04.01.2014 Views

Report

Report

Report

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

170 QUANTIFICATION OF BENEFITS FROM ECONOMIC COOPERATION IN SOUTH ASIA<br />

For cellular mobile it committed to four suppliers in<br />

addition to the government owned operator. The<br />

commitment also included the possibility of review of<br />

regulatory principles in the future. International Long<br />

Distance, however, remained a government monopoly<br />

and no bypass of the network facilities owned by the<br />

government has been permitted.<br />

Bangladesh also submitted an MFN exemption list<br />

to permit the government or the government-run<br />

operator to apply differential measures, such as<br />

accounting rates, in bilateral agreements with other<br />

operators or countries. Bangladesh has not submitted<br />

an offer to the WTO or at least it is not available in the<br />

public domain.<br />

The fact that the applicable regime is not bound<br />

for Bangladesh, (and for that matter for all SAFTA<br />

countries) cannot be for reasons to protect the incumbent<br />

supplier and gradually introduce it to competition.<br />

8 The reality on the ground is that competition<br />

already exists, and while the commitment does not<br />

permit bypass of government owned operator facilities,<br />

the applicable regime in Bangladesh is vastly different.<br />

An interconnection regime is in place and private long<br />

distance operators can carry traffic both within and<br />

outside the country. The reason must be therefore be<br />

found elsewhere. Binding the applicable regime under<br />

GATS rules out the possibility or at least makes it<br />

difficult to backtrack on liberalisation. However, entry<br />

restrictions in telecom are becoming increasingly<br />

difficult to justify given technological progress and the<br />

acknowledged benefits of competition. Therefore, the<br />

option value of ‘backtracking’ is also unlikely to provide<br />

the answer. The only real possibility is that Bangladesh<br />

like other SAFTA countries will look to trade off<br />

increased market access in telecom under GATS to<br />

secure benefits in sectors of their comparative<br />

advantage, such as Mode 4.<br />

India<br />

Prior to the liberalisation of the 1990s, the telecommunication<br />

sector in India was under a public monopoly,<br />

which was then considered essential due to the<br />

public good nature of the services. In the 1990s, Indian<br />

government gave up its monopoly and gradually<br />

introduced competition to enhance investment, improve<br />

productivity and the growth rate. The entry of private<br />

and foreign players led to significant expansion in<br />

telecommunication network, introduction of new<br />

technologies and striking improvement in productivity.<br />

As a consequence, India, today, has one of the largest<br />

telecommunication networks in the world. Given the<br />

rapid growth of the sector and huge investment potential,<br />

the country is an attractive destination for foreign<br />

direct investment. On its part, India needs to enhance<br />

the growth of telecommunication sector to sustain its<br />

global competitiveness in knowledge-based services.<br />

Before the mid-1990s, government was the sole<br />

provider of telecommunication services in India and<br />

all telecommunication services were provided by the<br />

incumbent monopoly – department of telecommunication<br />

(DoT). The first step towards deregulation was<br />

the announcement of the national telecommunication<br />

policy (NTP 1994). Although NTP 94 was a major step<br />

towards liberalisation, there were some problems in its<br />

implementation, among them being the non existence<br />

of an independent regulator (Kathuria 2007).<br />

The inadequacies of NTP 94 led to the formulation<br />

of a new, more elaborate policy – NTP 99, which tried<br />

to infuse more competition in the sector and also<br />

recognised the role of investment in the economy and<br />

convergence of IT, media, telecommunication and<br />

consumer electronics. It envisaged provision of telecom<br />

services to all Indian villages at affordable prices and<br />

the provision of high-level services. It led to a shift to a<br />

system of one-time entry fee combined with revenue<br />

sharing payments from the license fee bid system, while<br />

duopoly rights were discontinued in order to allow for<br />

unlimited competition. The private sector was allowed<br />

to provide domestic long-distance services and, from<br />

April 2002, international long distance voice services,<br />

with no restriction on the number of participants.<br />

In the past 15 years, telecommunication sector of<br />

India witness major changes due to liberalisation and<br />

technological changes. Today, there are no restrictions<br />

on the entry of new players in basic, national long<br />

distance (NLD), international long distance (ILD), internet<br />

service provider (ISP) and infrastructure businesses.<br />

Four operators are allowed in cellular mobile in each<br />

service area. This has led to intense competition and a<br />

downward trend in tariffs. Some of the strategies being<br />

employed by service providers to compete in the market<br />

are bundling, segmentation across subscriber types, customisation,<br />

etc. Due to intense competition, many private<br />

players found it difficult to remain financially viable.<br />

This led to mergers and acquisitions and emergence of<br />

few big players. India, now, has one of the largest telecommunication<br />

networks in the world and its regulatory<br />

regime is at par with international developments.<br />

8<br />

The classic infant industry type of protection.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!