INFRASTRUCTURE: A POLITICAL ANALYSIS by Theodore J. Lowi ...

INFRASTRUCTURE: A POLITICAL ANALYSIS by Theodore J. Lowi ... INFRASTRUCTURE: A POLITICAL ANALYSIS by Theodore J. Lowi ...

21.12.2013 Views

-1- INFRASTRUCTURE: A POLITICAL ANALYSIS by Theodore J. Lowi Department of Government Cornell University presented at Institute for Civil Infrastructure Systems (ICIS) Coordinated Renewal of the Civil Infrastructure Systems for Sustainable Human Environments April 21-22, 1999

-1-<br />

<strong>INFRASTRUCTURE</strong>: A <strong>POLITICAL</strong> <strong>ANALYSIS</strong><br />

<strong>by</strong><br />

<strong>Theodore</strong> J. <strong>Lowi</strong><br />

Department of Government<br />

Cornell University<br />

presented at<br />

Institute for Civil Infrastructure Systems (ICIS)<br />

Coordinated Renewal of the Civil Infrastructure Systems<br />

for Sustainable Human Environments<br />

April 21-22, 1999


-2-<br />

The enormous American national debt is perfectly<br />

justifiable. We used it to pay for victory in World War II and<br />

the Cold War. There was waste aplenty, but the need for<br />

redundancy to sustain urgent projects through the unexpected is<br />

almost always justifiable. Also justifiable is the financing of<br />

hot war and cold war <strong>by</strong> long-term debt, because our children and<br />

their children should help pay for the victories their parents<br />

and grandparents gave them. The same goes for any large public<br />

works, whose financing should be spread across a large portion of<br />

its useful life. But $2-4 billion in accumulated and deferred<br />

maintenance costs of the 45,744-mile U.S. Interstate Highway<br />

system is evidence of the sheer idiocy of leaving infrastructure<br />

to Congress, to cost benefit analysis, to civil engineers and to<br />

consulting economists. Moreover, the unplanned and<br />

unanticipated, and, mostly unwanted, social uses of public works,<br />

especially arterial highways, have to be taken into account. If<br />

"war is much too serious a matter to be entrusted to the<br />

military" (Clemenceau) we must add that "civil infrastructure is<br />

too important to be entrusted to engineers."<br />

If "civil infrastructure" is translated back into ordinary<br />

language, it is part of what we have traditionally called public<br />

works, and this translation reveals the oldest policy activity of<br />

the national government of the United States. Moreover the<br />

politics of this area of public policy is familiar and wellstudied.<br />

Thus, it would seem that we ought to be able to draw


-3-<br />

some lessons from this literature that can be applied directly to<br />

the phenomena of modern civil infrastructure. My task, as I see<br />

it, is to explore what, if anything, a political analysis can<br />

contribute to the understanding of infrastructure, how we got to<br />

where we are with it, and how we might improve our chances of<br />

getting to a more sustainable future.<br />

WHAT IS <strong>INFRASTRUCTURE</strong>?<br />

The Oxford English Dictionary defines infrastructure as "a<br />

collective term for the subordinate parts of an undertaking;<br />

substructure, foundation ... the permanent installations forming<br />

a basis for military operations ...." William Safire in his<br />

humorous but instructive Political Dictionary, defines it as<br />

"skeleton; a political entity's internal administrative<br />

apparatus." He correctly characterizes it as a "bit of jargon,"<br />

because its origin and purpose can be specifically identified.<br />

Oxford dates the first use with 1927, in a military context, and<br />

then attaches it to World War II. By 1950, Churchill stood<br />

before the House of Commons and denounced the word while<br />

recognizing that it was probably impossible to expunge it from<br />

the English language. It is still used most frequently in<br />

military contexts.<br />

Adding "civic" or "civil" to it as an adjective to<br />

infrastructure focuses the phenomenon on most projects of<br />

whatever sort are financed and built <strong>by</strong> governments, or in a


-4-<br />

mixed public/private endeavor in which the government role is<br />

essential. Whatever the case, the general category can and<br />

should be called public works. Infrastructure can be readily<br />

classified as a sub-category of the generic category of public<br />

works. I would venture to offer here a criterion for<br />

distinguishing civil infrastructure as a category within public<br />

works as follows: Civil infrastructure is a public works project<br />

which occupies such a strategic place in a geographic area or an<br />

economically definable one that the project produces intended and<br />

unintended consequences out into the indefinite future, with an<br />

influence not only on future public and private land uses but on<br />

the virtual process of thinking and planning itself, for a large<br />

but indefinite space around the project. Such strategically<br />

located projects can be called paradigmatic public works, with<br />

secondary and tertiary effects that not only influence investment<br />

but thinking and design (i.e., planning) in concentric circles of<br />

space and data around the given civil infrastructure project. We<br />

can follow here what Supreme Court Justice Potter Stewart said<br />

about pornography: Though we cannot necessarily define civil<br />

infrastructure to everybody's satisfaction, we know it when we<br />

see it.<br />

TOWARD A <strong>POLITICAL</strong> DEFINITION OF <strong>INFRASTRUCTURE</strong> POLICY<br />

A point made in the previous section could well be<br />

considered the governing premise of this endeavor:


-5-<br />

infrastructure policy is an organic part of the category of<br />

public works policy and as such is part of the oldest continuing<br />

category of public policy in the government of the United States.<br />

Just after the conquest of the territory and the defense of the<br />

new state, with a bit of an army and some taxation, public works<br />

is probably the oldest definable public policy category<br />

everywhere -- even before policies protecting private property.<br />

(I would consider relevant infrastructure as one of the basic<br />

prerequisites of an operating market economy.) Public works<br />

policy is the cornerstone of government and of politics in the<br />

United States.<br />

To appreciate this, we need a short course in public policy,<br />

in order to specify the various kinds of public policies to which<br />

public works policies can be compared -- defining what public<br />

works policy is and what it is not. I begin here with history<br />

rather than with a direct definition. Table 1 is a<br />

pictorialization of the public policy outputs of each of the<br />

levels of government in the United States, from roughly 1800 to<br />

1933. First examine Column 1, the domestic policy output of<br />

Congress throughout the 19th century. The first notable<br />

impression is that all these items share two common traits. The<br />

first is common purpose: the promotion or husbandry of commerce.<br />

So prominent and so well understood was this that many Europeans<br />

referred to the early American government as a "commercial<br />

republic." And indeed, the coup d'etat that moved us from the


-6-<br />

Articles of Confederation to the Constitution was precisely<br />

driven <strong>by</strong> frustration with the barriers to regional and national<br />

commerce under the first American republic. The second common<br />

trait is that all of these items of policy use government in same<br />

way: In the promotion of commerce, there is no involvement of<br />

direct coercion over individuals. All policies are coercive,<br />

because they are governmental; but, as we shall see, there are<br />

different kinds of coercion.<br />

Column 1 is better appreciated in the context of Column 2,<br />

policy outputs of state governments. State governments did a lot<br />

of the same kind of promotion of commerce that the national<br />

government did, especially through their local creatures, called<br />

cities, counties, etc. But the distinctive feature of state<br />

policy outputs, as shown on Column 2, is something else entirely.<br />

It does not take much reflection on the items in that long<br />

column to find what that is. And I should emphasize that each of<br />

these items is a basket of policies represented <strong>by</strong> at least one<br />

volume in state codes of legislation. The common trait through<br />

those items is referred to in constitutional history as "the<br />

police power." The modern rendering of that concept is:<br />

regulatory policy. This is a particular and distinctive use of<br />

state coercion, which involves the imposition of obligations on<br />

conduct, backed <strong>by</strong> sanctions.<br />

From that distinction alone, I think we can gain a clear<br />

picture of the nature of "public works" as a distinct category of


-7-<br />

policy. (This, <strong>by</strong> the way, gives also a clear picture of the<br />

true nature of federalism, as a form of functional division of<br />

power.) The classic examples of such policies are housed in a<br />

classic agency, the Army Corps of Engineers, possibly the oldest<br />

continuing agency in the national government, with the possible<br />

exception of the Postal Service. [PROVIDE DATES OF FOUNDING]<br />

The original assignment of the Corps of Engineers, "Rivers and<br />

Harbors," became the trade name for the whole category of public<br />

works, whose affectionate popular name became "pork barrel." And<br />

this brings us closer to a functional definition of the whole<br />

category, because the best guess is that "pork barrel" comes from<br />

the ante-bellum practice of distributing chunks of salt pork to<br />

slaves in large barrels, permitting them to fight over the barrel<br />

and grab as many chunks as they could possibly carry away. Like<br />

the pieces of pork in the barrel, promotional policies are<br />

policies that actually distribute valued resources to individuals<br />

in order to expand their alternatives or enable them to do<br />

something they were otherwise not able to do. And these valued<br />

resources can be disaggregated into larger and larger numbers of<br />

smaller and smaller chunks, like pork in the barrel. Table 2<br />

labels these "distributive policies," a term chosen in order to<br />

distinguish these from regulatory policies and from<br />

"redistributive" policies (of which more in a moment). But the<br />

best way to understand the distributive policies is to understand<br />

them as a particular use of the state called patronage.


-8-<br />

Patronage has been vulgarized to refer only to the public jobs<br />

and other individual privileges that the victorious political<br />

party can distribute to the faithful as incentives to work or as<br />

rewards for past services. The jobs, construction contracts, and<br />

licenses and other sorts of small chunks of government resources<br />

are a small part of the resources available as patronage<br />

(distributive policy) <strong>by</strong> government. The importance of patronage<br />

as a category of policy, or use of the state, can best be<br />

conveyed <strong>by</strong> identifying the practice that gave patronage its<br />

name: The feudal lord was patron to the vassals and serfs who<br />

occupied the lord's or baron's or monarch's domain, and these<br />

resources were distributed to each dependent individual on a<br />

personal, individualized basis, in return for services, loyalty,<br />

and reputation for the goodness of the chieftain. The "patron of<br />

the arts" is one of the derivations, seen in the dowager lady or<br />

retired philanthropist who distributes his or her resources on a<br />

personal basis to deserving artists, performers or other<br />

claimants. It is this subdivision of resources and their<br />

distribution on an individualized, personal basis that defines<br />

the character of patronage historically and the character of<br />

"distributive policy" in the logical scheme of Table 2.<br />

Table 2 places this one category in the context of other<br />

possible categories of policy, defined logically on the basis of<br />

my own conceptualization of the different types of coercion, or<br />

"uses of government." Regulatory policy already introduced, is


-9-<br />

also implemented on an individualized basis (see upper axis), but<br />

in this case the resources and incentives are not what is being<br />

distributed but actually obligations, mainly in the form of rules<br />

limiting and restricting individual conduct. Regulatory policy<br />

obviously establishes a relationship between citizen and<br />

government far different from the relationship prevailing under<br />

conditions of patronage policy. That is, each is a different way<br />

of using government, and therefore each creates the conditions<br />

for a very different kind of politics. This is the basis for a<br />

principle guiding my analysis of policy for the past 30 and more<br />

years: Policies cause politics.<br />

Two other categories, redistributive and constituent,<br />

complete the matrix and exhaust the types of policy governments<br />

can produce and the types of politics flowing therefrom. It is<br />

important also to note that this means political systems are not<br />

comprised of a single "political process" but are comprised of at<br />

least four different political processes, each with its own power<br />

structure and political behavior patterns among participants.<br />

The four boxes containing the four types of public policy are<br />

defined <strong>by</strong> the two major axes: policies are characterized <strong>by</strong><br />

whether the "likelihood of coercion" is remote or immediate (or<br />

indirect versus direct). This readily distinguishes the<br />

distributive or patronage policy from the regulatory policy, as<br />

shown in the two respective boxes. The second axis looks at<br />

policy in terms of whether the policy seeks to influence conduct


-10-<br />

<strong>by</strong> working on or through individuals or whether it seeks to<br />

influence conduct <strong>by</strong> manipulating the environment of that conduct<br />

or the conditions of its exercise. (Think of micro v. macro.)<br />

For example, on this axis distributive and regulatory policies<br />

are in the same dimension -- because both work through the<br />

individual (through individual incentives or through individual<br />

obligations). The "redistributive" policies can be just as<br />

coercive as the regulatory, but a change in the tax structure or<br />

a slight increase or cut in interest rates can seriously alter<br />

conduct <strong>by</strong> altering the conditions of that conduct without ever<br />

having to recognize or find out the identity of any individual on<br />

whom the impact is influential. Likewise, the creation of new<br />

budgeting methods or central purchasing, or laws having to do<br />

with elections or with the re-division of powers among<br />

institutions or Branches, are important policies but they are<br />

policies concerned with the internal workings of government and<br />

how these reforms create new environments for citizens. Then the<br />

linkage from these categories of policy to the most likely<br />

political process patterns are visualized on Diagram 2 <strong>by</strong> the<br />

lines running across the matrix to illustrative adjectives<br />

outside the matrix.<br />

This will be the context and source of criteria for<br />

examining and exploring the politics of infrastructure policy.<br />

My hope also is that they will help provide a basis for making<br />

normative judgments and actual policy recommendations.


-11-<br />

THE POLITICS OF <strong>INFRASTRUCTURE</strong> POLICY<br />

Some Case Studies<br />

New Haven: It's Not WHO GOVERNS?, Stupid; It's WHAT GOVERNS?<br />

Robert Dahl's classic study of New Haven, Who Governs?, was<br />

virtually the birth of the empirically-grounded pluralist theory<br />

of politics in America. Pluralist theory describes a special<br />

form of democracy, not directly of the people but one in which<br />

power is kept open and relatively decentralized <strong>by</strong> competition<br />

and bargaining among leaders, especially leaders of groups,<br />

making for multiple elites, based in pluralities of independent<br />

power centers or "nuclei." Governments were conducted, policies<br />

got made, and political equilibrium of sorts was maintained<br />

through bargaining. And those bargains between major private<br />

interest groups and other qualified players and public officials<br />

were formally inscribed as the public policies that were more<br />

likely to serve the public interest than any other realistic<br />

alternative. (This is directly inspired <strong>by</strong> the "invisible hand"<br />

dynamic of classical economics.) Dahl found the motherlode of<br />

pluralist political theory in the actual practices of the city of<br />

New Haven and the policies of urban development and redevelopment<br />

<strong>by</strong> carefully studying them for several years during<br />

the height of federal aid to urban infrastructure in the 1950s.<br />

By the mid-60s, New Haven had spend $790.25 in federal funds


-12-<br />

per capita on urban redevelopment, compared to the average for<br />

all cities of $453.51 [Wolfinger, The Politics of Progress, 1974,<br />

p. 195]. And the energy of its progress and the placement<br />

decisions in New Haven were being made <strong>by</strong> a plurastic process<br />

centered on the mayor. All this is well-documented <strong>by</strong> books and<br />

articles arising out of the best-studied city in America. But<br />

the bomb that started all this came not from within the city at<br />

all ("as a political system") but from a single decision made <strong>by</strong><br />

the lob<strong>by</strong>ing efforts of the mayor of New Haven and the governor<br />

of Connecticut, concentrating on the federal highway authorities<br />

and their Connecticut congressional delegation to add one exit<br />

off the new Interstate Highway 95. It came off just adjacent to<br />

an interchange already planned and in construction, and it was<br />

designed and built to run directly through the dead center of<br />

downtown New Haven, ending abruptly at a dead end intersection<br />

with a normal cross-street just a few blocks beyond the downtown.<br />

Why? Because the interchange ran through and wiped out the<br />

worst slum in the city, a neighborhood of dilapidated, low-rent<br />

flats and shops sprawled out between Yale University/New Haven<br />

Common on the one side and Grace-New Haven/Yale University<br />

Hospital on the other.<br />

Leaving aside the wisdom of that particular piece of<br />

infrastructure, its role in driving the New Haven re-development<br />

story for its decade as the most admired as well as the most<br />

studied city bring severe doubt on the whole theory and practice


-13-<br />

of pluralism in cities. The whole story of New Haven redevelopment<br />

could be re-told as a story of "national power<br />

structure" with cities as dependent units, far from the<br />

autonomous political systems <strong>by</strong> which they are usually<br />

characterized.<br />

This is not offered as a reversal or disconfirmation of<br />

Dahl's pluralistic heaven, but an amendment: When public works<br />

programs (and other programs too, but especially public works)<br />

are devolved from national or state governments, leaving<br />

discretion in the hands of city officials as to how to implement<br />

the programs and use the grants-in-aid money, the officials can<br />

build coalitions around these resources to carry out local plans<br />

and objectives they already had but didn't otherwise have the<br />

means. Two important points need to be added here. First,<br />

cities are inherently conservative -- in the sense that their<br />

obligations under state "police power" are "to maintain the<br />

health, safety and morals of the community," largely through<br />

keeping different classes, races and ethnic groups apart from<br />

each other. Second, the use of development money and discretion<br />

devolved from above is, in consequence, conservative.<br />

Conservatives are the best planners because their plans are for<br />

maintenance and conservation of existing social values and social<br />

structures, not, as with liberals, for their alteration. This<br />

constitutes Lesson #1, or the moral, of the story: When you<br />

commit to a piece of public works, especially if it is


-14-<br />

infrastructure (having a strong paradigmatic element) you have to<br />

have a social as well as a construction plan -- or someone else,<br />

unauthorized, will use the resources to make their own social<br />

plan, usually contrary to the one the planners would have had if<br />

they had developed one.<br />

This goes well beyond New Haven. All we have to do is look<br />

at the typical big city, as well as the middle size one. For<br />

example, the arterial highways in and around Chicago, built also<br />

in the 1950s and 60s, were definitely the engine for much of<br />

urban re-development in that city, which came to be called "Negro<br />

removal," "slum renewal," and "white and black, shoulder to<br />

shoulder, again the working classes." Nationally financed Dan<br />

Ryan Expressway (I-90 and I-94) plus the state-financed<br />

University of Illinois/Chicago campus, shoulder to shoulder,<br />

wiped out Chicago's largest downtown slum, the Maxwell Street<br />

slum. The University of Illinois/Chicago campus is called "the<br />

circle campus" because it was built on lands acquired and cleared<br />

in a stretch far beyond the gigantic interchange itself,<br />

comprised of concentric circles where north-bound Ryan meets<br />

west-bound I-290 (the Eisenhower Expressway). Another East-West<br />

connector had been planned to cut across one of the largest black<br />

neighborhoods in Chicago -- south of 63rd Street, Woodlawn,<br />

bordering on the University of Chicago; but <strong>by</strong> the 1960s, when<br />

construction and removal were to begin, the all-black Woodlawn<br />

Organization had developed sufficient strength and popular


-15-<br />

support to block it. Chicago is more segregated along race and<br />

class lines after the urban re-development/Interstate Highway era<br />

than before.<br />

Iron City: Another Look at Why Conservatives Make the Best<br />

Planners<br />

Iron City is a middle-size southern industrial city, near<br />

Birmingham and a small clone of Birmingham. 1<br />

What happened to<br />

infrastructure there happened almost everywhere else, but it is<br />

easier to see and to document in a smaller city, especially one<br />

that was so explicit about its own plan for how it would use the<br />

resources it would get from federal programs involving grants-inaid<br />

for urban infrastructure.<br />

In 1950, 20 percent of Iron City's population was black,<br />

but, unlike northern cities, blacks did not live in those<br />

concentrated neighborhoods that came to be called black ghettos.<br />

Like most southern cities, mainly because of slow general growth<br />

and slow and steady black immigration from near<strong>by</strong> rural areas,<br />

and particularly because so many, especially the women, worked as<br />

domestic servants in white households (before the universality of<br />

the automobile), white neighborhoods were interlarded with black.<br />

"Close quarters" it was often called. This was altogether<br />

stable and comfortable until the whole system of legal<br />

1 This account is drawn entirely from <strong>Lowi</strong>, The End of<br />

Liberalism, 1969, revisited 1979.


-16-<br />

segregation came into crisis, and then it became clear to the<br />

local elites that there would be no possible way Iron City could<br />

keep its public schools racially segregated <strong>by</strong> drawing school<br />

district lines that would pass judicial review or administrative<br />

review <strong>by</strong> the grant givers. The local planners were visionary in<br />

this, because they stepped into the crisis <strong>by</strong> forming the Iron<br />

City Planning Commission in 1951, and <strong>by</strong> 1952 the Commission had<br />

a handsome master plan, in full color, with transparent overlays<br />

and all the fancy design that mark professional planning. It<br />

laid out quite explicitly a five-point plan. (1) An all black<br />

neighborhood but with too small a population to warrant proper<br />

recreational, school or social services. (2) An all black<br />

neighborhood also with blighted and substandard housing but<br />

occupied <strong>by</strong> people not eligible for relocation in public housing<br />

or who personally preferred single-family homes. (3) An area<br />

also of "blighted and depreciating" housing but "growing as the<br />

focal point of Negro life." (4) An all black neighborhood<br />

sparsely filled <strong>by</strong> shacks with outside toilets but strung along<br />

the river on prime property slated for civic development. It<br />

happened also that #1 was located just behind the white<br />

neighborhood with the highest assess valued white housing and<br />

also abutting the largest all-white junior high school. Area<br />

designated #2 was located directly behind the central (white)<br />

high school. Area #3 was an all-black neighborhood, sparsely<br />

filled <strong>by</strong> shacks with outside toilets but strung along the river


-17-<br />

on property designated as prime property slated for civic<br />

development. Area #4 was "across the tracks;" it was the largest<br />

all-black neighborhood and also "blighted and depreciated" but<br />

was "growing as the focal point of Negro life." It happened also<br />

to be located next to the one all-black high school, junior high<br />

school and primary school.<br />

Area #1 was completely "urban renewed." A regular street<br />

plan replaced the dead-end alleys, and middle-class single-family<br />

homes replaced the shacks. This project more than met the<br />

planning criteria of federal urban policy, inasmuch as slums were<br />

cleared and a very significant amount of property was returned to<br />

the city tax base. The increased white population in the new<br />

area was accommodated <strong>by</strong> the expansion of the next-door junior<br />

high school and the addition of an elementary school with new<br />

playgrounds. Urban re-development and community facilities<br />

money.<br />

Area #2, directly behind the Central High School, was wiped<br />

out and replaced <strong>by</strong> public housing, all-white. Area #4 was also<br />

completely wiped out; part of the cleared land became the site<br />

for the new city hall and city jail, beautifully overlooking the<br />

river, and the rest was landscaped for "city beautiful." The<br />

community facilities money. Area #3 did indeed expand as "the<br />

focal point of Negro life," with public housing and with singlefamily<br />

homes financed <strong>by</strong> federal public housing grants-in-aid and<br />

federal urban re-development grants-in-aid keeping the cost of


-18-<br />

single-family homes and duplexes at rock bottom prices.<br />

Thus, the apartheid plan was a complete success. Iron City<br />

had its ghetto and the almost complete racial segregation of the<br />

population. And it was all done legally, explicitly, and with<br />

federal assistance. In fact it had not been possible without<br />

federal assistance. Between 1957 and 1961, when the plan was<br />

virtually complete, federal grants-in-aid came to almost exactly<br />

20 percent of Iron City's annual government budget. And this<br />

does not count an undetermined amount of federal highway<br />

assistance that had contributed to the removal of smaller and<br />

separated black neighborhoods that were not part of the original<br />

Iron City plan. It also does not count FHA and VA private<br />

financing for the lovely homes built in Area #1 or some of the<br />

homes built in the all-black area. It does count the building of<br />

the new all-black auditorium and the church that had been picked<br />

up from Area #1 and moved, with the black population, over to<br />

Area #3 to join the other focal points of Negro life.<br />

Moral to the story: If you want to be sure your city plan<br />

is a success, use the secondary and tertiary effects of<br />

infrastructure, and be sure there is plenty of money outside the<br />

local tax base.<br />

Death of a Village: Do Pure Scientists Make Good Planners?<br />

This story took place in the 1960s, and at that time we<br />

looked at it as an intimation of the future, because it involved


-19-<br />

pure scientists as planners and builders. It was a look at the<br />

future because more and more scientists were going to be<br />

involved, either as builders and planners themselves or as<br />

analysts and consultants to builders who would increasingly need<br />

a research and analysis base for any large project, especially<br />

one that was likely to be a paradigmatic, infrastructure project.<br />

It was clear <strong>by</strong> the time we finished the research and writing<br />

for the book that we were already living our future. Thirty<br />

years and a second edition have passed since then, and we are<br />

certainly living our future now. 2<br />

The National Accelerator<br />

Laboratory, FermiLab is located on 6800-acre site, 30 miles due<br />

west of the center of Chicago on what used to be 71 farms<br />

occupied <strong>by</strong> 71 farm families. It was, until recent years, the<br />

world's largest atom smasher, and it was a proud and comfortable<br />

location in DuPage County, one of America's most prosperous<br />

counties, near wealthy suburbs and also near mansion and horse<br />

country where, at least until recently, people still got together<br />

for fox hunts.<br />

Our story begins in 1959, when one farm owner decided to<br />

sell her 420-acre farm to a developer, who immediately sought<br />

permits from the county to subdivide the property and build 100<br />

low-cost single family homes at prices accessible to working-<br />

2 This account is based entirely on <strong>Lowi</strong> et al., Poliscide --<br />

Big Government, Big Science, Lilliputian Politics (Macmillan,<br />

1976; 2nd ed., University Press of America, 1990).


-20-<br />

class people. All hell broke loose. This was seen as a tipping<br />

point, because the ba<strong>by</strong> boom growth was in this direction, and<br />

many other farmers were caught in a vise: unable to make a<br />

living without an outside job to supplement farm income, and<br />

suffering a rate of taxation at suburban rather open-country<br />

levels. Every device available to local government was used to<br />

stop the developer, who was already beginning to advertise the<br />

new village of Weston, Illinois, for the good, solid working<br />

classes. Following some court victories, and the meeting of the<br />

stiff county criteria for access roads, plumbing and sewerage,<br />

construction codes, etc., the Weston developers found themselves<br />

unable to beat the conspiracy of banks and other private<br />

interests to block local financing. The developer persevered,<br />

finding outside financing -- which turned out to be Mafia money,<br />

but this only came out later, with the publication of our book.<br />

In order to meet the local construction criteria, each<br />

Weston home would have to be marketed at $30,000-plus, far above<br />

working-class capacity in 1959. 3<br />

But the county planner knew<br />

3 And there was still another impediment that would push the<br />

Weston home financing upwards: The Federal Housing Administration<br />

(FHA) and the Veterans Administration (VA) officials refused to<br />

provide insured mortgages for Weston homeowners. This is<br />

consistent with FHA and VA policy, first to cooperate with local<br />

authorities, and second, to refuse to insure home investments in<br />

urban slums. Another impediment was the refusal that the county<br />

got from the U.S. Post Office to make house-to-house delivery to<br />

the Weston homes, thus requiring that nearly a hundred mailboxes<br />

would be strung along the county highway, several hundred feet<br />

from the entrance to the village.


-21-<br />

that, once Weston got its incorporation, it would have power to<br />

carve 3 60-foot lots out of each pair of 90-foot lots, enabling<br />

the developers to offer Weston homes well below the regulated<br />

county housing market.<br />

By 1965, Weston was an operating community, with almost all<br />

of their houses occupied and fully financed. It appeared that<br />

the private developers had beaten the gigantic DuPage county<br />

government, despite all of its own formidable authority and<br />

despite the collateral help it had gotten in conspiracy with<br />

local private developers, banks, gentlemen farmers, and the like.<br />

But help was on the way. The Atomic Energy Commission (AEC) was<br />

engaged in a nationwide search for the site for what was to be<br />

the world's largest atom smasher. Immediately the AEC was<br />

deluged with over 200 proposals from 46 states, and the<br />

competition was intense, because the stakes were high: The 200-<br />

billion electronvolt (BeV) accelerator would be a highly<br />

desirable "clean industry," whose construction would cost over $1<br />

billion, whose operating needs would lead to the employment of an<br />

indeterminate but very large number of quality workers in stable,<br />

quality jobs -- not to count the large number of resident<br />

scientists and technicians, many of whom were expected to live in<br />

that vicinity.<br />

On December 15, 1966, Chicagoans learned they would soon be<br />

the proud neighbor of the world's largest atom smasher. It was<br />

to be located virtually on top of the village of Weston, whose


-22-<br />

inhabitants had been promised that their homes would be picked up<br />

bodily and moved to a near<strong>by</strong> location and would become the<br />

"service city" for the science installation. The mayor even<br />

arranged for the construction of an enormous billboard sign<br />

pointing attention to Weston, the country's first "atomic<br />

village." Almost exactly 20 months after the announcement that<br />

the Weston site could be selected <strong>by</strong> the AEC, no legal trace of<br />

the village or the farms remained. National Accelerator<br />

Laboratory (NAL) personnel occupied the village homes and the<br />

farmhouses while supervising construction of the underground<br />

ring, two miles in diameter. This was the village that was to<br />

have been moved with all of its occupants intact. And it was to<br />

be moved because the villagers had been told that the accelerator<br />

ring, for geological reasons, would have to be put directly on<br />

top of the village itself.<br />

This was a conspiracy to beat all conspiracies. It was a<br />

conspiracy with DuPage county officials at the center, with the<br />

State of Illinois Department of Business and Economic Development<br />

(DBED) as a key ax-wielder, with Mayor Daley's political troops<br />

in Chicago dealing directly with Chicago banks, with Chicago and<br />

county newspapers agreeing to have their real estate editors<br />

refuse advertisements promoting the Weston development, and<br />

several agencies of the U.S. national government, whose enormous<br />

largess for "science infrastructure" was being made available at<br />

the discretion of the local authorities on the scene.


-23-<br />

What is even more significant is the fact that the<br />

scientists -- both the visionary designers of the accelerator,<br />

including Cornell's most famous Robert Wilson -- and the science<br />

planners at AEC and at the National Academy of Science, and all<br />

the other sciences in the mid-West who had sought so hard to<br />

bring the great accelerator there instead of losing out once<br />

again to the East Coast or the West Coast scientists -- all of<br />

these people, one and together, singly and collectively, were<br />

totally ignorant of the secondary and tertiary uses to which the<br />

accelerator opportunity was being put. Judging from scores of<br />

interviews prior to publication, and almost as many reactions to<br />

our book when it was sent directly to a great number of the<br />

participants, the scientists never knew what hit them. Professor<br />

Robert Wilson, who had years earlier proposed a much cheaper<br />

alternative that could meet most of the needs of the giant atom<br />

smasher was, as a consequence, made the designer, supervisor and<br />

first director of FermiLab. And this very humane, very<br />

humanistic scientist-poet not only provided for the building of<br />

the accelerator at the lowest possible cost, but also engaged in<br />

a most enlightened hiring policy, in terms of race as well as<br />

class. And since the county had granted the NAL more than twice<br />

as much land as the original specifications required (6800<br />

instead of 3,000 acres, in order to include all the likely farms<br />

that would tip over into development), Dr. Wilson dedicated<br />

several acres of the surplus property to the construction of a


-24-<br />

model farm to be run <strong>by</strong> "Farmer Bob," a farm manager with a<br />

Ph.D., to help preserve "the only vestige of rural living in this<br />

area ...." They even installed a small herd of buffalo on the<br />

land that had been cleared from every vestige of natural rural<br />

life.<br />

Moral to the story: Scientists, just like highway<br />

developers, tend to be so project-oriented that they say to local<br />

planners, in effect, "Give us our toy, but don't tell us how you<br />

got it." When the center doesn't plan, the periphery will,<br />

usually with the imposition of local values, no matter how far<br />

removed they are from central values. When central planners<br />

plan, they are socialists. When local planners plan, they are<br />

"city fathers." You cannot have a strategic public work, any<br />

public work, without a plan. If you don't make the plan,<br />

somebody else will. With your dough.<br />

Back to the Twelfth Century: International Airports, the Modern<br />

Cathedrals<br />

[In the interest of time and space, this case will be added<br />

after the Conference, for the final draft.]<br />

REFLECTIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS<br />

My reflections have been anticipated in the moral at the end<br />

of each of the cases. By the very nature of public works<br />

policies -- especially infrastructure policies, if the


-25-<br />

paradigmatic element is understood to be present -- there will be<br />

secondary and tertiary effects. These will always be social and<br />

political as well as economic and technical. And the social and<br />

political will be the most extensive and will involve the largest<br />

range of "unanticipated consequences." Infrastructure -- again<br />

<strong>by</strong> its very nature -- will always be inhabited <strong>by</strong> local<br />

interests, and local interests will be far more intensely pursued<br />

than the regional, national, or other broader "public interests."<br />

Table 2 is reproduced from Poliscide and, as in the book, it<br />

is designed to be generalizable in large part to all large public<br />

works projects, especially those involving all three levels of<br />

government in the federal system. In fact, the larger the scale<br />

and cost of a public works project, the more likely all the<br />

levels of government in the federal system will be involved, with<br />

greater money provided from above and more discretion in<br />

implementation devolved downward. That is, the greater the<br />

distance from the money provider, the more discretion in the<br />

hands of the money distributor. The names of the players will<br />

not be the same as those on Table 2, but the roles and the<br />

perspectives flowing from each role remain about the same.<br />

Now back to the policy scheme introduced earlier. Putting<br />

this together within the federal system, we are well-advised to<br />

attach a label to all public works projects: Beware: This<br />

project can be harmful to your health. Public works policies<br />

make resources available on a highly disaggregable basis. That


-26-<br />

is, they can be subdivided into units and the units can be<br />

exchanged, traded and cumulated in a relatively fluid,<br />

individualized basis. Picture once again the pork barrel. But<br />

more. As observed earlier, this kind of policy uses government<br />

power in a promotional way, with a minimum of coercion and<br />

therefore produces a special relationship between government and<br />

citizen. This facilitates in turn a special kind of political<br />

process, one in which a very special kind of coalition prevails:<br />

logrolling. Logrolling is a vulgar, slang term for one of the<br />

fundamental types of political relationship. Logrolling can be<br />

defined as an agreement of mutual support between two or more<br />

people who have absolutely nothing in common -- except the<br />

agreement of mutual support. In contrast, coalitions in the<br />

struggle for regulatory policy are the classic compromise-type<br />

coalition in which all participants must make their respective<br />

interests known and then examine each others' interests,<br />

softening their respective demands until genuine accommodations<br />

are reached. Coalitions for redistributive policy also require<br />

mutual knowledge but demand broader knowledge than material<br />

interest -- reaching levels of broad social class, socio-economic<br />

principle, and, in a word, ideology.<br />

Logrolling, the only coalition type concerning us here, is<br />

the easiest to form and in many ways the most stable, because<br />

participants say to each other, in effect, "You support me on X<br />

and I'll support you on any issue -- don't tell me about it; just


-27-<br />

tell me when and how to support you." John Ferejohn, in his<br />

important book-length study of the politics of "pork barrel<br />

policies," written many years after my original characterization,<br />

emphasizes the same thing:<br />

If a bill calling for improvements in a<br />

single district is put [forward], it will not<br />

pass, since all the districts must pay and<br />

only one will benefit. Consequently, only an<br />

omnibus bill proposing expenditures in at<br />

least a majority of the districts has a<br />

chance of passage. 4<br />

But Ferejohn limits his observation to single pieces of<br />

traditional "rivers and harbors" type legislation (omnibus) in<br />

which dozens of individual projects are added up until a majority<br />

of districts are represented. But logrolling coalitions are also<br />

formed across several different projects in several different<br />

bills in the same session of the legislature or in later<br />

sessions, where payoffs of mutual support are made at later<br />

times. In fact, it is one of the major functions of the parties,<br />

or party leaders, to keep records of logrolls and to help<br />

facilitate later payoffs.<br />

Now I move to the immediate and highly predictable<br />

consequences of this kind of coalition: The projects and other<br />

items involved in the logrolling coalition are units of exchange<br />

that are intensely concentrated on the projects themselves and on<br />

the mutual assistance agreed upon. Little if any room is left<br />

4 John Ferejohn, Pork Barrel Politics, full citation to be<br />

provided.


-28-<br />

for considerations of secondary and tertiary effects and for<br />

"public goods" beyond the items involved in the transactions,<br />

because these introduce other interests and ideologies that<br />

interfere with logrolling. Logrolling coalitions are almost on<br />

principle antagonistic to larger public goods (say, in the realm<br />

of regulatory policy or redistributive policy) because the types<br />

of coalitions involved in those public goods tend to be<br />

incompatible with logrolling coalitions.<br />

Now add the other tendency identified above, that in our<br />

federal system greater discretion is devolved to the local<br />

implementing agencies because greater geographic and juridical<br />

distances are involved due to the fact that more intervening<br />

layers of delegation are involved. Now, any type of policy --<br />

distributive (patronage), regulatory, or redistributive -- that<br />

leaves maximum discretion to the local implementors must leave<br />

open, virtually absent, the guidelines and standards that are<br />

supposed to keep all implementors relatively close to the law's<br />

original intent. In other words, maximum discretion equals<br />

minimum rule of law. When the local implementors have this<br />

degree of discretion, they can convert almost any law, program,<br />

project into something close to patronage and therefore to<br />

logrolling coalitions, because they can disaggregate the policy<br />

into units of decision, and therefore units of logrolling in a<br />

logrolling coalition. Go back to Diagram 1 or Diagram 2 and draw<br />

a broad, curving arrow through all four boxes, starting with the


-29-<br />

regulation box and curving round to end with the distributive (or<br />

patronage) policy box. I call this the "entropic tendency" in<br />

politics, the tendency of any and all types of politics to<br />

deteriorate or drain downward toward the logrolling type of<br />

political process that prevails in the distributive or patronage<br />

policy category.<br />

To reveal the nature and dynamics of this peculiar type of<br />

coalition politics is not only to reveal the risk, indeed the<br />

danger, to society of the highly compartmentalized commitment to<br />

public works projects merely based on a positive cost-benefit<br />

analysis. It also provides some insight into ways we may combat<br />

the danger and have our infrastructure without the undue social<br />

costs and other unanticipated consequences we always seem to have<br />

to endure. We jolly well need a large proportion of the public<br />

works projects proposed. For the sake of argument, our society<br />

may well need all the infrastructure projects proposed. Yet, we<br />

cannot outlaw the narrow-minded logrolling coalitions that form<br />

in support of these projects and militate against broader<br />

considerations of social good. And we cannot preach our way out<br />

<strong>by</strong> stressing the goodness of the broader, ecology or justice<br />

oriented considerations. The logrolling coalition will always<br />

rollover those humane and philanthropic sentiments. We have to<br />

find a way out that is ruggedly equivalent to the way in,<br />

fighting fire with fire.<br />

First, it seems to me we have to recognize immediately that


-30-<br />

cost-benefit approaches are a trap. In the hands of projectoriented<br />

interests and their technologist consultants, it is a<br />

means of foreclosing debate, not a route toward enlightened<br />

policy. We can move the project away from the project mentality<br />

only <strong>by</strong> requiring that every project embody a genuine and clear<br />

policy -- rule of law -- to govern it. If the origin and the<br />

authorization and financing (all or part) are national, the<br />

policy must also be national. (If Americans no longer want a<br />

national government or trust a national government, then let the<br />

locals finance and construct their own highways and segregate<br />

their own populations without federal help.) And the policy<br />

governing the project must be a rule of law carefully oriented<br />

toward governing the secondary and tertiary (and broader<br />

spillover) effects of the project. We must require this not only<br />

because real policies embodying real rules of law are necessary<br />

if we are ever to improve our chances to attain the goals of<br />

sustainable development and social equality. Rules of law are<br />

necessary because we are supposed to be a constitutional<br />

democracy. Every public works project is freighted with social<br />

policy. The question is not whether public works should embody a<br />

social policy but who shall make the policy -- the law makers or<br />

the local elites. When project designers admit that they should<br />

be governed <strong>by</strong> the social policies of higher political<br />

authorities, they are doing more than behaving responsibly toward<br />

their positions. They are also setting limits on the extent to


-31-<br />

which local project recipients can abuse, misuse and misdirect<br />

these resources. This involves recognition that policy has to be<br />

a standard of responsible conduct for local authorities that are<br />

above and beyond their own immediate manipulation.<br />

There is still another advantage to attaching explicit<br />

social policies to each and every public works project. The<br />

larger policy works as a limit on the designers and the<br />

congressional budget makers themselves. The introduction of a<br />

larger social policy changes immediately the type of political<br />

process involved, and that is precisely the best way out of the<br />

danger of project-oriented decision making. This is the only way<br />

to put an end to such policy barons as Bud Shuster, chairman of<br />

the House Committee on Transportation and Infrastructure, who has<br />

put his congressional district under about six feet of concrete.<br />

Exit: the institutionalization of second thoughts:<br />

Public works projects, even including important<br />

infrastructure projects, are distinguished <strong>by</strong> decisions that<br />

embody no rule of conduct, because when each unit is discreet and<br />

treated discreetly, this is tantamount to saying that no rule or<br />

condition binds any of the recipients. It does not matter much<br />

whether the decision makers are political hacks, career<br />

bureaucrats, politically appointed lawyers, members of Congress,<br />

or high-energy physicists. Once the patronage policy process is<br />

set in train, the behavior series is predictable. On the other<br />

hand, a drastic and immediate change can be made in the decision


-32-<br />

series and the political process <strong>by</strong> the introduction of an<br />

important public policy that guides and sets limits on the goals<br />

and secondary and tertiary effects of the project. For example,<br />

when some Senators from some northeastern states sought to apply<br />

civil rights considerations to the selection of the national<br />

accelerator site, Illinois Senator Everett Dirksen replied:<br />

There are 20 states that have open occupancy<br />

laws. There are 30 states that have no such<br />

laws. If Congress in its wisdom undertakes<br />

at any time to draw that line [applying a<br />

civil rights condition to a specific public<br />

works project], then I want to say ... that<br />

line is going to be firmly drawn, and it is<br />

going to be equally firmly held.<br />

Since no one at that time wanted advances in civil rights badly<br />

enough to put an end to the pork barrel process, they withdrew<br />

their efforts to impose a civil rights policy on the accelerator.<br />

But it is nevertheless extremely important to set up a process<br />

where<strong>by</strong> law makers are forced to be explicit about the absence of<br />

policies governing projects and the fact that policies ought to<br />

govern selected aspects of the impact of the project. And if law<br />

makers recognized honestly that the absence of a governing rule<br />

established <strong>by</strong> them will simply leave open the opportunity for<br />

local units to make their own governing policies, perhaps they<br />

will be more determined to establish their own policies rather<br />

than leave all that to the locals.<br />

The public works process is certainly one of the worst<br />

processes in the American system from almost any and every


-33-<br />

perspective. It is bad in terms of the absence of the rule of<br />

law. It is bad in terms of the narrowness with which decision<br />

makers can allocate public resources. And it is measurably the<br />

worst to the extent that it enables locals to make social<br />

policies that would be definitively rejected if those policies<br />

were put before the public as a referendum.<br />

A worthy and pregnant conclusion is the simple proposition<br />

that it is the rule that makes the difference. When a policy is<br />

attached to a project, the "public works political process" is<br />

immediately transformed. The transformed process is a better one<br />

because it requires more "search behavior" on the part of the<br />

specialized agencies, search behavior beyond the immediateness of<br />

the project. It imposes -- without of course guaranteeing -- a<br />

more regular and nationally consistent consideration of social<br />

issues. And it institutionalizes second thoughts. Let the<br />

technologies be decided <strong>by</strong> technological specialists. But give<br />

them an institution that provides them with the opportunity for<br />

second thoughts.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!