08.01.2014 Views

Forests Sourcebook - HCV Resource Network

Forests Sourcebook - HCV Resource Network

Forests Sourcebook - HCV Resource Network

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Box 2.13<br />

Water Services Provided by <strong>Forests</strong>: Claims and Reality<br />

Claim<br />

<strong>Forests</strong> slow runoff<br />

<strong>Forests</strong> increase total annual water flow<br />

<strong>Forests</strong> increase dry season water flow<br />

<strong>Forests</strong> increase precipitation<br />

<strong>Forests</strong> reduce flooding<br />

<strong>Forests</strong> reduce erosion<br />

Reality<br />

True<br />

Because of increased evapotranspiration, forests usually<br />

reduce total annual water flow<br />

Exception: Cloud forests<br />

Unclear<br />

Minor effect, except at continental scale<br />

True at small scales, not at large scales<br />

Depends on use that is made of deforested areas<br />

Sources: Bruijnzeel 2004; Calder 1999; Chomitz and Kumari 1998.<br />

Charging service users<br />

It is sometimes asserted that water users will never pay for<br />

services. This assertion is manifestly false. In Costa Rica, a<br />

variety of water users (hydroelectric producers, bottlers,<br />

municipal water supply systems, agribusinesses, hotels)<br />

are paying to conserve the watersheds from which they<br />

draw their water, generating about US$500,000 annually<br />

in payments. Other examples exist throughout Central<br />

and South America, and in South Africa. In Kenya, the<br />

Nairobi Water Company has indicated its willingness in<br />

principle to pay for watershed protection. The principal<br />

challenge is to demonstrate to users that they will, in fact,<br />

benefit from making such payments, by reducing or<br />

avoiding costs from reduced water services. Nairobi<br />

Water, for example, is currently spending about<br />

US$150,000 a year in additional water treatment and<br />

desilting costs at its Sasumua treatment plant as a result of<br />

upstream degradation.<br />

In general, the primary interlocutors in such discussions<br />

are not the ultimate consumers of the water services<br />

but the companies and public agencies that generate<br />

hydropower, provide domestic water services, or distribute<br />

irrigation water. In many cases, funding for payments<br />

comes from the existing budgets of these agencies. Thus,<br />

Nairobi Water would finance payments for upstream conservation<br />

from the savings resulting from reduced costs at<br />

its treatment plant. Only in rare instances is it necessary to<br />

increase fees to consumers to pay for PES. In those<br />

instances, experience has shown that this can be achieved<br />

with public support if the need for and use of the revenue<br />

are clearly explained.<br />

As noted above, charging biodiversity users is difficult if<br />

not impossible. Most available funding from biodiversity<br />

users (for example, from the GEF) is short term, limiting its<br />

use to paying for the up-front costs of PES mechanism<br />

establishment or to capitalization of a trust fund.<br />

Paying service providers<br />

For PES to have the desired effect, the payments must reach<br />

the land users and do so in a way that motivates them to<br />

change their land use decisions. This is not easy. The historical<br />

record is replete with examples of efforts to induce land<br />

users to adopt particular land use practices, for a variety of<br />

reasons and using a variety of payment mechanisms. Most<br />

have very little to show for their efforts.<br />

In general, several principles are clear:<br />

Payments need to be ongoing. The benefits being sought<br />

are generally ongoing benefits, which will be enjoyed year<br />

after year as long as appropriate land uses are maintained.<br />

For this to occur, land users must receive payments as long<br />

as they maintain the land use. All too often, payments have<br />

been frontloaded into a few years. Predictably, however,<br />

when payments cease, any leverage over land users’ behavior<br />

also ceases.<br />

Payments need to be targeted. Environmental services<br />

depend on both the kind of land use and its location. An<br />

undifferentiated payment system that pays everyone the<br />

same will be much more expensive than a targeted scheme.<br />

It will also make it difficult to tailor interventions to the<br />

particular requirements of given situations.<br />

Perverse incentives need to be avoided. Particular care<br />

needs to be taken to avoid perverse incentives. For example,<br />

88 CHAPTER 2: ENGAGING THE PRIVATE SECTOR IN FOREST SECTOR DEVELOPMENT

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!