PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise

PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise PDF, GB, 139 p., 796 Ko - Femise

12.10.2013 Views

Figure 1 Macroeconomic Effects of Corruption Corruption Source: Own. Competition Price of Credit FDI Return from Investment Government Export Composition Among other effects of corruption Esty and Porter (2002) and Tanzi and Davoodi (1997) claim significant evidence for over-investment in public infrastructure in relatively corrupt countries. Mauro (1997) found that if a country was able to reduce corruption by two points on a 10-point scale, government expenditures on education would rise by 1.5 percent of the GDP. In support, Gupta, de Mello, and Sharan (2000) find that higher military spending and lower healthcare and education spending in relation to GDP and total governmental expenditure, tend to be associated with higher levels of corruption. Rajkumar and Swaroop (2002) find that public health spending lowers child and infant mortality rates only in countries characterized by no corruption. Gupta, Davoodi and Alonso-Tierre (1998) demonstrate that raising the TI index by two points gives the same consequences to inequality measured by the Gini coefficient, as cutting secondary school education by as much as 2, 3 years. Li, Xu and Zou (2000) confirm that corruption increases inequality. Gupta, Davoodi and Alonso-Terme (2002) also investigate the income growth of the bottom 20 per cent of 109 Consumption Investment Government Net Exports GDP Growth

society. In addition, they show that as countries fight corruption, public spending on primary education becomes more effective in expanding primary education enrolment. In many countries and especially in Post-communist and Mediterranean countries the role of the state is often carried out through the use of numerous rules or regulations. In these countries, licenses, permits, and authorizations of various sorts are required to engage in many economic activities (Kaufman 1997). The existence of such regulations and authorizations gives a monopoly power to the officials who must authorize or decide on such activities (Rose-Ackerman 1978). These officials may refuse the authorizations or may simply delay a decision for months or even years. Thus, they can use their public power to extract bribes from those who need the authorizations or permits most. Svensson (2003) argues that firms have to pay bribes when dealing with public officials whose actions directly affect the firms’ business and such dealings cannot be easily avoided. Therefore it is not a fixed sum for given services, but a function of sunk costs and future profits. Firms with higher overdue payments to utilities also appear to pay higher bribes (Clarke and Xu, 2002). Fisman and Svensson (2000) show that the raised risk of investing causes companies engaged in corrupt deals to grow slower. For the gathered data, one percent of an increase in given bribe slows the growth of the company by three percent, which was an effect three times greater than the effect of a similar raise in taxation. What is more important, the researchers controlling for more and more factors observed a diminishing role of taxation and an increasing impact of bribes. Consequently, officially organized firms in Ukraine and Russia are much more probable to admit to hiding sales and salaries than firms in Central Europe (Johnson, Kaufmann, McMillan, and Woodruff 2000). Illegal enterprises are more widespread in Russia and Ukraine, and such firms hide all of their output from the official scrutiny. What's more, firms in Ukraine and Russia inform about spending more time on administrative and regulatory matters than anywhere else (18% and 25% respectively compared to about 10% for the other countries). In Ukraine and Russia generally all firms report making illicit payments, and consequently they hide a high proportion of their revenues. In Central Europe, there exist a group of firms, which operates both corruptly and unofficially, but the practice is not so widespread. McArthur and Teal (2004) use survey data to investigate the importance of corruption in determining firm performance in Africa. They find that corruption is linked to significant adverse effects on firm performance in two ways. At the firm level, companies that 110

Figure 1 Macroeconomic Effects of Corruption<br />

Corruption<br />

Source: Own.<br />

Competition<br />

Price of<br />

Credit<br />

FDI<br />

Return from<br />

Investment<br />

Government<br />

Export<br />

Composition<br />

Among other effects of corruption Esty and Porter (2002) and Tanzi and Davoodi (1997)<br />

claim significant evidence for over-investment in public infrastructure in relatively corrupt<br />

countries. Mauro (1997) found that if a country was able to reduce corruption by two points<br />

on a 10-point scale, government expenditures on education would rise by 1.5 percent of the<br />

GDP. In support, Gupta, de Mello, and Sharan (2000) find that higher military spending and<br />

lower healthcare and education spending in relation to GDP and total governmental<br />

expenditure, tend to be associated with higher levels of corruption. Rajkumar and Swaroop<br />

(2002) find that public health spending lowers child and infant mortality rates only in<br />

countries characterized by no corruption. Gupta, Davoodi and Alonso-Tierre (1998)<br />

demonstrate that raising the TI index by two points gives the same consequences to inequality<br />

measured by the Gini coefficient, as cutting secondary school education by as much as 2, 3<br />

years. Li, Xu and Zou (2000) confirm that corruption increases inequality. Gupta, Davoodi<br />

and Alonso-Terme (2002) also investigate the income growth of the bottom 20 per cent of<br />

109<br />

Consumption<br />

Investment<br />

Government<br />

Net Exports<br />

GDP Growth

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!