20.12.2013 Views

Economic Regulation - IATA

Economic Regulation - IATA

Economic Regulation - IATA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

expectations set by the regulator without full knowledge<br />

of the true cost base. In that case, it is appropriate to use<br />

the new, lower cost level as the base for the next review<br />

period. However, to encourage further performance<br />

improvements, the system should have some scope for<br />

allowing exceptional efficiency gains to be recognised<br />

and rewarded in future period.<br />

Potential rather than actual costs.<br />

The regulator needs to ensure that the profile for each<br />

regulatory period is based upon potential improvements<br />

rather than simply an extrapolation of trends in actual<br />

costs. Though a resource intensive process, the<br />

assessment of potential costs can provide significant<br />

efficiency benefits. If the system reverts to actual costs<br />

as the benchmark, the incentive for firms to minimise<br />

future costs is weakened.<br />

Appropriate cost-of-capital allowance.<br />

The cost-of-capital return allowed needs to be a true<br />

reflection of the financing costs of the firm. If the<br />

allowed return is greater than the actual cost-of-capital,<br />

it increases the incentive for firms to add to their capital<br />

base (the Aversch-Johnson effect) regardless of user<br />

needs, as it increases their profits. This effect has been<br />

seen in several UK utility sectors, where firms have used<br />

cheap debt (as interest rates fell) to boost their asset<br />

base 23 .<br />

As discussed in chapter 5, price-cap regulation, subject<br />

to adjustments to address the issues above, does offer a<br />

clear process for improving productive efficiency. It can<br />

also provide sufficient incentives for dynamic efficiency<br />

(see chapter 8) while supplementing alternative<br />

mechanisms to improve allocative efficiency where<br />

capacity is constrained (see below).<br />

BENCHMARKING<br />

Regular and accurate performance assessments are<br />

required to assess the progress made in delivering<br />

efficiency improvements and the potential for further<br />

gains. Though airports, ANSPs and their regulatory<br />

frameworks are heterogeneous – each with different<br />

objectives and challenges – there are common standards<br />

that allow for the benchmarking of performance.<br />

Benchmarking can be of benefit to the regulators<br />

themselves, allowing them to minimise the risk of<br />

regulatory failure and to share best practice. Chapter 4<br />

discussed how an international or regional forum can be<br />

developed for regulators (following the example of the<br />

gas and electricity sectors in the EU). This could assess<br />

the progress of governments in ensuring an appropriate<br />

regulatory framework is established as well as the<br />

outcomes for efficiency and investment delivered under<br />

each system.<br />

However, benchmarking is also of benefit at the individual<br />

airport and ANSP level, assessing how each performs<br />

across a range of criteria against a relevant peer group.<br />

These criteria can cover a range of cost and service<br />

quality indicators, reflecting the interaction between the<br />

two areas.<br />

<strong>IATA</strong> has developed a performance benchmarking model<br />

for major airports and ANSPs, from which it openly shares<br />

information during charges negotiations (see Annex B<br />

for further details).<br />

The model is based upon published information, with the<br />

requirement on airports and ANSPs to provide alternative<br />

evidence if they do not agree with the published figures.<br />

Other forms of regulation are less clear in their impact<br />

upon efficiency, with some potentially providing little<br />

incentive for improvement. However, all are typically less<br />

resource-intensive than price-cap regulation. Rate-ofreturn<br />

regulation contains little clear incentive for cost<br />

minimisation, with costs being reimbursed regardless<br />

of their level and this creates an incentive for excessive<br />

investment. Price monitoring requires competition, airline<br />

power or a credible threat in order for incentives for cost<br />

minimisation to exist, though experience has shown this<br />

typically not to be the case. Contract negotiations can<br />

provide clear targets for efficiency improvements and<br />

risk-sharing, though depend crucially on the willingness<br />

of both parties to enter into open and fair negotiations.<br />

23<br />

See OXERA, (May 2006), “The Future of Infrastructure <strong>Regulation</strong>”,<br />

Conference, London

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!