02.01.2014 Views

Connecting the Future - Greenpeace UK

Connecting the Future - Greenpeace UK

Connecting the Future - Greenpeace UK

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future:<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable<br />

energy strategy<br />

A report by Dr Bridget Woodman<br />

of <strong>the</strong> University of Exeter<br />

Commissioned by <strong>Greenpeace</strong><br />

www.greenpeace.org.uk<br />

Canonbury Villas London N1 2PN<br />

+44 (0)20 7865 8100<br />

September 2008


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

<br />

FOREWORD<br />

INTRODUCTION<br />

1. ENERGY SYSTEMS<br />

1.1 The international context<br />

1.1.1 Germany<br />

1.1.2 Spain<br />

1.1.3 Conclusions: <strong>the</strong> international context<br />

2. <strong>UK</strong> TARGETS AND POLICY DELIVERY<br />

3. REDUCING ENERGY INTENSITY: EFFICIENCY AND DEMAND<br />

3.1 Business and industry<br />

3.1.1 Emissions trading<br />

3.1.2 Climate Change Levy and Climate Change Agreements<br />

3.1.3 Carbon Reduction Commitment<br />

3.1.4 O<strong>the</strong>r measures<br />

3.2 Domestic energy efficiency and demand reduction<br />

3.2.1 Energy Efficiency Commitment and Carbon Emission Reduction Target<br />

3.2.3 Building regulations, Zero Carbon Homes and <strong>the</strong> Code for<br />

Sustainable Homes<br />

3.2.4 O<strong>the</strong>r measures<br />

3.3 Conclusions: reducing energy intensity<br />

4. SUSTAINABLE ENERGY SYSTEMS<br />

4.1 Low-carbon electricity<br />

4.1.1 Renewables<br />

4.1.2 Green tariffs<br />

4.1.3 Microgeneration and <strong>the</strong> Low Carbon Buildings Programme<br />

4.2 Addressing heat<br />

4.2.1 Combined heat and power<br />

4.2.2 Biomass strategy<br />

4.3 Conclusions: sustainable energy systems<br />

5. BROADER SYSTEM ISSUES<br />

5.1 Planning<br />

5.2 Infrastructure<br />

5.3 Regulation and market design<br />

5.4 Social and institutional inertia<br />

5.5 Conclusions: broader system issues<br />

CONCLUSIONS<br />

REFERENCES<br />

GLOSSARY OF ACRONYMS<br />

3<br />

5<br />

9<br />

12<br />

12<br />

12<br />

14<br />

16<br />

21<br />

22<br />

23<br />

27<br />

29<br />

30<br />

31<br />

31<br />

32<br />

34<br />

35<br />

37<br />

38<br />

38<br />

45<br />

47<br />

49<br />

50<br />

51<br />

53<br />

55<br />

57<br />

58<br />

61<br />

62<br />

64<br />

66<br />

72<br />

77<br />

Cover: <strong>the</strong> ‘Arena’ concert hall in Berlin, Germany has a<br />

photovoltaic roof which supplies energy for floodlighting.<br />

©Langrock/Zenit/<strong>Greenpeace</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Foreword<br />

<br />

Foreword<br />

Back in <strong>the</strong> summer of 2005 – just before <strong>the</strong> G8 summit at Gleneagles on<br />

climate change – Prime Minister Tony Blair brought toge<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> world’s<br />

climate scientists in Exeter, to assess <strong>the</strong> latest climate science. Its conclusion?<br />

In order to avoid <strong>the</strong> worst effects of climate change, we need to stabilise<br />

global emissions within 10 years. At <strong>the</strong> end of 2007, <strong>the</strong> Intergovernmental<br />

Panel on Climate Change produced its latest assessment of <strong>the</strong> state of <strong>the</strong><br />

world’s climate, broadly confirming <strong>the</strong> findings of <strong>the</strong> Exeter Conference.<br />

At <strong>the</strong> beginning of August this year <strong>the</strong> clock really started ticking. We now<br />

have just 99 months to prevent <strong>the</strong> tipping point of catastrophic climate<br />

change. If global emissions have not been stabilised and begun declining by<br />

<strong>the</strong> end of 2015, <strong>the</strong>n our chances of keeping global temperature rise below<br />

two degrees – and <strong>the</strong>refore giving ourselves a good chance of avoiding<br />

catastrophic climate change – will be extremely remote.<br />

The need for a bold response from a nation that considers itself a world leader<br />

in tackling climate change has never been clearer, yet on too many fronts,<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> government seems intent upon repeating <strong>the</strong> mistakes of <strong>the</strong> past.<br />

From runways to new coal fired power stations, <strong>the</strong> government’s plans for<br />

resurrecting <strong>the</strong> icons that are <strong>the</strong> principle cause of climate change continue,<br />

despite <strong>the</strong> breadth of opposition marshalled against <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

Within this context, <strong>the</strong> government’s consultation on a new renewable<br />

energy strategy for <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> stands as a promising beacon of light. After years<br />

of timidity and failure, this consultation shows some small but encouraging<br />

signs that <strong>the</strong> government might just be starting to recognise <strong>the</strong> scale of<br />

potential for renewable energy in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>. The consultation proves that <strong>the</strong><br />

ambitious target of generating 15% of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s energy from renewable sources<br />

by 2020 (including electricity, heat and transport) is deliverable. It also shows<br />

though that in order to secure <strong>the</strong> enormous benefits this strategy could bring<br />

to <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s energy security, economy and <strong>the</strong> world’s climate, <strong>the</strong> government<br />

must put its money where its mouth is.<br />

As a contribution to <strong>the</strong> government’s consultation process, <strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong><br />

future systematically catalogues <strong>the</strong> history of initiatives, obligations and<br />

mechanisms introduced by <strong>the</strong> Labour government over <strong>the</strong> last decade to<br />

encourage renewable energy in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>, providing a comprehensive critique of<br />

Labour’s approach. It sets out clear recommendations for how <strong>the</strong> government<br />

can redress <strong>the</strong> missed opportunities over <strong>the</strong> last 10 years, and at last turn<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> into <strong>the</strong> renewable energy powerhouse it is so well placed to become,<br />

leading <strong>the</strong> world in showcasing <strong>the</strong> real solutions to <strong>the</strong> challenges of climate<br />

change and energy security.<br />

On efficiency, <strong>the</strong> report advocates a more aggressive demand reduction<br />

strategy as a tough approach to energy efficiency. But a more proactive<br />

approach is required than yet more voluntary schemes for which no one


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Foreword<br />

<br />

volunteers. It is time to regulate minimum standards and force manufacturers<br />

and builders to only design and produce smarter products, buildings and<br />

vehicles that use energy more effectively.<br />

We should also be looking closer to home, following Germany’s lead and using<br />

our own <strong>UK</strong> based companies for manufacturing <strong>the</strong> parts and technologies<br />

that we need to meet our targets. Nurturing our domestic industry would mean<br />

we could get parts more quickly, more easily and with more benefit to <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong><br />

economy. Then, like Germany, we could export our industry expertise. Right<br />

now, <strong>the</strong> first commercial wave farm is being assembled near Porto in Portugal,<br />

using wave power technology developed in Scotland. This technology could<br />

have been deployed in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> market if <strong>the</strong>re had been <strong>the</strong> proper support<br />

mechanisms in place.<br />

The <strong>UK</strong> has <strong>the</strong> best renewable energy resources in <strong>the</strong> European Union yet we<br />

are near <strong>the</strong> bottom of <strong>the</strong> European league table when it comes to exploiting<br />

it. In 2007 Spain installed eight times more wind capacity than <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>,<br />

Germany four times and France double. The government’s renewable energy<br />

strategy consultation could provide a blueprint for a green energy revolution<br />

in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>. It could slash emissions and meet <strong>the</strong> EU Renewable Energy Target.<br />

And its vision could put <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> back at <strong>the</strong> leading edge of technological and<br />

scientific innovation. But only if <strong>the</strong> government makes good on its proposals,<br />

follows through on <strong>the</strong> strategy and abandons its pursuit of new runways and<br />

coal fired power stations that will spell <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s reputation as a world<br />

leader on climate change.<br />

“The need for a bold<br />

response from a nation<br />

that considers itself a<br />

world leader in tackling<br />

climate change has never<br />

been clearer…”


Introduction<br />

56 Tomlinson Grove is a self sufficient zero fossil fuel energy development.<br />

The residential block in Bow, London is fitted with a wind turbine and solar panels.<br />

©Davison/<strong>Greenpeace</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Introduction<br />

<br />

Introduction<br />

In March 2007, <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> government signed up to an agreement that commits<br />

<strong>the</strong> EU to providing 20% of its energy from renewable resources and reducing<br />

its overall energy consumption by 20% by 2020. This is one of a series of<br />

measures designed to reduce <strong>the</strong> EU’s CO2 emissions and <strong>the</strong>reby contribute to<br />

<strong>the</strong> goal of limiting global temperature rise to a maximum of 2ºC above preindustrial<br />

levels (see Box 1) (European Council 2007). In January 2008, <strong>the</strong><br />

Commission published proposals for <strong>the</strong> different contributions to be required<br />

from each Member State in order for <strong>the</strong> EU as a whole to meet <strong>the</strong> renewable<br />

energy target: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s proposed share of energy from renewable sources by<br />

2020 is 15% (European Commission 2008).<br />

In March 2007 <strong>the</strong> EU Presidency reached<br />

<strong>the</strong> following conclusions:<br />

• ‘The European Council endorses an EU objective of a 30% reduction<br />

in greenhouse gas emissions by 2020 compared to 1990’<br />

(depending on action in o<strong>the</strong>r countries).<br />

• ‘The EU makes a firm independent commitment to achieve<br />

at least a 20% reduction of greenhouse gas emissions by<br />

2020 compared to 1990.’<br />

• The Presidency adopted an energy action plan based on proposals<br />

from <strong>the</strong> European Commission including <strong>the</strong> following targets:<br />

• ‘Saving 20% of <strong>the</strong> EU’s energy consumption<br />

compared to projections for 2020’<br />

• ‘A binding target of a 20% share of renewable<br />

energy in overall EU energy consumption by 2020’<br />

• ‘A 10 % binding minimum target to be achieved<br />

by all Member States for <strong>the</strong> share of biofuels in<br />

overall EU transport petrol and diesel consumption<br />

by 2020, to be introduced in a cost efficient way’.<br />

The <strong>UK</strong> government has repeatedly claimed a position of international leadership in<br />

<strong>the</strong> climate change debate and in efforts to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions.<br />

The publication of <strong>the</strong> government’s Stern Review on <strong>the</strong> economics of climate<br />

change was heralded as an international call to action. It argues that <strong>the</strong> impact of<br />

climate change will be equivalent to a loss in world GDP of between 5% and 20% if<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is no concerted action to mitigate it. It concludes that ‘<strong>the</strong> benefits of strong<br />

and early action far outweigh <strong>the</strong> economic costs of not acting’ (HM Treasury<br />

2006, p vi). The Prime Minister has recognised <strong>the</strong> urgency of acting on climate<br />

change, and that effective action will require commitment and decisive ‘governing


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Introduction<br />

<br />

not gimmickry’ (Brown 2007); while <strong>the</strong> Prime Minister’s Strategy unit has<br />

acknowledged that <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s international position in this field is heavily dependent on<br />

<strong>the</strong> commitment it shows to reducing emissions at home (Strategy Unit 2007, p 45):<br />

‘The credibility of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s international position is founded on <strong>the</strong><br />

strength of its own action and domestic performance.’<br />

Strong policy action, clarity of vision and delivery on targets will all be necessary to<br />

ensure that <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> achieves its aspiration to be a global leader on climate change.<br />

Despite this rhetoric of commitment and urgency, however, <strong>the</strong> Department<br />

of Trade and Industry (DTI) and its successor <strong>the</strong> Department of Business,<br />

Enterprise and Regulatory Reform (BERR) have actively sought, during<br />

negotiations, to minimise <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s contribution to <strong>the</strong> overall EU target. A memo<br />

leaked from BERR in 2007 showed that officials were at that time producing a<br />

strategy to commit <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> to sourcing only 9% of its energy from renewables<br />

by 2020 (BERR 2007). Even now that <strong>the</strong> proposed national levels have been<br />

published by <strong>the</strong> Commission, <strong>the</strong> government continues to be equivocal about<br />

<strong>the</strong> final allocation: instead of accepting <strong>the</strong> 15% figure on <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s<br />

relative wealth and potential for developing its ample renewable resources, <strong>the</strong><br />

government views it as a ‘good starting point for discussion’ within ongoing<br />

Council negotiations (BERR 2008a). At <strong>the</strong> same time, <strong>the</strong> government is trying<br />

to minimise <strong>the</strong> impact of whatever renewable energy target is finally agreed, for<br />

example by proposing that carbon capture and storage (CCS) projects attached<br />

to fossil fuel generating plants could be counted as contributing to <strong>the</strong> national<br />

renewables target (European Council 2008):<br />

‘As a means of incentivising support for <strong>the</strong>se projects, we should like<br />

to see <strong>the</strong>se projects taken into account in assessing Member States’<br />

compliance with national renewables targets. Of course CCS is not a<br />

renewable, but this could need to be [sic] treated as a special case …’<br />

Energy technology and infrastructure assets can last for decades, so if <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is no national commitment to putting in place as soon as possible <strong>the</strong> assets<br />

needed to achieve <strong>the</strong> EU’s 2020 targets, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>re will be little chance of<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> ei<strong>the</strong>r meeting those targets, or having sustainable energy systems for<br />

years to come. There would be long-term environmental and economic costs<br />

to missing <strong>the</strong> targets: <strong>the</strong> longer <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> takes to shift towards a low-carbon<br />

system, <strong>the</strong> higher <strong>the</strong> costs of action and <strong>the</strong> greater and <strong>the</strong> more greenhouse<br />

gases will be emitted in total before emissions start to tail off (DTI 2005). One<br />

reason is that delaying action to update or upgrade infrastructure will result in<br />

missing opportunities to do so incrementally; instead it will need to be upgraded<br />

or replaced rapidly at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong> target period, which will be more expensive<br />

and have negative effects on <strong>the</strong> wider economy. After years of hostility<br />

towards measures intended to reduce emissions, even <strong>the</strong> Confederation of<br />

British Industry (CBI) has come round to <strong>the</strong> position that delaying action will<br />

lead to higher costs in <strong>the</strong> long-term, and will also mean that <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> may lose<br />

out on <strong>the</strong> commercial opportunities offered by an international trade in


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Introduction<br />

<br />

low-carbon technologies (CBI 2007a). The long term nature of energy<br />

investments and <strong>the</strong> urgent need for action mean that policy which emphasises<br />

<strong>the</strong> short-term cost effectiveness of individual measures is misplaced: what is<br />

needed is a strategy for achieving sustainable energy systems in <strong>the</strong> long term.<br />

The absolute level of renewable energy output in 2020 will be determined by<br />

<strong>the</strong> extent to which measures to improve energy efficiency and reduce demand<br />

are effective. If such measures are successful, <strong>the</strong> level of renewable energy<br />

output required to meet 20% of total energy demand will be lower than if<br />

energy use continues to grow. The relationship between energy efficiency and<br />

<strong>the</strong> deployment of renewable energy technologies is <strong>the</strong>refore vital to achieving<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s EU targets. This is where a long-term, strategic policy vision is required.<br />

Given that <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s commitment to <strong>the</strong> EU targets came at <strong>the</strong> time <strong>the</strong><br />

government’s 2007 energy White Paper was being drafted, <strong>the</strong> need<br />

to develop a strategic approach to achieving <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s allocated 15%<br />

renewables target should have led at least to a reassessment of <strong>the</strong> policies<br />

being developed for <strong>the</strong> White Paper, or preferably to a reworking of <strong>the</strong><br />

government’s overall approach to energy systems. But <strong>the</strong> government missed<br />

this opportunity, and <strong>the</strong> White Paper’s target for 2020 is for all renewables to<br />

supply only around 5% of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s energy (DTI 2007). Less than a year after<br />

its publication, <strong>the</strong> government is <strong>the</strong>refore having to undertake a review of its<br />

overall renewable energy strategy. This is due to be published in Spring 2009,<br />

and may need to be supported by new legislation.<br />

However, even <strong>the</strong> development of this strategy appears to be flawed. The European<br />

targets address both energy consumption and <strong>the</strong> production of energy from<br />

renewable sources. Instead of trying to address both <strong>the</strong>se targets simultaneously<br />

to maximise <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> policy approach, <strong>the</strong> government is planning to<br />

address <strong>the</strong>m in separate consultation processes, <strong>the</strong>reby missing <strong>the</strong> opportunity to<br />

exploit any natural links between policy areas in order to maximise <strong>the</strong> reduction of<br />

energy demand and <strong>the</strong> increase in <strong>the</strong> use of renewable energy sources.<br />

Notwithstanding this limitation, <strong>the</strong> revised renewable energy strategy must<br />

usher in a new commitment to achieving large-scale deployment of renewable<br />

energy technologies if <strong>the</strong>re is to be any chance of meeting <strong>the</strong> EU target.<br />

With this in mind, <strong>the</strong> aim of this report is to outline <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s current renewable<br />

and sustainable energy policies and its performance, to date, in meeting both<br />

domestic and international targets, and to consider ways in which both policies<br />

and performance can be improved upon so as to increase <strong>the</strong> likelihood of <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>UK</strong> meeting its international responsibilities.


01<br />

Energy systems<br />

Win Pro Energy technicians working in <strong>the</strong> engine house<br />

of a 2.3 megawatt wind turbine at a height of 94 metres.<br />

©Langrock/Zenit/<strong>Greenpeace</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Energy systems<br />

10<br />

At <strong>the</strong> moment, policy makers tend to approach energy systems in a relatively<br />

short-term, simplistic way: for example, <strong>the</strong> main ways of ensuring security<br />

of supply are to build more generating capacity, and to secure greater supplies<br />

of fossil fuels. This is essentially <strong>the</strong> same predict-and-provide approach<br />

as has created <strong>the</strong> systems we have in place today: ensuring that demand<br />

is always met with sufficient supply, preferably at least cost. This approach<br />

would be understandable if policy makers’ only concern was <strong>the</strong> immediate<br />

security of supply, but it is inadequate both for dealing with <strong>the</strong> environmental<br />

problems caused by <strong>the</strong> energy industry – particularly climate change – and for<br />

encouraging new, initially more costly technologies to emerge and reach <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

potential. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> predict-and-provide model is based on <strong>the</strong> assumption<br />

of ever-growing demand, whereas new energy policies at both <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> and<br />

European levels are intended to limit or even reduce overall energy consumption.<br />

Encouraging <strong>the</strong> emergence of low-carbon energy systems will require a more<br />

sophisticated, dual approach, reducing energy use through increased efficiency<br />

and demand reduction, while at <strong>the</strong> same time putting in place <strong>the</strong> building<br />

blocks for a transition to a new style of energy system based around<br />

low-carbon technologies. In our current, fossil fuel based energy system,<br />

emissions can obviously be mitigated in <strong>the</strong> first instance by reducing how much<br />

energy we consume, and this encourages one-off policy initiatives which are<br />

often very cost-effective. So, for example, <strong>the</strong> decision to phase out old style<br />

light bulbs between 2008 and 2011 in favour of more efficient ones should<br />

deliver 1.2 MtC saving a year by 2020 (DTI 2006). However, this sort of<br />

one-off approach will not be enough in <strong>the</strong> longer-term, as we attempt to<br />

make <strong>the</strong> necessary permanent shifts in energy production and consumption<br />

to ensure long-term adoption of sustainable low-carbon energy systems.<br />

Achieving a deliberate change of system over a relatively short timescale<br />

will require determined action from policy makers, addressing <strong>the</strong> economic,<br />

regulatory, institutional and social barriers to technical change in a much more<br />

holistic way than has so far been <strong>the</strong> case.<br />

Many of <strong>the</strong> new low-carbon technologies do not conform to <strong>the</strong> characteristics<br />

of current energy systems. Often <strong>the</strong>y are small-scale, use renewable forms<br />

of energy and may operate intermittently. In contrast, <strong>the</strong> energy systems<br />

currently prevalent are largely based on fossil fuels and are overwhelmingly<br />

devised to deliver bulk quantities of energy or fuel in response to ever growing<br />

demand and to exploit economies of scale. Regulatory standards, <strong>the</strong> workings<br />

of <strong>the</strong> market, <strong>the</strong> operation of <strong>the</strong> transmission and distribution infrastructure,<br />

technical standards and o<strong>the</strong>r factors are designed or have evolved to<br />

support <strong>the</strong>se characteristics. Even large-scale forms of renewable electricity<br />

generation, such as offshore wind, do not conform to <strong>the</strong> overall characteristics<br />

of <strong>the</strong> system because <strong>the</strong>ir output is not necessarily constant. Renewable or<br />

small-scale low-carbon technologies thus have to operate in a system which<br />

ei<strong>the</strong>r does not support <strong>the</strong>m, or is actively hostile to <strong>the</strong>ir deployment and use.<br />

On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, it is important to recognise that <strong>the</strong>se technologies offer<br />

long-term advantages over traditional energy technologies. These advantages<br />

are not just environmental: <strong>the</strong>y also include enhanced security of supply


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Energy systems<br />

11<br />

through reduced reliance on fuel imports, and a degree of investment flexibility<br />

for new generating plant because of <strong>the</strong> small-scale modular nature of many<br />

renewables projects.<br />

Because of <strong>the</strong> interrelated nature of <strong>the</strong> components of current energy<br />

systems, mechanisms to encourage <strong>the</strong> emergence and implementation of<br />

new technologies cannot merely concentrate on individual aspects, such as<br />

offsetting <strong>the</strong>ir higher costs with subsidies. They must also mitigate or remove<br />

<strong>the</strong> wider barriers associated with <strong>the</strong> risks posed by competitive energy<br />

markets, technical standards designed to support current system configurations,<br />

and inadequate institutional arrangements for supporting new technologies and<br />

practices. While new technologies will ultimately have to be able to compete<br />

economically, <strong>the</strong> system in which <strong>the</strong>y are implemented needs to be sufficiently<br />

supportive for <strong>the</strong>m to become <strong>the</strong> logical choice for investment.<br />

The government does show some signs of recognising <strong>the</strong> importance of <strong>the</strong>se<br />

broader factors in its recent policy making. So, for example, <strong>the</strong> White Paper<br />

acknowledges that <strong>the</strong> current transmission system disadvantages renewable<br />

electricity: ‘The current technical, commercial and regulatory framework<br />

for transmission access will need to change to facilitate <strong>the</strong> cost effective<br />

integration of more diverse generation technologies into <strong>the</strong> electricity system.’<br />

(DTI 2007, para 5.3.75). However, this awareness has not yet been translated<br />

into effective policy. So, for example, a recent review of distributed generation<br />

acknowledges <strong>the</strong> barriers and disadvantages faced by small-scale generating<br />

technologies in a system designed around large-scale, centralised generation,<br />

but fails to suggest any significant measures to overcome <strong>the</strong> problem (DTI/<br />

Ofgem 2007). This could include, for example, allowing renewable generating<br />

technologies priority access to <strong>the</strong> electricity networks so that <strong>the</strong>ir output can<br />

displace that from fossil fuels stations. This measure is established in several<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r European countries, and is proving an effective means of reducing <strong>the</strong><br />

risk of investing in new renewable technologies by ensuring that <strong>the</strong>ir output<br />

can find a market.<br />

If <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> is to achieve its share of <strong>the</strong> EU renewables target, <strong>the</strong> government<br />

must not only rethink <strong>the</strong> policies set out in <strong>the</strong> White Paper, but also revise<br />

<strong>the</strong> thinking behind <strong>the</strong> White Paper, which is based on a limited understanding<br />

of what renewables and small-scale, more efficient generation can contribute<br />

to energy systems if <strong>the</strong> conditions for <strong>the</strong>ir deployment and operation are<br />

suitable. This in turn will require a shift from <strong>the</strong> current modular, piecemeal<br />

approach to policy making and technologies – for example, having <strong>the</strong><br />

Renewables Obligation to support more renewables generation, while at <strong>the</strong><br />

same time refusing to allow <strong>the</strong> technologies priority access to <strong>the</strong> networks<br />

– to a more strategic whole-system approach that can overcome <strong>the</strong> lock-in of<br />

existing technologies. Because of <strong>the</strong> long lived nature of energy investments,<br />

decisions made now will have implications for decades to come, so a new<br />

approach needs to be adopted now if <strong>the</strong>re is to be any chance of achieving<br />

low-carbon sustainable energy systems in time to meet <strong>the</strong> twin challenges of<br />

climate change and energy security.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Energy systems<br />

12<br />

1.1 The international context<br />

The government has stressed how ambitious <strong>the</strong> EU renewable targets are,<br />

and how demanding it will be to meet <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s allocated share. It strongly hints<br />

that it will seek to negotiate down <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s allocation on <strong>the</strong> grounds that <strong>the</strong><br />

country is starting from such a low base for renewable energy (BERR 2008c).<br />

So it is worth considering efforts in o<strong>the</strong>r EU states, which could provide<br />

lessons on how <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> can best meet its 15% allocation.<br />

1.1.1 Germany<br />

In Germany, under <strong>the</strong> 1990 Electricity Feed Act and <strong>the</strong> 2000 Renewable<br />

Energy Sources Act (Erneuerbare-Energien-Gesetz, or EEG), electricity<br />

suppliers are required to buy renewable output and pay a set price for it. This<br />

guarantees both a market for renewably generated electricity, and a price<br />

which allows an adequate rate of return on <strong>the</strong> financial investment in <strong>the</strong><br />

project. The prices are set according to which renewable technology is used,<br />

<strong>the</strong> year <strong>the</strong> project was built and <strong>the</strong> size of <strong>the</strong> plant. Although <strong>the</strong> tariff for a<br />

particular project is set for 20 years, giving <strong>the</strong> developer certainty about <strong>the</strong><br />

price <strong>the</strong>y will receive per unit of output, <strong>the</strong> tariffs for a technology as a class<br />

generally declines over time to reflect <strong>the</strong> falling costs of that technology as it is<br />

developed and refined. The EEG was revised in 2004 to adjust <strong>the</strong> tariffs: while<br />

some were raised, notably for photovoltaic installations, o<strong>the</strong>rs fell significantly,<br />

including that for onshore wind energy generation, to reflect <strong>the</strong> increasing<br />

cost effectiveness of <strong>the</strong> technology (Held, Ragwitz et al 2007).<br />

The EEG set a target of achieving 12.5% renewable electricity by 2010, and<br />

at least 20% by 2020. The target, however, has already been achieved, with<br />

renewables providing 14.2% of Germany’s electricity consumption in 2007.<br />

The cost of supporting renewably generated energy through <strong>the</strong> EEG is put<br />

at €4.3 bn in 2006 (€7.7bn minus € 3.4bn for energy companies’ avoided<br />

costs of purchasing conventional electricity) 1 . This translates to €1 ct/kWh, or<br />

around €1.45/month for a typical domestic customer (BMU 2008).<br />

The costs of <strong>the</strong> EEG should also be weighed against <strong>the</strong> broader socioeconomic<br />

benefits associated with <strong>the</strong> EEG. The Federation Ministry for <strong>the</strong><br />

Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety (Bundesministerium<br />

für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit, or BMU) estimates that<br />

employment in <strong>the</strong> renewable energy sector in Germany grew from 160,500 in<br />

2004 to 249,300 in 2007 (BMU 2007). Turnover from <strong>the</strong> construction and<br />

operation of renewable energy projects in Germany was around €24.6 billion<br />

in 2007, and export markets have grown strongly, with Germany achieving a<br />

global market share in renewable technologies of around 15% (BMU 2007).<br />

German policy has also encouraged <strong>the</strong> emergence of a renewable heat<br />

sector, with biomass plants increasingly playing a role. Biomass plants receive<br />

tariffs based on <strong>the</strong> specific technology and size of plant, but also <strong>the</strong> plant’s<br />

efficiency and <strong>the</strong> type of fuel used. The efficiency bonus is awarded if <strong>the</strong> heat<br />

produced by burning <strong>the</strong> biomass is also used, this has created an incentive to<br />

invest in heat distribution infrastructure 2 (BMU 2008). In addition, small scale<br />

1 <br />

These figures do not take into<br />

account downward effect on<br />

prices caused by renewables<br />

displacing <strong>the</strong> more expensive<br />

conventional generation (known<br />

as <strong>the</strong> merit order effect), nor<br />

avoided externalities associated<br />

with CO2 emissions.<br />

2 <br />

The bonus is paid for <strong>the</strong><br />

proportion of electricity which<br />

correlates to <strong>the</strong> heat used. This<br />

is calculated by multiplying <strong>the</strong><br />

amount of heat used by <strong>the</strong><br />

coefficient of <strong>the</strong> installation<br />

(BMU 2007a)


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Energy systems<br />

13<br />

renewable heat projects in <strong>the</strong> residential sector, and small and medium sized<br />

businesses have been eligible for grants and loans under <strong>the</strong> Market Stimulation<br />

Programme (Marktanreizprogramm, or MAP). The renewable heat sector<br />

expanded from 3.5% in 1998 to 6.6% in 2007 (BMU 2008a).<br />

16<br />

14<br />

Electricity production<br />

(% of total gross<br />

electricity consumption)<br />

12<br />

10<br />

Heating supply (% of<br />

total heating supply)<br />

%<br />

8<br />

6<br />

Fuel consumption (% of<br />

total road transport)<br />

4<br />

2<br />

Share of RES in total final<br />

energy consumption<br />

0<br />

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007<br />

Figure 1.1 Renewable energy share of energy consumption in Germany.<br />

Source BMU (2008a)<br />

In 1998, renewable energy provided 3.1% of total final energy consumption<br />

in Germany. By 2007, this had risen to 8.5% (Figure 1.1), and <strong>the</strong> German<br />

government has recently announced ambitious plans for fur<strong>the</strong>r expansion<br />

to 2020: 25-30% of electricity consumption, 14% of heat consumption and<br />

6.9% of transport fuel consumption (BMU 2007b). The rationale behind <strong>the</strong>se<br />

plans is partly to reduce CO2 emissions, but is also aimed at driving innovation<br />

and expanding Germany’s role in <strong>the</strong> international market for renewable energy<br />

technologies.<br />

1.1.2 Spain<br />

As with Germany, Spain has developed renewable energy policies shaped both<br />

by environmental concerns and industrial ambition. It has a target of 12.1%<br />

renewable energy by 2010, with renewable electricity supplying 30.3% of<br />

consumption. These are both challenging targets, and it appears unlikely that<br />

<strong>the</strong>y will be met: renewables supplied 18.8% of electricity consumption in<br />

2006, and 6.8% of primary energy (EREC 2008).<br />

The likely failure to meet <strong>the</strong> 2010 targets, however, does not mean that<br />

<strong>the</strong> expansion of renewables in Spain in recent years is not impressive. The<br />

wind sector in particular has grown significantly, from 2,235MW of installed<br />

3 <br />

This has led to a revision to <strong>the</strong><br />

tariff offered under <strong>the</strong> feed-in<br />

arrangements, which in turn is<br />

expected to slow future growth in<br />

<strong>the</strong> sector slightly.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Energy systems<br />

14<br />

capacity in 2000 to 15,145 in 2007, <strong>the</strong> strongest growth rate in Europe<br />

(GWEC 2008). The growth of photovoltaics is also impressive, and installed<br />

capacity in 2007 exceeded <strong>the</strong> target of 400 MW set for 2010 3 . Like<br />

Germany, Spain also has a dual requirement for priority access to <strong>the</strong> national<br />

grid for renewables generation, and a feed-in tariff. The design of <strong>the</strong> feed-in<br />

tariff, however, differs from <strong>the</strong> German model: energy suppliers can chose<br />

between fixed tariffs for each technology, or one which pays a premium on<br />

top of <strong>the</strong> market price for energy. Renewable energy suppliers can <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

rely on a guaranteed market and a higher price for <strong>the</strong>ir output than that in <strong>the</strong><br />

conventional power market.<br />

One of <strong>the</strong> results of this aggressive promotion plan is <strong>the</strong> emergence of<br />

a Spanish wind industry, spearheaded by Gamesa, which is increasingly<br />

competitive in <strong>the</strong> world market.<br />

1.1.3 Conclusions: <strong>the</strong> international context<br />

Compared to Germany and Spain, <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s performance in driving <strong>the</strong><br />

deployment of renewable electricity technologies is unimpressive (Figure<br />

1.2). The reason for this can be directly attributed to <strong>the</strong> design of support<br />

mechanisms aimed at encouraging <strong>the</strong> development and implementation of<br />

new technologies (BMU 2008). While <strong>the</strong> RO is characterised by uncertainty<br />

about <strong>the</strong> prices that renewable generation will receive, <strong>the</strong> feed-in tariff<br />

provides a guarantee that energy suppliers will receive a premium price for <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

output, <strong>the</strong>reby compensating <strong>the</strong>m for <strong>the</strong> additional risks <strong>the</strong>y are taking by<br />

using new technologies.<br />

16000<br />

14000<br />

12000<br />

10000<br />

Germany<br />

Spain<br />

United Kingdom<br />

8000<br />

6000<br />

4000<br />

2000<br />

0<br />

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005<br />

Figure 1.2 Renewable electricity production (1000toe)


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy Energy systems 15<br />

Any support mechanism for new technologies will cost money, and renewables<br />

are no exception. However, one of <strong>the</strong> results of a rapidly expanding renewable<br />

energy sector in Germany and Spain has been <strong>the</strong> emergence of domestic<br />

manufacturing industries, which are increasingly important on <strong>the</strong> world<br />

stage. Not only does this produce jobs domestically, <strong>the</strong> income generated<br />

compensates across <strong>the</strong> economy for <strong>the</strong> costs of <strong>the</strong> support mechanism.<br />

Ironically, although <strong>the</strong> RO was specifically designed to keep costs to consumers<br />

down, <strong>the</strong> mechanism works out as both more expensive than feed-in tariffs<br />

and less effective (Figure 1.3). This is all <strong>the</strong> more serious considering that no<br />

significant domestic manufacturers in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> have emerged to counter <strong>the</strong><br />

economic costs of <strong>the</strong> policy, so <strong>the</strong>re have been negligible broader<br />

socio-economic benefits.<br />

Effectiveness Indicator<br />

25<br />

ES–MO<br />

20<br />

IE ES–FP<br />

15 DE<br />

%<br />

10<br />

LT AT<br />

AT<br />

5<br />

CZ–MO<br />

CZ–FP FR<br />

SE 0<br />

BE–Wallonia<br />

FL<br />

-1 0 1 2 3<br />

Expected profit (€ Cent /KWh)<br />

<strong>UK</strong><br />

IT<br />

PL BE–Flanders<br />

4 5 6 7 8<br />

Feed in tariffs<br />

Quota/TGC<br />

Tender<br />

Tax incentives/<br />

investment grants<br />

Figure 1.3 Efficiency of support for onshore wind: effectiveness indicator<br />

compared to <strong>the</strong> expected profit for 2006<br />

Source: Ragwitz, Held et al (2007)<br />

Giving investors <strong>the</strong> confidence to finance new renewable energy projects<br />

through <strong>the</strong> introduction of feed-in tariffs (a guaranteed payment per unit<br />

of heat for a specified period for <strong>the</strong> supplier) that reduces <strong>the</strong> financial risks<br />

would create greater opportunity for <strong>the</strong>ir deployment.


16<br />

02<br />

<strong>UK</strong> targets and<br />

policy delivery<br />

The federal chancellery building ‘Bundeskanzleramt’ in Berlin,<br />

Germany has a photovoltaics facility on <strong>the</strong> roof.<br />

©Langrock/Zenit/<strong>Greenpeace</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

<strong>UK</strong> targets and policy delivery<br />

17<br />

The <strong>UK</strong> has numerous targets for reducing emissions of both GHGs in general<br />

and CO2 in particular, as well as for demand reduction and <strong>the</strong> introduction<br />

of low-carbon technologies, as set out in Table 2.1. These targets appear in a<br />

number of policy documents, including <strong>the</strong> 2000 and 2006 Climate Change<br />

Programme, and two Energy White Papers, <strong>the</strong> first in 2003 and <strong>the</strong> second<br />

in 2007. It is striking that while <strong>the</strong>re are targets for renewable electricity<br />

production and improvements in energy efficiency, <strong>the</strong>re are as yet none for<br />

heat, despite CO2 emissions from <strong>the</strong> heating sector constituting nearly half<br />

of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s total carbon emissions (BERR 2008), and only short-term targets<br />

for CHP. So while targets exist, at <strong>the</strong> moment <strong>the</strong>y create an incomplete<br />

framework for driving <strong>the</strong> emergence of sustainable energy systems.<br />

The <strong>UK</strong>’s performance on meeting its domestic 2010 targets has been<br />

poor, although it will achieve its Kyoto commitment to reducing overall<br />

GHG emissions by 2008–12 (Figure 2.1). At <strong>the</strong> moment, CO2 emissions<br />

are projected to be only around 16% below 1990 levels by 2010 at best,<br />

as against <strong>the</strong> target of 20%, while both renewable electricity supply and<br />

CHP capacity are likely to be well short of <strong>the</strong>ir targets. In part, <strong>the</strong> 2007<br />

energy White Paper and <strong>the</strong> energy review which preceded it in 2006 were<br />

designed to address <strong>the</strong> failure of o<strong>the</strong>r policy initiatives to achieve <strong>the</strong>se<br />

targets, and to put <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> back on track for its targets under <strong>the</strong> EU’s 2020<br />

commitments. These targets have superseded <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s domestic 2010 targets<br />

for renewable electricity and energy efficiency. As discussed earlier, <strong>the</strong><br />

European Commission’s proposals in January 2008 allocated <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> a target<br />

of 15% of overall energy being supplied from renewable sources by 2020. In<br />

addition, <strong>the</strong>y reaffirmed <strong>the</strong> aim of reducing European energy consumption by<br />

20% by 2020, and of reducing EU-wide GHG emissions by ei<strong>the</strong>r 20% or 30%<br />

(depending on <strong>the</strong> global response) by <strong>the</strong> same date. The sectoral split for<br />

meeting this target is yet to be formally agreed, but to illustrate <strong>the</strong> significance<br />

of <strong>the</strong> EU target, <strong>the</strong> new target for <strong>the</strong> electricity sector is expected to be set<br />

at around 40% by 2020 – double <strong>the</strong> domestic <strong>UK</strong> target.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

<strong>UK</strong> targets and policy delivery<br />

18<br />

Year<br />

Greenhouse<br />

gases<br />

(MtCe)<br />

CO2 (MtC)<br />

Renewables<br />

CHP Heat Energy<br />

efficiency/<br />

demand<br />

reduction<br />

1990<br />

(baseline)<br />

209.9 [1] 161.5 [1]<br />

2000<br />

5GW of CHP<br />

installed<br />

capacity [2]<br />

2003<br />

2010 Kyoto<br />

commitment:<br />

12.5% below<br />

1990 levels<br />

by 2008-12<br />

20%<br />

reduction on<br />

1990 level<br />

5% of<br />

electricity<br />

sales [2]<br />

10% of<br />

electricity<br />

sales<br />

10% of<br />

generation [3]<br />

10GWe of<br />

‘good quality’<br />

CHP installed<br />

capacity [2]<br />

2015<br />

2020 EU target Reduction to<br />

20% reduction around 110-<br />

(or 30% if with 120MtC (ie<br />

international<br />

action)<br />

26-32% cut<br />

from 1990<br />

level) [5]<br />

EU target to<br />

reduce<br />

emissions of<br />

industrial GHG<br />

emissions in<br />

non-Emissions<br />

Trading<br />

Scheme<br />

sectors by 10%<br />

from 2005<br />

level: <strong>UK</strong><br />

share is 16%<br />

2050 60%<br />

reduction [6]<br />

15% of<br />

electricity<br />

sales<br />

Aspiration<br />

for 20% of<br />

electricity<br />

sales [5,6]<br />

EU target<br />

of 20% of<br />

energy from<br />

renewable<br />

sources: <strong>UK</strong><br />

share is 15%<br />

30-40% of<br />

generation [5]<br />

EU target:<br />

9% average<br />

reduction<br />

in energy<br />

consumption<br />

from 2000<br />

level [4]<br />

EU target:<br />

20% average<br />

reduction<br />

in energy<br />

consumption<br />

from 2000<br />

level<br />

[1] Defra 2008<br />

[2] DETR 2000<br />

[3] EU Renewables Directive<br />

(NB <strong>the</strong> Directive’s definition of<br />

renewable generation differs from<br />

that in <strong>the</strong> Renewables Obligation)<br />

[4] EU Energy End Use and Energy<br />

Services Directive<br />

[5] DTI 2003<br />

[6] DTI 2007<br />

Table 2.1: <strong>UK</strong> climate change and energy targets


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

<strong>UK</strong> targets and policy delivery<br />

19<br />

900.0<br />

CO 2<br />

800.0<br />

All greenhouse gases<br />

700.0<br />

Kyoto GHG target<br />

Mt CO 2<br />

600.0<br />

500.0<br />

400.0<br />

2010 domestic<br />

CO 2<br />

goal<br />

2050 Climate Change<br />

Bill target upper limit<br />

300.0<br />

200.0<br />

2050 Climate Change<br />

Bill target lower limit<br />

100.0<br />

0.0<br />

1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020<br />

Figure 2.1: <strong>UK</strong> greenhouse gas targets and actual emissions<br />

Source: Defra 2008<br />

In addition to its various targets, <strong>the</strong> government has proposed in <strong>the</strong> Climate<br />

Change Bill a binding legal requirement to reduce CO2 emissions. The bill<br />

proposals would commit <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> to reducing CO2 emissions by 60% below 1990<br />

levels by 2050, and by between 26 and 32% by 2020. 4 Emissions of CO2 in<br />

1990 are estimated to have totalled 161.5MtC. The Bill’s 2020 target <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

equates to between 110 and 119.5MtC by 2020. However, <strong>the</strong> projections<br />

accompanying <strong>the</strong> 2007 energy White Paper show that achieving this reduction<br />

would require both very successful implementation of all <strong>the</strong> policy proposals<br />

in <strong>the</strong> White Paper, and <strong>the</strong> full implementation of <strong>the</strong> EU Emissions Trading<br />

Scheme (ETS) 5 , including <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> buying a proportion of emission allowances<br />

from overseas (Table 2.2) (BERR 2008b). 6 Even under this Central Price, High<br />

Policy Impact scenario, <strong>the</strong> Climate Change Bill targets for 2020 could be missed<br />

by more than 9MtC. If energy prices are lower than projected, or <strong>the</strong>re is a<br />

failure in performance of <strong>the</strong> policies, or if <strong>the</strong> carbon prices in <strong>the</strong> ETS are not<br />

high enough to drive emissions reductions, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> White Paper will fail to meet<br />

<strong>the</strong> targets in <strong>the</strong> Climate Change Bill.<br />

4 <br />

The government has<br />

subsequently asked <strong>the</strong><br />

newly formed Climate<br />

Change Committee to advise<br />

it on whe<strong>the</strong>r it would be<br />

more appropriate to have a<br />

commitment to reduce CO2<br />

emissions by 80% by 2050.<br />

5 <br />

It is worth noting here that <strong>the</strong>re<br />

can be a degree of confusion<br />

about what is included in<br />

assessments and projections of<br />

CO2 emissions in relation to <strong>the</strong><br />

domestic 2010 target. When <strong>the</strong><br />

target was overseas (Table 2.2)<br />

(BERR 2008b).<br />

6 <br />

Even under this Central Price,<br />

High Policy Impact scenario, <strong>the</strong><br />

Climate Change Bill targets for<br />

2020 could be missed by more<br />

than 9MtC. If energy prices are<br />

lower than projected, or <strong>the</strong>re is<br />

a failure in performance of <strong>the</strong><br />

policies, or if <strong>the</strong> carbon prices<br />

in <strong>the</strong> ETS are not high enough<br />

to drive emissions reductions,<br />

<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> White Paper will fail to<br />

meet <strong>the</strong> targets in <strong>the</strong> Climate<br />

Change Bill.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

<strong>UK</strong> targets and policy delivery<br />

20<br />

The emissions projections also make clear that even successful implementation of<br />

<strong>the</strong> new policies set out in <strong>the</strong> White Paper will not achieve <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> domestic target<br />

of reducing CO2 emissions by 20% by 2010 (ie to around 129.2 MtC).<br />

Achieving <strong>the</strong> 2020 target and putting <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> in a position to meet<br />

longer-term targets for additional emission reductions will require success in<br />

two separate areas: reducing energy intensity by increasing energy efficiency<br />

and reducing demand, and reducing <strong>the</strong> carbon intensity by decarbonising<br />

energy production. While reducing energy intensity can deliver fast, often<br />

very cost-effective reductions in CO2 emissions, in <strong>the</strong> longer term additional<br />

emission savings may well prove more difficult or less cost effective. So <strong>the</strong><br />

development of less carbon intensive energy systems must be pursued just<br />

as aggressively. The following two sections look at <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s main mechanisms<br />

to address energy efficiency/demand reduction and to encourage more lowcarbon<br />

sustainable energy sources.<br />

Central prices,<br />

low policy<br />

impact<br />

Central prices,<br />

central policy<br />

impact<br />

Central prices,<br />

high policy<br />

impact<br />

Low prices,<br />

central policy<br />

impact<br />

High prices,<br />

central policy<br />

impact<br />

1990<br />

161.5<br />

161.5<br />

161.5<br />

161.5<br />

161.5<br />

2010<br />

145.2<br />

144.4<br />

143.4<br />

146.0<br />

144.9<br />

2010 full EU ETS [1]<br />

136.1<br />

135.7<br />

135.2<br />

137.2<br />

134.7<br />

2020<br />

135.7<br />

132.2<br />

122.9<br />

136.5<br />

136.6<br />

2020 full EU ETS [1]<br />

128.8<br />

126.5<br />

119.2<br />

130.7<br />

123.9<br />

2020 reduction from<br />

1990 (%)<br />

-20.3<br />

-21.7<br />

-26.2<br />

-19.1<br />

-23.3<br />

Climate Change Bill<br />

goal (MtC)<br />

109.8 – 119.5<br />

109.8 – 119.5<br />

109.8 – 119.5<br />

109.8 – 119.5<br />

109.8 – 119.5<br />

Carbon Gap 2020<br />

9.3<br />

7 – 16.7<br />

-0.3 – 9.4<br />

11.2 – 20.9<br />

4.4 –14.1<br />

Table 2.2 White Paper Projections (MtC)<br />

Source: BERR 2008b, table F1<br />

Notes: [1] These projections assume a carbon price of €20/tCO2<br />

in 2010 and €25/tCO2 in 2015–20.


21<br />

03<br />

Reducing energy<br />

intensity: efficiency<br />

and demand<br />

Nuon CHP plant provides electricity, heat and cooling for <strong>the</strong> and surrounding<br />

office buildings and 450 residential dwellings in Amstelplein, Amsterdam.<br />

©Reynaers/<strong>Greenpeace</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

22<br />

The government recognises that ‘[u]sing energy more efficiently is <strong>the</strong> fastest<br />

and most cost effective way of cutting CO2 emissions’ (Defra 2007a, p5). This<br />

section sets out <strong>the</strong> main policy measures in place to reduce energy intensity in<br />

<strong>the</strong> economy. Many of <strong>the</strong> measures in <strong>the</strong> 2007 White Paper and earlier policy<br />

documents have been driven by EU legislation ra<strong>the</strong>r than being government<br />

initiatives. One of <strong>the</strong> key EU directives shaping <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s approach to energy<br />

efficiency is <strong>the</strong> Energy End-Use Efficiency and Energy Services Directive,<br />

which must be implemented by Member States by May 2008, and which<br />

requires <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> to reduce energy use by 9% by 2016. This directive and o<strong>the</strong>rs<br />

which have influenced <strong>the</strong> creation of <strong>UK</strong> policy are outlined in Table 3.1.<br />

Directive<br />

Aims<br />

EU Energy Labelling Framework<br />

Directive (92/75/EEC)<br />

Energy Performance of Buildings<br />

Directive (2002/91/EC)<br />

Eco-Design of Energy-using<br />

Products Directive (2005/32/EC)<br />

Energy End-Use Efficiency and<br />

Energy Services Directive<br />

(2006/32/EC)<br />

Certain appliances should be labelled with <strong>the</strong>ir energy consumption<br />

to allow a comparison between products.<br />

Reduction of 22% in energy use in existing buildings by 2010.<br />

This is <strong>the</strong> basis for <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s Energy Performance Certificates.<br />

Minimum environmental performance standards for products.<br />

A 9% reduction by 2016 in <strong>the</strong> annual average amount of annual<br />

final inland energy consumption of all energy users within <strong>the</strong> scope<br />

of <strong>the</strong> directive, taking as a baseline <strong>the</strong> five-year period immediately<br />

prior to its implementation. The directive does not cover energy<br />

reductions in installations covered by <strong>the</strong> EU ETS, nor energy use<br />

in <strong>the</strong> armed forces[source given below]. The <strong>UK</strong> five-year average<br />

annual consumption is 1,517TWh, which gives a 9% reduction target<br />

of 136.5TWh.<br />

Table 3.1: EU directives driving <strong>UK</strong> energy efficiency policy<br />

Sources: Defra 2007a, Boardman 2007<br />

3.1 Business and industry<br />

The commercial and industrial sectors offer significant carbon abatement<br />

opportunities which could be implemented cost effectively. The Carbon<br />

Trust estimates that <strong>the</strong> opportunities offered by existing technologies and<br />

behavioural change measures are in fact more than cost effective, and could<br />

generate a rate of return on investment for business and industry of above<br />

15%, while reducing emissions from manufacturing processes by at least<br />

12% and from non-domestic buildings by at least 20% by 2020 (Carbon<br />

Trust 2005). Innovation and technical advances over that time period<br />

could offer even more cost effective improvements. Energy efficiency and<br />

demand reduction across business and industry <strong>the</strong>refore offer huge potential<br />

contributions to both <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> and EU 2020 targets.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

23<br />

Set against this potential, however, is <strong>the</strong> fact that, despite recent rises,<br />

energy prices still make up a relatively small proportion of many organisations’<br />

turnover, and that energy use may thus be seen as a relatively unimportant<br />

issue. Government measures to encourage improved energy performance will<br />

<strong>the</strong>refore have to attract <strong>the</strong> attention of company directors by addressing<br />

<strong>the</strong> bottom line of financial performance. Carbon pricing as part of <strong>the</strong> EU ETS<br />

is <strong>the</strong> government’s preferred option for doing this, coupled with improved<br />

information on energy saving and help to improve performance provided by<br />

<strong>the</strong> Carbon Trust. However, to bring about significant change in business and<br />

industry <strong>the</strong> price of permits for <strong>the</strong> right to emit carbon would have to be high<br />

enough to threaten companies’ financial performance, with a strong likelihood<br />

that this high carbon price would endure for long enough to drive investment in<br />

energy efficiency improvements.<br />

3.1.1 Emissions trading<br />

The EU ETS is <strong>the</strong> central plank of <strong>the</strong> government’s strategy to reduce<br />

emissions, and is projected to save up to 13.7MtC a year by 2020 (DTI 2007).<br />

The EU ETS requires Member States to set permitted emission levels in line<br />

with <strong>the</strong>ir Kyoto commitments, and to produce national allocation plans setting<br />

out limits for different industrial sectors. At <strong>the</strong> moment, <strong>the</strong> EU ETS covers<br />

around 46% of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s emissions, although smaller emitters will be removed<br />

from <strong>the</strong> scheme from 2008, on <strong>the</strong> grounds that <strong>the</strong> high transaction costs of<br />

participation are not justified (Strategy Unit 2007). The first phase of <strong>the</strong> ETS<br />

ran from 2005 to 2007, while <strong>the</strong> second phase, designed to coincide with <strong>the</strong><br />

Kyoto commitment period, runs from 2008 to 2012. The scope of <strong>the</strong> scheme<br />

is currently under review by <strong>the</strong> European Commission, and it may ultimately<br />

include new sectors, notably aviation.<br />

Under <strong>the</strong> ETS, allowances to emit CO2 are allocated to specific sectors on <strong>the</strong><br />

basis of business-as-usual projections of <strong>the</strong>ir emissions. The results of <strong>the</strong> first<br />

phase show that <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> and o<strong>the</strong>r Member States over-allocated allowances<br />

to most sectors, with <strong>the</strong> result that most sectors had more allowances than<br />

<strong>the</strong>y needed to cover <strong>the</strong>ir emissions. The one exception to this is <strong>the</strong> energy<br />

generation sector, which has greatly exceeded its allocated allowances and had<br />

to buy additional permits each year (see Table 3.2). Indeed, in each of <strong>the</strong> three<br />

years this shortfall more than cancelled out <strong>the</strong> excess allowances of <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

sectors.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

24<br />

2005<br />

2006<br />

2007<br />

Allocation of<br />

allowances (millions)<br />

1 allowance = 1 tonne CO2<br />

Total<br />

Energy sector<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r sectors<br />

215.2<br />

135.7<br />

79.5<br />

217.3<br />

135.6<br />

81.7<br />

228.8<br />

136<br />

92.8<br />

Verified emissions<br />

(MtCO2)<br />

Total<br />

Energy sector<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r sectors<br />

242.3<br />

172.2<br />

70.1<br />

251.1<br />

181.5<br />

69.6<br />

256.4<br />

177.9<br />

78.5<br />

Excess or (shortfall)<br />

of allowances<br />

(millions)<br />

Total<br />

Energy sector<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r sectors<br />

(27.1)<br />

(36.5)<br />

9.5<br />

(33.8)<br />

(45.9)<br />

12.1<br />

(27.6)<br />

(41.9)<br />

14.3<br />

Table 3.2: Results from EU ETS, 2005–07<br />

Sources: Defra 2007 Table 3, Defra 2008a, Defra 2008b<br />

The <strong>the</strong>ory of emissions trading is that by giving businesses choice as to<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r and how to reduce <strong>the</strong>ir emissions, <strong>the</strong> required reductions will<br />

be produced in <strong>the</strong> most cost effective way (DTI 2007). This is entirely<br />

rational from an economic viewpoint as a way of correcting a market failure.<br />

The reality, however, is more complex. Any measure which increases <strong>the</strong><br />

regulatory burden on companies will be unpopular, particularly if it increases<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir costs, and industry has lobbied vigorously to ensure that <strong>the</strong> limits set on<br />

permitted emissions are as high as possible to minimise any possible impact<br />

on competitiveness (see for example CBI 2007). This is true not just in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong><br />

– governments in all Member States have experienced lobbying efforts from<br />

companies affected by <strong>the</strong> scheme. The outcome for <strong>the</strong> first phase of <strong>the</strong><br />

scheme was a series of high emission limits, resulting in an excess of permits<br />

on <strong>the</strong> market and volatile prices for permits, which ultimately plummeted<br />

(see Figures 3.1 and 3.2). The <strong>UK</strong> was in fact one of <strong>the</strong> few Member States<br />

to attempt to use <strong>the</strong> first phase of <strong>the</strong> scheme as a tool to manage emissions,<br />

albeit only from <strong>the</strong> energy sector. While <strong>the</strong> economic <strong>the</strong>ory may be sound,<br />

<strong>the</strong> reality so far has been that <strong>the</strong> ETS will always ultimately be shaped by<br />

political concerns, and businesses participating in <strong>the</strong> scheme have been<br />

reluctant to pay for <strong>the</strong>ir environmental externalities. The energy White Paper<br />

implicitly accepts this by hinting that it would guarantee carbon prices at a<br />

minimum level in order to provide greater certainty to investors (DTI 2007).


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

25<br />

<strong>UK</strong><br />

Italy<br />

Poland<br />

France<br />

Germany<br />

Czech Republic<br />

Ne<strong>the</strong>rlands<br />

Finland<br />

Belgium<br />

Denmark<br />

Estonia<br />

Lithuania<br />

Hungary<br />

Slovak Republic<br />

Sweden<br />

Greece<br />

Portugal<br />

Latvia<br />

Malta<br />

Luxembourg<br />

Cyprus<br />

Slovenia<br />

Ireland<br />

Austria<br />

Spain<br />

-40 -30 -20 -10 0 10 20 30 40 50 60<br />

Figure 3.1 EU Member States’ surplus/deficit of carbon allowances (M)<br />

Source: Defra 2008a Figure 20<br />

Actual surplus/deficit<br />

2006<br />

Actual surplus/deficit<br />

2005<br />

Phase II (Dec 2008) price<br />

Price (£)<br />

35.00<br />

30.00<br />

25.00<br />

20.00<br />

15.00<br />

10.00<br />

5.00<br />

12<br />

10<br />

8<br />

6<br />

4<br />

2<br />

Volume traded (000,000)<br />

Phase I (spot) price<br />

Total volume<br />

0<br />

22 Apr<br />

2005<br />

26 Jul<br />

2005<br />

26 Oct<br />

2005<br />

27 Jan<br />

2006<br />

1 May<br />

2006<br />

1 Aug<br />

2006<br />

31 Oct<br />

2006<br />

1 Feb<br />

2007<br />

4 May<br />

2007<br />

0<br />

3 Aug<br />

2007<br />

Figure 3.2 EU ETS carbon prices<br />

Source: Defra 2008a Figure 17


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

26<br />

The volatility of carbon prices and uncertainty about future prices means<br />

that <strong>the</strong> ETS is unlikely to have driven any long-term investment projects so<br />

far; it may well have led to some short-term reductions in energy intensity,<br />

but not appear to have increased <strong>the</strong> take up of longer-term, more capitalintensive<br />

low-carbon technologies (Carbon Trust 2007). The problem does<br />

not appear to have been solved for <strong>the</strong> second phase of <strong>the</strong> scheme, with<br />

prices still volatile and as yet insufficient to drive investment in low-carbon<br />

energy. Forward prices for Phase II are between €15 and €20 per tonne of CO2,<br />

while <strong>the</strong> Carbon Trust estimates that a sustained price of around€20/tCO2<br />

is needed to encourage investment in low-carbon technologies (Carbon Trust<br />

2007). Without a degree of certainty about <strong>the</strong> level and stability of future<br />

carbon prices, <strong>the</strong>re is little incentive to invest in potentially more expensive<br />

carbon reduction measures as <strong>the</strong>re is no guarantee that <strong>the</strong> investment will be<br />

recouped.<br />

While <strong>the</strong> price signals have been insufficient to drive low-carbon investments,<br />

Phase I of <strong>the</strong> scheme has proved profitable for energy companies, who in<br />

<strong>the</strong>ory have been hardest hit by <strong>the</strong> introduction of a price for carbon. At <strong>the</strong><br />

moment, most allowances are allocated free to <strong>the</strong> participants in <strong>the</strong> scheme,<br />

but companies have chosen to pass <strong>the</strong> costs associated with trading <strong>the</strong><br />

carbon permits between companies on to customers in <strong>the</strong> form of increased<br />

electricity prices. A recent report for WWF estimates that this practice could<br />

result in windfall profits for <strong>the</strong> energy sector of up to £12 billion during <strong>the</strong><br />

second phase of <strong>the</strong> scheme (Point Carbon 2008).<br />

For Phase II of <strong>the</strong> ETS, national emissions caps have been tightened by<br />

<strong>the</strong> European Commission. However, <strong>the</strong> scheme also places an increasing<br />

emphasis on <strong>the</strong> ability of Member States to take international action to reduce<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir emissions through Kyoto Protocol mechanisms, in <strong>the</strong> form of ei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

Joint Implementation (JI) or <strong>the</strong> Clean Development Mechanism (CDM). 7 At<br />

<strong>the</strong> moment, CDM/JI credits trade at around €8–10/tCO2e (REF), compared<br />

with €15–20 for Phase II ETS credits, making this an attractive alternative<br />

to investing in measures at home. There is a clear enthusiasm emerging in <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>UK</strong> for taking more international action of this sort (Strategy Unit 2007), and<br />

<strong>the</strong> Climate Change Bill allows for emission cuts made overseas to be counted<br />

towards <strong>the</strong> overall <strong>UK</strong> reduction target.<br />

From an economic point of view, it may well make sense for a company to buy<br />

<strong>the</strong> cheapest available allowances, although <strong>the</strong>re are potential problems with<br />

<strong>the</strong> verification of <strong>the</strong> resulting emissions reductions which might undermine<br />

any assessment of <strong>the</strong> effectiveness of this approach. This concern has<br />

recently been highlighted by <strong>the</strong> National Audit Office, which reported that<br />

<strong>the</strong> Office for National Statistics is reluctant to count allowances purchased<br />

through overseas action as part of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> programme to reduce emissions,<br />

because of <strong>the</strong> difficulties of verification (National Audit Office 2008). A more<br />

fundamental criticism, however, is that encouraging companies to make a<br />

significant or increasing proportion of <strong>the</strong>ir emissions reductions overseas<br />

diminishes <strong>the</strong> impetus to transform energy systems in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>. It also reduces<br />

7 <br />

JI allows industrialised (Annex 1)<br />

countries to take action to reduce<br />

emissions in o<strong>the</strong>r industrialised<br />

countries ra<strong>the</strong>r than at home.<br />

The CDM is similar, but allows for<br />

action in developing countries.<br />

Both mechanisms are aimed at<br />

allowing carbon reductions at<br />

least (or less) cost.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

27<br />

demand for <strong>the</strong> relatively more expensive ETS allowances which in turn<br />

depresses <strong>the</strong> overall carbon price. Thus <strong>the</strong> short-term pursuit of economic<br />

efficiency threatens to undermine <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s efforts to reduce energy intensity<br />

and encourage longer-term investment in sustainable energy technologies.<br />

Never<strong>the</strong>less, <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> government is lobbying <strong>the</strong> European Commission to<br />

allow an even greater proportion of national targets to be met by overseas<br />

emissions reductions.<br />

The leaked 2007 BERR memo already mentioned, makes clear <strong>the</strong> tension<br />

between <strong>the</strong> government’s climate change and economic aspirations: it argues<br />

against <strong>the</strong> rapid expansion of renewables and <strong>the</strong> implementation of energy<br />

efficiency measures to meet <strong>the</strong> EU targets on <strong>the</strong> grounds that this would<br />

undermine <strong>the</strong> price of carbon within <strong>the</strong> ETS: ‘if <strong>the</strong> EU has a 20% GHG target<br />

for 2020, <strong>the</strong> GHG emissions saving achieved through <strong>the</strong> renewables target<br />

and energy efficiency measures risk making <strong>the</strong> EU ETS redundant, and prices<br />

to collapse.’ (BERR 2007, p1). This argument neglects <strong>the</strong> fact that prices<br />

for carbon credits are set by emissions limits, ra<strong>the</strong>r than <strong>the</strong> effectiveness<br />

of energy efficiency and renewables: if new technologies are succeeding in<br />

reducing CO2 emissions, <strong>the</strong> response should be to tighten <strong>the</strong> ETS’s limits to<br />

ensure that prices remain sufficiently high to drive <strong>the</strong> fur<strong>the</strong>r deployment of<br />

those technologies. BERR’s statement, however, makes it difficult to avoid <strong>the</strong><br />

impression that promotion of <strong>the</strong> EU ETS is <strong>the</strong> priority for BERR, ra<strong>the</strong>r than<br />

<strong>the</strong> rapid reduction of CO2 emissions.<br />

The stability of carbon prices and <strong>the</strong>refore of long-term investment signals<br />

may improve in subsequent phases of <strong>the</strong> ETS. The Commission has proposed<br />

that individual national allocation plans should be replaced by a single set of<br />

EU-wide rules for setting reduction targets and allocating or auctioning<br />

allowances, with individual Member States conducting auctions but permitting<br />

any company from any country to buy allowances. Although companies would<br />

still have access to cheaper CDM credits, <strong>the</strong> level would initially be limited<br />

to that used in <strong>the</strong> current ETS period (European Commission 2008a). These<br />

measures should remove some of <strong>the</strong> problems caused by national<br />

over-allocation of allowances, although <strong>the</strong> continued eligibility of action under<br />

<strong>the</strong> CDM risks limiting action at <strong>the</strong> national level.<br />

3.1.2 The Climate Change Levy and Climate Change Agreements<br />

The 2001 Climate Change Levy (CCL) is a tax on <strong>the</strong> use of energy by business<br />

derived from fossil fuels or nuclear power. The CCL was initially projected to<br />

reduce <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s annual carbon emissions by at least 2MtC by 2010 against<br />

business-as-usual forecasts. A later assessment of <strong>the</strong> scheme estimated<br />

that that actual impact was more likely to be a 3.7MtC reduction by 2010,<br />

although this was later revised down to 3.5MtC (Cambridge Econometrics and<br />

Policy Studies Institute 2005, National Audit Office 2007). 8 Even at this lower<br />

estimate, however, <strong>the</strong> projected impact of <strong>the</strong> CCL on carbon emissions is a<br />

significant part of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s overall climate strategy. The CCL was meant to be<br />

revenue-neutral for business: when it was introduced it was accompanied by<br />

a 0.3% cut in employers’ National Insurance contributions (NICs). In <strong>the</strong> event<br />

8 <br />

The revision to <strong>the</strong> 3.5MtC<br />

estimate came about because<br />

<strong>the</strong> Cambridge Econometrics/PSI<br />

report assumed that <strong>the</strong> rate<br />

of <strong>the</strong> levy would increase in<br />

line with inflation from 2005,<br />

whereas in fact it remained<br />

<strong>the</strong> same until 2007, <strong>the</strong>reby<br />

reducing its power as a driver<br />

for increased energy efficiency<br />

(National Audit Office 2007).


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

28<br />

<strong>the</strong> reduction in NICs, valued at £1.2 billion in 2004–05, has far outweighed<br />

<strong>the</strong> monetary impact of <strong>the</strong> CCL on business, and many less carbon-intensive<br />

businesses gain more from reduced NIC payments than <strong>the</strong>y pay under <strong>the</strong> CCL<br />

(National Audit Office 2007).<br />

Despite <strong>the</strong> loss to <strong>the</strong> Treasury from <strong>the</strong> NIC rebate, <strong>the</strong> rate of <strong>the</strong> CCL was<br />

not increased between its introduction in 2001 and 2007. Given inflation rates<br />

and <strong>the</strong> increasing costs of energy over time, its power as a mechanism to<br />

improve <strong>the</strong> energy performance of business <strong>the</strong>refore declined between 2001<br />

and 2007, although this will be mitigated by future inflation-linked rises (see<br />

Table 3.3). Even so, <strong>the</strong> CCL will continue to represent a small proportion of<br />

overall energy costs for non-energy-intensive businesses, and its real impact<br />

as a driver will remain limited to companies whose energy costs form a<br />

significant proportion of <strong>the</strong>ir day-to-day operating costs (National Audit<br />

Office 2007).<br />

2001– 07<br />

2007– 08<br />

2008–09<br />

2009– 10<br />

Electricity<br />

0.43p/kWh<br />

0.441p/kWh<br />

0.456p/kWh<br />

0.470p/kWh<br />

Gas<br />

0.15p/kWh<br />

0.154p/kWh<br />

0.159p/kWh<br />

0.164p/kWh<br />

Coal and coke<br />

0.17p/kg<br />

1.201p/kg<br />

1.242p/kg<br />

1.281p/kg<br />

Liquified petroleum gas<br />

0.96p/kg<br />

0.985p/kg<br />

1.018p/kg<br />

1.050p/kg<br />

Table 3.3: Climate Change Levy rates<br />

Sources: HM Treasury (2006a), National Audit Office (2007),<br />

HM Revenue & Customs (2008)<br />

Climate Change Agreements (CCAs) were introduced alongside <strong>the</strong> CCL in<br />

2001, and allow energy-intensive companies an 80% discount on <strong>the</strong> CCL,<br />

provided that <strong>the</strong>y agree and meet specified targets, set by Defra, for reducing<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir energy use by 2010. There are currently 51 different sectors with CCAs,<br />

covering around 10,000 facilities. The sector targets are set until 2010, but<br />

<strong>the</strong> CCA scheme itself runs until <strong>the</strong> end of March 2013. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong><br />

facilities with CCAs will pay reduced CCL rates until 2013, provided <strong>the</strong>y meet<br />

<strong>the</strong> 2010 targets.<br />

The targets that participants in <strong>the</strong> agreements must meet involve reducing<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir CO2 emissions ei<strong>the</strong>r to an absolute defined level, or to a defined level<br />

relative to <strong>the</strong>ir output. In addition, <strong>the</strong>y can trade allowances with o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

participants. Performance is reviewed every two years. CCAs were originally<br />

projected to reduce annual CO2 emissions by about 9.2 MtCO2 (2.5MtC) by<br />

2010 compared with a business-as-usual projection. However, <strong>the</strong> targets<br />

were revised following a decline in activity in <strong>the</strong> iron and steel sector, leading<br />

to considerable overachievement in <strong>the</strong> first target periods. CCAs are currently<br />

estimated to deliver a reduction of approximately 7 MtCO2 (1.9MtC) in annual<br />

emissions by 2010 relative to <strong>the</strong> business-as-usual projection (Defra 2007b).


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

29<br />

There continues to be an apparent overachievement in meeting interim targets<br />

in advance of <strong>the</strong> 2010 target (Table 3.4). The National Audit Office states that<br />

a proportion of <strong>the</strong> agreements ‘have not been as stringent as possible’ (NAO<br />

2007, p27) The reasons cited include <strong>the</strong> influence of industry in negotiating<br />

sector targets, and <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> levels agreed did not take account of<br />

efficiency savings that would have occurred anyway, even without <strong>the</strong> CCL<br />

and CCAs, as a result of businesses reducing <strong>the</strong>ir energy consumption in<br />

response to increased prices or as a result of technological change leading<br />

to greater energy efficiency. As a result, <strong>the</strong> scheme has failed to take full<br />

advantage of <strong>the</strong> apparently greater scope for companies to take meaningful<br />

emissions reduction action, without significant impact on business activity<br />

or competitiveness. Moreover, <strong>the</strong> overachievement of targets means that<br />

participants can bank surplus allowances for possible trading in subsequent<br />

periods of <strong>the</strong> scheme, even though <strong>the</strong> surplus may have come about as a<br />

result of undemanding targets ra<strong>the</strong>r than through concrete action to reduce<br />

emissions – thus fur<strong>the</strong>r undermining <strong>the</strong> scheme’s effectiveness.<br />

Target period<br />

Actual CO2 emissions<br />

(MtCO2/year<br />

Target CO2 emissions<br />

(MtCO2/year<br />

Absolute saving from<br />

baseline (MtCO2/year<br />

Target period 1<br />

With adjusted steel target<br />

16.4<br />

6.0<br />

12.3<br />

10.4<br />

4.1<br />

Target period 2<br />

With adjusted steel target<br />

14.4<br />

5.5<br />

9.3<br />

8.9<br />

5.1<br />

Target period 3<br />

With adjusted steel target<br />

16.4<br />

9.1<br />

12.3<br />

7.3<br />

4.1<br />

Table 3.4: Climate Change Agreement results<br />

Source Defra 2007b<br />

3.1.3 Carbon Reduction Commitment<br />

The 2007 White Paper also sets out an additional mandatory emissions trading<br />

scheme for organisations’ direct and indirect energy use. The Carbon Reduction<br />

Commitment (CRC) is an auction-based cap-and-trade scheme which should<br />

be introduced in 2010; it will extend emissions trading to large, non-energyintensive<br />

private and public sector organisations not included in <strong>the</strong> EU ETS,<br />

including all central government departments – although organisations with<br />

more than 25% of <strong>the</strong>ir emissions covered by CCAs will be exempt. It was<br />

originally intended that organisations using at least 3,000MWhr/yr would be<br />

included, but <strong>the</strong> threshold was doubled in <strong>the</strong> White Paper to 6,000MWhr/yr.<br />

As a result, <strong>the</strong> projected CO2 emission reductions were cut from 1.2MtC a<br />

year in 2020 in <strong>the</strong> Energy Review to 1MtC in <strong>the</strong> White Paper (DTI 2006,<br />

2007).<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> scheme will be mandatory, participants will set <strong>the</strong>ir own<br />

reduction targets and will monitor, verify and report <strong>the</strong>ir emissions<br />

<strong>the</strong>mselves. Organisations will be required to estimate emissions for <strong>the</strong> year<br />

ahead, and to buy sufficient allowances to cover <strong>the</strong>m. Each phase of <strong>the</strong> CRC


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Future</strong>: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing Energy Intensity: Reducing<br />

Demand through Energy Efficiency<br />

30<br />

is intended to last five years, allowing it to be synchronised with <strong>the</strong> ETS if<br />

participants wish to buy additional allowances.<br />

Emission allowances will be auctioned in January each year and <strong>the</strong> revenue<br />

generated will be recycled to participants on <strong>the</strong> basis of <strong>the</strong>ir average<br />

emissions since <strong>the</strong> introduction of <strong>the</strong> CRC. Organisations will also ei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

receive a bonus in addition to <strong>the</strong> recycled payment, or be penalised by a<br />

reduction in this payment, according to <strong>the</strong>ir performance against three<br />

indicators: <strong>the</strong> carbon emissions reduction achieved, <strong>the</strong> carbon emissions<br />

reduction relative to <strong>the</strong>ir economic performance and action taken to<br />

implement energy saving measures. If an organisation fails to comply with<br />

<strong>the</strong> commitment, it will be charged £25/tCO2 during <strong>the</strong> introductory phase<br />

(2010–2013), and <strong>the</strong>n £70/tCO2 in subsequent phases post 2013. In<br />

contrast, Defra estimates that CRC allowances will cost £8–16/tCO2.<br />

The scheme is yet to be implemented, so it is difficult to draw conclusions about<br />

how well it may work. However, <strong>the</strong> design of <strong>the</strong> measure is unambitious in<br />

view of <strong>the</strong> potential cost effective emissions savings to be made by reducing<br />

energy use in business – <strong>the</strong> Regulatory Impact Assessment for <strong>the</strong> CRC puts<br />

<strong>the</strong> present value of benefits in terms of savings on energy bills between<br />

£1,437 million and £2,726 million, depending on <strong>the</strong> type and level of discount<br />

rate that is applied (Defra 2007). Overall, moreover, <strong>the</strong> scheme seems<br />

unnecessarily complex: <strong>the</strong>re will be interactions with both <strong>the</strong> ETS and CCAs<br />

that will make it difficult to predict <strong>the</strong> level of emissions reductions which <strong>the</strong><br />

CRC will deliver. For example, anything between 0% and 20% of organisations<br />

and emissions could be excluded from <strong>the</strong> scheme because of <strong>the</strong> interaction<br />

with CCAs (DTI 2007d). Finally, it remains to be seen whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong> system<br />

of self-monitoring and verification of emissions, combined with rewards for<br />

compliance, will be sufficiently stringent to act as a driver.<br />

3.1.4 O<strong>the</strong>r measures<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r measures to encourage <strong>the</strong> more efficient use of energy in business<br />

include Enhanced Capital Allowances as part of <strong>the</strong> CCL package, which allow<br />

businesses to write off <strong>the</strong> cost of investing in specified energy saving products<br />

against <strong>the</strong>ir taxable profits for that financial year. There is also an interest-free<br />

loans scheme to enable small and medium-sized enterprises to install energy<br />

efficient technologies.<br />

The emphasis of government action is clearly on reducing emissions from<br />

industrial processes and energy end use, driven by an enthusiasm for carbon<br />

pricing and trading, whe<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> or EU. An area which has been relatively<br />

neglected in <strong>the</strong> business and industrial sectors is <strong>the</strong> energy performance<br />

of buildings, despite extensive action being planned to improve energy<br />

performance in both <strong>the</strong> public and domestic sectors. Commercial buildings are<br />

of course subject to building regulations, which provide some impetus towards<br />

energy efficiency; but it should be technically and economically possible<br />

for new non-domestic buildings to achieve significantly greater emission<br />

reductions in <strong>the</strong> next decade, and for many to be zero carbon with regards


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

31<br />

non-process-related emissions (Defra 2007a). The government has<br />

recently announced an ‘ambition’ for new non-domestic buildings to be zero<br />

carbon from 2019, although it is yet to set out its strategy for driving such<br />

improvements, and has merely committed to developing an action plan at<br />

some stage in <strong>the</strong> future (HM Treasury 2008). This hesitancy is missing an<br />

opportunity not just to improve <strong>the</strong> energy performance of existing commercial<br />

and industrial buildings, but to drive a longer-term shift to more sustainable<br />

energy production and supply through <strong>the</strong> provision of zero carbon facilities in<br />

both new and existing facilities.<br />

3.2 The domestic sector<br />

Domestic properties are responsible for about 27% of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s CO2 emissions.<br />

Most domestic energy use (87%) is for space or water heating, with <strong>the</strong> rest<br />

used for lighting and appliances (DTI 2007a). However, energy consumption<br />

in lighting and appliances is growing and overall domestic energy demand is<br />

expected to grow by an average of 2.5% (0.85 MtC) a year over <strong>the</strong> next 10<br />

years (Communities and Local Government 2007, Defra 2007a). In <strong>the</strong> past,<br />

increases in domestic demand have been partly offset by increases in energy<br />

efficiency (historically, about 1% a year). Defra’s 2007 Energy Efficiency<br />

Action Plan states that <strong>the</strong> policies it outlines should improve <strong>the</strong> rate of<br />

increase in energy efficiency to <strong>the</strong> point where it will cancel out <strong>the</strong> growth in<br />

domestic energy demand by 2010. However, this is a relatively unambitious<br />

target – households could reduce emissions by around 25% using established<br />

technologies (Defra 2007a).<br />

3.2.1 Energy Efficiency Commitment and Carbon Emission<br />

Reduction Target<br />

The Energy Efficiency Commitment (EEC) scheme was run in two phases,<br />

2002–05 and 2005–08. It required energy suppliers to achieve targets<br />

for energy efficiency improvements in Britain. Suppliers tended to provide<br />

insulation, low-energy lighting and high-efficiency appliances or heating<br />

in order to meet <strong>the</strong>ir targets, and implemented <strong>the</strong> measures ei<strong>the</strong>r with<br />

individual householders or through projects with social housing providers.<br />

50% of <strong>the</strong> suppliers’ energy savings targets had to be implemented in projects<br />

involving low-income customers. The EEC has proven to be a very cost<br />

effective measure, with <strong>the</strong> cost of complying with <strong>the</strong> targets estimated at<br />

no more than £9/customer/year (Energy Savings Trust 2007).<br />

The Carbon Emission Reduction Target (CERT) is <strong>the</strong> successor to <strong>the</strong> EEC,<br />

and will run from 2008 to 2011. Unlike <strong>the</strong> EEC programme, CERT includes<br />

microgeneration and o<strong>the</strong>r measures aimed at reducing consumption of<br />

supplied energy. The Climate Change Programme announced that <strong>the</strong> carbon<br />

reductions target to be met by suppliers under CERT would be roughly double<br />

that of <strong>the</strong> second phase of <strong>the</strong> EEC, with an aim of achieving emissions savings<br />

of 4.2MtC a year by 2011. However, most suppliers have already met <strong>the</strong><br />

target set for <strong>the</strong> EEC and excess savings will count towards CERT, so <strong>the</strong> more<br />

stringent target is not as demanding as it might seem.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

32<br />

CERT will in turn be succeeded by a Supplier Obligation, which will be<br />

maintained until 2020. The 2007 White Paper sets out an ambition to maintain<br />

year on year reduction targets under <strong>the</strong> Supplier Obligation at least at <strong>the</strong><br />

same level as that stipulated for CERT. The shape of this programme is yet<br />

to be decided, but it could ei<strong>the</strong>r take <strong>the</strong> form of a cap-and-trade scheme,<br />

where suppliers would be subject to a target for customers’ energy use or CO2<br />

emissions, which <strong>the</strong>y could meet ei<strong>the</strong>r by reducing customers’ emissions/<br />

energy use, or by trading allowances; or it could be a purely measures-based<br />

scheme along <strong>the</strong> lines of <strong>the</strong> EEC and CERT (Defra 2007). The government<br />

will consult on its final form in 2008. As with CERT, action to meet <strong>the</strong> Supplier<br />

Obligation could involve <strong>the</strong> implementation of microgeneration or o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

measures aimed at reducing emissions while maintaining <strong>the</strong> level of energy<br />

service.<br />

Both CERT and <strong>the</strong> Supplier Obligation show a welcome shift towards<br />

mixing short term, efficiency-based measures with longer-term strategic<br />

development of more sustainable energy technologies. In addition, encouraging<br />

suppliers to adopt a more service-based approach to energy provision (ie<br />

selling light or heat, ra<strong>the</strong>r than just units of energy) should act as a driver for<br />

<strong>the</strong> implementation of measures which use input energy more efficiently while<br />

providing <strong>the</strong> same level of service. The 2008 Budget announced that <strong>the</strong><br />

government would develop voluntary agreements with energy suppliers for <strong>the</strong><br />

provision of energy services, although this seems to be directed solely towards<br />

businesses. Given <strong>the</strong> potential for developing an energy service approach, as<br />

implied by <strong>the</strong> CERT and <strong>the</strong> proposals for <strong>the</strong> Supplier Obligation, this intention<br />

should also be extended to <strong>the</strong> domestic sector.<br />

3.2.3 Building regulations, Zero Carbon Homes and <strong>the</strong> Code<br />

for Sustainable Homes<br />

A number of revisions to <strong>the</strong> building regulations since 2002 have significantly<br />

improved <strong>the</strong> energy performance standards of new homes: a house built<br />

today should be around 40% more efficient than one built before 2002 (Defra<br />

2007a). However, <strong>the</strong> extent of <strong>the</strong> impact of <strong>the</strong> new building regulations<br />

on new homes is difficult to verify, partly because of <strong>the</strong> difficulties of<br />

inspecting new buildings and ensuring compliance with <strong>the</strong> required standards.<br />

Despite long-standing concerns about this (see for example BRE 2004),<br />

<strong>the</strong> government did not introduce measures to simplify arrangements or<br />

improve training and awareness until 2006 (DTI 2007). Progress with <strong>the</strong> new<br />

measures will be reviewed in three years to assess <strong>the</strong>ir impact.<br />

The government has announced fur<strong>the</strong>r tightening of building regulations to<br />

improve <strong>the</strong> performance of new homes, and has proposed that all new homes<br />

in England and Wales should be zero carbon by 2016 (Communities and Local<br />

Government 2006). In addition to <strong>the</strong> 2016 target, building regulations will<br />

be used to drive interim improvements in new-build carbon performance<br />

towards targets of a 25% reduction in 2010 and 44% in 2013 compared to<br />

<strong>the</strong> standards in <strong>the</strong> 2006 Part L building regulations (Communities and Local<br />

Government 2006). Achieving this target should save at least 15MtC a year


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

33<br />

by 2050, although <strong>the</strong> contribution to <strong>the</strong> 2020 target is predicted to be<br />

more modest (1.1–1.2MtC) (DTI 2007, Communities and Local Government<br />

2007).<br />

A policy statement in July 2007 confirmed <strong>the</strong>se plans. The zero carbon goal<br />

is to be achieved both by improvements in <strong>the</strong> energy performance of homes<br />

and through <strong>the</strong> use of renewables and o<strong>the</strong>r low-carbon sources of energy,<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r microgeneration in individual homes or low-carbon power supplied<br />

to an entire development. A development will be able to import electricity<br />

from <strong>the</strong> grid, as long as emissions from energy use across <strong>the</strong> development<br />

as a whole are zero over <strong>the</strong> year (ie any imports are offset by equivalent lowcarbon<br />

exports) (Communities and Local Government 2007). The definition<br />

of low-carbon imports to developments may prove problematic: it could<br />

include <strong>the</strong> use of district heating and/or CHP projects outside <strong>the</strong> limits of <strong>the</strong><br />

development, which have clear efficiency advantages over traditional fossil fuel<br />

generation, but might presumably also include o<strong>the</strong>r ‘low-carbon’ sources such<br />

as nuclear power. One question yet to be resolved is how <strong>the</strong> ongoing carbon<br />

neutrality of a development will be ensured if power can be imported, given <strong>the</strong><br />

principle of consumer choice in energy supply. It is not clear how consumers in<br />

<strong>the</strong> new developments will be obliged to import only low or<br />

zero carbon energy.<br />

The Zero Carbon Homes initiative is complemented in England at least by <strong>the</strong><br />

Code for Sustainable Homes, which sets out voluntary standards for house<br />

design and construction beyond those required by building regulations. It<br />

encompasses water, materials, waste and ecology as well as energy. The code<br />

allows developers to gain a star rating reflecting a house’s environmental<br />

performance. There are six levels in <strong>the</strong> code, ranging from Level 1 – a 10%<br />

improvement in energy efficiency over <strong>the</strong> standards in <strong>the</strong> 2006 Building<br />

regulations – to Level 6, which denotes a completely zero carbon home.<br />

Levels 3 and beyond are likely to require some low- or zero carbon energy<br />

input, whe<strong>the</strong>r at <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> individual home or across a whole<br />

development. The code came in to effect in April 2007 and became mandatory<br />

for all new homes from May 2008.<br />

Responses to <strong>the</strong> government’s Zero Carbon Homes proposals were<br />

overwhelmingly positive, although many questions about what may or may<br />

not constitute zero carbon remain to be resolved (Communities and Local<br />

Government 2007). In addition, many responses highlighted <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is a relatively slow turnover in <strong>the</strong> housing stock, so that around 70% of <strong>the</strong><br />

houses which will be standing in 2050 have already been built (Defra 2007a).<br />

It is important to emphasise that action to reduce emissions from new houses<br />

should not be at <strong>the</strong> expense of ongoing measures to improve <strong>the</strong> energy<br />

performance of <strong>the</strong> existing stock.<br />

Setting a target for zero carbon homes 10 years into <strong>the</strong> future may have<br />

understandable attractions for <strong>the</strong> government and <strong>the</strong> house building industry<br />

in terms of regulatory certainty, and this approach is in fact supported by <strong>the</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

34<br />

Home Builders Federation and o<strong>the</strong>r private developer organisations. However,<br />

<strong>the</strong> potential to build zero carbon homes already exists, and given <strong>the</strong> scale of<br />

emissions from <strong>the</strong> domestic sector and <strong>the</strong> potential for <strong>the</strong>ir rapid reduction,<br />

it would have been both feasible and desirable to introduce <strong>the</strong> standards<br />

at an earlier date (House of Commons Environment, Food and Rural Affairs<br />

Committee (2007). Having said that, <strong>the</strong> plan to integrate efficiency measures<br />

and low-carbon generation projects is a sensible approach to shifting <strong>the</strong><br />

housing sector onto a more sustainable path in <strong>the</strong> longer-term. Similarly, <strong>the</strong><br />

ambition set out in <strong>the</strong> 2008 Budget for all new non-domestic buildings<br />

to be zero carbon from 2019 (or 2018 for new public sector buildings)<br />

is welcome. However, setting this ambition 10 years in <strong>the</strong> future again<br />

seems unnecessarily cautious, given <strong>the</strong> potential for rapid reductions in<br />

<strong>the</strong> short-term.<br />

There has also been recent confusion over what <strong>the</strong> development of a zero<br />

carbon home policy for 2016 will mean for measures directed at new homes<br />

now. Attention has focused in particular on <strong>the</strong> future of <strong>the</strong> Merton Rule,<br />

which allows local authorities to set a target for <strong>the</strong> use of on-site renewable<br />

energy to reduce CO2 emissions from major new developments. 9 It has been<br />

reported that Communities and Local Government is considering removing<br />

<strong>the</strong> rule from a forthcoming statement on planning policy, meaning that<br />

local authorities may no longer be able to require renewable energy as part<br />

of a development (Guardian 2007). The department’s justification for this is<br />

apparently that <strong>the</strong> necessity for a specific rule requiring renewables will be<br />

removed by <strong>the</strong> requirement for zero carbon development.<br />

The Merton Rule has been criticised by some builders’ federations, in part<br />

because of <strong>the</strong> cost of installing renewable energy technologies and in part<br />

because it argues that energy efficiency is a better option for reducing CO2<br />

emissions (British Property Federation 2007). This argument misses <strong>the</strong> point<br />

on two levels: firstly, <strong>the</strong> degree to which a development is energy efficient<br />

reduces <strong>the</strong> level of renewable energy required to meet <strong>the</strong> target set.<br />

Secondly, <strong>the</strong> additional costs of installing renewable energy technologies in<br />

new developments should ultimately be offset by <strong>the</strong> savings on <strong>the</strong> occupants’<br />

bills. The Merton Rule has led to <strong>the</strong> development of a market for small-scale<br />

renewables at <strong>the</strong> domestic level which is helping to establish <strong>the</strong> supply chain<br />

and expertise that will be required for <strong>the</strong> future much wider implementation of<br />

those technologies as part of <strong>the</strong> Zero Carbon Homes initiative. Abolishing <strong>the</strong><br />

Merton Rule would thus overlook <strong>the</strong> vital role it is playing in helping to create<br />

a viable market for small-scale renewables by 2016. The potential for a supply<br />

chain gap in suitable renewable energy technologies has been highlighted by<br />

<strong>the</strong> Renewables Advisory Board, which has warned that sufficient capacity<br />

must be built up gradually if <strong>the</strong> 2016 target for zero carbon homes is to be<br />

implemented effectively (Renewables Advisory Board 2007).<br />

3.2.4 O<strong>the</strong>r measures<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r measures in <strong>the</strong> 2007 White Paper are largely aimed at increasing<br />

consumers’ awareness of <strong>the</strong> value of energy and <strong>the</strong> potential for using it<br />

9 <br />

In October 2003, <strong>the</strong> London<br />

Borough of Merton adopted<br />

a policy specifying that all<br />

developments of 10 or more<br />

houses and ‘new non-residential<br />

development above a threshold<br />

of 1,000m2 will be expected to<br />

incorporate renewable energy<br />

production equipment to provide<br />

at least 10% of predicted energy<br />

requirements.’ Since <strong>the</strong>n similar<br />

prescriptive policies have been<br />

adopted by numerous o<strong>the</strong>r local<br />

authorities<br />

(www.<strong>the</strong>mertonrule.org).


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing energy intensity:<br />

efficiency and demand<br />

35<br />

more efficiently. They include <strong>the</strong> introduction of <strong>the</strong> Energy Performance<br />

Certificates (EPCs). EPCs have been introduced for homes with three or<br />

more bedrooms and will be introduced for commercial buildings from April<br />

2008. They will be complemented by information on how to improve energy<br />

performance. Fiscal measures have also been set up, for example reduced<br />

VAT for insulation and some microgeneration and heating technologies, and<br />

incentives for landlords to improve <strong>the</strong> energy efficiency of <strong>the</strong>ir properties.<br />

The White Paper also proposed requiring suppliers to include information on<br />

comparative historic energy consumption on domestic customers’ bills from<br />

May 2008 and set out its expectation that smart meters (including real time<br />

electricity display) should be sited in all homes within 10 years. It also proposed<br />

requiring that all replacement meters installed by energy suppliers in existing<br />

homes, and all meters in new homes, should include real time electricity<br />

displays by May 2008, and that o<strong>the</strong>r households requesting a real time display<br />

should be provided with one between 2008–10. The intention was is to make<br />

consumers more aware of how <strong>the</strong>y use energy, and so to reduce consumption.<br />

However, following consultation on <strong>the</strong> White Paper proposals, <strong>the</strong> government<br />

backed away from <strong>the</strong> plan to require real time displays, instead making<br />

this action voluntary for suppliers (BERR 2008d). This may not be a hugely<br />

significant shift in terms of overall carbon emissions, but <strong>the</strong> removal of <strong>the</strong><br />

requirement for real time displays in favour of voluntary action, largely on<br />

cost grounds, demonstrates <strong>the</strong> difficulty <strong>the</strong> government has in balancing its<br />

environmental goals with business interests.<br />

The White Paper commits <strong>the</strong> government to concrete action on improving<br />

end-use efficiency, largely driven by <strong>the</strong> requirements of EU legislation. This<br />

includes potential improvements to <strong>the</strong> labelling of products to show <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

energy consumption, and a target to phase out incandescent light bulbs from<br />

domestic use by 2011. This is ahead of <strong>the</strong> date expected to be set by EU<br />

legislation, which is unlikely to be implemented until 2010, but <strong>the</strong> impact of<br />

<strong>the</strong> measure is mitigated somewhat by confining it to <strong>the</strong> domestic sector, and<br />

qualifying <strong>the</strong> intention by stating that <strong>the</strong> bulbs will be phased out only ‘where<br />

an efficient alternative exists’.<br />

3.3 Conclusions: reducing energy intensity<br />

Energy efficiency and demand reduction measures are intended to reduce<br />

<strong>the</strong> energy intensity of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s economy. As well as reducing emissions<br />

overall, improved efficiency can have broader benefits, in particular in relation<br />

to industrial competitiveness. However, <strong>the</strong> measures in <strong>the</strong> 2007 White<br />

Paper are strikingly unambitious in comparison with <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s potential for<br />

cost effective improvements in energy efficiency. Greater reductions in<br />

emissions could be achieved relatively quickly and cheaply by increasing<br />

<strong>the</strong> impact of programmes directed at <strong>the</strong> industrial, business and<br />

domestic sectors.<br />

It is clear that <strong>the</strong>re is still enormous scope to reduce emissions from business<br />

and industry cost effectively; but in order to maximise <strong>the</strong>se,in <strong>the</strong> short term<br />

CCAs need to be tightened. Meanwhile, it is difficult to predict <strong>the</strong> likely impact


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Future</strong>: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Reducing Energy Intensity: Reducing<br />

Demand through Energy Efficiency<br />

36<br />

on emissions of <strong>the</strong> CRC. While it promises to be a useful means of improving<br />

<strong>the</strong> energy intensity of business and <strong>the</strong> public sector, it looks likely that <strong>the</strong><br />

scheme will entail a degree of crossover with both <strong>the</strong> ETS and <strong>the</strong> CCL/CCAs.<br />

Ra<strong>the</strong>r than having all <strong>the</strong>se schemes running in parallel. It would be simpler, and<br />

possibly more transparent, to rationalise <strong>the</strong> existing schemes, and ultimately<br />

to incorporate those companies with CCAs into <strong>the</strong> new CRC scheme and make<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir targets mandatory ra<strong>the</strong>r than voluntary. The government consulted on<br />

this more integrated approach at <strong>the</strong> end of 2007, although it is yet to publish<br />

its final conclusions (Defra 2007f).<br />

The government has recognised <strong>the</strong> potential for cuts in emissions associated<br />

with commercial buildings, but has not yet set out its strategy for this work or a<br />

target date for its implementation. Energy efficiency improvements in existing<br />

commercial buildings should be driven, at least in part, by established policy<br />

mechanisms, but <strong>the</strong> government should also quickly establish its framework<br />

to require all new non-domestic buildings to be zero carbon.<br />

Turning to <strong>the</strong> domestic sector, <strong>the</strong> EEC scheme has had some success,<br />

although <strong>the</strong> ongoing level of early overachievement shows that <strong>the</strong> targets<br />

are not sufficiently demanding. Both <strong>the</strong> new CERT and <strong>the</strong> commitment to <strong>the</strong><br />

Supplier Obligation in <strong>the</strong> longer-term need to be made more ambitious. This is<br />

particularly important given <strong>the</strong> slow turnover in housing stock and <strong>the</strong> sector’s<br />

overall contribution to CO2 emissions.<br />

The Zero Carbon Homes initiative is encouraging, although its implementation<br />

may prove complex given <strong>the</strong> current market framework and <strong>the</strong> emphasis on<br />

individual consumer choice in energy supply. zero carbon homes are feasible<br />

now, and <strong>the</strong> target date for implementation should be brought forward. In<br />

<strong>the</strong> meantime, <strong>the</strong> government needs to maintain <strong>the</strong> Merton Rule for new<br />

developments, whe<strong>the</strong>r in <strong>the</strong> domestic or commercial sector, as a way of<br />

maintaining and fur<strong>the</strong>r encouraging <strong>the</strong> emerging renewable energy systems<br />

supply chains.<br />

In <strong>the</strong> longer term, it is clear that <strong>the</strong> government is beginning to appreciate <strong>the</strong><br />

value that can come from an energy services approach to energy consumption.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> shift towards an Energy Service Companies (ESCOs) industry<br />

needs to come about more quickly: by 2020, <strong>the</strong> government should explicitly<br />

aim to ensure that all energy supply companies have an ESCOs approach for all<br />

energy sales.


37<br />

04<br />

Sustainable energy<br />

systems<br />

The ROCA 3 combined heat and power (CHP) plant in Rotterdam-capellen<br />

provides electricity and heat to 400,000 homes.<br />

©Reynaers/<strong>Greenpeace</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

38<br />

Reducing <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s reliance on carbon-intensive fuels is a longer-term approach<br />

to reducing overall emissions than <strong>the</strong> quick hits often offered by reductions in<br />

energy consumption. However, <strong>the</strong> technologies and infrastructure required<br />

to enable <strong>the</strong> development of sustainable energy systems must be put in place<br />

now if low-carbon energy is to be readily available in <strong>the</strong> longer term. Policy<br />

measures <strong>the</strong>refore need to incorporate a strategic approach to encouraging<br />

<strong>the</strong> development and deployment of low-carbon technologies, which are<br />

often newer and <strong>the</strong>refore riskier than conventional energy technologies.<br />

Without such a long term strategy, achieving <strong>the</strong> EU’s targets – or even moving<br />

significantly towards <strong>the</strong>m – seems a remote possibility. This section outlines<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s main measures aimed at addressing <strong>the</strong> implementation of new<br />

technologies.<br />

4.1 Low-carbon electricity<br />

The definition of low-carbon electricity can be very broad, encompassing<br />

various conventional generating sources as well as newer renewable sources.<br />

Supposedly clean coal technologies, using more efficient combustion<br />

techniques and/or carbon capture and storage (CSS), have been labelled as<br />

low-carbon sources of electricity in <strong>the</strong> Energy White Paper, as has nuclear<br />

power. However, while <strong>the</strong> generation of electricity from <strong>the</strong>se sources may<br />

produce relatively few carbon emissions in comparison with conventional<br />

fossil fuel plants, <strong>the</strong>y entail o<strong>the</strong>r environmental impacts, such as <strong>the</strong> waste<br />

products associated with nuclear power generation. In <strong>the</strong> case of ‘clean coal’,<br />

moreover, <strong>the</strong>re is uncertainty as to <strong>the</strong> commercial viability and technical<br />

applicability of CCS. The low-carbon options considered in this report are those<br />

which are ei<strong>the</strong>r renewable or use fossil fuels at a much increased efficiency<br />

by providing both electricity and usable heat. As well as often involving<br />

relatively new technologies, <strong>the</strong>se two approaches both face barriers within <strong>the</strong><br />

established energy system, as <strong>the</strong>ir characteristics do not conform to those of<br />

conventional generating technologies.<br />

4.1.1 Renewables<br />

The Renewables Obligation (RO), introduced in 2002, is <strong>the</strong> main support<br />

mechanism for renewables generation in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>. It is an obligation on electricity<br />

suppliers to provide a proportion of <strong>the</strong>ir supply from eligible renewable<br />

sources. The proportion is set to increase over time, from 3% in 2002 to 15.4%<br />

in 2015. The government has an ‘aspiration’ to achieve a 20% renewables<br />

supply by 2020, and is committed to raising <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> RO after 2015 on a<br />

guaranteed headroom basis, where <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> obligation for a given year is<br />

only raised if <strong>the</strong> level of renewables generation justifies it. So, although <strong>the</strong> RO<br />

could continue to increase after 2015, this will not necessarily deliver <strong>the</strong> 20%<br />

aspiration by 2020.<br />

Suppliers currently prove that <strong>the</strong>y have bought <strong>the</strong> specified level of<br />

renewable electricity by presenting to Ofgem Renewables Obligation<br />

Certificates (ROCs), each of which represent one megawatt hour of output.<br />

These ROCs can ei<strong>the</strong>r be obtained from a generator upon purchase of <strong>the</strong><br />

corresponding output, or <strong>the</strong>y can be bought and sold separately from <strong>the</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

39<br />

electricity itself. Alternatively, suppliers can also choose to pay a penalty<br />

buyout price to Ofgem if <strong>the</strong>y choose not to source <strong>the</strong> ROCs through <strong>the</strong><br />

means outlined previously. 10 The funds from buyout payments are recycled<br />

to electricity suppliers annually in line with <strong>the</strong> proportion of <strong>the</strong> RO <strong>the</strong>y<br />

have met. The value of an ROC is <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> buyout price<br />

plus <strong>the</strong> expected income from recycling <strong>the</strong> buyout funds at <strong>the</strong> end of <strong>the</strong><br />

year. The greater <strong>the</strong> shortfall in renewable supply compared with <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

annual target and <strong>the</strong> more buyout penalties suppliers have <strong>the</strong>refore had to<br />

pay, <strong>the</strong> greater <strong>the</strong> value of <strong>the</strong> buyout funds and <strong>the</strong>refore of an ROC. The<br />

redistribution of <strong>the</strong> buyout funds thus adds value to ROCs, although this would<br />

decrease dramatically if <strong>the</strong> annual target were met or almost met.<br />

So far, <strong>the</strong> annual targets for renewables generation have all been missed<br />

(Table 4.1). This is an almost inevitable outcome of <strong>the</strong> design of <strong>the</strong> RO: once<br />

<strong>the</strong> target is approached, <strong>the</strong> value of ROCs plummets as <strong>the</strong> additional value<br />

of buyout redistribution is reduced and as competition between renewable<br />

generators increases as <strong>the</strong> attraction of ROCs to suppliers declines. This in turn<br />

leads to <strong>the</strong> value of ROCs dropping near to <strong>the</strong> price of short-run marginal<br />

costs (Pöyry 2006, see Figure 4.1). This latter phenomenon removes <strong>the</strong><br />

incentive to invest in generation projects, particularly if <strong>the</strong>y entail high capital<br />

costs or a high level of investor risk. The 2007 White Paper proposes new<br />

arrangements to mitigate <strong>the</strong> risk of this cliff edge if necessary in <strong>the</strong> future.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> trend of failing to meet <strong>the</strong> targets is expected to continue, with<br />

energy consultancy Oxera estimating that <strong>the</strong> RO in its current form will deliver<br />

only 8.1% of supply from renewables by 2010, 11.4% by 2015 and 11.5% by<br />

2020 (Oxera 2007).<br />

Target percentage of<br />

total electricity supply<br />

from renewables<br />

Achieved percentage<br />

of total electricity<br />

supply<br />

Percentage of target<br />

achieved<br />

2002<br />

3.0<br />

1.8<br />

60<br />

2003<br />

4.3<br />

2.2<br />

51<br />

2004<br />

4.9<br />

3.1<br />

63<br />

2005<br />

5.5<br />

4.0<br />

73<br />

2006<br />

6.7<br />

4.4<br />

66<br />

Table 4.1: Renewables Obligation performance 2002 – 2007<br />

Sources: HMSO 2002, DTI 2007a<br />

Notes: The RO runs from 1 April - 31 March each year, while <strong>the</strong> DTI figures on <strong>the</strong><br />

percentages achieved uses data from 1 January - 31 December. However, <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

percentage should not differ significantly.<br />

10 <br />

The buyout price for 2008–<br />

2009 is set at £35.76. The price<br />

is increased annually in line with<br />

<strong>the</strong> Retail Price Index.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

40<br />

100<br />

90<br />

80<br />

70<br />

60<br />

50<br />

ROC values (£/MWh)<br />

for a £30/MWh<br />

buyout price<br />

40<br />

30<br />

20<br />

10<br />

0<br />

30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% 100% 110% 120%<br />

Figure 4.1 Renewables Obligation Certificate price cliff edge<br />

Source: Pöyry 2006, p6<br />

The RO was originally designed to be technology-blind – in o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong><br />

value of ROCs would be equal for all eligible technologies, regardless of <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

degree of technological maturity. In order to maximise profits, suppliers would<br />

<strong>the</strong>refore seek to buy output from <strong>the</strong> lowest-cost generating projects, using<br />

<strong>the</strong> most developed, least risky technology. This has led to a rapid expansion<br />

of projects using <strong>the</strong> relatively mature technologies of onshore wind and<br />

landfill gas, sited in <strong>the</strong> places with <strong>the</strong> best resource, and of biomass<br />

co-firing in existing coal fired power stations, which does not entail capital costs<br />

and is <strong>the</strong>refore relatively risk-free (Figure 4.2). Less mature technologies<br />

– for example some biomass and marine generation technologies – have<br />

been relatively unattractive because of <strong>the</strong> greater level of risk associated<br />

with <strong>the</strong>m. So while wind and landfill gas have benefited from <strong>the</strong> RO, o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

renewable technologies have been neglected.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

41<br />

1,800,000<br />

1,600,000<br />

1,400,000<br />

1,200,000<br />

1,000,000<br />

800,000<br />

600,000<br />

400,000<br />

200,000<br />

Number of<br />

ROCs<br />

issued<br />

Co-firing with<br />

energy crops<br />

Wave power<br />

Sewage gas<br />

Photovoltaics<br />

Onshore wind<br />

Offshore wind<br />

Micro hydro<br />

Landfill gas<br />

Hydro 20 MW<br />

DNC or less<br />

Co-firing biomass<br />

with fossil fuel<br />

Biomass with waste<br />

using ACT<br />

Biomass<br />

0<br />

Apr<br />

2002<br />

Oct<br />

2002<br />

Apr<br />

2003<br />

Oct<br />

2003<br />

Apr<br />

2004<br />

Oct<br />

2004<br />

Apr<br />

2005<br />

Oct<br />

2005<br />

Apr<br />

2006<br />

Figure 4.2: Renewables output under <strong>the</strong> Renewables Obligation<br />

Source: Ofgem data on ROC allocation, www.ofgem.gov.uk<br />

Oct<br />

2006<br />

When <strong>the</strong> RO was introduced, <strong>the</strong> government rejected <strong>the</strong> idea of banding<br />

<strong>the</strong> mechanism to provide different levels of support to newer and to more<br />

established technologies on <strong>the</strong> grounds that it would be tantamount to<br />

orchestrating <strong>the</strong> market mechanism in favour of one or more particular<br />

technologies over o<strong>the</strong>rs through regulatory intervention. However, <strong>the</strong><br />

government has gradually recognised that <strong>the</strong> RO has failed to encourage a<br />

diverse or particularly innovative set of renewables technologies (DTI 2007c).<br />

In response to this issue, <strong>the</strong> 2006 Energy Review and 2007 White Paper<br />

put forward a plan to create a banding system for <strong>the</strong> RO so as to try and<br />

compensate for <strong>the</strong> difficulties faced by new technologies. Existing projects will<br />

continue to be allocated one ROC per megawatt hour, but after <strong>the</strong> proposed<br />

changes take effect new renewables projects will receive different levels<br />

depending on <strong>the</strong> degree to which <strong>the</strong> technology is seen as mature (see Table<br />

4.2). Instead of <strong>the</strong> RO being set in terms of a proportion of electricity supplied,<br />

once <strong>the</strong> new banding system is introduced it will be defined by <strong>the</strong> number of<br />

ROCs presented to Ofgem by suppliers. The level of <strong>the</strong> obligation will increase<br />

each year on <strong>the</strong> basis of guaranteed headroom, with <strong>the</strong> headroom set at an<br />

additional 8% of <strong>the</strong> number of ROCs expected during any obligation period. 11<br />

The demand for ROCs for <strong>the</strong> next obligation period will <strong>the</strong>reby become <strong>the</strong><br />

driver for bringing new capacity on-line, up to <strong>the</strong> government’s 2020 20%<br />

renewables target. These changes are expected to come into force in April<br />

2009. However, even with <strong>the</strong> reforms, <strong>the</strong> RO is only predicted to deliver<br />

around 13.4% of electricity supply from renewables by 2015 and 14% in 2020<br />

– well short of <strong>the</strong> government’s 2020 ambition (BERR 2008c).<br />

11 <br />

The concept of guaranteed<br />

headroom means that <strong>the</strong> level<br />

of <strong>the</strong> Obligation for each period<br />

will be set at a level based on<br />

expected renewables generation<br />

plus a fur<strong>the</strong>r proportion<br />

– in this case, an addition<br />

8% of <strong>the</strong> ROCs expected<br />

to be issued in <strong>the</strong> relevant<br />

period. The guarantee of an<br />

obligation requiring more ROCs<br />

than generation in a period is<br />

designed to avoid <strong>the</strong> risk of<br />

ROC prices crashing as <strong>the</strong> gap<br />

between generation achieved<br />

and <strong>the</strong> obligation target is<br />

narrowed, with a consequent<br />

fall-off in <strong>the</strong> level of recycling<br />

of <strong>the</strong> buyout fund.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

42<br />

Band<br />

Technologies<br />

Support (ROC/MWh)<br />

Established 1<br />

Established 2<br />

Reference<br />

Post-demonstration<br />

Emerging<br />

Landfill<br />

Sewage gas; co-firing of non-energy-crop biomass<br />

Onshore wind [1]; hydro; energy from waste with CHP; co-firing<br />

of energy crops; geopressure<br />

Offshore wind; dedicated regular biomass<br />

Wave and tidal stream; anaerobic digestion, pyrolysis and<br />

gasification; dedicated biomass burning energy crops; dedicated<br />

biomass with CHP; photovoltaics; geo<strong>the</strong>rmal; tidal impoundment<br />

(tidal lagoons and barrages)


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

43<br />

of ROC price. If it is too low, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> technology will not be deployed. A key<br />

criterion for <strong>the</strong> success of <strong>the</strong> RO should not simply be whe<strong>the</strong>r or not <strong>the</strong><br />

target is reached, but how effective it is in encouraging <strong>the</strong> broad portfolio<br />

of renewable technologies that will be necessary to bring about a long term<br />

decarbonisation of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> energy system. It is <strong>the</strong>refore imperative that <strong>the</strong><br />

ROC banding results in a balanced renewable mix while meeting <strong>the</strong> quotas<br />

outlined as part of <strong>the</strong> obligation.<br />

The RO’s failure so far ei<strong>the</strong>r to meet its annual renewables targets or to<br />

encourage a diverse set of technologies has arisen because of <strong>the</strong> lack of<br />

long-term certainty about ROC prices, which increases developers’ uncertainty<br />

regarding risky new technologies. Banding may well succeed in encouraging<br />

development of certain technologies by guaranteeing a reasonable value for<br />

ROCs and so decreasing that uncertainty. However, <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r shortcomings of<br />

<strong>the</strong> RO will remain: although <strong>the</strong>re may well be higher returns for technologies in<br />

<strong>the</strong> emerging technologies bands, <strong>the</strong> more certain returns will still come from<br />

<strong>the</strong> established technologies which generate at lower cost and benefit from<br />

relatively high levels of experience. Certainty is a key factor in a competitive<br />

electricity market like <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s. So even if <strong>the</strong> banding is set at <strong>the</strong> appropriate<br />

levels, while <strong>the</strong> reformed RO may drive more investment in new renewables<br />

technologies, <strong>the</strong> most established and <strong>the</strong>refore least risky technologies – such<br />

as onshore wind - may well dominate despite <strong>the</strong> banding of <strong>the</strong> RO.<br />

The burning of biomass fuels in coal plants (co-firing) has been allowed under<br />

<strong>the</strong> RO, although <strong>the</strong>re is currently a cap of 10% on <strong>the</strong> proportion of any<br />

supplier’s obligation that can be met through co-firing. This reflects concerns<br />

that <strong>the</strong> practice might extend <strong>the</strong> life of existing coal plants and provide coal<br />

generators with additional income from ROCs without having to make any<br />

significant capital expenditure to merit it. In addition, much of <strong>the</strong> fuel used for<br />

co-firing is imported, and can <strong>the</strong>refore entail transport related CO2 emissions,<br />

particularly given that <strong>the</strong> largest proportion of biomass used in co-firing in<br />

2005 came from Indonesia and Asia (see Table 4.3).<br />

The 2007 review of <strong>the</strong> RO proposes removing <strong>the</strong> 10% cap on co-firing, on<br />

<strong>the</strong> grounds that an increase in co-firing will mitigate carbon emissions from<br />

coal plants that would be operating irrespective of whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y were using<br />

coal or biomass. However, under <strong>the</strong> same proposals co-firing will only be<br />

eligible for a reduced ROC level (0.25 ROC/MWh). These arrangements will be<br />

reviewed if co-firing ROCs make up more than 10% of <strong>the</strong> total RO; however,<br />

given that a generator will now have to generate 4MWh for every ROC earned,<br />

this will allow a considerable expansion of biomass co-firing before a review<br />

is triggered, provided it continues to be an economic option. 14 Whe<strong>the</strong>r this<br />

is desirable is arguable, however: on <strong>the</strong> one hand, <strong>the</strong>se new arrangements<br />

may encourage <strong>the</strong> emergence of viable biomass supply chains in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong><br />

- domestically sourced, sustainably produced biomass. On <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand,<br />

<strong>the</strong> most efficient use of limited sustainable biomass resources is in dedicated<br />

biomass combined heat and power (CHP) generators, ra<strong>the</strong>r than inefficient<br />

coal fired power stations, producing electricity but wasting <strong>the</strong> heat.<br />

14 <br />

There is now a clear distinction<br />

between general biomass and<br />

energy crops, which are defined<br />

as plant crops planted after<br />

1989 grown primarily for <strong>the</strong><br />

purpose of being used as a fuel,<br />

or which are miscanthus, shortrotation<br />

coppice willow or poplar.<br />

Energy crops will not be subject<br />

to <strong>the</strong> 10% co-firing trigger, and<br />

will have a higher level of ROC.<br />

This reflects <strong>the</strong> government’s<br />

aim of encouraging a viable and<br />

sustainable domestic energy<br />

crop supply chain.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

44<br />

Feedstock<br />

Quantity burned<br />

(tonnes)<br />

% of total<br />

quantity<br />

burned<br />

Likely<br />

country<br />

of origin<br />

Mode of<br />

transport<br />

Transport-related<br />

emissions (kg<br />

CO2/tonne)<br />

Energy stock (short-rotation<br />

coppice, granulated willow,<br />

miscanthus)<br />

4,306<br />

0.3<br />

<strong>UK</strong><br />

Road<br />

1.7<br />

Shea residues (meal and<br />

pellets)<br />

5,420<br />

0.4<br />

Africa<br />

Road and ship<br />

55.4<br />

Sunflower pellets<br />

Sewage sludge and<br />

waste-derived fuels<br />

20,331<br />

49,155<br />

1.4<br />

3.5<br />

Romania<br />

<strong>UK</strong><br />

Road and ship<br />

Road<br />

47.1<br />

3.4<br />

Cereal co-products and<br />

pellets<br />

102,246<br />

7.2<br />

<strong>UK</strong><br />

Road<br />

1.7<br />

Tallow<br />

119,828<br />

8.5<br />

<strong>UK</strong><br />

Road<br />

1.7<br />

Olive waste (residue and<br />

expeller)<br />

283,222<br />

20.1<br />

Greece, Italy,<br />

Spain<br />

Road and ship<br />

21.2<br />

Wood (sawdust, chips,<br />

pellets etc)<br />

377,956<br />

26.8<br />

<strong>UK</strong>, Canada,<br />

Latvia,<br />

Scandinavia<br />

Road and ship<br />

1.7 (<strong>UK</strong>)<br />

to 42.9<br />

Palm residues (palm kernel<br />

expeller, shell, pellets, oil)<br />

449,657<br />

31.8<br />

Indonesia,<br />

Malaysia<br />

Road and ship<br />

106.5 (Indonesia)<br />

to 107.4 (Malaysia)<br />

Total mass<br />

1,412,121<br />

Total energy (PJ)<br />

14.1<br />

Table 4.3: Feedstock used in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> for co-firing, 2005<br />

Source: DTI/DfT/Defra (2007), based on Themba Technology report for DTI,<br />

September 2006<br />

In addition to its failure so far to encourage <strong>the</strong> deployment of a diverse set of<br />

renewable technologies, <strong>the</strong> RO has proved to be an extremely costly mechanism<br />

for <strong>the</strong> amount of new output it has delivered, in comparison with mechanisms in<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r EU countries such as Germany or Spain (European Commission 2005).<br />

This poor performance on cost is due to <strong>the</strong> competitive nature of <strong>the</strong> RO,<br />

and <strong>the</strong> lack of guarantee of ROC prices for generators make it hard to predict<br />

revenue over <strong>the</strong> life of a project with any certainty (Gross et al. 2007),<br />

discouraging investors and leading to higher financing costs for new projects.<br />

In contrast, mechanisms which guarantee a preferential price for different<br />

renewable technologies’ output for a guaranteed period (feed-in tariffs), or<br />

which guarantee that generators will be paid an amount in addition to <strong>the</strong> market<br />

price (market uplift) entail much lower risks for generators, making it easier to<br />

finance new projects, and lowering <strong>the</strong> level of subsidy required. This is discussed<br />

in more detail in 4.1.2.<br />

Ofgem has responded to <strong>the</strong> European Commission’s analysis by calling for<br />

<strong>the</strong> RO to be replaced, ra<strong>the</strong>r than reviewed and redesigned along <strong>the</strong> lines of<br />

<strong>the</strong> 2007 reform proposals (Ofgem 2007, DTI 2007c). It recommends any of<br />

several options: <strong>the</strong> creation of feed-in tariffs for renewables; arrangements


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

45<br />

based on <strong>the</strong> market uplift model outlined above; or <strong>the</strong> redesign of <strong>the</strong> ROC<br />

market to remove <strong>the</strong> reliance on <strong>the</strong> redistribution of <strong>the</strong> buyout fund to provide<br />

additional value. Each of <strong>the</strong>se would provide a degree of additional certainty for<br />

generators and <strong>the</strong>refore reduce <strong>the</strong> costs of deploying increased levels<br />

of renewables.<br />

The proposals are likely to be unpopular with BERR, which has consistently<br />

argued against major changes to <strong>the</strong> RO on <strong>the</strong> grounds that <strong>the</strong> consequent<br />

regulatory uncertainty would undermine investor confidence, and has opposed a<br />

feed-in type mechanism on <strong>the</strong> grounds that it would be picking winners ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

than <strong>the</strong>oretically maintaining its neutrality towards technologies. However,<br />

<strong>the</strong> RO has undergone several revisions since its introduction (in 2004, 2005,<br />

2006 and most recently 2007 (DTI 2007c)), so <strong>the</strong> argument that policy<br />

stability is key to investor confidence can carry little weight. In addition, <strong>the</strong><br />

latest set of reforms encapsulate an approach so fundamentally different to <strong>the</strong><br />

original technology-blind philosophy of <strong>the</strong> RO that, whe<strong>the</strong>r or not investor<br />

confidence has been damaged, <strong>the</strong> credibility of <strong>the</strong> mechanism itself has been<br />

undermined. Finally, by allocating separate ROC bands to different technologies,<br />

<strong>the</strong> government has in effect already adopted <strong>the</strong> principles of a feed-in tariff,<br />

without <strong>the</strong> advantages that that mechanism can offer in terms of overall cost,<br />

from which <strong>the</strong> consumer would ultimately benefit.<br />

As Ofgem has pointed out, <strong>the</strong> latest set of proposals for <strong>the</strong> reform to <strong>the</strong><br />

RO have taken a relatively complex market-based system and made it even<br />

more complex, both to understand and to administer (Ofgem 2007).<br />

The government urgently needs to investigate ways in which it can rectify<br />

<strong>the</strong> key failure of <strong>the</strong> RO: <strong>the</strong> lack of certainty it provides to investors.<br />

Such measures might include extending well beyond its current timeframe<br />

of 2015, introducing feed-in tariffs to complement <strong>the</strong> existing RO as well<br />

as reviewing any banding modifications to assess <strong>the</strong>ir effectiveness at<br />

encouraging technologies that are fur<strong>the</strong>r from commercial deployment.<br />

4.1.2 Green tariffs<br />

The environmental benefits offered by renewable electricity mean that it can<br />

attract a premium price from consumers eager to contribute to CO2 emission<br />

reductions. Under current arrangements, however, <strong>the</strong>re is little consensus<br />

between electricity suppliers about what constitutes an acceptable scope for green<br />

tariffs. For example, should <strong>the</strong>y include <strong>the</strong> use of energy<br />

from waste, even though <strong>the</strong> supplier who buys and provides such energy<br />

is only doing what it is legally obliged to do under <strong>the</strong> RO. There have been a number<br />

of critical analyses of <strong>the</strong> various green tariffs on offer from electricity suppliers and<br />

<strong>the</strong> confusion that <strong>the</strong> lack of transparency can cause for consumers (Boardman et<br />

al. 2006, Graham 2007).<br />

Ofgem is currently developing guidelines for green tariffs which will attempt to<br />

classify and rank <strong>the</strong> various sources of energy which could be marketed as<br />

low-carbon and/or green (Ofgem 2007a). At <strong>the</strong> moment, Ofgem is proposing<br />

that low-carbon tariffs should include technologies such as ‘good quality’ 15<br />

15 <br />

The criteria behind <strong>the</strong><br />

government and industry’s<br />

definition of ‘good quality’ CHP<br />

include issues such as <strong>the</strong> overall<br />

efficiency of generation and <strong>the</strong><br />

fuel used. A full definition can be<br />

found at www.chpqa.com


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Future</strong>: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable Energy Systems<br />

46<br />

CHP, clean coal and nuclear power as well as renewables, ranked according to<br />

environmental impacts and efficiency. Ofgem suggests that <strong>the</strong>y could also<br />

be made to include <strong>the</strong> offsetting of carbon emissions. The concept of green<br />

tariffs could thus end up being extended to include a range of non-renewable<br />

technologies which may generate low-carbon power but some of which may<br />

bring o<strong>the</strong>r environmental problems. The guidelines for low-carbon tariffs are<br />

currently intended to be voluntary, with Ofgem having no formal enforcement role<br />

for <strong>the</strong> scheme. As it stands <strong>the</strong>re is a risk that some suppliers may be less than<br />

transparent in revealing <strong>the</strong> exact technology mix in <strong>the</strong>ir low-carbon scheme<br />

and <strong>the</strong>re is little that can be done to prevent this. This is particularly serious given<br />

<strong>the</strong> implicit blurring of <strong>the</strong> edges in <strong>the</strong> proposed classification of low-carbon<br />

offerings – between ‘low-carbon’ and ‘green’ supply. At <strong>the</strong> moment, this would<br />

allow nuclear power and fossil fuel power produced using carbon sequestration<br />

and storage to be marketed as ‘green’ despite <strong>the</strong> broader environmental problems<br />

associated with <strong>the</strong> technologies. Logically, if <strong>the</strong>se guidelines are for green power<br />

ra<strong>the</strong>r than just low-carbon power, <strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong>se broader impacts – for example, <strong>the</strong><br />

volumes and half-lives of nuclear waste – should also be listed.<br />

Central government departments have a commitment to source 10% of<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir electricity from renewable sources by March 2008. In June 2007,<br />

<strong>the</strong> government agreed a contract worth more than £1 billion for EDF to<br />

supply 1TWh of renewable electricity to government departments up to<br />

2011. This represents around a third of electricity currently supplied to central<br />

government (Office of Government Commerce 2007). The four year deal will<br />

cost no more than buying conventional power and paying <strong>the</strong> associated CCL.<br />

This is interesting in that it implies that <strong>the</strong> level of certainty offered to EDF by<br />

a long term supply contract has reduced <strong>the</strong> unit cost of <strong>the</strong> power – providing<br />

evidence in favour of long-term contracts and/or feed-in tariffs for renewable<br />

output. However, little information has been revealed about <strong>the</strong> details of <strong>the</strong><br />

deal. So, for example, it is not clear whe<strong>the</strong>r EDF or <strong>the</strong> government will retire<br />

<strong>the</strong> ROCs associated with <strong>the</strong> energy supplied, which would create additional<br />

demand for renewables output over and above that required by <strong>the</strong> RO.<br />

<strong>UK</strong> demand for green energy currently outstrips supply, with companies<br />

reportedly planning to buy 34TWh of green electricity in 2007 while<br />

renewables output amounted to only 18.1TWh in 2006 (Datamonitor 2007,<br />

DTI 2007a). Under current proposals, this shortfall in renewable generation<br />

could be met with non-renewable energy sources labelled as low-carbon, or by<br />

o<strong>the</strong>r schemes such as offsetting which, while <strong>the</strong>y may offer some emissions<br />

reduction benefits, are doing little to encourage a shift to lower-carbon energy<br />

systems in <strong>the</strong> longer term. The disparity between <strong>the</strong> supply of renewable<br />

energy and <strong>the</strong> demand from <strong>UK</strong> consumers demonstrates <strong>the</strong> failure of<br />

<strong>the</strong> government’s renewables policy to create <strong>the</strong> conditions necessary for<br />

renewables generation to expand at <strong>the</strong> rate required to meet public demand.<br />

The danger is that <strong>the</strong> demand for renewable power will contribute to a<br />

situation where low-carbon power is marketed as green regardless of its wider<br />

environmental impacts. Unless information on <strong>the</strong>se broad impacts is also


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

47<br />

provided, nuclear power and fossil fuel generation should be excluded from<br />

green tariff scheme marketing.<br />

4.1.3 Microgeneration and <strong>the</strong> Low Carbon Buildings Programme<br />

There is no specific target for microgeneration. However, <strong>the</strong> Energy Savings<br />

Trust has estimated that microgeneration technologies could provide 30–40%<br />

of <strong>UK</strong> electricity demand and reduce CO2 emissions by around 15% from <strong>the</strong><br />

household sector by 2050 (DTI 2006a). Microgeneration technologies benefit<br />

from a reduced rate of VAT of 5%, but <strong>the</strong> main mechanism aimed at encouraging<br />

greater deployment is <strong>the</strong> Low Carbon Buildings Programme (LCBP). This<br />

provides a maximum of £6 million a year, up to a total of £86 million in grants<br />

for <strong>the</strong> installation of microgeneration in households (phase one) and buildings<br />

belonging to <strong>the</strong> public sector and charitable organisations (phase two).<br />

The LCBP’s phase one household grant scheme was suspended in March 2007<br />

when, due to popularity, <strong>the</strong> month’s £500,000 funds ran out in less than an hour.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> government claimed that <strong>the</strong> suspension came about because <strong>the</strong><br />

microgeneration industry was finding it hard to meet demand, <strong>the</strong> industry has<br />

denied this (ENDS Report, May 2007). When <strong>the</strong> scheme was relaunched in May<br />

2007, <strong>the</strong>re was no longer a monthly cap on <strong>the</strong> funds available, and a new rule<br />

had been introduced requiring applicants to have received planning permission for<br />

<strong>the</strong> installation before applying. In addition, grants for some technologies had been<br />

reduced. The revised scheme appears to have run in to trouble, with a significant fall<br />

in <strong>the</strong> rate of grants being awarded for all technologies (ENDS Report, April 2008<br />

– see Table 4.4).<br />

The level of LCBP grants may initially have been set too high, leading to<br />

oversubscription of <strong>the</strong> scheme, but <strong>the</strong> revision following <strong>the</strong> scheme’s<br />

suspension appears to have cut <strong>the</strong> grants by too much, reducing <strong>the</strong> incentive<br />

to invest in <strong>the</strong> new technologies and <strong>the</strong>reby leading to an underspend.<br />

Although <strong>the</strong> scheme was originally planned to end in mid 2008, BERR has<br />

now decided to extend it until 2010, it was originally planned to end mid 2008,<br />

so that all allocated funds can be spent, ra<strong>the</strong>r than reconsidering <strong>the</strong> level of<br />

available grants.<br />

There do not seem to be plans to extend or expand <strong>the</strong> scheme beyond 2010,<br />

risking a collapse in <strong>the</strong> microgeneration market after that date. This risk may be<br />

mitigated by <strong>the</strong> inclusion of microgeneration in <strong>the</strong> new CERT scheme for energy<br />

suppliers, although given <strong>the</strong> availability of short-term, cheaper energy efficiency<br />

measures through which suppliers can meet <strong>the</strong>ir obligations, it seems unlikely<br />

that <strong>the</strong>y will install significant levels of microgeneration in <strong>the</strong> short-term.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

48<br />

Before reform<br />

After reform<br />

Solar <strong>the</strong>rmal<br />

Approved<br />

209<br />

129<br />

Paid<br />

168<br />

68<br />

Solar photovoltaic<br />

Approved<br />

56<br />

33<br />

Paid<br />

44<br />

17<br />

Wind<br />

Approved<br />

152<br />

17<br />

Paid<br />

41<br />

5<br />

Ground source heat pumps<br />

Approved<br />

28<br />

22<br />

Paid<br />

18<br />

3<br />

Total<br />

Approved<br />

445<br />

201<br />

Paid<br />

271<br />

93<br />

Table 4.4: Low Carbon Buildings Programme grants per month<br />

Source: ENDS Report February 2008, p7<br />

A key factor in driving consumer demand for some microgeneration<br />

technologies is <strong>the</strong> price that owners can receive from electricity suppliers<br />

for excess power that <strong>the</strong>y export to <strong>the</strong> networks (Energy Savings Trust et<br />

al. 2005). Under <strong>the</strong> Climate Change and Sustainable Energy Act 2006, <strong>the</strong><br />

government has <strong>the</strong> power to require electricity suppliers to pay a fair price<br />

for <strong>the</strong>se exports. However, <strong>the</strong> definition of a fair price is unclear: a review<br />

by Ofgem of <strong>the</strong> various tariffs on offer from electricity suppliers showed a<br />

huge range, from 4.25p/kWh (Scottish Power) to 18p/kWh (Scottish and<br />

Sou<strong>the</strong>rn Energy), all of which Ofgem considered to be fair on <strong>the</strong> grounds<br />

that exported microgeneration energy is worth between 0.1 and 5.9p/kWh<br />

to <strong>the</strong> suppliers depending on <strong>the</strong> technology deployed and fuel used (Ofgem<br />

2008). However, this does not include <strong>the</strong> value of ROCs that suppliers might<br />

receive toge<strong>the</strong>r with <strong>the</strong> energy (currently around 4.5p/kWh), which would<br />

boost <strong>the</strong> overall value of any microgeneration export considerably. Given <strong>the</strong><br />

disparity in prices and <strong>the</strong> exclusion of ROC values in Ofgem’s assessment, it is<br />

questionable whe<strong>the</strong>r all suppliers are offering a fair price for microgeneration<br />

exports. Despite this it appears unlikely that <strong>the</strong> government will pursue its<br />

powers under <strong>the</strong> Climate Change and Sustainable Energy Act to require <strong>the</strong>m<br />

to improve on <strong>the</strong>ir offerings, instead leaving it to individual microgenerators to<br />

shop around to find <strong>the</strong> best available rate. As Ofgem notes, <strong>the</strong> inconsistencies<br />

in information provided by suppliers means that this task can be difficult<br />

and time consuming and so might discourage individuals from adopting<br />

microgeneration technologies.<br />

Notwithstanding its commitment to aggressive implementation of its<br />

Microgeneration Strategy, <strong>the</strong> government’s approach to supporting<br />

microgeneration is thus confused at best. Despite <strong>the</strong> long-term potential of<br />

<strong>the</strong> various technologies to contribute to emissions reductions, <strong>the</strong>re is little<br />

short-term coherence in <strong>the</strong> policy approach to encouraging <strong>the</strong>ir adoption,<br />

with no apparent attempt to resolve <strong>the</strong> problems experienced by <strong>the</strong> LCBP<br />

since its relaunch, nor to ensure that suppliers approach <strong>the</strong> buying of energy


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

49<br />

exported from microgeneration installations in a consistent way. Both <strong>the</strong>se<br />

shortcomings can be relatively simply rectified by <strong>the</strong> government reviewing<br />

and extending <strong>the</strong> LCBP and ensuring – using legal powers if necessary – that<br />

<strong>the</strong> prices paid for microgeneration exports are both consistent and fair.<br />

4.2 Addressing heat<br />

Emissions from heat make up a very considerable proportion of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s total<br />

CO2 emissions (see Figure 4.4). However, until <strong>the</strong> 2007 White Paper <strong>the</strong>re<br />

was little policy attention focused on <strong>the</strong> potential to reduce emissions from<br />

heat systems. As with electricity generation, <strong>the</strong>re can be two approaches to<br />

reducing emissions from heat generation: decreasing ei<strong>the</strong>r energy intensity or<br />

carbon intensity. Fossil-fuelled CHP plants can be used to generate both heat<br />

and electricity in areas with a suitable demand for heat (industrial sites with<br />

a high demand for heat, areas of high population density) and so contribute<br />

to emission reduction through <strong>the</strong> more efficient use of such fuels. Fur<strong>the</strong>r<br />

reductions in carbon emissions can be obtained through <strong>the</strong> use of biomass as<br />

a substitute for fossil fuels, ei<strong>the</strong>r in CHP plants or as a heat-only technology.<br />

Low-carbon heat is also provided by renewable sources such as ground source<br />

heat pumps and solar <strong>the</strong>rmal arrays. However, modifying buildings’ existing<br />

heat systems to accommodate <strong>the</strong>se technologies will entail considerable<br />

investment and a shift in attitudes to how heat is produced and used. Achieving<br />

this will require strong direction from government, making it clear that<br />

renewable and low-carbon heat is a necessary part of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s goal of reduce<br />

its overall carbon emissions.<br />

Domestic heat 20%<br />

Services heat 7%<br />

Industrial heat 20%<br />

O<strong>the</strong>r 53%<br />

Source: DTI 2007a<br />

Notes: Figures for heat<br />

include emissions from<br />

generation of electricity<br />

used in turn<br />

to generate heat<br />

Figure 4.4 Carbon dioxide emissions by energy use


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

50<br />

4.2.1 Combined heat and power<br />

CHP burns fossil fuels or biomass to generate both heat and electricity. Even<br />

with <strong>the</strong> use of fossil fuels, CHP can produce around 30% lower emissions<br />

than conventional electricity generation technologies (Defra 2007a). The<br />

government has two long-standing targets for CHP capacity: 5GW of ‘good<br />

quality’ CHP capacity by 2000, and 10GW of ‘good quality’ CHP by 2010.<br />

However, despite <strong>the</strong>se targets, and <strong>the</strong> environmental benefits that CHP can<br />

provide, <strong>the</strong> technology has suffered from years of neglect in government<br />

policy, and <strong>the</strong>re have only been relatively small increases in its use over <strong>the</strong> last<br />

few years. The 2005 target was missed, and it is certain that, barring a massive<br />

shift in attitudes and policies, <strong>the</strong> 2010 target will be too – in 2006, capacity<br />

was around 5.5GW and Defra currently estimates that despite <strong>the</strong>re being <strong>the</strong><br />

potential for 13.6GW by 2010, only around 7.5GW of capacity will actually be<br />

on-line by <strong>the</strong>n (BERR 2007a, Defra 2007e).<br />

As with renewables, many CHP projects are relatively small-scale and most<br />

are connected to distribution lines. Larger plants are used to provide heat and<br />

power for industrial sites, but smaller plants can be used to provide all energy<br />

needs (heat, electricity and cooling) at <strong>the</strong> district level. Such plants are<br />

particularly suited to high-density urban populations (Royal Commission on<br />

Environmental Pollution 2007).<br />

New CHP projects face a number of hurdles among <strong>the</strong> most important of which<br />

is <strong>the</strong> capital cost of constructing <strong>the</strong> heat (and, where applicable, cooling)<br />

networks to distribute <strong>the</strong>ir output. The potential income from Levy Exemption<br />

Certificates (LECs) under <strong>the</strong> Climate Change Levy and ROCs (if <strong>the</strong> project<br />

uses renewable fuel) does not necessarily provide enough financial certainty<br />

to overcome <strong>the</strong> risk presented by <strong>the</strong>se initial high construction costs. In<br />

addition, <strong>the</strong> cost of generating electricity in CHP plants is higher than that of<br />

conventional generation, which puts CHP at a disadvantage in a competitive<br />

electricity market. Although operators get some revenue from <strong>the</strong> heat <strong>the</strong>y<br />

also supply, historically this has not been enough to offset <strong>the</strong> higher costs.<br />

It is clear from <strong>the</strong> 2007 White Paper and 2006 Climate Change Programme that<br />

<strong>the</strong> government recognises <strong>the</strong> potential importance of CHP at <strong>the</strong> industrial and<br />

district levels, but it has so far failed to produce policy measures to ensure that<br />

<strong>the</strong> technology is taken up more widely. The White Paper outlined <strong>the</strong> support<br />

schemes which could apply to CHP. These include <strong>the</strong> availability of some Enhanced<br />

Capital Allowances for equipment, exclusion from <strong>the</strong> CCL, partial exemption from<br />

business rates and recognition of <strong>the</strong> carbon savings associated with CHP within<br />

<strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s allocation of EU ETS permits. However, <strong>the</strong>se mechanisms are clearly not<br />

enough to overcome <strong>the</strong> barriers faced by CHP, in part because of <strong>the</strong> short lived<br />

nature of <strong>the</strong> CCL scheme, or uncertainty about <strong>the</strong>ir future prospects. Similarly,<br />

<strong>the</strong> requirement in building regulations to ‘consider’ <strong>the</strong> implementation of CHP<br />

schemes has proved ineffective because it is merely advisory.<br />

One way forward would be to establish some form of heat obligation on energy<br />

suppliers to require <strong>the</strong>m to provide a certain proportion of heat from CHP


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

51<br />

plants to <strong>the</strong>ir customers. However, <strong>the</strong> design and implementation of such a<br />

scheme would be complex and possibly subject to <strong>the</strong> same flaws as <strong>the</strong> RO.<br />

An alternative would be to provide heat suppliers with a guaranteed payment<br />

per unit of heat for a specified period of time (ie a feed-in tariff). The level of<br />

support could vary according to <strong>the</strong> technology used (ie whe<strong>the</strong>r renewable or<br />

not) and <strong>the</strong> level of carbon savings it was able to achieve.<br />

Yet ano<strong>the</strong>r approach would be to encourage energy suppliers to adopt a more<br />

adventurous approach to energy services than has been <strong>the</strong> case so far under<br />

<strong>the</strong> EEC. This appears to be occurring with <strong>the</strong> shift in emphasis towards ESCOs<br />

in <strong>the</strong> plans for <strong>the</strong> Supplier Obligation (see page 32), but <strong>the</strong> fact that this is<br />

only set to run until 2020 may undermine <strong>the</strong> prospects for projects entailing<br />

relatively high capital expenditure, which would include CHP. The Zero Carbon<br />

Homes initiative appears to offer more hope for <strong>the</strong> sector, given that it is<br />

whole developments that need to qualify as zero carbon ra<strong>the</strong>r than individual<br />

homes. However, this initiative will not contribute to <strong>the</strong> 2010 CHP target, and<br />

so <strong>the</strong> sector risks fur<strong>the</strong>r stagnation in <strong>the</strong> intervening years.<br />

4.2.2 Biomass strategy<br />

The use of biomass and o<strong>the</strong>r renewables to provide heat services has declined<br />

in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> since <strong>the</strong> mid 1990s (Figure 4.5). In 2006 Defra established <strong>the</strong><br />

Bioenergy Capital Grants Scheme to encourage <strong>the</strong> deployment of biomassfuelled<br />

CHP plants (Defra 2006a). However, <strong>the</strong> available funds are a modest<br />

£10–15 million spread over five years, which means that <strong>the</strong> impact <strong>the</strong><br />

scheme produces will be overshadowed by <strong>the</strong> continuing emphasis on <strong>the</strong> use<br />

of biomass fuels in co-firing.<br />

Understandably, <strong>the</strong>refore, hopes were raised when <strong>the</strong> 2007 White Paper was<br />

accompanied by a long-awaited biomass strategy intended to encourage <strong>the</strong><br />

creation of sustainable supply chains for biomass crops and increase <strong>the</strong> use of<br />

biomass in <strong>UK</strong> energy production.<br />

Two years earlier, <strong>the</strong> government’s Biomass Task Force had estimated that,<br />

if encouraged by policies to stimulate <strong>the</strong> creation of supply chains and to<br />

reward <strong>the</strong> provision of low-carbon heat, biomass could provide around 3%<br />

of <strong>UK</strong> heat demand by 2010, and 7% by 2015, reducing annual emissions by<br />

0.9MtC and 2.7MtC respectively (Biomass Task Force 2005). However, when<br />

finally published, <strong>the</strong> biomass strategy came as a disappointment – particularly<br />

in terms of its lack of commitment to driving a biomass heat sector, given its<br />

recognition that, in comparison with o<strong>the</strong>r biomass applications, heat provision<br />

is <strong>the</strong> most cost effective way of reducing carbon emissions. The strategy<br />

estimates that existing <strong>UK</strong> biomass resources could save emissions of between<br />

4.88MtC and 5.1MtC a year if used to supply both electricity and heat (see<br />

Table 4.5), and an additional 1.88MtCe through avoiding emissions from<br />

landfill. Yet it offers no new measures to encourage greater use of biomass in<br />

<strong>the</strong> energy system, nei<strong>the</strong>r does it establish any targets for <strong>the</strong> future use of<br />

biomass in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> (apart from biofuels) (DTI, DfT, Defra 2007).


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

52<br />

POTENTIAL CARBON SAVINGS (million tonnes C) ADDITIONAL CARBON<br />

Electricity only Heat only Heat and SAVINGS from avoided<br />

Biomass source electricity landfill (mtce)<br />

‘Dry’ materials<br />

Sawmill conversion products 0.23-0.27 0.38-0.44 0.46-0.54<br />

and arboricultural arisings<br />

Energy crops (short rotation 0.03-0.04 0.04-0.06 0.05-0.08<br />

coppice, e.g. willow / poplar<br />

and miscanthus)<br />

Cereal straw 0.40-0.48 0.65-0.80 0.79-0.97<br />

Paper and card [3] 0.13-0.34 0.21-0.55 0.27-0.71 0.59<br />

Garden / plant waste [3] 0.14 0.23 0.32 0.13<br />

Waste wood [3] 0.91 1.50 2.05 0.45<br />

Sewage sludge (dry solids) 0.05-0.07 0.08-0.11 0.10-0.13<br />

Poultry manure - meat / birds 0.15 0.25 0.30<br />

(60% DM)<br />

Sub total 2.04-2.40 3.34-3.94 4.34-5.10 1.17<br />

‘Wet’ materials<br />

Poultry manure - egg laying flock 0.03-0.06 0.04-0.08 0.05-0.10<br />

(30% DM)<br />

Dairy cattle slurry (10% SM) 0.15-0.16 0.19-0.20 0.24-0.26<br />

Pig manures (10% DM) 0.04 0.05 0.06<br />

Food waste [3] 0.09-0.16 0.14-0.26 0.19-0.33 0.71<br />

Sub total 0.31-0.42 0.42-0.59 0.54-0.75 0.71<br />

Total 2.35-2.82 3.76-4.53 4.88-5.85 1.88<br />

Table 4.5 Potential annual emission savings from replacing grid electricity<br />

and heating oil with biomass<br />

Data supplied by D.Turley, Central Science Laboratory<br />

except [3] provided by James Vause, Defra<br />

Biomass offers <strong>the</strong> possibility of compensating for <strong>the</strong> intermittency of o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

forms of renewable generation, while producing almost carbon-neutral energy<br />

(Biomass Task Force 2005). If <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> is to move towards more sustainable<br />

energy systems in <strong>the</strong> future, biomass will have an important role to play in<br />

ensuring <strong>the</strong>ir reliable delivery. Action to promote <strong>the</strong> expansion of a viable and<br />

sustainable biomass industry in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> is <strong>the</strong>refore vital in <strong>the</strong> short-term if<br />

<strong>the</strong> necessary longer-term strategic shifts in energy systems are to take place.<br />

This will involve an urgent change of emphasis in government policy from <strong>the</strong><br />

use of biomass for co-firing in conventional coal fired power stations to more<br />

local, smaller-scale CHP plants. And <strong>the</strong> establishment of viable supply chains<br />

between biomass producers and users. Given <strong>the</strong> range of players that would<br />

be involved, this will not be a simple task, but increasing <strong>the</strong> level of certainty


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Sustainable energy systems<br />

53<br />

for producers that <strong>the</strong>y will find a long term, preferably local market for <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

produce could be started by actively seeking to promote biomass CHP through<br />

<strong>the</strong> RO (or preferably a feed-in tariff) and equivalent support mechanism for<br />

renewable heat<br />

Thousands of tonnes of oil equivalent<br />

900.0<br />

800.0<br />

700.0<br />

600.0<br />

500.0<br />

400.0<br />

300.0<br />

200.0<br />

100.0<br />

Geo<strong>the</strong>rmal amplifiers<br />

Municipal solid biodegradable<br />

waste combustion<br />

Straw combustion, farm<br />

waste digestion, short rotation<br />

coppice<br />

Wood combustion industrial<br />

Wood combustion domestic<br />

Sewage sludge digestion<br />

Landfill gas<br />

Active solar heating<br />

0<br />

1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006<br />

Figure 4.5: Renewable energy use for heat and electricity, 1996–2006<br />

Source: DTI 2007a, Chart 2<br />

4.3 Conclusions: sustainable energy systems<br />

As with action to reduce energy intensity, <strong>the</strong> mechanisms <strong>the</strong> government<br />

has so far put in place to reduce <strong>the</strong> carbon intensity of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> economy show<br />

a remarkable lack of ambition and offer little prospect of <strong>the</strong> country meeting<br />

its provisional EU target of 15% of energy provided by renewable sources by<br />

2020, or <strong>the</strong> 26–32% cut in CO2 emissions proposed by <strong>the</strong> Climate Change<br />

Bill for <strong>the</strong> same date. The Renewables Obligation is <strong>the</strong> main mechanism<br />

intended to encourage <strong>the</strong> growth of renewable technologies, but it has so<br />

far failed to achieve its aims. The proposed revisions to <strong>the</strong> RO are unlikely to<br />

correct <strong>the</strong> failings in <strong>the</strong> mechanism completely because <strong>the</strong>y do not address<br />

<strong>the</strong> fundamental lack of certainty for investors. The RO should <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

be abandoned for new projects and a feed-in tariff established in its place<br />

to provide improved investor confidence and so stimulate higher levels of<br />

deployment of both established and emerging renewables technologies. On<br />

<strong>the</strong> basis of European experience, a feed-in tariff approach would also reduce<br />

<strong>the</strong> costs to <strong>the</strong> consumer of encouraging renewable technologies.<br />

Ano<strong>the</strong>r programme for encouraging renewables, <strong>the</strong> Low Carbon Buildings<br />

Programme, seems to have been successful in encouraging individuals and<br />

organisations to engage in small-scale renewables projects. In view of this<br />

success, <strong>the</strong> government should extend <strong>the</strong> scheme ra<strong>the</strong>r than allowing<br />

it to end in 2009. It makes no sense to discard <strong>the</strong> programme before <strong>the</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy Sustainable energy systems 54<br />

introduction of schemes aimed at encouraging energy suppliers to adopt an<br />

ESCO approach to <strong>the</strong>ir business, as this will leave a gap in <strong>the</strong> provision of<br />

incentives for building small-scale renewables.<br />

Of all <strong>the</strong> energy sectors, heat has been most neglected by <strong>the</strong> government,<br />

despite <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> sector is responsible for nearly half <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s CO2<br />

emissions. Combined heat and power systems offer ei<strong>the</strong>r hugely improved<br />

efficiency in fossil-fuel use, or carbon neutral energy in <strong>the</strong> case of those<br />

that use renewable resources. However, <strong>the</strong> government has done little to<br />

encourage <strong>the</strong> technology. Concrete requirements to encourage <strong>the</strong> greater<br />

deployment of CHP in all new developments are needed, and <strong>the</strong>re needs to<br />

be a clear presumption against any new fossil fuel power plant which does not<br />

provide heat as well as electricity. Additional drivers, such as carbon limits for<br />

new power plants, may also be necessary.<br />

The neglect of CHP is part of a wider lack of institutional support for heat<br />

related technologies. Responsibility for <strong>the</strong> heat sector is shared between<br />

BERR and Defra, but in practice seems to fall between <strong>the</strong> two, with nei<strong>the</strong>r<br />

department taking responsibility for example for encouraging <strong>the</strong> rapid<br />

deployment of CHP projects. Moreover, <strong>the</strong>re is no real regulatory framework<br />

for <strong>the</strong> sector, which could provide a basis for encouraging development of heat<br />

provision. A heat sector regulator needs to be set up with <strong>the</strong> explicit intention<br />

of encouraging <strong>the</strong> more efficient provision of low-carbon heat. In addition,<br />

<strong>the</strong>re needs to be a clear delineation between <strong>the</strong> responsibilities of different<br />

government departments and a binding target for <strong>the</strong> use of low carbon-heat<br />

should be introduced.


55<br />

05<br />

Broader system<br />

issues<br />

98% of <strong>the</strong> energy needs of this building in Malmö, Sweden<br />

and <strong>the</strong> offices within it, are met by renewable energy.<br />

©Reynaers/<strong>Greenpeace</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader system issues<br />

56<br />

This section set out some of <strong>the</strong> broader system issues which have to be<br />

addressed if <strong>the</strong>re is to be a shift to significantly lower-carbon energy systems.<br />

The implementation of new technologies is problematic because existing,<br />

conventional technologies are locked in by a variety of economic and social<br />

factors. These effectively exclude o<strong>the</strong>r technologies which do not conform to<br />

<strong>the</strong> characteristics of <strong>the</strong> conventional technologies.<br />

Traditionally, <strong>the</strong> electricity and heat sectors have been treated in policy and<br />

regulatory terms as entirely separate areas, with measures directed at encouraging<br />

technologies in one particular area. The RO (see section 4.1.1) is a good example<br />

of this sort of policy design, despite <strong>the</strong> fact that some renewables technologies,<br />

notably biomass, can offer heat services as well as electricity. Moreover, because<br />

<strong>the</strong> RO was designed to promote relatively large-scale renewable output,<br />

microgeneration technologies were effectively excluded from <strong>the</strong> scheme at <strong>the</strong><br />

outset. Although this situation has subsequently been adjusted, it remains complex<br />

and difficult for householders to access ROCs under <strong>the</strong> RO). Heat providing<br />

renewables technologies – ground source heat pumps, solar <strong>the</strong>rmal arrays – are<br />

excluded altoge<strong>the</strong>r, and do not have an equivalent mechanism to support <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

output. While this is perhaps understandable in that <strong>the</strong> RO was designed to<br />

promote renewable electricity supplies, never<strong>the</strong>less a more effective approach to<br />

improved efficiency and <strong>the</strong> longer-term shift to low-carbon energy systems could<br />

be provided by an integrated renewables support mechanism designed to maximise<br />

all <strong>the</strong> environmental benefits that renewables can offer, whe<strong>the</strong>r in electricity<br />

generation or in o<strong>the</strong>r energy systems.<br />

The increasing integration of energy systems will also require consideration of<br />

<strong>the</strong> environmental benefits that can potentially be offered by advanced fossil<br />

fuel technologies – in particular, <strong>the</strong> efficient use of fossil fuels in CHP plants,<br />

which produce lower CO2 emissions per unit of usable energy provided than<br />

plants producing only heat or electricity, and (in <strong>the</strong> case of smaller-scale local<br />

plants) offer improved efficiency in transporting electricity from <strong>the</strong> point of<br />

production to <strong>the</strong> point of use as a result of lower transmission and distribution<br />

losses.<br />

The need is <strong>the</strong>refore for a more integrated, holistic policy approach to<br />

minimising carbon emissions from <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s energy systems, which would<br />

involve explicitly considering and rewarding all technologies that can offer a<br />

reduction in emissions. This approach would set <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> more decisively on a<br />

path to achieving lower-carbon energy systems.<br />

Dealing separately with <strong>the</strong> various obstacles to <strong>the</strong> increased take up of<br />

renewables, and o<strong>the</strong>r low-carbon technologies, is to an extent artificial, in that<br />

such obstacles tend to be interrelated. For example, infrastructure problems<br />

can be connected to market conditions, planning issues, financial norms and so<br />

on. In o<strong>the</strong>r words, <strong>the</strong>ir extent and impact are to a degree influenced by o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

system components. With that proviso in mind, however, a review of some of<br />

<strong>the</strong> key regulatory and system obstacles to a low-carbon energy future in <strong>the</strong><br />

<strong>UK</strong> follows.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader system issues<br />

57<br />

5.1 Planning<br />

The design of <strong>the</strong> RO and <strong>the</strong> risks entailed in participating in <strong>the</strong> renewables<br />

market are not <strong>the</strong> only reasons why renewables development has lagged<br />

behind <strong>the</strong> RO targets, and why <strong>the</strong> 2010 target will be missed. Ano<strong>the</strong>r key<br />

issue is <strong>the</strong> planning regime, which has impacted on <strong>the</strong> development of both<br />

renewable generation projects and <strong>the</strong> network infrastructure that <strong>the</strong>y require<br />

to export <strong>the</strong>ir power. At present, for example, it takes on average 21 months<br />

for a wind farm to get planning consent under <strong>the</strong> Electricity Act (DTI 2007).<br />

Of course, <strong>the</strong> planning process raises hurdles for all energy technology<br />

options, including delays in obtaining consent, <strong>the</strong> costs of participating in<br />

inquiry processes, and high degrees of uncertainty for developers and local<br />

communities about <strong>the</strong> prospects of any particular project proceeding. The<br />

problems can be particularly acute for renewables development because of<br />

<strong>the</strong> high number of relatively small projects which are often sited in remote,<br />

undeveloped areas. This can raise concerns over landscape issues and impacts<br />

on wildlife. Conversely, because projects are often sited on distribution<br />

lines ra<strong>the</strong>r than on <strong>the</strong> transmission grid, <strong>the</strong>y may be less remote than<br />

conventional centralised generating plants. Their proximity to areas where<br />

people live brings advantages in improved system efficiency, but can also<br />

heighten public objections. This can be exacerbated by inconsistencies in<br />

different local planning authorities’ attitudes to various types of energy project.<br />

The 2007 White Paper put forward a range of measures intended to improve<br />

<strong>the</strong> planning context for renewables. These include a new Planning Policy<br />

Statement on Climate Change which emphasises <strong>the</strong> role that planning can play<br />

in achieving reductions in CO2 emissions, partly through increased levels of<br />

renewables development; and a proposal to encourage some microgeneration<br />

technologies by treating <strong>the</strong>m as permitted development not subject to<br />

planning permission in certain circumstances (Communities and Local<br />

Government 2007b).<br />

More fundamental changes to <strong>the</strong> planning inquiry process were also considered<br />

during <strong>the</strong> White Paper drafting process and a separate White Paper – Planning<br />

for a sustainable future – was published in May 2007 (Communities and Local<br />

Government 2007a). The reforms in this White Paper are aimed at major<br />

infrastructure projects, including generating stations over 50MW and some<br />

transmission and distribution lines. Decisions on major infrastructure will be taken<br />

by a planning commission, with <strong>the</strong> context for its decisions set by national policy<br />

statements setting out <strong>the</strong> government’s position on particular technologies and<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir role in meeting national energy goals.<br />

Ruling out debate about specific technologies and national policy goals, which<br />

has played an important role in public inquiries in <strong>the</strong> past, is aimed at speeding<br />

up and simplifying <strong>the</strong> decision process about major new infrastructure<br />

projects. This should bring a higher degree of certainty for developers of new<br />

generating projects which fall within <strong>the</strong> remit of <strong>the</strong> new arrangements.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong>se arrangements will remove <strong>the</strong> option for local communities


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader system issues<br />

58<br />

to engage directly in debates about national policy in response to specific<br />

proposals, including <strong>the</strong> prospect of new coal and nuclear plants as well as large<br />

renewable energy projects.<br />

In addition, <strong>the</strong> new arrangements do not cover onshore developments under<br />

50MW or offshore projects over 100MW. Ministers will have some discretion<br />

as to how <strong>the</strong>y approach smaller projects, allowing <strong>the</strong>m to fall under <strong>the</strong> new<br />

major infrastructure arrangements if <strong>the</strong>y are seen as of national significance,<br />

and a new Planning Policy Statement covering <strong>the</strong>se smaller projects should<br />

be published for consultation later in 2008. However, until that new planning<br />

policy statement comes in to force, <strong>the</strong>re is a risk that projects between <strong>the</strong><br />

upper limit of microgeneration and <strong>the</strong> lower limit of major infrastructure<br />

may not benefit from <strong>the</strong> new planning arrangements. This risk is of particular<br />

importance for renewables projects, many of which are below 50MW (although<br />

in <strong>the</strong> case of onshore wind, recent proposals have tended to be larger in scale<br />

than earlier projects and <strong>the</strong> new arrangements in <strong>the</strong> Planning for a Sustainable<br />

<strong>Future</strong> White Paper may well encourage this trend).<br />

The proposed changes to <strong>the</strong> planning regime, <strong>the</strong>n, acknowledge some of<br />

<strong>the</strong> difficulties that face large energy projects in <strong>the</strong> current arrangements.<br />

However, <strong>the</strong> advantages for renewables resulting from <strong>the</strong>se changes in <strong>the</strong><br />

planning regime are likely to be limited when compared to <strong>the</strong> benefits for<br />

conventional technologies for <strong>the</strong> following reasons:<br />

• The amount of time taken to secure approvals.<br />

• The scale of projects receiving individual approvals.<br />

• The fact that <strong>the</strong> arrangements will only benefit certain technologies<br />

(small scale wave and tidal power projects will see little benefit from<br />

<strong>the</strong>se proposals).<br />

• The fact that almost half of all renewable energy potential in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> is<br />

located in Scotland – and <strong>the</strong>refore under <strong>the</strong> jurisdiction of <strong>the</strong> Scottish<br />

Executive’s planning laws.<br />

5.2 Infrastructure<br />

The problem of existing infrastructure acting as a barrier to new technologies<br />

has been relatively well analysed in <strong>the</strong> context of <strong>the</strong> electricity system, where<br />

it is widely accepted that <strong>the</strong> rules of operation, <strong>the</strong> design of networks and<br />

<strong>the</strong> associated style of regulation have in particular discouraged generators<br />

from connecting renewables and small-scale generating projects to distribution<br />

networks (DTI 2001, Distributed Generation Co-ordinating Group 2005). In<br />

part <strong>the</strong>se problems arise from <strong>the</strong> historic design of <strong>the</strong> electricity system:<br />

increasingly centralised generation has led to a greater reliance on transporting<br />

electricity through <strong>the</strong> high-voltage transmission network, while <strong>the</strong><br />

lower-voltage distribution networks have become increasingly passive,<br />

required only to shift <strong>the</strong> electricity from <strong>the</strong> transmission network to <strong>the</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader system issues<br />

59<br />

point of use, and have tended to be designed for one-way power flows.<br />

These passive characteristics had been enshrined in technical and operational<br />

standards, which do not make allowance for energy inputs from distributed<br />

generation. The upsurge of smaller-scale renewables projects requiring<br />

connection to <strong>the</strong>se overwhelmingly passive networks <strong>the</strong>refore created<br />

problems for <strong>the</strong>ir operation.<br />

There has been some success with revising <strong>the</strong> technical rules governing<br />

<strong>the</strong> design and operation of distribution networks to allow <strong>the</strong>m to become<br />

more active. However, despite <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong> government recognises that<br />

distributed generation can offer advantages both in reduced CO2 emissions and<br />

improved system efficiency, institutional barriers still remain (DTI and Ofgem<br />

2007). These include a mismatch between <strong>the</strong> interests of project developers<br />

and those of <strong>the</strong> distribution network operator (DNO). The developer of a<br />

new project may face constraints as to where it can build, but <strong>the</strong> locations<br />

open to it may not coincide with <strong>the</strong> DNO’s plans for upgrading or renewing its<br />

network to allow more active operation. Certainly, respondents to <strong>the</strong> DTI/<br />

Ofgem consultation on <strong>the</strong> barriers to greater levels of distributed generation<br />

felt that ‘DNOs do not approach <strong>the</strong> connection of distributed generators in a<br />

sufficiently positive way.’ (DTI and Ofgem 2007, p23).<br />

Ofgem has recently tried to encourage both more distributed generation and<br />

innovation in <strong>the</strong> design and operation of distribution networks, through two<br />

mechanisms: <strong>the</strong> Innovation Funding Incentive (IFI) and Registered Power<br />

Zones (RPZs), both of which were introduced in April 2005. However, only four<br />

RPZs have been approved since 2005, well below <strong>the</strong> maximum limit imposed<br />

by Ofgem of two projects per DNO per year. One of <strong>the</strong> main reasons for this<br />

is <strong>the</strong> mismatch between <strong>the</strong> interests of generators and DNOs mentioned<br />

above. In contrast, <strong>the</strong> IFI allows DNOs to invest in research and development<br />

activities to improve <strong>the</strong> effective operation of <strong>the</strong>ir networks. However, in <strong>the</strong><br />

early stages of <strong>the</strong> IFI programme most DNO R&D expenditure was allocated to<br />

work on extending <strong>the</strong> lifetime of <strong>the</strong>ir existing assets, ra<strong>the</strong>r than investing in<br />

projects which would allow <strong>the</strong> networks to become more active and <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

more suited to higher levels of distributed generation. As regulated monopolies,<br />

DNOs are required to justify <strong>the</strong>ir expenditure on infrastructure to Ofgem,<br />

and despite <strong>the</strong> implementation of <strong>the</strong> IFI scheme, <strong>the</strong>re is still not a driver<br />

sufficiently strong to encourage <strong>the</strong>m to adopt a longer-term view of network<br />

design and operation that would enable greater levels of distributed generation:<br />

‘Sufficiently strong business drivers for DNOs to adopt ANM [active<br />

network management] solutions are not yet evident: <strong>the</strong> present<br />

regulatory regime gives little incentive for co-ordination and<br />

long-term strategic planning for ANM infrastructure or to adopt<br />

new technologies or operating practices. At present, it is difficult<br />

for DNOs to make <strong>the</strong> business case to adopt ANM solutions for<br />

generation connection applications even if <strong>the</strong>y may pave <strong>the</strong> way<br />

for more efficient network operation in <strong>the</strong> long-term.’<br />

(EA Technology 2006)


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader system issues<br />

60<br />

The extent to which infrastructure issues are inhibiting <strong>the</strong> expansion of<br />

low-carbon (in particular renewable) technologies is perhaps even more<br />

marked in <strong>the</strong> case of transmission networks. The creation of a single<br />

British electricity market (known as BETTA – British Electricity Trading and<br />

Transmissions Arrangements) led to a rush of applications for onshore wind<br />

projects in Scotland, which has <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s largest wind resource. The developers<br />

of <strong>the</strong>se projects were keen to export <strong>the</strong>ir electricity from Scotland into <strong>the</strong><br />

rest of <strong>the</strong> British system (DTI 2007). However, <strong>the</strong> exporting of electricity<br />

is constrained by a limited transmission connection between Scotland and <strong>the</strong><br />

north of England. This will need to be expanded before new renewables projects<br />

hoping to supply England and Wales can connect to <strong>the</strong> Scottish transmission<br />

network. As of 2007, more than 150 mainly renewables projects with a<br />

combined capacity of over 12GW were waiting for connection in Scotland<br />

(Ofgem and BERR 2007).<br />

The building of new transmission lines and <strong>the</strong> upgrading of existing ones are<br />

subject to planning approvals, which can take several years to be resolved.<br />

The last major investment in transmission lines, in <strong>the</strong> Vale of York, took<br />

nearly 15 years from <strong>the</strong> beginning of <strong>the</strong> project to delivery (AEA Energy<br />

and Environment 2007). The situation of <strong>the</strong> projects awaiting connection is<br />

fur<strong>the</strong>r complicated by <strong>the</strong> fact that offers for connection – which dictate <strong>the</strong><br />

place in <strong>the</strong> queue – are made on a first-come, first-served basis, and do not<br />

necessarily reflect <strong>the</strong> economic viability of <strong>the</strong> project nor its future prospects<br />

of operating.<br />

Most of <strong>the</strong> transmission capacity currently available is being used by<br />

conventional (ie coal, gas or nuclear) generation. This generation is <strong>the</strong>refore<br />

inhibiting <strong>the</strong> development and connection of more sustainable ways of<br />

generating electricity. An alternative approach, whereby renewables projects<br />

were granted priority access to <strong>the</strong> transmission network, and existing<br />

conventional generation was allocated spare capacity, would be more<br />

compatible with reducing CO2 emissions and encouraging <strong>the</strong> deployment of<br />

new technologies. It would also reduce <strong>the</strong> degree to which<br />

<strong>the</strong> annual RO targets are missed. This approach would be in line with<br />

transmission access arrangements in several o<strong>the</strong>r EU countries where<br />

renewables have experienced a rapid expansion in capacity. 16<br />

Beyond <strong>the</strong> question of access policy, however, <strong>the</strong> issues of distribution<br />

incompatibility and inadequate transmission capacity need to be viewed in<br />

<strong>the</strong> light of <strong>the</strong> fact that nearly 70% of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s electricity network<br />

infrastructure is ageing and in need of replacement or upgrading (Energy<br />

Networks Association 2006). This situation clearly provides an invaluable<br />

opportunity to design a new network around <strong>the</strong> needs of low-carbon<br />

generating technologies, giving <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> <strong>the</strong> best chance of ensuring a truly<br />

sustainable energy system and a future of steadily falling emissions. At <strong>the</strong><br />

same time, it raises <strong>the</strong> alarming prospect that, if this opportunity is not<br />

seized, <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> may find itself with a newly renovated infrastructure that is<br />

still incompatible with sustainable generation, setting back <strong>the</strong> country’s<br />

16 <br />

For example Denmark and<br />

Germany. Priority access<br />

to transmission networks<br />

is permitted by <strong>the</strong> 2001<br />

Renewables Directive (Directive<br />

2001/77/EC), which states<br />

that Member States ‘may also<br />

provide for priority access to<br />

<strong>the</strong> grid system of electricity<br />

produced from renewable energy<br />

sources’ (Article 7).


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Future</strong>: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader System Issues<br />

61<br />

low-carbon aspirations by several decades until <strong>the</strong> network is again in need of<br />

such a comprehensive overhaul.<br />

The issues may be less pronounced, or less well explored, in o<strong>the</strong>r energy<br />

systems. However, it is clear that <strong>the</strong>re are significant infrastructure issues<br />

which limit <strong>the</strong> emergence of heat networks, which currently lack any real<br />

incentive towards investment given <strong>the</strong> competitive nature of energy markets<br />

and <strong>the</strong> perceived social preference for heating provision through individual<br />

boilers (AEA Energy and Environment 2007).<br />

So while <strong>the</strong> shortcomings of physical infrastructure are acting as a constraint<br />

on renewables deployment in energy systems, this situation has in part come<br />

about because of failings in o<strong>the</strong>r system components such as planning,<br />

incentivisation and market design. Until <strong>the</strong> broader problems are identified<br />

and corrected, infrastructure will continue to act as a constraint on sustainable<br />

energy options. However, in <strong>the</strong> case of <strong>the</strong> electricity system in particular,<br />

<strong>the</strong>re is a real opportunity to act now to address <strong>the</strong> barriers in view of <strong>the</strong><br />

imminent need to overhaul <strong>the</strong> network infrastructure. Depending on how<br />

it approaches this challenge, <strong>the</strong> government can choose ei<strong>the</strong>r to enable<br />

<strong>the</strong> necessary investment to facilitate much greater levels of connection by<br />

sustainable generation, or to condemn small-scale and renewables projects to<br />

decades of fur<strong>the</strong>r difficulties in connecting to <strong>the</strong> grid.<br />

5.3 Regulation and market design<br />

As well as regulating <strong>the</strong> monopoly network operators, Ofgem is also<br />

responsible for <strong>the</strong> design of <strong>the</strong> market for electricity trading. While it does<br />

not directly regulate <strong>the</strong> choice of generating technology, it does exercise<br />

an indirect influence by <strong>the</strong> structure of its trading rules and its emphasis on<br />

lowest-cost output.<br />

Current electricity market arrangements reflect <strong>the</strong> centralised nature of<br />

<strong>the</strong> electricity system, and were designed with <strong>the</strong> intention of ensuring <strong>the</strong><br />

lowest possible energy costs for consumers. The characteristics of small-scale<br />

or renewable generation do not conform to <strong>the</strong> overall aims and design of <strong>the</strong><br />

market.<br />

The conflicts arise in two particular areas. Firstly, engaging in <strong>the</strong> market entails<br />

high transaction costs because of <strong>the</strong> need to monitor prices and arrangements<br />

on a constant basis; smaller companies do not have <strong>the</strong> financial or staff<br />

resources to engage at this level. Secondly, <strong>the</strong> market rewards predictable,<br />

flexible generation, and penalises generation which is less predictable and<br />

flexible, like much renewable and CHP output. Generators are required to state<br />

in advance how much energy <strong>the</strong>y will produce, and if <strong>the</strong>y fail to meet this<br />

forecast <strong>the</strong>y are penalised. This arrangement is meant to reflect <strong>the</strong> additional<br />

costs imposed on <strong>the</strong> system by <strong>the</strong> need to balance it at short notice to<br />

compensate for over or undersupply. However, <strong>the</strong> penalties have often<br />

outweighed <strong>the</strong> real costs of balancing <strong>the</strong> system, and in some cases have<br />

meant that wind generators are actually operating at a loss (AEA Energy and


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> <strong>Future</strong>: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader System Issues<br />

62<br />

Environment 2007). While <strong>the</strong>re is a case for arguing that renewable and<br />

small-scale generators should pay if <strong>the</strong>y complicate <strong>the</strong> operation of <strong>the</strong><br />

system, <strong>the</strong>re is no case for arguing that those costs should be higher than <strong>the</strong><br />

real costs of compensating for <strong>the</strong>ir unpredictability. As it stands, <strong>the</strong> market<br />

designed by Ofgem acts as a barrier to <strong>the</strong> viability of sustainable generating<br />

technologies.<br />

Heat from renewable and CHP sources, on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r hand, suffers from <strong>the</strong><br />

fact that <strong>the</strong>re is as yet no overarching market structure within which it can<br />

be deployed. Measures such as a requirement that no fossil fuel plant can be<br />

built without a specified end-use for its waste heat could be used to drive an<br />

expansion of <strong>the</strong> CHP market, but until <strong>the</strong> Zero Carbon Homes plan and <strong>the</strong><br />

ambition for zero carbon non-domestic buildings are implemented in 2016 and<br />

2019 respectively <strong>the</strong>re is little incentives for individuals or small consumers<br />

to pursue renewable heat technologies or CHP. Setting a clear target for<br />

renewable heat, and expanding <strong>the</strong> CHP targets may kick start an expansion<br />

of <strong>the</strong> sector and establishing a feed-in tariff will create extra impetus by<br />

rewarding renewable heat in comparison with conventional fossil fuel sources.<br />

These sorts of measures will, however, have to be delivered in a framework<br />

which protects both consumers and producers from unrealistic prices while at<br />

<strong>the</strong> same time encouraging investment in infrastructure to produce and deliver<br />

low-carbon heat. If Ofgem – or ano<strong>the</strong>r regulatory body – is put in charge,<br />

this sort of long-term strategic approach will need to be an explicit part of its<br />

market design.<br />

5.4 Social and institutional inertia<br />

A great deal of government action is aimed at informing <strong>the</strong> public about<br />

climate change, <strong>the</strong> advantages of energy efficiency and <strong>the</strong> potential of<br />

low-carbon generation. The intention behind such information is to encourage<br />

behavioural change. However, <strong>the</strong> level of any resulting change is extremely<br />

uncertain, and it may take years to emerge. So, for example, <strong>the</strong> costs of<br />

installing energy efficiency measures in <strong>the</strong> home act as a disincentive for some<br />

consumers, despite <strong>the</strong> financial benefits that can be realised in <strong>the</strong> longer<br />

term. Similarly, business is traditionally very wary about <strong>the</strong> imposition of new<br />

measures to increase energy efficiency – such as <strong>the</strong> Climate Change Levy<br />

– despite <strong>the</strong> fact that <strong>the</strong>y are designed to encourage savings in <strong>the</strong><br />

longer-term and may <strong>the</strong>refore improve businesses’ competitive advantage.<br />

Given <strong>the</strong> urgency of <strong>the</strong> need to reduce CO2 emissions, it may be necessary<br />

to introduce fur<strong>the</strong>r measures to force change, ra<strong>the</strong>r than placing too much<br />

reliance on voluntary action on <strong>the</strong> basis of improved information. The need for<br />

a broader approach, including regulation to force social change or changes in<br />

business practice, has been identified by <strong>the</strong> Prime Minister’s Strategy Unit:<br />

‘We need to strike <strong>the</strong> right balance between <strong>the</strong> state, market<br />

mechanisms and individual and community action. The solution lies not<br />

in any one by itself, but in <strong>the</strong> right combination. Carbon cap-and-trade,<br />

for example, is a very sophisticated mechanism because it guarantees<br />

achieving <strong>the</strong> outcome while allowing maximum flexibility. But this must


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader system issues<br />

63<br />

be supported by an active state. Behaviour is driven by a number<br />

of factors, not just by financial costs and benefits. The state has to<br />

provide additional incentives, regulation and information. Leaving it<br />

all to a vague notion of social responsibility will not reduce emissions.’<br />

(Prime Minister’s Strategy Unit 2007, p4)<br />

Institutional inertia can also act as a barrier to <strong>the</strong> implementation of<br />

sustainable energy technologies. The rules governing how institutions behave<br />

have a significant impact on policies and measures designed to govern <strong>the</strong><br />

operation of energy systems. Ofgem’s design of <strong>the</strong> electricity market,<br />

discussed above, is a good example of this. Ofgem’s role is defined by a series<br />

of duties which are set out in <strong>the</strong> Utilities Act 2000 and <strong>the</strong> Energy Act 2004.<br />

Its primary duty is to ‘protect <strong>the</strong> interests of consumers, present and future,<br />

wherever appropriate, by promoting effective competition between persons<br />

engaged in … <strong>the</strong> generation, transmission, distribution or supply of electricity’<br />

(Ofgem 2007b, p45). It also has various secondary or subsidiary duties (see<br />

Figure 5.1). The Energy Act added a secondary Duty on Ofgem to carry out<br />

its functions in <strong>the</strong> manner which it considers will best contribute to <strong>the</strong><br />

achievement of sustainable development.<br />

Principal objective:<br />

Protect <strong>the</strong> interests of present and future consumers,<br />

wherever appropriate by promoting effective competition<br />

In meeting <strong>the</strong> principal objective, Ofgem<br />

must have regard to:<br />

• Ensuring that all reasonable demands<br />

for electricity are met<br />

• Ensuring that licence holders are able to<br />

finance <strong>the</strong>ir obligations<br />

• Protecting <strong>the</strong> interests of certain<br />

groups, including <strong>the</strong> sick and elderly<br />

and those on low incomes<br />

It must also have regard to:<br />

• The effect on <strong>the</strong> environment<br />

of <strong>the</strong> generation, transmission,<br />

distribution and supply of electricity<br />

• Ensuring that regulatory principles<br />

are transparent, accountable,<br />

proportionate, consistent and targeted<br />

• The social and environmental guidance<br />

issued by <strong>the</strong> Secretary of State<br />

Subject to <strong>the</strong> above, Ofgem must carry out<br />

its duties in <strong>the</strong> way it considers is best calculated to:<br />

• Promote efficiency and economy<br />

• Protect <strong>the</strong> public from dangers<br />

• Secure a diverse and viable long-term electricity supply<br />

• Contribute to <strong>the</strong> achievement of sustainable development<br />

Figure 5.1: Ofgem’s duties<br />

Source: Ofgem 2007b<br />

The government has issued guidance on how Ofgem should approach <strong>the</strong><br />

need to balance its duties. Within its framework of primary and secondary<br />

objectives, Ofgem is free to exercise a significant level of discretion in weighing<br />

up issues and making decisions (Ofgem 2006). In addition, <strong>the</strong> sustainable<br />

development requirement is open to a high level of interpretation, in terms both


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Broader system issues<br />

64<br />

of what Ofgem considers to be sustainable development, and of <strong>the</strong> means in<br />

it may or may not consider appropriate to achieving it. Designing regulatory<br />

measures requires Ofgem to balance its economic role with a broader, long<br />

term consideration of its social and environmental impacts. However, both<br />

its sustainable development duty and <strong>the</strong> regard it must have to social and<br />

environmental guidance leave a great deal of latitude as to how Ofgem chooses<br />

to balance <strong>the</strong>m within its principal objective – most fundamentally in its design<br />

of electricity market arrangements which reward large scale, centralised, often<br />

fossil fuel plants at <strong>the</strong> expense of smaller scale renewable generation. The<br />

Sustainable Development Commission has recently reviewed Ofgem’s role and<br />

has recommended that its duties should be revised in order to achieve a more<br />

balanced approach between <strong>the</strong> short-term goal of ensuring <strong>the</strong> lowest possible<br />

costs to consumers and <strong>the</strong> longer-term need to encourage <strong>the</strong> development<br />

of more sustainable energy systems (Sustainable Development Commission<br />

2007). An alternative approach would be to streng<strong>the</strong>n <strong>the</strong> guidance issued by<br />

BERR on how Ofgem should balance its duties to make it explicit that it must<br />

contribute directly to achieving <strong>the</strong> government’s policies on renewables.<br />

The role of government departments in enabling or inhibiting a shift in<br />

energy systems should also not be underestimated. For example, <strong>the</strong> lack<br />

of specific departmental responsibility for <strong>the</strong> heat sector is an institutional<br />

barrier. At <strong>the</strong> moment, <strong>the</strong> responsibilities are split between BERR and Defra,<br />

although <strong>the</strong>re is no clear definition of how <strong>the</strong>y are to be shared between<br />

<strong>the</strong> two departments. Without a clear outline of who does what, and no<br />

departmental champions to build up <strong>the</strong> profile of <strong>the</strong> heat sector within <strong>the</strong><br />

more general policy debate about reducing CO2 emissions, it is very difficult<br />

to ensure accountability for delivery of policies. The Sustainable Development<br />

Commission has also identified <strong>the</strong> need for a heat sector regulator to ensure<br />

a stable framework to drive <strong>the</strong> development of more sustainable heating<br />

systems (Sustainable Development Commission 2007). Creating a heat sector<br />

regulator would complement departmental responsibility for heat by ensuring<br />

that <strong>the</strong>re was a broad spectrum of institutional interests aimed at encouraging<br />

sustainable heat networks and helping to make it commercially attractive for<br />

companies to invest in <strong>the</strong>m.<br />

5.5 Conclusions: broader system issues<br />

The revision of planning procedures will help large infrastructure projects,<br />

while <strong>the</strong> new Planning Policy Statement on climate change should encourage<br />

microgeneration, providing it is applied properly by local authorities. Many<br />

renewable projects, however, will fall between <strong>the</strong>se two initiatives – too big<br />

for microgeneration, but too small to be covered by <strong>the</strong> measures aimed at<br />

large infrastructure projects. It remains to be seen whe<strong>the</strong>r planning policy<br />

guidance aimed at encouraging more renewables will prove effective, but <strong>the</strong><br />

government must ultimately ensure that new renewables projects are explicitly<br />

supported by <strong>the</strong> planning system and that <strong>the</strong>y are dealt with in a timely way.<br />

Network infrastructure also needs urgent attention if it is to allow a transition to<br />

a sustainable energy system, particularly in view of <strong>the</strong> imminent requirement to


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy Broader system issues 65<br />

replace or upgrade some 70% of <strong>the</strong> network, which offers on <strong>the</strong> one hand an<br />

opportunity for radical change and on <strong>the</strong> o<strong>the</strong>r a threat of long-term stagnation.<br />

Distribution networks must be adapted to facilitate distributed generation, and<br />

transmission networks also need to offer much better access to sustainable energy<br />

technologies. Both of <strong>the</strong>se shifts will necessitate a change in Ofgem’s approach to<br />

<strong>the</strong> regulation of networks. Firstly, it should require all upgrades or new distribution<br />

infrastructure to allow networks to be actively managed. Secondly, given <strong>the</strong><br />

difficulties in expanding <strong>the</strong> transmission system to allow renewables to connect,<br />

it must grant <strong>the</strong>m priority access so that <strong>the</strong>y are no longer prevented from<br />

connecting by <strong>the</strong> ongoing operation of conventional fossil fuel plants.<br />

As yet, <strong>the</strong>re are few heat networks in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>. The problems of investing in<br />

heat networks are <strong>the</strong> same as for any high capital cost investment, and in a<br />

competitive market <strong>the</strong>re is no real guarantee of recovering an investment, as<br />

consumers can choose to source <strong>the</strong>ir heat from elsewhere. However, some<br />

environments are more compatible with <strong>the</strong> construction of heat networks<br />

than o<strong>the</strong>rs. For example, district heating can be incorporated in social housing<br />

schemes and o<strong>the</strong>r new developments. At <strong>the</strong> moment, <strong>the</strong>re is little pressure on<br />

developers to do this, and while <strong>the</strong> Zero Carbon Homes initiative may ultimately<br />

bring about some heating networks, <strong>the</strong> proposed deadline for all new homes to<br />

be zero carbon is still eight years away. In <strong>the</strong> meantime, <strong>the</strong> government should<br />

set up a capital grant scheme for new developments, or provide a source of<br />

low-interest funding to help cover <strong>the</strong> costs of installing heating networks.<br />

In addition, <strong>the</strong>re needs to be some form of institutional arrangement to<br />

promote heat policies. This could include a heat sector regulator. It may make<br />

sense that this should be Ofgem, or it may be more appropriate to create a new<br />

regulatory body with responsibility for driving CO2 reductions across <strong>the</strong> board,<br />

including by using heat more sustainably. Whichever option is chosen, <strong>the</strong>re<br />

needs to be an explicit institutional driver to promote sustainable heat and to<br />

require its deployment.<br />

Overall, <strong>the</strong> government needs to be less fixated on <strong>the</strong> market as <strong>the</strong><br />

answer to every question. Market forces can of course drive prices down for<br />

consumers, and market failures can to an extent be corrected by <strong>the</strong> imposition<br />

of market-based mechanisms such as <strong>the</strong> EU ETS. However, <strong>the</strong> emphasis in<br />

markets is on <strong>the</strong> short term, and a long term vision is needed in order to bring<br />

about a wholesale shift to sustainable energy systems. The government needs<br />

to set a framework for <strong>the</strong> market to 2020 and beyond. Merely announcing<br />

targets will not achieve this – as has been shown by <strong>the</strong> failure to meet<br />

renewables and CO2 targets so far. A stronger framework needs to be set, and<br />

this may well require regulation to force companies to act in good time. The<br />

Zero Carbon Homes initiative is an example of a regulatory framework being<br />

used to drive innovation and emission reductions, and <strong>the</strong> government needs to<br />

have <strong>the</strong> courage to extend this approach to o<strong>the</strong>r players as well to ensure that<br />

opportunities to drive renewable heat and power are coupled with improved<br />

energy efficiency and demand reduction in a more strategic way.


66<br />

Conclusions<br />

A technician welds parts of a wind turbine in<br />

Vesta’s factory in Campbeltown, Scotland.<br />

©Davison/<strong>Greenpeace</strong>


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Conclusions<br />

67<br />

This report has outlined some of <strong>the</strong> main policies put in place by <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong><br />

government to reduce CO2 emissions. It has been written in <strong>the</strong> context<br />

of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s commitment to a number of EU targets, including reducing<br />

energy consumption by 20% and increasing <strong>the</strong> level of renewable energy<br />

generation to 20% by 2020. It has also been written in <strong>the</strong> light of innumerable<br />

government statements about <strong>the</strong> immediate threat of climate change and<br />

<strong>the</strong> need to take rapid and decisive action to reduce emissions, both through<br />

improving energy efficiency and encouraging <strong>the</strong> deployment of low-carbon,<br />

sustainable energy options. Overall, this report has argued that <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong><br />

government is failing to grasp <strong>the</strong> opportunity offered by <strong>the</strong> EU targets, to set<br />

up a business and regulatory environment which will encourage <strong>the</strong> emergence<br />

of viable low-carbon energy systems in <strong>the</strong> longer-term.<br />

Achieving <strong>the</strong> EU’s targets will be challenging because of <strong>the</strong> degree of policy<br />

effort and system change that <strong>the</strong>y imply. Effective mechanisms to encourage<br />

<strong>the</strong> diffusion of renewable energy technologies and <strong>the</strong>ir integration in energy<br />

systems will need to be established quickly in order to achieve <strong>the</strong>m. There are<br />

some important initiatives in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s current programme, including <strong>the</strong> shift<br />

towards energy services companies (ESCOs) implied by CERT and an ongoing<br />

supplier obligation. However, <strong>the</strong>se are as yet unambitious and face delays in<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir implementation. O<strong>the</strong>r measures are less impressive, particularly those<br />

aimed at reducing <strong>the</strong> carbon intensity of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> economy by encouraging<br />

<strong>the</strong> deployment of new, low-carbon technologies. The RO in particular is<br />

an example of an ineffective mechanism, with <strong>the</strong> government persisting in<br />

preserving it despite more effective, less costly alternatives.<br />

The EU targets are undoubtedly challenging, and will require a shift in how<br />

energy is produced and used across <strong>the</strong> economy. However, whe<strong>the</strong>r <strong>the</strong>y<br />

are challenging or not, <strong>the</strong> targets are not an end in <strong>the</strong>mselves but ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> first step in <strong>the</strong> journey to create sustainable energy systems and allow<br />

<strong>the</strong> necessary reductions in CO2 emissions. If <strong>the</strong> mechanisms to enable a<br />

substantial shift in energy systems by 2020 are not put in place now, <strong>the</strong>re<br />

is little if any chance of <strong>the</strong> necessary longer term shift to low-carbon,<br />

sustainable energy production and use. O<strong>the</strong>r EU countries – notably Germany<br />

and Spain – have demonstrated how to initiate such a shift, with well designed<br />

policies put in place, backed up with political will. The rate of renewable energy<br />

adoption in Germany, and <strong>the</strong> deployment levels of renewable electricity<br />

technologies in Spain would, if replicated in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>, put this country firmly on<br />

<strong>the</strong> right track for meeting its 2020 commitment.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Conclusions<br />

68<br />

An evaluation of <strong>the</strong> main policies in <strong>the</strong> Climate Change Programme and <strong>the</strong><br />

2007 Energy White Paper shows a heavy emphasis on market mechanisms to<br />

achieve <strong>the</strong> necessary cuts in emissions. The problem with this approach is that<br />

it establishes short-term drivers to improve efficiency, but does not establish a<br />

long-term investment environment to encourage <strong>the</strong> implementation of<br />

low-carbon technologies. The uncertainties inherent in <strong>the</strong> ETS – relatively<br />

short periods for action, reliance on equal action in o<strong>the</strong>r member states, and<br />

<strong>the</strong> volatility of <strong>the</strong> price of carbon – mean that action with short-term, or<br />

even positive financial paybacks are logically more attractive for businesses than<br />

investment in new technologies which may be risky and are more expensive.<br />

It is clear that not only is <strong>the</strong> ETS central to <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s approach to reducing<br />

emissions, it is <strong>the</strong> only approach to reducing emissions. The leaked 2007 BERR<br />

memo argues that achieving <strong>the</strong> renewables target is undesirable because it<br />

might threaten <strong>the</strong> price of carbon in <strong>the</strong> ETS, this misses <strong>the</strong> point that <strong>the</strong> ETS<br />

is a means of achieving cost effective CO2 reductions, not an end in itself (BERR<br />

2007). The price of carbon will be set by <strong>the</strong> permitted level of emissions, not<br />

by <strong>the</strong> availability of low-carbon technologies – if <strong>the</strong> price is threatened, <strong>the</strong><br />

permitted limits should be tightened, ra<strong>the</strong>r than abandoning a commitment<br />

to sustainable energy technologies. This exposes a fundamental problem with<br />

<strong>the</strong> government’s approach to reducing emissions: its ideological commitment<br />

to market mechanisms over and above any o<strong>the</strong>r way of driving <strong>the</strong> necessary<br />

change is not just inadequate, it also risks actively undermining <strong>the</strong> new<br />

technologies and approaches which are needed.<br />

The government’s approach is astonishingly short sighted. Reducing emissions<br />

will of course involve improving energy efficiency, but it will also require a<br />

change in <strong>the</strong> ways that energy is produced. The nature of energy systems<br />

<strong>the</strong>mselves will have to change to be able to incorporate low-carbon, often<br />

renewable generating technologies. Given <strong>the</strong> length of time that energy<br />

assets remain in place – typically decades – this shift has to begin in earnest<br />

now if <strong>the</strong>re is to be a chance of meeting <strong>the</strong> required levels of CO2 emissions<br />

reduction up to 2050. If <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> misses <strong>the</strong> opportunity presented by <strong>the</strong> EU<br />

targets to begin meaningful development of new systems now, it will face an<br />

enormous struggle to meet <strong>the</strong> longer term targets.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Conclusions<br />

69<br />

Any new approach, which is urgently needed, will have to incorporate a<br />

much more sophisticated treatment of energy systems, innovation and<br />

technical change. It is not enough to put support mechanisms in place for new<br />

technologies and <strong>the</strong>n expect <strong>the</strong>m to automatically perform. The conditions<br />

in <strong>the</strong> broader system environment – such as planning, infrastructure,<br />

institutional and social attitudes – have to be supportive, or at least not hostile,<br />

to <strong>the</strong> new technologies. Without this, <strong>the</strong>y will forever remain marginal to <strong>the</strong><br />

current, unsustainable system configurations. In some cases, <strong>the</strong> government<br />

is beginning to address <strong>the</strong>se broader issues, while in o<strong>the</strong>rs it continues to fail<br />

to recognise <strong>the</strong> importance that <strong>the</strong>y play. This is particularly apparent in <strong>the</strong><br />

ongoing debate about <strong>the</strong> role of Ofgem, which has a significant influence over<br />

both <strong>the</strong> design of <strong>the</strong> market and <strong>the</strong>refore <strong>the</strong> economic performance of new<br />

technologies, and also <strong>the</strong> infrastructure which <strong>the</strong>y rely on to deliver <strong>the</strong>ir<br />

output.<br />

The time has come for <strong>the</strong> government to recognise that it cannot aspire to<br />

reduce emissions while also allowing Ofgem to construct market and regulatory<br />

arrangements which condemn new technologies to failure.<br />

Overall <strong>the</strong>n, <strong>the</strong> government must adopt a broader approach to energy<br />

systems and <strong>the</strong> mechanisms it employs to drive <strong>the</strong> necessary change. Its<br />

overwhelming preference for economic efficiency through market mechanisms<br />

may drive short-term gains, but will fail to put a longer-term strategic<br />

framework in place. It is, and will remain, an ineffective approach in enabling <strong>the</strong><br />

emergence of sustainable energy systems. Instead, <strong>the</strong> government needs to<br />

set out a long-term strategic vision for energy systems with ambitious targets<br />

and a long-term policy framework with clear commitments to decisive action,<br />

whe<strong>the</strong>r this involves market mechanisms or more traditional, ‘command and<br />

control’ regulatory measures. Its priority should be on creating a framework<br />

whereby investors have a degree of certainty about <strong>the</strong>ir investments in new<br />

technologies if <strong>the</strong>y are to have <strong>the</strong> necessary confidence to begin a shift to<br />

sustainable energy systems.<br />

Changing existing measures or introducing new ones could, of course,<br />

contribute to an improvement in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s performance. This could include:<br />

• A one off increase in <strong>the</strong> level of <strong>the</strong> Climate Change Levy above <strong>the</strong><br />

rate of inflation to re-establish its revenue neutrality for business, by<br />

bringing it back in line with <strong>the</strong> cut in National Insurance Contributions.<br />

• Bringing forward <strong>the</strong> target dates for both Zero Carbon Homes from<br />

2016, and establishing an aggressive timetable for zero carbon nondomestic<br />

buildings ra<strong>the</strong>r than pursuing an ‘ambition’ aimed at 2019.<br />

• Maintaining <strong>the</strong> Merton Rule so that it continues to help create a viable<br />

market for new developments, small-scale renewables and emerging<br />

renewable energy supply chains, whe<strong>the</strong>r domestic or commercial.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Conclusions<br />

70<br />

• Increasing <strong>the</strong> levels of carbon and energy savings for <strong>the</strong> Supplier<br />

Obligation which will succeed CERTs, given that this can contribute to<br />

<strong>the</strong> government’s fuel poverty and energy security agendas as well as<br />

<strong>the</strong> need to reduce carbon emissions.<br />

• Ensuring that all energy supply companies have an energy service<br />

company (ESCO) approach for all energy sales.<br />

• Recognising that <strong>the</strong> RO is not an effective mechanism, ei<strong>the</strong>r in terms<br />

of deployment or cost to <strong>the</strong> consumer. While it might be unfeasible<br />

to abandon <strong>the</strong> RO as a model for existing projects, <strong>the</strong> government<br />

should establish a feed-in tariff mechanism as a support option<br />

for new projects to provide <strong>the</strong>m with <strong>the</strong> financial certainty that is<br />

necessary to drive rapid deployment.<br />

• On <strong>the</strong> same grounds, <strong>the</strong> government should also recognise that<br />

setting up RO-like mechanisms for renewable heat is unlikely to<br />

produce sufficient levels to meet <strong>the</strong> respective targets. The<br />

government is yet to establish a mechanism for renewable heat, and it<br />

should avoid replicating <strong>the</strong> RO’s failure. A support mechanism based on<br />

a feed-in tariff for renewable heat fuels is much more likely to drive <strong>the</strong><br />

sector.<br />

• One of <strong>the</strong> main barriers to <strong>the</strong> development of heat networks<br />

– renewable or not – appears to be <strong>the</strong> willingness of operators to<br />

invest in high capital infrastructure in a market where a return on<br />

investment is so uncertain. A mechanism of capital grants would<br />

go some way towards addressing <strong>the</strong>se concerns, and this sort<br />

of aid is explicitly allowed under <strong>the</strong> European Commission’s new<br />

proposals for permissible State Aid. The government should support<br />

<strong>the</strong>se proposals, and implement a scheme of capital grants for heat<br />

networks. This in turn could act as a driver for <strong>the</strong> deployment of more<br />

combined heat and power.<br />

• Microgeneration technologies offer significant potential for carbon<br />

reductions in <strong>the</strong> long term. However, <strong>the</strong> Low Carbon Buildings<br />

Programme for supporting <strong>the</strong>ir deployment is confused and<br />

ineffective. The government needs to reassess <strong>the</strong> level of grants<br />

available, and extend <strong>the</strong> scheme to build up sufficient momentum<br />

in <strong>the</strong> sector to allow it to contribute to <strong>the</strong> achievement of o<strong>the</strong>r<br />

targets, in particular <strong>the</strong> Zero Carbon Homes target.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Conclusions<br />

71<br />

These specific measures should act as a driver to encourage <strong>the</strong> use of more<br />

efficient or renewable technologies. However, <strong>the</strong>y will not in <strong>the</strong>mselves be<br />

sufficient to drive <strong>the</strong> required shift to meet <strong>the</strong> 2020 targets and put <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong><br />

in a position to move beyond <strong>the</strong>m. This will require an intellectual shift on <strong>the</strong><br />

part of policy makers and a broader approach to energy systems as a whole. The<br />

technical, regulatory and market environment in which sustainable technologies<br />

are deployed has a fundamental effect on <strong>the</strong>ir performance and <strong>the</strong>refore on<br />

<strong>the</strong>ir economics.<br />

Instead of continuing <strong>the</strong> current, short-term approach to <strong>the</strong> economics of <strong>the</strong><br />

system, market design, regulation and system infrastructure should be judged<br />

against longer-term, more strategic criteria aimed at enabling a shift to a more<br />

sustainable energy system. This could include:<br />

• Requiring <strong>the</strong> use of active network management technologies as part<br />

of any distribution network infrastructure upgrade.<br />

• Ensuring that renewable and CHP projects have priority access to<br />

transmission networks.<br />

• Promoting <strong>the</strong> expansion of a viable and sustainable biomass industry<br />

using smaller-scale localised CHP, as opposed to <strong>the</strong> existing emphasis<br />

on co-firing in conventional coal fired power stations.<br />

• Reassessing <strong>the</strong> role of Ofgem, to ensure that its duties are geared<br />

specifically towards enabling a shift to a sustainable energy system,<br />

including considering <strong>the</strong> impact of market design on smaller<br />

generating projects and reducing <strong>the</strong> emphasis it places on short term<br />

competition.<br />

Without a fundamental shift in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s approach to policy and regulation,<br />

<strong>the</strong> government will fail to encourage <strong>the</strong> emergence of sustainable energy<br />

options and will fail to establish <strong>the</strong> conditions necessary to drive a shift<br />

to a low-carbon economy. The forthcoming review of <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable<br />

energy strategy offers <strong>the</strong> opportunity to guard against this possibility by<br />

implementing <strong>the</strong> new approach outlined in this report.


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

References<br />

72<br />

References<br />

AEA Energy and Environment (2007), Options for Changes to <strong>the</strong> Regulatory Framework Required to Deliver a Sustainable Energy<br />

System in Great Britain, Report to <strong>the</strong> Sustainable Development Commission, ED05434,<br />

www.sd-commission.org.uk/publications/downloads/Ogem_Review_AEA_Regulatory_Framework.pdf<br />

BERR (2007), Draft Options Paper on Renewables Target, http://image.guardian.co.uk/sys-files/Guardian/<br />

documents/2007/08/13/RenewablesTargetDocument.pdf<br />

BERR (2007a), Key Features of Phases 1 and 2 of <strong>the</strong> Low Carbon Buildings Programme relating to Charity/Community/Public<br />

Sector Organisations, www.lowcarbonbuildingsphase2.org.uk/filelibrary/LCBP2_Phase_1_vs_Phase2_v3.0.pdf<br />

BERR (2007b), Energy Trends, September, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file41460.pdf<br />

BERR (2008), Heat Call for Evidence, January, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file43609.pdf<br />

BERR (2008a), <strong>UK</strong> Renewable Energy Strategy and <strong>the</strong> EU Renewable Energy Directive, Written Ministerial Statement, URN<br />

08/688. http://www.berr.gov.uk/files/file45024.pdf<br />

BERR (2008b), Updated Energy and Carbon Emission Projections, Amended Version of 07/947, URN 07/947X, February.<br />

www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39580.pdf<br />

BERR (2008c), Renewables Obligation Consultation; Government Response, January. www.berr.gov.uk/files/file43545.pdf<br />

BERR (2008d), Energy Billing and Metering; Changing Customer Behaviour, Government Response to a Consultation, URN<br />

08/840, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file45996.pdf<br />

Biomass Task Force (2005), Report to Government, www.defra.gov.uk/farm/crops/industrial/energy/biomass-taskforce/pdf/<br />

btf-finalreport.pdf<br />

BMU (2007), Renewable Energy Sources Act (EEG), Progress Report 2007,<br />

BMU (2007a), EEG – <strong>the</strong> Renewable Energy Sources Act,<br />

BMU (2007b), Integrated Energy and Climate Programme of <strong>the</strong> German government, www.bmu.de/files/pdfs/allgemein/<br />

application/pdf/hintergrund_meseberg_en.pdf<br />

BMU (2008), Development of Renewable Energies in Germany in 2007,<br />

BMU (2008a), Development of Renewable Energy Sources in Germany in 2007, Graphics and Tables<br />

Boardman, B, Jardine, C, Lipp, J (2006), Green Electricity Code of Practice, a Scoping Study, Environmental Change Institute,<br />

Oxford,www.good-energy.co.uk/PDF/GE_COP_FinalReport.pdf<br />

Boardman, B (2007), Home Truths: a Low Carbon Strategy to Reduce <strong>UK</strong> Housing Emissions by 80% by 2050.<br />

www.eci.ox.ac.uk/research/energy/downloads/boardman07-hometruths.pdf<br />

British Property Federation (2007), Blinkered Thinking Hampering Green Targets, Press Release PR(07)34, 21.8.07,<br />

www.bpf.org.uk/newsroom/pressreleases/document/23195/blinkered-thinking-hampers-greener-buildings<br />

Brown, G (2007), Prime Minister Calls for Global Action on Climate Change,<br />

19 November, www.number-10.gov.uk/output/Page13791.asp<br />

Buildings Research Establishment (2004), BRE Welcomes Proposals for Changing Part L and Implementing <strong>the</strong> EU Energy<br />

Performance of Buildings Directive, press release, 22.8.04, www.bre.co.uk/newsdetails.jsp?id=242<br />

Cambridge Econometrics and Policy Studies Institute (2005), Modelling <strong>the</strong> Initial Effects of <strong>the</strong> Climate Change Levy, a<br />

Report for HM Customs, http://customs.hmrc.gov.uk/channelsPortalWebApp/channelsPortalWebApp.portal?_nfpb=true&_<br />

pageLabel=pageLibrary_ShowContent&id=HMCE_PROD1_023971&propertyType=document<br />

Carbon Trust (2005), The <strong>UK</strong> Climate Change Programme: Potential Evolution For Business And The Public Sector,<br />

www.carbontrust.co.uk/Publications/publicationdetail.htm?productid=CTC518<br />

Carbon Trust (2007), EU ETS Phase II Allocation: Implications and Lessons, www.carbontrust.co.uk/publications/publicationdetail.<br />

htm?productid=CTC715<br />

Communities and Local Government (2006), Building a Greener <strong>Future</strong>: Towards Zero Carbon Development – Consultation, 06<br />

SCDD 04276, www.communities.gov.uk/documents/planningandbuilding/pdf/153125<br />

Communities and Local Government (2006a), Code for Sustainable Homes: A step-change in sustainable home building practice,<br />

www.communities.gov.uk/publications/planningandbuilding/codesustainable


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

References<br />

73<br />

Communities and Local Government (2007), Building a Greener <strong>Future</strong>: Policy Statement,<br />

www.communities.gov.uk/documents/planningandbuilding/pdf/building-greener<br />

Communities and Local Government (2007a), Planning for a Sustainable <strong>Future</strong>.<br />

www.communities.gov.uk/documents/planningandbuilding/pdf/planningsustainablefuture.pdf<br />

Communities and Local Government (2007b), Changes to Permitted Development Consultation Paper 1: Permitted Development<br />

Rights for Householder Microgeneration, www.communities.gov.uk/documents/planningandbuilding/pdf/319354<br />

Confederation of British Industry (2007), Business Summaries, Emissions<br />

Trading, www.cbi.org.uk/ndbs/cbi_bss nsf/8dee44d616d5b<br />

99280256c5b004f042a80256c8300576d6880256cad005caf69?OpenDocument, accessed Sept 2007<br />

Confederation of British Industry (2007a), Climate Change: Everybody’s Business. www.cbi.org.uk/pdf/climatereport2007full.pdf<br />

Datamonitor (2007), Appetite for ‘Green’ Power Will Not Be Satisfied, Press Release, 29 March, www.datamonitor.com<br />

Defra (2004), The Government’s Strategy for Combined Heat and Power to 2010,<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/Environment/climatechange/uk/energy/chp/pdf/chp-strategy.pdf<br />

Defra (2006a), Defra opens up Bio-energy Capital Grants Scheme third round - support for biomass heat, press release 541/02,<br />

29 December, www.defra.gov.uk/news/2006/061229a.htm<br />

Defra (2006), Climate Change, The <strong>UK</strong> Programme 2006, Cm 6764,<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/ukccp/pdf/ukccp06-all.pdf<br />

Defra (2007), <strong>UK</strong> Climate Change Programme, Annual Report to Parliament, July 2007,<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/ukccp/pdf/ukcc-annrpt-07.pdf<br />

Defra (2007a), <strong>UK</strong> Energy Efficiency Action Plan, June,<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/energy/pdf/action-plan-2007.pdf<br />

Defra (2007b), Climate Change Agreements, Results of <strong>the</strong> Third Target Period Assessment, July,<br />

http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/business/ccl/pdf/cca-jul07.pdf<br />

Defra (2007c), Updated Partial Regulatory Impact Assessment on <strong>the</strong> Carbon Reduction Commitment, June,<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/corporate/consult/carbon-reduc/partial-ria.pdf<br />

Defra (2007d), The Household Energy Supplier Obligation from 2011: a Call for Evidence, June,<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/household/supplier/pdf/evidence-call.pdf<br />

Defra (2007e), Analysis of <strong>UK</strong> Potential for CHP – Evaluation of Progress Towards Meeting <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> Potential for CHP. October.<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/energy/chp/pdf/potential-report.pdf<br />

Defra (2007f), Consultation on <strong>the</strong> Recommendations of <strong>the</strong> Climate Change Simplification Project: Climate Change Instruments,<br />

Areas of overlap and options for simplification, www.defra.gov.uk/corporate/consult/cc-instruments/consultation.pdf<br />

Defra (2008), <strong>UK</strong> Climate Change Sustainable Development Indicator: 2006 Greenhouse Gas Emissions, Final Figures, Statistical<br />

Release 25/08, 31 January. www.defra.gov.uk/environment/statistics/globatmos/download/ghg_ns_20080131.pdf<br />

Defra (2008a), EU Emissions Trading Scheme: <strong>UK</strong> Results 2006 Report.<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/eu/results/pdf/euets-ukresults-2006.pdf<br />

Defra (2008b), Sector level summary of 2007 EU ETS results in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>, May,<br />

www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/trading/eu/pdf/sectorlevel-ukresults-2007.pdf<br />

DETR (2000), <strong>UK</strong> Climate Change Programme, http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/ukccp/2000/index.htm<br />

Distributed Generation Co-Ordinating Group (2005), Third Annual Report 2004/05, March,<br />

www.ofgem.gov.uk/Networks/ElecDist/Policy/DistGen/Documents1/10724-dgcg_annual_report_2004.pdf<br />

ZTI (2001), Embedded Generation Working Group, Report into Network Access Issues, January,<br />

www.ensg.gov.uk/assets/21_10_2002_main_report.pdf<br />

DTI (2003), Energy White Paper; Our Energy <strong>Future</strong>, Creating a Low Carbon Economy, URN 03/660,<br />

www.berr.gov.uk/files/file10719.pdf.<br />

DTI (2004), Social and Environmental Guidance to <strong>the</strong> Gas and Electricity Markets Authority,<br />

www.berr.gov.uk/files/file37517.pdf<br />

DTI (2005), Options for a Low Carbon <strong>Future</strong>: Review of Modelling Activities and an Update, DTI Occasional Paper No 1 by ICEPT/<br />

FES, September, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file14792.pdf


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

References<br />

74<br />

DTI (2006), The Energy Challenge, Energy Review Report, Cm 6887, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file31890.pdf<br />

DTI (2006a), Our Energy Challenge, Power from <strong>the</strong> People: Microgeneration Strategy, URN 06/993,<br />

www.berr.gov.uk/files/file27575.pdf<br />

DTI (2007), Meeting <strong>the</strong> Energy Challenge, A White Paper on Energy, May 2007, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39387.pdf<br />

DTI (2007a), Energy Trends, June, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file40156.pdf<br />

DTI (2007b), Updated Energy and Carbon Emissions Projections, The Energy White Paper, URN 07/947,<br />

www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39580.pdf<br />

DTI (2007c) Reform of <strong>the</strong> Renewables Obligation, URN 07/636, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39497.pdf<br />

DTI (2007d), Syn<strong>the</strong>sis of <strong>the</strong> Analysis of <strong>the</strong> Energy White Paper, URN 07/971, May, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39198.pdf<br />

DTI (2007e), Extra £6m for green householders – Darling, press release 21 March, P/2007/064, www.gnn.gov.uk/environment/<br />

fullDetail.asp?ReleaseID=273009&NewsAreaID=2&NavigatedFromDepartment=True<br />

DTI/DfT/Defra (2007), <strong>UK</strong> Biomass Strategy, May, http://www.defra.gov.uk/environment/climatechange/uk/energy/<br />

renewablefuel/pdf/ukbiomassstrategy-0507.pdf<br />

DTI/Ofgem (2007), Review of Distributed Generation, May, URN 07/943, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39025.pdf<br />

EA Technology (2006), A Technical Review and Assessment of Active Network Management Infrastructures and Practices, a<br />

report for <strong>the</strong> ENSG, URN 06/1196, http://reporting.dti.gov.uk/cgi-bin/rr.cgi/ www.dti.gov.uk/files/file30559.pdf?nourl=<br />

www.dti.gov.uk/publications/pdflink/&pubpdfdload=06%2F1196<br />

Energy Networks Association (2006), The State of Our Networks; Electricity and Gas in <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong> 2006 – 2050, www.<br />

energynetworks.org/spring/mediacentre/cms03/CMDocuments/contentManDoc_56_ea7207e7-05d7-46f5-b106-<br />

6d21ed10e699.pdf<br />

Energy Savings Trust, econnect, Element Energy (2005), Potential for Microgeneration, Study and Analysis, final report,<br />

November, www.berr.gov.uk/files/file27558.pdf<br />

Energy Savings Trust (2007), Energy Efficiency Commitment 2005 – 2008, Briefing Note, August,<br />

www.energysavingtrust.org.uk/uploads/documents/housingbuildings/eec2_CERT_bn.pdf<br />

EREC (2008), Renewable Policy Review; Spain, www.erec.org/fileadmin/erec_docs/Projcet_Documents/RES2020/SPAIN_RES__<br />

Policy_review_April_2008.pdf<br />

European Commission (2005), The Support of Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources, communication from <strong>the</strong> Commission, COM<br />

(2005) 627 final, http://ec.europa.eu/energy/res/biomass_action_plan/doc/2005_12_07_comm_biomass_electricity_en.pdf<br />

European Commission (2006), Renewable Energy Road Map - Renewable energies in <strong>the</strong> 21st century: building a more sustainable<br />

future, COM (2006) 848 final, http://ec.europa.eu/energy/energy_policy/doc/03_renewable_energy_roadmap_en.pdf<br />

European Commission (2008), Boosting Growth and Jobs by Meeting our Climate Change Commitments, 23 January, IP 09/80,<br />

http://europa.eu/rapid/pressReleasesAction.do?reference=IP/08/80<br />

European Commission (2008a), 20 20 by 2020: Europe’s Climate Change Opportunity, Communication from <strong>the</strong> Commission<br />

to <strong>the</strong> European Parliament, <strong>the</strong> Council, <strong>the</strong> European Economic and Social Committee and <strong>the</strong> Committee of <strong>the</strong> Regions, COM<br />

(2008) 30 final. http://ec.europa.eu/commission_barroso/president/pdf/COM2008_030_en.pdf<br />

European Commission (2008b), The Support of Electricity from Renewable Energy Sources, Commission Staff Working Document,<br />

SEC(2008)57, http://ec.europa.eu/energy/climate_actions/doc/2008_res_working_document_en.pdf<br />

European Council (2007), Presidency Conclusions, 7224/1/07 REV 1, May,<br />

www.consilium.europa.eu/uedocs/cms_Data/docs/pressdata/en/ec/93135.pdf<br />

European Council (2008), Climate-Energy Legislative Package – Policy Debate, Contribution from <strong>the</strong> United Kingdom, 7010/08,<br />

27 February, http://register.consilium.europa.eu/pdf/en/08/st07/st07010.en08.pdf<br />

Graham, V (2007), Reality or Rhetoric? Green Tariffs for Domestic Consumers, National Consumers Council,<br />

www.ncc.org.uk/nccpdf/poldocs/NCC144rr_reality_or_rhetoric.pdf<br />

Gross, R, Heptonstall, P, Blyth, W (2007), Investment in Electricity Generation: <strong>the</strong> Role of Costs, Incentives and Risks, <strong>UK</strong>ERC,<br />

www.ukerc.ac.uk/Downloads/PDF/06/0706_Investing_in_Power.pdf<br />

Guardian (2007), Housebuilders win battle against green technologies, 20.8.07,<br />

www.guardian.co.uk/environment/2007/aug/20/energy


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

References<br />

75<br />

GWEC (2008), Global Wind 2007 Report, http://www.gwec.net/fileadmin/documents/testfolder/Global_Wind_2007_Report_<br />

final.pdf<br />

Held, A, Ragwitz, M et al, (2007), Feed-In Systems in Germany, Spain and Slovenia, Fraunhofer Institute Systems and Innovation<br />

Research, Energy Economics Group Austria, Agencija za prestrukturiranje energetike, Slovenia,<br />

www.feed-in-cooperation.org/images/files/ific_comparison_of_fit-systems_de_es_sl.pdf<br />

HM Revenue and Customs (2008), Climate Change Levy Rates, 12 March 2008, BN84,<br />

www.hmrc.gov.uk/budget2008/bn84.pdf<br />

HMSO (2002), The Renewables Obligation Order 2002, Statutory Instrument 2002 Number 914,<br />

www.opsi.gov.uk/si/si2002/20020914.htm<br />

HM Treasury (2006), The Stern Review: <strong>the</strong> Economics of Climate Change, www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/independent_reviews/<br />

stern_review_economics_climate_change/stern_review_report.cfm<br />

HM Treasury (2006a), The Climate Change Levy Package, March, www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media/8/B/bud06_climate_169.pdf<br />

HM Treasury (2008), Stability and Opportunity: Building a Strong Sustainable <strong>Future</strong>, PN1, 12 March.<br />

www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/budget/budget_08/press_notices/bud_bud08_press01.cfm<br />

HM Treasury (2008a), Budget 2008: Stability and Opportunity, Building a Strong, Sustainable <strong>Future</strong>, HC 388,<br />

www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/media/9/9/bud08_completereport.pdf<br />

House of Commons Environmental Audit Committee (2003), Budget 2003 and Aviation, Ninth Report of Session 2002–03, HC<br />

672, www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200203/cmselect/cmenvaud/672/672.pdf<br />

House of Commons Environmental Audit Committee (2006), Reducing Carbon Emissions from Transport, Ninth Report of Session<br />

2005–06, HC 981-I, www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200506/cmselect/cmenvaud/981/981-i.pdf<br />

House of Commons Environment, Food and Rural Affairs Committee (2007), Climate Change: <strong>the</strong> ‘Citizen’s Agenda’, 8th Report<br />

Session 2006-07, HC 88-I. www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm200607/cmselect/cmenvfru/88/88i.pdf<br />

Mitchell, C, Bauknecht, D, Connor, P (2006), Effectiveness Through Risk Reduction, a Comparison of <strong>the</strong> Renewable Obligation in<br />

England and Wales and <strong>the</strong> Feed-In System in Germany, Energy Policy, Vol 34, No 3, pp 297-305<br />

National Audit Office (2007), The Climate Change Levy and Climate Change Agreements, a Review by <strong>the</strong> National Audit Office,<br />

August, www.nao.org.uk/publications/nao_reports/06-07/climate_change_review.pdf<br />

National Audit Office (2008), <strong>UK</strong> Greenhouse Gas Emissions: Measurement and Reporting, March,<br />

www.nao.org.uk/publications/0708_greenhouse_gas_emissions.pdf<br />

Ofgem (2006), Letter to Bernard Bulkin, Sustainable Development Commission, 2 November,<br />

www.ofgem.gov.uk/temp/ofgem/cache/cmsattach/17519_bulkin.pdf<br />

Ofgem (2007), Ofgem’s Response to BERR Consultation on Reform of <strong>the</strong> Renewables Obligation, Ref 222/07.<br />

www.ofgem.gov.uk/.../Documents1/Ofgem%20response%20to%20Renewables%20Obligation%20consultation%5B1%5D.pdf<br />

Ofgem (2007a), Cutting <strong>the</strong> Green Customer Confusion – Next Steps, 275/07, www.ofgem.gov.uk/SUSTAINABILITY/<br />

ENVIRONMNT/POLICY/Documents1/Cutting%20green%20customer%20confusion_consultation%20document.pdf<br />

Ofgem (2007b), Corporate Strategy and Plan 2007-2012, 60/07, March, www.ofgem.gov.uk/About%20us/CorpPlan/<br />

Documents1/19247_2007%20Corp%20Plan.pdf<br />

Ofgem/BERR (2007), Transmission Access Review, a Call for Evidence for a Review of Transmission Access, 212/07, www.ofgem.<br />

gov.uk/Networks/Trans/ElecTransPolicy/tar/Documents1/070816_Ex_TAR%20Call%20for%20Evidence_FINAL.pdf<br />

Ofgem (2008), Review of <strong>the</strong> Market for Exported Electricity from Microgeneration, www.ofgem.gov.uk/Pages/<br />

MoreInformation.aspx?docid=1&refer=Sustainability/Environmnt/Policy/SmallrGens/DomsScMicro<br />

Office of Government Commerce (2007), New Electricity Deal for Public Sector, press release 18 June 2007,<br />

www.ogc.gov.uk/About_OGC_news_7281.asp<br />

Oxera (2007), Reform of <strong>the</strong> Renewables Obligation; What is <strong>the</strong> Likely Impact of Changes?<br />

www.berr.gov.uk/files/file39039.pdf<br />

Point Carbon (2008), EU ETS Phase II; The Potential and Scale of Windfall Profits in <strong>the</strong> Power Sector, a report for WWF,<br />

www.wwf.org.uk/filelibrary/pdf/ets_windfall_report_0408.pdf


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

References<br />

76<br />

Pöyry (2006), Creating Ski Slopes from Cliff Edges: Removing Volume Risk from <strong>the</strong> Renewables Obligation, May,<br />

www.ilexenergy.com/pages/157SkiSlopesFromCliffEdges_v3_0.doc<br />

Pöyry (2008), Compliance Costs for Meeting <strong>the</strong> 20% Renewable Energy Target in 2020, a Report to <strong>the</strong> Department for Business,<br />

Enterprise and Regulatory Reform, March. www.berr.gov.uk/files/file45238.pdf<br />

Ragwitz, M, Held, A et al (2007), Assessment and Optimisation of Renewable Energy Support Scheme in <strong>the</strong> European Electricity<br />

Market, Final Report, Intelligent Energy Europe, www.optres.fhg.de/OPTRES_FINAL_REPORT.pdf<br />

Renewables Advisory Board (2007), The Role of On-Site Energy Generation in Delivering Zero Carbon Homes.<br />

www.renewables-advisory-board.org.uk/vBulletin/attachment.php?s=5ec9ef143d9c213c7b65592c9f872ac8&attachmenti<br />

d=334&d=1195724104<br />

Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution (2007), 26th Report: <strong>the</strong> Urban Environment, Cm 7009,<br />

www.rcep.org.uk/urban/report/urban-environment.pdf<br />

Royal Society (2008), Sustainable Biofuels. http://uwcalscommunication.com/wp-content/uploads/2008/RS_sustainable_<br />

biofuels_report_Jan_08.pdf<br />

Strategy Unit (2007), Building on Progress: Energy and Environment; HM Government Policy Review, 281354/0607,<br />

Society of Motor Manufacturers and Traders (2007), SMMT Annual CO2 Report, 2006 Market, http://smmtlib.findlay.co.uk/<br />

articles/homepagearticle/HomePageArticles/CO2%20Report%202006%20market%20-%20Overview.zip<br />

Sustainable Development Commission (2007), Lost in Transmission? The Role of Ofgem in a Changing Climate, September,<br />

www.sd-commission.org.uk/publications.php?id=594<br />

<strong>UK</strong>ERC (2006), Quick Hits 1; Eco-Driving, www.ukerc.ac.uk/Downloads/PDF/Q/Quick%20Hits/0609EcoDriving.pdf<br />

WWF (2007), Emission Impossible: Access to JI/CDM Credits in Phase II of <strong>the</strong> EU Emission Trading Scheme, June,<br />

www.wwf.org.uk/filelibrary/pdf/emission_impossible.pdf<br />

www.<strong>the</strong>mertonrule.org (2006) The Merton Rule 10%(+) Renewable energy policy briefing


<strong>Connecting</strong> <strong>the</strong> future: <strong>the</strong> <strong>UK</strong>’s renewable energy strategy<br />

Glossary of acronyms<br />

77<br />

Glossary of acronyms<br />

AEE<br />

ANM<br />

BERR<br />

BETTA<br />

BMU<br />

CBI<br />

CCA<br />

CCS<br />

CDM<br />

CERT<br />

CHP<br />

CLL<br />

CO2<br />

CRC<br />

DE<br />

Defra<br />

DETR<br />

DfT<br />

DNO<br />

DTI<br />

D<strong>UK</strong>ES<br />

EEC<br />

EEG<br />

EPA<br />

EPC<br />

EREC<br />

ESCO<br />

ETS<br />

EU<br />

EU ETS<br />

GDP<br />

GHG<br />

GWEC<br />

IFI<br />

JI<br />

LCBP<br />

LEC<br />

MAP<br />

NIC<br />

PPS<br />

R&D<br />

RIA<br />

RO<br />

ROC<br />

RPZ<br />

SDC<br />

<strong>UK</strong><br />

<strong>UK</strong>ERC<br />

WWF<br />

ZCH<br />

Spanish Wind Association - Asociacion Empresarial Eolica<br />

Active network management<br />

Department for Business, Enterprise & Regulatory Reform<br />

British Electricity Trading and Transmissions Arrangements<br />

Federation Ministry for <strong>the</strong> Environment, Nature Conservation and<br />

Nuclear Safety – Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und<br />

Reaktorsicherheit<br />

Confederation of British Industry<br />

Climate Change Agreements<br />

carbon capture and storage<br />

Clean Development Mechanism<br />

Carbon Emissions Reduction Target<br />

Combined heat and power<br />

Climate Change Levy<br />

Carbon dioxide<br />

Carbon Reduction Commitment<br />

Decentralised energy<br />

Department for Environment, Food and Rural Affairs<br />

Department of <strong>the</strong> Environment Transport and <strong>the</strong> Regions<br />

Department for Transport<br />

Distribution network operator<br />

Department of Trade and Industry<br />

Digest of <strong>UK</strong> Energy Statistics<br />

Energy Efficiency Commitment<br />

Renewable Energy Sources Act – Erneuerbare-Energien Gesetz<br />

Emissions Permit Allowance<br />

Energy Performance Certificate<br />

European Renewable Energy Council<br />

Energy Service Company<br />

Emissions Trading Scheme<br />

European Union<br />

European Union Emissions Trading Scheme<br />

Gross Domestic Product<br />

Greenhouse gas<br />

Global Wind Energy Council<br />

Iinnovation funding incentive<br />

Joint Implementation<br />

Low Carbon Buildings Programme<br />

Levy Exemption Certificate<br />

Market Stimulation Programme – Markantanreizprogramm<br />

National Insurance Contributions<br />

Planning Policy Statement<br />

Research and development<br />

Regulatory Impact Assessment<br />

Renewables Obligation<br />

Renewables Obligation Certificate<br />

Registered power zone<br />

Sustainable Development Comission<br />

United Kingdom<br />

<strong>UK</strong> Energy Research Centre<br />

World Wildlife Fund<br />

Zero Carbon Homes

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!