20.12.2013 Views

Economic Regulation - IATA

Economic Regulation - IATA

Economic Regulation - IATA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

05 - <strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> 37<br />

has been set to reflect increases in the asset base as<br />

major new investment is undertaken. An RPI+X profile<br />

can also provide efficiency incentives though, of course,<br />

it still relies on the correct value of X being set.<br />

Price-cap regulation does have a strong track-record in<br />

terms of improving the efficiency of infrastructure assets.<br />

However, it does also encounter some practical problems<br />

that need to be addressed:<br />

Resource intensive.<br />

Price-cap regulatory reviews involve significant amounts<br />

of regulatory resource costs and time. In addition, the<br />

degree of complexity has increased over time as the<br />

objectives and practice of regulation have evolved. For<br />

example, in the UK the first review of BAA airports in<br />

1991 took 12 months, determining a simple value of X.<br />

The review in 2002 took 32 months, setting a value of<br />

X with six trigger points and a service quality scheme<br />

covering 12 different parameters.<br />

Regulatory game playing.<br />

The regulated company has an incentive to take<br />

advantage of asymmetrical information in order to provide<br />

inflated expenditure and investment forecasts and to<br />

convince the regulator of the need for higher returns and<br />

a higher price cap. In particular, in the two years prior to<br />

each review the regulated company can be more focused<br />

on responding to the regulator rather than to the needs<br />

of customers.<br />

It can become based on actual rather than<br />

efficient costs.<br />

As discussed above, in light of asymmetric information<br />

and the need to reset CPI-X on a periodic basis, pricecap<br />

regulation can converge in practice towards a rateof-return<br />

system if set on an actual rather than optimal<br />

level of costs. If, over time, the price cap starts or tends to<br />

resemble a cost-plus system, its ability to deliver ongoing<br />

incentives is reduced.<br />

An increase in volatility of profits<br />

for the regulated company.<br />

Setting price-caps across four to five year regulatory<br />

periods can also expose the regulated companies to<br />

volatility in profits, especially with regard to external<br />

shocks. However, a large part of this potential volatility<br />

should be welcomed, as it represents a more appropriate<br />

sharing of risks within the industry. Airlines and their<br />

users cannot be expected to face the full burden of any<br />

external shocks. It should also incentivise the regulated<br />

firm to improve its contingency planning and response.<br />

Nevertheless, in extreme cases, force majeure clauses or<br />

an interim review can be used. However, in order to protect<br />

regulatory credibility it must remain the exception rather<br />

than the expectation in the event of an external shock.<br />

A potential, though unlikely, barrier to investment.<br />

Price cap regulation and its periodic reviews are<br />

sometimes argued to act as a barrier to new investment.<br />

Regulated companies are argued to face uncertainty<br />

over whether the regulator will “capture” future efficiency<br />

gains from investment and are subsequently deterred.<br />

However, experience does not provide any clear evidence<br />

that this is the case in practice. Indeed, the information<br />

asymmetries on capital expenditure plans may actually<br />

encourage investment in order to boost returns, while<br />

investment may also be undertaken as an entry-deterring<br />

strategy against other airports 17 .<br />

However, while these problems exist, as discussed above<br />

and in other chapters, they are not insurmountable.<br />

An effective and flexible price-cap regulation system<br />

can still provide significant incentives to improve efficiency<br />

and service quality, while also improving consultation with<br />

airline customers on their operational and investment<br />

needs.<br />

There are costs involved in undertaking price-cap<br />

regulation. For example, in 2003 the New Zealand<br />

Commerce Minister found that “the direct costs of<br />

control (including both the regulators’ and market<br />

participants’ costs) for a single airport might be NZ$1.1-<br />

$2.2 million (US$ 0.75-1.5 million) in a review year, and<br />

NZ$0.5-$1.1 million (US$ 0.35-0.75 million) in other<br />

years. Over a five year period, with one review, this<br />

suggests an annual average of between NZ$0.62-$1.32<br />

million (US$ 0.43-0.9 million) per year at each airport” 18 .<br />

As such, it is not something to apply to every airport, but<br />

only to those with clear market power and where the<br />

potential benefits of regulation outweigh the costs of its<br />

implementation.<br />

17<br />

See Starkie, D (2004), “Testing the Regulatory Model: The expansion of Stansted Airport, in Fiscal Studies, vol.25, no.4.<br />

18<br />

See: http://www.med.govt.nz/templates/MultipageDocumentPage_10435.aspx

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!