12.10.2013 Views

Dairy's role in sustaining New Zealand - Fonterra

Dairy's role in sustaining New Zealand - Fonterra

Dairy's role in sustaining New Zealand - Fonterra

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong> susta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong><br />

- the sector’s contribution to<br />

the economy<br />

REPORT TO FONTERRA AND DAIRY NZ<br />

December 2010


About NZIER<br />

NZIER is a specialist consult<strong>in</strong>g firm that uses applied economic research and analysis<br />

to provide a wide range of strategic advice to clients <strong>in</strong> the public and private sectors,<br />

throughout <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> and Australia, and further afield.<br />

NZIER is also known for its long-established Quarterly Survey of Bus<strong>in</strong>ess Op<strong>in</strong>ion and<br />

Quarterly Predictions.<br />

Our aim is to be the premier centre of applied economic research <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>. We pride<br />

ourselves on our reputation for <strong>in</strong>dependence and deliver<strong>in</strong>g quality analysis <strong>in</strong> the right<br />

form, and at the right time, for our clients. We ensure quality through teamwork on <strong>in</strong>dividual<br />

projects, critical review at <strong>in</strong>ternal sem<strong>in</strong>ars, and by peer review at various stages through a<br />

project by a senior staff member otherwise not <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> the project.<br />

NZIER was established <strong>in</strong> 1958.<br />

Authorship<br />

Prepared by: Chris Schill<strong>in</strong>g, James Zuccollo and Chris Nixon<br />

Quality approved by: John Ball<strong>in</strong>gall<br />

Date: 15/11/2010 3:49 PM<br />

Version: F<strong>in</strong>al<br />

Acknowledgements:


Key po<strong>in</strong>ts<br />

Dairy makes a very strong direct contribution to the NZ economy<br />

• The dairy sector directly accounts for 2.8% of GDP, or $5 billion. This contribution is:<br />

o greater than the GDP contribution of the fish<strong>in</strong>g, forestry and m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sectors<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

o around 10 times as large as the GDP of the w<strong>in</strong>e sector<br />

o about 3 times as large as the forestry and logg<strong>in</strong>g sector<br />

o over a third of the GDP contribution of the entire primary sector (dairy and meat<br />

farm<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g, horticulture, fish<strong>in</strong>g, forestry, m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g)<br />

o 40% larger than the entire utilities sector (electricity, gas and water)<br />

o 2/3 as large as the entire construction sector<br />

o 15% of the total GDP of the goods produc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries and<br />

o provides 26% of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s total goods exports.<br />

And contributes to the health of the NZ economy <strong>in</strong> many ways<br />

• But the sector’s <strong>in</strong>fluence extends well beyond its direct impacts. Dairy is closely<br />

<strong>in</strong>tertw<strong>in</strong>ed with the rest of the economy. This <strong>in</strong>cludes the jobs it delivers, the <strong>in</strong>come<br />

that these workers earn, its l<strong>in</strong>ks to supply<strong>in</strong>g firms, the effects of rural economic growth<br />

on urban centres, the tax revenue it provides and the public services that can be funded<br />

from this tax revenue. These l<strong>in</strong>ks are shown <strong>in</strong> the figure at the end of this section.<br />

• Of the $10.4 billion of dairy products exported <strong>in</strong> 2009,<br />

o $7.5 billion is used to purchase raw milk from the dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g sector.<br />

o $1.5 billion is reta<strong>in</strong>ed as returns to labour and capital (i.e. wages and rate of return).<br />

o $625 million is spent on <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts from <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>. This <strong>in</strong>cludes $85<br />

million of plastic conta<strong>in</strong>ers, $45 million on electricity and $22.5 million on f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

services.<br />

o Imported <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts account for $310 million – largely plastic conta<strong>in</strong>ers<br />

($182 million) and other food products to be used <strong>in</strong> process<strong>in</strong>g ($30 million).<br />

o $730 million is spent on retail<strong>in</strong>g/wholesal<strong>in</strong>g costs that get the dairy products from<br />

the plant to market.<br />

• Of the $7.5 billion value of raw milk output, $3.0 billion is reta<strong>in</strong>ed as returns to land,<br />

labour and capital. A further $3.6 billion is spent on domestically produced <strong>in</strong>termediate<br />

<strong>in</strong>puts, such as fertilizer ($447 million), feed ($723 million), agricultural services ($446<br />

million), f<strong>in</strong>ancial services<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

C


D Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

It generates jobs<br />

• The dairy sector employs around 35,000 workers, exclud<strong>in</strong>g those who are self-employed<br />

(which could be up to 10,000 people). The sector will <strong>in</strong>directly support many more jobs<br />

<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries that supply dairy, and that experience the benefits of additional <strong>in</strong>come<br />

flow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the region due to dairy volume and/or price growth.<br />

• It provides more jobs than each of the f<strong>in</strong>ance and accommodation sectors; around 65%<br />

more than the sheep and beef farm<strong>in</strong>g sector; 75% more than the fruit grow<strong>in</strong>g sector<br />

and double the jobs <strong>in</strong> the wood process<strong>in</strong>g sector.<br />

• In districts such as South Taranaki, Waimate, Otorohanga and Matamata-Piako, the dairy<br />

sector directly accounts for between 1 <strong>in</strong> 4 and 1 <strong>in</strong> 5 of the total number of jobs <strong>in</strong> the<br />

region.<br />

• A $1 per kg payout <strong>in</strong>crease results <strong>in</strong> the wealthier dairy sector and upstream and<br />

downstream <strong>in</strong>dustries employ<strong>in</strong>g approximately 4,600 more full time equivalent workers.<br />

It creates export earn<strong>in</strong>gs that improve Kiwis’ standard of liv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

• Dairy exports were $10.4 billion <strong>in</strong> calendar year 2009, account<strong>in</strong>g for around 26% of NZ’s<br />

total goods exports.<br />

• This contribution far outstrips that of any other goods export sector. Dairy exports are<br />

twice those of the meat sector, over 6 times larger than all fruit exports, n<strong>in</strong>e times larger<br />

than w<strong>in</strong>e exports, twelve times larger than alum<strong>in</strong>ium exports and 17 times larger than<br />

wool exports.<br />

• In fact, dairy exports are about the same as the sum of the next four largest export<br />

sectors: meat, wood, m<strong>in</strong>eral fuels (oil) and fruit & nuts.<br />

• Through its export earn<strong>in</strong>gs, the dairy sector makes a positive contribution to narrow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the current account deficit. Without this export growth, <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> would have had to<br />

face <strong>in</strong>creased foreign liabilities and <strong>in</strong>terest on foreign debt.<br />

• A smaller deficit reduces <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s country risk premium on mortgage and other<br />

borrow<strong>in</strong>g costs, which benefits all households and firms that are borrowers.<br />

• The volume growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector over the last decade has resulted <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong><br />

households be<strong>in</strong>g a cumulative $6.4 billion better off than if dairy activity had stagnated<br />

at 1999 levels.<br />

• A $1 dairy payout <strong>in</strong>crease delivers additional <strong>in</strong>come of over $270 per year of additional<br />

spend<strong>in</strong>g per man, woman and child <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>. This year’s <strong>in</strong>crease of $1.17 per kg<br />

will generate an extra $316 per person <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>.<br />

It fills the tax coffers<br />

• The dairy sector generates a substantial amount of tax revenue for the government,<br />

through the <strong>in</strong>come taxes of farmers, corporate taxes of processors, and the GST and<br />

other taxes on the <strong>in</strong>come and spend<strong>in</strong>g that dairy stimulates <strong>in</strong> the rest of the economy.<br />

• And because the sector has raised taxation revenue, benefits flow not just to the dairy<strong>in</strong>g<br />

districts but across the country as a whole.<br />

• Increased tax revenue com<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> means more money to spend on essential services such<br />

as schools, hospitals and police. In 2009, these sectors are 0.7%, 0.6% and 0.2% better off<br />

because of the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector over the past decade.


It drives many rural economies: “when dairy farmers are smil<strong>in</strong>g, the whole<br />

region smiles”<br />

• Dairy production is hugely important for many regional economies. It <strong>in</strong>jected over $700<br />

million <strong>in</strong>to the Southland economy <strong>in</strong> 2009, with South Taranaki and Matamata-Piako<br />

both receiv<strong>in</strong>g well over half a billion dollars.<br />

• For smaller district economies such as Ashburton ($471 million), Waipa ($361 million)<br />

and Selwyn ($270 million), the value of dairy production, relative to the total size of the<br />

economy, is likely to be significant.<br />

• As noted above, as many as 1 <strong>in</strong> 4 jobs <strong>in</strong> some rural areas are <strong>in</strong> the dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g and<br />

process<strong>in</strong>g sectors.<br />

• The dairy volume expansion over the past decade has delivered an additional $650 of<br />

<strong>in</strong>come per person <strong>in</strong> the Southland region and $590 per person <strong>in</strong> the Canterbury region<br />

above what would otherwise have happened. Northland ($110 per person) and the<br />

Waikato ($270) have also been major w<strong>in</strong>ners.<br />

• A $1/kg <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> milk solid prices delivers $170 per person of additional <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong><br />

Northland and Taranaki, $130 per person <strong>in</strong> the Waikato and $140 <strong>in</strong> the Manawatu-<br />

Wanganui region.<br />

It benefits urban consumers too<br />

• Firms benefit from sell<strong>in</strong>g goods and services to the dairy sector. The average dairy<br />

farmer spends well over half of their <strong>in</strong>come on goods and services to support on-farm<br />

operations. Many of these goods will come from urban areas.<br />

• Households benefit from the additional government spend<strong>in</strong>g that is facilitated by the<br />

tax revenue generated by the dairy sector.<br />

• They also pay lower mortgage and bus<strong>in</strong>ess borrow<strong>in</strong>g costs due to the reduction <strong>in</strong> the<br />

current account deficit (and thus the <strong>in</strong>terest rate premium on overseas funds) due to<br />

dairy export revenue.<br />

• The dairy sector’s strong export growth over the last decade has improved <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s<br />

balance of trade, and allowed for <strong>in</strong>creased consumption spend<strong>in</strong>g. This export growth<br />

reduced <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s net foreign liabilities to GDP ratio by over 1%. Together with the<br />

exchange rate appreciation, this has saved households a cumulative $1.2 billion <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest<br />

repayments on foreign debt over the past decade.<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

E


Figure 1<br />

F Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth


Contents<br />

1. The current contribution of dairy 1<br />

1.1 Purpose of report 1<br />

1.2 Direct contribution to GDP 1<br />

1.3 Contribution to regional <strong>in</strong>comes 2<br />

1.4 Contribution to export performance 2<br />

1.5 Contribution to Balance of Payments 4<br />

1.6 Contribution to employment 4<br />

1.7 Contribution to other sectors’performance 5<br />

1.7.1 Supply cha<strong>in</strong> 5<br />

1.7.2 Dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g 6<br />

1.7.3 Dairy process<strong>in</strong>g 7<br />

2. Modell<strong>in</strong>g dairy’s economic contribution over the past decade 9<br />

2.1 Objective of modell<strong>in</strong>g 9<br />

2.2 Modell<strong>in</strong>g technique 9<br />

2.3 Advantages of CGE modell<strong>in</strong>g 9<br />

2.4 Modell<strong>in</strong>g scenarios 10<br />

2.4.1 Scenario 1: The price of milk solids 10<br />

2.4.2 Scenario 2: The growth of dairy<strong>in</strong>g over the past decade 11<br />

2.5 How we analyse the modell<strong>in</strong>g results 12<br />

3. Milk solids price spike 13<br />

3.1 Headl<strong>in</strong>e results 13<br />

3.2 Detailed results 13<br />

3.2.1 Direct effects: the dairy sector 13<br />

3.2.2 Indirect impact on other <strong>in</strong>dustries 16<br />

3.2.3 Macroeconomic effects 17<br />

3.2.4 Regional impacts 18<br />

4. Production growth over the last decade 19<br />

4.1 Headl<strong>in</strong>e results 19<br />

4.2 Detailed results 20<br />

4.2.1 Direct impacts 20<br />

4.2.2 Indirect impacts on other <strong>in</strong>dustries 20<br />

4.2.3 Macroeconomic effects 21<br />

4.2.4 Regional impacts 22<br />

5. Conclusion 24<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

G


Appendices<br />

Figures<br />

Tables<br />

H Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Appendix A CGE modell<strong>in</strong>g framework 25<br />

A.1 The MONASH-<strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> CGE model: overview 25<br />

A.2 Dynamics of the MONASH-NZ model 26<br />

A.3 Database structure 26<br />

A.4 Production structure (Horridge, 2008b) 28<br />

A.5 Regional extension 29<br />

Appendix B CGE and multiplier analysis 30<br />

Appendix C Limitations of analysis 32<br />

Appendix D References 33<br />

Appendix E Dairy employment statistics 34<br />

Appendix F Value of regional dairy production 38<br />

Appendix G Chang<strong>in</strong>g dairy export markets 39<br />

Figure 1 Impacts of dairy growth on the rest of the economy F<br />

Figure 2 Growth <strong>in</strong> dairy exports over past decades 4<br />

Figure 3 Importance of dairy to regional employment 5<br />

Figure 4 Model structure of the sector 6<br />

Figure 5 Change <strong>in</strong> milk solids price: 1998-2009 11<br />

Figure 6 Processed milk solids 11<br />

Figure 7 Gross regional product impacts 17<br />

Figure 8 Dairy ga<strong>in</strong>s s<strong>in</strong>ce 1998/99 21<br />

Figure 9 2009 Gross regional product impacts 23<br />

Figure 10 Components of a CGE model 25<br />

Figure 11 The MONASH-NZ database 27<br />

Figure 12 Production structure 28<br />

Figure 13 Chang<strong>in</strong>g markets for <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s dairy exports 39<br />

Table 1 Value of regional dairy production 2<br />

Table 2 Export values 3<br />

Table 3 Farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry structure 7<br />

Table 4 Dairy process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry structure 7<br />

Table 5 Indirect impacts 2010 15<br />

Table 6 National results 16<br />

Table 7 Increase <strong>in</strong> gross regional product 17<br />

Table 8 Average Cap Farm Cashflow 18<br />

Table 9 Indirect impacts 2008/09 21<br />

Table 10 National results 2009 22<br />

Table 11 Increase <strong>in</strong> gross regional product 23<br />

Table 12 IO vs. CGE multipliers 31


1. The current contribution of dairy<br />

1.1 Purpose of report<br />

This report identifies the dairy sector’s current contribution to the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy<br />

and looks at how changes <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector over the past decade have benefited districts<br />

and households <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>.<br />

1.2 Direct contribution to GDP<br />

The dairy sector, compris<strong>in</strong>g farmers and dairy processors, directly contributed around $5.0<br />

billion of value added (or GDP) to the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy <strong>in</strong> 2010, around 2.8% of the<br />

total GDP figure 1 . By way of comparison, dairy GDP:<br />

• is greater than the GDP contribution of the fish<strong>in</strong>g, forestry and m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g sectors comb<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

• is around 10 times as large as the GDP of the w<strong>in</strong>e sector<br />

• is about 3 times as large as the forestry and logg<strong>in</strong>g sector<br />

• accounts for over a third of the GDP contribution of the entire primary sector (dairy and<br />

meat farm<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g, horticulture, fish<strong>in</strong>g, forestry, m<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g)<br />

• is 40% larger than the entire utilities sector (electricity, gas and water)<br />

• is 2/3 as large as the entire construction sector<br />

• accounts for 15% of the total GDP of the goods produc<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

Note that these figures are the direct contributions only. They do not take <strong>in</strong>to account the<br />

l<strong>in</strong>ks that the dairy sector has with the wider economy. In reality, the dairy sector also has<br />

<strong>in</strong>direct and <strong>in</strong>duced effects on the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy. The <strong>in</strong>direct effects accrue via<br />

the <strong>in</strong>dustries support<strong>in</strong>g the dairy sector (fertiliser, agricultural services, transport, etc). When<br />

the dairy sector grows, these support<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries will also grow. The <strong>in</strong>duced effects are<br />

attributable to the additional spend<strong>in</strong>g of dairy sector farmers and workers follow<strong>in</strong>g a boost<br />

<strong>in</strong> dairy returns. This spend<strong>in</strong>g will be directed <strong>in</strong>to sectors such as hous<strong>in</strong>g, cloth<strong>in</strong>g, bars and<br />

cafes, enterta<strong>in</strong>ment, etc. Some of these l<strong>in</strong>kages are discussed <strong>in</strong> section 1.7 below. 2<br />

1. Calculated from Statistics <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> SNA GDP by <strong>in</strong>dustry data and NZIER’s <strong>in</strong>dustry database. Measured <strong>in</strong> 2010 prices.<br />

2. Unless one uses an unrealistic and non-credible methodology, it is not possible to calculate the total (direct plus <strong>in</strong>direct<br />

and <strong>in</strong>duced) GDP contribution of dairy. See section 2.3 and Appendix B for further explanation<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

1


2 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

1.3 Contribution to regional <strong>in</strong>comes<br />

In many rural areas, the contribution of the dairy sector to the local economy is far greater<br />

than the national average of 2.8% mentioned above. The dairy sector pumps hundreds of<br />

millions of dollars of revenue <strong>in</strong>to regional economies each year. Table 1 shows the 15 highest<br />

revenue generat<strong>in</strong>g dairy districts <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>.<br />

Dairy production <strong>in</strong>jected over $700 million <strong>in</strong>to the Southland district economy <strong>in</strong> 2009, with<br />

South Taranaki and Matamata-Piako both receiv<strong>in</strong>g well over half a billion dollars. For smaller<br />

district economies such as Ashburton ($471 million), Waipa ($361 million) and Selwyn ($270<br />

million), the value of dairy production, relative to the total size of the district economy, is likely<br />

to be significant 3 . Also see Box story 1.<br />

Table 1 Value of regional dairy production<br />

$ millions, 2009<br />

Region Dairy revenue<br />

Southland 710.35<br />

South Taranaki 616.56<br />

Matamata-Piako 552.12<br />

Ashburton 471.11<br />

Waikato 389.91<br />

Waipa 361.00<br />

Selwyn 269.91<br />

South Waikato 262.53<br />

Rotorua 253.55<br />

Otorohanga 234.54<br />

<strong>New</strong> Plymouth 206.31<br />

Hauraki 196.40<br />

Tararua 188.28<br />

Timaru 185.13<br />

Clutha 181.72<br />

Notes: (1) Based on $5.50 price per Kg MS, 35c per Kg MS for stock sales and 4c per Kg of MS for other <strong>in</strong>come<br />

Source: Dairy <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>, <strong>Fonterra</strong>, NZIER<br />

1.4 Contribution to export performance<br />

Dairy exports were $10.4 billion <strong>in</strong> calendar year 2009, account<strong>in</strong>g for around 26% of NZ’s<br />

total goods exports. As Table 2 shows, this contribution far outstrips that of any other goods<br />

export sector. The third column <strong>in</strong> the table shows that dairy exports are twice those of the<br />

meat sector, over 6 times larger than all fruit exports, n<strong>in</strong>e times larger than w<strong>in</strong>e exports,<br />

twelve times larger than alum<strong>in</strong>ium exports and 17 times larger than wool exports.<br />

In fact, dairy exports are about the same as the sum of the next four largest export sectors:<br />

meat, wood, m<strong>in</strong>eral fuels (oil) and fruit & nuts.<br />

3. Regional GDP <strong>in</strong>formation at this level of detail is not available from Statistics <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>, so the shares cannot be<br />

calculated.


Table 2 Export values<br />

$ millions, 2009<br />

Sector Export value How many times dairy<br />

exports are larger than<br />

sector’s<br />

Dairy products 10,398<br />

Meat products 5,142 2.0<br />

Wood products 2,316 4.5<br />

M<strong>in</strong>eral fuels 1,891 5.6<br />

Fruit & nuts 1,597 6.6<br />

Mach<strong>in</strong>ery parts 1,294 8.1<br />

Fish 1,260 8.3<br />

Miscellaneous 1,211 8.7<br />

W<strong>in</strong>e & other beverages 1,183 8.9<br />

Alum<strong>in</strong>ium 880 11.9<br />

Electrical mach<strong>in</strong>ery 826 12.7<br />

Precious metals & stones 764 13.7<br />

Wool 637 16.5<br />

Wood pulp 610 17.2<br />

Iron & steel 565 18.6<br />

Optical & medical equipment 546 19.2<br />

Paper & paperboard 526 20.0<br />

Vegetables 405 25.9<br />

Plastics 401 26.2<br />

Hides & sk<strong>in</strong>s 375 28.0<br />

Notes: (1)<br />

Source: Dairy NZ, <strong>Fonterra</strong>, NZIER<br />

F<strong>in</strong>al report - 16 November 2010<br />

Over the past decade, dairy export values have grown by more than 8% per year. Dairy has<br />

grown more rapidly than most primary sectors, and has become an <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>gly important<br />

contributor to <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s total food and beverages and overall merchandise trade.<br />

Figure 2 Growth <strong>in</strong> dairy exports over past decades<br />

Figure Annual average 2 Growth growth <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> dairy export exports values, 1999-2009 over past decades<br />

Annual average growth <strong>in</strong> export values, 1999-2009<br />

Source: Statistics <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>, NZIER<br />

Source: Statistics <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>, NZIER<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Export growth has been driven by a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of strong global <strong>in</strong>come growth for<br />

3


4 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Export growth has been driven by a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of strong global <strong>in</strong>come growth for the<br />

majority of the decade, as well as a change <strong>in</strong> the composition of the markets that we sell to.<br />

As economies such as Ch<strong>in</strong>a and other parts of Asia experience higher liv<strong>in</strong>g standards, their<br />

tastes and preferences change, and staples such as rice, lentil and beans are replaced with<br />

higher prote<strong>in</strong> foods. The chang<strong>in</strong>g composition of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s dairy markets is shown<br />

<strong>in</strong> Figure 13 <strong>in</strong> Appendix G. Ch<strong>in</strong>a, for example, accounted for 0.4% of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s dairy<br />

exports <strong>in</strong> 1989 and now takes over 12%. The relative importance of major markets such as<br />

the UK, Japan and Mexico has dropped over this period.<br />

1.5 Contribution to Balance of Payments<br />

The strong export growth from the dairy sector has been a key factor <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s<br />

current account deficit (CAD) narrow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> recent years. This is important because as the CAD<br />

rises as a proportion of GDP, foreign <strong>in</strong>vestors and rat<strong>in</strong>gs agencies start to have concerns<br />

over the ability of the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy to withstand any unexpected negative<br />

economic shock (such as a global pandemic or f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis). These concerns translate <strong>in</strong>to<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> hav<strong>in</strong>g a higher risk premium attached to it on foreign borrow<strong>in</strong>gs – that is, it<br />

becomes more expensive for <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> firms, households and the government to borrow<br />

on <strong>in</strong>ternational markets. The most obvious channel would be through higher household<br />

mortgage repayments.<br />

The strength of the dairy sector has been very evident as <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> recovers from the<br />

global f<strong>in</strong>ancial crisis and domestic recession. With domestic demand cont<strong>in</strong>u<strong>in</strong>g to be<br />

anaemic, it is the export side of the economy that is be<strong>in</strong>g relied on to generate economic<br />

growth. It has recently been noted that dairy’s growth has resulted <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s trade<br />

surplus be<strong>in</strong>g at its highest level for eight years.<br />

1.6 Contribution to employment<br />

National<br />

The dairy sector <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> is a major employer, and is vital for a number of districts.<br />

On-farm employment is around 24,000 nationwide, with dairy process<strong>in</strong>g provid<strong>in</strong>g another<br />

10,000 jobs. These figures do not <strong>in</strong>clude those dairy farmers who are registered as selfemployed.<br />

Although dairy employment does not reach the employment levels present <strong>in</strong> a number of<br />

services sectors (for example, there are 110,000 workers <strong>in</strong> pre-school and school education<br />

alone), it provides more jobs than each of the f<strong>in</strong>ance and accommodation sectors (both<br />

around 32,000); around 65% more than the sheep and beef farm<strong>in</strong>g sector (20,500); 75% more<br />

than the fruit grow<strong>in</strong>g sector (19,300) and double the jobs <strong>in</strong> the wood process<strong>in</strong>g sector.<br />

Regional<br />

In districts such as South Taranaki, Waimate, Otorohanga and Matamata-Piako, the dairy sector<br />

directly accounts for between 1 <strong>in</strong> 4 and 1 <strong>in</strong> 5 of the total number of jobs <strong>in</strong> the region.<br />

The sector will <strong>in</strong>directly support many more jobs <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustries that supply dairy, and that<br />

experience the benefits of additional <strong>in</strong>come flow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to the region due to dairy volume<br />

and/or price growth.<br />

4. Department of Labour (DoL), ‘Regional Industry Tool 2009’http://www.dol.govt.nz/services/LMI/tools/regional-<strong>in</strong>dustry-tool.asp<br />

5. There is no official count of self-employed dairy farmers, but the figure has been estimated by Dairy NZ at around 10,000 based on<br />

owner-operator and sharemilker numbers.


Figure 3 Importance of dairy to regional employment<br />

Dairy farm and process<strong>in</strong>g jobs as % of total <strong>in</strong> region<br />

Figure 3 Importance of dairy to regional employment<br />

Dairy farm and process<strong>in</strong>g jobs as % of total <strong>in</strong> region<br />

Source: DoL, NZIER<br />

A complete<br />

A complete<br />

table<br />

table<br />

of<br />

of<br />

dairy employment<br />

employment<br />

statistics<br />

statistics<br />

for each<br />

for<br />

of <strong>New</strong><br />

each<br />

<strong>Zealand</strong>’s<br />

of <strong>New</strong><br />

74 Territorial<br />

<strong>Zealand</strong>’s<br />

Local<br />

74<br />

Authorities is conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Appendix E.<br />

Territorial Local Authorities is conta<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> Appendix E.<br />

1.7 Contribution to other sectors’ performance<br />

F<strong>in</strong>al report - 16 November 2010<br />

Of course, the dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g sector do not operate <strong>in</strong> isolation. They have<br />

strong upstream and downstream l<strong>in</strong>ks to other parts of the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy.<br />

1.7 Contribution to other sectors’ performance<br />

1.7.1 Supply cha<strong>in</strong><br />

Of course, the dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g and process<strong>in</strong>g sector do not operate <strong>in</strong> isolation. They<br />

The dairy sector can conceptually be broken <strong>in</strong>to a dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry and a dairy<br />

have strong<br />

process<strong>in</strong>g<br />

upstream<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry. Dairy<br />

and<br />

farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

downstream<br />

generates<br />

l<strong>in</strong>ks<br />

the raw<br />

to<br />

milk<br />

other<br />

that the<br />

parts<br />

dairy<br />

of<br />

process<strong>in</strong>g<br />

the <strong>New</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

<strong>Zealand</strong><br />

economy. uses as an <strong>in</strong>put, and produces processed dairy products for sale to domestic consumers,<br />

export markets and other <strong>in</strong>dustries.<br />

1.7.1 Supply cha<strong>in</strong><br />

The dairy sector can conceptually be broken <strong>in</strong>to a dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry and a dairy<br />

process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry. Dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g generates the raw milk that the dairy process<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry uses as an <strong>in</strong>put, and produces processed dairy products 6 for sale to<br />

domestic consumers, export markets and other <strong>in</strong>dustries.<br />

6<br />

In our model, we have a variety of processed dairy products, but for simplification for this work,<br />

we consider one generic processed dairy product. Similarly, farm <strong>in</strong>come from other sources than<br />

just milk 6. In (e.g. our model, stock we have and a variety other of processed sales) dairy is <strong>in</strong>cluded products, but <strong>in</strong> for the simplification modell<strong>in</strong>g for this but work, not we consider s<strong>in</strong>gled one generic out <strong>in</strong> processed the<br />

report<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

dairy product. Similarly, farm <strong>in</strong>come from other sources than just milk (e.g. stock and other sales) is <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the modell<strong>in</strong>g but<br />

not s<strong>in</strong>gled out <strong>in</strong> the report<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

6<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

5


Figure 4 Model structure of the sector<br />

Figure 4 Model structure of the sector<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

At each stage of production there is also labour, capital and other <strong>in</strong>termediate employment.<br />

At each stage of production there is also labour, capital and other <strong>in</strong>termediate<br />

employment. 1.7.2 Dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

The structure of the farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry is shown <strong>in</strong> Table 3. The farm<strong>in</strong>g sector produced around<br />

1.7.2 $7.5 Dairy billion farm<strong>in</strong>g worth of raw milk <strong>in</strong> the 2009/10 production year for sale to the process<strong>in</strong>g<br />

operations. As expected, farm<strong>in</strong>g uses a lot of land and the labour is not a large part of the<br />

The structure of the farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry is shown <strong>in</strong> Table 3. The farm<strong>in</strong>g sector<br />

farm’s costs. The on-farm sector employs around 24,000 full time equivalent (FTE) workers. The<br />

produced around $7.5 billion worth of raw milk <strong>in</strong> the 2009/10 production year for sale<br />

primary cashflow costs for farmers are fertiliser for the land and feed for the animals. These<br />

to the process<strong>in</strong>g two <strong>in</strong>dustries operations. are heavily affected As expected, by movements farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> demand uses for a milk lot of products. land and the labour<br />

is not a large part of the farm’s costs. The on-farm sector employs around 24,000 full<br />

We can break down the $7.5 billion of raw milk <strong>in</strong>to the follow<strong>in</strong>g parts:<br />

time equivalent (FTE) workers. The primary cashflow costs for farmers are fertiliser<br />

for the • land $3.0and billion feed is reta<strong>in</strong>ed for the as returns animals. to land, These labour two and<strong>in</strong>dustries capital. are heavily affected by<br />

movements • $3.6 <strong>in</strong> billion demand is spent for on milk domestically products. produced <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts, such as fertilizer ($447<br />

million), straw and feed ($723 million), agricultural services ($446 million), f<strong>in</strong>ancial services<br />

We can break ($341down million), the mach<strong>in</strong>ery $7.5 billion repairs of ($198 raw million) milk <strong>in</strong>to andthe petrol/diesel follow<strong>in</strong>g ($80 parts: million).<br />

• $3.0 • billion $440 million is reta<strong>in</strong>ed is spent as onreturns imported to <strong>in</strong>puts land, such labour as fertilizer and capital. ($138 million), pharmaceuticals<br />

($111 million), feed ($31 million), agricultural equipment ($26 million) and pesticides ($16<br />

• $3.6 billion million). is spent on domestically produced <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts, such as<br />

fertilizer ($447 million), straw and feed ($723 million), agricultural services ($446<br />

• $290 million is spent on marg<strong>in</strong> services such as transport.<br />

million), f<strong>in</strong>ancial services ($341 million), mach<strong>in</strong>ery repairs ($198 million) and<br />

petrol/diesel ($80 million).<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

6 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

F<strong>in</strong>al report - 16 November 2010<br />

• $440 million is spent on imported <strong>in</strong>puts such as fertilizer ($138 million),<br />

pharmaceuticals ($111 million), feed ($31 million), agricultural equipment ($26<br />

million) and pesticides ($16 million).<br />

• $290 million is spent on marg<strong>in</strong> services such as transport.<br />

7


Table 3 Farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry structure<br />

Input Dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g Comment<br />

Land 21% Includes Gross Marg<strong>in</strong><br />

Capital 15%<br />

Labour 5%<br />

Domestic <strong>in</strong>termediates 47% Ag services, feed, fertilizer<br />

Imported <strong>in</strong>termediates 8% Fertilizer, pharmaceuticals,<br />

feed<br />

Marg<strong>in</strong>s 4% Transport<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

1.7.3 Dairy process<strong>in</strong>g<br />

The dairy process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry takes the raw milk and turns it <strong>in</strong> to products that can be sold to<br />

customers and consumers. The <strong>in</strong>dustry produces a wide range of dairy products, from milk<br />

and cheese to ice cream and butter.<br />

The vast majority of the <strong>in</strong>dustry’s <strong>in</strong>put costs are the purchase of the raw milk, which<br />

accounts for 70% of the <strong>in</strong>dustry’s costs. In addition, the process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry uses about $1.1<br />

billion of capital and employs close to 10,000 FTE employees.<br />

Of the $10.4 billion exported by our model’s dairy process<strong>in</strong>g sector:<br />

• $7.5 billion is used to purchase raw milk from the dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g sector.<br />

• $1.5 billion is reta<strong>in</strong>ed as returns to labour and capital (i.e. wages and rate of return).<br />

• $625 million is spent on <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts from <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>. This <strong>in</strong>cludes $85 million<br />

of plastic conta<strong>in</strong>ers, $45 million on electricity and $22.5 million on f<strong>in</strong>ancial services.<br />

• Imported <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts account for $310 million – largely plastic conta<strong>in</strong>ers ($182<br />

million) and other food products to be used <strong>in</strong> process<strong>in</strong>g ($30 million).<br />

• $730 million is spent on retail<strong>in</strong>g/wholesal<strong>in</strong>g costs that get the dairy products from the<br />

plant to market.<br />

Table 4 Dairy process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry structure<br />

Input Share Comment<br />

Capital 7% Includes Gross Marg<strong>in</strong><br />

Labour 7%<br />

Raw milk 66%<br />

Other <strong>in</strong>termediates 12% Other farm <strong>in</strong>puts<br />

Other imported <strong>in</strong>termediates 6% Mostly plastic – packag<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Marg<strong>in</strong>s 2% Retail<strong>in</strong>g and wholesal<strong>in</strong>g<br />

costs<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

7


8 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Dairy exports and rural livelihoods<br />

Any <strong>in</strong>quiry <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy and its work<strong>in</strong>gs has to at some po<strong>in</strong>t focus<br />

on the central driv<strong>in</strong>g force of economic growth: trade. Trade is important because over<br />

time <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s spend<strong>in</strong>g must equal its <strong>in</strong>come. Without <strong>in</strong>ternational trade the<br />

<strong>in</strong>come of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> bus<strong>in</strong>esses is limited by domestic spend<strong>in</strong>g. International trade<br />

removes this limit.<br />

With dairy exports at 26% of goods exports, the impact of the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry on<br />

economic activity is considerable. The money that farmers spend <strong>in</strong> their communities<br />

and <strong>in</strong> other parts of the country drives further economic activity – the more they earn<br />

on <strong>in</strong>ternational markets the more they spend <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>. Dairy farmers’success is<br />

mirrored not only <strong>in</strong> their local communities but also <strong>in</strong> the cities of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> which<br />

produce the goods and services that are bought by farmers. Even imports have a local<br />

component s<strong>in</strong>ce they have to be transported to the po<strong>in</strong>t of sale.<br />

Nobody understands this more than the mayors of the districts, regions and cities of <strong>New</strong><br />

<strong>Zealand</strong>. Peter Tennent, Mayor of <strong>New</strong> Plymouth, says that “while the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> his<br />

region only makes up 2% of the workforce, 100% of the community are the benefactors<br />

of their efforts. When dairy farmers are smil<strong>in</strong>g, the region smiles”. Hugh Vercoe, Mayor of<br />

the Matamata Piako District, also knows how important dairy is to his district: “not only<br />

are we reliant on the dairy [farm<strong>in</strong>g] <strong>in</strong>dustry, we have five dairy process<strong>in</strong>g plants and<br />

very active sale yards. This helps to ma<strong>in</strong>ta<strong>in</strong> a vibrant community”. David Adamson, CEO<br />

of the Southland District Council says that the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry has “changed the face of<br />

Southland”. He adds that “its economy has weathered the recession well, ma<strong>in</strong>ly because<br />

of the <strong>in</strong>fluence of the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry”.<br />

In the first <strong>in</strong>stance farmers spend their <strong>in</strong>comes on <strong>in</strong>dustries that directly support<br />

their activities. They buy more cows, upgrade equipment, buy fertilizer, repay debt and<br />

make land improvements. David Adamson suggests that this is the most visible sign<br />

of the impact of dairy growth on the Southland region: “most of the money earned by<br />

farmers is spun out <strong>in</strong>to the community”. S<strong>in</strong>ce most of the goods and services come<br />

from outside of the prov<strong>in</strong>ces, other communities benefit as well. In work done by<br />

NZIER (2003) it is shown that it takes about 18 months for this economic ‘ripple’effect of<br />

additional export revenue to fully work through the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy, all of which<br />

leads to stronger household spend<strong>in</strong>g and bus<strong>in</strong>ess <strong>in</strong>vestment.<br />

What would <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> look like without the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry? Peter Tennent f<strong>in</strong>ds it<br />

difficult to imag<strong>in</strong>e this situation but one th<strong>in</strong>g he does know is that “<strong>New</strong> Plymouth<br />

would not have been judged the best place to live on the planet by the United Nations<br />

backed Liv.com Awards without the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry … we’d still be smil<strong>in</strong>g but not as<br />

wide … and there’d be far fewer bus<strong>in</strong>esses here”. Similar sentiments are echoed by<br />

David Adamson and Hugh Vercoe. Both said there would be fewer bus<strong>in</strong>esses, less<br />

vibrant community, and fewer job opportunities. Not only would there be fewer job<br />

opportunities and <strong>in</strong>creased movement of people to the cities, those cities would also be<br />

poorer.<br />

The dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry has had a major impact on <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> society and economy for<br />

over 130 years. Those <strong>in</strong>volved <strong>in</strong> runn<strong>in</strong>g districts and cities closest to the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

well understand the positive impact of dairy<strong>in</strong>g, not just on their regions and cities but<br />

on the rest of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>.


2. Modell<strong>in</strong>g dairy’s economic contribution<br />

over the past decade<br />

2.1 Objective of modell<strong>in</strong>g<br />

The section above has shown that the dairy sector has witnessed significant growth over the<br />

past decade. A key question is: how has this growth benefited the rest of the economy? In<br />

particular, we are <strong>in</strong>terested <strong>in</strong> two aspects of this growth:<br />

• The short term impacts of milk solids payout <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

• The longer term impacts of volume growth <strong>in</strong> the sector over the last 10 years.<br />

We exam<strong>in</strong>e these two aspects us<strong>in</strong>g a relatively newly developed economic model of the<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy.<br />

2.2 Modell<strong>in</strong>g technique<br />

The dairy sector <strong>in</strong>teracts with the rest of the economy by generat<strong>in</strong>g exports and<br />

employment, us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts such as fertilizer, and compet<strong>in</strong>g for use of land,<br />

labour and <strong>in</strong>vestment. In order to get a sense of how the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy as a whole<br />

might be impacted by production and price changes <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector, we need to use<br />

an economic model that takes these <strong>in</strong>teractions <strong>in</strong>to account. We use NZIER’s dynamic<br />

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model of the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy to evaluate the<br />

impacts of the price and volume growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector.<br />

2.3 Advantages of CGE modell<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Our dynamic CGE model is a more robust framework than alternatives approaches for<br />

estimat<strong>in</strong>g the contribution of the dairy sector to the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy. The most<br />

commonly used alternative is <strong>in</strong>put-output (IO) or ‘multiplier’analysis. IO or multiplier analysis<br />

has two significant limitations:<br />

• It does not adequately consider the reallocation of resources follow<strong>in</strong>g a ‘shock’to the<br />

economy, such as a surge <strong>in</strong> demand for dairy exports. In particular, multiplier analysis<br />

assumes that resources (land, labour, capital, energy, <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts) are available<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

9


10 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

<strong>in</strong> unlimited quantities for the expansion of a sector. It does not consider how those<br />

resources might otherwise have been used <strong>in</strong> the economy – their opportunity cost. In<br />

reality, resources are scarce and any additional resources used <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector must<br />

be diverted from other <strong>in</strong>dustries. The output of these <strong>in</strong>dustries must therefore fall. The<br />

overall macroeconomic impact of the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> demand <strong>in</strong> one sector should take <strong>in</strong>to<br />

account these losses elsewhere <strong>in</strong> the economy.<br />

• It does not account for relative price changes. For example, it assumes that wage rates<br />

do not change as the demand for labour rises or falls, and that the prices of <strong>in</strong>termediate<br />

goods such as transport and bus<strong>in</strong>ess services do not change <strong>in</strong> response to shifts <strong>in</strong><br />

demand. In reality, if there is additional demand for workers <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector, this will<br />

place upward pressure on wages across the economy. Even though this wage pressure<br />

might be relatively small, it will still have a negative impact on <strong>in</strong>put costs for other firms<br />

<strong>in</strong> the economy, and could lead to a drop <strong>in</strong> output. A similar story is true for <strong>in</strong>termediate<br />

<strong>in</strong>puts. As the dairy sector demands more of these <strong>in</strong>puts, their price rises for all other<br />

firms <strong>in</strong> the economy, caus<strong>in</strong>g their output to fall.<br />

Multiplier analysis therefore tends to vastly overstate the economic impacts of changes<br />

<strong>in</strong> demand <strong>in</strong> a specific sector. These unrealistically large impacts are thus not particularly<br />

<strong>in</strong>formative for policy makers or firms.<br />

CGE models explicitly address both resource allocation and relative price shifts, allow<strong>in</strong>g for<br />

a more credible, richer analysis of economic contribution. These models tend to produce<br />

more conservative estimates of impacts, but are more consistent with economic theory and<br />

practice. See Appendix B for a fuller discussion.<br />

2.4 Modell<strong>in</strong>g scenarios<br />

We <strong>in</strong>vestigate the impact of the dairy sector with two historical scenarios to show how real<br />

changes <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector translate <strong>in</strong>to benefits for the rest of the economy. The historical<br />

scenarios exam<strong>in</strong>e the benefits that have accrued over the past decade:<br />

• milk solids payout <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

• growth <strong>in</strong> the sector over the last 10 years.<br />

These two scenarios jo<strong>in</strong>tly capture both the benefits to the economy of the long term<br />

growth <strong>in</strong> the sector and the short-run wealth ga<strong>in</strong>s from <strong>in</strong>creased milk solids payouts.<br />

• milk solids payout <strong>in</strong>creases<br />

• growth <strong>in</strong> the sector over the last 10 years.<br />

These two scenarios jo<strong>in</strong>tly capture both the benefits to the economy of the long term<br />

growth <strong>in</strong> the sector and the short-run wealth ga<strong>in</strong>s from <strong>in</strong>creased milk solids payouts.<br />

2.4.1 Scenario 1: The price of milk solids<br />

The world price of milk solids has a significant impact on the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry and the wider<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy. It has also been fairly volatile of late, as can be seen from Figure 5.<br />

This first scenario assesses the effects on the economy of changes <strong>in</strong> the milk solids price paid<br />

to farmers. In order to generate higher prices for milk solids we assume that the world price<br />

has risen due to <strong>in</strong>creased world demand for dairy produce. Increased world demand for<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s dairy produce leads to rises <strong>in</strong> both milk prices for <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> dairy farmers<br />

and over a susta<strong>in</strong>ed period a rise <strong>in</strong> the quantity of milk solids produced domestically.<br />

We calibrate the price <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> this simulation to be ± $1/kg milk solids <strong>in</strong> <strong>Fonterra</strong>’s<br />

payout. So we are ask<strong>in</strong>g: what are the flow-on impacts for the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy from a<br />

$1 <strong>in</strong>crease or decrease <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Fonterra</strong> payout?


Figure 5 Change <strong>in</strong> milk solids price: 1998-2009<br />

$ per kg, 2008-09 prices<br />

Figure 5 Change <strong>in</strong> milk solids price: 1998-2009<br />

$ per kg, 2008-09 prices<br />

Figure 5 Change <strong>in</strong> milk solids price: 1998-2009<br />

$ per kg, 2008-09 prices<br />

Source: Dairy NZ<br />

F<strong>in</strong>al report - 16 November 2010<br />

2.4.2 Scenario Source: 2: Dairy The NZ growth of dairy<strong>in</strong>g over the past decade<br />

Over the 2.4.2 last Scenario 10 years 2: The the growth dairy of sector dairy<strong>in</strong>g has over grown the past significantly, decade <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g milk solid<br />

production 2.4.2 Scenario<br />

Over the<br />

by<br />

last<br />

58% 2:<br />

10 years<br />

between The growth<br />

the dairy<br />

1998/89 of<br />

sector has<br />

and dairy<strong>in</strong>g<br />

grown<br />

2008/09. over<br />

significantly,<br />

In the this<br />

<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g<br />

case past<br />

milk<br />

study, decade<br />

solid<br />

we ask the<br />

questions: Over the production last ‘what 10 by if years 58% it hadn’t between the dairy grown’? 1998/89 sector and has 2008/09. ‘what grown would In this significantly, case the study, economy we<strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g askhave the questions: missed milk solid out<br />

on production if dairy ‘what had if by it hadn’t stagnated 58% grown’? between at and 1999 1998/89 ‘what production wouldand the economy 2008/09. levels’? have In missed this case out onstudy, if dairywe had ask the<br />

questions: stagnated ‘what at 1999 if it hadn’t production grown’? levels’? and ‘what would the economy have missed out<br />

The factual is the actual volume path as it occurred; the counterfactual is volumes<br />

on if dairy The factual had stagnated is the actualat volume 1999 path production as it occurred; levels’? the counterfactual is volumes rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g<br />

rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g at 1998/99 levels, as per Figure 6.<br />

at 1998/99 levels, as per Figure 6.<br />

The factual is the actual volume path as it occurred; the counterfactual is volumes<br />

rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g Figure at 1998/99 6 6 Processed levels, milk as milk solids per Figure solids 6.<br />

Million kgs<br />

Figure 6 Processed milk solids<br />

Million kgs<br />

Source: Dairy Statistics 2008/09<br />

Source: Dairy Statistics 2008/09<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

12<br />

12<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

11


12 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

2.5 How we analyse the modell<strong>in</strong>g results<br />

In analys<strong>in</strong>g the modell<strong>in</strong>g results we take a systematic approach of track<strong>in</strong>g the impacts as<br />

they flow through the economy, beg<strong>in</strong>n<strong>in</strong>g with the direct impacts on the dairy sector itself.<br />

We look at the export and domestic markets, and how the sector responds to growth with<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased employment and <strong>in</strong>vestment.<br />

We then analyse the flow-on or <strong>in</strong>direct impacts on other <strong>in</strong>dustries. We split <strong>in</strong>direct impacts<br />

<strong>in</strong>to the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry categories:<br />

• Supply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that supply dairy with <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts are likely to<br />

benefit from a stronger dairy sector. These are <strong>in</strong>dustries such as agricultural services and<br />

the fertilizer <strong>in</strong>dustry.<br />

• Household expenditure <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that households spend money on are<br />

likely to benefit from <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>come that comes through higher employment and<br />

wages, and <strong>in</strong>creased returns to capital from a grow<strong>in</strong>g dairy sector.<br />

• Government <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that rely on government fund<strong>in</strong>g are positively<br />

impacted by a stronger economy and bigger tax takes, as this <strong>in</strong>creases the money<br />

available for the government to spend.<br />

• Compet<strong>in</strong>g export <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that compete for resources (such as land and<br />

labour) with the dairy sector lose from dairy’s growth.<br />

F<strong>in</strong>ally, we exam<strong>in</strong>e the macroeconomic effects. Here we report both value-add (GDP) and<br />

Net Economic Benefit/welfare (private and public consumption) measures.<br />

There are two ways to th<strong>in</strong>k about the way that export growth will affect GDP:<br />

(i) GDP is the sum of the value of expenditure on goods and services made <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong><br />

<strong>Zealand</strong> and exports are a component of that expenditure, so a change <strong>in</strong> exports<br />

directly affects the level of GDP. The change <strong>in</strong> exports will then have flow-on effects<br />

on other parts of the economy, as described <strong>in</strong> our results section.<br />

(ii) GDP is also the sum of the value of resources utilised <strong>in</strong> the economy. Increased dairy<br />

exports are generated, <strong>in</strong> part, by ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> productivity. Greater productivity allows<br />

the same resources – capital, land and labour – to generate greater value, so GDP<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases as productivity rises. Thus we expect export growth to have a direct impact<br />

on GDP and, <strong>in</strong> the long run, a positive impact.<br />

Although GDP is the most commonly used measure of economic performance, it does<br />

not capture necessarily how ‘well off’we are as a country. GDP is essentially a measure of<br />

how many goods and services <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> produces – it shows the size of the economy.<br />

Consumption shows how much household and government spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>creases follow<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a change <strong>in</strong> the economy. It is more appropriate than GDP as a measure of welfare (see<br />

Coleman, 2008), particularly <strong>in</strong> cases where we expect changes <strong>in</strong> the terms of trade 7 .<br />

Ultimately, the objective of an economic development is to raise the liv<strong>in</strong>g standards of the<br />

population. Liv<strong>in</strong>g standards are better proxied by household and government spend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

ability than by GDP. Thus our preferred NEB/welfare measure is consumption. Our CGE model<br />

allows us to determ<strong>in</strong>e, once all <strong>in</strong>ter-<strong>in</strong>dustry effects and factor price changes have occurred,<br />

the additional boost to <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s GDP and NEB/welfare result<strong>in</strong>g from a price change<br />

<strong>in</strong> the milk solids payout or volume growth <strong>in</strong> the sector. In addition, we also report other<br />

macroeconomic <strong>in</strong>dicators such as wages and employment.<br />

7. We use the term ‘welfare’here not <strong>in</strong> the technical economic sense but merely as a synonym for ‘wellbe<strong>in</strong>g’. The claim is merely that<br />

changes <strong>in</strong> consumption better proxy changes <strong>in</strong> welfare than do changes <strong>in</strong> GDP. We do not claim to actually measure welfare <strong>in</strong><br />

the technical sense.


3. Milk solids price spike<br />

3.1 Headl<strong>in</strong>e results<br />

A short term <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the price of milk solids generates immediate benefits for the national<br />

economy. The national benefit of an <strong>in</strong>crease of $1/kg <strong>in</strong> the <strong>Fonterra</strong> payout is a welfare<br />

ga<strong>in</strong> of $1.2 billion, as proxied by private and public consumption. In addition, national GDP<br />

is expected to rise by $400 million 8 . The richer dairy sector would generate employment of<br />

approximately 4,600 more FTEs and wages would later start to rise 9 .<br />

The welfare ga<strong>in</strong> is larger than the GDP ga<strong>in</strong> due to the impact of exchange rate movements:<br />

• the improved terms of trade allows us to consume more of our GDP (i.e. we have to<br />

export less to pay for a given amount of imports – mak<strong>in</strong>g the country better off as a<br />

whole)<br />

• the currency appreciation leads to a reduction <strong>in</strong> the value of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s foreign debt.<br />

Both effects improve <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>ers’household purchas<strong>in</strong>g power and allow greater<br />

consumption of goods and services.<br />

3.2 Detailed results<br />

3.2.1 Direct effects: the dairy sector<br />

In the first simulation the <strong>in</strong>creased world demand for dairy products drives up both the price<br />

and volume of dairy exports. That is passed on down the supply cha<strong>in</strong> and results <strong>in</strong> a $1<br />

per kilogram of milk solids <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> payments to dairy farmers. The <strong>in</strong>creased payout and<br />

volumes cause the dairy sector grows strongly to generate the extra production.<br />

The <strong>in</strong>creased payout causes <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the farm<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustry to grow by 44%, and<br />

employment by 20%. Investment <strong>in</strong> the process<strong>in</strong>g component of the <strong>in</strong>dustry grows by<br />

14% and employment by 5.5%, relative to what would otherwise have occurred. Investment<br />

growth is higher than employment growth because capital accumulation tends to lag beh<strong>in</strong>d<br />

employment growth. The farm<strong>in</strong>g component of the sector grows more strongly because<br />

we have assumed that the benefits of higher world prices will be passed on to farmers. If<br />

dairy processors were to <strong>in</strong>crease their profit marg<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>stead then the differences would<br />

dim<strong>in</strong>ish 10 .<br />

8. This is on top of the <strong>in</strong>come generated by the ‘base’price. That is, if the 2011 price (say) is $5 and the 2012 payout is $6, our results<br />

look just at the additional <strong>in</strong>come generated by the $1 price <strong>in</strong>crease.<br />

9. The direct impact on the economy of a $1 <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the milk solids price is a $1.3 billion <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> gross output. That gross<br />

output generates about $590 million of GDP once the cost of <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts is subtracted. Furthermore, the effect of the<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased dairy output is to <strong>in</strong>crease the price of resources to other <strong>in</strong>dustries and thus reduce their output. The net effect on GDP<br />

of the $1.3 billion <strong>in</strong>jection, once all these effects have been taken <strong>in</strong> to account, is the $400 million we report.<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

13


14 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

3.2.2 Indirect impact on other <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

The <strong>in</strong>direct impacts can be broken down <strong>in</strong>to the <strong>in</strong>dustry categories described <strong>in</strong> section<br />

2.5. The numerical results are summarised <strong>in</strong> Table 5.<br />

• Supply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that supply dairy with <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts are likely<br />

to benefit from a stronger dairy sector. However, the fertilizer <strong>in</strong>dustry loses 0.2% of its<br />

sales. That counter<strong>in</strong>tuitive result arises from the movements <strong>in</strong> the exchange rate, which<br />

will be discussed further <strong>in</strong> the next section. As exports rise, imports become relatively<br />

cheaper and that causes primary producers to switch away from domestically produced<br />

fertiliser <strong>in</strong> favour of imported fertilisers.<br />

• Government expenditure <strong>in</strong>dustries – as expected, the <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>comes from the<br />

higher milk solids payout boost tax revenues and enable the government to spend more<br />

provid<strong>in</strong>g services such as education, health, and law and order.<br />

• Household expenditure <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that households spend money on<br />

are likely to benefit from <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>comes generated <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector through<br />

employment and wage <strong>in</strong>creases, and <strong>in</strong>creased returns to capital. Such <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

<strong>in</strong>clude hous<strong>in</strong>g and real estate (which takes a large share of households’budget), and<br />

consumption goods from the retail trade sector.<br />

• Compet<strong>in</strong>g export <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that compete for resources with the dairy<br />

sector suffer from the dairy sector’s <strong>in</strong>creased spend<strong>in</strong>g power. That is particularly so<br />

for the sheep and beef sector, which uses many of the same resources. In addition,<br />

the appreciation of the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> dollar that results from <strong>in</strong>creased exports of<br />

dairy products hurts all exporters, as seen by the drop <strong>in</strong> production of the textile and<br />

horticulture sectors.<br />

10. The second simulation with a $1 per kilogram price decrease shows near identical effects <strong>in</strong> the opposite direction. In the <strong>in</strong>terests<br />

of brevity we report only the results for the price <strong>in</strong>crease here.


Table 5 Indirect impacts 2010<br />

Percentage deviation <strong>in</strong> value added from BAU levels, selected <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

Industry Type Impact<br />

Agricultural services Supply<strong>in</strong>g 0.09%<br />

Fertilizer Supply<strong>in</strong>g -0.2%<br />

Retail Household expenditure 0.7%<br />

Real estate Household expenditure 1.1%<br />

Residential property Household expenditure 0.03%<br />

Schools Government 1.1%<br />

Hospitals Government 1.3%<br />

Police Government 0.8%<br />

Apple and Pear Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -3.0%<br />

Sheep and Beef Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -0.4%<br />

Textiles Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -1.3%<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

3.2.3 Macroeconomic effects<br />

The national results follow naturally from the direct and <strong>in</strong>direct impacts described above. We<br />

focus on the key macroeconomic variables described <strong>in</strong> section 2.5: employment and Gross<br />

Domestic Product (GDP), as well as consumption, which is a measure of NEB (how ‘well off’<br />

we are).<br />

The NEB/welfare ga<strong>in</strong> for <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>, proxied by private and public consumption is an<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease of 1.2%. That represents an extra $1.2 billion of goods consumed <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>,<br />

relative to the situation if the price of milk solids had rema<strong>in</strong>ed constant. This equates to over<br />

$270 of additional spend<strong>in</strong>g per man, woman and child <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> due to the $1/kg<br />

price <strong>in</strong>crease.<br />

The change <strong>in</strong> real GDP of 0.24%, or $395 million, represents the <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the value of<br />

goods and services produced <strong>in</strong> the economy. The benefits arise from the <strong>in</strong>creased flows of<br />

<strong>in</strong>come to farmers be<strong>in</strong>g distributed throughout the economy via supply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries and<br />

government and household spend<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

The NEB ga<strong>in</strong> is larger than the GDP ga<strong>in</strong> for two reasons:<br />

• An <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the price of dairy exports improves <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s terms of trade. An<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the terms of trade allows us to consume more of our GDP.<br />

• The assumed <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> demand for dairy exports causes a currency appreciation that<br />

leads to a reduction <strong>in</strong> the domestic currency value of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s <strong>in</strong>terest repayments<br />

on foreign debt. This improves <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>ers’household purchas<strong>in</strong>g power and allows<br />

greater consumption of goods and services. Under different assumptions about the<br />

mechanisms of foreign <strong>in</strong>vestment, this contribution is dampened (see Appendix C).<br />

Overall, the <strong>in</strong>creased milk solids price draws wealth <strong>in</strong>to the country via dairy exports and<br />

that leads to an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s wealth and, thus, our liv<strong>in</strong>g standards.<br />

The impact on export compet<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries is negative because of the appreciation of our<br />

currency. However, that same appreciation allows us to buy more from overseas as can be<br />

seen by the rise <strong>in</strong> imports and private consumption (see Table 6).<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

15


16 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

The <strong>in</strong>creased production <strong>in</strong> dairy draws <strong>in</strong> more labour, which is shown by the rise <strong>in</strong><br />

employment. Note however that, <strong>in</strong> our modell<strong>in</strong>g, employment is assumed to vary much<br />

more quickly than wages. In the short timeframe of this simulation we would not expect to<br />

see much impact on wages because they have not had time to adjust. Similarly, while the<br />

rate of return on dairy capital has risen, the level of capital <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>dustry has not yet had<br />

time to accumulate.<br />

Table 6 National results<br />

Real percentage deviation from BAU levels<br />

Indicator Percentage change Levels change,<br />

$ millions<br />

GDP 0.24% $400<br />

Private Consumption 1.2% $1,200<br />

Public Consumption 1.2% $360<br />

Exports (volume) -1.8% -$1,000<br />

Imports (volume) 1.4% $720<br />

Employment 0.35% 4,600 FTEs<br />

Hospitals Government 1.3%<br />

Police Government 0.8%<br />

Apple and Pear Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -3.0%<br />

Sheep and Beef Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -0.4%<br />

Textiles Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -1.3%<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

3.2.4 Regional impacts<br />

The impact on the districts is <strong>in</strong> proportion to the importance of the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry to the<br />

region. The majority of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s dairy<strong>in</strong>g is <strong>in</strong> the central North Island and that is<br />

reflected <strong>in</strong> the strong growth of Taranaki, Waikato and the Manawatu. However, dairy is<br />

also very important to the small Northland economy, which is why the large ga<strong>in</strong>s are seen<br />

there. Districts that have strong red meat <strong>in</strong>dustries, such as Canterbury, suffer due to the<br />

competition for resources from the grow<strong>in</strong>g dairy sector <strong>in</strong> this simulation. Similarly, districts<br />

that depend on exports, such as Tasman’s w<strong>in</strong>e and Auckland’s manufactur<strong>in</strong>g, see low<br />

growth due to the costs imposed by the appreciation of the exchange rate.<br />

The impacts of a $1/kg price <strong>in</strong>crease on per person consumption or liv<strong>in</strong>g standards <strong>in</strong> each<br />

region are shown <strong>in</strong> Table 7.


Figure 7 Gross regional product impacts<br />

Real Figure percentage 7 Gross deviation regional from BAU product levels impacts<br />

Real percentage deviation from BAU levels<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

Table 7 Increase <strong>in</strong> gross regional product<br />

Table 7 Increase <strong>in</strong> gross regional product<br />

Region Northland $170 Per person <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> GRP<br />

Northland<br />

Auckland -$4<br />

$170<br />

Auckland<br />

Waikato $130<br />

-$4<br />

Waikato<br />

Bay Of Plenty<br />

Bay Of Plenty<br />

Gisborne<br />

Gisborne<br />

$66<br />

$100<br />

$130<br />

$66<br />

$100<br />

Hawkes Bay<br />

Hawkes Bay<br />

$39<br />

$39<br />

Taranaki<br />

Taranaki $160<br />

$160<br />

Manawatu-Wanganui $140<br />

$140<br />

Well<strong>in</strong>gton $140<br />

$140<br />

Tasman-Nelson $12<br />

$12<br />

Marlborough $54<br />

$54<br />

West West Coast Coast $69<br />

$69<br />

Canterbury<br />

Canterbury $41<br />

$41<br />

Otago<br />

Otago<br />

Southland<br />

Southland<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

$82<br />

$68<br />

$82<br />

$68<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Region Per person <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> GRP<br />

F<strong>in</strong>al report - 16 November 2010<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g 19 growth<br />

17


18 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Where the money goes<br />

To illustrate the impact of dairy farmer spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy, Table 8 sets<br />

out the key cash flow items for an average dairy farm operation for the current 2010/11 June<br />

year. In the current year Dairy NZ expects the average dairy farm to produce around 130,000<br />

kg of milksolids. The cash <strong>in</strong>come is the dollar amount received for milksolids sold to the<br />

factory (i.e. <strong>Fonterra</strong>) and also <strong>in</strong>cludes net livestock sales.<br />

Table 8: Average farm cashflow<br />

$ per farm, $ per kg MS<br />

2010/11<br />

$ per kg MS<br />

2010/11<br />

$ per kg MS<br />

Cash Income 840,000 6.80<br />

Less farm work<strong>in</strong>g expenses 475,000 3.60<br />

Cash Operat<strong>in</strong>g Surplus 365,000 3.20<br />

Less<br />

Interest and rent 185,000 1.50<br />

Tax 35,000 0.25<br />

Draw<strong>in</strong>gs 85,000 0.70<br />

Cash available for development/<br />

<strong>in</strong>vestment/debt repayment<br />

60,000 0.75<br />

Apple and Pear Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -3.0%<br />

Sheep and Beef Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -0.4%<br />

Textiles Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -1.3%<br />

Note: Figures are rounded so do not exactly add up<br />

Source: Dairy <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> 2010<br />

A substantial part of farmers’expenses are the farm work<strong>in</strong>g expenses. Farm work<strong>in</strong>g<br />

expenses typically <strong>in</strong>clude wages, animal health and breed<strong>in</strong>g, feed made and purchased,<br />

stock graz<strong>in</strong>g fertiliser, expenditure on remov<strong>in</strong>g weed and pests, repairs and ma<strong>in</strong>tenance,<br />

fuel, vehicle charges, adm<strong>in</strong>istration, <strong>in</strong>surance, ACC, and rates.<br />

This leaves what is known as the cash operat<strong>in</strong>g surplus. This is less than half of the <strong>in</strong>itial<br />

cash <strong>in</strong>come. From this farmers pay off <strong>in</strong>terest and rent (this <strong>in</strong>cludes overdraft and term<br />

payments and also rent of land), tax (term<strong>in</strong>al and estimated tax), and draw<strong>in</strong>gs (family liv<strong>in</strong>g<br />

expenses). This leaves the cash available for farm development, any <strong>in</strong>vestments made and<br />

repay<strong>in</strong>g pr<strong>in</strong>cipal on debt.<br />

This demonstrates that most of the money received by farmers as their cash <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong> one<br />

form or another is spent <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>. This is of fundamental importance for the <strong>New</strong><br />

<strong>Zealand</strong> economy s<strong>in</strong>ce it drives further <strong>in</strong>come generation and has a major impact on<br />

domestic economic activity.


4. Production growth over the last decade<br />

4.1 Headl<strong>in</strong>e results<br />

At the national level, the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector over the last decade has resulted <strong>in</strong>:<br />

• <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s 2009 GDP <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g by $690 million, relative to what it would have been<br />

had the dairy sector stagnated at 1998/99 levels. While labour and land can switch to<br />

alternative uses should dairy have stagnated, productivity ga<strong>in</strong>s and capital accumulation<br />

with<strong>in</strong> the sector are net ga<strong>in</strong>s to the economy.<br />

• <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s 2009 welfare as proxied by private and public consumption be<strong>in</strong>g<br />

$1.1 billion higher than it would otherwise been. From the po<strong>in</strong>t of view of 1999, the<br />

cumulative net present value (NPV) of the decade’s consumption growth to 2009 is $6.4<br />

billion.<br />

• The dairy sector’s strong export growth over the last decade has improved <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s<br />

balance of trade, and allowed for <strong>in</strong>creased consumption spend<strong>in</strong>g. This export growth<br />

reduced <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s net foreign liabilities to GDP ratio by over 1%. Together with the<br />

exchange rate appreciation, this saved $231 million <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest repayments on foreign<br />

debt <strong>in</strong> 2009, or cumulatively $1.2 billion from 1999.<br />

• Real wages <strong>in</strong> 2009 <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g by 0.9% as <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>comes means <strong>in</strong>creased demand<br />

for goods and services, which <strong>in</strong> turn results <strong>in</strong> higher wages for employees.<br />

Significantly, the ga<strong>in</strong>s from the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g wage rises, are not just<br />

felt with<strong>in</strong> the sector itself, but more widely throughout the economy:<br />

• Growth <strong>in</strong> the fertilizer and agricultural service <strong>in</strong>dustries, which supply the dairy sector<br />

with <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts, are up by 0.9% and 4.3% <strong>in</strong> 2009, relative to what they would<br />

have been if dairy stagnated.<br />

• Industries where households spend their <strong>in</strong>come, such as retail and hous<strong>in</strong>g, also benefit<br />

from the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector, with activity <strong>in</strong> 2009 0.5% and 0.9% higher than had<br />

dairy not grown as experienced.<br />

• These positive flow-on impacts have further flow-on impacts to the tax-take of the<br />

government. Increased tax revenue com<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> means more money to spend on essential<br />

services such as schools, hospitals and police. In 2009, these sectors are 0.7%, 0.6% and<br />

0.2% better off because of the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector.<br />

• Conversely, there are <strong>in</strong>dustries that have lost from growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector, most<br />

notably the sheep and beef sector which competes for resources. Our modell<strong>in</strong>g<br />

suggests that this <strong>in</strong>dustry would have grown by an extra 10% over the last decade,<br />

had dairy stagnated rather than grown. Similarly, other export <strong>in</strong>dustries such as textiles<br />

and apples and pears suffered from a higher exchange rate, down by -2.3% and -3.0%<br />

respectively.<br />

Regionally, the results favour those areas where dairy farm<strong>in</strong>g has grown the most:<br />

• Canterbury and Southland 2009 regional GDP levels are 1.4% and 1.3% higher than they<br />

would have been had dairy<strong>in</strong>g not <strong>in</strong>creased the economic activity with<strong>in</strong> their districts.<br />

• Hawkes Bay, with a strong dependence on fruit and horticulture, is 0.3% worse off<br />

because of the currency appreciation caused by the growth <strong>in</strong> dairy<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

19


20 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

because of the currency appreciation caused by the growth <strong>in</strong> dairy<strong>in</strong>g.<br />

4.2 Detailed results<br />

4.2.1 Direct impacts<br />

4.2 Detailed results<br />

The direct<br />

4.2.1<br />

impacts<br />

Direct<br />

are<br />

impacts<br />

the ga<strong>in</strong>s of the dairy sector over the last decade. Figure 8<br />

shows that the dairy sector grew substantially between 1998/99 and 2008/09. Milk<br />

The direct impacts are the ga<strong>in</strong>s of the dairy sector over the last decade. Figure 8 shows<br />

solids output<br />

that the<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased<br />

dairy sector grew<br />

by<br />

substantially<br />

58%, use<br />

between<br />

of land<br />

1998/99<br />

grew<br />

and<br />

by<br />

2008/09.<br />

25%,<br />

Milk<br />

while<br />

solids<br />

total<br />

output<br />

factor<br />

productivity <strong>in</strong>creased rema<strong>in</strong>ed by 58%, usepositive of land grewfor by 25%, most whileof total the factordecade, productivitybefore rema<strong>in</strong>eddropp<strong>in</strong>g, positive<br />

unsurpris<strong>in</strong>gly, for most of dur<strong>in</strong>g the decade, the drought before dropp<strong>in</strong>g, seasons. unsurpris<strong>in</strong>gly, Productivity dur<strong>in</strong>g growth the drought is likely seasons. to return to<br />

positive Productivity trend levels growth now is likely that to more return‘normal’ to positiveclimatic trend levels conditions now that more have ‘normal’climatic returned. The<br />

sector’s conditions employment have grew returned. by The around sector’s 7,500 employment FTEs. grew These by around ga<strong>in</strong>s 7,500 would FTEs. have These been ga<strong>in</strong>slost<br />

if dairy rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g would have stagnant been lost if at dairy 1998/99 rema<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g levels. stagnant at 1998/99 levels.<br />

Figure 8 Dairy ga<strong>in</strong>s s<strong>in</strong>ce 1998/99<br />

Figure 8 Dairy ga<strong>in</strong>s s<strong>in</strong>ce 1998/99<br />

Source: Dairy NZ<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

4.2.2 Indirect impacts on other <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

4.2.2 Indirect impacts on other <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

A grow<strong>in</strong>g dairy sector <strong>in</strong>directly impacts other <strong>in</strong>dustries. These <strong>in</strong>direct impacts can be split<br />

A grow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to dairy the follow<strong>in</strong>g sector categories: <strong>in</strong>directly impacts other <strong>in</strong>dustries. These <strong>in</strong>direct impacts can<br />

be split <strong>in</strong>to • Supply<strong>in</strong>g the follow<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries categories: – <strong>in</strong>dustries that supply dairy with <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts are likely to<br />

benefit from a stronger dairy sector. Both agricultural services and the fertilizer <strong>in</strong>dustry<br />

• Supply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that supply dairy with <strong>in</strong>termediate <strong>in</strong>puts are<br />

achieve significant ga<strong>in</strong>s, up 0.9% and 4.2% <strong>in</strong> 2009 versus where they would have been<br />

likely to benefit from a stronger dairy sector. Both agricultural services and the<br />

had dairy not grown over the last decade.<br />

fertilizer <strong>in</strong>dustry achieve significant ga<strong>in</strong>s, up 0.9% and 4.2% <strong>in</strong> 2009 versus<br />

where • they Household would expenditure have been <strong>in</strong>dustries had dairy – <strong>in</strong>dustries not grown that households over the last spend decade.<br />

money on are<br />

likely to benefit from <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>come that comes through employment and wages, and<br />

<strong>in</strong>creased returns to capital from a grow<strong>in</strong>g dairy sector. Retail trade and real estate are<br />

both up: 0.5% and 0.7% respectively.<br />

• Government <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that rely on government fund<strong>in</strong>g are positively<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s<br />

impacted<br />

<strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong><br />

by<br />

generat<strong>in</strong>g<br />

a stronger economy<br />

growth<br />

22<br />

and bigger tax takes, as this <strong>in</strong>creases the money<br />

available for the government to spend. Spend<strong>in</strong>g on hospitals, schools and police are up<br />

0.6%, 0.7% and 0.2% respectively.<br />

• Compet<strong>in</strong>g export <strong>in</strong>dustries – <strong>in</strong>dustries that compete for resources (such as land and<br />

labour) with the dairy sector lose from dairy’s growth. Sheep and beef, <strong>in</strong> particular, grew<br />

by 10% less, crowded out by the growth <strong>in</strong> dairy<strong>in</strong>g. Similarly, apple and pear and the<br />

textiles <strong>in</strong>dustry both suffer from a higher currency that is a result of the growth <strong>in</strong> dairy.


Table 9 Indirect impacts 2008/09<br />

Percentage deviation from BAU levels, selected <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

Industry Type Impact<br />

Agricultural services Supply<strong>in</strong>g 0.9%<br />

Fertilizer Supply<strong>in</strong>g 4.2%<br />

Retail Household expenditure 0.5%<br />

Real estate Household expenditure 0.7%<br />

Residential property Household expenditure 0.9%<br />

Schools Government 0.7%<br />

Hospitals Government 0.6%<br />

Police Government 0.2%<br />

Apple and Pear Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -2.3%<br />

Sheep and Beef Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -9.9%<br />

Textiles Compet<strong>in</strong>g export -3.0%<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

4.2.3 Macroeconomic effects<br />

The overall national result for the case study of the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector over the last<br />

decade, relative to a case where it stagnated at 1998/99 levels, is a real GDP ga<strong>in</strong> of 0.37% by<br />

2009, or around $690 million. The result is positive for NZ Inc because of:<br />

• export, capital and productivity ga<strong>in</strong>s that accrued over the last decade with<strong>in</strong> the dairy sector<br />

• positive flow-on impacts to supply<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries, household expenditure <strong>in</strong>dustries, and<br />

government funded <strong>in</strong>dustries.<br />

The NEB/welfare ga<strong>in</strong> for <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>, proxied by private and public consumption<br />

(household and government spend<strong>in</strong>g respectively), is an <strong>in</strong>crease of 0.8%. That represents a<br />

ga<strong>in</strong> of $1.1 billion of consumption <strong>in</strong> 2009, relative to BAU. The NEB result is greater than the<br />

GDP ga<strong>in</strong> for the same reasons given <strong>in</strong> section 3.2.3.<br />

An alternative way to th<strong>in</strong>k about the ga<strong>in</strong>s from growth <strong>in</strong> dairy production is through<br />

their cumulative effect. In each year there is an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> consumption that is enjoyed<br />

by consumers. So far, we have measured that by giv<strong>in</strong>g the ga<strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> 2009 of $1.1 billion.<br />

Exam<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stead the net present value (NPV) of the years’consumption ga<strong>in</strong>s gives a better<br />

picture of the cumulative benefit to the nation. 11 From the po<strong>in</strong>t of view of 1999, the NPV<br />

of the decade’s consumption growth to 2009 is $6.4 billion. That is to say the ga<strong>in</strong>s realised<br />

from 1999-2009 are equivalent to the nation’s consumption <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g by $6.4 billion <strong>in</strong> 1999,<br />

which would have been 4.3% of 1999’s total consumption.<br />

The significant export ga<strong>in</strong>s from dairy<strong>in</strong>g reduce the ratio of <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s foreign debt to<br />

GDP by over 1%. Together with the exchange rate appreciation, this saves the country $231<br />

million <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest repayments on foreign debt. Across the decade, the NPV of the <strong>in</strong>terest<br />

sav<strong>in</strong>gs from the viewpo<strong>in</strong>t of 1999 total $1.2 billion.<br />

These positive impacts are partially offset by crowd<strong>in</strong>g out of the sheep and beef and other<br />

export<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries that suffer from a currency appreciation, and the decreased availability<br />

of resources (capital, labour and land). Our modell<strong>in</strong>g captures the fact that land or labour not<br />

be<strong>in</strong>g used by a grow<strong>in</strong>g dairy sector could have been used by other <strong>in</strong>dustries such as sheep<br />

and beef. This dampens the impact of the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector, but doesn’t fully offset it. 12<br />

11. We use the Treasury’s preferred social discount rate of 8%pa.<br />

12. We do not consider Crown costs associated with the <strong>in</strong>creased greenhouse gas emissions result<strong>in</strong>g from dairy production. In our<br />

modell<strong>in</strong>g framework, if dairy had not grown s<strong>in</strong>ce 1998/99, other sectors would have soaked up the spare resources (land, labour,<br />

capital, energy, etc). These sectors would then have produced additional emissions. Ascerta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the net effect of this shift <strong>in</strong><br />

production is difficult.<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

21


22 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

The slight reduction <strong>in</strong> overall export volumes is a result of an <strong>in</strong>creased terms of trade, which<br />

allows <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> to export less quantity for more value.<br />

Overall, a comb<strong>in</strong>ation of higher output and higher exports means <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> is<br />

fundamentally wealthier because of the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector. In terms of the nation’s<br />

overall productive capacity, labour and land are able to switch to alternative uses (and<br />

therefore could have been used by alternative <strong>in</strong>dustries); however productivity and capital<br />

ga<strong>in</strong>s dur<strong>in</strong>g the growth of the dairy sector lead to an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s GDP.<br />

Table 10 National results 2009<br />

Real percentage deviation from BAU levels<br />

Indicator Percentage change Levels change, $<br />

millions<br />

GDP 0.37 $690<br />

Private Consumption 0.77 $860<br />

Public Consumption 0.77 $290<br />

Exports (volume) -0.13 -$66<br />

Imports (volume) 0.95 $350<br />

Real wage 0.92 n/a<br />

Capital 0.61 n/a<br />

Ratio foreign liabilities to GDP -1.04 -$231 (1)<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

(1) Change <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest repayments on foreign debt<br />

4.2.4 Regional impacts<br />

The regional results <strong>in</strong> Figure 9 show that the impacts of growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector are not<br />

uniformly distributed across the country. Some of the benefits are dist<strong>in</strong>ctly regional: much of<br />

the growth <strong>in</strong> dairy<strong>in</strong>g over the last decade has been <strong>in</strong> Canterbury and Southland. While this<br />

has reduced land available for sheep and beef farm<strong>in</strong>g, the <strong>in</strong>creased economic activity <strong>in</strong> the<br />

form of exports, wages and employment leads to strong growth <strong>in</strong> these districts.<br />

Northland and Waikato districts also benefit significantly from growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry.<br />

Increases <strong>in</strong> government spend<strong>in</strong>g lead to a benefit to the Well<strong>in</strong>gton regional economy,<br />

while Hawkes Bay, which is home to a large fruit and horticulture sector, has been slightly<br />

crowded out by the growth <strong>in</strong> the dairy sector.<br />

The impacts of volume growth on per person consumption or liv<strong>in</strong>g standards <strong>in</strong> each region<br />

are shown <strong>in</strong> Table 11.


Figure 9 2009 Gross regional product impacts<br />

Real percentage deviation from BAU levels<br />

Figure 7 Gross regional product impacts<br />

Real percentage deviation from BAU levels<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

Table 7 11 Increase <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong> gross regional product<br />

Region<br />

Region<br />

Per person <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> GRP<br />

Per person <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> GRP<br />

Northland<br />

Northland<br />

Auckland<br />

Auckland<br />

Waikato<br />

$170<br />

-$4<br />

$110<br />

$8<br />

$270<br />

Waikato<br />

Bay Of Plenty<br />

$130<br />

$84<br />

Bay Gisborne Of Plenty $66<br />

$74<br />

Gisborne Hawkes Bay $100<br />

-$100<br />

Hawkes Taranaki Bay $39<br />

$140<br />

Taranaki Manawatu-Wanganui $160<br />

$120<br />

Manawatu-Wanganui Well<strong>in</strong>gton $140<br />

$160<br />

Well<strong>in</strong>gton Tasman-Nelson $140<br />

$12<br />

Marlborough<br />

Tasman-Nelson $12<br />

-$4<br />

West Coast<br />

Marlborough<br />

Canterbury<br />

West Coast<br />

Otago<br />

$54<br />

$69<br />

$7<br />

$590<br />

$39<br />

Canterbury<br />

Southland<br />

$41<br />

$650<br />

Otago $82<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

Southland $68<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

F<strong>in</strong>al report - 16 November 2010<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> 19 generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

23


24 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

5. Conclusion<br />

Our modell<strong>in</strong>g shows that the dairy sector has delivered significant and ongo<strong>in</strong>g benefits to<br />

the <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> economy. Two historical case studies, based on events of the last decade,<br />

illustrate how tangible and widely known changes to the dairy sector have flowed through<br />

to the rest of the economy. Volume and price growth <strong>in</strong> the sector has delivered benefits<br />

to a wide range of sectors outside of the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry, and has generated liv<strong>in</strong>g standard<br />

improvements across <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s regional economies, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> metropolitan areas<br />

such as Auckland and Well<strong>in</strong>gton.


Appendix A CGE modell<strong>in</strong>g framework<br />

A.1 The MONASH-<strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> CGE model: overview<br />

The MONASH-NZ dynamic CGE model conta<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong>formation on 131 <strong>in</strong>dustries and 210<br />

commodities <strong>in</strong> its basic form. CGE modell<strong>in</strong>g is a highly-respected and well-developed<br />

technique that has a rich history for assess<strong>in</strong>g policy, regional and <strong>in</strong>dustry questions. Our<br />

model was developed <strong>in</strong> close collaboration with Monash University, a global leader <strong>in</strong><br />

build<strong>in</strong>g and apply<strong>in</strong>g CGE models. It captures the various <strong>in</strong>ter-l<strong>in</strong>kages between these<br />

sectors, as well as their l<strong>in</strong>ks to households (via the labour market), the government sector,<br />

capital markets and the global economy (via imports and exports). A visual representation is<br />

shown <strong>in</strong> Figure 10 highlight<strong>in</strong>g the complex and multidirectional relationships between the<br />

various parts of an economy.<br />

For this study we have calibrated the dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry <strong>in</strong> our database to match the aggregate<br />

dairy <strong>in</strong>dustry figures provided by <strong>Fonterra</strong> and Dairy NZ. More technical detail on the model<br />

is presented below.<br />

The model also <strong>in</strong>cludes a regional component. A ‘top-down’approach is used to<br />

decompose national impacts to the regional level, us<strong>in</strong>g regional employment data as<br />

weight<strong>in</strong>g. If a region has a high share of national output, then its regional <strong>in</strong>dustry output<br />

will be proportionally affected. The exception is <strong>in</strong>dustries that produce commodities<br />

(mostly services) that are largely consumed with<strong>in</strong> a region. These are deemed to be local<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustries, and it is assumed that their output moves <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the local demand for the<br />

correspond<strong>in</strong>g commodity, rather than with the national <strong>in</strong>dustry output. F<strong>in</strong>al This report captures - 16 November 2010<br />

“regional multiplier”effects: spend<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong> a region specifically benefits services with that<br />

region (Horridge, 2008).<br />

Figure 10 Components of a CGE model<br />

Figure 10 Components of a CGE model<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

A.2 Dynamics of the MONASH-NZ model<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

MONASH-NZ is a recursive dynamic CGE model based on the ORANI-NZ core. It<br />

25


26 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

A.2 Dynamics of the MONASH-NZ model<br />

MONASH-NZ is a recursive dynamic CGE model based on the ORANI-NZ core. It can be<br />

thought of as a series of static simulations l<strong>in</strong>ked by three dynamic adjustment procedures.<br />

Each year’s simulation takes the f<strong>in</strong>al database of the previous year’s simulation as its start<strong>in</strong>g<br />

po<strong>in</strong>t and applies the current period’s shocks. Because the solution for the current period<br />

depends only on the previous period’s solution and the current period’s shocks, it can be<br />

solved recursively, rather than hav<strong>in</strong>g to solve all periods simultaneously. Economists might<br />

refer to this sort of model as hav<strong>in</strong>g adaptive, rather than rational, expectations formation.<br />

In addition to solv<strong>in</strong>g a ‘static’problem <strong>in</strong> each period, the MONASH-NZ model improves<br />

upon ORANI-NZ simulations by add<strong>in</strong>g three dynamic adjustment processes:<br />

• Labour market adjustment: We assume that wages are sticky <strong>in</strong> the short run and<br />

gradually adjust over time. A mechanism <strong>in</strong> the model allows employment to first<br />

respond to <strong>in</strong>creases <strong>in</strong> aggregate demand and then return to the NAIRU over time as<br />

wages adjust.<br />

• Capital formation: An <strong>in</strong>dustry-specific capital accumulation mechanism allows <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

to build their stock of capital over time. Capital is generated by <strong>in</strong>vestment, which <strong>in</strong> turn<br />

responds to rates of return <strong>in</strong> each <strong>in</strong>dustry.<br />

• Balance of payments adjustment: The model tracks changes <strong>in</strong> the current account and<br />

capital account over time. Changes <strong>in</strong> net foreign liabilities affect domestic consumption<br />

through the level of <strong>in</strong>terest that must be paid to service the foreign debt.<br />

A.3 Database structure<br />

The model is based on a large database conta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g the value flows of the economy, as per<br />

Figure 11. The database def<strong>in</strong>es the <strong>in</strong>itial structure of the economy, which by def<strong>in</strong>ition is<br />

assumed to be <strong>in</strong> equilibrium <strong>in</strong> all markets. The structure of the database is broadly similar<br />

to traditional <strong>in</strong>put-output tables; for example commodities may be used as <strong>in</strong>termediate<br />

<strong>in</strong>put for further production, utilised <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>vestment, exported or consumed by households<br />

and the government. Industry costs <strong>in</strong>clude the cost of <strong>in</strong>termediates, marg<strong>in</strong>s, taxes and<br />

primary factor costs for labour, land and capital. As per the account<strong>in</strong>g identities <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>putoutput<br />

tables, the total value sum of producers’<strong>in</strong>put costs (<strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g marg<strong>in</strong>s, taxes, returns<br />

to factors and other costs) equates to the total value of output production (the ‘MAKE’matrix<br />

<strong>in</strong> the database).<br />

The MONASH-NZ model consists of:<br />

• 131 <strong>in</strong>dustries<br />

• 210 commodities<br />

• 14 regions<br />

• 1 household<br />

• 24 occupations<br />

The database has been sourced <strong>in</strong>itially from Statistics <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> 1995/96 Inter-Industry<br />

tables, updated us<strong>in</strong>g the subsequently released 2003 Supply and Use tables, and f<strong>in</strong>ally ‘upscaled’to<br />

2007 levels us<strong>in</strong>g latest Statistics <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> macroeconomic data.


Figure 11 The MONASH-NZ database<br />

Figure 11 The MONASH-NZ database<br />

Basic<br />

Flows<br />

Marg<strong>in</strong>s<br />

Taxes<br />

Labour<br />

Capital<br />

Land<br />

Production<br />

Tax<br />

Other<br />

Costs<br />

Source: Horridge, 2008b NZIER<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

F<strong>in</strong>al report - 16 November 2010<br />

Absorption Matrix<br />

1 2 3 4 5 6<br />

Producers Investors Household Export<br />

Change <strong>in</strong><br />

Government<br />

Inventories<br />

Size<br />

↑<br />

← I → ← I → ← 1 → ← 1 → ← 1 → ← 1 →<br />

C×S<br />

↓<br />

↑<br />

V1BAS V2BAS V3BAS V4BAS V5BAS V6BAS<br />

C×S×M<br />

↓<br />

↑<br />

V1MAR V2MAR V3MAR V4MAR V5MAR n/a<br />

C×S<br />

↓<br />

V1TAX V2TAX V3TAX V4TAX V5TAX n/a<br />

↑<br />

O V1LAB<br />

C = 210 Commodities<br />

↓<br />

I = 131 Industries<br />

↑<br />

1 V1CAP<br />

S = 2: Domestic, Imported<br />

↓<br />

O = 24 Occupation Types<br />

↑<br />

1<br />

↓<br />

↑<br />

V1LND<br />

M = 5 Commodities used as Marg<strong>in</strong>s<br />

1<br />

↓<br />

↑<br />

V1PTX<br />

1<br />

↓<br />

V1OCT<br />

Jo<strong>in</strong>t Production<br />

Matrix<br />

Import Duty<br />

Size ← I → Size ← 1 →<br />

↑<br />

C<br />

↓<br />

MAKE<br />

Source: Horridge, 2008b; NZIER<br />

↑<br />

C<br />

↓<br />

V0TAR<br />

A.4 Production structure (Horridge, 2008b)<br />

The production structure of the model is presented <strong>in</strong> Figure 12. Each <strong>in</strong>dustry can<br />

produce a number of different commodities. Production <strong>in</strong>puts are <strong>in</strong>termediate<br />

commodities, both domestic and imported, and primary factors labour, land and<br />

capital. Work<strong>in</strong>g from bottom to top, we see constant elasticity of substitution (CES)<br />

production nests for occupations, primary factors and the choice between imported<br />

and domestic commodities. In this case, an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> price moves sourc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

towards another <strong>in</strong>put, for example, if the price of imports <strong>in</strong>creases, more domestic<br />

commodities are demanded <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>termediate sourc<strong>in</strong>g CES nest.<br />

31<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

27


A.4 Production structure (Horridge, 2008b)<br />

The production structure of the model is presented <strong>in</strong> Figure 12. Each <strong>in</strong>dustry can produce<br />

a number of different commodities. Production <strong>in</strong>puts are <strong>in</strong>termediate commodities, both<br />

domestic and imported, and primary factors labour, land and capital. Work<strong>in</strong>g from bottom<br />

to top, we see constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production nests for occupations,<br />

primary factors and the choice between imported and domestic commodities. F<strong>in</strong>al report - In 16 this November 2010<br />

case, an <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> price moves sourc<strong>in</strong>g towards another <strong>in</strong>put, for example, if the price of<br />

imports <strong>in</strong>creases, more domestic commodities are demanded <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>termediate sourc<strong>in</strong>g<br />

CES nest.<br />

Figure Figure 12 12 Production structure<br />

Source: Horridge, 2008<br />

Source: Horridge, 2008<br />

At the activity level, <strong>in</strong>termediate goods, primary factors and other costs are<br />

comb<strong>in</strong>ed us<strong>in</strong>g a Leontief production function. This means the proportion of<br />

production <strong>in</strong>puts does not change. On the output side, there are two further<br />

constant elasticity of transformation (CET)<br />

28 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

13 nests. The production mix of each<br />

<strong>in</strong>dustry is dependent on the relative prices of each commodity. Similarly, the export


At the activity level, <strong>in</strong>termediate goods, primary factors and other costs are comb<strong>in</strong>ed<br />

us<strong>in</strong>g a Leontief production function. This means the proportion of production <strong>in</strong>puts does<br />

not change. On the output side, there are two further constant elasticity of transformation<br />

(CET) 13 nests. The production mix of each <strong>in</strong>dustry is dependent on the relative prices of each<br />

commodity. Similarly, the export nest determ<strong>in</strong>es local and export market shares depend<strong>in</strong>g<br />

on relative prices.<br />

A.5 Regional extension<br />

Policy impacts are often unevenly spread across <strong>in</strong>dustries and regions. To capture these<br />

heterogeneous effects, the model is extended to <strong>in</strong>clude a regional component. A ‘topdown’approach<br />

is used to decompose national impacts to the regional level, us<strong>in</strong>g regional<br />

employment data as weight<strong>in</strong>g. If a region has a high share of national output, then its<br />

regional <strong>in</strong>dustry output will be proportionally affected. The exception is <strong>in</strong>dustries that<br />

produce commodities (mostly services) that are largely consumed with<strong>in</strong> a region. These are<br />

deemed to be local <strong>in</strong>dustries, and it is assumed that their output moves <strong>in</strong> l<strong>in</strong>e with the local<br />

demand for the correspond<strong>in</strong>g commodity, rather than with the national <strong>in</strong>dustry output.<br />

Note that an <strong>in</strong>herent assumption <strong>in</strong> the ‘top-down’approach is that <strong>in</strong>dustries use the same<br />

production technology across all regions (Horridge, 2008).<br />

13. A CET function is identical to a CES function except that the transformation parameter has the opposite sign (i.e. <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g price<br />

<strong>in</strong>creases output <strong>in</strong> a CET; <strong>in</strong> a CES, <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g price reduces demand)<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

29


30 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Appendix B CGE and multiplier analysis<br />

Many studies attempt to quantify the economic contribution of a certa<strong>in</strong> sector or<br />

project us<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>put-output (IO) multipliers. This is a technique that NZIER (and many other<br />

consultancies) has used <strong>in</strong> the past.<br />

Despite their popularity, IO models have a number of significant drawbacks.<br />

The primary issue with IO models is that they assume that supply is unconstra<strong>in</strong>ed. That is,<br />

<strong>in</strong>puts such as labour, capital and land are always available for expand<strong>in</strong>g a sector. There is no<br />

recognition of the reality that resources used <strong>in</strong> one part of the economy are not available for<br />

use elsewhere. Labour and capital are unconstra<strong>in</strong>ed and available at a constant price <strong>in</strong> an IO<br />

framework. That is important because they are also assumed to be used <strong>in</strong> fixed proportions.<br />

Hence an IO model excludes any consideration of substitutability between factors of<br />

production.<br />

Furthermore, s<strong>in</strong>ce IO models exclude prices, they also assume that supply is perfectly elastic.<br />

This means that no matter how much labour (for example) is used, there is no change <strong>in</strong><br />

wages. The consequence is that they exclude all supply constra<strong>in</strong>ts, rigidities and price<br />

effects, lead<strong>in</strong>g to unrealistically large shifts <strong>in</strong> resource use and economic activity.<br />

The absence of substitution effects also extends to demand. There is no substitution between<br />

different goods as <strong>in</strong>comes rise. Rather, consumption is assumed to rise l<strong>in</strong>early with <strong>in</strong>comes<br />

and the proportion of different goods consumed rema<strong>in</strong>s constant. In reality, as <strong>in</strong>comes rise,<br />

people tend to buy relatively more luxuries and fewer necessities, and more services (such as<br />

tourism).<br />

IO models also exclude a treatment of exports and imports. Imports do not compete with<br />

domestic goods and exports are exogenously determ<strong>in</strong>ed. Neither depends on prices, s<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

relative prices cannot change.<br />

Among the other drawbacks, sav<strong>in</strong>gs are fixed as a proportion of <strong>in</strong>comes, so f<strong>in</strong>ancial<br />

markets are not <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the model. Technology is exogenous so technological progress<br />

cannot be modelled. This reflects the static nature of the model, which has no dynamic (time)<br />

element to it. The lack of explicit dynamics is problematic for a model which seeks to capture<br />

the change <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>dustry flows over time.<br />

As a consequence of the limitations outl<strong>in</strong>ed above, IO multipliers tend to systematically<br />

overestimate the true ripple effects and provide an unjustifiably rosy picture of the economic<br />

impacts of a project. This is particularly the case for employment multipliers (Mules, 1999).<br />

IO models are only appropriate for circumstances where there are no supply constra<strong>in</strong>ts<br />

and demand considerations completely dom<strong>in</strong>ate the analysis (Bandara, 1991). This set of<br />

circumstances may hold <strong>in</strong> small regional economies (Dwyer et al, 2005). In such economies<br />

factor and commodity flows from outside the region tend to be very free. If the region is<br />

small enough then relative prices can safely be regarded as exogenous, which allows IO<br />

models to be safely used so long as the assumptions and deficiencies are recognised.<br />

CGE models explicitly address many of the shortcom<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>in</strong> IO analysis. They allow resources<br />

to move between sectors <strong>in</strong> response to a shock, and the demand and supply of goods and<br />

factors respond to relative prices. CGE models tend to produce smaller economic impacts<br />

than IO models, primarily because they consider the opportunity costs of the expansion (or<br />

contraction) of a sector.<br />

It is helpful to consider an illustrative example of how IO multipliers compare to CGE<br />

estimates. A comparative assessment of CGE and IO multipliers was carried out for the<br />

regional and national impact of the Australian leg of the Formula 1 Grand Prix circuit. The<br />

2005 analysis of the 2000 Grand Prix resulted <strong>in</strong> the multipliers reported <strong>in</strong> Table 12.


Table 12 IO vs. CGE multipliers<br />

Multiplier values<br />

IO model CGE model<br />

Regional National Regional National<br />

Output multiplier 2.2 2.3 1.2 0.9<br />

Value added multiplier 0.8 0.8 0.4 0.3<br />

Employment multiplier 10.2 11.6 6.2 2.5<br />

Source: Dwyer et al (2005)<br />

As expected, the CGE multipliers are far lower than the IO multipliers, primarily due to the<br />

price and resource constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong> the CGE model. The CGE estimates <strong>in</strong> this study are<br />

between 20% and 55% of the IO multipliers. Such differences are not unusual <strong>in</strong> the literature.<br />

CGE models are a significant improvement on the previous generation of IO models,<br />

particularly when estimat<strong>in</strong>g the nationwide or regional effects of projects which are likely<br />

to have significant price effects. Indeed, CGE modell<strong>in</strong>g has become one of the most widely<br />

used tools for economic policy analysis over the past three decades. Today, the lead<strong>in</strong>g CGE<br />

modell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>stitutions are the World Bank, the International Food Policy Research Institute<br />

(IFPRI) and the Centre of Policy Studies at Monash University (CoPS). Much of the World Bank’s<br />

economic assessment of trade and environmental impacts is conducted us<strong>in</strong>g their LINKAGE<br />

and Env-LINKAGE CGE models. CoPS has done extensive work advis<strong>in</strong>g the government <strong>in</strong><br />

Australia us<strong>in</strong>g their CGE models. Variants of their models are used <strong>in</strong> over 400 organisations<br />

<strong>in</strong> over 70 countries.<br />

The widespread usage and acceptance of CGE results over the last thirty years re<strong>in</strong>forces the<br />

view taken <strong>in</strong> the literature that it is now the best method available for analys<strong>in</strong>g the impact<br />

of economy-wide shocks.<br />

14. For example, Dixon, Parmenter and Rimmer (2000); Adams et al (1994); Dixon, Picton, and Rimmer (2005), Dixon, Madden, and Peter<br />

(1993); Dixon and Rimmer (1999).<br />

15. GEMPACK homepage http://www.monash.edu.au/policy/gempack.htm<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

31


32 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Appendix C Limitations of analysis<br />

• Aggregation bias. We have not split out the dairy sector, but use aggregated dairy<br />

farm<strong>in</strong>g and dairy process<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>dustries. This leads to aggregation bias. For example,<br />

irrigated and non-irrigated farm<strong>in</strong>g practices and <strong>in</strong>dustry structures are likely to be quite<br />

different, and at present this is not captured with<strong>in</strong> our modell<strong>in</strong>g. Given adequate time,<br />

the model can be disaggregated to more accurately model the specific dairy sector.<br />

• Foreign debt account<strong>in</strong>g. We employ a standard ‘MONASH’method for account<strong>in</strong>g for<br />

the foreign debts – changes <strong>in</strong> net foreign liabilities come about if our <strong>in</strong>vestment is not<br />

met by domestic sav<strong>in</strong>gs. We pay <strong>in</strong>terest on foreign debt that is subtracted from national<br />

<strong>in</strong>come. The <strong>in</strong>terest, <strong>in</strong> foreign currency, is converted to domestic currency by the<br />

exchange rate. In this simulation, the exchange rate appreciation leads to a decrease <strong>in</strong><br />

the domestic currency value of the <strong>in</strong>terest repayments. It could be argued that much of<br />

the <strong>in</strong>terest on this foreign debt is likely to be dividend payments on equity. In this case,<br />

the appreciation of the exchange rate should not decrease overseas payments.<br />

• ‘Top-down’ regional modell<strong>in</strong>g. Regional data is by far the most difficult data to obta<strong>in</strong><br />

across the diverse range of <strong>in</strong>dustries and commodities that we have <strong>in</strong>corporated with<strong>in</strong><br />

our model. ‘Bottom-up’regional modell<strong>in</strong>g provides a clearer picture of regional activity<br />

and <strong>in</strong>-particular cross-region flows, however requires significant data resources. The topdown<br />

approach here provides <strong>in</strong>dicative regional splits.<br />

• Model structure. The CGE model is based on Statistics <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> Input Output tables,<br />

with decisions based on neoclassical economics. Structural changes to the economy from<br />

the reforms are therefore not captured <strong>in</strong> the modell<strong>in</strong>g, nor are any non-competitive<br />

market structures. This means the distributional elements of the results may differ <strong>in</strong><br />

reality if firms with market power do not pass on benefits.


Appendix D References<br />

Bandara, J. S. (1991). ‘Computable General Equilibrium Models for Development Policy<br />

Analysis <strong>in</strong> LDCs’. Journal of Economic Surveys 5, no. 1 (1991): 3-69.<br />

Coleman, W. (2008). ‘Gaug<strong>in</strong>g economic performance under chang<strong>in</strong>g terms of trade: real<br />

gross domestic <strong>in</strong>come or real gross domestic product?’ Economic Papers, Vol. 27 no.4,<br />

December 2008, pp. 329-343.<br />

Dixon, P. B., J. R. Madden, and M. W. Peter. (1993). ‘The effects of reallocat<strong>in</strong>g general revenue<br />

assistance among the Australian states’. Economic Record 69, no. 207 (1993): 367–381.<br />

Dixon, P. B., and B. R. Parmenter. (1996). ‘Computable general equilibrium modell<strong>in</strong>g for policy<br />

analysis and forecast<strong>in</strong>g’. Handbook of computational economics 1 (1996): 3–85.<br />

Dixon, P. B., B. R. Parmenter, and M. T. Rimmer. (2000). ‘Forecast<strong>in</strong>g and policy analysis with a<br />

dynamic CGE model of Australia’. Contributions to Economic Analysis 248 (2000): 363–406.<br />

Dixon, P. B, M. R Picton, and M. T Rimmer. (2005). ‘Efficiency effects of changes <strong>in</strong><br />

Commonwealth grants to the states: A CGE analysis’. Australian Economic Papers 44, no. 1<br />

(2005): 82–104.<br />

Dixon, P. B., and M. T Rimmer. (1999). ‘Changes <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>direct taxes <strong>in</strong> Australia: A dynamic general<br />

equilibrium analysis’. The Australian Economic Review 32, no. 4 (1999): 327–348.<br />

Dwyer, L, P. Forsyth, and R. Spurr. (2005). “Estimat<strong>in</strong>g the Impacts of Special Events on an<br />

Economy’. Journal of Travel Research 43, no. 4 (May 1, 2005): 351-359. http://jtr.sagepub.com/<br />

cgi/content/abstract/43/4/351<br />

Horridge, 2008. ‘Orani-G: A generic s<strong>in</strong>gle-country computable general equilibrium model’.<br />

CopS/IMPACT Work<strong>in</strong>g Paper op-93; Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University. First<br />

Published 2000. Revised 2008.<br />

Mules, T. (1999). ‘Estimat<strong>in</strong>g the economic impact of an event on a local government area,<br />

region, state or territory’. Valu<strong>in</strong>g tourism: Methods and techniques.<br />

NZIER. (2003). Globalisation a <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> perspective. CEDA chapter March 2003.<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

33


Appendix E Dairy employment statistics<br />

Farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Milk & cream Ice cream Cheese<br />

Total dairy Total dairy Total regional Dairy as % Region as % of<br />

employment process<strong>in</strong>g process<strong>in</strong>g process<strong>in</strong>g & process<strong>in</strong>g employment employment of regional total NZ dairy<br />

employment employment other dairy employment<br />

employment employment<br />

employment<br />

South Taranaki 1,450 0 0 1,570 1,570 3,020 11,675 25.9% 8.9%<br />

District<br />

Matamata-Piako 1,260 0 0 1,130 1,130 2,390 13,306 18.0% 7.1%<br />

District<br />

Southland 1,980 0 0 390 390 2,370 15,651 15.1% 7.0%<br />

District<br />

Waipa District 1,050 0 3 420 423 1,473 14,991 9.8% 4.4%<br />

Timaru District 530 0 0 650 650 1,180 21,151 5.6% 3.5%<br />

Ashburton 1,180 0 0 0 0 1,180 14,423 8.2% 3.5%<br />

District<br />

Whakatane 600 0 0 550 550 1,150 12,285 9.4% 3.4%<br />

District<br />

South Waikato 740 0 0 270 270 1,010 7,722 13.1% 3.0%<br />

District<br />

Waikato District 920 0 0 0 0 920 12,160 7.6% 2.7%<br />

Whangarei 510 0 0 400 400 910 30,341 3.0% 2.7%<br />

District<br />

Selwyn District 850 9 0 40 49 899 12,136 7.4% 2.7%<br />

Manawatu 540 210 0 140 350 890 8,660 10.3% 2.6%<br />

District<br />

Clutha District 680 0 0 150 150 830 8,440 9.8% 2.5%<br />

Hamilton City 50 50 0 720 770 820 75,536 1.1% 2.4%<br />

Rotorua District 570 0 0 180 180 750 29,341 2.6% 2.2%<br />

Kaipara District 580 0 0 130 130 710 5,445 13.0% 2.1%<br />

Tararua District 520 0 0 180 180 700 5,924 11.8% 2.1%<br />

Otorohanga 610 0 0 0 0 610 3,227 18.9% 1.8%<br />

District<br />

Taupo District 600 0 0 0 0 600 14,291 4.2% 1.8%<br />

Rangitikei District 280 0 0 290 290 570 5,926 9.6% 1.7%<br />

34 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth


Farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Milk & cream Ice cream Cheese<br />

Total dairy Total dairy Total regional Dairy as % Region as % of<br />

employment process<strong>in</strong>g process<strong>in</strong>g process<strong>in</strong>g & process<strong>in</strong>g employment employment of regional total NZ dairy<br />

employment employment other dairy employment<br />

employment employment<br />

employment<br />

<strong>New</strong> Plymouth 560 0 0 6 6 566 34,711 1.6% 1.7%<br />

District<br />

Waitaki District 460 0 0 75 75 535 9,410 5.7% 1.6%<br />

Westland District 270 0 0 240 240 510 3,730 13.7% 1.5%<br />

Waimate District 410 0 0 60 60 470 2,242 21.0% 1.4%<br />

Western Bay of 460 0 0 6 6 466 13,868 3.4% 1.4%<br />

Plenty District<br />

Tasman District 340 0 12 110 122 462 18,146 2.5% 1.4%<br />

Hauraki District 450 0 0 0 0 450 5,382 8.4% 1.3%<br />

Far North District 420 0 0 9 9 429 18,641 2.3% 1.3%<br />

Papakura District 20 140 0 250 390 410 15,071 2.7% 1.2%<br />

Duned<strong>in</strong> City 130 270 9 0 279 409 55,662 0.7% 1.2%<br />

Horowhenua 370 0 0 0 0 370 8,293 4.5% 1.1%<br />

District<br />

Frankl<strong>in</strong> District 330 15 0 18 33 363 18,581 2.0% 1.1%<br />

Auckland City 3 9 320 25 354 357 307,312 0.1% 1.1%<br />

Hurunui District 330 0 0 0 0 330 4,100 8.0% 1.0%<br />

Buller District 330 0 0 0 0 330 4,475 7.4% 1.0%<br />

Waimakariri 300 0 0 15 15 315 10,457 3.0% 0.9%<br />

District<br />

Christchurch City 40 210 12 45 267 307 188,948 0.2% 0.9%<br />

Stratford District 300 0 0 0 0 300 2,882 10.4% 0.9%<br />

Palmerston 80 110 0 85 195 275 45,355 0.6% 0.8%<br />

North City<br />

Gore District 260 0 0 0 0 260 6,500 4.0% 0.8%<br />

South Wairarapa 250 0 0 0 0 250 2,967 8.4% 0.7%<br />

District<br />

Rodney District 210 0 0 40 40 250 23,146 1.1% 0.7%<br />

Grey District 200 0 0 0 0 200 7,048 2.8% 0.6%<br />

Waitomo District 200 0 0 0 0 200 4,365 4.6% 0.6%<br />

Kapiti Coast 50 0 0 130 130 180 11,852 1.5% 0.5%<br />

District<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

35


Farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Milk & cream Ice cream Cheese<br />

Total dairy Total dairy Total regional Dairy as % Region as % of<br />

employment process<strong>in</strong>g process<strong>in</strong>g process<strong>in</strong>g & process<strong>in</strong>g employment employment of regional total NZ dairy<br />

employment employment other dairy employment<br />

employment employment<br />

employment<br />

Central Hawke’s 180 0 0 0 0 180 5,925 3.0% 0.5%<br />

Bay District<br />

Opotiki District 180 0 0 0 0 180 3,003 6.0% 0.5%<br />

Invercargill City 140 15 12 9 36 176 26,151 0.7% 0.5%<br />

Hast<strong>in</strong>gs District 120 0 0 35 35 155 41,110 0.4% 0.5%<br />

Manukau City 30 0 90 35 125 155 127,635 0.1% 0.5%<br />

North Shore City 0 0 65 85 150 150 86,346 0.2% 0.4%<br />

Marlborough 130 0 0 3 3 133 23,976 0.6% 0.4%<br />

District<br />

Carterton District 130 0 0 0 0 130 2,694 4.8% 0.4%<br />

Thames- 100 0 0 9 9 109 9,625 1.1% 0.3%<br />

Coromandel<br />

District<br />

Kaikoura District 75 0 0 25 25 100 1,656 6.0% 0.3%<br />

Wanganui 75 0 0 0 0 75 18,001 0.4% 0.2%<br />

District<br />

Gisborne District 50 0 0 25 25 75 20,196 0.4% 0.2%<br />

Masterton 55 0 0 3 3 58 10,437 0.6% 0.2%<br />

District<br />

Central Otago 50 0 0 0 0 50 10,757 0.5% 0.1%<br />

District<br />

Ruapehu District 40 0 0 0 0 40 5,994 0.7% 0.1%<br />

Mackenzie 35 0 0 0 0 35 1,886 1.9% 0.1%<br />

District<br />

Tauranga City 12 0 0 12 12 24 48,791 0.0% 0.1%<br />

Nelson City 12 0 9 0 9 21 24,656 0.1% 0.1%<br />

Wairoa District 18 0 0 0 0 18 3,586 0.5% 0.1%<br />

Lower Hutt City 0 0 0 6 6 6 44,927 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Waitakere City 0 0 3 0 3 3 46,742 0.0% 0.0%<br />

36 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth


Farm<strong>in</strong>g<br />

Milk & cream Ice cream Cheese<br />

Total dairy Total dairy Total regional Dairy as % Region as % of<br />

employment process<strong>in</strong>g process<strong>in</strong>g process<strong>in</strong>g & process<strong>in</strong>g employment employment of regional total NZ dairy<br />

employment employment other dairy employment<br />

employment employment<br />

employment<br />

Area Outside 0 0 0 0 0 0 33 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Territorial<br />

Authority<br />

Queenstown- 0 0 0 0 0 0 15,353 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Lakes District<br />

Chatham Islands 0 0 0 0 0 0 310 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Territory<br />

Well<strong>in</strong>gton City 0 0 0 0 0 0 137,966 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Upper Hutt City 0 0 0 0 0 0 11,395 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Porirua City 0 0 0 0 0 0 15,401 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Napier City 0 0 0 0 0 0 25,940 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Kawerau District 0 0 0 0 0 0 2,924 0.0% 0.0%<br />

Total (excl not 23,705 1,038 535 8,571 10,144 33,849 1,919,197 1.8% 100.0%<br />

elsw <strong>in</strong>cl)<br />

Source: Calculated by NZIER from Department of Labour, ‘Regional Industry Tool 2009’http://www.dol.govt.nz/services/LMI/tools/regional-<strong>in</strong>dustry-tool.asp<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

37


38 Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

Appendix F Value of regional dairy production<br />

Southland $ 710.35<br />

South Taranaki $ 616.56<br />

Matamata-Piako $ 552.12<br />

Ashburton $ 471.11<br />

Waikato $ 389.91<br />

Waipa $ 361.00<br />

Selwyn $ 269.91<br />

South Waikato $ 262.53<br />

Rotorua $ 253.55<br />

Otorohanga $ 234.54<br />

<strong>New</strong> Plymouth $ 206.31<br />

Hauraki $ 196.40<br />

Tararua $ 188.28<br />

Timaru $ 185.13<br />

Clutha $ 181.72<br />

Kawerau/Whakatane $ 180.33<br />

Manawatu $ 174.45<br />

Taupo $ 172.00<br />

Kaipara $ 167.59<br />

Whangarei $ 159.00<br />

Waitaki $ 146.93<br />

Gore $ 144.88<br />

Waimate $ 143.14<br />

Western Bay of Plenty $ 116.78<br />

Stratford $ 116.45<br />

Frankl<strong>in</strong> $ 112.07<br />

Hurunui $ 106.17<br />

Far North $ 106.08<br />

Tasman / Nelson $ 101.73<br />

Westland $ 97.06<br />

Waimakariri $ 94.65<br />

Horowhenua $ 87.16<br />

Buller $ 85.02<br />

Rangitikei $ 74.10<br />

Grey $ 71.19<br />

Rodney $ 70.08<br />

South Wairarapa $ 69.68<br />

Invercargill $ 67.21<br />

Duned<strong>in</strong> City $ 49.74<br />

Central Hawkes Bay $ 49.13<br />

Opotiki $ 43.54<br />

Thames-Coromandel $ 39.93<br />

Waitomo $ 39.87<br />

Carterton $ 38.01<br />

Marlborough $ 31.99<br />

Palmerston North City $ 27.97<br />

Napier $ 23.66<br />

Kaikoura $ 19.69<br />

Ruapehu $ 18.72<br />

MacKenzie $ 16.24<br />

Masterton $ 16.12<br />

Wanganui $ 14.94<br />

Central Otago $ 14.29<br />

Christchurch City $ 11.17<br />

Kapiti Coast $ 10.12<br />

Hamilton City $ 7.76<br />

Manukau City $ 6.53<br />

Wairoa $ 4.72<br />

Tauranga $ 4.72<br />

Hast<strong>in</strong>gs $ 4.64<br />

Banks Pen<strong>in</strong>sula $ 3.82<br />

Gisborne $ 2.84<br />

Upper Hutt City $ 1.40<br />

Papakura $ 1.38<br />

North Island $ 5,217.92<br />

South Island $ 2,993.32<br />

<strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong> $ 8,090.98


Appendix G Chang<strong>in</strong>g dairy export markets<br />

F<strong>in</strong>al report - 16 November 2010<br />

Appendix G Chang<strong>in</strong>g dairy export markets<br />

Figure 13 Chang<strong>in</strong>g markets for <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s dairy exports<br />

% of export value<br />

Figure 13 Chang<strong>in</strong>g markets for <strong>New</strong> <strong>Zealand</strong>’s dairy exports<br />

% of export value<br />

1989<br />

2009<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

Source: NZIER<br />

NZIER – Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

44<br />

Dairy’s <strong>role</strong> <strong>in</strong> generat<strong>in</strong>g growth<br />

39

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!