30.08.2013 Views

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

6 CHAPTER 1. GENERAL INTRODUCTION<br />

The second explanation for RPE is the opportunism-mitigation perspective. The opportunism-mitigation<br />

perspective relates to the way in which performance standards are determined.<br />

Murphy (2001) distinguishes between two main ways in which standards can<br />

be set: 1) they can be determined in an internal, administrative process; or 2) they can<br />

be externally determined. The difference between these alternatives lies in the extent<br />

to which employees can influence the target level (Murphy 2001). Internally determined<br />

standards include standards based on prior-year performance and standards derived from<br />

company plans or budgets. Such standards are affected by managers’ actions, and can have<br />

dysfunctional effects. For example, when standards are based on prior-year performance,<br />

managers have an incentive to avoid unusually positive outcomes, because good performance<br />

in the current period is penalized through an increased standard in the next period<br />

(Murphy 2001). In a similar vein, budget-based standards provide incentives to negotiate<br />

easy standards (Fisher, Frederickson & Peffer 2002) and disincentives to beat the budget,<br />

especially in a regime of incremental budgeting (Murphy 2001). In contrast, externally<br />

determined standards are less affected by managers’ actions because the difficulty of the<br />

standard is based on something outside the sphere of influence of the manager (e.g., it is<br />

based on market conditions or peer performance).<br />

RPE is an example of such an externally determined performance standard, because it<br />

incorporates information about the performance of an external reference group of agents.<br />

The performance of an industry peer group lies well outside the sphere of influence of<br />

the manager, yet it determines his performance target. RPE-based targets are not subject<br />

to the prior year’s performance, to negotiations between the evaluated manager and<br />

the top management of the firm, or to any other factor that the evaluated manager can<br />

easily manipulate. These considerations suggest that the room for managerial opportunistic<br />

behaviour can be delimited by incorporating the performance of a reference group of<br />

agents into the compensation plan and that RPE can aid in the standard-setting process.<br />

Throughout the thesis, I motivate and test the use of RPE with the two perspectives<br />

presented above.<br />

1.2.2 Empirical Results on RPE<br />

Despite a promising theoretical basis, the empirical literature, focusing mainly on executive<br />

compensation praxis, provides inconclusive evidence on the empirical relevance of RPE<br />

theory. Both Jensen & Murphy (1990) and Aggarwal & Samwick (1999) find that RPE is<br />

not a prominent feature of executive compensation contracts. Antle & Smith (1986) find<br />

weak support for RPE use in the executive compensation contracts of 16 firms in a sample<br />

of 39 firms with longitudinal data from 1947 to 1977. Also Liu & Stark (2008) find mixed<br />

support for RPE amongst 169 UK non-financial listed companies. They provide evidence<br />

for the presence of RPE in the design of board compensation based on stock market returns,<br />

but they find no relation between cash compensation of the board and peer group

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!