30.08.2013 Views

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

pdf - Nyenrode Business Universiteit

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

5.1. SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND DISCUSSION 123<br />

the manager cannot easily influence his own performance target, but, as Gibbons<br />

& Murphy (1990) argue colluding with other managers within the organization to<br />

opportunistically lower the performance target may not be difficult 2 .<br />

Based on the overall findings of chapters 2 & 4, I conclude that RPE, as it is implemented<br />

in practice, is not an effective means to reduce room for opportunistic<br />

behaviour amongst business unit managers. However, the fact that RPE is not often<br />

used to mitigate opportunism by comparing managerial performance to that of<br />

external peers exclusively, does not falsify Murphy’s claim that RPE can reduce opportunism.<br />

The use of internal peers is not a prerequisite for RPE. Rather, RPE as<br />

described in the executive compensation literature, most likely is based on performance<br />

information of external peers. After all, top managers do not have internal<br />

peers, whereas business unit managers do. <strong>Business</strong> unit managers may be comparable<br />

to other business unit managers within the organization. Notwithstanding my<br />

findings, RPE may still be an effective means of mitigating the room for opportunism<br />

amongst business unit managers if the peer comparison is based on an external reference<br />

group. Unfortunately, my data do not allow empirical analyses of this idea 3 ,<br />

as will be discussed in the limitations section at the end of this chapter.<br />

4. RPE use for both purposes simultaneously<br />

In the previous paragraph, we saw that, although many organizations use RPE, it<br />

is, on average, not used to mitigate opportunistic behaviour amongst business unit<br />

managers. Organizations may not use RPE for this purpose because in most cases,<br />

RPE adopters rely on reference groups containing internal peers. As argued previously,<br />

internal and mixed peer groups may not facilitate opportunism mitigation, at<br />

least not as well as external peer groups. This observation raises the question of<br />

why organizations, after investing in RPE as a control instrument, do not simply use<br />

external instead of internal peer groups and use RPE also to mitigate opportunism.<br />

Here, I present two post-hoc explanations for this phenomenon. These explanations<br />

refer to cost-benefit trade-offs and to control instrument design considerations,<br />

respectively. First, the respondents report low room for managerial opportunism regardless<br />

of whether they use RPE. This finding, which was discussed in chapter 4,<br />

suggests that, on average, the respondents do not need (additional) control instruments<br />

to reduce opportunistic behaviour. Thus, the benefits of using RPE to reduce<br />

2 The risk of collusion is documented in the analytical agency literature (see: Holmstrom 1982) and in<br />

experimental studies (see: Towry (2003) and Zhang (2008).<br />

3 An independent sample T-test shows no significant difference in the mean levels of the room for<br />

managerial opportunism between the RPE users who rely exclusively on external peers and the RPE<br />

adopters who use mixed or purely internal peers. However, this null result can easily be driven by the<br />

limited subsample size of the ’external peers only’ group (N=21).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!