30.08.2013 Views

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

2.1. INTRODUCTION 15<br />

is not a prominent feature of executive compensation contracts. Antle & Smith (1986)<br />

and Liu & Stark (2008) find some support for RPE, but they also present results that are<br />

inconsistent with RPE. Gibbons & Murphy (1990) report strong support, but the interpretation<br />

of their results has been criticized quite severely by Janakiraman et al. (1992).<br />

Even less in favour of RPE, Janakiraman et al.’s own empirical results (1992) are generally<br />

negative about RPE’s presence. Additionally, Bertrand & Mullainathan (2001), Garvey &<br />

Milbourn (2006), and Himmelberg & Hubbard (2000) report no support for RPE. However,<br />

Albuquerque (2009) argues that this is due to misspecification of the analyses. After<br />

respecification of the analyses, she finds partial support for RPE use amongst executives.<br />

Overall, the empirical evidence remains mixed at best, suggesting that RPE has limited<br />

empirical relevance 1 .<br />

However, the empirical evidence may be limited due to several characteristics that prior<br />

RPE studies have in common. A first reason for the prior literature’s limited support<br />

for RPE may lie in its focus on the executive level. If deployed at the highest organizational<br />

level, RPE might be less efficient, as Garvey & Milbourn (2003) argue. It is entirely<br />

possible that relatively wealthy executives can reduce noise in their incentive contracts<br />

more efficiently themselves by adjusting their own private investment portfolios. The option<br />

of managerial hedging may decrease the attractiveness of RPE, reducing its adoption<br />

amongst top-managers. However, private hedging is costly. As a result, it is probably not<br />

an efficient option at the level of (less wealthy) business unit managers. In support of this<br />

argument, Garvey & Milbourn found that although RPE is not an important feature in<br />

the compensation contract of the average manager, it is in fact present for younger and<br />

less wealthy executives, i.e., those managers for whom personal hedging is likely to be prohibitively<br />

costly (Garvey & Milbourn 2003:1557). If personal hedging is indeed too costly<br />

for less wealthy executives, it is probably also too costly for managers in lower echelons.<br />

This fact may render RPE more attractive at these levels.<br />

Another important characteristic of the extant RPE literature that may have caused the<br />

literature’s negative findings, concerns the type of data being used. Most empirical studies<br />

that are currently available in the literature rely on archival data from before 2006.<br />

Using archival data has several benefits (e.g., data availability, objectivity of the data,<br />

and sample size). However, prior to the SEC’s 2006 executive compensation disclosure<br />

rules, firms were not required to disclose detailed information about their compensation<br />

plans. As a result, pre-2006 archival data have the drawback of requiring indirect instead<br />

of direct analyses. Indirect analyses typically regress executive pay on firm performance<br />

and peer performance (e.g., Aggarwall & Samwick 1999, Albuquerque 2009, Janakiraman<br />

et al. 1992, Liu & Stark 2008). In these analyses, a positive coefficient for firm performance<br />

together with a negative coefficient for peer performance provides support for the<br />

1 The empirical RPE literature is discussed in more detail in the introductory chapter of this thesis in<br />

section 1.2.2 on page 6.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!