12.10.2013 Views

PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise

PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise

PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

and between 157% and 247% in 2004. These horrendous rates are there to protect not only<br />

small family farms but also moshavim (production cooperatives) and kibbutzim (communes).<br />

Tariff quotas apply to 12 product groups although for most of these products the in-quota<br />

tariff rate is above the MFN applied rate, thus rendering the quota redundant (WTO 2006).<br />

When it is not, there is obviously some scope for lobbying the Ministries of Agriculture and<br />

Rural Development (for agricultural products and fresh food) and Industry, Trade, and Labour<br />

(for processed food) which are the ones in charge of the administration of those quotas. They<br />

apply among others to imports of prunes, walnuts, sweet corn, and concentrated citrus fruit.<br />

Another protection measure for agriculture were variable import levies applied to imports of<br />

basic products like sugar, pasta, sunflower seeds, jams, fruits, wine, cheese and frozen fish<br />

(WTO, 1999). At the end of 1990’s, in accordance with the WTO Agreement on Agriculture,<br />

all variable levies were eliminated. Now, Israel applies tariff quotas to 12 product groups<br />

(nuts, corns, orange juice, sheep and goat milk and cheese). “However, for most of these<br />

products the in-quota tariff rate is above the MFN applied rate, thus rendering the quota<br />

redundant. 52 As a result, these tariff quotas are in general overfilled” (WTO, 2006, p. 63). On<br />

the other hand, note that some of the PTAs signed by Israel with third countries offer the latter<br />

some tariff preferences (generally within a quota). For instance, in 1996 Israel and the US<br />

signed an agricultural trade accord aimed at including the remaining goods not covered by the<br />

1985 FTA agreement. Accordingly, agricultural imports from the USA were entitled to a<br />

preference of 10 percent (USDA, 2005). This implies, of course, devastating trade diversion<br />

against non-preferred countries, such as Argentina.<br />

A second sector deserving particular attention covers food, beverages and tobacco industries.<br />

In 2002, it accounted for about 15% of industrial production; it was the second largest<br />

employer in the industrial sector with more than 16% of industrial employment in 2004. The<br />

sector exhibits an oligopolistic market structure, especially in the case of tobacco products,<br />

soft drinks, fresh juices and wines. According to the political economy models oligopolistic<br />

structure favours the emergence and operation of lobbies. The industries are mostly oriented<br />

towards the domestic market, with exports representing only 6% of production or less. The<br />

52<br />

In principle “in quota” tariff rates should be below MFN rates in order to enable a minimum level of imports<br />

to a protected market.<br />

96

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!