21.08.2013 Views

UNIVERSITÄT POTSDAM - Prof. Dr. Paul JJ Welfens

UNIVERSITÄT POTSDAM - Prof. Dr. Paul JJ Welfens

UNIVERSITÄT POTSDAM - Prof. Dr. Paul JJ Welfens

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

ing some further – more technical – assumptions, growth rates depend on innovation<br />

rates – that is, on the speed with which new technological knowledge is built up.<br />

Integrating two economies similar (or even identical) in terms of traditional endowments<br />

would lead to either unchanged trade patterns and growth rates or to increased<br />

specialization and higher growth rates in both countries. The dynamic properties<br />

of this model heavily depend on the characteristics of the stock of accumulated<br />

knowledge before integration. Because of similar endowments with traditional factors<br />

the only difference before globalization lies in the degree of knowledge specialization<br />

in different areas. Given that both economies are completely specialized on complementary<br />

fields of knowledge, integration will have no effects, neither on technological,<br />

production and trade patterns nor on long-run growth. Instead, if the stocks of knowledge<br />

have a certain overlap in both economies (e.g. knowledge accumulated in the<br />

same fields of science and technology) integration will weed out these “inefficiencies”.<br />

Each country specializes on one part of this knowledge available to both economies via<br />

full integration of markets. In this situation growth is higher in both countries compared<br />

with those in closed economies. To the extent that the Internet facilitates accumulation<br />

of knowledge and reduces international integration costs one may expect a growth bonus<br />

due to faster technological progress within a larger radius of integration. At the<br />

same time the rising adjustment speed in digital financial markets might contribute to<br />

more market volatility and hence transitorily or permanently reduced growth rates.<br />

Apart from new growth and new trade theory, evolutionary economics in a<br />

Schumpeterian tradition is concerned with the relationship between technology, trade<br />

and growth. Although it lacks a consistent body of formal modeling tools, evolutionary<br />

economics has provided a lot of interesting insights into the details of the working of<br />

economic systems. Evolutionary thinking is fundamentally based on the variationselection<br />

principle which allows one to look at the dynamic properties of systems and,<br />

thus, it is based on economic development. Basically, evolution is thought of as being<br />

generated by creating a variety of different products and processes. Selection processes<br />

(e.g. markets) then work on reducing this variety to a certain number of viable products.<br />

The diversity of evolutionary theorizing cannot be dealt with here (on this see<br />

DOSI / PAVITT / SOETE (1990), WITT (1993) or HODGSON (1993)). One of the<br />

main forces that generate new products or processes (and, thereby, increase variety) is<br />

innovation and technological change.<br />

Concentrating first on variation, empirical studies have found that higher rates<br />

of innovation lead to higher rates of economic growth (e.g. FAGERBERG (1988)). The<br />

larger the number of different products and the higher the rate of new product generation<br />

the higher the rate of long-run growth. Saviotti has worked out a conceptual and<br />

semi-formal tool to show that we are observing a constantly increasing number of different<br />

products. Higher degrees of product variety cause higher consumer utility. This<br />

is a main reason for economic growth (SAVIOTTI (1991)). This mechanism mainly<br />

29

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!