20.12.2013 Views

Economic Regulation - IATA

Economic Regulation - IATA

Economic Regulation - IATA

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

04 - <strong>Economic</strong> <strong>Regulation</strong> 29<br />

A greater constraint on market power.<br />

By calculating allowable revenues on the basis of total<br />

airport costs (including capital costs), it ensures that airport<br />

operators earn a reasonable return on total assets, while<br />

preventing them from exploiting their market power. A<br />

dual-till system leads to the derivation of monopoly rents,<br />

with an over-recovery of costs as commercial revenues<br />

are maximised and kept in full and aeronautical costs are<br />

fully recovered from airline users.<br />

Practical to apply.<br />

Airport operators are free to recover costs through any<br />

charging structure they deem suitable. By contrast, under<br />

a dual-till system it is difficult, in practice, to allocate both<br />

investments and operating costs between aeronautical<br />

and non-aeronautical activities. To the extent that some<br />

of the judgements that have to be made are arbitrary,<br />

future disputes about cost allocation could harm relations<br />

between the airport and its users.<br />

No clear evidence that it acts as a barrier<br />

to investment.<br />

Single-till regulation can mean that charges are relatively<br />

low at capacity-constrained airports but, by itself, this<br />

does not produce a barrier to new investment. Indeed,<br />

other factors such as planning constraints are likely to<br />

have a larger impact on investment decisions 12 . Instead,<br />

the single-till increases the efficiency and attractiveness<br />

of airports and ensures that operators take into account<br />

the total, not partial, returns from new investment<br />

Investment and/or secondary slot-trading, not<br />

a dual-till system, better address congestion.<br />

Under the single-till, as traffic grows over time, increased<br />

retail profits would see the price cap set at a lower level in<br />

each review, even at congested airports. Therefore, it can<br />

lead to a situation where one of the busiest airports in the<br />

world has low and declining charges. However, higher<br />

demand volumes should provide a sufficient trigger for<br />

new investment decisions while other schemes, such as<br />

secondary slot-trading, may help to ease congestion in<br />

the short-term. There is no clear evidence that a dual-till<br />

system would automatically relieve congestion, instead it<br />

would provide greater monopoly rents to the airport.<br />

Nevertheless, dual-till regulation has been adopted<br />

in some countries. Indeed, the objectives of some<br />

governments to maximise revenue from the lease or<br />

sale of airport infrastructure often results in their support<br />

for the dual till. The outcome often observed under the<br />

dual till system is consistent with some degree of overrecovery<br />

of costs.<br />

A dual-till system may encourage greater dynamic<br />

efficiency in the provision of non-aeronautical services,<br />

but this can sometimes create the risk of lower service<br />

quality standards on the aeronautical side. For example,<br />

if an airport devotes too much space to commercial<br />

activities it can negatively impact upon the speed and<br />

comfort of passengers using the terminal.<br />

It can also negatively impact on allocative efficiency, as<br />

price sensitive airline customers are deterred by higher<br />

fares as a result of higher user charges (i.e. airline load<br />

factors are reduced).<br />

In such cases, the user charges will be higher than<br />

otherwise, so it is important that the regulatory framework<br />

contains sufficient credibility to pursue greater efficiency<br />

and productivity from airports, with mechanisms to share<br />

improvements with users and to punish poor performance.<br />

It is not sufficient to believe that the dual-till approach acts<br />

as an effective incentive by providing ‘something to lose’<br />

(i.e. by a return to single-till in the future), as experience<br />

in Australia and elsewhere has shown that these threats<br />

are often not viewed credibly.<br />

If a dual till is adopted, the airport operator must commit<br />

to a service charter that sets out the general performance<br />

principles, criteria and measures to be adopted to ensure<br />

that no deterioration of service standards occur. As airlines<br />

deliver customers to airports, a dual-till framework could<br />

also provide an option for airlines to invest (e.g. take an<br />

equity stake) in non-aeronautical investments to ensure<br />

that they are appropriate for user needs and to share the<br />

risks and rewards.<br />

12<br />

See D. Starkie, “Investment Incentives and Airport <strong>Regulation</strong>”, in the December 2006 edition of the Utilities Policy Journal. In addition, in 2003<br />

the UK Competition Commission found no evidence that the single till system has led to under-investment in aeronautical assets at the three<br />

BAA London airports in the past, nor did it have any expectation that it would do so over the next regulatory period.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!