08.01.2014 Views

Forests Sourcebook - HCV Resource Network

Forests Sourcebook - HCV Resource Network

Forests Sourcebook - HCV Resource Network

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Historically, low-income producers have been at a disadvantage<br />

in accessing markets, leading to a need to address<br />

this issue by jointly building on local human and natural<br />

capital assets, and building the institutional framework for<br />

good governance and distributive aspects of growth over<br />

time (see figure 1.2; Dürr 2002; Scherr, White, and<br />

Kaimowitz 2003, 2004; Sunderlin, Dewi, and Puntodewo<br />

2006).<br />

OPERATIONAL ASPECTS<br />

There are many opportunities for forest management models<br />

to scale up the benefits they deliver for forest conservation<br />

and the rural poor or low-income producers. However,<br />

large gaps exist in information and experience and there are<br />

major challenges in finding the right market niches, supporting<br />

local forest businesses, and reforming policies to<br />

enable profitable market participation by local people.<br />

Addressing these challenges will require coordinated action<br />

by governments, international institutions, conservation<br />

and development organizations, and community producer<br />

organizations. Such action is necessary to level the playing<br />

field for low- income producers and give them a real chance<br />

to succeed.<br />

Two areas that would benefit from interventions in collaboration<br />

with client governments are removal of policy<br />

barriers and development of forest businesses.<br />

Potential measures for removing policy barriers include<br />

the following (based on Scherr, White, and Kaimowitz 2003,<br />

2004; Sunderlin, Dewi, and Puntodewo 2006):<br />

■<br />

■<br />

■<br />

■<br />

■<br />

■<br />

Secure forest access and tenure rights of local people (see<br />

note 1.4, Property and Access Rights).<br />

Remove state monopolies and other controls on harvest<br />

and marketing that are common in several Bank client<br />

countries. However, decisions on the extent and phasing<br />

of deregulation need to carefully consider potential<br />

impacts on Indigenous Peoples and other forestdependent<br />

communities and provide for capacitybuilding<br />

initiatives to avoid adverse effects and enhance<br />

their benefits from deregulation.<br />

Remove or revise regulatory barriers and excessive regulation<br />

that limits local forest producers from using their<br />

own or public forests. For example, in some regions of<br />

India, 10 separate permits are required for community<br />

forest producers to complete a timber sale. In other<br />

countries, indigenous communities have long-term<br />

rights to extensive tracts of natural forest, but they do not<br />

have the right to commercially exploit them.<br />

Revoke policies that discriminate against small producers<br />

(see box 1.22). For example, in Bolivia forest policy<br />

reforms have included formal recognition of indigenous<br />

groups’ forest rights, lowered concession fees for smallscale<br />

forest producers, and simplified the process for<br />

accessing municipal forests.<br />

Facilitate the creation of forest user associations or producer<br />

groups to create economies of scale and to increase<br />

bargaining power (see note 2.2, Small and Medium<br />

Enterprises).<br />

Actively involve local producers in forest policy negotiations<br />

with private industry, government agencies, and<br />

Figure 1.2<br />

Forest Market Development Strategy for Low-Income Producers<br />

Local people<br />

• Forest communities<br />

• Public forest users<br />

• Small-scale farmers<br />

• Landless workers<br />

Commercial<br />

market<br />

opportunities<br />

• Low-grade timber<br />

• High-value timber<br />

• Industrial pulpwood<br />

• Certified wood<br />

• Nontimber forest<br />

products<br />

• Processed products<br />

• Payments for<br />

ecosystem services<br />

Local<br />

comparative<br />

advantages<br />

• Control of forest<br />

resources<br />

• Lower costs<br />

structure<br />

• Forest management<br />

capacity<br />

• Lower supply risks<br />

• Attractive to socially<br />

responsible markets<br />

Develop forest business<br />

• Improve market position<br />

• Strengthen producers<br />

• Forge business partnerships<br />

• Pursue new financing<br />

• Encourage business<br />

service providers<br />

• Establish enterprise<br />

development programs<br />

• Target education and<br />

research<br />

Remove policy barriers<br />

• Secure local rights<br />

• Reduce regulatory burden<br />

• “Level playing field”<br />

• Involve producers in<br />

policy negotiations<br />

• Protect the poorest<br />

Outcomes<br />

Reduce<br />

poverty<br />

Increase<br />

market<br />

supply<br />

Conserve,<br />

restore<br />

forest<br />

resources<br />

Source: Scherr, White, and Kaimowitz 2004.<br />

NOTE 1.5: MAKING MARKETS WORK FOR THE FOREST-DEPENDENT POOR 57

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!