PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise

PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise

12.10.2013 Views

pay bribes have 20 percent lower levels of output per worker; at the macro level, firms in countries with pervasive corruption are some 70 per cent less efficient than firms in countries free of corruption. Causes of Corruption and the “Pull Effect” of the EU The previous sections suggest that improving the control of corruption is likely to be a productive way to initiate sustained growth in the MENA region. These benefits would be even greater for those countries below the norm on the World Bank’s Control of Corruption Index. Logically, knowing root causes of corruption is a necessary condition for successful tackling of the problems associated with it, however, a whole swarm of conditions can influence patterns of corruption and its pervasiveness. There are many public policies that might influence levels of political corruption around the world, but there is relatively less theoretical work that formalizes the ways in which this might occur. Cross-country data permit one to obtain a broad overview of the underlying causes of corruption and weak governance. The role of low development as a cause is strikingly clear in all research on the subject. The failure to control for the level of GDP is often regarded as a failure of the whole model. Among other variables, the empirical research on corruption has established that the level of competition, trade openness, state intervention, economic freedom, and foreign aid are significantly related to corruption (Ades and Di Tella, 1997; Leite i Weidman, 1999; Treisman, 2000; Paldam, 2002; Gerring and Thacker, 2005). Non-economical determinants, mostly correlated with the level of democracy, are also said to have a significant impact on the pattern of corruption – among other inequality, ethnic diversity, type of political system, voice and accountability, election participation, and freedom of the press (Sandholtz and Koetzle, 2000; Kunicova and Rose-Ackerman, 2002; Montinola and Jackman, 2002; Persson, Tabellini, and Trebbi, 2003; Reinikka and Svensson, 2005. At the same time, empirical research focusing on regions is relatively less developed. Of the few regional studies, post communist corruption has attracted the most attention. The World Bank’s two waves of surveys of the business environment in Central and Eastern Europe document the specific ways that corrupt officials and intrusive rules affect businesses and show how corrupt environments impose onerous costs (Hellman, Jones, and Kaufmann 2003, 111

Johnson, Kaufmann, McMillan, and Woodruff 2000). There are broad differences in corruption and protection payments between the Commonwealth of Independent States including Russia, on the one hand, and Central Europe, on the other. An important complementary finding is established by BEEPS (2003): firms with close connections with the government did better than other firms, but countries where such connections were seen as important for business success did worse overall than those where political influence was less closely tied to economic success. In macroeconomic empirical research, the phenomenon of postcommunist corruption has been attributed to: barriers to new businesses entry, the effectiveness of the legal system and the efficacy and competitiveness of services provided by infrastructure monopolies (Broadman and Recanatini, 2002); years spent under communism, protestant share of population, natural resource endowment, and the fact that these countries have not been an English colony (Treisman, 2003); larger share of central planning in the economy and lack of structural reforms (Goczek, 2006). Furthermore, the last author finds that fresh members of the European Union show distinctively lower levels of corruption as compared to other post communist countries, even when controlling for their higher level of development and less adverse initial conditions. This effect could be caused by adoption thousands of pages of, often almost exotic, technical law labelled "Acquis communautaire” that is adopted without any thought to it. It may be criticized on particularly that ground but this process is setting a new legal framework not prone to corrupt influences. Clearly, the UE gave a window of opportunity for a great deal of above average quality legislation and it is good that it was reasonably well used. Moreover, it seems that the EU was the driving force of the structural reforms in the region, which decreased the scope for corruption. Corruption in candidate countries had been one of the EU’s major concerns time after time, when the European Commission begun publishing its annual progress reports on candidates in 1997. The grounds for that anxiety were simple: the European legal system works (as in every democratic society) under the assumption that law will be implemented, controlled, and enforced by the public administration and judiciary of the member states (Peterson, 1997). Corruption endangers the implementation and execution of rules or makes their adoption merely formal, as that was the case. A clear implication of both the Regular Reports and the 112

Johnson, Kaufmann, McMillan, and Woodruff 2000). There are broad differences in<br />

corruption and protection payments between the Commonwealth of Independent States<br />

including Russia, on the one hand, and Central Europe, on the other. An important<br />

complementary finding is established by BEEPS (2003): firms with close connections with<br />

the government did better than other firms, but countries where such connections were seen as<br />

important for business success did worse overall than those where political influence was less<br />

closely tied to economic success.<br />

In macroeconomic empirical research, the phenomenon of postcommunist corruption has<br />

been attributed to: barriers to new businesses entry, the effectiveness of the legal system and<br />

the efficacy and competitiveness of services provided by infrastructure monopolies<br />

(Broadman and Recanatini, 2002); years spent under communism, protestant share of<br />

population, natural resource endowment, and the fact that these countries have not been an<br />

English colony (Treisman, 2003); larger share of central planning in the economy and lack of<br />

structural reforms (Goczek, 2006). Furthermore, the last author finds that fresh members of<br />

the European Union show distinctively lower levels of corruption as compared to other post<br />

communist countries, even when controlling for their higher level of development and less<br />

adverse initial conditions. This effect could be caused by adoption thousands of pages of,<br />

often almost exotic, technical law labelled "Acquis communautaire” that is adopted without<br />

any thought to it. It may be criticized on particularly that ground but this process is setting a<br />

new legal framework not prone to corrupt influences. Clearly, the UE gave a window of<br />

opportunity for a great deal of above average quality legislation and it is good that it was<br />

reasonably well used. Moreover, it seems that the EU was the driving force of the structural<br />

reforms in the region, which decreased the scope for corruption.<br />

Corruption in candidate countries had been one of the EU’s major concerns time after time,<br />

when the European Commission begun publishing its annual progress reports on candidates in<br />

1997. The grounds for that anxiety were simple: the European legal system works (as in<br />

every democratic society) under the assumption that law will be implemented, controlled, and<br />

enforced by the public administration and judiciary of the member states (Peterson, 1997).<br />

Corruption endangers the implementation and execution of rules or makes their adoption<br />

merely formal, as that was the case. A clear implication of both the Regular Reports and the<br />

112

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!