21.08.2013 Views

UNIVERSITÄT POTSDAM - Prof. Dr. Paul JJ Welfens

UNIVERSITÄT POTSDAM - Prof. Dr. Paul JJ Welfens

UNIVERSITÄT POTSDAM - Prof. Dr. Paul JJ Welfens

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

investigations offers a wide field for further research. Up to now, these effects are only<br />

taken rather roughly and partially into account in most empirical studies.<br />

Generally, studies which are based on time series data on levels of output and<br />

R&D stocks for individual US, French and Japanese companies found output elasticities<br />

lying between 0.06 and 0.1 (GRILICHES, 1995). Considering results of this kind<br />

of studies for Germany and France at different levels of aggregation, the estimated output<br />

elasticities turned out to be somewhat higher. For the total economy of West Germany<br />

PATEL / SOETE (1988) estimated 0.21 as the output elasticity of R&D. However,<br />

in a recent study BÖNTE (1998) estimated only output elasticities between 0.03<br />

and 0.04 for the R&D stock of selected sectors of West German manufacturing. At the<br />

firm level CUNEO / MAIRESSE (1984) estimated for the R&D stock output elasticities<br />

between 0.22 and 0.33 for France; MAIRESSE / CUNEO (1985) estimated values<br />

between 0.09 and 0.26, and MAIRESSE / HALL (1996) values between 0.00 and 0.17.<br />

At the level of the total economy PATEL / SOETE (1988) estimated a value of 0.13 for<br />

the output elasticity of R&D for France. COE / MOGHADAM (1993) estimated with<br />

their preferred specification an output elasticity of 0.17 for the R&D stock of France.<br />

When growth rates are used as dependent variables and R&D intensities as independent<br />

variables, the estimated rate of return lies – summarizing the bulk of empirical<br />

results for different countries and different levels of aggregation – mainly between<br />

0.2 and 0.5, with most of the recent estimates falling in the lower part of this range<br />

(GRILICHES, 1995). However, the results for West Germany are a little bit puzzling.<br />

At a firm level, BARDY (1974) estimated direct rates of return to R&D between 0.92<br />

and 0.97. However, at an industry level MÖHNEN / NADIRI / PRUCHA (1986) estimated<br />

a direct rate of return to R&D of 0.13, and O’MAHONY / WAGNER (1996)<br />

found at the same level a direct rate of return of 0.00. With a different approach<br />

BÖNTE (1998) calculated net rates of return for selected sectors of West German<br />

manufacturing between 0.23 and 0.3. This is quite in accordance with the general results<br />

and with the results for France at the firm level where GRILICHES / MAIRESSE<br />

(1983) estimated a rate of return to R&D of 0.31, and HALL / MAIRESSE (1995)<br />

found values between 0.22 and 0.34.<br />

However, most of the studies considered here simply treat R&D as another form<br />

of investment and do not allow for the effects of the externalities mentioned above.<br />

Therefore, it is unclear whether such studies underestimate or overestimate the effects<br />

of R&D. JONES / WILLIAMS (1997) derived an endogenous growth model, which<br />

takes these externalities into account, and calibrated it to a range of plausible parameter<br />

values. They find that in most cases the excess returns to R&D (calculated as the social<br />

return minus the private return) are positive, but less than 20 per cent. We may add that<br />

due to the globalization power of the Internet the divergence between private and social<br />

returns to R&D might increase – not least if the Internet reinforces international knowledge<br />

spillovers. This raises problems for R&D cooperation.<br />

32

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!