20.12.2013 Views

Economic Regulation - IATA

Economic Regulation - IATA

Economic Regulation - IATA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Republic of Ireland<br />

Price-cap regulation was initially established for the public<br />

sector airport operator, Aer Rianta, that operated Dublin,<br />

Cork and Shannon airports. Following the break-up of<br />

Aer Rianta in 2004, price-cap regulation concentrates<br />

only on the Dublin Airport Authority. Ireland shows that<br />

regulation can be both needed and beneficial for public<br />

sector airports, it isn’t just a requirement for privatised<br />

airports. In particular, it shows that a stable regulatory<br />

framework is beneficial in advance, rather than after, any<br />

eventual privatisation of the airports.<br />

The Commission for Aviation <strong>Regulation</strong> currently<br />

sets maximum levels of airport and aviation terminal<br />

services charges at Dublin Airport. The Commission is<br />

independent, but must comply with recommendations<br />

made by the government (similar to the ACCC and PC in<br />

Australia). Its statutory duties are to facilitate the efficient<br />

and economic development of the airport, to protect the<br />

reasonable interests of current and prospective users<br />

and to enable the airport to operate and develop in a<br />

sustainable and financially viable manner.<br />

The CAR uses a CPI-X price cap and a single-till system.<br />

It has been relatively successful in delivering efficiency<br />

improvements and minimising charges, with strong traffic<br />

growth and airport commercial revenues benefiting both<br />

the airport and airlines. However, as in the UK, the focus<br />

is now shifting towards the need for capital investment. In<br />

2005, the CAR determined charges at Dublin Airport for<br />

the period to 2009 with a CPI-4% price-cap. However,<br />

the further development of a major capital investment<br />

plan for Dublin airport since then has led the regulator to<br />

propose an interim review. The review would allow them<br />

to closely scrutinise the latest capital expenditure plans<br />

for the airport, allowing them and users to challenge the<br />

assumptions and estimates made by the airport. This<br />

demonstrates flexibility within the system to cope with<br />

major changes without removing underlying regulatory<br />

principles, but it must ensure that any interim review is<br />

seen as an exceptional case rather than an expectation<br />

in the event of any future shocks.<br />

Germany<br />

The privatisation of some airports in Germany, or even<br />

just a more commercial operating focus, has encouraged<br />

the introduction of some form of regulation. However, it<br />

has tended to be regional or airport specific (largely due<br />

to legal restrictions under Germany’s federal structure),<br />

with no national regulatory authority in place. In addition,<br />

where local regulators are established they are typically<br />

part of, rather than independent of, local governments<br />

– many of whom still have an ownership stake in the<br />

airport, creating potential conflicts of interest.<br />

Though regulation has been introduced it has taken<br />

different forms for different airports:<br />

Hamburg airport (price-cap).<br />

Hamburg airport has faced regulation since its partial<br />

privatisation in 2000, covering both a price-cap on charges<br />

and service quality targets. It is a dual-till CPI-X system,<br />

with X related to the projected growth in productivity.<br />

It prevents the airport from earning any windfall profits<br />

through a sliding scale of further reductions in charges<br />

based upon passenger growth beyond a trigger point. For<br />

example, the first regulatory period saw charges fixed at<br />

CPI-2%, but with further increases in X of 0.5% for every<br />

percentage point of traffic growth above 3%. If traffic<br />

growth is less than 3% there is no change to the CPI-<br />

2% formula. However, flexibility is built in to the system<br />

to cope with external shocks, with an agreed temporary<br />

abandonment of the sliding scale after 9/11 to allow the<br />

airport to recover faster from a sudden decrease in traffic.<br />

The system does not cover major investments, with each<br />

project subject to a separate public review.<br />

Düsseldorf airport (rate-of-return).<br />

The privatisation of Düsseldorf airport following a major<br />

fire in 1996 concentrated on restoring operations quickly<br />

rather than an appropriate regulatory structure. As such,<br />

regulation was based on a loose cost-plus principle.<br />

The cost-plus nature contains similar disadvantages in<br />

terms of weak efficiency incentives and over-investment<br />

as discussed above for US airports. It has also led to<br />

protracted legal battles between the airport and airlines<br />

over proposed charge increases, for example in 2000<br />

when a 7.1% increase in charges was granted by the<br />

local Government but was considered excessive by<br />

airlines.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!