24.08.2013 Views

Working Paper Series

Working Paper Series

Working Paper Series

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Centre for Law and Finance<br />

Centro di Diritto e Finanza<br />

<strong>Working</strong> <strong>Paper</strong> <strong>Series</strong><br />

GUIDO FERRARINI<br />

Origins of Limited Liability Companies and<br />

Company Law Modernisation in Italy:<br />

A Historical Outline<br />

WP 5-2002


Origins of Limited Liability Companies and Company Law Modernisation in Italy: A<br />

Historical Outline<br />

Guido A. Ferrarini<br />

Centre for Law and Finance<br />

University of Genoa<br />

1 INTRODUCTION<br />

In this paper, which is intended to celebrate, from an Italian perspective, 400 years since the<br />

foundation of the Dutch East India Company (Verenigde Oostindische Compagnie = VOC), I will<br />

briefly discuss the origins of business companies in the Middle Ages and the Renaissance, and then<br />

focus on the formation of the first Italian limited liability companies in the 17 th and 18 th centuries<br />

under the influence of the Dutch and English models. I will then examine concisely the codification<br />

of company law in the 19 th and 20 th centuries, and the recent reforms of corporate governance and<br />

capital market law. In covering such a wide historical spectrum, my purpose is twofold. Firstly, I<br />

intend to connect, within the confines of this paper, company law history to economic history, so as<br />

to place in the appropriate context the analysis of legal institutions which have been fundamental to<br />

the rise of modern capitalism. Secondly, I aim to offer a general view of the long path to modern<br />

corporate governance, from the time when limited liability companies were not covered by general<br />

private law rules, through the age of liberal codifications (starting from the Napoleonic Commercial<br />

Code) to the present times, in which company law is closely connected with capital markets law<br />

(and other areas of business regulation).<br />

2 VOC’S GENOESE PREDECESSORS AND EMULATORS<br />

In this Section, I will analyse the origins of limited liability companies, examining some<br />

Italian analogues of the VOC. Modern companies are indentified by four defining characteristics:<br />

limited liability for investors, free transferability of investor interests, legal personality and<br />

centralised management 1 . The analysis included in para. 2.1 and 2.2 will show that some of these<br />

characteristics gradually emerged in business techniques preceding the East India companies. In<br />

para. 2.3, I shall examine attempts made during the seventeenth century to do business in Genoa<br />

through limited liability companies along the Dutch model. The first companies were not successful<br />

as business enterprises; however, their model, once imported, was adopted in an increasing number<br />

1


of cases, also in other Italian cities, throughout the eighteenth century. Para. 2.4 will illustrate a few<br />

aspects of early corporate governance from the viewpoint of some companies’ articles of<br />

association.<br />

2.1 Early Techniques<br />

The commenda was the oldest technique to invest capital in a commercial venture, generally<br />

connected with international trade 2 . An amount of money was given to a merchant by an “investor”,<br />

who was not necessarily rich; also small savers made recourse to the commenda and a merchant<br />

might enter into more contracts of this type for the same venture 3 . If the venture was successful, the<br />

investor was entitled to three quarters of the profits; in case of losses, the investor had to bear them.<br />

If capital had been contributed also by the merchant, profits and losses had to be shared<br />

proportionally to the capital conferred 4 . Considering that, in the thirteenth century, many savers in a<br />

city like Venice made recourse to the commenda to invest their money, the great economic historian<br />

Carlo M. Cipolla argued: “In practice, the commenda contract, at those times, had, under different<br />

forms, the same function as the shares of limited companies have today, by allowing a great number<br />

of people to participate in the profits of the largest industrial, commercial and financial<br />

enterprises” 5 .<br />

In the fourteenth century, the commercial techniques changed, as the travelling merchants<br />

became less numerous and were replaced by resident merchants who traded internationally through<br />

agents and factors 6 . As a consequence, by the fifteenth century, the commenda had almost<br />

disappeared and the compagnia was used to collectively finance business ventures 7 . At the<br />

beginning, the compagnia was closely connected with the family. It was constituted by the members<br />

of the same casata contributing the family’s assets to the company; they were all liable for the<br />

company’s obligations, which were also obligations of the family 8 . As argued by Armando Sapori,<br />

the expansion of business created new financial needs and the companies had to accept outside<br />

financing; the inclusion of strangers concluded a stage of the compagnia’s history 9 . It also led to the<br />

introduction of limited liability for investors contributing capital to the company, as was done in the<br />

1<br />

See R.C. Clark, Corporate Law, New York, 1986, p. 2; P. Davies, Introduction to Company Law, Oxford,<br />

2002, p. 9.<br />

2<br />

See C. Cipolla, Storia economica dell’Europa pre-industriale, Bologna, 5th ed. 1994, p. 186.<br />

3<br />

Ibidem, p. 187.<br />

4<br />

Ibidem, p. 186.<br />

5<br />

Ibidem, p. 187.<br />

6<br />

Ibidem, p. 188.<br />

7<br />

Ibidem.<br />

8<br />

See A. Sapori, ‘Le compagnie mercantili toscane del Dugento’, in Studi di storia economica, Florence, 1955,<br />

II, pp. 803-805; Id., ‘Dalla Compagnia alla Holding’ (1956) Rivista delle Società 72; see also U. Santarelli, Mercanti e<br />

società tra mercanti, Turin, 2nd ed. 1992, p. 121 et seq.<br />

9<br />

Sapori, ‘Dalla Compagnia alla Holding’, supra n. 8, at 74.<br />

2


old commenda: a Florentine law of 1408 regulated the accomandita, allowing for the co-existence<br />

of unlimited and limited liability partners 10 . Another way of collectively financing an enterprise was<br />

by accepting deposits: this led to the formation of companies which had a commercial and financial<br />

nature at the same time, as in the famous case of the Medici’s business 11 .<br />

2.2 VOC’s Predecessors<br />

The compagnia and the accomandita (as well as the commenda before them), despite being<br />

functional equivalents of limited liability companies at their own times, were profoundly different<br />

from the latter, for very clear reasons. First, their organisation was elementary, compared with that<br />

of the VOC, and their size was much smaller, as the financing needs were lower. Second, the<br />

managers of the company, if not all the partners, were subject to unlimited liability for the<br />

company’s obligations. Third, there was not a secondary market for the investmens in those<br />

companies. If predecessors of the VOC existed at all in the Italian Middle Ages and Renaissance,<br />

these had to be found elsewhere.<br />

2.2.1 The Genoese Maone<br />

According to the great German commercial lawyer, Levin Goldschmidt, modern limited<br />

liability companies found their origins in the Italian practice of the compera delle imposte (purchase<br />

of tax receivables) 12 . This was a technique used in the Middle Ages to finance the purchase of tax<br />

receivables from either a State or a City with money raised amongst the public. The loans granted to<br />

the State or City by the investors, against an assignment of tax receivables or other rights (including<br />

trade privileges) were collectively denominated as mons (mountain) or maona (mahona). The<br />

creditors were registered in a public registry and the loans were divided into a number of equal parts<br />

(loca, partes), each creditor being the holder of one or more of them 13 . The loca were freely<br />

transferable and were traded as movables: the analogy with today’s securitisations is striking.<br />

The loca’s holders formed an organisation (societas comperarum) to collect the tax<br />

receivables and have their loans repaid. This organisation was temporary, as it was created for the<br />

purpose of the loans 14 . However, in the case of the Genoese Maona di Chio e di Focea, also<br />

denominated as Maona dei Giustiniani, the organisation lasted for a long time (1346-1566). In<br />

Goldschmidt’s opinion, this was a colonial joint-stock company, presumably the oldest 15 . The<br />

Maona was founded to finance the acquisition and operation of 29 galleys which were employed to<br />

10 Ibidem, 81.<br />

11 Ibidem, 78-79, arguing that the Medici formed a group of companies, each located in a different European<br />

country, all depending on the Florentine House, which functioned in some way as a holding company.<br />

12 L. Goldschmidt, Universalgeschichte des Handelsrechts, Stuttgart, 1891, p. 290.<br />

13 Ibidem, p. 292.<br />

14 Ibidem, p. 293.<br />

3


conquer Chio and the old and new Focea. The total debt was divided into loca, along the model of<br />

the compera delle imposte, and the Company was granted by the Genoese Republic, as a security<br />

for the repayment of the debt, the usufruct (dominium utile) of Chio and Focea, together with some<br />

trade privileges 16 . The powers of the State in the colonies were exercised by Genoese magistrates.<br />

The usufruct, however, was managed by the Maona, which came to have, towards the end of its life,<br />

600 “shareholders” 17 .<br />

Goldschmidt’s thesis that some of the Genoese maone were similar, in substance, to limited<br />

liability companies was criticised by other lawyers and historians 18 . A major difference is that the<br />

maona was an association of creditors, organised to protect them from the State as a debtor. In its<br />

genuine form, the maona did not even collect the taxes assigned to it, which were collected by<br />

companies of contractors on their behalf 19 . However, there are also similarities between the two<br />

institutions. First of all, the maonae were complex organisations, with a governance structure<br />

directed to represent the interests of a mass of investors. In addition, they were subject to a principle<br />

of limited liability 20 . Furthermore, despite the debt nature of the maona’s obligations towards its<br />

members, dividends were paid to the latter out of the cash flows received by the organisation,<br />

mainly through tax collections. These dividends fluctuated depending on the amount of the<br />

organisation’s cash flows as did consequently the prices of the loca on the secondary market 21 . With<br />

respect to the the “colonial” maonae, it is also striking that they enjoyed trade privileges, like the<br />

VOC, and were actively involved in the administration of their territories.<br />

2.2.2 The Banco di San Giorgio<br />

Goldschmidt included the Genoese Banco di San Giorgio amongst the predecessors of<br />

modern limited liability companies 22 . This institution was founded in 1407 as Officium<br />

procuratorum S. Georgii, to consolidate a certain number of comperae (i.e. State debts secured by<br />

tax receivables). By 1454 the Officium administered almost the whole Genoese public debt in the<br />

15 Ibidem, p. 295. Another company was the Genoese maona of Cyprus, founded in 1373.<br />

16 Ibidem. On the succession of a new maona to the old one and the relevant constitutional changes, see H.<br />

Sieveking, ‘Studio sulle finanze genovesi nel Medioevo e in particolare sulla Casa di S. Giorgio’ (translation by O.<br />

Soardi) (1905) Atti della Società Ligure di Storia Patria, XXXV, 1st part, p. 213 et seq.<br />

17 See Goldschmidt, supra n.12, p. 296.<br />

18 See K. Lehman, Die geschichtliche Entwicklung der Aktienrechts bis zur Code de Commerce, Berlin, 1895,<br />

p. 7 et seq.; H. Sieveking, supra n. 16, p. 221 et seq.; A. Vighi, ‘Notizie storiche sugli amministratori ed i sindaci delle<br />

società per azioni anteriori al codice di commercio francese (Contributo alla storia della società per azioni)’ (1969)<br />

Rivista delle società 663 (reprint of a paper dated Camerino, 1898); Vivante, Trattato di diritto commerciale, II, Le<br />

società commerciali, 5th ed., Milan, 1929, p. 7.<br />

19 Sieveking, supra n. 16, p. 212.<br />

20 Ibidem, p. 223.<br />

21 Ibidem.<br />

22 Godlschmidt, supra n. 12, p. 296.<br />

4


interest of investors 23 . Dividends were paid to the investors out of a cash flow generated by the<br />

collection of taxes and the Genoese colonies (including Corsica), the usufruct of which was later<br />

transferred to the House of S. Giorgio in exchange for financings to the State 24 . Therefore, the<br />

House of San Giorgio became a sovereign entity: dominius et status, as it called itself in the official<br />

documents 25 ; a state within a state, as it was defined by Niccolò Machiavelli 26 .<br />

The loca issued by the House of San Giorgio were registered in public books, where also<br />

the transfers of the loca were annotated. There was, in fact, a lively market for the loca 27 .<br />

Certificates were issued on demand, to document the annotations in the public books 28 . The San<br />

Giorgio’s governance structure was oligarchichal and the power belonged to the largest<br />

“stockholders” 29 . The Banco was managed by 8 protectors, with at least 100 loca each, whereas the<br />

supervisory and ruling powers were exercised by a Great Council made up of 480 stockholders,<br />

with at least 10 loca each. The protectors had also civil and criminal jurisdiction, given that the<br />

Banco was a sovereign entity. Their role was, therefore, considered to be similar to that of the<br />

Genoese magistrates 30 .<br />

The assimilation of the Banco di San Giorgio to limited liability companies, proposed by<br />

Levin Goldschmidt, was rejected by other authors 31 . Heinrich Sieveking, author of the main study<br />

on the Banco, argued that it was mainly an organisation of creditors, a “typical medieval institution”<br />

created to carry out some of a weak State’s functions. In his opinion, “the House of San Giorgio<br />

was a discrete political organisation to protect the capitalists’ class, which was the main holder of<br />

gilts”, not a commercial company 32 . However, as already argued for the maonae, there were also<br />

similarities between the Banco di San Giorgio and early joint-stock companies 33 . The issuance of<br />

financial instruments (loca) and an active market for those instruments were meaningful, despite<br />

their nature as debt obligations which was, anyhow, tempered by the distribution of dividends<br />

calculated on the cash flows received from the Banco.<br />

23<br />

See G. Felloni, ‘La Banca di San Giorgio a Genova’, in C. Cipolla, Storia facile dell’economia italiana dal<br />

Medioevo a oggi, Milan, 1996, p. 42.<br />

24<br />

Goldschmidt, p. 297, who makes reference also to the banking business of the House of San Giorgio, which<br />

was, however, exercised to the profit of the House and not of its creditors: see Sieveking, supra n. 16, 2 nd part, p. 62 et<br />

seq.<br />

25<br />

G. Felloni, supra n. 23, p. 42.<br />

26<br />

N. Machiavelli, Istorie fiorentine, 8, 29, cited by Costantini, p. 27.<br />

27<br />

Felloni, supra n. 25, p. 41.<br />

28<br />

Goldschmidt, supra n. 12, p. 297.<br />

29 nd<br />

Ibidem. For the original constitution, see Sieveking, supra n. 18, 2 part, p. 22 et seq.<br />

30<br />

C. Costantini, La Repubblica di Genova, Turin, 1986, p. 29.<br />

31<br />

Sieveking, supra n.16, p. 25; Vighi, supra n.18, p. 669 et seq.; Vivante, supra n. 18.<br />

32<br />

Supra n.16, p. 25<br />

33<br />

Supra para. 3.1; on these similarities, see also K. Lehman, Lehrbuch des Handelsrechts, Leipzig, 1908, p.<br />

370 et seq., making reference to Id., Recht der Aktiengesellschaften 1, § 4 et seq.<br />

5


2.2.3 Why not in Venice?<br />

The Venetians made also use of the maonae, particularly to finance their trade with<br />

Flanders. However, these companies had always a temporary nature, as they were created by the<br />

merchants interested in an individual expedition, with reference to all the vessels employed. As<br />

argued by F.C. Lane, the Venetian maonae could have been more important in the absence of the<br />

State’s strong intervention in the merchant navy area 34 . If whole fleets of vessels had not been built<br />

by the Venetian Government in its Arsenale (shipyard) and then chartered to traders, on the basis of<br />

public auctions, for employment in individual expeditions (often under rules issued by the Senate),<br />

the maonae would have been necessarily transformed into permanent organisations 35 . In other<br />

words, limited liability companies were not created in sixteenth century Venice because the<br />

Republic solved a great part of the financial problems inherent in international trade by building and<br />

owning the fleets needed to carry the merchandise to and from Flanders.<br />

2.3 VOC’s Emulators<br />

At the end of the sixteenth and throughout the seventeenth centuries, the leadership as to<br />

innovation in commercial techniques was taken by the Northern countries, particularly the<br />

Netherlands and England 36 . The extraordinary development of ocean trade and the growing need for<br />

capital to finance new ventures determined the formation of modern limited liability companies. It<br />

is no surprise, therefore, that the first Italian limited liability companies were created along the<br />

Dutch model in the area of shipping and international trade. One of them, in particular, was formed<br />

to do business with the East Indies, in competition with the VOC (see para. 2.3.2.).<br />

2.3.1 The Compagnia di Nostra Signora della Libertà<br />

The Compagnia di Nostra Signora della Libertà (CNSL) was the first company to be<br />

formed “all’olandese” (in the Dutch manner) 37 and is to be considered the first Italian limited<br />

liability company 38 . It was formed in Genoa, at the end of 1638, with the purpose of developing the<br />

use of “galee di libertà”, i.e. galleys armed with free men as rowers, instead of slaves, as was<br />

common at that time. The CNSL’s objective was also political, as the employment of slaves was<br />

more expensive and the recourse to free men was conceived of by the “navalist” party as a means to<br />

34<br />

F.C. Lane, I mercanti di Venezia, Torino, 1982 (translated by E. Basaglia), p. 245 et seq. (for the original<br />

text, see ‘Family Partnerships and Joint Ventures’ (1944) 4 Journal of Economic History 178-196).<br />

35<br />

Ibidem,<br />

36<br />

See Cipolla, supra n. 16, p. 190.<br />

37<br />

S. Subrahmanyam, ‘On the Significance of Gadflies: the Genovese East India Company of the 1640s’ (1988)<br />

17 Journal of European Economic History 559, at 564-565.<br />

38<br />

P. Ungari, Statuti di compagnie e società azionarie italiane (1638-1808). Per la storia delle società per<br />

azioni in Italia, Milan, 1993, p. 3 et seq.<br />

6


enhance the Genoese merchant marine 39 . The CNSL was approved, “not without difficulties (as for<br />

all new things)” 40 by the Genoese Senate and the first trip to Sicily was highly profitable. This<br />

increased the company’s appeal, so that the shareholders soon reached the number of 70 and<br />

deliberated to emulate the successful Dutch companies 41 . However, the CNSL’s activities met fierce<br />

opposition amongst those who were close to Spain and contrary to a new naval policy. As a result,<br />

the CNSL rapidly went out of business, but the basic project was not abandoned by its members, as<br />

we shall see in the following paragraph.<br />

2.3.2 The Compagnia Genovese delle Indie Orientali<br />

The Compagnia Genovese delle Indie Orientali (CGIO) was formed in early 1647 42 , with a<br />

capital of 100,000 scudi which was provided, for a substantial amount, by the principal shareholders<br />

in the earlier Compagnia di Nostra Signora di Libertà. The CGIO was created to start trade with the<br />

East Indies, along the lines which had already proven successful for the VOC. The creation of this<br />

company also reflected the current political orientations of the Republic of Genoa towards a<br />

renewed naval policy and the development of international trade 43 . The Genoese aimed, in<br />

particular, at resurrecting their maritime traditions, which had given way to the English and Dutch<br />

fleets in Mediterranean trades. In addition, they wanted to regain a share of international trade,<br />

possibly in co-operation and also in competition with England and the Netherlands, paying special<br />

attention to Portugal, which had recently left Spanish domination and appeared to be open to<br />

Genoese penetration. The Genoese ambitions were supported by a relatively peaceful European<br />

scenario, after years of wars and revolutions, and aimed to invest the private wealth accumulated by<br />

the leading families in lucrative trades with the East Indies and the American Continent 44 .<br />

There were also Dutch interests involved in the CGIO’s creation, of merchants presumably<br />

unhappy with the monopoly enjoyed by the VOC over Asian trade 45 . Soon after forming the CGIO,<br />

39 Costantini, supra n. 30, p. 308 et seq.; on the political conditions of that time, see R. Savelli, ‘Un seguace<br />

italiano di Selden: Pietro Battista Borghi’ in G. Tarello (Ed.), Materiali per una storia della cultura giuridica, III, 1,<br />

Bologna, 1973, p. 18 et seq., who illustrates the difficulties created for Genoa by the wars between France and Spain in<br />

Italy, and notes that the Genoese were divided almost into two groups, one politically conservative and close to Spain,<br />

the other reformist and either neutralist or francofile.<br />

40 R. Della Torre, Historie delli avvenimenti de’ suoi tempi, II, p. 1170, cited by Costantini, p. 308.<br />

41 Ibidem, p. 1173.<br />

42 See G. Pessagno, ‘La grande navigazione genovese al XVII secolo. La Compagnia delle Indie Orientali’<br />

(1930) 10 Genova 641-647; earlier information in L.T. Belgrano, ‘La Compagnia genovese delle Indie’ (1875) 2<br />

Giornale Ligustico 121-125; for more recent analyses, C. Costantini, supra n. 30, pp. 315-319; Subrahmanyam, supra n.<br />

37, 559-581; V. Borghesi, ‘La marineria olandese come modello per la Repubblica di Genova nella prima metà del<br />

Seicento’, paper presented at a symposium on ‘Genua, la Superba’, Utrecht, 6 may 1996, which was shown to me by the<br />

courtesy of the author.<br />

43 See Costantini, supra n. 30, pp. 314 et seq.<br />

44 Ibidem.<br />

45 See Subrahmanyam, supra n. 37, 566. One of these, Willem Meulman, a resident of Ams terdam, had a<br />

brother Hendrik who was the Dutch Consul in Genoa in the 1640s and apparently enjoyed close relations with the<br />

leading Genoese merchants: “The Meulman brothers promised to have the ships for the Company’s Asian voyages<br />

7


its founders submitted an application, on the 13 th March 1647, to obtain from the Government of the<br />

“Serenissima” (as the Genoese Republic used to be called) an authorisation of the venture and a<br />

special privilege for at least 50 years 46 . The Government answered on the 27 th March, granting a<br />

privilege for thirty years (“concedatur privilegium duraturum per annos triginta”) 47 . The authorised<br />

venture covered navigation and trade of goods to the Eastern Indies, including Japan, its vicinity<br />

and other free and practicable places. Another decree was issued by the “Serenissima” on the 22 nd<br />

January 1648, which is considered to be the Company’s official licence 48 .<br />

The CGIO’s trade was unsuccessful, as it encountered on the part of the VOC fierce<br />

resistance to new entrants in its Asian lucrative business. The CGIO’s ships had been secretely built<br />

in the Netherlands; however, even before they sailed from Genoa, the secret concerning their real<br />

destination was out 49 . The first to know of the secret were the Portuguese, who informed, through<br />

their ambassador in the Hague, the VOC’s seventeen directors about the planned expedition 50 . A<br />

few days later, the seventeen directors sent a letter to the Governor-General at Batavia with the<br />

“express charge, order and responsibility” to ensure that the monopoly rights of the Dutch in<br />

Indonesia and other parts of Asia be protected against the Genoese 51 . The VOC’s legal arguments<br />

were straightforward. On the one hand, the Dutch Government had, by a decree of 1632, forbidden<br />

“any person from the United Provinces to seek employ with another Company in Asia, the more so<br />

if he had earlier been an employee of the VOC” 52 . On the other, “the ‘exclusive treaties’ they had<br />

signed with rulers in various parts of Indonesia were seen by the Dutch as legally binding on other<br />

secretely constructed in Holland along the lines of the Dutch East Indiamen, and also agreed to arrange for expert<br />

steersmen, merchants and mariners to help staff the vessels. While it is not clear whether they in fact also financed a<br />

great proportion of the venture, the Meulmans almost certainly had a part interest” (Ibidem). Subrahmanyam’s study is<br />

of particular interest, as it makes use of Genoese, Dutch and Portuguese sources as to the CGIO.<br />

46<br />

See Pessagno, supra n. 42, at 642, quoting a document found at Archivio di Stato di Genova (Maritim. fil. 2).<br />

47<br />

Ibidem, p. 643.<br />

48<br />

Ibidem, quoting a document found at Archivio di Stato di Genova (Archivio Segreto, Fondo Gavazzo, fil. 2).<br />

This decree authorised the CGIO to sail the two vessels, which had been built in the Netherlands and were ready to sail<br />

from Genoa, to the East Indies under the leadership of Gio. Maes, a Dutch captain, and to fight against the Turkish and<br />

other “Infidelli” (unfaithful). Moreover, the decree mandated all the Genoese officers, either in land or at sea, to give<br />

their assistance for the success of the expedition and made a similar petition to anyone else who might be concerned. In<br />

addition, the decree provided for guns to be delivered to the two vessels from the “Camera” (Economic Ministry) and<br />

submitted to the “Giunta di Marina” (Admiralty) for approval the rules for the navigating crew. For information on the<br />

“enlistment contract”, which had to be detailed as the crew included Dutch seamen who were not subject to Ge noese<br />

laws, see D. Presotto, Da Genova alle Indie alla metà del Seicento: un singolare contratto di arruolamento marittimo<br />

((1979) Atti della Società Ligure di Storia Patria 71-91.<br />

49<br />

See Subrahmanyam, supra n. 37, 569.<br />

50<br />

Ibidem. As reported by the Portuguese ambassador, the seventeen directors were “amazed, because they<br />

knew nothing of it, as it had been done very secretly; they thanked me and said that we might rest assured that they<br />

would strive to undo the voyage and would also advise us of what would be required either from them or form us to<br />

prevent such navigations” (Letter from Francisco de Sousa Coutinho to D. João IV, quoted by Subrahmanyam, supra n.<br />

37, at 569).<br />

51<br />

Subrahmanyam, supra n. 37, 569-570.<br />

52 Ibidem, 570.<br />

8


parties and nations as well” 53 . Clearly, the Genoese and their Dutch partners in the CGIO had<br />

miscalculated the risk of such a reaction by the VOC, presumably counting on traditionally friendly<br />

relationships with the Netherlands 54 .<br />

As a result, when the expedition, characterised by adventures and fighting, even within the<br />

Dutch-Genoese crew and merchants, reached Sumatra and tried to enter into the pepper trade, the<br />

Dutch authorities in that area had already been alerted 55 . Immediate action was taken by the<br />

Governor-General van der Lijn, who sent out two fleets, each of four ships. The capture of the two<br />

Genoese vessels proved no problem and “the Dutch fleet returned to Batavia with its two prizes on<br />

26 April 1649, exactly a month after the first reports of the Genoese presence had been received” 56 .<br />

This event is richly illustrated in detail by an economic historian also to underline “the importance<br />

of violence in determining the success of the VOC”, as the Genoese had sadly to experiment in the<br />

CGIO’s expedition 57 .<br />

2.3.3 The Compagnia Marittima di S. Giorgio<br />

Despite the failure of the East Indies’ venture, the Genoese plans to renew their successes in<br />

international trade and navigation were not abandoned, but included in a more ambitious project.<br />

The CGIO was “transformed” into the Compagnia Marittima di S. Giorgio (CMSG) , which was<br />

made more powerful than its predecessor 58 . All the privileges which had been granted by the<br />

Genoese Republic to the CGIO were transferred to the CMSG and were extended to other trades.<br />

Other privileges and financings were given to the Company by the Casa di S. Giorgio (the old<br />

Genoese bank, which was provided with State-like sovereign power) 59 . In addition, among the<br />

CMSG’s shareholders several represented powerful interest groups, whereas its directors also<br />

occupied offices as naval magistrates of the Republic 60 . As implicitly argued in a well known<br />

treatise on Navigation and Commerce by Tobia Pallavicini 61 , the CMSG was near to the English<br />

and Dutch models of public limited liability companies, and was similarly in a very close<br />

relationship with the State. Several aspects of the Company’s mission reflected the link with the<br />

53<br />

Ibidem.<br />

54<br />

See Costantini, supra n.30, p. 318.<br />

55<br />

Subrahmanyam, supra n. 37, 570 et seq., where a recount of the expedition.<br />

56<br />

Ibidem, 576.<br />

57<br />

Ibidem, 581, also quoting a Genoese source such as G.B. Pallavicini, who wrote in 1653 of “the jealousy and<br />

envy of the Flemings in fearing that others would involve themselves in that trade, by the exercise of which [the Dutch]<br />

have transformed themselves from the inhabitants of a few marshes to the most powerful people in Europe” (Archivio di<br />

Stato di Genova, Archivio Segreto, Lettere ministri, 2185, dated 19 th December 1653, cited in C. Costantini, pp. 318-<br />

319).<br />

58<br />

See Costantini, supra n.30, pp. 319-321.<br />

59<br />

Ibidem, p. 319. See also the CMSG’s memorandum of association (“statuto”), found at Archivio di Stato di<br />

Genova (Notai Giudiziari, n. 2311, Camere Gerolamo, 1658) and published by Ungari, supra n. 38, pp. 10-13.<br />

60<br />

See Costantini, supra n.30, p. 319.<br />

9


Genoese Republic, such as the fight against pirates, the reintroduction of naval arts in Genoa, the<br />

education of sailors and the organisation of schools for naval officers 62 .<br />

As to the direction of its trades, the CGSG decided to experiment the opportunities offered<br />

by Portugal, which lacked ships and capital for trade with its colonies. However, the Company was<br />

to find out that the English already controlled most of the important routes and that the Genoese, in<br />

any case, lacked the experience required to compete with them 63 . The CGSG succeeded in sending<br />

two ships in a convoy to Brazil, but the expedition was unprofitable 64 , as the Company as a whole<br />

turned out to be despite its ambitions.<br />

2.4 Early Corporate Governance<br />

After the Genoese experiences just described, other limited liability companies were formed<br />

in Italy in the second half of the 17 th century and, above all, in the course of the 18 th century. A<br />

collection of articles of association of Italian companies formed before company law codification<br />

by Napoleon was published in 1993 by P. Ungari, following wide (though incomplete) research at<br />

the relevant archives 65 . It includes the statuti of 110 companies, while giving information on an<br />

equal number of companies for which the articles of association were not found. These statuti are<br />

characterised by increasing uniformity, despite the absence of legislation on limited liability<br />

companies. They also show an inclination on the part of Italian companies towards the English<br />

model, which was more ‘democratic’ than the Dutch model as reflected by the VOC 66 . Despite the<br />

acceptance, in some earlier companies, of a rather oligarchic structure, as evidenced either by the<br />

general meeting’s very limited powers or by the fact that only the major shareholders were admitted<br />

to vote 67 , a more balanced approach to the relationship between directors and shareholders later<br />

prevailed 68 .<br />

However, the relevance of limited liability companies in 18 th century Italy should not be<br />

overestimated. The need for an ad hoc government decree in order for these companies to be<br />

61<br />

Della Navigazione e del Commercio, Considerazioni politiche, Genoa 1656, cited by C. Costantini, supra<br />

n.30, p. 319, n. 2.<br />

62<br />

Ibidem, p. 320.<br />

63<br />

Ibidem, pp. 320-321.<br />

64<br />

See also Subrahmanyam, supra n. 37, 579.<br />

65<br />

Supra n. 38.<br />

66<br />

See Mignoli, ‘Idee e problemi nell’evoluzione della ‘company’ inglese’ (1960) Riv. Soc. 633, at 639 et seq.,<br />

who compares the English companies’ democratic organisation with the Dutch companies’ oligarchic structure.<br />

67<br />

See e.g. the articles of the Compagnia di negozio per il commercio con il Portogallo ed il Brasile, Turin,<br />

1681, in Ungari, supra n. 38, p. 16 et seq., dividing the governance powers between directors and supervisors, with little<br />

consideration for the members; and those of the Compagnia Generale di Assicurazioni Marittime, Genoa, 1741,<br />

granting full voting rights only to shareholders holding more than a stated number of shares.<br />

68<br />

See P. Ungari, Profilo storico del diritto delle anonime in Italia, Rome, 1974, p. 24 et seq. Early examples<br />

are found in the articles of the Compagnia Reale del Piemonte per le Opere e Negozi in Seta, Turin, 1752, in Ungari,<br />

supra n. 38, p. 91 et seq., including inter alia a ‘one share-one vote’ principle, and the Società Minerale di Livorno,<br />

Leghorn, 1756, ibidem, p. 195 et seq., foreseeing half-yearly shareholders’ meetings.<br />

10


formed, together with the poor economic and financial conditions of the country, which had<br />

suffered a steep economic decline in the 16 th and 17 th centuries 69 , explain why the accomandita was<br />

still successful as a business form at the turn of the century 70 .<br />

3 COMPANY LAW CODIFICATION<br />

In this Section, I intend to briefly analyse company law codification in Italy throughout the<br />

19 th and 20 th century, initially under the influence of the French Code which was made applicable to<br />

the Italian territories by Napoleon. This period is characterised by Italy’s strong economic<br />

development, mostly after the country’s unification in the second half of the 19 th century and, above<br />

all, in the wake of the ‘second industrial revolution’ led by the U.S.A. in the 20 th century. Another<br />

period of Italy’s economic expansion followed the second world war. It will be interesting to see<br />

how the successive Italian codes, adopted in 1882 and 1942 respectively, preceded by some years<br />

the relevant periods of economic development, and included rules on limited liability companies<br />

which soon appeared to be outdated with reference to the needs of economic reality. This will lead<br />

to the analysis, in the following Section, of recent reforms trying to cope with the foreseeable needs<br />

of company law in the 21 st century.<br />

3.1 The French Tradition<br />

The Code de commerce which was adopted by Napoleon in 1807 included a few Articles on<br />

the limited liability company (société anonyme). This company ceased to be subject to the special<br />

privilege of incorporation and was regulated in a general, though concise, way by the law 71 .<br />

However, the introduction of a general incorporation regime did not mean freedom to set up limited<br />

liability companies. Less liberal than the New York Law of 1811, which also abolished the special<br />

charter privileges, the Code de commerce introduced an administrative authorisation regime as to<br />

the formation of the société anonyme (Art. 37). This regime was officially justified with reference<br />

to private law arguments, such as the protection of subscribers and third parties from speculation<br />

and frauds; however, it also reflected more fundamental public policy concerns, as the centralism of<br />

the Empire did not tolerate independent social powers 72 .<br />

3.1.1 The Code de commerce in Italy<br />

Despite the elaboration of numerous draft commercial codes in the States into which Italy<br />

was divided before its unification, Napoleon made the Code de commerce applicable to the Italian<br />

Regions annexed to the French Empire (including Liguria, Piedmont and Tuscany), to the Regno<br />

69 See Cipolla, supra n. 2, p. 273 et seq.<br />

70 See Ungari, supra note 68, p. 26 et seq.<br />

71 See G. Ripert, Aspects juridiques du capitalism moderne, 2nd ed., Paris, 1951, p. 51.<br />

11


Italico (of which Milan was the capital) and to the Kingdom of Naples 73 . After the Restoration, the<br />

Code de commerce was kept in force in several regions, such as the Lombard-Venetian Kingdom,<br />

the Grand-dukedom of Tuscany and Genoa, while other States (such as Piedmont and the Pontifical<br />

State) adopted their own commercial codes, which, however, followed closely the French model 74 .<br />

The Kingdom of Sardinia proceeded to a new codification of all its laws in the thirties, which led to<br />

the adoption of a new commercial Code in 1842, still modelled on the French Code but with some<br />

differences. This Code, dubbed as Codice Albertino (after the name of King Carlo Alberto), was<br />

extended to the Kingdom of Italy in 1864, after the country’s unification 75 .<br />

The rules on limited liability companies (società anonime) were still grounded on the<br />

Napoleonic precedent. They focussed on the limitation of shareholders’ liability, on directors’<br />

powers and responsibility, and on shares and their transferability 76 . However, the practical<br />

relevance of the società anonima was probably very limited in the Italian States prior to unification;<br />

these had yet to recover from the sharp economic decline of the previous centuries and were still<br />

mainly rural, with only a few isolated cases of early industrialisation 77 . As in other countries, the<br />

main limited liability companies at the time of the country’s unification operated railways, with the<br />

contribution of foreign capital 78 .<br />

Stock exchange trading was also underdeveloped. The first stock exchanges were set up<br />

along the French model at the beginning of the nineteenth century, however they were not active for<br />

a long time 79 . Considering the two main exchanges, at the time of unification (1861) only 10<br />

companies were listed in Genoa and 8 in Milan; transactions in both exchanges were modest and<br />

price manipulation was easy 80 .<br />

3.1.2 The Commercial Code of 1865<br />

One of the main themes of discussion as to company law reform in the new Italian Kingdom<br />

was whether limited liability companies should be subject to governmental authorisation, as<br />

provided by the pre-unification commercial codes along the French model. In a report written by<br />

Tommaso Corsi, a member of the House of Representatives who worked on a company law reform<br />

72 See Ungari, supra n. 68, p. 30 et seq.<br />

73 See A. Padoa Schioppa, Saggi di storia del diritto commerciale, Milan, 1992, p. 137 et seq.<br />

74 Ibidem, p. 141 et seq.<br />

75 Ibidem, p. 149 et seq.<br />

76 The relevant rules were indeed simple, as shown by the little space dedicated to them in legal commentaries:<br />

see e.g. G. Marré, Corso di diritto commerciale, 2 nd ed., Florence, 1840, pp. 39-40.<br />

77 See N. Crepax, Storia dell’industria in Italia: uomini, imprese e prodotti, Bologna, 2002, p. 93 et seq.<br />

78 Ibidem, p. 105 et seq.<br />

79 See S. Baia Curioni, Regolazione e competizione: storia del mercato azionario in Italia, Bologna, 1995, p.<br />

47 et seq., with reference to the Milan Bourse, which was founded in 1808 under French influence.<br />

80 See A. Polsi, Alle origini del capitalismo italiano: Stato, banche e banchieri dopo l’Unità, Turin, 1993, p.<br />

142 et seq.<br />

12


project in 1862, a proposal was made to abolish the authorisation regime as incapable of preventing<br />

frauds and excessively limiting freedom of trade 81 . In lieu of the companies’ public surveillance, it<br />

was recommended to regulate better the relationships between shareholders and directors, as well as<br />

those amongst shareholders. However, this proposal was fiercely opposed also in the wake of<br />

financial fraud cases and was later rejected by Parliament when adopting the first Italian<br />

Commercial Code in 1865. This Code largely followed the Codice Albertino’s model and<br />

reinforced the public surveillance regime by instituting a new Control Office (Ufficio di sindacato)<br />

both to authorise new companies and to monitor existing ones 82 .<br />

3.2 The Commercial Code of 1882<br />

It was only with the second Commercial Code, adopted in 1882, that a more liberal attitude<br />

was taken and governmental authorisation was abolished, as had already been done in France in<br />

1867. Consequently, the conditions as to company formation were specified by the Code, and the<br />

Commercial Tribunal was empowered to ascertain these conditions before the company’s<br />

registration.<br />

The Code was the result of drafting efforts which extended over more than a decade with the<br />

participation of some of Italy’s finest scholars 83 . This was reflected by the high technical quality of<br />

the Code which was in line with its homologues in Europe, such as the English Law of 1861, the<br />

French Law of 1867, the German Commercial Code of 1861 (ADHG) and the Law of 1870, and the<br />

Belgian Law of 1873, all widely considered throughout the legislative work 84 . The Code included,<br />

for those times, advanced regulation of limited liability companies (società anonime). Amongst the<br />

novelties was the introduction of a board of auditors to monitor the company’s management and<br />

accounts on behalf of shareholders and creditors, along the model of English Law, and, as a<br />

counterbalance, the abolition of the administrative surveillance regime 85 . On the whole, the Code<br />

followed “the first systematic approach to companies. The general meeting and its functioning, the<br />

directors and their responsibility, corporate control and the protection of minorities, the regulation<br />

of accounts, liquidation and mergers found in these texts [i.e. the Code and its previous drafts] a<br />

modern treatment” 86<br />

81<br />

See A. Marghieri, I motivi del nuovo Codice di Commercio italiano, Naples, 1885-1886, Appendix, p. 193 et<br />

seq.<br />

82<br />

See Padoa Schioppa, supra n. 73, p. 213 et seq.<br />

83<br />

Ibidem, p. 157 et seq.<br />

84<br />

Ibidem, p. 226.<br />

85<br />

See P.E. Bensa, ‘I sindaci della società per azioni, cenni storici e comparativi’ (1883) Rassegna di diritto<br />

commerciale 1.<br />

86<br />

See G. Cottino and G. Minervini, ‘La società per azioni a cento anni dal codice di commercio’, in 1882-1982<br />

Cento anni dal Codice di Commercio, Milan, 1984, p. 112.<br />

13


All this helps to understand why the Commercial Code and its rules on companies, in<br />

particular, remained in force, with minor modifications, for sixty years. However, the economic<br />

development that occurred throughout this period of time exerted considerable strain on the Code’s<br />

regulation of limited companies. At the time of the Code’s adoption, Italy was still a rural country,<br />

despite some notable examples of industrialisation, particularly in the Northern regions and in the<br />

fields of mechanical and textile industries. But in the first decade of the 20 th century, Italy joined<br />

the small group of industrialised nations: “To be true, the industrial takeoff was completed only at<br />

the end of the first world war; in addition, a relevant part of the country was cut off from economic<br />

development. Nonetheless, from the beginning of the century the industrial structure of our country<br />

was consolidated and a modern society started to emerge, characterised by substantial urbanisation<br />

and fast growth of national income” 87 . This was also a reflection of the second industrial revolution<br />

occurring in other countries, particularly the United States and Germany 88 . New companies were<br />

formed in Italy to produce electricity, steel, automobiles, tyres, trains, typewriters, etc., with the<br />

financing on the part of a few large banks and the support of the State 89 .<br />

As a result, new problems were created to company law, with which the Commercial Code<br />

was ill-equipped to cope: the formation of company groups, cross-shareholdings, voting limitations<br />

and multiple voting shares, controlling minorities and the separation of ownership and control 90 .<br />

These and similar issues mainly derived from the increasing need of capital to finance the<br />

extraordinary growth of industry. In the first decade of 1900’s, the stock exchanges were able to<br />

provide a good portion of the financing required by the new businesses. Between 1900 and 1907 the<br />

number of companies listed at the Milan Bourse increased from 59 to 169, with the bulk of new<br />

listings concentrated in the last three years, a record figure in the whole century 91 . The stock<br />

exchanges’ capitalisation amounted to 70 per cent of Italian equity 92 . However, stock exchange<br />

trading was dominated by speculation, which was financed by the large banks, concurrently<br />

operating as providers of equity and loans to industry 93 . In 1907, the stock markets started<br />

declining, as a result of an international liquidity crisis which caused a credit restriction, and<br />

continued doing so until 1920, with a drop of 80 per cent in capitalisation in real terms. This crisis<br />

87<br />

See V. Castronovo, L’industria italiana dall’ottocento a oggi, Milan, 1990, p. 71.<br />

88<br />

See A.D. Chandler, F. Amatori and T. Hikino (Eds.), Big Business and the Wealth of Nations, Cambridge,<br />

1997, for a comparative analysis of several countries’ industrial development in the period in question.<br />

89<br />

See Crepax, supra n. 77, p. 37 et seq., noting that this was the American century, the age of “Fordism”, mass<br />

production and standardisation of products (p. 40).<br />

90<br />

See G. Ferri, ‘La disciplina delle società nel Codice di commercio del 1882’, in 1882-1982 Cento anni dal<br />

Codice di Commercio, Milan, 1984, p. 105. For an economic analysis of the relevant governance structures, see F.<br />

Amatori, ‘La grande impresa’, in Storia d’Italia, Annali, 15, L’industria, Turin, 1999, p. 691 et seq.<br />

91<br />

See G. Siciliano, Cento anni di borsa in Italia, Bologna, 2001, p. 17 et seq.<br />

92 Ibidem.<br />

93 Ibidem.<br />

14


caused significant problems to the banking system and is considered as a landmark in the history of<br />

Italian capital markets, which subsequently ceased to develop in relative terms and remained thin<br />

and inadequate to finance economic development 94 .<br />

3.3 The Civil Code of 1942<br />

Another severe crisis occurred a the beginning of the ‘30s as a result of the world economic<br />

recession and led to an impressive rescue operation concerning the large universal banks and almost<br />

half of the large industrial companies 95 . This operation was conducted by the Government through<br />

the Istituto per la Ricostruzione Industriale (IRI) which became the controlling shareholder of<br />

several industrial conglomerates (including a number of listed companies) and of the main Italian<br />

banks. At the same time, a new banking law was adopted to introduce a tighter system of<br />

surveillance and sever the residual links between bank and industry at the ownership level (with the<br />

exception of IRI) 96 . Public ownership of business was originally intended as a temporary measure,<br />

but it subsequently became a stable solution, characterising our system as a ‘mixed economy’ 97 . Not<br />

only several industrial conglomerates, but the prevailing part of our banking system, including all<br />

the large banks, were owned by the State until the wave of privatisations in the 1990s. On the other<br />

hand, capital markets suffered both from the wide role of the State in the economy and from the<br />

Fascist Government’s policy aimed at reducing the stock exchanges’ relevance in the financial<br />

system 98 .<br />

These comments help to put in an appropriate historical context the reformulation of<br />

company law rules in the Civil Code of 1942, which replaced both the Civil Code of 1865 and the<br />

Commercial Code of 1882 by unifying private law. The Code’s rules were the results of several<br />

reform projects which had been elaborated over more than forty years, as the industrial takeoff of<br />

the country and the diffusion of limited liability companies highlighted the limits of the<br />

Commercial Code in this area. The main projects were published in the first quarter of the last<br />

century and reflected either the need for improved protection of minority shareholders, widely<br />

shared by public opinion in the light of financial crisis and scandals (Vivante Project, 1922) or the<br />

industrialists’ wish for the maintenance of the status quo under which they enjoyed large freedom<br />

of action (Confindustria’s Proposals, 1925) 99 . A third initiative tried to mediate between the two<br />

94 Ibidem, quoting A.M. Biscaini Cotula and P. Ciocca, ‘Le strutture finanziarie: aspetti quantitative di lungo<br />

periodo (1870-1970), in F. Vicarelli (Ed.), Capitale industriale e capitale finanziario: il caso italiano, Bologna, 1979.<br />

95 See, also for references, P. Bianchi, La rincorsa frenata. L’industria italiana dall’unità nazionale<br />

all’unificazione europea, Bologna, 2002, p. 38 et seq.<br />

96 See G. Conti, ‘Le banche e il finanziamento industriale’, in Storia d’Italia, supra n.90, p. 483 et seq.<br />

97 See F. Barca and S. Trento, ‘La parabola delle partecipazioni statali: una missione tradita’, in F. Barca (Ed.),<br />

Storia del capitalismo italiano dal dopoguerra a oggi, Roma, 1997, p. 186 et seq.<br />

98 See Siciliano, supra n. 91, p. 32 et seq.<br />

99 See Padoa Schioppa, supra n. 73, p. 226 et seq.<br />

15


opposing camps by adopting only the innovations needed to foster the country’s economic<br />

development (D’Amelio Project, 1925) 100 .<br />

However, 15 years had to elapse before the reform activity was resumed, a long delay which<br />

can only partially be explained by reference to the conflicting views on company law reform and to<br />

the pressure exercised by industrial circles on the Fascist Government. An additional argument can<br />

be made with regard to the corporate governance and finance developments which took place in the<br />

thirties, along the lines stated above. The public ownership of a large part of the industrial and<br />

financial sectors, and a hostile policy towards the stock exchanges combined to play down the need<br />

for company law reform. This negatively affected the outline of such a reform, which almost<br />

ignored the connection between joint-stock companies and securities markets, and avoided some of<br />

the main issues of modern corporate governance, including the separation between ownership and<br />

control in listed companies 101 .<br />

As a result, the Civil Code’s rules on limited liability companies, despite making a<br />

distinction between private companies (società a responsabilità limitata) and joint-stock companies<br />

(società per azioni) so as to better allocate the regulatory burdens depending on the size and<br />

relevance of the business venture, dedicate an incomplete regulation to the latter type of companies.<br />

The limits of the Civil Code were clearly shown, almost forty years ago, by one of the leading<br />

commercial lawyers, Tullio Ascarelli, in his inaugural study on the Rivista delle società, where he<br />

highlighted the wide existence of ‘controlling minorities’ in listed companies and the ensuing<br />

separation of ownership and control 102 . This required, in the author’s opinion (explicitly inspired by<br />

the Anglo-American experience), improving the internal governance structure of joint-stock<br />

companies, reinforcing the shareholders’ powers and introducing a public regulator to protect<br />

investors in listed companies: measures which were taken incrementally by the Italian Legislator<br />

only in the last quarter of the last century, as will be shown below.<br />

3.4 The Rise of Capital Market Law<br />

The Civil Code’s fate was similar to that of the Commercial Code, to the extent that not<br />

many years after the Code’s adoption Italy went through a phase of extraordinary economic<br />

development, known as the ‘economic miracle’ 103 . Industrial productivity increased substantially,<br />

also as a consequence of the Common Market’s liberalisation policy, and this was reflected by the<br />

100 Ibidem, p. 240 et seq.<br />

101 See R. Teti, ‘Imprese, imprenditori e diritto’, in Storia d’Italia, supra n. 96, p. 1274 et seq., illustrating the<br />

lukewarm reception of protection of minorities’ principles in the Civil Code, which maintained a corporate governance<br />

structure similar to that foreseen by the Commercial Code, despite widespread criticism of the board of statutory<br />

auditors (collegio sindacale) and proposals to replace it with external auditors.<br />

102 T. Ascarelli, ‘I problemi delle società anonime per azioni’ (1956) Rivista delle società 3 et seq.<br />

103 See, instead of many, Bianchi, supra n. 95, p. 117 et seq.<br />

16


stock market’s exceptional performance in the post-war period 104 . However, despite the stock<br />

market’s significant contribution to the financing of industry, the former’s structural conditions (as<br />

measured for instance by the number of listed companies) were left substantially unchanged 105 .<br />

The renovated industrial successes of the country threw new light on the inadequacy of the<br />

Civil Code’s rules on joint-stock companies and led to the formulation of several reform<br />

projects 106 . However, T. Ascarelli’s proposal 107 of shareholders’ empowerment as a means for<br />

investor protection was generally rejected. The emphasis was rather put on the distinction between<br />

two shareholders’ groups in listed companies: those who are interested in the management of the<br />

company’s enterprise (‘shareholders-entrepreneurs’, as the controllers or block-holders used to be<br />

defined) and those who are only interested in investing (‘shareholders-investors’) 108 . In particular, it<br />

was argued that the shareholders-investors would never be active in corporate governance and<br />

would rather vote with their feet, by selling their shares in underperforming companies 109 . As a<br />

consequence, the legislator should mainly protect their position as investors, by introducing<br />

mandatory rules, improving disclosure and caring for the investors’ rights to dividends. Moreover, a<br />

public regulator should be created with competencies on corporate disclosure and, under some<br />

proposals, on the legality of corporate actions 110 .<br />

It was under the influence of these ideas that a reform of company law and stock exchange<br />

law took place in 1974. In lieu of focussing on the internal governance of listed companies, this<br />

‘small reform’ (miniriforma, as it was dubbed by the first commentators understating its relevance,<br />

as shown by later developments) sought to implement the investor protection principle through a<br />

number of regulatory innovations 111 . On the one hand, convertible bonds and saving shares (i.e.<br />

non-voting preferred shares) were specifically regulated to offer small investors, rather than<br />

controlling shareholders, financial instruments which were better suited to their investing goals (an<br />

assumption which was proven to be wrong by later developments concerning saving shares). On the<br />

other hand, a Securities Commission (Consob) was created with competences on corporate<br />

disclosure and stock exchange trading. In addition, information duties were placed on listed<br />

seq.<br />

104<br />

See Siciliano, supra n.91, p. 35 et seq.<br />

105<br />

Ibidem, p. 38.<br />

106<br />

See, also for references, Teti, supra n.101, p. 1284 et seq.<br />

107<br />

Supra n.102.<br />

108<br />

See G. Ferri, ‘La tutela dell’azionista in una prospettiva di riforma’ (1961) Rivista delle società 177.<br />

109<br />

Ibidem, p. 185 et seq.<br />

110<br />

See Teti, supra n.101, p. 1289 et seq., also for references to the reform projects of the ‘60s.<br />

111<br />

See P. Marchetti, ‘Diritto societario e disciplina della concorrenza’, in Barca (Ed.), supra n. 97, p. 489 et<br />

17


companies and companies making recourse to the capital markets. On the whole, this reform could<br />

be regarded as laying the foundations of a securities regulation system 112 .<br />

4 COMPANY LAW REFORM<br />

The legal framework of Italian capital markets was completed throughout the last two<br />

decades of the 20 th century, particularly by way of implementation of the European securities<br />

Directives. In addition, investment funds were regulated for the first time in 1983 and takeovers in<br />

1992, while a new regime on regulated markets was adopted in 1996 and the Italian Stock<br />

Exchange (consolidating pre-existing regional stock exchanges) was privatised in 1997 113 . These<br />

reforms reflected the new weight of capital markets in business financing and also their importance<br />

to the Italian Government’s privatisations program, which was executed throughout the second half<br />

of the ‘90s. As a result, a relatively modern capital market law came into existence, while company<br />

law appeared to be outdated, despite numerous Civil Code amendments mainly determined by the<br />

need to implement the European Directives. This led to further developments, which will be briefly<br />

analysed below.<br />

4.1 Corporate governance and the Draghi Law<br />

First of all, the emphasis put on corporate governance at the international level, both in<br />

practice and academia, made the 1974 reform appear inadequate, as it undervalued the internal<br />

governance of listed companies by focussing on disclosure and public regulation. While these two<br />

aspects still deserved consideration and improvement, also the corporate governance structure of<br />

listed companies needed upgrading. The Draghi Law of 1998 handled the matter from within a<br />

broader framework of capital market law consolidation. On the one hand, the Draghi Law<br />

strengthened the board of auditors’ (collegio sindacale) powers and responsibilities, so as to<br />

enhance its monitoring over the company’s management by the executive directors and the board of<br />

directors 114 . On the other, the law reinforced minority shareholders’ powers, introducing, inter alia,<br />

the right of a qualified minority (5 per cent) to sue the directors for damages caused to the company.<br />

In addition, the Draghi Law aimed to promote corporate control contestability in listed companies<br />

by attributing members of shareholders’ agreements the right to withdraw from the same in case of<br />

a takeover bid, so as to tender their shares to the bidder. This provision, together with other rules on<br />

takeovers, reflected the Draghi Law’s additional concern for the external governance of listed<br />

112<br />

See G. Rossi, Trasparenze e vergogna. Le società e la borsa, Milan, 1982, p. 113 et seq.<br />

113<br />

See, also for references, G. Ferrarini, ‘La riforma dei mercati finanziari e il testo unico’, in G. Ferrarini and<br />

P. Marchetti (Eds.), La riforma dei mercati finanziari, Milan, 1998, p. 25 et seq.<br />

114<br />

Italian governance structure consists of a board of directors and a board of statutory auditors, despite the<br />

fact that in listed companies accounting audits are performed by external auditors.<br />

18


companies and marked an important change in the Italian system, which had traditionally favoured<br />

corporate control stability over contestabilty 115 .<br />

4.2 Pending Company Law Reform<br />

By reforming the corporate governance of listed companies, the Draghi Law widened the<br />

regulatory differences between listed and unlisted companies and added arguments to the mounting<br />

criticism of traditional company law. An extensive overhaul of the limited liability company rules is<br />

now being conducted on the basis of a 2001 law empowering the Italian Government to adopt a<br />

reform the principles of which are loosely fixed by the same law. Among those principles is a<br />

clearer distinction between private companies (società a responsabilità limitata) and joint-stock<br />

companies (società per azioni). As to the former, the regime presently in force will be deregulated<br />

to the extent necessary to simplify the formation of these companies and allow more freedom in<br />

their organisation, so as to reflect their nature of closed companies. On the other hand, joint-stock<br />

companies’ rules will be reformulated on the assumption that these companies are allowed to make<br />

recourse to the equity markets, while stricter rules will be applicable to the same companies if they<br />

actually do so, thus becoming ‘public companies’. Also the joint-stock companies’ present regime<br />

will be, at least in part, deregulated and simplified. Moreover, three new governance structures will<br />

be available: one reflecting the structure presently in force, which consists of a board of directors<br />

and a board of statutory auditors (in addition to external auditors auditing the company’s accounts);<br />

another reflecting the German two-tier structure, however adapted to the Italian context; and a third<br />

one inspired by the Anglo-Saxon unitary board, with a majority of independent directors and a<br />

mandatory audit committee. The possibility to choose between these three different systems is<br />

intended as a substitute to regulatory competition, as the choice , for example, of the unitary board<br />

might work functionally as a (partial) equivalent to the choice of U.K. Law.<br />

5 CONCLUSIONS<br />

As shown in Section 2 of this paper, the origins of limited liability companies were closely<br />

linked to a particular stage of capitalistic development, which saw the Nordic countries dominate<br />

international trade which had, by that time, become ‘global’ after the discovery of the American<br />

Continent 116 . Italy was in a peripheral position with respect to the new trades with the East and the<br />

West Indies, as witnessed by the unsuccesses of the early Genoese companies formed in the Dutch<br />

115<br />

For an analysis of the philosophy of the Draghi Law see P. Marchetti, ‘Osservazioni sui profili societari<br />

della bozza di TU dei mercati finanziari’ (1998) Rivista delle società 140.<br />

116<br />

See F. Braudel, Espansione europea e capitalismo 1450–1650, Bologna, 1999, p. 52 et seq. (translation by<br />

G. Zattoni Nesi of ‘Expansion européenne et capitalisme (1450-1650)’, in R. Ayala and P. Braudel, Les Ambitions de<br />

l’Histoire, Paris, 1997).<br />

19


manner and by the limited relevance of this type of companies until the 19 th century. The scenario<br />

had been quite different in the first half of that millennium, when Italian cities dominated<br />

Mediterranean trades and some of the limited liabilities companies’ functions were exercised by the<br />

commenda (initially) and by the accomandita (at a later stage). However, the joint stock<br />

companies’ closest predecessors were found in the Genoese maone and the Banco di San Giorgio,<br />

which were involved in international trade and in the administration of colonies similarly to the<br />

VOC, in addition to issuing financial instruments largely traded on secondary markets.<br />

Limited liability companies became important in Italy only in the 19 th century after the<br />

country’s unification. Nonetheless, company law codification trailed several decades behind the<br />

diffusion of limited liability companies in economic reality, as explained in Section 3. The first<br />

code to include rules on limited liability companies was the Code de commerce, imported in Italy<br />

by Napoleon. Subsequent Italian codes were clearly influenced by this precedent, with the<br />

exception of the 1882 Commercial Code which was drafted along with the most recent European<br />

company laws. This Code carried remarkable regulatory novelties and liberalised the companies’<br />

formation by suppressing the administrative controls foreseen by previous legislation. Liberalisation<br />

was no doubt instrumental to rapid economic development at the turn of the century, when Italy<br />

joined the second industrial revolution. However, the diffusion of limited liability companies and<br />

the listing of their shares on the stock exchanges created problems which the Commercial Code was<br />

inadequate to cope with. These problems also depended on the governance structures of many<br />

Italian companies, which were already dominated by minority shareholders through cross-holdings,<br />

voting pacts and pyramidal groups, while small shareholders were largely passive. In addition,<br />

German-type universal banks concurred to the control of companies either directly or as proxies of<br />

their clients 117 .<br />

Another feature of Italian corporate governance was the role played by the State in<br />

economic development. Initially this role was limited to supporting industrial growth through<br />

protectionism, subsidies and the supply of goods and services to the State by private firms. At a<br />

later stage, the same role was extended through the acquisition of banks and industrial companies<br />

by the State 118 . This had an influence on company law reform and its repeated postponements,<br />

because public ownership of large sectors of the economy, as well as the equity markets’ limited<br />

role in the financing of industry, made company law modernisation less important from a policy<br />

perspective. As a result, the rules on limited liability companies, which were included in the Civil<br />

117 While banking law reform in the ‘30s operated to sever the links between banks and industries, other<br />

corporate governance features that first appeared at the beginning of the last century were carried over to the present<br />

times: see M. Bianchi, M. Bianco and L. Enriques, ‘Pyramidal Groups and the Separation between Ownership and<br />

Control in Italy’, in F. Barca and M. Becht (Eds.), The Control of Corporate Europe, Oxford, 2001, p. 154 et seq.<br />

20


Code of 1942 following private law unification, were very mild in protecting minorities and largely<br />

ignored the joint-stock companies’ role in the capital markets. More than thirty years elapsed before<br />

the introduction of disclosure rules for listed companies and a securities regulator.<br />

Corporate governance reform was delayed until the end of the ‘90s, as shown in section 4,<br />

while a general reform of company law is now expected by the Government. The Draghi Law took<br />

care of the listed companies’ internal governance, by enhancing the board of auditors’ role in the<br />

quasi-two-tier structure typical of Italian joint-stock companies and by reinforcing minority<br />

shareholders’ powers. Also the external governance of listed companies was dealt with by the<br />

Draghi Law, aiming to lower barriers to corporate control contestability and improve the role of the<br />

corporate control market. On the whole, this law tried to modernise the listed companies’ rules<br />

taking into account the traditional aspects of Italian corporate governance, such as ownership<br />

concentration, pyramidal groups and shareholders’ coalitions through voting agreements 119 . In the<br />

near future, general company law reform will revise the joint stock companies’ rules, along the lines<br />

of the Draghi Law and also for aspects not covered by the latter, while a new regime will be<br />

adopted for private companies to meet the needs of small and medium enterprises, still representing<br />

the backbone of the Italian economy.<br />

118 See F. Amatori, supra n. 90, p. 696 et seq.<br />

119 It is difficult to assess the Draghi Law’s impact on the Italian securities market. According to B. Bortolotti<br />

and D. Siniscalco, ‘Importare la corporate governance?’, in Centro Nazionale di Prevenzione e Difesa Sociale, Le<br />

nuove funzioni degli organi societari: verso la corporate governance?, Milan, 2002, p.120 et seq., this impact might<br />

have been modest. While minority shareholders’ protection was improved by international standards, the stock market<br />

capitalisation increased by a lower percentage than that predictable under law and finance theory (reference is made to<br />

R. La Porta et al., ‘Legal Determinants of External Finance (1997) 52 J. Fin.1131). This assessment, however, is open<br />

to argument, being based on oversimplification of the investor protection criteria and of their impact on the capital<br />

markets.<br />

21

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!