong>and</strong> Barnes 1979: 524).<br />

Ever since that study, a number of important books <strong>and</strong> essays have documented the<br />

spread <strong>and</strong> acceptance of protest activism or elite-challenging activities around the globe<br />

(Jennings <strong>and</strong> van Deth et al. 1990; Inglehart 1990; Parry, Moyser <strong>and</strong> Day 1992; Verba,<br />

Schlozman <strong>and</strong> Brady 1995; Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels 1996; Van Aelst <strong>and</strong> Walgrave 2001;<br />

Dalton 2002; Norris 2002; Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Catterberg 2003; Dalton <strong>and</strong> van Sickle 2004;<br />

Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005; Norris, Walgrave <strong>and</strong> Van Aelst 2005).<br />

Along similar lines, the social movement literature has described elite-challenging<br />

activities as contentious forms of collective action (Mc Adam 1988; Jenkins <strong>and</strong><br />

Kl<strong>and</strong>ermans 1995; Kriesi et al. 1995; Tarrow 1998; Rucht, Koopmans <strong>and</strong> Neidhardt<br />

1998; Giugni, McAdam <strong>and</strong> Tilly 1999; della Porta, Kriesi <strong>and</strong> Rucht 1999; Rucht 2001;<br />

McAdam, Tarrow <strong>and</strong> Tilly 2001; Diani <strong>and</strong> McAdam 2003; Davis et al. 2005).<br />

1


Whereas the early, more qualitatively oriented research in the tradition of Charles Tilly<br />

usually focused on single movements or nations, the more recent quantitative studies on<br />

these movements are of comparative nature, although limited in their scope due to the<br />

availability of protest event data. What these studies have in common is their focus on<br />

the movement or the contentious action itself, not on the resources or motivation of the<br />

participants or the large-scale democratic consequences of an exp<strong>and</strong>ed citizen action<br />

repertoire.<br />

Today participation in demonstrations <strong>and</strong> signing petitions are far from being a tool for<br />

marginal or democracy-endangering groups of societies. At the same time, we do not<br />

only observe rising numbers of participants but also an increase in the legitimacy that<br />

people attribute to these activities (Topf 1995; Van Aelst <strong>and</strong> Walgrave 2001).<br />

According to Fuchs (1990) we have faced a “normalization of the unconventional” (see<br />

also Della Porta 1999), although it should be noted that the term “unconventional<br />

participation” has been subject to debate since the very time it was introduced by the<br />

Political Action scholars. 1 Originally, the term “unconventional” referred to that<br />

political behavior in a regime that did not match its norms of law <strong>and</strong> custom with<br />

respect to political participation (Kaase <strong>and</strong> Marsh 1979: 41). Reflecting this academic<br />

dispute, the Political Action group has admitted that the term “unconventional” was<br />

already misleading by the time when it was introduced: “Only after getting into our data<br />

did we - <strong>and</strong> most other scholars - begin to realize that most, though not all, of the<br />

protest activities that we had targeted were in fact by that time viewed as quite<br />

conventional by large numbers of people <strong>and</strong> sometimes by strong majorities of the<br />

population. What is considered normal, conventional, even acceptable forms of political<br />

behavior is thus variable” (Barnes 2004: 4; emphasis as in the original).<br />

As these activities have become more widespread <strong>and</strong> accepted as a normal, even<br />

‘conventional’ political tool by the wider publics, the term ‘unconventional’ does no<br />

longer capture the nature of these activities. Inglehart has suggested referring to these<br />

1 Since then, the appropriateness of terminology has been debated, including counter-proposals for new<br />

typologies in participation research (Uehlinger 1988).<br />

2


forms of participation as elite-challenging activities (Inglehart 1990, 1997; Inglehart <strong>and</strong><br />

Catterberg 2003; Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005). These activities take place outside<br />

institutionalized channels of political participation (like voting or joining a political<br />

party) <strong>and</strong> are therefore distinct from elite-directed forms of mass activities (Inglehart<br />

<strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005: 118). Elite-challenging activities are a spontaneous, short-term <strong>and</strong><br />

issue-oriented rather than long-term <strong>and</strong> permanent form of engagement. They range<br />

from participation in demonstrations such as the Belgian white march 2 in 1996 or antiwar<br />

protests around the globe in 2003, to petitioning against child labor, or to<br />

deliberately buying CFC-free products, cosmetics that were not tested on animals, or<br />

fair-trade products. As these activities confront political <strong>and</strong> other elites with dem<strong>and</strong>s<br />

<strong>and</strong> pressure from below, “[c]itizen participation is becoming more closely linked to<br />

citizen influence” (Dalton 2000b: 929). It should be noted that the term “elite” is not<br />

referring to a group in a society that st<strong>and</strong>s out by characteristics such as social class or<br />

education but refers to people in leadership positions who regularly take part in<br />

(political) decision-making (Hoffmann-Lange 2007: 910). In this sense, it follows a<br />

broad underst<strong>and</strong>ing of the term as elites are not necessarily limited to political elites.<br />

What are the implications of the exp<strong>and</strong>ed action repertoire? Addressing this question,<br />

the thesis aims at contributing to the debate about declining civic activism (Putnam<br />

(1993, 1995a, 2000, 2002). The research question guiding this thesis is: What are the<br />

dynamics, causes (determinants) <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging activities? This<br />

question will be answered using a broad empirical database which combines information<br />

from different large-scale comparative survey projects over a period of more than 30<br />

years. The dynamic dimension refers to the expansion of the political action repertoire<br />

<strong>and</strong> is the starting point of the empirical analyses: How has participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities changed over the past decades? The descriptive part provides a<br />

first test for the robustness of the findings in other studies: Is the increase in noninstitutionalized<br />

forms occurring in all societies, or is this development restricted to<br />

2 The Belgian white march took place in the aftermath of a large case of child abuse <strong>and</strong> murder. Around<br />

300.000 people gathered in October 1996 in Brussels to demonstrate their solidarity with the victims <strong>and</strong><br />

their families <strong>and</strong> to display their anger about deficiencies in the police investigation <strong>and</strong> the judiciary<br />

system (Lippens 1998).<br />

3


Western postindustrial democracies? In addition to cross-country differences, a second<br />

emphasis is given to the relation between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong><br />

institutionalized forms of participation, discussing whether one goes at the expense of<br />

the other. The cause dimension examines determinants for elite-challenging activities: at<br />

the individual level as resources <strong>and</strong> motivation, <strong>and</strong> at the societal level as context<br />

factors. Political mobilization does not happen in a vacuum but is always the result of an<br />

interplay between personal characteristics <strong>and</strong> environmental factors. The two-level data<br />

structure also allows testing how the determinants on both levels are related to each<br />

other: Is participation in elite-challenging activities more driven by individual<br />

characteristics or rather by contextual factors? The consequence dimension looks at<br />

implications of elite-challenging activities, treating it no longer as a dependent but as an<br />

independent variable. Many consequences of elite-challenging activities have been<br />

claimed, most of them in an implicit way, a few explicitly. The core question here is<br />

whether elite-challenging forms of participation are overburdening the democratic<br />

system with dem<strong>and</strong>s from below, or rather call for responsive, accountable elite<br />

behavior.<br />

Contribution of the study<br />

The thesis contributes to the study of political participation in general <strong>and</strong> of noninstitutionalized<br />

participation in particular in several ways:<br />

First, it is a comparative study with a large N, going beyond classical studies that remain<br />

focused on single-nations <strong>and</strong> are dominating research on political participation (Norris<br />

2007: 643). It covers more than 90 societies on six continents that vary significantly in<br />

their political, social <strong>and</strong> economic developments. Even if studies are comparative in<br />

nature, they often only briefly touch on non-institutionalized forms of participation,<br />

examining it as one variant among many types. While those studies provide a<br />

comprehensive picture of citizen participation, they often leave little room for<br />

systematic in-depth analyses targeted at elite-challenging activities. To be sure, there is a<br />

growing literature on single forms of non-institutionalized participation, e.g. on political<br />

consumerism. These studies, however, often fall short of putting these activities in the<br />

broader research context of citizen participation <strong>and</strong> democracy. By contrast, this study<br />

4


attempts to link the different approaches by providing a systematic examination of<br />

dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging activities.<br />

Second, the study looks both at determinants <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging<br />

activities. Shifting the perspective from elite-challenging activities as a dependent<br />

variable (cause dimension) to a perspective where it is treated as an independent variable<br />

(consequence dimension) allows examining the implications of these actions. This is<br />

particularly vital as several determinants-related theories actually imply consequences of<br />

elite-challenging activities that are seldom tested empirically. The focus is here on the<br />

impact of these non-institutionalized activities for democracy <strong>and</strong> for social inequality.<br />

Third, when looking at determinants <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging activities,<br />

the study combines individual level <strong>and</strong> aggregate level factors. It therefore remedies<br />

one of the well-known shortcomings of participation studies: Despite the growing action<br />

repertoire “the analysis of contextual effects remained underdeveloped” (Norris 2007:<br />

630). Moreover, the study allows for a simultaneous testing of the individual <strong>and</strong><br />

societal influences, providing more knowledge to the question whether participation in<br />

elite-challenging activities is more driven by the participant’s personal characteristics or<br />

by his/her environment.<br />

The evaluation of elite-challenging activities as a bliss or bless for the flourishing of<br />

democracy is still a contested field. Normative evaluations differ so strongly not only<br />

because the interpretations are driven by contradictory normative concepts of democracy<br />

(such as elitist versus participative). They also differ because the empirical evidence is<br />

still patchy <strong>and</strong> too fragmentary in terms of longitudinal <strong>and</strong> geographical scope <strong>and</strong><br />

levels of analyses. This is where this thesis aims to contribute to existing research:<br />

providing an encompassing overview of the determinants, dynamics, <strong>and</strong> consequences<br />

of elite-challenging in both old <strong>and</strong> new democracies, so as to come to a<br />

substantiated re-evaluation of the contradictory normative assessments of elitechallenging<br />

activities on the basis of the broadest empirical evidence possible.<br />

Structure of the thesis<br />

The structure of the thesis follows the classical composition to answer the research<br />

question outlined above. The theory part (Section A) will provide the theoretical<br />

5


framework of the study with the objective to derive testable hypotheses. The methods<br />

part (Section B) will outline the methodological principles <strong>and</strong> present the data basis for<br />

the empirical analyses. The main part of the thesis is dedicated to the empirical analyses<br />

<strong>and</strong> their discussion (Section C).<br />

In more detail, I will proceed in the following way:<br />

Section A outlines the theoretical framework of the thesis. It has three objectives: to<br />

locate elite-challenging activities in the study of political participation research; to<br />

present theoretical approaches that can explain dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of<br />

elite-challenging activities; <strong>and</strong> to develop testable hypotheses. Chapter 1 examines how<br />

elite-challenging activities can be anchored conceptually in the context of political<br />

participation research. Chapter 2 examines five theoretical approaches to political<br />

participation with the goal to extract those relevant factors that can help to explain the<br />

dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging activities: In a first step, the<br />

concept of modernization is introduced, linking socio-economic development with<br />

emancipative value change <strong>and</strong> an exp<strong>and</strong>ing participation repertoire for citizens. After<br />

that, organizational changes are in the focus <strong>and</strong> put into the broader context of social<br />

capital <strong>and</strong> participation. Special attention is given to the relationship between<br />

traditional forms of political <strong>and</strong> social participation on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> elitechallenging<br />

activities on the other h<strong>and</strong>. In a third step, two different sets of individuallevel<br />

determinants are being looked at: resources <strong>and</strong> motivation. This part highlights<br />

the importance of political equality for the study of political participation. Elitechallenging<br />

activities are often considered to be more dem<strong>and</strong>ing in terms of required<br />

resources <strong>and</strong> motivation, thus contributing to a widening gap between those who can<br />

exercise political influence <strong>and</strong> those who cannot. Beyond individual-level resources<br />

<strong>and</strong> motivation, fourthly, context factors are presented, shedding light on the opportunity<br />

structures <strong>and</strong> societal resources for people to become active as well. Finally, the elitist<br />

<strong>and</strong> the participatory approach to democracy are contrasted, as the interpretation of the<br />

empirical findings – in particular with regard to the expansion of the political action<br />

repertoire – yield different results. Based on these theoretical approaches, Chapter 3<br />

summarizes the testable hypotheses.<br />

6


Section B then outlines the methodological basis of the study <strong>and</strong> introduces the data<br />

sets <strong>and</strong> measures (Chapter 4). The study applies a comparative perspective <strong>and</strong> uses<br />

survey data from longitudinal representative large-scale survey projects to measure<br />

participation in elite-challenging activities: the Political Action Study (1974), the World<br />

Values Surveys/European Values Surveys (1981-2005), <strong>and</strong> the European Social Survey<br />

(2002-2004). It includes more than 90 societies on six continents, thereby covering not<br />

only the majority of the world population, but also a great variety of economic, social<br />

<strong>and</strong> political environments. There is a limitation to this most different cases design: In<br />

order to assure that political participation – in particular in elite-challenging activities –<br />

is meaningful, case selection (beyond data availability) is guided by an external<br />

assessment of a country’s compliance with political rights <strong>and</strong> civil liberties. Finally, the<br />

measurement of the dependent variable (participation in elite-challenging activities) is<br />

introduced.<br />

Section C presents the empirical analyses – the testing of the hypotheses developed at<br />

the end of the theory section <strong>and</strong> the discussion of the results. The empirical part is<br />

organized as follows: Chapter 5 (“The ‘rise <strong>and</strong> fall’ of elite-challenging participation?”)<br />

provides a first descriptive data overview for succeeding empirical analyses. Covering<br />

more than 70 societies over a period of more than 25 years, it looks at trends <strong>and</strong> crosscountry<br />

differences in levels <strong>and</strong> forms of elite-challenging activities. A first overview<br />

suggests major differences in elite-challenging activities, with participation levels from<br />

as low as 10 percent in Jordan to up to more than 80 percent in Sweden. On average, at<br />

least twice as many people in high-income societies use petitions, demonstrations <strong>and</strong><br />

boycotts than in other societies. An inspection of the ESS data also shows a significant<br />

discrepancy between Western <strong>and</strong> Eastern Europe, the latter facing a “post-honeymoon”<br />

decline of civic action (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Catterberg 2003).<br />

Chapter 6 (“Common patterns of complement or displacement?”) looks at the<br />

relationship between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> other forms of political<br />

participation such as voting, conventional participation, or participation in interest<br />

organizations <strong>and</strong> citizen action groups. It addresses the question whether elitechallenging<br />

activities are going at the expense of more traditional forms of participation,<br />

7


or whether civic activism in general is even in decline, as some scholars suggest<br />

(Putnam <strong>and</strong> Goss 2002). The empirical results do not support any of the two<br />

propositions. Chapter 7 extends the analysis to the social capital debate, providing<br />

evidence that participation in elite-challenging activities can be understood as an<br />

outcome of prevailing social capital at the societal level <strong>and</strong> as an individual resource.<br />

Taking up the discussion about the role of resources as determinants of elite-challenging<br />

activities, Chapter 8 (“What matters for elite-challenging participation?”) asks which<br />

determinants have a greater impact on participation in elite-challenging activities:<br />

individual characteristics or context factors? The final empirical chapter (Chapter 9)<br />

considers participation in elite-challenging activities no longer as a dependent but as an<br />

independent variable. It examines the linkage between these forms of participation <strong>and</strong><br />

democracy on two levels: pro-democratic orientations at the individual level, <strong>and</strong> quality<br />

of democracy <strong>and</strong> elite compliance at the aggregate level.<br />

Finally, the conclusion summarizes the findings <strong>and</strong> discusses implications of the results<br />

for future research of citizen participation in today’s representative democracies.<br />

8


A<br />

THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS<br />

The theoretical framework has three aims. First, the question should be answered how<br />

elite-challenging activities can be anchored in the context of political participation<br />

research. A summarizing overview about the participation concept will be given,<br />

followed by a discussion about the challenges that these new action forms pose to the<br />

traditional concept. In a second step, theories on political participation are examined<br />

with the goal to extract those relevant factors that can help to explain the dynamics,<br />

causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging activities. Finally, testable hypotheses are<br />

derived from the theoretical approaches <strong>and</strong> summarized in a concluding chapter.<br />

1. Elite-Challenging Activities as Political <strong>Participation</strong><br />

Definitions of political participation that can be found in the literature are numerous, <strong>and</strong><br />

philosophers <strong>and</strong> social scientists have early pointed to the importance of participation<br />

for democracy. Aristotle, for example, argued that man is by nature a political animal<br />

(Kraut 2002: 95) <strong>and</strong> that participation together with others in shared activities is closely<br />

linked with having a good <strong>and</strong> happy life. Pericles stressed that a citizen without an<br />

interest in public affairs is a useless character (quoted in Popper 2002: 199). Although<br />

scholars ever since have argued about how much participation of what kind is needed<br />

<strong>and</strong> desirable in a democracy, there is little disagreement that political participation – in<br />

particular the right to vote in free <strong>and</strong> fair elections – is included in most definitions <strong>and</strong><br />

measurements of democracy, most prominently coined in Dahl’s constituting elements<br />

of polyarchy: competition <strong>and</strong> participation (Dahl 1971). In a nutshell, “any book about<br />

political participation is also a book about democracy” (Parry, Moyser <strong>and</strong> Day 1992:<br />

3), with democratic legitimacy being the link between the two.<br />

Broadly speaking, political participation is defined as “the opportunity for large numbers<br />

of citizens to engage in politics” (Abramson 1995: 913), referring to “those action of<br />

private citizens by which they seek to influence or to support government <strong>and</strong> politics”<br />

(Milbrath <strong>and</strong> Goel 1977: 2). More concretely, it encompasses “those legal activities by<br />

9


private citizens that are more less directly aimed at influencing the selection of<br />

governmental personnel <strong>and</strong>/or the actions they take” (Verba, Nie <strong>and</strong> Kim 1978: 46).<br />

Brady (1999: 737) summarizes four defining aspects of political participation: its<br />

reference to ordinary citizens as actors; the action component; the political nature of<br />

activity; <strong>and</strong> the instrumental aspect of attempting to influence politics.<br />

In addition, a fifth aspects should be highlighted – the voluntary element of<br />

participation. The authors of the Political Action Study explicitly refer to political<br />

participation as “all voluntary activities by individual citizens intended to influence<br />

either directly or indirectly political choices at various levels of the political system”<br />

(Kaase <strong>and</strong> Marsh 1979: 42).<br />

With the expansion of the political action repertoire to non-institutionalized forms of<br />

citizen activism the question arises whether this narrow definition of political<br />

participation is still adequate – in particular, as these activities share characteristics<br />

uncommon to forms of traditional participation:<br />

New targets<br />

The definition of political participation provided by Verba, Nie <strong>and</strong> Kim (1978) focuses<br />

on the specific target of participation: the governmental personnel. Traditionally,<br />

participation studies have focused on institutionalized channels of participation linked to<br />

the electoral process, national or local government <strong>and</strong> parties (Norris 2007: 638).<br />

Today, the addressee of citizens activities are often found outside political institutions,<br />

such as non-governmental organization or multinational corporations. For example,<br />

ordinary citizens articulate their concerns through various forms of political<br />

consumerism where the market is used as a political arena – with the goal to change<br />

market practices (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Micheletti 2005). This can either be done in its positive<br />

form by buying fair trade products in a supermarket, in its negative form by boycotting<br />

clothing produced in sweatshops, or by engaging in discourses about market practices.<br />

These new targets of the exp<strong>and</strong>ed action repertoire also show the declining importance<br />

of the nation state. Often, governmental elites at the national level are bypassed by<br />

citizens’ activities, <strong>and</strong> multinational corporations or international political organizations<br />

are targeted directly (Norris 2002: 193). Reasons can be manifold, either because<br />

10


citizens think that national governments <strong>and</strong> legislatures are not able (or willing) to<br />

change the legislative framework accordingly, or because they consider a direct<br />

targeting to be the most effective approach. Importantly, citizens “aim at targets<br />

regardless of whether they represent public or private institutions, the importance is that<br />

they have de facto political power” (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Hooghe 2005: 5). This is also the reason<br />

why these elite-challenging activities are not necessarily “state-challenging” or<br />

“institution-challenging”, as the targets are no longer to be found only among state<br />

actors or institutions. Any study on political participation that fails to include these new<br />

targets, will leave major new forms of mass activities unconsidered.<br />

New issues: Political or non-political participation?<br />

The past decades have not only brought new targets but also new topics on the agenda,<br />

blurring the distinction between political <strong>and</strong> nonpolitical activities as well as between<br />

political <strong>and</strong> social forms of participation. These new issues are closely linked to the<br />

expansion of the action repertoire for citizens. In particular younger generations have<br />

been found to engage in sporadic <strong>and</strong> issue-oriented forms outside hierarchical networks<br />

– rather than long-term commitment in a centralized mass organization that deal with<br />

governmental affairs.<br />

Among others, these new issues have been labeled lifestyle politics (Bennett 1998). Its<br />

main characteristic is a connection between activity <strong>and</strong> self-identity: “With each<br />

lifestyle there is a corresponding life story, in the sense that by creating this specific<br />

unity of practices the actor expresses who he or she wants to be” (Spaargaren <strong>and</strong> van<br />

Vliet 2000: 55). In fact, issues that have been characterized as lifestyle topics – such as<br />

environmental protection or health <strong>and</strong> child care issues – are not new per se. “However,<br />

the intensely personal way in which they are framed is more recent” (Bennett 1998:<br />

759), such as the discussion about abortion rights in the context of freedom of personal<br />

choice. Along similar lines, the emergence of identity politics, in particular since the rise<br />

of the New Social Movements in the 1980ies, has blurred the distinction between what<br />

is political <strong>and</strong> what is private even further, exemplified in Carol Hanisch’s famous<br />

phrase “the personal is the political” (1969). Postmaterialist or emancipative values such<br />

as gender equality or ethnicity are always related to personal identities, but the fact that<br />

11


they are not related to traditional areas of state activity (such as providing existential<br />

security) does not make them less political in their scope. “Because personal identity is<br />

replacing collective identity as the basis for contemporary political engagement, the<br />

character of politics itself is changing” (Bennett 1998: 755). Thus, an exclusive focus on<br />

traditional forms might underestimate how marginalized groups in a society – such as<br />

women, in particular housewives – are a politically active part of society (Stolle <strong>and</strong><br />

Micheletti 2005: 3).<br />

In addition to the emergence of identity politics, there is another reason why the<br />

traditional distinction between political <strong>and</strong> nonpolitical activities does no longer hold.<br />

The long period of economic growth <strong>and</strong> stability <strong>and</strong> the expansion of the welfare state<br />

over the past decades have led to growing state interventions <strong>and</strong> a politicization of<br />

other spheres: “The result is that democratic government in advanced industrial societies<br />

increasingly occupies a substantial part of the national product <strong>and</strong> is a party to such<br />

divergent aspects of social life as housing, education, transportation, social security,<br />

foreign trade, <strong>and</strong> health care” (van Deth 2001: 9). Due to the growth of the public<br />

sector over the past decades, more people than ever are affected by decisions about<br />

government spending, <strong>and</strong> politics is difficult to avoid. As a consequence, the dividing<br />

line between the political <strong>and</strong> the social sphere dissolves; the same applies to the<br />

distinction between what is public <strong>and</strong> what is private.<br />

New network structures <strong>and</strong> mobilization tactics<br />

Participants of elite-challenging activities are mainly organized in horizontal, less<br />

permanent <strong>and</strong> more flexible networks. Also the forms of mobilization follow a different<br />

logic than in permanent organizations such as political parties or interest groups. As<br />

elite-challenging actions are often less planned ahead, mobilization processes can be<br />

rather spontaneous <strong>and</strong> irregular. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, forms of political consumerism are<br />

often implemented into people’s daily consumption activities (Shah et al. 2007), “hoping<br />

that my choice, in concert with others, might influence public policy” (Sapiro 2000: 11).<br />

Accordingly, new channels of mobilization provide the means to get people involved:<br />

Electronic forms of communication such as internet websites or electronic newsletters<br />

are used to coordinate action; in Spain, one day after the bomb attack in Madrid in 2004,<br />

12


citizens used SMS to keep informed <strong>and</strong> mobilize each other into what later became the<br />

largest mass demonstration in Spanish history. Online or email campaigns themselves<br />

have developed into new forms of action. Clearly, these activities <strong>and</strong> the way they are<br />

coordinated do not follow the logic of regular face-to-face meetings known from<br />

voluntary organizations. As a consequence, there exists an easy exit option for<br />

participants (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Hooghe 2005: 5), which contributes to the ad-hoc <strong>and</strong> sporadic<br />

character of these activities.<br />

New forms of action: Individual acts <strong>and</strong> collective outcomes<br />

It is obvious that any form of political participation, including elite-challenging actions,<br />

needs many to achieve an effect (Sapiro 2000:11). These new activities are collective in<br />

their effects as well. The difference, however, is that the participation act itself is a more<br />

individualized form of political action. Examples are forwarding emails, buy-cotting a<br />

certain product in the supermarket or signing a petition. It is clear, however, that all<br />

these activities, though individual in nature, still need an opportunity structure <strong>and</strong> the<br />

coordination of the activities in order to be successful. “This leads to a paradox: while<br />

these forms of protest <strong>and</strong> participation can often be seen as examples of coordinated<br />

collective action, most participants simply performs such acts alone, at home before a<br />

computer screen or in a supermarket” (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Hooghe 2005: 6).<br />

In the past decades we could observe a change in the political action repertoire. The<br />

expansion towards elite-challenging activities such as demonstrations, petitions or<br />

political consumerism has posed the question whether <strong>and</strong> how these activities fit into<br />

the definition of political participation. Some have even claimed that we are running into<br />

the danger of a “broad theory of everything” when exp<strong>and</strong>ing the concept of political<br />

participation to all these new action forms (van Deth 2001). However, a conception of<br />

political participation that focuses too narrowly on traditional forms, targets <strong>and</strong> issues<br />

falls into the trap of falling behind reality <strong>and</strong> ignoring innovations, thus<br />

underestimating the interest <strong>and</strong> willingness of citizens around the world to be<br />

politically engaged. It also has important consequences for the way possible<br />

implications of elite-challenging activities are interpreted.<br />

13


In fact, the “Political Action Study” was the first systematic empirical study that<br />

challenged the – up to this point dominant – view among scholars <strong>and</strong> politicians that<br />

protest activism happened to be a threat to the democratic political order, even<br />

contributing to a “crisis of democracy” (Huntington 1968, 1974a, b; Croizier,<br />

Huntington <strong>and</strong> Watanuki 1975). Later on I will elaborate in more detail on the debated<br />

consequences of the “participatory revolution” (Kaase 1984) that has taken place in<br />

postindustrial democracies.<br />

To be sure, people gathering to voice their opinion, infuriated workers on strike, or any<br />

other form of disobedience, even collective violence, is surely not exclusively a<br />

characteristic of our time (Gurr 1970; Tilly, Tilly <strong>and</strong> Tilly 1975; Graham <strong>and</strong> Gurr<br />

1979; Dalton 2002: 58-60). However, violent forms of protest activism have been <strong>and</strong><br />

still are a marginal phenomenon in all postindustrial societies. Whereas also the<br />

acceptance to use violent means to support a political opinion is still very low,<br />

acceptance <strong>and</strong> exercise of non-violent elite-challenging activities have gained<br />

widespread popular support. The political action repertoire has exp<strong>and</strong>ed during the past<br />

decades as societies have undergone tremendous political, economic <strong>and</strong> social changes,<br />

summarized in the account of modernization theory. The following chapter will present<br />

different theoretical approaches to explain the dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of<br />

elite-challenging activities.<br />

14


2. Theoretical Framework: What Explains <strong>Dynamics</strong>, <strong>Causes</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Consequences of Elite-Challenging Activities?<br />

2.1 Modernization <strong>and</strong> Value Change<br />

Mostly linked with processes of democratization as their general outcome, theories of<br />

modernization also provide one of the predominant explanations for long-term<br />

developments in political participation (Norris 2002: 19). The cultural variant of<br />

modernization theory links socio-economic development to value change – in particular<br />

change in authority relations – to an expansion of the participation repertoire, allowing<br />

for propositions on all three dimensions of analysis: the dynamics, determinants <strong>and</strong><br />

consequences of elite-challenging activities.<br />

Despite its broad variety of meanings (Schmidt 2001: 9961-9963), the term<br />

“modernization” usually refers to a transformation process from a traditional, rural,<br />

agrarian society to a secular, urban <strong>and</strong> industrial society (Inglehart 2001: 9965-9971).<br />

This process is accompanied by profound economic, cultural <strong>and</strong> political changes that<br />

result in a deep societal reorganization which, in turn, affects the conditions for mass<br />

participation. Most importantly, modernization theory claims that the economic <strong>and</strong><br />

social circumstances leave an imprint on the people exposed to them, affecting people’s<br />

opportunities, their resources <strong>and</strong> what people think about <strong>and</strong> want out of life.<br />

“Socioeconomic development brings roughly predictable cultural changes” (Inglehart<br />

<strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005: 15) because with changing external conditions, experiences <strong>and</strong><br />

opportunities, people’s values tend to change into a similar direction. Obviously,<br />

adherents of this approach attribute a certain outcome to the modernization process –<br />

although scholars have argued extensively about the deterministic or probabilistic<br />

character of this relationship.<br />

In general, modernization is considered to be “one of the two giant leaps forward that<br />

have transformed the human condition” (Inglehart 2001: 9966). The agrarian revolution<br />

that marked the transition from hunting <strong>and</strong> gathering societies to agrarian societies is<br />

deemed as the first fundamental cut in societal development. One could debate which of<br />

these two crucial developments has been more fundamental in its scope of changing<br />

existing societies. Interestingly, they have been equally successful if one considers<br />

15


productivity <strong>and</strong> the possibility to provide people with food - in the course of both<br />

revolutions those capacities have been raised by a hundredfold. But considering the time<br />

span available for the changes to take place, a tremendous difference becomes apparent:<br />

“[W]hile it took thous<strong>and</strong>s of years for the discovery of agriculture to transform the<br />

world, the industrial revolution spread throughout the world in only two centuries”<br />

(Inglehart 2001: 9966).<br />

Since the 1950ies, numerous debates about economic, social <strong>and</strong> political consequences<br />

of modernization were stimulated in the social science community, even though<br />

modernization theory was also then not a new phenomenon. Nevertheless, it did not<br />

enjoy a broad scope of academic interest before the 1950ies <strong>and</strong> 60ies 3 , about 90 years<br />

after Karl Marx had published his influential pieces of work, anticipating the societal<br />

effects of economic growth (Marx 1990 [1867]; 1993 [1858]). Based on this work,<br />

subsequent scholars have argued that modernization theory rests upon the assumption<br />

that societal changes follow – to a certain degree – predictable pathways, meaning that<br />

particular developments are inevitable for such a society, simply because they are<br />

inherent to the process of modernization. Among those ‘side effects’, secularization,<br />

bureaucratization <strong>and</strong> individualization play a significant role but the economic process<br />

of industrialization is at the core of modernization (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Baker 2000: 20;<br />

Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005).<br />

Lipset (1959, 1981 [1960], 1992, 1994; see also Lipset, Seong <strong>and</strong> Torres 1993) is one<br />

of the most prominent proponents of this approach. Analyzing pathways to modernity in<br />

Britain, the US <strong>and</strong> Western Europe during the 19 th century, he could show that modern<br />

societies developed at the same time when these societies transformed into capitalist<br />

ones. Lipset was not the only one noting a relationship between market economy <strong>and</strong><br />

democracy (see, for example, Schumpeter 1950; Moore 1966; Diamond 1992; Diamond,<br />

Linz <strong>and</strong> Lipset 1988) but his résumé of what he considered to be a causal relationship<br />

3 With the emerging broad interest in modernization, Rustow noted a trend of changing paradigms from an<br />

institutional-legal to a behavioral-cultural approach within the discipline. This trend is also reflected in a<br />

wider acknowledgement of sociological, anthropological as well as psychological concepts among<br />

political scientists (Rustow 1968: 37-38).<br />

16


has impacted generations of academic scholars: “The more well-to-do a nation, the<br />

greater the chances that it will sustain democracies” (Lipset 1960: 48). 4<br />

Considering the eminent consequences of modernization, Lipset also acknowledged<br />

Marx’ prediction with regard to the relationship between capitalism <strong>and</strong> societal<br />

changes. His failures, among others his prediction about a proletarian revolution, are<br />

well known, but Marx (1990 [1867]; 1993 [1858]) succeeded in identifying very early<br />

the specific political <strong>and</strong> social consequences of a society’s development towards<br />

capitalism. And even though workers did not become the ruling class, they have been<br />

the ones strongly <strong>and</strong> successfully pushing for exp<strong>and</strong>ing universal suffrage <strong>and</strong> the<br />

rights of political parties (Rueschemeyer, Stephens <strong>and</strong> Stephens 1992). This line of<br />

argument also follows assumptions according to which modernization brings along<br />

social mobilization <strong>and</strong>, in the end, mass participation (Deutsch 1961).<br />

In contrast to the designated role that Marx earmarked for the working class, Lipset<br />

attributed a special role in pushing for democratization to the middle class of a society.<br />

For Lipset, democracy was a direct outcome of capitalism. Looking at the history of<br />

today’s representative democracies, his argument finds support in the fact that<br />

democratic societies have almost exclusively occurred in modern capitalist societies. In<br />

the past, this supposition (<strong>and</strong> the linear interpretation of the relationship between<br />

socioeconomic factors <strong>and</strong> democracy) has (mis)led some scholars to present<br />

“guidelines for democratizers” (Huntington 1991) – practical advice <strong>and</strong> instructions on<br />

how to create democracy. Duly applied, so the impression, it works like a recipe for a<br />

good lunch menu.<br />

During the last years, non-linear approaches to modernization have come to the fore of<br />

social science research. Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel (2005: 25), for example, have followed<br />

Bell (1973) in his differentiation between two distinct phases of modernization:<br />

industrialization <strong>and</strong> postindustrialization. Both phases differ significantly in the way<br />

4 To illustrate the importance of Lipset’s research: His 1959 article ranks amongst the all-time top-ten<br />

citations of the discipline’s top journal, the American Political Science Review (Siegelman 2006).<br />

“Excluding Duverger’s law on the effect of single-member districts on party systems, it may be the<br />

strongest empirical generalization we have in comparative politics to date” Boix (2003: 1-2).<br />

17


they affect societies: Whereas industrialization is accompanied by bureaucratization,<br />

centralization, rationalization <strong>and</strong> secularization, postindustrial societies show an<br />

increasing emphasis on autonomy, choice, creativity <strong>and</strong> self-expression. At the same<br />

time, both processes have changed the way people relate to authorities. Nevertheless, the<br />

authors acknowledge that cultures, even when they are exposed to the same (changing)<br />

conditions, remain relatively persistent, rejecting the notion of converging value<br />

patterns. So, societies are changing, <strong>and</strong> they change into similar directions – but the<br />

differences between these societies largely remain the same (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005:<br />

19-20).<br />

Technological innovations have been at the heart of the first modernization process, <strong>and</strong><br />

they had enormous implications. Before industrialization, “the vast majority made its<br />

living from agriculture <strong>and</strong> depended on things that came from heaven, like the sun <strong>and</strong><br />

rain” (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005: 26). When people gained, for the first time, control<br />

over the natural environment, this also meant challenging the authority of the church:<br />

“Praying to God for good harvest was no longer necessary when one could depend on<br />

fertilizer <strong>and</strong> insecticides” (ibid.). So, industrialization brought a secularization of<br />

authority, shifting the source of authority from religion to more secular ideologies.<br />

However, these societies were still characterized by pronounced authority relations <strong>and</strong><br />

socioeconomic conditions that are shaped by the disciplined, st<strong>and</strong>ardized <strong>and</strong> uniform<br />

mode of industrial production.<br />

Emancipation from authority takes place only during the postindustrialization phase,<br />

when the focus shifts from external authority to more individual autonomy <strong>and</strong> human<br />

choice (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Baker 2000; Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005). Economically,<br />

postindustrial societies are characterized by a shift of the major workforce from the<br />

industrial to the service sector. Working in service-oriented professions requires<br />

different skills than working at the production line, for example to fast process<br />

information, to make autonomous decisions or to propose creative ideas. “Service <strong>and</strong><br />

knowledge workers deal with people <strong>and</strong> concepts, operating in a world where<br />

innovation <strong>and</strong> the freedom to exercise individual judgements are essential. Creativity,<br />

imagination, <strong>and</strong> intellectual independence become central” (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005:<br />

18


28-29). The experience of these activities does not leave people’s value orientations<br />

unaltered, shifting priorities from survival to self-expression values.<br />

As Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel (2005: 28-29) have argued, postindustrial societies differ from<br />

industrial societies in three major aspects. First, postindustrial societies like the ones in<br />

Western Europe or the USA after World War II have experienced an unprecedented<br />

phase of peace, security <strong>and</strong> economic prosperity. As people tend to pursue goals that<br />

are short in supply (Inglehart 1977: 22), <strong>and</strong> as they strive for higher goals once material<br />

goals (like physical <strong>and</strong> economic security) are accomplished, people tend to put<br />

stronger emphasis on self-actualization Maslow (1954). 5<br />

Second, as tasks in the service sector tend to be cognitively more dem<strong>and</strong>ing than<br />

previous activities, broad access to higher education becomes a necessary condition for<br />

societies to become (or stay) competitive. Postindustrial societies are therefore<br />

characterized by higher levels of formal education. At the same time, this cognitive<br />

mobilization leaves an imprint on people’s belief systems. “Thus, rising levels of<br />

education, increasing cognitive <strong>and</strong> informational requirements in economic activities,<br />

<strong>and</strong> increasing proliferation of knowledge via mass media make people intellectually<br />

more independent, diminishing cognitive constraints on human choice” (Inglehart <strong>and</strong><br />

Welzel 2005: 29).<br />

Third, as their daily work activities become more independent <strong>and</strong> dest<strong>and</strong>ardized,<br />

people dem<strong>and</strong> the same kind of independence, choice <strong>and</strong> creative power in other areas<br />

of their lives. The expansion of the welfare state has contributed to the realization of<br />

these dem<strong>and</strong>s, protecting the individual against certain risks that previously have been<br />

covered by close group ties. Today, the belonging to a group, be it the family or the<br />

church, is no longer a question of survival but of choice (Beck 2002). Families <strong>and</strong> other<br />

group affiliations are changing “from a community of need to elective affinities” (Beck-<br />

Gernsheim 1998).<br />

All three processes show how people change their values as a response to the conditions<br />

that surround them. Given the favorable circumstances described above, all three<br />

5 Inglehart (1977, 1990) has referred to Maslow’s values of self-actualization as postmaterialistic values,<br />

emphasizing nonphysiological needs such as (self) esteem, self-enhancement <strong>and</strong> aesthetic satisfaction.<br />

Opposed to that are materialistic values, fulfilling material or physiological needs such as survival <strong>and</strong><br />

security.<br />

19


contribute to a change in people’s value priorities, shifting the emphasis from survival to<br />

self-expression values. As people acquire most of their basic value priorities in their<br />

formative years, that is during childhood <strong>and</strong> adolescence, it has been argued that value<br />

change can only proceed as an intergenerational process (Inglehart 1977: 23, 1990: 33).<br />

As political, social <strong>and</strong> economic conditions are changing as a consequence of<br />

postindustrialization, younger generations adapt to these circumstances <strong>and</strong> internalize<br />

postmaterialistic or self-expression values (Inglehart 1990: 136; Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel<br />

2005: 100-105).<br />

These changing value priorities as consequences of societal modernization have had<br />

important implications for political participation. Industrialization <strong>and</strong> the shifting<br />

emphasis towards secular-rational values, on the one h<strong>and</strong>, opened, for the first time in<br />

human history, the door for mass participation, promoting not only universal suffrage<br />

but also mass organizations to represent interests of people, even majorities, who had so<br />

far been excluded from any kind of political participation <strong>and</strong> interest representation. As<br />

such, catch-all parties (like socialist parties as mass organizations for workers’ interests)<br />

emerged (Kirchheimer 1965), <strong>and</strong> most of the parties that were formed as a response to<br />

deeply rooted societal conflicts of that time still shape the structure of today’s Western<br />

European party systems (Lipset <strong>and</strong> Rokkan 1967; Rokkan 2000).<br />

While industrialization brought unprecedented levels of inclusion <strong>and</strong> political<br />

participation, the consequences of postindustrialization are less straightforward since<br />

these social changes tend to produce “cross-cutting developments, some of which could<br />

possibly depress activism, while others seem likely to encourage civic engagement”<br />

(Norris 2002: 23). Postindustrialization produces a citizenry that is better educated, more<br />

skilled <strong>and</strong> more informed than ever before. Generally, they also have more leisure time,<br />

<strong>and</strong> through the expansion <strong>and</strong> diversification of the media system (e.g. internet),<br />

information <strong>and</strong> knowledge is easier accessible. Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel (2005) now argue<br />

that the value change from survival to self-expression values brings about greater<br />

skepticism towards all kinds of authorities, including political authorities (see also<br />

Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Catterberg 2003: 79). As these authority relations become weaker, people<br />

tend to question political elites, to become more critical <strong>and</strong> less inclined to participate<br />

20


in mass-based, hierarchical organizations that could not function without the discipline<br />

<strong>and</strong> ordination of its members.<br />

The cultural variant of modernization theory leads to a number of hypotheses about the<br />

dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging activities.<br />

On the individual level, younger citizens <strong>and</strong> those with higher emancipative values are<br />

more actively participating in demonstrations, petitions <strong>and</strong> political consumerism. This<br />

hypothesis refers to the cause dimension.<br />

On the aggregate level, three propositions can be derived. First, as a consequence of<br />

progressing postindustrialization, an increase in the overall level of elite-challenging<br />

activities can be observed. This hypothesis refers to the dynamics dimension. Second,<br />

societies with higher socioeconomic development show higher levels of elitechallenging<br />

activities (cause dimension). Third, as elite-challenging activities push for<br />

responsible <strong>and</strong> transparent elite behavior, thus limiting the abuse of entrusted power,<br />

the quality of democracy improves with higher levels of elite-challenging activities. This<br />

refers to the consequence dimension of elite-challenging participation.<br />

As individualization affects several areas of their life, people are today less ready to<br />

show a long-term commitment to any kind of organization. Rather, they prefer to<br />

become politically involved in more short-term, issue-oriented <strong>and</strong> expressive forms of<br />

political participation – forms that are rather elite-challenging than elite-directed<br />

(Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005: 118). This has important consequences for traditional<br />

organizations.<br />

2.2 Organizational Changes <strong>and</strong> Social Capital<br />

2.2.1 Organizational changes<br />

Most visibly, this change has affected political parties. Repeatedly <strong>and</strong> almost<br />

unanimously, political parties have been characterized as an integral part of modern<br />

representative democracies (Schattschneider 1942; Sartori 1976). The complexity of<br />

their various activities (interest aggregation, articulation <strong>and</strong> representation; political<br />

21


education <strong>and</strong> information; elite recruitment; program development, to name only a few)<br />

has led scholars to argue that modern democracy without political parties was<br />

“unthinkable” (Schattschneider 1942: 1; see also Dalton <strong>and</strong> Wattenberg 2000a).<br />

Recent literature on party politics, however, is more characterized by a depiction of<br />

crisis than of enthusiasm: “Today, mounting evidence points to a declining role for<br />

political parties in shaping the politics of advanced industrial democracies” (Dalton <strong>and</strong><br />

Wattenberg 2000a: 3). Summarizing a multitude of simultaneous processes, this trend of<br />

decreasing importance of political parties has been described as “partisan dealignment”<br />

(Dalton 1984; Dalton, Flanagan <strong>and</strong> Beck 1984; Schmitt <strong>and</strong> Holmberg 1995; Dalton<br />

2000). Processes of individualization are the driving force behind this development<br />

where organizational changes <strong>and</strong> the rise of elite-challenging activities are often seen as<br />

two sides of the same coin. This has important <strong>and</strong> multifaceted consequences for<br />

representative democracies, ranging from questions of political socialization <strong>and</strong> civic<br />

disengagement to questions of social coherence <strong>and</strong> political accountability. But what do<br />

organizational changes mean?<br />

For one, the decreasing importance of ‘old’ mobilizing institutions such as political<br />

parties (but also labor unions, churches, <strong>and</strong> alike) is mirrored in a shrinking basis of<br />

support, suggesting that the linkage between citizens <strong>and</strong> political parties has weakened.<br />

First empirical evidence for this comes from inspecting time-series data on party<br />

membership:<br />

22


Figure 2-1: Change in Party Membership (1980 – 2000, in %) *<br />

Spain<br />

Greece<br />

Portugal<br />

Germany<br />

Belgium<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Denmark<br />

Sweden<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Austria<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Norway<br />

US<br />

Italy<br />

France<br />

-100 -50 0 50 100 150 200<br />

* Source: Numbers taken from Mair <strong>and</strong> van Biezen (2001: 12).<br />

Time frame: Spain (1980-2000), Greece (1980-1998), Portugal (1980-2000), Germany (1980-1999), Belgium (1980-<br />

1999), Irel<strong>and</strong> (1980-1998), Denmark (1980-1998), Sweden (1980-1998), Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (1977-1997), Austria (1980-1999),<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (1980-2000), Finl<strong>and</strong> (1980-1998), Norway (1980-1997), United States (1980-1998), Italy (1980-1998),<br />

France (1979-1998).<br />

As Figure 2-1 shows, with the exception of Southern Europe’s third wave democracies<br />

Spain, Portugal <strong>and</strong> Greece, political parties in postindustrial democracies have been<br />

facing a decline of membership rates over the past 20 years, some even around 50<br />

percent It is not only the fall in absolute (<strong>and</strong> relative) numbers that should attract<br />

attention but also the consistency with which the decline is occurring (Mair <strong>and</strong> van<br />

Biezen 2001: 13). For political parties, declining membership rates have enormous<br />

consequences. As citizens are less inclined to show long-term commitment to traditional<br />

organizations, these organizational bodies are losing the capacities to mobilize <strong>and</strong><br />

engage citizens into politics, including electoral participation. The decrease of voter<br />

turnout in postindustrial democracies can partially be attributed to this development. As<br />

conventional participation is also revolving around party politics, it is very likely that<br />

these forms of participation are affected as well. A shrinking membership basis does<br />

23


also mean that political parties are faced with decreasing financial contributions through<br />

missing membership fees. In addition, recruiting qualified political personnel also<br />

becomes much more difficult, in particular among the younger generations that above<br />

average tend to stay away from traditional, hierarchical organizations.<br />

The “broad <strong>and</strong> ongoing decline in the role of political parties for contemporary publics”<br />

(Dalton 2000: 23) is also reflected, second, in rising unfavorable orientations towards<br />

these institutions among the citizenry. A growing number of citizens indicate that they<br />

have lost confidence in politicians <strong>and</strong> a number of political institutions (Holmberg<br />

1999; Dalton 1999, 2004). In fact, political parties are among those institutions with the<br />

largest drop in confidence. This dissatisfaction seems to have a spill-over effect to other<br />

institutions where party politics plays a decisive role within a democratic system:<br />

government <strong>and</strong> parliament (Klingemann 1999: 51). At the same time, in almost all<br />

postindustrial democracies, a considerable decline in party identifications can be<br />

observed (Dalton 1999: 66; 2000). This is in fact a twofold trend: Not only is the general<br />

number of identifiers in a country in decline. Of those citizens still holding a party<br />

identification, it is also the strength of such an affective tie that is weakening. As<br />

research on electoral behavior has shown, party identifications have been among the<br />

most influential factors to mobilize citizens into electoral participation <strong>and</strong> to determine<br />

their voting preference. Declining party identification means, as a consequence, higher<br />

volatility in the electorate, so that political parties are, once again, losing their capacities<br />

to mobilize citizens.<br />

A third development that affects status <strong>and</strong> function of political parties in democracies is<br />

the changing nature of collective actors. Until the 1960ies, citizens’ interest articulation<br />

<strong>and</strong> aggregation operated almost exclusively through political parties <strong>and</strong> citizen<br />

participation in elections. Opportunity structures were largely determined by party<br />

competition. During the past decades, new collective actors have entered the political<br />

scene, most of these organizations rooted in protest movements. They were labeled ‘new<br />

social movements’ because they tackled ‘new’ political issues such as environmental<br />

protection, women’s rights or nuclear power. In addition, they used new, unconventional<br />

forms of political expression. “These actions forms had two sources: they had either<br />

been reactivated from the tradition of the workers’ movement or were newly developed<br />

24


in the context of the movements themselves” (Fuchs 1990: 1). These citizen action<br />

groups that have emerged in various ways have been challenging the political parties in<br />

their traditional role as organizations of interest representation 6 – by taking over some of<br />

the core democratic functions of political parties. Not only do they provide political<br />

information to citizens <strong>and</strong> contribute, thereby, to the political education of citizens.<br />

Like political parties, they also aim at providing informational shortcuts that help people<br />

to structure political reality. They also mobilize citizens into political participation.<br />

Some of these movement groups have even started out their ‘march through the<br />

institutions’, such as the Green parties in Western Europe that emanated from various<br />

activist groups on anti-nuclear energy, women’s rights, environmental issues or peace.<br />

The main mobilization focus of these loosely connected networks, however, is on noninstitutionalized<br />

forms of participation, such as organizing petitions or calling for<br />

boycotts around specific issues.<br />

Summarizing the developments of organizational changes <strong>and</strong> party politics leads to the<br />

following hypotheses:<br />

On the individual level, the rise of elite-challenging activities goes at the expense of<br />

participation in traditional forms of participation: Citizens participating in elitechallenging<br />

activities abstain from engagement through traditional channels (cause<br />

dimension). On the aggregate level, elite-challenging activities should go at the expense<br />

of traditional forms of activity as well. First, as a cross-sectional result: <strong>Participation</strong> in<br />

traditional forms of participation should be low in societies where elite-challenging<br />

activities are widespread (cause dimension). Second, as diverging trends: As elitechallenging<br />

activities are becoming more widespread over time, we observe a decrease<br />

in institutionalized, traditional forms of political participation (dynamics dimension).<br />

2.2.2 Declining Social Capital <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

Along similar lines, Putnam (1995a, 2000, 2002) reports about the diminishing role of<br />

voluntary associations in general. Various scholars have been alerted by this depiction<br />

6 In addition, political parties are also under pressure by rapidly changing mass media that have replaced<br />

political parties as the main source of political information <strong>and</strong> communication. In this way, parties are<br />

required to change their strategies how they present themselves to the public.<br />

25


since they attribute a number of positive effects to the membership in these associations.<br />

Next to the equality argument (only through pluralist forms of interest representation the<br />

various, even conflicting, interests in a society can equally be protected <strong>and</strong> balanced,<br />

see Schlozman, Verba <strong>and</strong> Brady 1999), mainly two kinds of organizational benefits are<br />

discussed in the literature. The first one refers to the individual-level, the second one to<br />

the aggregate level.<br />

For one thing, civic benefits are attributed to the individual member(ship) in voluntary<br />

associations. Through their engagement in groups, citizens do not only learn how to<br />

cooperate with others for mutual benefit. Their work in an association, in particular the<br />

sharing of information <strong>and</strong> knowledge about the objectives <strong>and</strong> routines, also equip them<br />

with more competence <strong>and</strong> skills. Finally, the permanent contact <strong>and</strong> exchange with<br />

others facilitates the adoption of civic virtues such as trust <strong>and</strong> tolerance among the<br />

members of an association (Almond <strong>and</strong> Verba 1963: 322; Etzioni 1993; Putnam 1995a:<br />

67; Bellah et al. 1996; Uslaner 2002).<br />

Second, these individual civic skills, taken together, have important consequences for<br />

the communal <strong>and</strong> democratic life in a society. Following the de Tocquevillian notion of<br />

associations as “schools of democracy” (Tocqueville (2000 [1835/40]), Putnam argues<br />

that such organizations provide platforms for face-to-face meetings which lead, on the<br />

societal level, to dense social networks <strong>and</strong> the emergence of horizontal (social) trust<br />

among the members of a society. In doing so, a vibrant associational life contributes to<br />

the emergence of civic communities <strong>and</strong> produces high levels of social capital (Putnam<br />

1993).<br />

According to Putnam’s definition, social capital refers to “connections among<br />

individuals – social networks <strong>and</strong> the norms of reciprocity <strong>and</strong> trustworthiness that arise<br />

from them” (Putnam 2000: 19). It has been argued, for example, that societies with a<br />

vibrant associational life <strong>and</strong> higher levels of social capital have more responsive,<br />

accountable <strong>and</strong> effective political institutions, that their economy performs better, <strong>and</strong><br />

that they outperform societies where social capital is scarce in terms of lower crime<br />

figures, better health <strong>and</strong> higher educational achievement (Putnam 1993; 1995a: 67;<br />

Putnam 2000: 296-333; Smith 2001).<br />

26


It is therefore no wonder that the concept of social capital has gained enormous<br />

scientific, public <strong>and</strong> political attention during the past decades, offering an answer to<br />

one of the most important questions of all social sciences: What keeps societies together<br />

<strong>and</strong> lets them act for collective goals? (Welzel, Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Deutsch 2005; Stolle <strong>and</strong><br />

Hooghe 2004). Putnam’s core argument is: Social capital is so important because it<br />

helps societies to overcome the collective action dilemma <strong>and</strong> to cooperate for mutual<br />

benefit. The ambiguity of the term has been repeatedly criticized, but this debate has not<br />

prevented the increasing popularity of the concept. Recently, the concept of social<br />

capital has also been adopted by the World Bank 7 , stating that “[i]ncreasing evidence<br />

shows that social cohesion is critical for societies to prosper economically <strong>and</strong> for<br />

development to be sustainable. [...] Social networks can increase productivity by<br />

reducing the costs of doing business. Social capital facilitates coordination <strong>and</strong><br />

cooperation”.<br />

To be sure, the concept of social capital goes way back in social science research, in<br />

particular to Hanifan (1916, 1920), <strong>Jacobs</strong> (1961), Granovetter (1973), Bourdieu (1983)<br />

<strong>and</strong> Coleman (1988, 1990). However, Putnam’s work during the past decade has<br />

brought social capital in the center of - also public – attention, stimulating innumerous<br />

debates. One of the discussions is centered on definitional questions. According to<br />

Putnam, the concept of social capital has two components: a structural component<br />

(networks) that enables people to act together; <strong>and</strong> a motivational component (cultural<br />

norms <strong>and</strong> values) that stimulates cooperation among people (Norris 2002: 138).<br />

However, others have argued in favor of a more concise definition of social capital that<br />

restricts the term to its core element of people’s connectedness (Coleman 1988; 1990).<br />

A second debate aims at the question at which level social capital can be found. It has<br />

been argued that social capital is a collective resource (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Rochon 1998) – “if<br />

social capital is anything, it is a societal not an individual property” (Newton 2001:<br />

207). Norris stresses the same point, “as social capital is a relational phenomenon that<br />

can be the property of groups, local communities, <strong>and</strong> nations, but not of individuals”<br />

(Norris 2002: 139). These authors explicitly contradict Bourdieu’s underst<strong>and</strong>ing of<br />

social capital as an individual characteristic – the networks <strong>and</strong> ties that people can use<br />

7 http://www1.worldbank.org/prem/poverty/scapital/whatsc.htm<br />

27


in order to pursue goals in relation to others. Along similar lines, Nin (1999; 2001)<br />

defines social capital as an individual investment in social relations with expected<br />

returns, that is what a person anticipates as benefit or profit. However, irrespectively of<br />

an individual or societal approach to the concept of social capital, it remains undisputed<br />

that it is the interaction between people that constitutes the benefits of social capital (Nin<br />

1999: 32).<br />

A third – <strong>and</strong> probably most important – debate deals with Putnam’s observation of<br />

decreasing membership rates <strong>and</strong> declining social capital. If one follows the appraisal of<br />

voluntary associations <strong>and</strong> its civic consequences, then the future of democratic societies<br />

as we know them must be seen in an alarming light. Consequently, Putnam’s thesis of<br />

declining social capital <strong>and</strong> the decreased vibrancy of American civil society (Putnam<br />

1995a: 65) has led to heated debates within the social science community (for an<br />

overview see Stolle <strong>and</strong> Hooghe 2004).<br />

As the main reason for the erosion of social capital Putnam blames the processes of<br />

individualization. Those processes led to a significant decline in active membership<br />

associations, such as PTAs, football teams or community groups. Instead of enjoying<br />

community activities with others, people tend to spend their free time in individualized<br />

leisure activities (“Bowling Alone”). As a result, social capital is eroding – which, in the<br />

end, leads to a more general decline of political <strong>and</strong> social engagement. Among others,<br />

Putnam reports about decreasing voting turnout, political interest <strong>and</strong> grass root<br />

activities, so his diagnosis is not restricted to conventional forms of political<br />

participation. Quite the contrary: By stating a decline in the willingness of American<br />

citizens to sign petitions, declining social capital also seems to have an impact on<br />

unconventional political participation (for a critique on the reliability of Putnam’s data,<br />

measurement <strong>and</strong> interpretation see for example Ladd 1996, 1999, Paxton 1999; Stolle<br />

<strong>and</strong> Hooghe 2004).<br />

This observation has led to Putnam’s diagnosis that today’s democracies are facing a<br />

general decline of political <strong>and</strong> social activities: “Ironically – just at the moment of<br />

liberal democracy’s greatest triumph there is also unhappiness about the performance of<br />

major social institutions, including the institutions of representative government, among<br />

the established democracies (…). At least in the United States, there is reason to suspect<br />

28


that some fundamental social <strong>and</strong> cultural preconditions for effective democracy may<br />

have been eroded in recent decades, the result of a gradual but widespread process of<br />

civic engagement“ (Putnam <strong>and</strong> Goss 2002: 4).<br />

The same consequences of modernization that Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel (2005) <strong>and</strong> so many<br />

others have positively interpreted as giving rise to a more self-expressive, critical,<br />

democratic <strong>and</strong> participatory citizenry, Putnam identifies as the forces that lead to<br />

declining social capital <strong>and</strong> therefore declining levels of participation: individualization,<br />

decreasing significance of traditional organizations, progressing participation of women<br />

in the labor market, or increasing television usage (Putnam 1995a, b, 2000). This leads<br />

to the next hypothesis: If Putnam <strong>and</strong> his coauthors are right, there should be empirical<br />

evidence of a long-term trend towards civic disengagement, including forms of elitechallenging<br />

activities (dynamics dimension).<br />

Given the decline of organizational membership, the tradition in social capital research<br />

to view voluntary association as the cradle for the emergence of social capital must,<br />

sooner or later, inevitably result in the finding that social capital is in decline. But this<br />

interpretation should be challenged for three reasons. First, because it confuses<br />

community ties (e.g. civic networks) that are a prerequisite for social capital with<br />

collective action (e.g. participation in voluntary organizations) as an outcome of social<br />

capital (Welzel, Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Deutsch 2005: 140-141). This distinction is important,<br />

second, because it allows considering all kinds of community activities as a result of<br />

social capital. Research on social movements could repeatedly show that it is through<br />

networks (the main component of social capital) that activities are initiated, <strong>and</strong> that<br />

networks are needed in order to mobilize people into action (McAdam 1986; Tarrow<br />

1998, McAdam et al. 2001). This leads us to the next hypothesis: There should be<br />

empirical evidence that participation in elite-challenging activities is a direct result of<br />

social capital: embeddedness in networks <strong>and</strong> trust (cause dimension). The hypothesis<br />

can be tested on the individual as well as on the aggregate level.<br />

If it is true that elite-challenging activities are a consequence of mobilization within<br />

networks, meaning a reflection of social capital available in a society, <strong>and</strong> if it is true<br />

that elite-challenging activities are becoming more widespread, then social capital in<br />

general is maybe not in decline. Rather, it has found a different way how to translate<br />

29


into community action. Third, often too willingly democratic benefits are attributed to<br />

voluntary organizations. But not all associations are alike (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Rochon 1998;<br />

Warren 2001). Some organizations produce private, not public goods; some have<br />

hierarchical, not horizontal inner structures; some cooperative skills that work within a<br />

certain closed community may not cross the boundary to interaction scenarios outside<br />

the group; <strong>and</strong> some associations simply have goals that run against basic principles in a<br />

democracy (Boix <strong>and</strong> Posner 1996). So, in the end it remains an empirical question<br />

whether declining membership in voluntary associations indeed poses a threat to<br />

effective democracy, as Putnam claims (Putnam <strong>and</strong> Goss 2002: 4). The hypothesis to<br />

be tested on the aggregate level is: Elite-challenging activities as individualized<br />

activities have a negative impact on democracy (consequence dimension).<br />

The following paragraph shifts the focus from overall tendencies in civic engagement to<br />

individual characteristics of activism: “What matters is not only the amount of civic<br />

activity but also its distribution, not just how many people take part but also who they<br />

are. In short, concern for democratic equality forces us not only to inquire how many<br />

people are bowling <strong>and</strong> whether they do it solo or in leagues, but also to ask who bowls”<br />

(Schlozman, Verba <strong>and</strong> Brady 1999: 428).<br />

2.3 Resources, Motivation <strong>and</strong> the Question of Political Equality<br />

Some scholars have claimed that elite-challenging activities broaden the equality gap in<br />

political participation (Verba, Schlozman <strong>and</strong> Brady 1995a; Skocpol 2003). What does<br />

that mean? Which aspects of political equality are affected?<br />

2.3.1 Political Equality<br />

Political equality is a basic axiom of modern democracies (Dahl 1989, 1998, 2006), one<br />

of the “bedrock principles in a democracy” (Verba 2001). The idea that all citizens are<br />

equally qualified to take part in collective decision-making <strong>and</strong>, therefore, granted the<br />

same political rights is reflected in several legal guarantees of today’s democratic<br />

30


constitutions: universal suffrage, the principle of “one man, one vote”, the freedom to<br />

raise one’s voice <strong>and</strong> to form associations, or equality before law, to name just a few.<br />

Given the definition of political equality as “the extent to which citizens have an equal<br />

voice in governmental decisions” (Verba 2003: 663), equality <strong>and</strong> political participation<br />

are closely related in democracies. Individual citizens <strong>and</strong> groups must become active to<br />

be heard – it is only then that they can communicate their preferences, dem<strong>and</strong>s, wishes<br />

<strong>and</strong> needs to political elites, <strong>and</strong> the same time, hold office holders responsible. In a<br />

democracy, equality in participation is ensured, first, by giving each citizen a voice,<br />

entitling her/him with equal rights to participate.<br />

Whether these legal guarantees of equality are in place or not addresses the basic<br />

question of whether a political system can be considered as democratic. Since<br />

democratic regimes comply with this idea of equality, whereas literally all nondemocratic<br />

regimes violate it (see for example the Freedom House methodology for<br />

assessing political rights <strong>and</strong> civil liberties), it shall be of no further concern here. There<br />

is almost no variation among democracies when it comes to this aspect of political<br />

equality, the legal boundaries for elite-challenging participation. From a perspective<br />

concerned with democratic quality, other aspects of equality are more interesting.<br />

Referring to Rae et al. (1981), Verba argues that there are various forms of equalities<br />

(Verba 2003: 664-665). Besides the equal right to participate, equality in participation<br />

can also mean, second <strong>and</strong> among others 8 , that participation in its amount <strong>and</strong> form is<br />

equally distributed among individuals <strong>and</strong> groups in a given society.<br />

Importantly, Verba points here to a significant distinction between two important goals<br />

of democratic rule: equality <strong>and</strong> legitimacy. In terms of democratic legitimacy,<br />

participation by as many as possible is desirable. The more people contribute to the<br />

input-flow in a political decision-making process, the more legitimacy a democratic<br />

system can draw on. Both aspects, equality <strong>and</strong> legitimacy, are also closely related in the<br />

sense that full participation (all citizens are active) also means the realization of full<br />

equality (everyone is involved). However, a negative relationship between the two is<br />

also possible. <strong>Participation</strong> of many, not all, can go at the expense of political equality:<br />

8 Other forms of equality refer, for example, to the equal reception of one’s voice, or the equality of<br />

response given by political elites.<br />

31


There can be high levels of participation with low equality because not all groups in a<br />

society have equal access to influencing government decisions <strong>and</strong> remain<br />

unrepresented. Conversely, there can be low levels of participation with high equality<br />

because the composition of the small active group reflects more or less the scope of<br />

individual interests prevailing in a society. For elite-challenging activities this means:<br />

Within a given society, participation in petitions, demonstrations or boycotts should be<br />

distributed as equal as possible among its members <strong>and</strong> groups.<br />

Closely related to this, Verba (2003: 664-665) points to a third interpretation of equality,<br />

that is the equal capacity <strong>and</strong> opportunity to participate. This aspect of equality goes<br />

beyond the constitutional guarantee for <strong>and</strong> equal distribution of citizen participation. It<br />

addresses the question in how far these legal rights, equally granted to all citizens, are<br />

ensured <strong>and</strong> implemented. In his concept of polyarchy, Dahl (1989, 1998) has argued<br />

that political equality is at the heart of the democratic idea, deducing from that several<br />

criteria for a democratic process, among them “effective participation”. Going beyond<br />

constitutional rights to participate, “effective participation” also explicitly grants<br />

effective opportunities to citizens to make their voices heard (Dahl 1998: 37). This<br />

distinction is important: in modern democracies where people are granted equal rights to<br />

participate, not all citizens make use of these rights. Some citizens participate more,<br />

others less, a few never have. For social scientists this discrepancy between the<br />

democratic ideal of equality on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> actual political activity on the other,<br />

holds a puzzle: “If equal consideration of the needs <strong>and</strong> preferences of all citizens is a<br />

central principle of democracy, then participatory inequality represents a violation of<br />

democratic principles” (Verba 2003: 667).<br />

It would be less problematic for a democracy as long as inactivity was a r<strong>and</strong>om<br />

phenomenon in the sense that citizens participate at one occasion but not at another, with<br />

no individual or group of citizens systematically being excluded from political<br />

engagement. Facing reality, this is of course not true. The reason for unequal<br />

participation is that rights also require resources, <strong>and</strong> resources are unequally distributed<br />

among the members of a society (Verba 2003: 665). Besides individual resources,<br />

empirical studies on political participation have shown that it is also the motivation to<br />

participate that influences whether a person engages in politics or not. Both determinants<br />

32


of political activism in general <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities in particular, resources<br />

<strong>and</strong> motivation, are addressed in the following paragraph.<br />

2.3.2 Resources, Equality <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

The resource model (Verba <strong>and</strong> Nie 1972; Verba, Nie <strong>and</strong> Kim 1978; Verba, Schlozman<br />

<strong>and</strong> Brady 1995a, b) argues that political activity depends on the availability of<br />

individual resources. To intervene in the political decision-making process citizens need<br />

at least some basic knowledge about political actors <strong>and</strong> procedures; skills are needed to<br />

communicate own preferences in public; writing a letter to a politician requires time <strong>and</strong><br />

some intellectual skills; donating money for a political campaign requires material<br />

resources, namely money; <strong>and</strong> any kind of political engagement requires at least some<br />

interest in political processes, is often time-consuming <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>s flexibility. “In<br />

short, for citizen politics to be purposeful, the electorate must have at least a basic level<br />

of political skills” (Dalton 2006: 15).<br />

Several participation studies have indicated that a person’s socioeconomic background<br />

(education <strong>and</strong> income) <strong>and</strong> its sociodemographic characteristics (such as age <strong>and</strong><br />

gender) are the most influential individual resources impacting political participation<br />

(Almond <strong>and</strong> Verba 1963; Verba, Schlozman <strong>and</strong> Brady 1995a; Norris 2002; Dalton<br />

2006). Resources help individuals to influence the political decision-making process in<br />

two ways. Education, for example, does not only allow “people to surmount the barriers<br />

of participation” (Rosenstone <strong>and</strong> Hansen 1996: 74), so that people with higher<br />

education will become more active in the first place. Political elites, in return, also<br />

appear to be more responsive to the higher educated – as the two authors put it, “they<br />

travel in social circles that make them targets of both direct <strong>and</strong> indirect participation”<br />

(Rosenstone <strong>and</strong> Hansen 1996: 76).<br />

Another major problem that arises when resources are not equally available in a society<br />

is that disadvantages in resources <strong>and</strong> disadvantages in unfavorable policy decisions<br />

may reinforce each other. Those active citizens who have already more resources than<br />

others may use this advantage to influence government decisions that favor already<br />

privileged people <strong>and</strong> disfavor fringe groups. Also in that way, political inequality is<br />

reinforced (Verba 2003: 667).<br />

33


It was mentioned earlier that the democratic principle of “one man, one vote” is the<br />

basic link between the equal consideration of citizens <strong>and</strong> political participation. As<br />

such, <strong>and</strong> not just on paper, voting in an election is the most common <strong>and</strong> widespread<br />

form of participation. Through its preassigned procedures, institutionalized opportunity<br />

structure <strong>and</strong> electoral campaigns, it requires the least individual resources in the matter<br />

of time, skills or property. Looking at the individual characteristics of voters <strong>and</strong><br />

nonvoters it is, compared to other activities, one of the most equal forms of political<br />

activism in democratic societies (Lutz <strong>and</strong> Gill<strong>and</strong> 2004).<br />

By contrast, elite-challenging activities in particular have been blamed for contributing<br />

to political inequality, widening the gap between those who participate <strong>and</strong> those who<br />

do not (Skocpol 2003, 2004; Verba, Schlozman <strong>and</strong> Brady 1995a). Elite-challenging<br />

activities are often characterized as being more dem<strong>and</strong>ing in terms of required<br />

resources than other forms of political participation, indicating pronounced unequal<br />

opportunities (determined by age, gender, education, income, etc.) to take part in public<br />

life (Dalton 2000b: 929-930). For example, actors in conventional participation <strong>and</strong><br />

actors in unconventional, elite-challenging participation differ in the direction that age<br />

affects activism. For conventional forms of political participation, the relationship<br />

reveals a curvilinear pattern, indicating that individuals are most active in their middle<br />

ages, whereas rather young or old people show less engagement. By contrast, empirical<br />

studies so far have shown that age is negatively linked with elite-challenging forms of<br />

protest activity (Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al. 1979; Jennings <strong>and</strong> van Deth 1990; Kaase 1990;<br />

Jenkins <strong>and</strong> Wallace 1996). This is very much in line with Inglehart’s early observation<br />

that unconventional participation was more prevalent among the more postmaterialist<br />

younger generations, a finding that is still valid until today (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005:<br />

chapter 4). The resource hypothesis to be tested reads as follows: Participants in elitechallenging<br />

activities are young, better educated <strong>and</strong> have a higher income (cause<br />

dimension).<br />

The general claim that elite-challenging activities are reinforcing political inequality<br />

largely disregards that there are pronounced differences among the different elitechallenging<br />

activities. Of course, looking at consumer buy-cotts (a positive form of<br />

34


political consumerism) as the conscious decision to purchase a product for ethical,<br />

political or environmental reasons, inequalities between buy-cotters <strong>and</strong> non-buy-cotters<br />

are quite plausible. Buy-cotters are more educated, thus more aware <strong>and</strong> concerned with<br />

issues of Fair Trade or sustainable development, <strong>and</strong> they have a higher income that<br />

enables them to afford the more expensive Fair Trade products or organic foods (Goul<br />

Andersen <strong>and</strong> Tobiasen 2004; Stolle <strong>and</strong> Micheletti 2005). On the other h<strong>and</strong>, forms of<br />

political consumerism are one of the few activities exercised by more women than men,<br />

turning old gender role models upside down (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Hooghe 2005: 10-11).<br />

Furthermore, as Rosenstone <strong>and</strong> Hansen (1996: 74-76, 130-136) could demonstrate with<br />

their US data, signing a petition requires even less social resources than other forms of<br />

participation in governmental politics, including forms of electoral participation (among<br />

them voting in a Presidential election). 9 Finally, in a comparison of party members, civic<br />

joiners (members of voluntary associations) <strong>and</strong> demonstrators in Belgium, Norris,<br />

Walgrave <strong>and</strong> van Aelst (2005) showed that participating in a demonstration is less<br />

determined by unequal opportunities than other forms of activity: “A comparison of the<br />

characteristics of the (…) activists indicates clearly that demonstrators most closely<br />

resemble the electorate at large” (Norris, Walgrave <strong>and</strong> van Aelst 2005: 200). The<br />

results suggest that the relationship between inequality <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities<br />

deserves a closer look since it is not as straightforward as some scholars suggest.<br />

2.3.3 Motivation, Equality <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

Resources are closely linked with the motivation to become active: People with<br />

resources favorable for political participation may also show a higher motivation to<br />

engage in political action. Empirical participation studies have so far focused on<br />

attitudes like political interest, political efficacy, support for democracy, confidence in<br />

political institutions, or satisfaction with government performance (Almond <strong>and</strong> Verba<br />

1963; Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al. 1979; Jennings, van Deth et al. 1990; Parry, Moyser <strong>and</strong><br />

Day 1992; Verba, Schlozman <strong>and</strong> Brady 1995a; Norris 2002; Stolle <strong>and</strong> Hooghe 2005).<br />

9 One should keep in mind, however, that in the United States participating in elections requires the citizen<br />

to register beforeh<strong>and</strong>, imposing another threshold for people with fewer resources.<br />

35


For some of these orientations it is reasonable to assume that they work in favor of<br />

political activism in general <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activism in particular: Without a<br />

minimum of political interest “as the degree to which politics arouses a citizen’s<br />

curiosity” (van Deth 1990: 278) 10 , no meaningful political participation is possible since<br />

people would not know about the political issues at h<strong>and</strong> or the means of participation.<br />

The more people are attentive towards politics (Zaller 1992: 18), the better the chances<br />

for participation (Lazarsfeld, Berelson <strong>and</strong> Gaudet 1948; Milbrath <strong>and</strong> Goel 1977). The<br />

same should be true for political efficacy. Internal political efficacy (the belief that one<br />

is competent <strong>and</strong> able to underst<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> influence the political process) <strong>and</strong> external<br />

political efficacy (the belief that the political system is, in general, open to citizen<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>s, that is, responsive) should both contribute to political engagement – simply<br />

because there is no point of becoming active if one considers the own behavior as totally<br />

inconsequential (Almond <strong>and</strong> Verba 1963: 188; Milbrath <strong>and</strong> Goel 1977: 57).<br />

Whereas we would expect that citizens who are interested in politics <strong>and</strong> feel more<br />

confident to effectively influence the political decision-making process tend to be more<br />

politically engaged, the link between other political orientations <strong>and</strong> activism is not that<br />

straightforward. Consider, for example, dissatisfaction with how the current government<br />

performs: Such discontent may stimulate participation, not only in order to express<br />

discontent but also to push for political change. Since the early writings of Karl Marx<br />

<strong>and</strong> Emile Durkheim, forms of protest activities have been associated with<br />

dissatisfaction, deprivation <strong>and</strong> alienation (Gabriel 1996: 193). But these feelings do not<br />

simply translate into action. Rather, at least two conditions have to be fulfilled. On the<br />

one h<strong>and</strong>, people must be able to attribute their misery to be the result of action by other<br />

people. Since uncertainty about whom to address thwarts any form of collective action,<br />

such “blame attribution” turns out to be necessary condition to translate grievance into<br />

action (Javeline 2003: 13; Rucht, Koopmans <strong>and</strong> Neidhardt 1998: 7). Second, people<br />

must consider their action to have an effect, meaning that the selected form of action is<br />

regarded as appropriate to improve the situation. This also means that citizens must have<br />

a sense of political efficacy to become active. Political efficacy, or the feeling of<br />

10 How political interest relates to political involvement or political motivation will not be discussed here<br />

(for an overview, see van Deth 1990: 276-78). Whether political interest finds its manifestation in actual<br />

36


“subjective political competence” (Almond <strong>and</strong> Verba 1963), is an intervening factor<br />

that, if present, is conducive to elite-challenging activism. In case of absence, apathy <strong>and</strong><br />

withdrawal from politics is much more likely (Milbrath <strong>and</strong> Goel 1977: 69; Gabriel<br />

1996: 198-199). Along similar lines, low levels of confidence in core political<br />

institutions may be a driving force for activity, in particular when there’s a chance to<br />

avoid institutionalized channels of participation. A citizen who does not have confidence<br />

in the national parliament as a whole will probably be less inclined to participate in the<br />

next national election that determines the composition of this institution. However, if<br />

she/he wants to be politically engaged, it might be through other, alternative channels of<br />

participation. In either case: Discontent in any form is not sufficient to stimulate action<br />

when resources for this activity are absent <strong>and</strong> people do not consider their themselves<br />

<strong>and</strong> their activities as being efficacious (Kitschelt 1986: 59).<br />

This leads to the motivation hypothesis: Participants in elite-challenging activities are<br />

politically interested, dissatisfied <strong>and</strong> show more pronounced feelings of political<br />

efficacy (cause dimension).<br />

Taking into account the discussion about political equality <strong>and</strong> the consequences of the<br />

rise of elite-challenging activities, a third hypothesis can be developed: <strong>Participation</strong> in<br />

elite-challenging activities is stronger determined by an unequal distribution of<br />

resources <strong>and</strong> motivation than other forms of participation, thus contributing to a<br />

manifestation of political inequality (consequence dimension).<br />

“[W]hen we address the topic of citizen politics in the mass, the temptation appears to<br />

be overwhelming to shift the level of underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> analysis to that of independent<br />

individuals...” (Huckfeldt <strong>and</strong> Sprague 1993: 281). However, not only individuals but<br />

also societies differ in their levels <strong>and</strong> forms of participation. This also applies to those<br />

countries that show similar socioeconomic levels of development. Voter turnout, for<br />

example, is lower in the US than it is in Sweden. And compared to the overall electorate,<br />

the share of party members is higher in Norway than it is in Germany (Mair <strong>and</strong> van<br />

Biezen 2001: 15-16). Some scholars have argued that these differences can be attributed<br />

to differences in the opportunity structures for political activities. If this was true, we<br />

behavior or not is an empirical question.<br />

37


should also be able to find systematic differences in context factors for elite-challenging<br />

activities.<br />

2.4 Opportunity Structures <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

In order to “reconstruct a compelling account of political life (Huckfeldt <strong>and</strong> Sprague<br />

1993: 281), the contextual approach (or: opportunity structure approach) acknowledges<br />

that citizens do not become active in a political vacuum. Instead, political participation<br />

does not only depend on individual characteristics but also evolves from an interaction<br />

of the individual with its environment. “Political opportunity structures are comprised of<br />

specific configurations of resources, institutional arrangements <strong>and</strong> historical precedents<br />

for social mobilization” (Kitschelt 1986: 58). This approach was originally developed in<br />

the context of social movements, assessing the degree of openness <strong>and</strong> accessibility of a<br />

political system to movement dem<strong>and</strong>s, <strong>and</strong> shifted the focus from actors <strong>and</strong> their<br />

strategic choices to external conditions (Kitschelt 1986: 59; Tarrow 1998: 18). Since<br />

then the concept has been widely used but often overloaded, so that it has been “in<br />

danger of becoming a sponge that soaks up every aspect of the social movement<br />

environment” (Gamson <strong>and</strong> Meyer 1996: 275). 11 But despite all criticism for<br />

operationalizational attempts, the main idea is a valid one - that external conditions, or<br />

contexts, determine how successful activists are in mobilizing support <strong>and</strong> promoting<br />

their dem<strong>and</strong>s (Meyer 2004: 126).<br />

How opportunity structures affect the content, tactics, cycles <strong>and</strong> success of actors <strong>and</strong><br />

social movements has often been examined by focussing on a single movement over<br />

time (see for example McAdam 1982; Kitschelt 1986; Tarrow 1989; Jenkins <strong>and</strong><br />

Kl<strong>and</strong>ermans 1995). However, opportunity structures are not only important for the<br />

policy success of social movements <strong>and</strong> interest groups. Citizens in their decision to<br />

participate are affected by direct <strong>and</strong> indirect contextual factors as well. Referring to the<br />

Political Action Study (Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al 1979: 43) Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels (1996)<br />

11 An ambitious attempt to clarify <strong>and</strong> conceptualize political opportunity structures can be found in<br />

Meyer <strong>and</strong> Minkhoff (2004).<br />

38


have differentiated between two types of context factors that can mobilize citizens into<br />

action. On the one h<strong>and</strong>, their environment is shaped by an interplay of collective actors,<br />

for example political parties, interest groups, citizen groups, etc. On the other h<strong>and</strong>,<br />

political <strong>and</strong> socioeconomic characteristics of a society can work in favor or against<br />

citizen participation. Both kinds of contextual factors shape the opportunity structure for<br />

individual activity.<br />

Firstly, individual participation can be seen as an outcome of her/his personal<br />

organizational context. Challenging Verba <strong>and</strong> his colleagues’ view on the importance<br />

of individual characteristics for political activism (Verba et al. 1995a), Rosenstone <strong>and</strong><br />

Hansen (1993: 5) have argued that people “participate in politics not so much because of<br />

who they are but because of the political choices <strong>and</strong> incentives they are offered”. In this<br />

way, the mobilization approach is closely related to Putnam’s work on the importance of<br />

dense social networks <strong>and</strong> a lively associational life (Putnam 1995, 2000). On the<br />

individual level, opportunity structures closely relate to mobilizing capacities of<br />

organizations, in particular organizational membership (Kaase 1990; Parry, Moyser <strong>and</strong><br />

Day 1992). Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels (1996: 2) refer to the organizational context of an<br />

individual as the close context. With respect to individual-level participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities this means: Embeddedness into an organizational context (in an<br />

association or an informal network) creates a favorable mobilization context, thus<br />

increasing the chances that a person participates in elite-challenging activities (cause<br />

dimension).<br />

Beyond the individual embeddedness into an organizational context, societal <strong>and</strong><br />

political factors can also serve as opportunity structures for political participation. Roller<br />

<strong>and</strong> Wessels (1996: 2) have defined these conditions as the wider context for<br />

participation. In particular, the institutional set-up in a country can create or impede<br />

opportunities for participation. A simple example is to differentiate between democratic<br />

<strong>and</strong> non-democratic types of political regimes – whether citizens have the opportunity to<br />

effectively participate depends on what participation means in a political system <strong>and</strong><br />

which functions it has. In addition, the time span people have experienced political <strong>and</strong><br />

civil rights, lowering the barrier for all kinds of political participation (Dahl 1975: 125).<br />

39


Within democratic systems, empirical studies on the performances of different types of<br />

democracies have repeatedly shown that institutional designs (such as parliamentary or<br />

presidential systems, majoritarian or consensus democracies) make a difference<br />

(Lijphart 1999; Linz <strong>and</strong> Valenzuela 1994). Studies on electoral behavior have shown<br />

that turnout also depends on design of electoral laws. Citizens in Australia <strong>and</strong> Belgium,<br />

for example, are faced with a peculiar form of electoral opportunity structure:<br />

compulsory voting (Franklin 2004). But also where voting is not m<strong>and</strong>atory, incentives<br />

for participating vary: In a majoritarian system like in the UK, it can be discouraging for<br />

a voter, having just one vote, to go to the polls, when this constituency has always been<br />

taken by one <strong>and</strong> the same party. In a proportional system, the voter has a greater chance<br />

to be represented in the election result, so this might stimulate electoral participation.<br />

The context factors shaped by the concrete design of political institutions could impact<br />

the level of elite-challenging activities in various ways: The choice for a specific<br />

electoral system <strong>and</strong> system of governance shapes the number <strong>and</strong> character of the<br />

relevant political actors, determining the conditions under which citizen action groups<br />

could gain influence. Another example is the guarantee <strong>and</strong> enforcement of freedom <strong>and</strong><br />

participation rights which lowers the entry barrier for participation, thus increasing<br />

participation in elite-challenging activities. The aggregate-level hypothesis to be tested<br />

is: Political conditions such as guaranteeing <strong>and</strong> enforcing freedom <strong>and</strong> participation<br />

rights, or the fact that a society spent a long time under democratic rule, lower the entry<br />

barriers for participation, thus increasing levels of elite-challenging activities (cause<br />

dimension).<br />

As argued before, not only political factors but also socioeconomic conditions should<br />

shape opportunity structures on a societal level. As processes of modernization <strong>and</strong><br />

postindustrialization progress, more resources (e.g. education, economic <strong>and</strong> social<br />

security, etc.) become available to the wider public. Increasing speed of information <strong>and</strong><br />

knowledge transfer as well as diversified communication structures offer people<br />

opportunities to activate these resources <strong>and</strong> translate them into action (Roller <strong>and</strong><br />

Wessels 1996: 25-26). As a consequence, elite-challenging activities should be more<br />

pronounced among societies with higher levels of socioeconomic conditions such as<br />

high GDP or high levels of tertiarization (cause dimension).<br />

40


For the design of an empirical participation studies the consideration of contextual<br />

factors in addition to individual characteristics has important implications. “Contextual<br />

theories of politics are inherently multi-level – they require cross-level inference – <strong>and</strong><br />

hence have consequences for the way in which politics is conceived as multiple levels of<br />

analysis <strong>and</strong> meaning” (Huckfeldt <strong>and</strong> Sprague 1993: 281). As a consequence, empirical<br />

analyses have to make sure that cross-level inferences can be modeled, using measures<br />

on multiple levels of analysis – not only for individual characteristics but also for the<br />

environment the individual is imbedded in. However, as important these context factors<br />

are, they have one important shortcoming. Due to the considerable stability of<br />

institutional arrangements creating an opportunity structure, this approach partly fails to<br />

explain variation over time.<br />

2.5 Crisis of <strong>Democracy</strong>: Government Overload <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities<br />

About 30 years ago, under the impression of upcoming, sometimes radical student <strong>and</strong><br />

worker protests, Croizier, Huntington <strong>and</strong> Watanuki (1975) published a highly debated<br />

report that drew a rather pessimistic picture of the future of democracy. As the core<br />

finding of their study, the authors argued that a “crisis of democracy” was troubling the<br />

trilateral democracies in the United States, Europe <strong>and</strong> Japan: that the democracies faced<br />

a government overload because citizens were displaying rising political dem<strong>and</strong>s<br />

towards their governments. As a consequence, widespread concerns with regard to the<br />

democracies’ governmentability capabilities were raised (Croizier, Huntington <strong>and</strong><br />

Watanuki 1975; see also Putnam, Pharr <strong>and</strong> Dalton 2000).<br />

“These challenges, we argued, were leading to the delegitimation of governmental<br />

authority, mounting political dem<strong>and</strong>s that pointed to the overloading of government,<br />

the fracturing <strong>and</strong> disaggregation of political parties <strong>and</strong> political purposes, <strong>and</strong><br />

intensified parochialism <strong>and</strong> disagreement among democracies on international issues”<br />

(Huntington 2000: xxiii-xxiv). The report outlined three general types of challenges: (1)<br />

contextual challenges (from the outside: security threats, oil price increases, etc.); (2)<br />

41


social trends (increasing power of popular movements, intellectuals, media, etc.); (3)<br />

intrinsic characteristics of democracy that contribute to its own weakening. Croizier,<br />

Huntington <strong>and</strong> Watanuki (1975) argued that democracies were confronted with citizens<br />

who increasingly challenged authority, called for a new political agenda <strong>and</strong> an<br />

expansion of participation rights, thus more <strong>and</strong> more overloading the political system<br />

with their persistent dem<strong>and</strong>s (see also Putnam, Pharr <strong>and</strong> Dalton 2000; Kaase <strong>and</strong><br />

Newton 1995). The aim of the study was, according to the authors, to restore the balance<br />

between democracy on the one h<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> governability on the other.<br />

As a response to the challenges, the authors suggested several counter measures to deal<br />

with the crisis, “including measures for promoting sustained economic growth <strong>and</strong> the<br />

reduction of poverty, strengthening executive <strong>and</strong> legislative institutions, reinvigorating<br />

political parties, restoring a more balanced relationship between government <strong>and</strong> media,<br />

slowing the expansion of higher education, achieving more participation of workers in<br />

the organization <strong>and</strong> management of the workplace, <strong>and</strong> creating a permanent Trilateral<br />

institute [...]“ (Huntington 2000: xxiv, own emphasis).<br />

Croizer, Huntington <strong>and</strong> Watanuki rightly name a number of serious challenges that<br />

trouble modern democracies until today - growing dissatisfaction <strong>and</strong> decreasing<br />

confidence in the functioning of democratic institutions. Some of their conclusions,<br />

however, are misleading <strong>and</strong> reflecting the authors’ suspicion of knowledgeable, welleducated,<br />

critical democratic citizens who, as a part of the dem<strong>and</strong>s, show an increasing<br />

intention to have a say <strong>and</strong> to question authority. By proposing to limit education<br />

because democracies should fear educated, mature, dem<strong>and</strong>ing citizens, Croizer,<br />

Huntington <strong>and</strong> Watanuki follow the Schumpeterian tradition of an elite-centered<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy that largely restricts the role of the individual citizen:<br />

“According to the view we have taken, democracy does not mean <strong>and</strong> cannot mean that<br />

the people actually rule in any obvious sense of the term “people” <strong>and</strong> “rule”.<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> means only that the people have the opportunity of accepting or refusing the<br />

men who are to rule them” (Schumpeter 1976: 270).<br />

For theorists like Schumpeter, participation by citizens has only played a marginal role.<br />

This approach goes h<strong>and</strong> in h<strong>and</strong> with a general mistrust towards ordinary citizens: “The<br />

electoral mass is incapable of action other than stampede” (Schumpeter 1942: 283). In<br />

42


general, political participation should be restricted to voting in elections every few<br />

years, where political parties <strong>and</strong> other actors are competing for citizens’ support. In<br />

between elections, people’s involvement is considered to be a rather disturbing, or even<br />

destabilizing, force, challenging the ‘division of labor’ between those who govern <strong>and</strong><br />

those who are governed. In Dahl’s minimal definition of democracy as “contestation<br />

open to participation” (Dahl 1971: 20), adherents of elite-centered approaches<br />

emphasize the competition (or contest) character of democracy, rather than the<br />

participation aspect. A rise of elite-challenging activism is therefore viewed as a threat<br />

for democracy, overburdening the political elites with dem<strong>and</strong>s from below. Thus, the<br />

hypothesis to be tested reads as follows: Rising levels of elite-challenging activities lead<br />

to government overload <strong>and</strong> overstressing of elites with dem<strong>and</strong>s from below, thus<br />

interfering with the democratic political process. <strong>Democracy</strong> suffers from high levels of<br />

elite-challenging action (consequence dimension).<br />

By contrast, the school of participatory democracy stresses the participation (or<br />

inclusion) aspect of democracy, emphasizing citizen involvement as the core idea of<br />

democracy’s ‘government by the people’. In this sense, only a participatory democracy<br />

can be a ‘strong’ democracy (Barber 1984; for an overview see Held 1996 <strong>and</strong> Pateman<br />

1970). This is not to say that these theorists consider today’s democracies to meet the<br />

ideal of participatory democracy. However, the important point is that citizens are<br />

offered various opportunities to take part (see already John Stewart Mill 1975 [1861])<br />

<strong>and</strong> that they are encouraged to use them. In modern democracies, there is a whole range<br />

of possibilities available for citizens to make their voices heard, ranging from writing<br />

letters or emails to politicians, joining campaign groups, signing petitions to attending<br />

demonstrations or public debates. In this sense, citizen participation is not just a<br />

‘necessary evil’ but an important <strong>and</strong> desirable feature of democracy.<br />

As a consequence of the two opposing approaches, interpretations vary with respect to<br />

levels <strong>and</strong> diversity of participation in democracies. In an elite-centered view, high<br />

levels <strong>and</strong> diversified forms of citizen involvement are considered as a threat to<br />

governmentability <strong>and</strong>, thus, to the stability of democracy. As empirical evidence for<br />

declining confidence in government <strong>and</strong> political institutions in general accumulates<br />

(Pharr <strong>and</strong> Putnam 2000), this concern is nourished: Distrust may spill over into a<br />

43


deeper dissatisfaction with the democratic process, leading to decreasing support for<br />

democracy <strong>and</strong> a serious challenge for democratic legitimacy (Easton 1965, 1975;<br />

Norris 1999b).<br />

By contrast, adherents of a participatory democracy should regard high levels <strong>and</strong> an<br />

extended repertoire of participation forms as conducive for democracy, for these<br />

activities are a sign of an alert, critical public that dem<strong>and</strong> honest, transparent <strong>and</strong><br />

accountable elite behavior. Along similar lines, the rise of critical citizens (Norris<br />

1999a) or dissatisfied democrats (Klingemann 1999: 32), who “clearly approve of<br />

democracy as a mode of governance, but (…) are discontented with the way their own<br />

system is currently operating” (ibid.) is seen as a potential for reforms <strong>and</strong><br />

improvements of democratic procedures, not as their death knell. The counter hypothesis<br />

to be tested against the Huntington et al. claim is: Rising levels of elite-challenging<br />

activities are an indication for a critical public that calls for accountable elite behavior.<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> benefits from high levels of elite-challenging action (consequence<br />

dimension).<br />

3. Hypotheses<br />

What are the dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging activities? To<br />

answer this question, testable hypotheses are needed. To generate these hypotheses I<br />

drew on a number of theoretical approaches on political participation <strong>and</strong> societal<br />

change in general <strong>and</strong> applied them on elite-challenging activities in particular. Not all<br />

hypotheses can be tested on all three dimensions, as the theories they originate from<br />

differ in the way they relate to <strong>and</strong> allow for conclusions about the dynamics, causes,<br />

<strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging activities. Along similar lines, some of the<br />

approaches are better suited for propositions at the individual level, whereas others refer<br />

to the societal level, or to both. The different theoretical approaches are of course<br />

interlinked. Organizational changes, for example, are a direct outcome of a value change<br />

towards more emancipative values. The fact that these hierarchical mass organizations<br />

face a significant decline in their memberships has, in turn, direct consequences for their<br />

44


mobilization capacity. As these organizations act as mobilizing agents – be it in a<br />

personal or in a societal context – fewer opportunities are created for citizens to become<br />

active. As a consequence, participation levels should decline.<br />

In the following, a systematic overview about the hypotheses will be given, concluding<br />

with a summarizing table.<br />

Modernization, value change, <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities<br />

In a simplified form, the cultural variant of modernization suggests that socioeconomic<br />

development has important consequences for the values people hold, in particular the<br />

way they orient themselves towards authorities. Rising self expression or emancipative<br />

values facilitate elite-challenging activities, which in turn have pro-democracy<br />

consequences. The cultural variant of modernization theory leads to the following<br />

hypotheses with regard to dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of elite-challenging<br />

activities:<br />

Hypotheses on the individual level:<br />

(1) Younger citizens <strong>and</strong> those with higher emancipative values are more actively<br />

participating in demonstrations, petitions <strong>and</strong> political consumerism (cause dimension).<br />

Hypotheses on the aggregate level:<br />

(2a) As a consequences of progressing postindustrialization, an increase in the overall<br />

level of elite-challenging activities can be observed (dynamics dimension).<br />

(2b) Societies with higher socioeconomic development show higher levels of elitechallenging<br />

activities (cause dimension).<br />

(3) As elite-challenging activities push for responsible <strong>and</strong> transparent elite behavior,<br />

thus limiting the abuse of entrusted power, the quality of democracy improves with<br />

higher levels of elite-challenging activities (consequence dimension).<br />

Organizational changes, social capital <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities<br />

Theories on organizational changes <strong>and</strong> social capital suggest that traditional mobilizing<br />

agents such as political parties, labor unions or churches are becoming less important.<br />

As a consequence, political <strong>and</strong> social participation are negatively affected, social<br />

capital <strong>and</strong> civic activism in general is in decline. As traditional agents are seen as<br />

45


“schools of democracy”, a decline of their importance <strong>and</strong> membership has negative<br />

consequences for democracy. The rise of elite-challenging activities is not seen as a<br />

countertrend to this development. Here, adherents of an emancipative values change<br />

contradict (see previous paragraph): Elite-challenging activities, as any other form of<br />

community involvement, are a result of prevailing social capital. The rise of elitechallenging<br />

activities has positive consequences for democracy.<br />

Hypotheses on the individual level:<br />

(1) The rise of elite-challenging activities goes at the expense of participation in<br />

traditional forms of participation: Citizens participating in elite-challenging activities<br />

abstain from engagement through traditional channels (cause dimension).<br />

(2) <strong>Participation</strong> in elite-challenging activities is a result of social capital: embeddedness<br />

in networks <strong>and</strong> trust (cause dimension).<br />

Hypotheses on the aggregate level:<br />

(3) There is a “gradual but widespread process of civic disengagement” (Putnam <strong>and</strong><br />

Goss 2002: 4), including forms of elite-challenging activities (dynamics dimension).<br />

(4) In societies in which elite-challenging activities are widespread, participation in<br />

traditional forms of participation should be low (cause dimension).<br />

(5) Diverging trends: As elite-challenging activities are becoming more widespread over<br />

time, we observe a decrease in institutionalized, traditional forms of political<br />

participation (dynamics dimension).<br />

(6) Elite-challenging activities as individualized activities have a negative impact on<br />

democracy (consequence dimension).<br />

Resources, motivation <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities<br />

Resources <strong>and</strong> motivation as refer to the classical determinants approach in political<br />

participation, including the SES (Socio-Economic Status) model of political activity.<br />

How the distribution of resources <strong>and</strong> motivation affects elite-challenging participation<br />

is closely linked to the question of political equality. The hypotheses only refer to the<br />

individual level.<br />

Hypotheses on the individual level:<br />

46


(1) Resources: Participants in elite-challenging activities are young, better educated <strong>and</strong><br />

have a higher income (cause dimension).<br />

(2) Motivation: Participants in elite-challenging activities are politically interested,<br />

dissatisfied <strong>and</strong> show more pronounced feelings of political efficacy (cause dimension).<br />

(3) <strong>Participation</strong> in elite-challenging activities is stronger determined by an unequal<br />

distribution of resources <strong>and</strong> motivation than other forms of participation, thus<br />

contributing to a manifestation of political inequality (consequence dimension).<br />

Opportunity structures <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities<br />

This approach acknowledges that participation in elite-challenging activities is not only<br />

driven by the resources <strong>and</strong> motivation of an individual citizen, but develops as a result<br />

of his/her interaction with the environment. Opportunity structures for elite-challenging<br />

activities can be created at the individual <strong>and</strong> at the societal level.<br />

Hypotheses on the individual level:<br />

(1) Embeddedness into an organizational context (in an association or an informal<br />

network) creates a mobilization context, thus increasing the chances that a person<br />

participates in elite-challenging activities (cause dimension).<br />

Hypotheses on the aggregate level:<br />

(2) Socioeconomic conditions such as high GDP or high levels of tertiarization provide<br />

favorable conditions for elite-challenging participation (cause dimension).<br />

(3) Political conditions such as guaranteeing <strong>and</strong> enforcing freedom <strong>and</strong> participation<br />

rights, or the fact that a society spent a long time under democratic rule, lower the entry<br />

barriers for participation, thus increasing levels of elite-challenging activities (cause<br />

dimension).<br />

47


Table 3-1:<br />

Summary of Hypotheses<br />

Theoretical<br />

Approach<br />

Dimension<br />

<strong>Dynamics</strong><br />

in elite-challenging<br />

activities<br />

<strong>Causes</strong>/determinants<br />

of elite-challenging<br />

activities<br />

Consequences<br />

of elite-challenging<br />

activities<br />

Modernization <strong>and</strong> Value<br />

Change<br />

Increase<br />

(1) Self expression<br />

values, pro-democratic<br />

orientations, youth<br />

(positive)<br />

Positive impact on<br />

democracy<br />

(2) Postindustrialization<br />

(positive)<br />

Organizational Changes<br />

<strong>and</strong> Social Capital<br />

Decrease /<br />

Increase<br />

(1) Social capital:<br />

networks <strong>and</strong> trust<br />

(positive);<br />

Negative impact on<br />

democracy<br />

(2) Traditional forms of<br />

political participation<br />

(negative)<br />

Resources <strong>and</strong> Motivation<br />

--<br />

(1) Resources: young <strong>and</strong><br />

high-skilled citizens<br />

(positive)<br />

Increasing political<br />

inequality<br />

(2) Motivation: political<br />

interest, dissatisfaction,<br />

efficacy (positive)<br />

Opportunity Structures<br />

--<br />

(1) Close context for<br />

mobilization:<br />

organizational<br />

membership (positive)<br />

--<br />

(2) Wider context for<br />

mobilization: political<br />

<strong>and</strong> economic conditions<br />

(positive)<br />

Crisis of <strong>Democracy</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

Government Overload<br />

--<br />

Non-democratic<br />

orientations<br />

Crisis of democracy<br />

Crisis of democracy: Government overload <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities<br />

The government overload debate centers on the question what kind of consequences the<br />

exp<strong>and</strong>ed action repertoire of citizens in today’s representative democracies has.<br />

Depending on their stance in democratic theory, elite-challenging activities are either<br />

seen as a threat or as an asset for democracy.<br />

48


Hypotheses on the aggregate level:<br />

(1) Rising levels of elite-challenging activities lead to government overload <strong>and</strong><br />

overstressing of elites with dem<strong>and</strong>s from below, thus interfering with the democratic<br />

political process. <strong>Democracy</strong> suffers from high levels of elite-challenging action<br />

(consequence dimension).<br />

As a counter hypothesis:<br />

(2) Rising levels of elite-challenging activities are an indication for a critical public that<br />

calls for accountable elite behavior. <strong>Democracy</strong> benefits from high levels of elitechallenging<br />

action (consequence dimension).<br />

Table 3-1 summarizes the hypotheses according to their explanatory power for the three<br />

dimensions under consideration: dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of elitechallenging<br />

activities.<br />

Before continuing to testing the hypotheses, the following chapter presents the<br />

methodological background of the study <strong>and</strong> introduces the data <strong>and</strong> measurement.<br />

49


B<br />

METHODS AND DATA<br />

4. Methodological Background, Data <strong>and</strong> Measures<br />

In order to systematically examine the dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong> consequences of elitechallenging<br />

activities, this study adopts a comparative research design. It covers a large<br />

number of countries, aiming to find recognizable, general patterns in elite-challenging<br />

activities. It follows the assumption “that human or social behavior can be explained in<br />

term of general laws established by observation” (Przeworski/Teune 1970: 4). 12 For<br />

several reasons, comparative cross-national studies are essential for social science theory<br />

building: They a) help to formulate clear <strong>and</strong> culturally salient concepts; b) allow to<br />

cover the largest possible variation in the dependent <strong>and</strong> independent variable(s), which<br />

means that several potential factors are included in the analysis, <strong>and</strong> help, therefore, c) to<br />

determine the generality of a finding (Warwick <strong>and</strong> Osherson 1973: 8). Cross-national<br />

studies enable us to assess whether a postulated relationship (that might be based on an<br />

individual case) is also valid across national boundaries: “General theories of why<br />

people participate in democratic politics should apply to citizens regardless of their<br />

nationality” (Dalton 2002: 3). This is of course also true for the consequence dimension<br />

of elite-challenging activities. So, only by taking up a comparative perspective, it is<br />

possible to draw general conclusions <strong>and</strong> to distinguish factors that are system-specific<br />

from those ones that can claim to be universal (Warwick <strong>and</strong> Osherson 1973: vi).<br />

Among the five types of comparative studies that Peters (1998: 10) distinguishes, this<br />

study on elite-challenging activities falls into the fifth category: statistical analyses<br />

testing relationships or developing patterns across a whole range of countries. 13<br />

12 Such comparative observation can address more than one social system (“synchronous comparison”), or<br />

the same social system at more than one point in time (“diachronous comparison”), or a combination of<br />

both (Warwick <strong>and</strong> Osherson 1973: 8; Schmidt 1995: 1001).<br />

13 The first four types of comparative research are: (1) single case study; description of politics in a<br />

country, region, etc.; (2) limited number of countries, selected for analytical reasons; analysis of similar<br />

processes, institutions, etc.; (3) typologies or classification schemes; typologies for analyzing single<br />

country’s internal politics as well as for comparisons of country groups; (4) statistical analysis for a<br />

subgroup of the world’s countries; testing of hypotheses for sub-sample.<br />

50


To measure participation in elite-challenging challenging activities, survey data are used<br />

as the main source of information on reported political participation. Before presenting<br />

the comparative survey data sets, the criteria for country selection will be explained.<br />

Finally, the measures for elite-challenging action are introduced, as they provide the<br />

basis for the subsequent empirical analyses.<br />

4.1 Survey Research <strong>and</strong> Alternative Ways to Measure <strong>Participation</strong><br />

To test the hypotheses developed in Chapter 3, participation data are required both on<br />

the individual <strong>and</strong> on the aggregate level. These types of information are best<br />

represented in cross-national survey programs. How can elite-challenging participation<br />

be measured?<br />

Measuring means, in a nutshell, to assign numbers to objects according to certain rules<br />

(Stevens 1946), <strong>and</strong> for social scientists this process is almost never free of problems.<br />

Accordingly, measuring elite-challenging political action is not a straightforward thing<br />

to do, <strong>and</strong> any method of quantifying political participation has its benefits <strong>and</strong> flaws<br />

(Parry, Moyser <strong>and</strong> Day 1992: 31). Besides methods like participant observation, indepth<br />

interviews with participants or activists, or using event data as a source of<br />

information, research on political activism can also be based on survey data.<br />

St<strong>and</strong>ardized surveys allow for the collection, processing <strong>and</strong> analysis of mass data,<br />

covering a considerable time span. Looking at the social science literature, Brady (1999:<br />

742) distinguishes three survey approaches “to get ordinary citizens to provide valid<br />

reports of their political activities”. Besides a) the study of institutions <strong>and</strong> organization<br />

where action might occur 14 , <strong>and</strong> b) the identification of problems that might lead to<br />

14 The institutions approach follows the assumption that participation is usually a group activity. Survey<br />

questions about the respondent’s work life, church life, family life, etc. are followed by questions about<br />

specific activities (contacted officials, etc.) as part of the group activity. It is almost unnecessary to point<br />

out that this form of surveying is highly time-consuming <strong>and</strong> might be inattentive to forms of engagement<br />

outside voluntary organizations.<br />

51


participation 15 , the most prominent approach is simple <strong>and</strong> direct: c) to ask people<br />

whether they have participated in a particular form of activity or not.<br />

The main idea to use surveys for information on elite-challenging activities is to focus<br />

on those who are actually taking part in various forms of political activities - the people<br />

- <strong>and</strong> to use their reports as a source for immediate information, because: “If one is<br />

interested in finding out what a person thinks or believes one had better asked directly”<br />

(Esmer 2004: 385). In addition, the results based on representative sample allow for a, of<br />

course always careful, generalization <strong>and</strong> inference from the sample to the larger<br />

population (Parry, Moyser <strong>and</strong> Day 1992: 31).<br />

By contrast, early studies on violent forms of political protest (Gurr 1970) have mainly<br />

relied on event data, derived from reports in diverse media formats (newspapers,<br />

journals, TV, etc.). The integration of protest as a subject of study into the field of social<br />

movement research has added to the increasing popularity of content analyses of media<br />

reports (Rucht <strong>and</strong> Ohlemacher 1992). During the past decades, the use of newspaper<br />

data has not only contributed to the theorizing of collective action but has also enabled<br />

researchers to conduct empirical studies. For a number of historical research questions<br />

where alternative sources are hardly available, newspaper articles are sometimes the<br />

only source of historical data. 16 However, due to resource limitations truly comparative<br />

studies are rare. A counter example is the impressive data collection on political protest<br />

in 136 countries (1948-1977) for several volumes of the World H<strong>and</strong>book (Russet et al.<br />

1964; Taylor <strong>and</strong> Hudson 1972; Taylor <strong>and</strong> Jodice 1983). Another cross-national<br />

research project was conducted by Kriesi <strong>and</strong> others (Rucht <strong>and</strong> Ohlemacher 1992;<br />

Kriesi et al. 1995; Dekker, Koopmans <strong>and</strong> van den Broek 1997; for an overview about<br />

the analysis of protest event data, see Rucht, Koopmans <strong>and</strong> Neidhardt 1998), analyzing<br />

political protest in Germany, France, Great Britain, the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Spain between<br />

1977 <strong>and</strong> 1989. Focusing on developments in the context of New Social Movements, the<br />

15 The problems approach follows the assumption that people must have concerns, worries or needs in<br />

order to get involved. The survey questions are formulated in such a way that the respondents are asked<br />

about issues that are important to them, <strong>and</strong> afterwards whether they have become active in order to<br />

articulate their concern. The goal is to establish direct link between motivation <strong>and</strong> action.<br />

16 Collecting event data is very resource intensive <strong>and</strong>, in particular, time-consuming, especially when the<br />

data are intended to cover a longer time span. Examples of such hard-work endeavors can be found in<br />

Charles Tilly’s work on France or Great Britain (Tilly 1978; 1986; 1995), Sidney Tarrow’s research on<br />

Italy (Tarrow 1989), or Dieter Rucht’s work on Germany (Rucht 2001).<br />

52


authors have demonstrated how a comparative approach can be applied in a large-scale<br />

project based on media reports in several countries. 17<br />

However, aiming at dynamics of protests, this approach focuses on a protest event or a<br />

series of events as the unit(s) of analysis. 18 The information that can be gathered from<br />

media reports is usually not very detailed <strong>and</strong> restricted to the individual event (Rucht<br />

<strong>and</strong> Ohlemacher 1992: 77). Thus, media reports concentrate on an event as the unit of<br />

analysis, <strong>and</strong> this focus may not suit all research questions addressing scope <strong>and</strong> changes<br />

in political behavior. In particular, the fact that media-reported events provide only little<br />

information about the individuals who are participating appears to be a major drawback<br />

of this approach.<br />

In comparison to alternative ways to gain knowledge about people’s attitudes <strong>and</strong><br />

behavior, asking people directly whether they have participation in elite-challenging<br />

activities appears to be the most fruitful approach. In contrast to measures of<br />

institutionalized participation, information about spontaneous <strong>and</strong> irregular political<br />

activities cannot be obtained through official data collections about membership rates or<br />

the number of participants (an exception might be when the number of participants is<br />

estimated by police officials). Official statistics exist, for example, only for voter<br />

turnout, very often broken down to levels of national, regional <strong>and</strong> local elections. Their<br />

advantage is, in most cases, that the data are quite reliable <strong>and</strong> easily accessible. 19 Also<br />

available for a number of cases but less precise are membership figures for political<br />

parties or labor unions. However, for elite-challenging participation this is not an option,<br />

given the short-term, issue-specific, transient <strong>and</strong> irregular nature of this activity. As a<br />

consequence, the subsequent empirical analyses on elite-challenging participation will<br />

be based on data provided by cross-national surveys.<br />

Survey research has often been criticized for various reasons that I will not outline here<br />

in detail, <strong>and</strong> it also did not escape criticism when applied to measure participation.<br />

Three major points of critique as well as suggestions on how to deal with these problems<br />

17 The research project was coordinated at the Science Centre in Berlin, Germany (Wissenschaftszentrum<br />

Berlin, WZB).<br />

18 „A protest event is defined as a distinct collective action pursuing an explicit goal by the use of<br />

confrontative, disruptive or violent means“ (Rucht <strong>and</strong> Ohlemacher 1992: 77).<br />

53


are discussed in the following section. Basically all of them address the question of<br />

reliability with respect to the information that respondents provide during a st<strong>and</strong>ardized<br />

survey.<br />

First, one of the difficulties in measuring political activism can be attributed to the<br />

differences between attitudes <strong>and</strong> behavior. Whereas people’s attitudes are rather stable<br />

<strong>and</strong> can, therefore, more easily be measured at one point in timed, people’s participation<br />

in political action is seldom an activity that people engage in with steady enthusiasm <strong>and</strong><br />

dedication (Brady 1999: 741). Because of its rather spontaneous <strong>and</strong> irregular character,<br />

this is even more true for elite-challenging action. Since the respondents are asked to<br />

report about their behavior that lies in the past, people’s memory can be another<br />

potential source of error. Tulving (1983) speaks here about a respondent’s “episodic<br />

memory” (as distinct from the “semantic memory”).<br />

Second, survey-based research plays a crucial role in the empirical study of social<br />

behavior (Niedermayer 1997: 89). However, for studies that cover a considerate number<br />

of nations, questions of measurement, comparability <strong>and</strong> equivalence become important<br />

(van Deth 1998a, 1998b; Peters 1998: 209). Inglehart, too, points out that comparative<br />

research, in particular survey research, is dispensable if the problem that given words<br />

have comparable meanings in different societies is not satisfyingly solved (Inglehart<br />

1998).<br />

There has been a tendency in survey research to shift the focus on comparable measures<br />

away from a claim for identity, to a claim for (functional) equivalence (Allerbeck 1977;<br />

van Deth 1998a). In short, equivalence refers to a characteristic that two phenomena<br />

have in common with respect to their value, their use or their function. The similarity<br />

here does not refer to all characteristics but rather to those ones that are of importance<br />

<strong>and</strong> relevance for the research interest (van Deth 1998a: 5). Considering the wide range<br />

of societies <strong>and</strong> cultures included for example in the World Values Survey, questions of<br />

general validity <strong>and</strong> cross-cultural equivalence are of great importance for such<br />

comparative projects.<br />

There are ways to cope with the problem of equivalence. After decades of cross-cultural<br />

research, a good deal of knowledge has accumulated on how to conduct surveys in<br />

19 For example, by using data from IDEA: www.idea.org .<br />

54


different countries <strong>and</strong> languages. Extensive pilot studies <strong>and</strong> pre-tests additionally help<br />

to ensure that questions have a shared meaning to the respondents. In a survey project<br />

that involves several countries, also a close cooperation with national researchers is<br />

essential. In case of the World Values Surveys, most of the principal investigators in a<br />

participating country come from <strong>and</strong> work in the respective country where the survey is<br />

conducted. With their in-depth knowledge about cultural particularities, they are also<br />

responsible for the back-translation of the questionnaire. This st<strong>and</strong>ard method ensures<br />

that the given words <strong>and</strong> questions show as much cross-cultural equivalence as possible.<br />

Another strategy to ensure that questions are meaningful to respondents (whatever their<br />

background is) to increase the level of abstraction: More general questions are preferred<br />

to questions that address a very specific situation (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Caballo 1997; van Deth<br />

1998a; Inglehart 1998).<br />

After the survey data are collected, there are additional methods to validate the quality<br />

of the data. An attempt to check for internal validation can include tests for internal<br />

consistency (e.g. the structure of an item battery), stability over time or correlations with<br />

other attitudes or socio-economic characteristics. Besides analyzing the structures or<br />

crystallization of answers given by respondents in different societies, there are attempts<br />

to externally validate results. This can be done by correlating the data with external data<br />

on the aggregate level, or by confirming the results through independent observation (or<br />

written report) of activity.<br />

All attempts to ensure cross-cultural equivalence notwithst<strong>and</strong>ing, it needs to be noted<br />

that “[g]iven words almost never mean the same thing in different settings or different<br />

languages” (Inglehart 1998). However, this is not an exclusive problem of comparative,<br />

cross-national research. There is no guarantee that a given question will mean the same<br />

to people within one society, not even within the same city. “This line of reasoning can<br />

easily lead us to the position that since no two individuals’ cognitive processes are<br />

identical, a question cannot be st<strong>and</strong>ardized even for two persons in the same<br />

household” (Esmer 2004: 387). Since this is not an option for social scientists interested<br />

in profound relationships <strong>and</strong> general patterns, cross-cultural cooperation seems to be a<br />

promising way to deal with the challenge of equivalence.<br />

55


4.2 Country Selection<br />

The following empirical analyses will be focusing on democracies. Selection criterion is<br />

how the Freedom House Organization assesses a country’s compliance with political<br />

<strong>and</strong> civil rights.<br />

Since 1972, the yearly “Freedom in the World” report informs about basic political,<br />

social <strong>and</strong> economic developments in the countries of the world. As its main task, the<br />

nonprofit organization monitors the countries’ compliance with two essential parts of<br />

freedom: political rights <strong>and</strong> civil liberties. 20 The information is collected through expert<br />

surveys <strong>and</strong> then presented in a st<strong>and</strong>ardized form. Political rights are assessed by<br />

evaluating the electoral process (free <strong>and</strong> fair elections), presence or absence of political<br />

pluralism <strong>and</strong> participation opportunities, functioning of government <strong>and</strong> protection of<br />

minority rights in a country. Freedom of expression <strong>and</strong> belief, the right to form an<br />

association <strong>and</strong> organization, compliance with the rule of law as well as the guarantee of<br />

personal autonomy <strong>and</strong> individual rights are among the st<strong>and</strong>ards for evaluating civil<br />

liberties. 21 The measurement of freedom is based on the two scales, ranging between 1<br />

<strong>and</strong> 7, with 1 meeting the highest st<strong>and</strong>ards (=highest level of freedom) <strong>and</strong> 7 failing to<br />

meet the st<strong>and</strong>ards (=lowest level of freedom). An average value for the two scales is<br />

calculated, indicating whether a country can be classified as “free” (average of 1 to 2.5),<br />

“partly free” (average of 3 to 5.0) or “not free” (average of 5.5 to 7). 22 According to the<br />

Freedom House index, free <strong>and</strong> partly free countries qualify as electoral democracies. 23<br />

Since its beginning, Freedom House has documented both an enormous increase in the<br />

number of independent states <strong>and</strong>, most importantly, a substantial spread of freedom <strong>and</strong><br />

democracy around the world (Karatnycky 2003: 100). Parallel to this development,<br />

Freedom House itself has made an impressive career in the social sciences. After the<br />

breakdown of communist regimes <strong>and</strong> the presumed victory of democracy <strong>and</strong> the rule<br />

20 In 2008, “Freedom in the World” covered 193 countries <strong>and</strong> 15 related <strong>and</strong> disputed territories. For<br />

detailed information, see www.freedomhouse.org .<br />

21 For a detailed list of the criteria applied by Freedom House, see Appendix A4-2.<br />

22 Until 2003, countries with average ratings between 1.0 <strong>and</strong> 2,5 were considered “free”; between 3.0 <strong>and</strong><br />

5.5 “partly free” <strong>and</strong> between 5.5 <strong>and</strong> 7.0 “not free.”<br />

56


of law, scholars became more <strong>and</strong> more interested in the quality of democracy. Together<br />

with the concern to find reliable <strong>and</strong> valid empirical assessments for democracy <strong>and</strong><br />

democratization (for overview <strong>and</strong> discussion, see among others Beetham 1994;<br />

Vanhanen 1997; 2000; Bollen <strong>and</strong> Paxton 2000; Lauth, Pickel <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2000;<br />

Schmidt 2000; Munck <strong>and</strong> Verkuilen 2002; Berg-Schlosser 2002), this interest has<br />

contributed to the emergence of a new <strong>and</strong> young discipline – measuring democracy<br />

(Lauth 2003: 2). In this context, Freedom House has become a widely accepted <strong>and</strong><br />

frequently used source for empirical comparative studies. 24<br />

Strictly speaking, Freedom House is not aiming at assessing the quality of democracy<br />

but of political rights <strong>and</strong> civil liberties (Gastil 1991; Karatnycky 1999). However, these<br />

two scales cover central elements of democracy, such as prevailing political liberties <strong>and</strong><br />

equality, or political <strong>and</strong> judicial control (Lauth 2003: 4). Moreover, the scales are<br />

designed to evaluate not only the constitutional requirement but also how these given<br />

rights <strong>and</strong> rules work in reality on a day-to-day basis (Schmidt 2000: 409; Karatnycky<br />

2003: 102).<br />

According to the earlier definition, political participation needs to be a voluntary<br />

activity. Consequently, there is an obvious reason to limit the study on elite-challenging<br />

action to countries that adhere to fundamental democratic rules. Democracies are similar<br />

in the basic functioning of the democratic process <strong>and</strong> the role that is given to citizens<br />

within this process. The opportunity to articulate own interests <strong>and</strong> to participate at<br />

one’s own discretion is the mechanism that links people to the political system <strong>and</strong><br />

constantly contributes to its democratic legitimacy. Only this mechanism ensures that<br />

political decisions can, in principle, be traced back to people’s will. If this is not the<br />

case, mass participation serves a fundamentally different purpose (like for example in<br />

authoritarian or totalitarian regimes). Levels of participation can hardly be interpreted in<br />

a meaningful way. Voter turnout, for example, has been highest in communist countries<br />

with non-competitive elections where people did not experience electoral freedom<br />

(Nohlen 2002, chapter 1). Along similar lines, non-democratic regimes have frequently<br />

23 Freedom House formulated additional criteria for electoral democracies. They can be found in<br />

Appendix A4-1.<br />

57


used the image of mobilized masses participating in demonstrations, military parades or<br />

similar ways, in order to display the own strength <strong>and</strong> superiority. Mass mobilization<br />

<strong>and</strong> participation can be a characteristic of non-democratic regimes, especially of leftwing<br />

authoritarianism (Dickersen <strong>and</strong> Flanagan 2002, chapter 19). Therefore, also from<br />

a methodic point, information about how many people participated cannot be considered<br />

as a reliable measure.<br />

The focus on democracies follows also another rationale: Non-democracies do not allow<br />

for this mixture of elite-challenging yet system-supporting participation which is unique<br />

to democracies.<br />

The second limitation of the study comes from the availability of survey data. To be<br />

sure, the choice of cases for analysis must follow theoretical considerations. But reality<br />

shows that the availability of data presents a serious constraint for the researcher.<br />

Thanks to the World Values Survey group, the availability of survey data has<br />

tremendously improved over the past 30 years. For a number of countries, the World<br />

Values Surveys are the only available source of information about people’s attitudes,<br />

beliefs <strong>and</strong> values. For reasons outlined before, the succeeding analyses will be limited<br />

to those countries that meet basic requirements of granting human rights <strong>and</strong> liberties.<br />

Table 4-1 gives an overview about all cases relevant for analysis. It documents for each<br />

society whether it was included in one of the surveys of the three survey projects:<br />

Political Action Study, World Values Survey/European Values Survey <strong>and</strong> European<br />

Social Survey. If a society was covered by a survey, it is marked “x”. Surveys that did<br />

not include questions about elite-challenging activities were not considered - they<br />

contain other very interesting variables but the dependent variable is not reproducible.<br />

This applies to China in all EVS/WVS waves, Hungary in the first wave (1982),<br />

Romania in the second wave (1990), <strong>and</strong> Iran <strong>and</strong> Hong Kong in the fifth wave (2005).<br />

24 This implies by no means that the Freedom House index has escaped criticism. For an critical<br />

discussion, see Bollen <strong>and</strong> Paxton (2000); Schmidt (2000: 408-413); Lauth (2003) <strong>and</strong> Munck <strong>and</strong><br />

Verkuilen (2002).<br />

58


Table 4-1: Democratic Societies Included in the Survey Projects: Political Action<br />

Study (PA), World Values Survey/European Values Survey (WVS/EVS)<br />

<strong>and</strong> European Social Survey (ESS)<br />

PA WVS/EVS ESS<br />

1974 1980-81 1990-91 1995-97 1999-01 2005-07 2002/04<br />

Australia x x x<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> x x<br />

United States x x x x x x<br />

Canada x x x x<br />

Andorra<br />

x<br />

Austria x x x x/x<br />

Belgium x x x x/x<br />

Denmark x x x x/x<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> x x x x x x x/x<br />

France x x x x x/x<br />

Great Britain x x x x x x/x<br />

Greece x x/x<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> x x x 0/x<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> x x x x/x<br />

Italy x x x x x x/x<br />

Luxembourg x x/x<br />

Malta<br />

x<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s x x x x x x/x<br />

N. Irel<strong>and</strong> x x x x/x<br />

Norway x x x x x/x<br />

Portugal x x x/x<br />

Spain x x x x x x/x<br />

Sweden x x x x x x/x<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> x x x x x/x<br />

W. Germany x x x x x x x/x<br />

Albania x x<br />

Armenia<br />

x<br />

Azerbaijan<br />

x<br />

Belarus x x (x)<br />

Bosnia-Her. x x<br />

Bulgaria x x x x<br />

Croatia x x<br />

Cyprus<br />

x<br />

Czech Rep. x x x x/x<br />

Georgia<br />

x<br />

E. Germany x x x x x/x<br />

Estonia x x x 0/x<br />

Hungary x x x x/x<br />

Latvia x x x<br />

Lithuania x x x<br />

Macedonia x x<br />

Moldova x x x<br />

Montenegro (x) x<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> x x x x x/x<br />

Romania x x x<br />

Russia x x x x<br />

Serbia (x) x x<br />

59


PA WVS/EVS ESS<br />

1974 1980-81 1990-91 1995-97 1999-01 2005-07 2002/04<br />

Slovakia x x x 0/x<br />

Slovenia x x x x x/x<br />

Ukraine x x x 0/x<br />

Bangladesh x x<br />

China<br />

(x)<br />

Hong Kong<br />

India x x x x<br />

Indonesia x x<br />

Israel x x/0<br />

Japan x x x x x<br />

Malaysia<br />

x<br />

Pakistan x (x)<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong><br />

x<br />

Turkey x x x x<br />

Philippines x x<br />

Singapore<br />

x<br />

South Korea x x x x x<br />

Taiwan x x<br />

Vietnam (x) (x)<br />

Algeria<br />

(x)<br />

Burkina Faso<br />

x<br />

Egypt (x) (x)<br />

Ethiopia<br />

x<br />

Ghana<br />

x<br />

Iraq<br />

(x)<br />

Iran<br />

(x)<br />

Jordan x x<br />

Mali<br />

x<br />

Morocco x x<br />

Nigeria x (x) x<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a<br />

(x)<br />

South Africa x x x x x<br />

Tanzania<br />

x<br />

Trinidad & Tobago<br />

x<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a<br />

x<br />

Zambia<br />

x<br />

Argentina x x x x x<br />

Brazil x x x<br />

Chile x x x x<br />

Colombia x x<br />

Dom. Republic<br />

x<br />

El Salvador<br />

(x)<br />

Guatemala<br />

x<br />

Mexico x x x x x<br />

Peru x x x<br />

Uruguay x x<br />

Venezuela x x<br />

Kyrgyzstan<br />

(x)<br />

Zimbabwe<br />

(x)<br />

x indicates that the country will be included in the analyses. (x) indicates that the country will be excluded<br />

from analysis. 0 indicates that the country was not included in one of the rounds of the ESS.<br />

60


The empirical analyses exclude societies Freedom House considered as “not free” in the<br />

year before, during <strong>and</strong> after the survey was conducted. 25 In Table 4-1, brackets “(x)”<br />

mark that a survey was not considered for analysis. The Freedom House ratings 1981-<br />

2008 for all societies included in the surveys can be found in Appendix A4-3.<br />

4.3 Data Sets <strong>and</strong> Measures of Elite-Challenging Behavior<br />

The succeeding empirical analyses will be based on data from different cross-cultural<br />

survey projects, so the following section is dedicated to briefly introduce the various<br />

survey data sets. Each of them holds different strengths. Indicators assessing individual<br />

participation in elite-challenging activities that go farthest back in time can be found in<br />

the studies conducted within the Political Action Project. One advantage of the project<br />

(<strong>and</strong> its data) is it was conducted as an explicit participation study, designed “as a<br />

substantial cross-national attempt to underst<strong>and</strong> the nature of political participation in<br />

advanced industrial democracies in the 1970ies” (Barnes 2004: 2).<br />

Political Action Study<br />

As a response to the student movements <strong>and</strong> emergence of new forms of citizens’<br />

involvement, the Political Action Project was designed to underst<strong>and</strong> the changing<br />

nature of political participation in Western democracies of the 1970ies.<br />

The major cross-national Political Action Study was conducted between 1973 <strong>and</strong> 1976,<br />

covering eight countries: Austria, Great Britain, Finl<strong>and</strong>, Italy, West Germany, the<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the United States. Empirical results of that first Political<br />

Action Study were published in Barnes, Kaase et al. (1979: “Political Action. Mass<br />

<strong>Participation</strong> in Five Western Democracies”). 26 Between 1979 <strong>and</strong> 1981 a second study<br />

followed in three of the eight original countries (West Germany, the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> the<br />

25 Detailed information about when the fieldwork was conducted can be obtained from World Values<br />

Survey Association website: www.worldvaluessurvey.org .<br />

61


US). The follow-up project, looking at “Continuities in Political Action” (Jennings <strong>and</strong><br />

van Deth et al. 1990), replicated the measures introduced in the earlier survey. The<br />

second Political Action Study was implemented in such a way that it had a crossnational<br />

survey with a supplementary component in form of a panel study. For the panel<br />

study, respondents of the first round were re-interviewed.<br />

Both rounds of the Political Action Study included a broad variety of items to measure<br />

elite-challenging activities. In order to assess (1) an affective orientation (indicating<br />

approval or disapproval of action); (2) a cognitive orientation (judging effectiveness or<br />

ineffectiveness of action); (3) a behavioral orientation (stating participation “have done”<br />

or intention (“would do” or “would never do”), ten different forms of political<br />

engagement were presented to the respondents:<br />

(1) Signing a petition<br />

(2) Joining in boycotts<br />

(3) Attending lawful demonstrations<br />

(4) Refusing to pay rent or taxes<br />

(5) Joining in wildcat strikes<br />

(6) Painting slogans on walls<br />

(7) Occupying buildings or factories: “Sit ins”<br />

(8) Blocking traffic with a street demonstration<br />

(9) Damage things like breaking windows, removing road signs, etc.<br />

(10) Using personal violence like fighting with other demonstrators or the police<br />

The respondents were confronted with cards showing the activities, <strong>and</strong> the following<br />

questions: “On each of these cards you will find a description of some kind of action<br />

that people sometimes take to protest about something or simply to make their view<br />

known to other people. Are there any you’ve never heard about or don’t underst<strong>and</strong>?<br />

(…) We would like to know how you feel about these things. Please look at this card.<br />

26 Due to the fact that Italy, Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Finl<strong>and</strong> joined the project only at a later point in time, the<br />

analyses of the “Political Action” book are limited to the five original countries. A second book, published<br />

in 1990 (Sänkiaho et al.: People <strong>and</strong> their Polities), encompasses results from all the eight countries.<br />

62


Will you please place each of the little cards you have there on one of the parts of this<br />

card to show me:<br />

A) Whether, in a general way, you feel you approve strongly, approve, disapprove, or<br />

disapprove strongly.<br />

B) The extent to which these action may be effective when people use them in pressing<br />

for changes. Are they usually very effective, somewhat effective, not very effective, or<br />

not at all effective?<br />

C) Whether 1) you have actually done any of these things on the cards during the past<br />

ten years; 2) you would do any of these things if it were important to you; 3) you might<br />

do it in a particular situation or 4) you would never do it under any circumstances.”<br />

Some of the items used in the first Political Action Study entered the questionnaire of<br />

the World Values Survey project, providing the largest data set available in terms of<br />

number <strong>and</strong> variety of societies.<br />

World Values Surveys/European Values Surveys<br />

The World Values Survey (WVS) <strong>and</strong> the European Values Survey (EVS) provide the<br />

largest source for data on values <strong>and</strong> attitudes of people around the globe. First carried<br />

out in 1981 <strong>and</strong> originally based on 10 countries in Europe (EVS) <strong>and</strong> additional 14<br />

countries around the world (WVS), the Values Surveys have become the broadest crossnational<br />

surveys with a gradually increasing number of participating countries. The<br />

second wave, conducted 1990 <strong>and</strong> 1991, covered already 43 societies; the third wave<br />

between 1995 <strong>and</strong> 1997 included 62 societies (Diez-Medrano <strong>and</strong> Luijkx 2004: 399).<br />

The fourth wave - carried out between 1999 <strong>and</strong> 2002 - surveyed, all in all, 81 societies,<br />

comprising (Inglehart, Halman <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2004: 1). The fifth wave of the World Values<br />

Survey was carried out between 2005 <strong>and</strong> 2007 27 in 52 societies around the globe.<br />

Altogether, the World Values Surveys include surveys from 97 societies, covering about<br />

90 percent of the world population. 28<br />

27 Exception: Egypt’s fieldwork was carried out in 2008.<br />

28 Further information can be obtained from the following website: http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org.<br />

63


Coordinated by Ronald Inglehart, <strong>University</strong> of Michigan in Ann Arbor, <strong>and</strong> the WVS<br />

Executive Board the implementation of the surveys are at the responsibility of principle<br />

investigators in each participating country who also supervise the conducting of surveys<br />

by established national research institutes.<br />

The Values Surveys offer st<strong>and</strong>ardized cross-cultural measures of human values <strong>and</strong><br />

goals concerning politics, economics, religion, gender roles, family values, political <strong>and</strong><br />

civic participation, etc. The advantage of choosing these data are straightforward: First,<br />

no other survey-based data set includes so many countries differing so strongly in terms<br />

of political, economic <strong>and</strong> human development. This gives new rise to possibilities to<br />

control for the impact of especially contextual or societal factors on political<br />

participation. Second, the data set has the advantage of continuity, not only referring to<br />

the country selection, but also (<strong>and</strong> especially) with respect to the wording of questions.<br />

With all the drawbacks of survey research, this allows for as much comparability -<br />

across time <strong>and</strong> nations - as possible. Besides, the World Values Surveys provide<br />

continuous information on countries that were not at all or no longer covered by other<br />

surveys. Most countries applied a stratified multistage r<strong>and</strong>om sample, drawn from the<br />

entire population aged 18+ (Diez-Medrano <strong>and</strong> Luijkx 2004: 400). The respondents<br />

were asked by conducting face-to-face interviews.<br />

The Values Surveys contain the following question on elite-challenging behavior:<br />

“Now I’d like you to look at this card. I’m going to read out some different forms of<br />

political action that people can take, <strong>and</strong> I’d like you to tell me, for each one, whether<br />

you have actually done any on these things, whether you might do it or would never,<br />

under any circumstances, do it.<br />

(1) Signing a petition<br />

(2) Joining in boycotts<br />

(3) Attending lawful demonstrations<br />

(4) Joining unofficial strikes<br />

(5) Occupying buildings <strong>and</strong> factories.”<br />

The most recent wave of the World Values Survey (WVS 2005-07) includes only the<br />

first three items.<br />

64


European Social Survey<br />

The European Social Survey (ESS) is a large-scale survey project covering attitudes <strong>and</strong><br />

values in various European countries. Applying a high-quality methodology, the surveys<br />

are “designed to chart <strong>and</strong> explain the interaction between Europe's changing institutions<br />

<strong>and</strong> the attitudes, beliefs <strong>and</strong> behaviour patterns of its diverse populations” 29 .<br />

The fieldwork in the first round, completed in December 2002, encompassed 22<br />

countries: EU’s 15 old member states (Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finl<strong>and</strong>, France,<br />

Germany, Greece, Irel<strong>and</strong>, Italy, Luxemburg, the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Portugal, Spain, Sweden,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the UK), four new member states (Czech Republic, Hungary, Pol<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Slovenia)<br />

plus Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Norway <strong>and</strong> Israel. The second round has been completed in<br />

December 2004, increasing the number of countries to 26 (first round participants plus<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong>, Slovakia, Ukraine <strong>and</strong> Estonia; Israel dropped out). The ESS samples are<br />

representative probability samples, covering persons aged 15+ years who are residents<br />

of the country, regardless of citizenship or nationality. The surveys were conducted in<br />

face-to-face interviews; the sample sizes of the first ESS round vary from 950<br />

respondents in France to 2.250 in Denmark.<br />

The first round European Social Survey asked the following question on elitechallenging<br />

activism:<br />

“There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent things<br />

from going wrong. During the last 12 months, have you done any of the following?<br />

(1) Signed a petition<br />

(2) Taken part in a lawful public demonstration<br />

(3) Boycotted certain products<br />

(4) Deliberately bought certain products for political, ethical or environmental reasons<br />

(5) Participated in illegal protest activities.”<br />

The ESS 2004 wave includes the first three of the five items.<br />

29 See the study description at http://www.europeansocialsurvey.org/. The project website also provides<br />

more detailed information about the European Social Survey <strong>and</strong> its methodology.<br />

65


4.4 Measurement of Elite-Challenging Political Action (dependent variable)<br />

When Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al. (1979) published their l<strong>and</strong>mark study on changing<br />

political behavior in postindustrial democracies, the participating researchers considered<br />

it rather unlikely that a considerable share of the population had already engaged in noninstitutionalized<br />

forms of political action. Rather, they argued that considerable changes<br />

had occurred with respect to citizens’ attitudes (not yet behavior) towards<br />

unconventional participation. In order to trace these changes in a comprehensive way, it<br />

was therefore of crucial importance to detect the size of a protest potential in a society.<br />

In fact, the decision to also assess the protest potential in a society in addition to levels<br />

of the (reported) behavior has generated a debate about the benefit of such undertaking.<br />

In complementing reports of protest behavior with attitudes towards protest, the<br />

researchers hoped to get a more precise picture about the development of new forms of<br />

political activism. Respondents were asked to indicate, first, whether they approved that<br />

form of action; <strong>and</strong> second, whether they were willing <strong>and</strong>/or could picture themselves<br />

become politically involved in such a way. Moreover, it was also an empirical argument<br />

to implement such a scale in order to overcome the problem of small numbers of<br />

participants in unconventional action.<br />

Today, the methodological problem of only few cases or participants has largely<br />

vanished, in particular in postindustrial democracies where elite-challenging activities<br />

have evolved into a conventional, widely accepted <strong>and</strong> frequently used mode of political<br />

action. Some scholars have also put forward a theoretical concern against measuring<br />

potentials. First, since “[a] potential which is not converted into behavior, however,<br />

remains relatively ineffective politically” (Fuchs 1990: 7). In this sense, assessing a<br />

potential for participation is a dispensable undertaking. Along similar lines, some have,<br />

second, argued that “hypothetical questions (‘Might you ever demonstrate or join a<br />

boycott?’) may well prove to be poor predictors of actual behavior” (Norris 2002: 194)<br />

because of the social desirability of answers. Third, the argument that action potential<br />

means that a political trigger situation has not yet occurred to turn the potential into<br />

action, is contradicted by longitudinal survey research. The gap between action potential<br />

66


<strong>and</strong> actual participation has not narrowed: “Rather, time-series data show that positive<br />

responses to questions about hypothetical future actions are poor indicators of what<br />

actions people do subsequently perform” (Topf 1995: 58). And fourth, elite-challenging<br />

activities are conceptualized as a form of political participation which has an action<br />

component as one of its defining characteristics. Definitions of political participation<br />

explicitly exclude attitudes, even if the willingness to participate might be highly<br />

correlated with political activity (Brady 1999: 737). In this sense, the following measure<br />

of elite-challenging activities is limited to those activities where people report to have<br />

participated (“have done”). 30<br />

In order to conceptualize different forms of elite-challenging activities, Figure 4-1<br />

displays thresholds between conventional <strong>and</strong> unconventional participation.<br />

Figure 4-1:<br />

Thresholds in Unconventional <strong>Participation</strong><br />

Thresholds<br />

1 2 3 4<br />

Conventional<br />

Politics:<br />

Petitions Boycotts Unofficial<br />

strikes<br />

Unlawful<br />

demonstrations<br />

Sabotage,<br />

Guerilla<br />

Voting<br />

Warfare, War<br />

Lobbying Slogans Occupations Hijacking<br />

Formal<br />

Assassination<br />

Interest<br />

Groups, etc.<br />

Lawful<br />

demonstrations<br />

Rent strikes Damage Bombing,<br />

Revolutions,<br />

Violence<br />

Kidnapping<br />

Orthodox Political Behavior<br />

Unorthodox political behavior<br />

Direct action<br />

Illegal action<br />

Violence<br />

Source: Dalton (2002: 61) after Marsh (1977: 42).<br />

Originally introduced by Marsh (1977: 42) <strong>and</strong> further developed by Dalton (2002: 61),<br />

the figure shows unconventional, or elite-challenging participation, as a one-dimensional<br />

30 If one is interested in how far elite-challenging activities have gained acceptance among the publics<br />

over the past three decades, one could, instead, rely on rejection figures (“would never do…”). Over time,<br />

a decline in rejection rates should be noticeable, indicating a growing acceptance of elite-challenging<br />

activities.<br />

67


concept, ranging from the least (left) to the most extreme (right) form of activism. The<br />

concept is characterized by four thresholds: the first one marks the transition from<br />

conventional to unconventional participation, the second the transition to direct action,<br />

the third the transition to illegal but nonviolent action, <strong>and</strong> the fourth the transition to<br />

violent forms of activities (Dalton 2002: 61; Prados <strong>and</strong> Tejada 2003: 132).<br />

For reasons of comparability, measurements of the dependent variable concentrate on<br />

the items available in the largest comparative survey study, the World Values Surveys.<br />

The WVS/EVS ask the respondents about their participation in five elite-challenging<br />

activities. (1) Signing petitions <strong>and</strong> (3) attending lawful demonstrations are rather mild<br />

forms of activity. More direct action is exercised through (2) joining in boycotts,<br />

whereas (4) joining unofficial strikes <strong>and</strong> (5) occupying buildings tend to be illegal,<br />

sometimes even violent forms of activity. Both rounds of the European Social Survey<br />

include the first three activities.<br />

Table 4-2:<br />

Factor Analysis for Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

Political<br />

Action<br />

(1974)<br />

EVS/<br />

WVS<br />

(1981)<br />

EVS/<br />

WVS<br />

(1990)<br />

WVS<br />

(1995)<br />

EVS/<br />

WVS<br />

(1999)<br />

WVS<br />

(2005)<br />

ESS<br />

(2002)<br />

ESS<br />

(2004)<br />

Signing petitions .65 .79 .77 .78 .78 .82 .79 .77<br />

Joining in boycott .74 .77 .77 .76 .78 .84 .69 .74<br />

Attending lawful .78 .75 .75 .75 .75 .83 .66 .79<br />

demonstrations<br />

Joining in unofficial .66 .71 .67 .69 .70 - - -<br />

strikes<br />

Occupying buildings .69 .61 .65 .62 .64 - - -<br />

% of Variance 50% 53% 52% 52% 53% 68% 51% 59%<br />

Pooled samples. The samples of the Political Action Study <strong>and</strong> WVS/EVS are weighted with equal weight<br />

= 1.000. The ESS data were adjusted according to the population size.<br />

Information about the countries included in the analysis can be obtained from Table 1.<br />

A factor analysis (see Table 4-2) using the five elite-challenging activities supports<br />

Marsh’s one-dimensional conception. In all surveys, the items load on one factor (see<br />

Table 4-2). To test the internal validity, Bartlett’s test of sphericity <strong>and</strong> the Kaiser-<br />

Mayer-Olkin measure were calculated, showing acceptable values for both tests. 31<br />

31 Bartlett’s test of sphericity gave the following results: Political Action (1974) = 6690.313; EVS/WVS<br />

(1981) = 23961.418; WVS/EVS (1990) = 55188.297; WVS (1995) = 72737.898; WVS/EVS (1999) =<br />

91138.229; WVS (2005) = 35820.762; ESS (2002) = 6949.719; ESS (2004) = 24887.328. All values are<br />

significant, so that a null-hypothesis can be rejected. It should be noted, however, that the sample sizes are<br />

68


In a first step, the single items in each survey were dichotomized, coding answers of<br />

respondents who report to have taken part in one activity against those who have not (1;<br />

0). For examinations of single elite-challenging activities these items will be used.<br />

In a second step, an additive index can be created from these dichotomies, resulting in a<br />

scale that ranges from 0 (= for respondents who have not taken part in any of these<br />

activities) to 5 (= respondents who have taken part in all of these activities). This<br />

additive scale can be used to model cumulative aspects of elite-challenging activities. 32<br />

However, the question to be examined here is not whether some individuals use a<br />

multitude of different activities, such as petitioning or demonstrating. From research<br />

questions’ point of view, the more relevant distinction is between participation <strong>and</strong> nonparticipation,<br />

so between people who participate in elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> those<br />

who abstain from it. Elite-challenging participation will therefore be calculated as a<br />

dichotomous variable: Participated in any activity is coded 1, whereas non-participation<br />

is coded 0. This procedure is applied because using the additive scale as a basis for<br />

dichotomizing elite-challenging participation would lead to a removal of those<br />

respondents from the sample who lack a valid answer in one of the components – even if<br />

the respondent has reported to have participated in one or even all other activities.<br />

quite large. For Kaiser-Mayer-Olkin’s measure the results are as follows: Political Action = .763;<br />

WVS/EVS 1981 = .790; WVS/EVS 1990 = .787; WVS (1995) = 778; WVS/EVS (1999) = .788; WVS<br />

(2005) = .700; ESS (2002) = .582; ESS (2004) = .652.<br />

32 The reliability of the scale was tested for all four waves of the WVS/EVS. Appendix A4-2 reports<br />

measures for internal consistency (Cronbach’s alpha) <strong>and</strong> inter-item correlations for pooled samples of the<br />

surveys. The coefficients for all surveys are at the lower end of values of what can still be considered as<br />

acceptable values for the internal consistency of the scale, conventionally values of 0.6 to 0.7.<br />

69


C<br />

EMPIRICAL ANALYSES<br />

5. “The Rise <strong>and</strong> Fall” of Elite-Challenging Political <strong>Participation</strong>?<br />

Trends <strong>and</strong> Cross-Country Differences in Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

This chapter presents the starting point for further empirical analyses. How do societies<br />

differ in the levels <strong>and</strong> forms of elite-challenging activities, <strong>and</strong> how have these<br />

activities changed during the past decades?<br />

5.1 Cross-Country Differences in Levels <strong>and</strong> Forms of Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities<br />

Theoretical accounts of modernization attribute specific attitudinal <strong>and</strong> behavioral<br />

consequences to socioeconomic development of a society. With respect to political<br />

participation, this theory expects an expansion of people’s action repertoire. As societies<br />

move towards postindustrialization, elite-challenging activities should become more<br />

widespread <strong>and</strong> accepted as a ‘normal’ tool of political participation. At the same time,<br />

differences between societies in the readiness with which people make use of these tools<br />

should be attributed to different levels of socioeconomic developments. As people in<br />

postindustrial democracies are becoming more critical towards authority, in particular<br />

towards political authority, elite-challenging participation should be most pronounced in<br />

these societies. To test this assumption in first, preliminary steps, the following figures<br />

examine levels of elite-challenging activities in various groups of societies. 33<br />

33 The data for the single elite-challenging activities included in the surveys for all societies at each point<br />

in time are documented in Appendix B.<br />

70


Figure 5-1: <strong>Participation</strong> in Elite-Challenging Activities, by Country in % (pooled WVS/EVS 2000-02/2005-07)<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong><br />

Swit zerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Sweden<br />

Aust ralia<br />

Canada<br />

Belgium<br />

Norway<br />

France<br />

USA<br />

Great Brit ain<br />

Norway<br />

Denmark<br />

Greece<br />

Japan<br />

It aly<br />

Slovakia<br />

Andorra<br />

Nort hern Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Luxembourg<br />

Brazil<br />

Aust ria<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong><br />

East Germany<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Czech Republic<br />

Net herl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

West Germany<br />

Israel<br />

Spain<br />

Albania<br />

Malt a<br />

Peru<br />

India<br />

Croat ia<br />

Sout h Korea<br />

Slovenia<br />

Lat via<br />

Armenia<br />

Serbia<br />

Cyprus<br />

Tanzania<br />

Mont enegro<br />

Lit huania<br />

Macedonia<br />

Uruguay<br />

Et hiopia<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a<br />

Mexico<br />

Trinidad & Tobago<br />

Burkina Faso<br />

Dom. Republic<br />

Russia<br />

Argent ina<br />

Zambia<br />

Est onia<br />

Bosnia <strong>and</strong> Herzegovina<br />

Port ugal<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Moldova<br />

Georgia<br />

Chile<br />

Belarus<br />

Colombia<br />

Azerbajan<br />

Nigeria<br />

Morocco<br />

Sout h Af rica<br />

Ukraine<br />

Bulgaria<br />

Venezuela<br />

Indonesia<br />

Bangladesh<br />

Hungary<br />

Guat emala<br />

Turkey<br />

Taiwan<br />

Philippines<br />

Ghana<br />

Romania<br />

Jordan<br />

Malaysia<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong><br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities: measured as the percentage of respondents who “Have done” any of the following activities: Signing petition, joining<br />

boycotts, attending lawful demonstration.<br />

71


Based on pooled data from the World Values Survey/European Values Survey 1999-2001<br />

<strong>and</strong> 2005-2007, Figure 5-1 shows for more than 80 societies how much experience<br />

people have in signing petitions, attending demonstrations, joining boycotts, etc. The bars<br />

indicate the share of people who have participated in at least one elite-challenging<br />

activity, ranging from less than 10 percent in Jordan or Malaysia up to more than 80<br />

percent of participants in New Zeal<strong>and</strong> or Sweden. In general, the highest levels of elitechallenging<br />

activities can be found among the English-speaking societies. New Zeal<strong>and</strong>,<br />

the United States, Great Britain, Australia <strong>and</strong> Canada make up five of the top ten most<br />

active societies, with the Irish publics still being in the top quarter. Signing petitions has<br />

been traditionally high in English-speaking societies as it requires little effort for the<br />

signer, <strong>and</strong> it has reached participation levels comparable to voting (Parry, Moyser <strong>and</strong><br />

Day 1992: 46; Dalton 2002: 62). Most of the established Western democracies follow,<br />

with at least half of the population engaging in elite-challenging activities. A continuous<br />

exception to that are the democracies in Southern Europe, Spain <strong>and</strong> Portugal, displaying<br />

lower levels (about 30 percent) of activism (see also Norris 2002: 199).<br />

The lowest third of the figure is largely composed of three groups: Islamic societies<br />

(Jordan, Pakistan, Indonesia, Bangladesh, Turkey, Morocco, Azerbaijan), postcommunist<br />

societies (Hungary, Romania, Bulgaria, Ukraine, Estonia, Belarus, Bosnia<br />

<strong>and</strong> Herzegovina, Georgia, Albania) <strong>and</strong> Latin-American societies (Mexico, Venezuela,<br />

Colombia, Chile, Argentina). These groups are not inclusive. In particular among the<br />

post-communist societies there are ‘deviant’ cases such as the Czech Republic or<br />

Slovakia with relatively high activity levels. However, altogether elite-challenging<br />

activities tend to be less pronounced outside well-developed societies.<br />

This finding would support modernization theory in its suggestion that socio-economic<br />

development has an important impact on people’s values <strong>and</strong> behavior. To examine this<br />

in a second step Figure 5-2 groups the societies according to the World Bank’s<br />

assessment of their economic performance. The World Bank uses the simple measure of<br />

the gross national income (GNI) to generate four categories, ranging from low-income<br />

societies (935 $) to high-income societies (11.456 $ <strong>and</strong> more). Even though the<br />

limitation of a single indicator should be taken into consideration, a simple grouping of<br />

this kind offers already interesting results. In general, levels of elite-challenging activities<br />

72


increase as national income rises. People in high-income societies tend to use elitechallenging<br />

activities twice as often as in other societies – more than 60 percent of the<br />

population report to have signed a petition or attended a demonstration, etc., suggesting a<br />

more critical attitude towards authorities. However, the differences between the first three<br />

groups - low, lower-middle <strong>and</strong> middle-lower income societies - are almost nonexistent.<br />

Between 27 <strong>and</strong> 30 percent indicate to have participated in at least one elite-challenging<br />

activity.<br />

Figure 5-2:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Various Societies, in %, pooled<br />

WVS/EVS 1999-2001 <strong>and</strong> WVS 2005-07 34<br />

0.7<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0<br />

low-income societies<br />

lower-middle-income<br />

societies<br />

upper-middle-income<br />

societies<br />

high-income societies<br />

All societies are weighted n = 1000. See Figure 5-1 for the measurement of elite-challening activities.<br />

Classification of societies according to the World Bank’ country classification, based on the 2007 GNI per capita: low<br />

income societies = $935 or less; lower-middle income societies = $936 to $3,705; upper-middle income societies = $3,706<br />

- $11,455; high-income societies = $11,456 or more. See http://www.worldbank.org/data for more detail.<br />

34 Low-income societies: Ghana, Ethiopia, Burkina Faso, Zambia (all 2005); Bangladesh, Nigeria, Ug<strong>and</strong>a,<br />

Tanzania (all 2000); Lower-middle income societies: Brazil, Bulgaria, Ukraine, Moldova, Thail<strong>and</strong>,<br />

Indonesia, Jordan, Republic of Moldova, Colombia, Serbia, Guatemala (all 2005); Peru, Philippines,<br />

Albania, Republic of Macedonia, Bosnia Herzegovina (all 2000); Belarus, Georgia, Dominican Republic<br />

(all 1996), Armenia, Azerbaijan (all 1997). Upper-middle income societies: Argentina, Chile, Mexico,<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong>, Romania, Russian Federation, South Africa, Uruguay, Malaysia (all 2005); Croatia, Czech<br />

Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Slovakia, Venezuela (all 2000). High-income societies:<br />

Australia, Canada, Finl<strong>and</strong>, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, South Korea, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>,<br />

Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Great Britain, United States, Cyprus, Andorra, Trinidad & Tobago<br />

(all 2005); Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Greece, Icel<strong>and</strong>, Irel<strong>and</strong>, Israel, Luxembourg, Malta, Portugal,<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> (all 2000); Norway (1996).<br />

73


Although modernization theory would predict that societies with increasing economic<br />

capacities show more distinct patterns in the spread of elite-challenging activities, the<br />

figure largely supports that elite-challenging activities are most prevalent among those<br />

societies where resources are abundant. It should also be noted that among the societies<br />

that the World Bank classified as upper-middle income societies, more than half of them<br />

are new democracies in former communist regimes. As will be shown later, most of these<br />

societies have experienced a decline in elite-challenging activities after extraordinary<br />

high levels of mass activities during the transition period, so this might explain why the<br />

differences between societies in the two middle-income categories are not more<br />

pronounced.<br />

As a consequence of this differentiation, the next grouping of societies acknowledges that<br />

societies are not only determined by their socioeconomic development. Rather, what<br />

people think <strong>and</strong> how people act is also shaped by their cultural heritage that tends to<br />

have a rather stable impact (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005: 19). As, in particular, “the<br />

collapse of communism did not create a tabula rasa by erasing people’s prior experiences;<br />

rather, those very experiences influence people’s current behavior” (Howard 2003: 105),<br />

it makes sense to control for people’s exposure to communist rule during their<br />

socialization phase. However, not only did the rigidity of the communist rule differ<br />

among the countries of the former socialist bloc. Also traditions prior to the communist<br />

regimes varied – some of the societies, in particular in Central Europe, are rooted in<br />

Western Christian traditions (such as Hungary or Slovakia), while in others, in particular<br />

in Southern Eastern Europe <strong>and</strong> among the post-soviet societies, people have been<br />

closely connected to various Christian-Orthodox churches or to Islamic religion. The<br />

Baltic states have been exceptional cases within the former Soviet Union, as they were<br />

the only Soviet republics with a Western Christian tradition.<br />

Figure 5-3, combining both socioeconomic <strong>and</strong> cultural factors, displays differences in<br />

levels of elite-challenging activities between postindustrial democracies, four different<br />

groups of post-communist societies, Latin American societies, other developing societies,<br />

<strong>and</strong> low-income societies.<br />

74


Once again, with almost two thirds of participants, postindustrial democracies show the<br />

highest level of elite-challenging activities, <strong>and</strong> the distance to the next group of societies<br />

is again larger than the distances between all other groups. Nevertheless, even though<br />

elite-challenging activities are most pronounced in rich, established, mostly Western<br />

democracies, this form of participation is more than a peripheral phenomenon to other<br />

societies. Even in the group of societies where people engage the least, still more than 20<br />

percent of the population is found to be active.<br />

Figure 5-3:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Various Societies 35 , in % (WVS/EVS<br />

1999-2002)<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Postindustrial<br />

societies<br />

Excommunist<br />

Western<br />

societies<br />

Latin<br />

American<br />

societies<br />

Excommunist<br />

Baltic<br />

societies<br />

Excommunist<br />

Soviet<br />

societies<br />

Excommunist<br />

Eastern<br />

societies<br />

Other<br />

developing<br />

societies<br />

Low income<br />

societies<br />

Pooled sample. Data are weighted n = 1.000.<br />

35 Postindustrial societies: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finl<strong>and</strong>, France, West Germany,<br />

Greece, Icel<strong>and</strong>, Irel<strong>and</strong>, Israel, Italy, Japan, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden,<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Great Britain, Northern Irel<strong>and</strong>, United States of America. Ex-communist Western societies:<br />

Czech Republic, Slovakia, Hungary, Pol<strong>and</strong>, Croatia, Slovenia, East Germany. Ex-communist Eastern<br />

societies: Albania, Bulgaria, Romania, Bosnia <strong>and</strong> Herzegovina, Republic of Macedonia, Serbia <strong>and</strong><br />

Montenegro. Ex-communist soviet societies: Russian Federation, Georgia, Ukraine, Belarus, Armenia,<br />

Azerbaijan, Republic of Moldova. Ex-communist Baltic societies: Estonia, Latvia, Lithuania. Latin<br />

American societies: Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Mexico, Peru, Uruguay, Venezuela. Other developing<br />

societies: South Africa, South Korea, Turkey, Taiwan. Low income societies: Bangladesh, Colombia,<br />

Dominican Republic, India, Indonesia, Jordan, Morocco, Nigeria, Pakistan, Philippines, Ug<strong>and</strong>a, Tanzania.<br />

Data are weighted n = 1000.<br />

75


In addition, the figure shows that it was useful to further differentiate between the<br />

middle-income societies presented in Figure 5-2, in particular with respect to the new<br />

democracies in Central <strong>and</strong> Eastern Europe. Those post-communist societies in Central<br />

Europe that show the longest Western tradition (Czech Republic, Slovakia, Pol<strong>and</strong>,<br />

Slovenia, Croatia <strong>and</strong> East Germany) also show significantly higher levels of elitechallenging<br />

activity. 36 By contrast, the former member states of the Soviet Union,<br />

including the Baltic states despite their Western tradition, <strong>and</strong> the new democracies in<br />

Eastern Europe (Albania, Bulgaria, Romania, Bosnia <strong>and</strong> Herzegovina, Republic of<br />

Macedonia, Serbia <strong>and</strong> Montenegro) show only low participation rates in these activities.<br />

More recent data from the European Social Survey support the finding that Western <strong>and</strong><br />

Eastern European publics differ significantly in the extent to which they participate in<br />

elite-challenging activities. Table 5-1 documents the average levels of single elitechallenging<br />

activities in Western <strong>and</strong> Eastern Europe for those countries that have been<br />

included in both rounds of the ESS.<br />

Looking at the levels of activity, small changes have occurred between the first <strong>and</strong> the<br />

second round. Given the time reference that limits people’s activities to the “past 12<br />

month”, these changes can probably be explained by variations in the importance of<br />

(potential) mobilizing issues. Against this background, the changes between 2002 <strong>and</strong><br />

2004 can be considered as minor - the overall pattern is stability.<br />

Table 5-1: Elite-Challenging Activities in %, ESS 2002, 2004<br />

Western Europe<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

2002 2004 2002 2004<br />

Signing petition 29,5 28,5 8,1 9,4<br />

Joining in Boycotts 20,0 17,9 5,2 5,4<br />

Attending demonstrations 8,7 10,8 2,3 1,9<br />

Buying product for political reason 30,6 - 12,3 -<br />

Participating in illegal protest activities 1,1 - 0,5 -<br />

N 22.304 23.170 5.000 5.049<br />

Western Europe: Austria, Belgium, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Germany, Denmark, Spain, Finl<strong>and</strong>, United Kingdom,<br />

Greece, Irel<strong>and</strong>, Luxembourg, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Norway, Portugal, Sweden; Eastern Europe: Czech Republic,<br />

Hungary, Pol<strong>and</strong>, Slovenia. Data are weighted according to the population size.<br />

36 As noted in Figure 5-1, Hungary is an exception – whereas about two thirds of the Czechs report to have<br />

participated in elite-challenging activities, only one sixths of the Hungarian population has done so.<br />

76


The societies in Europe show different levels of activity: In all elite-challenging forms of<br />

participation, Western European publics are about three times as active as the ones in<br />

Eastern European. However, the structure in both groups is rather similar. <strong>Participation</strong> in<br />

illegal activities is absolutely a marginal phenomenon, in no society attracting more than<br />

4 percent of participants (see Appendix A5-1). In all types of societies, political<br />

consumerism (buying or boycotting products for political or ethical reasons) <strong>and</strong> signing<br />

petitions are the most common form of elite-challenging activity. 37<br />

Figure 5-4: Signed Petition during the past 12 Months, ESS 2004, in %<br />

Sweden<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong><br />

Norway<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

UK<br />

Germany<br />

France<br />

Denmark<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Slovakia<br />

Spain<br />

Austria<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Belgium<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Czech<br />

Ukraine<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Hungary<br />

Slovenia<br />

Portugal<br />

Estonia<br />

Greece<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60<br />

Source: European Social Survey 2004, Round 2. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample<br />

(design weight).<br />

Question wordings: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent things from going<br />

wrong. During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (...) Signed a petition”.<br />

For almost all societies, signing a petition is the most simple <strong>and</strong>, therefore, frequently<br />

used form of elite-challenging activity (Figure 5-4). Often directed to political or other<br />

elites, it does not have a binding character, but the number of signatures emphasizes the<br />

37 This also means that the European Social Survey, in its decision to reduce the battery of elite-challenging<br />

forms of participation in 2004, does no longer cover the most significant <strong>and</strong> frequently used form of elitechallenging<br />

actions, both in Western <strong>and</strong> Eastern Europe.<br />

77


claim stated in the petition <strong>and</strong> potentially adds public pressure. Signing petitions is most<br />

common to Sc<strong>and</strong>inavian societies, whereas the post-communist <strong>and</strong> Southern European<br />

societies rank at the bottom.<br />

Figure 5-5 documents the participation in demonstrations as a public, collective display<br />

of opinion. Also in this activity, more than a decade after the masses have been out in the<br />

streets to protest against the communist regimes, most of the post-communist societies<br />

show considerable low rates of participation in demonstrations.<br />

Figure 5-5: Attended Demonstration during the past 12 Months, ESS 2004, in %<br />

Spain<br />

Ukraine<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong><br />

Luxembourg<br />

France<br />

Norway<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Germany<br />

Sweden<br />

Belgium<br />

Austria<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Denmark<br />

Greece<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Slovakia<br />

UK<br />

Portugal<br />

Czech<br />

Estonia<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Slovenia<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Hungary<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60<br />

Source: European Social Survey 2004, Round 2. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample<br />

(design weight).<br />

Question wordings: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent things from going<br />

wrong. During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (...)” “Taken part in a lawful demonstration”.<br />

However, Figure 5-5 also shows how single events or issues can mobilize people in<br />

action, <strong>and</strong> how sensitive surveys are to these developments. In the case of Spain <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Ukraine this is particularly interesting since both societies usually show low levels of<br />

elite-challenging political action when compared to similar societies in Western <strong>and</strong><br />

Eastern Europe. In Spain, the responses documented in Figure 5-5 reflect the<br />

demonstrations in many Spanish cities that started as a reaction to the Madrid train<br />

bombings on March 11, 2004, <strong>and</strong> turned into protests against the former Prime Minister<br />

José María Aznar, his government <strong>and</strong> their information policy with regard to the terrorist<br />

78


attack. These massive demonstrations finally led to Aznar’s defeat in the national<br />

elections. The time frame of these demonstrations was limited to only a few days, but it<br />

mobilized a whole society – on March 12, 2004 alone, more than 11 million Spaniards<br />

were out in the streets.<br />

In the Ukraine, where the fieldwork of the ESS study was conducted in early 2005, the<br />

high levels of demonstrations shown in Figure 5-5 mirror the incidents after the 2004<br />

Ukrainian presidential elections, resulting in the so-called Orange Revolution that took<br />

place between November 2004 <strong>and</strong> January 2005. These protests <strong>and</strong> massive<br />

demonstrations against the incumbent-led electoral fraud led to new, free <strong>and</strong> fair<br />

elections, for the first time in Ukrainian history, <strong>and</strong> brought the oppositional c<strong>and</strong>idate,<br />

Viktor Yushchenko, into presidential office.<br />

As the examples of Spain <strong>and</strong> the Ukraine show, attending demonstrations is an activity<br />

that is very sensitive to particular issues. Especially non-activists take part in<br />

demonstrations not on a regular basis but when an issue is of particular importance to<br />

them. So, the specific opportunity structure for this activity comes <strong>and</strong> goes, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

activity remains sporadic <strong>and</strong> restricted to an event. This is different for political<br />

consumerism, being a rather individual than collective form of elite-challenging activity<br />

<strong>and</strong> maybe therefore easier incorporated into people’s everyday life <strong>and</strong> their shopping<br />

routines.<br />

Using the market as an arena for politics, boycotting <strong>and</strong> buy-cotting reflect the<br />

“consumer choice of producers <strong>and</strong> products based on a variety of ethical <strong>and</strong> political<br />

considerations” (Stolle, Hooghe <strong>and</strong> Micheletti 2003: 3). Figure 5-6 displays the<br />

frequency of positive <strong>and</strong> negative political consumerism among European publics.<br />

Political consumerism is a widespread elite-challenging activity, traditionally most<br />

pronounced in Sc<strong>and</strong>inavian <strong>and</strong> German-speaking societies <strong>and</strong> again lowest in Southern<br />

<strong>and</strong> Eastern European societies.<br />

79


Figure 5-6: Political Consumerism, ESS 2002, in %<br />

Sweden<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Germany<br />

Denmark<br />

UK<br />

Austria<br />

Norway<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Israel<br />

Belgium<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Spain<br />

Italy<br />

Hungary<br />

Greece<br />

Slovenia<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Portugal<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60<br />

Source: European Social Survey 2002, Round 1. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample<br />

(design weight).<br />

Dark grey column: Have participated in both forms of political consumerism: boycotting <strong>and</strong> buy-cotting.<br />

Light grey column: Have participated in one form of political consumerism: boycotting or buy-cotting.<br />

Question wordings: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent things from going<br />

wrong. During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? Boycotted certain products; Deliberately bought<br />

certain products for political, ethical or environmental reasons”.<br />

An examination of levels <strong>and</strong> forms of elite-challenging activities identified already<br />

important differences among various types of societies. Socioeconomic development is a<br />

crucial determinant for activity, as publics in postindustrial societies are overall more<br />

engaged in these activities than others. Within this group, Sc<strong>and</strong>inavian countries <strong>and</strong><br />

English-speaking societies show the highest level of activism, in particular in signing<br />

petitions, whereas the third-wave democracies in Southern Europe rank rather low, often<br />

showing similar levels of activity as some of the post-communist societies. Among this<br />

particular group of new democracies, those societies that are better off, not post-soviet<br />

<strong>and</strong> traditionally more Western oriented tend to be the most active. The following section<br />

will examine whether these patterns still hold when comparing the activity levels of<br />

societies over time.<br />

80


5.2 Trends in Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

Survey-based studies on behavior or values that are interested in longitudinal, crosscultural<br />

comparison are often confronted with very practical problems that arise from<br />

inconsistencies <strong>and</strong> lacking continuity of topics, items or question formulation. Even<br />

within a data set, changes in the phrasing of a question or an item occur. Fortunately,<br />

batteries on elite-challenging activities have found their ways into large-scale, crossnational<br />

survey projects such as the World Values Survey/European Values Survey.<br />

Taking up substantial components of participation measures used in the Political Action<br />

Studies, the Values Surveys offer continuing information on elite-challenging behavior.<br />

Six out of eight nations that were originally covered by the first Political Action Study<br />

have been participating in subsequent rounds of the WVS/EVS, that is Finl<strong>and</strong>, Great<br />

Britain, Italy, the Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, the United States <strong>and</strong> West Germany. 38 Thanks to the fact<br />

that both projects applied almost similar wording of their questions on these particular<br />

forms of political action, Figure 5-7 displays a considerable time-series of almost 30<br />

years available for elite-challenging activities in six post-industrial democracies 39 , a<br />

rather rare phenomenon in survey research.<br />

The overall picture of the trend in elite-challenging activities is clear <strong>and</strong> supports the<br />

prognosis that participants of the Political Action project gave at the end of their study:<br />

“We interpret this increase in potential for protest to be a lasting characteristic of<br />

democratic mass publics <strong>and</strong> not just a sudden surge in political involvement bound to<br />

fade away as time goes by” (Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al.: 1979: 524). As Figure 5-7 shows,<br />

almost three decades later, this potential has turned into real participation. The rank order<br />

of the single activities has remained the same, as petitioning has been the most common<br />

form at all points in time, followed by participation in demonstrations <strong>and</strong> boycotts.<br />

38 Austria was not part of the 1981 WVS/EVS survey. Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, as the eighth country included in the<br />

Political Action Study, did not participate in the 1981 <strong>and</strong> 1999 survey. Both countries were excluded from<br />

succeeding examination.<br />

39 It should be noted that despite similar wording of questions in the two surveys, the answer categories that<br />

were offered to the respondents differed in one important aspect. Whereas the EVS/WVS asked the<br />

respondents whether they had already participated, might participate or would never participate in a form of<br />

activity, the earlier Political Action Study had a different focus on protest potential <strong>and</strong>, thus, distinguished<br />

for theoretical reasons between respondents who “might do” <strong>and</strong> respondents who “would do” take part in<br />

an activity. Although this difference should actually not affect the responses of those who had already taken<br />

part, this should still be kept in mind while comparing the data.<br />

81


Figure 5-7:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities 1974-1999 in Six Postindustrial<br />

Democracies, in %<br />

70<br />

60<br />

Signing petitions<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

Attending demonstration<br />

Joining in boycott<br />

Joining in strike<br />

Occupying building<br />

1974 1981 1990 1999<br />

Source: Political Action Study (1974); WVS/EVS (1981, 1990, 1999). Pooled samples.<br />

Societies included: Great Britain, West Germany, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Italy, Finl<strong>and</strong>, USA.<br />

Data are weighted with n = 1.000.<br />

Between 1974 <strong>and</strong> 1999 people’s engagement in these three of the five activities - signing<br />

petitions joining boycotts <strong>and</strong> attending demonstrations – has doubled in the six societies.<br />

Today, the majority of people engage in non-violent activities outside institutionalized<br />

channels of participation. By sharp contrast, participation in potentially non-peaceful,<br />

rather illegal activities like joining wild strikes <strong>and</strong> occupying buildings has been <strong>and</strong><br />

clearly remains a marginal phenomenon in Western societies.<br />

Since the mid 1970ies, elite-challenging activities in these six postindustrial societies<br />

have developed into widely accepted <strong>and</strong> common forms of people’s general<br />

participation repertoire. This trend is not limited to this particular set of countries, as it<br />

can also be observed in other postindustrial democracies. Exp<strong>and</strong>ing the number of<br />

postindustrial societies under consideration to those where a time-series since the early<br />

1980ies is available, Figures 5-8a <strong>and</strong> 5-8b document the increase in elite-challenging<br />

political activities in 15 societies. To avoid an overload of the figure, the postindustrial<br />

82


societies were split into English-speaking societies <strong>and</strong> Japan (Figure 5-8a) <strong>and</strong> Western<br />

European societies (Figure 5-8b).<br />

Figure 5-8a:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Postindustrial Democracies:<br />

English-Speaking Societies <strong>and</strong> Japan, in %, WVS/EVS<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

USA<br />

Great Britain<br />

Canada<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Japan<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

1981 1990 1999<br />

Figure 5-8b:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Postindustrial Democracies:<br />

Western European Societies, in %, WVS/EVS<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Sweden<br />

France<br />

Belgium<br />

Denmark<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Italy<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong><br />

West Germany<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Spain<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

1981 1990 1999<br />

83


At the turn of the century, more people than ever participate in elite-challenging<br />

activities, in most countries reaching the level of participation in elections. With the<br />

exception of Spain, the majority of citizens in all societies report to have participated in at<br />

least one activity. West Germany <strong>and</strong> Canada between 1990 <strong>and</strong> 1999 are the only two<br />

cases where the level of the 1990 activity exceeds the one that was measured 9 years<br />

later.<br />

Elite-challenging activities have been <strong>and</strong> still are most pronounced in Sweden <strong>and</strong> the<br />

USA, <strong>and</strong> the high levels in all postindustrial societies suggest that they are not motivated<br />

by objective economic or social hardship. In all postindustrial societies the most common<br />

elite-challenging activity is petitioning as a “clearly a very mild form of unconventional<br />

action” (Dalton 2002: 62). In the 1980ies <strong>and</strong> 1990ies, this form of participation has<br />

increased from 40 to 60 percent on average. 40 On a lower level but likewise increasing<br />

are participation in demonstration <strong>and</strong> joining in boycotts (see also Friedman 1999).<br />

After looking at trends in elite-challenging activities in established postindustrial<br />

democracies, the succeeding figures shift the focus to the new democracies in Central <strong>and</strong><br />

Eastern Europe. All these societies share a “postcommunist legacy”, a set of specific<br />

experiences with socialist ideology that is distinct from other types of authoritarian<br />

regimes, <strong>and</strong> that affects the values <strong>and</strong> behavior of people in these societies until today<br />

(Howard 2003). 41<br />

Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Catterberg (2003) have argued that the new democracies in Central <strong>and</strong><br />

Eastern Europe have witnessed a “post-honeymoon effect” in direct, elite-challenging<br />

activities. After experiencing extraordinarily high levels of mass activities during the<br />

transition period to democracy, it was considered as almost inevitable that these rates<br />

should decline as the immediate reason for mass mobilizations disappeared <strong>and</strong> people<br />

returned to their everyday life.<br />

40 See Appendix A5-2 for an overview about trends (1981-1999) in the single elite-challenging activities in<br />

15 postindustrial democracies.<br />

41 More specifically, Howard (2003) argues that this postcommunist legacy is the reason why civil society<br />

in these countries tends to so weak. Three factors - a general mistrust towards communist organizations (or<br />

mass organizations in general), the persistence of friendship networks as well as post-communist<br />

disappointment expectations towards the new regime have not been met - account for the weakness of civil<br />

society in these new democracies.<br />

84


However, Figure 5-9 reveals that this has not been the case for all post-communist<br />

societies, in particular not for most of the new democracies in Central Europe. A decade<br />

after the transition to democracy, in the Czech Republic, Slovakia, Slovenia <strong>and</strong> Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

even more people participate in demonstrations, join boycotts or sign petitions than in the<br />

early 1990ies.<br />

Figure 5-9: Elite-Challenging Activities in Ex-Communist Societies, in %,<br />

WVS/EVS<br />

70<br />

60<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Slovakia<br />

50<br />

40<br />

Slovenia<br />

30<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

20<br />

10<br />

Hungary<br />

Bulgaria<br />

0<br />

1990 1999<br />

Elite-challenging participation in Hungary has slightly declined between 1990 <strong>and</strong> 1999<br />

from an already low level. Among the ex-communist countries in Central <strong>and</strong> Eastern<br />

Europe outside the Soviet Union, Bulgaria shows the largest drop in these activities (data<br />

for Romania 1990 are not available).<br />

Exp<strong>and</strong>ing the view to post-communist societies under Soviet rule, the expected posthoneymoon<br />

decline in elite-challenging activities now becomes visible (see Figure 5-10).<br />

The decline in the decade after the collapse of communist rule has most strongly affected<br />

the new Baltic democracies, but also those countries that have not successfully<br />

transformed into full-fledged democracies but that developed into a gray-zone democracy<br />

with serious deficiencies (Russia) or that have replaced one authoritarian system with<br />

another one (Belarus).<br />

85


There are a number of plausible reasons why this decline in elite-challenging activities<br />

has taken place in these societies. When the communist regimes in Central <strong>and</strong> Eastern<br />

Europe collapsed in a kind of snowballing effect, many people put high hopes into the<br />

transition to democracy. But as Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel (2005: 119) have argued, support<br />

for a regime change, also displayed in massive protests such as demonstrations, does not<br />

necessarily have to be intrinsically motivated.<br />

Figure 5-10: Elite-Challenging Activities in Ex-Communist Post-Soviet Societies, in<br />

%, WVS/EVS<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

Lithuania<br />

Latvia<br />

40<br />

Estonia<br />

30<br />

20<br />

Belarus*<br />

Russia<br />

10<br />

0<br />

1990 1999<br />

* Belarus: Survey from 1997 (see chapter on methods <strong>and</strong> data for country selection). The decline in elitechallenging<br />

activities between the 1990 <strong>and</strong> the 2000 survey shows an even steeper decline.<br />

In particular, when people support democracy not because of its procedures but because<br />

they associate material benefits <strong>and</strong> prosperity with it, these economic expectations are<br />

open to disillusionment when the new regime cannot deliver. In the first years after the<br />

transition, socio-economic conditions have worsened in almost all post-communist<br />

countries. But whereas the more Western-oriented, Central European countries could<br />

recover, the post-soviet societies have suffered from economic <strong>and</strong> social hardship in an<br />

almost unprecedented manner. As a consequence of deteriorating social <strong>and</strong> health<br />

services, living st<strong>and</strong>ards dropped sharply in the early 1990ies, <strong>and</strong> fertility rate <strong>and</strong> life<br />

86


expectancy declined (in particular in Russia where male life expectancy reached its alltime<br />

low with 58 years in 2001). Considering, in addition, the lasting imprint of the<br />

“post-communist legacy” that has shaped the post-soviet societies to a greater extent than<br />

others (Howard 2003), the low levels <strong>and</strong> decline of elite-challenging activities have been<br />

inevitable as people lack resources to become politically engaged.<br />

Along similar lines, although to a more moderate extent, the decrease of these activities<br />

in two Latin American societies, Mexico <strong>and</strong> Chile, can also be considered as a posthoneymoon<br />

effect after transition to democracy (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Catterberg 2003: 87).<br />

Figure 5-11:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities in Other Societies, in %, WVS<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

Argentina<br />

Nigeria<br />

South Africa<br />

India<br />

Chile<br />

Mexico<br />

10<br />

Turkey<br />

0<br />

1990 1999<br />

Figure 5-11 also demonstrates that in those developing societies where democratic<br />

change has either not occurred within the past 15 years or has been more modest, a much<br />

more stable pattern can be observed. For South Africa, India, Turkey, Nigeria <strong>and</strong><br />

Argentina no changes in the level of elite-challenging activities have taken place in the<br />

1990ies.<br />

To summarize, participation in elite-challenging activities is less common for societies<br />

outside the postindustrial world as they are bound to the availability of socioeconomic<br />

87


esources in a society (see Figure 5-2). As an outcome of a long-term development, a<br />

systematic increase in these activities can be observed in post-industrial democracies, on<br />

average with two thirds of the population being politically engaged. Within this group,<br />

some societies are considerably more active (Sc<strong>and</strong>inavian <strong>and</strong> English-speaking<br />

societies) than others (Southern European societies). Post-communist societies show<br />

much lower participation figures than advanced industrial democracies, but there are<br />

important differences within this group of societies. In those countries with a more<br />

Western tradition, situated in Central Europe <strong>and</strong> since 2004 member states of the<br />

European Union, people tend to actively challenge political elites in a way that is similar<br />

to Western publics. The participation levels are not yet comparable to all postindustrial<br />

societies, but in 2000 more Slovaks <strong>and</strong> Czechs have participated in at least one elitechallenging<br />

activity than people in West Germany or Finl<strong>and</strong>.<br />

88


6. Common Patterns of Complement or Displacement?<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Other Forms of Political Activism<br />

Since the 1990ies there has been an ongoing debate whether democracies today really<br />

face a “gradual but widespread process of civic disengagement” (Putnam <strong>and</strong> Goss 2002:<br />

4) as some scholars suggest (Putnam 2000, 2002; Pharr <strong>and</strong> Putnam 2000) or not. The<br />

previous chapter presented long-term evidence contradicting this claim of erosion: People<br />

are becoming more <strong>and</strong> more inclined to make their voices heard through demonstrations<br />

or petitions, <strong>and</strong> they have discovered the marketplace as a political arena where their<br />

every-day decision in favor or against certain products has the potential to influence the<br />

market practices <strong>and</strong> government regulations. So, people are not generally withdrawing<br />

from politics as these elite-challenging activities are becoming more widespread <strong>and</strong><br />

normal for citizens in democracies, supplementing people’s traditional participation<br />

repertoire. Even though these activities are most pronounced in postindustrial established<br />

democracies, people in other societies use these means as well to intervene into the<br />

political decision-making process <strong>and</strong> to make their voices heard. The question whether<br />

we were celebrating the success of democracy by staying at home (Dalton 2002: 32),<br />

deserves a negative answer: civic activism in general is not in decline.<br />

This general trend, however, does not allow for hasty conclusions about the way different<br />

forms of political participation are related to each other. Despite some early evidence<br />

from the Political Action Study that unconventional <strong>and</strong> conventional participation were<br />

not mutually exclusive (Kaase <strong>and</strong> Marsh 1979b: 152), some of the concern about<br />

declining political engagement comes from the worry that elite-challenging activities<br />

might go at the expense of more traditional forms of political participation. As people<br />

tend to participate more in sporadic, issue-based <strong>and</strong> short-term activities, this rise of new<br />

participation styles may lead to a gradual replacement of older forms of activity, if people<br />

at the same time abstain from engagement through traditional channels. In order to<br />

examine the decline thesis more thoroughly, this chapter turns to the question how elitechallenging<br />

activities <strong>and</strong> other forms of political participation are interrelated. The focus<br />

will be on three forms of participation: voting, conventional participation <strong>and</strong> activity in<br />

political action groups.<br />

89


The political participation literature offers a number of classifications of the various ways<br />

people can participate in politics. Verba, Nie <strong>and</strong> Kim (1971, 1978), for example,<br />

specified four ‘modes of democratic participation’: Campaigning, communal activity<br />

(working with a group in the community), personalized contacts, <strong>and</strong> voting. Building on<br />

this classification, Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al. (1979) described these modes as conventional<br />

activities because these were considered to be more traditional <strong>and</strong> institutionalized forms<br />

of political participation. As conceptually distinct, the authors identified more<br />

spontaneous, less formally organized activities as unconventional forms of participation.<br />

Within the traditional forms of political activity, participation in elections has been<br />

considered to be of particular quality (<strong>and</strong> quantity) <strong>and</strong> therefore regarded as a separate<br />

form of institutionalized activities (Verba <strong>and</strong> Nie 1972: 79). The special role that voting<br />

plays in representative democracies has also been acknowledged in the Political Action<br />

Study: “With reflection it becomes apparent that voting is a unique form of political<br />

behavior in the sense that it occurs only rarely, is highly biased by strong mechanisms of<br />

social control <strong>and</strong> social desirability enhanced by the rain-danced ritual of campaigning,<br />

<strong>and</strong> does not involve the voter in major informational or other costs” (Marsh <strong>and</strong> Kaase<br />

1979: 86). Following this differentiation, voting <strong>and</strong> conventional participation will be<br />

considered as two distinct forms of political participation.<br />

As a third form of institutionalized activity, people’s participation in voluntary<br />

associations will be examined. In representative democracies, people’s effort to join with<br />

others on an organizational basis is not restricted to political parties. Rather, today’s<br />

political arena is characterized by a great variety of associations that appear as political<br />

actors, trying to influence the political decision-making process <strong>and</strong> often specializing in<br />

one particular issue. The emergence of new social movements brought these new<br />

organizations to the fore, concerned for example with questions of peace, women’s<br />

rights, social inequality, ecological sustainability, or human rights issues. Although not<br />

every action in the context of these voluntary associations may have a distinct political<br />

character, to disregard these activities as forms of political engagement would mean to<br />

neglect a considerable dimension of people’s political action repertoire.<br />

90


If it was true that elite-challenging activities went at the expense of other participation<br />

forms <strong>and</strong>, in doing so, in the end contributed to an erosion of political activism, then at<br />

least one of the three following propositions should be confirmed:<br />

- Societies in which elite-challenging activities are widespread, other forms of political<br />

participation should be low (negative relationship at the societal level).<br />

- People who engage in elite-challenging activities should abstain from participating in<br />

more institutionalized forms of activity (negative relationship at the individual level).<br />

- As elite-challenging activities become more widespread over time, other forms of<br />

civic engagement in these societies should, in return, decrease (diverging trends).<br />

These propositions will be examined mainly on the basis of data from the European<br />

Social Survey 2002. 42 It contains indicators for various forms of political participation,<br />

<strong>and</strong> a factor analysis confirmed that voting <strong>and</strong> conventional participation are two distinct<br />

modes of political activism (see Appendix A6-1). So, these forms of political<br />

participation will be treated separately. Unfortunately, the ESS data do not allow for<br />

comparisons over time. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, the World Values Survey/European Values<br />

Survey does not contain comparable measures of participation in conventional activities,<br />

such as attending political meetings, contacting politicians or campaigning, or a direct<br />

account of electoral participation. However, the WVS/EVS asks their respondents about<br />

institutionalized activism, measured by active membership in formal voluntary<br />

associations. For some of these indicators a considerable time series of 20 years is<br />

available.<br />

6.1 Voting<br />

In democracies, voting is by far the most common <strong>and</strong> frequently used form of political<br />

participation. Still, there are differences between societies in the degree to which people<br />

make use of their right to vote, among others depending on the frequency <strong>and</strong> variety of<br />

42 The ESS 2002 includes the broadest range of questions on political <strong>and</strong> social participation, as it included<br />

a module on “Citizenship, Involvement <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>”. For more information see the ESS website:<br />

http://www.europeansocialsurvey.org/ .<br />

91


elections (Dalton 2002: 38). 43 It is well documented, for example, that the USA <strong>and</strong><br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> show comparatively low levels of turnout, while at the same time offering<br />

their citizens the broadest scope of other possibilities to take an active st<strong>and</strong> in political<br />

decision-making. Research on electoral participation over the past two decades has been<br />

characterized by a debate about declining voter turnout in postindustrial democracies.<br />

Even though some scholars have argued that “the evidence indicates that over recent<br />

years there was no general trend towards a decline in institutionalized participation”<br />

(Klingemann <strong>and</strong> Fuchs 1995: 422), it can be considered as an established finding today<br />

that voter turnout is falling in postindustrial democracies (Gray <strong>and</strong> Caul 2000: 1095;<br />

Wattenberg 2000; Fox Piven <strong>and</strong> Cloward 2000; Mair 2001).<br />

To test the first proposition of a negative linkage between voting <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging<br />

activities 44 , Figure 6-1 relates levels of these two activities in 21 societies to each other.<br />

As the analysis is based on ESS data, the proposition test is limited to core postindustrial<br />

Western European <strong>and</strong> four postcommunist Central European societies.<br />

<strong>Participation</strong> in elections is generally quite high, in all societies reaching levels between<br />

50 <strong>and</strong> 90 percent. The societies under observation differ less in their turnout levels than<br />

in the degree people are taking part in elite-challenging activities. As Figure 6-1 shows,<br />

there is no relationship between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> voting at the aggregate<br />

level (r = -.05 n.s.). Among the 21 European democracies there are some societies with<br />

high levels of elite-challenging action <strong>and</strong> comparatively low participation in elections<br />

(Luxembourg, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>); some where elite-challenging activities are low <strong>and</strong> voter<br />

turnout is high (Greece, Italy, Hungary); <strong>and</strong> some where both forms of political<br />

participation are high (Denmark, Sweden) or where both are low (Portugal). So, on the<br />

aggregate level, general levels of participation in elections do not allow for any<br />

conclusion about people’s activity outside traditional channels (<strong>and</strong> vice versa),<br />

suggesting at least no trade-off between the two.<br />

43 Among other factors, the institutional design plays a crucial role, such as compulsory voting (e.g. in<br />

Belgium) or voter registration (e.g. in the USA).<br />

44 Elite-challenging activities are measured as the share of people who have participated in at least one of<br />

those activities during the past 12 months: Signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted<br />

certain products, deliberately bought certain products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

92


Figure 6-1: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Voting (ESS 2002)<br />

100<br />

Voting, in %<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

Denmark<br />

Greece Italy<br />

Austria<br />

Sweden<br />

Norway<br />

Hungary Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Belgium<br />

Germany<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Portugal<br />

Slovenia<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Israel Spain<br />

UK<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Luxembourg<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities, in %<br />

Data Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R = -0.05 n.s.<br />

Elite-challenging activities (In the past 12 months: signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain<br />

products, deliberately bought certain products for political, ethical or environmental reasons) <strong>and</strong> voting (“Did you vote in<br />

the last national election?”) measure the percentages of respondents in each sample who have reported to have done any<br />

of these activities.<br />

Despite the fact that elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> voting did not show a negative<br />

relationship at the aggregate level, in fact no relationship at all, it could still be the case<br />

that these two forms of activities are negatively linked at the individual level, suggesting<br />

that people who demonstrate, sign petitions or are active political consumers stay away<br />

from the ballot box more often than others. To test this second proposition, Table 6-1<br />

presents the linkage between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> voting.<br />

Also at the individual level, elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> voting are only weakly<br />

correlated. In five of the 21 societies, the correlation coefficient is even insignificant, so<br />

the linkages between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> participating in elections vary from<br />

nation to nation. The overall relationship is weak but positive which means that people<br />

who participate in elections also modestly tend to become active outside institutionalized<br />

channels of political participation. The high level of electoral participation in democratic<br />

93


societies, but in particular reflected in survey responses 45 , might account for the weakness<br />

of the relationship. Most of the societies show a turnout of more than 70 percent. It seems<br />

very likely that this group of voters is simply too large <strong>and</strong> inclusive to differentiate<br />

between participants <strong>and</strong> nonparticipants in elite-challenging activities.<br />

Table 6-1:<br />

Individual-Level Correlations between Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> Voting (ESS 2002)<br />

Austria<br />

Belgium<br />

.03 n.s.<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> .19 ***<br />

Czech Republic .12 ***<br />

Germany .16 ***<br />

East .17 ***<br />

West .15 ***<br />

Denmark .07 **<br />

Spain<br />

.04 n.s.<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .09 ***<br />

UK .17 ***<br />

Greece<br />

.02 n.s.<br />

Hungary .11 ***<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .07 **<br />

Israel .12 ***<br />

Italy<br />

.06 n.s.<br />

Luxembourg .11 ***<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .08 ***<br />

Norway .09 ***<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .06 **<br />

Portugal .12 ***<br />

Sweden .10 ***<br />

Slovenia .06 *<br />

Elite-challenging participation <strong>and</strong> voting<br />

.07 n.s.<br />

Western Europe .08 ***<br />

Eastern Europe .15 ***<br />

Data Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each<br />

sample (design weight). Data entries are Pearson’s r.<br />

Elite-challenging activities: “Have done” any of the following activities in the past 12 month: Signed<br />

petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain<br />

products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

Voting: “Did vote in the last national election”.<br />

45 Electoral research has acknowledged the problem of overreporting when assessing electoral participation<br />

in surveys, often caused by the desire of the respondent to engage in socially desirable behavior (Silver,<br />

Anderson <strong>and</strong> Abramson 1986; Karp <strong>and</strong> Brockington 2005).<br />

94


This conclusion is supported by the fact that the linkage (<strong>and</strong> so the discrimination<br />

between these two groups) is strongest in those societies that show a low or modest<br />

participation in elections (see Figure 6-1: Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, UK, Czech Republic,<br />

Luxembourg), suggesting that the smaller active parts in a society tend to engage using<br />

multiple channels of political activism.<br />

6.2 Conventional <strong>Participation</strong><br />

As Verba, Nie <strong>and</strong> Kim (1971, 1978) <strong>and</strong> Barnes <strong>and</strong> Kaase et al. (1979) have argued<br />

there are three modes of political participation besides voting: Campaign activity,<br />

communal activity (working with a group in the community) <strong>and</strong> contacting officials.<br />

This differentiation is supported by a factor analysis based on the ESS data, revealing a<br />

similar structure both in Western <strong>and</strong> Eastern Europe (see Appendix A6-1). Now, Figure<br />

6-2 shifts the perspective to conventional forms of political participation, relating those<br />

levels in a society to its levels of elite-challenging activities. Conventional participation is<br />

displayed at the y-axis, indicating the percentage of people who have participated in at<br />

least one of the four activities during the past 12 months:<br />

- Contacted a politician, government or local official<br />

- Worked in a political party or action group<br />

- Donated money to a political organization or group<br />

- Worked in another organization or association.<br />

These four activities relate to Verba et al.’s modes of democratic participation as working<br />

for a political party or action group as well as donating money can be considered as<br />

campaign activities whereas working in other organizations is a form of communal<br />

activity (see also Dalton 2002).<br />

95


Figure 6-2: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Conventional <strong>Participation</strong> (ESS 2002)<br />

50<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Norway<br />

40<br />

Belgium<br />

Conventional <strong>Participation</strong>, in %<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Greece<br />

Portugal<br />

Hungary<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Italy<br />

Slovenia<br />

Spain<br />

Israel<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Austria<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> Sweden<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Germany<br />

UK<br />

Denmark<br />

0<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging Activities, in %<br />

Data Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R=.80 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities (signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, deliberately<br />

bought certain products for political, ethical or environmental reasons) <strong>and</strong> conventional participation (contacted a<br />

politician, government or local official, worked in a political party or action group, donated money to a political organization<br />

or group, or worked in another organization or association) measure the percentages of respondents in each sample who<br />

have reported to have done any of these activities in the past 12 months.<br />

In contrast to voting, Figure 6-2 reveals a visible linkage between levels of elitechallenging<br />

activities <strong>and</strong> conventional participation. But it is not a negative one, as it<br />

should be if these new activities were developing at the expense of the others. Rather, in<br />

societies where elite-challenging activities are high, participation in conventional forms<br />

also tends to be more pronounced: In Sc<strong>and</strong>inavia <strong>and</strong> the German-speaking societies<br />

both forms are widespread; in Southern Europe <strong>and</strong> in the new democracies of Central<br />

Europe, both forms tend to be low. Considering the limited number of cases, the<br />

correlation coefficient of r = .80 *** should be h<strong>and</strong>led with care. However, the overall<br />

impression of Figure 2 supports the assumption of a positive linkage at the societal level.<br />

Table 6-2 shifts the focus to the relationship between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong><br />

conventional participation at the individual level. Do people who refuse to use traditional<br />

ways to influence politics when they are use alternative ways of participation?<br />

96


Table 6-2:<br />

Individual-Level Correlations between Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

<strong>and</strong> Conventional <strong>Participation</strong> (ESS 2002)<br />

Austria .29 ***<br />

Belgium .30 ***<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> .31 ***<br />

Czech Republic .26 ***<br />

Germany .28 ***<br />

East .28 ***<br />

West .29 ***<br />

Denmark .20 ***<br />

Spain .46 ***<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .18 ***<br />

UK .24 ***<br />

Greece .31 ***<br />

Hungary .26 ***<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .32 ***<br />

Israel .31 ***<br />

Italy .36 ***<br />

Luxembourg .29 ***<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .29 ***<br />

Norway .26 ***<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .33 ***<br />

Portugal .43 ***<br />

Sweden .23 ***<br />

Slovenia .24 ***<br />

Western Europe .33 ***<br />

Eastern Europe .31 ***<br />

Elite-challenging participation <strong>and</strong><br />

conventional participation<br />

Data Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each<br />

sample (design weight). Data entries are Pearson’s r.<br />

Elite-challenging activities: “Have done” any of the following in the past 12 months: signed petition, taken<br />

part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain products for<br />

political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

Conventional participation: “Have done” any of the following in the past 12 months: contacted a politician,<br />

government or local official, worked in a political party or action group, donated money to a political<br />

organization or group, or worked in another organization or association.<br />

Whereas there was only a weak positive linkage between electoral participation <strong>and</strong> elitechallenging<br />

activities at the individual level, elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> conventional<br />

participation are more strongly linked with each other. In all societies, without exception,<br />

the linkage is positive <strong>and</strong> significant, pointing to a considerable correlation of above .30,<br />

barely higher in Western Europe (r = .33) than in Eastern Europe (r = .31). The general<br />

97


level of conventional participation is noticeably lower than voting 46 , <strong>and</strong> the threshold to<br />

become active seems to be more dem<strong>and</strong>ing as the distinction between those who<br />

participate <strong>and</strong> those who do not is more pronounced. In contrast to the previous analysis,<br />

no coherent pattern can be observed when comparing societies with high <strong>and</strong> low levels<br />

of conventional participation: The linkage to elite-challenging participation is strongest in<br />

Portugal, Pol<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Italy (where conventional participation is low) but also in Spain<br />

(medium level) as well as in Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Belgium (high level); the linkage is below<br />

average in Finl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Sweden (where conventional participation is high) but also in<br />

Hungary <strong>and</strong> in Slovenia (low level).<br />

Despite all national differences, in all societies individuals who engage in conventional<br />

activities are more likely to participate in elite-challenging activities than those<br />

individuals who do not engage in the traditional activities. In short, the groups of<br />

participants in elite-challenging <strong>and</strong> conventional activities overlap to a considerable<br />

degree. Accordingly, there is also no obvious trade-off between conventional <strong>and</strong> elitechallenging<br />

activities at the individual level, such that elite-challenging activities would<br />

go at the expense of other political activities. Of all single conventional activities, active<br />

involvement in a political party shows the weakest relationship with elite-challenging<br />

activities (see Appendix A6-2). However, both forms of political participation are still<br />

positively interrelated in all societies except one, so even for the form of political<br />

participation that is conceptually most distinct from elite-challenging activities, no tradeoff<br />

can be observed.<br />

6.3 Civic Activism<br />

<strong>Participation</strong> in voluntary associations is considered to be important for democracy, not<br />

only because of what these organizations do but also because of the skills people acquire<br />

during their interaction with others. Being active in a voluntary association makes<br />

46 Conventional <strong>Participation</strong> varies between a low 16 to 18 percent (Portugal, Hungary, Slovenia, Italy,<br />

Greece, Pol<strong>and</strong>) <strong>and</strong> a high 45 percent in Finl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> Norway. See Figure 6-2.<br />

98


democracy alive at the very grassroots of a society. Moreover, these associations are<br />

regarded as mobilizing agents, providing an organizational context for various kinds of<br />

political activism (Rosenstone <strong>and</strong> Hansen 1993; Norris 2002). This mobilizing theory<br />

would suggest a positive linkage between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> activity in<br />

voluntary associations. The thesis of erosion of political activism, however, proposes a<br />

negative link.<br />

Whereas these propositions rooted in the social capital approach will be tested in more<br />

detail in the next chapter (Chapter 7), the focus now is on the question whether elitechallenging<br />

activities have emerged at the expense of organizational membership. This<br />

question can be examined on a broader empirical basis as the WVS/EVS includes<br />

questions about institutionalized activism, measured by surveying active membership in<br />

formal organizations. From the variety of voluntary associations, not all have a distinct<br />

political character. Active members in sports associations, cultural organizations or<br />

church groups, for example, contribute to communal life but their activities are less<br />

motivated by an attempt to influence policy makers. By contrast, there are other<br />

organizations where most of the goals are inherently of a political kind, or whose<br />

activities <strong>and</strong> decisions have implications for the political process. Considering these<br />

organizations, a factor analysis (see Appendix A6-3) showed two distinct types of<br />

voluntary associations where people can be politically active: a first type is composed of<br />

political parties, labor unions <strong>and</strong> professional associations as organizations of interest<br />

representation. As a second type, civic action groups can be distinguished. These are<br />

organizations that are issued-based, concerned with social welfare service, human rights,<br />

youth work, women’s rights, peace movement, environmental issues as well as local<br />

community action groups.<br />

Figure 6-3 shows how elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> activity in interest organizations<br />

are linked at the societal level, <strong>and</strong> the figure reveals a U-shaped pattern between these<br />

two forms of political engagement.<br />

99


Figure 6-3:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Activity in Interest Organizations<br />

(WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

25<br />

Activity in interest organizations, in %<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

Albania<br />

USA<br />

Sweden<br />

India<br />

Moldova<br />

Slovakia<br />

Macedonia<br />

Greece Canada<br />

South Africa<br />

Great Britain<br />

R omania Peru<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong><br />

D enmark<br />

Philippines<br />

South Korea Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Bulgaria Croatia Malta Finl<strong>and</strong> Italy<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Chile<br />

Slovenia<br />

Austria Belgium<br />

Mexico Bosnia <strong>and</strong> Herzegovina<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Uk raineRussia<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Hungary<br />

ArgentinaSerbia <strong>and</strong> Montenegro<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Spain<br />

Latvia Japan<br />

Estonia Lithuania<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

France<br />

East Germany<br />

Portugal<br />

W est Germany<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

Data Source: World Values Survey/European Values Survey 1999-2001. R = .24 n.s.<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Measured as percentage of respondents per sample who report to “Have done” any of the<br />

following activities: signed a petition, joined in boycotts, attended lawful demonstrations, joining unofficial strikes, or<br />

occupying buildings or factories.<br />

Activity in interest organizations: Measured as percentage of respondents per sample who report to be currently doing<br />

unpaid voluntary work for political parties, labor unions, or professional associations.<br />

Even considering that the activity rates for organizational activity seem to be based on<br />

over-reporting for Albania or India, high levels of elite-challenging activities in a society<br />

are not generally associated with high levels of activity in interest organizations. The<br />

latter is true for Sweden or the USA, but not for Germany, Japan <strong>and</strong> France where elitechallenging<br />

activities are high but organizational activity in interest organizations is low.<br />

So at large, the extent to which people are active in interest organizations in a society<br />

only seems barely to contribute to mobilizing people into elite-challenging activities (r =<br />

.24 n.s.).<br />

The picture looks a little different for activity in citizen action groups. Figure 6-4<br />

suggests that there is a rather positive linkage between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong><br />

100


participation in citizen action groups at the aggregate level. In societies where a lot of<br />

people are engaged in citizen action groups, people tend to participate more in elitechallenging<br />

activities (r = .41 ** ).<br />

Figure 6-4:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Activity in Citizen Action Groups<br />

(WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

50<br />

45<br />

Activity in citizen action groups, in %<br />

40<br />

35<br />

30<br />

25<br />

20<br />

15<br />

10<br />

5<br />

0<br />

Philippines<br />

Albania<br />

South Africa<br />

Greece<br />

Canada<br />

Slovakia<br />

C hile<br />

South Korea<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Luxembourg<br />

India Peru<br />

Macedonia Finl<strong>and</strong> Icel<strong>and</strong><br />

Belgium<br />

Mexico Moldova Slovenia<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Denmark<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Malta Austria<br />

Argentina<br />

I taly<br />

Japan<br />

Bosnia <strong>and</strong> Herzegovina<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Spain<br />

France<br />

Estonia<br />

Hungary<br />

Croatia<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

West Germany<br />

Bulgaria Portugal Serbia <strong>and</strong> Montenegro<br />

East Germany<br />

Romania Ukraine<br />

Lithuania Latvia<br />

Russia<br />

USA<br />

Great Britain<br />

Sweden<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

Data Source: World Values Survey/European Values Survey 1999-2001. R = .41 ** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Measured as percentage of respondents per sample who report to “Have done” any of the<br />

following activities: signed a petition, joined in boycotts, attended lawful demonstrations, joining unofficial strikes, or<br />

occupying buildings or factories.<br />

Activity in citizen action groups: Measured as percentage of respondents per sample who report to be currently doing<br />

unpaid voluntary work for social welfare service organizations, human rights organizations, youth work organizations, local<br />

community action groups, women’s groups, peace movement, organizations for environment, conservation, or animal<br />

rights.<br />

This finding is quite logical: political engagement from below, as displayed through<br />

demonstrations, petitions, etc., is by definition a grassroots activity. These forms of<br />

political participation became widespread <strong>and</strong> normal for large parts of the populace in<br />

postindustrial democracies as citizen action groups were rising in the context of a general<br />

advent of new social movements, dealing with issues that were considered to be<br />

101


insufficiently represented by traditional institutions of interest aggregation <strong>and</strong><br />

articulation such as political parties. In short, elite-challenging activities demonstrate the<br />

ways citizen groups try to exercise political influence from below (Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels<br />

1996: 27). The positive relationship between these particular associations <strong>and</strong> elitechallenging<br />

activities reflect, therefore, the distinct positive opportunity structure<br />

prevalent in a society for people to participate in these activities. So, if elite-challenging<br />

activities did not show a trade-off with other forms of political activism at the societal<br />

level, this is all the more true for activism in civic action groups. This result is different<br />

from the findings in Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels (1996: 29) where ‘traditional organizational<br />

memberships’ (corresponding to my interest organizations) turned out to be a better<br />

predictor for levels of legal protests than ‘memberships in new organizations’<br />

(corresponding to the citizen action groups considered here). 47<br />

Whether the positive linkage at the societal level also holds at the individual level is<br />

addressed in Table 6-3, complemented by a test of individual-level correlations between<br />

elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> active participation in interest organizations.<br />

Examining the question whether people tend to be active in one form or another, or in<br />

both forms of political participation, Table 6-3 shows, in general, a weak positive<br />

(however significant) linkage between elite-challenging activities on the one h<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the<br />

two different forms of civic activism on the other h<strong>and</strong>, suggesting that people, if they<br />

once surmounted the threshold of political activism, also tend to use multiple channels to<br />

become politically engaged. However, an important qualification should be made with<br />

regard to two groups of societies. Whereas one group shows overall a similar correlation<br />

with both types of organizational engagement (that is in postindustrial societies <strong>and</strong> the<br />

new member states of the European Union, meaning the more Western oriented new<br />

democracies in Central Europe as well as the Baltic states), all other societies are<br />

characterized by a linkage that is much stronger between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong><br />

47 The different result may be explained with three crucial differences in the design of the study. First,<br />

Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels (1996) base their conclusions on 16 postindustrial democracies, limiting their analyses<br />

to societies within Western Europe <strong>and</strong> North America. Second, their measurement of activity in voluntary<br />

associations includes passive membership whereas mine only takes active members into account, as I am<br />

interested in political activism. Third, their ‘new organizations’ under consideration are limited to three<br />

voluntary associations: environmental, peace <strong>and</strong> animal rights groups. Important other citizen action<br />

groups like human rights organizations, organized women’s movements or social welfare groups remain<br />

unconsidered.<br />

102


interest organizations than the one between these activities <strong>and</strong> citizen action groups. In<br />

other words, active members in political parties, labor unions <strong>and</strong> professional<br />

associations are more likely to participate in elite-challenging activities than activists in<br />

citizen action groups. Here in this group of societies, where elite-challenging activities<br />

are in general less pronounced, people seem to be mobilized into demonstrations,<br />

petitions, etc. rather through their active role in interest associations than through citizen<br />

action groups. The closer linkage between citizen action groups concerned with human<br />

rights, environmental issues or social questions, <strong>and</strong> activities outside traditional channels<br />

of political participation seems to be largely a characteristic of postindustrial<br />

democracies, as also the picture at the aggregate level suggested. The fact that the<br />

individual-level correlation between the two forms of activity has become stronger in<br />

these postindustrial societies supports this impression. 48<br />

Table 6-3:<br />

Individual-Level Correlation between Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Civic Activism (WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

Elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong><br />

citizen action groups<br />

Elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong><br />

interest organizations<br />

Austria .07 ** .09 ***<br />

Belgium .09 *** .08 **<br />

Canada .15 *** .12 ***<br />

Denmark .07 * .11 **<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .05 .12 ***<br />

France .04 .07 **<br />

Greece .07 * .12 ***<br />

Germany .05 * .06 *<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> .08 * .12 ***<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .10 ** .09 **<br />

Italy .09 *** .14 ***<br />

Japan .08 ** .05<br />

Luxembourg .08 ** .06 *<br />

Malta .07 * .15 ***<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .10 ** .10 **<br />

Portugal .14 *** .10 **<br />

Spain .11 *** .14 ***<br />

Sweden .04 .04<br />

48 The correlation coefficient for elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> activity in citizen action groups doubled in<br />

these societies between 1981 <strong>and</strong> 1999 from r = .06 to r = .11. The coefficient for activity in interest<br />

organizations remained the same: r = .11 in 1981, r = .12 in 1999. All correlation coefficients were<br />

significant at the .00 level.<br />

103


Continued:<br />

Elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong><br />

citizen action groups<br />

Elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong><br />

interest organizations<br />

Great Britain .04 .02<br />

USA .08 ** .08 **<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> .13 *** .07 *<br />

Postindustrial societies .13 *** .12 ***<br />

Slovenia .03 .04<br />

Croatia .17 *** .07 *<br />

Czech Republic .04 .07 **<br />

Hungary .12 *** .09 **<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .06 * .10 **<br />

Slovakia .05 .15 ***<br />

Ex-communist Western societies .12 *** .12 ***<br />

Albania .01 .15 ***<br />

Bosnia <strong>and</strong> Herzegovina .10 ** .11 ***<br />

Bulgaria .15 *** .10 **<br />

Romania .01 .31 ***<br />

Republic of Macedonia .14 *** .21 ***<br />

Serbia <strong>and</strong> Montenegro .03 .10 ***<br />

Ex-communist Eastern societies .10 *** .17 ***<br />

Republic of Moldova .09 ** .15 ***<br />

Russia .06 ** .08 ***<br />

Ukraine .05 .10 ***<br />

Ex-communist soviet societies .07 *** .12 ***<br />

Estonia .16 *** .12 ***<br />

Latvia .10 ** .09 **<br />

Lithuania .04 .10 **<br />

Ex-communist Baltic societies .10 *** .10 ***<br />

Argentina .08 ** .18 ***<br />

Chile .11 *** .17 ***<br />

Mexico .14 *** .15 ***<br />

Peru .05 .13 ***<br />

Latin American societies .09 *** .16 ***<br />

South Africa .01 .19 ***<br />

Other developing societies .01 .19 ***<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a .06 .19 ***<br />

Philippines .10 ** .16 ***<br />

India .14 *** .27 ***<br />

Low-income societies .10 *** .24 ***<br />

Average All .11 *** .12 ***<br />

Source: World Values Survey/European Values Survey 1999-2001. Data are weighted (n = 1.000 for group<br />

averages). Data entries are Pearson’s r.<br />

Elite-challenging activities: “Have done” any of the following activities: signed a petition, joined in<br />

boycotts, attended lawful demonstrations, joining unofficial strikes, or occupying buildings or factories.<br />

Activity in interest organizations: Currently doing unpaid voluntary work for political parties, labor unions,<br />

or professional associations.<br />

Activity in citizen action groups: Currently doing unpaid voluntary work for social welfare service<br />

organizations, human rights organizations, youth work organizations, local community action groups,<br />

women’s groups, peace movement, organizations for environment, conservation, or animal rights.<br />

104


Figure 6-5 takes up the trend depictions of the previous chapter, documenting how the<br />

two forms of civic activism have developed over a time period of 20 years compared to<br />

elite-challenging activities. Unfortunately, longitudinal data are not available for all<br />

voluntary associations included so far. For a comparison over time, activity in citizen<br />

action groups is limited to social welfare organizations, youth work groups <strong>and</strong> human<br />

rights organizations. A factor analysis confirmed that the conceptual differentiation<br />

between interest organizations <strong>and</strong> citizen action groups is still valid for the reduced<br />

measure (see Appendix A6-4).<br />

Figure 6-5 shows the rise of elite-challenging activities in established postindustrial<br />

democracies, <strong>and</strong> this increase is even more impressive when displayed against the other<br />

two forms of political activism. During the 1980ies <strong>and</strong> 1990ies participation in<br />

demonstrations, petitions or boycotts increased by 20 percent points to a level where, on<br />

average, two thirds of the populations use these forms of activity.<br />

Figure 6-5: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Civic Activism in Selected<br />

Postindustrial Democracies 1981-1999 (WVS/EVS)<br />

70<br />

Elite-challenging activities<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

1981 1990 1999<br />

Citizen action groups<br />

Interest organizations<br />

Source: World Values Survey/European Values Survey. Data are weighted n = 1.000.<br />

Societies included: Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finl<strong>and</strong>, France, Icel<strong>and</strong>, Irel<strong>and</strong>, Italy, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Spain, Sweden,<br />

Great Britain, Northern Irel<strong>and</strong>, USA, West Germany.<br />

By contrast, people’s engagement in voluntary associations showed only minor<br />

fluctuation over time, largely staying at the same level: below 10 percent for active<br />

membership in associations for interest representation, <strong>and</strong> a little above 10 percent for<br />

105


unpaid voluntary work in citizen action groups. These results do not suggest that elitechallenging<br />

activities became more widespread at the expense of other forms of political<br />

activism.<br />

This outcome can be generalized as no trade-off between elite-challenging <strong>and</strong> other<br />

forms of political activism could be observed. At the aggregate level, the share of people<br />

taking part in demonstrations, petitions, buy- or boycotts was not linked to voter turnout.<br />

A positive relationship was found for conventional participation, suggesting that if a<br />

society has generally a higher level of political participation, also participation outside<br />

traditional channels is more pronounced. Finally, a positive linkage could be found<br />

between the level of associational activity <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities, highlighting<br />

the significance of a mobilizing context that provides opportunities for citizens to become<br />

politically active. At the individual level, elite-challenging activities were only weakly<br />

correlated with voting but positively linked with forms of conventional participation,<br />

again suggesting that if people become active, they aim at influencing the political<br />

decision-making process through multiple activities. This also applies to the personal<br />

organizational context (although societal differences were pronounced) that mobilizes<br />

people through direct contacts into elite-challenging activities, both in interest<br />

organizations <strong>and</strong> citizens action groups. The following chapter examines this in more<br />

detail, putting elite-challenging activities in the broader context of social capital research.<br />

106


7. Down <strong>and</strong> Down We Go? Social Capital <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

The previous two chapters have provided little empirical evidence that could support the<br />

thesis of widespread political disengagement: neither is civic activism in general going<br />

down, nor have elite-challenging activities found their way into people’s action repertoire<br />

only at the expense of other forms of political participation. This chapter now turns to the<br />

question how participation in demonstrations, petitions, boy- <strong>and</strong> buy-cotts is linked with<br />

forms of social participation. 49<br />

Social participation is usually described as individual engagement on voluntary basis in<br />

clubs, unions or voluntary associations. The socializing aspect <strong>and</strong> the frequent<br />

interaction among members have made scholars celebrate the democratic benefits of<br />

people’s social participation as it is supposed to promote values of cooperation, trust <strong>and</strong><br />

reciprocity (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Rochon 1998; Rossteutscher 1999; Putnam 2000; Stolle 2001;<br />

Wollebeck <strong>and</strong> Selle 2002).<br />

The linkage between social participation <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities is not necessarily<br />

straightforward. Following Hirschman (1979), van Deth (1997: 10) has argued that<br />

limited time resources may make people reconsider their initial decision to become<br />

engaged in multiple ways - sooner or later, individuals opt for only one form of activity.<br />

This could imply that both forms of community involvement, social participation <strong>and</strong><br />

elite-challenging activities, are not or even negatively correlated. There are, however,<br />

good reasons to believe that quite the opposite is true. As examining the relationship<br />

between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> other forms of political participation has shown,<br />

participation tends to breed participation, both on the individual <strong>and</strong> on the societal level.<br />

This may also be true for social participation in associations: On the one h<strong>and</strong>, voluntary<br />

associations can provide a ‘close mobilization context’: As people are embedded in social<br />

networks, direct <strong>and</strong> indirect contacting of potential participants is facilitated (Rosenstone<br />

<strong>and</strong> Hansen 1993; Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels 1996). Similarly, the density of social networks at<br />

the societal level can present a ‘wide participation context’ or ‘organizing capacity’<br />

(Wessels 1997) of a society. As people also respond to the chances they are given,<br />

49 The empirical analyses are based on the European Social Survey 2002. Their module on “Citizenship,<br />

Involvement <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>” explicitly included questions on different aspects of social capital.<br />

107


participation in elite-challenging activities should be higher in those societies where more<br />

people are involved in voluntary associations. In these societies, the density of networks<br />

creates more opportunities, thus contributing to favorable external conditions for<br />

participation.<br />

On both levels, the focus is on favorable conditions that mobilize people into collective<br />

activities, i.e. demonstrations. Voluntary associations contribute to these conditions from<br />

a networks perspective, but they are not the only factors. From a cultural perspective, by<br />

contrast, it is the norms of reciprocity <strong>and</strong> social trust that are conducive to participation.<br />

Both approaches are closely linked with (<strong>and</strong> often combined in) the concept of social<br />

capital – as structural <strong>and</strong> cultural preconditions for cooperation among individuals.<br />

The fuzzy concept of social capital<br />

As democratic societies do not function without a minimum of social cohesion, social<br />

capital has been considered to be precisely that glue that holds a society together. “It is a<br />

social force that binds society together by transforming individuals from self-seeking <strong>and</strong><br />

egocentric calculators, with little social conscience or sense of mutual obligation, into<br />

members of a community with shared interests, shared assumptions about social<br />

relations, <strong>and</strong> a sense of the common good” (Newton 2001: 226). With its potential to<br />

solve the collective action dilemma <strong>and</strong> to enable people to act together with others, the<br />

concept of social capital has gained great significance among social scientists <strong>and</strong> policymakers<br />

during the past 15 years.<br />

Strangely, it seems that the constant attention paid to this concept has led to more<br />

conceptual confusion than definitional clarity. Besides the question whether to locate<br />

social capital on the individual or the societal level (or both), scholars have also<br />

emphasized different elements when working with the concept. Whereas Bourdieu <strong>and</strong><br />

others (Bourdieu 1983; Coleman 1988, 1990) have argued in favor of a minimalist<br />

definition of social capital that is limited to the structural component, the networks <strong>and</strong><br />

ties that enable people to engage in collective actions, others have exp<strong>and</strong>ed the concept.<br />

Putnam, for example, has added a motivational or cultural component to the structures,<br />

focusing on norms of reciprocity <strong>and</strong> trustworthiness that arise within the networks<br />

(Putnam 2000: 19). In this sense networks per se, no matter how dense they are, are not<br />

108


enough to stimulate people into action if they lack the resources, that is the norms <strong>and</strong><br />

values, to do so (Norris 2002: 138). A third group has included an additional component<br />

into the concept of social capital - civic engagement - as the first two “represent only<br />

necessary not sufficient conditions” (Wollebaek <strong>and</strong> Selle 2002: 34). The problem<br />

becomes immediately evident: The more characteristics are used to describe social<br />

capital, the more the concept becomes overloaded, <strong>and</strong> the more difficult it is to<br />

differentiate between what social capital needs (community ties), what it is (resourcebased<br />

capabilities, institution-based incentives, <strong>and</strong> value-based motivators), <strong>and</strong> what it<br />

does (producing collective action, that is all kinds of voluntary communal activities, see<br />

Welzel, Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Deutsch 2005: 141).<br />

Since this is not a study about social capital per se but it is interested in that concept only<br />

insofar as it has an impact on elite-challenging activities as a form of mass action, it<br />

seems to be useful to disentangle the concept of social capital <strong>and</strong> examine its levels<br />

(individual <strong>and</strong> societal level) <strong>and</strong> components separately. As the core social capital<br />

literature distinguishes between the structural component <strong>and</strong> the motivational (or<br />

cultural) component of social capital, the focus will be on the two 50 . The structural or<br />

network approach to social capital is the least contested in the literature, so emphasis will<br />

be on its capacities to mobilize people into elite-challenging activities.<br />

7.1 The Structural Component: Voluntary Associations <strong>and</strong> Informal Networks<br />

Both theoretically <strong>and</strong> empirically, it is one of the most widely held claims in social<br />

science research that democracies cannot function without people taking part in political<br />

decision-making processes. Beyond political engagement, the past 15 years have also<br />

seen scholars re-emphasizing the importance of social participation as a core<br />

50 Following Welzel, Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Deutsch (2005), elite-challenging activities as a form of collective<br />

action are considered as an indicator for the productivity of social capital, not as a measure of social capital<br />

itself. So, elite-challenging mass action is the dependent variable, social capital the independent one. If one<br />

follows Wollebaek <strong>and</strong> Selle (2002) in their presumption to consider civic engagement as a component of<br />

social capital (<strong>and</strong> not as its consequence), then examining the relationship between social capital <strong>and</strong> elitechallenging<br />

activities would take place within the limits of the social capital concept. More precisely, this<br />

would mean to test the relationship between the structural <strong>and</strong> motivational component of social capital on<br />

the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> the civic engagement component on the other h<strong>and</strong>.<br />

109


characteristic of democratic societies (Putnam 2000; Edwards, Foley <strong>and</strong> Diani 2001;<br />

Van Deth 2004). At the workplace, among families <strong>and</strong> friends, or in clubs <strong>and</strong> other<br />

organizations people interact on a regular basis, building up feelings of belongingness<br />

<strong>and</strong> identity, thus diminishing the distances between people <strong>and</strong> reducing social isolation<br />

(van Deth 2004: 295).<br />

With its particular importance for civil society, engagement in voluntary associations has<br />

been at the very heart of social participation research. Edwards <strong>and</strong> Foley (2001: 5-6)<br />

argue that voluntary associations fulfill three main functions in a democratic society (see<br />

also Warren 2001 <strong>and</strong> Fung 2003). The first two are external functions: In one way or<br />

another, many of the voluntary associations have objectives to help <strong>and</strong> support the weak,<br />

the poor <strong>and</strong> other disadvantaged groups in a society, through which they carry out<br />

‘public <strong>and</strong> quasi-public functions’. In addition, they are groups of interest articulation<br />

<strong>and</strong> aggregation. Advocating different, sometimes diverging interests, voluntary<br />

associations have a ‘representative or contestatory function’ (Edwards <strong>and</strong> Foley 2001: 5-<br />

6). Van Deth describes this as the macro-perspective when examining voluntary<br />

associations, as the organizations’ success in mediating between citizen groups, or<br />

citizens <strong>and</strong> the state, contributes to system integration at large (van Deth 1997: 1-2).<br />

Much more important from the social capital perspective is the internal function of<br />

voluntary associations. From a micro-perspective, attention is paid to mobilization <strong>and</strong><br />

socialization aspects. Since de Tocqueville (2000 [1837/40]) voluntary associations have<br />

been described as schools of democracy, underlining the importance of regular face-toface<br />

meetings. People learn to argue, to deliberate <strong>and</strong> to reach compromises despite<br />

differences of opinion; they develop a sense of responsibility, learn how to trust each<br />

other <strong>and</strong> to form a stronger sense of community (Rossteutscher 1999: 3). So, voluntary<br />

associations have an internal socialization <strong>and</strong> education function for their members<br />

(Wollebeck <strong>and</strong> Selle 2002: 35), considered to be important for the creation <strong>and</strong><br />

transmission of social capital. Whether <strong>and</strong> under what conditions those skills acquired<br />

through interaction with other members can transcend the boundaries of the association is<br />

one of the core questions of social capital research.<br />

110


The European Social Survey (ESS 2002) asks the respondents about their membership<br />

during the past 12 months in the following voluntary associations (see Appendix A7-1 for<br />

question wording):<br />

- sports club or club for outdoor activities,<br />

- organization for cultural or hobby activities,<br />

- trade union,<br />

- business, professional or farmers’ organization,<br />

- consumer or automobile organization,<br />

- organization for humanitarian aid, human rights, minorities or immigrants,<br />

- organization for environmental protection, peace or animal rights,<br />

- religious or church organization,<br />

- political party,<br />

- organization for science, education, teachers or parents,<br />

- social club, club for the young, the retired/elderly, women or friendly societies.<br />

As virtually all scholars agree that social capital needs a structural basis to develop <strong>and</strong> to<br />

be transmitted, people’s connectedness provides the structural precondition for<br />

cooperation among individuals. On the aggregate level, organizational membership in a<br />

society provides a good measure for the organizing capacity of a society (Wessels 1997:<br />

199-200). So, membership in voluntary associations is calculated as the share of people<br />

in a society organized in at least one association. Figure 7-1 shows how membership in<br />

associations <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities are linked at the societal level.<br />

111


Figure 7-1: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Membership in Associations (ESS 2002)<br />

80<br />

70<br />

Sweden<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Spain<br />

Israel<br />

UK<br />

Norway Denmark<br />

Germany<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Belgium<br />

Austria<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Italy<br />

20<br />

10<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Greece<br />

Hungary<br />

Portugal<br />

Slovenia<br />

0<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Membership in any association, in %<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R = .91 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Percentage of respondents who “Have done” any of the following activities in the past 12<br />

month: Signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain<br />

products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

Membership in any association: Percentage of respondents who are a member in any of the following organizations:<br />

sports club or club for outdoor activities; organization for cultural or hobby activities; trade union; business, professional or<br />

farmers’ organization; consumer or automobile organization; organization for humanitarian aid, human rights, minorities or<br />

immigrants; organization for environmental protection, peace or animal rights; religious or church organization; political<br />

party; organization for science, education, teachers or parents; social club, club for the young, the retired/elderly, women<br />

or friendly societies.<br />

As Figure 7-1 clearly reveals, in societies that are characterized by a vibrant associational<br />

life, the level of elite-challenging activities is comparably high (r = .91 *** ). The<br />

Sc<strong>and</strong>inavian societies, for example, show both a great integration of the population into<br />

organizations <strong>and</strong> the highest level of elite-challenging activities, whereas the new<br />

democracies in Central Eastern Europe as well as the Southern European societies rank<br />

low in both organizational membership <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities. Apparently, the<br />

characteristics of societal networks shape the wider context of mass action (Roller <strong>and</strong><br />

Wessels 1996: 26). The density of such networks affects how easy (or hard) it is to<br />

mobilize people into action. The closer the ties in a society, the lower the barrier to other<br />

forms of participation, independently of individual attributes: “You don’t even have to be<br />

112


a member of one single organization (…) in order to profit from the fact that in this<br />

society the transaction cost are low” (van Deth 2001: 9). As a consequence, collective<br />

action in form of elite-challenging activities is much more likely to occur in those<br />

societies where low transaction costs provide the opportunity structure to do so.<br />

That the sheer membership levels, irrespectively of the role that members hold within<br />

these organizations, already show such a clear linkage with elite-challenging activities at<br />

the societal level should not be considered as self-evident. Within the social capital<br />

approach, one controversial issue is the question whether membership in voluntary<br />

associations is already enough to create social capital. Putnam, for example, has argued<br />

that membership without activity does not contribute to the emergence of social capital:<br />

“What really matters from the point of view of social capital <strong>and</strong> civic engagement is not<br />

merely nominal membership, but active <strong>and</strong> involved membership” (Putnam 2000: 58).<br />

According to Putnam, social capital can only emerge <strong>and</strong> be conferred when people<br />

directly interact. Where regular face-to-face encounters do not take place, for example<br />

because the members of an association only meet sporadically, communicate through<br />

email lists or limit their involvement to reading the organization’s newsletter, social<br />

capital is not built. So, activity levels, not membership rates are the appropriate measure<br />

for social capital. Others, however, have shown that empirically there is hardly any<br />

difference between active <strong>and</strong> passive members of an association (Wollebaek <strong>and</strong> Selle<br />

2002).<br />

For the societal level, the Figures 7-2 <strong>and</strong> 7-3 demonstrate that the results of Wollebaek<br />

<strong>and</strong> Selle’s Norwegian study can be more or less corroborated: Active membership in an<br />

organization as well as social participation in general are also highly correlated with elitechallenging<br />

activities – but the linkages are even weaker than for pure membership in the<br />

previous measure of social capital.<br />

113


Figure 7-2: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Active Membership in Associations<br />

80<br />

70<br />

Sweden<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Israel<br />

Italy<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Spain<br />

Hungary<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Austria<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Slovenia<br />

Germany<br />

Belgium<br />

UK<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Norway<br />

Denmark<br />

10<br />

Portugal<br />

Greece<br />

0<br />

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50<br />

Active membership, in %<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R = .72 ** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Percentage of respondents who “Have done” any of the following activities in the past 12<br />

month: Signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain<br />

products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

Active Membership: Percentage of respondents who are members <strong>and</strong> participated in activities of any of the following<br />

organizations during the past 12 months: sports club or club for outdoor activities; organization for cultural or hobby<br />

activities; trade union; business, professional or farmers’ organization; consumer or automobile organization; organization<br />

for humanitarian aid, human rights, minorities or immigrants; organization for environmental protection, peace or animal<br />

rights; religious or church organization; political party; organization for science, education, teachers or parents; social club,<br />

club for the young, the retired/elderly, women or friendly societies.<br />

Figure 7-2 shows that the level of organizational engagement drops considerably when<br />

the focus is shifted from pure membership figures to active membership, limiting the<br />

scope to those members who, during the past 12 months, have participated in<br />

organizational activities or voluntarily worked for an association. 51 The linkage to elitechallenging<br />

activities is weaker but remains positive, significant <strong>and</strong> considerably high (r<br />

= .72 *** ). In Figure 7-3 the formal aspect of membership cards is entirely disregarded by<br />

just looking at levels of activity (participation or voluntary work) in the context of<br />

51 See Appendix A7-1 for a detailed overview about active membership in all voluntary associations.<br />

114


associations. Social activity in European societies is by far less pronounced than mere<br />

membership rates 52 ; but it also becomes obvious that the various forms of organizational<br />

activities are not only put into practice by members of an association. Again, elitechallenging<br />

activities are most widespread in those societies that also show high levels of<br />

organizational activities (r = .87 *** ).<br />

Figure 7-3: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Social Activity (ESS 2002)<br />

80<br />

70<br />

Sweden<br />

Elite-challenging activities<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Germ any Denmark<br />

UK Norway<br />

Luxembourg Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Austria<br />

Belgium<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Israel<br />

Spain<br />

Italy<br />

20<br />

10<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Greece<br />

Hungary<br />

Portugal<br />

Slovenia<br />

0<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60<br />

Social activity, in %<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R = .87 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Percentage of respondents who “Have done” any of the following activities in the past 12<br />

month: Signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain<br />

products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

Social Activity: Percentage of respondents who participated in activities or did voluntary work in any of the following<br />

organizations during the past 12 months: sports club or club for outdoor activities; organization for cultural or hobby<br />

activities; trade union; business, professional or farmers’ organization; consumer or automobile organization; organization<br />

for humanitarian aid, human rights, minorities or immigrants; organization for environmental protection, peace or animal<br />

rights; religious or church organization; political party; organization for science, education, teachers or parents; social club,<br />

club for the young, the retired/elderly, women or friendly societies.<br />

So far, the focus has been on the diffusion of networks in a society, measured by a<br />

society’s share of people involved in at least one organization. The idea was that societies<br />

52 For an overview, see Appendix A7-2.<br />

115


differ in their capability to accumulate productive social capital because they differ in the<br />

degree to which people can be educated, contacted <strong>and</strong> mobilized through formal<br />

channels of associations (<strong>and</strong> people not being part of such networks).<br />

Others, however, have argued that social capital has the potential to be more productive<br />

when networks in a society are stronger <strong>and</strong> more diverse, meaning if the society is<br />

steeped in a variety of different horizontal ties. Assuming that the productivity of social<br />

capital in a society should increase the more its members are interconnected, Figure 7-4<br />

looks at the average number of associational membership. Also this measure of the<br />

structural aspect of social capital is highly correlated with elite-challenging activities (r =<br />

.89 *** ).<br />

Figure 7-4:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Average Membership in European<br />

Societies (ESS 2002)<br />

80<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Italy<br />

Spain<br />

UK<br />

Germany<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Belgium<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Israel<br />

Sweden<br />

Denmark<br />

Luxembourg Norway<br />

Austria<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

20<br />

10<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Greece<br />

Hungary<br />

Portugal<br />

Slovenia<br />

0<br />

0.00 0.20 0.40 0.60 0.80 1.00 1.20 1.40 1.60 1.80 2.00 2.20 2.40 2.60<br />

Average number of memberships<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R = .89 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Percentage of respondents who “Have done” any of the following activities in the past 12<br />

month: Signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain<br />

products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

Average number of membership: see previous figures for the different organizations.<br />

The fact that the vast majority of the social capital literature has focused on voluntary<br />

associations (be it active or passive membership) has not escaped criticism. It has a long<br />

116


tradition to assume that organizations help to convey values <strong>and</strong> norms related to<br />

interpersonal trust, reciprocity <strong>and</strong> compromises, thus enabling people to cooperate for<br />

mutual benefit: “The associations are thought to play a major role, if not the major role,<br />

in building citizenship skills <strong>and</strong> attitudes crucial for motivating citizens to use these<br />

skills” (Edwards <strong>and</strong> Foley 2001: 5).<br />

Others like Newton (1999: 185) have argued that the empirical test of this assumption has<br />

not sufficiently corroborated the link between voluntary associations, social capital <strong>and</strong><br />

democracy. In particular the effect of voluntary associations on pro-democratic values is<br />

found (if at all) to be rather modest (Hooghe 2003: 48). Whereas Hooghe (2003)<br />

identified measurement problems on the part of associational membership as the main<br />

reason for the weak linkage, Newton objected <strong>and</strong> held the almost exclusive focus on<br />

voluntary associations as the main source for social capital responsible. Other forms of<br />

social networks have often remained unconsidered, neglecting their potential to create<br />

social capital: “The more informal networks, with horizontal linkages, may now be more<br />

important for the creation of abstract trust in modern societies” (Newton 2001: 232).<br />

Family, friends, the workplace <strong>and</strong> other communities are interpersonal networks which<br />

essentially shape people’s values. There is good reason to believe that these networks are<br />

more important than formal membership ties because people tend to spend more time in<br />

these informal networks than in clubs or unions (besides the fact that large minorities are<br />

not part of organizational networks at all), <strong>and</strong> they are usually emotionally more<br />

attached (Newton 2001: 229).<br />

The European Social Survey (ESS 2002) provides some indicators for informal networks,<br />

assessing the scope of respondents’ social contacts:<br />

(1) Frequency of social contacts: “Using this card, how often do you meet socially<br />

with friends, relatives, or work colleagues?” Answers ranging from 1 (“never”) to<br />

7 (“every day”).<br />

(2) Level of social activities: “Compared to other people of your age, how often<br />

would you say you take part in social activities? Please use this card.” Answers<br />

ranging from 1 (“Much less than most”) to 5 (”Much more than most”).<br />

117


(3) Having a friend to share personal matters: “Do you have anyone with whom you<br />

can discuss intimate <strong>and</strong> personal matters?” The original answers “yes/no” were<br />

recoded, so that the higher value indicates the availability of an intimate friend.<br />

Table 7-1 summarizes the three items in separate factor analyses on aggregate <strong>and</strong><br />

individual level, showing for both levels a single-factor result. The factor scores on<br />

aggregate level are used in Figure 7-5 to measure the strength of informal networks in a<br />

society as a proxy for the structural component of social capital. Again, the linkage<br />

between this aspect of social capital <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities is positive <strong>and</strong><br />

pronounced (r = .75 *** ), indicating that not only voluntary associations create productive<br />

social capital but that other informal networks teach people how to coordinate their<br />

activities for mutual benefit.<br />

Table 7-1: Factor Analyses for Measures of Informal Networks (ESS 2002):<br />

Aggregate<br />

Individual level<br />

level Western Europe Eastern Europe<br />

Frequency of social contacts .77 .75 .79<br />

Level of social activities .95 .73 .81<br />

Having a friend to share personal matters .78 .57 .47<br />

Explained variance 70% 47% 50%<br />

KMO .48 .57 .54<br />

Bartlett’s test of sphericity 24.798 *** 3516.989 *** 1075.140 ***<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for population size.<br />

Societies included: Austria, Belgium, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Germany, Denmark, Spain, Finl<strong>and</strong>, UK, Greece,<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong>, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Norway, Portugal, Sweden (all Western Europe). Czech Republic,<br />

Hungary, Pol<strong>and</strong>, Slovenia (all Eastern Europe).<br />

118


Figure 7-5:<br />

Informal Networks in European Societies <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities (ESS 2002)<br />

80<br />

70<br />

Sweden<br />

Elite-challenging activit ies, in %<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Italy<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Luxembourg Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Belgium<br />

Austria<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Israel<br />

Spain<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

UK<br />

Germany<br />

Denmark<br />

Norway<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

20<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Slovenia<br />

10<br />

Hungary<br />

Greece<br />

Portugal<br />

0<br />

-2.40 -2.00 -1.60 -1.20 -0.80 -0.40 0.00 0.40 0.80 1.20 1.60 2.00<br />

Strength of informal networks<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R = .75 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Percentage of respondents who “Have done” any of the following activities in the past 12<br />

month: Signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain<br />

products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

Strength of informal networks: Factor scores (aggregate level), see Table 7-1.<br />

The degree to which the members of a society are interconnected through horizontal ties<br />

has a great impact on the productivity of social capital. Irrespective of the measures of the<br />

structural aspect of social capital – formal membership in voluntary associations,<br />

voluntary work or other forms of activity in the context of these organizations, or other<br />

informal networks – the more a society is characterized through networks, the more<br />

people are involved in elite-challenging forms of collective activities.<br />

Table 7-2 turns to the question whether this linkage also holds at the individual level. The<br />

idea is that a person has social capital at her/his disposal – similarly to other forms of<br />

capital it is conceptualized as a kind of investment, here in social relations – that<br />

promises an added value for personal benefit (Norris 2002: 138). Depending on the<br />

objective of such an investment <strong>and</strong> on the structure, size <strong>and</strong> diversity of the network,<br />

119


the individual payoff can vary. Some studies have shown, for example, that people who<br />

are more connected with others participate more successfully in the labor market<br />

(Granovetter 1995; Lin 1999), or tend to be happier, healthier <strong>and</strong> to live longer<br />

(Kawachi et al. 1997; Pevalin <strong>and</strong> Rose 2002). 53 As social capital reduces the transaction<br />

costs for cooperation, political engagement should be higher among those people who are<br />

better integrated into horizontal networks. Contrasting this view, van Deth (1997: 10)<br />

points to a quite different interpretation of this linkage. His main argument is that time<br />

resources available to an individual are limited, <strong>and</strong> that people experience this limitation<br />

when they become involved. So, they will use their resources carefully. Adopting<br />

Hirschman’s thesis of shifting involvements (Hirschman 1979: 100-101), he argues that<br />

people then tend to concentrate on one form of – private, social or political –<br />

involvement, suggesting some kind of trade-off between the various forms of<br />

engagement. Following this argument, individual-level social participation <strong>and</strong><br />

engagement in elite-challenging activities should be negatively correlated.<br />

Table 7-2 shows that also at the individual level people’s embeddedness in social<br />

networks is positively linked with people’s engagement in mass activities from below.<br />

For almost all societies, the measures of the structural component of social capital show a<br />

positive <strong>and</strong> significant correlation with elite-challenging activities. As on the societal<br />

level, the strongest mobilizing factors are membership in voluntary associations <strong>and</strong> the<br />

multiplicity of associational membership, the people who are part of multiple (<strong>and</strong><br />

different) horizontal networks are easier mobilized into elite-challenging activities than<br />

people outside these networks.<br />

53 See already Emile Durkheim’s early <strong>and</strong> groundbreaking study on the effect of social integration on<br />

suicide rates in various groups of society (Durkheim [1897] 2002).<br />

120


Table 7-2:<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Measures of Social Capital’s Structural<br />

Component <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities (ESS 2002)<br />

Membership in<br />

Associations<br />

Active<br />

Membership in<br />

Associations<br />

Social Activity<br />

Average Number<br />

of Memberships<br />

in Associations<br />

Informal<br />

Networks<br />

Austria .17 *** .01 .15 *** .27 *** .11 ***<br />

Belgium .16 *** .04 .19 *** .26 *** .15 ***<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> - - - - .09 ***<br />

Czech Republic - - - - .16 ***<br />

Germany .19 *** .12 *** .17 *** .22 *** .13 ***<br />

Denmark .13 *** .13 *** .16 *** .24 *** .16 ***<br />

Spain .28 *** .17 *** .25 *** .30 *** .20 ***<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .09 *** .01 .17 *** .13 *** .13 ***<br />

UK .24 *** .17 *** .24 *** .29 *** .11 ***<br />

Greece .25 *** .14 *** .18 *** .32 *** .12 ***<br />

Hungary .13 *** .09 *** .17 *** .18 *** .11 ***<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .19 *** .12 *** .20 *** .26 *** .10 ***<br />

Israel .26 *** .05 * .14 *** .30 *** .10 ***<br />

Italy .21 *** -.03 .25 *** .23 *** .17 ***<br />

Luxembourg .17 *** .12 *** .14 *** .25 *** .19 ***<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .14 *** .14 *** .15 *** .28 *** .10 ***<br />

Norway .14 *** .17 *** .19 *** .23 *** .18 ***<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .20 *** .15 *** .23 *** .21 *** .08 ***<br />

Portugal .24 *** .12 *** .12 *** .31 *** .08 **<br />

Sweden .15 *** .12 *** .15 *** .21 *** .16 ***<br />

Slovenia .15 *** .11 *** .17 *** .21 *** .15 ***<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample<br />

(design weight). Data entries are Pearson’s r.<br />

7.2 The Motivational or Cultural Component: Social Trust<br />

Some scholars like Putnam have extended their definition of social capital, arguing that<br />

structures are not sufficient in stimulating coordination <strong>and</strong> cooperation among the<br />

members of a network if these ties are not accompanied by shared norms of reciprocity<br />

<strong>and</strong> generalized horizontal trust. Inglehart (1997: 188), for example, talks about “a<br />

culture of trust <strong>and</strong> tolerance” when referring to social capital. Along similar lines,<br />

Fukuyama claims that social capital is “a capability that arises from the prevalence of<br />

trust in a society or certain parts of it” (Fukuyama 1995: 26).<br />

121


The European Social Survey contains two questions on social trust, both measured on a<br />

0-to-10 scale, with higher values indicating more trust towards other people. The question<br />

formulations read as follows:<br />

(1) “Using this card, generally speaking, would you say that most people can be<br />

trusted, or that you can’t be too careful in dealing with people?”, <strong>and</strong>:<br />

(2) “Using this card, do you think that most people would try to take advantage<br />

of you if they got the chance, or would they try to be fair?”.<br />

In Figure 7-6 the two items were combined, resulting in a scale that ranges from 0 to 20,<br />

<strong>and</strong> an average trust value per society was calculated. 54 The values are displayed at the x-<br />

axis (see Appendix A7-3 for the distribution of the scale per society).<br />

As a societal characteristic, the motivational aspect of social capital has also been<br />

conceptualized as networks of trust that help to sustain the social cohesion in a society. A<br />

society can thus be imagined as a sum of single trust circles where people are willing to<br />

accept cooperative norms (Fukuyama 1999: 3). In societies where these “radii of trust”<br />

(p.2) are large (meaning that they involve a lot of people), more social capital is available<br />

to all members of a society. As a consequence, in high-trust societies the prevailing social<br />

capital should be more productive in stimulating collective activism than in low-trust<br />

societies. 55<br />

54 Cronbach’s alpha for the added scale: 0.742.<br />

55 For the concept of “high-trust societies” <strong>and</strong> “low-trust societies” see Fukuyama (1995).<br />

122


Figure 7-6: Trust Level <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities (ESS 2002)<br />

80<br />

70<br />

Sweden<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Germany<br />

UK<br />

Belgium<br />

Austria<br />

Israel<br />

Spain<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Norway<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Denmark<br />

Italy<br />

20<br />

10<br />

Greece<br />

Slovenia<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Hungary Portugal<br />

0<br />

7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15<br />

Mean trust level (scale: 0 to 20)<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R = .82 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Percentage of respondents who “Have done” any of the following activities in the past 12<br />

month: Signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain<br />

products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

Mean trust level: Mean score on added scale (0 to 20): High values indicate that respondents from a given country think<br />

that most people can be trusted <strong>and</strong> that people try to be fair.<br />

As Figure 7-6 confirms, the level of social trust in a society is considerably related to<br />

elite-challenging activities (r = .82 *** ). Here, social trust was measured as the mean score<br />

on the additive trust scale (ranging from 0 to 20; higher values indicate more trust in<br />

other people) per society, but the relationship also holds, for example, when the<br />

prevalence of high trust levels is considered instead (r = .75 *** , for the figure see<br />

Appendix A7-4). On the societal level, social trust appears to provide an opportunity<br />

structure that is in principle available to all members of a society <strong>and</strong> creates a positive<br />

environment for mass activities. So, the prevalence of trust (like in the Sc<strong>and</strong>inavian<br />

societies) serves as a precondition for elite-challenging activities – in societies where<br />

123


people tend to be rather distrustful (like in the former Ex-communist or Southern<br />

European societies), less cooperative actions can be observed.<br />

On the individual level, trust (as the motivational component of social capital) is<br />

differently conceptualized from what Inglehart (1997: 188) called “culture of trust”. In<br />

contrast to the societal attribute, it characterizes “an aspect of the relationship among<br />

individuals to be found in networks” (van Deth 2001: 7). Coleman (1980, 1990) has<br />

proposed a game-theoretical approach, arguing that trust is the outcome of a cost-benefit<br />

analysis in a given situation. Taking into account all available information the<br />

counterpart’s trustworthiness is estimated <strong>and</strong> weighed against the consequences if the<br />

own trust is betrayed. In this underst<strong>and</strong>ing, trust is granted to a particular person as the<br />

result of a rational decision in response to a concrete situational context. Coleman’s<br />

approach that defines trust as person-specific, situational-specific <strong>and</strong> intentional refers to<br />

interpersonal trust. This concept, however, largely disregards that trust can also be crosspersonal<br />

<strong>and</strong> cross-situational, in other words: generalized (McKnight, Cummings <strong>and</strong><br />

Chervany 1995: 13). The two questions in the European Social Survey refer then to<br />

generalized trust as a disposition or propensity to trust others, irrespectively of the<br />

concrete situation, “a sense of basic trust, which is a pervasive attitude toward oneself<br />

<strong>and</strong> the world” (Erikson 1968: 96). It refers to so-called thin trust between strangers <strong>and</strong><br />

acquaintances (Delhey <strong>and</strong> Newton 2005: 311) <strong>and</strong> is conceptually distinct from<br />

personalized (or particularized) trust that is generated only in face-to-face meetings.<br />

Here, voluntary associations <strong>and</strong> other forms of networks come into play again as<br />

generalized trust can emerge from face-to-face interaction: “through mechanisms not yet<br />

clearly understood the development of interpersonal trust <strong>and</strong> cooperative experience<br />

between members tends to be generalized to the society as a whole” (Stolle 2001: 205).<br />

For the social capital approach, this generalized trust is of particular importance for<br />

cooperation among individuals. People who have the disposition to generally consider<br />

others as trustworthy should also be more willing to participate with others in common<br />

activities.<br />

Table 7-3 looks at the individual-level linkage between social trust <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging<br />

activities. The correlation is a positive one <strong>and</strong>, with one exception, significant in all<br />

societies. Although the coefficients are not very high, the results in Table 7-3 suggest that<br />

124


generalized horizontal trust also provides some kind of a personal opportunity structure<br />

through which trusting individuals can be easier mobilized into collective activities than<br />

those who do not trust others. As on the societal level, generalized trust tends to minimize<br />

transaction costs, helping individuals to overcome the usual collective action dilemma<br />

that occurs when people need to work together for a common goal: “Especially the<br />

existence of mutual trust <strong>and</strong> norms of reciprocity reduces the risk that a co-operative<br />

individual will be invited to pay the bill left behind by cheating partners” (van Deth 2001:<br />

7).<br />

Table 7-3:<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Social Trust <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities (ESS 2002)<br />

Austria .08 ***<br />

Belgium .07 **<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> .12 ***<br />

Czech Republic .10 ***<br />

Germany .14 ***<br />

Denmark .09 **<br />

Spain .12 ***<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .06 **<br />

UK .10 ***<br />

Greece .08 ***<br />

Hungary .09 ***<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .06 *<br />

Israel .13 ***<br />

Italy .17 ***<br />

Luxembourg .12 ***<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .12 ***<br />

Norway .04<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .12 ***<br />

Portugal .06 *<br />

Sweden .10 **<br />

Slovenia .09 **<br />

Trust <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample<br />

(design weight). Data entries are Pearson’s r.<br />

125


7.3 Networks or Trust: Which Component of Social Capital Generates Elite-<br />

Challenging Activities?<br />

The motivational <strong>and</strong> the structural aspect of social capital are closely linked with each<br />

other as associations <strong>and</strong> other forms of networks help to facilitate generalized trust <strong>and</strong><br />

norms of reciprocity. The question may arise which of these two components is more<br />

successful in generating productive social capital. Table 7-4 displays the results of a<br />

binary logistic regression analysis at the individual level, with participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities as the dependent variable. The motivational component of social<br />

capital as one of the explanatory factors is captured with a grouped trust variable, derived<br />

from the 21-point trust scale described above. The measure of the structural component<br />

of social capital is based on the previous analyses, but adds one important aspect for<br />

connectedness: the degree to which people are embedded in virtual networks such as<br />

online networks. Whereas Wellmann et al. (1996) have argued that computer (or virtual)<br />

networks are in fact real social networks, others have argued quite differently: contacts<br />

via Internet in fact do not create social capital as people do not interact on a face-to-face<br />

basis but often anonymously <strong>and</strong> without a social context, thus encouraging “’easy in,<br />

easy out,’, ‘drive-by’ relationships” (Putnam 2000: 177). In his underst<strong>and</strong>ing, “the<br />

poverty of social cues in computer-mediated communication inhibits interpersonal<br />

collaboration <strong>and</strong> trust” (Putnam 2000: 176). The frequent use of email <strong>and</strong> Internet for<br />

personal communication should be a good indicator for embeddedness in (virtual)<br />

networks. In Putnam’s view, virtual networks should be not at all or even negatively<br />

linked with elite-challenging activities. By contrast, if virtual networks are real networks,<br />

they should have the capacity to mobilize people into participation (Hampton <strong>and</strong><br />

Wellman 2003: 305).<br />

The structural aspect of social capital is measured with three sets of variables: (1) Formal<br />

membership in voluntary associations; (2) the three single items that entered the factor<br />

analysis on informal networks: frequency of social contacts, level of social activities,<br />

having a friend to share personal matters; <strong>and</strong> (3) the frequency of personal Internet <strong>and</strong><br />

email usage (question formulation: “Now, using this card, how often do you use the<br />

internet, the World Wide Web or e-mail – whether at home or at work – for your personal<br />

use?”).<br />

126


Table 7-4 presents two separate regression models for Western <strong>and</strong> Eastern Europe, with<br />

the first one showing the impact of structural <strong>and</strong> motivational factors on the participation<br />

in elite-challenging activities. The second model includes control factors: sex, age,<br />

education <strong>and</strong> TV consumption.<br />

Table 7-4: Individual-Level, Binary Logistic Regression (ESS 2002)<br />

Dependent Variable: Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

Model I<br />

Model II<br />

Western Europe Eastern Europe<br />

Western Europe Eastern Europe<br />

Structural component:<br />

Member in any association 2.68 *** (.99) 2.30 *** (.83) 2.51 *** (.92) 2.14 *** (.76)<br />

Frequency of social contacts 1.00 (.01) .99 (-.02) 1.01 (.02) 1.05 (.05)<br />

Level of social activities 1.24 *** (.22) 1.08 (.07) 1.22 *** (.20) 1.01 (.01)<br />

Having a friend to discuss personal 1.54 *** (.43) 1.55 * (.44) 1.37 *** (.32) 1.36 (.31)<br />

matters<br />

Personal internet <strong>and</strong> email usage 1.16 *** (.15) 1.21 *** (.19) 1.09 *** (.09) 1.10 *** (.10)<br />

Motivational component:<br />

Interpersonal Trust<br />

Reference category: low trust level<br />

Medium trust level<br />

High trust level<br />

1.42 *** (.35)<br />

1.66 *** (.51)<br />

1.11 (.11)<br />

1.58 ** (.46)<br />

1.34 *** (.30)<br />

1.50 *** (.41)<br />

1.02 (.02)<br />

1.43 * (.36)<br />

Control variables:<br />

Sex - 1.35 *** (.30) 1.16 (.15)<br />

Age - 1.00 (.00) 1.00 (.00)<br />

Education - 1.37 *** (.31) 1.45 *** (.37)<br />

TV consumption - 1.00 (.00) 0.99 (-.01)<br />

Explained variance (Nagelkerke’s R 2 ) .20 .12 .24 .18<br />

N 25.148 4.911 25.148 4.911<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for population size.<br />

Data entries are odds ratios with beta coefficients in parentheses.<br />

Significance level: * p ≤ .05, ** p ≤ .01, *** p = .00<br />

Membership in a voluntary association appears to be the strongest explanatory factor in<br />

both regions, <strong>and</strong> its impact hardly diminishes when controlling for sociodemographic<br />

characteristics. The effect of Internet use <strong>and</strong> e-mailing is also positive <strong>and</strong> significant in<br />

all cases. So, people’s embeddedness in these networks increases their chance to become<br />

active, simply because they are more exposed to information <strong>and</strong> attempts for<br />

127


mobilization. The result for the single informal network variables is rather mixed. The<br />

effect of frequency of social contacts is consistently insignificant, whereas the other two<br />

have an independent effect on community activism throughout Western Europe but not in<br />

the former communist societies. The picture looks similar for generalized trust as it has<br />

an independent effect on elite-challenging activities even when controlled for<br />

associational membership <strong>and</strong> the strength of personal informal networks. Ex post, this<br />

also corroborates the differentiation between networks <strong>and</strong> ties on the one h<strong>and</strong>, <strong>and</strong> trust<br />

on the other h<strong>and</strong> as conceptually distinct components of social capital.<br />

The level of TV consumption as well as age, both introduced into the model as a control<br />

factors, do not play any role for activity in elite-challenging participation. At least for the<br />

first variable this is in fact a little surprising. Ironically, just at the time as social capital<br />

had been (re)discovered <strong>and</strong> defended in its potential democratic benefits for a society, in<br />

particular by its strongest advocates, the communitarian school, concerns were raised that<br />

this valuable resource was already about to diminish. A last ‘long civic generation’<br />

(Putnam 1995b: 674-677) was discovered, born between 1910 <strong>and</strong> 1940, “a broad group<br />

of people substantially more engaged in community affairs <strong>and</strong> substantially more<br />

trusting than those younger than they” (Putnam, 1995b: 675). When the subsequent ‘postcivic<br />

generations’, more couch potatoes than community activists, gradually replaced the<br />

actively involved generation, decades of “a national deterioration in social capital”<br />

(Putnam 1995b: 677) followed. Following this argument, older generations should have<br />

more social capital, as they are more connected <strong>and</strong> trustful, <strong>and</strong> this should also become<br />

visible in the productivity of social capital. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, there is no good reason to<br />

assume why older people should participate in these particular forms of community<br />

activism. A number of empirical studies have shown that participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities is often tied to a particular set of values prevailing among the<br />

younger, not the older, generations. Putnam made a strong claim linking decreasing<br />

social capital to the recreational habits of the younger generations. “The culprit is<br />

television” (Putnam 1995b: 667), he argued, but in particular the multitude of processes<br />

of individualization have been blamed for undermining the role membership-based<br />

organizations.<br />

128


Summarizing the results so far, elite-challenging activities as forms of community<br />

involvement depend both on networks <strong>and</strong> trust, in short: they are an outcome of social<br />

capital. Social capital was examined in its effect on collective activities on two levels: as<br />

an individual characteristic (embeddedness in a network <strong>and</strong> social trust) <strong>and</strong> a societal<br />

condition (organizing capacity of a society) for participation. However, as the two-level<br />

characteristics have not been included in one <strong>and</strong> the same analysis, it is not possible to<br />

determine whether social capital has the greater impact on participating in elitechallenging<br />

activities as an individual or as a societal characteristic. This will be done<br />

now in a final step: social capital variables on the individual <strong>and</strong> on the societal level will<br />

be incorporated into one multilevel model explaining people’s participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities.<br />

As underst<strong>and</strong>ing the logic of multilevel models is necessary to follow the interpretation<br />

of the results, this final empirical test is presented in more detail. A multilevel analysis<br />

allows singling out independent effects of the variables on each level on a dependent<br />

variable (measured on the lowest possible level), but also interaction effects between<br />

level-1 (individual level) <strong>and</strong> level-2 (societal level) factors that might explain why<br />

people participate. As the dependent variable, participation in elite-challenging activities,<br />

is measured as a dichotomous variable, a hierarchical nonlinear regression model must be<br />

applied. A nonlinear model (also: generalized linear model) is in many ways similar to a<br />

linear model, except that the level-1 model follows a logistic function instead of a linear<br />

one. In general, a multilevel model follows a three-step logic. In the first model, only<br />

individual-level predictors are included; the second model introduces the direct effects of<br />

societal-factors; the third model is the full model that finally incorporates the interaction<br />

effects.<br />

As a first step, a baseline model is calculated, taking into account individual-level<br />

variables only (Model 1). For the social capital model explaining elite-challenging<br />

activities, these are (1) membership in voluntary associations, (2) embeddedness in<br />

informal networks, <strong>and</strong> (3) social trust. It is assumed that group differences can be<br />

observed, meaning that the individual-level variables have different effects across<br />

societies. The first model looks like this:<br />

129


Model 1:<br />

Prob (Yij) = (1/ β j ) = P<br />

η ij = log [P/(1-P)] = β 0j + β 1j (Membership) ij + β 2j (Informal networks) ij + β 3j (Trust) ij + r ij<br />

The model is similar to a logistic regression model, except that the parameters are not<br />

fixed but vary across societies (level-2 units, see Steenbergen <strong>and</strong> Jones 2002: 221). η ij is<br />

the dependent variable (participation in elite-challenging activities) for a level-1 unit<br />

(individual i), nested in a level-2 unit (society j), more precisely: the logit of the odds that<br />

someone will participate in elite-challenging activities. These odds (or chances) are<br />

defined as P/(1-P), i.e. the probability (that someone participates, so ‘an event will<br />

occur’) divided by one minus the probability (that someone does not participate, so ‘an<br />

event will not occur’). The β 0i coefficient is the individual-level intercept, the other beta<br />

coefficients in the model are the individual-level effects (slopes). Finally, r ij represents<br />

the error term in this model.<br />

The main goal of a multilevel analysis is “to account for variance in a dependent variable<br />

that is measured at the lowest level of analysis by considering information from all levels<br />

of analysis” (Steenbergen <strong>and</strong> Jones 2002: 219). The information from the superior level,<br />

the societal level, is taken into account in the next two steps. Here, it is assumed that<br />

level-2 variables can have direct effects (Model 2) but may also shape the effects of<br />

level-1 variables (Model 3).<br />

So, in the second step of analyzing multilevel data, level-2 variables are introduced to<br />

assess their independent effects on the individual-level intercept β 0j . In the social capital<br />

model, level-2 variables are (1) membership level, (2) level of informal networks, <strong>and</strong> (3)<br />

the trust level in a society:<br />

Model 2:<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (Membership level j ) + γ 02 (Level of informal networks j ) + γ 03 (Trust level j )<br />

+ u ij .<br />

In the equation, γ 00 is the societal level intercept, the other γ coefficients are level-2<br />

effects on the level-1 intercept β 0j . The level-2 error term is summarized in u ij .<br />

Finally, level-2 variables have to be considered in their interaction with level-1 variables.<br />

Model 3 summarizes the level-2 effects on the other level-1 regression parameters:<br />

130


Model 3:<br />

β 1j = γ 10 + γ 11 (Membership level) + γ 12 (Level of informal networks) + γ 13 (Trust level)<br />

+ u 1j .<br />

β 2j = γ 20 + γ 21 (Membership level) + γ 22 (Level of informal networks) + γ 23 (Trust level)<br />

+ u 2j .<br />

β 3j = γ 30 + γ 31 (Membership level) + γ 32 (Level of informal networks) + γ 33 (Trust level)<br />

+ u 3j .<br />

γ 10 , γ 20 <strong>and</strong> γ 30 are the intercepts for the respective membership, informal networks <strong>and</strong><br />

trust slopes. γ 11 , γ 12 <strong>and</strong> γ 13 are the effects of the level-2 factors membership level, level<br />

of informal networks, <strong>and</strong> trust level in a society on individual membership in a voluntary<br />

association. γ 21 , γ 22 <strong>and</strong> γ 23 are the effects of the same level-2 factors on individual<br />

embeddedness in informal networks, γ 31 , γ 32 <strong>and</strong> γ 33 represent the level-2 effects on trust.<br />

After introducing the model equations, Table 6-5 presents the results of the multi-level<br />

model. For an easier interpretation, odds ratios (instead of log odds coefficients) are<br />

documented. The data entries show how the odds ratios are changing when a one-unit<br />

increase in the independent variable occurs (odds with increase compared to odds without<br />

an increase in the predictor). Does social capital as an individual or as a societal attribute<br />

(or as an interplay of both) make people participate in elite-challenging activities? 56<br />

The results in Table 7-5 are straightforward. All three social-capital related, individuallevel<br />

predictors in Model 1 have a positive <strong>and</strong> significant effect on participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities. Members in voluntary associations join demonstrations, petitions,<br />

<strong>and</strong> activities of political consumerism twice as often as nonmembers. Compared to<br />

membership, the other social capital characteristics, embeddedness in informal networks<br />

<strong>and</strong> trust, do not play such an important role. Contrasting the lowest with the highest<br />

possible trust score (21-point scale), for example, the odds ratio to participate in elitechallenging<br />

activities improves not even by factor two (1.8). Looking at the sociodemographic<br />

control factors, females are slightly more likely to take part in elitechallenging<br />

activities than men (1.2). <strong>Participation</strong> decreases with age, <strong>and</strong>, corroborating<br />

several participation studies, the level of education has a positive effect on people’s<br />

56 For the detailed stepwise multi-level model (HGLM) please see Appendix A7-5.<br />

131


inclination to become engaged: Comparing the lowest with the highest educational<br />

degree (7-point scale), the odd ratio for participation increases to 10.8. 57<br />

The effects of individual-level socio-demographic characteristics as well as social capital<br />

factors also remain robust after introducing societal-level effects in Model 2. Of the three<br />

societal condition factors, only the membership level in a society plays a role,<br />

contributing remarkably to a favorable opportunity structure for people to become active.<br />

The other societal-level effects of social capital, the levels of informal networks <strong>and</strong> trust<br />

in a society, are of no relevance for individual participation in elite-challenging activities.<br />

As the last box at the bottom of Table 7-5 shows, the introduction of societal<br />

characteristics (foremost: level of organizational membership) improves the fit of the<br />

model intercept substantially (almost 75 percent compared to the baseline model). The<br />

variance components documented here show how much of the variation across societies<br />

can be explained by including level-2 variables into the model. In fact, the coefficients<br />

display how much of the variance remains still unexplained. From these components, the<br />

reduction in error variance can be calculated (Kreft <strong>and</strong> de Leeuw 1998: 118). 58<br />

57 About the interpretation of odds ratios for continuous variables: If a change of two or more units in the<br />

independent variable occurs, the odds ratios are multiplied (not added!). Example: Education is measured<br />

on a 7-point scale, the odds ratio for a one-unit increase in the independent variable is 1.405 (see Table 7-<br />

5). The odds ratio for the lowest compared with the highest educational degree is, therefore, 1.405 7 = 10.8<br />

in favor of the highest educational degree.<br />

58 As there is no ‘true’ R 2 in HLM, there are a number of suggestions on how to calculate the explained<br />

variance in a multilevel model. In one way or another, all of them refer to a comparison of the error terms<br />

in an unrestricted <strong>and</strong> a restricted model. Kreft <strong>and</strong> de Leeuw (1998) suggest for the between society<br />

)<br />

variance: 2<br />

u<br />

0<br />

− u1<br />

R between<br />

= , with u0 being the error term in the “r<strong>and</strong>om intercept, r<strong>and</strong>om slope” model<br />

u<br />

0<br />

(unrestricted model), <strong>and</strong> u 1 being the error term in the “full model with interaction effects” (restricted<br />

)<br />

model). Accordingly, the within society variance is 2 v0<br />

− v1<br />

R within<br />

= , with v 0 being the error term in the<br />

v0<br />

“r<strong>and</strong>om intercept only” model (null model or unrestricted model), <strong>and</strong> v 1 being the error term in the<br />

“r<strong>and</strong>om intercept, r<strong>and</strong>om slope” model (restricted model). Appendix 5 shows the stepwise multi-level<br />

model – here, the within-society variance is reported.<br />

In both cases, the variance of the new model is subtracted from the variance of the restricted model: “The<br />

difference is compared to the original variance (the null model variance) as a proportion reduction in that<br />

variance” (Kreft <strong>and</strong> de Leeuw 1998: 188). As the authors point out, this simple approach has its drawbacks<br />

(as other approaches have as well): Negative results might occur when the variance of the unrestricted<br />

model is larger than the variance of the restricted model (Kreft <strong>and</strong> de Leeuw 1998: 118).<br />

132


Table 7-5: Multi-Level (Hierarchical Generalized Linear) Model of Social Capital<br />

<strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities (ESS 2002)<br />

Dependent variable: <strong>Participation</strong> in Elite-Challenging Activities (dichotomous, individual-level measure)<br />

Model 1:<br />

Individual-level<br />

predictors<br />

(R<strong>and</strong>om intercept,<br />

r<strong>and</strong>om slope)<br />

Model 2:<br />

Societal-level<br />

effects on intercept<br />

Model 3:<br />

Full model<br />

with interaction<br />

effects<br />

Intercept 0.439*** (-4.344) 0.029** (-3.670) 0.061** (-3.321)<br />

Individual-level effects (slopes):<br />

Membership in voluntary association 2.020*** (14.686) 2.014*** (24.108) 5.104** (4.083)<br />

Embeddedness in informal networks 1.158*** (8.905) 1.163*** (11.536) 0.881 (-0.753)<br />

Trust<br />

1.028*** (7.463) 1.028*** (8.601) 1.035 (0.832)<br />

Control Factors<br />

Gender<br />

1.200** (3.510) 1.239*** (8.700) 1.209** (3.712)<br />

Age<br />

0.990*** (-9.936) 0.990*** (-14.43) 0.990*** (-8.834)<br />

Education<br />

1.405*** (19.377) 1.396*** (36.088) 1.405*** (19.187)<br />

Societal-level effects (intercepts):<br />

Membership level<br />

Level of informal networks<br />

Trust level<br />

Cross-level interaction effects (slopes):<br />

Individual-level membership in voluntary<br />

associations<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

Individual-level embeddedness in informal<br />

networks<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

Individual-level trust<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

Remaining between-society variance:<br />

Intercept (Contribution to variance)<br />

Membership in voluntary association<br />

Informal networks<br />

Trust<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

Education<br />

0.6486***<br />

0.0262***<br />

0.0018<br />

0.0001<br />

0.0389***<br />

0.0000**<br />

0.0041***<br />

30.251** (4.003)<br />

0.963 (-0.202)<br />

1.061 (0.542)<br />

19.603** (3,994)<br />

1.0334 (0.201)<br />

1.016 (0.168)<br />

0.437* (-2.304)<br />

1.194* (2.239)<br />

0.959 (-0.922)<br />

1.062 (0.390)<br />

0.931 (-2.015)<br />

1.023 (1.228)<br />

0.972 (-0.779)<br />

1.002 (0.269)<br />

1.001 (0.225)<br />

0.1656*** (74.5%) 0.1323*** (79.6%)<br />

0.0146 (44.3%)<br />

0.0021 (-16.7%)<br />

0.0001 (0%)<br />

0.0369*** (5.1%)<br />

0.0000** (0%)<br />

0.0042*** (-2.4%)<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. N (individual level) = 35.303. N (societal level) = 19.<br />

Data entries are odds ratios with T-values in parentheses. Hierarchical generalized linear model calculated<br />

with HLM 6.03. Significance level: * p ≤ .05, ** p ≤ .01, *** p = .00<br />

Individual-level variables: Membership in any voluntary association (0/1), Embeddedness in informal<br />

networks (factor scores, see Table 1), Trust (scale 0 to 20), Gender (1=male, 2=female), Age (low to high),<br />

Education (7-point scale, 0=not completed primary education, 6=second stage or tertiary level).<br />

Societal-level variables: Level of Membership in vol. associations (in % per society), Level of informal<br />

networks (average factor score, see Table 7-1), Trust level (average societal score on trust scale 0 to 20).<br />

133


Comparing the Models 2 <strong>and</strong> 3, including cross-level interaction effects does not<br />

substantially improve the model. The interaction coefficients are barely significant, <strong>and</strong><br />

the overall unexplained variance in Model 3 is only marginally reduced (the variance<br />

components show an additional reduction from 75 to 80 percent compared to Model 1).<br />

Considering the vast improvement after introducing the direct impact of societal factors<br />

to the previous model, Model 3 can only modestly contribute to further explain<br />

participation in elite-challenging activities. In addition, the already weak (but positive)<br />

effect of embeddedness in informal networks <strong>and</strong> trust on people’s participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities vanishes. By contrast, the impact of individual membership in<br />

voluntary associations increases (from 2.01 to 5.10).<br />

To summarize the results of the multilevel model, it is the structural aspect of social<br />

capital, in particular the voluntary associations, that mobilizes people into elitechallenging<br />

activities. This mechanism works both on the individual as on the societal<br />

level: Membership in voluntary associations creates a close mobilization context, giving<br />

members better chances to also participate in other forms of collective activities. Along<br />

similar lines, an individual living in a society that is characterized by a high membership<br />

level is much more likely to be a demonstrator, a petitioner or a political consumerist than<br />

the one living in a society where only a minority of the people joins voluntary<br />

associations. So, societies with a high density of voluntary associations indeed<br />

demonstrate their organizing capacity.<br />

In addition to the social capital factors, the multi-level models also revealed a linkage<br />

between sociodemographic characteristics <strong>and</strong> individual participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities. Originally introduced as control factors, the impact of these<br />

characteristics (e.g. education) proved to be quite robust. Picking up these linkages, the<br />

next chapter will, among others, discuss the impact of individual-level resources <strong>and</strong><br />

motivation on elite-challenging participation, in particular with regard to the question of<br />

political equality. Building up on the results of networks as favorable context factors, the<br />

following chapter will, furthermore, address other societal resources <strong>and</strong> opportunity<br />

structures for participation in elite-challenging activities.<br />

134


8. Individual Characteristics or Context Factors:<br />

What Matters for Elite-Challenging <strong>Participation</strong>?<br />

This chapter, building on the results of the previous analyses, is dedicated to the question<br />

whether participation in elite-challenging activities is determined more by individual<br />

characteristics or rather an outcome of contextual conditions. The analysis follows a<br />

three-fold strategy:<br />

In a first step, the chapter examines individual-level characteristics <strong>and</strong> how they shape<br />

the eagerness of people to become engaged in politics. This question is closely linked<br />

with the problem of participation <strong>and</strong> inequality, as the spread of elite-challenging<br />

activities has been blamed to go at the expense of political equality. Individual-level<br />

analyses for six societies are presented, comparing the impact of resources <strong>and</strong><br />

motivation on elite-challenging participation over a period of 30 years. The analyses are<br />

based on data from the Political Action Study (1974) <strong>and</strong> the European Social Survey<br />

(2004). The results for elite-challenging participation are then contrasted with other forms<br />

of political action – conventional participation <strong>and</strong> voting – in order to determine whether<br />

<strong>and</strong> to what extent elite-challenging activities contribute to the inequality gap in political<br />

participation, <strong>and</strong> whether this has changed over time.<br />

In a second step, the impact of different context factors on elite-challenging activities is<br />

tested. It is widely acknowledged that, in addition to individual-level resources <strong>and</strong><br />

motivation, opportunity structures <strong>and</strong> societal resources matter for participation as well.<br />

The data for the dependent variable come from the World Values Survey 2000-2005. The<br />

78 societies included in the analysis differ significantly in their political, economic <strong>and</strong><br />

social characteristics <strong>and</strong> are therefore well suited to examine the role of national<br />

affluence, democratic quality or other system characteristics in mobilizing people into<br />

collective action.<br />

Finally, the relative impact of the context factors <strong>and</strong> individual-level characteristics will<br />

be determined in a multi-level analysis. Such an analysis does not only allow us to test<br />

the impact of the two levels simultaneously <strong>and</strong> under mutual control, but also to<br />

investigate whether individual characteristics differ in their impact on elite-challenging<br />

participation across contexts.<br />

135


8.1 Elite-Challenging <strong>Participation</strong> <strong>and</strong> Individual-Level Resources <strong>and</strong><br />

Motivation: The Question of Inequality<br />

For the past decades, inequality in participation has been an important topic in<br />

participation research. Political equality <strong>and</strong> political participation are both basic<br />

democratic premises, in principle compatible, but in reality hard to achieve<br />

simultaneously (Lijphart 1997: 1). It is one of the best established findings in political<br />

science that resources matter for political participation, <strong>and</strong> that resources are not equally<br />

distributed among citizens of a society. The more intensive a form of political<br />

participation is, the fewer people participate, <strong>and</strong> the greater the chances that those<br />

participants come from more privileged parts of the citizenry. Elite-challenging forms of<br />

participation have been blamed for increasing political inequality, widening the gap<br />

between those who participate <strong>and</strong> those who don’t (Skocpol 2003, 2004). “Because of<br />

their upwardly biased social composition, direct action groups do not even out, but in fact<br />

accelerate, differences in socio-political resources” (Kaase <strong>and</strong> Barnes 1979: 526). Elitechallenging<br />

activities are often said to be more dem<strong>and</strong>ing in terms of required resources<br />

than other forms of political participation, pointing to pronounced unequal opportunities<br />

to take part in public life (Dalton 2000: 929-930). These individual opportunity structures<br />

are shaped by factors such as education or income, but also age or gender.<br />

Recent studies on particular forms of elite-challenging activities, however, suggest that<br />

those – unequal – participation patterns are changing. An exploratory study on political<br />

consumerism in Canada, Belgium <strong>and</strong> Sweden, for example, could show that the gender<br />

gap is reversing, with more <strong>and</strong> more women using this form of civic <strong>and</strong> political<br />

activism (Stolle <strong>and</strong> Micheletti 2003). Another empirical study on participants in<br />

demonstrations in Belgium documents that demonstrators have become similar to the<br />

Belgium population (Norris, Walgrave <strong>and</strong> van Aelst 2005).<br />

The following chapter examines whether elite-challenging participation reinforces social<br />

inequality. If this was the case, socio-demographic characteristics should have a stronger<br />

impact on participation in elite-challenging activities than on participation in<br />

conventional forms of political participation or on voting. Given that elite-challenging<br />

activities are more dem<strong>and</strong>ing than other forms of participation, the spread of these<br />

136


activities over the past decades should also have led to a greater social gap between<br />

participants <strong>and</strong> non-participants. These assumptions will be tested with data from the<br />

Political Action Study (1974) <strong>and</strong> the European Social Survey (2004). Social<br />

characteristics will include gender, age, education <strong>and</strong> income.<br />

In addition, a factor controlling for status inconsistency is introduced. The concept goes<br />

back to Lenski (1954) who argued that not only the status of an individual matters for<br />

political orientations, but also his position at different status dimensions, i.e. low on<br />

education <strong>and</strong> high on income. The concept was then taken up by Beck (1973) <strong>and</strong> is,<br />

because of its implications for social inequality, often considered to be at the heart of the<br />

individualization thesis: 59 individualization leads to a decrease of status crystallization,<br />

or: an increase of status inconsistency. Along similar lines, Coleman (1990: 477) has<br />

argued that times of rapid change produce status inconsistencies for many people.<br />

According to Kohler (2005: 231) this growing inconsistency on the vertical dimension of<br />

inequality has an impact for the horizontal dimension as well, in the sense that it leads to<br />

a diversification (or: de-structuralization) of status groups, where the individual position<br />

on the vertical dimension matters less for the prediction of favorable or unfavorable<br />

living conditions. Status inconsistency is operationalized as the result of a pair-wise<br />

comparison between the respondent’s position on an education <strong>and</strong> an income scale.<br />

Status consistency is achieved when the position on education corresponds to the position<br />

on income. An individual is characterized by a positive status inconsistency when the<br />

income is higher than the education would predict. A negative status inconsistency can be<br />

found when income is lower than an individual’s education level would suggest.<br />

Table 8-1 presents results of a first logistic regression. The three models have different<br />

dependent variables: <strong>Participation</strong> in elite-challenging activities (Model 1), in<br />

conventional forms of participation (Model 2), <strong>and</strong> in voting (Model 3). Each model<br />

contrasts the impact of socio-economic resources on participation between 1974 <strong>and</strong><br />

2004. To be sure, two points in time do not constitute a time-series, but a comparison<br />

over 30 years allows us to draw at least some preliminary conclusions about the relative<br />

strengths of socio-economic factors for individual participation.<br />

137


Table 8-1:<br />

Binary-Logistic Regression: Resources <strong>and</strong> <strong>Participation</strong><br />

(Political Action Study 1974 <strong>and</strong> European Social Survey 2004)<br />

Dependent variable:<br />

Elite-Challenging<br />

participation<br />

Political<br />

Action<br />

(1974)<br />

ESS<br />

(2004)<br />

Conventional<br />

<strong>Participation</strong><br />

Political<br />

Action<br />

(1974)<br />

ESS<br />

(2004)<br />

Political<br />

Action<br />

(1974)<br />

Voting<br />

Gender (0=male) .70 *** 1.20 ** 0.37 *** 0.68 *** 0.94 0.91<br />

Age<br />

reference: 65+ years<br />

25 <strong>and</strong> younger<br />

26 to 35 years<br />

36 to 45 years<br />

46 to 55 years<br />

56 to 65 years<br />

Education<br />

reference: com. level<br />

middle level<br />

higher level<br />

Income<br />

reference: low level<br />

middle level<br />

high level<br />

Status inconsistency:<br />

reference: positive<br />

no inconsistency<br />

1.22<br />

1.54 **<br />

1.59 **<br />

1.48 **<br />

1.11<br />

ESS<br />

(2004)<br />

2.37 ***<br />

1.89 ***<br />

1.88 ***<br />

1.81 ***<br />

1.56 *** 0.89<br />

1.33 *<br />

1.47 **<br />

1.45 **<br />

1.44 ** 0.88<br />

1.05<br />

1.45 *<br />

2.16 ***<br />

1.74 *** 0.11 ***<br />

0.71 *<br />

1.24<br />

1.32<br />

1.45 * 0.36 ***<br />

0.36 ***<br />

0.54 ***<br />

0.83<br />

1.14<br />

1.65 *** 2.32 ** 1.73 *** 1.17<br />

1.91 * 4.04 * 3.29 *** 1.85<br />

1.57 * 0.95<br />

2.20 ** 1.14<br />

1.10<br />

1.45<br />

1.02<br />

1.34<br />

1.09 1.45 *<br />

3.58 ** 4.40<br />

0.87<br />

0.84<br />

1.05<br />

1.12<br />

negative inconsistency<br />

1.24<br />

1.89 * 0.83<br />

0.83<br />

.97<br />

.96<br />

1.01<br />

1.12<br />

0.74<br />

0.62<br />

0.94<br />

0.76<br />

Constant 0.32 0.15 1.15 0.20 7.97 3.87<br />

N 6.539 7.636 7.126 7.662 7.077 7.071<br />

Pseudo R sq. .09 .08 .13 .06 .24 .08<br />

Countries included: Great Britain, West Germany, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Austria, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Finl<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Samples equally weighted n = 1.000. Coding of the variables:<br />

(1) Elite-challenging participation<br />

Political Action Study: “Please place the cards on this scale to show me first whether 1) you have actually<br />

done any of these things on the cards using the past ten years; 2) you would do any of these things if it were<br />

important to you; 3) you might do it in a particular situation or 4) you would never do it under any<br />

circumstances.”<br />

- Signing a petition?<br />

- Joining in boycotts?<br />

- Attending lawful demonstrations?<br />

Recoded into 0=have not done anything, 1=have done at least one of the activities.<br />

ESS: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in (country) or help prevent things from going<br />

wrong. During the last 12 months, have you done any of the following?“<br />

- signed a petition?<br />

- taken part in a lawful demonstration?<br />

- boycotted certain products?<br />

Recoded into 0=have not done anything, 1=have done at least one of the activities.<br />

59 Kohler (2005: 230) refers to Friedrich (1998) who identified four different aspects of individualization: a<br />

broadened action repertoire; a decreasing importance of legitimized rules of behavior; an emergence of new<br />

inequalities; <strong>and</strong> an increase of the share of people who view themselves as individuals.<br />

138


(2) Conventional <strong>Participation</strong><br />

Political Action Study: “How often do you contact public officials or politicians?” <strong>and</strong> “How often do you<br />

spend time working for a political party or a c<strong>and</strong>idate?” Original answers 1=often, 2=sometimes,<br />

3=seldom, 4=never were recoded (0=have not done; 1=have done) <strong>and</strong> combined into 0=have not done<br />

anything, 1=have done at least one of these activities.<br />

ESS: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in (country) or help prevent things from going<br />

wrong. During the last 12 months, have you done any of the following?“<br />

- worked in a political party or action group?<br />

- contacted a politician, government or local government official?<br />

Recoded into 0=have not done anything, 1=have done at least one of these activities.<br />

(3) Voting<br />

Political Action Study: “Did you vote in the last general election?” Recoded into 0=no, 1=yes.<br />

ESS: “Some people don’t vote nowadays for one reason or another. Did you vote in the last national<br />

election?” Recoded into 0=no, 1=yes.<br />

(4) Education<br />

Political Action Study: Compulsory level, middle level, higher level.<br />

ESS: 7-point scale recoded into compulsory level, middle level, higher level.<br />

(5) Income<br />

Political Action Study: Different scales (all: low to high) used in the samples. Britain <strong>and</strong> Austria: 12-point<br />

scale. Germany, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s <strong>and</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong>: 10-point scale. Finl<strong>and</strong>: 18-point scale. Recoded into 1=low,<br />

2=middle, 3=high.<br />

ESS: 12-point scale from low to high. Recoded into 1=low, 2=middle, 3=high.<br />

(6) Status Inconsistency<br />

Political Action Study <strong>and</strong> ESS: Pair-wise comparison of recoded education <strong>and</strong> income scale. No status<br />

inconsistency: low education <strong>and</strong> low income, middle education <strong>and</strong> middle income, high education <strong>and</strong><br />

high income. Positive status inconsistency: low or middle education <strong>and</strong> high income, low education <strong>and</strong><br />

middle income. Negative status inconsistency: middle or high education <strong>and</strong> low income, high education<br />

<strong>and</strong> middle income.<br />

Recoded into -1=positive status inconsistency, 0=no status inconsistency, 1=status inconsistency.<br />

A first thing that becomes obvious is that the explanatory power of socio-economic<br />

factors for all three forms of participation is weaker in 2004 than in 1974. Nagelkerke’s<br />

R 2 was cut in half for conventional participation (from .13 in 1974 to .06 in 2004) <strong>and</strong> has<br />

dropped by two thirds for voting (from .24 in 1974 to .08 in 2004). This is less true for<br />

elite-challenging activities where the general model fit (Nagelkerke’s R 2 ) has been<br />

continuously low (from .09 in 1974 to .08 in 2004). Over the past three decades, the<br />

overall relevance of socio-economic factors for participation has weakened.<br />

As for the predictive power of the single variables, education has become more important<br />

for elite-challenging activities (not so for conventional participation <strong>and</strong> voting), whereas<br />

the impact of income has diminished. The latter finding is true for all three modes of<br />

participation. Negative status inconsistency – when income is lower than education<br />

would predict – should have a mobilizing impact on participation in elite-challenging<br />

activities. However, the significant effect that could be observed in 1974 disappeared in<br />

139


2004. A comparison with regression models run without status inconsistency as an<br />

independent variable suggests slightly stronger effects for income, whereas the effects for<br />

education remain largely unaffected or even underestimated. 60<br />

The most important change affects the relationship between gender <strong>and</strong> participation in<br />

elite-challenging activities. Within a 30-years time, the gender gap that used to<br />

characterize political participation has reversed: Today women rather than men<br />

participate in elite-challenging activities. It should be noted that the dependent variable in<br />

Model 1 contains only one item for political consumerism – boycotting certain products.<br />

A closer inspection of a combined measure for political consumerism (buy-cotting <strong>and</strong><br />

boycotting) in the 2004 ESS data reveals that the changing gender relations are even<br />

more pronounced: political consumerism is female (see also Stolle <strong>and</strong> Hooghe 2005).<br />

But also the gender gap in conventional participation has become smaller, although this<br />

mode of participation is still a domain of men (see Model 2), whereas the results of<br />

Model 3 confirm findings of the participation literature: there is no more a gender gap in<br />

voting.<br />

To summarize the analysis, gender, education <strong>and</strong> age are the main resources that affect<br />

participation in elite-challenging action. Do the results change when motivation<br />

components are added to the analysis?<br />

Table 8-2 presents the results of a second logistic regression that uses in addition to<br />

socio-economic resources also motivational components to predict participation. From<br />

the broad range of variables presented in the participation literature, the following factors<br />

are included: political interest, political efficacy, life satisfaction, <strong>and</strong> the respondent’s<br />

position on the left-right scale. Postmaterialism is also known as a main motivation factor<br />

for elite-challenging activities, but the ESS 2004 does unfortunately not include any item<br />

from Inglehart’s postmaterialism scale. An inspection of a Political Action Study model<br />

(1974) that includes postmaterialism as a predictor confirms a positive <strong>and</strong> significant<br />

relationship (table not shown). The multi-level model based on data from the World<br />

Values Survey data will take this into account <strong>and</strong> include it as a predictor.<br />

60 The results are robust: Alternative ways of operationalizing status inconsistency yielded similar results:<br />

(a) 5 types of status inconsistency (instead of 3); (b) a dichotomy with 1= positive status inconsistency; (c)<br />

st<strong>and</strong>ardized residuals from a regression of education on income, <strong>and</strong> (d) status inconsistency squared<br />

(based on (c)).<br />

140


Table 8-2:<br />

Binary-Logistic Regressions: Resources, Motivation <strong>and</strong> <strong>Participation</strong><br />

(Political Action Study 1974 <strong>and</strong> European Social Survey 2004)<br />

Dependent variable:<br />

Elite-Challenging<br />

participation<br />

Political<br />

Action<br />

(1974)<br />

ESS<br />

(2004)<br />

Conventional<br />

<strong>Participation</strong><br />

Political<br />

Action<br />

(1974)<br />

ESS<br />

(2004)<br />

Political<br />

Action<br />

(1974)<br />

Voting<br />

Gender .78 ** 1.34 *** .48 *** .83 * 1.26 * 1.20<br />

Age<br />

reference: 65+ years<br />

25 <strong>and</strong> younger<br />

26 to 35 years<br />

36 to 45 years<br />

46 to 55 years<br />

56 to 65 years<br />

Education<br />

reference: com. level<br />

middle level<br />

higher level<br />

Income<br />

reference: low level<br />

middle level<br />

high level<br />

Status inconsistency<br />

reference: positive inc.<br />

no inconsistency<br />

negative inconsistency<br />

Politically interested<br />

Reference: not at all<br />

not much<br />

somewhat<br />

very<br />

Internal efficacy *<br />

reference: low<br />

middle to low<br />

middle to high<br />

high<br />

Life satisfaction<br />

reference: low<br />

middle<br />

high<br />

Left-right positioning<br />

reference: right<br />

left<br />

1.37 *<br />

1.52 **<br />

1.59 **<br />

1.46 *<br />

1.13<br />

1.42 **<br />

1.34<br />

2.62 *** 1.01<br />

2.17 *** 1.31<br />

1.99 *** 1.54 **<br />

1.76 *** 1.39 *<br />

1.52 **<br />

1.96 *** 1.24<br />

2.88 *** 1.79<br />

1.62 * 0.96 1.05<br />

2.34 ** 1.12 * 1.28<br />

1.29 .87<br />

2.44 ** .87<br />

1.37 * 1.16<br />

1.01<br />

1.00<br />

0.08 ***<br />

1.37 0.60 **<br />

1.82 *** 1.19<br />

2.47 *** 1.17<br />

1.83 *** 1.28<br />

1.21<br />

1.92<br />

0.84<br />

0.78<br />

.81<br />

.73<br />

0.89<br />

2.26<br />

0.75<br />

0.62<br />

0.72<br />

0.55<br />

ESS<br />

(2004)<br />

0.35 ***<br />

0.40 ***<br />

0.58 **<br />

0.79<br />

1.05<br />

1.14<br />

2.79<br />

0.74<br />

0.58<br />

.86<br />

.56<br />

1.54 ** 1.37 2.07 *** 1.34 1.74 *** 2.41 ***<br />

3.49 *** 3.63 *** 7.28 *** 5.20 *** 5.58 ***<br />

2.09 *** 2.54 *** 4.12 *** 2.58 *** 4.15 *** 5.59 ***<br />

1.02 1.10<br />

1.05 1.18<br />

1.43 * 1.13<br />

0.90<br />

1.23<br />

1.08<br />

0.91<br />

0.99<br />

1.24 * 0.91<br />

1.80 *** 0.80<br />

1.98 *** 0.93<br />

1.11<br />

0.94<br />

1.05<br />

0.63<br />

0.81<br />

1.15<br />

1.22<br />

1.08<br />

1.46<br />

1.54<br />

11.76 ***<br />

1.12<br />

1.27<br />

1.76 **<br />

1.49<br />

1.18<br />

1.98 **<br />

center<br />

1.90 ***<br />

1.49 *** 1.89 ***<br />

1.10<br />

1.12<br />

0.97<br />

0.84<br />

0.76 * 0.87<br />

0.72 * 0.87<br />

0.79 *<br />

Constant 0.09 .057 0.24 .15 2.77 0.87<br />

N 5.715 7.126 6.092 7.150 6.062 6.645<br />

Pseudo R sq. .14 .13 .22 .11 .31 .20<br />

Societies included: Great Britain, West Germany, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Austria, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Finl<strong>and</strong>. Samples<br />

equally weighted n = 1.000.<br />

* Different categories in the ESS data set. Coding of the variables:<br />

141


(1) Political Interest<br />

Political Action Study: “How interested would you say you are in politics – are you very interested,<br />

somewhat interested, not much interested or not at all interested?”<br />

ESS: “How interested would you say you are in politics? Are you very interested, quite interested, hardly<br />

interested, or not at all interested?”<br />

(2) Internal efficacy<br />

Political Action Study: “Sometimes politics <strong>and</strong> government seem so complicated that a person like me<br />

cannot really underst<strong>and</strong> what is going on.” Agree strongly, agree, disagree, disagree strongly.<br />

ESS: How often does politics seem so complicated that you can’t really underst<strong>and</strong> what’s going on?<br />

Never, seldom, occasionally, regularly, frequently.<br />

(3) Life satisfaction<br />

Political Action Study: “Now, let’s think about your life as a whole. All things considered, how satisfied or<br />

dissatisfied are you with your life these days? Where do you put yourself on the scale?” 0=completely<br />

dissatisfied to 10=completely satisfied.<br />

ESS: “All things considered, how satisfied are you with your life as a whole nowadays? Please answer<br />

using this card, where 0 means extremely dissatisfied <strong>and</strong> 10 means extremely satisfied.”<br />

Recoded into 1=low (0 to 3), 2=middle (4 to 6), 3=high (7to 10).<br />

(4) Left-Right-Positioning<br />

Political Action Study: “Many people think of political attitudes as being on the “left” or the “right”. This is<br />

a scale stretching from the “left” to the “right”. When you think of your own political attitudes, where<br />

would you put yourself?” 1=left to 10=right. Recoded into 1=left (1 to 3), 2=center (4 to 7), 3=right (8 to<br />

10).<br />

ESS: “In politics people sometimes talk of “left” <strong>and</strong> “right”. Using this card, where would you place<br />

yourself on this scale, where 0 means the left <strong>and</strong> 10 means the right?” 0=left to 10=right. Recoded into<br />

1=left (0 to 3), 2=center (4 to 6), 3=right (7 to 10).<br />

For the coding of all other variables, please see Table 8-1.<br />

The results in Table 8-2 confirm the results of the first regression analysis. Even when<br />

controlling for motivational factors, resources such as age, education <strong>and</strong> gender still<br />

remain significant determinants of elite-challenging participation. Looking at the impact<br />

of the motivational determinants, interest in politics st<strong>and</strong>s out as the most important<br />

predictors for participation in elite-challenging activities, both in 1974 <strong>and</strong> 2004. In 2004,<br />

those with high political interest have show a chance to participate in demonstrations,<br />

petitions <strong>and</strong> boycotts that is 3.6 times higher than those who are not interested in<br />

politics. From the inequality perspective, however, it is interesting to note that the gap<br />

between participants <strong>and</strong> nonparticipants in terms of political interest is much higher in<br />

the other forms of political participation: conventional participation (odd = 5.2) <strong>and</strong><br />

voting (odd = 11.7). Internal efficacy as well as life satisfaction matter modestly only for<br />

voting, whereas it is insignificant for elite-challenging participation. Self-positioning on<br />

the political scale, however, works in the expected direction: being left-oriented doubles<br />

142


the chances to participate in elite-challenging activities, compared to those who position<br />

themselves more to the center <strong>and</strong> the right.<br />

These results for resources <strong>and</strong> motivation are not necessarily universal, as Appendix A-1<br />

<strong>and</strong> A-2 show. The tables list the correlations of the individual characteristics <strong>and</strong> elitechallenging<br />

action for more than 70 societies from the WVS/EVS 2000-2005. Some<br />

effects hold across almost all societies (e.g., political interest or self expression values),<br />

whereas others show noticeable differences in the strength <strong>and</strong> the direction of the effects<br />

(e.g., gender or age). Whether there is a systematic pattern in the context variation <strong>and</strong><br />

how it can be explained will be tested later on in a multilevel model.<br />

This section has looked at individual-level factors – resources <strong>and</strong> motivation – to predict<br />

elite-challenging activities. Besides the characteristics of an individual <strong>and</strong> in order to<br />

account for a complete picture on the question why people participate in these activities,<br />

contextual factors must be taken into account. Contextual factors provide opportunity<br />

structures that determine how successfully – or not – activists can mobilize supporters<br />

into action (Meyer 2004: 126).<br />

8.2 Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Context Factors<br />

Context matters for participation. The previous chapter addressed the importance of<br />

personal organizational opportunity structure, or, what Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels (1996: 2) have<br />

coined the ‘close context’ for participation. This section will now deal with the ‘wider<br />

context’ for political participation, specifically with political <strong>and</strong> socioeconomic<br />

characteristics of a society, which shape the conditions <strong>and</strong> opportunities for<br />

participation. A number of different indicators will be considered:<br />

In order for people to effectively participate, the political opportunity structure must be<br />

shaped in such a way that low barriers for participation exist, for example by granting<br />

several freedom rights (Dahl 1975: 125). This form of opportunity structure will be<br />

measured by two indicators: the World Bank’s Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability, <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

Stock as suggested by Gerring et al. (2005). In addition to political factors,<br />

143


socioeconomic conditions shape the participation context in a society as well:<br />

Modernization <strong>and</strong> postindustrialization processes make resources such as education<br />

available to the wider public, <strong>and</strong> technologically new ways of communicating allow<br />

people to activate these resources <strong>and</strong> translate them into action. GDP per capita<br />

measures the general affluence of a country, whereas the level of Tertiarization is<br />

operationalized using the employment structure of a society. As an unequal distribution<br />

of resources in a society is likely to create a barrier for people to participate, a third<br />

measure for socioeconomic conditions is introduced: the Gini coefficient assesses how<br />

wealth is distributed among the members of a society. An additional factor to assess the<br />

distribution of resources in a society is the Happiness Level. The happiness level is a<br />

subjective assessment of how widespread feelings of deprivation are among the members<br />

of a society. Finally, two types of institutional set-up are introduced in order to examine<br />

how they shape the political opportunity structure for people to participate outside<br />

institutionalized forms of political engagement: A measure for the type of electoral<br />

system <strong>and</strong> a measure for the regime type assess how the institutional context affects the<br />

success of mobilization processes.<br />

In a first step, the impact of each single context factor on the societal level of elitechallenging<br />

activities is tested. In a second step, the context factors will enter a multilevel<br />

analysis. The model will examine the impact of context factors <strong>and</strong> individual-level<br />

determinants on individual participation. To cover the largest possible variety of<br />

societies, the measure of elite-challenging activities does not only include the most recent<br />

wave of the WVS (2005). For societies not included in the fifth wave, data from the<br />

fourth wave (2000) are supplemented (for an overview of the societies <strong>and</strong> surveys used,<br />

see Appendix A8-1).<br />

Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability<br />

Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability is one of the six Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI)<br />

provided by the World Bank. It ranks more than 210 countries along six dimensions of<br />

governance. 61 It measures “perceptions of the extent to which a country’s citizens are<br />

61 The other indicators are: Political Stability <strong>and</strong> Absence of Violence, Government Effectiveness,<br />

Regulatory Quality, Rule of Law, <strong>and</strong> Control of Corruption.<br />

144


able to participate in selecting their government, as well as freedom of expression,<br />

freedom of association, <strong>and</strong> a free media” (Kaufmann, Kraay <strong>and</strong> Mastruzzi 2008: 7).<br />

Sources of the indicator come from various institutions 62 <strong>and</strong> cover elements that do not<br />

only refer to the electoral process but also to freedom of speech, of association, assembly<br />

<strong>and</strong> demonstration. Societies scoring high on the Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability indicator<br />

should have lower barriers for citizens to participate, thus providing an opportunity<br />

structure that is conducive for people to participate in elite-challenging activities.<br />

Figure 8-1: Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> Voice &<br />

Accountability<br />

1.0<br />

0.9<br />

NZ<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

0.8<br />

0.7<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

Braz<br />

Switz<br />

Swe<br />

Aus<br />

Can<br />

Fra<br />

Bel<br />

USA<br />

Nor<br />

GB<br />

Gre<br />

Den<br />

Czech Jap<br />

N-Ire<br />

Slovak Italy Ire<br />

Aut Lux<br />

E-Ger<br />

Ice<br />

Neth<br />

W-Ger Fin<br />

Alba<br />

Isr<br />

Spain<br />

Malt<br />

Mali<br />

Peru Croa S-Kor Slov<br />

Serb<br />

Monte<br />

Tanz<br />

Ind<br />

Lat<br />

Lith<br />

Cyp<br />

Eth<br />

Maced<br />

Uru<br />

Bu-Fa<br />

Tr & To<br />

Ugan<br />

Rus<br />

Mex<br />

Zam Bos Arg<br />

Est Por<br />

Pol<br />

Colom<br />

Mold<br />

Chi<br />

Nig<br />

Mor<br />

Ven<br />

Bul S-Afr<br />

Ukr Indon<br />

Bang<br />

Hun<br />

Guat<br />

Tur<br />

Gha<br />

Tai<br />

Rom<br />

Jord<br />

Malay<br />

Singa<br />

Thai<br />

0.0<br />

-2.00 -1.60 -1.20 -0.80 -0.40 0.00 0.40 0.80 1.20 1.60 2.00<br />

Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability<br />

N=78, R = 0.67 *** . Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability measured in 2000.<br />

62<br />

For example: Economist Intelligence Unit; Freedom House; World Economic Forum Global<br />

Competitiveness Report; Global Insight Business Conditions <strong>and</strong> Risk Indicators; Gallup World Poll;<br />

Political Risk Services International Country Risk Guide; Bertelsmann Transformation Index; Institutional<br />

Profiles Database; Cingranelli Richards Human Rights Database <strong>and</strong> Political Terror Scale. See Kaufmann,<br />

Kraay <strong>and</strong> Mastruzzi (2008: 72) for a more detailed description.<br />

145


Figure 8-1 displays the relationship between the governance indicator <strong>and</strong> a society’s<br />

level of elite-challenging activism. There is a positive link between Voice <strong>and</strong><br />

Accountability <strong>and</strong> the level of elite-challenging activism in a society (r = 0.67 *** ), with<br />

convergence at higher values of the governance indicator. Whereas at lower to medium<br />

levels of a democratic opportunity structure, only a marginal effect with respect to the<br />

spread of political activism can be observed, high scores on Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability are<br />

closely associated with high levels of participation in petitions, boycotts <strong>and</strong> strikes. This<br />

suggests that improvements at lower levels of democratic freedom rights do not<br />

immediately translate into widespread non-institutionalized mass action. Rather, high<br />

levels of elite-challenging participation can be found in societies that provide stable <strong>and</strong><br />

conducive conditions to associate, assemble <strong>and</strong> articulate opinions.<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> Stock<br />

For political opportunity structures to become effective it is not only important how much<br />

freedom rights are granted to the citizens today, but also for how long these have been in<br />

place. The longer citizens experience a democratic rule, the more occasions are created<br />

for political participation, <strong>and</strong> the more time citizens have to experiment with various<br />

forms of participation (Roller <strong>and</strong> Wessels 1996: 28). “The core insight is that<br />

institutional effects unfold over time, sometimes a great deal of time, <strong>and</strong> that these<br />

temporal effects are cumulative.” (Gerring et al. 2005: 325). The measure of <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

Stock takes this accumulation process of democratic experience into account, as<br />

democracy is considered as a stock – not level – variable (Gerring et al. 2005: 324).<br />

Polity 2 scores are added, beginning in 1900, with a 1 percent depreciation rate per year.<br />

Figure 8-2 shows how <strong>Democracy</strong> Stock <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities are linked: There<br />

is a positive, almost linear relationship (r = .73 *** ), meaning that societies with a longst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

‘democratic memory’ tend to have a more active citizenry. The length of<br />

democratic experience is crucial when it comes to creating political opportunity<br />

structures for elite-challenging activities, but there are also clear ‘over-achievers’, most<br />

of them post-communist societies. Their level of elite-challenging action still reflects the<br />

legacy of a citizen-driven transition to democracy, whereas their actual democratic<br />

experience falls short in predicting this form of mass participation.<br />

146


Figure 8-2:<br />

1.0<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong> Stock<br />

0.9<br />

NZ<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

0.8<br />

0.7<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

Swe Switz<br />

Aus<br />

Can<br />

Fra<br />

Bel Nor<br />

USA<br />

GB<br />

Den<br />

Gre<br />

Jap<br />

Czech<br />

Italy<br />

Slovak<br />

Ire N-Ire<br />

Braz<br />

Aut<br />

Lux<br />

Ice<br />

E-Ger<br />

W-Ger Fin Neth<br />

Alba<br />

Spain<br />

Isr<br />

Malt<br />

Croa<br />

Mali<br />

Peru<br />

Lat<br />

Slov<br />

S-Kor<br />

Ind<br />

Lith Monte Tanz<br />

Cyp<br />

Serb<br />

Eth Maced<br />

Uru<br />

Ugan<br />

Rus<br />

Mex Bu-Fa<br />

Tr & To<br />

Bos<br />

Arg Por<br />

Est Zam<br />

Pol<br />

Mold<br />

Chi<br />

Mor<br />

Nig<br />

Colom<br />

Ukr Bul Indon<br />

Ven<br />

S-Afr<br />

Hun<br />

Bang<br />

Guat<br />

Tur<br />

Gha<br />

Tai<br />

Rom<br />

Jord<br />

Singa<br />

Malay<br />

Thai<br />

0.0<br />

-600.00 -400.00 -200.00 0.00 200.00 400.00 600.00<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> Stock (1900 - 1995)<br />

N=78, R = 0.73 *** . <strong>Democracy</strong> Stock is measured between 1900 <strong>and</strong> 1995.<br />

National Affluence: GDP per capita<br />

Socioeconomic development is at the core of modernization theory, <strong>and</strong> it should be<br />

positively linked with elite-challenging activities. For one, modernization leads to a<br />

growing number <strong>and</strong> greater variety of interest groups <strong>and</strong> other associations, forming<br />

denser networks of activists <strong>and</strong> supporters. Such associational networks are conducive to<br />

mobilization <strong>and</strong>, as chapter 6 has shown, positively linked with elite-challenging<br />

activities. Another important factor is that socioeconomic development promotes an<br />

expansion of education (“educational revolution”). Information <strong>and</strong> knowledge become<br />

available to the wider public, making people more interested <strong>and</strong> aware about what is<br />

happening in their neighborhoods, cities or countries. At the same time, citizens who<br />

acquire these skills become also more confident about using their resources to articulate<br />

<strong>and</strong> promote their interests. As a result, the knowledge <strong>and</strong> information gap between<br />

elites <strong>and</strong> citizens is slowly closing.<br />

147


Figure 8-3:<br />

1.0<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> National Affluence<br />

0.9<br />

NZ<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

0.8<br />

0.7<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

Mali<br />

Malt<br />

Peru<br />

Ind<br />

Croa<br />

S-Kor<br />

Monte Lat<br />

Tanz<br />

Lith<br />

Serb<br />

Slov<br />

Eth<br />

Maced<br />

Uru<br />

Cyp<br />

Ugan<br />

Mex<br />

Bu-Fa<br />

Tr & To<br />

Rus<br />

Zam Bos Arg Est<br />

Pol Por<br />

Mold<br />

Colom Chi<br />

Nig<br />

Mor Ukr S-Afr<br />

Bul<br />

Indon Ven<br />

Bang<br />

Hun<br />

Guat Tur<br />

Tai<br />

Gha Rom<br />

Jord<br />

Alba<br />

Slovak<br />

Thai<br />

Braz<br />

Malay<br />

Czech<br />

Gre<br />

Isr<br />

N-Ire<br />

Den<br />

Ice<br />

Bel<br />

Italy Jap<br />

Ire<br />

Aut<br />

E-Ger<br />

Fin<br />

W-Ger<br />

Spain<br />

Fra<br />

GB<br />

Swe<br />

Aus<br />

Singa<br />

Can<br />

Neth<br />

Switz<br />

USA<br />

Nor<br />

Lux<br />

0.0<br />

0.00 10000.00 20000.00 30000.00 40000.00 50000.00<br />

GDP per capita, ppp<br />

N=78, R = 0.69 *** . GDP per capita, ppp is measured in the respective survey year (2000 or 2005).<br />

National Affluence is measured by the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita,<br />

adjusted for purchasing power parity. Data were taken for the survey year of each society<br />

(2000 or 2005) <strong>and</strong> come from the World Economic Outlook (WEO) database from the<br />

International Monetary Fund. 63 Figure 8-3 shows the relationship between national<br />

affluence <strong>and</strong> the level of elite-challenging activities. The overall trend is a positive link,<br />

but we can also see that the relationship is more diffuse at the lower end of economic<br />

development, whereas the trend becomes more linear as we move to higher levels of<br />

GDP. Luxembourg, Taiwan <strong>and</strong> Singapore are clear low-performers when it comes to<br />

mass participation: Their economic position would predict a much more active citizenry.<br />

63 Website: http://www.imf.org/external/ns/cs.aspx?id=28 .<br />

148


Inequality: Gini coefficient<br />

The inequality measure has a correcting function to the measure of economic<br />

development. GDP per capita can only grasp the overall level of national wealth, but not<br />

whether the resources are in principle available to all members of the society. This issue<br />

addresses the question whether wealth is unequally distributed in the society. Inequality<br />

is measured by the Gini coefficient, taken from the Human Development Report<br />

2007/2008. The time of measurement varies between 1998 <strong>and</strong> 2003 for the majority of<br />

the countries. 64 The Gini coefficient ranges between 0 (absolute equality) <strong>and</strong> 100<br />

(absolute inequality).<br />

Figure 8-4:<br />

1.0<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> Inequality in a<br />

Society<br />

0.9<br />

NZ<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

0.8<br />

0.7<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

Swe<br />

Nor<br />

Bel<br />

Fra<br />

GB<br />

Den<br />

Gre<br />

Jap<br />

Czech<br />

It aly<br />

Slovak<br />

Lux<br />

N-Ire<br />

Ire<br />

Ice Aut<br />

E-Ger<br />

Fin<br />

W-Ger<br />

Malt<br />

Alba<br />

Can<br />

Swit z<br />

Aus<br />

Spain<br />

Net h<br />

Isr<br />

USA<br />

Croa<br />

Ind<br />

S-Kor<br />

Mali<br />

Peru<br />

Slov<br />

Tanz<br />

Serb<br />

Lat<br />

Lit h<br />

Uru<br />

Cyp<br />

Mont e Maced<br />

Ugan<br />

Et h<br />

Tr & To<br />

Bu-Fa<br />

Zam<br />

Bos<br />

Est<br />

Mex<br />

Pol Rus<br />

Arg<br />

Por<br />

Mold<br />

Nig<br />

Chi<br />

Ukr<br />

Bul<br />

Mor<br />

Ven<br />

Indon<br />

Hun<br />

Bang<br />

Tur<br />

Tai<br />

Gha<br />

Guat<br />

Rom<br />

Singa<br />

Jord<br />

Malay<br />

Thai<br />

Braz<br />

Colom<br />

S-Af r<br />

0.0<br />

20.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 60.00<br />

Inequality: Gini coefficient<br />

N=78, R = -.40 *** . The Gini coefficient is measured in 2000.<br />

64 Missing data have been supplemented by previous HDR reports <strong>and</strong> the World Income Inequality<br />

Database (V2.0c May 2008) provided by World Institute for Development Economics Research of the<br />

United Nations <strong>University</strong> (UNU-WIDER): http://www.wider.unu.edu/research/Database/en_GB/wiid/ .<br />

149


Figure 8-4 displays the relationship between inequality in a society <strong>and</strong> its level of elitechallenging<br />

activism – both are only weakly linked (r = -.40 *** ), its distribution resembles<br />

more an exponential than a linear function. There is a modest trend that more equal<br />

societies are also more active, for example all postindustrial democracies in the upper left<br />

of the figure, but most postcommunist societies with a similar score on the inequality<br />

measure (here: low) show significantly lower levels of elite-challenging participation.<br />

Tertiarization<br />

As a third indicator for socioeconomic opportunity structures, the level of tertiarization is<br />

introduced. The shift of the major workforce from the industrial to the service sector did<br />

not only change the modes of production, but most importantly the communication<br />

structures in a society. Information <strong>and</strong> knowledge formation have gained tremendous<br />

importance, creating new dem<strong>and</strong>s for people at the workplace: “Service <strong>and</strong> knowledge<br />

workers deal with people <strong>and</strong> concepts, operating in a world where innovation <strong>and</strong> the<br />

freedom to exercise individual judgements are essential. Creativity, imagination, <strong>and</strong><br />

intellectual independence become central” (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005: 28-29). The<br />

experience of these activities does not leave people’s value orientations unaltered: They<br />

show an increasing emphasis on autonomy, choice, creativity <strong>and</strong> self-expression, which<br />

should be positively linked with elite-challenging activities.<br />

Tertiarization is measured by subtracting the share of labor force working in industry<br />

from the share of the labor force employed in the service sector of a society. Data come<br />

from the International Labour Organization, more specifically from their Key Indicators<br />

of the Labour Market (KILM, fifth edition, 2007). Most of the data refer to the year<br />

2000. 65 Figure 8-5 shows how tertiarization <strong>and</strong> mass participation in a society are linked:<br />

there is a positive relationship (r=.54 *** ), but with quite some deviation from the trend.<br />

65 Missing or questionable data have been cross-checked with other data sources <strong>and</strong> then either replaced by<br />

an alternative year of the ILO measure, or supplemented with data from the CIA Factbook (Nigeria 1999,<br />

India 2003, Mali 2005) or from the United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE, Bosnia<br />

Herzegovina 2006, Serbia <strong>and</strong> Montenegro 2000).<br />

150


Figure 8-5:<br />

1.0<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> Tertiarization<br />

0.9<br />

NZ<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

0.8<br />

0.7<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

Swe<br />

Switz Aus<br />

Fra Can<br />

Bel Nor<br />

GB USA<br />

Gre Den<br />

Czech<br />

Italy Jap<br />

Ire<br />

N-Ire<br />

Slovak<br />

Lux<br />

Aut Braz<br />

Ice<br />

E-Ger<br />

W-Ger Fin<br />

Neth<br />

Alba<br />

Spain<br />

Isr<br />

Malt<br />

Mali Ind<br />

Croa<br />

Serb S-Kor<br />

Maced<br />

Eth<br />

Slov Monte Lith<br />

Cyp<br />

Tanz<br />

Lat<br />

Uru<br />

Ugan<br />

Mex<br />

Zam<br />

Bos<br />

Bu-Fa<br />

Por<br />

Rus<br />

Pol Est<br />

Chi<br />

Mold<br />

Nig Mor<br />

Colom<br />

Bul<br />

Ukr<br />

Ven<br />

Indon<br />

S-Afr<br />

Bang<br />

Tai<br />

Hun<br />

Tur<br />

Gha<br />

Guat<br />

Rom<br />

Jord<br />

Malay<br />

Singa<br />

Thai<br />

Peru<br />

Tr & To<br />

Arg<br />

0.0<br />

0.00 10.00 20.00 30.00 40.00 50.00 60.00 70.00<br />

Postindustrialization (% employed in service minus % industry sector)<br />

N = 78. R = 0.54 ***<br />

Happiness<br />

The link between happiness <strong>and</strong> the level of elite-challenging action in a society is not<br />

necessarily straightforward. One the one h<strong>and</strong>, the level of happiness can be taken as a<br />

proxy for the prevalence (or absence) of relative deprivation in a society. As we know<br />

from happiness research, people’s happiness tends to reflect how they perceive their<br />

position relative to others. In that sense, the societal happiness level can be considered as<br />

a supplement to the inequality measure, for the first represents a subjective assessment,<br />

the latter an objective assessment of how resources are distributed in the society. On the<br />

other h<strong>and</strong>, levels of happiness are closely linked with trust, tolerance <strong>and</strong> self expression<br />

values, <strong>and</strong> with democracy <strong>and</strong> economic prosperity (Inglehart 1990, 2006). As the<br />

previous analyses have confirmed, these characteristics themselves are conducive for<br />

elite-challenging activities. The measure for the level of happiness in a society comes<br />

151


from the World Values Survey (2000-2005). The x-axis in Figure 8-6 indicates how a<br />

society scores on average on the 10-point scale question of life satisfaction.<br />

Figure 8-6:<br />

1.0<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005) <strong>and</strong> the Happiness<br />

Level in a Society<br />

0.9<br />

NZ<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

Swe<br />

Aus Switz<br />

Can<br />

Fra Bel<br />

Nor<br />

USA GB<br />

Gre<br />

Jap<br />

Den<br />

N-Ire<br />

Slovak Italy Czech<br />

Lux Ire<br />

Aut<br />

E-Ger Braz<br />

Ice<br />

Fin<br />

W-Ger Neth<br />

Isr<br />

Alba<br />

Spain<br />

Malt<br />

Ind Mali Croa<br />

Lat<br />

Peru<br />

Lith<br />

Tanz<br />

Monte S-Kor<br />

Slov<br />

Serb<br />

Cyp<br />

Maced Ugan<br />

Uru<br />

Eth<br />

Bos<br />

Tr & To Mex<br />

Bu-Fa Zam<br />

Por<br />

Rus<br />

Mold Est<br />

Pol Arg<br />

Nig Chi<br />

Colom<br />

Mor<br />

Ukr<br />

S-Afr Ven<br />

Bul<br />

Bang<br />

Indon<br />

Hun<br />

Tur<br />

Guat<br />

Gha<br />

Tai<br />

Rom<br />

Singa<br />

Jord<br />

Malay<br />

Thai<br />

0.8<br />

0.7<br />

0.6<br />

0.5<br />

0.4<br />

0.3<br />

0.2<br />

0.1<br />

0.0<br />

3.00 4.00 5.00 6.00 7.00 8.00 9.00<br />

Happiness level, country mean, scale 1 to 10<br />

N=78, R = 0.43 *** .<br />

The results in Figure 8-6 modestly support the latter assumption: higher levels of<br />

happiness reflect the prevalence of societal resources that enable people to participate in<br />

elite-challenging activities (r=.43 *** ). The positive link, however, is mainly attributed to<br />

societies with a higher happiness level, as the link breaks down among the less happy<br />

societies.<br />

Electoral System <strong>and</strong> Political System<br />

The way how authorities are selected <strong>and</strong> political power is exercised are the two main<br />

functions of liberal democracies (Sartori 1994). Fuchs (2000) has therefore suggested to<br />

152


assess the formal structure of a democratic regime by looking at a country’s electoral<br />

system <strong>and</strong> the system of governance. As the main typologies within these structures,<br />

electoral systems are characterized by proportional vs. majoritarian modes of translating<br />

electoral votes into parliament seats. The system of governance is most often identified<br />

by the interplay between the main democratic institutions: parliament <strong>and</strong> government,<br />

leading to a typology of systems that is often transferred into a dichotomy of presidential<br />

vs. parliamentary democracies. Data for the electoral system <strong>and</strong> system of governance<br />

come from the Database of Political Institutions provided by the World Bank (2000-<br />

2005). 66 The measure for proportional representation was already coded as a dichotomous<br />

variable. The measure for system of governance has been recoded into a dichotomy as<br />

well, so that now proportional representation <strong>and</strong> parliamentary system have a value of 1,<br />

whereas other system indicators have been coded 0. 67<br />

The choice of electoral system <strong>and</strong> system of governance should have an impact on the<br />

opportunity structure for mass action in a society, as both shape the number <strong>and</strong> character<br />

of relevant political actors <strong>and</strong> determine the chances for citizen action groups to gain<br />

political influence. To address the question whether a proportional electoral system or a<br />

parliamentary democracy provides a particular opportunity structure that is conducive for<br />

the mobilization of people into collective action, Table 8-3 shows the result of a T-Test.<br />

The tables show, first of all, the mean score of elite-challenging activities per group<br />

(majoritarian vs. proportional system; presidential vs. parliamentary system) <strong>and</strong>, second,<br />

whether the mean difference found between the two groups is actually significant.<br />

66 The two indicators are taken from Jan Teorell, Sören Holmberg <strong>and</strong> Bo Rothenstein (2008): The Quality<br />

of Government Dataset, version 15 May/08, <strong>University</strong> of Gothenburg: The Quality of Government<br />

Institute. http://www.qog.pol.gu.se .<br />

67 Regime type was originally coded: 0 = direct presidential, 1 = strong president elected by assembly, 2 =<br />

parliamentary. The first two categories have been coded as presidential system. The original coding of<br />

electoral system was already dichotomous, based on the question whether proportional representation was<br />

used as an electoral rule to select any c<strong>and</strong>idate in any house (see the Codebook of the Quality of<br />

Government Dataset, p. 73).<br />

153


Table 8-3a-b: T-Test for System Indicators<br />

Table 8-3a: T-Test for Electoral System <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS<br />

2000-2005):<br />

N<br />

Mean<br />

(St<strong>and</strong>ard deviation)<br />

Majoritarian or mixed 21 0.34 (0.236)<br />

system<br />

Proportional system 57 0.43 (0.204)<br />

T (df)<br />

P<br />

(two-tailed)<br />

-1.653 (76) .102<br />

Levene test for homogeneity of variance was insignificant: F=.127, p=.723, so equal variances are assumed.<br />

Table 8-3b:<br />

T-Test for System of Governance <strong>and</strong> Elite-Challenging Activities<br />

(WVS 2000-2005):<br />

N<br />

Mean<br />

(St<strong>and</strong>ard deviation)<br />

Presidential system 37 0.31 (0.127)<br />

Parliamentary system 41 0.51 (0.237)<br />

T (df)<br />

P<br />

(two-tailed)<br />

-4.591 (62.5) .000<br />

Levene test for homogeneity of variance was significant: F=22.601, p=.000, so equal variances are not<br />

assumed.<br />

The results in Table 8-3a-b are straightforward: The level of elite-challenging activities is<br />

slightly higher in proportional (43% on average) than in majority or mixed electoral<br />

systems (34%), but the difference is not significant (p=.102). There is, however, a<br />

significant effect of the regime type: In parliamentary systems we find more active<br />

publics (51% participate on average), whereas in presidential systems people participate<br />

less (31%; significance level p=.000).<br />

To summarize: Higher levels of economic development (GDP per capita, tertiarization),<br />

pronounced democratic structures <strong>and</strong> experiences as well as rising happiness levels<br />

provide societal resources <strong>and</strong> create opportunity structures that are conducive for mass<br />

participation. An unequal distribution of resources in a society works against it, as it<br />

raises the entry barrier for participation <strong>and</strong> therefore tends to exclude large parts of a<br />

society. Living in a parliamentary system is favorable for elite-challenging activities,<br />

whereas the choice of the electoral system has no effect for the societies under<br />

consideration. In a next step the significant level-2 factors will enter a multi-level model<br />

analysis to investigate whether the effects still hold when we control for individual-level<br />

characteristics.<br />

154


8.3 The Multilevel Model: What Determines Elite-Challenging Activities?<br />

As stated in the previous chapter, a multilevel analysis allows to examine independent<br />

effects of individual- und societal-level predictors on a dependent variable (measured on<br />

the lowest possible level), <strong>and</strong> at the same time modeling interaction effects between<br />

level-1 (individual level) <strong>and</strong> level-2 (societal level) factors to explain why people<br />

participate in elite-challenging activities. Again, due to the dichotomous character of the<br />

dependent variable, a hierarchical nonlinear regression model is used. 68<br />

As a first step, a baseline model is calculated, taking into account only the individuallevel<br />

variables (Model 1). There are two types of predictors. For one, motivation is<br />

operationalized with (1) life satisfaction, (2) left-right self positioning (inversely<br />

measured), (3) political interest, <strong>and</strong> (4) self expression values. Postmaterialism is part of<br />

the self expression measure <strong>and</strong> not considered separately: As the correlations in<br />

Appendix A8-2 showed, self expression values are the stronger predictor for participation<br />

in elite-challenging activities. Resources are measured by (5) gender, (6) age, (7)<br />

education <strong>and</strong> (8) income. Status inconsistency is not considered here, as it did not show<br />

any significant effect in the resource model.<br />

It is assumed that group differences can be observed (see Appendix A8-1 <strong>and</strong> A8-2),<br />

meaning that the individual-level variables have different effects across societies. The<br />

first model looks like this:<br />

Model 1:<br />

Prob (Yij) = (1/ β j ) = P<br />

η ij = log [P/(1-P)] = β 0j + β 1j (life satisfaction) ij + β 2j (left-right self positioning) ij +<br />

β 3j (political interest) ij + β 4j (self expression values) ij + β 5j (gender) ij + β 6j (age) ij +<br />

β 7j (education) ij + β 8j (income) ij + r ij.<br />

η ij is the dependent variable (participation in elite-challenging activities) for a level-1 unit<br />

(individual i), nested in a level-2 unit (society j), or more precisely: the logit of the odds<br />

68 For a more detailed outline of the model assumptions, please see chapter 6.<br />

155


that someone will participate in elite-challenging activities. These odds (or chances) are<br />

defined as P/(1-P), i.e. the probability (that someone participates, so ‘an event will<br />

occur’) divided by one minus the probability (that someone does not participate, so ‘an<br />

event will not occur’). The β 0i coefficient is the individual-level intercept, the other beta<br />

coefficients in the model are the individual-level effects (slopes). Finally, r ij represents<br />

the error term in this model.<br />

The main goal of a multilevel analysis is “to account for variance in a dependent variable<br />

that is measured at the lowest level of analysis by considering information from all levels<br />

of analysis” (Steenbergen <strong>and</strong> Jones 2002: 219). The information from the subordinate<br />

level, the societal level, is taken into account in the next two steps. Here, it is assumed<br />

that level-2 variables can have direct effects (Model 2) but may also mediate the effects<br />

of level-1 predictors (Model 3).<br />

In the second step of analyzing multilevel data, level-2 variables are introduced to<br />

estimate their independent effects on the individual-level intercept β 0j . In Model 2, the<br />

level-2 variables are (1) Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability, (2) <strong>Democracy</strong> Stock, (3) GDP per<br />

capita, (4) Tertiarization, (5) Inequality, (6) Happiness level, <strong>and</strong> (7) Parliamentary<br />

system. The variable Electoral system (Proportional system) was excluded from analysis,<br />

as the predictor did not have a significant effect on the level of elite-challenging<br />

participation (see T-test in Table 8-3a) <strong>and</strong> was insignificant even when introduced as the<br />

only predictor for individual-level participation in the multilevel model. The model for<br />

the context factors looks as follows:<br />

Model 2:<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability j ) + γ 02 (<strong>Democracy</strong> Stock j ) +<br />

γ 03 (GDP per capita j ) + γ 04 (Tertiarization j ) + γ 05 (Inequality j ) + γ 06 (Happiness level j) +<br />

γ 07 (Parliamentary system j ) + u ij .<br />

In the equation, γ 00 is the societal level intercept, the other γ coefficients are level-2<br />

effects on the level-1 intercept β 0j . The level-2 error term is summarized in u ij .<br />

With eight individual-level <strong>and</strong> seven context factors, the problem of multicollinearity<br />

must be addressed before we begin with the statistical analysis. Multicollinearity is a<br />

156


well-known phenomenon in regression analysis, <strong>and</strong> it also poses a serious challenge<br />

when applying multi-level models. In short, it refers to a considerable correlation among<br />

the independent variables, which leads most likely to an unreliable estimation of effects.<br />

In a multilevel analysis, multicollinearity can occur among predictors of the same level,<br />

or between an interaction effect <strong>and</strong> a level-1 <strong>and</strong>/or level-2 predictor. Looking at the<br />

variables in the Models 1 <strong>and</strong> 2, collinearity among variables seems to be unavoidable: a<br />

central finding in participation research, for example, is the correlation between<br />

education <strong>and</strong> political interest. At the aggregate level, Seymour Martin Lipset’s central<br />

claim of modernization theory – “The more well-to-do a nation, the greater the chances<br />

that it will sustain democracy.” (Lipset 1959: 75) – suggests a strong correlation between<br />

the World Bank’s governance indicators <strong>and</strong> a country’s economic development. Table 8-<br />

4 documents the correlation coefficients among the level-2 predictors, suggesting a<br />

multicollinearity problem also at the aggregate level. Correlations are most pronounced<br />

between the level-2 variables <strong>and</strong> economic development (GDP per capita) as well as the<br />

democracy measures:<br />

Table 8-4:<br />

Correlation Effects Among Level-2 Variables<br />

V & A<br />

Dem.<br />

Stock<br />

GDP per<br />

capita<br />

Happiness<br />

Parliamenta.<br />

Proportional<br />

Inequality<br />

Tertiarization<br />

Voice <strong>and</strong><br />

Accountability -- .71 *** .59 *** .55 *** .27 * .81 *** -.41 *** .56 ***<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong><br />

Stock .71 *** -- .72 *** .52 *** .01 .78 *** -.12 .69 ***<br />

Happiness Level .59 *** .72 *** -- .31 ** .17 .63 *** .10 .61 ***<br />

Regime Type:<br />

Parliamentarism .55 *** .52 *** .31 ** -- .00 .55 *** -.46 *** .11<br />

Proportional<br />

System .27 * .01 .17 .00 -- .17 .26 * .09<br />

GDP per capita .81 *** .78 *** .63 *** .55 *** .17 -- -.39 *** .61 ***<br />

Inequality<br />

(Gini coefficient) -.41 *** -.12 *** .10 -.46 *** -.26 * -.39 *** -- .07<br />

Tertiarization .56 *** .69 *** .61 *** .14 .09 .61 *** .07 --<br />

N=78. Data entries are Pearson’s r.<br />

The problem of multicollinearity in the multilevel model becomes evident when<br />

introducing the level-2 predictors to the multilevel model: When each factor is entered<br />

157


separately <strong>and</strong> without controlling for any other level-2 factor, each predictor has a<br />

significant <strong>and</strong> positive impact (exception: the impact of inequality is negative, but also<br />

significant). When entering all level-2 factors simultaneously (mutually controlling for<br />

each other), all factors – with the exception of tertiarization <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong> stock –<br />

become insignificant, hence pointing to a multicollinearity problem.<br />

But how to deal with that problem? To be sure, deleting one of the highly correlated<br />

variables is often suggested, but the level-2 factors are theoretically distinct <strong>and</strong> represent<br />

different notions of societal opportunity structures, so that this statistics-driven approach<br />

is not very satisfying. Another option is to reduce the number of correlated level-2 factors<br />

in the model by entering only two factors simultaneously to the model. As Table 8-4<br />

suggested, GDP per capita is the strongest correlative of all level-2 predictors, so all other<br />

level-2 factors could enter the analysis under the control of a nation’s economic<br />

development. The step-wise modified Model 2a could look as follows:<br />

Modified Model 2a (separate models):<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (<strong>Democracy</strong> Stock j ) + γ 02 (GDP per capita j) + u ij .<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability j ) + γ 02 (GDP per capita j) + u ij .<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (Tertiarization j ) + γ 02 (GDP per capita j) + u ij .<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (Inequality j ) + γ 02 (GDP per capita j) + u ij .<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (Happiness level j) + γ 02 (GDP per capita j) + u ij .<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (Parliamentary system j ) + γ 02 (GDP per capita j) + u ij .<br />

It could be argued, however, that examining the single explanatory power of strongly<br />

correlated phenomena in a statistical model is not only a pointless endeavor, but also<br />

doesn’t make much sense from a more conceptual point of view. Some of the level-2<br />

factors seem rather to represent a common syndrome than separate effects: GDP per<br />

capita, Tertiarization, Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability, <strong>Democracy</strong> Stock, <strong>and</strong> the Level of<br />

Happiness represent the political, social <strong>and</strong> economic changes associated with processes<br />

of modernization. As a consequence, the highly correlated variables can be summarized<br />

in one factor, which could also solve the multicollinearity problem. A factor analysis with<br />

the five most strongly correlated level-2 factors supports this argument, so it is possible<br />

158


to replace the five single predictors by a common factor (see Appendix A8-3 for the<br />

result of the factor analysis). In addition, the variable “Parliamentarism” was eliminated.<br />

The system of government is highly correlated with the variables composing the factor<br />

score, but not conceptually related to the modernization syndrome, so that adding it to the<br />

analysis does not have any additional value. This leads to a modified Model 2b:<br />

Modified Model 2b:<br />

β 0j = γ 00 + γ 01 (Modernization j ) + γ 02 (Inequality j ) + u ij .<br />

The downside, however, of introducing a syndrome as a main predictor is that it does not<br />

allow us anymore to attribute the effects to a single factor, or to determine the relative<br />

strength of a single factor in predicting elite-challenging activities on the individual level.<br />

Besides deletion or recoding of variables, HLM offers additional ways to tackle the<br />

problem of multicollinearity. A first solution is centering, in particular of the level-1<br />

variables. For the subsequent analysis, the level-1 variables were centered around their<br />

group mean (except for gender which was not centered because it is a dichotomous<br />

variable): “When group mean centering is used, the correlation between second-level<br />

variables <strong>and</strong> both first-level variables <strong>and</strong> cross-level interactions are equal to zero, so<br />

that only the correlations between cross-level interactions <strong>and</strong> level-1 variables remain as<br />

a potential source of estimation problems” (SSI 2008: 84). 69 The level-2 predictors were<br />

centered around their gr<strong>and</strong> mean (exception: regime type as a dichotomous variable).<br />

The main idea of centering is to assign a meaningful zero point to each variable<br />

(Raudenbush <strong>and</strong> Bryk 2002: 32). 70<br />

A second solution to detect <strong>and</strong> eliminate multicollinearity, if HLM posts a warning<br />

message about multicollinearity, is to inspect the Tau Matrix in the output, as correlations<br />

close to 1 or -1 (excluding the diagonal, of course) can be an indication of<br />

69 Please see the website of Scientific Software International, Inc., the provider of the HLM software:<br />

http://www.ssicentral.com/hlm/help6/faq/Multicollinearity.pdf .<br />

70 Centering is central to the interpretation of any intercept β 0j, as it is the expected outcome for a person<br />

who scores 0 in all other variables. Therefore, it is crucial that any predictor variable has a meaningful zero<br />

point: Centering assigns the zero point to the group (or gr<strong>and</strong>) mean score.<br />

159


multicollinearity. In none of the models, however, a multicollinearity warning occurred,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Tau correlations were in no case close to perfect.<br />

The four-fold strategy of (1) summarizing highly correlated level-2 predictors in one<br />

factor, (2) entering the level-2 predictors pair-wise to the model, (3) centering the level-1<br />

<strong>and</strong> level-2 variables, <strong>and</strong> (4) a close inspection of the output file with regard to<br />

multicollinearity indications should alleviate the effects of multicollinearity.<br />

In a last step, level-2 variables should be considered in their interaction effects with level-<br />

1 variables on the dependent variable. Again, with so many variables <strong>and</strong> interaction<br />

effects possible, instability of the model might evolve. As there is no clear assumption<br />

from the participation literature which societal characteristics should have an effect on<br />

which individual-level predictors for elite-challenging action – <strong>and</strong> which should not – a<br />

more inductive procedure is applied (see also Weldon 2006: 341). In order not to exclude<br />

any potential cross-level effect, a full model was calculated <strong>and</strong> then a method of<br />

backwards elimination of effects applied, based on a significance level of p ≤ 0.05 <strong>and</strong> a<br />

contribution to explained variance (as also suggested in Duncan et al. 2003: 249). Model<br />

3 summarizes only those level-2 interaction effects on level-1 regression parameters that<br />

turned out to be significant:<br />

Model 3:<br />

β 2j = γ 20 + γ 21 (Modernization) + u 2j<br />

β 5j = γ 50 + γ 51 (Modernization) + γ 52 (Inequality) + u 5j<br />

β 6j = γ 60 + γ 61 (Inequality) + u 6j<br />

β kj = γ k .<br />

γ 20 , γ 50 <strong>and</strong> γ 60 are the intercepts for the respective life satisfaction, gender <strong>and</strong> age slopes,<br />

γ 21 , γ 51 , γ 52 , <strong>and</strong> γ 61 are the effects of the context factors on the level-1 slopes. The term<br />

β kj =γ k captures all other level-1 predictors that did not vary across contexts.<br />

Before introducing the results, we should first have a look how the variance is<br />

distributed: Does elite-challenging participation vary more within or between societies?<br />

160


The intraclass correlation coefficient (ICC) usually suggest whether it is worthwhile<br />

doing a multilevel analysis, as it informs how much of the overall variance can be<br />

attributed to group-specific differences. The ICC is calculated as p = T 00 / (T 00 + σ 2 ), with<br />

T 00 as the level-2 variance <strong>and</strong> σ 2 as the level-1 variance. In cases where the level-1<br />

equation is a logit link (because of the nonlinear dependent variable), no level-1 variance<br />

is given (see the equation of Model 1: there is no error term for the logit link function).<br />

Snijders <strong>and</strong> Bosker (1999) have suggested an alternative way of calculating the ICC for<br />

binomial models, treating the dependent variable as a latent continuous variable. In the<br />

logistic regression models, the error variance for the level-1 r<strong>and</strong>om effects is fixed to σ 2<br />

= Π 2 / 3. Thus, the ICC for logistic regression models is calculated as p = T 00 / (T 00 + Π 2<br />

/ 3) .<br />

In our model, the ICC represents the proportion of variance in elite-challenging<br />

participation between societies. Substituting the variance components for their respective<br />

parameters (T 00 = 0.72507 in the empty model, p = .000) results in an ICC of 0.18:<br />

p = T 00 / (T 00 + Π 2 / 3) = 0.72507/ (0.72507 + 3.28987) = 0.18059.<br />

In total, 18 percent of the variance in participation in elite-challenging activities is<br />

between societies. 82 percent lies within the level-2 units:<br />

Level-1 variance = (Π 2 /3) / (T 00 + (Π 2 / 3)) = 3.28987 / (0.72507 + 3.28987) = 0.81941.<br />

The distribution of variance already suggests that variation in elite-challenging activities<br />

is mainly determined by differences between individuals within a society, rather than by<br />

differences between societies. With a multilevel model we can now test how much of the<br />

variance within <strong>and</strong> between societies can be explained by introducing individual-level<br />

characteristics <strong>and</strong> context factors. Table 8-5 presents the results of the multi-level model.<br />

As in the previous chapter, odds ratios (instead of log odds coefficients) are documented,<br />

as they are easier to interpret. 71 The data entries show how the odds ratios are changing<br />

71 Odds are calculated from log odds as exp(x), the inverse function of the natural logarithm:<br />

161


when a one-unit increase in the independent variable occurs (odds with increase<br />

compared to odds without an increase in the predictor).<br />

The results in Table 8-5 show that all resource <strong>and</strong> motivation predictors in Model 1 have<br />

a significant effect on participation in elite-challenging activities. Across all 70 societies,<br />

people who are rather left-oriented, slightly dissatisfied, more interested in politics <strong>and</strong><br />

who score higher on self expression values are more likely to join demonstrations,<br />

petitions, <strong>and</strong> boycotts than others. In addition, participants can more likely be found<br />

among male <strong>and</strong> higher educated persons. Age <strong>and</strong> income have a modest but still<br />

significantly positive effect.<br />

odds<br />

⎛<br />

=<br />

⎜<br />

⎝ 1 −<br />

p<br />

p<br />

⎞<br />

⎟ = e<br />

⎠<br />

⎛ p<br />

ln<br />

⎜<br />

⎝ 1−<br />

p<br />

⎞<br />

⎟<br />

⎠<br />

162


Table 8-5:<br />

Multi-Level Model (HGLM): Individual-Level <strong>and</strong> Contextual<br />

Determinants of Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005)<br />

Model 1:<br />

Individual-level only<br />

(r<strong>and</strong>om intercept,<br />

r<strong>and</strong>om slope)<br />

Individual- <strong>and</strong> societal-level predictors<br />

Model 2:<br />

Societal-level effects<br />

on intercept<br />

Alternative Model 3:<br />

Full model with<br />

significant interaction<br />

effects<br />

Intercept 0.919 (-0.780) 0.912 (-1.017) 0.919 (-1.004)<br />

Individual-level effects (slopes):<br />

Life Satisfaction<br />

0.973*** (-3.882) 0.975*** (-5.063) 0.975*** (-5.024)<br />

Left-Right Positioning (reversed) 1.045*** (4.215) 1.043*** (9.469) 1.012 (0.938)<br />

Interest in Politics<br />

1.544*** (22.127) 1.530*** (37.100) 1.532*** (36.628)<br />

Self Expression Values<br />

3.441*** (13.312) 3.812*** (21.189) 3.430*** (19.161)<br />

Control Factors:<br />

Gender<br />

0.858** (-3.758) 0.869*** (-6.980) 0.859*** (-4.701)<br />

Age<br />

1.004* (2.415) 1.003*** (4.925) 1.003* (2.141)<br />

Education<br />

1.154*** (14.658) 1.157*** (27.428) 1.158*** (27.098)<br />

Income<br />

1.030** (2.937) 1.027*** (5.494) 1.027*** (5.408)<br />

Societal-level effects (intercepts):<br />

Modernization (factor score)<br />

Inequality: Gini coefficient<br />

Cross-level interaction effects<br />

(slopes):<br />

Left-Right Positioning (reversed)<br />

* Postmodernization<br />

Gender<br />

* Inequality<br />

* Postmodernization<br />

Age<br />

* Inequality<br />

Remaining between-society<br />

variance:<br />

Intercept<br />

(Contribution to variance)<br />

Left-Right Positioning (reversed)<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

0.7439***<br />

0.0060***<br />

0.0834***<br />

0.0002***<br />

2.112*** (8.806)<br />

0.973*** (-2.714)<br />

0.5076***<br />

(31,8%)<br />

1.677*** (6.175)<br />

0.986 (-1.449)<br />

1.052*** (6.295)<br />

0.991* (-2.474)<br />

1.181*** (5.233)<br />

1.001** (3.993)<br />

0.4239***<br />

(43,0%)<br />

0.0033*** (45,0%)<br />

0.0405*** (51,4%)<br />

0.0001*** (50.0%)<br />

Source: World Values Survey 2000-2005. N (individual level) = 56.284. N (societal level) = 70.<br />

Significance level: * p ≤ .05, ** p ≤ .01, *** p = .00. Data entries are odds ratios with T-values in<br />

parentheses. Hierarchical generalized linear model calculated with HLM 6.06.<br />

Individual-level variables: WVS 2000-2005. Gender (1=male, 2=female), Age (low to high), Education (8-<br />

point scale), Income (10-point scale).<br />

Societal-level variables:<br />

Modernization is measured as the factor score (factor analysis with GDP per capita, tertiarization, Voice<br />

<strong>and</strong> Accountability, <strong>Democracy</strong> stock, <strong>and</strong> happiness level). For the coding of the variables, please see<br />

Appendix A8-4.<br />

Inequality: Gini coefficient: Data taken from the Human Development Report (HDR) 2007/08. Note that<br />

the survey years vary. Missing data have been supplemented by previous HDR reports <strong>and</strong> the World<br />

Income Inequality Database (V2.0c May 2008) provided by World Institute for Development Economics<br />

Research of the United Nations <strong>University</strong> (UNU-WIDER): http://www.wider.unu.edu/research/Database<br />

/en_GB/wiid/ .<br />

163


Model 2 enters the societal-level variables to the analysis. To account for the<br />

mulicollinearity problem, five of the seven level-2 predictors are summarized in a factor<br />

score. The alternative model (Modified Model 2a), entering the predictors separately<br />

while using GDP per capita as the reference predictor, is documented in Appendix A8-4.<br />

Modernization (factor score) increases participation in elite-challenging activities<br />

significantly: Holding other predictors constant, an increase in one st<strong>and</strong>ard deviation in<br />

the independent variables increases the odds ratio by 2.11, meaning that the chances for<br />

participation in elite-challenging activities are more than doubled. Inequality, by contrast,<br />

decreases the chances for participation. An unequal distribution of resources in a society,<br />

measured by the Gini coefficient on a scale between 0 <strong>and</strong> 100, lowers the odds ratio for<br />

participation to 0.97, when the independent variables is increased by one unit.<br />

Respectively, two otherwise similar societies that differ on the inequality scale by 10<br />

points show a difference in the odds of elite-challenging activities of 1 to 0.74.<br />

The alternative multilevel model based on a pair-wise comparison of level-2 effects (see<br />

Appendix A8-4) supports the result that modernization matters as a context factor: GDP<br />

per capita has a significant effect on elite-challenging activities 72 , the same is true for the<br />

variable <strong>Democracy</strong> Stock. The level of tertiarization is the only other, however weakly,<br />

significant level-2 effect on the intercept (odds ratio = 1.02), suggesting that a change of<br />

the composition of the workforce in favor of the service sector by 30 percent leads to an<br />

increase in the odds ratio to 1.81. All other level-2 predictors are insignificant.<br />

Model 3 adds the significant cross-level interaction effects to the model. The most<br />

important result can be found with respect to the gender gap in participation: Whereas<br />

elite-challenging activities across all societies under consideration are mainly exercised<br />

by men (Model 1: 0.86), women do not only close the gap but take the lead in these forms<br />

of political participation when modernization comes in (Model 3: 1.18). These results<br />

support the earlier findings in the chapter that were based on a selected number of<br />

72 The odds ratio of 1.00 seems to suggest that there is no substantial contribution of the predictor.<br />

However, that would mean jumping to conclusions: The rounding of the reported odds ratio conceals the<br />

real effect (=1.000032). As GDP per capita is measured in US-Dollars, the odds ration for participation<br />

increases to within a 1.000 US-Dollars difference in GDP to 1.03, within a difference of 10.000 US-Dollars<br />

to 1.38, <strong>and</strong> within 30.000 to 2.61. Remember that the interpretation of odds ratios for a continuous<br />

variable differs: If a change of two or more units in the independent variable occurs, the odds ratios are<br />

multiplied (not added!).<br />

164


European societies only. The effect of being left on elite-challenging participation is<br />

mediated by modernization, too. A left-wing political orientation matters more in<br />

economically developed <strong>and</strong> democratic societies (Table 8-2 suggests that this hasn’t<br />

changed much over the past three decades). The overall effect of modernization remains<br />

significant but becomes smaller (Model 2: 2.11, Model 3: 1.68), as some of its<br />

explanatory power is taken up by the mediating effects via individual-level predictors<br />

(gender <strong>and</strong> left-right positioning).<br />

The alternative model (see Appendix A8-4) based on a pair-wise comparison largely<br />

confirms the findings: As a general opportunity structure, the cumulative democratic<br />

experience of enjoying participation rights <strong>and</strong> occasions is the most important context<br />

factor. For the participation of women, however, the re-distribution <strong>and</strong> increasing<br />

availability of economic resources is most crucial: Rising GDP per capita closes the<br />

gender gap in elite-challenging participation.<br />

The information at the bottom of Table 8-5 indicates in how far the introduction of level-<br />

2 factors has improved the fit of the model intercept (32 percent when Modernization <strong>and</strong><br />

Inequality are introduced). The variance components documented here show how much<br />

of the variation between societies (level-2 variance) can be explained by including level-2<br />

variables into the model. In fact, the coefficients display how much of the variance<br />

remains still unexplained. From these components, the reduction in error variance can be<br />

calculated (Kreft <strong>and</strong> de Leeuw 1998: 118). 73 Comparing the Models 2 <strong>and</strong> 3, including<br />

cross-level interaction effects improved the model as well: the overall unexplained<br />

variance in Model 3 could be reduced by including the interaction effects (the variance<br />

components show an additional reduction from 32 to 43 percent compared to Model 1<br />

73 As there is no ‘true’ R 2 in HLM, there are a number of suggestions on how to calculate the explained<br />

variance in a multilevel model. In one way or another, all of them refer to a comparison of the error terms<br />

in an unrestricted <strong>and</strong> a restricted model. Kreft <strong>and</strong> de Leeuw (1998) suggest for the between society<br />

)<br />

variance: 2<br />

u<br />

0<br />

− u1<br />

R between<br />

= , with u0 being the error term in the “r<strong>and</strong>om intercept, r<strong>and</strong>om slope” model<br />

u<br />

0<br />

(unrestricted model), <strong>and</strong> u 1 being the error term in the “full model with interaction effects” (restricted<br />

model). The variance of the new model is subtracted from the variance of the restricted model: “The<br />

difference is compared to the original variance (the null model variance) as a proportion reduction in that<br />

variance” (Kreft <strong>and</strong> de Leeuw 1998: 188). As the authors point out, this simple approach has its drawbacks<br />

(as other approaches have as well): Negative results might occur when the variance of the unrestricted<br />

model is larger than the variance of the restricted model (Kreft <strong>and</strong> de Leeuw 1998: 118).<br />

165


<strong>and</strong> 2). The reduction of unexplained variance, however, is more modest compared to the<br />

introduction of level-2 factors.<br />

To summarize the results: <strong>Participation</strong> in elite-challenging activities is mainly driven by<br />

individual-level resources (mainly gender, education <strong>and</strong> income) <strong>and</strong> motivation<br />

(foremost political interest <strong>and</strong> self expression values). At the aggregate level, processes<br />

of modernization change the political, economic <strong>and</strong> social conditions, creating an<br />

opportunity structure that is conducive for elite-challenging participation. In particular,<br />

development yields a redistribution <strong>and</strong> accessibility of resources that enables women to<br />

become politically engaged.<br />

166


9. Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

The spread of elite-challenging activities over the past decades has added a new facet to<br />

the debate about the link between participation <strong>and</strong> democracy. In particular in the 1970s,<br />

student protests have been regarded as a threat to the democratic order <strong>and</strong> stability, as<br />

these citizens increasingly questioned authority <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>ed, among others, an<br />

expansion of participation rights (Huntington 2000). Croizier, Huntington <strong>and</strong> Watanuki<br />

(1975) claimed in their “crisis of democracy” study that democracies are in danger of<br />

being overloaded by these rising public dem<strong>and</strong>s (see Chapter 2.5), posing a threat to<br />

governability. More recently, Putnam’s work on declining social capital has shown that<br />

people tend to abstain from traditional organizations <strong>and</strong> engage in individualized<br />

activities instead, claiming that this development has severe negative consequences for<br />

communities <strong>and</strong> democracies at large, as the social basis of communities is eroding<br />

(Putnam 1995, 2000, 2002). But is there empirical evidence that the spread of elitechallenging<br />

activities poses a threat to democracies?<br />

This chapter distinguishes between two levels of effects: In the interpretation of Croizier<br />

et al. high levels of mass participation outside institutionalized channels should have a<br />

paralyzing impact on the democratic process. This affects the aggregate level of<br />

democratic governance. A second interpretation of the participation-democracy link takes<br />

a more indirect perspective: Individual participation in elite-challenging activities might<br />

be driven by non-democratic orientations (or more moderately, attitudes that are not<br />

conducive to democracy). Given that mass attitudes matter for the design <strong>and</strong> efficacy of<br />

political institutions, individual participation that is motivated by de-stabilizing attitudes<br />

can pose a problem for democratic governance. This scenario relates to the individual<br />

level. Let’s first have a look at the aggregate level.<br />

9.1 The Societal Level: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

Does participation in elite-challenging activities really jeopardize democracy? The main<br />

idea of the authors of the “Crisis of <strong>Democracy</strong>” study was not only that dem<strong>and</strong>s<br />

167


ought forward by the masses are usually in danger of following populistic tendencies.<br />

More important for the question of governability is that high levels of elite-challenging<br />

participation in a society tend to pressure elites, in particular political ones, <strong>and</strong> that his<br />

pressure creates constraints for autonomous decision-making among these elites. By<br />

contrast, adherents of a more emancipative approach would argue that it is exactly that<br />

kind of mass pressure that keeps elites responsive <strong>and</strong> accountable, making the<br />

democratic process more effective (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2005; Welzel, Inglehart <strong>and</strong><br />

Deutsch 2005; Dalton 2008). To test these two assumptions empirically, data on<br />

democratic quality <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities are needed. The measure for<br />

participation in elite-challenging activities comes from the WVS/EVS 1999-2001 <strong>and</strong><br />

precedes the democracy measures. To assess the quality of democracy a number of<br />

indicators is available in the social science literature. None of these is encompassing.<br />

Each measurement has its strengths <strong>and</strong> drawbacks, as the single measurements focus on<br />

different aspects of democracy. The following analyses use data from the Polity I-IV<br />

project, Freedom House, Transparency International <strong>and</strong> the World Bank. Average scores<br />

of several years are used to account for short-term fluctuation. 74<br />

9.1.1 Measures of <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

The Polity Scale (Jaggers <strong>and</strong> Gurr)<br />

The Polity Scale presented by the Polity project is a combined measure, consisting of the<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> <strong>and</strong> Autocracy Scales. The scales reflect the institutional component of<br />

democracy, thereby measuring constitutional democracy (Jaggers & Gurr 1995). The data<br />

set derived from the Polity (I-IV) project comprises historical data reaching back until<br />

1800. 75<br />

The authors consider three major dimensions to be inevitable for institutionalized<br />

democracy: a) competitiveness of political participation; b) openness of executive<br />

recruitment; <strong>and</strong> c) constraints on the chief executive. From these dimensions, indicators<br />

74 It should be noted that non-democracies were excluded from analysis from the very beginning (see case<br />

selection in Chapter 4), based on their Freedom House ratings in the year before, during or after the survey<br />

was conducted. This way a bias in the selection of countries occurs, but non-democracies are still in the<br />

sample, for example Belarus (survey data taken from 1996).<br />

168


for both scales are derived. According to these indicators, each country is assessed on an<br />

11-point scale, ranging from 0 to 10. For the <strong>Democracy</strong> Scale, 0 is indicating the<br />

absence of democratic elements, whereas 10 means the full presence of institutionalized<br />

democracy (the Autocracy Scale is composed respectively). The Polity Scale is calculated<br />

by subtracting the Autocracy Scale from the <strong>Democracy</strong> Scale. The Polity data have been<br />

criticized for their focus on the purely formal institutionalization of democracy <strong>and</strong>,<br />

respectively, their neglect of democracy in actual practice.<br />

Figure 9-1:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Institutional <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

(POLITY I-IV, 2001-2004)<br />

Lux, Ice, Jap, Aut, NIre, Ire, Ita, Czech,<br />

Swi, EGer, Neth, Den, Gre, Bel<br />

POLITY Scale 2001-2004<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

0<br />

Hun<br />

Lith<br />

Spa Uru<br />

Slove<br />

W Ger<br />

Port<br />

Malt Isr Fin<br />

Tai<br />

Pol Chil<br />

Bul<br />

India<br />

Peru<br />

S Afr<br />

Rom<br />

Lat<br />

Mold<br />

Slovak<br />

Phil Mex Arg<br />

Mace<br />

Dom<br />

S Kor Braz<br />

Tur Col Alb Croa<br />

Indo<br />

Rus<br />

Serb<br />

Bang<br />

Ven<br />

Est<br />

Ukr<br />

Geor<br />

Arm<br />

Nig<br />

Tan<br />

Can<br />

Fran<br />

Aus<br />

GB<br />

Swe<br />

N Zea<br />

USA<br />

-2<br />

Jord<br />

-4<br />

Uga<br />

-6<br />

-8<br />

Pak<br />

Mor<br />

Aze<br />

Bela<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

POLITY SCALE: Source: Polity (I-IV) Project. Mean score on Polity Scale 2001-2004. Polity Scale (-10 to +10):<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> Scale (0 to 10) minus Autocracy Scale (0 to 10). R=0.48 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: measured as percentage of respondents per sample who report to “Have done” any of the<br />

following activities: signed a petition, joined in boycotts, attended lawful demonstrations, joining unofficial strikes, or<br />

occupying buildings or factories. Data taken from WVS/EVS 1999-2001 (wave IV), except for Armenia (1997), Australia<br />

75 Information about the Polity I-IV projects <strong>and</strong> the respective data sets can be found on the following<br />

website: http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/polity/. Registration <strong>and</strong> acquisition of the data sets are also<br />

possible from this website.<br />

169


(1995), Azerbaijan (1997), Belarus (1996), Brazil (1997), Dominican Republic (1996) <strong>and</strong> Georgia (1996), New Zeal<strong>and</strong><br />

(1998), Norway (1996), Pakistan (1997), South Korea (1996) <strong>and</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (1996).<br />

Figure 9-1 displays the relationship between a society’s level of participation in elite<br />

challenging activities, measured around 2000, <strong>and</strong> the degree of institutional democracy,<br />

measured as the average Polity score 2001 to 2004. 76 The link between the two is modest<br />

(r = .48 *** ) but positive, disconfirming the claim that elite-challenging activities<br />

undermine democracy.<br />

Except for six cases (Belarus, Azerbaidjan, Pakistan, Morocco, Ug<strong>and</strong>a <strong>and</strong> Jordan) all<br />

countries under consideration have a positive Polity score, indicating that democratic<br />

rather than authoritarian constitutional elements dominate the political system. In fact, the<br />

majority of countries scores between 8 <strong>and</strong> 10 on the Polity scale (10 being the<br />

maximum), <strong>and</strong> the weak relationship between the participation level in a society <strong>and</strong> the<br />

country’s institutional arrangement reflects the fact that the given country sample shows<br />

little variation in the formal institutionalization of democracy.<br />

Freedom House scores<br />

A more encompassing measure of democracy comes from the Freedom House<br />

Organization. By its own account, Freedom House does not assess quality of democracy<br />

but ordinary people’s freedoms in terms of political rights <strong>and</strong> civil liberties (Gastil 1991;<br />

Karatnycky 1999). However, these two scales cover central elements of any conception<br />

of liberal democracy, including freedom of religions, movement <strong>and</strong> speech, or rights to<br />

vote, run for office <strong>and</strong> sue officials (Lauth 2003: 4). Moreover, the scales are designed to<br />

evaluate not only constitutional requirements but also how these given rights <strong>and</strong> rules<br />

work in reality on a day-to-day basis (Schmidt 2000: 409; Karatnycky 2003: 102).<br />

The yearly “Freedom in the World” report has two components, political rights <strong>and</strong> civil<br />

liberties. The report presents two scales to assess each country’s degree of freedom, each<br />

scale ranging between 1 (=highest level of freedom) <strong>and</strong> 7 (=lowest level of freedom).<br />

The scores are based on expert surveys. Political rights are assessed by evaluating the<br />

electoral process (free <strong>and</strong> fair elections), presence or absence of political pluralism <strong>and</strong><br />

participation opportunities, functioning of government <strong>and</strong> protection of minority rights<br />

76 2004 is the most recent year available.<br />

170


in a country. Civil liberties are rated by evaluating freedom of expression <strong>and</strong> belief, the<br />

right to form an association <strong>and</strong> organization, compliance with the rule of law as well as<br />

the guarantee of personal autonomy <strong>and</strong> individual rights (for a detailed overview see<br />

also Chapter 4).<br />

Figure 9-2:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>: Freedom House<br />

(2000-2006)<br />

Freedom House 2000-2006 (in per cent)<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Port<br />

Slove<br />

Uru W Ger<br />

LuxIce<br />

Aut<br />

IreE GerSwi<br />

Neth<br />

FranCan<br />

Aus N Zea<br />

Spa Malt<br />

N Ire<br />

Ita<br />

USA<br />

Swe<br />

Hun<br />

Chil<br />

Den<br />

Pol<br />

Slovak<br />

Bel GB<br />

Est<br />

Fin<br />

Lat<br />

Czech<br />

Tai<br />

Lith<br />

Bul<br />

S Afr S Kor<br />

Jap<br />

Gre<br />

Isr<br />

Dom<br />

Mex<br />

Croa<br />

Rom<br />

Arg India<br />

Braz<br />

Peru Serb<br />

Phil<br />

Alb<br />

Indo<br />

Mace<br />

Tur<br />

Ukr<br />

Mold<br />

Col Geor<br />

Tan<br />

Bang Ven Bosn<br />

Nig<br />

Arm<br />

Jord Mor<br />

Uga<br />

Rus<br />

Pak<br />

Aze<br />

20<br />

Bela<br />

10<br />

0<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

Freedom House: Source: “Freedom in the World” Report. The scales for Political Rights (1 to 7) <strong>and</strong> Civil Liberties (1 to 7)<br />

were transformed, so that higher scores indicate more freedom, <strong>and</strong> added. Mean Score 2000-2006, in per cent of the<br />

highest possible score. R=0.62 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: measured as percentage of respondents per sample who report to “Have done” any of the<br />

following activities: signed a petition, joined in boycotts, attended lawful demonstrations, joining unofficial strikes, or<br />

occupying buildings or factories. Data taken from WVS/EVS 1999-2001 (wave IV), except for Armenia (1997), Australia<br />

(1995), Azerbaijan (1997), Belarus (1996), Brazil (1997), Dominican Republic (1996) <strong>and</strong> Georgia (1996), New Zeal<strong>and</strong><br />

(1998), Norway (1996), Pakistan (1997), South Korea (1996) <strong>and</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (1996).<br />

Figure 9-2 links the level of elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> liberal democracy, measured<br />

by the transformed mean score (highest possible score equals 100 percent) of Freedom<br />

171


House between 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2006. 77 The relationship between participation <strong>and</strong> democracy<br />

is considerably stronger than the one using the Polity Scale as a measure of democracy (r<br />

= .62 *** ). Figure 9-2 also shows that the Freedom House measure is more dem<strong>and</strong>ing in<br />

its criteria, discriminating more carefully between countries with low levels of freedom<br />

(Belarus, 18 percent), mediocre levels of freedom (Moldova, 62 percent) <strong>and</strong> high levels<br />

of freedom Sweden (100 percent). Having a greater variance on the y-axis produces a<br />

closer link between the level of elite-challenging activities in a society <strong>and</strong> the presence<br />

<strong>and</strong> implementation of political rights <strong>and</strong> civil liberties: Elite-challenging participation<br />

<strong>and</strong> liberal democracy are systematically linked – again in a positive manner, such that<br />

higher levels of elite-challenging action go together with higher levels of democracy.<br />

Once more, there is no evidence of a corrosive effect of elite-challenging masses with<br />

respect to democracy.<br />

Closely related to the debate about the quality of democracy, another concept has gained<br />

considerable political <strong>and</strong> academic significance: the concept of corruption. There is a<br />

close link between the absence of democracy <strong>and</strong> corruption as the latter undermines a<br />

significant element of democratic governance: “Corruption is the abuse of entrusted<br />

power for private gain. It hurts everyone whose life, livelihood or happiness depends on<br />

the integrity of people in a position of authority” (Transparency International) 78 . If formal<br />

democratic rights are established but elites do not show law-abiding behavior, the<br />

effectiveness of democracy is considerably restricted. To avoid misunderst<strong>and</strong>ings, lawabiding<br />

behavior on the part of power holders, or what Welzel et al. (2003) have called<br />

“elite integrity,” does not by itself make a country democratic. But it does indicate to<br />

which extent a given democracy level becomes effective in the daily practice of state<br />

power. There is a number of corruption measures available, the following two figures use<br />

the most prominent ones, provided by Transparency International <strong>and</strong> the World Bank.<br />

77 See Appendix A9-1 for a figure that includes the Freedom House score for 2007.<br />

78 This is the working definition of corruption that Transparency International is using. See also:<br />

http://www.transparency.org/about_us. This definition also provides the basis for their Global Corruption<br />

Reports that are published yearly. See for example the 2008 Global Corruption Report on water <strong>and</strong><br />

corruption, here: Plummer (2008: 6).<br />

172


9.1.2 Measures of Elite Integrity<br />

a) Transparency International<br />

Figure 9-3:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Perception of Corruption<br />

(Transparency International, 2001-2006)<br />

10<br />

Fin<br />

Ice<br />

Den<br />

N Zea<br />

9<br />

Lux<br />

Swi<br />

Neth<br />

Aut<br />

Can Aus<br />

GB<br />

Swe<br />

Corruption Perception Index 2001-2006<br />

8<br />

7<br />

6<br />

5<br />

4<br />

3<br />

2<br />

Tai<br />

Jord Hun<br />

Chil<br />

Spa<br />

Malt<br />

Port<br />

Slove<br />

Est<br />

Uru<br />

Lith<br />

S Afr<br />

Lat<br />

Bul<br />

Pol<br />

Mex Col<br />

Peru Croa<br />

Tur<br />

Bela<br />

Mor<br />

Bosn Dom<br />

Arm<br />

Alb India<br />

Rom<br />

Tan<br />

Phil<br />

Mold<br />

Arg<br />

Serb<br />

Ven Ukr Mace<br />

Pak<br />

Geor Rus<br />

Indo Aze Uga<br />

Isr<br />

W Ger<br />

S Kor<br />

N Ire<br />

E Ger<br />

Bel<br />

Ire<br />

Jap<br />

Fran<br />

Ita<br />

Slovak Czech Gre<br />

Braz<br />

USA<br />

1<br />

Bang<br />

Nig<br />

0<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

CPI: Corruption Perception Index (0=highly corrupt to 10=highly clean). Source: Transparency International. Mean score<br />

2001 <strong>and</strong> 2006. R= 0.76 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: measured as percentage of respondents per sample who report to “Have done” any of the<br />

following activities: signed a petition, joined in boycotts, attended lawful demonstrations, joining unofficial strikes, or<br />

occupying buildings or factories. Data taken from WVS/EVS 1999-2001 (wave IV), except for Armenia (1997), Australia<br />

(1995), Azerbaijan (1997), Belarus (1996), Brazil (1997), Dominican Republic (1996) <strong>and</strong> Georgia (1996), New Zeal<strong>and</strong><br />

(1998), Norway (1996), Pakistan (1997), South Korea (1996) <strong>and</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (1996).<br />

Transparency International, founded in 1993, is a non-profit organization that aims at<br />

publicizing <strong>and</strong> fighting corruption. Among others, it provides an assessment for the level<br />

of corruption in a given country: the Corruption Perception Index (CPI). The index is<br />

based on a number of single indicators from various sources (for a detailed overview see<br />

Appendix A9-2), relying on estimations by business administrators <strong>and</strong> country analysts.<br />

CPI ranges between 0 (highly corrupt) <strong>and</strong> 10 (highly clean). By now, Transparency<br />

173


International ranks the perceived level of corruption in about 180 countries. Figure 9-3<br />

plots societies according to their participation level <strong>and</strong> their score on the Corruption<br />

Perception Index (average score 2001 to 2006).<br />

The link between elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> the absence of corruption in a country is<br />

stronger than using Freedom House as a measure of democracy (r = .76 *** ). Societies in<br />

which only few people participate in elite-challenging activities show high levels of<br />

corruption (e.g. Bangladesh or Azerbaijan), whereas strongly elite-challenging societies<br />

are characterized by a minimum of corruption (e.g. New Zeal<strong>and</strong> or Sweden).<br />

b) World Bank: Control of Corruption<br />

The World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) rank more than 210<br />

countries along six dimensions of governance: (1) voice <strong>and</strong> accountability, (2) political<br />

stability <strong>and</strong> absence of violence, (3) government effectiveness, (4) regulatory quality, (5)<br />

rule of law, <strong>and</strong> (6) control of corruption. Similar to the concept used by Transparency<br />

International, corruption is measured as the “extent to which public power is exercised<br />

for private gain, including both petty <strong>and</strong> gr<strong>and</strong> forms of corruption, as well as ‘capture’<br />

of the state by elites <strong>and</strong> private interests” (Kaufmann, Kraay <strong>and</strong> Mastruzzi 2007: 4). As<br />

the other governance indicators, control of corruption is a combined measure using<br />

sources from various institutions (e.g. World Economic Forum Global Competitiveness<br />

Report; Global Insight Business Conditions <strong>and</strong> Risk Indicators; Gallup World Poll;<br />

Economist Intelligence Unit; Political Risk Services International Country Risk Guide;<br />

Merchant International Group Gray Area <strong>Dynamics</strong>; Business Environment Risk<br />

Intelligence Financial Ethics Index). Some of the corruption measures are based on<br />

expert ratings, but most information comes from citizen surveys <strong>and</strong> surveys from<br />

companies operating in these countries (for a more detailed overview, see Kaufmann,<br />

Kraay <strong>and</strong> Mastruzzi 2004, 2006, 2007).<br />

Figure 9-4 uses Control of Corruption as a measure of the extent to which people in<br />

authority positions misuse their entrusted power (Control of Corruption averaged 2002 to<br />

2006). Of all measures considered, the relationship between the level of participation in<br />

elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> the absence of corruption comes closest to a linear<br />

relationship (r = .76 *** ).<br />

174


Figure 9-4:<br />

Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Control of Corruption<br />

(World Bank, 2002-2006)<br />

2.5<br />

2.0<br />

Fin<br />

W Ger<br />

Ice Den<br />

Aut<br />

Swi<br />

Neth<br />

E Ger<br />

Can Aus<br />

Lux N Ire<br />

GB<br />

N Zea<br />

Swe<br />

1.5<br />

Chil<br />

Spa<br />

Ire<br />

Fran<br />

Bel<br />

USA<br />

Control of Corruption 2002-2006<br />

1.0<br />

0.5<br />

0.0<br />

-0.5<br />

-1.0<br />

Malt<br />

Port<br />

Aze<br />

Slove<br />

Uru Isr<br />

Est<br />

Tai<br />

Hun<br />

Lat S Afr<br />

Jord<br />

Pol Lith<br />

S Kor<br />

Bul<br />

Croa<br />

Mor<br />

Tur<br />

Bela<br />

Col India<br />

Rom Bosn<br />

Peru<br />

Mex<br />

Phil<br />

Arg Mace<br />

Dom<br />

Serb<br />

Arm<br />

Indo<br />

Tan<br />

Pak<br />

Ven<br />

Braz<br />

Jap<br />

Slovak<br />

Ita<br />

Czech<br />

Gre<br />

-1.5<br />

Bang<br />

Nig<br />

-2.0<br />

Ukr, Geor, Alb, Mold, Rus, Uga<br />

-2.5<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

CC: Control of Corruption (-2.5 to +2.5). Source: World Bank, Worldwide Governance Indicators. Mean score 2002-2006.<br />

R=0.76 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: measured as percentage of respondents per sample who report to “Have done” any of the<br />

following activities: signed a petition, joined in boycotts, attended lawful demonstrations, joining unofficial strikes, or<br />

occupying buildings or factories. Data taken from WVS/EVS 1999-2001 (wave IV), except for Armenia (1997), Australia<br />

(1995), Azerbaijan (1997), Belarus (1996), Brazil (1997), Dominican Republic (1996) <strong>and</strong> Georgia (1996), New Zeal<strong>and</strong><br />

(1998), Norway (1996), Pakistan (1997), South Korea (1996) <strong>and</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (1996).<br />

Also the previous figures suggest that high levels of mass participation create an<br />

environment that puts constraints on elite behavior. Self-assertive, elite challenging<br />

publics seem to produce democratic elites who tend to use their entrusted power for the<br />

benefit of the community. In societies in which people push less for transparent <strong>and</strong><br />

accountable elite behavior, elites are under weaker domestic pressures <strong>and</strong> so they re<br />

freer to abuse entrusted power, <strong>and</strong> corruption is high. Perhaps, however, the positive<br />

relationship operates in the opposite direction as well: higher levels of democracy <strong>and</strong><br />

more accountable <strong>and</strong> transparent elites encourage elite-challenging activities. This<br />

175


possibility is less easily reconcilable with the temporal order of our variables but it is not<br />

entirely foreclosed.<br />

So far, we have seen bivariate correlations between elite-challenging activities in around<br />

2000 <strong>and</strong> measures of the level as well as the quality of democracy after 2001. In a final<br />

step, empirical evidence will be provided showing that the causal direction in this<br />

relationship is primarily operating from higher levels of elite-challenging activities on<br />

more democratic <strong>and</strong> responsive elite behavior. In order to do so, survey data on elitechallenging<br />

participation are measured at an even earlier point in time, now coming from<br />

the earliest available survey, i.e. from the second <strong>and</strong> third wave of the World Value<br />

Survey (1990-97). So the temporal order is controlled for more strictly, making sure that<br />

the measurement of activism really precedes the measurement of democracy.<br />

Now one could argue that, despite controlling for the temporal order of the two variables,<br />

the impact of participation levels still reflects an artificial construct since these levels of<br />

participation strongly depend on prior levels of democracy. Anticipating this objection,<br />

Table 9-1 demonstrates that the relationship still holds after controlling for prior levels of<br />

democracy as well, so after introducing some kind of a lagged dependent variable. 79 This<br />

procedure partials out that part of elite-challenging actions that is generated by prior<br />

democracy; it then looks at whether this independent part still has an effect on subsequent<br />

democracy.<br />

Table 9-1 includes two democracy measurements: the scale measuring Political Rights<br />

<strong>and</strong> Civil Liberties by Freedom House, <strong>and</strong> the Control of Corruption measure from the<br />

World Bank. The Polity Scale was not included as the zero-order correlation was already<br />

rather weak. Transparency International’s CPI has a problem with data availability – as<br />

for the World Bank indicator, measures are only available since the mid 1990ies, but for<br />

CPI the number of countries covered in the early years was limited. The problem can,<br />

however, be neglected as the two anti-corruption indicators show a correlation of r ≥<br />

.90 *** .<br />

79 Note that this is still the level of correlation analysis, even if one direction of the linkage is more<br />

plausible than the other.<br />

176


Table 9-1:<br />

Zero-Order <strong>and</strong> Partial Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Democracy</strong><br />

Level of participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities (earliest available<br />

survey, WVS II-III, 1990-1997)<br />

1 controlled for Freedom House 1982-87<br />

2 controlled for Control of Corruption 1996-98<br />

Zero-Order<br />

Correlation<br />

Freedom House<br />

2001-2006<br />

Partial<br />

Correlation 1<br />

Control of Corruption<br />

Zero-Order<br />

Correlation<br />

2002-2006<br />

Partial<br />

Correlation 2<br />

.50*** .34*** .70*** .34**<br />

N = 59 N = 59<br />

Table 9-1 contrasts the (zero-order) correlation effects with the partial correlation effects.<br />

Zero-order effects mean that the level of participation precedes the measures from<br />

Freedom House <strong>and</strong> the World Bank. The partial correlation does not only account for<br />

the temporal order of the two variables, but also controls for previous stages of<br />

democracy or absence of corruption.<br />

As one would expect when assuming the relation between participation <strong>and</strong> democracy to<br />

be circular, the impact of elite-challenging activities on democracy decreases once one<br />

accounts for the temporal autocorrelation of the democracy <strong>and</strong> corruption measure. The<br />

correlation drops because elite-challenging actions are themselves partially depending on<br />

prior measures of democracy <strong>and</strong> corruption <strong>and</strong> when one takes this partial dependence<br />

into account, the remaining independent part of elite-challenging actions shows a<br />

considerably weaker effect on subsequent democracy <strong>and</strong> corruption. However, the effect<br />

remains fully significant <strong>and</strong> continues to show a considerable magnitude. In part elitechallenging<br />

actions depend on prior democracy to be high <strong>and</strong> prior corruption to be low<br />

but to a larger part they help making subsequent democracy high <strong>and</strong> subsequent<br />

corruption low. Elite-challenging activities do exactly what the name says: they challenge<br />

elites, dem<strong>and</strong> responsible <strong>and</strong> transparent elite-behavior, <strong>and</strong> limit the abuse of entrusted<br />

power.<br />

177


9.2 The Individual Level: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Democratic Orientations<br />

How are democratic orientations linked to participation in elite-challenging activities?<br />

Ever since Eckstein’s famous congruence theory (1966) <strong>and</strong> Almond <strong>and</strong> Verba’s Civic<br />

Culture Study (1963) the core assumption of political culture research is that, for a<br />

political system to be stable, people’s authority orientations (or summarized: political<br />

culture) should be in congruence with authority patterns (or: political structure). As a<br />

consequence, democratic institutions can only function properly <strong>and</strong> in the long-run if the<br />

prevailing orientations among the population are also favorable to democracy. What these<br />

orientations are <strong>and</strong> how they are composed has for decades been subject to debate<br />

among scholars.<br />

9.2.1 Support for <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

The concept of political support by David Easton (1965) is widely used in the analysis of<br />

democratic orientations. According to Easton, people can orient themselves towards<br />

three, hierarchically ordered objects of support: political authorities, political regime, <strong>and</strong><br />

political community. The premise of the political support approach is that people are able<br />

to make this differentiation, meaning that they can, for example, distinguish between<br />

current incumbents <strong>and</strong> the regime or the performance of the regime <strong>and</strong> its underlying<br />

norms, in which case they should also be able to distinguish a given regime from its<br />

alternatives (Klingemann 1999: 35). Nevertheless, the objects of political support are<br />

interdependent. Dissatisfaction on one level can have spill-over effects on other levels,<br />

such as that accumulating negative orientations on a lower level (e.g. with political<br />

authorities) can, in the long run, diminish more general levels of support for democracy.<br />

It could be that people who participate in elite-challenging activities do this for<br />

instrumental reasons because they are dissatisfied with concrete policies <strong>and</strong> politicians<br />

or, more general, with the way democracy is developing in the country. In case this is so,<br />

the question is whether these concrete forms of dissatisfaction translate into antidemocratic<br />

orientations by sifting the blame from the concrete situation to the abstract<br />

idea of democracy. Alternatively, people might be attracted to elite-challenging actions<br />

for normative reasons as they have internalized a participatory citizenship model in which<br />

178


the ideal citizen voices his or her concerns. In this case elite-challenging actions might<br />

indicate dissatisfaction with concrete situations but would nevertheless go together with<br />

support of democratic regime norms.<br />

Table 9-2 documents individual-level correlations between people’s support for<br />

democracy <strong>and</strong> their participation in elite-challenging activities. The data again come<br />

from the World Values Survey, allowing for the broadest possible coverage of the world<br />

population. The WVS/EVS 1999-2001 offers two questions assessing people’s support<br />

for democracy. 80 For one, people are asked to rate on a four-point scale how they like<br />

“Having a democratic political system” as a way of governing their country (first column<br />

in Table 9-2). A second question asks respondents if they agree (or not, again on a fourpoint<br />

scale) with the statement that “<strong>Democracy</strong> may have its problems but it’s better<br />

than any other form of government” (second column in Table 9-2). The third column in<br />

Table 9-2 uses a combined measure of the two single items. In Column 4 a net-support<br />

for democracy was calculated by subtracting support for authoritarian alternatives (added<br />

scale of the items “Having a strong leader.” <strong>and</strong> “Having the army rule.”) from support<br />

for democracy (for a detailed description see the annotation below the table).<br />

Table 9-2:<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Support for <strong>Democracy</strong> (WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

“Having democratic<br />

rule”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“<strong>Democracy</strong> may have<br />

its problems but it’s<br />

better than others”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Both items added:<br />

Dem_Support<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Net Support (Dem_<br />

Support minus<br />

authorit.)<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

Serbia .18*** (79) .15*** (75) .17*** (72) .20*** (67)<br />

Bulgaria .16*** (64) .11** (65) .13** (60) .12** (50)<br />

Montenegro .12** (65) .08* (64) .14*** (62) .11* (55)<br />

Bosnia .12** (86) .18*** (86) .18*** (85) .14*** (79)<br />

Romania .11** (70) .10** (71) .11** (67) .11** (58)<br />

Albania .04 (57) .03 (58) .05 (56) -.04 (51)<br />

Macedonia .00 (83) -.02 (82) -.02 (79) .04 (74)<br />

80 The WVS 2005-2007 includes only one of the two batteries measuring support for democracy (<strong>and</strong> its<br />

alternatives).<br />

179


“Having democratic<br />

rule”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“<strong>Democracy</strong> may have<br />

its problems but it’s<br />

better than others”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Both items added:<br />

Dem_Support<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Net Support (Dem_<br />

Support minus<br />

authorit.)<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Slovenia .17*** (85) .15*** (86) .20*** (84) .25*** (82)<br />

Croatia .14*** (84) .14*** (82) .18*** (81) .20*** (79)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .13*** (86) .13*** (86) .16*** (81) .18*** (76)<br />

Czech Republic .10*** (90) .10*** (90) .12*** (88) .14*** (84)<br />

Slovakia .07* (81) .03 (82) .06* (77) .04 (73)<br />

Hungary .04 (86) .11** (82) .09* (79) .17*** (76)<br />

Post-soviet societies<br />

Belarus -.01 (69) -.04 (69) -.03 (64) .00 (59)<br />

Kyrgyzstan .04 (94) .06 (94) .06 (92) .08* (91)<br />

Moldova .06 (65) -.07 (62) .01 (55) .10* (81)<br />

Ukraine .04 (66) .06 (69) .05 (59) .06 (52)<br />

Russia .04 (69) -.02 (69) .00 (61) .00 (54)<br />

Baltic states<br />

Latvia .15*** (76) .14*** (78) .15*** (72) .19*** (67)<br />

Lithuania .15** (55) .19*** (54) .16*** (47) .20*** (43)<br />

Estonia .10** (69) .11** (71) .12** (65) .12** (62)<br />

Western Europe<br />

East Germany .20*** (87) .06 (85) .16*** (83) .03 (80)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .18*** (99) .12*** (98) .17*** (98) .21*** (97)<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> .18*** (97) .21*** (96) .22*** (95) .28*** (94)<br />

Belgium .15*** (90) .08** (91) .12*** (88) .16*** (85)<br />

Spain .15*** (77) .10*** (79) .14*** (75) .19*** (68)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .12*** (90) .11** (87) .14*** (85) .19*** (80)<br />

Italy .12*** (89) .13*** (89) .15*** (87) .18*** (85)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .12** (87) .08* (87) .11** (85) .14*** (83)<br />

France .10*** (88) .08** (89) .12*** (86) .14*** (83)<br />

Sweden .10** (97) .05 (98) .08* (96) .12*** (92)<br />

Denmark .09** (92) .06 (92) .08* (90) .11** (88)<br />

Malta .08* (94) .09** (93) .09** (92) .06 (90)<br />

Austria .08** (94) .08** (94) .09* (92) .14*** (89)<br />

West Germany .07* (90) .03 (91) .06 (89) .07* (87)<br />

Greece .05 (95) .08** (95) .08** (94) .15*** (93)<br />

Luxembourg .03 (81) -.01 (81) .01 (77) .00 (72)<br />

Portugal .01 (85 ) -.04 (86) -.02 (83) .05 (68)<br />

Anglo-Saxon societies<br />

USA .20*** (95) .20*** (96) .25*** (93) .23*** (92)<br />

Canada .14*** (91) .10*** (91) .15*** (88) .20*** (86)<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> .05 (82) -.02 (82) .02 (78) .10* (69)<br />

Great Britain .03 (84) .11** (93) .06 (82) .04 (76)<br />

Central & Southern America<br />

Argentina .17*** (85) .13*** (85) .17*** (82) .23*** (72)<br />

Chile .06* (86) .04 (87) .05 (84) .04 (78)<br />

Peru .06* (86) .06* (85) .07** (83) .02 (77)<br />

Puerto Rico .07 (93) .00 (93) .04 (92) .10* (89)<br />

Mexico .03 (71) .06 (67) .05 (64) .01 (58)<br />

Venezuela .02 (93) .04 (93) .03 (92) -.03 (86)<br />

180


Continued:<br />

“Having democratic<br />

rule”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“<strong>Democracy</strong> may have<br />

its problems but it’s<br />

better than others”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Both items added:<br />

Dem_Support<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Net Support (Dem_<br />

Support minus<br />

authorit.)<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Africa<br />

Algeria -.06 (79) -.04 (75) -.07* (72) .02 (67)<br />

Jordan .02 (86) .10** (83) .09** (79) .10** (76)<br />

Morocco .08** (59) .04 (53) .06* (51) .08* (42)<br />

Egypt .01 (95) .00 (93) .01 (92) - -<br />

South Africa .14*** (82) .11*** (82) .16*** (78) .16*** (72)<br />

Zimbabwe .14*** (81) .02 (78) .09* (74) .07 (70)<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a .10* (60) -.02 (57) .04 (57) .05 (56)<br />

Nigeria .07** (88) .01 (88) .05* (87) .03 (85)<br />

Tanzania -.04 (96) -.07* (94) -.07* (93) -.15*** (90)<br />

Confucian societies<br />

Japan .14*** (73) .09** (62) .13*** (61) .10** (57)<br />

Southern Asia<br />

Bangladesh .10** (79) .02 (79) .07* (78) -.16*** (73)<br />

Turkey .09*** (89) .07*** (88) .09*** (86) .18*** (82)<br />

Indonesia .07 (82) .07* (77) .08* (75) .06 (73)<br />

Philippines .04 (97) .00 (97) .02 (96) .05 (95)<br />

Vietnam -.03 (77) -.03 (67) -.05 (67) .02 (66)<br />

Pakistan -.02 (83) .03 (90) -.01 (82) -.01 (72)<br />

India -.01 (67) -.08** (64 ) -.07* (62) -.02 (58)<br />

Source: WVS/EVS 1999-2001. The variables are coded:<br />

(1) Having democratic rule (recoded: 1= very bad to 4= very good): “I'm going to describe various types of<br />

political systems <strong>and</strong> ask what you think about each as a way of governing this country. For each one,<br />

would you say it is a very good, fairly good, fairly bad or very bad way of governing this country? (…)<br />

Having a democratic political system.”<br />

(2) “<strong>Democracy</strong> may have its problems but it’s better than others” (recoded: 1= strongly disagree to<br />

4=agree strongly): “I’m going to read off some things that people sometimes say about a democratic<br />

political system. Could you please tell me if you agree strongly, agree, disagree or disagree strongly? (…)<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> may have its problems but it’s better than any other form of government.”<br />

(3) Dem_Support (1= no support to 7= high level of support). Added scale: “Having democratic rule” <strong>and</strong><br />

“<strong>Democracy</strong> may have its problems”. Transformed (1 to 7).<br />

(4) Net Support: Dem_Support minus Auth_Support. Auth_Support (1= no support to 7= high level of<br />

support): Added scale: “Having a strong leader” <strong>and</strong> “Having the army rule”. Transformed (1 to 7). Having<br />

a strong leader (recoded: 1= very bad to 4= very good): “I'm going to describe various types of political<br />

systems <strong>and</strong> ask what you think about each as a way of governing this country. For each one, would you<br />

say it is a very good, fairly good, fairly bad or very bad way of governing this country? (…) Having a<br />

strong leader who does not have to bother with parliament <strong>and</strong> elections.” Having the army rule (recoded:<br />

1= very bad to 4= very good): “I'm going to describe various types of political systems <strong>and</strong> ask what you<br />

think about each as a way of governing this country. For each one, would you say it is a very good, fairly<br />

good, fairly bad or very bad way of governing this country? (…) Having the army rule.”<br />

The majority of the correlations is significant, <strong>and</strong> almost all significant correlations<br />

show a positive sign, indicating that those individuals who participate in demonstrations<br />

or sign petitions also support democracy as a form of governance. 81 In roughly half the<br />

81 There are three exceptions: Bangladesh, India <strong>and</strong> Tanzania.<br />

181


societies, but almost all societies in Western Europe <strong>and</strong> Central Eastern Europe, the<br />

correlation with elite-challenging participation is strongest for the net-support variable. In<br />

these societies, people who participate in these activities do not only show lip-service<br />

support for democracy, but at the same time also reject non-democratic alternatives that<br />

favor governance by a small a group of non-elected officials.<br />

This interpretation is also supported when one looks at another aspect of political support<br />

in a democracy. Within the framework of Easton’s concept of political support (Easton<br />

1965, 1975) confidence in political institutions is an important evaluative orientation of<br />

the regime’s performance (Klingemann 1999). Appendix A9-3 shows that elitechallenging<br />

activities <strong>and</strong> confidence in government, parties <strong>and</strong> parliament are only<br />

weakly correlated, whereas the link between non-institutionalized participation <strong>and</strong> the<br />

importance that people attach to living in a democracy is more pronounced. Again, this<br />

suggests that elite-challenging activities in democracies are predominantly systemsupporting<br />

participation.<br />

This conclusion is seconded by looking at the question what people think what a<br />

democracy is. In the most recent wave of the World Values Survey (2005-07)<br />

respondents where asked which characteristics they considered as essential elements of a<br />

democratic political order. Among these characteristics, four items resemble a processoriented<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy: that people choose their leaders in free elections<br />

<strong>and</strong> civil rights protect people’s liberty against oppression; that people can change laws in<br />

referendums <strong>and</strong> women have the same rights as men.<br />

Another four elements reflect an output-oriented underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy: that<br />

governments tax the rich <strong>and</strong> subsidize the poor <strong>and</strong> people receive state aid for<br />

unemployment; that the economy is prospering <strong>and</strong> criminals are severely punished. A<br />

factor analysis with the four statements shows that these characteristics are not only<br />

theoretically meaningful but also empirically relevant (see Appendix A9-4). The question<br />

now is whether people who participate in elite-challenging activities tend to have a<br />

process- or an output-oriented underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy. In general, a democratic<br />

system needs the intrinsic support from those citizens with a process-oriented<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy in order to avoid a sudden loss of support if there is a<br />

temporary weakness in the system’s output.<br />

182


Table 9-3:<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Underst<strong>and</strong>ing of <strong>Democracy</strong> (WVS/EVS 2005-07)<br />

Process-oriented<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

183<br />

Output-oriented<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

Serbia .01 .03 (911)<br />

Bulgaria .08* .07 (630)<br />

Romania .10*** -.06* (1.335)<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Slovenia .13*** -.01 (806)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .14*** -.03 (784)<br />

Post-soviet societies<br />

Moldova .04 .05 (897)<br />

Ukraine .01 -.06 (734)<br />

Russia -.02 -.02 (1.582)<br />

Western Europe<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .16*** .03 (858)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .13*** -.13*** (924)<br />

France .12*** -.01 (948)<br />

Sweden .14*** -.07* (939)<br />

Germany .18*** -.09*** (1.818)<br />

Anglo-Saxon societies<br />

USA .29*** -.03 (1.177)<br />

Canada .17*** -.06** (1.736)<br />

Great Britain .24*** .03 (863)<br />

Australia .16*** -.01 (1.330)<br />

Central & Southern America<br />

Argentina .16*** -.04 (662)<br />

Brazil .09** -.04 (1.282)<br />

Chile .17*** -.07 (787)<br />

Mexico .13*** .00 (1.248)<br />

Uruguay .11** .04 (908)<br />

Africa<br />

Zambia .01 .01 (1.232)<br />

Ethiopia .17*** -.09** (939)<br />

Ghana .01 .02 (1.262)<br />

Mali -.14*** -.16*** (892)<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a -.03 -.11*** (1.118)<br />

Burkina Faso .02 -.03 (966)<br />

Confucian societies<br />

Japan .09* -.01 (690)<br />

South Korea .10*** -.05 (1.198)<br />

Taiwan .06* -.04 (1.200)<br />

South & Southern Asia<br />

Indonesia -.09*** .07** (1.521)<br />

Vietnam -.03 -.06* (1.295)<br />

India .05 -.06 (996)<br />

Malaysia -.08** -.14*** (1.195)<br />

Source: World Values Survey 2005-07. The coding of the variables:<br />

“Many things may be desirable, but not all of them are essential characteristics of democracy. Please tell<br />

me for each of the following things how essential you think it is as a characteristic of democracy. Use this<br />

N


scale where 1 means “not at all an essential characteristic of democracy” <strong>and</strong> 10 means it definitely is “an<br />

essential characteristic of democracy”.” The two variables on people’s underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy are the<br />

result of a factor analysis (see Appendix 4) where the following items loaded on:<br />

(1) Process-oriented underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy:<br />

- People choose their leaders in free elections.<br />

- Civil rights protect people’s liberty against oppression.<br />

- People can change laws in referendums.<br />

- Women have the same rights as men.<br />

(2) Output-oriented underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy:<br />

- Governments tax the rich <strong>and</strong> subsidize the poor.<br />

- People receive state aid for unemployment.<br />

- The economy is prospering.<br />

- Criminals are severely punished.<br />

Table 9-3 documents quite some differences between the societies included: Whereas the<br />

post-soviet societies, Serbia <strong>and</strong> some African countries do not show any significant<br />

correlation (meaning that in these societies, participants do not have a particular<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy that is distinct from non-participants), the picture looks<br />

different for all EU member states, Anglo-Saxon societies, Central <strong>and</strong> Latin America<br />

<strong>and</strong> the Confucian societies. Here we find that elite-challenging participation goes pretty<br />

well together with a process-oriented underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy. By contrast,<br />

participation <strong>and</strong> output-orientation are not or even negatively correlated: In the majority<br />

of industrial or postindustrial societies, people are driven into participation by an intrinsic<br />

democratic motivation, not because they expect the democratic system to deliver certain<br />

material goods. This is a theoretically important finding. It indicates that elite-challenging<br />

actions in advanced postindustrial societies, but less so in developing <strong>and</strong> struggling<br />

societies, is primarily normatively <strong>and</strong> not instrumentally motivated.<br />

9.2.2 Political Involvement<br />

Political involvement is another core democratic orientation – if citizens do not have at<br />

least a basic interest in political affairs, if they do not know about their participation<br />

possibilities, their rights <strong>and</strong> responsibilities as a citizen, then democracy is at danger: “It<br />

is (...) the prerequisite of showing some degree of political interest <strong>and</strong> concern that<br />

establishes the line of demarcation between democratic <strong>and</strong> non-democratic citizenship”<br />

(van Deth <strong>and</strong> Elff 2000: 1). This does not mean that political involvement always<br />

translates into political participation, or that each political act is motivated by a high level<br />

of political interest. However, it is one of the most established research findings that<br />

184


political interest is a dominant factor in explaining all kinds of political participation, in<br />

particular in forms of conventional participation. With respect to participation in elitechallenging<br />

activities, however, Croizier et al. were warning against an uninformed,<br />

uncritical public going on the streets <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> more than the government can deliver.<br />

In their closing chapter of “Political Action,” Kaase <strong>and</strong> Barnes (1979: 527-534) have<br />

also argued that the balance between emotional <strong>and</strong> rational participation is highly<br />

relevant for the political system. Emotional participation means action without political<br />

interest or underst<strong>and</strong>ing <strong>and</strong> is described as “highly disruptive” (Kaase <strong>and</strong> Branes 1979:<br />

528), whereas rational participation is driven by high political involvement. Using the<br />

data from the WVS/EVS it is possible to test whether individual-level participation in<br />

these activities is indeed driven by low or high levels of political involvement, so whether<br />

elite-challenging participation is (in the terminology of the Political Action Study)<br />

emotional or rational. The WVS/EVS includes two items that are available for the<br />

majority of societies: people’s interest in politics <strong>and</strong> the importance of politics in<br />

people’s life (both four-point scales).<br />

Table 9-4 shows – against the “crisis of democracy” assumption – that it is not a<br />

momentarily mobilized, otherwise uninterested, citizenry that is demonstrating,<br />

petitioning or boycotting products. Quite the contrary, elites are challenged by citizens<br />

for whom politics is important: in almost all societies participation in elite-challenging<br />

activities is positively linked with political involvement. This is not a Western<br />

phenomenon: Individual-level participation in elite-challenging activities in African,<br />

Asian <strong>and</strong> Eastern European societies is similarly driven by high political involvement.<br />

185


Table 9-4:<br />

Individual-Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Political<br />

Involvement, WVS/EVS 1999-2001<br />

Interest in Politics<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Importance of Politics in Life<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

Serbia .31*** (88) .24*** (87)<br />

Bulgaria .23*** (77) .17*** (75)<br />

Montenegro .40*** (70) .28*** (70)<br />

Bosnia .18*** (90) .12** (90)<br />

Romania .12*** (78)<br />

Albania .24*** (59) .16*** (58)<br />

Macedonia .15*** (89) .04 (89)<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Slovenia .15*** (90) .06 (90)<br />

Croatia .02 (95)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .24*** (98) .19*** (97)<br />

Czech Republic .20*** (92) .12*** (92)<br />

Slovakia .17*** (88)<br />

Hungary .12*** (93)<br />

Post-soviet societies<br />

Belarus .20*** (89) .12*** (88)<br />

Kyrgyzstan .17*** (98) .08* (97)<br />

Moldova .14*** (82) .14*** (80)<br />

Ukraine .20*** (84) .15*** (81)<br />

Russia .18*** (90) .11*** (89)<br />

Baltic states<br />

Latvia .12** (87)<br />

Lithuania .25*** (71) .16*** (70)<br />

Estonia .09** (82)<br />

Western Europe<br />

East Germany .21*** (94) .10** (94)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .24*** (100) .16*** (100)<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> .23*** (98) .12*** (98)<br />

Belgium .23*** (95) .18*** (96)<br />

Spain .27*** (84) .18*** (84)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .19*** (95) .13*** (93)<br />

Italy .27*** (92) .16*** (92)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .23*** (91) .16*** (91)<br />

France .22*** (96) .19*** (95)<br />

Sweden .03 (99)<br />

Denmark .15*** (95) .13*** (95)<br />

Malta .20*** (97)<br />

Austria .27*** (97) .17*** (97)<br />

West Germany .25*** (92) .21*** (91)<br />

Greece .21*** (95) .16*** (95)<br />

Luxembourg .16*** (89) .09** (90)<br />

Portugal .32*** (92) .19*** (92)<br />

Anglo-Saxon societies<br />

USA .15*** (98) .10** (98)<br />

Canada .19*** (98) .11*** (98)<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> .12*** (94) .08* (93)<br />

Great Britain .20*** (96) .15*** (97)<br />

186


Continued:<br />

Interest in Politics<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Importance of Politics in Life<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Central & Southern America<br />

Argentina .28*** (89) .18*** (90)<br />

Chile .26*** (92) .20*** (90)<br />

Peru .18*** (89) .07* (88)<br />

Puerto Rico .26*** (95) .07 (95)<br />

Mexico .21*** (80) .11*** (80)<br />

Venezuela .20*** (94) .04 (94)<br />

Africa<br />

Algeria .25*** (86) .14*** (84)<br />

Jordan .16*** (98) .14*** (97)<br />

Morocco .28*** (80) .24*** (80)<br />

Egypt .00 (99) .00 (97)<br />

South Africa .29*** (87) .22*** (87)<br />

Zimbabwe .12*** (88) .06 (86)<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a .23*** (63) .16*** (62)<br />

Nigeria .20*** (89) .12*** (89)<br />

Tanzania .06 (96) .09** (84)<br />

Confucian societies<br />

Japan .21*** (80) .21*** (75)<br />

Southern Asia<br />

Bangladesh .25*** (79) .14*** (80)<br />

Turkey .26*** (72) .20*** (96)<br />

Indonesia .21*** (85) .08* (81)<br />

Philippines .12*** (98) .08** (98)<br />

Vietnam .14*** (81) .03 (80)<br />

Pakistan .30*** (91) .32*** (90)<br />

India .32*** (77) .23*** (77)<br />

Israel .11* (89) .00 (89)<br />

Source: World Values Survey 1999-2001. The coding of the variables:<br />

(1) Interest in politics: “How interested would you say are you in politics?” Very interested, somewhat<br />

interested, not very interested, not at all interested. The variable was recoded: 4 = very interested in politics,<br />

(...) 1 = not at all interested in politics.<br />

(2) Importance of politics in life: “For each of the following, indicate how important it is in your life.<br />

Would you say it is: very important, rather important, not very important, not at all important? (...)<br />

Politics”. The variable was recoded: 4 = politics is very important, (...) 1 = politics is not at all important.<br />

9.2.3 Liberal Orientations<br />

The concept of political support, <strong>and</strong> hereby the traditional political culture school, has<br />

focused on specific political attitudes when it comes to orientations that are conducive for<br />

democracy. By contrast, early concepts from psychology have focused on non-political<br />

orientations instead, arguing that these more general predispositions matter for people’s<br />

everyday life, <strong>and</strong> in the end also for a political system (for an overview see Welzel<br />

187


2006). 82 Lasswell’s “democratic character” (1951), for example, champions freedom<br />

from anxiety, self-esteem, humanism <strong>and</strong> an open ego as pro-democratic orientations.<br />

Rokeach (1960) argues that liberal <strong>and</strong> altruistic orientations, going together in an “open<br />

belief system,” are most appropriate for a democratic system. In general, all these<br />

psychological approaches (see also Adorno et al. 1950; Maslow 1954) identify a certain<br />

form of physical security as the basis for trust in oneself <strong>and</strong> in others, which are<br />

considered as core democratic orientations.<br />

According to the social psychological approach people with a high self-esteem do not<br />

only trust others more, they are also less scared of people who might be different – be it<br />

by religion, race, or attitudes. Rather, difference is seen as something beneficial. The<br />

World Values Survey also includes questions on tolerance to test whether participation in<br />

elite-challenging activities is driven by tolerant or intolerant orientations. Table 9-5,<br />

column 1 documents the correlation between participation <strong>and</strong> tolerance towards<br />

foreigners. (In)Tolerance towards foreigners is measured with the “least liked neighbor”<br />

question, asking respondents if there was any group that they would not like to live in<br />

their neighborhood. Foreigners summarize people with a different race as well as<br />

immigrants or foreign workers (correlations with the single items can be found in<br />

Appendix A9-5). Overall, the link between tolerance <strong>and</strong> participation is only modest. In<br />

about half of the societies included the correlation is not even significant. Where the<br />

individual-level correlation is significant, with the exception of Bangladesh, the<br />

correlation is positive, but exceeds only in eight societies .10.<br />

In addition to the tolerance towards foreigners, the WVS/EVS also includes questions<br />

about how respondents see themselves as masters of their own lives, <strong>and</strong> whether they<br />

accept that other people make autonomous choices about their own way of living. In the<br />

first case, the respondents were asked on a ten-point scale whether they felt that they have<br />

free choice <strong>and</strong> control over their lives. The second question is measured on a ten-point<br />

scale as well. Here, people were asked whether they considered homosexuality <strong>and</strong><br />

divorce as justifiable. In Table 9-5 the columns 2 (tolerance of other lifestyles) <strong>and</strong> 3<br />

(own choice <strong>and</strong> control over life) show the individual-level correlations with<br />

82 For a critical view on linking non-political orientations <strong>and</strong> democracy see already Almond <strong>and</strong> Verba<br />

1963: 10.<br />

188


participation in elite-challenging activities. Surprisingly, the perception of having control<br />

over one’s life is only in few societies linked with elite-challenging activities. The picture<br />

changes when it comes to granting this freedom to others: for the majority of societies a<br />

significant <strong>and</strong> positive correlation between people’s tolerance towards other lifestyles<br />

<strong>and</strong> participation in elite-challenging activities can be observed. However, there are<br />

noticeable differences among the societies under consideration: While in societies in<br />

Central <strong>and</strong> Western Europe, Anglo-Saxon societies <strong>and</strong> Latin America people who<br />

demonstrate, sign petitions <strong>and</strong> participate in buy- <strong>and</strong> boycotts are tolerant towards<br />

people’s lifestyles, most of the African <strong>and</strong> Asian societies do not show this link. 83<br />

Table 9-5:<br />

Individual-Level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> Liberal<br />

Orientations (WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

Tolerance<br />

towards<br />

foreigners<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Tolerance of<br />

different<br />

lifestyles<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Own choice<br />

<strong>and</strong> control<br />

over life<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Gender<br />

Equality<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Trust in others<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

Serbia .07* (88) .23*** (80) .12*** (85) .13*** (75) -.05 (86)<br />

Bulgaria .08* (78) .15*** (69) .19*** (73) .09* (73)<br />

Montenegro .13*** (70) .19*** (61) -.01 (64) .04 (61) .11** (69)<br />

Bosnia -.03 (90) .05 (89) .02 (89) .02 (88) .07 (89)<br />

Romania .10** (79) .11** (73) .04 (74) -.01 (78)<br />

Albania .08 (59) .05 (57) .08* (59) .00 (55) -.03 (58)<br />

Macedonia .07* (90) .05 (88) .03 (88) .06 (87) .02 (88)<br />

Serbia .07* (88) .23*** (80) .13*** (75) -.05 (86)<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Slovenia .11** (90) .24*** (87) .03 (90) .08* (89)<br />

Croatia .04 (86) .08* (84) .09** (85) .02 (84)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .07* (99) .13*** (90) .01 (95) .03 (96)<br />

Czech Rep. .08*** (92) .12*** (88) .09*** (92) .08** (91)<br />

Slovakia .03 (89) .04 (79) .10** (87) .05 (86)<br />

Hungary .16*** (87) .02 (91) .11** (92)<br />

Post-soviet societies<br />

Belarus .09** (90) .08* (81) .07* (84) .00 (83)<br />

Kyrgyzstan .04 (98) .13*** (97) -.01 (97) -.02 (96) .00 (97)<br />

Moldova .03 (82) -.06 (71) .05 (77) .05 (72) .07 (79)<br />

Ukraine .07* (84) .02 (74) .09** (77) .01 (80)<br />

Russia -.02 (90) .01 (77) .02 (87) .06** (88)<br />

Baltic states<br />

Latvia .00 (88) .09* (81) -.02 (84) .04 (86)<br />

Lithuania .10** (72) .05 (64) -.02 (69) .13** (69)<br />

Estonia .08* (83) .06 (71) .08* (81) .09* (81)<br />

83 There are noticeable exceptions: South Africa <strong>and</strong> Zimbabwe, Turkey, Bangladesh <strong>and</strong> Indonesia.<br />

189


Continued:<br />

Tolerance<br />

towards<br />

foreigners<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Tolerance of<br />

different<br />

lifestyles<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Own choice<br />

<strong>and</strong> control<br />

over life<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Gender<br />

Equality<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Trust in others<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Baltic states<br />

Latvia .00 (88) .09* (81) -.02 (84) .04 (86)<br />

Lithuania .10** (72) .05 (64) -.02 (69) .13** (69)<br />

Estonia .08* (83) .06 (71) .08* (81) .09* (81)<br />

Western Europe<br />

East Germany .02 (86) .13*** (85) -.03 (94) .10** (91)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .15*** (100) .26*** (99) .05 (100) .17*** (99)<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> .08* (98) .21*** (92) .06 (97) .09** (94)<br />

Belgium .18*** (97) .22*** (93) .03 (95) .08** (93)<br />

Spain .10*** (84) .29*** (79) .04 (81) .16*** (40) .09*** (81)<br />

Italy .11*** (93) .26*** (88) .11*** (90) .15*** (91)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .09** (91) .20*** (87) .12*** (90) .10** (89)<br />

France .02 (96) .13*** (89) -.02 (95) .07** (92)<br />

Sweden -.01 (99) .12*** (95) .03 (99) .10** (94) .11** (95)<br />

Denmark .10** (95) .22*** (89) .08* (94) .14*** (92)<br />

Malta .05 (97) .17*** (98) -.05 (97) .05 (96)<br />

Austria .13*** (97) .23*** (93) -.05 (96) .15*** (90)<br />

W. Germany .00 (82) .18*** (88) .01 (91) .00 (88)<br />

Greece .10** (96) .24*** (89) .01 (95) .15*** (83)<br />

Luxembourg .09 (91) .19*** (87) .01 (90) .06* (88)<br />

Portugal .01 (92) .17*** (87) .00 (90) .16*** (90)<br />

Anglo-Saxon societies<br />

USA .06 (98) .10*** (96) .06* (98) .11*** (92) .14*** (97)<br />

Canada -.01 (98) .24*** (93) .06* (98) .16*** (94) .09*** (97)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .10** (95) .28*** (87) .01 (94) .12*** (93)<br />

North. Irel<strong>and</strong> .08* (94) .16*** (84) -.15*** (92) .01 (92)<br />

Great Britain -.04 (98) .10** (95) -.08* (97) .01 (94)<br />

Central & Southern America<br />

Argentina .07* (90) .15*** (81) -.02 (87) .10** (81) .15*** (88)<br />

Chile -.11 (92) .17*** (87) .12*** (91) .13*** (89) .10** (90)<br />

Peru -.03 (89) .08** (87) .02 (88) -.01 (85) .04 (88)<br />

Puerto Rico .08* (96) .18*** (93) .03 (95) .08 (92) .15*** (95)<br />

Mexico -.02 (81) .07* (74) -.03 (76) -.03 (76) .04 (79)<br />

Venezuela -.03 (94) .04 (93) -.04 (94) -.02 (90) .03 (94)<br />

Africa<br />

Algeria .06* (87) .10** (84) .07* (82) .01 (82) .03 (85)<br />

Jordan .01 (98) .09** (96) .05 (97) .04 (97) .05 (96)<br />

Morocco .08** (82) .10*** (80) .15*** (68) -.08*** (80)<br />

Egypt .01 (100) -.01 (100) .03 (99) .00 (99) -.02 (99)<br />

South Africa .11*** (88) .12*** (85) .22*** (87) .07** (82) .02 (87)<br />

Zimbabwe .06 (90) .14*** (88) -.07* (89) .00 (85) -.04 (88)<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a -.02 (63) -.02 (63) .25*** (62) .01 (62) .05 (63)<br />

Nigeria .00 (89) .04 (89) .05* (89) -.04 (87) .00 (89)<br />

Tanzania -.04 (97) .03 (95) -.02 (96) -.10** (95) .15*** (93)<br />

Confucian societies<br />

Japan -.03 (71) .00 (77) .06 (54) .11*** (75)<br />

190


Continued:<br />

Tolerance<br />

towards<br />

foreigners<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Tolerance of<br />

different<br />

lifestyles<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Own choice<br />

<strong>and</strong> control<br />

over life<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Gender<br />

Equality<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Trust in others<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Southern Asia<br />

Bangladesh -.07* (82) .18*** (81) .04 (72) .14*** (80) -.01 (81)<br />

Turkey .14*** (97) .29*** (25) .14*** (97) .14*** (70) .02 (96)<br />

Indonesia -.01 (87) .17*** (87) -.05 (83) -.02 (83) -.08* (77)<br />

Philippines -.01 (98) .01 (97) .01 (98) .01 (97) .04 (97)<br />

Vietnam .01 (81) -.01 (76) -.11* (81) .07 (77) .06 (77)<br />

Pakistan -.04 (92) .01 (88) -.08** (69) -.02 (85) .07** (84)<br />

India .01 (78) .05 (61) .07* (72) .08** (71) -.01 (76)<br />

Israel .29*** (90) .19*** (92)<br />

Source: World Values Survey 1999-2001. The coding of the variables:<br />

(1) Tolerance towards foreigners: “On this list are various groups of people. Could you please sort out any<br />

that you would not like to have as neighbors?”<br />

- People with a different race<br />

- Immigrants/foreign workers<br />

Respondents who have mentioned any of the two = -1. None of the groups mentioned = 0.<br />

(2) Tolerance of different lifestyles: “Please tell me for each of the following statements whether you think<br />

it can always be justified, never be justified, or something in between, using this card.”<br />

- Homosexuality<br />

- Divorce<br />

Never justifiable = 1. Always justifiable = 10. The two scales were added.<br />

(3) Gender Equality: Two items added (each coded from 1 = agree strongly to 4 = strongly disagree):<br />

“On the whole, men make better political leaders than women do.”<br />

“A university education is more important for a boy than for a girl.”<br />

(4) Trust in Others: “Generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted or that you need to<br />

be very careful in dealing with people?” Recoded: Need to be very careful = 0. Most people can be trusted<br />

= 1.<br />

The third <strong>and</strong> fourth column of Table 9-5 complements the analysis of the link between<br />

elite-challenging activities <strong>and</strong> liberal orientations. Questions on gender equality are<br />

available only in a limited number of countries <strong>and</strong> show a positive link only in relatively<br />

modern societies (exception: Bangladesh). More important is the influence of social trust:<br />

trust, an important resource for cooperation with others, <strong>and</strong> elite-challenging activities<br />

are positively linked at the individual level (as demonstrated in Chapter 7).<br />

For a final overview, Table 9-6 summarizes the most relevant factors of the three<br />

approaches in a regression, testing which of these predictors has the strongest effect on<br />

why people participate in elite-challenging activities. The regression analyses are<br />

191


conducted separately for different country groups, the results are controlled for sex, age<br />

<strong>and</strong> education effects.<br />

Table 9-6: Binary Logistic Regression Analysis, WVS/EVS 1999-2001<br />

(dependent variable: Elite-Challenging Activities)<br />

Eastern<br />

Europe<br />

Central<br />

Eastern<br />

Europe<br />

Post-soviet<br />

societies<br />

Baltic states<br />

Western<br />

Europe<br />

Political culture approach:<br />

Net_support for democracy 1.09*** 1.14*** 1.02 1.14*** 1.07***<br />

Political involvement: Politics<br />

important<br />

Ref: not at all<br />

not very<br />

rather<br />

very important<br />

Liberal orientation:<br />

Tolerance of different lifestyles<br />

Ref: low<br />

medium<br />

high<br />

Constant<br />

Nagelkerke R sq.<br />

N<br />

1.38***<br />

1.82***<br />

2.17***<br />

1.19*<br />

1.80***<br />

.325<br />

.07<br />

4.523<br />

1.42***<br />

1.94***<br />

1.75***<br />

1.47***<br />

2.44***<br />

.178<br />

.12<br />

5.483<br />

1.50**<br />

1.86***<br />

1.68**<br />

1.32**<br />

1.55**<br />

.068<br />

.05<br />

3.367<br />

0.75*<br />

1.27<br />

1.80*<br />

.81<br />

.88<br />

.138<br />

.10<br />

1.610<br />

1.34***<br />

1.88***<br />

2.20***<br />

1.60***<br />

2.56***<br />

.398<br />

.14<br />

15.709<br />

Anglo-Saxon<br />

societies<br />

Central &<br />

Southern<br />

America<br />

Africa<br />

Southern<br />

Asia<br />

Political culture approach:<br />

Net_support for democracy 1.12*** 1.01 1.04** 1.09*** 1.10<br />

Political involvement: Politics<br />

important<br />

Ref: not at all<br />

not very<br />

rather<br />

very important<br />

Liberal orientation:<br />

Tolerance of different lifestyles<br />

Ref: low<br />

medium<br />

high<br />

Constant<br />

Nagelkerke R sq.<br />

N<br />

1.45**<br />

1.88***<br />

1.85***<br />

1.76***<br />

2.84***<br />

.607<br />

.12<br />

4.668<br />

1.06<br />

1.56***<br />

1.59***<br />

1.42***<br />

2.09***<br />

.154<br />

.07<br />

5.381<br />

1.27*<br />

1.53***<br />

2.00***<br />

1.91***<br />

2.28***<br />

.163<br />

.09<br />

7.578<br />

.97<br />

1.25<br />

1.71***<br />

1.85***<br />

3.28***<br />

.144<br />

.11<br />

6.733<br />

Source: World Values Survey 1999-2001, pooled sample. Samples equally weighted with n = 1.000.<br />

The results are controlled for sex, age <strong>and</strong> education.<br />

Data entries: Odds ratios.<br />

1.01<br />

1.64<br />

1.66<br />

Japan<br />

1.20<br />

1.21<br />

.065<br />

.14<br />

659<br />

192


The results in Table 9-6 show that all three approaches can, to a certain degree, explain<br />

what motivates people into participating, <strong>and</strong> that these factors still come through after<br />

controlling for socio-demographic characteristics <strong>and</strong> mutual influences. Of the three<br />

factors, however, support for democracy shows the weakest impact (note that an odds<br />

ratio = 1.00 means that there is no difference between groups in the probability for an<br />

event to happen (i.e. to participate) <strong>and</strong> for an event not to happen (i.e. not to<br />

participate)). <strong>Participation</strong> in elite-challenging activities is more driven by people’s<br />

political involvement <strong>and</strong> their liberal orientation: Whereas in most of the postcommunist<br />

European societies (with the exception of Central Eastern Europe) the<br />

importance of politics has a greatest impact on participation, in all other country groups<br />

(<strong>and</strong> strongest in Western Europe, Anglo-Saxon societies <strong>and</strong> Southern Asia) it is a<br />

liberal view on human emancipation that motivates people into elite-challenging<br />

activities.<br />

The previous analyses could find no evidence – neither at the individual nor at the<br />

aggregate level – that elite-challenging participation poses a threat to democracy.<br />

Participants show high support for the idea of democracy <strong>and</strong> at the same time reject<br />

authoritarian alternatives; they are motivated by a process-oriented underst<strong>and</strong>ing of<br />

democracy; they show high levels of political involvement <strong>and</strong> emancipative values. It<br />

should be noted, however, that several of these characteristics are most pronounced in<br />

postindustrial societies. A similar link can be found at the aggregate level: In societies<br />

with higher levels of elite-challenging activities political processes are more democratic<br />

<strong>and</strong> elites less corrupt. The rise of elite-challenging publics gives therefore no reason to<br />

worry about democracy.<br />

193


Conclusion<br />

As one consequence of the collapse of communist regimes about 20 years ago, the<br />

scholarly focus in political science has shifted from more ideological debates to an<br />

analysis of the current state of contemporary democracies. The vanishing of the system<br />

alternative in the wake of the third wave of democratization has led some to celebrate the<br />

victory of democracy (Fukuyama 1992): Never in history have so many people all over<br />

the world enjoyed political freedoms <strong>and</strong> civil rights. At the same time, however, the<br />

thorough examination of the conditions <strong>and</strong> challenges has increased the awareness of the<br />

functional weaknesses of today’s representative democracies. “Paradoxically it seems<br />

that democracy at the beginning of a new millennium is at one <strong>and</strong> the same time<br />

triumphant <strong>and</strong> in crisis” (Blaug <strong>and</strong> Schwarzmantel 2001: 1). This applies especially to<br />

the relationship between the citizen <strong>and</strong> the state which has recently regained scholarly<br />

attention: Contemporary democracies are faced with a citizenry that shows increasing<br />

skepticism towards the main institutions of representative democracies. Examples are<br />

declining voter turnout, low confidence in the core institutions of representative<br />

democracies, or the diminishing role of traditional mass organizations such as political<br />

parties. Dalton (2002: 32) has summarized these developments in the provocative<br />

question: “Are we celebrating the success of democracy by staying at home”?<br />

The results presented in this thesis come to a different conclusion. Civic engagement is<br />

not in decline, quite the contrary. Around the globe we observe a consistent enlargement<br />

of the citizen action repertoire <strong>and</strong> an increase in non-institutionalized forms of political<br />

activities, corroborating the main claim of the early Political Action Study: the lasting<br />

existence of protest potential <strong>and</strong> activities.<br />

The aim of this thesis was to systematically test hypotheses about dynamics, causes <strong>and</strong><br />

consequences in elite-challenging activities in contemporary representative democracies,<br />

thereby contributing to closing a gap in participation research: Whereas there is a broad<br />

consensus that the action repertoire has exp<strong>and</strong>ed, “the research agenda has often failed<br />

to innovate sufficiently to capture the broader range of activities which have now become<br />

more common” (Norris 2007: 644). Based on the broadest empirical basis available, the<br />

study focused on citizens participating in demonstrations, political consumerism, or<br />

194


signing petitions. Major accounts of political participation were used to derive hypotheses<br />

about how participation in non-institutionalized forms has changed over time, how these<br />

activities can be explained <strong>and</strong> what implication they have for contemporary<br />

democracies. Table C-1 provides a summarizing overview of the hypotheses testing:<br />

some propositions found support in the analyses, while others did not. The main findings<br />

of the five empirical chapters are:<br />

<strong>Dynamics</strong> of elite-challenging activities<br />

Over the past 30 years, participation in demonstrations, petitions <strong>and</strong> political<br />

consumerism has increased in almost all regions of the world. There are pronounced<br />

cross-country differences, most of which can be explained by the societies’ socioeconomic<br />

development. Elite-challenging activities are particularly widespread in<br />

postindustrial democracies – on average two thirds of the population have participated in<br />

these activities. However, even in low income societies this form of participation is more<br />

than a marginal phenomenon. The cultural variant of modernization theory suggested this<br />

increase of elite-challenging activities whereas the social capital account, represented by<br />

Putnam, claimed a general decrease of civic activism that exp<strong>and</strong>ed to noninstitutionalized<br />

participation. No empirical evidence could be found for the latter<br />

proposition: Rather, people are becoming increasingly active through demonstrations <strong>and</strong><br />

petitions, <strong>and</strong> they have discovered the marketplace as a political arena to pressure elites<br />

by altering their own day-to-day consumption behavior. Citizens in contemporary<br />

democracies have not withdrawn from participation in general but supplemented their<br />

traditional action repertoire, using diversified channels to make their voices heard.<br />

195


Table C-1:<br />

Results of Hypotheses Testing<br />

Theoretical<br />

Approach<br />

Dimension<br />

<strong>Dynamics</strong><br />

in elite-challenging<br />

activities<br />

<strong>Causes</strong>/determinants<br />

of elite-challenging<br />

activities<br />

Consequences<br />

of elite-challenging<br />

activities<br />

Modernization <strong>and</strong><br />

Value Change<br />

Increase<br />

<br />

(1) Self expression<br />

values, prodemocratic<br />

orientations, youth<br />

(positive)<br />

(2) Postindustrialization<br />

(positive)<br />

<br />

<br />

Positive impact on<br />

democracy<br />

<br />

Organizational Changes<br />

<strong>and</strong> Social Capital<br />

Decrease/<br />

Increase<br />

<br />

<br />

(1) Social capital:<br />

networks <strong>and</strong> trust<br />

(positive);<br />

(2) Traditional<br />

forms of political<br />

participation<br />

(negative)<br />

<br />

<br />

Negative impact<br />

on democracy<br />

<br />

Resources <strong>and</strong><br />

Motivation<br />

--<br />

(1) Resources:<br />

young <strong>and</strong> highskilled<br />

citizens<br />

(positive)<br />

(2) Motivation:<br />

political interest,<br />

dissatisfaction,<br />

efficacy (positive)<br />

<br />

<br />

Increasing<br />

political inequality /<br />

<br />

Opportunity Structures<br />

--<br />

(1) Close context<br />

for mobilization:<br />

organizational<br />

membership<br />

(positive)<br />

(2) Wider context<br />

for mobilization:<br />

political <strong>and</strong><br />

economic<br />

conditions<br />

(positive)<br />

<br />

<br />

--<br />

Crisis of <strong>Democracy</strong>/<br />

Government Overload<br />

--<br />

Non-democratic<br />

orientations<br />

<br />

Crisis of<br />

democracy<br />

<br />

Empirical findings support the hypothesis.<br />

Empirical findings do not support the hypothesis.<br />

196


<strong>Causes</strong> of elite-challenging activities<br />

In fact, the social capital/organizational change account did not take a unified position on<br />

the decrease debate, as several other authors in the social capital literature accept the<br />

increase thesis, but think that this development goes at the expense of traditional forms of<br />

participation. The data also did not provide empirical support for this hypothesis: Neither<br />

on the individual nor on the societal level nor in analyses over time did the results<br />

substantiate a negative relationship between elite-challenging participation <strong>and</strong> voting,<br />

conventional participation, or membership in interest organizations <strong>and</strong> citizen action<br />

groups. Quite the contrary: On the aggregate level, the participation levels are either not<br />

linked at all or show a positive relationship; on the individual level demonstrators,<br />

petitioners <strong>and</strong> political consumers still vote <strong>and</strong> enroll in organizations.<br />

The study also examined other individual-level <strong>and</strong> contextual determinants,<br />

acknowledging that political mobilization does not happen in a vacuum but is always the<br />

result of an interplay between personal characteristics <strong>and</strong> environmental factors.<br />

Empirical evidence could be found for most of the theoretically assumed determinants:<br />

On the individual level, resources such as being young, highly educated <strong>and</strong> having a<br />

higher income are positively linked with elite-challenging participation. Motivations such<br />

as emancipative <strong>and</strong> pro-democratic values, political interest, political efficacy, trust <strong>and</strong><br />

being politically left-wing are favorable characteristics as well. In addition,<br />

organizational membership <strong>and</strong> embeddedness into informal networks provide an<br />

individual mobilization context for non-institutionalized participation. On the aggregate<br />

level, the organizing capacity of a society, density of informal networks, a climate of<br />

interpersonal trust, democracy <strong>and</strong> economic development provide a favorable wider<br />

context that facilitates participation in elite-challenging activities. Multi-level tests could<br />

show that both influences – determinants on the individual <strong>and</strong> on the aggregate level –<br />

also hold under mutual control. In the case of gender, the analyses yielded a reverse in the<br />

gender gap when controlling for socio-economic development: As resource are<br />

redistributed <strong>and</strong> become more accessible for women, they become the dominant actors<br />

of elite-challenging participation.<br />

197


Consequences of elite-challenging activities<br />

Finally, the study addressed the consequences of rising levels of elite-challenging<br />

activities for the democratic process. The results for political inequality are mixed. Still<br />

today, participation in elite-challenging activities requires more resources than for<br />

example voting. However, the differences appear much smaller when contrasting elitechallenging<br />

<strong>and</strong> conventional participation; this is particularly true for the gender gap.<br />

Moreover, some of the differences in resources <strong>and</strong> motivation have become smaller over<br />

the past 30 years, suggesting that resource discrepancies between participants <strong>and</strong> nonparticipants<br />

of elite-challenging actions are leveling out in the long run.<br />

Turning the attention to the debate about democratic governability, the empirical findings<br />

did not support the hypothesis that elite-challenging activities pose a threat to<br />

democracies. On the individual level, participation in demonstrations, petitions <strong>and</strong><br />

political consumerism is largely linked with pro-democratic orientations such as support<br />

for democracy (<strong>and</strong> at the same time rejecting authoritarian alternatives), a processoriented<br />

underst<strong>and</strong>ing of democracy, political involvement <strong>and</strong>, most importantly,<br />

liberal orientations such as tolerance towards foreigners <strong>and</strong> other people’s lifestyle,<br />

gender equality <strong>and</strong> trust. It should be noted however, that these findings are most<br />

pronounced – although not limited to – postindustrial democracies.<br />

On the aggregate level, the results were even more straightforward: high levels of elitechallenging<br />

activities are linked with several indicators that measure an effective<br />

democratic process. In particular elite behavior is impacted by a critical citizenry: In<br />

societies where elites are pressured with dem<strong>and</strong>s from below, elite behavior appears to<br />

be less corrupt <strong>and</strong> more transparent <strong>and</strong> accountable, limiting the abuse of entrusted<br />

power.<br />

What are the implications of the results for further research?<br />

First, from a theoretical point of view, a new conceptualization of the citizen action<br />

repertoire is needed. Elite-challenging activities have become a widely used participation<br />

tool, ranging from sporadic participation in demonstrations to a modified consumption<br />

behavior as a day-to-day activity. The issues around which non-institutionalized activities<br />

evolve often blur the traditional distinction between political <strong>and</strong> nonpolitical, private <strong>and</strong><br />

198


public behavior. The elite-challenging character of these activities – pressuring elites with<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>s from below – exp<strong>and</strong>s to targets beyond the (mostly national) governmental<br />

system. Thus, any conceptualization of political participation that neglects the new<br />

qualities of targets, issues, network structures <strong>and</strong> mobilization tactics of these<br />

individualized activities falls short of estimating the actual action repertoire <strong>and</strong><br />

participation level in contemporary democracies.<br />

Second, from a methodological point of view, it is clear that survey questions have their<br />

limits in the study of elite-challenging participation. 84 Overreporting due to social<br />

desirability bias (Brady 1999: 789), a well-known phenomenon in studies on electoral<br />

participation, is probably less of a problem for elite-challenging activities. A bigger<br />

problem is that the st<strong>and</strong>ardized format of questionnaires is rather insensitive to issues<br />

around which people are mobilized into demonstrations, petitions <strong>and</strong> political<br />

consumerism. In addition, the large surveys do not capture how much time people are<br />

dedicating to these activities. More information on these issues would help to better<br />

underst<strong>and</strong> the motivation for participating <strong>and</strong> shed light on the ‘in <strong>and</strong> out’ option that<br />

characterizes elite-challenging activities.<br />

Third, whereas this study is a first step, more comparative studies are needed, in<br />

particular with a focus on sporadic forms of political participation. Obviously, every<br />

country has its own participation profile, but Verba, Nie <strong>and</strong> Kim (1978) found similar<br />

modes of participation in a number of democracies they examined. The empirical results<br />

presented here support the idea that non-institutionalized activities can be compared<br />

across countries in a meaningful way. Despite the efforts of large comparative survey<br />

projects such as the Worlds Values Survey or other organizations summarized in the<br />

Global Barometers, the major limitation remains data availability for countries outside<br />

the postindustrial world.<br />

Beyond the comparison aspect, the study also suggests that more attention should be<br />

given to the linkage <strong>and</strong> interaction between individual characteristics <strong>and</strong> contextual<br />

factors determining whether, through what channels <strong>and</strong> around which issues people are<br />

84 Brady (1999: 795) suggests five rules to improve survey items on participation: “Aim for concreteness<br />

through detailed description of the act. Ask about a short <strong>and</strong> definite time interval (e.g., one year). Ask for<br />

details of the activity to help the respondent remember it. Ask for amounts of time or money, if possible.<br />

Design questions to discourage overreporting <strong>and</strong> social desirability bias”.<br />

199


mobilized into elite-challenging activities. This aspect also poses the biggest challenge to<br />

the future study of non-institutionalized participation. Early studies have almost<br />

exclusively focused on personal resources <strong>and</strong> motivation, whereas social movement <strong>and</strong><br />

activists studies have rather examined network structures <strong>and</strong> mobilization effects. The<br />

main objective of future studies should be to bring those two approaches together.<br />

Finally, the consequence dimension of elite-challenging activities deserves further<br />

attention. Almost all theoretical approaches to political participation make implicit (a<br />

few: explicit) claims about the consequences of an increase or decrease, or a specific<br />

composition of determinants of non-institutionalized actions – be it for democracy,<br />

political inequality, social cohesion, or democratic accountability. A systematic empirical<br />

testing of these propositions, however, is rather scarce. Instead, anecdotal evidence is<br />

presented, or individual-level findings are the basis for drawing conclusions on the<br />

societal level. 85 Without systematically testing the proposed relationships at the adequate<br />

level of analysis, the conclusions made must remain speculative. In my point of view, this<br />

is especially true for the recuring crisis scenarios in the relationship between the citizen<br />

<strong>and</strong> the state.<br />

Looking at the long-term implications of rising elite-challenging activities for<br />

contemporary representative democracies, the consequences largely depend on the ability<br />

of democratic institutions to adapt to those changes in the citizen participation repertoire.<br />

The direction <strong>and</strong> speed of social change <strong>and</strong> individualization processes make it very<br />

unlikely that the withdrawal from traditional – largely hierarchical – mass organizations<br />

that we could observe over the past decades is trend that can be reversed. This study has<br />

shown that citizens are not turning their back on politics per se, but that they get involved<br />

on their own terms when they are concerned about specific political or social issues. In<br />

the past, democracies have proved to be astonishingly flexible <strong>and</strong> adaptive in meeting<br />

challenges. The great challenge for contemporary democracies today – which is at the<br />

same time a tremendous potential – is to reform the democratic process to meet these<br />

participation dem<strong>and</strong>s by its citizens.<br />

85 This means committing an individualistic fallacy (Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Welzel 2003: 62).<br />

200


Bibliography<br />

Abramson, Paul R. (1995): Political <strong>Participation</strong>, in: Seymour Martin Lipset (ed.), The<br />

Encyclopedia of <strong>Democracy</strong>, Washington, DC: Congressional Quarterly Inc., pp. 913-<br />

921.<br />

Adorno, Theodor W., Else Frenkel-Brunswick, Daniel J. Levinson <strong>and</strong> R. Nevitt Sanford<br />

(1950): Authoritarian Personality, New York: Harper.<br />

Allerbeck, Klaus R. (1977): Analysis <strong>and</strong> Inference in Cross-National Survey Research,<br />

in: Alex<strong>and</strong>er Szalai, Ricardo Petrella, Stein Rokkan <strong>and</strong> Erwin K. Scheuch (eds.), Cross-<br />

National Comparative Survey Research. Theory <strong>and</strong> Praxis, Oxford: Pergamon Press, pp.<br />

373-402.<br />

Almond, Gabriel A. <strong>and</strong> Sidney Verba (1989 [1963]): The Civic Culture. Political<br />

Attitudes <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong> in Five Nations, Newbury Park et al.: Sage.<br />

Almond, Gabriel A., G. Bingham Powell, Jr. <strong>and</strong> Robert J. Mundt (1996): Comparative<br />

Politics. A Theoretical Framework, 2nd edition, New York: HarperCollins College<br />

Publishers.<br />

Barber, Benjamin (1984): Strong <strong>Democracy</strong>. Participatory Politics for a New Age,<br />

Berkeley: <strong>University</strong> of California Press.<br />

Barnes, Samuel H. (2004): Perspectives on Political Action. Paper Presented at the ECPR<br />

Joint Sessions of Workshops, Uppsala, Sweden, April 13-18, 2004.<br />

http://www.essex.ac.uk/ECPR/events/jointsessions/paperarchive/uppsala/ws24/Barnes2.p<br />

df<br />

Barnes, Samuel H. <strong>and</strong> Max Kaase et al. (1979): Political Action. Mass <strong>Participation</strong> in<br />

Five Western Democracies, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.<br />

Beck, Ulrich (1986): Risikogesellschaft. Auf dem Weg in eine <strong>and</strong>ere Moderne,<br />

Frankfurt a.M.: Suhrkamp (English Version: Ulrich Beck (1992): Risk Society. Towards<br />

a New Modernity, London: Sage).<br />

Beck, Ulrich (2002): Losing the Traditional. Individualization <strong>and</strong> ‘Precarious<br />

Freedoms’, in: Ulrich Beck <strong>and</strong> Elizabeth Beck-Gernsheim (eds.), Individualization,<br />

London: Sage, pp.1-21.<br />

Beck-Gernsheim, Elizabeth (1998): On the Way to a Post-Familial Family. From a<br />

Community of Need to Elective Affinities, in: Theory, Culture & Society, Vol. 15(3), pp.<br />

53-70.<br />

Beetham, David (ed.) (1994): Defining <strong>and</strong> Measuring <strong>Democracy</strong>, London: Sage.<br />

201


Bell, Daniel (1999 [1973]): The Coming of Post-Industrial Society. A Venture in Social<br />

Forecasting, New York: Basic Books.<br />

Bellah, Robert N. et al. (1996): Habits of the Heart. Individualism <strong>and</strong> Commitment in<br />

American Life. Updated Edition With a New Introduction, Berkeley et al.: <strong>University</strong> of<br />

California Press.<br />

Bennett, W. Lance (1998): The UnCivic Culture: Communication, Identity, <strong>and</strong> the Rise<br />

of Lifestyle Politics. 1998 Ithiel De Sola Pool Lecture, in: PS Politics <strong>and</strong> Science,<br />

December 1998, pp. 741-761.<br />

Berg-Schlosser, Dirk (2002): Indicators of Democratization <strong>and</strong> Good Governance as<br />

Measures of the Quality of <strong>Democracy</strong> – A Critical Appraisal. Paper Presented at the<br />

Annual Meeting of the International Sociology Association in Brisbane, Australia, July<br />

2002.<br />

Boix, Carles (2003): <strong>Democracy</strong> <strong>and</strong> Redistribution, Cambridge et al.: Cambridge<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Boix, Carles <strong>and</strong> Daniel N., Posner (1996): Making Social Capital Work: A Review of<br />

Robert Putnam's Making <strong>Democracy</strong> Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy, Columbia<br />

International Affairs Online, http://www.ciaonet.org/wps/boc01/index.html.<br />

Bollen, Kenneth A. <strong>and</strong> Pamela Paxton (2000): Subjective Measures of Liberal<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong>, in: Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 33(1), pp. 58-86.<br />

Bourdieu, Pierre (1983): The Forms of Capital, in: J.G. Richardson (ed.), H<strong>and</strong>book of<br />

Theory <strong>and</strong> Research for the Sociology of Education, New York: Greenwood Press.<br />

Brady, Henry E. (1999): Political <strong>Participation</strong>, in: John P. Robinson, Phillip R. Shaver<br />

<strong>and</strong> Lawrence S. Wrightsman (eds.), Measures of Political Attitudes. Volume 2 of<br />

Measures of Social Psychological Attitudes, San Diego, CA, et al.: Academic Press, pp.<br />

737-801.<br />

Coleman, James S. (1988): Social Capital in the Creation of Social Capital, in: American<br />

Journal of Sociology, Vol. 94, pp. 95-121.<br />

Coleman, James S. (1990): Foundations of Social Theory, Cambridge, MA: Harvard<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Craig (1980): The Mobilization of Political Discontent, in: Political Behavior, Vol. 2(2),<br />

pp.189-209.<br />

Croizier, Michel, Samuel P. Huntington <strong>and</strong> Joji Watanuki (1975): The Crisis of<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong>. Report on the Governability of Democracies to the Trilateral Commission,<br />

New York: New York <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

202


Dahl, Robert D. (1971): Polyarchy: <strong>Participation</strong> <strong>and</strong> Opposition, New Haven: Yale<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Dahl, Robert D. (1975): Governments <strong>and</strong> Political Oppositions, in: Fred I. Greenstein<br />

<strong>and</strong> Nelson W. Polsby (eds.), Macropolitical Theory. H<strong>and</strong>book of Political Science, Vol.<br />

3, Reading et al.: Addison_Wesley, pp. 115-174.<br />

Dahl, Robert D. (1989): <strong>Democracy</strong> <strong>and</strong> Its Critiques, New Haven <strong>and</strong> London: Yale<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Dahl, Robert D. (1998): On <strong>Democracy</strong>, New Haven <strong>and</strong> London: Yale <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Dahl, Robert D. (2006): On Political Equality, New Haven <strong>and</strong> London: Yale <strong>University</strong><br />

Press.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. (1984): Cognitive Mobilization <strong>and</strong> Partisan Dealignment in Advanced<br />

Industrial Democracies, in: Journal of Politics 46(1), pp. 264-284.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. (1999): Political Support in Advanced Industrial Democracies, in:<br />

Pippa Norris (ed.), Critical Citizens. Global Support for Democratic Governance, Oxford:<br />

Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 57-77.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. (2000a): The Decline of Party Identifications, in: Russell J. Dalton <strong>and</strong><br />

Martin P. Wattenberg (eds.), Parties Without Partisans. Political Change in Advanced<br />

Industrial Democracies, Oxford/New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 19-36.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. (2000b): Citizen Attitudes <strong>and</strong> Political Behavior, in: Comparative<br />

Political Studies, Vol. 33(6/7), pp. 912-940.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. (2002): Citizen Politics. Public Opinion <strong>and</strong> Political Parties in<br />

Advanced Industrial Democracies, 3rd edition, New York/London: Chatham House<br />

Publishers.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. (2004): The Social Transformation of Trust in Government, in:<br />

International Review of Sociology, Vol. 15(1), pp. 133-154.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. (2006): Citizen Politics. Public Opinion <strong>and</strong> Political Parties in<br />

Advanced Industrial Democracies, 4th edition, Washington, DC: CQ Press.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. (2008): The Good Citizen. How a Younger Generation Is Reshaping<br />

American Politics, Washington, D.C.: CQ Press.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. <strong>and</strong> Alix van Sickle (2004): Why People Protest? The Resource,<br />

Structural, <strong>and</strong> Cultural Bases of Protest. Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the<br />

203


Annual Meetings of the American Political Science Association, Chicago, IL, September<br />

1-5, 2004.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. <strong>and</strong> Martin P. Wattenberg (2000a): Unthinkable <strong>Democracy</strong>. Political<br />

Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies, in: Russell J. Dalton <strong>and</strong> Martin P.<br />

Wattenberg (eds.), Parties Without Partisans. Political Change in Advanced Industrial<br />

Democracies, Oxford/New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 3-16.<br />

Dalton, Russell J. <strong>and</strong> Martin P. Wattenberg (eds.) (2000): Parties without Partisans.<br />

Political Change in Advanced Industrial Democracies, Oxford: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Dalton, Russell J., Scott Flanagan <strong>and</strong> Paul Beck (eds.) (1984): Electoral Change in<br />

Advanced Industrial Democracies, Princeton: Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Davis, Gerald et al. (2005): Social Movements <strong>and</strong> Organization, New York: Cambridge<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Dekker, Paul, Ruud Koopmans <strong>and</strong> Andries van den Broek (1997): Voluntary<br />

Associations, Social Movements <strong>and</strong> Individual Political Behaviour in Western Europe,<br />

in: Jan W. van Deth (ed.), Private Groups <strong>and</strong> Public Life. Social <strong>Participation</strong>, Voluntary<br />

Associations <strong>and</strong> Political Involvement in Representative Democracies, London/New<br />

York: Routledge, pp.220-239.<br />

Delhey, Jan <strong>and</strong> Kenneth Newton (2005): Predicting Cross-National Levels of Social<br />

Trust: Global Patterns or Nordic Exceptionalism?, in: European Sociological Review,<br />

Vol. 21(4), pp. 311-327.<br />

Della Porta, Donatella (1999): Protest, Protesters <strong>and</strong> Protest Policing, in: Marco Guini,<br />

Douglas McAdam <strong>and</strong> Charles Tilly (eds.), How Social Movements Matter, Minnesota:<br />

Minnesota <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 66-96.<br />

Della Porta, Donatella, Hans-Peter Kriesi <strong>and</strong> Dieter Rucht (eds.) (1999): Social<br />

Movements in a Globalizing World, Basingstoke: Macmillan.<br />

Deutsch, Karl W. (1961): Social Mobilization <strong>and</strong> Political Development, in: American<br />

Political Science Review, 55 (September), pp. 493-514.<br />

Diamond, Larry (1992): Economic Development <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong> Reconsidered, in: Gary<br />

Marks <strong>and</strong> Larry Diamond (eds.), Reexamining <strong>Democracy</strong>: Essays in Honor of Seymour<br />

Martin Lipset, Newbury Park, CA: Sage, pp. 93-193.<br />

Diamond, Larry, Juan Linz <strong>and</strong> Seymour Martin Lipset (eds.) (1988): Democracies in<br />

Developing Countries; Africa, Boulder, CA: Lynne Rienner.<br />

Diani, Mario <strong>and</strong> Doug McAdam (2003): Social Movements <strong>and</strong> Networks. Relational<br />

Approaches to Collective Action, Oxford: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

204


Dickerson, Mark <strong>and</strong> Thomas Flanagan (2002): An Introduction to Government <strong>and</strong><br />

Politics, 6th edition, Toronto: Nelson.<br />

Diez-Medrano, Jaime <strong>and</strong> Ruud Luijkx (2004): Technical Note, in: Ronald Inglehart et<br />

al. (eds.), Human Beliefs <strong>and</strong> Values. A Cross-Cultural Sourcebook Based on the 1999-<br />

2002 Values Surveys, Mexico City: Siglo XXI Editores, pp. 399-411.<br />

Duncan, Terry E. et al. (2003): A Multilevel Contextual Model of Neighborhood<br />

Collective Efficacy, in: American Journal of Community Psychology, Vol. 32(3/4), pp.<br />

245-252.<br />

Durkheim, Emile (2002) [1897]: Suicide. A Study in Sociology, London: Routledge.<br />

Earl, Jennifer, Andrew Martin, John D. McCarthy <strong>and</strong> Sarah A. Soule (2004): The Use of<br />

Newspaper Data in the Study of Collective Action, in: Annual Review of Sociology, Vol.<br />

30, pp. 65-80.<br />

Easton, David (1965): A Systems Analysis of Political Life, New York: Wiley.<br />

Easton, David (1975): A Reassessment of the Concept of Political Support, in: British<br />

Journal of Political Science, Vol. 5, pp. 435-457.<br />

Eckstein, Harry (1966): A Theory of Stable <strong>Democracy</strong>. Princeton: Princeton <strong>University</strong><br />

Press.<br />

Edwards, Bob <strong>and</strong> Michael W. Foley (2001): Civil Society <strong>and</strong> Social Capital. A Primer,<br />

in: Bob Edwards, Michael W. Foley <strong>and</strong> Mario Diani (eds.), Beyond Tocqueville. Civil<br />

Society <strong>and</strong> the Social Capital Debate in Comparative Perspective, Hanover <strong>and</strong> London:<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press of New Engl<strong>and</strong>, pp. 1-14.<br />

Edwards, Bob Michael W. Foley <strong>and</strong> Mario Diani (eds.) (2001): Beyond Tocqueville.<br />

Civil Society <strong>and</strong> the Social Capital Debate in Comparative Perspective, Hanover <strong>and</strong><br />

London: <strong>University</strong> Press of New Engl<strong>and</strong>.<br />

Erikson, Erik H. (1968): Identity. Youth <strong>and</strong> Crisis, New York: W.W. Norton.<br />

Esmer, Yilmaz (2004): Cross-Cultural Comparisons, Survey Methodology <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Values Surveys, in: Ronald Inglehart, Miguel Basáñez, Jaime Diez-Medrano, Loek<br />

Halman <strong>and</strong> Ruud Luijkx, Human Beliefs <strong>and</strong> Values. A Cross-Cultural Sourcebook<br />

Based on the 1999-2002 Values Surveys, Mexico City: Siglo XXI Editores, pp.385-397.<br />

Etzioni, Amitai (1993): The Spirit of Community. Rights, Responsibilities, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Communitarian Agenda, New York: Crown Publishers.<br />

205


Fox Piven, Frances <strong>and</strong> Richard Cloward (2000): Why American Still Don’t Vote: And<br />

Why Politicians Want It That Way, Boston: Beacon Press.<br />

Franklin, Mark N. (2004): Voter Turnout <strong>and</strong> the <strong>Dynamics</strong> of Electoral Competition in<br />

Established Democracies since 1945, New York: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press,<br />

Friedman, Monroe (1999): Comsumer Boycotts. Effecting Change Through the<br />

Marketplace <strong>and</strong> the Media, New York <strong>and</strong> London: Routledge.<br />

Friedrichs, Jürgen (1998): Die Individualisierungs-These. Eine Explikation im Rahmen<br />

der Rational-Choice-Theorie, in: Jürgen Friedrichs (ed.), Die Individualisierungshypothese,<br />

Opladen: Leske + Budrich, pp. 33-47.<br />

Fuchs, Dieter (1990): The Normalization of the Unconventional. Forms of Political<br />

Action <strong>and</strong> New Social Movements, Discussion Paper, FS III 90-203, Berlin:<br />

Wissenschaftszentrum für Sozialforschung.<br />

Fuchs, Dieter (2000): Typen und Indizes demokratischer Regime. Eine Analyse des<br />

Präsidentialismus- und des Veto-Spieler-Ansatzes. Discussion Paper FS III 00-205,<br />

Berlin: Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung (WZB).<br />

Fukuyama, Francis (1995): Trust. The Social Virtues <strong>and</strong> the Creation of Prosperity, New<br />

York: Free Press.<br />

Fukuyama, Francis (1999): Social Capital <strong>and</strong> Civil Society. Paper for Delivery at the<br />

IMF Conference on Second Generation Reforms, October 1999:<br />

http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/seminar/1999/reforms/fukuyama.htm<br />

Fung, Archon (2003): Associations <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>. Between Theories, Hopes, <strong>and</strong><br />

Realities, in: Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 29, pp. 515-539.<br />

Gabriel, Oscar W. (1996): Distrust, Involvement, <strong>and</strong> Political Protest in Western<br />

Democracies, in: Neil Nevitte <strong>and</strong> Loek Halman (eds.), Political Value Change in<br />

Western Democracies. Integration, Values, Identification <strong>and</strong> <strong>Participation</strong>, Tilburg:<br />

Tilburg <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 193-220.<br />

Gamson, W.A. <strong>and</strong> David S. Meyer (1996): Framing Political Opportunity, in: Doug<br />

McAdam, John McCarthy <strong>and</strong> Mayer Zald (eds.), Comparative Perspectives on Social<br />

Movements, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 275-290.<br />

Gastil, Raymond Duncan (1991): The Comparative Survey of Freedom. Experiences <strong>and</strong><br />

Suggestions, in: Alex Inkeles (ed.), On Measuring <strong>Democracy</strong>. Its Consequences <strong>and</strong><br />

Concomitants, New Brunswick/London: Transaction Publishers, pp. 21-46.<br />

Gerring, John (2001): Social Science Methodology, Cambridge: Cambridge <strong>University</strong><br />

Press.<br />

206


Gerring, John, Philip Bond, William T. Barndt <strong>and</strong> Carola Moreno (2005): <strong>Democracy</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> Economic Growth. A Historical Perspective, in: World Politics, Vol. 57 (April), pp.<br />

323-364.<br />

Giddens, Anthony (1990): The Consequences of Modernity, Stanford, CA: Stanford<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Giugni, Marco, Doug McAdam <strong>and</strong> Charles Tilly (eds.) (1999): How Movements Matter.<br />

Theoretical <strong>and</strong> Comparative Studies on the Consequences of Social Movements,<br />

Minneapolis: <strong>University</strong> of Minnesota Press.<br />

Goul Andersen, Jørgen <strong>and</strong> Mette Tobiasen (2004): Who Are These Political Consumers<br />

Anyway? Survey Evidence from Denmark, in: Michele Micheletti, Andreas Follesdal <strong>and</strong><br />

Dietlind Stolle (eds.), Politics, Products, <strong>and</strong> Markets, New Brunswick <strong>and</strong> London:<br />

Transaction Publishers, pp. 203-221.<br />

Graham, Hugh Davis <strong>and</strong> Ted Robert Gurr (eds.) (1979): Violence in America. Historical<br />

<strong>and</strong> Comparative Perspectives, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.<br />

Granovetter, Mark S. (1973): The Strength of Weak Ties, in: American Journal of<br />

Sociology, Vol. 78, pp. 1360-1380.<br />

Granovetter, Mark S. (1995): Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts <strong>and</strong> Careers, 2nd<br />

edition, Chicago: <strong>University</strong> of Chicago Press.<br />

Gray, Mark <strong>and</strong> Miki Caul (2000): Declining Voter Turnout in Advanced Industrial<br />

Democracies, 1950 to 1997. The Effects of Declining Group Mobilization, in:<br />

Comparative Political studies, Vol. 33 (9), pp. 1091-1122.<br />

Grugel, Jean (2002): Democratization. A Critical Introduction, Houndmills et al.:<br />

Palgrave.<br />

Gurr, Ted (1970): Why Men Rebel, Princeton: Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Hampton, Keith <strong>and</strong> Barry Wellman (2003): Neighboring in Netville. How the Internet<br />

Supports Community <strong>and</strong> Social Capital in a Wired Suburb, in: City <strong>and</strong> Community,<br />

Vol. 2(4), pp. 277-311.<br />

Hanifan, Lyda Judson (1916): The Rural School Community Center, in: Annals of the<br />

American Academy of Political <strong>and</strong> Social Science, Vol. 67, pp. 130-138.<br />

Hanifan, Lyda Judson (1920): The Community Center, Boston: Silver Burdett.<br />

Held, David (1996): Models of <strong>Democracy</strong>, Cambridge: Polity Press.<br />

207


Hirschman, Albert O. (1979): Shifting Involvements. Private Interests <strong>and</strong> Public Action,<br />

Princeton, NJ: Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Hocke, Peter (1998): Determining the Selection Bias in Local <strong>and</strong> National Newspaper<br />

Reports on Political Protest, in: Dieter Rucht, Ruud Koopmans <strong>and</strong> Friedhelm Neidhardt<br />

(eds.), Acts of Dissent. New Developments in the Study of Protest, Berlin: edition sigma,<br />

pp. 130-163.<br />

Holmberg, Sören (1999): Down <strong>and</strong> Down We Go: Political Trust in Sweden, in: Pippa<br />

Norris (ed.), Critical Citizens. Global Support for Democratic Governance, Oxford:<br />

Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 103-122.<br />

Hooghe, Marc (2003): <strong>Participation</strong> in Voluntary Associations <strong>and</strong> Value Indicators: The<br />

Effect of Current <strong>and</strong> Previous <strong>Participation</strong> Experiences, in: Nonprofit <strong>and</strong> Voluntary<br />

Sector Quarterly, Vol. 32(1), pp. 47-69.<br />

Hoffmann-Lange, Ursula (2007): Methods of Elite-Research, in: Russell J. Dalton <strong>and</strong><br />

Hans-Dieter Klingemann (eds.), The Oxford H<strong>and</strong>book of Political Behavior,<br />

Oxford/New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 910-927.<br />

Howard, Marc Morjé (2003): The Weakness of Civil Society in Post-Communist Europe,<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Huckfeldt, Robert <strong>and</strong> John Sprague (1993): Citizens, Contexts, <strong>and</strong> Politics, in: Ada W.<br />

Finifter (ed.), Political Science: The State of the Discipline II, Washington, D.C.: The<br />

American Political Science Association, pp. 281-303.<br />

Human Development Report (2007/2008): Fighting Climate Change. Human Solidarity<br />

in a Divided World. Published for the United Nations Development Programme (UNDP).<br />

Website: http://hdr.undp.org/en/ .<br />

Huntington, Samuel P. (1968): Political Order in Changing Societies, New Haven: Yale<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Huntington, Samuel P. (1974a): Postindustrial Politics: How Benign Will It Be?, in:<br />

Comparative Politics, 6, pp. 147-177.<br />

Huntington, Samuel P. (1974b): Political Development <strong>and</strong> Political Decay, in: Norman<br />

J.Vig <strong>and</strong> Rodney P. Stiefbold (eds.), Politics in Advanced Nations: Modernization,<br />

Development <strong>and</strong> Contemporary Change, Englewood Cliffs (NJ): Prentice Hall, pp. 108-<br />

130.<br />

Huntington, Samuel P. (1991): The Third Wave: Democratization in the Late Twentieth<br />

Century, Norman, OK: <strong>University</strong> of Oklahama.<br />

208


Huntington, Samuel P. (2000): Foreword, in: Susan J. Pharr <strong>and</strong> Robert D. Putnam (eds.),<br />

Disaffected Democracies. What’s Troubling the Trilateral Countries?, Princeton:<br />

Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. xxiii-xxvi.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald (1990): Culture Shift in Advanced Industrial Societies, Princeton:<br />

Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald (1997): Modernization <strong>and</strong> Postmodernization. Cultural, Economic <strong>and</strong><br />

Political Change in 43 Societies, Princeton, NJ: Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald (1998): Political Values, in: Jan W. van Deth (ed.), Comparative<br />

Research. The Problem of Equivalence, London/New York: Routledge, pp. 61-85.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald (2001): Sociological Theories of Modernization, in: International<br />

Encyclopedia of the Social <strong>and</strong> Behavioral Sciences, Elsevier Science Ltd., pp. 9965-<br />

9971.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald (2006): <strong>Democracy</strong> <strong>and</strong> Happiness. What <strong>Causes</strong> What? Paper<br />

presented Conference on Human Happiness at Notre Dame <strong>University</strong>, Oct. 22-24, 2006.<br />

http://www.nd.edu/~adutt/activities/documents/InglehartHappiness<strong>and</strong><strong>Democracy</strong>1.pdf .<br />

Inglehart, Ronald <strong>and</strong> Christian Welzel (2005): Modernization, Cultural Change <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Democracy</strong>: The Human Development Sequence, Cambridge: Cambridge <strong>University</strong><br />

Press.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald <strong>and</strong> Gabriela Catterberg (2003): Trends in Political Action. The<br />

Developmental Trend <strong>and</strong> the Post-Honeymoon Decline, in: Ronald Inglehart (ed.),<br />

Islam, Gender, Culture, <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>. Findings from the World Values Survey <strong>and</strong> the<br />

European Values Survey. Special Issue of International Studies in Social Science,<br />

Willowdale, Canada: de Sitter Publications, pp. 77-93.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald <strong>and</strong> Marita Carballo (1997): Does Latin America Exist? (And Is There<br />

a Confucian Culture?): A Global Analysis of Cross-Cultural Differences, in: PS: Political<br />

Science & Politics, Vol. 30(1), pp. 34-46.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald <strong>and</strong> Wayne E. Baker (2000): Modernization, Cultural Change, <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Persistence of Traditional Values, in: American Sociological Review, 65 (February), pp.<br />

19-51.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald, Loek Halman <strong>and</strong> Christian Welzel (2004): Introduction, in: Ronald<br />

Inglehart et al. (eds.), Human Beliefs <strong>and</strong> Values. A Cross-Cultural Sourcebook Based on<br />

the 1999-2002 Values Surveys, Mexico City: Siglo XXI Editores, pp. 1-20.<br />

Inglehart, Ronald, Miguel Basanez, Jaime Diez-Medrano, Loek Halman <strong>and</strong> Ruud Luijkx<br />

(2004) (eds.): Human Beliefs <strong>and</strong> Values. A Cross-Cultural Sourcebook Based on the<br />

1999-2002 Values Surveys, Mexico City: Siglo XXI Editores.<br />

209


<strong>Jacobs</strong>, Jane (1961): The Death <strong>and</strong> Life of Great American Cities, New York: R<strong>and</strong>om.<br />

Jaggers, Keith <strong>and</strong> Ted Robert Gurr (1995): Tracking <strong>Democracy</strong>’s Third Wave with the<br />

Polity III Data, in: Journal of Peace Research 32(4), pp. 469–482.<br />

Javeline, Debra (2003): Protest <strong>and</strong> the Politics of Blame. The Russian Response to<br />

Unpaid Wages, Ann Arbor: The <strong>University</strong> of Michigan Press.<br />

Jenkins, J. Craig <strong>and</strong> Bert Kl<strong>and</strong>ermans (eds.) (1995): The Politics of Social Protest.<br />

Comparative Perspectives on States <strong>and</strong> Social Movements, Minneapolis: <strong>University</strong> of<br />

Minnesota Press.<br />

Jenkins, J. Craig <strong>and</strong> Michael Wallace (1996): The Generalized Action Potential of<br />

Protest Movements. The New Class, Social Trends, <strong>and</strong> Political Exclusion Explanations,<br />

in: Sociological Forum, Vol. 11 (2), pp. 183-207.<br />

Jennings, M. Kent <strong>and</strong> Jan W. van Deth et al. (1990): Continuities in Political Action. A<br />

Longitudinal Study of Political Orientations in Three Western Democracies, Berlin/New<br />

York: de Gruyter.<br />

Kaase, Max (1984): The Challenges of the ‘Participatory Revolution’ in Pluralist<br />

Democracies, in: International Political Science Review, Vol. 5, pp. 299-318.<br />

Kaase, Max (1990): Mass <strong>Participation</strong>, in: M. Kent Jennings <strong>and</strong> Jan W. van Deth et al.,<br />

Continuities in Political Action. A Longitudinal Study of Political Orientations in Three<br />

Western Democracies, Berlin/New York: de Gruyter, pp. 23-64.<br />

Kaase, Max <strong>and</strong> Alan Marsh (1979a): Political Action. A Theoretical Perspective, in:<br />

Samuel H. Barnes <strong>and</strong> Max Kaase et al., Political Action. Mass <strong>Participation</strong> in Five<br />

Western Democracies, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, pp. 27-56.<br />

Kaase, Max <strong>and</strong> Alan Marsh (1979b): Political Action Repertory. Changes over Time <strong>and</strong><br />

a New Typology, in: Samuel H. Barnes <strong>and</strong> Max Kaase et al., Political Action. Mass<br />

<strong>Participation</strong> in Five Western Democracies, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, pp. 137-166.<br />

Kaase, Max <strong>and</strong> Kenneth Newton (1995): Beliefs in Government (Beliefs in<br />

Government, Volume Five), Oxford: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Kaase, Max <strong>and</strong> Samuel H. Barnes (1979): In Conclusion. The Future of Political Protest<br />

in Western Democracies, in: Samuel H. Barnes <strong>and</strong> Max Kaase et al., Political Action.<br />

Mass <strong>Participation</strong> in Five Western Democracies, Beverly Hills <strong>and</strong> London: Sage.<br />

Kaase, Max <strong>and</strong> Samuel H. Barnes (1979): In Conclusion: The Future of Political Protest<br />

in Western Democracies, in: Samuel H. Barnes <strong>and</strong> Max Kaase et al., Political Action.<br />

Mass <strong>Participation</strong> in Five Western Democracies, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, pp. 523-536.<br />

210


Karatnycky, Adrian (1999): The Decline of Illiberal <strong>Democracy</strong>, in: Journal of<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong>, Vol. 10(1), pp. 112-125.<br />

Karatnycky, Adrian (2003): Liberty’s Advances in a Troubled World, in: Journal of<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong>, Vol. 14(1), pp. 100-113.<br />

Karp, Jeffrey A. <strong>and</strong> David Brockington (2005): Social Desirability <strong>and</strong> Response<br />

Validity. A Comparative Analysis of Overreporting Voter Turnout in Five Countries, in:<br />

Journal of Politics, Vol. 67(3), pp. 825-840.<br />

Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay <strong>and</strong> Massimo Mastruzzi (2004): Governance Matters III:<br />

Governance Indicators 1996, 1998, 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2002, in: World Bank Economic Review,<br />

Vol. 18, pp. 253-287.<br />

Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay <strong>and</strong> Massimo Mastruzzi (2006): Measuring Corruption:<br />

Myths <strong>and</strong> Realities, in: Development Outreach, September 2006, World Bank Institute:<br />

http://www1.worldbank.org/devoutreach/september06/article.asp?id=371 .<br />

Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay <strong>and</strong> Massimo Mastruzzi (2007): Governance Matters VI:<br />

Aggregate <strong>and</strong> Individual Governance Indicators 1996-2006.<br />

Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay <strong>and</strong> Massimo Mastruzzi (2008): Governance Matters VII:<br />

Aggregate <strong>and</strong> Individual Governance Indicators 1996-2007, Policy Research Working<br />

Paper 4654.<br />

Kawachi, Ichiro et al. (1997): Social Capital, Income Inequality, <strong>and</strong> Mortality, in:<br />

American Journal of Public Health, Vol. 87(9), pp. 1491-1498.<br />

Kirchheimer, Otto (1965): Der W<strong>and</strong>el des westeuropäischen Parteiensystems, in:<br />

Politische Vierteljahresschrift, Vol. 6(1), pp. 20-41.<br />

Kitschelt, Herbert P. (1986): Political Opportunity Structures <strong>and</strong> Political Protest: Anti-<br />

Nuclear Movements in Four Democracies, in: British Journal of Political Science, Vol.<br />

16, pp. 57-85.<br />

Klingemann, Hans-Dieter (1999): Mapping Political Support in the 1990ies: A Global<br />

Analysis, in: Pippa Norris (ed.), Critical Citizens. Global Support for Democratic<br />

Governance, Oxford <strong>and</strong> New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 31-56.<br />

Klingemann, Hans-Dieter <strong>and</strong> Dieter Fuchs (1995): Conclusion, in: Hans-Dieter<br />

Klingemann <strong>and</strong> Dieter Fuchs (eds.), Citizens <strong>and</strong> the State, Oxford: Oxford <strong>University</strong><br />

Press, pp.<br />

Klingemann, Hans-Dieter <strong>and</strong> Dieter Fuchs (eds.) (1995): Citizens <strong>and</strong> the State. Beliefs<br />

in Government, Vol.1, Oxford/New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

211


Kohler, Ulrich (2005): Statusinkonsistenz und Entstrukturierung von Lebenslagen.<br />

Empirische Untersuchung zweier Individualisierungshypothesen mit Querschnittsdaten<br />

aus 28 Ländern, in: Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie, Vol. 57(2),<br />

pp. 230-253.<br />

Kohn, Malvin L. (1987): Cross-National Research as an Analytical Strategy. American<br />

Sociological Association, 1987 Presidential Address, in: American Sociological Review,<br />

Vol. 52(December), pp. 713-731.<br />

Koopmans, Ruud <strong>and</strong> Dieter Rucht (2002): Protest Event Analysis, in: Bert Kl<strong>and</strong>ermans<br />

<strong>and</strong> Suzanne Staggenborg (eds.), Methods of Social Movement Research, Minneapolis:<br />

<strong>University</strong> of Minnesota Press, pp. 231-259.<br />

Kraut, Richard (2002): Aristotle: Political Philosophy. Founders of Modern Political <strong>and</strong><br />

Social Thought Series, Oxford/New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Kreft, Ita <strong>and</strong> Jan de Leeuw (1998): Introducing Multilevel Modeling, London et al.:<br />

Sage.<br />

Kriesi, Hanspeter, Ruud Koopmans, Jan Willem Dyvendak <strong>and</strong> Marco G. Giugni (1995):<br />

New Social Movements in Western Europe. A Comparative Analysis, Minneapolis:<br />

Minnesota <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Ladd, Everett C. (1996): The Data Just Don’t Show Erosion of America’s Social Capital,<br />

in: Public Perspectives, Vol. 7, pp. 1-30.<br />

Ladd, Everett C. (1999): The Ladd Report, New York: Free Press.<br />

Lambsdorff, Johann Graf (2006): The Methodology of the Corruption Perception Index<br />

2006, Transparency International (TI) <strong>and</strong> <strong>University</strong> of Passau, October 2006.<br />

Lasswell, Harold D. (1951): Democratic Character, in: ibid., The Political Writings of<br />

Harold D. Lasswell. Glencoe, IL: Free Press.<br />

Lauth, Hans-Joachim (2003): Problems <strong>and</strong> Limitations of Measuring <strong>Democracy</strong>. Paper<br />

Presented at a Conference “Reassessing <strong>Democracy</strong>: New Approaches to Governance,<br />

Citizenship <strong>and</strong> Multiple Identities in Comparative Research” in Bremen, Germany, June<br />

20-22, 2003.<br />

Lauth, Hans-Joachim, Gert Pickel <strong>and</strong> Christian Welzel (eds.) (2000):<br />

Demokratiemessung. Konzepte und Befunde im Internationalen Vergleich, Wiesbaden:<br />

Westdeutscher Verlag.<br />

Lazarsfeld, Berelson <strong>and</strong> Gaudet (1948): The People’s Choice, New York: Columbia<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

212


Lenski, Gerhard E. (1954): Status Crystallization. A Non-Vertical Dimension of Social<br />

Status, in: American Sociological Review, Vol. 19, pp. 405-413.<br />

Lijphart, Arena (1971): Comparative Politics <strong>and</strong> the Comparative Method, in: American<br />

Political Science Review, Vol. 65, pp. 682-693.<br />

Lijphart, Arena (1997): Unequal <strong>Participation</strong>: <strong>Democracy</strong>’s Unresolved Dilemma.<br />

Presidential Address, American Political Science Association, 1996, in: American<br />

Political Science Review, Vol. 91(1), pp. 1-14.<br />

Lin, Nan (1999a): Building a Network Theory of Social Capital, in: Connections, Vol.<br />

22(1): 28-51.<br />

Lin, Nan (1999b): Social Networks <strong>and</strong> Status Attainment, in: Annual Review of<br />

Sociology, Vol. 25, pp. 467-487.<br />

Lin, Nan (2001): Social Capital. A Theory of Social Structure <strong>and</strong> Action, Cambridge:<br />

Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Linz, Juan L. <strong>and</strong> Arturo Valenzuela (1994): The Failure of Presidential <strong>Democracy</strong>,<br />

London: Johns Hopkins Press.<br />

Lipset, Seymour Martin (1959): Some Social Requisites of <strong>Democracy</strong>: Economic<br />

Development <strong>and</strong> Political Legitimacy, in: American Political Science Review, 53<br />

(March), pp. 69-105.<br />

Lipset, Seymour Martin (1981 [1960]): Political Man: The Social Bases of Politics,<br />

Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Lipset, Seymour Martin (1992): Conditions of the Democratic Order <strong>and</strong> Social Change:<br />

A Comparative Discussion, in: S.N. Eisenstadt (ed.), Studies in Human Society:<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> <strong>and</strong> Modernity, New York: E. J. Brill, pp. 1-14.<br />

Lipset, Seymour Martin (1994): The Social Requisites of <strong>Democracy</strong> Revisited. 1993<br />

Presidential Address, in: American Sociological Review, 59 (February), pp. 1-22.<br />

Lipset, Seymour Martin <strong>and</strong> Stein Rokkan (1967): Cleavage Structures, Party Systems,<br />

<strong>and</strong> Voter Alignments: An Introduction, in: ibid. (eds.), Party Systems <strong>and</strong> Voter<br />

Alignments: Cross-National Perspectives, New York: The Free Press, pp. 1-64.<br />

Lipset, Seymour Martin, Kyoung-Ryung Seong <strong>and</strong> John Charles Torres (1993): A<br />

Comparative Analysis of the Social Requisites of <strong>Democracy</strong>, in: International Social<br />

Science Journal, 45, pp. 155-175.<br />

213


Lutz, Georg <strong>and</strong> Karin Gill<strong>and</strong> (2004): Do More Opportunities to Participate Lead to<br />

More Equality? Paper Presented at the 100th APSA Annual Meeting, Chicago,<br />

September 02-05, 2004.<br />

Mair, Peter (2001): In the Aggregate. Mass Electoral Behavior in Western Europe, 1950-<br />

2000, in: Hans Keman (ed.), Comparative Democratic Politics, London: Sage, pp. 122-<br />

140.<br />

Mair, Peter <strong>and</strong> Ingrid van Biezen (2001): Party Membership in Twenty European<br />

Democracies, in: Party Politics, 7(1), pp. 5-22.<br />

Marsh, Alan (1977): Protest <strong>and</strong> Political Consciousness, Beverly Hills <strong>and</strong> London:<br />

Sage Publications.<br />

Marsh, Alan <strong>and</strong> Max Kaase (1979): Background of Political Action, in: Samuel H.<br />

Barnes <strong>and</strong> Max Kaase et al., Political Action. Mass <strong>Participation</strong> in Five Western<br />

Democracies, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage, pp. 97-136.<br />

Marsh, Alan <strong>and</strong> Max Kaase (1979): Measuring Political Action, in: Samuel H. Barnes<br />

<strong>and</strong> Max Kaase et al., Political Action. Mass <strong>Participation</strong> in Five Western Democracies,<br />

Beverly Hills/London: Sage, pp. 57-96.<br />

Marx, Karl (1990 [1867]): Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, Volume 1 (Das<br />

Kapital. Kritik der politischen Ökonomie, B<strong>and</strong> 1), introduced by Ernest M<strong>and</strong>el,<br />

translated by Ben Fowkes, London/New York: Penguin (in association with New Left<br />

Review).<br />

Marx, Karl (1993 [1858]): Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy (Rough<br />

Draft) Grundrisse der Kritik der politischen Ökonomie (Rohentwurf), translated with a<br />

foreword by Martin Nicolaus, London/New York: Penguin (in association with New Left<br />

Review).<br />

Maslow, Abraham Harold (1987 [1954]): Motivation <strong>and</strong> Personality, New York:<br />

HarperCollins Publishers<br />

McAdam, Doug (1982): Political Process <strong>and</strong> the Development of Black Insurgency,<br />

1930-1970, Chicago: <strong>University</strong> of Chicago Press.<br />

McAdam, Doug (1988): Freedom Summer, New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

McAdam, Doug, Sidney Tarrow <strong>and</strong> Charles Tilly (2001): <strong>Dynamics</strong> of Contention,<br />

Cambridge: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

McCarthy, John D., Clark McPhail <strong>and</strong> Jackie Smith (1996): Images of protest.<br />

Dimensions of Selection Bias in Media Coverage of Washington Demonstrations, 1982<br />

<strong>and</strong> 1991, in: American Sociological Review, Vol. 61, pp. 478-499.<br />

214


McCarthy, John D., Clark McPhail, Jackie Smith <strong>and</strong> Louis J. Crishock (1998):<br />

Electronic <strong>and</strong> Print Media Representations of Washington, D.C. Demonstrations, 1982<br />

<strong>and</strong> 1991. A Demography of Description Bias, in: Dieter Rucht, Ruud Koopmans <strong>and</strong><br />

Friedhelm Neidhardt (eds.), Acts of Dissent. New Developments in the Study of Protest,<br />

Berlin: edition sigma, pp. 113-130.<br />

McKnight, D. Harrison, Larry L. Cummings <strong>and</strong> Norman L. Chervany (1996): Trust<br />

Formation in New Organizational Relationships, MISRC Working Paper Series,<br />

<strong>University</strong> of Minnesota:<br />

http://www.misrc.umn.edu/workingpapers/fullPapers/1996/9601_080197.pdf .<br />

McPhail, Clark <strong>and</strong> David Schweingruber (1998): Unpacking Protest Events. A<br />

Description Bias Analysis of Media Record with Systematic Direct Observations of<br />

Collective Action – the 1995 March for Life in Washington, D.C., in: Dieter Rucht, Ruud<br />

Koopmans <strong>and</strong> Friedhelm Neidhardt (eds.), Acts of Dissent. New Developments in the<br />

Study of Protest, Berlin: edition sigma, pp. 164-195.<br />

Meyer, David S. (2004): Protest <strong>and</strong> Political Opportunities, in: Annual Review of<br />

Sociology, Vol. 30, pp. 125-145.<br />

Meyer, David S. <strong>and</strong> Debra C. Minkoff (2004): Conceptualizing Political Opportunity,<br />

in: Social Forces, Vol. 82(4), pp. 1457-1492.<br />

Milbrath, Lester <strong>and</strong> M.L. Goel (1977): Political <strong>Participation</strong>. How <strong>and</strong> Why Do People<br />

Get Involved Into Politics? 2nd edition, New York: <strong>University</strong> Press of America.<br />

Mill, John Stuart (1975 [1861]: Considerations on Representative Government, in: John<br />

Stuart Mill, Three Essays, Oxford et al.: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Moore, Barrington (1993 [1963]): Social Origins of Dictatorship <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>. Lord<br />

<strong>and</strong> Peasant in the Making of the Modern World, Boston: Beacon Press.<br />

Munck, Gerardo L. <strong>and</strong> Jay Verkuilen (2002): Conceptualizing <strong>and</strong> Measuring<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong>. Evaluating Alternative Indices, in: Comparative Political Studies, Vol. 35(1),<br />

pp. 5-34.<br />

Newton, Kenneth (1999): Social Capital <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong> in Modern Europe, in: Jan W.<br />

van Deth et al. (ed.), Social Capital <strong>and</strong> European <strong>Democracy</strong>. A Comparative Analysis,<br />

London: Routledge, pp. 3-24.<br />

Newton, Kenneth (2001): Social Capital <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>, in: Bob Edwards, Michael W.<br />

Foley <strong>and</strong> Mario Diani (eds.), Beyond Tocqueville. Civil Society <strong>and</strong> the Social Capital<br />

Debate in Comparative Perspective, Hanover <strong>and</strong> London: <strong>University</strong> Press of New<br />

Engl<strong>and</strong>, pp. 225-234.<br />

215


Newton, Kenneth (2001): Trust, Social Capital, Civil Society, <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>, in:<br />

International Political Science Review, Vol. 22(2), pp. 201-214.<br />

Niedermayer, Oskar (1997): Vergleichende Umfrageforschung: Probleme und<br />

Perspektiven, in: Dirk Berg-Schlosser <strong>and</strong> Ferdin<strong>and</strong> Müller-Rommel (eds.),<br />

Vergleichende Politikwissenschaft. Ein einführendes Studienh<strong>and</strong>buch, 3. überarbeitete<br />

und ergänzte Auflage, Opladen: Leske + Budrich, pp. 89-102.<br />

Nohlen, Dieter (2002): Wahlrecht und Parteiensystem, 3. Auflage, Opladen: Leske +<br />

Budrich.<br />

Norris, Pippa (ed.) (1999a): Critical Citizens. Global Support for Democratic<br />

Governance, Oxford: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Norris, Pippa (1999b): Introduction. The Growth of Critical Citizens?, in: Pippa Norris<br />

(ed.), Critical Citizens. Global Support for Democratic Governance, Oxford: Oxford<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 1-27.<br />

Norris, Pippa (2002): Democratic Phoenix. Reinventing Political Activism, Cambridge:<br />

Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Norris, Pippa (2007): Political Activism: New Challenges, New Opportunities, in: Carles<br />

Boix <strong>and</strong> Susan C. Stokes (eds.), The Oxford H<strong>and</strong>book of Comparative Politics,<br />

Oxford/New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 628-649.<br />

Norris, Pippa, Stefaan Walgrave <strong>and</strong> Peter Van Aelst (2005): Who Demonstrates?<br />

Antistate Rebels, Conventional Participants, or Everyone?, in Comparative Politics, Vol.<br />

37(2), pp. 189-206.<br />

O’Donnell, Guillermo (1979): Modernization <strong>and</strong> Bureaucratic Authoritarianism. Studies<br />

in South American Politics, Berkeley, CA: <strong>University</strong> of California Press.<br />

Pados, Juan Sebastian Fern<strong>and</strong>ez <strong>and</strong> Antonio Jose Rojas Tejada (2003): Analysis of the<br />

Unconventional Political Action Scale: Results in Spain, in: Field Methods, Vol. 15(2),<br />

pp. 131-142.<br />

Parry, Geraint, George Moyser <strong>and</strong> Neil Day (1992): Political <strong>Participation</strong> <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> in America, Cambridge, UK: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Pateman, Carol (1970): <strong>Participation</strong> <strong>and</strong> Democratic Theory, Cambridge: Cambridge<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Paxton, Pamela (1999): Is Social Capital Declining in the United States? A Multiple<br />

Indicator Assessment, in: American Journal of Sociology, Vol. 105(1), pp. 88-127.<br />

216


Peters, B. Guy (1998): Comparative Politics. Theory <strong>and</strong> Methods, Houndmills et al.:<br />

Macmillan Press.<br />

Pevalin, David J. <strong>and</strong> David Rose (2002): Social Capital for Health. Investigating the<br />

Links Between Social Capital <strong>and</strong> Health Using the British Household Panel Survey,<br />

London: Health Development Agency.<br />

Pharr, Susan J. <strong>and</strong> Robert D. Putnam (eds.) (2000): Disaffected Democracies. What’s<br />

Troubling the Trilateral Countries? Princeton, NJ: Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Plummer, Janelle (2008): Water <strong>and</strong> Corruption. A Destructive Partnership, in:<br />

Transparency International: Global Corruption Report 2008. Corruption in the Water<br />

Sector, Cambridge et al.: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 3-15.<br />

Popper, Karl (2002 [1935]): The Logic of Scientific Discovery, London/New York:<br />

Routledge (first published in English in 1959).<br />

Popper, Karl (2002): The Open Society <strong>and</strong> Its Enemies. Volume One: The Spell of<br />

Plato, London: Routledge.<br />

Przeworski, Adam <strong>and</strong> Fern<strong>and</strong>o Limongi (1997): Modernization: Theories <strong>and</strong> Facts, in:<br />

World Politics, 49 (2), pp. 155-183.<br />

Przeworski, Adam <strong>and</strong> Henry Teune (1982 [1970]): The Logic of Comparative Social<br />

Inquiry, Malabar, Florida: Krieger Publishing Company.<br />

Przeworski, Adam, Michael Alvarez, José Antonio Cheibub <strong>and</strong> Fern<strong>and</strong>o Limongi<br />

(1996): What Makes Democracies Endure?, in: Journal of <strong>Democracy</strong>, 7, pp. 39-55.<br />

Putnam, Robert D. (1993): Making <strong>Democracy</strong> Work. Civic Traditions in Modern Italy,<br />

Princeton, NJ: Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Putnam, Robert D. (1995a): Bowling Alone. America’s Declining Social Capital, in:<br />

Journal of <strong>Democracy</strong>, Vol. 6, pp. 65-78.<br />

Putnam, Robert D. (1995b): Tuning In, Tuning Out. The Strange Disappearance of Social<br />

Capital in America. The 1995 Ithiel de Sola Pool Lecture, in: PS: Political Science <strong>and</strong><br />

Politics, Vol. 29, pp. 664-683.<br />

Putnam, Robert D. (2000): Bowling Alone. The Collapse <strong>and</strong> Revival of American<br />

Community, New York: Simon <strong>and</strong> Schuster.<br />

Putnam, Robert D. (ed.) (2002): Democracies in Flux. The Evolution of Social Capital in<br />

Contemporary Society, Oxford: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

217


Putnam, Robert D. <strong>and</strong> Kristin A. Goss (2002): Introduction, in: Robert D. Putnam (ed.),<br />

Democracies in Flux. The Evolution of Social Capital in Contemporary Society, Oxford:<br />

Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 3-20.<br />

Putnam, Robert D., Susan J. Pharr <strong>and</strong> Russell J. Dalton (2000): Introduction: What’s<br />

Troubling the Trilateral Democracies?, in: Susan J. Pharr <strong>and</strong> Robert D. Putnam (eds.),<br />

Disaffected Democracies. What’s Troubling the Trilateral Countries?, Princeton:<br />

Princeton <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 3-27.<br />

Rae, Douglas, Douglas Yates, Jennifer Hochschildt, Joseph Morone, <strong>and</strong> Carol Fessler<br />

(1981): Equalities, Cambridge: Harvard <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Robinson, John P., Phillip R. Shaver <strong>and</strong> Lawrence S. Wrightsman (eds.) (1999):<br />

Measures of Political Attitudes. Volume 2 of Measures of Social Psychological Attitudes,<br />

San Diego, CA, et al.: Academic Press.<br />

Rokeach, Milton (1960): The Open <strong>and</strong> Closed Mind, New York: Basic Books.<br />

Rokkan, Stein (1972): Vergleichende Politikwissenschaft. Die Entwicklung der interkulturellen,<br />

inter-gesellschaftlichen und inter-nationalen Forschung. Hauptströme der<br />

sozialwissenschaftlichen Forschung. Herausgegeben von der Unesco, Frankfurt a.M.:<br />

Ullstein.<br />

Rokkan, Stein (2000) Nation, Demokratie in Europa. Die Theorie Stein Rokkans aus<br />

seinen gesammelten Werken rekonstruiert und eingeleitet von Peter Flora,<br />

Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp.<br />

Roller, Edeltraud <strong>and</strong> Berhard Wessels (1996): Contexts of Political Protest in Western<br />

Democracies: Political Organization <strong>and</strong> Modernity, Discussion Paper, FS III 96-202,<br />

Berlin: Wissenschaftszentrum Berlin für Sozialforschung (WZB).<br />

Rootes, Christopher A. (1981): On the Future of Protest Politics in Western Democracies<br />

– A Critique of Barnes, Kaase et al., Political Action, in: European Journal of Political<br />

Research, 9, pp. 421-432.<br />

Rosenstone, Steven J. <strong>and</strong> John Mark Hansen (1993): Mobilization, <strong>Participation</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> in America, New York: Macmillan.<br />

Rossteutscher, Sigrid (1999): Associative <strong>Democracy</strong>. Citizens’ Involvement in a Post-<br />

Tocquevillean World. Paper Presented at the Annual Meeting of the ECPR Joint Sessions<br />

of Workshops, Mannheim, March 26-31, 1999.<br />

Rucht, Dieter (2001): Protest in der Bundesrepublik Deutschl<strong>and</strong>. Strukturen und<br />

Entwicklungen, Frankfurt a.M.: Campus Verlag.<br />

218


Rucht, Dieter <strong>and</strong> Thomas Ohlemacher (1992): Protest Event Data: Collection, Uses <strong>and</strong><br />

Perspectives, in: Mario Diani <strong>and</strong> Ron Eyerman (eds.), Studying Political Action, London<br />

et al.: Sage, pp. 76-106.<br />

Rucht, Dieter, Ruud Koopmans <strong>and</strong> Friedhelm Neidhardt (eds.) (1998): Acts of Dissent.<br />

New Developments in the Study of Protest, Berlin: edition sigma.<br />

Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, Evelyne Huber Stephens <strong>and</strong> John D. Stephens (1992):<br />

Capitalist Development <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>, Chicago, IL: <strong>University</strong> of Chicago.<br />

Russet, Bruce M., Hayward R. Jr. Alkner, Karl W. Deutsch <strong>and</strong> Harold D. Laswell<br />

(1964): World H<strong>and</strong>book of Political <strong>and</strong> Social Indicators (First Edition), New Haven,<br />

CT: Yale <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Rustow, Dankwart A. (1968): Modernization <strong>and</strong> Comparative Politics. Prospects in<br />

Research <strong>and</strong> Theory, in: Comparative Politics, 1 (October), pp. 37-51.<br />

Sänkiaho, Risto et al. (1990): People <strong>and</strong> Their Polities. Festschrift for Pertti Pesonen,<br />

Helsinki: Finnish Political Science Association.<br />

Sapiro, Virginia (2000): Economic Activity as Political Activity. Paper presented at the<br />

annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.<br />

Sartori, Giovanni (1976) (2005): Parties <strong>and</strong> Party Systems. A Framework for Analysis.<br />

With a New Preface by the Author <strong>and</strong> an Introduction by Peter Mair, Colchester: ECPR.<br />

Sartori, Giovanni (1987): The Theory of <strong>Democracy</strong> Revisited, Chatham, NJ: Chatham<br />

House Publishers.<br />

Sartori, Giovanni (1991): Comparing <strong>and</strong> Miscomparing, in: Journal of Theoretical<br />

Politics, 3, 243-257.<br />

Sartori, Giovanni (1994): Comparative Constitutional Engineering. An Inquiry into<br />

Structures, Incentives, <strong>and</strong> Outcomes, Houndsmills: Macmillan.<br />

Schattschneider, E.E. (1942): Party Government, New York: Rinehart.<br />

Schlozman, Kay Lehman, Sidney Verba <strong>and</strong> Henry E. Brady (1999): Civic <strong>Participation</strong><br />

<strong>and</strong> the Equality Problem, in: Theda Skocpol <strong>and</strong> Morris P. Fiorina (eds.), Civic<br />

Engagement in American America, Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press, pp.<br />

427-459.<br />

Schmidt, Manfred G. (1995): Wörterbuch zur Politik, Stuttgart: Alfred Kröner Verlag.<br />

Schmidt, Manfred G. (2000): Demokratietheorien. Eine Einführung. 3. überarbeitete und<br />

erweiterte Auflage, Opladen: Leske + Budrich.<br />

219


Schmidt, Manfred G. (2001): Political Modernization: Alternate Paths, in: International<br />

Encyclopedia of the Social <strong>and</strong> Behavioral Sciences, Elsevier Science Ltd., pp. 9961-<br />

9963.<br />

Schmitt, Hermann <strong>and</strong> Sören Holmberg (1995): Political Parties in Decline?, in: Hans-<br />

Dieter Klingemann <strong>and</strong> Dieter Fuchs (eds.), Citizens <strong>and</strong> the State. Beliefs in<br />

Government, Vol.1, Oxford/New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 95-133.<br />

Schumpeter, Joseph (1942/1950/1976): Capitalism, Socialism, <strong>and</strong> <strong>Democracy</strong>, 3rd<br />

edition, New York: Harper <strong>and</strong> Row.<br />

Shah, Dhavam V. et al. (2007): Political Consumerism. How Communication <strong>and</strong><br />

Consumption Orientations Drive “Lifestyle Politics”, in: Annals, AAPSS, Vol. 611, pp.<br />

217-235.<br />

Siegelman, Lee (2006): Top Twenty Commentaries: The American Political Science<br />

Review Citation Classics, in: American Political Science Review, Vol. 100, pp. 667-687.<br />

Silver, Brian D., Barbara A. Anderson <strong>and</strong> Paul R. Abramson (1986): Who Overreports<br />

Voting?, in: American Political Science Review, Vol. 80(2), pp. 613-624.<br />

Skocpol, Theda (1994 [1981]): Social Revolutions in the Modern World.<br />

Cambridge/New York: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Skocpol, Theda (2003): Diminished <strong>Democracy</strong>. From Membership to Management in<br />

American Civic Life, Norman: <strong>University</strong> Oklahoma Press.<br />

Skocpol, Theda (2004): Voice <strong>and</strong> Inequality: The Transformation of American Civic<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong>. APSA Presidential Address, in: Perspectives on Politics, Vol. 2(1), pp. 3-20.<br />

Smith, Mark K. (2001): Social Capital, in: The Encyclopedia of Informal Education.<br />

www.infed.org/biblio/social_capital.htm .<br />

Spaargaren, Gert <strong>and</strong> Bas van Vliert (2000): Lifestyle, Consumption <strong>and</strong> the<br />

Environment. The Ecological Modernization of Domestic Consumption, in:<br />

Environmental Politics, Vol. 9(1), pp. 50-77.<br />

Steenbergen, Marco R. <strong>and</strong> Bradford S. Jones (2002): Modeling Multilevel Data<br />

Structures, in: American Journal of Political Science, Vol. 46(1), pp. 218-237.<br />

Stevens, Stanley Smith (1946): On the Theory of Scales of Measurement, in: Science,<br />

Vol. 103, pp. 677-680<br />

220


Stolle, Dietlind (2001): Clubs <strong>and</strong> Congregations: The Benefits of Joining an<br />

Association, in: Karen S. Cook (ed.), Trust in Society. Volume II in the Russell Sage<br />

Foundation Series on Trust, New York: Russell Sage Foundation, pp. 202-244.<br />

Stolle, Dietlind <strong>and</strong> Marc Hooghe (2004): Review Article: Inaccurate, Exceptional, One-<br />

Sided or Irrelevant?, in: British Journal of Political Science, Vol. 35, pp. 149-167.<br />

Stolle, Dietlind <strong>and</strong> Marc Hooghe (2005): Shifting Inequalities? Patterns of Exclusion<br />

<strong>and</strong> Inclusion in Emerging Forms of Political <strong>Participation</strong>. Paper Prepared for<br />

Presentation at the 101st Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association,<br />

Washington, D.C, September 01-04, 2005.<br />

Stolle, Dietlind <strong>and</strong> Michele Micheletti (2003): The Gender Gap Reversed: Political<br />

Consumerism as a Women-Friendly Form of Civic <strong>and</strong> Political Engagement. An<br />

Exploratory Study in Canada, Belgium <strong>and</strong> Sweden. Paper prepared for the Gender <strong>and</strong><br />

Social Capital Conference, May 2-3, 2003, St. John’s College, <strong>University</strong> of Manitoba.<br />

Stolle, Dietlind <strong>and</strong> Michele Micheletti (2005): What Motivates Political Consumers?.<br />

First draft for the Special Issue on “The Underestimated Consumer-Power – Prospects for<br />

the New Consumer Movement” in “Forschungsjournal Neue Soziale Bewegungen”, No<br />

4, 2005.<br />

Stolle, Dietlind <strong>and</strong> Thomas Rochon (1998): Are All Associations Alike? Member<br />

Diversity, Associational Type <strong>and</strong> the Creation of Social Capital, in: American<br />

Behavioral Scientist, Vol. 42(1), pp. 47-65.<br />

Stolle, Dietlind, Marc Hooghe <strong>and</strong> Michele Micheletti (2003): Political Consumerism –<br />

A New Phenomenon of Political <strong>Participation</strong>? An Exploratory Study in Canada,<br />

Belgium <strong>and</strong> Sweden. Paper Presented at the ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops,<br />

Edinburgh, March 28 – April 02, 2003.<br />

Tarrow, Sidney (1989): <strong>Democracy</strong> <strong>and</strong> Disorder. Protest <strong>and</strong> Politics in Italy 1965-1975,<br />

New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Tarrow, Sidney (1998): Power in Movement: Social Movements <strong>and</strong> Contentious<br />

Politics, Cambridge: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Taylor, Charles Lewis <strong>and</strong> David A. Jodice (1983): World H<strong>and</strong>book of Political <strong>and</strong><br />

Social Indicators (Third Edition), Volume 2: Political Protest <strong>and</strong> Government Change,<br />

New Haven, CT: Yale <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Taylor, Charles Lewis <strong>and</strong> Michael C. Hudson (1972): World H<strong>and</strong>book of Political <strong>and</strong><br />

Social Indicators (Second Edition), New Haven, CT: Yale <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

221


Teorell, Jan, Sören Holmberg <strong>and</strong> Bo Rothenstein (2008): The Quality of Government<br />

Dataset, version 15 May/08, <strong>University</strong> of Gothenburg: The Quality of Government<br />

Institute. Website: http://www.qog.pol.gu.se .<br />

Tilly, Charles (1978): From Mobilization to Revolution, Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.<br />

Tilly, Charles (1986): The Contentious French, Cambridge, MA: Harvard <strong>University</strong><br />

Press.<br />

Tilly, Charles (1995): Popular Contention in Great Britain 1758-1834, Cambridge, MA:<br />

Harvard <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Tilly, Charles, Louise Tilly <strong>and</strong> Richard Tilly (1975): The Rebellious Century. 1830<br />

1930, Cambridge, MA: Harvard <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Tocqueville, Alexis de (2000 [1837/40]) <strong>Democracy</strong> in America. Translated, Edited, <strong>and</strong><br />

with an Introduction by Harvey C. Mansfield <strong>and</strong> Delba Winthrop. Chicago: <strong>University</strong><br />

of Chicago Press.<br />

Topf, Richard (1995): Beyond Electoral <strong>Participation</strong>, in: Hans-Dieter Klingemann <strong>and</strong><br />

Dieter Fuchs (eds.), Citizens <strong>and</strong> the State. Beliefs in Government, Vol.1, Oxford/New<br />

York: Oxford <strong>University</strong> Press, pp. 52-91.<br />

Tulving, Endel (1983): Elements of Episodic Memory, New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong><br />

Press.<br />

Uehlinger, Hans-Martin (1988): Politische Partizipation in der Bundesrepublik.<br />

Strukturen und Erklärungsmodelle [Political <strong>Participation</strong> in the Federal Republic.<br />

Structures <strong>and</strong> Models of Explanation], Opladen: Westdeutscher Verlag.<br />

Uslaner, Eric M. (2002): Volunteering <strong>and</strong> Social Capital. How Trust <strong>and</strong> Religion Shape<br />

Civic <strong>Participation</strong> in the United States, in: Paul Dekker <strong>and</strong> Eric M. Uslaner (ed.), Social<br />

Capital <strong>and</strong> <strong>Participation</strong> in Everyday Life, London: Routledge, pp. 104-117.<br />

Van Aelst, Peter <strong>and</strong> Stefaan Walgrave (2001): Who Is That (Wo)Men in the Street?<br />

From the Normalization of Protest to the Normalization of the Protester, in: European<br />

Journal of Political Research, 39, pp. 461-486.<br />

Van Deth, Jan W. (1990): Interest in Politics, in: M. Kent Jennings <strong>and</strong> Jan W. van Deth<br />

(eds.), Continuities in Political Action. A Longitudinal Study of Political Orientations in<br />

Three Western Democracies, Berlin <strong>and</strong> New York: Walter de Gruyter, pp. 275-312.<br />

Van Deth, Jan W. (1997): Introduction. Social Involvement <strong>and</strong> Democratic Politics, in:<br />

Jan W. van Deth (ed.), Private Groups <strong>and</strong> Public Life. Social <strong>Participation</strong>, Voluntary<br />

Associations <strong>and</strong> Political Involvement in Representative Democracies, London <strong>and</strong> New<br />

York: Routledge, pp. 1-23.<br />

222


Van Deth, Jan W. (1998a): Equivalence in Comparative Research, in: Jan W. van Deth<br />

(ed.), Comparative Research. The Problem of Equivalence, London/New York:<br />

Routledge, pp. 1-19.<br />

Van Deth, Jan W. (ed.) (1998b): Comparative Research. The Problem of Equivalence,<br />

London/New York: Routledge.<br />

Van Deth, Jan W. (2001a): Studying Political <strong>Participation</strong>: Towards a Broad Theory of<br />

Everything? Paper Prepared for Delivery at the Joint Sessions of Workshops, ECPR,<br />

Workshop “Electronic Demcocracy: Mobilization, Organization <strong>and</strong> <strong>Participation</strong> via<br />

new ICTs”, Grenoble, 6-11 April 2001.<br />

Van Deth, Jan W. (2001b): The Proof of the Pudding: Social Capital, <strong>Democracy</strong>, <strong>and</strong><br />

Citizenship. Modified paper prepared for delivery at the EURESCO Conference “Social<br />

Capital: Interdisciplinary Perspectives”, Exeter, UK, September 15-20, 2001.<br />

Van Deth, Jan W. (2004): Soziale Partizipation, in: Jan W. van Deth (ed.), Deutschl<strong>and</strong> in<br />

Europa. Ergebnisse des European Social Survey 2002-2003, Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für<br />

Sozialwissenschaften, pp. 295-315.<br />

Van Deth, Jan W. <strong>and</strong> Martin Elff (2000): Political Involvement <strong>and</strong> Apathy in Europe<br />

1973-1998. Working Paper MZES, Nr. 33, Mannheim.<br />

Vanhanen Tatu (1997): Prospects of <strong>Democracy</strong>. A Study of 172 Countries, London/New<br />

York: Routledge.<br />

Vanhanen Tatu (2000): A New Dataset for Measuring <strong>Democracy</strong>, 1810-1998, in:<br />

Journal of Peace Research, Vol. 37(2), pp. 251-265.<br />

Verba, Sidney (2001): Thoughts About Political Equality. What Is It? Why Do We Want<br />

It? Paper presented at the Inequality Summer Institute, Kennedy School of Government,<br />

Harvard <strong>University</strong>.<br />

Verba, Sidney (2003): Would the Dream of Political Equality Turn out to Be a<br />

Nightmare?, in: Perspectives on Politics 1(4), pp. 663-679.<br />

Verba, Sidney <strong>and</strong> Norman Nie (1972): <strong>Participation</strong> in America, New York: Harper <strong>and</strong><br />

Row.<br />

Verba, Sidney, Kay Lehman Schlozman <strong>and</strong> Henry E. Brady (1995a): Voice <strong>and</strong><br />

Equality. Civic Voluntarism in American Politics, Cambridge, Mass./London: Harvard<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

223


Verba, Sidney, Kay Lehman Schlozman <strong>and</strong> Henry E. Brady (1995b): Beyond SES. A<br />

Resource Model of Political <strong>Participation</strong>, in: American Political Science Review, Vol.<br />

89(2), pp. 271-294.<br />

Verba, Sidney, Norman Nie (1972): <strong>Participation</strong> in America, New York: Harper <strong>and</strong><br />

Row.<br />

Verba, Sidney, Norman Nie <strong>and</strong> J.O. Kim (1971): The Modes of Democratic<br />

<strong>Participation</strong>, Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Professional Papers in Comparative Politics.<br />

Verba, Sidney, Norman Nie <strong>and</strong> J.O. Kim (1978): <strong>Participation</strong> <strong>and</strong> Political Equality. A<br />

Seven-Nation Comparison, New York: Cambridge <strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

Warren, Mark (2001): <strong>Democracy</strong> <strong>and</strong> Association, Princeton: Princeton <strong>University</strong><br />

Press.<br />

Warwick, Donald P <strong>and</strong> Samuel Osherson (1973): Comparative Analysis in the Social<br />

Sciences, in: Donald P. Warwick <strong>and</strong> Samuel Osherson (eds.), Comparative Research<br />

Methods, Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 3-41.<br />

Wattenberg, Martin P. (2000): The Decline of Party Mobilization, in: Russell J. Dalton<br />

<strong>and</strong> Martin Wattenberg (eds.), Parties Without Partisans, New York: Oxford <strong>University</strong><br />

Press, pp. 64-76.<br />

Weldon, Steven A. (2006): The Institutional Context of Tolerance for Ethnic Minorities.<br />

A Comparative, Multilevel Analysis of Western Europe, in: American Journal of Political<br />

Science, Vol. 50(2), pp. 331-349.<br />

Welzel, Christian (2006): Individual Modernity, in: Russell J. Dalton <strong>and</strong> Hans-Dieter<br />

Klingemann (eds.), Oxford H<strong>and</strong>book of Political Behavior, Oxford: Oxford <strong>University</strong><br />

Press.<br />

Welzel, Christian, Ronald Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Franziska Deutsch (2005): Social Capital,<br />

Voluntary Associations, <strong>and</strong> Collective Action: Which Aspects of Social Capital Have<br />

the Greatest “Civic” Payoff?, in: Journal of Civil Society, Vol. 1(2), pp. 121-146.<br />

Welzel, Christian, Ronald Inglehart <strong>and</strong> Hans-Dieter Klingemann (2003): The Theory of<br />

Human Development: A Cross-Cultural Analysis, in: European Journal of Political<br />

Research, Vol. 42 (3), pp. 341-380.<br />

Wellman, Barry et al. (1996): Computer Networks as Social Networks: Collaborative<br />

Work, Telework, <strong>and</strong> Virtual Community, in: Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 22, pp.<br />

213-238.<br />

Wessels, Bernhard (1997): Organizing Capacity of Societies <strong>and</strong> Modernity, in: Jan W.<br />

van Deth (ed.), Private Groups <strong>and</strong> Public Life. Social <strong>Participation</strong>, Voluntary<br />

224


Associations <strong>and</strong> Political Involvement in Representative Democracies, London <strong>and</strong> New<br />

York: Routledge, pp. 198-219.<br />

Wollebaek, Dag <strong>and</strong> Per Selle (2002): Does <strong>Participation</strong> in Voluntary Associations<br />

Contribute to Social Capital? The Impact of Intensity, Scope, <strong>and</strong> Type, in: Nonprofit <strong>and</strong><br />

Voluntary Sector Quarterly, Vol. 31(1), pp. 32-61.<br />

Zaller, John R. (1992): The Nature <strong>and</strong> Origin of Mass Opinion, Cambridge: Cambridge<br />

<strong>University</strong> Press.<br />

225


Appendix A4-1: Criteria for an Electoral <strong>Democracy</strong> according to Freedom House:<br />

(1) Competitive, multiparty political system.<br />

(2) Universal adult suffrage for all citizens.<br />

(3) Regularly contested elections conducted in conditions of ballot secrecy,<br />

reasonable ballot security, <strong>and</strong> in the absence of massive voter fraud that yields<br />

results that are unrepresentative of the public will.<br />

(4) Significant public access of major political parties to the electorate through<br />

media <strong>and</strong> through generally open political campaigning.<br />

Source: www.freedomhouse.org<br />

Appendix A4-2: Ratings for Political Rights <strong>and</strong> Civil Liberties according to<br />

Freedom House<br />

For each of the following checklist questions, a separate score between 0 <strong>and</strong> 4 is given<br />

to a country, with 0 being the least prevailing rights <strong>and</strong> liberties <strong>and</strong> 4 being the most.<br />

For each scale, the points are added. The raw scores is then transformed into a scale<br />

according to the following scheme:<br />

Political Rights<br />

Civil Liberties<br />

Total Raw Scores PR Rating Total Raw Scores CL Rating<br />

36-40 1 53-60 1<br />

30-35 2 44-52 2<br />

24-29 3 35-43 3<br />

18-23 4 26-34 4<br />

12-17 5 17-25 5<br />

6-11 6 8-16 6<br />

0-5 7 0-7 7<br />

226


Checklist 1: Criteria for evaluating Political Rights according to Freedom House:<br />

A) Electoral Process<br />

1) Is the head of state <strong>and</strong>/or head of government or other chief authority elected through<br />

free <strong>and</strong> fair elections?<br />

2) Are the legislative representatives elected through free <strong>and</strong> fair elections?<br />

3) Are there fair electoral rules, equal campaigning opportunities, fair polling, <strong>and</strong><br />

honest tabulation of ballots?<br />

B) Political Pluralism <strong>and</strong> <strong>Participation</strong><br />

1) Do the people have the right to organize in different political parties or other political<br />

competitive groupings of their choice, <strong>and</strong> is the system open to the rise <strong>and</strong> fall of<br />

these competing parties or groupings?<br />

2) Is there a significant opposition vote, de facto opposition power, <strong>and</strong> a realistic<br />

possibility for the opposition to increase its support or gain power through elections?<br />

3) Are the people’s political choices free from domination by the military, foreign<br />

powers, totalitarian parties, religious hierarchies, economic oligarchies, or any other<br />

powerful group?<br />

4) Do cultural, ethnic, religious, <strong>and</strong> other minority groups have reasonable selfdetermination,<br />

self-government. autonomy, or participation through informal<br />

consensus in the decision-making process?<br />

C) Functioning of Government<br />

1) Do freely elected representatives determine the policies of the government?<br />

2) Is the government free from pervasive corruption?<br />

3) Is the government accountable to the electorate between elections, <strong>and</strong> does it operate<br />

with openness <strong>and</strong> transparency?<br />

227


Checklist 2: Criteria for evaluating Civil Liberties according to Freedom House:<br />

D) Freedom of Expression <strong>and</strong> Belief<br />

1) Are there free <strong>and</strong> independent media <strong>and</strong> other forms of cultural expression? (Note:<br />

in cases where the media are state-controlled but offers pluralistic points of view, the<br />

survey gives the system credit.)<br />

2) Are there free religious institutions, <strong>and</strong> is there free private <strong>and</strong> public religious<br />

expression?<br />

3) Is there academic freedom, <strong>and</strong> is the educational system free of extensive political<br />

indoctrination?<br />

4) Is there open <strong>and</strong> free private discussion?<br />

E) Associational <strong>and</strong> Organizational Rights<br />

1) Is there freedom of assembly, demonstrations, <strong>and</strong> open public discussion?<br />

2) Is there freedom of political or quasi-political organization? (Note: this includes<br />

political parties, civic organizations, ad hoc discussion groups, etc.)<br />

3) Are there free trade unions <strong>and</strong> peasant organizations or equivalents, <strong>and</strong> is there<br />

effective collective bargaining? Are there free professional <strong>and</strong> other private<br />

organizations?<br />

F) Rule of Law<br />

1) Is there an independent judiciary?<br />

2) Does the rule of law prevail in civil <strong>and</strong> criminal matters? Are police under direct<br />

civilian control?<br />

3) Is there protection from police terror, unjustified imprisonment, exile, or torture,<br />

whether by groups that support or oppose the system? Is there freedom from war <strong>and</strong><br />

insurgencies?<br />

4) Is the population treated equally under law?<br />

228


G) Personal Autonomy <strong>and</strong> Individual Rights<br />

1) Is there personal autonomy? Does the state control travel, choice of residence, or<br />

choice of employment? Is there freedom from indoctrination <strong>and</strong> excessive<br />

dependency on the state?<br />

2) Do citizens have the right to own property <strong>and</strong> establish private businesses? Is private<br />

business activity unduly influenced by government officials, the security forces, or<br />

organized crime?<br />

3) Are there personal social freedoms, including gender equality, choice of marriage<br />

partners, <strong>and</strong> size of family?<br />

4) Is there equality of opportunity <strong>and</strong> the absence of economic exploitation?<br />

229


Appendix A4-3: Overview: Political Rights <strong>and</strong> Civil Liberties according to Freedom House: 1981-2008<br />

1981 1982 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94<br />

PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL<br />

Albania 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 6 4 4 4 3 2 4<br />

Algeria 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 6 4 4 4 4 4 7 6 7 6<br />

Andorra 2 1<br />

Argentina 6 5 3 3 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 2 1 3 1 3 2 3 2 3<br />

Armenia 5 5 4 3 3 4<br />

Australia 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Austria 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Azerbaijan 5 5 5 5 6 6<br />

Bangladesh 3 4 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 4 5 5 2 3 2 3 2 4<br />

Belarus 4 4 4 3 5 4<br />

Belgium 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Bosnia Herzeg. 6 6 6 6<br />

Brazil 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 2 2 3 2 3 2 3 3 4<br />

Bulgaria 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 3 4 2 3 2 3 2 2<br />

Burkina Faso 6 5 6 5 6 5 7 5 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 5 5 4<br />

Canada 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Chile 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 4 4 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

China 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7<br />

Colombia 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 3 4 3 4 2 4 2 4 2 4<br />

Croatia 3 4 4 4 4 4<br />

Cyprus (Greek) 3 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Czech Republic 1 2<br />

Czechoslovakia 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 6 6 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Denmark 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Dom. Republic 2 3 1 2 1 2 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 3 3<br />

Egypt 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 4 4 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 5 5 6 6 6<br />

El Salvador 5 5 5 5 4 5 3 5 2 4 3 4 3 4 3 3 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 3 3 3<br />

Estonia 2 3 3 3 3 2<br />

Ethiopia 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 6 7 6 7 7 7 7 7 6 5 6 4 6 5 6 5<br />

230


1981 1982 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94<br />

PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

France 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

Georgia 6 5 4 5 5 5<br />

Germany 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

Germany East 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 6 6<br />

Germany West 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1<br />

Ghana 2 3 6 5 6 5 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 6 6 6 5 6 5 6 6 5 5 5 4<br />

Great Britain 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

Greece 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 3<br />

Guatemala 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 4 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 4 3 5 4 5 4 5<br />

Hungary 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 4 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

India 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 3 4 3 4 4 4<br />

Indonesia 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 5 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 7 6<br />

Iran 5 5 6 6 6 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 6 5 6 5 6 6 6 7<br />

Iraq 6 7 6 7 6 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 6 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2<br />

Israel 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 3<br />

Italy 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 3<br />

Japan 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 2 2<br />

Jordan 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 6 5 5 5 5 5 4 4 3 3 4 4<br />

Korea, South 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 4 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 2<br />

Latvia 2 3 3 3 3 3<br />

Lithuania 2 3 2 3 1 3<br />

Luxembourg 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Macedonia 3 4 3 3<br />

Malaysia 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 5 3 5 3 5 3 5 4 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 4 5<br />

Mali 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 4 2 3 2 3<br />

Malta 2 3 2 4 2 4 2 4 2 4 2 4 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

231


1981 1982 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993-94<br />

PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL<br />

Mexico 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 4<br />

Moldova 5 4 5 5 5 5<br />

Montenegro 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 6 5 6 5 6 6<br />

Morocco 4 4 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 4 4 4 5 5 6 5 5 5<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Nigeria 2 3 2 3 2 3 7 5 7 5 7 5 6 5 5 5 6 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 7 5<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

Norway 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Pakistan 7 5 7 5 7 5 7 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 3 3 3 3 4 4 4 5 4 5 3 5<br />

Peru 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 4 3 4 3 5 6 5 5 5<br />

Philippines 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 4 4 3 4 2 2 2 2 3 2 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 4<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 6 4 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 5 5 5 4 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Portugal 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Romania 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 6 5 5 5 4 4 4 4<br />

Russian Fed. 3 3 3 4 3 4<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 5<br />

Serbia 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 6 5 6 5 6 6<br />

Singapore 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 5 5<br />

Slovakia 3 4<br />

Slovenia 2 3 2 2 1 2<br />

South Africa 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 6 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4<br />

Soviet Union 6 7 6 7 6 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 6 6 5 6 5 5 4 4 4<br />

Spain 2 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2<br />

Sweden 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Taiwan 5 6 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 5 3 4 3 3 3 5 5 3 3 4 4<br />

Tanzania 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 6 4 3 4 3 5<br />

232


1981 1982 1983-84 1984-85 1985-86 1986-87 1987-88 1988-89 1989-90 1990-91 1991-92 1992-93 1993- 94<br />

PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL<br />

Trinidad & Tob. 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Turkey 6 5 5 5 5 5 3 5 3 5 3 4 2 4 2 4 3 3 2 4 2 4 2 4 4 4<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a 4 4 4 5 4 5 4 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 5 6 4 6 5 6 6 6 5 6 5<br />

Ukraine 3 3 3 3 4 4<br />

United States 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Uruguay 5 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 2<br />

Venezuela 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 3 1 3 1 3 3 3 3 3<br />

Vietnam 7 7 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 7 7 7 6 7 6 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7<br />

Zambia 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 2 3 2 3 3 4<br />

Table continued:<br />

1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998- 1999- 2000-01 2001-02 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

1999 2000<br />

PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL<br />

Albania 3 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 4 5 4 5 3 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3<br />

Algeria 7 7 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5<br />

Andorra 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Argentina 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 3 3 2 3 1 2 3 3 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Armenia 3 4 4 4 5 4 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4<br />

Australia 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Austria 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Azerbaijan 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 4 6 4 6 4 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5<br />

Bangladesh 2 4 3 4 2 4 2 4 2 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 4<br />

Belarus 4 4 5 5 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6<br />

Belgium 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Bosnia H. 6 6 6 6 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 3 3 3 4 3<br />

Brazil 2 4 2 4 2 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Bulgaria 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 1 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

Burkina Fa. 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 4 5 3 5 3 5 3<br />

Canada 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Chile 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

233


China 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6<br />

Colombia 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 3 3 3 3 3<br />

Croatia 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Cyprus (Gr) 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Czech Rep. 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Denmark 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Dom.Rep. 4 3 4 3 3 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Egypt 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 5 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5<br />

El Salvador 3 3 3 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3<br />

Estonia 3 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Ethiopia 6 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 4 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

France 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Georgia 5 5 4 5 4 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 3 3 3 3 4 4<br />

Germany 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Ghana 5 4 4 4 3 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

GBritain 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Greece 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

Guatemala 4 5 4 5 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 3 4<br />

Hungary 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

India 4 4 4 4 2 4 2 4 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3<br />

Indonesia 7 6 7 6 7 5 7 5 6 4 4 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 2 3 2 3 2 3<br />

Iran 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6<br />

Iraq 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 5 7 5 6 5 6 6 6 6<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Israel 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 2 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 3 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

Italy 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Japan 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

Jordan 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 4 4 4 4 5 5 6 5 5 5 6 5 5 4 5 4 5 4<br />

Korea,<br />

South<br />

2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2<br />

234


1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999- 2000-01 2001-02 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

2000<br />

PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL<br />

Latvia 3 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 2 1<br />

Lithuania 1 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Luxembourg 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Macedonia 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 3 3 3 3 4 3 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3<br />

Malaysia 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4<br />

Mali 2 4 2 3 2 2 3 3 3 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 3<br />

Malta 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Mexico 4 4 4 4 4 3 3 4 3 4 3 4 2 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 3<br />

Moldova 4 4 4 4 3 4 3 4 2 4 2 4 2 4 2 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4<br />

Montenegro 2 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 5 4 4 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 3 3 3<br />

Morocco 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

N. Zeal<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Nigeria 7 6 7 7 7 6 7 6 6 4 4 3 4 4 4 5 4 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4<br />

N. Irel<strong>and</strong> 1 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Norway 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Pakistan 3 5 3 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 7 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5<br />

Peru 5 4 5 4 4 3 5 4 5 4 5 4 3 3 1 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3<br />

Philippines 3 4 2 4 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 3 3 3 3 4 3<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Portugal 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Romania 4 3 4 3 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Russian Fed. 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 4 4 4 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a 7 7 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5 6 5<br />

Serbia 2 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 5 5 4 4 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2<br />

Singapore 5 5 5 5 4 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4<br />

Slovakia 2 3 2 3 2 4 2 4 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Slovenia 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

South Africa 2 3 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Spain 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Tanzania 6 6 5 5 5 5 5 5 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> 3 5 3 4 3 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 3 3 7 4 6 4<br />

235


1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998- 1999- 2000-01 2001- 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008<br />

1999 2000<br />

2002<br />

PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL PR CL<br />

Sweden 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Taiwan 3 3 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 2 1 2 1<br />

Trin. & Tob. 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 2 2 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 2 2 2 2 2<br />

Turkey 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 3 4 3 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a 5 5 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 5 6 5 6 5 6 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4<br />

Ukraine 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 3 2 3 2 3 2<br />

USA 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Uruguay 2 2 2 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1<br />

Venezuela 3 3 3 3 2 3 2 3 2 3 4 4 3 5 3 5 3 4 3 4 3 4 4 4 4 4 4 4<br />

Vietnam 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 6 7 5 7 5 7 5<br />

Zambia 3 4 3 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 4 3 4 3 4<br />

For the countries of the former Soviet Union <strong>and</strong> Czechoslovakia: Scores are given for the countries after independence. For scores before independence, please<br />

refer to the formerly unified states.<br />

For the countries of the former Yugoslavian Republic: Scores are given for the countries after independence. For scores before the country’s independence,<br />

please refer to the Serbia Montenegro.<br />

1 The Freedom House scores for Great Britain <strong>and</strong> Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> are based on the scores for the United Kingdom. The WVS/EVS conducts separate surveys in<br />

both part parts of the UK.<br />

2 The Freedom House scores for Montenegro <strong>and</strong> Serbia are based on the scores for Serbia <strong>and</strong> Montenegro. The WVS conducts separate surveys in both parts of<br />

the country.<br />

Freedom House Ratings:<br />

Free<br />

Partly Free<br />

Not Free<br />

236


Appendix A4-4:<br />

Internal Consistency <strong>and</strong> Inter-Item Correlations of the Additive<br />

Scale for Elite-Challenging <strong>Participation</strong><br />

Political<br />

Action<br />

(1974)<br />

WVS/<br />

EVS<br />

(1981)<br />

WVS/<br />

EVS<br />

(1990)<br />

WVS<br />

(1995)<br />

WVS/<br />

EVS<br />

(1999)<br />

WVS<br />

(2005)<br />

ESS<br />

(2002)<br />

ESS<br />

(2004)<br />

Signing petitions .31 .33 .36 .37 .40 .42 .41 .38<br />

Joining in boycott .34 .43 .43 .46 .45 .44 .32 .31<br />

Attending lawful .36 .47 .47 .46 .49 .44 .30 .26<br />

demonstrations<br />

Joining in unofficial .15 .34 .35 .36 .36 - - -<br />

strikes<br />

Occupying buildings .23 .30 .27 .24 .26 - - -<br />

Cronbach’s Alpha .46 .58 .59 .59 .61 .61 .52 .49<br />

Pooled samples. The samples of the Political Action Study <strong>and</strong> WVS/EVS are weighted with equal weight<br />

= 1.000. The ESS data were adjusted according to the population size.<br />

Data entries are corrected item-total correlations.<br />

Information about the countries included in the analysis can be obtained from Table 1.<br />

237


Appendix A5-1:<br />

Participated in Illegal Protests during the past 12 Months, in<br />

% (ESS 2002)<br />

Luxembourg<br />

France<br />

Belgium<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Italy<br />

Spain<br />

Greece<br />

Israel<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Austria<br />

Denmark<br />

Germany<br />

Slovenia<br />

Sweden<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Hungary<br />

UK<br />

Norway<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Portugal<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60<br />

Source: European Social Survey 2002, Round 1. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample<br />

(design weight).<br />

Question wording: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent things from going<br />

wrong. During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (...) Participated in illegal protest activities.”<br />

238


Appendix A5-2: Elite-Challenging Activities in 15 postindustrial societies, 1981-<br />

1999, in % (WVS/EVS)<br />

70<br />

Signing petition<br />

60<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Attending demonstration<br />

20<br />

Joining boycott<br />

10<br />

0<br />

1981 1990 1999<br />

Joining strike<br />

Occupying building<br />

Source: WVS/EVS 1981-1999.<br />

15 societies were included: West Germany, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Belgium, Sweden, Icel<strong>and</strong>, Denmark, Spain, France, Italy, Great<br />

Britain, Northern Irel<strong>and</strong>, Irel<strong>and</strong>, USA, Canada, Japan. The results are weighted with n=1000 for each samples society.<br />

Because Spain was represented with two samples both in the second <strong>and</strong> fourth wave, the results are only based on one<br />

1990 <strong>and</strong> the 1999 sample.<br />

239


Appendix A6-1: Factor Analysis: Conventional <strong>Participation</strong> <strong>and</strong> Voting (ESS 2002)<br />

Worked in political party or<br />

action group<br />

Contacted politician,<br />

government or local<br />

government official<br />

Worked in another<br />

organization or association<br />

Donated money to a<br />

political organization or<br />

group<br />

Conventional<br />

<strong>Participation</strong><br />

All Western Europe Eastern Europe<br />

Voting<br />

Conventional<br />

<strong>Participation</strong><br />

Voting<br />

Conventional<br />

<strong>Participation</strong><br />

Voting<br />

.73 .02 .74 .02 .69 -.08<br />

.65 -.14 .65 -.15 .64 -.15<br />

.64 -.18 .64 -.19 .66 -.05<br />

.62 .11 .63 .11 .60 .12<br />

Voted in last election -.05 .98 -.05 .97 -.05 .98<br />

Explained Variance 36% 19% 36% 20% 35% 19%<br />

K-M-O measure .69 .69 .68<br />

Bartlett’s test of sphericity 12931.268 *** 100058.179 *** 1947.495 ***<br />

Data Source: European Social Survey, 2002.<br />

Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design weight).<br />

Question formulation for conventional participation: “There are different ways to improve things in [country] or help prevent things from going wrong. During<br />

the last 12 months, have you done any of the following?”<br />

Question formulation for voting: “Some people don’t vote nowadays for one reason or another. Did you vote in the last [country] national election in<br />

[month/year]?” Respondents who have not been eligible to vote have been excluded from analysis.<br />

240


Appendix A6-2: Individual-Level Correlation between Elite-Challenging<br />

Activities <strong>and</strong> Forms of Conventional <strong>Participation</strong><br />

Elite-<br />

Challenging<br />

Activities <strong>and</strong>...<br />

Contacted<br />

politician<br />

Worked in a<br />

party<br />

Donated<br />

money<br />

Worked in<br />

another<br />

organization<br />

Austria .18 *** .13 *** .22 *** .22 ***<br />

Belgium .16 *** .15 *** .16 *** .23 ***<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> .21 *** .13 *** .23 *** .21 ***<br />

Czech Republic .18 *** .10 *** .18 *** .18 ***<br />

Germany .18 *** .11 *** .20 *** .22 ***<br />

East .23 *** .13 *** .14 *** .24 ***<br />

West .16 *** .10 *** .22 *** .22 ***<br />

Denmark .14 *** .09 *** .14 *** .14 ***<br />

Spain .29 *** .28 *** .28 *** .41 ***<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .16 *** .02 .09 *** .15 ***<br />

UK .19 *** .12 *** .17 *** .18 ***<br />

Greece .26 *** .18 *** .25 *** .31 ***<br />

Hungary .21 *** .18 *** .28 *** .24 ***<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .21 *** .17 *** .19 *** .27 ***<br />

Israel .19 *** .18 *** .20 *** .23 ***<br />

Italy .28 *** .27 *** .22 *** .31 ***<br />

Luxembourg .19 *** .13 *** .22 *** .24 ***<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .21 *** .13 *** .20 *** .21 ***<br />

Norway .16 *** .14 *** .15 *** .21 ***<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .23 *** .16 *** .29 *** .19 ***<br />

Portugal .32 *** .37 *** .33 *** .33 ***<br />

Sweden .14 *** .10 *** .11 *** .18 ***<br />

Slovenia .16 *** .13 *** .19 *** .12 ***<br />

Western Europe .22 *** .17 *** .22 *** .26 ***<br />

Eastern Europe .21 *** .13 *** .19 *** .28 ***<br />

Data Source: European Social Survey, 2002.<br />

Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design weight).<br />

241


Appendix A6-3: Factor Analysis: Unpaid Work in Various Voluntary Associations (WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

Factor I:<br />

Citizen action groups<br />

Factor II:<br />

Interest organizations<br />

Labor unions .03 .73<br />

Professional associations .19 .56<br />

Political parties .11 .64<br />

Social welfare service organizations .50 .06<br />

Human rights organizations .64 .04<br />

Youth work organizations .40 .16<br />

Local community action groups .55 .18<br />

Women’s groups .43 .08<br />

Peace movement .61 .06<br />

Environment, conservation, animal rights .59 .10<br />

Explained variance 24% 11%<br />

KMO .805<br />

Bartlett’s test of sphericity 33064.449 ***<br />

Data Source: World Values Survey/European Values Survey 1999-2001.<br />

Societies included: Albania, Argentina, Austria, Belgium, Bosnia <strong>and</strong> Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Canada, Chile, Croatia, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia,<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong>, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Icel<strong>and</strong>, India, Irel<strong>and</strong>, Italy, Japan, Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Malta, Mexico, Republic of Moldova,<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Peru, Philippines, Pol<strong>and</strong>, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Slovakia, Slovenia, South Africa, Spain, Sweden, Ug<strong>and</strong>a, Ukraine, Republic of Macedonia,<br />

Great Britain, Northern Irel<strong>and</strong>, USA, Serbia <strong>and</strong> Montenegro.<br />

Data are weighted n=1.000.<br />

Question formulation: “Please look carefully at the following list of voluntary organizations <strong>and</strong> activities <strong>and</strong> say for which, if any, are you currently doing<br />

unpaid voluntary work?”<br />

242


Appendix A6-4: Factor Analysis: Unpaid Work in Various Voluntary Associations (WVS/EVS)<br />

FI:<br />

Interest<br />

organizations<br />

1981 1990 1999<br />

FII:<br />

Citizen<br />

action groups<br />

FI:<br />

Interest<br />

organizations<br />

FII:<br />

Citizen<br />

action groups<br />

FI:<br />

Interest<br />

organizations<br />

FII:<br />

Citizen<br />

action groups<br />

Political parties .61 .10 .63 .17 .59 .15<br />

Labor unions .69 -.08 .74 -.03 .78 -.12<br />

Professional associations .61 .05 .63 .11 .56 .24<br />

Social welfare service organizations .06 .70 -.06 .73 .09 .62<br />

Human rights organizations .41 .34 .13 .64 .04 .67<br />

Youth work organizations -.01 .71 .16 .56 .11 .60<br />

Explained variance 25% 17% 27% 18% 26% 17%<br />

KMO .639 .657 .651<br />

Bartlett’s test of sphericity 1926.186 *** 3166.438 *** 2739.591 ***<br />

Data Source: World Values Survey/European Values Survey.<br />

Societies included: Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finl<strong>and</strong>, France, West Germany, Icel<strong>and</strong>, Irel<strong>and</strong>, Italy, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Spain, Sweden, Great Britain, Northern<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong>, USA.<br />

Data are weighted n = 1.000.<br />

243


Appendix A7-1: Social activities in % (ESS 2002)<br />

Sports club or club for outdoor activities<br />

Organization for cultural or hobby<br />

activities<br />

Trade union<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Austria 26,4 13,3 3,1 17,5 13,4 3,2 21,5 3,2 0,5<br />

Belgium 28,9 22,7 8,1 22,3 18,9 6,6 27,6 4,8 0,9<br />

Germany 31,7 20,5 11,1 16,5 14,1 7,3 14,0 3,3 1,4<br />

Denmark 36,1 23,7 13,1 25,8 17,9 7,2 64,5 10,6 2,0<br />

Spain 12,4 10,2 1,3 11,0 7,5 3,3 5,5 1,8 0,5<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 22,4 12,4 4,0 13,4 10,2 2,0 45,9 3,5 0,4<br />

UK 27,4 22,5 6,2 16,1 16,0 4,8 15,7 2,7 0,5<br />

Greece 4,3 2,7 1,0 5,7 3,3 1,7 5,3 2,4 0,8<br />

Hungary 5,4 6,1 2,1 4,5 5,8 2,6 6,0 2,6 0,8<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 33,9 17,7 5,6 18,4 10,5 3,2 19,0 3,5 0,8<br />

Israel 16,9 10,5 0,7 13,1 10,0 1,3 14,1 2,8 0,5<br />

Italy 8,4 9,5 0,9 7,2 6,1 0,7 8,8 4,7 0,3<br />

Luxembourg 25,5 12,6 5,4 21,3 10,0 4,9 22,2 2,6 0,8<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 46,2 25,1 13,4 19,0 11,1 6,3 21,6 2,3 0,7<br />

Norway 32,0 20,6 19,9 22,0 17,0 12,5 47,3 9,6 5,2<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 4,2 2,2 1,0 3,3 2,8 1,3 6,1 1,6 0,5<br />

Portugal 8,3 6,4 1,4 3,6 3,1 0,8 5,2 1,4 0,3<br />

Sweden 38,5 23,3 17,0 24,6 16,4 9,5 55,6 6,9 2,1<br />

Slovenia 16,1 10,2 7,6 8,1 5,1 4,9 19,3 3,0 1,6<br />

No results for Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Czech Republic.<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design weight)<br />

Question: “For each of the voluntary organizations I will now mention, please use this card to tell me whether any of these things apply to you now or in the last<br />

12 months, <strong>and</strong>, if so, which.” Answers included: “Member”, “Participated”, <strong>and</strong> “Voluntary Work”.<br />

244


Continued (1)…<br />

Social activities in % (ESS 2002)<br />

Business, professional, or farmers’<br />

organization<br />

Consumer or automobile organization<br />

Organization for humanitarian aid,<br />

human rights, minorities, or immigrants<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Austria 9,8 3,3 0,6 32,5 2,6 0,1 8,3 4,5 1,5<br />

Belgium 9,0 4,7 2,1 9,2 1,4 0,7 6,5 4,4 2,9<br />

Germany 8,6 3,4 1,4 28,1 1,1 0,3 5,8 2,9 2,0<br />

Denmark 14,3 5,8 1,6 17,5 1,0 0,3 11,4 2,7 3,4<br />

Spain 4,7 1,9 0,1 3,7 1,4 0,0 4,0 4,0 1,4<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 11,8 3,1 0,6 4,6 0,9 0,1 3,8 2,6 1,8<br />

UK 13,1 5,4 1,4 32,2 2,4 0,2 3,5 2,9 2,1<br />

Greece 5,5 2,2 0,7 0,4 0,3 0,1 1,0 0,7 0,7<br />

Hungary 3,3 3,1 1,1 2,8 0,7 0,1 0,7 0,8 0,8<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 15,6 5,6 1,4 8,9 1,2 0,2 4,7 3,4 1,6<br />

Israel 7,7 1,3 0,3 24,5 1,6 0,1 2,8 2,1 1,2<br />

Italy 9,1 2,9 0,2 6,3 0,9 0,0 4,4 2,1 1,1<br />

Luxembourg 11,4 2,6 1,4 45,8 0,3 0,0 9,3 2,2 1,7<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 12,8 5,0 1,2 31,6 1,9 0,4 7,9 1,4 2,8<br />

Norway 14,7 4,8 1,8 33,1 1,2 0,6 16,9 3,3 3,5<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 1,1 0,9 0,5 0,4 0,3 0,1 0,5 0,8 0,4<br />

Portugal 3,0 0,7 0,4 1,5 0,5 0,1 1,9 1,8 0,4<br />

Sweden 8,6 3,8 1,8 37,3 1,9 0,8 13,5 4,1 3,9<br />

Slovenia 7,6 2,9 2,0 8,8 0,9 0,5 5,4 1,9 2,1<br />

No results for Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Czech Republic.<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design weight)<br />

Question: “For each of the voluntary organizations I will now mention, please use this card to tell me whether any of these things apply to you now or in the last<br />

12 months, <strong>and</strong>, if so, which.” Answers included: “Member”, “Participated”, <strong>and</strong> “Voluntary Work”.<br />

245


Continued (2)…<br />

Social activities in % (ESS 2002)<br />

Organization for environmental<br />

protection, peace or animal rights<br />

Religious or church organization<br />

Political party<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Austria 13,1 5,5 1,0 31,7 9,3 3,1 11,4 5,2 2,2<br />

Belgium 7,7 4,5 2,1 6,7 5,4 2,7 6,4 3,2 2,0<br />

Germany 6,2 3,5 1,6 18,9 9,0 5,2 3,3 3,5 2,1<br />

Denmark 12,4 1,9 1,0 26,7 7,6 2,3 6,2 2,6 1,3<br />

Spain 1,8 2,1 0,3 6,0 4,4 1,3 2,8 1,8 0,8<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 2,2 2,1 0,6 24,8 7,1 2,4 6,2 1,7 0,5<br />

UK 5,9 3,1 1,4 13,5 12,3 5,8 2,7 0,8 0,5<br />

Greece 1,4 0,8 0,3 1,4 0,7 0,5 4,0 1,9 1,2<br />

Hungary 0,4 1,1 0,5 5,9 4,6 1,9 1,5 1,4 0,8<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 4,3 3,2 1,1 24,8 11,2 4,7 3,8 1,5 1,2<br />

Israel 3,5 2,2 0,9 5,4 2,2 0,7 8,4 1,6 0,6<br />

Italy 2,8 1,8 0,8 5,0 3,5 1,3 3,2 1,7 0,5<br />

Luxembourg 14,2 1,9 1,1 4,9 2,0 1,1 6,3 1,2 0,6<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 20,1 1,9 1,0 26,2 10,1 6,8 4,6 1,7 0,9<br />

Norway 5,0 1,1 0,6 15,2 7,3 6,1 9,2 3,5 2,4<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 1,0 0,7 0,4 3,0 2,2 0,9 1,7 0,7 0,3<br />

Portugal 1,0 1,5 0,7 5,5 7,9 1,6 4,0 1,9 0,7<br />

Sweden 6,9 1,7 1,1 15,2 6,8 4,3 8,4 3,5 2,1<br />

Slovenia 1,2 0,5 0,7 8,1 1,6 2,7 4,0 1,8 1,4<br />

No results for Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Czech Republic.<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design weight)<br />

Question: “For each of the voluntary organizations I will now mention, please use this card to tell me whether any of these things apply to you now or in the last<br />

12 months, <strong>and</strong>, if so, which.” Answers included: “Member”, “Participated”, <strong>and</strong> “Voluntary Work”.<br />

246


Continued (3)…<br />

Social activities in % (ESS 2002)<br />

Organization for science, education, or teacher<br />

<strong>and</strong> parents<br />

Social club, club for the young, the<br />

retired/elderly, women, of friendly societies<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Member Participated Voluntary<br />

work<br />

Austria 10,3 5,2 2,4 18,7 6,0 2,7<br />

Belgium 8,3 7,5 3,3 19,5 15,9 7,7<br />

Germany 6,0 4,6 2,8 13,3 10,2 4,6<br />

Denmark 7,3 3,5 1,3 17,8 9,3 3,7<br />

Spain 7,5 3,9 1,3 7,0 5,4 1,4<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 4,9 4,8 1,0 8,6 3,7 1,1<br />

UK 6,6 7,4 3,9 15,9 11,4 4,4<br />

Greece 4,0 1,6 0,8 3,2 1,9 1,0<br />

Hungary 3,1 2,6 1,4 5,3 4,6 1,0<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 7,7 4,3 2,1 15,7 8,0 4,5<br />

Israel 8,8 5,0 0,8 10,5 6,5 1,8<br />

Italy 2,2 1,2 0,2 4,6 2,2 0,5<br />

Luxembourg 11,0 2,8 1,6 16,9 5,1 3,0<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 9,7 5,0 3,9 9,5 4,9 3,5<br />

Norway 8,2 5,0 4,5 22,4 13,3 8,9<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 1,8 1,3 0,5 2,0 1,5 0,4<br />

Portugal 1,3 1,8 0,3 4,6 2,2 0,2<br />

Sweden 10,9 5,6 3,2 19,3 10,9 6,0<br />

Slovenia 5,2 2,0 0,8 0 4,9 3,6<br />

No results for Switzerl<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> the Czech Republic.<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design weight).<br />

Question: “For each of the voluntary organizations I will now mention, please use this card to tell me whether any of these things apply to you now or in the last<br />

12 months, <strong>and</strong>, if so, which.” Answers included: “Member”, “Participated”, <strong>and</strong> “Voluntary Work”.<br />

247


Appendix A7-2: General Activity Level in European Societies, in % (ESS 2002)<br />

Member<br />

in any association<br />

Active member<br />

in any association<br />

Activity<br />

in any association<br />

Austria 75,2 17,5 37,7<br />

Belgium 71,2 28,1 51,8<br />

Germany 71,1 33,4 46,0<br />

Denmark 92,0 45,8 51,7<br />

Spain 36,3 12,0 26,2<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 76,4 4,8 41,0<br />

UK 70,0 35,8 50,6<br />

Greece 24,8 11,4 13,4<br />

Hungary 27,1 10,7 20,8<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 68,1 21,5 38,0<br />

Israel 55,0 5,1 28,8<br />

Italy 34,9 0,7 24,8<br />

Luxembourg 77,6 17,5 31,1<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 83,8 35,5 48,6<br />

Norway 84,0 41,4 51,7<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 20,7 5,9 11,8<br />

Portugal 28,9 8,9 17,8<br />

Sweden 90,2 42,5 51,4<br />

Slovenia 52,3 16,9 31,2<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample<br />

(design weight).<br />

Associations included: sports club, cultural/hobby organization, trade union, business/professional/farmer<br />

association, consumer/automobile organization, humanitarian organization, environmental/peace/animal<br />

organization, religious/church organization, political party, science/education/teacher organization, social<br />

club.<br />

Active member in any association: Members in any association who participated or did voluntary work.<br />

Activity in any association: People who participated or did voluntary work, independently from<br />

membership in any association.<br />

248


Appendix A7-3: Social Trust in European Societies, in % (ESS 2002)<br />

Low trust level<br />

Medium trust<br />

level<br />

High trust level<br />

Mean trust level (0-20)<br />

Mean<br />

Std. Dev.<br />

Austria 15,7 55,3 27,1 10,75 4.297<br />

Belgium 16,3 57,9 24,6 10,43 3.943<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> 7,4 55,9 36,4 11,84 3.606<br />

Czech Republic 24,0 55,3 17,5 9,44 4.183<br />

Germany 14,9 63,5 21,3 10,44 3.781<br />

Denmark 2,5 31,6 64,9 14,32 3.341<br />

Spain 19,0 59,0 20,3 10,11 4.015<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> 4,0 40,0 55,7 13,34 3.326<br />

UK 14,1 62,8 22,7 10,61 3.724<br />

Greece 45,5 45,0 8,7 7,33 4.389<br />

Hungary 28,5 56,9 12,9 8,72 4.242<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 13,5 50,9 34,5 11,47 4.193<br />

Israel 22,4 48,7 27,2 10,26 4.621<br />

Italy 25,8 59,4 13,7 9,11 4.150<br />

Luxembourg 15,1 56,7 25,5 10,67 4.131<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s 8,0 54,9 36,7 11,90 3.499<br />

Norway 3,2 38,1 58,5 13,65 3.351<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> 32,1 56,7 8,3 8,24 4.023<br />

Portugal 22,4 61,4 15,4 9,42 3.992<br />

Sweden 6,3 43,4 49,4 12,76 3.634<br />

Slovenia 32,1 52,1 14,4 8,67 4.424<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample<br />

(design weight).<br />

Question formulation:<br />

(1) “Using this card, generally speaking, would you say that most people can be trusted, or that you can’t<br />

be too careful in dealing with people? Please tell me on a score of 0 to 10, where 0 means you can’t be<br />

too careful <strong>and</strong> 10 means that most people can be trusted.”<br />

(2) “Using this card, do you think that most people would try to take advantage of you if they got the<br />

chance, or would they try to be fair?” (0=Most people try to take advantage of me; 10= Most people try<br />

to be fair).<br />

Based on the two items, an additive scale was created:<br />

Low trust level: Score 0 to 6 on the additive scale.<br />

Medium trust level: Score 7 to 13 on the additive scale.<br />

High trust level: Score 14 to 20 on the additive scale.<br />

249


Appendix A7-4:Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong> High Trust Levels, in % (ESS 2002)<br />

70<br />

Denmark<br />

60<br />

Norway<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong><br />

High trust level, in %<br />

50<br />

40<br />

30<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong><br />

Austria<br />

Israel<br />

Sweden<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong><br />

Luxembourg<br />

20<br />

10<br />

Portugal<br />

Slovenia<br />

Italy<br />

Hungary<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong><br />

Greece<br />

Belgium<br />

Spain<br />

Czech Republic<br />

UK<br />

Germany<br />

0<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. Data are weighted to correct for a sampling bias within each sample (design<br />

weight). R = .75 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: Percentage of respondents who “Have done” any of the following activities in the past 12<br />

month: Signed petition, taken part in a lawful demonstration, boycotted certain products, or deliberately bought certain<br />

products for political, ethical or environmental reasons.<br />

High trust level: Percentage of respondents who show high trust levels (scoring 14 to 20 on an additive scale raging from<br />

0 to 20).<br />

250


Appendix A7-5:<br />

Stepwise Multi-Level Model (Hierarchical Generalized Linear Model) of Social Capital <strong>and</strong> Elite-<br />

Challenging Activities<br />

Dependent variable: <strong>Participation</strong> in Elite-Challenging Activities (dichotomous, individual-level measure)<br />

Part 1:<br />

Individual-level predictors only<br />

Model 1a:<br />

R<strong>and</strong>om intercept<br />

only (“null model”)<br />

Model 1b:<br />

Intercept as outcome<br />

Model 1c:<br />

Slope as outcome<br />

Model 1d:<br />

R<strong>and</strong>om intercept,<br />

r<strong>and</strong>om slope<br />

Intercept 0.625* (-2.387) 0.423** (-3.832) 0.525*** (-16.604) 0.439*** (-4.344)<br />

Individual-level effects (slopes):<br />

Membership in voluntary association<br />

Embeddedness in informal networks<br />

Trust<br />

Control Factors<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

Education<br />

2.014*** (24.109)<br />

1.163*** (11.534)<br />

1.028*** (8.599)<br />

1.239*** (8.699)<br />

0.990*** (-14.427)<br />

1.396*** (36.082)<br />

1.985*** (14.763)<br />

1.143*** (8.323)<br />

1.027*** (7.133)<br />

1.085 (0.584)<br />

0.990*** (-8.528)<br />

1.400*** (19.288)<br />

2.020*** (14.686)<br />

1.158*** (8.905)<br />

1.028*** (7.463)<br />

1.200** (3.510)<br />

0.990*** (-9.936)<br />

1.405*** (19.377)<br />

Remaining within-society variance:<br />

Intercept (Contribution to variance)<br />

Membership in voluntary association<br />

Embeddedness in informal networks<br />

Trust<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

Education<br />

0.7331*** 0.9284*** (-26.6%)<br />

0.0236**<br />

0.0017<br />

0.0001<br />

0.3577***<br />

0.0000***<br />

0.0040***<br />

0.6486*** (11.5%)<br />

0.0262***<br />

0.0018<br />

0.0001<br />

0.0389***<br />

0.0000**<br />

0.0041***<br />

251


Continued (1)….<br />

Part 2:<br />

Individual- <strong>and</strong> societal-level predictors<br />

Model 1d:<br />

R<strong>and</strong>om intercept,<br />

r<strong>and</strong>om slope<br />

Model 2:<br />

Societal-level effects on<br />

intercept<br />

Model 3:<br />

Full model with<br />

interaction effects<br />

Alternative Model 3:<br />

Full model with<br />

interaction effects<br />

Intercept 0.439*** (-4.344) 0.029** (-3.670) 0.061** (-3.321) 0.100* (-2.426)<br />

Individual-level effects (slopes):<br />

Membership in voluntary association<br />

Embeddedness in informal networks<br />

Trust<br />

2.020*** (14.686)<br />

1.158*** (8.905)<br />

1.028*** (7.463)<br />

2.014*** (24.108)<br />

1.163*** (11.536)<br />

1.028*** (8.601)<br />

5.104** (4.083)<br />

0.881 (-0.753)<br />

1.035 (0.832)<br />

5.557** (4.133)<br />

0.845 (-0.951)<br />

1.040 (0.950)<br />

Control Factors<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

Education<br />

Societal-level effects (intercepts):<br />

Membership level<br />

Level of informal networks<br />

Trust level<br />

Cross-level interaction effects (slopes):<br />

Individual-level membership in voluntary<br />

associations<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

Individual-level embeddedness in informal<br />

networks<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

Individual-level trust<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

1.200** (3.510)<br />

0.990*** (-9.936)<br />

1.405*** (19.377)<br />

1.239*** (8.700)<br />

0.990*** (-14.433)<br />

1.396*** (36.088)<br />

30.251** (4.003)<br />

0.963 (-0.202)<br />

1.061 (0.542)<br />

1.209** (3.712)<br />

0.990*** (-8.834)<br />

1.405*** (19.187)<br />

19.603** (3,994)<br />

1.0334 (0.201)<br />

1.016 (0.168)<br />

0.437* (-2.304)<br />

1.194* (2.239)<br />

0.959 (-0.922)<br />

1.062 (0.390)<br />

0.931 (-2.015)<br />

1.023 (1.228)<br />

0.972 (-0.779)<br />

1.002 (0.269)<br />

1.001 (0.225)<br />

0.532 (-1.289)<br />

0.997 (-0.238)<br />

1.368 (1.684)<br />

20.393** (3.557)<br />

1.084 (0.432)<br />

0.969 (-0.289)<br />

0.567 (-1.527)<br />

1.173 (1.949)<br />

0.937 (-1.367)<br />

1.165 (0.939)<br />

0.924* (-2.147)<br />

1.022 (1.092)<br />

0.977 (-0.638)<br />

1.002 (0.248)<br />

1.000 (0.063)<br />

252


Continued (2)….<br />

Gender<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

Age<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

Education<br />

* Societal membership level<br />

* Level of informal networks<br />

* Trust level<br />

Remaining between-society variance:<br />

Intercept (Contribution to variance)<br />

Membership in voluntary association<br />

Informal networks<br />

Trust<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

Education<br />

0.6486***<br />

0.0262***<br />

0.0018<br />

0.0001<br />

0.0389***<br />

0.0000**<br />

0.0041***<br />

0.1656*** (74.5%) 0.1323*** (79.6%)<br />

0.0146 (44.3%)<br />

0.0021 (-16.7%)<br />

0.0001 (0%)<br />

0.0369*** (5.1%)<br />

0.0000** (0%)<br />

0.0042*** (-2.4%)<br />

1.429 (0.813)<br />

0.919 (-0.868)<br />

1.058 (1.020)<br />

1.016 (1.561)<br />

0.998 (-0.974)<br />

0.998 (-1.268)<br />

0.764 (-1.667)<br />

1.014 (0.369)<br />

1.018 (0.842)<br />

0.1298*** (80,0%)<br />

0.0139 (47.0%)<br />

0.0020 (-11.1%)<br />

0.0001 (0%)<br />

0.0302*** (22.4%)<br />

0.0000** (0%)<br />

0.0042*** (-2.4%)<br />

Source: European Social Survey, 2002. N (individual level) = 35.303. N (societal level) = 19.<br />

Data entries are odds ratios with T-values in parentheses. Hierarchical generalized linear model calculated with HLM 6.03.<br />

Significance level: * p ≤ .05, ** p ≤ .01, *** p = .00<br />

Individual-level variables: Membership in any voluntary association (0/1), Embeddedness in informal networks (factor scores, see Table 1), Trust (scale 0 to 20).<br />

Societal-level variables: Level of Membership in voluntary associations (members in % in a society), Level of informal networks (average factor score, see Table<br />

1), Trust level (average societal score on trust scale 0 to 20).<br />

253


Appendix A8-1:<br />

Individual-Level Correlations: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Resources, pooled WVS/EVS 2000-05<br />

Gender<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Age<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Age sq.<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Education<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Income<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

Serbia -.05 (92) -.10 *** (92) -.11 *** (92) .22 *** (92) .03 (90)<br />

Bulgaria -.08 ** (82) -.03 (82) -.05 (82) .14 *** (82) .18 *** (78)<br />

Montenegro -.17 *** (81) -.02 (81) -.03 (81) .15 *** (81) .02 (64)<br />

Bosnia -.06 * (93) .04 (93) .03 (93) .09 ** (93) .12 *** (92)<br />

Romania -.08 ** (92) .01 (92) .00 (92) .17 *** (90) .17 *** (84)<br />

Albania -.19 *** (62) -.03 (62) -.04 (62) .12 *** (62) .14 *** (61)<br />

Macedonia -.07 ** (92) -.01 (92) -.03 (92) .12 *** (92) .10 *** (90)<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Slovenia -.07 * (92) -.15 *** (92) -.15 *** (92) .33 *** (92) .20 *** (89)<br />

Croatia -.03 (92) -.09 ** (92) -.09 ** (92) .09 *** (92) .07 * (90)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> -.09 ** (93) -.12 *** (93) -.13 *** (93) .21 *** (93) .15 *** (88)<br />

Czech Republic -.04 (93) .00 (93) -.02 (93) .14 *** (93) .08 ** (85)<br />

Slovakia -.01 (92) -.07 * (92) -.08 ** (92) .13 *** (92) .06 * -85<br />

Hungary -.01 (94) -.07 * (94) -.09 ** (94) .28 *** (94) .07 * (91)<br />

Post-soviet societies<br />

Moldova -.01 (96) -.02 (96) -.04 (96) .11 *** (96) .11 *** (95)<br />

Ukraine -.10 *** (93) -.03 (93) -.03 (93) .10 *** (92) .09 ** (90)<br />

Russia -.01 (92) .15 *** (92) .15 *** (92) .06 * (91 .01 (77)<br />

Baltic states<br />

Latvia -.05 (90) .07 * (90) .05 (90) .21 *** (89) .08 ** (85)<br />

Lithuania -.01 (77) .06 * (77) .05 (77) .13 *** (77) .02 (65)<br />

Estonia -.03 (85) .05 (85) .04 (85) .19 *** (85) .13 *** (76)<br />

Western Europe<br />

East Germany -.01 (94) -.05 (94) -.07 ** (94) .31 *** (94) .05 (85)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .01 (88) .00 (88) -.04 (88) .18 *** (88) .04 (70)<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> -.05 * (98) -.16 *** (98) -.18 *** (98) .25 *** (97) .14 *** (92)<br />

Belgium -.09 ** (97) -.22 *** (97) -.23 *** (97) .27 *** (96) .26 *** (80)<br />

Spain -.08 ** (91) -.17 *** (91) -.19 *** (91) .26 *** (90) .17 *** (85)<br />

Italy -.05 (94) -.09 ** (94) -.09 *** (94) .24 *** (93) .15 *** (63)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .10 *** (95) -.14 *** (95) -.17 *** (95) .27 *** (95) .10 *** (88)<br />

France -.03 (99) -.06 * (99) -.08 ** (99) .16 *** (99) .09 ** (87)<br />

Sweden .08 ** (98) -.17 *** (98) -.19 *** (98) .19 *** (98) .07 * (93)<br />

Denmark .04 (96) -.10 *** (96) -.12 *** (96) .22 *** (90) .11 *** (86)<br />

Norway .07 ** (100) -.08 * (100) -.11 *** (100) .18 *** (99) .15 *** (92)<br />

Malta -.11 *** (98) -.05 * (98) -.06 * (98) .17 *** (98) .13 *** (70)<br />

Austria -.05 (98) -.15 *** (98) -.17 *** (98) .27 *** (98) .17 *** (79)<br />

West Germany .06 * (96) -.08 ** (96) -.11 *** (96) .20 *** (95) .11 *** (86)<br />

Greece -.08 ** (96) -.07 ** (94) -.08 ** (94) .23 *** (96) .16 *** (82)<br />

Cyprus -.11 *** (100) -.09 ** (100) -.10 *** (100) .24 *** (99) .10 *** (99)<br />

Luxembourg .02 (93) -.09 *** (93) -.10 *** (93) .21 *** (91) .09 * (51)<br />

Portugal -.07 ** (94) -.11 *** (94) -.12 *** (94) .32 *** (94) .22 *** (66)<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> .00 (99) -.02 (99) -.05 (99) .14 *** (98) .03 (89)<br />

Andorra .06 * (98) -.10 *** (98) -.12 *** (98) .28 *** (98) .10 *** (93)<br />

254


Gender<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Age<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Age sq.<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Education<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Income<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Anglo-Saxon societies<br />

USA .04 (98) .23 *** (98) .21 *** (98) .14 *** (98) -.01 (92)<br />

Canada -.01 (96) -.04 (96) -.07 ** (96) .20 *** (96) .17 *** (82)<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> -.07 * (95) -.08 ** (91) -.10 *** (91) .12 *** (94) .08 ** (67)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 2000 -.07 * (95) -.17 *** (93) -.19 *** (93) .29 *** (95) .25 *** (81)<br />

Great Britain .06 * (95) .10 *** (95) .07 * (95) .10 *** (94) .08 * (76)<br />

Australia .98 ** (98) -.06 * (98) -.08 ** (98) .14 *** (97) .14 *** (91)<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> .05 (93) .07 * (93) .05 (93) .05 (93) .12 *** (85)<br />

Central & Southern America<br />

Argentina .03 (89) -.06 * (89) -.07 * (89) .34 *** (89) .13 *** (82)<br />

Chile -.07 ** (98) -.13 *** (98) -.12 *** (98) .28 *** (98) .11 *** (92)<br />

Peru -.07 ** (94) .07 * (94) .05 (94) .23 *** (94) .22 *** (87)<br />

Mexico -.05 * (89) .11 *** (89) .10 *** (89) .15 *** (89) .12 *** (83)<br />

Venezuela -.09 ** (95) .13 *** (95) .12 *** (95) .03 (95) .04 (80)<br />

Brazil -.04 (98) -.08 ** (98) -.09 *** (98) .25 *** (98) .05 (97)<br />

Uruguay -.07 ** (99) .02 (99) -.01 (99) .27 *** (99) .15 *** (97)<br />

Colombia -.08 ** (99) .05 (99) .04 (99) .17 *** (99) .14 *** (91)<br />

Guatemala -.04 (95) .09 ** (95) .08 * (95) .13 *** (95) .09 ** (90)<br />

Trinidad & Tobago -.03 (96) -.04 (96) -.05 * (96) .18 *** (96) .06 * (94)<br />

Africa<br />

Algeria -.13 *** (87) .07 * (87) .07 * (87) .11 *** (87) .06 (87)<br />

Jordan -.15 *** (99) -.02 (99) -.03 (99) .18 *** (99) .14 *** (91)<br />

Morocco -.09 ** (87) -.08 ** (87) -.08 ** (87) .37 *** (87) .25 *** (86)<br />

Egypt -.15 *** (99) - - - - - - - -<br />

South Africa -.08 ** (92) .08 ** (92) .05 (92) .16 *** (92) .02 (87)<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a -.23 *** (75) -.07 * (75) -.07 * (75) .15 *** (74) .09 * (44)<br />

Tanzania -.01 (97) .01 (96) .01 (96) .05 (96) -.06 * (89)<br />

Ghana -.14 *** (90) -.01 (90) -.01 (90) .21 *** (90) .13 *** (84)<br />

Nigeria -.21 *** (93) .07 * (93) .06 * (93) .20 *** (93) .11 *** (90)<br />

Burkina Faso -.15 *** (76) .01 (74) .00 (74) .33 *** (76) .20 *** (66)<br />

Ethiopia -.05 (72) .01 (72) .02 (72) .00 (72) -.26 *** (70)<br />

Mali -.05 (73) .01 (69) .-01 (69) .10 ** (68) .05 (58)<br />

Zambia -.11 *** (94) .12 *** (94) .10 *** (94) .22 *** (92) .08 ** (81)<br />

Confucian societies<br />

Japan .06 * (85) .26 *** (85) .22 *** (85) -.03 (83) -.10 ** (79)<br />

South Korea -.03 (100) -.02 (100) -.03 (100) .06 * (100) .02 (100)<br />

Southern Asia<br />

Bangladesh -.17 *** (84) .02 (84) .04 (84) .23 *** (83) .08 ** (83)<br />

Malaysia -.05 (100) .06 * (100) .05 * (100) .03 (100) .06 * (100)<br />

Turkey -.09 *** (98) -.04 (98) -.07 *** (97) .32 *** (95) .10 *** (97)<br />

Indonesia -.12 *** (87) -.13 *** (87) -.13 *** (87) .17 *** (87) .01 (80)<br />

Philippines -.13 *** (98) .01 (98) .01 (98) .12 *** (98) .07 ** (98)<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> -.06 * (99) -.08 ** (99) -.07 ** (99) .13 *** (99) .06 * (98)<br />

India -.18 *** (77) .09 ** (77) .08 ** (77) .16 *** (76) .08 ** (77)<br />

Taiwan .01 (100) .01 (100) -.01 (100) .16 *** (100) .06 * (100)<br />

Israel -.02 (96) -.13 *** (95) -.15 *** (95) .26 *** (95) .33 *** (78)<br />

Singapore -.09 ** (98) -.09 ** (98) -.09 ** (98) .10 *** (98) .06 * (90)<br />

Data entries are Pearson’s r. In case of gender Cramer’s V was used.<br />

For the dates of the respective surveys, see Appendix A8-2.<br />

255


Appendix A8-2:<br />

Individual-Level Correlations: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Motivation, pooled WVS 2000-05<br />

Political interest<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Life Satisfaction<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Left-Right Scale<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Postmaterialism<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Self expression<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

Serbia .19 *** (87) .02 (89) .14 *** (68) .03 (71) -.05 (84)<br />

Bulgaria .16 *** (80) .07 * (79) .18 *** (60) .14 *** (80) .16 *** (79)<br />

Montenegro .34 *** (81) .01 (79) .20 *** (57) .09 ** (78) .20 *** (79)<br />

Bosnia .17 *** (93) .04 (93) .01 (84) .01 (91) .08 ** (93)<br />

Romania .16 *** (91) .08 ** (86) .04 (48) .09 ** (85) .11 *** (86)<br />

Albania .21 *** (62) -.08 * (62) .15 *** (60) .09 * (58) .10 ** (60)<br />

Macedonia .12 *** (92) .01 (92) .01 (75) .04 (89) .04 (91)<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Slovenia .21 *** (92) .10 *** (92) -.13 *** (59) .20 *** (87) .03 (90)<br />

Croatia - - .02 (91) .03 (71) .14 *** (89) .15 *** (86)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .21 *** (93) .02 (92) -.08 * (67) .17 *** (88) .17 *** (89)<br />

Czech Republic .19 *** (93) .00 (93) .07 * (87) .11 *** (90) .16 *** (88)<br />

Slovakia - - .03 (91) .07 * (78) .15 *** (85) .13 *** (79)<br />

Hungary - - .02 (94) -.13 *** (75) .19 *** (90) .17 *** (87)<br />

Post-soviet societies<br />

Moldova .21 *** (96) .05 (96) .04 (75) .14 *** (95) .12 *** (95)<br />

Ukraine .20 *** (90) .14 *** (93) .16 *** (56) .14 *** (91) .05 (89)<br />

Russia .11 *** (90) -.05 (91) - - .03 (90) -.03 (89)<br />

Baltic states<br />

Latvia - - .02 (90) .00 (62) .04 (88) .04 (80)<br />

Lithuania .20 *** (76) -.07 * (75) .11 ** (51) .06 (72) .09 ** (65)<br />

Estonia - - .07 * (85) .07 * (61) .08 * (81) .10 ** (72)<br />

Western Europe<br />

East Germany .26 *** (94) .09 ** (94) -.18 *** (86) .20 *** (93) .16 *** (92)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .19 *** (88) -.05 (88) -.20 *** (79) .09 ** (86) .15 *** (87)<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> .21 *** (98) -.02 (98) -.09 ** (90) .21 *** (97) .25 *** (88)<br />

Belgium .22 *** (96) -.05 (96) -.13 *** (80) .23 *** (92) .23 *** (90)<br />

Spain .22 *** (91) .08 ** (91) -.12 *** (80) .13 *** (89) .18 *** (89)<br />

Italy .27 *** (94) .05 (93) -.15 *** (71) .23 *** (91) .29 *** (91)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .24 *** (95) .04 (95) -.05 (85) .23 *** (93) .27 *** (94)<br />

France .23 *** (99) .04 (99) -.14 *** (93) .16 *** (98) .20 *** (98)<br />

Sweden .16 *** (97) -.02 (98) -.10 *** (95) .19 *** (97) .21 *** (98)<br />

Denmark .17 *** (96) .03 (96) -.15 *** (87) .19 *** (89) .26 *** (87)<br />

Norway .15 *** (100) -.01 (99) -.18 *** (97) .09 ** (98) .11 *** (99)<br />

Malta - - -.02 (98) -.07 ** (95) .13 *** (98) .15 *** (97)<br />

Austria .25 *** (97) -.03 (97) -.11 *** (80) .14 *** (94) .27 *** (87)<br />

West Germany .25 *** (96) .05 * (95) -.19 *** (85) .29 *** (92) .26 *** (91)<br />

Greece .23 *** (95) .05 * (96) -.20 *** (86) .08 * (91) .24 *** (78)<br />

Cyprus .16 *** (99) -.03 (100) -.06 * (94) .07 * (99) .14 *** (100)<br />

Luxembourg .14 *** (90) .06 * (92) -.12 *** (72) .14 *** (83) .20 *** (84)<br />

Portugal .27 *** (94) .09 ** (93) -.10 ** (72) .15 *** (90) .17 *** (84)<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> .16 *** (99) -.02 (99) -.09 ** (90) .12 *** (97) .16 *** (96)<br />

Andorra .18 *** (98) .00 (98) -.20 *** (90) .10 ** (98) .23 *** (98)<br />

256


Political interest<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Life Satisfaction<br />

(percent valid)<br />

257<br />

Left-Right Scale<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Postmaterialism<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Self expression<br />

(percent valid)<br />

Anglo-Saxon societies<br />

USA .27 *** (98) .00 (97) -.02 (95) .05 (97) .13 *** (98)<br />

Canada .18 *** (96) .06 * (96) -.12 *** (77) .09 ** (96) .27 *** (98)<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> .13 *** (94) -.06 * (94) -.03 (75) .12 *** (89) .12 *** (83)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> 2000 .19 *** (95) .00 (95) -.16 *** (80) .12 *** (92) .24 *** (86)<br />

Great Britain .23 *** (95) -.01 (95) -.07 *** (81) .11 *** (91) .19 *** (93)<br />

Australia .17 *** (99) .01 (98) -.14 *** (94) .14 *** (96) .11 *** (99)<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> .15 *** (95) .07 ** (93) -.09 ** (65) .03 (78) .10 *** (88)<br />

Central & Southern America<br />

Argentina .19 *** (88) -.14 *** (88) -.20 *** (65) .21 *** (84) .20 *** (84)<br />

Chile .24 *** (98) .06 * (98) -.13 *** (68) .14 *** (96) .11 *** (67)<br />

Peru .24 *** (94) .02 (94) -.02 (72) .12 *** (90) .18 *** (86)<br />

Mexico .25 *** (89) -.02 (88) -.04 (77) .06 (87) .11 *** (87)<br />

Venezuela .16 *** (95) -.01 (95) -.06 * (78) .04 (94) .04 (95)<br />

Brazil .14 *** (97) -.03 (98) -.04 (90) .17 *** (94) .08 ** (97)<br />

Uruguay .33 *** (98) .04 (99) -.26 *** (86) .22 *** (89) .25 *** (93)<br />

Colombia .18 *** (99) -.01 (99) -.04 (74) .09 ** (95) .09 ** (97)<br />

Guatemala .12 *** (94) .02 (95) -.04 (77) .06 (94) .04 (95)<br />

Trinidad & Tobago .04 (96) .04 (96) -.02 (61) .06 (95) .08 ** (96)<br />

Africa<br />

Algeria<br />

Jordan .18 *** (98) .04 (98) .09 (28) .06 (97) .06 * (99)<br />

Morocco .27 *** (84) .26 *** (86) .26 *** (41) .17 *** (84) .25 *** (79)<br />

South Africa .13 *** (91) -.01 (92) -.07 * (76) .03 (88) .07 * (91)<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a .19 *** (75) -.02 (75) .03 (68) .02 (75) .08 ** (75)<br />

Tanzania .05 * (96) .01 (96) -.01 (68) .07 * (92) .03 (95)<br />

Ghana .11 *** (89) .03 (90) .03 (47) .07 * (90) .01 (90)<br />

Nigeria .18 *** (93) .06 * (93) .10 *** (91) .12 *** (93) .08 ** (93)<br />

Burkina Faso .11 *** (75) .05 (76) -.02 (61) .14 *** (75) .02 (74)<br />

Ethiopia .07 ** (69) -.13 *** (72) -.12 *** (63) .04 (68) -.02 (70)<br />

Mali .15 *** (70) .00 (68) .00 (62) .02 (70) .03 (69)<br />

Zambia .14 *** (91) .02 (92) -.01 (62) .10 ** (92) .06 * (93)<br />

Confucian societies<br />

Japan .19 *** (84) .00 (84) -.04 (69) .07 (74) .02 (79)<br />

South Korea .22 *** (100) -.08 ** (100) -.02 (100) .05 (100) -.04 (100)<br />

Southern Asia<br />

Bangladesh .22 *** (82) .14 *** (83) -.15 *** (67) .13 *** (82) .06 * (83)<br />

Malaysia .12 *** (99) -.05 * (100) - - .03 (99) .13 *** (100)<br />

Turkey .18 *** (98) -.08 ** (98) -.15 *** (84) .06 (96) .06 * (98)<br />

Indonesia .14 *** (87) .00 (84) -.04 (64) .12 *** (83) .05 (98)<br />

Philippines .10 *** (98) -.02 (98) -.05 (94) .10 ** (98) .08 ** (83)<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> .07 ** (100) .09 *** (100) .05 (100) .02 (96) .00 (99)<br />

India .31 *** (73) -.01 (75) .07 (42) .14 *** (67) .11 *** (67)<br />

Taiwan .24 *** (100) .02 (100) -.03 (99) .05 (100) .11 *** (100)<br />

Israel .11 *** (96) .13 *** (96) -.01 (89) .14 *** (89) .30 *** (82)<br />

Singapore .07 ** (98) .05 (98) - - .08 ** (97) .16 *** (98)<br />

Source: WVS 2000 <strong>and</strong> 2005. Data entries are Pearson’s r.<br />

Data taken from WVS 2005 for France, Great Britain, West Germany, Italy, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Spain, USA,<br />

Canada, Japan, Mexico, South Africa, Australia, Norway, Sweden, Finl<strong>and</strong>, Argentina, South Korea,<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong>, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Brazil, Chile, India, East Germany, Slovenia, Bulgaria, Romania, Taiwan, Turkey,<br />

Ukraine, Russia, Peru, Uruguay, Ghana, Moldova, Thail<strong>and</strong>, Indonesia, Colombia, Serbia, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>,<br />

Morocco, Jordan, Cyprus, Guatemala, Trinidad <strong>and</strong> Tobago, Andorra, Malaysia, Burkina Faso, Ethiopia,<br />

Mali, Zambia.


Appendix A8-3:<br />

Factor Analysis of Level-2 Predictors<br />

Modernization<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> stock .913<br />

GDP per capita, adjusted for ppp .897<br />

Voice <strong>and</strong> Accountability .858<br />

Happiness level .822<br />

Level of tertiarization .799<br />

Eigenvalue 3.689<br />

N=78. Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin Measure: .857. Bartlett’s Test of Sphericity: 264.036 ***<br />

258


Appendix A8-4:<br />

Alternative Multi-Level Model (Hierarchical Generalized Linear Model):<br />

Individual- <strong>and</strong> Contextual Determinants of Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS 2000-2005)<br />

Model 1:<br />

Individual-level<br />

only<br />

(r<strong>and</strong>om<br />

intercept, r<strong>and</strong>om<br />

slope)<br />

Model 2:<br />

Societal-level effects on intercept<br />

Intercept 0.92 (-0.780) 0.91 (-0.969) 0.91 (-1.058) 0.91 (-0.972) 0.91 (-0.986) 0.91 (-0.963) 0.91 (-0.963)<br />

Individual-level effects<br />

(slopes):<br />

Life Satisfaction<br />

Left-Right Positioning (rev.)<br />

Interest in Politics<br />

Self Expression Values<br />

Control Factors:<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

Education<br />

Income<br />

Societal-level effects<br />

(intercepts):<br />

GDP per capita, ppp<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> Stock<br />

Voice & Accountability<br />

Tertiarization<br />

Inequality: Gini coefficient<br />

Happiness level<br />

Remaining between-society<br />

variance:<br />

Intercept<br />

(Contribution to variance)<br />

Left-Right Positioning (rev.)<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

0.97 *** (-3.882)<br />

1.05 *** (4.215)<br />

1.54 *** (22.127)<br />

3.44 *** (13.312)<br />

0.86 ** (-3.758)<br />

1.00 * (2.415)<br />

1.15 *** (14.658)<br />

1.03 ** (2.937)<br />

1.00 *** (8.941)<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

0.7439 ***<br />

0.5697 ***<br />

(23.4%)<br />

0.0060 ***<br />

0.0834 ***<br />

0.0002 ***<br />

1.00 ** (2.790)<br />

1.00 *** (3.877)<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

0.4713 ***<br />

(36,6%)<br />

1.00 *** (3.448)<br />

--<br />

1.36 (1.404)<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

0.5619 ***<br />

(24.5%)<br />

1.00 *** (6.014)<br />

--<br />

--<br />

1.02 * (1.971)<br />

--<br />

--<br />

0.5461 ***<br />

(26.6%)<br />

0.98 *** (-5.063)<br />

1.04 *** (9.469)<br />

1.53 *** (37.100)<br />

3.81 *** (21.189)<br />

0.87 *** (-6.980)<br />

1.00 *** (4.925)<br />

1.16 *** (27.428)<br />

1.03 *** (5.494)<br />

1.00 *** (7.778)<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

0.99 (-0.466)<br />

--<br />

0.5765 ***<br />

(22.5%)<br />

1.00 *** (7.087)<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

--<br />

0.96 (-0.327)<br />

0.5774 ***<br />

(22.4%)<br />

259


Intercept 0.92 (-0.940)<br />

Individual-level effects (slopes):<br />

Life Satisfaction<br />

0.98 *** (-5.027)<br />

Left-Right Positioning (reversed)<br />

1.05 (6.511)<br />

Interest in Politics<br />

1.53 *** (36.665)<br />

Self Expression Values<br />

3.43 *** (19.168)<br />

Control Factors:<br />

Gender<br />

0.86 *** (-5.047)<br />

Age<br />

1.00 * (2.168)<br />

Education<br />

1.16 *** (27.074)<br />

Income<br />

1.03 *** (5.388)<br />

Societal-level effects (intercepts):<br />

GDP per capita, ppp<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> Stock<br />

Cross-level interaction effects (slopes)<br />

Left-Right Positioning (reversed)<br />

* <strong>Democracy</strong> Stock<br />

Gender<br />

* GDP per capita, ppp<br />

Age<br />

* Inequality<br />

Remaining between-society variance:<br />

Intercept (Contribution to variance)<br />

Left-Right Positioning (reversed)<br />

Gender<br />

Age<br />

Model 3:<br />

Full model with significant interaction effects<br />

1.00 (0.713)<br />

1.00 *** (4.086)<br />

1.00 *** (6.511)<br />

1.00 *** (7.310)<br />

1.00 *** (4.020)<br />

0.3843 *** (48,3%)<br />

0.0032 *** (46,7%)<br />

0.0299 *** (64.2%)<br />

0.0001 *** (50.0%)<br />

Source: World Values Survey 2000-2005. N (individual level) = 56.284. N (societal level) = 70.<br />

Significance level: * p ≤ .05, ** p ≤ .01, *** p = .00.<br />

Data entries are odds ratios with T-values in parentheses. Hierarchical generalized linear model calculated<br />

with HLM 6.06.<br />

Individual-level variables: WVS 2000-2005. Gender (1=male, 2=female), Age (low to high), Education (8-<br />

point scale), Income (10-point scale).<br />

Societal-level variables:<br />

Voice & Accountability: Government Indicators, World Bank 2000.<br />

<strong>Democracy</strong> Stock: Gering et al. (2005).<br />

GDP per capita, adjusted for purchasing power parity, International Monetary Fund (IMF). Data were taken<br />

for the survey year (2000 or 2005).<br />

Inequality: Gini coefficient: Human Development Report (HDR) 2007/08. Note that the survey years vary.<br />

Missing data have been supplemented by previous HDR reports <strong>and</strong> the World Income Inequality<br />

Database (V2.0c May 2008) provided by World Institute for Development Economics Research of the<br />

United Nations <strong>University</strong> (UNU-WIDER): http://www.wider.unu.edu/research/Database/en_GB/wiid/ .<br />

Happiness level: Country mean score of Life Satisfaction (10-point scale), WVS 2000-2005.<br />

Parliamentary system: 0/1, Database of Political Institutions, World Bank, 2000-2005. The indicator is<br />

taken from Jan Teorell, Sören Holmberg <strong>and</strong> Bo Rothenstein (2008): The Quality of Government Dataset,<br />

version 15 May/08, <strong>University</strong> of Gothenburg: The Quality of Government Institute.<br />

http://www.qog.pol.gu.se.<br />

260


Appendix A9-1: Elite-Challenging Activities (WVS/EVS 1999-2001) <strong>and</strong><br />

<strong>Democracy</strong>: Freedom House (2007)<br />

Lux, Slovak, Ice, Czech, Aut,<br />

Ire, Ita, East Ger, Swi, Den,<br />

Neth, Fran, Bel, Can<br />

100<br />

Tai<br />

Hun<br />

Chil<br />

Lat Slove Uru<br />

Lith<br />

Est<br />

Pol Port Spa Malt<br />

W Ger<br />

Fin<br />

Aus<br />

GB<br />

USA<br />

N Zea<br />

Swe<br />

90<br />

80<br />

Mex<br />

Bul<br />

Rom<br />

Arg<br />

Dom<br />

S Afr<br />

Croa<br />

Isr<br />

S Kor<br />

Braz<br />

Jap<br />

Gre<br />

Freedom House 2007<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

Indo<br />

Phil<br />

Bang<br />

India<br />

Serb<br />

Ukr Peru<br />

Tur<br />

Col Alb<br />

Geor<br />

Mace<br />

Bosn Mold Tan<br />

Ven Nig<br />

40<br />

Jord<br />

Mor<br />

Uga<br />

Arm<br />

30<br />

20<br />

Pak<br />

Aze<br />

Rus<br />

10<br />

Bela<br />

0<br />

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100<br />

Elite-challenging activities, in %<br />

Freedom House: Source: “Freedom in the World” Report. The scales for Political Rights (1 to 7) <strong>and</strong> Civil Liberties (1 to 7)<br />

were transformed, so that higher scores indicate more freedom, <strong>and</strong> added. Mean Score 2000-2006, in per cent of the<br />

highest possible score. R=0.57 *** .<br />

Elite-challenging activities: in percent.<br />

Data taken from WVS/EVS 1999-2001 (wave IV), except for Armenia (1997), Australia (1995), Azerbaijan (1997), Belarus<br />

(1996), Brazil (1997), Dominican Republic (1996) <strong>and</strong> Georgia (1996), New Zeal<strong>and</strong> (1998), Norway (1996), Pakistan<br />

(1997), South Korea (1996) <strong>and</strong> Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (1996).<br />

261


Appendix A9-2: Transparency International: Corruption Perception Index (CPI)<br />

The Corruption Perception Index (CPI) is composed of several indices that are based on<br />

surveys of business people <strong>and</strong> assessments by country analysts. The yearly composition<br />

of the index can vary. As an example, partial rates of the CPI 2006 come from nine<br />

different institutions (Lambsdorff 2006: 2):<br />

- CPIA, the Country Policy <strong>and</strong> Institutional Assessment by the IDA <strong>and</strong> IBRD (World<br />

Bank, 2005); surveys country teams, experts inside <strong>and</strong> outside the bank; coverage:<br />

76 countries<br />

- EIU, the Economist Intelligence Unit, 2006; expert staff ratings; coverage: 157<br />

countries<br />

- FH, Freedom House Nations in Transit, 2006; expert staff assessments (originating or<br />

resident in respective countries); coverage: 29 countries/territories<br />

- IMD, the International Institute for Management Development, World<br />

Competitiveness Center, Lausanne (two annual publications from 2005-2006);<br />

- MIG, Grey Area <strong>Dynamics</strong> Ratings by the Merchant International Group, 2006<br />

- PERC, the Political <strong>and</strong> Economic Risk Consultancy, Hong Kong (two annual<br />

publications from 2005-2006)<br />

- UNECA, United Nations Economic Commission for Africa, African Governance<br />

Report 2005<br />

- WEF, the World Economic Forum (two annual publications from 2005-2006)<br />

- WRMC, the World Markets Research Centre, 2006.<br />

262


Appendix A9-3:<br />

Individual-level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Confidence in Political Institutions (WVS/EVS 2005)<br />

“Confidence in<br />

government”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“Confidence in<br />

political<br />

parties”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“Confidence in<br />

parliament”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“Importance of<br />

democracy”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“Evaluation of<br />

democraticness<br />

in own country”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

Serbia -.09 ** (90) .00 (90) -.06 (90) .05 (90) .01 (89)<br />

Bulgaria -.03 (81) -.04 (80) .00 (80) .09 * (80) -.03 (80)<br />

Romania .04 (89) .07 ** (89) .04 (89) .11 *** (87) .03 (84)<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Slovenia .00 (89) .01 (88) .04 (88) .18 *** (89) .03 (86)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .03 (87) .04 (87) .09 ** (87) .12 *** (88) .05 (85)<br />

Post-soviet societies<br />

Moldova .02 (95) .07 (95) .04 (95) .16 *** (93) .01 (91)<br />

Ukraine -.05 (73) .01 (81) .04 (83) .12 *** (88) -.04 (88)<br />

Russia -.03 (87) .01 (85) .02 (83) -.02 (86) -.06 * (82)<br />

Western Europe<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s -.04 (87) .00 (85) .02 (85) .10 ** (87) -.03 (86)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .00 (94) .02 (94) .04 (94) .08 * (94) .01 (94)<br />

France -.05 (98) .07 * (98) -.01 (97) .14 *** (98) .04 (98)<br />

Sweden .02 (97) .05 (97) .06 (96) .06 (98) .05 (97)<br />

Norway .23 *** (99) .18 *** (99) .24 *** (99) .07 * (99) -.06 (99)<br />

Italy .01 (92) .12 *** (92) .12 *** (91) .09 ** (93) -.03 (91)<br />

Spain .01 (90) -.01 (89) .01 (89) .05 (90) .07 * (90)<br />

Cyprus -.11 *** (100) -.09 ** (100) -.10 ** (100) .04 (100) -.04 (100)<br />

Andorra -.09 ** (97) -.02 (98) - - .06 * (98) -.04 (97)<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> .06 * (96) .06 * (95) .05 (95) .08 ** (98) .09 ** (98)<br />

W. Germany -.07 * (93) -.09 ** (93) -.03 (93) .19 *** (95) .09 ** (95)<br />

East Germany .05 (93) .06 (92) .09 ** (92) .09 ** (93) .04 (93)<br />

Anglo-Saxon societies<br />

USA -.01 (96) .01 (96) .05 (94) .29 *** (96) .02 (95)<br />

Canada -.08 *** (91) -.02 (92) -.03 (91) .14 *** (95) .01 (93)<br />

Great Britain -.04 (92) .07 * (89) .03 (90) .23 *** (92) .09 ** (91)<br />

Australia -.08 ** (97) .00 (97) -.04 (97) .07 ** (97) -.03 (97)<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> .02 (88) .03 (87) .05 (89) - - - -<br />

Central & Southern America<br />

Argentina -.10 ** (87) -.09 * (87) -.10 ** (85) .16 *** (88) -.19 *** (86)<br />

Colombia .03 (98) .04 (98) .06 ** (95) .10 *** (94) -.04 * (93)<br />

Brazil .02 (97) -.02 (97) -.02 (97) .13 *** (96) .01 (95)<br />

Chile .08 * (96) .07 * (96) .08 * (95) .19 *** (94) .06 (93)<br />

Peru .10 *** (93) .09 ** (93) .03 (93) .12 *** (92) .06 * (91)<br />

Mexico .04 (88) .05 * (88) .03 (88) .01 (88) -.04 (87)<br />

Uruguay .17 *** (98) .12 *** (98) .09 ** (97) .13 *** (97) .07 * (97)<br />

Guatemala .06 (94) -.01 (94) .01 (94) - - - -<br />

Tri. & Tobago -.01 -94 .02 (94) .03 (95) .12 *** (95) -.03 (94)<br />

263


“Confidence in<br />

government”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“Confidence in<br />

political<br />

parties”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“Confidence in<br />

parliament”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“Importance of<br />

democracy”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

“Evaluation of<br />

democraticness<br />

in own country”<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Africa<br />

Zambia .03 (92) .05 (90) .09 ** (89) .03 (92) .01 (91)<br />

South Africa -.10 *** (91) -.05 * (89) -.08 *** (90) .05 * (90) -.04 * (89)<br />

Burkina Faso -.11 *** (72) -.12 *** (71) -.06 * (70) .01 (73) -.15 *** (70)<br />

Morocco .00 (84) -.01 (80 .05 (82) .12 *** (77) .09 ** (72)<br />

Jordan -.12 *** (94) -.05 (77) -.15 *** (86) -.03 (94) -.07 * (88)<br />

Ethiopia -.13 *** (66) .10 ** (68) -.12 *** (67) .12 *** (71) -.16 *** (70)<br />

Ghana .01 (89) .03 (89) .07 ** (88) .01 (89) -.07 ** (89)<br />

Mali .00 (69) .05 (68) -.05 (66) .00 (70) .00 (70)<br />

Confucian societies<br />

Japan .02 (81) .01 (80) .02 (80) .19 *** (81) .09 ** (79)<br />

South Korea -.05 (100) .03 (100) .04 (100) -.06 * (100) -.05 (100)<br />

Taiwan -.05 (100) .03 (99) -.09 ** (99) .07 ** (100) .02 (99)<br />

South & Southern Asia<br />

Indonesia -.09 *** (95) .01 (85) -.05 (84) .00 (84) -.09 *** (82)<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> .08 ** (100) .11 *** (99) .06 * (100) .12 *** (100) .05 * (100)<br />

India -.11 *** (66) -.01 (66) -.08 ** (63) .00 (66) -.03 (61)<br />

Malaysia -.11 *** (100) -.04 (100) -.12 *** (100) -.10 *** (100) -.13 *** (100)<br />

Turkey -.21 *** (95) -.09 ** (94) -.15 *** (93) .04 (96) -.15 *** (94)<br />

Source: World Values Survey 2005-07. Data entries are Pearson’s r. The coding of the variables:<br />

(1) Confidence in political institutions:<br />

“I am going to name a number of organizations. For each one, could you tell me how much confidence you<br />

have in them: is it a great deal of confidence, quite a lot of confidence, not very much confidence or none at<br />

all?<br />

- the government (in your nation’s capital)<br />

- political parties<br />

- parliament<br />

(2) Importance of democracy:<br />

“How important is it for you to live in a country that is governed democratically? On this scale where 1<br />

means it is “not at all important” <strong>and</strong> 10 means “absolutely important” what position would you choose?”<br />

(3) Evaluation of democraticness in own country:<br />

“And how democratically is this country being governed today? Again using a scale from 1 to 10, where 1<br />

means that it is “not at all democratic” <strong>and</strong> 10 means that it is “completely democratic,” what position<br />

would you choose?”<br />

264


Appendix A9-4:<br />

Factor Analysis: Essential Characteristics of <strong>Democracy</strong>,<br />

World Values Survey 2005-07<br />

Procedural<br />

Underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

Output-<br />

Oriented<br />

Underst<strong>and</strong>ing<br />

People choose their leaders in free elections. .686 .216<br />

Civil rights protect people’s liberty against<br />

oppression.<br />

.643 .307<br />

People can change laws in referendums. .715 .149<br />

Women have the same rights as men. .766 .090<br />

Governments tax the rich <strong>and</strong> subsidize the poor. -.056 .767<br />

People receive state aid for unemployment. .261 .572<br />

The economy is prospering .334 .652<br />

Criminals are severely punished. .268 .605<br />

Eigenvalue 3.080 1.034<br />

Varimax rotation.<br />

Source: WVS 2005-2007. Countries included in analysis (weight n=1.000): France, Britain, Italy,<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, USA, Canada, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Japan, Mexico, Australia, Sweden, Germany, Argentina,<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong>, South Korea, Pol<strong>and</strong>, Brazil, Chile, India, Slovenia, Bulgaria, Romania, Taiwan, Ukraine, Russia,<br />

Uruguay, Ghana, Moldova, Indonesia, Vietnam, Serbia, Malaysia, Burkina Faso, Ethiopia, Mali, Rw<strong>and</strong>a,<br />

Zambia.<br />

Question formulation:<br />

“Many things may be desirable, but not all of them are essential characteristics of democracy. Please tell<br />

me for each of the following things how essential you think it is as a characteristic of democracy. Use this<br />

scale where 1 means “not at all an essential characteristic of democracy” <strong>and</strong> 10 means it definitely is “an<br />

essential characteristic of democracy”.”<br />

265


Appendix A9-5:<br />

Individual-level Correlation: Elite-Challenging Activities <strong>and</strong><br />

Tolerance, single items (WVS/EVS 1999-2001)<br />

People with a<br />

different race<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Immigrants/ foreign<br />

workers<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

People who have<br />

AIDS<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Homosexuals<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Eastern Europe<br />

Serbia .11*** (88) .02 (88) .16*** (88) .12*** (88)<br />

Bulgaria .03 (78) .03 (78) .06 (78) .13*** (78)<br />

Montenegro .13** (70) .14*** (70) .16*** (70) .24*** (70)<br />

Bosnia .08 (89) .15** (89) .11* (89) .05 (89)<br />

Romania .12*** (79) .08* (79) .14*** (79) .03 (79)<br />

Albania .09* (59) .11** (59) .12** (59) .06 (59)<br />

Macedonia .08* (90) .08* (90) .08* (90) .04 (90)<br />

Central Eastern Europe<br />

Slovenia .07* (90) .12*** (90) .11** (90) .14*** (90)<br />

Croatia .08* (86) .03 (86) .04 (86) .11** (86)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> .07* (99) .05 (99) .09** (99) .08* (99)<br />

Czech Republic .07** (92) .06* (92) .05* (92) .06* (92)<br />

Slovakia .03 (89) .01 (89) -.04 (89) -.02 (89)<br />

Hungary<br />

Post-soviet societies<br />

Belarus .04 (90) .11** (90) .05 (90) -.01 (90)<br />

Kyrgyzstan .04 (98) .06 (98) .05 (98) .01 (98)<br />

Moldova .07 (82) -.02 (82) .05 (82) .03 (82)<br />

Ukraine .03 (84) .06 (84) .08** (84) -.07* (84)<br />

Russia .00 (90) -.03 (90) .01 (90) -.04 (90)<br />

Baltic states<br />

Latvia .01 (88) -.01 (88) .04 (88) -.05 (88)<br />

Lithuania .07 (72) .07 (72) .05 (72) -.05 (72)<br />

Estonia .10** (83) .07 (83) .11** (83) .00 (83)<br />

Western Europe<br />

East Germany -.02 (86) .03 (86) -.04 (86) -.03 (86)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s .10** (100) .11*** (100) .15*** (100) .11*** (100)<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> .05 (98) .06 (98) .07* (98) .10** (98)<br />

Belgium .14*** (97) .17*** (97) .12*** (97) .11*** (97)<br />

Spain .08*** (84) .08*** (84) .09*** (84) .08** (84)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> .12*** (95) .05 (95) .14*** (95) .12*** (95)<br />

Italy .09*** (93) .09*** (93) .17*** (93) .15*** (93)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> .08* (91) .09** (91) .15*** (91) .12*** (91)<br />

France .03 (96) .01 (96) .05* (96) .07** (96)<br />

Sweden .01 (99) -.02 (99) .00 (99) .04 (99)<br />

Denmark .11*** (95) .10** (95) .16*** (95) .18*** (95)<br />

Malta .05 (97) -.01 (97) .06* (97) .11** (97)<br />

Austria .07** (97) .12*** (97) .19*** (97) .15*** (97)<br />

West Germany .00 (82) .04 (82) .11** (82) .06 (82)<br />

Greece .09** (96) .09** (96) .16*** (96) .13*** (96)<br />

Luxembourg .05 (91) .07* (91) .11*** (91) .14*** (91)<br />

Portugal .02 (92) -.02 (92) .12*** (92) .03 (92)<br />

266


Continued:<br />

People with a<br />

different race<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Immigrants/ foreign<br />

workers<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

People who have<br />

AIDS<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Homosexuals<br />

(Percent valid)<br />

Anglo-Saxon societies<br />

USA .07* (98) .04 (98) .06* (98) .08** (98)<br />

Canada .00 (98) .00 (98) .09*** (98) .15*** (98)<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> .08* (94) .07* (94) .03 (94) .08* (94)<br />

Great Britain -.04 (98) -.04 (98) -.02 (98) .01 (98)<br />

Central & Southern America<br />

Argentina .08** (90) .06* (90) .08** (90) .06 (90)<br />

Chile -.15*** (92) -.10*** (92) -.04 (92) .08 (92)<br />

Peru .00 (89) -.01 (89) .00 (89) .06* (89)<br />

Puerto Rico .01 (96) .09* (96) .03 (96) .03 (96)<br />

Mexico -.01 (81) .00 (81) .03 (81) .05 (81)<br />

Venezuela .03 (94) .04 (94) .07* (94) .06* (94)<br />

Africa<br />

Algeria .04 (87) .08** (87) .05 (87) -.01 (87)<br />

Jordan .02 (98) -.01 (98) -.02 (98) -.04 (98)<br />

Morocco .09*** (82) .06* (82) .18*** (82) .03 (82)<br />

Egypt .02 (100) .00 (100) -.03 (100) -.02 (100)<br />

South Africa .02 (88) .12*** (88) .03 (88) .03 (88)<br />

Zimbabwe .06 (90) .07* (90) .05 (90) -.07* (90)<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a -.06 (63) -.01 (63) -.06 (63) -.01 (63)<br />

Nigeria .01 (89) .00 (89) -.03 (89) .01 (89)<br />

Tanzania -.01 (97) -.05 (97) .03 (97) .06* (97)<br />

Confucian societies<br />

Japan<br />

Southern Asia<br />

Bangladesh -.06* (82) -.07* (82) -.03 (82) -.06* (82)<br />

Turkey .14*** (97) .12*** (97) .17*** (97) .18*** (97)<br />

Indonesia -.00 (87) -.02 (87) -.01 (87) -.05 (87)<br />

Philippines .03 (98) -.03 (98) .13*** (98) .05 (98)<br />

Vietnam .01 (81) -.03 (81) .03 (81) -.02 (81)<br />

Pakistan -.03 (92) -.03 (92) -.04 (92) - (92)<br />

India .00 (78) .02 (78) .02 (78) -.07** (78)<br />

Source: World Values Survey 1999-2001. Data entries are Phi. The coding of the variables:<br />

Tolerance Items:<br />

“On this list are various groups of people. Could you please sort out any that you would not like to have as<br />

neighbors?”<br />

- People with a different race<br />

- Immigrants/foreign workers<br />

- People who have AIDS<br />

- Homosexuals<br />

Group mentioned = -1. Group not mentioned = 0.<br />

267


Appendix B:<br />

Documentation of Survey Results<br />

Political Action Study I<br />

Signing a Petition Have done Would do Might do Would never do<br />

Great Britain (n=1483) 22,2 31,0 21,8 21,1<br />

West Germany (n=2307) 30,5 39,8 13,3 14,3<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1201) 20,9 54,2 12,9 8,6<br />

Austria (n=1585) 34,2 30,6 9,5 14,0<br />

USA (n=1719) 57,6 20,0 13,1 5,5<br />

Italy (n=1779) 9,9 26,8 12,6 10,2<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=1290) 44,3 31,1 13,6 8,4<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=1224) 18,7 26,5 26,7 22,7<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “We would like to know how you feel about these things, Please place each of the little<br />

cards you have there on one of the parts of this card to show me, (…) Whether you have actually done any<br />

of these things on the cards during the past ten years, If not, the extent to which you feel you might do each<br />

of these things [“would do” or “might do”] or whether you would never, under any circumstances, do each<br />

of these things, (…) Signing a petition,”<br />

Boycotts Have done Would do Might do Would never do<br />

Great Britain (n=1483) 5,3 17,4 23,1 47,3<br />

West Germany (n=2307) 4,3 23,8 22,6 44,5<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1201) 5,2 26,5 21,6 41,1<br />

Austria (n=1585) 2,1 11,6 14,8 46,3<br />

USA (n=1719) 14,5 19,5 27,1 31,4<br />

Italy (n=1779) 0,8 4,0 7,1 44,7<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=1290) 4,4 16,1 23,2 40,9<br />

268


Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=1224) 1,1 11,9 28,1 51,3<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “We would like to know how you feel about these things, Please place each of the little<br />

cards you have there on one of the parts of this card to show me, (…) Whether you have actually done any<br />

of these things on the cards during the past ten years, If not, the extent to which you feel you might do each<br />

of these things [“would do” or “might do”] or whether you would never, under any circumstances, do each<br />

of these things, (…) Boycotts,”<br />

Lawful Demonstrations Have done Would do Might do Would never do<br />

Great Britain (n=1483) 5,6 24,7 24,2 41,7<br />

West Germany (n=2307) 8,5 32,6 23,6 32,9<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1201) 7,0 39,2 22,1 29,1<br />

Austria (n=1585) 6,2 21,3 17,3 42,7<br />

USA (n=1719) 11,4 27,5 28,7 27,7<br />

Italy (n=1779) 16,7 34,4 18,7 18,9<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=1290) 8,0 28,8 28,3 30,4<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=1224) 5,7 22,1 29,0 39,8<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “We would like to know how you feel about these things, Please place each of the little<br />

cards you have there on one of the parts of this card to show me, (…) Whether you have actually done any<br />

of these things on the cards during the past ten years, If not, the extent to which you feel you might do each<br />

of these things [“would do” or “might do”] or whether you would never, under any circumstances, do each<br />

of these things, (…) Lawful demonstrations,”<br />

269


Joining strike Have done Would do Might do Would never do<br />

Great Britain (n=1483) 4,6 7,1 15,4 69,4<br />

West Germany (n=2307) 0,9 5,7 15,7 74,9<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1201) 1,5 13,7 16,7 64,0<br />

Austria (n=1585) 0,7 3,1 10,6 70,7<br />

USA (n=1719) 1,6 4,8 20,2 59,4<br />

Italy (n=1779) 1,1 3,1 6,1 76,0<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=1290) 0,2 3,9 13,5 73,5<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=1224) 4,2 6,7 18,4 65,7<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “We would like to know how you feel about these things, Please place each of the little<br />

cards you have there on one of the parts of this card to show me, (…) Whether you have actually done any<br />

of these things on the cards during the past ten years, If not, the extent to which you feel you might do each<br />

of these things [“would do” or “might do”] or whether you would never, under any circumstances, do each<br />

of these things, (…) Joining strike,”<br />

Occupying Buildings Have done Would do Might do Would never do<br />

Great Britain (n=1483) 0,8 6,2 12,5 77,0<br />

West Germany (n=2307) 0,2 3,6 13,0 80,3<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1201) 1,5 22,6 19,0 54,1<br />

Austria (n=1585) 0,3 2,1 8,1 72,1<br />

USA (n=1719) 1,5 4,9 16,6 71,4<br />

Italy (n=1779) 4,3 15,2 15,4 59,0<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=1290) 0,2 3,9 30,2 53,8<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=1224) 4,2 11,8 77,9 94,0<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “We would like to know how you feel about these things, Please place each of the little<br />

cards you have there on one of the parts of this card to show me, (…) Whether you have actually done any<br />

of these things on the cards during the past ten years, If not, the extent to which you feel you might do each<br />

of these things [“would do” or “might do”] or whether you would never, under any circumstances, do each<br />

of these things, (…) Occupying Buildings”.<br />

270


World Values Survey/European Values Survey<br />

Signing a Petition<br />

1981 1990 1999-2000 2005-2007<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Albania (n= 999) 23,0 28,2 33,0 (n= 1000) 15,2 29,0 23,8<br />

Algeria (n= 1282) 13,7 26,0 50,7<br />

Andorra (n= 1003) 55,1 35,9 8,3<br />

Argentina (n= 1005) 29,4 31,7 22,7 (n= 1002) 21,4 31,0 43,0 (n= 1280) 21,5 29,7 43,4 (n= 1002) 25,2 35,7 30,1<br />

Armenia (n= 2000) 17,3 38,0 41,8<br />

Australia (n= 1228) 68,6 24,9 5,1 (n= 2048) 78,0 16,1 5,4 (n= 1421) 78,6 16,2 4,5<br />

Austria (n= 1460) 44,8 29,3 21,6 (n= 1522) 55,9 23,6 19,1<br />

Azerbaijan (n= 2002) 9,4 14,9 69,4<br />

Bangladesh (n= 1500) 13,0 38,1 39,2<br />

Belarus (n= 2092) 9,1 26,9 59,2<br />

Belgium (n= 1145) 21,7 33,6 33,4 (n= 2792) 47,4 25,7 21,5 (n= 1912) 67,5 19,7 11,4<br />

Bosnia-Herz. (n= 1200) 20,7 46,6 26,8<br />

Brazil (n= 1782) 49,8 30,6 18,6 (n= 1149) 46,6 34,2 18,1 (n= 1500) 55,5 27,3 16,8<br />

Bulgaria (n= 1034) 18,7 34,0 33,8 (n= 1000) 9,2 30,6 42,4 (n= 1001) 10,2 24,7 50,5<br />

271


Burkina Faso (n= 1534) 11,9 46,9 17,9<br />

Canada (n= 1254) 60,6 25,6 11,2 (n= 1730) 75,9 14,7 8,2 (n= 1931) 72,7 18,5 8,0 (n= 2148) 71,4 17,8 8,3<br />

Chile (n= 1500) 22,1 32,4 42,0 (n= 1200) 18,6 25,4 49,6 (n= 1000) 16,8 20,1 61,9<br />

Colombia (n= 6025) 18,1 46,5 31,1 (n= 3025) 15,1 51,2 33,3<br />

Croatia (n= 1003) 33,5 56,9 5,3<br />

Cyprus (n= 1050) 24,5 37,3 38,2<br />

Czech Republic (n*=2109) 44,5 29,8 18,2 (n= 1908) 56,4 25,7 14,0<br />

Denmark (n= 1182) 41,0 27,6 25,7 (n= 1030) 50,3 25,0 23,0 (n= 1023) 55,2 26,4 15,6<br />

Dom. Republic (n= 417) 13,7 53,7 24,5<br />

East Germany (n= 1336) 66,1 25,1 6,2 (n= 999) 58,5 28,9 8,3 (n= 1076) 47,7 27,3 21,3<br />

Egypt (n= 3000) 19,8 37,3 42,9 (n= 3051) 6,9 14,6 78,5<br />

Estonia (n= 1008) 36,0 35,5 20,8 (n= 1005) 18,7 29,6 42,3<br />

Ethiopia (n= 1500) 15,3 31,7 25,5<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1003) 29,0 40,0 28,4 (n= 588) 34,0 38,1 11,6 (n= 1038) 46,8 34,8 12,9 (n= 1014) 49 31,1 16,9<br />

France (n= 1200) 43,2 30,5 23,2 (n= 1002) 51,4 27,7 16,6 (n= 1615) 67,4 22,1 9,1 (n= 1001) 66,4 22,8 10,3<br />

Georgia (n= 2008) 13,5 14,2 69,5<br />

Ghana (n= 1534) 3,8 35,9 52,4<br />

Great Britain (n= 1167) 62,3 26,7 9,7 (n= 1484) 74,7 16,7 7,6 (n= 1000) 78,1 14,9 5,5 (n= 1041) 65,9 22,5 8,3<br />

272


Greece (n= 1142) 48,4 37,5 11,7<br />

Guatemala (n= 1000) 12,3 40,1 45,9<br />

Hungary (n= 999) 17,2 28,6 50,1 (n= 1000) 14,1 30,9 50,8<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> (n= 927) 36,9 45,7 15,5 (n= 702) 46,6 36,0 16,0 (n= 968) 52,5 36,8 9,7<br />

India (n= 2500) 22,4 40,8 27,1 (n= 2002) 23,8 23,5 35,0 (n= 2001) 22,6 20,1 35,4<br />

Indonesia (n= 1004) 4,8 18,3 65,1 (n= 2015) 5,4 22,5 59,4<br />

Iraq (n= 2701) 8,1 25,6 48,2<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 1217) 27,4 44,4 23,0 (n= 1000) 41,4 39,2 17,9 (n= 1012) 58,3 25,2 14,4<br />

Israel (n= 1199) 37,9 29,0 30,3<br />

Italy (n= 1348) 36,4 28,5 24,1 (n= 2018) 42,1 31,4 17,2 (n= 2000) 52,4 29,2 14,4 (n= 1012) 52,1 30,9 13,4<br />

Japan (n= 1204) 42,4 28,5 13,4 (n= 1011) 52,0 21,4 11,2 (n= 1362) 56,8 26,6 6,5 (n= 1096) 54,9 25,5 11,3<br />

Jordan (n= 1223) 7,9 8,9 81,8 (n= 1200) 3,6 6,8 88,1<br />

Latvia (n= 903) 59,4 21,5 11,1 (n= 1013) 17,7 30,4 44,5<br />

Lithuania (n= 1000) 55,4 27,2 12,4 (n= 1018) 22,2 31,4 27,6<br />

Luxembourg (n= 1211) 50,2 30,4 13,7<br />

Macedonia (n= 1055) 24,7 37,5 31,2<br />

Malaysia (n= 1201) 6,4 25,9 67,7<br />

Mali (n= 1534) 14,2 30,7 31,9<br />

273


Malta (n= 467) 14,8 27,0 37,0 (n= 393) 28,1 21,3 34,0 (n= 1002) 32,8 35,2 30,8<br />

Mexico (n= 1837) 8,5 33,4 43,6 (n= 1531) 31,4 40,1 19,1 (n= 1535) 14,8 33,8 39,7 (n= 1560) 19,7 38,5 37,1<br />

Moldova (n= 1008) 15,2 18,6 50,6 (n= 1046) 10,3 31,1 57,5<br />

Montenegro (n= 1060) 20,4 43,5 21,2<br />

Morocco (n= 2264) 13,0 29,0 44,0 (n= 1200) 8,8 28,3 50,9<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n= 1221) 32,7 37,9 23,4 (n= 1017) 49,3 30,9 18,3 (n= 1003) 59,0 29,6 11,2 (n= 1050) 42,1 34,7 15,1<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> (n= 1201) 88,1 7,7 1,5 (n= 954) 84,1 10,8 1,8<br />

N. Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 312) 32,6 40,9 20,6 (n=304) 57,9 26,3 12,8 (n= 1000) 58,4 20,2 18,1<br />

Norway (n= 1051) 53,2 26,2 18,1 (n= 1239) 59,4 27,0 10,8 (n=1127) 64,5 25,9 9,3 (n= 1025) 69,2 20,8 9,7<br />

Peru (n= 1501) 21,0 54,9 17,8 (n= 1500) 23,9 36,8 36<br />

Philippines (n= 1200) 9,2 22,8 66,7<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n= 1929) 15,4 36,4 34,0 (n= 1095) 22,3 28,1 48,4 (n= 1000) 22,5 28,7 44,8<br />

Portugal (n= 1185) 26,9 42,2 23,0 (n= 1000) 21,7 37,5 37,0<br />

Romania (n= 1146) 9,0 30,1 44,8 (n= 1776) 5,8 26,7 62,4<br />

Russia (n= 1961) 26,5 39,5 23,6 (n= 2500) 10,9 29,7 53,0 (n= 2033) 7,7 21 63,9<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a (n= 1507) 8,1 19,3 61,4<br />

Serbia (n= 1200) 27,3 34,3 32,9 (n= 1220) 28,4 31,4 33,9<br />

Singapore (n= 1512) 7,2 39,0 52,3<br />

274


Slovakia (n*=1136) 34,8 31,9 18,1 (n= 1331) 57,0 21,7 17,4<br />

Slovenia (n= 1035) 22,2 27,1 31,1 (n= 1006) 30,7 41,3 22,8 (n= 1037) 29,3 33,7 32,1<br />

South Africa (n= 1595) 17,1 34,1 33,5 (n= 2736) 31,5 40,3 20,1 (n= 3000) 20,6 40,5 32,5 (n= 2988) 10,8 32,4 49,3<br />

South Korea (n= 970) 15,7 39,9 23,1 (n= 1251) 40,6 40,4 15,7 (n= 1200) 47,3 33,5 9,6 (n= 1200) 33,9 43,2 22,7<br />

Spain (n= 2303) 20,4 37,8 27,9 (n= 4147) 16,9 31,3 33,6 (n= 2409) 24,1 32,4 31,0 (n= 1200) 22,2 44,3 28,5<br />

Sweden (n= 954) 53,0 36,6 8,3 (n= 1047) 69,9 23,2 4,4 (n= 1015) 87,2 10,2 2,5 (n= 1003) 77,6 16,6 5<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1212) 62,3 17,4 18,3 (n= 1241) 77,2 13,9 8,3<br />

Tanzania (n= 1171) 10,2 45,8 41,7<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> (n= 1534) 3,2 15,6 81,1<br />

Trinidad <strong>and</strong><br />

Tobago<br />

(n= 1002) 22,3 51,2 24,4<br />

Turkey (n= 1030) 12,8 38,4 42,9 (n= 4607) 13,7 41,5 43,3 (n= 1346) 11,7 35 52<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a (n= 1002) 15,9 32,5 27,6<br />

Ukraine (n= 1195) 12,8 31,6 45,3 (n= 1000) 6,6 24,9 62,3<br />

Uruguay (n= 1000) 33,5 27,9 33 (n= 1000) 29,6 26,6 43<br />

USA (n= 2325) 60,5 22,6 12,3 (n= 1839) 69,6 19,2 8,2 (n= 1200) 80,7 15,8 3,0 (n= 1249) 68,9 23,6 5,4<br />

Venezuela (n= 1200) 14,4 65,9 16,3<br />

Vietnam (n= 1000) 5,3 43,5 45,2 (n= 1495) 5,4 19,5 73,4<br />

275


West Germany (n= 1305) 43,8 35,2 16,8 (n= 2101) 54,6 30,3 11,7 (n= 1037) 45,5 34,5 14,8 (n= 988) 49,2 31 17,5<br />

Zambia (n= 1500) 11,6 38,8 43,6<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values.<br />

Question wording: “Now I’d like you to look at this card, I’m going to read out some different form of political action that people can take, <strong>and</strong> I’d like you to<br />

tell me, for each one, whether you have actually done any of these things, whether you might do it or would never, under any circumstances, do it, (…) Signing a<br />

petition”.<br />

* Czech Republic <strong>and</strong> Slovakia: During the third WVS wave two surveys were conducted, one in 1990, another one in 1991, With the exception of “Attending<br />

lawful demonstrations”, the results are based on the 1991 surveys with 2109 Czech respondents <strong>and</strong> 1136 Slovak respondents, respectively.<br />

Azerbaijan, Australia, Armenia, Brazil, Uruguay, Colombia, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Norway, Dominican Republic, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Georgia, Belarus: Data from 1995-97<br />

WVS.<br />

276


Joining in Boycotts<br />

1981 1990 1999-2000 2005-2007<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Albania (n= 999) 9,1 14,5 54,8 (n= 1000) 3,7 15,4 47,2<br />

Algeria (n= 1282) 7,0 26,3 55,3<br />

Andorra (n= 1003) 10,5 25,2 62,8<br />

Argentina (n= 1005) 2,1 16,3 62,9 (n= 1002) 3,2 8,7 82,8 (n= 1280) 1,8 6,6 83,1 (n= 1002) 2,7 13,8 73,7<br />

Armenia (n= 2000) 11,6 20,8 63,4<br />

Australia (n= 1228) 4,7 38,2 54,2 (n=2048) 21,1 42,2 34,9 (n= 1421) 15,1 47,9 34,7<br />

Austria (n= 1460) 4,8 23,3 64,2 (n= 1522) 9,4 32,8 54,1<br />

Azerbaijan (n= 2002) 2,5 11,5 80,3<br />

Bangladesh (n= 1500) 5,3 35,0 47,1<br />

Belarus (n= 2092) 3,3 17,9 73,3<br />

Belgium (n= 1145) 2,6 20,2 62,7 (n= 2792) 9,2 25,1 55,2 (n= 1912) 9,8 28,0 57,1<br />

Bosnia Herz. (n= 1200) 6,3 42,1 44,3<br />

Brazil (n= 1782) 9,9 34,8 51,2 (n= 1149) 6,2 28,0 62,4 (n= 1500) 7,8 24,9 64,5<br />

Bulgaria (n= 1034) 2,9 27,5 54,1 (n= 1000) 2,9 21,6 55,2 (n= 1001) 1,9 15,3 68,8<br />

Burkina Faso (n= 1534) 11,1 35,5 32,8<br />

277


Canada (n= 1254) 14,4 42,1 39,5 (n= 1730) 21,6 41,9 33,3 (n= 1931) 20,1 41,0 36,6 (n= 2148) 21,6 36 37,6<br />

Chile (n= 1500) 3,9 11,1 81,9 (n= 1200) 4,9 12,3 76,4 (n= 1000) 2,7 11,2 85<br />

Colombia (n= 6025) 7,2 26,9 59,3 (n= 3025) 2,4 18,9 78,1<br />

Croatia (n= 1003) 5,9 52,7 33,9<br />

Cyprus (n= 1050) 10,4 30,4 59<br />

Czech Republic (n*=2109) 8,1 24,8 51,3 (n= 1908) 8,3 27,3 54,8<br />

Denmark (n= 1182) 6,9 24,3 55,2 (n= 1030) 10,2 30,4 55,4 (n= 1023) 23,9 35,3 36,8<br />

Dom. Republic (n= 417) 4,8 22,3 58,8<br />

East Germany (n= 1336) 2,7 26,6 57,4 (n= 999) 5,1 36,8 49,9 (n= 1076) 5,7 35 52,8<br />

Egypt (n= 3000) 36,9 30,0 33,1 (n= 3051) 1,3 7,5 91,1<br />

Estonia (n= 1008) 2,9 34,8 48,6 (n= 1005) 2,6 24,0 62,3<br />

Ethiopia (n= 1500) 7,8 29 33,5<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1003) 8,2 41,7 46,3 (n= 588) 11,6 59,0 15,1 (n= 1038) 13,5 50,1 30,0 (n= 1014) 15,3 45,2 34,7<br />

France (n= 1200 ) 9,7 32,9 50,7 (n= 1002) 11,3 36,3 42,8 (n= 1615) 12,1 39,4 40,1 (n= 1001) 13,9 41,7 42,6<br />

Georgia (n= 2008) 5,6 9,2 82,3<br />

Ghana (n= 1534) 1,8 27,9 63<br />

Great Britain (n= 1167) 6,4 28,7 60,3 (n= 1484) 14,3 33,5 49,6 (n= 1000) 16,2 42,9 37,8 (n= 1041) 16,2 35,7 42,3<br />

Greece (n= 1142) 4,3 19,9 68,0<br />

278


Guatemala (n= 1000) 1,2 8,8 85,5<br />

Hungary (n= 999) 2,0 13,2 77,6 (n= 1000) 2,6 17,4 74,2<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> (n= 927) 7,6 55,7 34,1 (n= 702) 21,1 52,0 25,5 (n= 968) 17,6 58,4 22,5<br />

India (n= 2500) 15,2 40,5 35,3 (n= 2002) 10,5 21,6 47,3 (n= 2001) 11,7 22,9 43,2<br />

Indonesia (n= 1004) 2,7 18,8 72,0 (n= 2015) 3,1 17,8 68,3<br />

Iraq (n= 2701) 13,2 20,4 51<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 1217) 6,3 30,9 55,2 (n= 1000) 7,2 32,4 57,6 (n= 1012) 8,6 34,3 52,5<br />

Israel (n= 1199) 7,4 30,3 58,0<br />

Italy (n= 1348) 5,2 25,4 60,3 (n= 2018) 8,6 41,6 41,3 (n= 2000) 9,7 40,8 43,1 (n= 1012) 18,6 47 28,6<br />

Japan (n= 1204) 2,4 40,4 31,6 (n= 1011) 2,7 37,1 30,7 (n= 1362) 6,6 50,4 21,5 (n= 1096) 5,6 41 32,6<br />

Jordan (n= 1223) 2,3 6,0 90,3 (n= 1200) 2,9 6 89,8<br />

Latvia (n= 903) 2,9 26,0 41,5 (n= 1013) 3,7 24,6 64,0<br />

Lithuania (n= 1000) 6,5 53,2 28,9 (n= 1018) 3,6 28,8 44,6<br />

Luxembourg (n= 1211) 8,2 36,2 47,2<br />

Macedonia (n= 1055) 12,5 37,2 43,7<br />

Malaysia (n= 1201) 3,1 16,5 80,4<br />

Mali (n= 1534) 7 25 44,5<br />

Malta (n= 467) 10,1 13,1 54,0 (n= 393) 12,2 17,6 52,0 (n= 1002) 10,0 27,5 59,7<br />

279


Mexico (n= 1837) 1,1 15,5 69,1 (n= 1531) 6,0 30,4 50,1 (n= 1535) 1,7 14,4 65,8 (n= 1560) 2,7 12,9 72,4<br />

Moldova (n= 1008) 3,4 10,6 68,3 (n= 1046) 4,8 20,2 72,2<br />

Montenegro (n= 1060) 13,6 48,2 23,6<br />

Morocco (n= 2264) 5,5 24,0 56,9 (n= 1200) 7 29,7 50,8<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n= 1221) 5,6 26,4 60,3 (n=1017) 8,2 32,4 57,3 (n= 1003) 21,3 38,4 40,1 (n= 1050) 11,9 36,9 38,7<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> (n= 1201) 16,2 48,3 20,6 (n= 954 15,4 48,1 22,9<br />

N. Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 312) 4,9 34,0 56,2 (n=304) 8,9 28,3 58,9 (n= 1000) 13,0 24,8 57,4<br />

Norway (n= 1051) 6,4 35,8 52,0 (n= 1239) 11,1 48,1 33,8 (n=1127) 17,9 55,8 25,5 (n= 1025) 24 42,1 33,4<br />

Peru (n= 1501) 7,2 38,5 47,2 (n= 1500) 4,6 24 66<br />

Philippines (n= 1200) 4,4 12,1 82,5<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n= 1920) 5,3 24,3 56,0 (n= 1095) 4,1 23,5 71,1 (n= 1000) 4,7 18,5 71,9<br />

Portugal (n= 1185) 4,1 28,0 57,5 (n= 1000) 4,4 31,6 59,2<br />

Romania (n= 1146) 1,5 13,1 64,0 (n= 1776) 1 12,8 78,7<br />

Russia (n= 1961) 3,8 30,8 50,5 (n= 2500) 2,4 20,8 69,9 (n= 2033) 2,4 16,7 73,6<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a (n= 1507) 3,6 8,5 80,7<br />

Serbia (n= 1200) 17,8 30,1 44,8 (n= 1220) 15,2 35 42<br />

Singapore (n= 1512) 1,3 17,6 79,9<br />

Slovakia (n*=1136) 3,3 27,7 44,1 (n= 1331) 3,5 24,0 55,3<br />

280


Slovenia (n= 1035) 6,4 37,ß 36,8 (n= 1006) 7,7 50,6 35,2 (n= 1037) 5,9 42 45,4<br />

South Africa (n= 1596) 7,9 19,1 57,1 (n= 2736) 14,1 32,6 45,2 (n= 3000) 20,1 27,8 47,6 (n= 2988) 9,4 23 61,5<br />

South Korea (n= 970) 1,8 36,6 38,2 (n= 1251) 10,5 46,1 36,2 (n= 1200) 7,3 44,7 20,3 (n= 1200) 6 52,2 41,7<br />

Spain (n= 2303) 7,7 24,2 54,4 (n= 4147) 4,5 20,8 56,5 (n= 2409) 4,9 20,1 60,8 (n= 1200) 6,3 31,6 52<br />

Sweden (n= 954) 8,0 48,8 37,2 (n= 1047) 15,8 58,9 20,9 (n= 1015) 32,4 53,9 12,0 (n= 1003) 27,5 47,3 22,2<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1212) 11,5 32,5 50,8 (n= 1241) 18,8 35,9 43,1<br />

Tanzania (n= 1171) 4,6 21,9 70,8<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> (n= 1534) 2,5 15,1 82,2<br />

Trinidad <strong>and</strong><br />

Tobago<br />

(n= 1002) 8,1 47,8 40,7<br />

Turkey (n= 1039) 5,2 21,4 66,7 (n= 4607) 5,5 28,1 65,0 (n= 1346) 5,3 29,5 63,9<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a (n= 1002) 10,4 29,5 39,8<br />

Ukraine (n= 1195) 4,5 22,2 62,2 (n= 1000) 4,2 15,9 74,1<br />

Uruguay (n= 1000) 3,6 16,2 71 (n= 1000) 1,9 8,3 88,7<br />

USA (n= 2325) 14,7 32,2 46,5 (n= 1839) 18,0 42,5 34,4 (n= 1200) 25,2 50,2 22,8 (n= 1249) 19,2 52 26,4<br />

Venezuela (n= 1200) 1,5 5,8 88,9<br />

Vietnam (n= 1000) 0,5 14,7 75,8 (n= 1495) 0,5 12,6 85,2<br />

West Germany (n= 1305) 5,8 28,4 56,6 (n= 2101) 8,9 32,7 47,2 (n= 1037) 10,4 38,9 42,9 (n= 988) 12,3 41,6 41,4<br />

281


Zambia (n= 1500) 12,9 32,2 50,1<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values.<br />

Question wording: “Now I’d like you to look at this card, I’m going to read out some different form of political action that people can take, <strong>and</strong> I’d like you to<br />

tell me, for each one, whether you have actually done any of these things, whether you might do it or would never, under any circumstances, do it, (…) Joining in<br />

boycotts”.<br />

*<br />

Czech Republic <strong>and</strong> Slovakia: During the third WVS wave two surveys were conducted, one in 1990, another one in 1991, With the exception of “Attending<br />

lawful demonstrations”, the results are based on the 1991 surveys with 2109 Czech respondents <strong>and</strong> 1136 Slovak respondents, respectively.<br />

Azerbaijan, Australia, Armenia, Brazil, Uruguay, Colombia, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Norway, Dominican Republic, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Georgia, Belarus: Data from 1995-97<br />

WVS.<br />

282


Attending Lawful Demonstrations<br />

1981 1990 1999-2000 2005-2007<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never do<br />

Albania (n= 999) 16,1 50,8 17,8 (n= 1000) 19,3 40,8 18,5<br />

Algeria (n= 1282) 18,5 28,2 45,9<br />

Andorra (n= 1003) 39,9 40,2 19,1<br />

Argentina (n= 1005) 19,1 27,2 37,3 (n= 1002) 14,6 20,5 62,1 (n= 1280) 12,7 22,1 61,4 (n= 1002) 16,3 37,3 39,3<br />

Armenia (n= 2000) 27,5 27,4 42,4<br />

Australia (n= 1228) 12,0 33,6 52,5 (n=2048) 17,6 41,5 39,5 (n= 1421) 19,8 46 32,7<br />

Austria (n= 1460) 9,7 31,9 52,5 (n= 1522) 16,3 35,2 46,6<br />

Azerbaijan (n= 2002) 19,5 21,1 54,6<br />

Bangladesh (n=1500) 6,3 34,9 45,5<br />

Belarus (n= 2092) 19,4 29,9 47,4<br />

Belgium (n= 1145) 12,6 28,8 48,4 (n= 2792) 23,7 27,5 42,4 (n=1912) 34,7 29,7 32,7<br />

Bosnia-Herz. (n= 1200) 8,6 45,5 39,6<br />

Brazil (n= 1782) 18,5 39,3 40,9 (n= 1149) 24,7 37,9 37,0 (n= 1500) 18,2 39,6 41,3<br />

Bulgaria (n= 1034) 12,9 42,8 32,8 (n= 1000) 12,6 32,5 40,0 (n= 1001) 10,9 30,8 46,3<br />

283


Burkina Faso (n= 1534) 18,1 41 22,2<br />

Canada (n= 1254) 13,1 42,7 41,5 (n= 1730) 20,2 41,5 35,2 (n= 1931) 19,2 40,2 39,0 (n= 2148) 24,3 41,6 30,5<br />

Chile (n= 1500) 29,5 23,3 45,3 (n= 1200) 15,1 21,8 58,1 (n= 1000) 16,7 18,7 63,5<br />

Colombia (n= 6025) 11 40,7 44,3 (n= 3025) 13,7 38,6 47,6<br />

Croatia (n= 1003) 6,6 61,1 27,0<br />

Cyprus (n= 1050) 27,7 34,7 37,5<br />

Czech Republic (n*=3033) 30,3 42,9 19,5 (n= 1908) 26,1 39,2 28,7<br />

Denmark (n= 1182) 15,6 32,8 45,8 (n= 1030) 27,0 31,4 40,1 (n=1023) 28,4 38,1 30,4<br />

Dom. Republic (n= 417) 24,0 48,0 18,7<br />

East Germany (n= 1336) 48,3 33,9 14,2 (n= 999) 43,3 31,0 20,2 (n= 1076) 35,1 35,2 25,4<br />

Egypt (n= 3000) 2,5 15,0 82,5 (n= 3051) 1,5 7,2 91,3<br />

Estonia (n= 1008) 23,9 39,0 29,3 (n= 1005) 10,1 27,9 52,2<br />

Ethiopia (n= 1500) 19,2 31,9 21,7<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1003) 14,2 35,8 48,1 (n= 588) 11,9 44,9 27,2 (n= 1038) 13,7 41,2 39,0 (n= 1014) 9,9 37 48,5<br />

France (n= 1200 ) 24,5 27,4 45,1 (n= 1002 ) 31,2 30,9 33,2 (n= 1615) 38,5 32,9 25,6 (n= 1001) 37,2 31,6 30,4<br />

Georgia (n= 2008) 18,9 14,5 64,7<br />

Ghana (n= 1534) 8 41,1 45,6<br />

Great Britain (n= 1167) 8,7 31,6 57,2 (n= 1484) 13,4 34,0 51,0 (n= 1000) 13,0 37,3 46,3 (n= 1041) 15,9 43 37<br />

284


Greece (n= 1142) 46,1 37,1 13,7<br />

Guatemala (n= 1000) 2,1 8,5 88,8<br />

Hungary (n= 999) 4,2 25,9 65,9 (n= 1000) 4,3 28,1 63,3<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> (n= 927) 14,3 62,2 21,7 (n= 702) 23,4 51,7 23,5 (n= 968) 20,5 58,7 19,7<br />

India (n= 2500) 15,3 39,1 36,0 (n= 2002) 18,8 24,1 39,0 (n= 2001) 15 20,8 41,4<br />

Indonesia (n= 1004) 10,9 24,1 60,1 (n= 2015) 12,9 31,4 47,8<br />

Iraq (n= 2701) 16,5 25,6 44,1<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 1217) 12,6 37,4 43,7 (n= 1000) 16,3 40,9 41,3 (n= 1012) 20,3 44,0 32,6<br />

Israel (n= 1199) 23,9 30,2 43,2<br />

Italy (n= 1348) 22,1 20,5 50,5 (n= 2018) 32,1 35,1 27,5 (n= 2000) 33,0 37,3 24,5 (n= 1012) 34,3 31,5 29,5<br />

Japan (n= 1204) 7,0 20,9 47,6 (n= 1011) 9,4 18,1 43,7 (n= 1362) 9,6 27,5 37,5 (n= 1096) 8 25 45,9<br />

Jordan (n= 1223) 3,0 6,1 89,4 (n= 1200) 3,7 7,6 87,4<br />

Latvia (n= 903) 30,5 36,0 19,9 (n= 1013) 23,7 34,8 35,9<br />

Lithuania (n= 1000) 32,5 48,5 14,5 (n= 1018) 9,6 40,2 33,4<br />

Luxembourg (n= 1211) 26,7 40,3 27,4<br />

Macedonia (n= 1055) 16,5 40,2 37,0<br />

Malaysia (n= 1201) 2,7 25,5 71,9<br />

Mali (n= 1534) 19,2 33,8 26,3<br />

285


Malta (n= 467) 9,6 16,1 54,8 (n= 393) 17,0 13,7 52,3 (n= 1002) 24,7 21,8 51,9<br />

Mexico (n= 1837) 7,6 31,5 47,2 (n= 1531) 20,2 39,7 31,9 (n= 1535) 3,4 9,4 77,5 (n= 1560) 15,7 41,6 39,3<br />

Moldova (n= 1008) 15,8 23,2 48,5 (n= 1046) 18,2 32,1 48,2<br />

Montenegro (n= 1060) 16,6 38,6 27,7<br />

Morocco (n= 2264) 9,6 25,8 54,3 (n= 1200) 16,3 25,1 47,3<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n= 1221) 11,8 30,1 52,2 (n= 1017) 24,5 38,3 36,0 (n= 1003) 31,2 36,8 32,0 (n= 1050) 18,5 33,7 39,6<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> (n= 1201) 18,6 45,6 22,6 (n= 954) 18,2 44,1 25,6<br />

N. Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 312) 17,7 26,6 52,5 (n=304) 17,8 29,3 46,7 (n= 1000) 20,8 28,7 45,4<br />

Norway (n= 1051) 18,3 43,4 36,2 (n= 1239) 19,0 54,2 24,4 (n=1127) 26,1 52,3 21,5 (n= 1025) 29,1 45,1 25,6<br />

Peru (n= 1501) 16,1 48,3 29,8 (n= 1500) 23,5 39 35,2<br />

Philippines (n= 1200) 5,8 13,8 79,8<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n= 1920) 14,1 38,9 37,0 (n= 1095) 10,0 31,0 58,4 (n= 1000) 9,6 28,8 56,4<br />

Portugal (n= 1185) 23,0 45,4 24,5 (n= 1000) 14,2 37,2 44,1<br />

Romania (n= 1146) 13,4 37,5 39,7 (n= 1776) 6 27,4 61,4<br />

Russia (n= 1961) 30,5 39,0 23,0 (n= 2500) 22,5 31,5 42,3 (n= 2033) 15 26,8 52,3<br />

Rw<strong>and</strong>a (n= 1507) 13,5 16,2 64,5<br />

Serbia (n= 1200) 22,6 30,3 41,2 (n= 1220) 20,6 33 38,9<br />

Singapore (n= 1512) 1,2 22,5 75,0<br />

286


Slovakia (n*=1602) 19,3 47,0 21,1 (n= 1331) 13,0 39,5 38,7<br />

Slovenia (n= 1035) 8,5 42,2 33,5 (n= 1006) 9,2 54,7 30,2 (n= 1037) 12 47 36,5<br />

South Africa (n= 1595) 6,4 25,3 51,4 (n= 2736) 13,3 37,6 40,2 (n= 3000) 21,8 30,6 42,4 (n= 2988) 12,2 33,3 50<br />

South Korea (n= 970) 5,4 27,4 42,7 (n= 1251) 18,9 31,5 44,8 (n= 1200) 18,7 36,7 27,0 (n= 1200) 11,4 45 43,5<br />

Spain (n= 2303) 21,0 31,7 35,2 (n= 4147) 20,3 32,8 34,1 (n= 2409) 24,3 34,2 32,9 (n= 1200) 34,4 38 23,5<br />

Sweden (n= 954) 15,1 49,8 33,3 (n= 1047) 21,8 56,8 18,0 (n= 1015) 34,7 51,9 11,8 (n= 1003) 30,9 46,5 21<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1212) 16,1 31,5 48 (n= 1241) 27,8 37,9 33,2<br />

Tanzania (n= 1171) 28,1 54,8 15,5<br />

Thail<strong>and</strong> (n= 1534) 2,3 12,8 84,6<br />

Trinidad <strong>and</strong><br />

Tobago<br />

(n= 1002) 15,1 58,5 24,3<br />

Turkey (n= 1030) 5,3 29,5 58,5 (n= 4607) 6,8 34,2 57,4 (n= 1346) 5,8 30,6 62,4<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a (n= 1002) 11,9 28,7 39,2<br />

Ukraine (n= 1195) 17,3 31,2 43,1 (n= 1000) 15,8 26,1 53,6<br />

Uruguay (n= 1000) 18 22 59,1<br />

USA (n= 2325) 11,9 35,8 45,6 (n= 1839) 14,8 41,7 38,9 (n= 1200) 21,1 53,5 24,0 (n= 1249) 14,7 53,3 29,4<br />

Venezuela (n= 1200) 7,6 33,5 56,2<br />

Vietnam (n= 1000) 1,8 35,4 56,5 (n= 1495) 0,9 19 78,2<br />

287


West Germany (n= 1305) 11,9 31,9 49,9 (n= 2101) 19,1 38,9 34,9 (n= 1037) 21,2 40,8 31,6 (n= 988) 23,3 39,7 32,7<br />

Zambia (n= 1500) 20,3 41,1 34,4<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values.<br />

Question wording: “Now I’d like you to look at this card, I’m going to read out some different form of political action that people can take, <strong>and</strong> I’d like you to<br />

tell me, for each one, whether you have actually done any of these things, whether you might do it or would never, under any circumstances, do it, (…) Attending<br />

lawful demonstrations”.<br />

* Czech Republic: During the third WVS wave two surveys were conducted, one in 1990, another one in 1991, The results for “Attending lawful<br />

demonstrations” are based on a combined survey with 3033 Czech respondents <strong>and</strong> 1602 Slovak respondents, respectively.<br />

Azerbaijan, Australia, Armenia, Brazil, Uruguay, Colombia, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Norway, Dominican Republic, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Georgia, Belarus: Data from 1995-97<br />

WVS.<br />

288


Joining Unofficial Strikes<br />

1981 1990 1999-2000<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never<br />

do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never<br />

do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never<br />

do<br />

Albania (n= 999) 0,3 2,9 87,9 (n= 1000) 1,8 4,0 79,8<br />

Algeria (n= 1282) 8,0 7,2 76,0<br />

Argentina (n= 1005) 7,7 12,3 61,3 (n= 1002) 7,0 10,5 78,0 (n= 1280) 5,1 9,7 80,7<br />

Armenia (n= 2000) 14,4 17,8 63,9<br />

Australia (n= 1228) 5,0 22,2 70,2 (n=2048) 7,9 31,9 58,0<br />

Austria (n= 1460) 0,8 8,6 85,4 (n= 1522) 2,1 17,0 77,1<br />

Azerbaijan (n=2002) 8,5 10,6 76,2<br />

Belgium (n= 1145) 3,2 12,0 73,2 (n= 2792) 6,5 16,2 67,7 (n=1912) 8,0 18,1 69,4<br />

Bosnia-Herzegovina (n= 1200) 3,3 28,2 59,9<br />

Brazil (n= 1782) 7,6 18,6 73,0 (n= 1149) 6,4 14,8 78,1<br />

Bulgaria (n= 1034) 2,7 21,4 60,8 (n= 1000) 4,0 17,0 61,0<br />

Canada (n=1254) 4,5 15,8 75,6 (n= 1730) 6,7 26,7 61,8 (n= 1931) 6,9 25,7 65,1<br />

Chile (n= 1500) 8,0 15,9 73,5 (n= 1200) 8,4 14,7 71,6<br />

Colombia (n= 6025) 4,7 17,8 74,3<br />

289


Croatia (n= 1003) 2,6 33,4 55,3<br />

Czech Republic (n*=2109) 12,7 27,5 46,1 (n= 1908) 9,1 25,7 54,3<br />

Denmark (n= 1182) 8,4 21,4 62,3 (n= 1030) 16,7 22,4 57,1 (n=1023) 21,3 29,5 45,1<br />

Dominican Republic (n= 417) 7,4 10,6 71,0<br />

East Germany (n= 1336) 1,3 12,4 75,0 (n= 999) 1,5 14,7 75,8<br />

Egypt (n= 3000) 0,1 2,6 97,3<br />

Estonia (n= 1008) 3,7 16,6 68,1 (n= 1005) 1,2 10,6 77,8<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1003) 5,5 14,8 76,1 (n= 588) 6,6 28,6 46,9 (n= 1038) 2,4 23,2 67,2<br />

France (n= 1200) 9,5 21,8 63,5 (n=1002 ) 9,4 23,2 60,6 (n= 1615) 11,7 29,9 51,9<br />

Georgia (n= 2008) 9,6 5,7 82,3<br />

Great Britain (n= 1167) 7,5 15,3 73,9 (n= 1484) 8,3 18,3 71,0 (n= 1000) 9,1 26,8 58,5<br />

Greece (n= 1142) 9,1 30,5 53,8<br />

Hungary (n= 999) 2,7 25,7 65,8 (n= 1000) 0,8 9,1 85,0<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> (n= 927) 3,0 24,1 70,5 (n= 702) 4,8 19,8 72,5 (n= 968) 3,3 28,9 65,6<br />

India (n= 2500) 5,4 14,6 69,4 (n= 2002) 7,8 14,1 57,1<br />

Indonesia (n= 1004) 1,9 6,0 85,5<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 1217) 4,9 20,6 65,7 (n= 1000) 3,6 22,5 70,2 (n= 1012) 5,9 29,5 59,4<br />

Israel (n= 1199) 6,8 23,2 65,6<br />

290


Italy (n= 1348) 2,3 8,0 83,4 (n= 2018) 5,1 16,2 69,9 (n= 2000) 5,0 14,5 73,6<br />

Japan (n= 1204) 2,2 10,8 64,0 (n= 1011) 2,2 9,4 59,5 (n= 1362) 2,0 14,4 57,9<br />

Jordan (n= 1223) 1,4 2,8 94,4<br />

Latvia (n= 903) 4,4 21,7 46,7 (n= 1013) 1,0 13,2 77,3<br />

Lithuania (n= 1000) 2,3 43,5 41,2 (n= 1018) 1,7 18,5 56,2<br />

Luxembourg (n= 1211) 6,0 21,0 65,0<br />

Macedonia (n= 1055) 4,5 25,8 61,4<br />

Malta (n= 467) 3,9 10,1 66,2 (n= 393) 4,8 11,3 64,5 (n= 1002 4,5 15,7 76,1<br />

Mexico (n= 1837) 1,6 8,9 76,7 (n= 1531) 6,6 32,3 50,9 (n= 1535) 2,3 10,7 78,3<br />

Moldova (n= 1008) 10,8 19,6 55,6<br />

Montenegro (n= 1060) 3,4 22,6 47,0<br />

Morocco (n= 2264) 1,5 2,2 87,8<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n= 1221) 1,6 12,2 80,5 (n= 1017) 2,6 20,3 75,0 (n= 1003) 4,3 28,1 67,5<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> (n= 1201) 4,2 28,4 49,1<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 312) 5,6 19,6 71,9 (n=304) 9,9 16,8 69,7 (n= 1000) 9,0 19,1 66,3<br />

Norway (n= 1051) 3,3 10,6 83,1 (n= 1239) ** 23,7 56,3 17,0 (n=1127) 5,1 27,5 65,9<br />

Peru (n= 1501) 3,7 13,9 76,1<br />

Philippines (n= 1200) 2,2 6,3 91,1<br />

291


Pol<strong>and</strong> (n= 1929) 5,4 16,4 64,6 (n= 1095) 4,7 15,8 78,6<br />

Portugal (n= 1185) 3,3 17,8 71,2 (n= 1000) 2,9 19,6 73,0<br />

Romania (n= 1146) 1,0 7,4 81,5<br />

Russia (n= 1961) 2,2 25,3 57,5 (n= 2500) 1,5 15,1 76,5<br />

Serbia (n= 1200) 6,8 26,8 57,3<br />

Singapore (n= 1512) - - -<br />

Slovakia (n*= 1136) 5,6 29,8 43,8 (n= 1331) 1,9 17,1 62,4<br />

Slovenia (n= 1035) 1,3 6,6 74,8 (n= 1006) 3,4 30,3 58,9<br />

South Africa (n= 1595) 2,6 12,0 68,0 (n= 2736) 5,0 16,5 67,7 (n= 3000) 11,8 12,8 67,4<br />

South Korea (n= 970) 1,1 10,6 61,0 n,a, (n= 1200) 7,6 43,8 28,8<br />

Spain (n= 2303) 6,2 17,6 64,3 (n= 4147) 5,6 16,3 62,8 (n= 2409) 7,3 18,3 63,0<br />

Sweden (n= 954) 1,5 23,5 69,1 (n= 1047) 2,9 38,3 52,4 (n= 1015) 4,4 45,8 46,2<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1212) 1,8 15,1 76,2<br />

Turkey (n= 1030) 1,4 6,0 86,2 (n= 4607) 1,8 12,5 83,8<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a (n= 1002) 4,7 17,1 55,1<br />

Ukraine (n= 1195) 2,4 14,2 71,4<br />

Uruguay (n= 1000) 9,4 18,1 64,4<br />

USA (n= 2325) 3,0 15,3 75,1 (n= 1839) 4,6 28,5 61,9 (n= 1200) 5,8 37,2 53,9<br />

292


Venezuela (n= 1200) 2,4 6,1 87,9<br />

Vietnam (n= 1000) 0,3 9,6 82,3<br />

West Germany (n= 1305) 1,6 11,1 80,8 (n= 2101) 2,1 12,1 75,2 (n= 1037) 1,8 15,4 76,1<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values.<br />

Question wording: “Now I’d like you to look at this card, I’m going to read out some different form of political action that people can take, <strong>and</strong> I’d like you to<br />

tell me, for each one, whether you have actually done any of these things, whether you might do it or would never, under any circumstances, do it, (…) Joining<br />

unofficial strikes”.<br />

* Czech Republic <strong>and</strong> Slovakia: During the third WVS wave two surveys were conducted, one in 1990, another one in 1991, With the exception of “Attending<br />

lawful demonstrations”, the results are based on the 1991 surveys with 2109 Czech respondents <strong>and</strong> 1136 Slovak respondents, respectively,<br />

** Please note that in the1990 Norwegian sample the question aimed at “official” <strong>and</strong> not “unofficial” strikes. The unusually high participation rates are therefore<br />

due to the question wording.<br />

Azerbaijan, Australia, Armenia, Brazil, Uruguay, Colombia, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Norway, Dominican Republic, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Georgia : Data from 1995-97 WVS.<br />

293


Occupying Buildings<br />

1981 1990 1999-2000<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never<br />

do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never<br />

do<br />

Have<br />

done<br />

Might<br />

do<br />

Would<br />

never<br />

do<br />

Albania (n= 999) 0,3 2,0 92,1 (n= 1000) 0,4 1,4 82,2<br />

Algeria (n= 1282) 1,4 3,5 85,3<br />

Argentina (n= 1005) 3,0 7,2 71,6 (n= 1002) 2,6 7,8 84,7 (n= 1280) 1,8 8,7 85,1<br />

Armenia (n= 2000) 1,1 11,8 82,3<br />

Australia (n= 1228) 2,0 14,3 81,7 - - - - (n=2048) 1,9 17,0 78,7<br />

Austria (n= 1460) 0,7 6,3 88,1 (n= 1522) 0,6 9,3 86,5<br />

Azerbaijan (n= 2002) 0,1 3 91,7<br />

Belgium (n= 1145) 2,4 14,6 70,0 (n= 2792) 3,9 18,8 68,2 (n=1912) 5,5 24,6 65,3<br />

Bosnia-Herzegovina (n= 1200) 0,5 11,0 80,6<br />

Brazil (n= 1782) 1,9 12,3 83,5 (n= 1149) 2,7 15,8 79,7<br />

Bulgaria (n= 1034) 1,3 11,9 72,0 (n= 1000) 2,5 11,5 67,5<br />

Canada (n=1254) 2,4 14,1 79,2 (n= 1730) 2,9 19,6 72,4 (n= 1931) 3,0 17,6 76,7<br />

Chile (n= 1500) 4,1 10,6 82,9 (n= 1200) 4,0 9,1 81,2<br />

Colombia (n= 6025) 1,3 10,7 85,1<br />

294


Croatia (n= 1003) 0,7 16,6 73,3<br />

Czech Republic (n*=2109) 1,3 13,8 67,9 (n= 1908) 0,9 9,1 79,9<br />

Denmark (n= 1182) 2,2 8,2 83,9 (n= 1030) 2,0 6,5 89,1 (n=1023) 2,7 11,7 82,6<br />

Dominican Republic (n= 417) 4,1 24,2 59,5<br />

East Germany (n= 1336) 0,8 12,0 76,4 (n= 999) 0,8 13,1 78,4<br />

Egypt (n= 3000) 2,4 2,4 95,1<br />

Estonia (n= 1008) 0,7 6,3 82,5 (n= 1005) 0,1 4,6 88,0<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1003) 0,7 9,1 87,0 (n= 588) 1,4 17,0 67,7 (n= 1038) 0,1 14,0 79,2<br />

France (n=1200 ) 6,7 20,8 67,2 (n=1002 ) 7,2 22,7 61,7 (n= 1615) 8,4 32,9 51,8<br />

Georgia (n=2008) 0,7 2 95<br />

Great Britain (n= 1167) 2,2 10,1 85,4 (n= 1484) 2,3 9,8 86,1 (n= 1000) 2,1 15,3 77,9<br />

Greece (n= 1142) 26,0 25,2 43,7<br />

Hungary (n= 999) 0,1 3,7 91,1 (n= 1000) 0,5 4,1 90,4<br />

Icel<strong>and</strong> (n= 927) 0,4 8,3 89,2 (n= 702) 1,3 9,1 86,9 (n= 968) 0,7 12,0 85,4<br />

India (n= 2500) 0,7 5,2 84,3 (n= 2002) 3,5 9,7 64,0<br />

Indonesia (n= 1004) 3,7 8,8 79,4<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 1217) 1,9 13,7 78,4 (n= 1000) 1,9 18,4 75,6 (n= 1012) 2,2 15,3 78,4<br />

Israel (n= 1199) 0,9 6,4 88,4<br />

295


Italy (n= 1348) 4,2 10,5 77,6 (n= 2018) 6,1 17,9 67,6 (n= 2000) 7,5 16,4 69,0<br />

Japan (n= 1204) 0,5 4,5 73,9 (n= 1011) 0,3 5,2 70,1 (n= 1362) 0,1 6,2 73,8<br />

Jordan (n= 1223) 0,0 0,5 98,0<br />

Latvia (n= 903) 0,9 4,2 72,8 (n= 1013) 0,3 3,8 90,5<br />

Lithuania (n= 1000) 0,2 17,9 67,9 (n= 1018) 1,1 9,1 65,2<br />

Luxembourg (n= 393) 2,2 8,2 66,2 (n= 1211) 1,4 16,6 72,0<br />

Macedonia (n= 1055) 1,0 14,1 75,6<br />

Malta (n= 467) 1,5 4,9 73,7 (n= 1002 1,2 12,8 82,3<br />

Mexico (n= 1837) 1,4 10,6 74,9 (n= 1531) 4,6 25,3 58,6 (n= 1535) 1,8 6,5 82,0<br />

Moldova (n= 1008) 1,8 9,5 73,4<br />

Montenegro (n= 1060) 0,8 12,4 62,2<br />

Morocco (n= 2264) 0,4 4,1 84,3<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n= 1221) 2,0 18,3 73,5 (n= 1017) 3,0 21,3 73,3 (n= 1003) 4,9 23,3 71,7<br />

New Zeal<strong>and</strong> (n= 1201) 1,0 16,0 65,0<br />

Nigeria (n= 1001) (n= 2022)<br />

Northern Irel<strong>and</strong> (n= 312) 1,0 7,9 86,2 (n= 304) 1,0 7,6 87,2 (n= 1000) 2,3 9,7 82,4<br />

Norway (n= 1051) 0,9 3,8 93,6 (n= 1239) 1,0 9,7 84,5 (n=1127) 1,8 10,3 87,5<br />

Pakistan (n= 2000)<br />

296


Peru (n= 1501) 1,6 11,5 80,7<br />

Philippines (n= 1200) 0,6 6,4 92,2<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n= 1920) 3,4 12,8 70,1 (n= 1095) 2,8 15,6 80,6<br />

Portugal (n= 1185) 1,3 10,2 80,6 (n= 1000) 1,1 20,9 72,8<br />

Puerto Rico (n= 720)<br />

Romania (n= 1146) 0,4 5,0 84,3<br />

Russia (n= 1961) 0,7 10,1 72,9 (n= 2500) 0,6 7,8 83,9<br />

Serbia (n= 1200) 1,8 15,0 74,0<br />

Singapore (n= 1512) - - -<br />

Slovakia (n*= 1136) 0,5 14,1 62,4 (n= 1331) 0,7 11,9 69,3<br />

Slovenia (n= 1035) 0,7 10,0 72,5 (n= 1006) 1,5 22,1 68,8<br />

South Africa (n= 1596) 1,3 7,2 72,9 (n= 2736) 1,9 16,0 64,5 (n= 3000) 4,8 17,9 66,8<br />

South Korea (n= 970) 1,3 7,1 64,4 (n= 1251) 10,1 34,7 49,4 - - - -<br />

Spain (n= 2303) 2,6 11,6 74,6 (n= 4147) 2,4 16,1 64,9 (n= 2409) 2,4 13,9 71,8<br />

Sweden (n= 954) 0,3 11,0 84,6 (n= 1047) 0,2 18,3 76,2 (n= 1015) 2,5 18,5 76,1<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n= 1212) 1 12,3 80,6<br />

Turkey (n= 1030) 1,2 2,5 89,6 (n= 4607) 0,5 4,5 92,8<br />

Ug<strong>and</strong>a (n= 1002) 5,3 25,7 25,5<br />

297


Ukraine (n= 1195) 0,8 4,7 84,7<br />

Uruguay (n= 1000) 7 15,2 69,9<br />

USA (n= 2325) 1,4 8,4 83,8 (n= 1839) 1,4 16,5 77,4 (n= 1200) 3,9 23,7 67,1<br />

Venezuela (n= 1200) 1,7 8,0 87,3<br />

Vietnam (n= 1000) 1,0 18,7 65,0<br />

West Germany (n= 1305) 1,0 9,9 83,2 (n= 2101) 1,0 9,0 82,1 (n= 1037) 0,7 13,0 80,8<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values.<br />

Question wording: “Now I’d like you to look at this card, I’m going to read out some different form of political action that people can take, <strong>and</strong> I’d like you to<br />

tell me, for each one, whether you have actually done any of these things, whether you might do it or would never, under any circumstances, do it, (…)<br />

Occupying buildings or factories”.<br />

* Czech Republic <strong>and</strong> Slovakia: During the third WVS wave two surveys were conducted, one in 1990, another one in 1991, With the exception of “Attending<br />

lawful demonstrations”, the results are based on the 1991 surveys with 2109 Czech respondents <strong>and</strong> 1136 Slovak respondents, respectively,<br />

Azerbaijan, Australia, Armenia, Brazil, Uruguay, Colombia, New Zeal<strong>and</strong>, Norway, Dominican Republic, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Georgia: Data from 1995-97 WVS.<br />

298


European Social Survey<br />

2002 <strong>and</strong> 2004 (Round 1 <strong>and</strong> 2)<br />

Worn or displayed campaign badge/sticker<br />

2002 (Round 1) 2004 (Round 2)<br />

Yes No Yes No<br />

France (n=1503) 11,4 88,4 12,9 87,1 France (n=1806)<br />

Norway (n=2036) 22,8 77,2 23,2 76,6 Norway (n=1760)<br />

Austria (n=2257) 7,8 91,0 8,6 89,7 Austria (n=2256)<br />

Belgium (n=1899) 7,4 92,3 5,2 94,7 Belgium (n=1778)<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2039) 9,4 90,5 8,5 91,5 Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2141)<br />

Czech Republic (n=1360) 4,9 92,9 4,6 93,5 Czech Republic (n=3026)<br />

Germany (n=2919) 5,8 94,2 4,4 95,6 Germany (n=2870)<br />

Denmark (n=1506) 5,1 94,6 8,0 91,8 Denmark (n=1487)<br />

Spain (n=1729) 9,7 89,1 11,5 87,7 Spain (n=1663)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2000) 15,7 84,3 14,1 85,8 Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2022)<br />

UK (n=2052) 9,8 90,1 7,5 92,3 UK (n=1897)<br />

Greece (n=2566) 2,7 96,2 2,6 97,2 Greece (n=2406)<br />

Hungary (n=1685) 3,2 96,6 1,4 98,2 Hungary (n=1498)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2046) 9,2 88,4 7,5 90,0 Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2286)<br />

Israel (n=2499) 11,8 87,6<br />

Italy (n=1207) 7,3 92,0<br />

Luxembourg (n=1552) 5,2 94,4 5,6 94,1 Luxembourg (n=1635)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=2364) 3,8 96,1 5,4 94,5 Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1881)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=2110) 2,9 96,5 3,8 95,9 Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=1716)<br />

Portugal (n=1511) 6,5 92,8 2,5 97,0 Portugal (n=2052)<br />

Sweden (n=1999) 10,7 89,1 12,7 87,1 Sweden (n=1948)<br />

Slovenia (n=1519) 2,1 96,6 1,9 97,3 Slovenia (n=1442)


2,7 96,8 Estonia (n=1989)<br />

33,5 63,9 Icel<strong>and</strong> (n=579)<br />

5,2 93,8 Slovakia (n=1512)<br />

13,3 85,8 Ukraine (n=2031)<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent<br />

things from going wrong, During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (,,,) Worn or<br />

displayed a campaign badge/sticker,”<br />

Signed Petition<br />

2002 (Round 1) 2004 (Round 2)<br />

Yes No Yes No<br />

France (n=1503) 34,7 65,0 31,8 67,8 France (n=1806)<br />

Norway (n=2036) 37,2 62,6 38,5 61,1 Norway (n=1760)<br />

Austria (n=2257) 27,0 71,9 24,3 73,9 Austria (n=2256)<br />

Belgium (n=1899) 33,6 65,5 21,9 77,8 Belgium (n=1778)<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2039) 39,0 60,2 37,9 61,2 Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2141)<br />

Czech Republic (n=1360) 15,8 82,5 13,3 84,7 Czech Republic (n=3026)<br />

Germany (n=2919) 30,4 69,4 32,4 67,5 Germany (n=2870)<br />

Denmark (n=1506) 28,1 71,5 28,8 70,3 Denmark (n=1487)<br />

Spain (n=1729) 23,9 74,8 24,7 75,1 Spain (n=1663)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2000) 24,0 75,9 25,5 74,2 Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2022)<br />

UK (n=2052) 40,0 59,8 35,4 64,1 UK (n=1897)<br />

Greece (n=2566) 4,7 94,7 3,0 96,9 Greece (n=2406)<br />

Hungary (n=1685) 4,2 95,6 6,3 93,3 Hungary (n=1498)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2046) 27,0 70,7 22,3 75,3 Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2286)<br />

Israel (n=2499) 18,2 80,6<br />

Italy (n=1207) 17,2 81,7<br />

Luxembourg (n=1552) 28,6 70,4 20,7 78,8 Luxembourg (n=1635)<br />

300


Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=2364) 22,3 77,2 23,4 76,2 Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1881)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=2110) 6,8 92,6 9,3 90,3 Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=1716)<br />

Portugal (n=1511) 7,3 92,0 4,5 95,0 Portugal (n=2052)<br />

Sweden (n=1999) 40,4 58,7 48,4 51,1 Sweden (n=1948)<br />

Slovenia (n=1519) 11,7 87,2 5,7 93,6 Slovenia (n=1442)<br />

4,1 95,5 Estonia (n=1989)<br />

47,5 49,9 Icel<strong>and</strong> (n=579)<br />

24,9 72,9 Slovakia (n=1512)<br />

9,3 89,1 Ukraine (n=2031)<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent<br />

things from going wrong, During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (,,,) Signed a<br />

petition,”<br />

Taken part in a lawful demonstration<br />

2002 (Round 1) 2004 (Round 2)<br />

Yes No Yes No<br />

France (n=1503) 17,9 82,0 12,8 87,1 France (n=1806)<br />

Norway (n=2036) 9,0 91,0 10,6 89,4 Norway (n=1760)<br />

Austria (n=2257) 9,5 89,5 6,5 92,1 Austria (n=2256)<br />

Belgium (n=1899) 8,4 91,0 6,5 93,5 Belgium (n=1778)<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2039) 7,9 92,1 8,8 91,2 Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2141)<br />

Czech Republic (n=1360) 4,5 93,5 3,3 94,7 Czech Republic (n=3026)<br />

Germany (n=2919) 10,6 89,4 8,5 91,5 Germany (n=2870)<br />

Denmark (n=1506) 8,3 91,4 5,4 94,4 Denmark (n=1487)<br />

Spain (n=1729) 17,3 81,5 33,9 65,7 Spain (n=1663)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2000) 2,0 98,0 2,0 98,0 Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2022)<br />

UK (n=2052) 4,4 95,6 3,7 96,1 UK (n=1897)<br />

Greece (n=2566) 4,5 95,1 5,0 95,0 Greece (n=2406)<br />

301


Hungary (n=1685) 3,7 96,1 1,6 98,0 Hungary (n=1498)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2046) 6,9 90,4 5,7 92,0 Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2286)<br />

Israel (n=2499) 9,8 89,2<br />

Italy (n=1207) 10,9 88,5<br />

Luxembourg (n=1552) 20,7 78,6 14,8 85,1 Luxembourg (n=1635)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=2364) 2,9 96,8 4,4 95,4 Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1881)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=2110) 1,3 98,2 1,6 98,2 Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=1716)<br />

Portugal (n=1511) 4,3 95,0 3,5 96,3 Portugal (n=2052)<br />

Sweden (n=1999) 6,4 93,5 7,5 92,5 Sweden (n=1948)<br />

Slovenia (n=1519) 2,7 96,1 1,6 97,7 Slovenia (n=1442)<br />

2,0 97,6 Estonia (n=1989)<br />

15,2 83,2 Icel<strong>and</strong> (n=579)<br />

3,7 95,5 Slovakia (n=1512)<br />

21,6 77,8 Ukraine (n=2031)<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent<br />

things from going wrong, During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (,,,) Taken part in<br />

a lawful demonstration,”<br />

Boycotted certain products<br />

2002 (Round 1) 2004 (Round 2)<br />

Yes No Yes No<br />

France (n=1503) 26,6 73,2 29,9 69,8 France (n=1806)<br />

Norway (n=2036) 36,6 63,3 23,5 76,4 Norway (n=1760)<br />

Austria (n=2257) 21,2 77,1 19,1 78,4 Austria (n=2256)<br />

Belgium (n=1899) 12,7 86,6 9,8 89,9 Belgium (n=1778)<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2039) 31,3 68,3 24,9 74,9 Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2141)<br />

Czech Republic (n=1360) 10,5 86,7 6,7 90,3 Czech Republic (n=3026)<br />

Germany (n=2919) 26,0 73,8 21,9 77,9 Germany (n=2870)<br />

302


Denmark (n=1506) 22,8 76,8 28,2 71,2 Denmark (n=1487)<br />

Spain (n=1729) 7,8 90,3 13,9 85,6 Spain (n=1663)<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2000) 26,8 73,0 29,3 70,7 Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2022)<br />

UK (n=2052) 26,0 73,6 20,5 79,1 UK (n=1897)<br />

Greece (n=2566) 8,4 90,3 5,1 94,8 Greece (n=2406)<br />

Hungary (n=1685) 4,8 94,9 5,1 94,3 Hungary (n=1498)<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2046) 13,3 84,3 10,6 86,8 Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2286)<br />

Israel (n=2499) 14,8 84,1<br />

Italy (n=1207) 7,5 91,9<br />

Luxembourg (n=1552) 15,7 78,6 14,0 85,1 Luxembourg (n=1635)<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=2364) 10,4 89,4 8,3 91,1 Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=1881)<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=2110) 3,6 95,8 5,0 94,5 Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=1716)<br />

Portugal (n=1511) 3,4 95,9 2,0 97,5 Portugal (n=2052)<br />

Sweden (n=1999) 32,3 67,2 34,8 65,2 Sweden (n=1948)<br />

Slovenia (n=1519) 5,1 93,6 2,1 97,2 Slovenia (n=1442)<br />

4,1 95,2 Estonia (n=1989)<br />

27,6 70,5 Icel<strong>and</strong> (n=579)<br />

11,2 86,2 Slovakia (n=1512)<br />

1,8 97,4 Ukraine (n=2031)<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent<br />

things from going wrong, During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (,,,) Boycotted<br />

certain products,”<br />

303


Bought product for political/ethical/environmental reason<br />

2002 (Round 1)<br />

Yes<br />

No<br />

France (n=1503) 28,0 71,7<br />

Norway (n=2036) 11,5 88,4<br />

Austria (n=2257) 29,2 69,1<br />

Belgium (n=1899) 26,8 72,6<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2039) 44,3 55,2<br />

Czech Republic (n=1360) 21,9 74,9<br />

Germany (n=2919) 39,1 60,6<br />

Denmark (n=1506) 43,6 56,0<br />

Spain (n=1729) 11,4 86,9<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2000) 41,8 58,1<br />

UK (n=2052) 32,3 67,6<br />

Greece (n=2566) 6,5 92,7<br />

Hungary (n=1685) 10,4 89,2<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2046) 24,0 73,3<br />

Israel (n=2499) 17,6 81,5<br />

Italy (n=1207) 6,5 92,8<br />

Luxembourg (n=1552) 29,6 69,2<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=2364) 25,7 74,2<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=2110) 9,8 89,6<br />

Portugal (n=1511) 6,8 92,3<br />

Sweden (n=1999) 54,9 44,7<br />

Slovenia (n=1519) 9,5 88,9<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent<br />

things from going wrong, During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (,,,) Deliberately<br />

bought certain products for political, ethical or environmental reasons,”<br />

304


Participated in illegal protest activities<br />

2002 (Round 1)<br />

Yes<br />

No<br />

France (n=1503) 2,6 97,1<br />

Norway (n=2036) 0,8 99,2<br />

Austria (n=2257) 1,3 97,7<br />

Belgium (n=1899) 2,4 97,1<br />

Switzerl<strong>and</strong> (n=2039) 1,9 98,0<br />

Czech Republic (n=1360) 1,3 96,9<br />

Germany (n=2919) 1,1 98,8<br />

Denmark (n=1506) 1,1 98,6<br />

Spain (n=1729) 1,7 96,2<br />

Finl<strong>and</strong> (n=2000) 0,3 99,6<br />

UK (n=2052) 0,8 99,2<br />

Greece (n=2566) 1,5 98,0<br />

Hungary (n=1685) 0,8 99,1<br />

Irel<strong>and</strong> (n=2046) 0,8 97,0<br />

Israel (n=2499) 1,3 97,6<br />

Italy (n=1207) 1,8 97,6<br />

Luxembourg (n=1552) 3,5 95,5<br />

Netherl<strong>and</strong>s (n=2364) 0,4 99,4<br />

Pol<strong>and</strong> (n=2110) 0,2 99,3<br />

Portugal (n=1511) 0,3 98,9<br />

Sweden (n=1999) 0,8 99,2<br />

Slovenia (n=1519) 0,8 97,8<br />

Where values do not add up to 100 percent, it is due to missing values,<br />

Question wording: “There are different ways of trying to improve things in [country] or help prevent<br />

things from going wrong, During the last 12 months, have you done any of following? (,,,) Participated<br />

in illegal protest activities,”<br />

305

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!